Anda di halaman 1dari 20

Chapter 25

Monopoly

Copyright 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

Introduction
Economists have found that when nations governments proclaim that a single church denomination represents the official state religion, the church loses attendance equal to an average of about 15% of the nations population. Lower attendance at such churches is a prediction of the theory of monopoly applied to religious institutions. In this chapter, you will learn why a monopoly produces less output of a good or service that we would observe in a perfectly competitive market.

25-2
Copyright 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

Learning Objectives
Identify situations that can give rise to monopoly Describe the demand and marginal revenue conditions a monopolist faces Discuss how a monopolist determines how much output to produce and what price to charge Evaluate the profits earned by a monopolist Understand price discrimination Explain the social cost of monopolies

25-3
Copyright 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

Chapter Outline
Definition of a Monopolist Barriers to Entry The Demand Curve a Monopolist Face Elasticity and Monopoly Cost and Monopoly Profit Maximization Calculating Monopoly Profit On Making Higher Profits: Price Discrimination The Social Cost of Monopolies
25-4
Copyright 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

Did You Know That...


Many chefs are now patenting specific dishes? Some chefs now have dozens of patents, all aimed at preventing other chefs from competing against them with copies of their own products. This creates a situation called monopoly.

25-5
Copyright 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

Definition of a Monopolist
Monopolist
A single supplier of a good or service for which there is no close substitute The monopolist therefore constitutes the entire industry.

25-6
Copyright 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

Barriers to Entry
Question
How does a firm obtain monopoly power?

Answer
Barriers to entry that allow the firm to make long-run economic profits Barriers to entry are restrictions on who can start as well as stay in business.

25-7
Copyright 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

Barriers to Entry (cont'd)


Barriers to entry include
Ownership of resources without close substitutes Economies of scale Legal or governmental restrictions

25-8
Copyright 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

Barriers to Entry (cont'd)


Ownership of resources without close substitutes
The Aluminum Company of America (ALCOA) at one time owned most of of the worlds bauxite.

25-9
Copyright 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

Barriers to Entry (cont'd)


Economies of scale
Low unit costs and prices drive out rivals. The largest firm can produce at the lowest average total cost.

25-10
Copyright 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

Barriers to Entry (cont'd)


Natural Monopoly
A monopoly that arises from the peculiar production characteristics in an industry It usually arises when there are large economies of scale One firm can produce at a lower average cost than can be achieved by multiple firms

25-11
Copyright 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

Figure 25-1 The Cost Curves That Might Lead to a Natural Monopoly

25-12
Copyright 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

Barriers to Entry (cont'd)


Legal or governmental restrictions
Licenses, franchises, and certificates of convenience Examples include
Electrical utilities Radio and television broadcasting

25-13
Copyright 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

International Policy Example: German Chimney-Sweep Competition Goes Up in Smoke


In 1937, the acting interior minister of German, Heinrich Himmler, decreed that chimney sweeps were required to be German and had to be assigned to districts. The 8,000 districts were geographic regions in which only a single chimney sweep was allowed to practice the trade. The requirement of only one chimney sweep per district still remains in force today. Thus, within each district, a chimney sweep has a monopoly strictly enforced by German law. What is the basic shape of each of the demand curves faced by the 8,000 German chimney sweeps?

25-14
Copyright 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

Barriers to Entry (cont'd)


Legal or governmental restrictions
Patents
Intellectual property

Tariffs
Taxes on imported goods

Regulation
Government enforcement of safety and quality

25-15
Copyright 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

The Demand Curve a Monopolist Faces


The monopolist faces the industry demand curve because the monopolist is the entire industry.

25-16
Copyright 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

The Demand Curve a Monopolist Faces (cont'd)


Recall that under perfect competition
Firm faces perfectly elastic demand curve, it is a price taker The forces of supply and demand establish the price per unit Marginal revenue, average revenue, and price are all the same

25-17
Copyright 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

The Demand Curve a Monopolist Faces (cont'd)


Marginal revenue equals the change in total revenue due to a one-unit change in the quantity produced and sold

25-18
Copyright 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

The Demand Curve a Monopolist Faces (cont'd)


Perfect competition versus monopoly
The perfect competitor doesnt have to worry about lowering price to sell more. In a purely competitive situation, the firm accounts for a small part of the market.
It can sell its entire output, whatever that may be, at the same price.

25-19
Copyright 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

The Demand Curve a Monopolist Faces (cont'd)


Perfect competition versus monopoly
The more the monopolist wants to sell, the lower the price it has to charge on the last unit sold. To sell the last unit, the monopolist has to lower the price because it is facing a downward sloping demand curve.

25-20
Copyright 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

Figure 25-2 Demand Curves for the Perfect Competitor and the Monopolist

25-21
Copyright 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

The Demand Curve a Monopolist Faces (cont'd)


Monopoly
Single seller Faces entire industry demand Must lower price to sell more Not all units sold for same price (MR < P)
Copyright 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

Perfect Competition
Many sellers Faces perfectly elastic demand Must produce more to sell more All units sold for same price (P = MR)
25-22

Figure 25-3 Marginal Revenue: Always Less Than Price

25-23
Copyright 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

Elasticity and Monopoly


The monopolist faces a downward-sloping demand curve (its average revenue curve). That means that it cannot charge just any price with no changes in quantity (a common misconception) because, depending on the price charged, a different quantity will be demanded.

25-24
Copyright 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

Elasticity and Monopoly (cont'd)


Question
If a monopoly raises price, what will happen to quantity demanded?

Hint
Remember how consumers respond to a change in price.

25-25
Copyright 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

Elasticity and Monopoly (cont'd)


Recall
A monopolist is a single seller of a well-defined good or service with no close substitute.
Think of some imperfect substitutes.

The demand curve slopes downward because individuals compare marginal satisfaction to cost.

25-26
Copyright 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

Elasticity and Monopoly (cont'd)


After all, consumers have limited incomes and unlimited wants. The market demand curve, which the monopolist alone faces in this situation, slopes downward because individuals compare the marginal satisfaction they will receive to the cost of the commodity to be purchased.

25-27
Copyright 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

Costs and Monopoly Profit Maximization


We assume profit maximization is the goal of the pure monopolist, just as it is for the perfect competitor.

25-28
Copyright 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

Costs and Monopoly Profit Maximization (cont'd)


Perfect competitor has only to decide on the profit-maximizing output rate because price is given.
The perfect competitor is a price taker.

For the pure monopolist, we must seek a profit-maximizing price output combination.
The monopolist is a price searcher.

25-29
Copyright 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

Costs and Monopoly Profit Maximization (cont'd)


Price Searcher
A firm that must determine the price-output combination that maximizes profit because it faces a downward-sloping demand curve

25-30
Copyright 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

Costs and Monopoly Profit Maximization (cont'd)


We can determine the profit-maximizing price-output combination with either of two equivalent approaches:
By looking at total revenues and total costs or By looking at marginal revenues and marginal costs

25-31
Copyright 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

Costs and Monopoly Profit Maximization (cont'd)


Total revenues-total costs approach
Maximize the positive difference between total revenues and total costs

Marginal revenue-marginal cost approach


Profit maximization will also occur where marginal revenue equals marginal cost.

25-32
Copyright 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

Costs and Monopoly Profit Maximization (cont'd)


Question
Why produce where marginal revenue equals marginal cost?

Answer
This is where the greatest positive difference between total revenue and total cost occurs.

25-33
Copyright 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

Figure 25-4 Monopoly Costs, Revenues, and Profits, Panel (a)

25-34
Copyright 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

Figure 25-4 Monopoly Costs, Revenues, and Profits, Panels (b) and (c)

25-35
Copyright 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

Costs and Monopoly Profit Maximization (cont'd)


Producing past where MR = MC
Result is that incremental cost will exceed incremental revenue

Producing less than where MR = MC


The monopolist is not maximizing profits through this approach either

25-36
Copyright 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

Figure 25-5 Maximizing Profits

25-37
Copyright 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

Cost and Monopoly Profit Maximization (contd) Real-World Informational Limitations


Price searching by a less-than perfect competitor is a process. A monopolist can only estimate the actual demand curve and make an educated guess when it sets its profit-maximizing profit. For the perfect competitor, price is given already by the intersection of market demand and supply.

25-38
Copyright 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

Calculating Monopoly Profit


Monopoly profit is given by the shaded area in Figure 25-6, which is equal to total revenues (P Q) minus total costs (ATC Q).

25-39
Copyright 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

Figure 25-6 Monopoly Profit

25-40
Copyright 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

Calculating Monopoly Profit (cont'd)


No guarantee of profits
The term monopoly conjures up the notion of a greedy firm ripping off the public.
If ATC is everywhere above AR, or demand
No price-output combination allows the monopolist to cover costs

25-41
Copyright 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

Figure 25-7 Monopolies: Not Always Profitable

25-42
Copyright 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

On Making Higher Profits: Price Discrimination


Price Discrimination
Selling a given product at more than one price, with the difference being unrelated to differences in cost

25-43
Copyright 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

On Making Higher Profits: Price Discrimination (cont'd)


Price Differentiation
Establishing different prices for similar products to reflect differences in marginal cost in providing those commodities to different groups of buyers

25-44
Copyright 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

On Making Higher Profits: Price Discrimination (cont'd)


Necessary conditions for price discrimination
1. The firm must face a downward-sloping demand curve. 2. The firm must be able to readily (and cheaply) identify buyers or groups of buyers with predictably different elasticities of demand. 3. The firm must be able to prevent resale of the product or service.

25-45
Copyright 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

Example: Why Students Pay Different Prices to Attend College


Out-of-pocket tuition rates for any two college students can differ by considerable amounts, even if the students happen to major in the same subjects and enroll in many of the same courses. The reason for this is that colleges offer students diverse financial aid packages depending on their financial need. To document their need for financial aid, students must provide detailed information about family income and wealth. This information, of course, helps the college determine the prices that different families are most likely to be willing and able to pay, so that it can engage in price discrimination. Figure 25-8 shows how this collegiate price-discrimination process works.

25-46
Copyright 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

Figure 25-8 Toward Perfect Price Discrimination in College Tuition Rates

25-47
Copyright 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

The Social Cost of Monopolies


Comparing monopoly with perfect competition
Lets assume a monopolist comes in and buys up every single perfect competitor. Notice the monopolist produces a smaller quantity and sells at a higher price.

25-48
Copyright 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

The Social Cost of Monopolies (cont'd)


Comparing monopoly with perfect competition
Monopolists raise the price and restrict production compared to a perfectly competitive situation. Consumers pay a price that exceeds the marginal cost of production and resources are misallocated in such a situation.

25-49
Copyright 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

Figure 25-9 The Effects of Monopolizing an Industry

25-50
Copyright 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

Issues and Applications: The Predictable Consequences of European State Religion Monopolies
For years, the church of Sweden was the official institution of the Swedish state. Today, though about 75% of the population of Sweden remain official members, the regular attendance at Sunday church services is low. The key to understanding the low Sunday service attendance by members of the Church of Sweden is its traditional status as a state monopoly. Economists who study the economics of religion have found that the pattern of low attendance experienced by Sweden holds true in all nations in which a single church predominates through state favors. The reason for this is that granting a religion monopoly has a very predictable effect: restriction of religious output and higher-priced services.
25-51
Copyright 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

Issues and Applications: The Predictable Consequences of European State Religion Monopolies (contd) Religious competition gradually is developing across Europe. For this reason, many economists predict that religious output is likely to increase in Europe in the coming years. Why might economists disagree about the appropriateness of using rates of church attendance as a proxy measure of religious output?

25-52
Copyright 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

Summary Discussion of Learning Objectives (cont'd)


Why a monopoly can occur
Barriers to entry

Demand and marginal revenue conditions faced by a monopolist


Because the monopolist constitutes the entire industry, it faces the entire market demand curve. Marginal revenue is less than price.

25-53
Copyright 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

Summary Discussion of Learning Objectives (cont'd)


How a monopolist determines how much output to produce and what price to charge
Seeks to maximize its economic profits Produces where marginal revenue equals marginal cost Charges maximum price for the amount of output where MR = MC

25-54
Copyright 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

Summary Discussion of Learning Objectives (cont'd)


A monopolists profits
Profit earned by monopolist is equal to the difference between the price it charges and its average production cost times the amount of output it produces and sells. Monopolist typically earns positive economic profits.

25-55
Copyright 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

Summary Discussion of Learning Objectives (cont'd)


Price discrimination
Selling at more than one price with the price differences being unrelated to differences in production costs. Monopolist sells some of its output at higher prices to consumers with less elastic demand.

25-56
Copyright 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

Summary Discussion of Learning Objectives (cont'd)


Social cost of monopolies
Price exceeds marginal cost. The price is higher and output is lower for a monopolist as compared to a perfectly competitive industry.

25-57
Copyright 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

Figure F-1 Consumer Surplus

25-58
Copyright 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

Figure F-2 Consumer Surplus in a Perfectly Competitive Market

25-59
Copyright 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

Figure F-3 Losses Generated by Monopoly

25-60
Copyright 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

Anda mungkin juga menyukai