Anda di halaman 1dari 14

11/14/13

Which India Matters? by Pankaj Mishra | The New York Review of Books

Font Size: A A A
November 21, 2013 Issue

Which India Matters?


Pankaj Mishra

An Uncertain Glory: India and Its Contradictions


by Jean Drze and Amartya Sen Princeton University Press, 434 pp., $29.95

Why Growth Matters: How Economic Growth in India Reduced Poverty and the Lessons for Other Developing Countries
by Jagdish Bhagwati and Arvind Panagariya PublicAffairs, 280 pp., $28.99

Jonas Bendiksen/Magnum Photos

A man hammering inks and dyes rejected from nearby factories into powder that can then be resold, Mumbai, India, 2006

In 1961, soon after arriving in Japan as the American ambassador, Edwin O. Reischauer held a public conversation with the Japanese economist Nakayama Ichiro.1 Their differences of
www.nybooks.com/articles/archives/2013/nov/21/which-india-matters/?pagination=false&printpage=true 1/14

11/14/13

Which India Matters? by Pankaj Mishra | The New York Review of Books

perception illuminate many dilemmas of a developing nation like India today. The American diplomat, a particularly sanguine exponent of Modernization Theory, believed that rapid economic growth was well on its way to making Japan a Western-style developed nation and a model for other non-Communist Asian countries. The Japanese economist worried that economic growth that didnt take account of the social and political changes accompanying it was unhealthy, and created more problems than it solved. Like all modernizing countries with large rural populations, such as India and China, Japan was hobbled by an economy with two distinct sectors: one was defined by modern technology, a high ratio of capital to labor, and high worker productivity and wages; the other had all the opposite traits. Rapid, unbalanced economic growth aggravated the innate inequities of the dual structure, which in Nakayamas vision had serious political consequences. Countries that develop without drawing large parts of the rural population into the modern sectors of the economy were prone to social unrest and authoritarian regimes. Nakayama knew this from bitter experience of the war that Japan, beset by severe internal crises in the 1930s, had subsequently waged against many Asian countries and the United States.2 Accordingly, he was keen to see postwar Japan develop an open, egalitarian, and pacifist democracy. Largely due to the macroeconomic approach of Nakayama and his colleagues, which emphasized labor over capital productivity and technical training for people moving out of the agrarian economy, Japan achieved sustained growth for close to two decades.3 Helped considerably by American procurements during the Korean War and infusions afterward of aid, investment, and technological innovations, Japan then turned into a major exporter of goods and capital to East and Southeast Asia.4 Japan also became an example to the region with its land reforms, industrial policy, well-designed state intervention in markets, investments in education and health, which created a skilled and productive labor force, and economic nationalismthe features that when carefully adopted helped in the remarkable economic emergence of such countries as South Korea, Singapore, Taiwan, and Thailand.5 Most of these developing states in East and Southeast Asia, however, came late to electoral democracy. Indias own, much greater, challenges in the previous half-century are highlighted by the fact that this bewilderingly diverse and oppressively hierarchical society set out in the late 1940s to simultaneously build, without possessing much basis for either, an egalitarian democracy and a modern industrial economy.6 Decades of colonial rule had damaged India, saddling it by 1947 with an underproductive agricultural economy, a weak industrial base, and extremely low levels of literacy (27 percent for men, 9 for women).7 Even more urgently than their counterparts in Japan or South Korea, Indian leaders had to be sensitive to the
www.nybooks.com/articles/archives/2013/nov/21/which-india-matters/?pagination=false&printpage=true 2/14

11/14/13

Which India Matters? by Pankaj Mishra | The New York Review of Books

needs of the poor, especially those among the low castes, and improve their capacities to build the basis for both an equitable society and sustained economic growth. In the early decades, India did make some gains in heavy industry and agriculture.8 Investments in higher education created, among other things, generations of highly skilled upper-caste Indians, many of whom can be found today in senior corporate and university positions in the West.9 Poverty failed to decline appreciably despite Indian economic planners obsession with growth. As the Columbia University economist Jagdish Bhagwati put it, looking back in 1985 at his work in the 1960s with Indias Planning Commission, their basic theme, i.e. growth with a view to eliminating poverty was too optimistic.10

ong-term investments in education and public health were needed. But in these primary tasks, Indias rulers failed disastrously. Their breathtakingly conservative approach to social services can be blamed, as Amartya Sen has often argued, on the elitist character of Indian society and politics. Democracy in India, B.R. Ambedkar, the leader of Indias lowcaste Hindus and the main author of Indias constitution, famously warned, is only a top dressing on an Indian soil, which is essentially undemocratic. Certainly, for people who claimed to be, and are still often mistakenly derided, as socialist,11 Indias rulers neither matched the educational accomplishments of some socialist countries, nor did they help unleash, like their counterparts in South Korea and Japan, entrepreneurial energies in the countrys protected private sector, which accounted for the bulk of manufacturing output.12 Instead of making the public sector more accountable, they imposed, as Bhagwati has often lamented, irrational restrictions on business, spawning the license-permit Raj that mostly enriched corrupt politicians and officials. The liberalization of the Indian economy in 1991, and successive governments increased business-friendliness, inspired fresh hopes that Indias extreme inequalities could be alleviated. Indias economy had grown, moving from a rate of 5 percent in the 1980s to nearly 10 percent until slowing down dramatically to less than half that rate in recent months. In India in Transition: Freeing the Economy (1993), Bhagwati was among the first to hail his old college friend Prime Minister Manmohan Singh, then the finance minister, for leading India to a fresh tryst with destiny. By then Bhagwati had turned into, in his own words, the worlds foremost free-trader. Claiming to be the intellectual inspiration behind the 1991 reforms, he declared, We are finally in the spring of hope.13 The period after 1991 did manifest some vivid and impressive signs of Indias transformation by consumer capitalism. Helped by cheap credit, Western brands finally became accessible to a middle class long starved of them by an economic regime that substituted Indian products for imports. Many of Indias old corporate families, such as Tata, acquired major
www.nybooks.com/articles/archives/2013/nov/21/which-india-matters/?pagination=false&printpage=true 3/14

11/14/13

Which India Matters? by Pankaj Mishra | The New York Review of Books

international companies. The potential size of Indias market1.2 billion consumers managed to provoke a great deal of hype among hopeful businessmen, boosterish investment consultants, financial journalists, and day-tripping columnists in the West. (Interestingly, Chinese commentators and investors as- sessed Indias progress much more soberly.) Yet today Indias economy manifests more serious impediments to widespread growth than any of the other Asian economies. Economic growth has been led by the services sectora loose category that includes information technology, telecommunications, banking, and real estate and contributes nearly 50 percent to the GDPrather than manufacturing, which has powered the growth of other East Asian economies.14 Agriculture, which still employs a majority of Indias population, remains stagnant.15 A small, well-educated workforce enjoys rising salaries, but there have been only very small increases in wages and productivity for people trapped in the bottom half of the dual economy: agriculture and the so-called informal or unorganized sector, which employ more than 90 percent of Indias labor force.16 The bulk of Indias aggregate growth, the Cornell economist Kaushik Basu warns, is occurring through a disproportionate rise in the incomes at the upper end of the income ladder.17 By 2010 Indias one hundred wealthiest people had increased their combined worth to $300 billion, a quarter of the countrys GDP. Recent corruption scandals involving the sale of billions of dollars worth of national resources such as mines, forests, land, water, and telecom spectrums reveal that crony capitalism and rent-seeking, rather than entrepreneurial dynamism and innovation in a free market, are the real engines of Indias economic growth. Furthermore, to a large extent this growth does not create jobsan alarming fact about an overwhelmingly youthful country that adds 12 million to the workforce each year and whose present economic pattern obliges it to move many millions more to urban areas from a crisis-ridden agricultural sector where hundreds of thousands of farmers have committed suicide in recent years. According to a widely cited report by Michael Walton, an economist at Harvard University, the quality and distribution of Indias rate of GDP growth are structurally disequalizing, i.e., causing more inequality. Its not only that India isnt overflowing with Horatio Alger stories, as The Wall Street Journal put it. It is also developing all the ingredients necessary for a Latin Americanstyle oligarchy. Growth Matters, however, is a passionate case for more privatization and W hy liberalization, and less protection for labor. Bhagwati and Arvind Panagariya, who holds a professorial chair named after his coauthor at Columbia, claim that India has already been transformed from a basket case into a powerful engine of growth. They are convinced that
www.nybooks.com/articles/archives/2013/nov/21/which-india-matters/?pagination=false&printpage=true 4/14

11/14/13

Which India Matters? by Pankaj Mishra | The New York Review of Books

faster growth and freer markets remain the best remedy for poverty, inequality, pollution, and ill-health. A contrasting viewthat there is something defective in Indias path to development and a very different list of priorities appear in An Uncertain Glory: India and Its Contradictions. Amartya Sen and his frequent collaborator, the Belgian-Indian economist Jean Drze, acknowledge that aggregate economic growth is important for generating public revenue, which can be used to reduce poverty. But it is only one of many different concerns that need attention. Amartya Sen has never wavered from his belief that, as he wrote in these pages in 1983, growth rate is a very daftand a deeply alienatedway of judging economic progress. Sen and Drze warned as early as 1995 that reforms that boost growth, though important, were not enough to improve the living conditions of the poorest, let alone dismantle caste and gender hierarchies and generate employment. They have to be supplemented, they wrote, by a radical shift in public policy in education and health.18 Brazil, for instance, grew only 1 percent compared to Indias 5 percent from 1993 to 2005 but reduced poverty much faster. Bangladesh, which is only half as rich as India measured by per capita income, now exceeds India in, among other social indicators, life expectancy, child mortality, and immunization. And China, by investing a greater proportion of its revenue in education, health, and nutrition, has created a more solid basis for economic growthalthough Sen has often pointed out that under Chinas authoritarian system, in which public criticism is suppressed, such catastrophes as the death of over 30 million people by famine could take place.19 Hoping to present material for informed and reasoned public engagement, Sen and Drze carefully explain such issues as health care, education, corruption, lack of accountability, growing inequality, and their suppression in Indias elite-dominated public space. It is only the poor record and capacity of the Indian government that make one question their advocacy of urgent state action on behalf of the poor. The 2011 census revealed that half of all Indian households have to practice open defecation. Nearly half of all Indian children are underweight (compared to 25 percent in sub-Saharan Africa), and as Sen and Drze point out, despite a rise in literacy rates, a large proportion of them learn very little at school. Almost all Indians buy health services from private providers, exposing themselves to crippling debt as well as quackery. Inequalities have widened between classes, regions, and rural and urban areas. More worryingly, they seem unbridgeable owing to the lack of adequate education and public health. Not surprisingly, poverty declines very slowly in India, slower than in Nepal and Bangladesh, and unevenly.20 Calorie and protein intake among the poor has actually dropped.21
www.nybooks.com/articles/archives/2013/nov/21/which-india-matters/?pagination=false&printpage=true 5/14

11/14/13

Which India Matters? by Pankaj Mishra | The New York Review of Books

India today, the historian Ramachandra Guha writes, is an environmental basket-case; marked by polluted skies, dead rivers, falling water-tables, everincreasing amounts of untreated wastes, disappearing forests.22 Meanwhile, as Sen and Drze write, the largely corporate-owned media, deeply indifferent to poverty and inequality, and reflexively intolerant of any remedial action by the government, produce an unreal picture of the lives of Indians in general by celebrating the fame and wealth of billionaires and cricket and Bollywood stars. Indeed, perennially aggrieved columnists and TV anchors have a crucial part in the deeper drama in India, according to the political scientist Atul Kohli in Poverty Amid Plenty in the New India (2012). That drama is one of an elite that expands and is entrenching itself. Increasingly impatient with the rules and ethics of democracy, Indias ruling class today consists, as C. Rammanohar Reddy, editor of Subir Halder/India Today Group/Getty Images The Economic and Political Weekly, defines it, of Amartya Sen and Jean Drze, 2009 large Indian businesses, the new entrepreneurs in real estate, finance, and IT, the upper segment of the urban middle classes, the upper echelons among the bureaucracy, and even large sections of the media. Whats immediately striking about this class of the relatively affluent is the degree to which it shares the same interests and beliefs, and its reflexive hostility to government spending on welfarealthough political parties feel particularly obliged to indulge in such spending before elections.23 But the conservative rhetoric about buoyantly self-reliant entrepreneurs hides the fact that, as Kohli writes, the Indian state since the 1980s has been pro-business rather than pro-market, responsible both for the dynamic forces at the apex of Indias economy and the failure to include Indias numerous excluded groups in the polity and the economy. This collaborative capitalism, of which Narendra Modi, the Hindu nationalist chief minister of Gujarat, is the most egregious exponent, consists of the state extending tax benefits to Indias largest businesses and facilitating their cheap access to national resources of oil, gas,
24 www.nybooks.com/articles/archives/2013/nov/21/which-india-matters/?pagination=false&printpage=true
6/14

11/14/13

Which India Matters? by Pankaj Mishra | The New York Review of Books

forests, and minerals.24 In turn, the disproportionate control over economic resources, Kohli writes, enables businessmen to buy politicians, shape decision-making through the media, and even enter politics themselves.25 voice in the echo chamber of Indias elite belongs to rich and powerful Indians A major abroad, especially in the United States, many of whom were naturally enthusiastic about, and now wish to direct, the progress of the poor country they had to leave in the 1960s and 1970s. Their reestablished links with the old country have underpinned the new strategic and economic relationship between India and the United States.26 This diaspora has promoted a friendly image of India, Bhagwati and Panagariya write in their new book, and with their analysis and advocacykept pressure in favor of continued reforms. Indeed, one of the most distinguished figures of this impressively credentialed Indian-American elitewhich includes the venture capitalist Vinod Khosla, Vikram Pandit, the former CEO of Citibank, and (until his conviction on insider trading) the investment banker Rajat Guptais Jagdish Bhagwati himself. Educated at Oxford and Cambridge, together with Manmohan Singh, Bhagwati worked with Amartya Sen at the Delhi School of Economics before moving to the United States in the 1970s. In the changing ideological climate of Anglo-America in the 1980s and 1990s, he emerged as a major advocate of free trade and globalization. We were economic theorists, he recalls in his new book, and later turned to policy analysis that would help transform India and the world. His pioneering work on trade policy became central in shaping the AngloAmerican assumption, also known as the Washington Consensus, that was the dominant ideological orthodoxy before the economic crisis of 2008: that no nation can advance without reining in labor unions, eliminating trade barriers, ending subsidies, and, most importantly, minimizing the role of the government. From his perch at Columbia and the Council on Foreign Relations, Bhagwati has provided intellectual authority and sustenance to those who think that India, by prioritizing wealth-creation over health and education, can become a role model for other developing nations.27 Adversity in this endeavormanifested by Indias falling growth rate as well as rising inequality and violenceseems to have made Bhagwati particularly cross with his fellow Oxbridge-educated Indian economists who are still riding the bus that he and Manmohan Singh, he claims, have gotten off. They fancied themselves, he writes in one of the books many polemical asides, as Rosa Parks; in truth they were just intellectually lazy and unwilling to learn from the ruin they had visited on India and its poor. The people Bhagwati considers intellectually lazy or dishonest are a diverse lot. In his new book, he accuses Joseph Stiglitz and George Soros of practicing Jurassic Park Economics
www.nybooks.com/articles/archives/2013/nov/21/which-india-matters/?pagination=false&printpage=true 7/14

11/14/13

Which India Matters? by Pankaj Mishra | The New York Review of Books

and derides the works of Dani Rodrik, the well-known economist at the Institute for Advanced Study, as hollow.28 He has denounced Oxfam as well as Muhammad Yunus, the Bangladeshi economist who won the Nobel Peace Prize for promoting micro-credit ventures among the poor. But no one has impersonated Rosa Parks more vexingly in Bhagwatis mind than his former colleague Amartya Sen.29 Why Growth Matters provides further variations on Bhagwatis insistent complaint that Sen has used his prestigious Nobel Prize as a weapon of mass destruction against Indias potential for economic growth. Much of the book consists of an attempt to mock and repudiate Sen and Drzes ideas, even where the two are not named; it then deplores what Bhagwati and Panagariya see as the sentimental liberalism embodied by such institutions as the World Bank and the World Health Organization. Were health and education neglected during Indias early decades? Not at all, the authors assert. Slow growth and limited revenues were to blame. Does India today resemble Americas Gilded Age in the privileges of its upper classes? The allegation is not persuasive. What about inequality? When mobility is high, as they claim it is in India, the poor may react by celebrating the conspicuous inequality. Is India doing worse than Bangladesh in human development despite its much higher growth? These inferences are plain wrong. What about corruption? The reforms Bhagwati advocated bid good-bye to many forms of corruption. Does the decline in Indian calorie consumption, as shown by WHO statistics, reflect increased hunger and poverty? The decline could be due to a shift from coarse grains to rice and fruits. In any case, Bhagwati and Panagariya add, without saying how it can be done, malnourished families should be shifting their diet to more milk and fruits.30 There is much about this shadow-boxing that makes one wonder if Bhagwati, moving like many intellectual elites between the bubble of universities and think tanks and the private hothouse of professional rivalry, has lost touch with how the other halfor the 99 percent lives. Bhagwati and Panagariya dont examine in any depth the nature or likely sustainability of Indias economic growth, which, based primarily on extractionof natural resources and cheap labor and foreign capital inflowsrather than high productivity and innovation, seems to have run up against its built-in limits.31 They urge India to develop more Chinese-style low-skilled, labor-intensive industries. They are right to blame mindless regulation for Indias lost lead over a smaller and poorer country, Bangladesh, of clothing export. But then, investors keep shifting factories to low-wage countries because of the mobility of capital and the fierce trade competitiveness that Bhagwati recommends as a sure formula for
32 www.nybooks.com/articles/archives/2013/nov/21/which-india-matters/?pagination=false&printpage=true
8/14

11/14/13

Which India Matters? by Pankaj Mishra | The New York Review of Books

prosperity.32 His fervent advocacy on behalf of Indias potential clashes with the fact that globalization can shrink a nations comparative advantage pretty quickly, and, even when usefully deployed, can entrap late-industrializing national economies in low income. Why Growth Matters does offer some practicable improvements to Indias poor social infrastructure, for example, training programs for nurses and collectively insuring residents of rural regions against major illnesses. But too many of its recommendations seem indistinguishable from the talking points of Paul Ryan: the authors advocate vouchers for schools and hospitals, and targeted rather than universal health coverage. As for extensive environmental destruction, the correct way to diagnose this issue is to say that we have a missing market regarding pollution. How such a market could come into effect and reduce pollution they do not make clear. Predictably, Bhagwati and Panagariya propose direct cash transfers for performance of specific jobs rather than guaranteed wage employment in public works. Exemplifying another right-wing article of faith, they admire the weakness of labor unions in not only Taiwan, South Korea, and China, but also Bangladesh, which allows firms to hire and fire workers under reasonable conditions and maintain a balance between the rights of both workers and employerswords that would have sounded bizarre even before the collapse in April this year of a garment factory in Dhaka that killed more than a thousand workers, exposing yet again the slave-labor conditions of many unprotected toilers in the globalized economy.33

ooking back at the conversation between Nakayama and Reischauer, and its echoes in Bhagwatis disagreements with Sen, it seems clear that for postwar Japanese economists and policymakers, eliminating poverty and reducing inequality were profoundly political and ethicalchallenges. Writing in the early 1970s, Reischauer seemed to concede the argument to his Japanese interlocutor by admitting a broad causal relationship between imbalanced growth and eventual instability.34 Nakayamas implicit argumentthat high economic growth can empower an insular, selfish, and antidemocratic elite in an unequal societyseems particularly applicable now to a cruelly stratified country like India, where, as judges of the Indian Supreme Court recently put it, predatory forms of capitalism, supported and promoted by the State are pushing the poor to the wall. This is exemplified vividly by the tribals protesting their dispossession by mining companies and local governments in central Indiapeople often led by armed Maoists.35 Rising social unrest is making an insecure Indian elite gravitate to such hard-line leaders as Narendra Modi, whose well-advertised toughness with labor unions and PR-enhanced
www.nybooks.com/articles/archives/2013/nov/21/which-india-matters/?pagination=false&printpage=true 9/14

11/14/13

Which India Matters? by Pankaj Mishra | The New York Review of Books

business-friendliness make him the preferred choice of many corporate leaders, economists, and commentators as Indias next prime minister.36 Bhagwati, for instance, has described Modi as a positive role model with an unblemished record of personal integrity. As chief minister of Gujarat, Modi was allegedly complicit in the killing of over a thousand Muslims there in 2002 and was barred from traveling to the United States as a result. But he still embodies managerial efficiency and iron discipline to those disturbed by the political assertiveness of the poor and the disaffected.37 In fact, the political energies of the hundreds of millions of the poor and disaffected are still underdeployed. Could they lead to a more accountable and responsive state and, in the long run, to a more egalitarian and democratic India? Sen and Drze seem convinced that the poor themselves rather than technocratic elites can help remove poverty and inequality by keenly participating in the public sphere. This bottom-up democratization may seem like a remnant of modernization theory. And Sen and Drze offer no clear vision of the economicas distinct from politicalprocess that would help their cause of equity, and also check environmental destruction. But the poor in India still have a great capacity to aspire, as the social anthropologist Arjun Appadurai claims in his new book.38 And their collective efforts can make the state more accountable and efficienta possibility that Bhagwati and Panagariya ignore while lamenting the states incapacity and corruption. In the state of Tamil Nadu, for instance, mobilized lower-caste groups not only achieved political power. They also, as Sen and Drze have written, established a social infrastructureschools, health centers, roads, public transportthat is now envied across India.39 Sen and Drze also reveal how democracy in its simplest manifestation, the scramble for votes, can drive successful implementation of welfare programs such as the Public Distribution System.40 They see more hopeful signs in the recent mass agitations against corruption and violence against women. Many observers of India are generally impressed by the procedures of Indian democracy, with its routine elections. India, Bhagwati and Panagariya assert, has all elements of a liberal democracy with the poor and the underprivileged having access to effective politics at the ballot box. But as Sen and Drze point out, the success of a democracy depends ultimately on the vigor of its practice. Certainly, creeping authoritarianism of the kind witnessed in India can make political reform from below seem more urgent than economic engineering from the top. Educate, agitate, and organize, the disenchanted low-caste author of Indias constitution B.R. Ambedkar exhorted. Many more Indians will have to exercise these democratic rights if they wish to transform the profoundly damaging elitist character of Indian society and politics.
www.nybooks.com/articles/archives/2013/nov/21/which-india-matters/?pagination=false&printpage=true 10/14

11/14/13

Which India Matters? by Pankaj Mishra | The New York Review of Books

1 For a fascinating discussion of the challenges confronting postwar Japanese economists, see Laura E. Hein, In Search of Peace and Democracy: Japanese Economic Debate in Political Context, The Journal of Asian Studies, Vol. 53, No. 3 (August 1994). 2 Nakayama suspected that the ruling elites pathology of endless growth had led his country into domestic repression and external aggression. Reischauer, like all teleological-minded modernizers, was inclined to see Japans aggression as a blip on its way to the modern world, one caused by bad decision-making and aberrant militarism. Such a view was in line with the American attempt to present Japan as an exemplar of benign Westernization to non-Communist Asia during the height of the cold war. This normalization of Japan extended to whitewashing the war crimes of Emperor Hirohito. M any scholars of pre-1945 Japan did not buy the Reischauer Line, as the evolutionary modernization argument was subsequently called. An early and prominent dissenter was the Canadian diplomat E.H. Norman, who pointed to the facts of uneven development and widespread poverty in pre-war Japan. See John W. Dower, E.H. Norman, Japan, and the Uses of History in Ways of Forgetting, Ways of Remembering: Japan in the Modern World (New Press, 2012). 3 The debate between Reischauer and Nakayama took place just before economic growth in Japan began to reveal its costs, provoking a strong down with GNP protest movement. Environmental spoliation and urban overcrowding on a large scale mocked the original goal of raising living standards. The dualism Nakayama feared did vanish, but it reincarnated itself in gaps between permanent and temporary jobs, male and female workforces. 4 A classic account of Japans economic rise is Chalmers Johnson, MITI and the Japanese Miracle: The Growth of Industrial Policy, 19251975 (Stanford University Press, 1982). 5 For an insightful analysis, see the articles in The Political Economy of the New Asian Industrialism, edited by Frederic C. Deyo (Cornell University Press, 1987), especially the one by Bruce Cumings. A more journalistic and contemporary account is in Joe Studwell, How Asia Works: Success and Failure in the Worlds Most Dynamic Region (Grove, 2013). 6 The uniqueness of this experience is best illustrated by the fact that much of Europe introduced universal suffrage and social welfare programs in the early twentieth century after building a capitalist and industrial economy, constructing a bureaucratic state, and achieving a degree of prosperity. Democracy in India, promulgated before the preconditions for it existed, has seemed to hamper both economic growth and national cohesionone reason why many in the countrys middle classes revere such authoritarian figures as Singapores Lee Kuan Yew. 7 M uch scholarship has been devoted to the destruction of Indias vibrant eighteenth-century economy by British imperialists. Some new evidence is presented in Prasannan Parthasarathi, Why Europe Grew Rich and Asia Did Not: Global Economic Divergence, 16001850 (Cambridge University Press, 2011). 8 Deepak Nayyar argues that Indias economic performance in the 1950s, 1960s, and 1970s was a great departure from the past, and not much inferior to that of comparative countries. See Deepak Nayyar, Indias Unfinished Journey: Transforming Growth into Development Modern Asian Studies, Vol. 40, No. 3 (July 2006). For a panoramic account, see Stuart Corbridge, The Political Economy of India since Independence in Routledge Handbook of South Asian Politics: India, Pakistan, Bangladesh, Sri Lanka, and Nepal, edited by Paul R. Brass (Routledge, 2010). 9 For a full account of the making of this elite that the writer Vijay Prashad calls twice blessed, first by Indias world-class institutions and then by immigration reform in the United States, see Anita Raghavan, The Billionaires Apprentice: The Rise of the Indian-American Elite and the Fall of the Galleon Hedge Fund (Business Plus, 2013). 10 Dependence and Interdependence: Essays in Development Economics, Vol. 2, edited by Jagdish Bhagwati and Gene M . Grossman (Basil Blackwell, 1985). 11 For a skeptical view of Indian socialism, see Kaushik Basu, The Enigma of Indias Arrival: A Review of Arvind Virmanis
www.nybooks.com/articles/archives/2013/nov/21/which-india-matters/?pagination=false&printpage=true 11/14

11/14/13

Which India Matters? by Pankaj Mishra | The New York Review of Books

Propelling India: From Socialist Stagnation to Global Power, Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 46, No. 2 (June 2008). 12 The socialist Indian state is commonly blamed for putting Indias economy into a protective straitjacket, and for a feeble industrial policy that led to Indias failure to capitalize, along with East Asian economies, on the new openings for world trade in the 1970s. Vivek Chibber, among others, has argued that Indian industrialists successfully campaigned against state-led development of the kind South Korea benefited from. See Locked in Place: State-Building and Late Industrialization in India (Princeton University Press, 2003). 13 Bhagwati helped seed the euphoric notioncommonplace now among most commentators on South Asiathat India began to move out of decades of socialist stagnation after seeing in 1991 the light of free trade and globalization. In fact, growth had started accelerating in the 1980s, helped by the governments pro-business reforms. Irrational exuberance in the West, and effective networking at such forums as Davos by Indian politicians and corporate chieftains, account for the breathless and repetitive descriptions of India as a tiger economy in recent years. There was little reason to compare it to Chinas immensely larger, more productive, and broad-based economy. 14 The overall share of manufacturing in the GDP has stagnated at 16 percent. It partly accounts for Indias tiny 1.4 percent share of world trade, compared to Chinas 15 percent. 15 Despite its serious flaws, China has managed relatively smoothly its structural transformation from an agrarian to an urban, laborintensive economy. In India, jobs in manufacturing as well as agriculture have actually shrunk in the previous decade. The construction sector has absorbed many of the displaced job-seekers, but they will be unemployed again when the real estate boom ends. See Hans P. Binswanger-M khize, The Stunted Structural Transformation of the Indian Economy, The Economic and Political Weekly, June 29, 2013. 16 Wages in Chinas manufacturing sector have grown by 12 percent since 2000, compared with 2.5 percent in India. There are also more workers without social security than before in Indias organized industrial sector. Thus, economic growth has not benefitted even employed workers, let alone the vast majority of the unemployed and unemployable. See Himanshu, Growth Versus Redistribution, Mint, July 19, 2013. The social anthropologist Jan Breman, a long-standing observer of Indias uniquely large informal economy, writes perceptively in his new book about the abysmal working conditions of the poor in Gujarat, a highgrowth state. See At Work in the Informal Economy of India: A Perspective from the Bottom Up (Oxford University Press, 2013). 17 Basu is a former economic adviser to the Indian prime minister M anmohan Singh. See his Indias Dilemmas: The Political Economy of Policymaking in a Globalised World, The Economic and Political Weekly (February 28, 2008). 18 See India: Economic Development and Social Opportunity (Oxford University Press, 1996), p. 16. 19 See his essay Press Freedom: Who Is It Good For?, to be published in the autumn issue of Index on Censorship. 20 The measurement and estimates of poverty are vigorously contested. But it is fair to say that by even the most conservative estimate, the absolute number of poor in India is enormous, and may exceed the entire population of the United States. See Sabina Alkire and Suman Seth, M ultidimensional Poverty Reduction in India between 1999 and 2006: Where and How?, Oxford Poverty and Human Development Initiative Working Paper No. 60, M arch 2013. Increasing inequality only slows down the rate of poverty reduction. See Himanshu, Poverty and Inequality in IndiaII: Widening Disparities during the 1990s, The Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. 39, No. 39 ( September 25October 1, 2004). 21 See Harsh M ander, Ash in the Belly: Indias Unfinished Battle against Hunger (New Delhi: Penguin, 2012). 22 The recent floods in Himalayan valleys, which claimed thousands of lives, focused international attention on illegal deforestation, construction, and mining, and feckless dam-building. The World Bank estimates that environmental damage reduces Indias GDP by 5.7 percent. The figure would be greater if it took into account the loss of livelihoods of millions of Indians who depend on forests, farms, rivers, coasts, and grasslands. For an eye-opening account of environmental depredation in India, see Aseem Shrivastava and Ashis Kothari, Churning the Earth: The Making of Global India (Delhi: Penguin, 2012).
www.nybooks.com/articles/archives/2013/nov/21/which-india-matters/?pagination=false&printpage=true 12/14

11/14/13

Which India Matters? by Pankaj Mishra | The New York Review of Books

23 Though, according to a new report by the Asian Development Bank, India spends less than Nepal and Timor-Lesteonly 1.7 percent of its GDP on health, income, employment, and other forms of social protection. As Sen and Drze point out, affluent Indians protesting against the right-to-food bill that would annually cost Rs. 27,000 do not object to the tax exemption on diamond and gold imports that annually costs the Indian treasury more than Rs. 57,000 crores a year, or the even more wasteful subsidies on diesel fuel that benefit the rich. The advocacy by Sen and Drze of social services, and their opposition to Narendra M odi, have provoked many angry attacks on them in the corporate-owned media, including the baseless charge of charlatanry. See R. Jagannathan, Food Bill: Amartya Sens Charlatan Economics Debunked, Firstpost, July 10, 2013. 24 Such incentives make it harder for the government to raise the revenues needed for public spending. Also, the possibility that they may not be enhanced, or even withdrawn, provokes Indian businessmen to look elsewhere for greater profits. Indian beneficiaries of both the old protectionist and new crony capitalist regime such as Birla and Ambani are now putting the bulk of their investments abroad. 25 The pecuniary logic of the free market is redefining Indias journalism as well as politics. In 2010, Indias leading television personalities were caught on tape offering their services to business lobbyists. The managing editor of the Times of India, Indias biggest English-language newspaper, which pioneered the phenomenon of paid news, recently told The New Yorker that we are not in the newspaper business, we are in the advertising business. The Press Council of India, a monitoring body, commissioned and then tried to suppress a report on paid news. It can be read at www.outlookindia.com/article.aspx?266542. Investigative reports on corporate-political skullduggery or police brutality are confined to small-circulation magazines such as such as Tehelka and Caravan. In one of Indias most recent scandals, the government raised gas prices in order to benefit one of the Indias largest corporations, Reliance, and its global partner, British Petroleum. The corporate-owned media as well as the main opposition parties stayed conspicuously silent. See Anuradha Raman and Prarthna Gahilote, Lips and Purse-Strings, Outlook India, July 15, 2013. 26 Briefly, in the 2000s, India seemed to have replaced Japan in the American strategic imagination as an exemplary Asian democracy with pro-American elitesone that can be usefully counterposed to authoritarian China. 27 The intellectual synergy that creates the elite consensus about reforms in India is now subsidized by conservative American think tanks such as the American Enterprise Institute, the Cato Institute, and the Peterson Institute, which employ economists and journalists of Indian origin and ancestry. 28 Full disclosure: in a speech to the Indian parliament, Bhagwati described my October 2010 New York Times Op-Ed on rising inequality, farmer suicides, and M aoist insurgency in India as fiction masquerading as non-fiction. 29 M ore recently, Bhagwati has compared Sen, unfavorably, to M other Teresa. 30 Arvind Panagariya has attempted to prove that malnutrition rates in India are based on faulty WHO methodology and that Indian children are genetically programmed to be short. See Does India Really Suffer from Worse Child M alnutrition Than Sub-Saharan Africa?, The Economic and Political Weekly, M ay 4, 2013. Also see a rebuttal of Panagariyas argument by several economists in The Economic and Political Weekly, August 24, 2013. 31 For a sobering analysis, which claims that Indias economic boom, part of a worldwide expansion before the crisis of 2008, and led by debt and exceptional flows of foreign capital, was unsustainable, see R. Nagaraj, Indias Dream Run, 20032008: Understanding the Boom and its Aftermath, The Economic and Political Weekly, M ay 18, 2013. 32 As Thomas Friedman put it in his inimitable fashion, if you are a little too slow or too costly...you will be left as roadkill before you know what hit you. 33 Even Walmart now calls Bangladeshs working conditions unacceptable. See Jim Yardley, Bangladesh Pollution Told in Colors and Smells, The New York Times, July 14, 2013. On Indias own unsafe work sites, see the series of articles by M aitreyee Handique for Mint, including Damage Done, But Damages Stay Unpaid, October 8, 2009. 34 What Went Wrong? in Dilemmas of Growth in Prewar Japan, edited by James William M orley (Princeton University Press,
www.nybooks.com/articles/archives/2013/nov/21/which-india-matters/?pagination=false&printpage=true 13/14

11/14/13

Which India Matters? by Pankaj Mishra | The New York Review of Books

1971). 35 An estimated 10,000 to 20,000 armed M aoists are active in one third of Indias districts. The governments response is borrowed from its counter-insurgency measures in Kashmir and the northeastern states. But the show of brute force in affected parts of central India by paramilitaries and private militias makes the situation even worse. 36 For a revealing profile of M odi by Vinod K. Jose, one of Indias best journalists, see The Emperor Uncrowned: The Rise of Narendra M odi, The Caravan, M arch 2012. Also see Christophe Jaffrelot, Gujarat Elections: The Sub-Text of M odis HattrickHigh Tech Populism and the Neo-middle Class, Studies in Indian Politics, Vol. 1, No. 1, (June 2013). 37 As in pre-war Japan, and many other countries, the elites quest for power expresses itself as a preference for a hardline state. 38 The Future as Cultural Fact: Essays on the Global Condition (Verso, 2013). 39 For more links between political enlightenment, democratic mobilization from below, and egalitarianism, see Kohlis Poverty Amid Plenty in the New India, with its comparative studies of West Bengal, Uttar Pradesh, Kerala, and Gujarat. 40 According to the Planning Commission, poverty rates in rural areas, especially those in states with low growth rates, have declined faster than in urban India due to increased government spending on welfare programs.

1963-2013 NYREV, Inc. All rights reserved.

www.nybooks.com/articles/archives/2013/nov/21/which-india-matters/?pagination=false&printpage=true

14/14

Anda mungkin juga menyukai