Anda di halaman 1dari 4

From 1982 to 2008 debt levels grew exponentially in the United States, handily outstripping growth in

gross domestic product (GDP). Accordingly, the ratio of total debt to GDP leaped from less than 170%
to 375% over that period – a 2.2x increase.

This kind of growth is inherently unsustainable because it leads to interest costs shooting far ahead of
borrowers' ability to meet them. Debt growth was able to outstrip GDP growth for a such a long time,
however, because the economy acquired elements of Ponzi scheme: once debt reached excessive levels,
the economy (i.e., borrowers in the aggregate) began to service its debt by continually taking on new
debt.

This process was self-reinforcing: debt growth raised asset prices by increasing liquidity and monetary
velocity. This asset appreciation gave borrowers the ability to further increase debt, regardless of
whether existing debt could be serviced from cash flows. The housing bubble exemplified this:
borrowers took out mortgages they couldn't afford on “investment” houses, assuming prices would
continue to quickly increase and they would be able to sell or refinance into new, larger loans.

The ever-increasing debt levels and asset prices also pushed economic growth above its normal rate.
This fed back into debt growth and asset appreciation.

As debt issuance expanded, recent borrowers had incrementally worse credit than earlier borrowers.
Eventually debt growth reached the worst borrowers of all: subprime homebuyers. The terrible quality
of subprime borrowers – many defaulted within a few months of getting loans – forced lenders to
suddenly pull back. Since the debt Ponzi depended on continuously increasing debt levels to prop up
asset prices, the subprime crisis proved to be its end.

THE FUTURE: DEFLATION

It took 25 years of exponential growth for debt to reach its current level. It will likewise take a long
time for debt to return to a lower, sustainable norm. For the foreseeable future, expect the opposite of
the recent past: instead of debt growth fueling economic growth and rising asset prices, expect debt
reduction to limit economic growth and pressure monetary velocity and asset prices.

This process, in light of its deflationary effects, is known as debt deflation. Like the debt Ponzi, debt
deflation is self-reinforcing: by reducing asset prices (and thus the ability to borrow), debt reduction
begets further debt reduction.

A prominent feature of debt deflation is what Keynes called the paradox of thrift. The paradox occurs
when many consumers and businesses simultaneously cut back on spending and investment (in this
case, as a necessary step toward paying down debt). This creates a vicious cycle: when everyone cuts
back, everyone also sees their revenue/income decrease because of others' cutbacks. This reduces
economic activity without necessarily improving the capacity to service and repay debt.

The Federal Reserve is trying to forestall debt deflation by creating bank reserves (which expands
liquidity and would, under normal circumstances, have clear inflationary effects), and the
overwhelming consensus on Wall Street is that it will succeed. I disagree for two reasons:

1. There are four major forms of liquidity: the monetary base (i.e., physical money and bank reserves),
bank loans, securitized debt, and derivatives. The Federal Reserve exerts direct control over the
monetary base, and it has indirect control over bank lending. It does not, however, have control over
securitized debt or derivatives, which together dwarf the monetary base and bank loans in notional
value by a factor of 13. While these uncontrolled forms of liquidity don't meet the classical definition of
money, they often have the same economic effects. As Friedrich Hayek wrote (and as originally posted
on Zero Hedge):

“There can be no doubt that besides the regular types of the circulating medium, such as coin, notes
and bank deposits, which are generally recognised to be money or currency, and the quantity of which
is regulated by some central authority or can at least be imagined to be so regulated, there exist still
other forms of media of exchange which occasionally or permanently do the service of money. Now
while for certain practical purposes we are accustomed to distinguish these forms of media of exchange
from money proper as being mere substitutes for money, it is clear that, other things equal, any
increase or decrease of these money substitutes will have exactly the same effects as an increase or
decrease of the quantity of money proper, and should therefore, for the purposes of theoretical analysis,
be counted as money” (Prices and Production, 1935, p. 96).

Derivatives and securitized debt are now contracting severely. Bank lending, despite the increase in
reserves, has also begun to contract. This will outweigh any increases in the comparatively small
monetary base.

2. Capacity utilization is at a 60-year low. Excess capacity has put a lid on pricing power, which will
prevent monetary expansion from easily translating into higher price levels. For a more detailed
explanation of this, I highly recommend Hoisington Investment Management's first-quarter economic
review:

http://www.hoisingtonmgt.com/pdf/HIM2009Q1NP.pdf

EQUITIES

Equities are residual securities – in other words, they get what's left over after debt and operating costs
are paid – so they're first to feel the effects of any decline in profits or asset prices. Hence, equities are
the asset class likely to suffer most under debt deflation.

Recent history bears this out: in 1990, Japan entered a debt deflation from which it has yet to emerge.
Japan's stock market reached its peak in 1989 and its nadir in 2003. In the intervening period, nominal
GDP grew ~.5% per year and real GDP grew ~1% per year. Despite this slight growth, Japanese
equities fell 80% over the same period, or 11.5% per year.

Japan had lower debt to GDP in 1990 than the U.S. does now. Japan also had the benefit that its debt
deflation was solitary: the rest of the world had escaped deflation, so the Japanese depression was
ameliorated by continued strong exports. By contrast, today there are many countries besides the
United States that suffer from incipient debt deflation. So it's possible that the U.S. market will fall
even more than Japan's did, although there also are mitigating factors (the Japanese market traded at a
higher valuation in 1990 than the US market at its recent peak).

A few other points to consider:

• To some extent, debt reduction will involve substitution of equity capital for debt capital (e.g.,
companies issuing stock and using the proceeds to pay down debt). Because of equities' residual nature,
they tend to carry higher returns than debt. Hence, equity-for-debt substitution will increase companies'
cost of capital. The flip side of this is declining asset prices.

Equity-for-debt substitution will be merely one of many factors behind debt reduction and declining
asset prices. Nevertheless, it should have an outsized impact on investor psychology due to the speed
with which it changes capital structure and cost of capital (versus gradual paydown of debt) and its
increasing prominence in the public securities markets.

• If businesses are forced to give debt reduction priority, dividends to equity holders will be pushed out
into the future, reducing the present value of equity dividend streams.

• If equities were cheap by historical standards, they might make for a good investment in spite of debt
deflation. Unfortunately, they aren't.

One of my favorite valuation tools is the ratio of stock market capitalization to GDP. The advantage of
this is that GDP is much less volatile than other economic series such as corporate earnings. Since the
1920s, the stock market has traded at an average market cap to GDP ratio of 60%. During major
recessions, the ratio has frequently gone below 35%. By contrast, as of today (June 26th), the ratio is
85%. Even at the market's March lows it remained above 60%. It's absurd to see equities trade at an
above-average multiple in the face of both a severe recession and a secular rise in the cost of capital.

COMMODITIES

Like equities, commodities fare poorly in debt deflation. In this instance, commodities will fare
particularly poorly because they underwent an extreme bubble in recent years. As Frank Veneroso
details in his 2007 World Bank presentation (http://www.venerosoassociates.com/Reserve Management
Parts I andII WBP Public 71907.pdf), the notional value of outstanding commodity derivatives surged
beginning in 2004, eventually coming to exceed the value of above-ground commodity stocks by a
large multiple. Veneroso mentions that the bubble was particularly dramatic in the metals group. In the
aggregate, industrial metals (copper, lead, zinc, etc.) rose more this decade than in any other period in
both nominal and – especially – real terms.

Today, even after a broad commodities sell-off, most metals trade at 2-4 times their historical average
prices. Oil and many agricultural commodities are at similar multiples to their historic averages. As
with equities, it's absurd to see commodities trade at above-average prices in the face of a severe
recession.

To the extent that the derivatives build-up has been responsible for high commodity prices, debt
deflation will engender lower prices. Microeconomic factors such as substitution will do the same.

CURRENCIES

The dollar fell inexorably from 2002-2008, driven by three related phenomena:

1. Debt levels grew at an increasing rate, from already high levels. This was a worldwide phenomenon,
but the amount of debt was particularly large in the U.S. and a lot of incremental foreign debt was
denominated in dollars.

2. The U.S.'s debt build-up necessitated running a large current account deficit (CAD), putting technical
pressure on the dollar.

3. Foreign countries, especially emerging markets, experienced a surge in trade because of the U.S.
CAD. Many investors noticed this strength and began favoring foreign-currency-denominated assets
over dollar-denominated assets.

Debt deflation has reversed this process, leading to a nascent decline in U.S. private debt and
corresponding declines in the CAD and in enthusiasm for emerging-market assets. This process should
accelerate as deflation continues, with the upshot being a stronger dollar.

The U.S.'s high ratio of debt to GDP is typically seen as a negative for the dollar, but I believe it's
actually a technical positive. Debt growth increases the effective money supply, reducing the value of
money relative to the value of real assets. Debt deflation has the opposite effect: it reduces the effective
money supply, increasing the value of money relative to the value of real assets. Since the U.S. has
more debt, proportionally, than other countries, worldwide debt deflation should benefit the dollar.

And while the United States has a high ratio of total debt to GDP, most foreign economies have higher
rates of debt growth and depend more on debt to generate GDP growth. Most foreign economies also
have a higher level of financial liabilities as a percentage of GDP than the U.S. (the level is twice as
high in the Eurozone, for instance). Consequently, debt deflation is more likely to cause a financial
crisis in these economies than in the U.S. As James Clayton writes, “It appears that a rapid buildup in
private debt can create more risk than an already high level of debt that has been adequately funded”
(The Global Debt Bomb, 2000, p. 79).

FOREIGN EQUITIES

The prospect of a stronger dollar makes foreign equities less attractive than U.S. equities. Beyond that,
two things make me wary of foreign stocks:

1. As mentioned above, many foreign economies have higher financial leverage than the U.S.
Specifically, the typical European bank has twice the ratio of assets to equity as the typical U.S. bank.
European banks also have much higher exposure to emerging markets than their U.S. counterparts and
have been slower to take writedowns on toxic structured assets.

2. Most foreign economies have higher operational leverage than the U.S., in the form of a higher ratio
of exports to GDP. Many leading economies (China, Germany, Japan) are geared toward exporting
manufactured goods, while many others (Australia, Brazil, Canada, numerous Middle Eastern
countries) are geared toward exporting commodities. During the Great Depression – the best-known
instance of debt deflation – export-oriented economies experienced much deeper contractions than
consumption-oriented economies.

Anda mungkin juga menyukai