Anda di halaman 1dari 272

Competition Law and Patents

NEW HORIZONS IN COMPETITION LAW AND ECONOMICS


Series Editors: Steven D. Anderman, Department of Law, University of Essex,
UK and Rudolph J.R. Peritz, New York Law School, USA
This series has been created to provide research based analysis and discussion
of the appropriate role for economic thinking in the formulation of competition
law and policy. The books in the series will move beyond studies of the
traditional role of economics that of helping to define markets and assess
market power to explore the extent to which economic thinking can play a
role in the formulation of legal norms, such as abuse of a dominant position,
restriction of competition and substantial impediments to or lessening of
competition. This in many ways is the new horizon of competition law policy.
US antitrust policy, influenced in its formative years by the Chicago School, has
already experienced an expansion of the role of economic thinking in its
competition rules. Now the EU is committed to a greater role for economic
thinking in its Block Exemption Regulations and Modernisation package as
well as possibly in its reform of Article 82. Yet these developments still raise
the issue of the extent to which economics should be adopted in defining the
public interest in competition policy and what role economists should play in
legal arguments. The series will provide a forum for research perspectives that
are critical of an unduly-expanded role for economics as well as those that
support its greater use.
Titles in the series include:
Antitrust, Patents and Copyright
EU and US Perspectives
Edited by Franois Lvque and Howard Shelanski
Innovation Markets and Competition Analysis
EU Competition Law and US Antitrust Law
Marcus Glader
Competition Law and Patents
A Follow-on Innovation Perspective in the Biopharmaceutical Industry
Irina Haracoglou

Competition Law and


Patents
A Follow-on Innovation Perspective in the
Biopharmaceutical Industry

Irina Haracoglou
Attorney at Law, Independent Researcher/Consultant

NEW HORIZONS IN COMPETITION LAW AND ECONOMICS

Edward Elgar
Cheltenham, UK Northampton, MA, USA

Irina Haracoglou 2008


All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval
system or transmitted in any form or by any means, electronic, mechanical or
photocopying, recording, or otherwise without the prior permission of the publisher.
Published by
Edward Elgar Publishing Limited
Glensanda House
Montpellier parade
Cheltenham
Glos GL50 1UA
UK
Edward Elgar Publishing, Inc.
William Pratt House
9 Dewey Court
Northampton
Massachusetts 01060
USA

A catalogue record for this book


is available from the British Library
Library of Congress Cataloguing in Publication Data
Haracoglou, Irina, 1981
Competition law and patents : a follow-on innovation perspective in the
biopharmaceutical industry / by Irina Haracoglou.
p. cm. (New horizons in competition law and economics series)
Includes bibliographical references and index.
1. Patent laws and legislation. 2. Pharmaceutical biotechnologyPatents.
3. Pharmaceutical biotechnologyLaw and legislation. 4. Competition,
Unfair. I. Title.
K1575.H37 2008
346.04'86dc22

2007038609
ISBN 978 1 84720 599 5
Typeset by Manton Typesetters, Louth, Lincolnshire, UK
Printed and bound in Great Britain by MPG Books Ltd, Bodmin, Cornwall

To Mum for her love & patience


To Dad for his persistence & perfectionism
To Dimitris (my stepfather) for his kindness & generosity

Contents
List of abbreviations
Preface
Acknowledgements
Table of cases

xii
xiv
xv
xvi

Part I:The problem Access as a necessary element


of follow-on innovation?
1. Biopharmaceutical R&D: the increased importance of cumulative
innovation and related concerns

1.1 Introduction
1.2 The case of research tools

1.2.1 Defining research tools

1.2.2 The patent experience in biotechnology: biomedical

research tools

1.2.3 The effect of patent trends on the patent balance for

research tools

1.3 Conclusion

3
3
7
7
9
12
16

Part II:The Patent Balance and Working Solutions


in the Patent System
2. The patent system as a system of balancing

2.1 The Patent Balance

2.2 The particular importance of the patent balance in the

biopharmaceutical industry

2.2.1 The patent system and the biopharmaceutical industry

2.2.1.1 Biopharmaceutical innovation and patenting

2.2.1.2 Has the importance of patents been

overstated?

2.3 Conclusion

21
21

3. The patent system and some potential safety nets


3.1 Introduction to the patent safety nets

36
36

vii

25
25
28
31
34

viii

Contents


3.2 The patent safety nets

3.2.1 Experimental use exemption

3.2.1.1 The experimental use exemption: a viable

and effective working solution?

3.2.1.2 The US experience: a helpful paradigm?

3.2.1.3 Conclusion on the EUE

3.2.2 The reverse doctrine of equivalents and blocking
patents


3.2.3 Patent pools

3.2.4 Compulsory licensing in the patent provisions

3.2.4.1 Introduction to compulsory licensing

(a) Definition and history

(b) Support and opposition for CL

(c) Grounds for granting a compulsory

licence

3.2.4.2 Analysis of the role of CL

(a) The role of CL in balancing

commensurability

(i) CL as a mechanism to induce

broad licensing

(ii) CL for non-use

(iii) CL for significant technological

advances

(iv) CL to address health

emergencies

(v) CL as a remedy for anti
competitive conduct

(b) Conclusions on CL

37
39

4. The right to health as an interpretive principle of patent law



4.1 Introduction

4.2 The right to health as a human right and its status in

European law

4.2.1 Introduction to the right to health

4.2.2 Sources of the right to health

4.2.3 Implications of the right to health

4.2.3.1 Elements of the right to health

4.2.3.2 Obligation to respect, protect and fulfil

4.2.4 International Efforts to Strengthen the Right to Health

4.3 The right to health and patent law: The fundamental nature of

health concerns and the move towards a right to health as an

interpretive principle in patent law

70
70

39
44
46
48
51
54
54
54
54
57
58
58
58
59
59
61
63
63

71
71
74
76
77
79
80
82

Contents


4.3.1 The link between the right to health and patent law

4.3.1.1 The effect of patent law on the right to

health

4.3.1.2 The effect of the right to health on patent

law

4.3.2 The right to property and IP: IP as a human right

4.3.2.1 Striking the balance: limitations in the
public interest


4.3.3 Patenting and the right to health

4.3.3.1 Direct effect

4.3.3.2 The indirect effect of the right to health

4.3.4 The right to health as an interpretive principle in

patent law

4.3.4.1 Effect on specific patent provisions

4.3.4.2 Case-law on public health

4.3.4.3 European cases on IP and fundamental

rights analysis

4.4 Conclusions

ix

82
82
83
84
86
87
87
88
90
91
93
94
96

PART III:Antitrust as a Complement to the Patent


System
5. Unilateral conduct, intellectual property rights and Competition
Law: a systems interaction

5.1 Introduction
5.2 The practice of the courts

5.2.1 The existence/exercise distinction

5.3 IPRs and competition: A systems interaction

5.3.1 IPRs public goods, exclusivity and information

goods

5.3.1.1 Public goods and market failure

5.3.1.2 Patronage, procurement and property

5.3.2 Implications for competition

5.3.2.1 IP like other property rights for the purposes

of competition

5.3.2.2 Competition embedded in the IP system

5.3.2.3 The transition from separate to unified fields

5.3.2.4 How antitrust control affects incentives to

innovate

5.3.3 Recent recognition of antitrust control

5.4 Conclusions

101
101
103
103
107
107
107
109
112
112
114
114
116
119
121

Contents

6. The Duty to Deal under Art. 82 EC



6.1 Introduction

6.1.1 What is a refusal to deal and what is the rationale

behind its prohibition?

6.1.2 Concerns relating to a refusal to deal: Potential harm

to competition

6.2 The state of the law

6.2.1 Cutting off existing customers: The dependence cases

6.2.2 Reservation of an ancillary activity and leverage

economics

6.2.3 The indispensability requirement and the essential

facilities doctrine (EFD)

6.2.3.1 Indispensability

6.2.3.2 Two-market requirement

6.2.3.3 Objective justification

6.2.4 New product innovation

6.3 Conclusions

Appendix The refusal to deal cases under Art. 82

122
122
122
123
126
128
130
133
135
138
139
141
143
145

PART IV:A MORE INNOVATION SENSITIVE APPROACH TO THE


INTERFACE OF COMPETITION LAW AND PATENTS?
7. The duty to deal as applied to address technology access problems
in the biopharmaceutical industry

7.1 Conclusions on the patent system in the case of research

tools

7.1.1 The particularity of research tools: pre-commercial

stage patents

7.1.2 A gap in the patent system?

7.1.3 The more the better? Optimal market structure for

innovation

7.2 Two possible avenues for increased access to essential

research tools

7.2.1 Patent law

7.2.2 A role for Art. 82?

7.2.2.1 Indispensability

7.2.2.2 Preventing the emergence of a new product

for which there is potential consumer

demand

7.2.2.3 Elimination of competition on a downstream

or neighbouring market/two-market

requirement

177
177
177
179
179
181
181
185
186
187
187

Contents

xi


7.2.2.4 The absence of an objective justification

7.2.3.1 The impact of Art. 82 duty to deal with case
law on the patent system

7.2.3.2 An innovation sensitive approach:

innovation markets in Art. 82?

7.2.3.3 Conclusions on compulsory licensing as a

safety net

7.2.4 Conclusion: A human rights approach to competition
law?

188

Bibliography
Legislation and Guidelines
Reports and Studies
Authors
Index

200
200
204
210
239

189
191
195
196

Abbreviations
ACIP
AIPLA
Am. Bus. L. J.
Am. J. L. and Med.
Antitr. L. J.
Berk. Tech. L. J.
Buff. Hum. Rts. L. Rev.
CAFC
CFI
Chi. Kent L. Rev.
Chi. Trib.
CL
CML Rev
Col. L. Rev.
Community
Community Courts
CPC
CPTech
DOJ
EC Treaty
ECJ
ECLR
ECR
EEA
EFD
EGE
EIPR
ELR
EMEA
EPC
EPO
ESCRC
EU
EUE
FDA

Advisory Council on Intellectual Property


American Intellectual Property Law Association
American Business Law Journal
American Journal of Law and Medicine
Antitrust Law Journal
Berkeley Technology Law Journal
Buffalo Human Rights Law Review
Court of Appeals for the Federal Circuit
Court of First Instance
Chicago Kent Law Review
Chicago Tribunal
Compulsory licensing
Common Market Law Review
Columbia Law Review
European Community
CFI and ECJ
Community Patent Convention
Consumer Project on Technology
Department of Justice
Treaty Establishing the European Community
European Court of Justice
European Competition Law Review
European Court Reports
European Economic Area
Essential Facilities Doctrine
European Group of Ethics
European Intellectual Property Review
European Law Review
European Medicines Evaluation Agency
European Patent Convention
European Patent Office
Economics, Social and Cultural Rights Committee
European Union
Experimental use exemption
Food and Drug Administration
xii

Abbreviations

xiii

Ford. Corp. L. Inst.


Ford. Int. L. J.
FTC
GATS
IACHR
IIC

Fordham Corporate Law Institute


Fordham International Law Journal
Federal Trade Commission
General Agreement on Trade in Services
Inter-American Court on Human Rights
International Review of Industrial Property and
Copyright Law
IMA
Innovation Markets Approach
IP
Intellectual property
IPR
Intellectual property right
J.L. and Econ.
Journal of Law and Economics
JPE
Journal of Political Economy
JPTOS
Journal of the Patent and Trademark Office Society
LQR
Law Quarterly Review
Mich. L. Rev.
Michigan Law Review
NYU Law Review
New York University Law Review
OECD
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and
Development
OFT
Office of Fair Trading
OJ
Official Journal
OJ
Objective justification
OUP
Oxford University Press
R&D
Research and Development
RJE
Rand Journal of Economics
SME
Small and medium-sized enterprise
SPC
Supplementary Protection Certificate
SSM
Specific Subject Matter
Stan. L. Rev.
Stanford Law Review
TTBER
Technology Transfer Block Exemption Regulation
TRIPS
Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual
Property Rights
U. Chi. L. Rev.
University Of Chicago Law Review
U. Ill. L. Rev
University Of Illinois Law Review
USA
United States of America
USPTO
Patent and Trademark Office, USA
Va. J. Trans. L. Vanderbuilt Journal of Transnational Law
Va. L. Rev. Vanderbuilt Law Review
VI Vertical Integration
WIPO
World Intellectual Property Organization
WTO
World Trade Organization
Note:Other abbreviations that have been used are either defined in the text or can be found in the
bibliography.

Preface
In June 2005 the European Commission announced that it had fined AstraZeneca
60 million for misusing the patent system to delay entry of competitors thereby
abusing its dominant position in contravention of Art. 82 EC. In October 2005
a complaint by six phone manufacturers was reported against Qualcomm, a chip
manufacturer that owns patents over technology used in 3G handsets, alleging
that Qualcomm refused to license essential patents on fair terms, and charged
excessive royalties for its essential patents thereby acting anti-competitively.
In December 2005 the Commission published a Discussion Paper on the Application of Art. 82 to Exclusionary Abuses. In February 2007 the Commission
opened an investigation into Boehringers best selling drug last year, Spiriva, in
relation to possible misuses of the patent system to exclude competition from
the market.
These initiatives have as their backdrop two central questions, inter alia: first,
the relationship between competition law and intellectual property rights; and
secondly, the duty of dominant undertakings to deal/license/supply other
undertakings.
Against this background and in view of the increased significance these questions are likely to assume in the future, this book deals broadly with the
relationship between competition law and intellectual property rights, and more
specifically, with the interface between patent law and competition abuses by
virtue of refusal to deal in the biopharmaceutical industry. It focuses on a
paramount element for competition: access. It addresses the following question: how do we strike the balance between initial and follow-on innovation so
as to ensure that access to essential research tools (or other fundamental elements for follow-on innovation) is not impeded?

Commission press release IP/05/737. AstraZeneca abused its dominance by making misrepresentations to national patent offices with a view to obtaining supplementary
protection certificates, as well as by misusing rules and procedures of medicines agencies
to block entry of generic products or parallel traders.

N. Gohring, Qualcomm accused of anticompetitive conduct in EU, 28 October
2005, available at www.infoworld.com.

December 2005, available at http://ec.europa.eu/competition/antitrust/others/article_82_review.html.

Case COMP/B2/39246.

xiv

Acknowledgements
This book started from a series of coincidences, evolved into a test of persistence
and patience, and culminated in a series of good fortunes the most significant
of which was to see ones long-awaited aspiration realised.
It has certainly not been a smooth ride throughout as there have been many
moments of frustration, questioning and disbelief, together with many moments
of challenge, excitement and great fulfilment.
The various stages of the manuscript travelled with me across countries, and
have certainly filled me with many experiences that I have grown with and for
which I am most grateful.
I owe my most profound and sincere gratitude to my supervisor, Prof. Ullrich,
who has provided me with great support, understanding and words of
wisdom.
I am also deeply grateful to the following people who have helped me with
their support and useful comments: Prof. Shelanski, Prof. Joerges, Prof. Lemley,
Prof. Blackburn, Prof. Barton, Prof. Lvque, Luk Peepercorn, Sandro Paollichi,
Dimitrios Giotakos, Dr Alan Riley, Dr Barry Rodger, Emanuela Lecchi, Andreas
Avgousti, Katherine Llorca and many more.
My warmest thanks are due to the European University Institute for the support and funding they granted me over the years as well as my funding body,
the Department of Education and Skills. I would also like to thank the University
of California, Berkeley and European Commission, DG COMP who, during my
stay there, were instrumental in helping my research. I am also grateful to the
members of CLASF for listening to drafts of my papers and providing me with
comments, Charles Russell LLP as well as to the TRA (Bahrain).
I am, of course, most grateful to my publisher, Edward Elgar and the people
therein who gave me their support, particularly Luke Adams, Jo Betteridge and
Kate Pearce.
Most of all, I would like to thank my friends and family without whose support this experience would not have been so remarkable: Mum and Alexia thanks
for listening during my many hours of frustration; Yianni and Eleni thanks for
providing me with immeasurable entertainment; Manoli thanks for supporting
me in the finish!

xv

Cases
European Courts Decisions
Case 402/85 Basset v SACEM [1987] ECR 1747
196
Case 77/77 Benzine en Petroleum Handelsmaatschappik BV and others v Commission [1978] ECR 1513
129, 146
Case 311/84 Centre Belge dEtudes du March-Tlmarketing SA (CBEM) v
Companie Luxembourgeoise de Tldiffusion [1985] ECR 3261 127, 130,

1512, 171, 173
Case T-201/04 Competition Microsoft v Commission, Order of the President of
the CFI, 22 December 2004 (Proceedings for interim relief Art. 82 EC)

144, 169, 173, 179, 187, 188, 190
Case 78/70 Deutsche Grammophon [1974] ECR 1147
104
Case 56 and 58/64 Etablissements Consten SA and Grundig-Verkaufs-GmbH v
Commission [1966] ECR 299
104
Case T-374/94 European Night Services [1998] ECR II-3141
165
Case C 418/01, IMS, not yet reported, judgment of 29 April 2004 123, 126,

127, 1367, 139, 141, 142, 143, 144,

1659, 172, 173, 186, 187, 188, 198
Case 6/73 Istituto Chemioterapico Italiano and Commercial Solvents v Commission [1974] ECR 223
126, 127, 128, 130, 1457, 171, 173
Case C-200/96, Metronome Music v Music Camp, Judgment of the Court of 28
April 1998, ECR I-01953
95
Case 322/81 Michelin v Commission [1983] ECR 3461
148
Case C-377/98 Netherlands v Council, [2001] ECR I-07079
945
Case C-7/97 Oscar Bronner v Mediaprint [1998] ECR I-7791 103, 123, 127,

133, 136, 141, 143, 1625, 172, 173
Cases C-241/91 P and C-242/91 P, Radio Telefis Eireann (RTE) and Independent
Television Publications (ITP) v Commission (Magill), [1995] ECR I-743

103, 1056, 121, 123, 126, 127, 128,

130, 133, 141, 15961, 172, 173, 190
Case C-53/03 Synetairismos Farmakopoion Aitolias & Akarnanias (Syfait) and
Others v Glaxosmithkline AEVE, Opinion of the A-G Jacobs, reference 28
October 2004, not yet reported
124, 128, 140, 143, 170, 173
Case 88/501 Tetra Pak I (BTG license) [1988] OJ L272/27
190, 191

xvi

Cases

xvii

Case C-333/94 Tetra Pak v Commission [1996] ECR I-5951


1489
Case T-504/93 Tierce Ladbroke v Commission [1997] ECR II 923 126, 127,

128, 1412, 1612, 172, 173
Case 27/76 United Brands Co. and United Brands Continental BV v Commission [1978] ECR 207
1245, 127, 128, 130, 1479, 157, 171, 173
Case 238/87 Volvo v Veng (UK) Ltd [1988] ECR 6211 105, 123, 128, 1534,

171, 173

Community Commission Decisions


Case COMP/B2/39246 Boehringer [2007], not yet reported
63, 197
Commission Decision M.877 Boeing-McDonnell-Douglas, OJ 1997 C.59/877

192
Commission Decision Boosey & Hawkes, OJ 1987 L. 286/36
146, 157
Commission Decision British Midland/Aer Lingus, OJ 1992 L. 96/34
127,

130, 1567, 172
Commission Decision Ciba-GeigySandoz, OJ 1996 C.102/737
197
Commission Decision Crown Cork, OJ 1995 L. 75/39
192
Commission Decision Decca Navigator System, OJ 1989 L. 43/27 126, 127,

1556, 172, 173
Commission Decision DSD and others, OJ 2001 L. 319/1
104, 106
Commission Decision M.984 DuPont-ICI, OJ 1997 L. 2985
192
Commission Decision M.555 Glaxo-Wellcome and others, OJ 1995 L. 2985

192
Commission Decision IGR Stereo Television EC, in Comm XI Competition
Policy Report, 1982, p.63
150, 173
Commission Decision Info-Lab/Ricoh, in 1999 Competition Policy News
letter
165
Commission Decision Konsortium, OJ 1990 L. 228/31
192
Commission Decision London European-Sabena, OJ 1988 L. 317/47
126,

127, 154, 171, 173
Commission Decision in Case COMP/C-3/37.792 Microsoft [2004], not yet
reported
121, 137, 140, 142, 143, 169, 173
Commission Decision M.468 MSG-Media Services, OJ 1994 L. 364/01 192
Commission Decision Sea Containers v Stena Sealink, OJ 1994 L. 15/08

126, 127, 135, 1434, 158, 172, 173
Commission Decisions Shell-Montedison, OJ 1994 L. 332/49
192
Commission Press release IP/05/737, AstraZeneca
173, 188

xviii

Cases

International Case-law
Alejandro Moreno Alvarez v Estado Colombiano, SU.819/99, Corte
Constitucional de Colombia 1999, available at http://bob.minjusticia.gov.vo/
jurisprudencia/CorteConstitucional/1999/Tutela/su819-99.htm
81
Alvarez v Caja Costarricense de Seguro Social, Exp. 5778-V-97, No. 5934-97,
Sala Constitucional de la Corte Suprema de Justicia de Costa Rica 70, 81
Ceballos v Instituto de Seguros Sociales, T-484 Corte Constitucional de Colombia 1992, available at http://bib.minjusticia.gov.co/jurisprudencia/Corte
8081
Constitucional/1992/Tutela/T-48492.htm
Glenda Lopez v Instituto Venezolano de Seguros Sociales, 487-060401 Supreme
Court of Venezuela, Constitutional Chamber 1997, available at www.tsj.gov.
ve/decisiones/scon/Abril/487-060401-001343.htm
81
Minister of Health v Treatment Action Campaign, CCT 8/02 Constitutional
Court of South Africa, July 2002, available at www.tac.org.za/Documents

80
In The Matter Between Mpho Makhathnini, Nelislwe Mthethwa, Musa Msomi,
Elijah Paul Musoke, Tom Myers, AIDS Healthcare Foundation Limited, and
GlaxoSmithKline (Pty) Ltd, Glaxo Group Limited, Case Number 34/CR/
Apr04
98, 178, 197
Odir Miranda v El Salvador Case 12.249, Report No. 29/01, Inter-Am. CHR,
Annual Report 2000, OEA/Ser./L/V/II.111, Doc. 20 Rev. 2001 available at
www.cidh.oas.org/annualrep/2000eng/ChapterIII/Admissible/
ElSalvador12.249.htm
88
Pharmaceutical Wholesalers and Glaxo Wellcome, case 68/IR/Jun00, 18 June
2003 available at www.comptrib.co.za/decidedcases/pdf/68IRJUN00kinesis.
pdf
98, 178
Protection Writ. Judgment of Fabio Moron Diaz, Magistrado Ponente, T-328/98
Corte Constitucional de Colombia 1998, available at http://bib.minjusticia.
gov.vo/jurisprudencia/CorteConstitucional/1998/Tutela/T-328-98.htm 81
Social and Economic Rights Action Center v Nigeria, Communication 155/96
(African Commission on Human and Peoples Rights, Oct. 2001), available
at www.achpr.org/DECISIONS_30th_Session-_Oct.2001_eng.pdf
80
Street Children Case (Morales v Guatemala), Joint Concurring Opinion of
Judges A.A. Cancado Trinidade and A. Abreu-Burelli, Inter-Am. Ct H.R.
(Ser. C) No. 63, available at www.corteidh.or.cr/seriecing/VotocancadoabreuSerie_c_63_ing.doc
80

Cases

xix

US case-law
Akro Agate Co. v Master Marble Co. No. 119, District Court, N.D. West Virginia, 18 F. Supp. 305; 1937 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 2087, 16 January, 1937 45
American Home Products/American Cyanamid, American Home Prods Corp.,
FTC Docket No. C-3557 (1995)
191
Amgen Inc. v Chugai Pharmaceutical Co. 927 F. 2d 1200 (Fed. Cir. 2000) 48
Aspen Highlands Skiing Corp. v Aspen Skiing Co., 738 F.2d 1509 (10th Cir.
1984) affd on other grounds, 472 US 585 (1985)
133
Baxter/Immuno, Baxter Intl, Inc., 123 FTC 904 (1997)
191
BellSouth Advertising and Publishing Corp. v Donnelly Information Publishing,
Inc., 933 F.2d 952 (11th Cir. 1991), vacated, 977 F.2d 1435 (11th Cir. 1992),
and reversed en banc on other grounds, 999 F.2d 1436 (11th Cir. 1993), cert.
denied, 114 S. Ct. 943 (1994)
133
Ciba-Geigy/Sandoz, Ciba-Geigy Ltd, 123 FTC 842 (1997)
191
Consolidated Gas Co. of Florida v City Gas Co. of Florida, 880 F.2d 297 (11th
Cir. 1989)
133
Embrex Inc. v Service Engineering Corp 99-1064, US CAFC, 216 F.3d 1343;
2000 US App. LEXIS 15036; 55 USPQ2D (BNA) 1161, 28 June, 2000 44
Fishman v Wirtz, 807 F.2d 520 (7th Cir. 1986)
133
Glaxo/Burroughs Wellcome, Glaxo Inc., 119 FTC 815 (1995)
191
Graver Tank case 339 US 605 (1950)
48
Hecht v Pro-Football No. 2815-66, US Dist. Ct. for Distr. Of Columbia, 312 F.
Supp. 472; 1970 US Dist. LEXIS 12049; 1970 Trade Cas. (CCH) P73,170,
16 April,1970
1356
Hecht v Pro-Football, Inc., 570 F.2d 982 (D.C. Cir. 1977), cert. denied, 436 US
956 (1978)
133
Hoechst/Rhone-Poulenc, Hoechst AG, FTC Docket No. C-3929 (2000) 191
Howard Hughes case 366 F. 2d 303 (2nd Cir. 1966)
92
Madey v Duke 01-1567 US CA for Fed. Circ. 307 F.3d 1351
44
MCI Communications Group and MCI Telecommunications Corp. v American
Telephone and Telegraph 708 F.2d 1-81 (7th Cir. 1983)
133, 134
Pfizer/Warner-Lambert, Pfizer Inc., FTC Docket No. C-3957 (2000)
191
Roche/Genentech, Roche Holding Ltd, 113 FTC 1086 (1990)
191
Roche Products v Bolar Pharmaceutical Company 733 F.2d 858 (CA Fed.),
cert. denied, 469 US 856 (1984)
45
Sawin v Guild 21 F.Cas 554 (C.C.D. 1813) (No. 12,391)
44
Scripps Clinic and Research Found. v Genentech, 666 F. Supp. 1379 (N.D. Cal.
1987); 927 F.2d 1565 (Fed. Cir. 1991)
11, 48
Sensormatic/Knogo, Sensormatic Elec. Corp., FTC Docket No. C-3572
(1995)
191
Texas Inst. v ITC, 6 USPQ 2d 1886 (Fed. Cir. 1988)
34

xx

Cases

Time Inc. v Bernard Geis Associates NYLR, 21 January 1994, p.5 (CD Cal. 11
June 1993)
92
Upjohn/Pharmacia, The Upjohn Co. 121 FTC 44 (1996)
191
US v General Motors Corp., No. 93-530 (D. Del. Filed 23 March 1998) 191
US v Griffith 334 US 100 (1948)
133
US v Lockheed Martin and Northrop Grumman (DDC filed 23 March 1998)

191
US v Terminal Railroad Association of St. Louis, 224 US 383 (1912)
133
48
Westinghouse v Boyden Power Brake Co. 170 US 537 (1898)
Whittemore v Cutter 29 F. Cas 1120 (C.C.D. 1813)
44, 45
Wilson Sporting Goods v David Geoffrey and Associations, 904 F.2d 677 (Fed.
Cir. 1991)
48

EU national case-law
Ethofumesate Case, (1991) 22 IIC 541, 546 (Germany)
40
Frearson v Loe (1878) Ch.D. 48 (UK)
40, 43
Hollow plastic profiles II BGJ GRUR 1982, 301 (Germany)
16
Inhale Therapeutic Systems Inc v Quadrant Healthcare Plc [2002] RPC 21
(UK)
43
Klinische Versuche Federal Supreme Court (BGH), 11 July 1995, GRUR 1996,
109; 1997 IIC 103 (Germany)
42
LG Berlin (Photographs of Ulrike Meinhof) [1978] GRUR 108 (Germany) 92
Lili Marleen BGH, 7 March 1985 [1987] GRUR 34 (Germany)
92
Medicopharma N.V. et al. v ICI plc, 14 Rechtspraak van de week 7989 (1993),
(the Netherlands)
40
Monsanto v Stauffer [1985] RPC 515 CA (UK)
43
Sandisk Corporation v Koninklijke Phillips Electronics NV and Others [2007]
EWHC 332 Ch. (UK)
188
Scientology decision [2003] Mediaforum 337, note Visser; (2003) 6 AMI 217,
note Hugenholtz; (2003) 6 IER 352, note Grosheide. Appeal to the Supreme
Court pending (the Netherlands)
92
Smith Kline and French Laboratories Ltd v Evans Medical Ltd [1989] FSR 513
(UK)
43
Telegraaf case; Decision of director-general Dutch Competition Authority 10
September 1998, 1/501.o119 (Telegraaf v NOS/HMG); Trade and Industry
Appeals Tribunal 15 July 2004, www.rechtspraak.nl, LJN-nummer: AQ1727
(Netherlands)
140, 142
Zwangslizenz, Federal Supreme Court (BGH), 5 December 1995, GRUR [1996]
190; 24 IIC 397 (1993) (Germany)
423, 61

Part I

The problem access as a necessary element of


follow-on innovation?

1. Biopharmaceutical R&D: the


increased importance of cumulative
innovation and related concerns
We often talk about how important patents are to promote innovation, because without
patents, people dont appropriate the returns to their innovation activity, and I certainly very strongly subscribe to that On the other hand, some people jump from
that to the conclusion that the broader the patent rights are, the better it is for innovation, and that isnt always correct, because we have an innovation system in which
one innovation builds on another. If you get monopoly rights down at the bottom you
may stifle competition that uses those patents later on, and so the breadth and utilization of patent rights can be used not only to stifle competition, but also [can] have
adverse effects in the long run in innovation. We have to strike a balance.

1.1 Introduction
Recent changes in the nature of research in the biopharmaceutical industry have
given rise to new concerns regarding innovation. In the US, in particular, the
industry has become fragmented into a two-tier system, in which small biotech
firms carry out all of the innovative research, which the large pharmaceutical
companies then further develop, produce, prepare and market.
Much of the research carried out by small biotech firms involves upstream
innovative research that is fundamental to the development of downstream research on products and processes. Hence, research has increasingly become
dependent on access to other fundamental upstream research.


J.E. Stiglitz before the FTC Hearings on Global and Innovation-Based Competition, 12 October 1995; also quoted in D.A. Valentine, Abuse of Dominance in Relation
to Intellectual Property: US Perspectives and the Intel Cases, at the Israel International
Antitrust Law Conference, 15 November, 1999 at http://www.ftc.gov/speeches/other/
dvisraelin.htm.

J. Walsh and J. Cohen, Research Tool Patenting and Licensing and Biomedical
Innovation, in Cohen and SMerill (eds), Patents in the Knowledge-Based Society, Washington DC, National Academies Press (2003), p.285; A. Gambardella et al. Global
Competitiveness in Pharmaceutical Industry (2002).

Ibid. See OECD, The Pharmaceutical Industry, Paris (2001).

Access as a necessary element of follow-on innovation?

Unlike most industries where innovation involves improving upon a first


product, in the biopharmaceutical industry, most cumulative innovation occurs
in the pre-commercial stage, before the initial marketable product is produced.
Once a marketable product has been developed, it is usually only subject to
competition by me-too drugs or generics, and not subject to significant improvements in the end-product market. It is important, for this reason, to ensure that
cumulative innovation in the pre-commercial stage is not impeded. This is significant as it may otherwise lead to a limitation in the paths to biomedical
research.
The recent increase in patenting in the biotechnological field has raised
several concerns regarding the potential implications for healthcare. For example, the grant of a patent over the BRCA1 gene raised concerns that the
patent would hamper innovation and the identification of new tests and diagnostic methods, impairing equitable access to testing and the public health
approach.
Related to this, was the concern that patents are sometimes granted in cases
too broadly to even cover unanticipated utilities, which may hamper further research. Hence, the CCR5 Receptor gene used in research for HIV/AIDS drugs
spurred concerns regarding the reasonableness of rewarding estimations of util-


R.K. Rai, Fostering Cumulative Innovation in the Biopharmaceutical Industry:
The Role of Patents and Antitrust, 16 Berkeley Tech Law Journal 813 (2001).

Ibid. The author notes that an exception to this is where the patented drug is not
a traditional small molecule chemical, but rather, a biologic (e.g. protein or macromolecule) and the improver has come up with a method to produce the biologic that is
drastically different.

Ibid. p.813. Competition is perceived to be a driving force and to allow multiple
independent research paths that are important for creative development.

Biotechnology Industry Organization: Editors & Reporters Guide to Biotechnology (Feb. 2000), available at www.bio.org/aboutbio/guide2000/facts.html shows, for
example, that in the USA biotechnology patenting escalated from 2,000 patents issued
in 1985 to more than 9,000 patents issued in 1998. See also Report of the National Institutes of Health NIH, Working Group on Research Tools, presented to the Advisory
Committee to the Director, 4 June 1998, referring to an increasing use of the patent
system to obtain proprietary rights in research tools.

The BRCA1 gene indicates susceptibility to breast cancer. Its discovery was reported by Myriad Genetics and Utah University in 1994, and ever since the gene and its
mutations have been part of numerous patent applications. See Nuffield Council on
Bioethics, The Ethics of Patenting DNA, 2001 Case Studies, pp.3940.

This led to a Resolution from the European Parliament in October 2001 opposing
the patenting of the BRCA1 gene. Resolutions B5-0633, 0641, 0651 and 0663/2001 on
the patenting of BRCA1 and BRCA2 (breast cancer) genes OJ 2002 C 87/265. R. Dalp,
L. Bouchard, A-J. Houle, L. Bdard, Watching the race to find the breast cancer genes,
28(2) Science, Technology, and Human Values 187216 (2002); Nuffield (2001) op. cit.
pp.3940.

Biopharmaceutical R&D

ity, and the effect that such patents may have on research if they are not licensed
extensively.10
While in the 1980s upstream innovative research was mainly governmentsponsored research, with the rise in privatisation this came into the hands of
private firms who were able to exclude others from their findings. As more
stages, actors and inter-connectiveness complemented the drug development
process, patenting made commercial sense where before there was nothing to
patent.11
These two trends immediately raised fears that patents would deter innovation. In an article published in Science magazine, Heller and Eisenberg
postulated a theory that too many patents on upstream innovation could lead to
two eventualities.12
First, the granting of too many fragmented patents may lead to a situation
identified as the tragedy of the anti-commons, whereby too many people have
the right to exclude and no one has an effective right to use; this means that one
can impede others from using his technology but is also impeded from using
the technology himself by the rights of exclusion of others. The creation of too
many fragmented and overlapping patent rights could lead to high transaction
costs, which, coupled with the heterogeneous interests of owners and the cognitive biases of researchers,13 could make bargaining unlikely in most cases,
leading to the creation of fewer products and to less innovation.
The second eventuality postulated is that the granting of patents for fundamental upstream research could lead to a situation whereby patent owners stack
licenses on top of future discoveries of downstream users, and/or impede the
creation of downstream-dependent inventions.14
Heller and Eisenberg did not present scientific data to support their theory.
The degree to which research is fragmented and dependent on too many other
patents depends on many other factors including the breadth of the grant of the
patent, the nature of the research and the extent to which it is cumulative or

10

Ibid. p.41.
While inventions were made, patents were not taken out.
12
M.A. Heller and R. Eisenberg, Can Patents Deter Innovation? Anti-commons in
Biomedical Research, 280 Science 698, 1 May 1998.
13
This refers to a situation whereby every patent holder over-estimates his position
and the value of his patents, therefore, it is difficult to reach an agreement on licences.
14
R. Eisenberg Bargaining Over the Transfer of Proprietary Research Tools, in R.
Dreyfuss et al., Expanding the Boundaries of Intellectual Property, Oxford, Oxford
University Press (2001). op. cit. See also R. Eisenberg, Technology Transfer and the
Genome Project: Problems with Patenting of Research Tools, 5 RISK 163 (1994), p.168,
which states that: the stacking of intellectual property obligations as successive tools
are used in the course of an extended research project has the potential to impede or even
preclude the development of new and better diagnostic and therapeutic products.
11

Access as a necessary element of follow-on innovation?

discrete, and the bargaining power of the players. However, no evidence was
given in support of these factors.
Thereafter, Walsh and Cohen15 attempted to test these hypotheses against
more scientific data. They found that while there is an increase in the patents
on inputs to the discovery of the drug, the discovery was not substantially impeded except in the case of patented genetic diagnostics.
With regard to the anti-commons, more specifically, they found that while
there may be some delays in negotiating access and that negotiations could be
costly, there was no evidence of bargaining breakdowns or of a real threat of
royalty stacking or a failure to undertake projects on this basis. However, the
approximately 33 per cent increase in the transaction costs for filing, enforcing
and contracting for patents may make a difference between entering or not entering such negotiations, depending on the size of the firm. They also found that
working solutions such as licensing, inventing around the patents, challenging
patents and relying on the goodwill and information sharing between companies,
nonetheless, constitute important tools for advancing research.16
Walsh and Cohen were less conclusive, however, on the issue of restricted
access to upstream discoveries and its effects on innovation. They found that
access to foundational discoveries can be restricted, and that patents over targets
may limit access in certain cases.17 Depending on the breadth of the interpretation and the capacity of a firm to market in a timely fashion, the lack of access
might lead to less innovation. In particular, in the case of targets, this might be
problematic depending on the breadth and degree of restriction compared to the
incentive necessary to invest in the first place. The effect of control upon such
discoveries will depend, first, on how essential it is for subsequent innovation,
and secondly, on the degree of rivalness in use of the first and subsequent products as this will, in turn, determine the motives for refusing access or not.18
Although such concerns have arisen, there is not much scientific evidence to
support one finding over another.19 Does the existence of many patents hinder

15

J. Walsh and J. Cohen (2003) op. cit.


Ibid. See also J. Holzapfel et al. (2002) op. cit.; E.G. Campbell et al. (2002) op.
cit.; C. Lawson, (2002) op. cit.
17
Ibid.
18
Ibid.
19
D. Nicol and J. Nielsen, Patents and Medical Biotechnology: An Empirical Analysis of Issues Facing Australian Industry, Centre for Law and Generics Occasional Paper
No. 6 (2003). It is stated that it is quite difficult to obtain quantitative data on the number
of projects abandoned. It may be that this will occur because of patent thickets and
perceived future negotiating difficulties (i.e. anti-commons issues). However, we do acknowledge that projects will be abandoned or redirected for a whole host of reasons, and
these may often be more to do with the intrinsic value and likelihood of success of the
technology than the level of encumbrance.
16

Biopharmaceutical R&D

the development of products related to health care? Do upstream patents deter


further innovation and is exclusion really a problem? This concern has been
heightened in the case of research tools.20

1.2 The case of research tools


1.2.1 Defining Research Tools
The term research tools has many meanings depending on the perspective.
Researchers who use them in the laboratory may view them as tools, whereas
firms who primarily manufacture and sell these resources may consider them
end products.21
In their broadest sense, research tools embrace the full range of resources
that scientists use in the laboratory22 including cell lines, monoclonal antibodies, reagents, animal models, growth factors, combinatorial chemistry libraries,
drugs and drug targets, clones and cloning tools, methods, laboratory equipment
and machines, databases and computer software.23
Hence, they can be sequences used in research with no immediate therapeutic
or diagnostic value. In this sense, they are a means to develop a commercial
product such as a medicine or a vaccine, but not an end product sold directly to
consumers. Research tools are licensed for particular sequences or applied to
discover drugs or other research, and in this way, may realise a commercial
value. They are a typical example of upstream innovation required to develop
downstream innovation. For example, the EST approach involving the rapid
sequencing of the coding parts of genes was used as a means to locate entire
genes.
A high percentage of the basic research tools of biotechnology are subject to
proprietary restraints (such as patents) or material transfer agreements. 24 Patent

20
Though focus is on the case of research tools, it may be that they are only an illustration of a more general concern also present in other cases. See Chapter 7 for
discussion of Pharmacy Benefits Management (PBM) networks.
21
NIH Report on Research Tools (1998) op. cit. and J.M. Mueller, No Dilettante
Affair: Rethinking the Experimental Use Exception to Patent Infringement for Biomedical
Research Tools, 76 Wash. L. Rev. 1 (2001), p.10.
22
NIH Report on Research Tools (1998) op. cit. p.3.
23
Ibid. See also G. Cullem, Panning for Biotechnology Gold: Reach-Through Royalty Damage Awards for Infringing Uses of Patented Molecular Sleeves, 29 IDEA 533
(1999).
24
J.M. Mueller (2001) op. cit. p.11. A material transfer agreement (MTA) is a negotiated contract between the owner of a material and a party that seeks to use it for
research.

Access as a necessary element of follow-on innovation?

protection is deemed necessary for such tools to recover the high cost of their
development.25 The biotechnological research environment is complicated by
the fact that researchers need access to several research tools to conduct their
research.26
Some of the most important research tools include:27

The Cohen-Boyer Patents covering the basic method and plasmids for
gene cloning.28
l Polymerase chain reaction technology (PCR), a basic method of amplifying DNA sequences and its key reagent, the enzyme Taq DNA
polymerase.29 The PCR selectively multiplies a region of DNA so that it
can be experimented on and analysed.
l The Harvard oncomouse useful in cancer research.30
l Expressed sequence tags (ESTs) identified in decoding the human genome. These are a fragment of complementary DNA (cDNA) and are
useful in finding the full-length gene.31

25
S.A. Chambers, Comments on the Patentability of Certain Inventions Associated
with the Identification of Partical CDNA Sequences, 23 AIPLA Q.J. 53 (1995); M.A.
Flores, Taking the Profits out of Biomedical Research Tools, 17 Nature Biotechnology
819 (1999).
26
See S. Junnarkar, GeneChip Encodes DNA on Silicon, N.Y. Times, 15 March
1997, describing DNA chips that offer a myriad of potential applications for studying
genes and diagnosing genetic mutations. On these chips more than 40,000 sequences
may be attached, and if each of these is covered by a patent, licensing will prove to be
exceedingly difficult.
27
J.M. Mueller (2001) op. cit. pp.1214.
28
This research tool has been extensively licensed. See R.K. Seide and J.M. McLeod,
Response to Policy Commentary, SCIENCE at www.sciencemag.org/feature/data/980465/
seide.shl.
29
This was initially owned by the Cetus Corporation.
30
The patent was assigned by Leder-Stewart to Harvard University who exclusively
licensed it to E.I. du Pont de Nemours. See J.M. Mueller (2001) op. cit. p.13.
31
Ibid. pp.1314. See also R.S. Eisenberg and R.P. Merges, Opinion Letter as to
the Patentability of Certain Inventions Associated with the Identification of Partical
cDNA Sequences, 23 AIPLA Q.J. 1 (1995). There has been some debate on whether
ESTs are truly research tools. See R. Blackburn, Chief Patent Counsel, Chiron Corporation, remarks at the National Academies Board of Science, Technology and Economic
Policys Conference on Intellectual Property Rights: How Far Should They Be Extended?
Washington DC, 3 February (2000).

Biopharmaceutical R&D

1.2.2 The Patent Experience in Biotechnology: Biomedical Research


Tools
The thermostable enzyme Thermus aquaticus YTI DNA polymerase (Taq) is a
basic and widely used biotechnology tool.32 In 1995, Hoffman-La-Roche accused more than 40 US universities and research institutes and more than 200
scientists of infringing its patents.33 The alleged wrongdoing involved the purchase of Taq for use in the PCR process34 from a company which, according to
Roche, was not licensed to sell Taq for such use.35 Roches attempts to restrict
the use of Taq and PCR provoked great alarm, which were described as violating practices and principles basic to the advancement of knowledge for the
public welfare.36
The possibility that this large number of actors would be found guilty of infringement triggered a whole debate on the patenting of research tools and the
implications for technological and medical progress.37 Coupled with the increase
in patenting in recent years,38 the use of these biomedical tools to advance R&D
for new drugs and therapies, diagnostic methods and other therapeutic products
and the heightened difficulties in their access and dissemination have continued
to trouble the research community.
In essence, the dispute involves the broad rights stemming from patents on
such tools, but is also complicated by other factors and determinants such as
the definition of infringement, transaction costs, proliferation complications and
licensing practices.39 According to the Nuffield Report:

32

J.M. Mueller (2001) op. cit. p.2.


M.C. Aguilera, Local Institutes Named in Lawsuit, San Diego Daily Transcript,
25 May (1995); M. Barinaga, Scientists Named in PCR Suit, 268 Science 1273 (1995).
34
PCR refers to the polymerase chain reaction, the revolutionary DNA amplification
process using Taq. Taq allows the PCR process to be automated. The latter consists of
multiplying a specific region of DNA, producing quantities of DNA sufficient for experimentation and analysis. See J.M. Mueller (2001) op. cit. p.3. See also K. Drlica,
Understanding DNA and Gene Cloning: A Guide for the Curious, New York: Wiley edn,
3rd edn (1997), pp.1537, (4th edn 2003); P. Rabinow, Making PCR: A story of Biotechnology, Chicago, University of Chicago Press (1996), pp.12832.
35
J.M. Mueller (2001) op. cit.
36
Hoffman-La-Roche Challenges Freedom of Researcher; List of Infringers Includes Hundreds of Researchers and Dozens of Government-Supported Laboratories,
Bus. Wire, 24 May (1995).
37
J.M. Mueller (2001) op. cit.; B. Rubenstein, La Roche and Promega in Tug of War
Over Enzyme; DNA-Testing Tool Patent at Issue, Corp. Legal Times, Jan. 1996, at 15.
38
Nuffield Report (2001) op. cit.
39
In addition, the narrow interpretation of some of the working solutions such as
the experimental use exemption, aggravates the situation. See Chapter 3.
33

10

Access as a necessary element of follow-on innovation?


There are various ways in which patents on DNA sequences which have a primary
use as research tools may inhibit innovation and development: the cost of research
may increase, as the grant of increasing numbers of patents will mean that ever more
licenses are required before research can be conducted; research may, as a matter of
practice, be made more difficult if researchers are required first to negotiate the use
of patented genes and sequences; a patent owner may withhold a license to gain
maximum financial benefits, or license it exclusively to one or a limited number of
licensees; companies that wish to acquire the rights to several DNA sequences may
decide not to develop a therapeutic protein or diagnostic test because of the number
of royalty payments that would be required (this is sometimes referred to as
royalty-stacking).40

Hence, there is a concern regarding the breadth of the patent on such tools. The
Nuffield Institute of Biotechnology concluded that the law is generous in granting patents to DNA sequences, as they are broad in scope (covering all of the
uses of DNA obtained and sometimes protein DNA produces) and/or are granted
when the criteria for inventiveness and utility are weakly applied. This is because the patent system provides that in the case of patents directed to novel
and inventive DNA and other chemical entities, inventors are entitled to property
rights not only over the uses of their invention that they anticipated or predicted,
but also over new uses that are developed. The case studies also reveal that some
patent offices have been willing to adopt low thresholds for inventiveness and
utility.41
In the case of diagnostic tests, the problem has been highlighted as the fact
that excessively broad patents containing a claim to all conceivable diagnostic
tests create a monopoly such that there is little incentive to develop improved
tests.42 A study has shown that almost half of the research laboratories surveyed
ceased to pursue research on genetic testing because of the patents on DNA sequences.43 Another study is also quoted, which proved that 30 per cent of the
laboratories discontinued or did not develop genetic testing for haemochromatosis because of exclusive licensing of patents that asserted rights over the most
common mutation in gene involved.44
40

Nuffield Report (2001) op. cit.


Ibid. p.47.
42
Ibid. para. 5.14.
43
See M.K. Cho, Ethical and Legal Issues in the 21st Century, in Preparing for the
Millennium: Laboratory Medicine in the 21st century, Washington DC, AACC Press,
2nd edn, 1998, pp.4763.
44
See J.F. Metz, et al., Diagnostic testing fails the test, 415 Nature 5779, (2002).
Metz produces some evidence that individual researchers may have terminated individual
research projects as a consequence of property disputes. On the other hand, L. Bendekgey
and D. Hamlet-Cox, Gene Patents and Innovation, 77 Academic Medicine 1373 (2002),
argue that the evidence does not indicate any aggregate reduction in biological research
as a consequence of gene patenting.
41

Biopharmaceutical R&D

11

Other patents, it is felt, are granted without being warranted. Genetic information was initially found to be patentable as it was thought that by isolating it or
producing it through a technological process, the required threshold of not existing in nature had been satisfied. This, however, is now being questioned as there
may no longer be a need for cloning in order to identify a DNA sequence and
that identification may be achieved by computer databases.45
In addition, patents confer broad rights to the owner as he can prevent others
from using the patented invention without distinction as to the nature or the
purpose of the use. Products developed through the use of the invention may
be found infringing even though they do not involve the sale of the patented
invention.46 The interpretation of the breadth of the patent as regards infringing
activity can be determinative, and can shift the balance one way or the
other.47
Hence, the broad interpretation of infringing activity by the courts may aggravate the perceived broad nature (relative to disclosure) of such patent rights.
The lax application of the patentability requirements may lead to unjustified

45
See Nuffield Report (2001) op. cit. para. 6.4. We have considered the question
of whether DNA sequences should be eligible for patenting. Even though we think that
the judgment that isolated DNA sequences are eligible for patenting is based on a questionable extrapolation to the case of genetic information from the case of the isolation
of chemical compounds, we accept that a limited number of the early patents granted on
the basis need not now be called into question, in view of the inventiveness required to
isolate the DNA sequences. Since the early days of the pioneering experiments using
positional cloning techniques, patents have been filed on many DNA sequences which
were mass produced by a mixture of computational and cloning techniques. Even if it
can be convincingly argued that these sequences were eligible for patenting, the patents
should be examined in the light of the criteria for inventiveness and utility. We note that
as techniques have advanced, and in particular as the use of computers to identify genes
has become more widespread, the eligibility of DNA sequences for patenting should
have diminished.
46
J.M. Mueller (2001) op. cit. p.5. Use liability arises under the patent laws even
though the researcher has not physically incorporated the patented tool into the new
product that is ultimately marketed. The selling prohibition has not been violated because the research tool is not incorporated in the commercial product.
47
In the USA, in Scripps Clinic and Research Foundation v Genentech, 666 F. Supp.
1379 (N.D. Cal. 1987) the Federal Circuit found a patent infringement by virtue of the
production of the same protein by recombinant means, refusing to construe product
claims to include inherent process limitations. It found that product by process claims
are not limited to products prepared by the process set forth in the claims. The decision
reflects two antagonistic results, creating possible process-related exceptions to infringement of a product claim that on its face, makes no reference to any process parameters,
while reading process limitations out of a claim that expressly recites them. Y. Ko, An
Economic Analysis of Biotechnology Patent Protection, 102 Yale Law Journal 777
(1992).

12

Access as a necessary element of follow-on innovation?

grants or extensions in scope which heighten the risk of restricted research tool
access when coupled with a wide interpretation of infringement.48 Accordingly,
Art. 9 and Recital 25 of the Biotechnology Directive recognise that in determining the scope of protection of corresponding claims, there may be an overlap in
an essential part of the invention.49
1.2.3 The Effect of Patent Trends on the Patent Balance for Research
Tools
The effect of the issues raised above on the research community and more generally on innovation, however, is unclear. While the existing case studies have
not shown a recognisable problem with access to upstream research tools,50
some commentators believe that this is becoming a growing concern.51

48
In a joint article of the President of the US National Academy of Sciences and the
President of the Royal Society of London, both EU and US researchers admonish that
those who patent DNA sequences without real knowledge of their utility are stacking
claims not only to what little they know at present but also to everything that might later
be discovered about genes and protein associated with the sequence. They are in effect
laying claim to a function that is not yet known or a use that does not yet exist. This may
be in current shareholders interests, but it does not always serve society well. D. Gitter,
International Conflicts over Patenting Human DNA Sequences in the US and the EU:
An Argument for Compulsory Licensing and the Fair Use Exemption, 76 NYUL Rev.
1623 (2001), p.1642.
49
Recital 25 provides: Whereas, for the purposes of interpreting rights conferred
by a patent, when sequences overlap only in parts which are not essential to the invention,
each sequence will be considered as an independent sequence in patent law terms. Biotech Directive (1998) op. cit.
See also Vossiues and Partner, The Patenting and Enforcement of Inventions Relating
to Research Tools: Chances and Problems, at www.vossiusandpartner.com/eng/publication/pub-patenting_and_enforcement.html. As regards ESTs and SNPs, they might be
considered essential as a whole. However, for partial DNA sequences it may become
relevant to distinguish between coding and non-coding sequences.
50
See, for example, the case of recombinant DNA, in which the patented research
tool was non-exclusively licensed with low fees, the case of PCR and TAQ Polymerase,
in which licensing arrangements were controversial, and the case of protein and DNA
sequencing instruments, in which strong patent protection promoted broad access, in R.
Eisenberg, Patenting Research Tools and the Law, in IPRs and Research Tools in Molecular Biology, Summary of Workshop Held at the National Academies of Sciences,
1516 February 1996.
51
See I.N. Feit, Biotechnology Research and the Experimental Use Exception to
Patent Infringement, 71 J. Pat. & Trademark Off. Socy 819 (1989) p.821, predicting
that as commercial products of biotechnology become available, the infringement of
patents covering the basic research methods that led to the product will become an increasingly difficult problem. See also L. Nelsen, The Rise of Intellectual Property
Protection in the American University, 279 Science 1460 (1998). Nelsen describes the

Biopharmaceutical R&D

13

Opinion differs in the pharmaceutical industry as to the effect of this on the discovery
of new medicines. Some companies take the view that the additional costs incurred
through the need to take out large numbers of licenses on DNA sequences for use in
research are not significant. Others consider that the costs incurred are already having
a significant impact on profit markets. These differences of view most likely reflect
the extent to which individual companies own patents that assert rights over DNA
sequences. Access to research tools based on DNA sequences may indeed prove to
be difficult and expensive unless the patents that protect them are licensed easily and
widely.52

In the least grave of cases, evidence has shown that such patents may lead to
more costly negotiations, which might make the difference for small firms between being on and off the market.53 The increasingly high transaction costs are
becoming a real problem and might pose a barrier to researchers and hence act
as an effective lack of access. The stacking of intellectual property obligations
as successive tools are used in the course of an extended research project has
the potential to impede or even preclude the development of new and better diagnostic and therapeutic products.54 This situation also results in increases in
secrecy and delays in research.55
Altogether this leads to a heightened concern among scientists regarding the
high prices and burdensome licensing conditions associated with research
tools.56 Numerous upstream patents must be practised to make a new down-

restricted availability or delays in exchange of research tools (such as vectors or


transgenic mice in biological research as one of the problems that universities face,
pp.146061.
52
Nuffield Report (2001) op. cit. pp.5960. See also R. Eisenberg (2001) op. cit.
p.223 who claims that one of the difficulties in the biopharmaceutical industry in concluding transactions is the heterogeneity among the institutions. The universities,
pharmaceutical firms and biotechnology firms each have different expectations. For example, in biotechnology, the emergence of commercial biotechnology firms in market
niches can be seen. These firms lie somewhere in between fundamental academic research and end product development. They are also most likely to depend on the
commercialisation and the financial value of the research tools as they lack end products
for sale to non-research consumers.
Even within a single institution the interests may be different between the scientists,
lawyers and business people involved in the negotiations.
53
See Should Congress Liberate Gene Data? Chi. Trib., 16 September, 1999, Holders of genetic patents have been charging steep licensing fees for use of their information
and sending cease and desist notices to competing companies, academic medical
centres and clinical laboratories that use it without permission.
54
NIH Report on Research Tools (1998) op. cit. p.22.
55
OECD, Genetic Inventions, IPRs and Licensing Practices: Evidence and Policies,
Paris (2002).
56
J.M. Mueller (2001) op. cit. p.8. See also E. Marshall, A Deluge of Patents Creates
Legal Hassles for Research, 288 Science 255 (2000), pp.2557.

14

Access as a necessary element of follow-on innovation?

stream product, thus leading to a problem of royalty stacking.57 Patents on


research tools can create obstacles to subsequent research and development
and add to a thicket of rights that firms must negotiate their way past before
they can get their products on the market.58
In the case of clinical use, protection appears to have impeded access to information and therefore concern has been raised over the high costs and limited
access to genetic testing. In 1999, a survey showed that almost all patents were
licensed exclusively. This could mean, in practice, that they are offered at prohibitive costs, thus impeding the provision of genetic testing services.59 Genetic
testing for a predisposition to diseases and early diagnosis is an issue of great
importance and restrictions on its availability may raise ethical concerns. Hence,
it has often been said that patents have a negative impact on access, the costs
and quality of testing and on information sharing between researchers.60
It is difficult to assess the frequency of access issues and their effect on R&D
and so whether the problem is occasional or systematic is unclear. An empirical
study of German inventions and the patent system concluded that there is a
proliferation of DNA patents and unduly broad patents causing a situation in
which patents are dependent on earlier inventions, which may cause a reluctance
to enter certain fields in which genes have already been patented and that royalty
stacking and higher transaction costs are present, leading to an explosion of legal
disputes and potential delays in innovation.61 Hence, the existence of patents
may lead to a redirection of research in other fields if it is perceived that dependency might be avoided.
It should be clarified, however, that research tool patents are not viewed in
all cases as an obstacle to research. In some cases, research tools have been
treated as staple goods that can be easily purchased, even without disclosure of

57
R. Eisenberg (2001) op. cit. Reach-through licensing terms attempt to govern
rights to potential future inventions made by the user of the research tool. In this way,
the tool owners try to leverage their proprietary rights in early innovations in order to
have a share in the profits of future innovations. However, if there are too many pre-commitments to future products, this may cause difficulties and complicate the situation by
virtue of the licence of several research tools.
58
R.S. Eisenberg (1994) op. cit. p.168.
59
Ibid.
60
Nuffield Report (2001) op. cit. p.69; However, in genetic tests, it was also found
that exclusive licensing might be necessary to the additional investment needed to develop and test the potential economic viability of the product.
61
J. Strauss, Genetic Inventions and Patent Law, at OECD Workshop on Genetic
Inventions, IPRs and Licensing Practices: Evidence and Policies, Paris, 2002. See also
Should Congress Liberate Gene Data? (1999) op. cit. which states that rather than risk
a lawsuit or pay fees they consider exorbitant, some researchers have stopped exploring
diseases whose genetic profiles already have been licensed.

Biopharmaceutical R&D

15

intended use. Some proprietary research tools have been widely distributed
under license agreements that permit subsequent research to go forward while
preserving a return for the patent owner.62 In such cases, for example in the
case of the Cohen-Boyer patent on recombinant DNA technology,63 there has
been no problem with regard to access.
In addition, practical considerations may be used to allay the concerns raised
by research tool patenting. First, pre-issuance use of the patent between the time
of publication and the time of the granting might be possible, although damages
might be available for this purpose.64 Policing is also quite difficult, therefore it
has been suggested that, in view of the difficulty in negotiating something speculative, some firms could use the patented research tools without a licence,
assuming that they can settle the matter once, and if, they discover something
meaningful.65 In addition, while it constitutes an infringement to import a product
made by a patented process in the USA as long as the product made abroad has
not been materially changed, it is unclear whether a process claim which covers
the screening of a drug would be infringed by the importation of the data resulting
from the screening process.66 As the detection of the use of a research tool may
not occur until a commercialised product has been developed, it may even be
possible to escape any liability whatsoever due to the statute of limitations.67

62

R. Eisenberg (2001) op. cit. p.229.


This was owned jointly by Stanford University and the University of California
and constituted a fundamental technology which was useful for research into a range of
problems. The terms of its licence permitted its wide dissemination and use. See Intellectual Property Rights and the Dissemination of Research Tools in Molecular Biology,
Summary of a Workshop held at the National Academies of Sciences, 1516 February,
1996 (1997), pp.4042.
64
J.A. Goldstein, Patenting the Tools of Drug Discovery, Drug Discovery World,
Summer 2001, p.9. See also Art. 67 EPC which states that from the date of publication
of a European patent application, the applicant can claim compensation reasonable in
the circumstances from any person who has used the invention in the said State in circumstances where that person would be liable under national law for infringement of a
national patent.
65
R. Eisenberg (2001) op. cit. p.233. Though this may be becoming increasingly
difficult in view of the recent US decision that allows for the initiation of litigation based
on a previous request for information from the potential defendant. J.A. Goldstein (2001)
op. cit. p.9.
66
J.A. Goldstein (2001) op. cit. p.9. In addition, in the US and now in the EU there
is immunity for infringement when it is done in pursuit of regulatory approval for the drug.
Yet it is not clear whether a patented receptor of software used in the pursuit of regulatory
approval for a drug would be immune under the clinical research exemption. The issue in
such a case would be that the material for which approval is sought (the drug) is not the
patented invention for which the immunity is sought (the target or the software).
67
In Germany section 141 PatG provides that claims for infringement lapse after
three years from the time when the claimant obtains knowledge of the infringement and
63

16

Access as a necessary element of follow-on innovation?

1.3 Conclusion
In conclusion, in view of the increasingly cumulative nature of innovation, a
concern has been raised regarding the proliferation of patents, which may impede access to essential technology and, as a result, hinder innovation.
More specifically, the case of research tools was examined as it captures the
essence of the concern in relation to follow-on/downstream innovation in the
biopharmaceutical industry and striking the patent balance. Research tools have
been at the centre of these discussions, although the problems in this area might
simply represent an instance of what might be a more general problem.
Practical evidence confirms that patents have been extended both in subject
matter and in scope, and this may often be seen as unjustified by the research
community. As patents, by definition, involve a degree of exclusivity, their very
grant is bound to affect access to the patented technology. Where their grant is
unjustified or overbroad, lack of access is bound to be seen as unwarranted.
While it is felt that this may in turn lead to the hindering of innovation, there
has been no evidence to date produced which unambiguously establishes a clear
negative effect on innovation.
The main concern relates to the increased transaction costs68 and the difficulty
in reaching licensing agreements.69 More specifically, regarding the issue of
exclusion, current practice shows broad licensing patterns in most cases. Nevertheless, there is still some concern in the industry that access to essential

of the identity of the infringer. Bearing in mind that damages are only high enough to
merit instituting legal proceedings after a new pharmaceutical compound is successfully
put on the market, this is unlikely as it normally takes more than three years to get approval for a pharmaceutical compound. (It might, however, be possible to claim damages
in license analogy for unjustified enrichment, whose limitation period is 30 years, although the Federal Supreme Court held that, in this case, damages can only amount to
a reasonable royalty. BGH GRUR 1982, 301 Hollow plastic profiles II).
See also the UK statute of limitations barring infringement actions after six years and
the equitable doctrine of laches which might estop the patent proprietor from bringing
an action in the first place.
68
This may stem from the proliferation of patents, the need to negotiate with a wide
range of people or from other factors associated with the need to negotiate access to upstream patents such as exclusion or high prices.
69
See R. Eisenberg (2001) op. cit. pp.23247. Eisenberg attributes this to the following four factors: (1) the fact that transaction costs are a greater obstacle in low-value
exchanges and might be inhibited; (2) the heterogeneity among institutions leading to
complications in reaching agreeable terms of exchange; (3) the differences amongst
agents in institutions such as between scientists and lawyers and business people; and
(4) the fact that the evaluation of research tools involves an estimation of their contribution to potential future discoveries which is a highly speculative and subjective
process.

Biopharmaceutical R&D

17

upstream technology may be refused and it is felt that this may impact negatively
on innovation.70 Whether this should be seen as a systematic failure in the patent
system, or simply as individual instances of restricted access, is not clear.
The industry also attributes the lack of evidence of a discernible impact on
innovation to the existence of working solutions, however, it is not clear what
these solutions involve or how the situation would differ in their absence.71 In
addition, as one of the working solutions is infringement, it could be questioned
whether it is sensible to have a system that relies on encouraging infringement.
Despite the ambiguous nature of the evidence on the purported lack of access
and its impact on innovation, industry participants still feel that this is a problem
that needs to be addressed. Burgeoning research and development will require
ever-greater numbers of proprietary tools, giving rise to transaction costs associated with acquiring the right to use each such tool. In some cases, the patentee
may refuse to license the research tool altogether. The sum total of the transaction costs involved with acquisition of all necessary research tools may be so
severe as to impede, postpone, or stop the development of important new
products.72
The Nuffield Committee has admonished:
There is insufficient evidence to judge the extent to which the granting of patents that
assert rights over DNA sequences based on a primary use as research tools is producing the potentially deleterious effects set out above. However, we take the view that
the exercise of a monopoly over what are now essentially discoveries of genetic information accessible by routine methods is, in principle, highly undesirable. We
consider that the development of a culture among those who carry out scientific research, whereby claims are made to naturally-occurring material which can be
isolated by routine procedures and to which a weakly demonstrated or hypothetical
utility may be ascribed to secure some possible future value, if endorsed by the patent
offices, amounts to a misapplication of the patent system. We consider, therefore, that
in general, the granting of patents which assert rights over DNA sequences as research
tools should be discouraged.

This report also recommended that wide licences should be encouraged.


In view of the above discussion, the next chapter considers the significance
that striking the balance correctly assumes in the biopharmaceutical industry,

70
See NIH Report on Research Tools (1998) op. cit. which lists refusal to license
as one of the key concerns in the area of research tools. The definition of obstacles includes: refusals to license, onerous royalty obligations, restrictions on the dissemination
of materials and information restrictions on the ability to collaborate with commercial
firms, and advance commitments regarding intellectual property rights in future discoveries, p.4.
71
J. Walsh and J. Cohen (2003) op. cit. p.290.
72
J.M. Mueller (2001) op. cit. pp.67.

18

Access as a necessary element of follow-on innovation?

and the mechanisms available within the patent system to encourage wide licences and to reduce the problem of transaction costs in the area of research
tools.

Part II

The patent balance and working solutions in the


patent system

2. The patent system as a system of


balancing
2.1 The Patent Balance
The patent system is an integrated means of addressing public policy concerns.
It is concerned with encouraging the R&D of new intellectual products that
would otherwise remain undeveloped or under-developed due to the ease of
appropriability of knowledge and the difficulty in excluding others. While its
main objective is to encourage innovation, it also has competing interests to
address.

Box 2.1: Main rationales of patent


system
1. Invention motivation. The patent system provides incentives for
investment in innovation by granting a limited monopoly that
allows the inventor the opportunity to make a profit on the invention. This is the most common rationale for the patent
system and its justification is usually based on the market failure rationale. In the absence of the government grant of
property rights, it is argued that the competitive market would
not give a sufficient incentive to induce the optimal amount of
innovation. This is because knowledge could be described as
a durable, indivisible, and non-rival commodity. While the costs
of production are high, the costs of imitation and reproduction
are low and there is ease of appropriability. Hence, it is argued


ABA, The Economics of Innovation: A Survey, ABA, July 2002 available at http://
www.ftc.gov/opp/intellect/0207salabasrvy.pdf; F. Machlup, An Economic Review of the
Patent System, Study No. 15 of the Subcomm. on Patents, Trademarks and Copyrights of
the Senate Comm. on the Judiciary, 85th Cong., 2nd Sess. (1958); E.W. Kitch, The Nature
and Function of the Patent System, 20 Journal of Law and Economics 265 (1977).

P.A. David, Intellectual Property Institutions and Pandas Thumb: Patents, Copyrights and Trade Secrets in Economic Theory and History, in M. Wallerstein, M. Mogee

21

22

The patent balance

that in the absence of patents people would fail to or would


under-invest as they would lose on their investment. This rationale is based on the assumption that the inventor cannot
reap the full benefits by relying solely on secrecy measures to
prevent imitation. It generally views inventions as one-off events
and not as a cumulative process. Hence, the costs are related
to static ones of reduced access and the possible exercise of
market power. There may, however, also be dynamic costs associated with the deterrence of other innovation, and waste
due to patent races. The latter is associated with duplicative
investment by entering races or by over-investment. It also
raises the possibility that investment could be made at a faster
rate than the social optimum.
2. Invention dissemination. The patent system encourages dissemination by requiring the disclosure and publication of the
invention and details on how it works. This may in turn lead to
a wider use of the inventions, particularly where the inventor
cannot exploit the potential of the invention himself and where
secrecy would allow the inventor to reap some of the returns
effectively. This is often the case for process innovations. Patent publications may also improve the free flow of information.
Disclosure, in turn, may be beneficial to rivals. A study of the
spillover value of patents in the biotechnology sector showed
that core technology patents valued between $13 and $21
million may have knowledge spillovers generating economic
values of $3 to $6 million per rival firm, although some highprofile patents are viewed as harmful to rivals and most patents
do not generate significant market effects.
3. Invention commercialisation. The commercialisation of an invention often requires a large investment. Patents allow for the
development of inventions that may have little value in the initial
stages and need further development in order to be commercially valuable. In some cases, a head-start might assist in

and R. Schoen (eds), Global Dimensions of IPRs in Science and Technology, National
Research Council, Washington, National Academy Press (1993).

ABA (2002) op. cit.

Process innovations refer to changes in the production process to reduce the costs
related to producing a product, while product innovations refer to changes in the product
itself to improve quality.

D. Austin, Patents, Spillovers and Competition in Biotechnology, Discussion Paper
00-53, November 2000, at http://www.rff.org.

The patent system as a system of balancing

23

regard to this objective, although the role of head-start is not


particularly important in the pharmaceutical industry.
4. Orderly cumulative development of innovation. Broad patents
may facilitate follow-on inventions by controlling the licensing
terms and avoiding duplicative efforts. However, they may also
hinder it if the transaction costs are high or if there is an overarching threat of infringement.
One of the central goals of the patent system is ensuring that follow-on research building on previous inventions is not impeded by the granting of an
overly restrictive legal monopoly. The function of the patented invention as an
output has to be balanced against its function as an input for further development. This is the vertical dilemma which the patent provisions seek to
address.
The patent system, however, also seeks to address issues associated with the
dissemination of the patented invention, as it would be counter-productive if
one could simply monopolise a particular invention and then not utilise it, for
example. In this way, ensuring that an invention is adequately disseminated is
the horizontal dilemma that the patent system addresses.10
In the non-cumulative model, patents involve a trade-off between incentives
and static efficiency loss associated with market power.11 In order to encourage
innovation in the long term, exclusive property rights are granted allowing producers to restrict output and raise prices in the short term leading to static
losses.
In the cumulative framework, however, patents are concerned not only with
providing the best incentives for the primary invention, but also to ensure incen-


H. Grabowski, Patents and New Product Development in the Pharmaceutical and
Biotechnology Industries, in Science and Cents, April (2002), Federal Reserve Bank of
Dallas.

S. Scotchmer, Cumulative Innovation in Theory and Practice, Goldman School
of Public Policy Working Paper 240, University of California (Berkeley), February
(1999), p.1.

H. Ullrich, Legal Protection of Innovative Technologies: Property or Policy? in
O. Grandstrand, The Swedish Intellectual Property Symposium (2001), p.5; Y. Benkler,
Free as the Air to Common Use: A Political Economy of the Public Domain, in R. Dreyfuss et al. (ed.), Expanding the Boundaries of Intellectual Property, Oxford, Oxford
University Press (2001).

The issue of whether and when such a motive might be present is not addressed
here.
10
H. Ullrich (2001) op. cit. p.5; P. A. David (1993) op. cit. pp.19, 32.
11
E.W. Kitch (1977) op. cit.

24

The patent balance

tives for follow-on inventions.12 Adjusting patent length and breadth might give
effect to some of these considerations. The problem is, however, that it is not
clear how much incentives are necessary.13 The dilemma in the area of sequential
innovation reflects the clash between monopoly and competition theorists, the
former arguing that monopolies eliminate duplicative efforts and ensure that
invention takes place,14 and the latter arguing that innovation incentives are often
smaller in monopolistic conditions and that competition may yield different
results in the race.15
The optimal length of patents is sensitive to price elasticity of demand in the
product market, and the responsiveness of the costs of the production process
to the amount of R&D resources devoted to its invention.16 In cases where the
demand is more elastic, the patent length should be shorter. This is because if
prices are higher, the quantity will be lower and there will be more deadweight
losses.
On the other hand, a wider breadth would provide strong incentives for the
breakthrough inventions and weaken incentives for the follow-on inventors.
Scotchmer and Green have shown that a broad scope puts followers at a disadvantage in negotiating the terms of licences for complementary elements
that they seek to patent, and results in additional costs in attempting to invent
around the blocking first generation patent.17 Innovation is often cumulative
so that the patent could interfere with further discovery; inhibition of progress
as opposed to discouraging inventions.18 Weak and narrow patents encourage
firms to cross-license and disseminate, however, this may discourage fundamental inventions.19

12

S. Scotchmer (1999) op. cit.


F.M. Scherer, Nordhaus Theory of Optimal Patent Life: A Geometric Reinterpretation, 62(3) American Economic Review 422 (1972); R. Gilbert and C. Shapiro, Optimal
Patent Protection and Breadth, 21 Rand J. of Econcs 106 (1990); P. Klemperer, How
Broad Should the Scope of Patent Protection Be? 21 Rand J. of Econcs 113 (1990); P.A.
David (1993) op. cit.; F. Machlup (1958) op. cit.
14
See, for example, E.W. Kitch (1977) op. cit.; J. Schumpeter, Capitalism, Socialism
and Democracy, New York, NY Harper (1942) .
15
R. Merges and R. Nelson, On the Complex Economics of Patent Scope, 90 Colum
L Rev 839 (1990); G.C. Loury, Market Structure and Innovation, 93 Quarterly J. of
Econcs 345 (1979); M. Lemley, The Economics of Improvements in Intellectual Property
Law, 75 Texas L. Rev. 993 (1997).
16
P.A. David (1993) op. cit.
17
J. Green and S. Scotchmer, On the Division of Profit between Sequential Innovators, 26 Rand J. of Econcs 2033 (1995); S. Scotchmer, Standing on the Shoulders of
Giants: Cumulative Research and the Patent Law, 1 J. of Econ. Perss 29 (1991).
18
Ibid. J. Ordover, A Patent System for Both Diffusion and Exclusion, 5 J. of Econ.
Perss 21229 (1991).
19
Ibid.
13

The patent system as a system of balancing

25

There is no clear dividing line and it is difficult to determine how much incentives are necessary in view of the various and often competing policy objectives.
The balancing process necessarily involves certain trade-offs. For example,
where initial innovation ought to be encouraged the patent breadth will tend to
be wider, whereas to account for follow-on innovation, the exclusivity will have
to be restricted.
Table 2.1 The existing EU patent systems and sources determining their
applicability and implementation
Patent systems in
the EU:

Patentability

Infringement and
validity

National patent

To be determined by
Member States, but de
facto harmonisation in
view of TRIPS, EPC
and CPC

To be determined by
Member States, but de
facto harmonisation in
view of TRIPS and CPC

European patent

EPC

To be determined by
Member States, but de
facto harmonisation in
view of TRIPS and CPC

Community patent

EPC

Community Patent
Regulation

2.2 The particular importance of the patent


balance in the biopharmaceutical
industry
2.2.1 The Patent System and the Biopharmaceutical Industry
The patent balance assumes a particular significance in the biopharmaceutical
industry. First, it is an industry that affects public policy as it improves health
and the standard of living. These goods are not ordinary ones, and therefore
optimising innovation and striking the balance between short-term and longterm innovation and ensuring access becomes fundamental.
Secondly, the patent system is perceived as being vital to the industry. In
contrast with many others, this industry relies heavily on the patent system to
appropriate returns and much of the innovation is based on the patent system

26

The patent balance

as an incentive mechanism. It hence becomes important to preserve this incentive. On the other hand, consumers expect to gain access to new and effective
drugs at an affordable cost, not only in the short term but also in the long
term.

Box 2.2: The nature of biopharmaceutical


innovation
Innovation is the main source of competitiveness in the biopharmaceutical industry.20 However, the dynamics of innovation are far
from clear.21 Research is a costly and risky business. There are increasingly stringent requirements for approval, and research has
become orientated towards complex drug discovery, leading to a
sharp increase in the resources needed to develop new drugs.22 A
20
The nature of competition in the industry is such that a premium is based on research and innovation in a dynamic sense. E. Halm and A. Gelijns, An Introduction to
the Changing Economics of Technology Innovation in Medicine, in A.C. Gelijns and
E.A. Halm (eds), The Changing Economics of Medical Technology, Institute of Medicine,
Medical Innovation at the Crossroads Vol. II, Washington, National Academies Press
(1991).
The biopharmaceutical is a highly research-based industry. The primary operations
of the industry are linked to: innovation, which is a risky and costly business; production,
which requires specialised methods; marketing, which aims at persuading the choice of
one product over another and is aimed at physicians who usually make the decisions relating to which drug to prescribe; and distribution, which is usually done through
specialised wholesalers who in turn sell to retail pharmacists. EUROPE, Pharmaceutical
Products, Single Market Review (1996).
21
ABA (2002) op. cit. Much economic research has concentrated on whether competition and potential competition can increase innovative activity. Whether concentration
or competition is more conducive to innovation is not clear. F.M. Scherer, Firm Size,
Market Structure, Opportunity and the Output of Patented Inventions, 55 American
Economic Review 1097125 (1965); F.M. Scherer, D. Harhoff, J. Kukies, Uncertainty
and the Size of Distribution of Rewards from Innovation, 10 J. of Evoly Econcs 175-200
(2000).
22
A. Gambardella, L. Orsengo, F. Pammoli, Global Competitiveness in Pharmaceutical Industry. A European Perspective, for DG Enterprise of European Commission, 2002.
In the EU the pharmaceutical industry is a highly regulated industry with provisions
controlling reward and safety, the quantity and quality of expenditures and, in some
cases, price controls. However, while there is a Community system for granting marketing authorisation, the market for medicines is still quite fragmented by national controls
especially over price. There are two means by which companies may receive authorisation to market a drug in the EU: the first is through an application to the European
Medicines Evaluation Agency (EMEA) which cooperates with the competent national
authority to scientifically assess the product and then sends its advisory opinion to the

The patent system as a system of balancing

27

study undertaken in 1985 concluded that the average annual expenditure on R&D represented 810 per cent of sales, although it
was even higher for some firms.23
Basic research is an on-going process,24 but once a new substance is discovered, its development follows three stages: the
synthesis of active materials and determinations of their biological
effects; extensive biological testing on animals and then on humans
to establish its pharmacological activity and to detect adverse effects; and finally, product development.25 This process is lengthy,
costly and uncertain.
The growth rate of discovery and pre-clinical development costs
have increased substantially due to the need for a detailed understanding of the mechanisms involved, including highly specialised
medical, biological and biochemical skills, and the clinical costs
which have grown at a rapid rate.26 The rise in costs and length of
drug development is partly due to the more extensive clinical research required prior to marketing and the nature of the disease
areas of research. Attention is focused on treating chronic clinical
conditions requiring greater overall resources prior to commercial

European Commission, which prepares a draft decision that becomes law if it is not opposed. This procedure is mandatory for biotechnological products and optional for
high-tech medicines. The second route is based on mutual recognition, where a licence
to enter the market is given after an investigation into the efficacy and quality of the
process. Quality and quantity control is achieved by direct or indirect means on the prescribing/consumption practices, and price regulation is a national affair in the EU.
See also Directives 92/26, 92/28, 92/27, 92/23 on the rational use of medicines, OJ
1992 L113/13, which have harmonised the classification of medicines for prescription
and non-prescription products, the advertising of medicines, the information to be provided to patients and pharmaceutical wholesaling. See also Directive 98/44/EC on the
Legal Protection of Biotechnology Inventions, OJ 1998 L213/13 that provides a common
set of principles regarding the grant of patents, but only four Member States have adopted
the necessary legislation so far.
23
OECD, The Pharmaceutical Industry, Paris (1985).
24
The industry is made up of different types of firms. There are small companies
that specialise in sales of non-R&D intensive drugs which are mainly involved in the
manufacturing and commercial activities. There are also the New Biotechnology Firms
(NBFs) that specialise in biotechnology and who are mostly concerned with the discovery
and development of new drug compounds and the development of research tools which
pharmaceutical companies may subsequently develop and commercialise. A. Gambardella et al. (2002) op. cit.
25
Ibid.
26
H. Grabowski, Patents and New Product Development in the Pharmaceutical and
Biotechnology Industries, in Science and Cents (April, 2002) (Federal Reserve Bank of
Dallas).

28

The patent balance

sale.27 However, the physiological effects of compounds can now


be predicted with greater ease.
It takes approximately 10 to 15 years to develop a new drug, and
most of these do not survive the development process. In the USA,
it has been found that only 20 out of every 5000 compounds
screened, enter the pre-clinical testing stage, and only one out of
every five drugs entering the clinical trials has been approved by
the FDA as fulfilling the safety and efficacy requirements. Clinical
trial requirements have increased, and hence the costs have risen,
while the average returns from marketing a new drug have decreased.28 It has been estimated that, on average, the development
of a new drug costs $802 million.29 In addition, most of the marketed drugs fail to cover their R&D costs, and so the development of
blockbuster drugs every two to three years is necessary for a company to be able to survive the R&D process.30
It has, however, been found that there is a positive correlation
between R&D intensity and the probability of discovering a new
drug,31 although the causal relationship is not clear, in other words
whether R&D expenditure leads to patents that provide lucrative
earnings or vice versa.32
2.2.1.1 Biopharmaceutical innovation and patenting
In view of the complexity and the cost of the innovation process, patents are perceived to be of primary significance. Several researchers have commented that
27
H. Grabowski, The Changing Economics of Pharmaceutical R&D, in A.C. Gelijns
and E.A. Halm, (Eds), The Changing Economics of Medical Technology, Institute of
Medicine, Medical Innovation at the Crossroads Vol. II, Washington, National Academies
Press (1991).
28
G. Glover, Competition in the Pharmaceutical Marketplace before the FTC, Proceedings on Competition and IPRS: A. Diverse perspectives on patents. B. Business
perspectives on patents. Biotechnology and pharmaceuticals, 19 March 2002; A Congressional Report 1998 showed that there was a 12% decline since 1984.
29
Ibid. See also H. Grabowski (1991) op. cit., for the best estimate of the average
cost of drug development as being $231 million in 1991. He estimated the R&D costs
per approved drug amounted to $400 million.
30
G. Glover (2002) op. cit. Out of every 10 drugs on the market, only three cover
their average development costs and this was prior to the facilitation of generic drug
competition.
31
E. Jensen, Research Expenditures and the Discovery of New Drugs, 36 Journal of
Industrial Economics 83 (1987).
32
M. Baily, R&D Costs and Returns: the US Pharmaceutical Industry, 80 Journal
of Political Economy 70 (1972).

The patent system as a system of balancing

29

the industry would not exist but for the patent system.33 Innovators would be reluctant to invest as they would be unable to make a reasonable return, and in this
way there would not be any products to be copied for the generic brands.34
The market would only afford two types of benefits to innovators: de facto
exclusivity from being the first mover, and a sizeable segment of consumers
which prefers branded products over generic ones. In the less serious cases, it
is thought that without patent protection, R&D would fall by almost 60 per
cent.35 This is also consistent with Mansfield, who reports that 65 per cent of
innovations generated from 1981 to 1983 would not have been marketed and
60 per cent would not have been developed if there had not been patent
protection.36
By comparing the four factors for appropriating the benefits from product
inventions, one study has concluded that patents are the most effective mechanism. On a scale of one to seven, seven connoting very effective, patents had a
marking of 6.53 compared to learning by doing 4.24, lead time 5.47 and sales
and services 5.59. In other industries, these variations were very different, for
example in the computer industry patents were effective in a scale of 3.43 compared to lead time that was 6.33.37 The importance of the patent system is
attributed to four main factors: the high costs of R&D; the low costs of imitation; the fact that claims may be defined precisely for new chemical molecules,
making it easier to prove infringement; and the long life-span of pharmaceutical
inventions rendering lead time less important.38
Only one out of every eight patents has a significant economic value, therefore, apart from a few cases, the market does not seem to treat patents as
winner-take-all prizes.39 In addition, evidence shows that newer drugs reduce
33
See DOJ/FTC Proceedings on the pharmaceutical industry: Business perspectives
on the use and the role of patents in the biotech industry, 26 February 2002.
34
G. Glover (2002) op. cit.
35
Snyder in FTC/DOJ Proceedings on Competition and IPRs: A. Diverse perspectives on patents. B. Business perspectives on patents. Biotechnology and pharmaceuticals,
19 March 2002. See also OECD Report, Competition and Regulation Issues in the
Pharmaceutical Industry, Paris (2001); where it is estimated that 65% of drugs would
not have been introduced without patent protection.
36
S.A. Singham, Competition Policy and the Stimulation of Innovation: TRIPS and
the Interface Between Competition and Patent Protection in the Pharmaceutical Industry,
26 Brooklyn J Intl L 363 (2000).
37
H. Grabowski (2002) op. cit.
38
F.M. Scherer, D. Harhoff, J. Kukies, Policy Implications of a World Skew-Distributed Returns on Innovation, 29 Research Policy 559 (2000); F.M. Scherer et al.
Uncertainty and Size Distribution of Returns from Technological Innovation 10 J. Evoln
Econcs 17 (2000); WTO, WTO Agreements and Public Health, A Joint Study by WHO
and the WTO Secretariat (2002); pp.923.
39
Ibid.

30

The patent balance

non-drug expenditures 7.2 times as much as they increase drug expenditure.40


Dynamic efficiency evidence further supports the effectiveness and preservation
of the patent system; While providing greater access to the current stock of
prescription drugs would yield large benefits to consumers in absolute terms,
realizing those benefits has yet greater costs in terms of lost consumer surplus
from reduction in flow of new prescription drugs. The ratio of harm to benefit
is three to one.41 Moreover, patents do not render entry impossible or even unlikely. Within four years of their introduction, a study has shown that 60 per
cent of patented successful innovations had been imitated.42 However, the patent
system generally increases the costs of imitations by about 30 per cent in the
industry.43
In addition, in view of the tight regulatory requirements, a substantial amount
of patent time is lost during clinical development and regulatory approval periods. Effective patent life in the pharmaceutical industry was usually around
seven years. In order to address this problem, the Supplementary Protection
Certificate44 was created, which allows for an additional protection of five years
on top of the 20 years from the filing period, with a cap of 15 years protection
in total, rendering the average effective patent life 10 to 12 years in which
companies must recover their expenses.
The patent system, however, does not address all of the public policy concerns
in the industry. While patents may be important for investing in R&D, pharmaceutical companies mainly focus on the diseases likely to yield high returns for
the shareholders, therefore diseases suffered by the poor or afflicting a small
number of people are neglected.45 Only 10 per cent of global R&D is directed

40
F. Lichtenberg, Benefits and Costs of Newer Drugs: An Update, 2002 at http://
www.nber.org/papers/w8996.
41
E.A. Snyder (2002) op. cit.
42
E. Mansfield, Unauthorized Use of IP: Effects on Investment, Technology Transfer
and Innovation, in Global Dimensions of IPRs in Science and Technology, National Research Council, edited by M. Wallerstein, M. Mogee, R. Schoen, Washington, National
Academy Press (1993).
43
Ibid.
44
Regulation 1768/92 EEC, concerning the creation of a Supplementary Protection
Certificate for medicinal products, OJ 1992 L182.
45
It is for this reason that different mechanisms to stimulate innovation in diseases
afflicting a small proportion of the population have been created, such as the Orphans
Drugs Act. Regulation 141/2000/EC, on Orphan Medicinal Product OJ 2000 L 18/1.
See D.M. Richardson, The Orphan Drug Tax Credit: An Inadequate Response to An IllDefined Problem, 6 The American Journal of Tax Policy 135 (1987). See also, P.J.
Kenney, The Orphan Drug Act Is it a Barrier to Innovation? Does it Create Unintended
Windfalls? 43 Food Drug Cosmetic Law Journal 66779 (1988). See also in the USA
the Orphan Drug Act that provides incentives to undertake orphan drug indications including tax credits, clinical research grants programme, accelerated review by the FDA,

The patent system as a system of balancing

31

towards illnesses that account for 90 per cent of the worldwide diseases. The
problem is rooted in poverty, not in industrial incentive structures.46 In addition,
WHO estimates that one-third of the worlds population currently lacks access
to essential drugs and over 50 per cent of people in poor countries in Africa and
Asia do not even have access to the most basic drugs.47
2.2.1.2 Has the importance of patents been overstated?
While patenting is vital for the biopharmaceutical industry, its importance
should not be overstated.48 Many pharmaceutical patents are awarded to secondary and often trivial inventions rather than authentic ones, which attempt to use
patents strategically to extend their monopoly by restricting competition, creating large areas of exclusion around their inventions, thus preventing other
companies from exploiting their own patents and enhancing their bargaining
power in cross-licensing deals.49
For example, while the industry claims that it is a risky industry relying on
the few blockbuster drugs developed, the Public Citizen study has concluded

and guaranteed market exclusivity for seven years from the date of FDA approval. The
effects have been impressive as more than 200 drugs and biologicals for rare diseases
were developed between 1983 and 1999.
46
Oxfam, Patent Injustice: How the World Trade Rules Threaten the Health of Poor
People; at www.oxfam.org.uk p.7. In such cases supplementary mechanisms need to be
embedded in the system, in the form of push mechanisms involving financial contributions towards R&D, and pull mechanisms aimed at ensuring the existence of an attractive
level of demand in the event that successful drugs or vaccines are generated.
47
WTO (2002) op. cit. p.16. Access to essential drugs depends on four critical elements: rational selection and use, sustainable financing, reliable supply systems and
affordable prices. Access to drugs requires availability and affordability, and is conditioned on many factors including price controls, medical insurance, import duties and
tariffs, local taxes, limited competition mark-ups for wholesaling, distribution and dispensing. Cullet, Patents Bill, TRIPS and the Right to Health, XXXVI/43 Economic and
Political Weekly, 27 Oct. 2001.
48
The industry will want to lobby for the highest level of protection as it directly
affects its stock prices. For example when the US court granted pharmaceutical conglomerate Eli Lilly an extension on its patent for Prozac that was two years shorter than
it had requested, its share fell by almost one third, wiping out $38bn of its market capitalization. For this reason, pharmaceutical companies spend a huge amount on lobbying.
PhRMAs political influence comes at a price. Between 1997 and 1999, PhRMAs
members spent US$236m lobbying Congress and the executive branch of the government. Another US$14m was provided to political parties in 1999 alone. Approximately
two-thirds of corporate investment in political lobbying in the USA is directed towards
the Republican Party, raising doubts about corporate influence over the new Administration. Oxfam, on patents op. cit. p.7.
49
G. Dutfield, IPRs and the Life Science Industries, A 20th Century History, Aldershot, Ashgate (2003).

32

The patent balance

that pharmaceutical R&D is not particularly risky, as most new drugs are metoo drugs, (in other words close substitutes for successful drugs), and that the
initial R&D costs of many important drugs comes from public funds.50 It has
been shown that pharmaceutical companies have recently been found guilty of
paying generic producers to delay selling their versions of the drugs.51
In addition, the link between an increase in profits and an increase in R&D
in the industry is also not clear-cut, although a recent study has shown that as
profits increase, firms will compete to exploit them by increasing R&D investments.52 The lack of a direct correlation between research expenditure and
patent-based income renders it difficult to determine if the patent system is fair.
The price of drugs does not always correlate with the costs of R&D and production as marketing costs, profit margins, subsidies, tariffs and tax are added to
those. Pharmaceutical firms spend more on advertising and promotion than on
R&D and this cannot be justified by the need for patent exclusivity. There is
no apparent justification for allowing patent-based pricing to generate income
for advertisements.53 This is particularly evident in the case of essential drugs
that are not dependent on advertising.54
It is also argued that companies exploit incremental innovations and patent
improvements or minor changes in order to extend the effective term of protection for the original invention.55 Therefore, it is claimed that the patent system
often rewards not only inventions which constitute a moral triumph, but also
those of predictable outcome.56
The patent system has also been accused of creating a situation in which
patents are used to stifle small firms that may be a prime source of innovation
in areas of new technology.57 The evidence is ambiguous, however, as other
studies have suggested that patent protection may be the key to commercial

50

WTO (2002) op. cit. pp.923.


FTC, FTC Antitrust Actions in Pharmaceutical Services and Products, October
2003. See also the Commission announcement that it had fined AstraZeneca 60 million
for abusing its dominance by misusing the patent system. Commission Press Release
IP/05/737.
52
F.M. Scherer, New Perspectives on Economic Growth and Technological Innovation, Washington, DC, Brookings Institution Press (1999).
53
See F.M. Abbott (2001) op. cit.
54
In such cases, other means may be warranted to allow for the recovery of research
costs such as tax credits, subsidies and prizes.
55
C. Correa, Internalization of the Patent System and New Technology in WIPO
Conference on the International Patent System, Geneva, 2527 March (2002).
56
Ibid.
57
J. Barton, Adapting IP System to New Technology, in Global Dimensions of IPRs
in Science and Technology, National Research Council, edited by M. Wallerstein, M.
Mogee, R. Schoen, Washington, National Academy Press (1993).
51

The patent system as a system of balancing

33

success for medium-sized firms with the research capacity to produce innovative
new products but lacking the capital to fully exploit and commercialise their
inventions.58
Finally, it should be remembered that major breakthroughs are usually made
in universities, and companies are more likely to encourage research with obvious commercial applications in the interest of increasing profits. Pharmaceutical
companies have often been reproached for investing in lifestyle drugs treating
trivial conditions that need to be treated on a continuous basis (as opposed to
cured), such as baldness, rather than in lifesaving drugs.
A comparative analysis of the experience of several countries raises further
doubts as to the role of patents in ensuring a commitment to expensive R&D.
For Britain and France, the product patent regime was largely ineffective, while
in Switzerland, despite the absence of chemical industry patents, the industry
has evolved rapidly. Italy is also representative of the fact that the introduction
of product patent protection does not necessarily lead to increased innovative
R&D among domestic firms,59 though another study has shown that multinational corporations limited their involvement in the Indian drug market after the
adoption of the weak patent system in 1970.60 None the less, stronger patent
protection does not necessarily result in more innovation and less patent protection does not necessarily mean less innovation. Therefore, caution should be
exercised in introducing overly-restrictive patent protection when there are other
discernible negative effects.
The above considerations should not lead us to conclude that the patent system should be abolished, nor to undermine the importance of the patent system
in the biopharmaceutical industry. Rather, they seek to clarify the underlying
objectives of the industry in their quest for an absolute and unqualified patent
protection. Exclusivity involves a full scale of degree ranging from absolute
exclusivity to the complete lack of it.61 The level of patent protection is, therefore, a matter of degree and involves the careful balancing of competing
objectives.
58
See the case of Pliva which patented azythromycin worldwide, and then reached
a licensing agreement with Pfizer Inc. in which both companies and the public could
benefit from the commercialisation of the antibiotic. See WIPO, Azythromocin: A world
best-selling antibiotic Pliva, at www.wipo.int.
59
F.M Scherer and S. Weisburst, Economic Effects of Strengthening Pharmaceutical
Patent Protection in Italy, 26 IIC 1009 (1995), p.1023. G. Dutfield (2003) op. cit.
p.241.
60
R. Garg et al., Four Opportunities in Indias Pharmaceutical Market, 4 MCKINSEY Q. 132 (1996); S. A. Singham (2000) op. cit.
61
This depends, amongst other things, on how one determines an infringement, how
extensively compulsory licensing is used and how moral considerations affect the patent
grant or its invalidation.

34

The patent balance

2.3 Conclusion
Despite the significance of patent protection for the biopharmaceutical industry
and the centrality of the right to exclude in this respect, one should view with
caution requests for unlimited patent protection, as a balance is envisaged within
the system itself. Patent protection has various objectives to address and exclusivity therefore is a matter of degree.
The continuous progress of innovation and production of improvements is a
central part of the patent balance, particularly in the biopharmaceutical industry.
To this end, it aims to encourage not only pioneer inventions,62 involving a distinct step in the progress of the art, but also technological improvements
resulting from independent discoveries or intentional efforts to design around
and therefore avoid infringing the patent.63
The patent system aims to achieve a balance between competing interests and
the incremental nature of innovation. As a result, patent rights may interact and
overlap in different ways, with different consequences in each case. In cases of
technological improvements, patents may block each other. In cases where different inventors patent different components of a larger invention independently,
patents are complementary and thus ineffective without a licence to each of the
patented products. In other cases, patents may be substitutes or inventions
around other patents and so may compete. Yet the categorisation amongst such
different types of patents and relations is not perfect and so, for example, complementary patents may also compete.64
The patents system attempts to distinguish and cater for such competing and
often conflicting interests through limitations, exemptions from scope or other
provisions. For example, in the case of improvements, the patent system treats
them differently according to their significance and value in relation to the pioneer invention.65

62
A pioneer invention is defined as a distinct step in the progress of art, distinguished from a mere improvement or perfection of what had gone before. Texas Inst. v
ITC, 6 USPQ 2d 1886 (Fed. Cir. 1988).
63
M. J. Conigliaro, A.C. Greenberg and M.A. Lemley, Foreseeability in Patent Law,
16 Berkeley Tech L.J. 1045 (2001).
64
S.C. Carlson, Patent Pools and the Antitrust Dilemma, 6 Yale J. on Reg. 369
(1999).
65
M.A. Lemley (1997) op. cit. This is also consistent with the inventive step determination in case of pharmaceuticals. The greater the structural distance and the better
the technical effect of the invention as compared with the state of the art, the greater the
likelihood that inventive step will be found. See B. Domeij, Pharmaceutical Patents in
Europe, Deventer, Kluwer Law International (2000).
At the bottom of the scale are minor improvers for which the law offers no protection
and who may appropriate their findings only by trade secrets or first mover advantages.

The patent system as a system of balancing

35

It is therefore in no way inconsistent with the patent system to state that there
are limitations and safety nets within the system itself that may address competing interests, including follow-on innovation considerations.

The law, however, does not make allowance for an infringement of the pioneer invention.
Higher up the scale are significant improvers that exceed the minimum social value
threshold for patentability and are thus able to get an improvement patent. While they
may not use the pioneer invention without the permission of the patent holder, they may
prevent the patent holder (and any other unlicensed party), from using their improvement.
This often leads to the case of blocking patents which, according to the transactional
view of IPRs, is conducive to levelling the playing field and to minimising the chances
of a bargaining breakdown. In the EU, there is also a provision for compulsory licensing
in cases where the improvement patent involves an important technological advance of
considerable economic interest Art. 53 EPC 1973 (Convention for the grant of European
Patents, which came into force in 1977, also known as the Munich Convention).
At the top of the scale there are radical improvements that depart from prior patents
and are afforded independent protection. In such cases, they may be found to depart from
prior patents even though they fall within the literal language of the claim. This is done
in the USA through the reverse doctrine of equivalence. As will be seen, where efficient
licensing will not occur, the law allows the improver to use the pioneer idea without that
being infringement, avoiding the hold up problem. This is done, as will be shown, by
interpreting the improvement as being sufficiently radical to escape the scope of the pioneer patent.

3. The patent system and some potential


safety nets
3.1 Introduction to the patent safety nets
Recent developments in biopharmaceutical R&D have raised concerns regarding
the basic assumption of most patent systems that society benefits more from
innovation than it is harmed by the grant of a legal monopoly. This chapter examines the safeguards in the system to ensure that follow-on innovation is not
unduly impeded in the case of research tools.
Before examining the means available within the patent system to ensure
access to such research tools, it should be clarified that the analysis is limited
to the patented tools used to develop biopharmaceutical products that do not
physically incorporate the tool. In addition, the analysis is limited to the situations in which access to the patented tool is problematic. As it was shown, access
has not proven to be problematic in most cases. None the less, access to research tools remains problematic in some cases. This may be due to the
hesitation on the part of researchers to disclose the nature of their research in
the course of obtaining a licence, to a refusal on the part of the tool holder to license it, or to placement of significant limitations on the licences, or to
demanding a price amounting to an effective refusal to license.
The analysis will centre largely on the mechanisms available in patent law to
deal with a refusal to license. The mechanisms examined only involve potential
remedies once a patent has been granted. Therefore, for example, considerations
leading up to the grant of the patent such as whether certain types of inventions
should be patentable or not are outside the scope of the present examination.


The distinction has been highlighted by J.M. Mueller (2001) op. cit. p.14 as it
does not trigger infringement liability for selling or offering to sell the patented products,
but rather only for use.

See Chapter 2.

J.M. Mueller (2001) op. cit.

Article 53 EPC provides for certain exceptions from patentability for ordre public,
under which research tools could arguably fall. The Guidelines for Examination in the
EPO provide that a fair test to determine what should be excluded from patentability on
this ground is if it is something which the public at large would consider so abhorrent

36

The patent system and some potential safety nets

37

The patent working solutions will be examined with reference to the research
tool experience, though their application may be equally applicable (or nonapplicable) in other cases involving similar issues. It should be stressed,
however, that the particularity of the case of research tools lies in the fact that
it is concerned with access to some technology for research purposes at a precommercial stage (as distinct from product supply).

3.2 The patent safety nets


The following safety nets/limitations to patents are examined:



experimental use exemption;


reverse doctrine of equivalents and blocking patents;
l patent pools;
l compulsory licensing.
l

as to render a patent inconceivable. It is contemplated that this provision will be used


only in rare and extreme cases where an invention is likely to induce riot or public disorder, or lead to criminal or generally offensive behavior. None the less the possibility
of such an exclusion from patenting is not considered as it is assumed that patents in this
context are more desirable than not.
It also bears noting, however, that in the EU there is a group of advisers on the ethical
implications of biotechnology serving the interests of European society and respecting
the fundamental rights of every European citizen. The Group submits reports amongst
others on the compatibility of policies including patent policies with fundamental rights
such as the dignity of the human person. The Group gives its advisory opinion on ethical
aspects of patenting inventions involving, for example, elements of human origin, cloning
techniques, health care in the information society and gene therapy. So, for example, in
the EU we have a Biotech Directive (1998) op. cit. excluding the patenting of inventions
which would be contrary to public order of morality, and a Directive 98/79/EC, on InVitro Diagnostic Medical Devices, OJ 1998 L331/1 referring to the protection of the
integrity of human persons. See the Report of the European Group on Ethics in Science
and New Technologies on the Charter on Fundamental Rights Related to Technological
Innovation, as requested by President Prodi, on 3 February 2000. The Group also decided
that the recourse to compulsory licensing should be encouraged when the access to diagnostic and treatments is blocked by a misuse of patent rights and stressed that it is the
responsibility of the states to establish a legal procedure for compulsory licensing where
that is justified by fair access to health care. In addition to the European Group, there
are also National Ethics Committees such as the Hellenic National Bioethics Commission
and the Nuffield Council on Bioethics considering issues of ethics and patenting and that
could potentially consider the issue of patenting when a life-saving drug is in issue, or
as otherwise required by the right to health.

38

The patent balance

Table 3.1 Community patent provisions for the grant and extent of patent
protection
Source

Rule

Requirements

Exceptions/ Exclusions/
Limitations

Article

European
Patent
Convention
(EPC)

Patentability

Inventions:
concrete
technical
character

Exclusions:
artistic works
scientific theories and
mathematical methods
presentation of
information
business methods
Exceptions to
patentability:
against ordre public
plant or animal
varieties
Exception:
methods of medical
treatment or methods
of diagnosis

Art. 52

Limits of exclusive rights:


acts done privately and
for non-commercial
purposes
acts done for
experimental purposes
preparation of
medicine in pharmacy
according to medical
prescription
exhaustion
prior use
Compulsory licensing:
non-use for 3 yrs from
grant and 4 yrs from
application
to use second
otherwise infringing
patent where
important technical
advance of
considerable economic
significance
cases of extreme
urgency

Art. 7, 8,
9, 10, 11,
12

Industrial
application
Novelty
Inventive step
Community
Patent
Regulation
(CPR)

Infringement

direct use
indirect use

Art. 53

Art. 57

Art. 54
Art. 56

Art. 21

The patent system and some potential safety nets

39

3.2.1 Experimental Use Exemption


3.2.1.1 The experimental use exemption: a viable and effective working
solution?
The experimental use doctrine is a very narrow exception that excuses the infringement of a patent. To the extent that the experimental use exemption is
present in Europe, it is governed by national law. Article 54(1) of the European
Patent Convention (EPC) provides that the rights conferred by a European patent
shall be the same as those conferred by a national patent for each of the designated states. Article 64(3) of the EPC provides that any infringement of a
European patent shall be dealt with under national law.
Patent legislation in EPC countries contains limitations of the rights of patentees. Article 69 EPC specifies that the scope of the patent right is determined
by the claim, but the infringement exceptions can be found in the Community
Patent Convention (CPC) Arts 2528. Article 27(b) provides that the Community Patent shall not extend to acts done for experimental purposes relating
to the subject matter of the patented invention. The national patent systems
have generally accepted this exemption from patent infringement.
The general opinion is that the experimental use of a patented invention in
order to check the accuracy of the patent specification, or to carry out experiments with no commercial impact or profit motive, does not amount to patent
infringement.10 An important rationale behind the experimental use exemption


The experimental use exemption at its current state is viewed as only useful in
exceptional cases. See M. Kern, Recent Federal Supreme Court Decision on Experimental Use and Compulsory Licensing, 3(2) CASRIP Newsletter 2, Summer (1996).

See IPR Helpdesk, at http://www.ipr-helpdesk.org/ on Patenting and the Research
Exemption.

A similar provisions was also found in Art. 9 of the Draft Council Regulation on
the Community Patent COMM (2000) 412 final (that has now been modified by Doc
7119/04 PI 18, Revised Proposal for Council Regulation on the Community Patent, 8
March 2004, COM(2004) 7119).

All EU states except for Austria have introduced such a general exception.

See W.R. Cornish, Experimental Use of Patented Inventions in European Community States, 29(7) IIC 736 (1998).
See French Patent Law Including Modifications of 1978, Art. 29 providing that acts
accomplished for personal or domestic purposes or for the purpose of testing the object
of the patented invention shall not be considered as affecting the patentees rights. German Patent Act of 16 December 1980, 11.2 effects of the patent shall not extend to
acts done for experimental purposes relating to the subject matter of the patented invention. UK Patent Act 1977 60(5) exempting acts done privately and for purposes
which are not commercial as well as those acts done for experimental purposes relating
to the subject matter of the invention.
10
D. Gilat, Experimental Use and Patents, 16 IIC 1 (1995).

40

The patent balance

(EUE) is to prevent technical and scientific progress from becoming


paralysed.11
The EUE relates to two types of experiments: market-oriented and researchoriented.12 Market-oriented experiments include generic drug manufacturers
who seek to make the drugs during the patent life in order to obtain marketing
authorisation and sell the generic products as soon as the patent lapses. The
position regarding these types of experiments has been more or less settled following the introduction of the Drug Price Competition and Patent Term
Restoration Act 198413 in the USA, and the recent adoption of the Bolar exception in the EU.14
In the context of research tools, however, the issue is different. Typical litigants do not involve a research and a generic drugs company, but rather it
involves two research companies which have invested a large amount of financial resources and time in R&D. In such cases, the issue before the courts
involves the question of which policy would better serve the promotion of
progress: an ex ante incentive to invest, disclose and innovate or the ex post legitimation of research and development efforts which have contributed to
advancing technology one step forward.15
This distinction has been recognised in several European cases. For example,
the German Supreme Court in the Ethofumesate case stated that experimental
activities are considered permissible to the extent that they serve the purpose of
technically perfecting and further developing the patented subject matter.16

11
See ibid. and British case Frearson v Loe (1878) Ch.D. 48, 66, where Jessel MR
said that if a man merely makes a bona fide experiment with the aim of improving upon
the invention the subject matter of the patent, or with the view of seeing whether an improvement can be made or not, that is not an invasion of the exclusive rights granted by
the patent. Patents were never granted to prevent persons of ingenuity exercising their
talents in a fair way.
12
Ibid.
13
Drug Price Competition and Patent Term Restoration Act 1984, Public Law
98-417.
14
See 11 March 2004 when the Council of Ministers adopted a new European
Pharmaceutical regulatory package including a provision allowing pre-patent expiry
development work and registration and generic approval. Directive 2004/27/EC of the
European Parliament and of the Council amending Directive 2001/83/EC, on the Community code relating to medicinal products for human use O.J 2004 L 36/34.
15
D. Gilat (1995) op. cit. p.9.
16
Ethofumesate Case 22 IIC 541 (1991), p.546. The Supreme Court distinguished
experiments aimed at developing the subject matter of the patent and experiments aimed
at gaining an advantage in the market once the patent expires.
A similar distinction can be found in the British Case Frearson v Loe (1878) 9 Ch.D.
48, and in the Dutch case Medicopharma N.V. et al. v ICI plc, 14 Rechtspraak van de
week 7989 (1993).

The patent system and some potential safety nets

41

The application of the EUE remains a highly contentious matter with different
authors arguing for different applications.17 It seems that one of the guiding
principles in its application involves checking whether consensual licensing
would take place so that the exemption covers the other cases.18
The EUE is linked, to a large extent, to the problem of high transaction costs
which hinder the carrying out of experiments. From a policy perspective, it is
desirable that competitors should be able to experiment and improve on an invention, especially in fields such as the biopharmaceutical industry where
therapeutic advances are of great significance.
It is unlikely that a licence would be negotiated as the parties usually have
different views on the value, validity and scope of protection of the patent and
the experiment, and therefore the transaction costs for such negotiations are
likely to be significant. In addition, if a product patent is framed in a way that
includes all therapeutic indications and the exemption cannot be invoked, it is
impossible for someone to search for new indications as the patent holder would
view him as a possible future producer and would be reluctant to negotiate a licence. This situation would impede competition and innovation within the scope
of the patents already granted. If research can result in a product with added
value, the experimental use exception should probably be applicable, as it is not
likely that this research would happen without it. The transaction costs would
prevent the negotiation of a license.19 In such cases, experiments using the invention as an object and not as a tool are exempt.
Therefore, if a competitor seeks to use the invention, as there is a danger that
the inventors profits will decrease when the experimenter commercially exploits
his results, it is unlikely that a licensing arrangement will be made. If the experimenter seeks to invent around the patent, denying the exemption might result
in the paralysation of progress, whereas invoking it would undermine incen-

17
See R.D. Hantman, Experimental Use as an Exception to Patent Infringement,
67 JPTOS 617 (1985) basing the distinction on monetary profit or lack of it and distinguishing experimenting on and for experimental purposes. See also N.A. Israelsen,
Making, Using and Selling Without Infringement: An Examination of 35 U.S.C.Sec.271(e)
and the Experimental Use Exception to Patent Infringement, 16 AIPLA Q.J. 457
(198889); R.S. Eisenberg, Patents and the Progress of Science: Exclusive Rights and
Experimental Use, 56 Univ. Chi. Law Rev. 1017 (1989); L.T. Welch, The Experimental
Use Exception to Patent Infringement in the USA, 19 Patent & Licensing 17 (1989); D.E.
Tuffery, Experimental Use as a Defense to Infringement in New Zealand, Patent World,
Oct. (1992), p.22.
18
D. Gilat (1995) op. cit. pp.19 and 29 According to the thesis suggested in this
study, where there is no barrier to a consensual license or an assignment transaction between the patentee and the user of the invention an exemption from patent infringement
is not required.
19
B. Domeij (2000) op. cit.

42

The patent balance

tives to invent. The conclusion was that the patent policy of encouraging
inventing around should prevail over the incentives policy.20
Hence, a distinction was drawn between experimenting on and experimenting with the patented invention. The former refers to use in order to study its
underlying technology and to invent around the patent which is considered
exempted, while the latter refers to use in order to study something else that
is not covered by the exemption. Hence, for example, a research tool that is
used for conducting work will require permission from the patent holder,
whereas people that study the research tools themselves will be considered
exempted.21
As regards the interpretation of the provision in the different European countries, it appears that Germany is the most liberal in its interpretation. German
courts generally find that the use of the patented invention to obtain further information about the product falls within the exception.22 During the mid-1990s,
the German Supreme Court in two cases known as Clinical Trials I and II,23
ruled that experiments or trials on a patented substance such as pharmaceutical
products were permitted, both in order to test the claimed properties and for
new indications, as long as they were directed on the substance itself. The
Constitutional Court of Germany affirmed these decisions in the interest of the
development of the state of the art and the public interest.24
20
See D. Gilat (1995) op. cit. p.53 referring to a distinction as to mere improvement
and delineation of substitute and alternative.
21
One may question whether this is a sensible approach as it is exactly in the case
of improvements and competing products that the patent exclusivity may be advantageous. None the less, it is thought that this amounts to research in the technology field
and that the inventions are used for a different purpose than that for which they were
originally created. Hence, this only represents a small loss of revenue to the patentee as
his main market resides in their non-experimental uses. The fact that such research may
lead to improvements or new competing products that are patentable does not change
the analysis. On the other hand, it is felt that experimentation with a patented invention
does not advance the field of technology or contribute to innovation as they leave the invention unchanged, hence this is not exempted.
See P. Ducor, Research Tool Patents and the Experimental Use Exemption A no-win
situation? 17 Nature Biotechnology 1027 (1999).
22
C. Laherty and Y. Shibata, Harmonization of Patent Term Extension and Experimental Use Laws Related to Drug Development and Testing, Comparative Patent law
Seminar, Spring 2001 at http://www.law.washington.edu/casrip/Harmonization/PDF/ExperimentalUse.pdf.
23
Klinische Versuche I (BGH, 11 July 1995); Klinische Versuche (BGH, 17 April
1997); 1997 IIC 103
24
See Cases Federal Supreme Court (BGH) 11 July 1995, GRUG 1996, 109 Klinische Verusche and 5 December 1995 GRUG 1996, 190 Zwanglizenz concerning the
protein, interferon. The Dsseldorf Court of Appeals held that experiments undertaken
that neither establish the characteristics of the substance nor the feasibility of its produc-

The patent system and some potential safety nets

43

On the other hand, the exception has been construed more narrowly in the
UK.25 For example, in the case Smith Kline & French Laboratories Ltd v Evans
Medical Ltd [1989] FSR 513, experimental purposes relating to the subject
matter of the invention was interpreted to mean in the sense of having a real
and direct connection with that subject matter.26

tion fall outside the scope of s.11(2) as otherwise it would be inconsistent with the
principle of product patents extending to all possible uses of its subject matter. The Court
stressed that what was important was not the activity itself but the purpose of the activity,
but that experiment was limited to those directed to the subject matter of the patented
invention.
25
See Frearson v Loe [1878] 9 Ch.D. 48, where the Court held that experimentation
with a patented product with no intention to sell or use but just to improve upon the invention or to see whether an improvement can be made does not amount to infringement.
See also Monsanto v Stauffer [1985] RPC 515 CA, where the Court stated trials carried
out in order to discover something unknown or to test an hypothesis or even in order to
find out something which is known to work in specific conditions would work in different
conditions or even perhaps to see if the experimenter could manufacture commercially
in accordance with the patent. These can fairly be regarded as experiments, but trials
carried out in order to demonstrate to a third party [such as a regulatory body] that a
product works, or in order to amass information to satisfy a third party, whether a customer or body that the product works as its maker claims are not to be regarded as acts
done for experimental purposes. Of course the recent European Directive referred to
above has to some extent changed and harmonised the position as regards regulatory
bodies.
See also Smith Kline & French Laboratories Ltd v Evans Medical Ltd [1989] FSR
513, observing what is or not an experiment must depend on the facts of each case but
can include experiments designed with a commercial end view.
In Inhale Therapeutic Systems Inc v Quadrant Healthcare Plc [2002] RPC 21, the
Patents County Court observed it is said that there is a defence of experimental use.
This fails on the facts. None of the exploitation of the products or technology complained
of was conducted by Quadrant for its own experimental purposes. In all cases Quadrant
was trying to exploit and sell its technology to third parties. This is not experimental
use. To the extent this viewpoint is endorsed it seems that the UK is moving away from
the liberal stance of Germany towards the more narrow view of the exemption of the
USA.
26
See M. Fysh, Supplementary Certificate Legal Issues in Exploiting Drug Patents
in Europe, LES-Italy Conference, Milan, 2002, I believe that the exception may therefore have a very narrow effect under UK/Irish law. The qualification may cover such acts
as verifications of various kinds (such as seeing whether a compound can be made as
proposed or will work in a particular climate), assessment of validity, and in-house experiment for the purpose of improvement and modification etc. But the exception would
not in my view exclude the use of a patented process in experiments specifically to test
some other product or process with the view to the direct use of the results thereof for a
commercial purpose.

44

The patent balance

3.2.1.2 The US experience: a helpful paradigm?


The experimental use doctrine originated in the USA as a narrow judge-made
exemption to patent infringement for anyone who makes, uses or sells a patented
invention purely to satisfy scientific curiosity, or philosophical reasons. It was
initially expounded by J. Story in a dictum in Whittemore v Cutter27 in 1813, in
which he stated that it could never have been the intention of the legislature to
punish a man who constructed a patented machine merely for philosophical
experiments, or for the purpose of ascertaining the sufficiency of the machine
to produce its described effects. In Sawin v Guild,28 J. Story further elaborated
on the exceptions to infringement. In order to constitute an infringement, it must
involve the making with intent to use for profit, not for the mere purpose of
philosophical experiment, or to ascertain the verity and exactness of the
specification.
The defence reflects an understanding that the interests of the patent holder
are not harmed, and this is dependent to a large extent on whether the alleged
infringer derives profit from the patented article. However, in most cases, the
defence has failed, and whilst the recent US decision of Madey v Duke29 affirms
the existence of the doctrine, it defined its applicability in a very narrow sense. 30
The scope of the exemption remains unclear both in terms of applicability and
policy.
The breadth of the exemption relies on how one defines curiosity, amusement
and philosophical experiment. Arguably, the latter is prone to different interpretations that would have different implications on the applicability of the
exemption. Could philosophical include the acts of designing around an invention as this arguably leads to the creation of new knowledge?
The exemption shifts the importance to the intention behind the use of the
patent, and directs an evaluation into whether the use is commercial or not. The
making must be with an intent to infringe the patent rights, and deprive the
owner of the lawful rewards of his discovery.31 Damages will only be available
where there is some commercial use involved, yet damages cannot be used alone
as the benchmark of its application as there might also be non-infringing uses
that result in a loss of revenue to the patent holder, which he would not be justified in claiming. In addition, while infringement consists of use, inter alia,

27

Whittemore v Cutter 29 F.Cas 1120 (C.C.D. 1813).


Sawin v Guild 21 F.Cas 554 (C.C.D. 1813) (No. 12,391).
29
Madey v Duke 01-1567 US CA for Fed. Circ. 307 F.3d 1351.
30
Ibid. See also Embrex Inc. v Service Engineering Corp 99-1064, USCA for Fed.
Cir., 216 F.3d 1343; 2000 U.S. App. LEXIS 15036; 55 U.S.P.Q.2D (BNA) 1161, June
28, 2000, Decided; where the Federal Commission commented that the experimental
use exemption is construed very narrowly.
31
Sawin v Guild, 21 F.Cas 554 (C.C.D. 1813) (No. 12,391) and J. Story dicta.
28

The patent system and some potential safety nets

45

irrespective of the purpose of the use, under patent law, the exemption imports
a subjective evaluation into the motives underlying the use. The extent to which
this is sound is contentious. Can intent and purpose make something exempt
from infringement when it is irrelevant to establishing an infringement in the
first place?
In the case of corporations, there is an unspoken assumption that these activities are motivated by a commercial intent. Hence, a distinction was initially
made in the case of universities, where it was thought that there was no commercial intent. This assumption, however, has been called into question in
recent times with the increasing commercialisation of activities on the part of
universities, especially in the USA.32 However, when does a use become commercial? Even while researching or upon the development of a commercial
product? Under the current status of the exemption it seems that even use for
the purpose of testing will be infringing if it also has a proximate commercial
purpose.
Hence, the practical utility of such an exemption can be questioned. It is
thought that an infringement action is unlikely to occur in the first place in cases
where an invention is used for commercially insignificant purposes, and while
the exemption may exist in theory, it is hard to sustain it in practice. It seems to
be applicable only in cases of use to assess the commercial viability and applicability of the results where that does not lead to commercial gain for the user
and a loss of interest for the patentee.33
With regard to the specific case of pharmaceuticals, in the USA, in the case
of Roche Products v Bolar Pharmaceutical Company,34 the CAFC in 1984 rejected the argument that a generic drug manufacturer should be able to use a
patented drug to conduct clinical trials during the term of the patent, with a view
to commercialisation immediately after the expiration of the patent. It was held
that the defence is truly narrow and cannot permit experiments conducted with
a view to commercial exploitation.
The US Congress has, however, reconsidered the effects of this ruling as it
was felt it, in fact, extended the term of effective patent protection to include

32

R. Eisenberg (2001) op. cit.


In US common law the defence has seldom succeeded. In Whittemore v Cutter
29 F.Cas. 1120 (C.C.D. 1813) the use of a product to assess its applicability to a commercial process was exempted. Similarly, in Akro Agate Co. v Master Marble Co. No.
119, District Court, N.D. West Virginia, 18 F. Supp. 305; 1937 US Dist. LEXIS 2087,
16 January 1937; the use of a machine merely to assess its usefulness that was then
abandoned voluntarily was also found exempted. But these represent very specific and
limited instances of philosophic inquiry.
34
Roche Products v Bolar Pharmaceutical Company 733 F.2d 858 (CA Fed.), cert.
denied, 469 US 856 (1984).
33

46

The patent balance

the period required for generic companies to obtain marketing authorisation


once the patent had expired, in other words, for another one to two years. It also
noted that there was no economic effect on the patent holders by virtue of such
conduct. In view of the significant impact it might have on public health, it
amended the statute to permit the use of inventions for the purpose of developing
and submitting information under laws regulating the manufacture, use or sale
of drugs.
The Drug Price Competition and Patent Terms Restoration Act 1984 202,
later codified as 35 USC 271(e)(1)(2001),35 permits clinical trials for the purpose of providing data to official regulatory authorities for market clearance of
a medicine developed by a non-licensed third party covered by a patent that is
due to expire. It protects drug manufacturers whose use of products is necessary
to satisfy the pre-market testing requirements of the FDA: the patented drugs
should be used solely for purposes reasonably related to testing requirements
under federal law.36 Furthermore, reasonably related is an objective test of
acts deemed to constitute an infringement except for 271.
Therefore, although Bolar was overruled, the judgment still presents a valuable insight into the notion of infringement, as the patent cannot be permitted
under the guise of scientific inquiry when the inquiry has definite, cognizable
and not insubstantial commercial purposes.37
While the US experience has proved useful in encouraging Europe to also
endorse a Bolar-type exemption, the dilemmas facing research tools and the
problem with the applicability of the experimental use exemption is the same
and might even be more heightened in view of their more limited interpretation
of the doctrine.
3.2.1.3 Conclusion on the EUE
The purpose of the experimental use doctrine is not to subsidize new research
at the expense of the patentee, but rather to allow such research when market
forces prevent it.38 In the case of research tools used by other researchers for
the purpose for which they were created, it was traditionally believed that no
barrier to licensing exists as they are the ordinary consumers, and therefore the
exception should not be invoked.39 The distinction between experimenting on

35

Public Law 98-417.


G.N. Pate, Analysis of the Experimental Use Exception, 3(2) North Carolina
Journal of Law and Technology 253 (2002).
37
For an analysis of the Bolar exemption see J. Love, Bolar Exemption, 1998 at
http://lists.essential.org/1998/pharm-policy/msg00004.html.
38
D. Gilat (1995) op. cit. p.41.
39
Ibid. p.44. See also R.S. Eisenberg, Proprietary Rights and the Norms of Science
in Biotechnology Research, 97 Yale L. J. 177 (1987) p.225.
36

The patent system and some potential safety nets

47

and experimenting with would not provide access in cases of downstream research, as it would be inapplicable. The problem is that researchers are ordinary
consumers of patented research tools, and that if these consumers were exempt
from infringement liability, the patent holder would have nowhere else to turn
to collect patent royalties.40
In light of the increasing difficulties in reaching an agreement or securing a
licence, however, this assumption may be called into question. The Working
Group on research tools has concluded that an EUE should not be available to
those working with a patented invention as such workers are truly ordinary
consumers of the tool.41 This is only reasonable, however, if the research tools
to these people can be freely acquired in the marketplace at a reasonable cost
via anonymous purchasing without the need for licensing transactions. The
growing incidence of high transaction costs associated with accessing multiple
patented research tools contravenes the ordinary consumer assumption, however.
When research tool transaction costs are severe enough to impede or stop the
development of new biomedical products, line-drawing between experimenting
on and experimenting with may no longer be justified.42
In addition, there may be further complications with maintaining this distinction, as the Australian Department of Health and Ageing has stated:
It should also be noted that there are also practical problems in some fields of
technology in making this distinction including biotechnology, with its tendency
towards broad patents research using knowledge of the structure of a gene, directed towards identifying treatment for disease associated with abnormal forms
of the gene may be regarded as research with the gene. Research intended to identify
variation within the gene may be regarded as research on the invention. However,
clinical diagnostic testing, which can be regarded as technology subject to commercial application, could in principle be thought of as research on the invention.
This is in the sense that it is research directed towards identifying the exact structure
or property of the invention in the specific individual being tested. The distinction
between research genetic testing and clinical diagnosis is also clouded by the fact
that, although the objectives may differ, the processes generally remain identical.
This problem seems inherent in the patenting of inventions which are also a form
of discovery.43

40

R. Eisenberg (1996) op. cit.


J.M. Mueller (2001) op. cit. p.40.
42
Ibid. p.40.
43
ACIP, Patents and Experimental Use, Options Paper, Advisory Council on Intellectual Property, December 2004.
41

48

The patent balance

3.2.2 The Reverse Doctrine of Equivalents and Blocking Patents


The reverse doctrine of equivalents is an equitable doctrine devised by the courts
in the USA to excuse infringement even though it may be within the scope of
the patent claim, by taking the importance of the improvement in question into
consideration. Although falling within the literal words of the claim, it refers to
a situation in which the improvement performs the same or similar function in
a substantially different way, and in this way, the reverse doctrine of equivalents
is used to bring it outside the scope of patent protection.44
While the US Supreme Court has made reference to this doctrine on several
occasions,45 the Federal Circuit has viewed it with some scepticism although it
has been validated in theory.46 None the less, the doctrine has rarely been invoked and even more rarely applied, therefore, its practical effectiveness remains
a contested issue.
In the EU no provision is made as to the reverse doctrine of equivalents, although a proposal for a similar measure has been made. Domeij has proposed
that the reverse doctrine of equivalents should be used in Europe so as to facilitate the entry of new products into the market that are of high value to consumers
in cases that would otherwise encroach on the scope of the patent granted.47
However, it appears that the indirect use of the principle may be made upon interpreting the scope of the patent.
It has been argued that the doctrine is a judicial response to the likelihood of
breakdown in bargaining between the pioneer and the improvers.48 This breakdown is likely to occur, first, due to the difficulty in setting the value on the
relative contributions and, secondly, the uncertainty over the future development
of the technology, as well as its profitability.49 Strategic bargaining may aggravate the situations and lead to a failure in reaching an agreement, despite the
existence of a cooperative surplus.

44
L.A. Handley, Refining the Graver Tank Analysis with Hypothetical Claims: A
Biotechnology Exemplar, 5 Harvard J. Law & Tech 31 (1991).
45
See Westinghouse v Boyden Power Brake Co. 170 US 537 (1898), and Graver
Tank case 339 US 605 (1950).
46
Wilson Sporting Goods v David Geoffrey & Associations, 904 F.2d 677 (Fed. Cir.
1991). See also Amgen Inc. v Chugai Pharmaceutical Co. 927 F.2d 1200 (Fed. Cir. 2000),
and Scripps Clinic and Research Foundation v Genetech Inc. 927 F.2d 1565 (Fed. Cir.
1991), where the Federal Circuit limited the scope of the inventors claims of purified
natural products and applied the reverse doctrine of equivalents.
47
B. Domeij (2000) op. cit.
48
R. Merges, IPRs and Bargaining Breakdown: The Case of Blocking Patents, 62
Tenn. L. Rev. 75, (1994).
49
Ibid.

The patent system and some potential safety nets

49

In such cases, the reverse doctrine of equivalents promotes the voluntary licensing between parties by creating a threat to the pioneer patentee, encouraging
them to reach a socially productive agreement without recourse to statutory
compulsory licensing. In the USA, it allows the radical improver to use the pioneer inventors idea in certain cases in which the latter would otherwise have
held the radical improver hostage.50 In such cases, it is not necessary to have
recourse to compulsory licensing as the improvement falls outside the scope of
protection. The radical improver is exempt from liability regardless of whether
it lies within the literal scope of the claim, so as to encourage its creation and
ensure it reaches the market.51
According to this, the improvement is treated as a function of its value and
significance in relation to the original invention. A minor improvement is not
eligible for a patent and in order to reach an agreement with the patent holder,
it must overcome Arrows paradox of information.52 The latter refers to the situation in which the improver is unable to protect the information once it has been
disclosed, yet needs to disclose it in some way in order to reach an agreement
with the patentee. The improver cannot stop the pioneer from using the improvement and it is unlikely that an agreement will be reached. The minor improver
is also likely to infringe, whether literally or by virtue of the doctrine of
equivalents.
In the case of a significant improvement, however, a property right is given
to the improver in the form of a patent, although his unauthorised use of the
original patent would still be infringing. This creates a mutually blocking situation which levels the bargaining power of parties and creates an incentive for
both parties to reach an agreement and to push technology forward.53
The rationale of the blocking patents doctrine in US patent law reflects the
statutory provision in EU law and in TRIPS regarding dependent patents. Under
European patent law, it is possible to get a compulsory licence in cases of a
secondary dependent patent that involves an important technological advance
of considerable economic interest.54 Hence, while there is no provision for
compulsory licensing (CL) of dependent patents in US law, as it exists in the
EU, the blocking patents doctrine attempts to have the same effect by maximising the situations in which licensing can occur. 55

50

M.A. Lemley (1997) op. cit.


Ibid.
52
Ibid.
53
R. Merges (1994) op. cit. The author elaborates on a transactional view of
IPRs.
54
See further down at 3.2.4.2(a).
55
R. Merges (1994) op. cit. Delineating the scope of the patent according to the
value of the improvement relative to the pioneer patent also overcomes the incentive ac 51

50

The patent balance

The transactional view of patents permeates doctrines such as the doctrine of


equivalents and the reverse doctrine of equivalents. Consideration is paid to
when parties are likely to reach an agreement and how to maximise the cases
of important agreements for follow-on innovation, so as to ensure that commercially value-added innovation reaches the market.
Despite the lack of certainty, in many respects, on the law relating to improvements and the delineation of the relationship between the initial and subsequent
patents, the extent to which the current provisions or doctrines would cater for
the problem of research tools is not clear. This is because, first, the reverse
doctrine of equivalents only applies to radically different inventions, and secondly, and most significantly, research tools do not usually fall within the
category of improvements.
As explained, access to research tools is mostly needed to research downstream pharmaceutical products. In such cases, the reverse doctrine of
equivalents would not remedy the problem relating to access. The doctrine could
only have a small role to play in cases dealing with improvements on the research tools as such, and even here it would be limited as it would only cover
radical improvements (involving inventing around) and would also fail to justify
of itself experimentations on the invention until such time as the improvement
has been developed.56 The doctrine would be of little use in cases in which access is needed to the research tool for downstream research. It therefore becomes
necessary to examine what other provisions may be used to give effect to such
concerns.

cess paradox of compelling access in cases where the incentive for the pioneer work is
most significant. This is because the improvements value is measured relative to the
original patent. Practical evidence, however, is equivocal on the role of commercially
added value as the most significant factor in determining the scope of patent protection.
It is feared that this will lead to uncertainty from a technical point of view as the scope
of protection will effectively depend on the value of the improvement. See the authors
proposal that the portion of the scope of protection devised by the courts be mainly
thought of as an ex post facto adjustment taking into account the value of the attacked
embodiment, and that the doctrine of equivalents be seen as an economic test not a
technical one. He argues that patent claims define the invention but do not conclusively
define the scope of protection since it is impossible at the time of the grant to foresee all
possibly infringing products that add something of importance and therefore should be
encouraged by the courts.
56
In fact, as regards access to the patented technology it provides no means of ensuring that and only seems to operate ex post to excuse infringement by taking the
improvement out of the pioneers scope. To that end see the experimental use exemption
analysed next.

The patent system and some potential safety nets

51

3.2.3 Patent Pools


The creation of patent pools provides another working solution to the problem
of blocking patents and stacking licences. Patent pools are predominantly used
in situations where patent thickets57 arise, so that the commercialisation of new
technologies is not impeded by an overlapping set of patent rights. They refer
to the aggregation of IPRs which are subject to cross licensing, whether they
are transferred directly by the patentee to the licensee or through some medium
such as a joint venture set up specifically to administer the patent pool.58 Patent
pools have been described as private liability rule organisations that function
in a similar way to compulsory licences except that they have been devised by
an organisation.59
Typically, a single entity licenses the patents of two or more companies to
third parties as a package, and this offers the convenience of a one-stop shop.
In cases of standardisation any patents necessary to comply with the standard
become really essential and, in such cases, patent pools may be particularly effective. Hence patent pools mostly arise in cases of standards, in cases where
essentiality is not readily defined or in cases where there are blocking patents
from different companies that are not part of a standard.60 Where a patent is essential to the practice of the relevant technology field then the blocking situation
is present.
Patent pools are typically created in industries in which parties have a longstanding relationship and form a homogenous group, where there are repeat-play
transactions and they hold mutually blocking patents.61
While the object is to ensure that access to essential inputs is not impeded, it
refers predominantly to a situation of complementary and multiple patent rights
that are interdependent and potentially inter-blocking in the absence of coordination. Hence, they are more a solution to the balkanisation of rights that may
lead to higher prices than a single package price, high licence fees and may also

57
For an explanation of the term patent thicket, see C. Shapiro, Navigating the
Patent Thicket: Cross Licenses, Patent Pools and Standard-Setting, UCLA Department
of Economics in its series Levines Working Paper Archive no. 122247000000000539,
2004.
58
J. Clark, J. Piccolo, B. Stanton, K. Tyson, Patent Pools: A Solution to the Problem
of Access in Biotechnology Patents? US PTO, 5 December (2000) at http://www.uspto.
gov/web/offices/pac/dapp/opla/patentpool.pdf.
59
See R.P. Merges, Institutions for Intellectual Property Transactions: The Case
of Patent Pools, in R. Dreyfuss et al., Expanding the Boundaries of Intellectual Property,
Oxford, Oxford University Press (2001).
60
J. Kubalski, Comments on Patent Pools and Standards, for the FTC Hearings on
IP and Antitrust, January 2002.
61
ACIP (2004) op. cit.

52

The patent balance

dynamically be a drag on innovation, than access to a single essential input


technology.62 Patent pools are particularly effective in cases of complementary
as opposed to substitute patents, minimising transaction costs in negotiating
individual licences and reducing the possibilities of a hold-up problem.63
Patent pools are perceived as particularly beneficial in the biotechnology industry as they may assist in integrating technology, reduce the often high
transaction costs, prevent blocking positions, avoid costly litigation and promote
the dissemination of technology. The biotech landscape, it is often felt, is such
that the vast amount of genetic information and its significance as a fundamental research tool even absent functional knowledge can give rise to an almost
overwhelming number of patents, the true value of which may be unascertainable without the cooperative efforts of other companies.64
Hence one-stop shopping may be particularly effective in this industry to save
time, money and resources that can be directed instead to further innovation.65
It also leads to the distribution of risk benefit as the members share the risks associated with R&D and each member may receive a set of income based on the
percentage of the royalty earned from the pool. It can also be advantageous as
it provides a mechanism for the free sharing of technical information relating to
the patented technology and provides an incentive for avoiding overlapping efforts, leading to a more effective and efficient allocation of limited resources.
However, these perceived benefits have not gone unchallenged. First, it is
questionable whether the genetic inventions market is amenable to patent pools.
While there is a significant degree of interdependence and high transaction costs,
some have argued that unlike the electronic industry, the definition of standards
and need to ensure interoperability is not essential in the pharmaceutical industry, especially in the development of therapeutics.66 It is also often found that
the number of patents to which access is effectively required is usually
manageable.
Patent pools have also been criticised as potentially ineffective in view of the
likely disagreement over the value of the patents. In addition, as the industry is
made up of diverse, heterogeneous players and parties who are often involved
in one-off transactions, the usefulness of pools may be limited.67 Criticism is

62

C. Shapiro (2004) op. cit.


Ibid. See also R.P. Merges (2001) op. cit. describing the need for strict complimentarity of patent pools, i.e. that none of the parties be able to have any return in the
absence of an agreement to pool.
64
L. Sung, Greater predictability may result in patent pools, 8 February 2002 in
CPTech on Collective Management of IPRS: Patent Pools at www.cptech.org.
65
J. Clark et al. (2000) op. cit.
66
OECD (2002) op. cit.
67
ACIP (2004) op. cit. p.59.
63

The patent system and some potential safety nets

53

also made regarding the fact that they may inflate the costs of competitively
priced goods (although this could be remedied if truly blocking patents are
identified), shield invalid patents and encourage collusion and price fixing.68
The latter, however, would seem to be amenable to control if an independent
expert were charged with evaluating the patents, and if a field of application
could be defined and the essential patents identified. In this case, the patent
pools may be deemed worthy of consideration.
Empirical evidence has shown that some patent pools have been created in
the biotech industry such as the SNP Consortium and the Genebank pool.69
These have been viewed as particularly effective pools. On the other hand, empirical evidence from Germany has shown that patent pools were not deemed
to be effective in increasing access to genetic inventions due to the difficulty in
assessing contributions.70 Furthermore, in some cases, pools have been found
to be inefficient. For example, the patent pool between VISX and Summit
Technology, of the only two FDA-approved manufacturers of lasers used in
photo refractive keratoctomy, was condemned as it was perceived to act as a
tool for fixing prices and eliminating horizontal competition between the companies, in view of the ability of both companies to enter the market
independently.71 The careful examination of the true complementarity and dependency therefore seems to be paramount.72
In conclusion, while patent pools may prove particularly advantageous in
certain cases, it would seem that they have been directed more towards the
problem of the proliferation of patent rights and the creation of patent thickets,
than to the problem of access to a single essential upstream technology as in
the case of research tools.73 In order for patent pools to function, a symmetrical
structure is required in which everyone owns patents. This is not usually the
case for upstream biotechnological research and downstream pharmaceutical
developments. Patent pools are also usually dependent on the voluntary decision
to pool the patents, which is not likely to arise in the absence of interdependence
in cases of access to essential inputs.

68

J. Clark et al. (2000) op. cit.


This is analysed in CPTech on Collective Management of IPRS: Patent Pools at
www.cptech.org.
70
J. Strauss (2002) op. cit.
71
CPTech on Collective Management of IPRS: Patent Pools at www.cptech.org.
72
See though R.P. Merges (2001) op. cit. who argues that the most important factors
are open membership to the pool and non-exclusive licensing.
73
See the submissions on p.59 ACIP (2004) op. cit. It should be remembered that
patent pools are promoted as a solution to patent thickets, or anti-commons issues, so
they do not assist where blocking patents are used in an exclusionary manner.
69

54

The patent balance

3.2.4 Compulsory Licensing in the Patent Provisions


3.2.4.1 Introduction to compulsory licensing
(a) Definition and History
A compulsory licence enables a government to license a third party to use the
patented invention without the patent holders consent. The competent authority
will grant the licence to a designated body or person that usually compensates
the patent holder by providing him with reasonable remuneration. Contrary to
other balancing mechanisms in the patent system, compulsory licences do not
arise automatically but instead only after a decision has been made by the competent body.
Historically, compulsory licensing (CL) arose to ameliorate the risk of forfeiting the patent, which was used to encourage the development of national
industry by requiring a domestic patentee to work his invention, directly or indirectly in the relevant country.74 Patentees are generally required to work their
invention in nearly every country in which a patent has been obtained.75 Forfeiture of the patent, however, as a sanction for failing to work it, had social costs,
especially in instances where investment and/or know-how was not sufficient
to encourage competitors to produce the invention themselves. CL developed
against this background, marking a shift of the sanction from forfeiture to
CL.76
(b) Support and Opposition for CL
CL has been met with support but also with opposition. There are several factors
that point to the desirability of CL when certain conditions are met.77 CL might
be considered desirable, first, where the demand for the product has not been
met.
According to economic theory, a monopolist will intentionally under-supply
goods (to sell at higher prices) in order to maximise profit. In such circumstances, CL may facilitate entry into the market leading to enhanced consumer

74
J. Reichman, C. Hasenzahl, Non-Voluntary Licensing of Patenting Inventions:
Historical Perspective, Legal Framework under TRIPS, and an Overview of the Practice
in Canada and the USA, UNCTAD (2002), p.5.
75
See survey of patent laws in Table 3.2.
76
See Art. 5 of the Paris Convention for the Protection of Industrial Property of 20
March 1883 as revised at Brussels on 14 December 1900, at Washington on 2 June 1911,
at the Hague on 6 November 1925, at London on 2 June 1934, at Lisbon on 31 October
1958, and at Stockholm on 14 July 1967, and as amended on 2 October, 1979.
77
See also ACIP (2004) op. cit. p.58 confirming the perception of the compulsory
licensing as desirable as a tool in certain cases.

The patent system and some potential safety nets

55

choice and lower prices. There is a risk, however, of eliminating the monopoly
position of the intellectual property (IP) holder, although this may be justified
to assure a more complete utilization and commercialization of innovative
products.78
Compulsory licences may also be desirable in certain cases as they may facilitate further innovations, especially the case of improvements or patents
building upon previous ones. Proponents of this view also argue that IP rights
can reinforce market power in the areas of network industries. CL may also be
desirable for products which are vital to the public, such as those relating to
public health, welfare and national defence.79
CL is also supported under patent law by virtue of deadweight loss concerns.
According to the deadweight loss argument, wasteful levels of research activity
can be invested in the race to be the first to innovate and reap the first-mover
profits. The reason is that social utility is a function of the overall likelihood of
innovation which is a function of the absolute level of research activity.80 Therefore, in line with this argument, there may be some benefits in weakening IP
protection through CL as it results in a reduction in wasteful activity.
Indeed, in certain cases, considerations of explicit costs and opportunity costs
could militate against the provision of a particular product or service at a higher
rather than a lower level.
The socially optimal level of a particular good is the level at which the marginal
benefit of providing another unit is equal to the marginal cost of providing an additional unit. Pointing to the fact that CL will lead to a less-than marginal level of R&D
is not dispositive as the social cost of providing those additional units of research
may outweigh their social utility.81
78
C.M. Fauver, Compulsory Patent Licensing in the US: An Idea Whose Time Has
Come, 8 J Intl. L Bus. 666 (1988).
79
Ibid.
80
T.C. Bailey, Innovation and Access: The Role of Compulsory Licensing in the
Development and Distribution of the HIV Drug, U. Ill. J. L. Tech. & Poly 193, 2001.
The author refers to the work of P. Tandon. The author explains that competing firms
will engage in absolute levels of research that exceed the point at which such activity
contributes positively to social utility, as it may contribute to the firms individual utility
by increasing the likelihood that it will invent first and reap the profits. In a dynamic
model, relaxation of patent protection may lead a firm to refrain from competition, and
although that may reduce research activity at an absolute level, the level may be socially
optimal avoiding wasteful activity. A firm will have an incentive to invest in a particular
industry as long as the profits earned in that industry are more than the average profit
rate of industry as a whole, assuming there are no barriers to entry. Hence, in such industries, weakening patent protection may not actually decrease innovation, or at least
may reduce it to an optimal level. P. Tandon, Optimal Patents with Compulsory Licensing
90(3) J. of Politl Econy 47086 (1982).
81
Ibid.

56

The patent balance

The social costs include the potential consumers who would be able to afford
a product or service in a competitive market but who cannot afford it at
monopoly prices. This is the deadweight loss associated with monopoly
pricing.82
CL has also been severely criticised, however, as it is feared that it reduces
incentives for the original innovation.83 This rests on the assumption that a reduction in incentives would dramatically reduce the level of investment. It is
also argued that a compulsory licence would discourage the IP owner to engage
in further research as he would have normally used the profits from the IPRs
for this purpose. Empirical evidence is ambiguous on this matter. For example,
an analysis of patenting activity from 1954 to 1956 has shown that patent owners
subject to CL significantly reduced their patenting activity.84 By contrast, a 1975
study did not find any evidence that CL adversely affected corporate R&D expenditure.85 It would seem, therefore, that the effect of CL is also dependent on
other factors, such as first-mover advantages and royalty rates.86
82
Ibid. Hence, the concept of deadweight loss considers the consumers who are
not able to afford the monopoly product, and the wasteful levels of research activity in
the race to reap the first-mover profits.
It should be noted, however, that this is part of a general problem and used as an argument on behalf of those advocating a liability system. See, for example, C.T. Taylor and
Z.A. Silberston, The Economic Impact of the Patent System, Cambridge, Cambridge
University Press (1973), pp.1989.
83
V. Korah, Compulsory Licenses and Incentives to Invest in Innovation and Compulsory Licenses, OECD (1998).
84
F.M. Scherer, The Economic Effects of Compulsory Patent Licensing, New York,
New York University Monograph Series in Finance and Economics (1977), pp.4350.
See also C.T. Taylor and Z.A. Silberston (1973) op. cit. pp.1989 which shows that
British pharmaceutical executives believed that some forms of licensing could harm
innovation.
85
H. Hovenkamp, J. Mark, M. Lemley, Intellectual Property and Antitrust: An
Analysis of Antitrust Principles Applied to Intellectual Property law, New York: Aspen
Law & Business, c. 2002, 2003 Supplement. See also F.M. Scherer (1977) op. cit.
pp.4350. He concludes that the licensing had no long-term negative impact on licensors
innovation, even for industries like pharmaceuticals. Indeed, companies subjected to
compulsory licensing actually spent more, on average, on R&D than similar firms in
their industry that had not been subjected to compulsory licensing. A study of Canadas
compulsory licensing programmes found similar results, i.e. that there was no negative
impact on pharmaceutical innovation. D.G. McFetridge, Intellectual Property, Technology Diffusion, and Growth in the Canadian Economy, in Competition Policy and
Intellectual Property Rights in the Knowledge Based Economy, R.D. Anderson and N.T.
Gallini (eds) (1998), p.65.
86
See, for example, C.V. Chien, Cheap Drugs at What Price to Innovation: Does
the Compulsory Licensing of Pharmaceuticals Hurt Innovation? 18 Berkeley Technology
Law Journal 853 (2003), pp.212 who analyses the effects of compulsory licensing and
states that it is likely to depend not only on the price that will be set but also two other

The patent system and some potential safety nets

57

(c) Grounds for Granting a Compulsory Licence


A survey of European and international IP law reveals that there are three primary grounds for CL: where a dependent patent is blocked; where a patent is
not being worked; or where the public interest so dictates whether because it
relates to food or medicine, to an antitrust remedy, to national defence or to the
sovereign.87
Accordingly, the TRIPS Agreement provides for three main cases in which
CL may arise. These include:

the non-use of a patent for three years from its grant or four years from
its application;
l when necessary to use a second otherwise infringing patent that constitutes an important technical advance of considerable economic
significance; and
l in cases of extreme urgency, crisis, or to remedy anti-competitive
behaviour.88

While the provisions relating to CL are sufficiently broad to cater for different
interpretations, the Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of Property Rights
(TRIPS Agreement) lays down some procedural safeguards that should be
followed in exercising the discretion to grant a CL. They stipulate that governments should consider the cases on their individual merits, that prior to the
authorisation of third party use there should be an effort to negotiate a voluntary licence on reasonable commercial terms, and that the government
provides adequate remuneration taking into account the economic value of
significant factors, namely, market significance and predictability. Market significance
refers to the extent to which a licensee actually threatens the patentees market, while
predictability refers to the extent to which a licensor anticipates a compulsory licence.
Unpredictable licenses that cover only existing technologies are more limited in scope
than those that are predictable and cover future inventions. Although unanticipated loss
of exclusivity that accompanies an unpredictable compulsory license may influence a
companys decisions about investing in follow-on innovation, development and commercialization, the licensing event may come at a point that is too late for the company
to change course. This is not the case with an order that requires licensing of future patents. The licensor may choose to redirect R&D investment, put off inventive activity
until the license has expired, or choose trade secret over patent protection. See also
Chapter 5 at 5.3.2.4 on harm to incentives.
87
The survey shows that some states merely refer to a broad notion of public interest
that could potentially include these more specific considerations, whereas others refer
more particularly to these three grounds. See survey of patent laws in Table 3.2. See also
G. Julian-Arnold, International Compulsory Licensing: The Rationales and the Reality,
1993 IDEA 349.
88
TRIPS Agreement (1994) op. cit.

58

The patent balance

the authorisation.89 Article 32(f) of TRIPS also requires that use should be
authorised predominantly for the supply of the domestic market.90
3.2.4.2 Analysis of the role of CL
(a) The Role of CL in Balancing Commensurability
As was shown above, it would seem that neither the EUE nor the patent pools
solutions are adequate in addressing the potential blocking of access to upstream
innovation. In such a technological environment, it would seem that the CL
provisions could serve many functions. On the one hand, it might work as a
factor to induce voluntary licensing, and on the other hand, it could be used as
a safety net to address substantive concerns.91
The usefulness of the CL provisions in the context of research tools depends
on both the substantive and the practical aspect. Substantively most countries
contemplate licences where the public interest so dictates. This diverts the question to the interpretation of public interest. Other countries refer more
specifically to the specific cases of non-use, dependent patents and emergency
or anti-competitive situations.92
(i) CL as a mechanism to induce broad licensing CL may be used as a means
to encourage and induce broad licensing techniques. Evidence has shown that
89
It should also be noted that some of these requirements may be waived in cases
of national emergency.
90
Related to this provision is the issue of the extent to which a country that has no
manufacturing capacity of its own could use CL to compel manufacturers in another
country to export to it. This issue is particularly relevant to developing countries, as the
South Africa and Brazilian experiences have shown. However, this issue is not addressed
in the present paper. In such cases, however, CL works to reduce the adverse effects that
patents may have on prices and availability. For developing countries, the issue which
needs to be resolved centres on how to overcome limitations on prospective importing
states as to the sources of the products, and of exporting states in their capacity to establish economies of scale. See F. Abbott, Compulsory Licensing for Pubic Health Needs:
The TRIPS Agenda and the WTO after the Doha Declaration on Public Health, Quaker
UN Office, February 2002, p.16. See also the recent developments with the Proposal for
a Regulation of the European Parliament and of the Council on Compulsory Licensing
of patents relating to the manufacture of pharmaceutical products for export to countries
with public health problems, COM/2004/0737 COD 2004/0258.
See also the Netherlands Policy rules on issuing compulsory licenses pursuant to the
WTO decision WT/L/540 on the implementation of paragraph 6 of the Doha Declaration
on the TRIPS Agreement and public health, under s.57(1) of the Kingdom Act on Patents
of 1995 available at www.cptech.org/ip/health/cl/netherlands-export-rules.html.
91
With regard to the latter, see H. Hovenkamp, J. Mark, M. Lemley (2003) op. cit.
para. 6-53, who state that: compulsory licensing should be used as a last resort.
92
See survey of patent laws in Table 3.2.

The patent system and some potential safety nets

59

even the threat of CL is effective in exerting power on firms to reach a consensual agreement on licensing. Hence in cases where the upstream patentee would
have otherwise refused to deal with a downstream competitor, the possibility of
a compulsory licence might be effective in obtaining a voluntary licence.
The Brazilian experience is illuminating in this respect.93 The government of
Brazil threatened to produce pegylated interferon locally, which is a medicine
used to cure Hepatitis C, unless the branded producers reduced their price. This
led to an agreement between the government and the patent-holder, Roche, who
offered to sell the drug in Brazil at an additional 40 per cent discount in order
for Brazil to refrain from issuing a compulsory licence. The practical value of
CL, therefore, is not only its use, but also that the threat of it usually induces
the grant of contractual licences on reasonable terms, and thus the objective of
actually working the invention is accomplished.94
(ii) CL for non-use It is in the interest of every state to promote the working
of the patents as this assures the supply of new and better goods.95 Non-use
provisions are therefore implemented in order to promote local working of the
inventions and to forward the public interest in having access to novel and desired subject matter.96
It is argued that this type of CL would not serve as a possible safety net in
the context of research tools as they address different issues. The research tool
problem is grounded on lack of access rather than a lack of any kind of working
of the patented invention.
(iii) CL for significant technological advances It is also possible to have
recourse to a provision allowing for the granting of a licence in cases in which
a product or process would otherwise be infringing a first patent, and which
represents an important technological improvement of considerable economic
significance.97

93

J. Reichman and C. Hasenzahl (2002) op. cit. p.97.


Ibid. See also Roches bid for a compulsory licence in May 2001 of Chirons
blood screening patents in Germany, which led to a licensing agreement between the
parties. See www.cptech.org/ip/health/cl/cl-eu.html.
95
Bhatnager, GATT Intellectual Property Protection Proposals in Context with
Developing Countries and the Paris Convention, 40 Patent World 33 (1992).
96
G. Julian-Arnold (1993) op. cit. p.349. See also S.P Ladas, Patents, Trademarks
and Related Rights: National and International Protection, Cambridge: Harvard University Press (1975), 2459, pp.42336.
97
This provision existed in Art. 21 of the 2000 version of the Proposal for a Council
Regulation, however, it was not included in the 2004 version. EC Commission Proposal
for a Council Regulation on Community Patent, 1 August 2000, COM (2000) 412 final
94

60

The patent balance

This is broadly referred to as the dependent patent, as it cannot be worked


without infringing the earlier issued patent.98 If a licence agreement has not
been reached, the dependent patent cannot be used. The ramifications of this
depend on the value of the second patent in relation to the first patent. Hence,
the hold-up problem could be significant where the improvement is of much
larger value than the original patent. In some countries, the delay in introducing
the improvement is perceived as being contrary to the public interest in having
the unencumbered working of all patented inventions.99 To this end, CL provisions seek to remedy this situation.
For example, Art. 36 of the Swiss Patent Law provides that: If a patented
invention cannot be used without violating the prior patent, the owner of the
more recent patent shall have the right to the grant of a licence to the extent required for such use of his invention, provided that that invention serves a purpose
entirely different from that of the prior patent, or that it involves a considerable
technical advance. The rationale is to provide incentives for the promotion of
technical and economic development.
Industry-specific similar provisions have also been created such as the European Directive on Biotechnological Inventions that allows breeders to request
a CL if it has not been possible to acquire or exploit a plant variety without infringing a prior patent.100 It also allows for CL where the patent holder cannot
use a protected variety without infringing third party rights.101
While these provisions may be desirable, it is questionable whether they are
sufficient as they have been narrowly interpreted and so only applied in exceptional cases.102 For example, the provision on substantial improvements was

Doc. 7119/04 PI 18, Revised Proposal for Council Regulation on the Community Patent,
8 March 2004.
See also UK section 48 Patents Act 1977; France Art. L 613.15 Industrial Property
Code 1992; Netherlands, section 57 Patent Act 1995. For example, in the UK
s.48(3)(d)(ii) provides that three years after the date of patent grant a compulsory licence may be granted where the working of another patented invention is being
prevented or hindered by the refusal to grant licences on reasonable terms. This is
subject to the condition that the compulsory licensee is prepared to cross-license its
own dependent patent on reasonable terms. (section 48(7) PA 1977). None the less,
this case of compulsory licensing has not been the subject of litigation in the UK. See
M. Kern (1996) op. cit.
98
See G. Julian-Arnold (1993) op. cit p.349.
99
Ibid. See survey in Table 3.2.
100
Biotech Directive (1998) op. cit. See also UK SI 2002/247 on Patents and Plant
Variety Rights (Compulsory Licensing) Regulations 2002 that envisage compulsory licensing in cases constituting significant technical progress of considerable economic
interest in relation to the invention protected by the patent.
101
Ibid.
102
M. Kern (1996) op. cit.

The patent system and some potential safety nets

61

applied by the German Federal Patent Court on 7 June 1991, in favour of the
granting of a CL.103 In this case, Bioferon owned a patent for a pharmaceutical
product, polyferon, for the treatment of chronic polyarthritis and it also held
dependent patents on specific uses of human immune interferon. The Court
found that there was a public interest in the medical use of polyferon which was
dependent on the dominant substance patent, however, in December 1995, the
Federal Supreme Court ruled that a CL would not be granted if the public interest could be satisfied with an alternative mechanism of equivalent effect. On the
facts, it found that the substantially improved therapeutic properties had not
been established.104
It is noteworthy that a study published in 1990 has shown that the last dependent compulsory licence in Japan had been granted more than 20 years before,
and that the Federal Court in Switzerland had not dealt with such a case since
the law had come into force in 1956.105
In cases involving a significant technological advance impeded by another
patent and raising public health concerns, one could potentially envisage the
use of CL under this provision to remedy the blocking effect, however, the usefulness of this approach has not been tested thus far.106
It should also be noted that it is unclear whether this provision can only be
used for improvements or if it can also be used for dependent downstream
technology. The wording of the Community Patent Regulation only provides
for a second infringing patent, therefore it, prima facie, covers both cases.
However, it seems that this provision would be inadequate to deal with cases
raising similar issues such as research tools, as use is required prior to any potential patent. Hence, it would seem that this provision could not be used in
cases of blocked access to an upstream innovation for downstream research, as
opposed to patents that have already been granted.107
(iv) CL to address health emergencies Most countries have provisions in
their patent laws relating to the grant of CL in situations involving a national
103
Zwangslizenz Federal Supreme Court (BGH), 5 December 1995, GRUR 1996,
190; 24 IIC 397 (1993). See also Grounds for Granting Compulsory Licensing, at www.
southecentre.org.
104
See Grounds for Granting Compulsory Licensing, at www.southecentre.org, p.4.
For a critique of the strict interpretation of the notion of public interest by the Court,
see M. Kern (1996) op. cit.
105
W.G. Walter, Compulsory Licenses and Dependent Patents, 21 IIC 532 (1990).
106
See IPR Helpdesk, Some Basic Issues Surrounding Improvements Made to Patented Invention and to Dependent Patents, at http://www.ipr-helpdesk.org/.
107
As it was shown earlier, downstream research to potentially obtain a second patent
would not be exempted under the experimental use exemption, as it would constitute
commercial use and experimenting with as opposed to on the invention.

62

The patent balance

emergency108 which may include health emergencies.109 Some countries, such


as the USA, have even enacted more sector-specific legislation to cater for the
particular interests affected by pharmaceutical patenting.
In this way, the Public Health Emergencies Act110 gives the US Secretary of
Health and Human Services broad discretion to issue CL to address public health
emergencies.111 It also provides that, in the determination of reasonable remuneration, account should be taken of the following factors: the risks and costs
associated with the invention; the efficacy and innovative nature and the importance of the invention or of products using the invention to public health; the
degree to which the invention has benefited from publicly funded research; the
need for adequate incentives for the creation and commercialisation of new inventions; the public interest in health care services; the public health benefits
of wider access to inventions; the benefits of making inventions available to
working families and retired persons; and the need to correct anti-competitive
practices or other public interest considerations. The USA has also enacted the
Affordable Prescription Drugs Act,112 that seeks to use competition to bring

108
See section 24(1) of the German Patent Act which states that If the applicant or
patentee refuses to permit the exploitation of the invention by another person offering
to pay reasonable compensation and to furnish security therefore, that person shall be
given authority to exploit the invention if permission is indispensable in the public
interest.
See also Art. L.613-16 of the French Code on Intellectual Property which provides
for compulsory licensing of patents if required in the interest of public health. According to WHOs publication, Globalization and Access to Drugs, Implications of the
WTO/TRIPS Agreement, WHO, November 1997, this law authorised this procedure when
patented drugs are only made available to the public in insufficient quantity or at abnormally high prices.
See also according to G. Julian-Arnold (1993) op. cit. p.349 who states that in Greece
for imperative reasons of public health, if the invention has been insufficiently exploited
to satisfy local needs a license may be granted.
On health emergencies, see Proposal for Regulation of the European Parliament and
Council on Compulsory Licensing of patents relating to the manufacture of pharmaceutical products for export to countries with public health problems, COM (2004) 737.
109
See Doha Declaration, WT/MIN(01)/DEC/1 November 2001 5(c) providing
Each member has the right to determine what constitutes a national emergency or other
circumstances of extreme urgency it being understood that public health crises can
represent a national emergency, or other circumstances of extreme urgency.
110
Public Health Emergencies Act HR 3235, 6 November 2001.
111
The anthrax scare in 2001 led the DHHS Secretary Thomson to seek a large
stockpile of ciprofloxacin (Cipro) that would be sufficient to treat 10 million people.
However, as the quantity was greater than Bayer was able to produce in a timely manner,
Thomson was asked to issue compulsory licences to generic manufacturers on 16 October. For more information see www.cptech.org/ip/health/cl/recent-example.html.
112
Affordable Prescription Drugs Act HR 1708, 27 April 2001.

The patent system and some potential safety nets

63

down the cost of the prescription drugs. If the patent privilege is misused at the
expense of consumers, generic competition is seen as having an important role
in ensuring broader access and reasonable prices. HR 2927 also provides for
the CL of certain patented medical inventions.113
The Competition Commission in South Africa found that GlaxoSmithKline
and Boehringer Ingelheim had contravened the Competition Act of 1998 and
abused their dominant positions in the anti-retroviral markets by virtue of excessive pricing in respect of ritonavir, lamivudine, ritonavir+lamivudine and
nevirapine.114 Therefore, this may provide another avenue to give effect to the
predominance of health concerns.
(v) CL as a remedy for anti-competitive conduct The final ground for granting a compulsory licence is to remedy practices found to be anti-competitive.115
In this context, it is possible to contemplate a situation in which a compulsory
licence could be imposed if a dominant firm refuses to grant access to its upstream innovation, thereby impeding innovation on downstream research or
follow-on innovation. This might represent a threshold that is lower than the
dependency provisions within the patent system as it does not necessitate the
existence of a significant technological advance of considerable economic interest. In this respect, it may be broader and more effective than the dependency
provision. On the other hand, it should be remembered that liability for a unilateral refusal to deal is only imposed in anti-trust law on dominant undertakings
and not on a general level. The implications of this type of CL are not dependent
on the internal patent provisions but rather on the external anti-trust
determination.
(b) Conclusions on CL
CL is envisaged to take many different forms in order to cater for the potential
problems relating to research tools. The outcome largely depends on the interpretation and the recourse made of the provisions relating to public interest/health
emergency, dependent patents and anti-competitive practices.
In view of the uncertainty of pharmaceutical patent protection regarding its
effect on prices, profitability and innovation, it is difficult to evaluate the desir-

113

Affordable Prescription Drugs Act, HR 2927, 23 September 1999.


For an extensive discussion see www.cptech.org/ip/health/cl/recent-examples.
html.
115
While this has not been found to be a ground justifying CL in most European
national patent laws, it is within the scope of lawful CL under TRIPS, and could find its
way into national law if it is deemed desirable through the interpretation of public interest which is present in most national systems. See survey of CL provisions in Table
3.2.
114

64

The patent balance

ability of compulsory licences. A study which analysed the effects of CL on the


R&D expenditure of firms and sought to establish whether the incentives to invest were hampered by such licences, found that in relation to the 70 companies
surveyed, a negative effect on R&D could not be established, and that there was
even a discernible rise in comparison to similar companies that were not subject
to such licences.116
As was shown, however, much depends on the interpretation and application
of the patent provisions as an overly narrow interpretation could render them
useless.117 Julian Arnold has found that compulsory licences have rarely been
applied in cases where dependent patents were blocked.118 This is due to the
practical problems associated with the fact that an improvement on the invention must be made prior to an application, a patent must have been granted,
the improvement patent must survive the possible length of the opposition
proceedings, and an attempt to voluntarily reach an agreement must have been
made. The dependency provisions might prove to be even less helpful in the
context of research tools as they apply to secondary patents and not research
as such.
CL may also prove to be problematic due to the costs associated with patent
litigation. The costs of the litigation in the AZT patent case were estimated at
$100,000 per day, and it is common in the US for parties to spend more than
$1million to litigate a patent dispute.119 In cases where access is needed to
simply carry out research with the research tool which is at a stage where it is
unclear whether it will be successful, these practical obstacles might be decisive
and might render CL inefficient.
Empirical evidence from other European countries confirms that although
some form of compulsory licence scheme exists, it is rarely exercised in practice.120 For example, statistical data for the German Federal Patents Court, which

116
See F.M Scherer, The Patent System and Innovation in Pharmaceuticals, Cambridge, Harvard University Press (1998), pp.1078; Grounds for Granting Compulsory
Licensing, www.southcentre.org, p.6. It is also known that pharmaceutical companies
spend more on advertising and promotion than on R&D which is hard to justify in the
case of life-saving drugs such as antiretrovirals, that are essential and do not require advertising. See F. Abbott (2001) op. cit. p.41.
117
See, for example, in Australia where only one application has been made to the
Federal Court for a CL on the grounds that the reasonable requirements of the public
with respect to the patented invention have not been satisfied. This claim was rejected.
See ACIP (2004) op. cit.
118
G. Julian-Arnold (1993) op. cit.
119
J. Love, Implementing TRIPS safeguards with particular attention to administrative models for compulsory licensing of patents, WHO meeting in Harare, Zimbabwe,
21 August 2001.
120
See M. Kern (1996) op. cit. p.2.

The patent system and some potential safety nets

65

was founded in 1961, shows that until the end of 1991 there had been only 12
cases in which parties had instituted proceedings for compulsory licences.121
In practice, compulsory licensing is not greatly used. Between 1991 and 1993, the
Patent Office did not receive any applications for compulsory licenses, although between 1988 and 1990 it received eight. As Jeremy Phillips has pointed out however,
these figures do not necessarily tell the whole story. The licensing provisions also act
as a form of deterrent against abuse or to look at it another way, of encouragement
to grant licenses voluntarily. Actual applications under s. 48 may therefore be regarded as instances where the compulsory license provisions have failed, while on
many other occasions they may have been successful in encouraging voluntary
agreements.122

Despite this, some governments might even be unwilling to impose a compulsory licence in cases of national emergency due to the uncertainty over the
potential compensation. It has been suggested that the reluctance of the Bush
administration to act in a way that would override the patent, could be attributed to the concern over what the Treasury might thereafter charge for lost
revenues. As a consequence of concerns about uncontrolled or unpredictable
costs, public health officials will act conservatively and expose the public to
higher risks.123
In conclusion, while CL might be associated with different contexts, the most
relevant patent law situation relates to dependent patents. The interpretation and
practical use of this provision has thus far been quite limited, therefore in its
current form it is doubtful whether it would be helpful in the context of research
tools. Apart from internal licensing, there are only two other instances that might
be helpful in the research tool context, which include cases of extreme urgency
including public health and CL as a remedy to anti-competitive conduct. However, as these involve licences outside the patent system, they need to be
analysed externally, in line with their own system. The application and interpretation of both of these cases as an effective means to address follow-on
innovation concerns are discussed in the following section. In this regard, it will
be endeavoured to ascertain the implications of the right to health on the duty
to deal and how this may potentially cater for situations of blocked access to
essential research inputs.

121

Ibid.
R. Battcock, IPRs, software copyright and competition law: restricting the rights
of intellectual property owners in the wider public interest, available at www.cptech.
org/ip/health/cl/cl-eu.html.
123
CPTech comments on H.R. 3235, the Public Health Emergency Medicines Act,
7 November 2001, http://lists.essential.org, p.1.
122

66

The patent balance

Table 3.2 European national provisions for compulsory licensing and on the
experimental use exemption
Country

Applicable statute

Compulsory licensing
provisions

Patent infringement
limitationsexperimental use
exemption

Austria

Austrian Patent Law


(Patentgesetz 1970) as
last amended by the
Law No. 234 of
23 May 1984

36. CL for
non working
dependent patents
where of
considerable
commercial or
industrial
significance
public interest

Denmark

The Consolidate
Patents Act
Patents Act No. 479
1967 as last amended
by Act No. 733,
27 Nov. 1989

CL for
non working (s.45)
dependent patents if
reasonable in view
of its importance
(s.46)
if required by
important public
interests (s.47)

Art. 3(3) excuses noncommercial use and


use for experimental
purposes relating to the
subject matter of the
invention

Finland

Finnish Patents Act


Patent Law
(Patenttilaki) No. 550
1967 as last amended
by Act No. 243,
21 Mar. 1997

CL for
non working (s.45)
dependent patents if
reasonable (s.23)
where considerable
public interest
(s.47)

Section 3: exclusive
right does not apply to
use of experiments
relating to the
inventions as such

France

Intellectual Property
Code
French Patent Act
Law No. 92-597 (as
last amended by Law
No. 96-1106 1996)

CL for non-working
and for dependent
patents
Art. L 613-16 in the
interests of public
health, patents granted
for medicines
See also Use of
Inventions for Service
of State Section 78 (for
the maintenance of
supplies essential to
life, for promoting
productivity)

L. 613-6 acts
performed on an
experimental basis and
which relate to the
object of the patented
invention

The patent system and some potential safety nets

67

Table 3.2 continued



Country

Applicable statute

Compulsory licensing
provisions

Patent infringement
limitationsexperimental use
exemption

Germany

German Patent Act


Patent Law of 16 Dec.
1980 as last amended
by Law of 25 Oct. 1994

Section 24(1) where


the public interest so
commands

Section 11 No.2 acts


done for experimental
purposes which are
related to the subject
matter of the patented
invention
No.1 excuses private
uses for noncommercial purposes

Greece

Technology Transfer,
Inventions and
Technological
Innovation Law
1733/1987 as last
amended by Law No.
17/39 1987 and
Presidential Decrees
No. 54/1992

13, 14 CL for
non-working
dependent patents if
significant progress
in comparison with
invention of prior
patent,
imperative reasons
of public health or
national defence
(Art. 14)

Art. 10 (2) a. nonprofessional or research


purposes

Italy

Law on Patents for


Inventions; Royal
Decree No. 1127 1939
as last amended by
Legislative Decree No.
198 1996

54 CL for non
working, dependent
patents important
technological
improvement

Art. 1(3) exclusive


rights do not extend to
non-commercial use/
experimental use/
private use

Netherlands

Dutch Patent Act 1910


as last amended by the
Act of the Kingdom of
29 May, 1987

Section 34(1)
compulsory license
based on public
interest
Section 34(2) and
(3) for non-use
Section 34(4) to
enable use of
younger patent

Section 30(3) acts


exclusively done for
experimental purposes
relating to the subject
matter of the invention,
including the product
obtained directly as a
result of applying the
patented process

68

The patent balance

Table 3.2 continued



Country

Applicable statute

Compulsory licensing
provisions

Patent infringement
limitationsexperimental use
exemption

Norway

Patents Act No. 9 1967


as amended by Act No.
104, 20 Dec. 1996

4350 CL for
non-working
dependent patent
important
technological
advance of
considerable
economic
significance,
important public
interests

Art. 3 excuses
experiments outside
professional activities
or experiments relating
to the subject-matter of
the invention

Portugal

Industrial Property
Code Decree Law No.
16/95 1995

CL for
non-working (art.
103)
dependency when
considerable
technological
advance (art. 107)
public interest incl.
public health or
national defence
(Art. 102)

Art. 98 on experimental
purposes

Spain

Spanish Law on
Patents No. 11 (20
March 1986) as last
amended by Law 50,
1998

86 CL for
non-working
dependent patents
so long as the
invention has
distinctive
industrial objectives
or represents
considerable
technical progress
reasons of public
interest where
paramount for
public health or
national defence
Also special provisions
for cases of medicines
and public health.

Art. 52 patent rights


not extend to acts
carried out for
experimental purposes
which relate to the
subject matter of the
patented invention.
Also exemption as to
private and noncommercial use.

The patent system and some potential safety nets

69

Table 3.2 concluded



Country

Applicable statute

Compulsory licensing
provisions

Patent infringement
limitationsexperimental use
exemption

Sweden

Swedish Patents Act


No. 837 1967 as last
amended by Act No.
1406 of 1998
(Patentlag)

CL when
non working (s.45)
dependent patents
where reasonable
(s.46)
required by public
interests of extreme
importance (s.47)

Section 3: excludes use


from exclusive right
that is not commercial,
use for experiments
which relate to the
invention

Switzerland

Federal Law on Patents


for Inventions 1954 (as
last amended on
24 March 1995)
Swiss Patent Act

CL for
Art. 40(1) public
interest
Non-working Art.
37
dependent patents
Art. 36 when
important
technological
advance of
significant
importance

Implicit support for


EUE via Art. 26(1) No.
3 disclosure not
sufficiently clear and
complete is a nullity
and Art. 36
acknowledging
dependent inventions
or patents.

UK

UK Patents Act 1977


as last amended by the
Copyright, Designs and
patents Act 1988

Section 48(3)
Non working
dependent patent if
the working of an
invention which
makes a substantial
contribution to the
art is hindered
demand not met
Section 51 CL in
consequence of report
of Monopolies and
Mergers Commission
where would be in
public interest
Sections 5557 on
Crown Use for public
interest

Section 60(5) acts


done privately and for
purposes that are not
commercial for
experimental purposes
relating to the subject
matter of the invention

European
Communities

Directive 98/44/EC on
legal protection of
biotechnological
inventions

Art. 12 significant
technical progress of
considerable economic
interest

See recent endorsement


of Bolar exemption
See EPC Art. 27(b) for
EUE

4. The right to health as an interpretive


principle of patent law
In a state of law, the right to life, and in consequence the right to health, receives
particular attention. Any economic criterion that pretends to annul the exercise of
such rights must cede in importance because without the right to life all of the
other rights are useless Of what use are all other rights and guarantees, the institutions and programs, the advantages and benefits of our system of liberties, if even
one person cannot count on having the rights to health and life guaranteed? (Alvarez
v Caja Costarricense de Seguro Social, Exp. 5778-V-97, No. 5934-97, Sala Constitucional de la Corte Suprema de Justicia de Costa Rica)

4.1 Introduction
One of the particularities of the biopharmaceutical industry is that human rights
and specifically the right to health may have implications on policy making.
This is due to the nature of the goods produced as any unintended impact on
the balance may lead to an increased social cost.
The implications that the right to health might have on the patent balance
cannot therefore be overlooked. The objective of this chapter is to enquire into
the extent to which patent law could be affected by the existence of the right to
health, whether directly or indirectly.
As shown in the previous chapter, patent law does not contain specific provisions for cases where the right to health might be in issue, however, it does
envisage the possibility of granting a compulsory licence in the interest of
public health. It also allows for exceptions and exclusions to be created in
the interest of ordre public, which may include health concerns in certain
cases.


See Chapter 3 and Art. 8 of the TRIPS Agreement, Principles. The reference to
public health does not directly incorporate the right to health, although one might assume that the latter is included in it.

In the EU, the European Group on Ethics in Science and Technology is an independent pluralist multidisciplinary body, which was set up in 1992 by the Commission
to advise on the ethical aspects of new technologies envisaged in Community policies
or proposed legislation.

70

The right to health

71

In order to examine the potential implications of the right to health on the


patent system and, more specifically, on the duty to deal in the pharmaceutical
industry, the following elements will be assessed:
1. Does a right to health exist and what obligations does it create?
2. Does a right to intellectual property law exist and can it be described as a
human right?
3. How does the right to health impact on patent law? How does the right to
health affect patent statutes, either through interpretation or as a means of
invalidation?

4.2 The right to health as a human right and


its status in European law
4.2.1 Introduction to the Right to Health
The right to health as a human right has its roots in the public health movement
of the nineteenth century when the first health legislation was adopted. Due to
the development of commerce and transportation, the creation of a mechanism
was sought to prevent transmittable diseases at the international level, as it was
believed that diseases would hinder international trade. Gradually, the foundations for the recognition of health as a human right were laid both at national
and international level. It was quickly understood that in order to improve health,
issues such as poverty and sanitary conditions would have to be tackled.
The starting point for the protection of health can be found in the WHO
Constitution, which states that the enjoyment of the highest attainable standard
of health is one of the fundamental rights of every human being without discrimination as to race, religion, political belief, economic or social condition.
The promotion and protection of health is fundamental to the individuals wellbeing and dignity and, therefore, health services became an important social
good. States have responsibilities in relation to public health, which crystallise


C.A. Toebes, The Right to Health as A Human Right In International Law, Oxford,
Intersentia- Hart 1999, pp.1517; P. Farmer, Pathologies of Power. Health, human rights
and the new war on the poor, Berkeley, University of California Press (2003); N. Birdsall
and E. James, Health, government and the poor: The case for the private sector, in J.N.
Gribble and S.H. Preston (eds), The Epidemiological Transition Policy and Planning
Implications for Developing Countries, Washington DC, National Academy Press (1993),
pp.22951.

Article 1 of the WHO Constitution, 1945 available at http://www.who.int/rarebooks/official_records/constitution.pdf.

72

The patent balance

in the obligation to create some basic conditions to protect and enhance public
health; however, this does not extend to an obligation to guarantee the well-being of every individual.
In view of its paramount importance in society, health has been recognised
as a human right in several international, regional or national human rights
treaties. There is much controversy surrounding the existence of this right, even
in the use of the term.


At the international level, it is set out in myriad international treaties including


the ICESCR GA Res. 2200, UN GAOR, Supp. No. 16, UN Doc. A/6316 (1966), 999
UNTS 171 (entered into force 23 March 1976) (see further down), Art. 24 of the Childrens Convention (Convention on the Rights of the Child, No. 20 1989 GA Res. 44/25,
UN GAOR 44th Sess., Supp. No. 49, at 167, UN Doc. A/44/49 1989) stating State parties recognize the right of the child to the enjoyment of the highest attainable standard
of health , the International Convention on the Elimination of All Forms of Racial
Discrimination of 1965, UN GAOR Res. 2106 A(XX), and the Convention on the Elimination of All Forms of Discrimination against Women of 1979, GA Res. 34/180 UN
GAOR 34th Sess., Supp/No. 44 at 193, UN Doc A/34/36 91980 (entered into force 3
September 1981) at Art. 12.
At the regional level, there are also several instruments setting out the right to health
care and the obligation to undertake public health measures, such as Art 16 of the Banjul
Charter (African [Banjul] Charter on Human and Peoples Rights, adopted 27 June 1981,
OAU Doc. CAB/LEG/67/3 rev. 5, 21 I.L.M. 58 (1982) entered into force 1986) securing
the right to the best attainable state of physical and mental health, and the European
Social Charter, ETS 35 Social Charter, 18.X.1961, 18 October 1961 (available at www.
conventions.coe.int/Treaty/en/treaties/hetml/035.htm) Art. 11(3) referring to the obligation to take appropriate measures to prevent as far as possible epidemic, endemic and
other diseases and Art. 13(1) to ensure that any person who is without adequate resources and who is unable to secure such resources be granted adequate assistance,
and in case of sickness, the care necessitated by his condition.
At the domestic level, the right to health has been enshrined in more than 60 national
constitutions. See The Right of Everyone to the Highest Attainable Standard of Physical
and Mental Health, Report of the Special Rapporteur, Paul Hunt, submitted in accordance with Commission Resolution 2002/31, UN ESCOR, 59th Sess., Agenda Item 23,
20, UN Doc. E/CN.4/2003/58 (2003).

While the term, right to health, is most often used in international law, reference
is made in some cases to the right to health care, or to health protection. Some even allege that there is no such right at all as it makes no sense to confer a right unless someone
else has the ability to meet that need. So any right to medical care imposes on someone
the obligation to provide care to those who cannot provide it for themselves. See D.
Kelley, Is there a right to health care, The Objectivist Centre (1993), http://www.objectivistcenter.org/articles/delley_right-to-health-care.asp.
Others have described the right to health as misleading by arguing that it should be
converted to the right to health protection including the right to health care and a right
to healthy conditions. H.L. Fuenzalida-Puelma/S.S. Connor, The Right to Health in the
Americas, Pan-American Health Organization, Scientific Publication No. 509, Washington, D.C., 1989. V.A. Leary, The Right to Health in International Human Rights Law,
1(1) Health and Human Rights: An International Journal 1, (1994).

The right to health

73

The right to health is used in the international human rights context, first, to
refer to the more lengthy detailed provisions relating to health in the WHO
Constitution and in legally binding human rights treaties, and secondly, to
emphasise the social and ethical aspects of health care and status. The concept
of a right to health implies that fundamental human rights principles such as
dignity, non-discrimination, participation and justice are relevant to issues of
health care and health status. Three aspects of the right to health have been
enshrined in the international instruments on human rights: the declaration on
the right to health as a basic human right; the prescription of standards aimed
at meeting the health needs of specific groups of persons; and the prescription
of ways and means for implementing the right to health.
Conceptualising health issues as a right emphasises their exceptional importance as social or public goals and not merely as medical, technical or economic
problems.10 It focuses on the dignity of persons as recognised in the Preamble
to the Universal Declaration of Human Rights (UDHR),11 which provides for

The right to health, however, is probably the most desirable term as it recognises a
right not only to health care, but also to underlying preconditions for health such as occupational health and environmental health. C.A. Toebes (1999) op. cit. p.17.
See also R.K. Lie, Health, human rights and mobilization of resources for health, 4
BMC International Health and Human Rights 4 (2004).

See The Committee on Economic Social and Cultural Rights which monitors
compliance with the International Covenant on Economic, Social and Cultural Rights,
G.A. Res. 2200 (XXI), UN GAOR, Supp. (No. 16) 49, UN Doc. A(6316) 1966. This
Committee held a Day of General Discussion on the Right to Health on 6 Dec. 1993
(the right to the enjoyment of the highest attainable standard of physical and mental
health) UN Information Service, Press Release HR/3604, 6 December 1993; R.J. Cook,
Human Rights in Relation to Womens Health, The Promotion and Protection of Womens
Health through International Human Rights Law, WHO/DGH/93.l; Fuenzalida-Puelma
and Connor (1989) op. cit.

V.A. Leary (1994) op. cit. p.2.

T.C. Van Boven, The Right to Health, pp.5472, in R-J. Dupuy (ed.), The Right
to Health as a Human Right, Workshop, The Hague Academy of International Law and
the United Nations University, Sijthoff & Noordhoff, Alphen aan den Rijn, The Netherlands (1979), pp.5455.
10
V.A. Leary (1994) op. cit. p.8. A. Chetley, A Healthy Business? World Health and
the Pharmaceutical Industry, London, Zed Books (1990), p.206; R-J Dupuy (1979) The
Right to Health and Human Rights, Alphen aan den Rijn, The Netherlands: Sijthoff &
Noordhoff, 1979.
11
Recognition of the inherent dignity and of the equal and inalienable rights of all
members of the human family is the foundation of freedom, justice and peace in the
world. UDHR, GA Res. 217 A(III), UN Doc. A/810 (1948) Preamble. In the health
context, this stresses that the dignity of each person must be central in all aspects of
health, including health care, experiments etc. The focus is on the good of the individual
not the collective good.

74

The patent balance

equality or non-discrimination,12 the participation of individuals and groups in


issues affecting them,13 implies an entitlement14 and interdependence with other
rights, and that limitations should be subject to strict scrutiny.15
However, as a socio-economic right, the precise content of the right to health
is unclear. Contrary to civil and political rights which are frequently invoked in
national judicial proceedings and which are enshrined in many international
complaint mechanisms, economic, social and cultural rights are often regarded
non-justiciable at the national level, and viewed as ineffective due to the lack
of effective complaint systems at the international level. This is often due to the
reluctance of states to accept the high costs associated with ensuring entitlements to health or housing or food and education.16
4.2.2 Sources of the Right to Health
Within EC law, the most relevant provisions on the right to health can be found
in the Charter on Fundamental Rights.17 The European Charter on Fundamental
Rights18 was drawn up in order to strengthen the protection of fundamental
rights in the light of changes in society, social progress and scientific and technological developments by making those rights more visible in a Charter.19
Article 35 of the Charter provides for the right of access to preventive health
care and the right to benefit from medical treatment under the conditions established by national law and practice. It is not considered as a right to individual

12
See Art. 2 of the Universal Declaration on Human Rights GA Res. 217 A(III), UN
Doc. A/810 (1948) recognising the fundamental nature of non-discrimination in the human rights context: Everyone is entitled to all the rights and freedoms set forth in this
Declaration, without distinction of any kind such as race, colour, sex, language, religion,
political or other opinion, national or social origin.
13
The Declaration of Alma-Ata on Primary Health Care states: The people have
the right and duty to participate individually and collectively in the planning and implementation of their health care. Declaration of Alma-Ata, adopted at the International
Conference on Primary Health Care, 12th September 1978, World Health Organization,
Geneva.
14
This means that governments have a duty to provide for individuals, not just to
society in general.
15
According to the International Covenant on Civil and Political Right, UNGA
Resolution 2200A [XX1], 16 December 1966, limitations are permitted on the rights to
liberty of movement, freedom of religion, freedom of expression and the right to freedom
of association, in the interest of protecting public health (e.g. Art. 18(3)).
16
B.C.A. Toebes (1999) op. cit.
17
Other national, regional or international relevant provisions were mentioned above.
op. cit.
18
Charter of Fundamental Rights of the European Union OJ 2000 C 364/01.
19
Ibid. Preamble.

The right to health

75

health, but rather, a right to conditions that may lead to it. The extent and level
of protection is left to the discretion of individual states, although it stipulates
that a high level of human health protection should be ensured.20
The right to health has been recognised on several occasions at the international level, the most important of which include: first, the Universal Declaration
of Human Rights,21 which affirms in Art. 25(1) that: Everyone has the right to
a standard of living adequate for the health and well-being of himself and of
his family, including food, clothing, housing and medical care and necessary
social services, and the right to security in the event of unemployment, sickness,
disability, widowhood, old age or other lack of livelihood in circumstances beyond his control.
In addition, the International Covenant on Economic, Social and Cultural
Rights contains the following provisions:22 Art. 11(1) states that The States
Parties to the present Covenant recognise the right of everyone to an adequate

20
The rights recognised in the Charter are addressed to the institutions and bodies
of the EU and to the Member States in the implementation of Union law, and therefore,
they are not building on individual pharmaceutical companies (Art. 51). Limitations on
such rights may be provided for by law if they respect the essence of these rights and
freedoms and are proportional, necessary and meet the objectives of the general interest
recognised by the Union or are necessary to protect the rights and freedoms of others
(Art. 52). Hence, it would seem that the Charter seeks to balance potentially competing
interests in particular through the proportionality and necessity principle.
Important safeguards and provisions regarding the right to health can also be found
in the European Charter of Patients Rights. The latter is directed to active citizenship
organisations working on patients rights at the national level, yet it also addresses health
care professionals, managers, governments, legislatures and administrative bodies. The
dissemination and application of the contents of the Charter is carried out on many levels,
particularly at European, national and local levels. The supremacy of the rights of patients
over financial constraints is underlined, and an attempt is made to harmonise respect for
the patients rights throughout the Union. It complements the Charter of Fundamental
Rights in affirming the inalienable and universal nature of these individual rights. It explains that the protection of the right to health as provided for in Art. 35 is both an
individual and a social good. The Charter proposes 14 patients rights which would be
concrete, applicable and appropriate to the transitory nature of the health services. The
latter includes: the right to preventive measures, access, information, consent, free choice,
privacy and confidentiality, respect of patients time, observance of quality standards,
safety, innovation, avoidance of unnecessary suffering and pain and personalised treatment, and the right to complain and to receive compensation. The Charter effectively
stresses the need to ensure that the criteria of economic sustainability do not prevail
over the right to health care. Article 12 Active Citizenship Network. European Charter
of Patients Rights, 2002, available at http://www.activecitizenship.net/health/european_charter.pdf.
21
GA Res. 217 A(III), UN Doc. A/810 (1948).
22
GA Res. 2200, UN GAOR, Supp. No. 16, UN Doc. A/6316 (1966), 999 UNTS
171 (entered into force 23 March, 1976).

76

The patent balance

standard of living for himself and his family, including adequate food, clothing
and housing and to the continuous improvement of living conditions. According
to Art. 12(1): The State Parties to the present Covenant recognise the right of
everyone to the enjoyment of the highest attainable standard of physical and
mental health. Article 12(2) states:
The steps to be taken by the States Parties to the present Covenant to achieve the full
realisation of this right shall include those necessary for:
(a) The provision for the reduction of stillbirth-rate and of infant mortality and for
the healthy development of the child;
(b) The improvement of all aspects of environmental and industrial hygiene;
(c) The prevention, treatment and control of epidemic, occupational and other
diseases;
(d) The creation of conditions which would assure to all medical service and medical attention in the event of sickness.

The latter is the most comprehensive provision on the right to health in international human rights law.23 General Comment 14 of 2000 analyses the
implications of Art. 12 and its recognition of the right to the highest attainable
standard of health.24
4.2.3 Implications of the Right to Health
The right to health is dependent on and related to respect for human dignity and
the realisation of other human rights including the rights to food, life, non-discrimination, equality and privacy. Within the preamble to the Constitution of
WHO, health is defined as a state of complete physical, mental and social wellbeing and not merely the absence of disease or infirmity.25 However, as the
General Comment highlights, the right to health does not refer exclusively to
the right to health care but also embraces a range of socio-economic factors that
promote conditions for a healthy life, and extend to other aspects such as food,
nutrition, housing and a healthy environment.26

23
Other international provisions affirming the right to health can be found in: Art.
5(e)(iv) of the International Convention on the Elimination of All Forms of Racial Discrimination, 1965; Arts 11.1(f) and 12 of the Convention on the Elimination of All forms
of Discrimination against Women, 1979; and Art. 24 of the Convention of the Rights of
the Child, 1989 op. cit.
24
E/C.12/2000/4, The Right to the Highest Attainable Standard of Health, CESCR
General Comment 14, 11 August 2000.
25
WHO Constitution (1945) op. cit.
26
See General Comment No. 14 (2000) op. cit. See also R-J Dupuy (1979) op. cit.;
International Institute for Human Rights Studies. Le mdecin face aux droits de l homme.

The right to health

77

Health care is therefore simply a part of the right to health, which encompasses broader factors as shown above. Access to medication is a critical
component of the right to health, both for epidemic and endemic diseases.27 The
right to health does not, however, guarantee the right to be healthy, as health is
a very subjective matter:
Health is a state of being, not something that can be given, and only in indirect ways
something that can be taken away or undermined by other human beings. It no more
makes sense to claim a right to health than a right to wisdom or courage. These excellences of soul and of body require natural gift, attention, effort, and discipline on the
part of each person who desires them. To make my health someone elses duty is not
only unfair; it is to impose a duty impossible to fulfil.28

4.2.3.1 Elements of the right to health


The right to health consists primarily of the right to health care and the preconditions for health. It also involves two levels of obligations: those which can be
realised progressively and those which can be realised irrespective of the financial resources of a state; the scope and core content of the right to health
respectively.29

Padova: CEDAM, 1990. p.1485; J. Montgomery, Rights to Health and Health Care, in
A. Coote (ed.), The Welfare of Citizens, Developing New Social Rights, London, Institute
for Public Policy Research/Rivers Oram Press (1992).
27
See Art. 12(2)(c) and (d) ICESCR. See A.E. Yamin, Not Just A Tragedy: Access
to Medications as a Right under International Law, 21 Boston University International
Law Journal 178 (2003).
28
L.R. Kass, Regarding the End of Medicine and the Pursuit of Health, 40 The
Public Interest 11 (1975). The right to health does not signify a right to be healthy, but
instead it contains freedoms such as the right to control ones health and body, and entitlements such as the right to a system of health protection that provides an equal
opportunity for people to enjoy the highest attainable standard of life. The latter refers
not only to the individuals biological and socio-economic conditions, but also to the
states available resources and so is bound to vary. The state may not ensure good health
services, therefore the right to health must be understood as a right to the enjoyment of
a variety of facilities, goods, services and conditions necessary for the realisation of the
highest attainable standard of health. Hence, the right to health includes not only appropriate health care but also the determinants of health, and the right of individual
participation in health-related decision-making at all levels including national, community and international levels.
29
While there are several elements which impact on health, they should not be included in the scope of the right if they are not referred to in the treaties or protected
through other human rights, as in the case of torture and protection against compulsory
medical treatment or experimentation. M. Whitehead, The Concepts and Principles of
Equity and Health. WHO Regional Office for Europe: Copenhagen, 1990. World Health
Organization. Indicators to Measure the Realization of the Right to Health, Background
Paper for Seminar on Appropriate Indicators to Measure Achievements in the Progressive

78

The patent balance

The core content of the right to health is comprised of the following aspects:
maternal and child health care; immunisation against major infectious diseases;
appropriate treatment of common diseases and injuries; the provision of essential drugs; and an adequate supply of safe water and basic sanitation and freedom
from serious environmental health threats.30
The General Comment clarifies that the right to health depends on four elements that may be applied at the discretion of the State in line with the
availability of resources. These include:
1. Availability: public health, health-care facilities, goods and services should
be made available in a sufficient quantity at the national level.
2. Accessibility: health facilities, goods and services should be accessible to
all without discrimination. This involves non-discrimination, physical
accessibility (within safe physical reach), economic accessibility (affordability), and information accessibility (the right to seek, receive and impart
information and ideas concerning health issues though also preserving
confidentiality of personal health data). Accessibility requires that the vulnerable and marginalised groups are not prejudiced in any way.
3. Acceptability: this refers to the fact that facilities, goods and services must
respect medical ethics and should be sensitive to cultural needs.
4. Quality: facilities, goods and services must be of the appropriate standards
and quality.
While the right to the highest attainable standard of health is a progressively
realisable right due to resource limitations, some obligations are immediate,
such as those relating to non-discrimination and the provision of deliberate,
concrete and targeted steps.

Realization of Economic, Cultural and Social Rights. Geneva, 2529 January 1993,
HR/Geneva/1993/Sem/BP.
30
In addition, it is believed that the services should be geographically, culturally
and functionally within easy reach of the whole community. It has also been suggested
that additional health services should be available, subject to equal access, give extra
protection to vulnerable groups and that the quality of those services should be taken
into account. Toebes (1999) op. cit., pp 2878. See also A.E. Yamin (2003) op. cit.; P.
Carl, et al., AIDS and Human Rights in the European Communities, Utrecht, Netherlands
Institute of Human Rights (1991); L. Gostin and J. Mann, Towards the Development of
a Human Rights Impact Assessment for the Formulation and Evaluation of Health Policies, 1(6) Health and Human Rights: An International Journal 58 (1994).

The right to health

79

4.2.3.2 Obligation to respect, protect and fulfil


As with all human rights, states have a three-fold obligation; namely, the obligations to respect, protect and fulfil.31 The obligation to respect requires that the
State should not interfere directly or indirectly with the enjoyment of the right
to health, and to refrain from denying or limiting equal access for all persons.
The obligation to protect requires the state to take measures to prevent third
parties from interfering in the attainment of the right to health,32 while the obligation to fulfil requires the adoption of appropriate legislative, administrative,
budgetary, judicial, promotional and other measures for the full realisation of
the right to health.33
The right to health could be violated in the following ways: the suspension
of legislation or the adoption of laws or policies that interfere with the enjoyment of any of the components of the right to health; the failure of the state to
take its legal obligations regarding the right to health into account when entering
into bilateral or multilateral agreements with other states, international organisations and other entities such as multinational corporations; the failure to regulate
the activities of individuals, groups or corporations so as to prevent them from
violating the right to health of others and the failure to take measures to reduce
the inequitable distribution of health facilities, food and basic services.34

31
A.E. Yamin (2003) op. cit.; WHO, Indicators to Measure the Realization of the
Right to Health, (1993) op. cit.; J. Montgomery (1992) op. cit.; R-J. Dupuy (1979) op.
cit.
32
Failure to take action to restrict the harmful conduct of pharmaceutical companies
might potentially be such a breach of obligations.
33
Despite the above core and scope obligations, however, it cannot be concluded
that the right to health is justiciable as such at the international level. The term recognise
in contrast with to ensure or guarantee, reflects its non-binding character. None the
less, some elements of the Article are justiciable such as the obligation of non-discrimination and the obligation to realise the core content.
The core content of the right to health consists of both negative (freedom from serious
health infringements) and positive (access to basic health services) obligations. When
translated into the core obligations, the obligation to respect the right to health means
that states have to respect the equal access to basic health services, and refrain from acts
that seriously encroach upon peoples health. The obligation to protect consists of the
obligation to take legislative and other measures to assure that people have equal access
to basic health services if provided by third parties, and to take legislative and/or other
measures to protect people from serious health infringements by third parties. Finally,
the obligation to fulfil requires states to adopt a national health policy and devote a sufficient amount of their budget to health, and to provide the basic health services or create
conditions under which individuals have adequate and sufficient access to health
services.
34
See also E/CN.4/Sub.2/2002/9, Economic, Social and Cultural Rights, Liberalization of trade in services and human rights, Report of the High Commissioner, 25 June
2002.

80

The patent balance

4.2.4 International Efforts to Strengthen the Right to Health


There have been some steps taken to strengthen the obligations imposed by the
right to health or its related provisions at the international level.35 The Nigerian
government was recently found to have violated the right to life, to health and
to housing, amongst other things, due to pollution and environmental degradation.36 The obligation of states is not simply a negative duty to refrain from
interfering arbitrarily with peoples rights, but also the positive obligation to
take all measures necessary to ensure that basic rights are not violated, either
by public or private entities.37
In the specific case of access to pharmaceutical products, it seems that domestic courts are increasingly willing to find that the denial of access to certain
medication may constitute a violation of the constitutional right to life.38 The

35
Attempts have been made at the international level to make the right to health
more concrete. In 2002, the main UN policy-making body on human rights, the Commission on Human Rights, adopted a resolution on the right to health to appoint a special
rapporteur (an independent expert) to report annually to the Commission on the extent
to which governments are fulfilling the right to health. Press release WHO/61 24 July
2002, New WHO publication explores important links between health and human rights
an area drawing increased attention. A new mechanism to create a means for individuals
to petition their governments at the international level for failure to respect, protect, or
fulfil human rights obligations is also being examined.
See also, for example, the right to life, There has been a tendency to move towards
a broader and more comprehensive concept of the right to life which characterizes the
right to life not only as the legal foundation for all other rights, but also as an integral
part of all the rights that are essential to guarantee the access of every human being to
all the goods required for the development of his/her material, moral, and spiritual
existence. IACHR, Status of Human Rights in Several Countries: Nicaragua, Annual
report of the Inter-American Commission on Human Rights 1993, OEA/Ser.L/V/II.85,
Doc. 9 Rev. (1994) at 465, available at www.cidh.org/annualrep/93span/cap.IVe.htm
(quoting The Right of Everyone to Own Property Alone as well as in Association with
Others, UN Commission on Human Rights, 49th Sess., Provisional Agenda Item 7, at
25, UN Doc. E/CN.4/1993/15).
36
Social and Economic Rights Action Center v Nigeria, Communication 155/96
(African Commission on Human and Peoples Rights, Oct. 2001), available at www.
achpr.org/DECISIONS_30th_Session-_Oct.2001_eng.pdf.
37
See Street Children Case (Morales v Guatemala), Joint Concurring Opinion of
Judges A.A. Cancado Trinidade and A. Abreu-Burelli, Inter-Am. Ct H.R. (Ser. C) No.
63, 24, available at www.corteidh.or.cr/seriecing/VotocancadoabreuSerie_c_63_ing.
doc.
38
Costa Rica, India, Venezuela, Colombia, Argentina and South Africa are among
the many countries in which national courts have recognised an obligation on states to
provide medication in HIV/AIDS cases and for other diseases. See Minister of Health v
Treatment Action Campaign, CCT 8/02 Constitutional Court of South Africa, July 2002,
at www.tac.org.za/Documents; Ceballos v Instituto de Seguros Sociales, T-484 Corte

The right to health

81

Constitutional Court of Colombia set out a four-pronged test in order to determine the situations in which the right to health services might be justiciable.
The health issues must implicate fundamental rights such as life, work or education. There must be a grave and imminent threat to human life or health
presented by the failure of the state to provide services. The claimant must be
in extreme financial and physical need of the services and there must be a possibility of providing the service.39 In this way, the right to health has been
increasingly found to be justiciable,40 and this may have implications for patented products which impact upon access to essential drugs.
In addition, with regard to private entities, the ESCR Committee clarified that
the obligation of states to protect includes, inter alia, ensuring that privatization
of the health sector does not constitute a threat to the availability, accessibility,
acceptability and quality of health services; controlling the marketing of medical
equipment and medicines by third parties; and States ensuring that third parties
do not limit peoples access to health-related information and services.41

Constitucional de Colombia 1992, available at http://bib.minjusticia.gov.co/jurisprudencia/CorteConstitucional/1992/Tutela/T-48492.htm; Alvarez v Caja Costarricense de


Seguro Social, Exp. 5778-V-97, No. 5934-97, Sala Constitucional de la Corte Suprema
de Justicia de Costa Rica.
See Glenda Lopez v Instituto Venezolano de Seguros Sociales, 487-060401 Supreme
Court of Venezuela, Constitutional Chamber 1997 available at www.tsj.gov.ve/decisiones/scon/Abril/487-060401-001343.htm. (This Court found a violation of the right
to life on the part of the social security institute by virtue of failing to provide antiretroviral treatment on a regular basis that could lead to an inexorable deterioration of the
immune system in addition to viral resistance, leading to opportunistic infections and
death.) See also Protection Writ. Judgment of Fabio Moron Diaz, Magistrado Ponente,
T-328/98 Corte Constitucional de Colombia 1998, available at http://bib.minjusticia.gov.
vo/jurisprudencia/CorteConstitucional/1998/Tutela/T-328-98.htm.
See also S. Shah, Illuminating the Possible in the Developing World: Guaranteeing
the Human Right to Health in India, 32 VAND. J. TRANSNATL L. 435 (1999).
39
Alejandro Moreno Alvarez v Estado Colombiano, SU.819/99, Corte Constitucional
de Colombia 1999, available at http://bob.minjusticia.gov.vo/jurisprudencia/Corte
Constitucional/1999/Tutela/su819-99.htm.
40
A.E. Yamin (2003) op. cit.; P. Carl (1991) op. cit.; R-J Dupuy (1979) op. cit.
41
General Comment 14 (2000) op. cit. 35.

82

The patent balance

4.3 The right to health and patent law: The


fundamental nature of health concerns
and the move towards a right to health
as an interpretive principle in patent law
4.3.1 The Link Between the Right to Health and Patent Law
4.3.1.1 The effect of patent law on the right to health
The patent system may affect health considerations, on the one hand, by leading
to reduced access to pharmaceutical products,42 and on the other hand, by restricting access to products or processes that are necessary for downstream
innovation or the creation of improvements.
The increasing justiciability of the right to health coupled with the implications of the obligation to protect highlight increased attention regarding the
duties of private entities (namely pharmaceutical companies) as regards the right
to health and specifically, in access to essential medications.
The obligation to protect the right to health also requires states to ensure that
threats by third parties are restricted. This requires the creation of institutions
to prevent and monitor the violation of fundamental rights by private actors.
The right to health may, therefore, influence the way adjudicative and legislative
bodies make decisions relating to health. It creates legal obligations and ac-

42
Generic products may have an impact on drug prices, for example, as shown in
the case of HIV drugs. The UNDP Human Development Report 2000 notes that generic
production of the HIV treatment fluconazole, a treatment for AIDS-related meningitis
in India has remained at $55 for 150 mg compared to $697 in Malaysia, $703 in Indonesia and $817 in the Philippines. According to Medecins Sans Frontires, generic drugs
are approximately 7090% cheaper than branded drugs. In some cases, they can be
200300% cheaper than the branded equivalent made in the West. In Thailand, fluconazole, which treats cryptococcal meningitisan infection affecting one in five of AIDS
suffererswas supplied exclusively by US company, Pfizer, until 1998. Since local alternatives have become available, the cost of a daily dosage of 400mg has fallen from
US$14 to 5% of the price. Thus, it costs only US$0.30 a day in Thailand. However, this
same drug costs US$18.00 a day in Kenya where it is patent protected. U. Ally Mwalimu,
Implications of WTO/TRIPS in East Africa-With Special Emphasis on Pharmaceutical
Patents, Economics and Social Research Foundation, Workshop on Globalization and
East Africa, 1516 April 2002.
None the less, access to drugs is conditioned by many factors including price controls,
medical insurance, import duties and tariffs, local taxes, limited competition mark-up
for wholesale, distribution and dispensing, and hence, not solely on prices and the availability of generics. See WHO, More equitable pricing for essential drugs: What do we
mean and what are the issues? Background paper for the WHO-WTO Secretariat Workshop on Differential Pricing and Financing of Essential Drugs, Hosbjor, Norway, 811
April 2001, p.9.

The right to health

83

countability, not only with regard to the organisation of the health system, but
also, inter alia, in competition, pricing, licensing and other laws.43 Hence, the
right to health provisions may work as an external enforcement mechanism
imposing concrete obligations, and also have an internal impact, guiding the
interpretation and application of other laws in order to ensure consistency with
its provisions.44
4.3.1.2 The effect of the right to health on patent law
The impact of the right to health on patent law depends largely on the link between the right to health and intellectual property rights (IPRs).
The relationship between fundamental rights and IP, in general, can be viewed
in two simplistic ways.45 On the one hand, IP could be seen as a human right
and the property character of IPRs could be overemphasised at the expense of
other fundamental rights. Accordingly, the appropriate balance should be created
by the legislator and, therefore, any interference would not only hinder the dynamics of the system, but would also be undemocratic. At the other extreme
there can be the view that IP is merely an institution which infringes on fundamental rights. The reality, it is argued, lies somewhere in between these polarised
views.
Therefore, in order to establish the potential impact of health concerns and
the right to health on patent law, either externally or internally, the following
elements need to be established:
1. Is IP a human right and would this make a difference?
2. Is there an inherent conflict between IP and human rights, or more specifically, the right to health (since IP may also be a human right)?
3. How can patent laws be interpreted to fulfil the spirit of the right to health?
Does this obligation exist?

43
Therefore, the enforcement of competition rules in cases where patent holders
refuse to grant licences and charge excessive prices for their products, or issue a compulsory licence in the interest of public health should be considered to support the right
to health objectives. See A.E. Yamin (2003) op. cit.
44
M.G. Bloche, WTO Deference to National Health Policy: Toward an Interpretive
Principle, 5(4) Journal of International Economic Law 825 (2002).
See also T. Mully, Intellectual Property, Fundamental Rights (and Competition Law):
Do They Interoperate? International Conference, Intellectual Property Beyond Rights,
2526 October 2004, Hanasaari Cultural Centre, Finland. Mully argues that fundamental
rights have the greatest impact through interpretation and systematisation.
45
T. Mully (2004) op. cit.

84

The patent balance

4.3.2 The Right to Property and IP: IP as a Human Right


The right to property and more specifically IP can be found in several European
and international human right treaties. Article 1 of Protocol 1 of the European
Convention on Human Rights46 provides that:
Every natural person or legal person is entitled to the peaceful enjoyment of his possession. No-one shall be deprived of his possessions except in the public interest and
subject to the conditions provided for by law and by the general principles of international law.
The preceding provisions shall not, however, in any way impair the right of a State
to enforce such laws as it deems necessary to control the use of property in accordance with the general interest or to secure the payment of taxes or other contributions
or penalties.

In line with the above provisions, Art. 17 of the European Charter on Fundamental Rights47 provides for the right to property, however, this is subject to the
limitations, deprivations and regulation as required in the public interest and
conditions provided for in law, the general interest and subject to fair
compensation.
At the international level, the UDHR48 recognises the right of authors to the
moral and material interests resulting from their scientific, literary and artistic
productions.49 Similarly, Art. 15 of the International Covenant on Economic,
Social and Cultural Rights (ICESCR)50 provides: The State Parties to the
present Covenant recognise the right of everyone: to take part in cultural life;
to enjoy the benefits of scientific progress and its applications; to benefit from
the protection of the moral and material interests resulting from any scientific,
literary or artistic production of which he is the author.
This provision implies the recognition of the legitimate interest of the public
in intellectual productions. IPRs should contribute to the scientific, cultural and
economic enrichment of society, however, as an author, the individual also has
a right to benefit from these works.
While the provisions require states to protect the interests of authors and inventors, they are in vague and general terms in order to leave a broad margin of
discretion to states regarding implementation. Therefore, exclusive property
46

213 UNTS 221 (1953).


C-2000 OJ 2000 364/01.
48
GA Res. 217 A(III), UN Doc. A/810 (1948).
49
See Art. 27(2): Everyone has the right to the protection of the moral and material
interests resulting from any scientific, literary or artistic production of which he is the
author.
50
GA Res. 2200, UN GAOR, Supp. No. 16, UN Doc. A/6316 (1966), 999 UNTS
171 (entered into force 23 March 1976).
47

The right to health

85

rights are not the only possible means of protection, nor is the instrument itself
transformed into a human right, although the interest itself may constitute a
fundamental right. Neither the Universal Declaration nor the ICESCR creates
an obligation on the part of the states to establish (and certainly not an individual
right to) exclusive rights, as the latter is only one alternative way of safeguarding
the individuals interests protected This does not exclude the idea that intellectual property rights may protect individual interests of fundamental rights
nature.51
In addition, there is no minimum level of protection required, therefore, the
level of protection found in international IP instruments such as the TRIPS
Agreement easily satisfies and exceeds the requirements laid down in the human
rights instruments. Against this background of IP protection, the UDHR and
ICESCR are of little significance as protective provisions have already been put
in place.
It is problematic to consider IPRs exclusively as human rights if one considers
the nature of human rights.
Human rights are inalienable and universal claims belonging to individuals, and in
some situations to communities but never to corporations. Human rights are understood to exist independently of recognition or implementation while IPRs are granted
by the State according to criteria by national legislation. In contrast with human rights
which establish permanent and irrevocable entitlements, IPRs are temporary; they
exist for a limited period and can be revoked, licensed or assigned to someone
else.52

In addition, the history of the drafting of the international human rights conventions affirms the weakness inherent in the claims of IP as a human right
which was only accepted after considerable discussion and controversy.53 In
both cases, it was supported mainly because it is instrumental in the realisation
of other rights of a stronger moral basis.
What the phraseology of intellectual property as a human right does is to convert a
question of legislative policy to be addressed with fundamental rights analysis into
something changing the analytical premises of this effort: in this metamorphosis intellectual property protection transforms from the object of fundamental rights analysis
(legislative policy) into its very subject, namely a fundamental right in itself not to
be interfered with even by the legislator, less to the extent required by other funda-

51

T. Mully (2004) op. cit. p.10.


Report on Science and Human Rights, AAAS Science and Human Rights Program,
Winter 2002 Vol. XXII, No. 1, at http://shr.aaas.org/report/xxii/ip.htm.
53
A.R. Chapman, Approaching IP as a Human Right, Obligations related to Art.
15(1)(c), Copyright Bulleting, Vol. XXXV No. 3, 2001, UNESCO Publishing, E/C.12/
2000/12.
52

86

The patent balance


mental rights and sufficiently serious policy reasons necessary and proportionate in
a democratic society. As a corollary, institutional alternatives for the protection of the
interests mentioned in the human rights instruments, such as liability rules and direct
protection of creativity and innovation, are precluded as being in irreconcilable conflict with the intellectual property fundamental rights.54

4.3.2.1 Striking the balance: limitations in the public interest


The EU Charter and the European Convention on Human Rights (ECHR) envisage limitations on property rights which are necessary in the public interest.
Article 15 of the International Covenant on Economic, Social and Cultural
Rights, requires states parties to respect, protect and fulfil individuals cultural
rights, and achieve a balance between the protection of public and private interests in intellectual property.55 This balance refers, on the one hand, to the
right of everyone to take part in cultural life and enjoy the benefits of scientific
progress, and on the other hand, to the right of authors of scientific, literary or
artistic work to benefit from the protection of their moral and material
interests.
This balance is recognised in IP instruments. A balance of rights and obligations is also an objective of TRIPS,56 and limitations have been put in place to
reflect certain public interest concerns.57
This means that IP is subordinated to the general public interest. Exclusive
property rights may be overridden if it is required by important concerns such
as public health, and this is not incompatible with the right to property even if
it is considered to be a human right. Indeed, limitations have even been accepted
in the context of other human rights in the interest of public health. Under the
International Covenant on Civil and Political Rights, limitations are permitted
on the rights to liberty of movement, freedom of religion, freedom of expression
and the right to freedom of association, for the protection of public health.58

54

T. Mully (2004) op. cit. p.11.


See E/CN.4/Sub.2/2001/27, on the impact of the Agreement on Trade-Related
Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights on Human Rights, Report of the High Commissioner, 27 June 2001.
56
See Art. 7 TRIPS.
57
Article 8 TRIPS allows for measures to be taken that are necessary to protect
public health and to promote the public interest in sectors of vital importance to their
socio-economic and technological development. Patent protection excludes the patenting
of inventions that might be contrary to the ordre public or morality, including the protection of human, animal or plant life or health. See Chapter 3.
58
U.N.T.S. No. 14668, vol.999 (1976), p.171. e.g. Art. 18(3).
55

The right to health

87

4.3.3 Patenting and the Right to Health


4.3.3.1 Direct effect
Patent law impacts most significantly on the right to health as it may lead to
higher drug prices in the short term and, hence, it may result in restricted access.59 In addition, patent law encourages a specific type of research that is not
always in the public interest.60 Furthermore, patent law may affect the creation
of improvements or downstream innovation with potential implications on the
development of medical products.61
Although patent law may affect health, it is not incompatible with the right
to health. It promotes long-term health interests by encouraging research and
also by providing for the balancing of instruments in the short term, such as
compulsory licensing or exclusions in the interest of ordre public.62
For this reason, it is unlikely the right to health would have a direct impact
on patent law in general, as it would rarely be found to be unconstitutional for
infringing the right to health. Patent laws would not be created in such a way
as to overly infringe the right to health. Nevertheless, it is possible to envisage
that a state might be found to have violated the obligation to protect the right to
health, for example by failing to grant a compulsory licence in a case in which

59
There are several other factors which affect access to drugs such as rational selection and the use of drugs, sustainable financing and reliable health and supply
systems. Similarly, the price of drugs is affected by factors other than just patents, such
as import duties, taxes and local market approval costs. See WHO (2001a) op. cit.
p.9.
60
See, for example, the Orphan Drug Act created to stimulate research into diseases
that affect a small number of people, for which pharmaceutical companies would otherwise not invest a significant amount of resources. The US Orphan Drug Regulations (57
FR 62076) 29 Dec. 1992 and CFR Part 316 et seq. In the EU Orphan Medicinal Product
Regulation (2000) op. cit. See D.M. Richardson (1987) op. cit.. See also P.J. Kenney
(1988) op. cit. S. Boseley, EU loophole sends drug prices soaring, Guardian Weekly, 24
June 2002. See also http://www.cptech.org/ip/health/orphan/.
61
See Chapter 2.
62
op. cit. As already noted, there is a group of advisers in the EU on the ethical implication of biotechnology serving the interests of European society and respecting the
fundamental rights of every European citizen. The Group submits reports amongst other
on the compatibility of policies including patent policies with fundamental rights such
as the dignity of the human person. The Group gives its advisory opinion on ethical aspects of patenting inventions involving, for example, elements of human origin, cloning
techniques, health care in the information society and gene therapy. So, for example, in
the EU we have a Directive 98/44/EC on the Legal Protection of Biotechnology Inventions OJ 1998 L213/13, excluding the patenting of inventions which would be contrary
to public order or morality, and a Directive 98/79/EC, on In-Vitro Diagnostic Medical
Devices 1998 OJ No. L 331/1 referring to the protection of the integrity of human persons. See also Chapter 3.

88

The patent balance

private commercial pricing practices are shown to be probabilistically related


to impaired or reduced access to medication.63
4.3.3.2 The indirect effect of the right to health
The right to health may have indirect effects in such cases through its internal
effects on the patent system itself. The obligations to respect, to protect and to
fulfil obviously overlap to some extent and indeed, the manner in which a state
enforces and interprets its legislation, including competition, patent, and intellectual property legislation, in cases involving access to medicines involves
important administrative and other measures needed to fulfil the right to
health.64 Hence the objectives of the right to health may need to be read in the
patent provisions so as to guide their interpretation and application.
In the case of Odir Miranda v El Salvador,65 the refusal of El Salvador to
purchase the triple therapy and other medication to improve the quality of life
of people suffering from HIV/AIDS and to prevent deaths, was found to be a
violation of the right to life and health. The Inter-American Court of Human
Rights (IACHT) concluded that while it did not have the competence to determine violations of Art. 10 of the Protocol of San Salvador, it would take the
provisions relating to the right to health into account in analysing the merits of
the case.66 Following this reasoning, it should be possible for the provisions relating to the right to health to be taken into account when applying patent law.
The Recent WTO Ministerial Declaration on the TRIPS Agreement and
Public Health recognised the gravity of health problems and stressed the need
for TRIPS to be part of the wider national and international activities to address
these problems. In this regard, it was stated that the TRIPS Agreement does
not and should not prevent Members from taking measures to protect public

63
A.E. Yamin (2003) op. cit. p.207; P. Drahos, Biotechnology Patents, Markets and
Morality, 21(9) EIPR 441 (1999); B. Cornish, M. Llewelyn, M. Adcock, Intellectual
Property Rights and Genetics. A study into the impact and management of intellectual
property rights within the healthcare sector, 2003 at http://www.phgu.org.uk/about_
phgu/resources/word/s-ipr1.doc; C. Pekari, Intellectual Property and Human Rights:
Where to after the first WSIS? at http://www.eumap.org/journal/features/2004/infohr1/
infohr/ipandhr/.
64
A.E. Yamin (2003) op. cit.; H. Hogerzeil, Access to Essential Medicines as a Human Right, 33 Essential Drugs Monitor 25, 2003 at http://www.who.int/medicines/
library/monitor/33/EDM33_25-26_Access_e.pdf; R-J Dupuy (1979) op. cit; M. Whitehead, The Concepts and Principles of Equity and Health, Copenhagen, WHO Regional
Office for Europe (1990).
65
Odir Miranda v El Salvador Case 12.249, Report No. 29/01, Inter-Am. CHR,
Annual Report 2000, OEA/Ser./L/V/II.111, Doc. 20 Rev. 2001 available at www.cidh.
oas.org/annualrep/2000eng/ChapterIII/Admissible/ElSalvador12.249.htm.
66
Ibid. 36.

The right to health

89

health.67 It also affirmed that the TRIPS Agreement should be interpreted and
implemented in a manner supportive of WTO Members right to protect public
health.
Furthermore, in 2000 the Sub-Commission on Human Rights affirmed the
primacy of human rights obligations over economic policies and agreements.68
Therefore, international human rights law addresses the need to ensure that the
TRIPS Agreement, and hence, the Community IP provisions which are consistent with the former, should not be implemented in a way that negatively impacts
on the enjoyment of human rights as provided for in international human rights
instruments.69 States parties must take action that is conducive to realising the
right to health, and as recognised in Doha, the TRIPS Agreement can and
should be interpreted in a manner that supports their obligations with regard
to the right to health.

67
In the main Doha Declaration, it was stated that: We recognize that under WTO
rules no country should be prevented from taking measures for the protection of human,
animal or plant life or health, or of the environment at the levels it considers appropriate,
subject to the requirement that they are not applied in a manner which would constitute
a means of arbitrary or unjustifiable discrimination between countries where the same
conditions would prevail, or a disguised restriction on international trade, and are otherwise in accordance with the provisions of the WTO Agreements (para 6) Doha
Declaration (2001) op. cit.
See also R. Elliott, Realizing the right to health: access to HIV/AIDS-related medication, 3 April 2002 at http://www.aidslaw.ca/Maincontent/issues/cts/righttohealth.doc.
As clarified by the Doha Declaration, the TRIPS Agreement must be interpreted in
accordance with the rules of public international law found in the Vienna Convention on
the Law of Treaties, which requires that the interpretation of a Treaty must take subsequent agreements on the interpretation of the Treaty, subsequent practice, and any
relevant rules of international law into account. As the Doha Declaration is an example
of a subsequent agreement, the TRIPS Agreement can and should be interpreted and
implemented in a manner supportive of the right to protect public health and promote
access to medicines for all. Hence, the TRIPS Agreement must be interpreted in this way
in order to be consistent with the obligation to protect, respect and fulfil human rights,
including the right to health.
68
E/CN.4/SUB.2/RES.2000/7, United Nations High Commissioner for Human
Rights, Intellectual Property and Human Rights, Sub-Commission on Human Rights.
This was reiterated in the UN Resolution of the Sub-Commission on Human Rights
2001/21. See also E/C.12/2001/15, Human Rights and Intellectual Property Issues,
Statement by the Committee on Economic, Social and Cultural Rights, 26 November
2001, Intellectual Property and Human Rights (Geneva: World Intellectual Property
Organization and the Office of the United Nations High Commissioner for Human
Rights, 1999), WIPO Publication No. 762(E).
69
Ibid.

90

The patent balance

4.3.4 The Right to Health as an Interpretive Principle in Patent Law


The Report of the High Commissioner on the Impact of the TRIPS Agreement
on Human Rights70 stresses the importance of a human rights approach to IP.
This approach relies upon striking a balance with the primary objective of promoting and protecting human rights without causing a negative impact on any
other rights in the Covenant. Human rights are the first responsibility of
Governments.71
A human rights approach to IP differs in some ways from commercial IP
rights. A human rights approach to IP highlights the often implicit balance between the interests of the public and the right holder, and makes it more explicit.
The human rights approach is predicated on the centrality of protecting and
nurturing human dignity and the common good. The goal is to improve human
welfare and not to maximize the economic benefit. From a human rights perspective IP protection is understood more as a social product with a social
function and not primarily as an economic relationship.72
A similar approach has been advocated in the context of trade liberalisation.
In 2002, the need for the WTO to endorse a human rights approach to trade and
promote and protect human rights was recognised in the Report of the High
Commissioner on the liberalisation of trade.73
This approach, amongst other things, involves setting the promotion and
protection of human rights among the objectives of trade liberalisation, taking
the rights of individuals into account in determining the effects of trade liberalisation, and promoting international cooperation for the realisation of human
rights and freedoms in the context of trade liberalisation. Hence consideration
must be paid to the protection of human rights in negotiating, implementing

70
E/CN.4/Sub.2/2001/27, The Impact of the Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects
of Intellectual Property Rights on Human Rights, Report of the High Commissioner, 27
June 2001.
71
Vienna Declaration and Program of Action, World Conference on Human rights,
25 June 1993.
The TRIPS agreement envisages human rights as exceptions to the rule rather than as
an explicit guiding principle.
72
A.R. Chapman, The Human Rights Implications of Intellectual Property Protection, in 5 Journal of International Economic Law 861 (2002). See also D. Weissbrod and
K. Schoff, Human Rights Approach to Intellectual Property Protection: The Genesis and
Application of Sub-Commission Resolution 2000/7, 5(1) Minnesota Intellectual Property
Review 1-46 (2003); T.A. Lipinski and J.C. Pekari, J Britz, Rethinking the ownership of
information in the twenty first century: Ethical implications, 2 Ethics and Information
Technology 4971 (2000).
73
E/CN.4/Sub.2/2002/9, Report of the High Commissioner, Economic, Social and
Cultural Rights, Liberalization of trade in services and human rights, 25 June 2002.

The right to health

91

and interpreting the scope of GATS and in assessing the limitations of trade
practices.
In addition to this interpretive requirement, GATS also includes general exceptions to protect public morals as well as human, animal and plant life and
the protection of certain aspects of individual privacy.74 The report lists some
types of action to promote a human rights approach to the liberalisation of trade
in services, including: the guarantee of equal access for basic services; the
preservation of states parties right and duty to regulate; encouraging compatibility with human rights in the interpretation of GATS; undertaking human rights
assessments of trade policies; the provision of international cooperation and
assistance and increasing dialogue between human rights and trade.
4.3.4.1 Effect on specific patent provisions
It would therefore seem that a human rights approach to IP would require that
the limitation provisions and those relating to compulsory licensing (CL) should
be given a broader interpretation, and that health issues should be considered
in the application of standards relating to patentability.75 This would require a
more explicit consideration of the publics interests to the detriment of the economic interests of individual right holders.76 A human rights (or at least a right
to health) approach would differ from the approach of IP law, as it would place
greater emphasis on the interests of the public in the short term, as well as in
the long term.
For example, if the application of a law could potentially impact on the right
to health, a right to health standard should be applied as a guiding principle.
This could be seen in the case of patent law, subverting issues such as compulsory licensing to address health concerns and exceptions to patentability to the
right to health body of law. In this way, patent law could incorporate the right
to health standards in its decision-making process.
The use of human rights as an interpretive principle in the patent CL provisions would not only require that the provision referring to extreme urgency
including public health, would be judged from a human rights perspective, but

74

Ibid.
See, for example, the interpretation of ordre public as involving something abhorrent to the overwhelming majority of the public or a contravention of the totality of
accepted norms op. cit.
76
See, for example, A.R. Chapman (2002) op. cit. who contends that many factors
indicate that IP rights are inconsistent with the human rights approach, and perhaps even
human rights law in general. These include: the fact that IP does not necessarily protect
the rights of the inventors, especially in the case of employment; the lack of democratic
control and participation; and the often inadequate protection of the human interest or
ethical concerns.
75

92

The patent balance

Patent scope
Public health, including
the right to health as
determined by human
rights law and public
policy; not IP law.
Figure 4.1 What the CL provisions show in relation to IP and public health

it would also potentially affect the interpretation of the CL provisions relating


to significant technological advances. In such cases, it might lead to a more lenient application of the provisions and, also, to a lower threshold for CL. If the
impact of the improvement on public health is deemed to be significant, it will
be easier to prove that a technological advance has taken place.77 In addition,
77
Apart from the interpretive principle to be used in cases of CL or to exclude specific cases from patentability, it might also be possible for the principle to become a
defence to patent infringement. Cases of a similar nature have been brought in the USA,
in which the question has been posed in terms of the First Amendment guarantee of
freedom of speech, and the extent to which it may be used as a defence to copyright infringement. See Howard Hughes case 366 F.2d 303 (2nd Cir. 1966). See Time Inc. v
Bernard Geis Associates NYLR, 21 January, 1994, p.5 (CD Cal. June 11, 1993). In
Germany see LG Berlin (Photographs of Ulrike Meinhof) [1978] GRUR 108 and BGH,
7 March 1985 (Lili Marleen) [1987] GRUR 34. See also Pinto, The Influence of the European Convention on Human Rights [2002] EIPR 217; P. Loughlan, Looking at the
Matrix: Intellectual Property and Expressive Freedom [2002] EIPR 30; Dutch Scientology decision [2003] Mediaforum 337, note Visser; (2003) 6 AMI 217, note Hugenholtz;
(2003) 6 IER 352, note Grosheide. An appeal to the Supreme Court is pending. In this
case, while an infringement of the copyright was found, it was argued that it was disproportional in comparison to the general interest in freedom of information of Art. 10, para.
1 of the ECHR and therefore the publication was allowed. It should also be noted that
the Dutch Civil Code provides for cases of abuse of copyright including cases where
there is a disproportionate balance between the interest protected and those harmed by
the exclusive right. ((Civil Code Art. 3:13): Instances of abuse of right are (1) the exercise of a right with the sole intention of harming another or (2) for a purpose other than
that for which it was granted or (3) the exercise of a right where its holder could not reasonably have decided to exercise it, given the disproportion between the interest to
exercise the right and the harm caused thereby.) See also H.C. Jehoram, Copyright and

The right to health

93

in considering exclusions on the grounds of ordre public, the right to health


would also need to be considered.
4.3.4.2 Case-law on public health
Health emergencies provide sufficient ground for derogating from the rules laid
down in TRIPS, which on the one hand reflects the potential supremacy of human right concerns such as the right to health, and on the other hand, it
demonstrates the flexibility granted by the TRIPS Agreement allowing for the
consideration and implementation of fundamental concerns, such as those relating to the right to health.78 The experience of both Brazil and South Africa reflect
these considerations.
In South Africa, the debate centred on the 1997 Medicines and Related Substances Control Amendment Act, which represented a response to the HIV/AIDS
crisis and the lack of access to affordable drugs. This Act authorises the government to determine the extent to which a specific drug patent may apply, and to
authorise parallel imports from other countries where the same medicine is also
manufactured.79
The pharmaceutical companies challenged the first provision of this Act, alleging that it was unconstitutional in granting too much discretion to the
government in determining the circumstances in which patents could be curtailed. The upholding of the right to curtail patent rights would appear to confirm
the supremacy of health concerns. The Act could either be seen as compatible
with the limitations provided for in the patent system itself and thereby constitutional, or it could be found that the right to property did not allow for such
interventions in the exclusivity and was unaffected by the right to health, and
therefore be found to be unconstitutional.
The petition was abandoned in April 2001 in the face of strong public opposition. While we can only speculate on the outcome of the case, the abandoning

Freedom of Expression, Abuse of Rights and Standard Chicanery: American and Dutch
Approaches, 26(7) EIPR 275, 2004.
In such instances, use of the defence is rare, although IP statutes are increasingly being
openly read and narrowly construed in order to take the requirements of freedom of expression into consideration. Hence, it might be that one could legitimately raise the
defence of the right to health in a patent infringement case, although it is more likely
that the latter would work as a ground for the granting of a CL rather than a right to infringe it. Otherwise, this would lead to private companies being found to have infringed
the right to health by restricting access to drugs, despite acting in line with patent law.
However, it is difficult to imagine that the right to health would ever be entrenched to
such a degree.
78
Cullet (2001) op. cit.
79
Section 15C of the Medicines and Related Substances Control Amendment Act
1997 (Republic of South Africa, Government Gazette, 12 December 1997).

94

The patent balance

of the case could be interpreted as support for the predominance of health


concerns.
The Brazilian experience could also be seen as a reflection of the flexibility
envisaged in TRIPS in order to give effect to human rights. In this case, the
government made a decision to facilitate access to drugs in the face of the
HIV/AIDS crisis by implementing a strong CL regime. It was stipulated that
unless it was economically unfeasible, inventors had a duty to manufacture the
products in Brazil. The US government objected to this requirement and initiated
WTO complaint proceedings, on the grounds that the local working requirement constituted a protective industrial policy measure inconsistent with the
provisions of the TRIPS Agreement. Following some bilateral negotiations, the
case was withdrawn after a few months.
Brazil has gone further than TRIPS in recognising the possibility for CL
for national emergencies and public interest, as well as establishing the rules
for the granting of these licences and defining the public interest to include
public health, nutrition, the protection of the environment, and elements of
primordial importance for technological, social or economic development.80
The fact that the case was dropped could be read as the acceptance of the
subordination of patent policy to the public interest or at least it could be interpreted as reflecting the flexibility of patent protection in addressing health
emergencies.
In line with the TRIPS Agreement, the parties are permitted to address national emergencies and public health issues without infringing patent laws, by
interpreting the flexibility in a manner that is conducive to the public interest
and health. This would be consistent with the right to health as an interpretive
principle in patent protection.81
4.3.4.3 European cases on IP and fundamental rights analysis
Within the EU framework, the ECJ has handed down two judgments on IPRs
involving fundamental rights, although it should be noted that neither of these
cases involved the right to health.
In Netherlands v Council and Parliament, the ECJ analysed the Biotechnology Directive.82 In this case, the ECJ stated that the granting of a patent does
not preclude legal limitations from applying to research into or the exploitation
of patented products. It further held that the purpose of the Directive was not to

80
See WTO, WTO Agreements and Public Health, A Joint Study by WHO and the
WTO Secretariat, 2002, pp.1046.
81
M.G. Bloche (2002) op. cit.
82
Case C-377/98 Netherlands v Council, Judgment of the Court of 9 October 2001,
ECR I-07079.

The right to health

95

place restrictive provisions guaranteeing compliance with certain ethical rules


outside the scope of the Directive.83
The ECJ adopted a narrow reading of fundamental rights by finding that they
are misplaced as against a directive which concerns only the grant of patents.84
The ECJ thereby insulated ethical and fundamental rights considerations from
the granting of the patent and, in this way, it could be argued that its approach
differs significantly from the idea of a human rights interpretive principle. The
potential existence of restrictive provisions outside patent law does not exclude
the need to take fundamental rights into account also within patent law. When
the exclusion from patentability is related to the protection of a fundamental
right, the patent law principle of narrow interpretation of exclusions from patentability becomes very problematic.85
In Metronome Music v Music Point Hokamp the ECJ considered whether the
Directive on rental and lending rights was consistent with the freedom to pursue
a trade or a profession and also with the right to property.86 The Advocate General Tesauro had contended that Art. 27(2) recognises copyright as a human
right and the Court found that the granting of an exclusive right certainly constitutes the most effective form of protection . 87 The Court also found that
the freedom to pursue trade or profession cannot be interpreted in isolation from
the general principles relating to IPRs.
Insofar as the Court omitted any reference to the collective good provided
for in the human rights treaties and in the public interest, the reasoning is insufficient. In addition, the view that the exclusive property regime is the least
restrictive and most effective regime, can be criticised as the right to IP does
not precipitate exclusive rights and a liability system could also be put in place
to safeguard these interests.88
In both cases, the ECJ did not attribute any particular importance to the fundamental rights in interpreting IP and, to this extent, it appeared to be in favour
of stronger IP protection.89 This is regrettable as it is set against the background

83
Ibid. para. 7980. See also M. MacLaren, Patently Unsatisfactory?: Community
Legislative Competence and the ECJ Biotech Decision, 2 German Law Journal 18
(2002).
84
Ibid. para. 79.
85
T. Mully (2004) op. cit.
86
Case C-200/96, Metronome Music v Music Camp, Judgement of the Court of 28
April 1998, ECR I-01953.
87
Ibid, para. 24.
88
See Chapter 5 at 5.3.1.2. However, the Court also referred to the right to property
(in addition to the freedom to pursue trade or profession) as not being absolute but rather
should be viewed in relation to their [its] social function which could be used in future
cases in such way as to support the public interest.
89
T. Mully (2004) op. cit.

96

The patent balance

of the proliferation of IPRs and the increasing concerns in the biopharmaceutical


industry,90 although arguably, if the right to health had been at stake, the ECJ
might have ruled otherwise.
To the extent fundamental rights analysis does not form part of the balancing
instruments within IP laws, a right to health interpretive principle should be
endorsed where applicable.

4.4 Conclusions
In this chapter it was shown that the right to health constitutes a central concern
and continues to be one of the primary obligations of governments. It assumes
a particular significance in relation to the biopharmaceutical industry, as goods
are used to enhance the quality of life.
The right to health has become increasingly justiciable, particularly in countries where access to medication has become a national emergency. In this
context, the relationship between the right to health and patent law has become
critical.
In general, the right to health and the right to IP (whether this is regarded as
a human right or not) are not incompatible.91 It is, therefore, unlikely that the
right to health would have a direct impact on patent law in the sense of finding
the latter unconstitutional. None the less, the subordination of the analysis of
IP rights to the public interest plays a pivotal role, and in light of these conditions the right to health could be decisive as an interpretive principle to patent
law.
The Doha Declaration clarified that TRIPS should not prevent members from
taking action to protect public health and that the flexibility provided for in
TRIPS could be used for this purpose. It also highlights that the TRIPS Agreement should be interpreted and implemented in line with the right to protect
health and promote access to medicine for all and highlights the importance of
the reference to the balance of interests within the objectives and principles
of TRIPS.
The right to health as an interpretive principle would most likely have the
greatest impact in the interpretation of the CL provisions and the provisions
relating to exclusions in the interest of the ordre public. In the case of CL, it
would direct the determination of extreme urgency, public health and
90

See Chapter 2.
Patent law deals with long-term health considerations by providing the incentive
for the development of pharmaceutical products. In addition, patent law contains a provision allowing for CL in cases that are warranted by public health and other similar
provisions such as the interest of ordre public.
91

The right to health

97

public interest to the health provisions and related considerations. It could


also serve to lower the threshold of CL in cases involving secondary dependent
patents of significant economic advantage. In such cases, an invention would
be more likely to warrant a licence if it has clear relevance to public health
concerns.
The international trends demonstrate a wider application of fundamental
rights analysis and the increased justiciability of the right to health. On the
other hand, the ECJ has considered fundamental rights in relation to IP on two
occasions, and in both cases that analysis worked to strengthen IP protection,
making no reference to the public interest. While it is true that there has not
been a case in which the right to health has been explicitly violated in the EU,
the health interpretive principle to patent law, where applicable, would appear
to be consistent with its obligations and with the international trends in this
domain.
None the less, the health interpretive principle does not resolve the problematic issues in the biopharmaceutical industry. The principle is directed more to
end product accessibility and dissemination rather than access to research inputs,
therefore, in the absence of a patent mechanism, a right to health interpretation
would not be helpful. Imposing a direct obligation in cases involving access to
inputs to carry out downstream research to ensure consistency with the right to
health would be too far-fetched, as it involves potential innovation with only
potential effects on health.92
In the absence of more general IP provisions, competition may have a role
to play in this instance of restricted access to necessary inputs to downstream
innovation.93 This would also be consistent with the obligations of states to
protect the right to health, and ensure compliance in their interpretation of
competition laws.94 In a situation of alleged conflict between patent law and the
potential health and right to health implications, the human rights approach
could require more flexibility in analysing competition law provisions.95 Indeed

92
See also the attempt of families of children afflicted with Canavan disease, a rare
genetic disorder of the brain, to sue the research scientists who had patented the gene in
an effort to ensure broader and improved licensing terms. P. Gorner, Parents Suing Over
Patenting of Genetic Test, Chi. Trib., 19 November 2000, p.1.
93
See Chapter 7.
94
Strong enforcement of anti-competition rules where patent holders refuse to grant
licenses to generic producers and excessively price their products is therefore a measure
that can and should be taken to reduce the inequitable distribution of health facilities,
goods and services in contemplation of the ESCR Committees General Comment No.
14. Statement by consumer project on technology, concerning an alleged prohibited
practice in terms of section 49B(2)(a) of the Competition Act 89 of 1998, Feb. 2003 at
http://www.cptech.org/ip/health/cl-cases/rsa-tac/cptech-statement-3feb2003.doc, p.12.
95
H. Hogerzeil (2003) op. cit.; B. Cornish et al. (2003) op. cit.

98

The patent balance

the recent South African judgment which found an abuse of a dominant position
by virtue of excessive pricing could be seen as a move in this direction.96

96
In The Matter Between Mpho Makhathnini, Nelislwe Mthethwa, Musa Msomi,
Elijah Paul Musoke, Tom Myers, AIDS Healthcare Foundation Limited, and GlaxoSmithKline (Pty) Ltd, Glaxo Group Limited, Case Number 34/CR/Apr04, in which the South
African courts found GlaxoSmithKlyne to have abused its dominant position by virtue
of the excessive price of drugs. See also the South African Competition Tribunals decision and order in Pharmaceutical Wholesalers and Glaxo Wellcome, Case 68/IR/Jun00,
18 June 2003 at www.comptrib.co.za/decidedcases/pdf/68IRJUN00kinesis.pdf, and Case
No. 15/CAC/Feb02. See Chapter 7.

PART III

Antitrust as a complement to the patent system

5. Unilateral conduct, intellectual


property rights and competition law: a
systems interaction
5.1 Introduction
The relationship between intellectual property (IP) and competition is a controversial subject. Whilst both share a common objective, namely, the enhancement
of consumer welfare and promoting innovation, some problems arise as they
operate in different ways.
Antitrust seeks to achieve the object of maximising allocative and productive
efficiency by preventing monopolistic output reduction and unlawful restrictions on competition, whilst intellectual property rights (IPRs) endeavour to
achieve the same result by providing a legal monopoly as an incentive for innovation and for the manufacture of new and cheaper products. In the short run
consumers are supplied with an additional choice, albeit at a monopoly price;
and in the long run when the patent expires, the industry as a whole can produce
more and at lower cost.
Hence, while the relationship between IP and competition is no longer
perceived as inherently conflictual, and the possible pro-competitive role of
IPRs has been recognised, at least for long-term competition, there are still
cases where EC competition law will intervene if it is perceived that the shortterm impact on competition outweighs the long-term efficiencies. This is
usually the case where the patent holder is able to extend his legal monopoly
beyond the statutory grant, often to overlap with an economic monopoly, or
to pursue aims against the letter and the spirit of the EU competition
provisions.


Allocative efficiency presupposes that the price mechanism will ensure that producers produce what the consumers want, and productive efficiency presupposes that
competition from other producers will produce at near optimum costs. See S. Anderman,
EC Competition Law and IPRs: The Regulation of Innovation, Oxford University Press
(1998), p.17.

R. Merkin, The Interface between Antitrust and Intellectual Property [1985] ECLR
377.

101

102

Antitrust as a complement to the patent system

Table 5.1 EC Treaty relevant provisions


EC Treaty Wording
Provisions
Art. 3

For the purposes set out in Art. 2, the activities of the


Community shall include
(c) an internal market characterised by the abolition, as
between Member States, of obstacles to the free
movement of goods, persons, services and capital
(g) a system ensuring that competition in the internal market
is not distorted

Art. 28

Quantitative restrictions on imports and all measures having


equivalent effect shall be prohibited between Member States.

Art. 29

Quantitative restrictions on exports and all measures having


equivalent effect shall be prohibited between Member States.

Art. 30

The provisions of Arts 28 and 29 shall not preclude


prohibitions or restrictions on imports, exports or goods in
transit justified on grounds of the protection of industrial
and commercial property. Such prohibitions or restrictions shall
not, however, constitute a means of arbitrary discrimination or
a disguised restriction on trade between Member States.

Art. 82

Any abuse by one or more undertakings of a dominant position


within the common market or in a substantial part of it shall be
prohibited as incompatible with the common market in so far
as it may affect trade between Member States. Such abuse may,
in particular consist of:
(a) directly or indirectly imposing unfair purchase or selling
prices or other unfair trading conditions;
(b) limiting production, markets or technical development to
the prejudice of consumers;
(c) applying dissimilar conditions to equivalent transactions
with other trading parties, thereby placing them at a
competitive disadvantage;
(d) making the conclusion of contracts subject to acceptance
by the other parties of supplementary obligations which,
by their nature or according to commercial usage, have no
connection with the subject of such contracts.

Art. 295

This Treaty shall in no way prejudice the rules in Member States


governing the system of property ownership.

Unilateral conduct, intellectual property rights and competition law

103

Whilst it has been repeatedly recognised that the grant and scope of IPRs is
a matter for national law, in the absence of harmonisation, the ECJ and the
Commission have also repeatedly confirmed that the exercise of IPRs can be
subject to competition control and, in certain cases, the unilateral refusal of an
IP holder may even be found to constitute an abuse.
This chapter examines the relationship between the two bodies of law as applied to unilateral conduct. The approach of the European Courts is examined
against the economic theory and the conclusions are drawn in the final section.

5.2 The practice of the courts


Article 82 of the EC Treaty prohibits the abuse of a position by dominant undertakings. However, the precise content of an abuse in the case of IPRs is a
contentious issue. The Commission and Courts have struggled to draw a clear
distinction between a lawful exercise of exclusivity and an unlawful one, under
Art. 82.
The whole debate on how competition should deal with IPRs and whether it
is able to trump national IP laws, can be traced back to Art. 295, which provides
that the Treaty shall in no way prejudice the rules in Member States governing
the system of property ownership. In an attempt to uphold Art. 295, the Courts
and Commission came up with several doctrines seeking to balance the national
character and independent status of property rights with the Community laws
and policy objectives.
In general, the Courts and Commission have followed an approach that distinguishes IP from other cases, thus, a more favourable stance is taken whereby
the exercise of exclusivity will only constitute an abuse in exceptional cases.
5.2.1 The Existence/Exercise Distinction
The tensions that have been traditionally perceived between national IPRs and
EC competition law has led the Commission and Courts to try to achieve a balance between the two bodies of law, most significantly, distinguishing between

Case 89/205 Magill [1995] ECR I-743.


See case-law analysed in 5.2.

A-G Jacobs in Oscar Bronner (Case C-7/97 [1998] ECR I-7791) referred to the
essential facilities doctrine in relation to IPRs: Where such exclusive rights are granted
for a limited period, that in itself involves a balancing of the interest in free competition
with that of providing an incentive for R&D and for creativity. It is therefore with good
reason that the Court has held that the refusal to license does not of itself, in the absence
of other factors, constitute an abuse.


104

Antitrust as a complement to the patent system

the existence and exercise of IPRs. According to this doctrine, the existence of
an IPR would be unaffected by competition law, while competition law could
control the way these rights were exercised in certain cases.
The origin of this distinction can be found in the competition law case of
Consten and Grundig, in which the Court stated that the Commissions decision
did not affect the grant of the rights but only limited their exercise in order to
avoid a presumed violation of Art. 222 of the Treaty of Rome (now Art. 295)
(providing that the Treaty shall in no way prejudice the rules in Member States
governing the system of property ownership).
Following this judgment, the doctrine was criticised as being incoherent and
unnecessary. The existence/exercise distinction appears to have arisen from a
hasty response by the Court to Constens and Grundigs argument regarding
Art. 222 (now Art. 295). Marenco and Banks note that the Court could have
given a wholly different answer by pointing out that Art. 222 (now Art. 295) is
not a guarantee of property (as is Art. 36) (now Art. 30) but a provision ensuring
that the Treaty does not detract from the freedom of Member States (MS) to
determine the private or public ownership of enterprises.
In the context of the free movement (specifically Arts 30 and 36) (now Arts
28 and 30) the doctrine was believed to be necessary at a time when IP laws
were only national in nature. It was felt that a balance had to be struck between
the need to respect national IP laws while also ensuring that they were not used
in a way to impede the free movement within the Community. In this way, the
doctrine was used to justify a de facto harmonisation of IPRs.
In an attempt to distinguish between the existence and exercise of IPRs in line
with the principle of free movement, the court then developed the specific subject
matter concept (SSM),10 referred to elsewhere also as the essential function.11
The exercise of IPRs in a manner inconsistent with Art. 30 is only permitted
under Art. 36 if such exercise is in the course of protecting the SSM. 12


Case 56 and 58/64 Etablissements Consten SA and Grundig-Verkaufs-GmbH v
Commission [1966] ECR 299.

T.C. Vinje, Magill: Its Impact on the IT industry [1992] EIPR 397.

Marenco and Bancs, IP and the Community Rules on Free Movement: Discrimination Unearthed, 15 ELR 224 (1990).

When IPRs are reviewed under Art. 36, the Court strikes out one part of national
IP law. IPRs are interpreted and applied in order to ensure compatibility with Community law. See Myrick, Will IP on Technology still be Viable in a Unitary Market [1992]
EIPR 9.
10
Case 78/70 Deutsche Grammophon [1974] ECR 1147.
11
See Commission Decision DSD and others, OJ 2001 L 319/1, in which it was
stated that the crucial question concerns the essential function.
12
S. Smith, The Changing Approach of the European Court to Intellectual Property,
at www.solent.ac.uk/law/ssmith2.html, p 8. See also M. Van Der Wal, Art 86: The Limits

Unilateral conduct, intellectual property rights and competition law

105

In the competition law context, however, it is questionable whether these


concepts are applicable.13 Control is not directed to state measures but rather
individual entities. Article 36 requires that the restrictions on imports should be
justified by the protection of IPRs. Article 295, which is applicable to the
competition rules, does not include this requirement. Arts 85 and 86 (now Arts
81 and 82) should not be invoked to limit the substance of IPRs under national
laws. The ECJ, at least in competition cases, will not attempt to second guess
the national legislatures wisdom in granting an author or inventor a particular
right.14
In addition, the existence/exercise distinction is not particularly helpful in
distinguishing a permissible use from an abuse of IPRs. An obligation upon
the proprietor of a protected design to grant third parties, even in return for a
reasonable royalty, a licence for the supply of products incorporating the design
would lead to the proprietor thereof being deprived of the substance of his exclusive right.15 In cases where national law grants an IPR, its existence cannot
generally be divorced from its availability in each particular case.
The SSM doctrine did not assist in clarifying the demarcation of unlawful
conduct.16 Abusive exercise requires certain additional features over and above
the mere refusal to allow others to use the protected rights.17 Similarly, in
Magill, it was stated that the aims of Art. 86 should be respected, thus rendering
the attempt to make this distinction largely redundant.18 The abusive element
of Compulsory Licensing [1994] ECLR 231; Reindl, The Magic of Magill: TV Program
Guides as a Limit of Copyright Law? [1993] IIC 60; A. Robertson, Compulsory Licensing
Under EC Law? [1992] LQR 39.
13
S. Smith op. cit. p 8. The distinction between the inviolability of the exercise of
IPRs (per Art. 222, now 295) and the vulnerability of their exercise under Treaty provisions is illogical, since a prohibition on the exercise of rights means that an essential part
of the relevant law is unenforceable, and thus is an attack on the very existence of such
laws. Beier, Industrial Property and Internal Market, 2 IIC 131, 1990.
14
Myrick (1992) op. cit.
15
Case 238/87 Volvo v Veng (UK) Ltd [1988] ECR 6211.
16
See Case C-241 and 242/91P Magill [1995] ECR I-743. In this case the CFI stated
that while it is plain that the exercise of the exclusive right to reproduce a protected
work is not in itself an abuse, that does not apply where in the light of the details of each
individual case, it is apparent that that right is exercised in such ways as in fact to pursue
an aim manifestly contrary to the objectives of Art. 86. In that event, the copyright is no
longer exercised in a manner which corresponds to its essential function which is
while respecting the aims of, in particular, Art 86. While the Court made reference to
the essential function, it also stated that the objectives of Art. 86 should be taken into
account in determining this function.
17
Ibid.
18
See also C.G. Miller, Magill: Time to Abandon the Specific Subject-Matter Concept [1994] EIPR 415, who argues for the abandonment of the SSM because it is
illogical, causes confusion, leads to inconsistent results and is wrong. He describes the

106

Antitrust as a complement to the patent system

related to the provisions of Art. 82 and it was the objectives that were subject
to control, rather than an exercise beyond the SSM.
Since the Magill case, the ECJ has not made reference to the existence/exercise doctrine and it is hoped that it is silently pronouncing its death.19 Instead,
the circumstance-based approach was upheld as a means of determining
whether a particular conduct constitutes an abuse. While the circumstance
approach represents a positive step as it is not reliant on an all-encompassing
rule, and allows each case to be judged according to the circumstances, it is believed that the ECJ should have provided more details on what constitutes
exceptional circumstances, and IP differs from other cases.20 Economic theory
supports the view that there is no reason to treat IP differently from other property rights.

distinction between the exercise of IPRs and the abusive exercise of market dominance
as the source of the confusion. He draws the distinction between the copyright itself, and
the ancillary freedoms stemming from this right. He explains that abuses are exercises
of ancillary freedoms and not of copyright, which are possible because of its dominance.
It is thus unnecessary to identify the core rights as they are already set out in legislation.
Further, he argues that abuses of dominance involving IPRs are committed without the
exercise of an IPR. The author makes an analogy with real property: an undertaking
that has become dominant, in part because it has built up the largest, or one of the few
largest, and most efficient manufacturing facilities in Europe. Any exercise of its rights
of property ownership over the land, buildings and machinery, to prevent competitors
coming on to his property to use his facility to compete, could prevent or restrict competition. However, such an exercise can never be an abuse of market dominance. It is
plainly and simply and obviously an exercise of property rights conferred by law. This
is not an exercise of market power in order to prevent others competing. The SSM and
essential function of such rights are simply not an issue.
19
However, see also the Commission Decision in DSD (2001) op. cit. in which it is
stated that the crucial question concerns the essential function. Some have argued that
this does not mean that IPRs have no special status, as they do not constitute per se an
abuse or require exceptional circumstances. S. Anderman, The Aftermath of Magill [1996]
Yearbook of Media and Entertainment Law 235. However, do the other refusal to license
cases constitute an abuse per se? The response would appear to be negative according
to the latest trends. And as to exceptional circumstances, it is also not clear if this alludes
to a different threshold than the general situations of a duty to deal.
20
T. Vinje, The final word on Magill [1995] EIPR 297.

Unilateral conduct, intellectual property rights and competition law

107

5.3 IPRs and competition: A systems


interaction
5.3.1 IPRs Public Goods, Exclusivity and Information Goods
5.3.1.1 Public goods and market failure
IPRs are an instrument used to further public policy objectives. In an information-based economy, policy objectives broadly refer to the desire to maximise
the net social benefits arising from new information assets, and to ensure the
equal social net rate of return on investments. More specifically, the aim is to
ensure the optimal flow of improvements and development of scientific and
technological knowledge in order to ensure that the information created is used
efficiently for the maximum social benefit of producers and consumers and that
knowledge is diffused to a desirable extent, and to ensure that the creative conditions are such that the social costs of productions are minimised with regard to
the social costs of producing new knowledge and the use of existing
knowledge.21
Knowledge is an unusual commodity with many distinct characteristics arising from its intangible nature. It is difficult to define knowledge precisely or to
clearly demarcate its boundaries or specific attributes and measurements. It can
function both as a pure consumption good and as a capital good having an intrinsic value when combined with another asset. Therefore, for example,
information relating to a cost-reducing process has value of itself. As with classical public goods, knowledge is indivisible and durable. This means that once
it has been obtained, it can last forever, and can be used repeatedly with no need
to recreate it. Its multiple and simultaneous use will not deplete it, therefore, in
terms of consumption, it is a non-rival good.22 While someone might be impoverished by sharing a fish that he has caught with someone, he does not lose
anything if he teaches him how to fish, except to the extent that too many are
educated in such a way as to depend on the same embodiments of the intangible
knowledge, namely here, the fish. As with traditional public goods, information
is also non-excludable. In addition, while the cost of producing information is

21
P.A. David, IP Institutions and Pandas Thumb: Patents, Copyrights, and Trade
Secrets in Economic Theory and History, in Global Dimensions of IPRs in Science and
Technology, Washington, National Academy Press (1993), pp.2445.
22
However, knowledge can often be a positional good in the sense that its value may
depend on how many other people possess it. Hence in many cases the value of information depends on whether it is also available to other people and to how many people. It
works similar to the case of information about a shortcut to a place, that is not crowded
with cars. This might be very valuable information to a taxi driver, but if too many people
know about it then its value would be diminished.

108

Antitrust as a complement to the patent system

high, the cost of transmitting knowledge is negligible in most cases. Hence, had
it not been for the incentives to create it, it should in most cases have been left
free.23
Due to these characteristics, information resembles traditional public goods
like a lighthouse, in that it can be used to the benefit of many without any depletion in use, and it is non-excludable in nature. Its utility is based on its exchange
and propagation. However, contrary to other public goods, knowledge has two
additional characteristics. First, the attributes, characteristics and value of the
commodity are not known beforehand, therefore there is some asymmetry in
the distribution of information. The complete contents of information are not
known beforehand, often even by the interested parties. This renders the conclusion of contracts for the production and use of new information particularly
difficult.24 Secondly, knowledge is cumulative, therefore it builds on prior
knowledge, interacts with other knowledge and involves a recombinant
process.
The problem with public goods is that because they are indivisible, not easilyappropriable and non-rival by nature, the competitive market fails to give
sufficient incentives to induce the optimal amount of innovation. This is because
the competitive market leads prices near the marginal cost of production and
thereby even fails to cover the high fixed production costs. Every consumer is
a potential producer, supplying only at the cost of copying. This implies that in
order to protect oneself against imitation, whether by means of secrecy or otherwise, the inventor will have to incur high transaction costs, thus rendering the
production and sale of the products inefficient.25 In addition, a single unit may
satisfy an infinite number of users at zero or almost zero marginal cost.26 Hence,
without intervention, as in the case of other public goods, a market failure would
result, as witnessed in the form of under-investment in information goods.27

23
For a more extensive discussion of public goods, see H. Perritt, Property and Innovation in the Global Information Infrastructure, 1996 U. Chi. Legal Forum 261; P.A.
David (1993) op. cit. pp.2445; J. Boyle, Law and Economic of IPRs: Cruel, Mean, or
Lavish? Economic Analysis, Price Discrimination and Digital Intellectual Property, 53
Vand. L. Rev. 2007, 2000; Europe Economics, Global Public Goods in Health, May
2001, at www.europe-economics.com/. The costs are not only high for production, but
also to ensure that information is assimilated that learning takes place.
24
P.A. David (1993) op. cit. pp.2445, 28.
25
H. Perritt (1996) op. cit.
26
J. Boyle (2000) op. cit.
27
This proposition, however, is subject to the qualification that it may be time-consuming or impossible to copy information in certain cases, therefore, property rights may
not be required to overcome under-investment. This is apparently the case with Coca
Cola which has not been copied in the past 100 years even though it is not subject to
patent protection. See S. Shavell, Economic Analysis of Property Law, Harvard Law and

Unilateral conduct, intellectual property rights and competition law

109

While the fact that there will otherwise be a market failure does not precipitate
the creation of private rights, due to certain characteristics of information, that
are analysed below, it would seem that it is the most desirable.
5.3.1.2 Patronage, procurement and property
There are three solutions traditionally associated with the problem of public
goods: patronage/subsidies, procurement/direct government production and
property/regulated monopoly.28 The first solution, patronage, refers to publicly
financed subsidies, while the second, procurement, refers to state taxes to finance
contracting with private parties.
Both schemes involve the supply of information without charge, although
patronage is more conducive to the speedy disclosure of information based on
reputation.29 The major drawback of both schemes is that it is almost impossible
to lay down efficient terms for the contract due to the uncertainty surrounding
the nature of the information as well as its value, due to the problem of asymmetry. Hence, there would be very high transaction costs coupled with a huge
administrative burden, which would only lead to imperfect agreements.30
The third option, property, refers to a publicly regulated private monopoly,
which operates for a normal rate of profit, however this is not guaranteed. This
consists of granting exclusive property rights which allow for the formation of
a market, which will, in turn, provide an opportunity for the right holder to
benefit from the profits. The advantage of this approach lies in the fact that there
is no need to predetermine the economic benefits as these are left to the market.
It is the only system that allows for individuals to respond to market opportunities and in this way it also grants economic freedom to the individuals
concerned.31
Property rights are devised to allow for the efficient exploitation of scarce
resources. Right holders must choose the most efficient type of conduct, avoiding problems relating to the overuse of common property, also known as the

Economics Discussion Paper No. 399, Dec. 2002, chapter 12. Indeed, without some form
of protection for information, there would be some degree of creation, reflected also in
the fact that some highly industrialised countries, such as Switzerland, did not adopt
patent legislation until recently, however, it is thought the level of creation would fall
short of the optimal.
28
P.A. David (1993) op. cit. pp.2445, 29.
29
Ibid. pp.2931.
30
See, however, S. Shavell (2002) op. cit. chapter 12, who discusses the reward
system and concludes that For a variety of reasons, apparently more political than based
on consensus about the intellectual appeal of the patent system, the latter system won
out. p.20.
31
It is clear that not all individuals will be able to make choices to respond to the
market, as many will be excluded.

110

Antitrust as a complement to the patent system

tragedy of the commons.32 With regard to information, while not scarce of itself, its specialisation is, in the sense that its creation requires special incentives
to ensure that the creator devotes time to this task. The exclusive right turns a
public good into a private one. As a means of managing scarcity, property rights
assign the responsibility of working with the scarce resource to one individual,
as well as the benefits and losses of that decision. If property rights are transferable, a market may operate and a price can be set. However, the viability of
these rights rests on the need to ensure a sufficient level of exclusivity.33
Different information goods have different public and private good characteristics so that in certain cases there are sources of excludability and rivalness
negating the need for a property right. Lead time, costly copying, less than perfect copies, inability to use copies without the assistance of the inventor and
reputational advantages may be present in such a way in certain types of information, that the public goods justification is obviated.34 The intellectual property
system has to strike a balance between the free knowledge, the knowledge that
is appropriable but not transferable, and the transferable exclusive rights namely the cases where protection is granted.35 Hence, the two basic questions that
IP protection faces are, first, when information deserves protection under property rights, and secondly, the length and breadth of those rights.
Like in all systems, trade-offs are involved in the production of knowledge
and in the grant of property rights. The priority system, for example, on which
the patent system is built, allows for the speedy disclosure of inventions. This
reflects the objective of constant innovation, and rapid development. However,

32
R. Hardin, Valuing Intellectual Property, 68 Chi. Kent L. Rev. 659 (1993); M.A.
Heller, The Tragedy of the Anti-commons: Property in the Transition from Marx to
Markets, 111 Harv. L. Rev. 621 (1998).
33
E. Mackaay, Economic View of Information Law in E.J. Dommering, P.B. Hugenholtz, J.J. Kabel, Information Law towards the 21st century, Deventer/Boston: Kluwer
Law and Taxation Publishers (1992).
See also H. Perritt (1996) op. cit. Perritt justifies the grant of property rights based on
the transaction costs of public goods stemming from their characteristics of non-rivalness
and non-excludability. Every consumer is a potential source of supply at only the cost
of copying and that increases transaction costs. Property rights mitigate free riding by
increasing the pirates costs so that he not only incurs the marginal cost of copying, but
also the legal costs of expected liability. As with all property rights, they are limited in
some way by the needs of the public. See also R. Merges, IPRs and Bargaining Breakdown: The Case of Blocking Patents, 62 Tenn. L. Rev. 75 (1994), where the property
basis of IPRs is defended as it grants the remedy of an injunction that is desirable in view
of the difficulty of calculating the losses resulting from copying.
34
H. Perritt (1996) op. cit. p.269.
35
This is also reflected in the different forms of protection for information according
to its perceived merit. Some information may be protected by trade secret law and tort
and contract law, while other might warrant strong property rights.

Unilateral conduct, intellectual property rights and competition law

111

it also leads to a rush to innovate and rivalries amongst inventors based on a


winner-take-all solution. Too many inventors in the race to innovate and to be
the first to discover or file a particular invention are likely to lead to common
pool problems associated with the fact that people will be individually minded
without consideration of their effects on other competitors.36 It may also lead to
allocative inefficiencies. In addition, as the IP systems like the patent system,
being built on the race-to-innovate, make coordination impossible, they might
lead to wasteful duplication that may be an even larger problem than the common
pool problem. Problems, however, associated with excess or under-investment
are sought to be resolved by the adjustment of the patent length and breadth, so
as to induce optimal innovation.37
However, another disadvantage of the property system relates to the withholding of access to the new knowledge, hindering the creation of similar
knowledge of a superior quality at a possible lower price. This can be witnessed
both by reduced dissemination of the invention in question, and also in the reduced development of improvements or dependent products or services which
depend on the initial invention. The difference between the benefit offered by
the information under property rights and the benefit that would accrue if exploitation had been made on a competitive basis, is the deadweight burden of
the patent monopoly.38
As mentioned above, the implications of the trade-off between the incentives
for new knowledge and its efficient dissemination and exploitation may change
by varying the length and breadth of the endowed property rights. In this way,
it has been shown, for example, that weak and narrow patents may encourage
cross-licences and hence allow for dissemination and improvements, while
strong broad patents may encourage more fundamental, initial breakthrough
inventions.39 The optimal length and breadth, however, is far from clear due to
all of these uncertain and competing interests that need to be addressed in the
patent system. The problems are aggravated by the fact the desirable level and
type of innovation is also unclear.

36

P.A. David (1993) op. cit. pp.2445.


Awarding the property rights early, namely, as soon as it is known that a party has
worked out the essentials of an invention, may mitigate this wasteful effect, but may also
lead to the control of a whole market, or to the suppression of improvements on technology. It is difficult to achieve this balance.
38
P.A. David (1993) op. cit. p.34.
39
R. Merges and R.R. Nelson, On the Complex Economics of Patent Scope, 90
Colum. L. Rev. 839 (1990). The scope of protection includes different aspects, such as
the type of behaviour which constitutes an infringement. It is generally believed that
conduct will be judged to be an infringement if it produces benefits to the right holder
at a low social cost, and vice versa. See S. Shavell (2002) op. cit. chapter 12.
37

112

Antitrust as a complement to the patent system

In conclusion, IP is viewed as an effort to cure a form of market failure arising


in the case of public goods. While it is not the only means of overcoming the
problem of public goods, it is the most desirable solution due to the asymmetry
of information, and the difficulty of placing a value on knowledge prior to its
creation. The advantage of property rights is that they are granted at a time when
the desirability of an invention is not known.40 IP itself, however, involves tradeoffs usually addressed through changes in the length and breadth of the patent.
The trade-offs involved in IP have broadly been described as the vertical and
the horizontal dilemma. The latter involves a compromise between the right to
exclude as an incentive for new technology, and competition for the optimal
exploitation and dissemination of the new technology. The former addresses the
clash between the interests of new technology as an output, and its use as an
input for further research and development of a dependent or similar technology.
Hence, in the definition and demarcation of IPRs it is endeavoured to achieve
the optimal balance between incentives and use and accessibility, and pioneering
works and improvement. These competing considerations reflect the difficulty
and the clashing interests involved in IP as a system.
5.3.2 Implications for competition
5.3.2.1 IP like other property rights for the purposes of competition
IP statutes allow for a market to operate in four ways: they create property rights,
lower transaction costs, provide valuable information, and contain a mechanism
for enforcement.41 Hence, IPRs are devised to create a market for information
goods that would not be established otherwise, or at least not at an optimal level:
IP is conceived to bring informational subject-matter into the realm of market
rules to optimize their creation.42 Private parties are left to internalise the decision of whether to create a type of knowledge whose value is not known
beforehand, and are given the opportunity to respond to the market created, that
will in turn set the price of the information created. The rationale is similar to
the rationale behind real property: There appears then to be some truth in the
conservative dictum that everybodys property is nobodys property. Wealth that
is free for all is valued by no one because he that is fool enough to wait for its

40
N. Siebrasse, A Property Rights Theory and the Limits of Copyright, 51 U. of Toronto L. J. 1 (2001).
41
H. Ullrich, Intellectual Property, Access to Information and Antitrust: Harmony,
Disharmony and International Harmonization, in Expanding the Boundaries of Intellectual Property: Innovation Policy for the Knowledge Society, Oxford University Press
(2001); H. Ullrich, Legal Protection of Innovative Technologies: Property or Policy?
(2001) in O. Grandstrand, The Swedish Intellectual Property Symposium.
42
Ibid.

Unilateral conduct, intellectual property rights and competition law

113

proper time of use will only find that it has been taken by another The fish
in the sea are valueless to the fisherman, because there is no assurance that they
will be there for him tomorrow if they are left behind today.43 Efficient exploitation is therefore attained by privatisation.
Hence, IPRs are not exemptions from the competition provisions, but rather,
the IP system depends on the proper functioning of competition, and has only
been devised to allow for the response to the opportunities and conditions of
the market.44 Hence, the IP system is not conceived as protection from competition, but rather protection for competition in the market of intangible products,
whose tangible embodiments are set against and valued according to the competitive market conditions which competition protects. IP does not guarantee a
reward, and as with any other property right, it merely grants the opportunity
for a reward on the market. Therefore, IP can only require equal treatment by
virtue of the competition provisions. In a similar way to other property rights,
the exclusivity allows for the autonomous determination of conduct and does
not modify antitrust rules.45
IP sets out the regulatory framework, under which it provides for the grant
of individual property. The exclusivity of rights turns the public good into an
economic good, for which competition alone can determine the value, providing
incentives and rewards in line with demand.46 In such cases, it depends on the
proper functioning of competition within the market. As a piece of individual
property, however, it provides for the autonomy of decision-making and freedom
of contracting, as with any other property, which must conform with competition
rules.47 In this case, IP does not constitute a justification for the infringement
of competition, nor does it grant the right to restrain or impair residual competition. The exclusivity is granted to allow to respond to the opportunities in the
market not to control it.48 It is the competition provisions which determine
when it controls the market, whether an IP or any other case is concerned, in
the same way. Therefore, there is no economic justification for treating IP
differently.

43
H.S. Gordon, The Economic Theory of a Common-Property Research: The Fishery, 62 Journal of Political Economy 124 (1954).
44
The IP system, indeed, is a constitutive element of the market.
45
H. Ullrich, Legal Protection of Innovative Technologies: Property or Policy? in
O. Grandstand, The Swedish Intellectual Property Symposium (2001).
46
As the price is set by the market, this was the basic reason underlying the preference of property rights over the other schemes.
47
Related to this issue is the question of whether IPRs are a right to do something
suboptimal but useful, or merely a basic right to optimise that can be overridden. The
analysis of this issue is beyond the scope of the present inquiry.
48
H. Ullrich, Legal Protection of Innovative Technologies (2001).

114

Antitrust as a complement to the patent system

5.3.2.2 Competition embedded in the IP system


IP, however, is not neutral to the competition rules. By changing a non-market
into a market place, the terms and conditions for autonomy of exploitation are
provided, along with a framework regulation of the market. It modifies the
conditions of competition and thereby creates new markets. While in one sense
it excludes competitors from the technology market, this does not mean that it
is also exempted from competition liability arising from anti-competitive
conduct.
The paradox only seems to arise in cases where the exclusion (as such) becomes the reason for anti-trust liability, such as in the refusal to deal cases. It
is feared that imposing competition law liability for conduct consisting solely
of a refusal to deal negates the grant of property rights whose essence is the
right to exclude. However, even here, liability does not arise solely by virtue of
the exclusion, but as set against the market conditions and structure. It is no
more different than the case with real property and the right to exclude, only
that in the case of intangible goods the exclusivity might be less efficient and
may entail a far larger amount of monopoly power.49
In addition, as IP addresses competing objectives, and seeks to achieve a
balance between incentives and dissemination and exploitation, competition
considerations are built-in in the IP provisions. This is reflected in the limitations
in the length and the breadth of the property rights, and in exceptions, such as
CL for non-use of patents, and the fair use and experimental use doctrine. However, it is not clear what kind of competition system should be embedded in the
IP system in order for it to achieve its objectives. None the less IP is a constitutive element of competition allowing for a market to operate, and not a
restriction of it.50
5.3.2.3 The transition from separate to unified fields
The traditional confusion with regard to IP and its consideration as exempt from
or requiring a different threshold from competition, springs from the assumption
that there must be complete exclusivity, which allows the IP, inter alia, holder
to charge any price, and so IP is allowed to exclude competition in the short
term, as it will enhance dynamic competition in the long term.
The problem with this approach is that, by an equation of the protected intangible
subject-matter with its tangible embodiments, it creates a confusion between the

49
E. Mackaay (1992) op. cit. Although, there may be other problems in the case of
real property also, mostly associated with physical and economic constraints preventing
duplication, and also with capacity to supply, that are, in most cases, not an issue with
regard to information.
50
H. Ullrich, Legal Protection of Innovative Technologies (2001).

Unilateral conduct, intellectual property rights and competition law

115

reasons justifying the exclusivity (on the technology market) and an alleged right to
restrain competition (on the product market). Therefore it assumes an antagonism
where there is none. The reason for protecting technologies is that by their very
nature, they cannot be exposed to competition, unless they are protected against imitation, in one way or the other.51

Hence, the traditional approach viewed antitrust and IP as two competing and
separate fields, where IP granted a monopoly within which the property rights
were absolute. In viewing these fields as separate spheres involving an inherent
tension required the determination of the precise scope of the property rights,
so that anything within was lawful whereas anything beyond, constituted an
antitrust violation. It is in this context that the European Courts and Commission
resorted to the doctrines of existence/exercise, the specific subject matter and
the essential function. These doctrines attempted to determine what was in the
scope of the property right in question, and to set the boundaries for anti-competitiveness. The result was an artificial and incoherent demarcation of the scope
of property rights.
While such a formalistic approach may have the advantage of creating clear
rules that are predictable and transparent, and can be efficiently administered,
it is undesirable as it shifts the emphasis in the determination on the precise
scope envisioned in IP statutes, which may lead, as indeed did, to artificial results and distinctions and effects that may prevent certain types of transactions
that foster innovation, or lead to a false determination of illegality.52
The transition from the perception of antitrust and IP as two separate and
competing fields, to a unified field, in the sense of working towards the common
goal of maximising wealth by producing what consumers want at the lowest
cost, introduces the benefits of treating IP in the same way as any other property
right. While this might impose a burden of analysis of the market conditions,
and might result in a slow, resource-intensive and less predictable system, consideration of the effects allows for a more accurate determination of what
constitutes pro- and anti-competitive activity, without resorting to artificial
doctrines.
IP and competition policy address the same dilemma through different means,
namely, the balance of the monopoly privilege, and its disseminationthe
vertical and horizontal dilemma. IP addresses these questions through the definition of exclusivity and outlining its limitations. Competition addresses these
questions by maintaining competition in the face of exclusivity as defined by IP.
This is also reflected in the fact that claims of patent infringement and the abuse

51

Ibid. p.7.
W.K. Tom and J.A. Newberg, Antitrust and IP: From Separate Fields to a Unified
Field, 66 Antitrust L. J. 167 (1997).
52

116

Antitrust as a complement to the patent system

of a dominant position based on refusal to grant access address the same problem: the definition of degree of exclusivity permitted and patent breadth. While
both respond to a series of social, economic and political considerations, and
therefore may point to different conclusions depending on their different policies, IP and competition policy are interdependent and mutually determining.
In conclusion, IP and competition law are interdependent and inter-determining. IP changes a non-market to a market, sets out a regulatory framework
embodying competition concerns, and by granting exclusive rights it limits
competitors in certain respects, as with any other type of property. However, as
a piece of individual property, it is open to abuse, both exploitatively or structurally as any other case, as provided for in competition law. It is in this sense that
IP can be said to be a constitutive element of competition, and indeed a protection for competition, but is not a restriction or exemption from competition
law.53
5.3.2.4 How antitrust control affects incentives to innovate
The idea that antitrust law would hamper incentives to innovate is the most
common and strong argument against using antitrust law as a means to control
conduct that is condoned under IP laws, and in favour of immunising it from
liability.
While there is very little empirical evidence on the effects of this control in
general, and compulsory licensing in particular,54 it is none the less argued that
such a concern is based on a series of erroneous assumptions.55 First, it assumes
that IP laws grant holders an economic monopoly. Secondly, it assumes that the

53
Hence, economically there is no reason for treating IP differently from other
property. IP confers a property right as in the case of tangible property, however, that is
not unlimited and unqualified. Restrictions may be built into the system granting these
rights, but they may also come externally from other sources, such as competition laws.
While IPR legislation can change the market conditions and has built-in safeguards to
restrict the scope of the exclusivity granted, it cannot be expected to assume the responsibilities of competition law and ensure the proper functioning of market forces. See
Anderman (1998) op. cit. Hence, for example, just as a port owner might be required to
grant access to competing ferry services, in a similar situation the IP owner might be required to grant access to products or services covered by the IPR, especially where a
monopolisation of derivative markets might otherwise have been permitted.
With regard to competition, IP grants a legal monopoly that does not necessarily coincide with the economic monopoly, therefore, if the latter is present, competition law
assumes its usual role. While IP restricts competitors and affects the competitive market,
competition controls the IP-holder and the way in which he uses his property rights as
in any other case. It is the exclusivity as exercised against the market conditions that is
controlled and not exclusively by virtue of the exclusivity.
54
F.M. Scherer (1977) op. cit.
55
S. Genevaz (2004) op. cit.

Unilateral conduct, intellectual property rights and competition law

117

acquisition of monopoly power is the only way to appropriate revenues from


inventions, and thirdly, it assumes that antitrust liability would necessarily have
overall adverse effects on incentives to innovate.
IP rights in general, and patents in particular, do not necessarily and automatically confer monopoly power on their owners.56 The intellectual property laws
do not purport to confer any monopoly, however, but only the right to exclude
others from producing the good, expression or symbol covered by the intellectual property interest. This right is a property right that is not different in
principle from other property rights.57 The law encourages the creation of substitutes, of inventing around inventions and therefore substitutes may exist in
the market. Hence, the legal monopoly granted by a patent does not coincide
with an economic monopoly in the marketplace in most cases.
As regards the appropriation of revenues which provides an incentive to innovate, it is clear that IPRs are not the most significant factor in most cases in
ensuring returns in most industries. Factors such as lead time, reputation and
costly copying may present greater sources of excludability and profit.58 While
it is true that patents are the most significant factors in appropriating returns in
the pharmaceutical industry, in this specific case, economic analyses dispute
the idea that the concentration of market power is the best way to ensure an optimal appropriation.59 Kenneth Arrow suggests that a monopolist has less
incentive to innovate than a firm in a competitive industry, as the latter has a
higher incentive to reduce the cost of its product.60 Hence, anti-trust liability
does not necessarily lead to an overall reduction in incentives to innovate in the
relevant industry.
In addition, as antitrust control is limited to exceptional cases, it would only
rarely impose a constraint on the courses of action available to IP owners.61
Ayres and Klemperer suggest that the loss of incentive is negligible in comparison to the increase in social welfare stemming from limited restrictions on the
patentees market power.62 However, the latters suggestion applies only in cases

56

Ibid.
H. Hovenkamp et al. (2003) op. cit.
58
See H. Perritt (1996) op. cit.
59
S. Genevaz (2004) op. cit. p.750.
60
Ibid. See also K.J. Arrow, Economic Welfare and the Allocation of Resources for
Invention, in Essays in the Theory of Risk-Bearing, Chicago, Markham Publishing Co.
(1971).
61
Ibid. p.10.
62
I. Ayres and P. Klemperer, Limiting Patentees Market Power Without Reducing
Innovation Incentives: The Perverse Benefits of Uncertainty and Non-Injunctive Remedies, 97 Mich. L. Rev. 985, (1999), p.990: Because the last bit of monopoly overcharging
is so disproportionately damaging, restricting the patentees monopoly power a small
amount is likely to increase social welfare. The benefit of reducing the deadweight loss
57

118

Antitrust as a complement to the patent system

where there is high price elasticity in the market so that every price reduction
results in an increase in demand.63 In industries such as the biopharmaceutical
industry, where demand for the end product is not elastic as consumers need
access to medicine (as opposed to luxury products), a reduction in the monopoly
price may have few consequences on the deadweight loss and can greatly diminish incentives to innovate. Nevertheless, this may not be the case in the
pre-commercial stage of research where demand for research tools by competing
firms takes place on different levels of the market, as distinct from end product
situations.
In addition, Scherer concluded that CL had little effect on incentives to innovate in industries in which the parties had to maintain a high level of R&D to
remain competitive or where the ability of competitors to invent around patents
reduced the value of patent protection.64 Even testimonies of industry operators
themselves seem to take for granted that antitrust liability might arise as in any
other case, and this is not perceived to impact negatively on incentives.65
Finally, it would also make little sense, in practice, to have different rules for
immunity for refusals to deal by patent holders as that would encourage the arbitrary incorporation of protected components in designs simply to escape

of supra-competitive pricing is likely to outweigh the costs of a slightly lower incentive


to innovate.
See also S. Semerano, The Efficiency and Fairness of Enforced Sharing: An Examination of the Essence of Antitrust, 52 Kansas Law Rev. 57 (2003), p.25: All things being
equal, forced sharing may discourage both the innovator and the sharer from investing
in improvements. But all things are not equal. Shared property may enable more vigorous
competition than would otherwise occur, and that competition may stimulate investment
to a greater extent than forced sharing may reduce it. A firm not faced with competition
will only consider innovations demand-expanding and entry-delaying effects. A firm
faced with competition, however, will have an incentive to innovate not only to expand
the existing market and deter entry, but also because of the fear of losing market share
to, and the desire to gain it from, a competitor.
63
S. Genevaz (2004) op. cit. p.752.
64
F.M. Scherer (1977) op. cit.; F.M. Scherer and D. Ross, Industrial Market Structure and Economic Performance, 3rd edn, Boston, Houghton Mifflin Co. (1990): all in
all the substantial amount of evidence now available suggest that compulsory patent licensing, judiciously confined to cases in which patent-based monopoly power has been
abused would have little or no adverse impact on the rate of technological progress
, pp.4567
See also C.V. Chien (2003) who compares inventive activity with compulsory licenses
to conclude that no decline in innovation can be seen. Hence the author argues against
a blanket exclusion to CL, although also stresses the importance of two factors, predictability and importance that may be decisive in the impact of CL.
65
FTC/DOJ Proceedings on Competition and IPRS: A. Diverse perspectives on
patents. B. Business perspectives on patents. Biotechnology and Pharmaceuticals, 19th
March 2002.

Unilateral conduct, intellectual property rights and competition law

119

liability. Hence, it is submitted that the solution cannot be found in immunising


IP, but rather in determining the cases in which antitrust liability should be imposed for a refusal to deal.
5.3.3 Recent Recognition of Antitrust Control
This approach has come to be recognised in recent IP legislation, in which it is
stipulated that an abuse of the property rights conferred is possible, and thus
IPRs are not unlimited rights. Furthermore, no provision is made for a different
threshold.66
Article 8 of TRIPS provides that appropriate measures may be needed to
prevent the abuses of intellectual property rights This reflects the fact that
IPRs are not immune from the competition provisions and that it is possible for
patent holders to abuse their position.
The EC Database Directive 96/9/EC also envisages the possibility of abuse
by a copyright holder: protection by the sui generis right must not be afforded
in such a way as to facilitate abuses of a dominant position. Whereas the
provisions of this Directive are without prejudice to the application of Community or national competition rules. The Directive can be interpreted as
reflecting the idea that IP is not exempt and that it is subject to the application
of competition rules, just as with any other property rights.
Hence, in accordance with TRIPS, the patent system could provide for the
compulsory licensing of patents if it would be judged anti-competitive by competition law and not IP.67 This could be seen as a reflection of the fact that, in

66
In the USA, this is explicitly recognised in the US FTC/DOJ Antitrust Guidelines
for the Licensing of Intellectual Property (6th April 1995), reprinted in 4 Trade Reg. Rep.
(CCH) 13, 132, available at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/guidelines/ipguide.
htm#back1 which provide that liability IP will be treated like any other kind of property
for the purposes of antitrust, that there should be no presumption of market power, and that
licensing may allow complementary factors of production and hence be pro-competitive.
See also UK Patent Act s. 51 on powers exercisable following the report of the Competition Commission, in which action may be taken in situations that are likely to operate
against the public interest either because of a refusal to license or of the licensing
conditions.
See also Berne Convention for the Protection of Literary and Artistic Works of 9
September 1886, as last amended on 28 September 1979, and by Council Directive
91/250/EEC of 14 May 1991, on the legal protection of computer programs, OJ 1991 L
122/ 42. In the 27th recital, that Directive states that its provisions are without prejudice
to the application of the competition rules under Art. 82 EC if a dominant supplier
refuses to make information available which is necessary for interoperability as defined
in this Directive.
67
See the Draft Proposal for a Council Regulation on the Community Patent (2000)
op. cit. and the explanatory Memorandum.

120

Antitrust as a complement to the patent system

accordance with economic theory, the patent is the same as any other property
right for the purposes of competition law, and that the incentives and need for
innovation do not justify an immunity, first, because it is not clear how much
incentive is required, and therefore it may not be sensitive to these limited instances of control, and secondly, because there may be static distortions
outweighing the dynamic benefits or other concerns regarding follow-on
inventions.
Patents grant a legal monopoly that cannot necessarily be equated with an
economic monopoly. For example, in the pharmaceutical industry, patents do
not award a legal monopoly over the treatment of a specific disease, but only
over a specific product or process. Hence, there is often some potential for strong
competition between products in a therapeutic class. The fact that a legal monopoly does not coincide with an economic monopoly operates on two levels.
On the one hand, it should not be assumed that patents create market power.68
Equally, however, when the legal monopoly that patents confer, coincide with
an economic monopoly, they will not be exempt from competition control.
Competition control operates ex post according to the market conditions, while
patent protection operates ex ante irrespective of the market conditions.
The provisions of TRIPS are important in recognising that IP and competition
are no longer understood as separate spheres, so that the metes and bounds must
be sought within which IP is absolute, but IP remains subject to competition
law liability as provided for by the latter for any case according to its effects.
Indeed TRIPS may be read as the legitimation (on the part of IP instruments)
of such competition control.
With regard to competition law, it is clear that IP is subject to competition
law rules as shown in the practice of the EC Commission and Courts. While the
Courts and Commission have abandoned the insistence on defining the scope
of IP protection under the existence/exercise and specific subject matter doctrines, in their latest decisions they still nevertheless continue to reflect a
theoretical understanding that IP warrants a different threshold of general immunity except in exceptional circumstances.69 As has been shown, this
difference cannot be justified. The circumstances should be regarded as more
exceptional than in other cases.
There is no defining-line in IP determining when an act will be deemed anticompetitive. Rather, the latter will be determined according to the impact of
specific practice under a rule of reason analysis. The scope of a patent is not
something concrete that exists in isolation, but is also dependent on external

68

This is recognised in the US FTC/DOJ IP Licensing Guidelines (1995) op. cit.


I insist on theoretical understanding, as in practice, it would seem that the circumstances are not any different from the other cases.
69

Unilateral conduct, intellectual property rights and competition law

121

factors such as antitrust control. In this way, antitrust law should be seen as
simply another factor in determining patent scope.

5.4 Conclusions
In this chapter, a case has been made for the lack of economic justification in
treating IP differently from other property rights for the purposes of competition
law. Whilst different doctrines were created by the EC Courts to distinguish
IPRs in theory, this control has been applied in practice as exceptionally as in
other cases, thus according to the facts of the case. The EU Commission seems
to be more willing recently to recognise this approach, and indeed in its recent
Microsoft decision, it resorted to the Magill case to argue that intellectual
property rights are not in a different category to property rights as such.70
The next chapter addresses the antitrust duty to deal under Art. 82 and its
application in the biopharmaceutical industry.

70
See C-3/37 Microsoft Case 792, 2004, para. 550: The Court of Justice stated that
the refusal by the owner of an exclusive right [copyright] to grant a license, even if it
is the act of an undertaking holding a dominant position, cannot in itself constitute abuse
of a dominant position. It pointed out, however, that the exercise of an exclusive right
by the proprietor may, in exceptional circumstances, involve abusive conduct thereby
clarifying that intellectual property rights are not in a different category to property rights
as such.

6. The duty to deal under Art. 82 EC


6.1 Introduction
This chapter considers the duty of a dominant firm to deal with competitors/
customers and the cases in which it is lawful under Art. 82 EC to refuse or cease
to deal. The chapter does not address the general objections and rationale behind
compulsory licensing as these have already been addressed. Furthermore, it does
not consider the role of contract law as this is beyond the scope of enquiry for
the purposes of this chapter. In contrast, this chapter undertakes a pragmatic
examination of the case law and seeks to propose a specific interpretation of the
state of the law.
There is no consistent rationale behind the case law in this area and therefore
the state of the law is far from clear. Many questions remain unanswered, nevertheless, as will be shown in the next chapter, it is still possible to use Art. 82
in its current form to address concerns relating to access in the biopharmaceutical industry.
The chapter proceeds on the basis of the categorisation of the Advocate
General in Oscar Bronner, which identifies the three main factors leading to a
duty to deal under EC competition law. These involve the dependence cases,
the leverage cases and/or the essential facilities cases. Based on these factors,
it examines the rationale behind the duty to deal, and what each of these circumstances involves.
6.1.1 What is a Refusal to Deal and What is the Rationale Behind its
Prohibition?
Clear guidance on the refusal to deal is difficult to find as the existing case law
is scarce and rather inconsistent. While it is clear that there is no general obligation under EC competition law to deal with somebody (whether a competitor
or a customer), none the less in certain exceptional circumstances, a duty to

Case C-7/97 [1998] ECR I-7791.

122

The duty to deal under Art. 82 EC

123

deal will be imposed. The duty is exceptional regardless of whether an intellectual or other property right is involved.
In this context, a refusal to deal refers to a situation in which the licensor
refuses to give a licence, leaving potential licensees with no option but to seek
a compulsory licence. However, a refusal to license is not limited to cases of
outright refusal but may also include situations in which there is a delay in negotiations or cases in which the acceptance of the licensing terms proves to be
so difficult that they amount to an effective refusal to deal.
In general, even dominant undertakings have the right to refuse to license and
to unilaterally decide which third party they wish to deal with. In the absence
of other special circumstances, Art. 82(c), which requires the application of
similar conditions to equivalent transactions, cannot be invoked to challenge a
refusal to license or to order a licence on the same terms. However, if a certain
abusive conduct or exceptional circumstances are deemed to exist, a duty
will be imposed.
6.1.2 Concerns Relating to a Refusal to Deal: Potential Harm to
Competition
The main economic consideration behind the striking down of certain refusals
to deal relates to the potential of harm to competition, as opposed to individual
competitors.


ECJ, Cases C-241/91 P and C-242/91 P, Radio Telefis Eireann (RTE) and Independent Television Publications (ITP) v Commission (Magill), [1995] ECR I-743, para 50.

See Chapter 5.

Delays in negotiations are only abusive if there is a duty to deal. Hence, when
negotiations are delayed it should first be examined whether there is a duty to negotiate
and reach an agreement in the first place.

With regard to the licensing terms, while they may in themselves on many occasions amount to an abuse of a dominant position (e.g. tying, non-compete obligations
etc) there may also be cases where this is not the case, such as high royalty rates. Where
the terms are such that any licensee is prevented from making an economically viable
use of the license, then the offer to deal may amount to a refusal.

Once access is given to one licensee, there should not be an automatic obligation
to grant identical access to everybody else, as this would inhibit the first license, and
may not be reasonable.

Case 238/87 Volvo v Veng [1988] ECR 6211 (para 9).

D. W. Carlton, Antitrust at the millennium: A general analysis of exclusionary
conduct and refusal to deal, 68 Antitrust L J 659, (2001).
See also the ECJ in Case C 418/01, IMS, judgement of 29 April 2004, para. 145 referring to the requirement that it should be impossible or at least unreasonably difficult for
any undertaking seeking to operate in the market to create an alternative, confirming
that harm to competition should not be equated with harm to a particular competitor.

124

Antitrust as a complement to the patent system

The refusal to license will not in itself constitute an abuse in all cases. Hence,
the refusal to license can be seen as the means, and harm to competition as the
end, prohibited in Art. 82. Accordingly, in GlaxoSmithKline the AdvocateGeneral made a distinction between the negative consequences for competition
of a refusal to supply that may be abusive, and the refusal to supply with the
object/effect of restricting parallel trade, which was found on the facts to be
non-abusive.10
A refusal which seriously disrupts competition on a market may constitute
an abuse. On the other hand, a refusal that merely restricts the supply and distribution of an end product so as to restrain parallel trade is not abusive if there
is no harm to competition.11
The concerns relating to the potential harm to competition consider the direct
impact on end consumers, who may have to pay higher costs, with a more restricted choice or lower product quality by virtue of the refusal, resulting in a
loss in consumer welfare.12 In essence, four categories of refusals have been
identified in the literature:13
1. A refusal to take part in a joint venture: in such a situation, it is found that
if the parties do not wish to take part in such a venture there is no harm to
competition as it means that the joint venture would not have been efficient
for them.
2. Where an enterprise in a dominant position refuses to deal with any customer who deals with his competitor. This echoes the situation in United
Brands14 in so far as United Brands (UBs) refusal was based on Olesens
promotion of a competing firm. In such a case, economic theory provides
that exclusive dealing may be pro-competitive insofar as it creates incentives for UB to incur expenses that might otherwise have been avoided due
to the possibility of free riding by the competitors. This case may, however,
also raise competitive concerns as if economies of scale are present, exclu-


Case C-53/03 Synetairismos Farmakopoion Aitolias & Akarnanias (Syfait) and
Others v Glaxosmithkline AEVE, Opinion of the AG Jacobs, 28 October 2004.
10
Ibid para. 104. As stated by AG Jacobs, I would note that the above analysis
does not preclude the possibility that a restriction of supply by a dominant pharmaceutical
undertaking might fall foul of the Courts established case-law on refusal to supply if it
had negative consequences for competition arising other than as a consequence of its
restriction of parallel trade.
11
Ibid para. 104. This was, however, based on the particularities of the pharmaceutical industry.
12
J.K. Mackie-Mason, What about Unilateral Refusal to Deal? In FTC/DOJ Hearings on IP and Competition Policy 2002.
13
D. W. Carlton (2001) op. cit.
14
Case 27/76 United Brands [1978] ECR 207.

The duty to deal under Art. 82 EC

125

sive dealing might inhibit the second firm (Olesen) from achieving
efficiency. Hence, a rule of reason is required, in order to inquire into the
possibility of economies of scale and offsetting efficiencies.
3. Where there are two markets, in which firm one (F1) is present, and the
product of market A is a necessary input for market B, in which firm two
(F2) is also present, and F1 refuses to license F2. Economic theory suggests
that F1 will only refuse F2 if the latter does not allow him to price discriminate, as in other cases, F1 will wish to keep F2 in the market if he is more
efficient as he can receive profits from his supply of product A. This is not
the case, however, if products A and B are not complements for some consumers and economies of scale are present. In such a case, F1 may refuse
to deal in order to preserve its power on market B. If F1 refuses to supply
product A to any customer consuming B from F2, F2s scales will drop,
forcing him to leave the market. In this case, customers only want product
B and will be faced with a monopoly and thereby suffer as a result of the
reduced competition.
4. Finally, the dynamic model, in which F1 is present on market A and both
firms are present on market B, but there is a possibility of competition in
A and economies of scale in B. In this case, F1 will seek to limit the power
of F2 in market B so that it preserves its power in market A. By keeping F2
small in market B so that it is not an effective supplier of market B to competitors, F1 protects its position in market A. This will also allow F1 to
transfer his monopoly over time from one product to another.
Economics clearly cautions us about the possible net harm to competition if
there is a significant foreclosure of the distribution system, thus preventing a
competitor from achieving economies of scale, or if the monopolist excludes a
competitor by depriving it of customers who also need the first product of the
monopolist.15
In economics, the optimal balance is empirical, however, this is complicated
due to the potential global effects and the fact that the decision should not only
take ex post rewards for investments into account, but also, how the latter will
affect ex ante future decisions to invest. The optimal balance will depend on the
static allocative inefficiency resulting across firms, industries, time, the amount
of additional innovative effort it is likely to induce and the amount of future
consumer welfare induced by the incremental investment.16

15
It should also be remembered that economics takes not only the local effects of
the case at issue into account, but also its global effects, as this affects the expected returns from innovation.
16
J.K. Mackie-Mason (2002) op. cit.

126

Antitrust as a complement to the patent system

The risk of harm to competition is also dependent on the type of market


structure put in place and the extent to which it is conducive to innovation.17 To
some extent, this is reflected in the clash between the monopolist18 and competition theorists.19 The conclusions in this regard are ambiguous: Permitting
greater consolidation of market power in a market may increase or decrease innovative activity in that market.20 A clear economic formula which would
differentiate between desirable and undesirable refusals to deal has not yet been
devised.21

6.2 The State of the law


A duty to deal has been imposed in the following EC competition law cases:22
1. Cases involving two markets:

(a) Refusal to supply an input to downstream competitors in vertically
related markets to preserve market power in market B: Commercial
Solvents,23 Magill,24 Ladbroke.25

(b) Denial of access to a facility necessary to compete with a downstream
competitor, to preserve market power in market B: Sabena,26 Decca
Navigation Systems,27 Sea Containers,28 IMS.29

17

See ABA (2002) op. cit. See also chapter 7.


F. Parisi, B. Depoorter, The Market for Intellectual Property: The Case for Complementary Oligopoly, in The Economics of Copyright: Developments in Research and
Analysis, W. Gordon and R. Watt, eds., Cheltenham, UK and Northampton, MA, USA,
Edward Elgar (2003); J. Schumpeter, Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy, New York,
NY, Harper (1942).
19
S. Yi, Market Structure and Incentives to Innovate: The Case of Cournot Oligopoly, 65 Economics Letters 379388 (1999). J. Boone, Intensity of Competition and
Incentives to Innovate, 19 Interl J. Ind. Orgn 705, (2001).
20
J.K. Mackie-Mason (2002) op. cit.
21
See also the Commission discussion paper on possible principles for the application of Article 82 to exclusionary abuses, published on the Commission website for
consultation in December 2005.
22
See end of chapter for a closer analysis of the cases.
23
Case 7/73 Commercial Solvents [1974] ECR 223.
24
Case C-241 & 242/91P Magill [1995] ECR I-743.
25
Case T-504/93 Tierce Ladrbroke [1997] ECR 927.
26
Commission Decision London European-Sabena, OJ 1988 L 317/47.
27
Commission Decision Decca Navigator System, OJ 1989 L 43/27.
28
Commission Decision Sea Containers v Stena Sealink, OJ 1994 L15/08.
29
Case C-418/01 IMS [2004] ECR I-05039.
18

The duty to deal under Art. 82 EC

127

(c) Refusal to grant access to the distribution system to an upstream


competitor or a refusal to share methods in reaching customers to
preserve market power in market A: Bronner.30

(d) Essential facilities: Sabena, Decca Navigation, Sea Containers,
Magill, Ladbroke, Bronner, IMS.

(e) Refusal to share spare parts with independent providers of aftermarket
support/complementary markets: Volvo.31
2. Cases involving one market:

(a) Refusal to deal with distributors promoting a competing brand to
preserve market power in market A: United Brands.32

(b) Refusal to deal with suppliers dealing with competitors to preserve
market power in market B: Telemarketing.33

(c) Refusal to join or continue a joint venture with competitors/
(disproportional sanction?) Aer Lingus.34

(d) No competitive relationship between parties in any market: Ladbroke.
The relationship between these categories, however, is unclear and some
may indeed overlap to some degree. There are three common denominators in
the cases in the sense that they may involve the cutting off of previous relationships as a response to the conduct of the dependent firm, the possibility of using
power on one market to create or preserve market power on another market,
and the indispensable nature of facilities for the operation of a firm on another
market.
These main considerations are also reflected in the categorisation of the Advocate-General in Oscar Bronner,35 who outlined the situations in which a duty
to deal will arise under EC competition law:

Cases involving the cutting off of supplies to existing customers: Commercial Solvent, United Brands.
l Cases in which an undertaking holding a dominant position on a particular
market reserves to itself an ancillary activity without objective necessity
which might be carried out by another undertaking as part of its activities
on a neighbouring but separate market, with the possibility of eliminating
all competition from such undertakings: Telemarketing.

30

Case C-7/97 Oscar Bronner [1998] ECR I-7791.


Case 238/87 Volvo v Veng [1988] ECR 6211.
32
Case 27/76 United Brands [1978] ECR 207.
33
Case 311/84 Centre Belge dEtudes du March-Tlmarketing SA (CBEM) v
Companie Luxembourgeoise de Tldiffusion [1985] ECR 3261.
34
Commission Decision British Midland/ Aer Lingus, OJ 1992 L 96/34.
35
Case C-7/97 [1998] ECR I-7791 para 33-53.
31

128

Antitrust as a complement to the patent system

Cases in which the refusal concerned a product or service that was either
essential to the exercise of the activity in question, in the sense that there
was no actual or potential substitute, or a new product whose entry might
have been prevented despite the constant, specific and regular potential
demand by consumers: Volvo, Magill, Tierce Ladbroke.36

Any obligation to deal, however, will only be imposed after close scrutiny
of the factual and economic context and even then within narrow limits.37
6.2.1 Cutting Off Existing Customers: The Dependence Cases
The case-law demonstrates that an obligation to deal has been imposed in situations where a dominant firm cuts off supplies to existing customers.
In Commercial Solvents38 the party was compelled to continue supplying Zoja
with the raw materials necessary for the production of a derivative, despite its
decision to vertically integrate and also become operative on the downstream
market for the supply of the derivative. The Court held that a refusal to license
in such cases constitutes an abuse of a dominant position where it thereby risks
eliminating all competition on the part of this customer.39
Similarly, in the United Brands case40 the Court considered that an undertaking in a dominant position cannot stop supplying a long standing customer who
abides by regular commercial practice, if the orders placed by that customer are
in no way out of the ordinary.41 Such conduct would be incompatible with Art.
82 as it would limit markets to the prejudice of consumers and would amount
to discrimination which might in the end eliminate a trading party from the relevant market.42 The Court also held that a dominant undertaking has the right
36
He concludes that a dominant undertaking commits an abuse where without
justification it cuts off supplies of goods and services to an existing customer or eliminates competition in a related market by tying separate goods and services. However, it
also seems that an abuse may consist in mere refusal to license where that prevents a
new product from coming on a neighbouring market in competition with the dominant
undertakings own product on that market para. 43. It seems that the Advocate-General
is looking for an additional element to find an abuse, such as tying sales, or discriminating vis--vis independent competitors.
37
Case C-53/03 Synetairismos Farmakopoion Aitolias & Akarnanias (Syfait) and
Others v Glaxosmithkline AEVE, Opinion of the AG Jacobs, 28 October 2004 at para.
53.
38
Case 6/73 Istituto Chemioterapico Italiano and Commercial Solvents v Commission [1974] ECR 223.
39
Para. 25 of the judgment.
40
Case 27/76 [1978] ECR 207.
41
Para. 182 of the judgment.
42
Para. 183 of the judgment.

The duty to deal under Art. 82 EC

129

to take reasonable steps to protect its commercial interests, provided its behaviour is proportionate to the threat and not aimed at strengthening or abusing a
dominant position.43
Hence, in the BP case, the restriction of supply by a dominant petroleum
company during an oil shortage in a manner which was reasonable to the particularities of the commercial situation and relations between different
customers, was not found to constitute an abuse of a dominant position.44
There is a three-fold rationale behind the relevance of previous dealing.45
First, previous dealing proves that dealing is feasible and consistent with investment and creation. Secondly, it is possible to use the previous terms as a
benchmark, and thirdly, people may have relied on the expectation of a deal.46
However, flexibility should also be preserved, as the conditions of the licence
may have changed, or the party may reasonably seek to change the terms and
cost of the licence.47
An obligation to deal can, thus, be imposed in circumstances where the retaliation to a behaviour of the customer/competitor is not proportional to the
behaviour that it aims to sanction.48 This may be seen as an extension of the
abuse of market power to cases of relational market power.
Furthermore, in Germany for example, the concept of economic dependence
has been introduced.49 Nacke also contemplates that a partenaire obligatoire
may also be found in the Community law, under which a company may be

43

Paras. 189 and 190 of the judgment.


Case 77/77 BP [1978] ECR 1513 paras. 28, 29, 30, 32, 33, and 42 of the
judgement.
45
C. Shapiro, Competition and IP Law and Policy in the Knowledge-Based Society:
Is there a Cause for Concern about Unilateral refusals to Deal? in DOJ/FTC Hearing
on IP and Competition Law, May 1 2002.
46
The latter argument echoes the estoppel argument present in UK common law.
The rationale for estoppel is based on the idea that if somebody makes a representation
on which the other party relies to his detriment, then he should be held to the representation that he made.
47
Courts must be careful not to penalise people for making bad licensing choices
which cannot be reviewed or altered as this might create an incentive to refrain from licensing in the future. J. Glenken, Competition and IP Law and Policy in the
Knowledge-Based Society: Is there a Cause for Concern about Unilateral refusals to
Deal? in DOJ/FTC Hearings on IP and Competition Law, 1 May 2002.
See also C. Shapiro (2002) op. cit.; who states shouldnt private parties if they are
going to make reliance on investments seek their own assurances that a standard will be
open or something will be licensed on an ongoing basis, rather than some sort of broad
antitrust regime that would require ongoing dealing?
48
See also analysis of S. Anderman (1998) op. cit. Chapter 14.
49
See s 26(2) of German Act Against Restraints of Competition: relative dominance for dependent customers/competitors.
44

130

Antitrust as a complement to the patent system

found guilty of an abuse if those dependent on it cannot substitute, if the abuse


is unlikely to encourage new competitors and if the company is not constrained
in its behaviour by competition in wider downstream markets.50
These dependence considerations are also consistent with the proportionality
principle contained in Art. 82, which requires that the action taken by the dominant firm to attain a legitimate objective should take the form of the least
restrictive means available.51
While one may question the extent to which the concept of dependence
makes sense from a competition law perspective, as it seems to be more similar
to a contractual notion, none the less, it could be considered to be legitimate if
it is limited according to the proportionality principle of EC law since the leverage and/or essential facilities rationale is also present in most cases.52
Indeed, one could even argue that following the Telemarketing case,53 claimants will also have to establish the presence of the other considerations. In this
case, despite the existence of previous dealing, the Court focused on the essential
nature of the facility and the leverage possibility.
The Court held that where an undertaking holding a dominant position reserves to itself or its subsidiary another activity on a neighbouring but separate
market, without any objective necessity, with the possibility of eliminating all
competition from such undertaking, it constitutes an abuse of its dominance. It
also noted that the input withheld should be indispensable for the activities.54
6.2.2 Reservation of an Ancillary Activity and Leverage Economics
In line with the Telemarketing case, in Magill the Court considered the fact that
the broadcasters, by their conduct, reserved themselves the secondary market
of weekly television guides by excluding all competition on that market, was
relevant in determining an abuse of a dominant position.55

50
T. Nacke, Abuse of Dominant Positions, 1995 at http://europa.eu.int/comm/competition/speeches/text/sp1995_025_en.html, p.6.
51
Ibid.
52
In Commercial Solvents (1974) op. cit. for example consideration was also paid
to the possibility of leverage by virtue of vertical integration, and there might even have
been a case for arguing that the raw materials were essential facilities. Similarly, in
Telemarketing (1985) op. cit. the focus was on the essentiality of access for the secondary
market to operate, and on the possibility of leverage.
On the other hand, in United Brands (1978) op. cit. and British Midland/ Aer Lingus
(1993) op. cit. these considerations were present, but the focus was on the hardship suffered by the customer/competitor.
53
Case 311/84 [1985] ECR 3261.
54
Ibid. para. 25 to 27.
55
Magill (1995) op. cit. para. 56 of the judgment.

The duty to deal under Art. 82 EC

131

This was based on the concern that the dominant firm would limit access to
the upstream product to gain power in the downstream market.56 The rationale
behind this can be found in the idea of the economics of leverage which claims
that a firm with market power on one market may use that market power to gain
additional power in a related but independent market.
This theory has been criticised as it is argued that a firm cannot obtain two
monopoly rents, and that there is no gain from leveraging as one can extract
all monopoly rents on the first market.57 The Chicago school has argued that
if product A is used as an input, the monopolist could simply charge a high
price for it.58 If it is used on a stand-alone basis, the monopolist would welcome competition in the complementary segment as this would increase the
value of the good and the consumer could still be charged the monopoly
price.59 The chain link model thus concludes that refusals are generally efficient as monopolists do not need to refuse to deal in order to extract monopoly
profits.60
It cannot be assumed that efficiency can be found in cases in which the monopolist is unable to make monopoly profits.61 If the monopolist is unable to
obtain monopoly rents, then it might refuse to deal in order to eliminate competition on lower levels and receive a monopoly price.62 This would arise in the
following cases: if the nature of the product and business relationship renders
the transaction costs of metering prohibitive; if a variable fee for use would lead

56
In the case that the firm is present in the downstream market (hence, vertically
integrated) it can do this by refusing to deal, charging high wholesale prices or by making
the upstream product incompatible with the downstream ones, amongst other. If such
vertical integration is not present, he may do so by favouring a particular downstream
competitor by exclusive dealing or by discriminatory treatment.
57
M. Whitener, Competition and IP Law and Policy in the Knowledge-Based Society: Is there a Cause for Concern about Unilateral refusals to Deal? in DOJ/FTC
Hearings on IP and Competition Law, May 1 2002. The theory has also been criticised
for failing to capture the essence of patents, which are capable of having more than one
end use and therefore it is believed that the number of markets that the patent can be divided into, should be irrelevant for antitrust purposes.
58
D.G. Gerber, Rethinking the Monopolists Duty to Deal: A Legal and Economic
Critique of the Doctrine of Essential Facilities, 74 VA L Rev 1069 (1988).
59
See for example D.G. Gerber (1988) op. cit. pp.10691085. The presumption
that vertically integrated plaintiffs seek to decrease competition in downstream markets
contradicts the widely held view that vertical arrangements generally cannot augment
monopoly power. See also D.W. Carlton, (2001) op. cit.
60
Ibid. This is because the profits of the licensee firm can be extracted through the
pricing of the product on the upstream market, to which access is required in order to
produce in the downstream market.
61
Ibid.
62
Ibid.

132

Antitrust as a complement to the patent system

to resource under-utilisation and thereby sub-optimal profits for the competitor;


or where the monopolist seeks to eliminate risk sharing.63
An anti-competitive refusal to deal therefore arises either in situations involving a regulated industry in which the monopolist vertically integrates in order
to avoid regulation, or in cases where the link between charging user fees on
market A and creating a monopoly price on market B has been disrupted as
in the public goods case.64
In order for a leveraging claim to be valid, however, there must be a monopoly
in the primary market (as there is nothing to leverage otherwise), and the secondary market must be concentrated and protected by barriers to entry. Hence,
certain structural preconditions must exist before vertical integration can become
harmful competition, and, in fact, it can also lead to efficiencies.65
It becomes clear that vertical integration is not necessarily a negative development and must be reviewed through a rule of reason approach in order to
establish if the structural preconditions exist for a possible harm to competition
and whether other offsetting efficiencies are also present. Even in such cases,
leverage will only be profitable if the monopolist controls an input that can be
used in variable proportions with other inputs so that the monopolist induces

63
Ibid. If the upstream and downstream products are not complementary for some
consumers, and there are economies of scale in the production of the downstream product, there may be a risk to competition arising from the refusal to supply, In addition,
there may be instances of dynamic models in which there will be the possibility of
competition for the upstream product in the future periods and scale economies for the
downstream product, in which case the dominant firm will wish to ensure that the dependant firm remains limited in its production of the downstream product so that it does
not become an effective supplier of competitors in the upstream product.
64
Ibid.
65
Ibid. Efficiencies can result from the elimination of the double marginalisation
problem associated with successive monopolies. The latter relates to the fact that all
parties wish to maximise profit by increasing prices. By vertically integrating, there are
no longer several companies seeking to make a profit but rather one and this may lead
to lower prices. Vertical integration can also lead to efficiencies arising from the reduction
of transaction costs. This is because it reduces the friction in the organisation of the enterprises, internalizes certain transactions and avoids the necessity of having to protect
oneself against opportunistic behaviour such as hold up and free riding. See however
N.W. Hawker, Open Windows: The Essential Facilities Doctrine and Microsoft, 25 Ohio
NUL Rev. 115 (1999); P. Rey, Competition and IP Law and Policy in the KnowledgeBased Society: Is there a Cause for Concern about Unilateral Refusals to Deal? in
DOJ/FTC Hearings on IP and Competition Law, 1 May 2002, which suggests that vertical
integration by a monopolist may also increase the difficulty of entering either market,
by requiring competitors to enter both markets simultaneously.

The duty to deal under Art. 82 EC

133

customers to deviate from the most efficient input mix, or where the monopolist
is subject to rate regulation and integrates in order to avoid it.66
In this way, the economic theories on leveraging and foreclosure have hence
largely been discredited and, even if they still have some support, they depend
on structural preconditions underlying the exceptional nature of a duty to deal.
In Magill the Court reasoned that the reservation of the secondary market of
weekly TV guides was abusive as it excluded competition from the market by
denying access to the basic information which was the raw material indispensable for the compilation of such a guide.67
6.2.3 The Indispensability Requirement and the Essential Facilities
Doctrine (EFD)
In Oscar Bronner68 the Court, in line with Magill, observed that in order to find
an abuse, it is necessary to establish not only that the refusal of the service would
most probably lead to the elimination of all competition in the market and that
such a refusal would be incapable of being objectively justified, but also that
the service itself must be indispensable for the running of the individuals business, as there is no actual or potential substitute for this scheme.69
The indispensability requirement alludes to the essential facilities doctrine
(EFD). The EFD has its origins in US antitrust cases and it describes instances
in which access to something is mandated for those who would not have access
otherwise.70 It specifies the situations in which the owner of an essential facility
(EF) is required to provide access to this facility to competitors at a reasonable
price. It traditionally requires the existence of two markets, the upstream market

66
C.S. Yoo, Vertical Integration and Media Regulation in the New Economy, 19
Yale Journal on Regulation 171 (2002).
67
Case C-241 & 242/91P [1995] ECR I-743, para. 56.
68
Case 7/97 [1998] ECR I-7791.
69
Ibid. para. 38, 41, 42 and 44.
70
See United States v Terminal Railroad Assn of St. Louis, 224 U.S. 383 (1912);
United States v Griffith 334 U.S. 100 (1948). Aspen Highlands Skiing Corp. v Aspen
Skiing Co., 738 F.2d 1509 (10th Cir. 1984) affd on other grounds, 472 U.S. 585 (1985);
Fishman v Wirtz, 807 F.2d 520 (7th Cir. 1986); Hecht v Pro-Football, Inc., 570 F.2d 982
(D.C. Cir. 1977), cert. denied, 436 U.S. 956 (1978); Consolidated Gas Co. of Florida v
City Gas Co. of Florida , 880 F.2d 297 (11th Cir. 1989); BellSouth Advertising & Publishing Corp. v Donnelly Information Publishing, Inc., 933 F.2d 952 (11th Cir. 1991) ,
vacated, 977 F.2d 1435 (11th Cir. 1992), and reversed en banc on other grounds, 999
F.2d 1436 (11th Cir. 1993), cert. denied, 114 S. Ct. 943 (1994). MCI Communications
Group and MCI Telecommunications Corp v American Telephone & Telegraph 708 F.2d
1-81 (7th Cir. 1983).

134

Antitrust as a complement to the patent system

and the downstream market.71 The dominant firm will usually be active on both
markets, and the other firm will be active or wish to become active in the downstream market. The latter normally seeks access to an input of the integrated
firm that has been denied.72
The usual elements quoted as necessary for the establishment of mandatory
access are found in the US case MCI.73 They include: the control of an essential
facility by a monopolist; the competitors inability to practically or reasonably
duplicate the EF (requiring more than being more economical than alternatives,
or mere inconvenience or economic loss); the denial of the facility to the competitor (including the charging of unreasonable prices); and the ability to provide
the facility.74

71
Whether the existence of two markets is a prerequisite is a matter of debate, and
this is evident from the conflicting arguments of the parties in IMS.
72
While the EFD may arise in purely private circumstances, it is often raised in
situations involving regulation or involving some state-related or state-owned facility.
This explains why it is often a public policy choice. OECD, Essential Facilities Doctrine,
Paris (1996).
73
P. Areeda, Essential Facilities: An Epithet In Need of Limiting Principles, 58
Antitrust Law Jnl 841, (1989).
74
However, there are significant variations in the definitions of the doctrine. It has
even been described as follows: It is less a doctrine than an epithet, indicating some
exception to the right to keep ones creations to oneself, but not telling us what those
exceptions are. Ibid. A. Kezsborn and A.V. Goldman, No Shortcut to Antitrust Analysis:
The Twisted Journey of the Essential Facilities Doctrine, 1996 Colum Bus L Rev 1. See,
for example, the issue of whether the doctrine should be limited to natural monopolies.
This is based on the argument that as these markets are particularly vulnerable to tipping,
the tendency will be for a monopoly. In such cases, the key to maintaining a monopoly
the key is to create a large installed base, as it tends to become self-perpetuating afterwards as users will become locked-in because of high switching costs. A monopolist can
use the monopoly base to tip the downstream market creating a bandwagon effect, by
creating technological links between the two products. M.H. Harz, Dominance and Duty
in the EU: A Look through Microsoft Windows at the Essential Facilities Doctrine, 11
Emory Intl Rev 189 (1997). Harz explains that, in natural monopolies, free market forces
do not gravitate toward an equilibrium point, the maximum production and most efficient
resource allocation, and there are many equilibrium points. Tipping may move the market
off its equilibrium point towards a new point that favours a competitor or a particular
product. J.S. Venit, J.J. Kallaugher, Essential Facilities: A Comparative Law Approach,
in Hawk ed, 1994 Fordham Corp. L. Institute, pp.245-344.
Others argue that as antitrust cannot change the structural characteristics of natural
monopolies, its applicability in these industries will depend on the specific costs and
benefits of an EFD and whether it is likely to do more good than harm. See A. B. Lipsky
and J.G. Sidak, Essential Facilities, 51 Stan Law Rev 1187, (1999); See also C.O. Robinson, On Refusing to Deal with Rivals, 87 Cornell L. Rev. 1177 (2002); Troy, Unclogging
the Bottleneck: A New Essential Facilities Doctrine, 83 Colum L Rev 441 (1983).

The duty to deal under Art. 82 EC

135

The essential facilities doctrine requires that the facility should at least be
indispensable to viably compete on the market and that there should be clear
anti-competitive effects in the product or technology market. This, in effect,
requires that there would not be any workable alternative technology available,
and that there would be a potential effect to eliminate competition by the requesting party or from any third party.75 The facility, whether physical or
technological, must be indispensable to enter or stay on the market. Once a facility is deemed essential and unless there is a legitimate justification, the denial
of access will amount to an abuse of dominance.
The application of the indispensability requirement (similar to essentiality in
the EFD) raises three fundamental questions on its application: first, what constitutes indispensable/essential, secondly, whether there is a need for two
markets, and thirdly, what classifies as an objective justification.
6.2.3.1 Indispensability
Different definitions have been proposed as regards the issue of essentiality/indispensability.76 In Sealink,77 the Court defined an essential facility as a facility
or infrastructure, without access to which one cannot provide services to their
customers.

75

Commercial Solvents (1974), Telemarketing (1985), Bronner (1998) op. cit.


Areeda understands that to meet the threshold of essential the following requirements must be met: the competitor must be essential to competition in the market place;
it must be essential to the individual competitor, (in the sense of being critical to its
competitive vitality); and that duplication of the facility and practical alternatives must
not be available. P. Areeda (1989) op. cit.; see also D.E. Troy (1983) op. cit., who proposes that a facility should not be deemed essential unless the facility is necessary for
entry into the market, duplication of the facility is beyond the standard cost of entry into
the foreclosed market and the plaintiff cannot commercially exist without access to this.
The test advocated by the author is objective, focusing solely on the effects of the monopolists decision.
Other commentators claim that a facility is essential only when public necessity justifies treating the facility as essential, so that consumer preferences, analysis of the market
and the needs of competitors are irrelevant in a determination of essentiality. C.M. Seelen,
The Essential Facilities Doctrine: What does it mean to be Essential?, 8 Marq L Rev
117 (1997). Others have defined essentiality according to whether it is required by a
competitor in order to compete effectively. N. W. Hawker (1999) op. cit.
See D. J. Gerber (1988) op. cit. who offers a legal and economic definition of essentiality. Economically, it involves facilities that can impede the users production or access
to a market. It requires the presence of four characteristics: a. the facility must be unique
in that there are no similar and competing facilities and duplication is precluded; b.
preservation of uniqueness; c. the facility must be centrally located, and the flow of production and distribution must flow from there; and d. the monopolist must be able to
regulate his facility- functional control. The legal definition as established in Hecht v
Pro-Football No. 2815-66, US Dist, Ct for Dist. Of Columbia, 312 F. Supp. 472; 1970
76

136

Antitrust as a complement to the patent system

77

It would seem difficult to justify a test of essentiality or practicability of duplication that was in any way less stringent than the tests of market power.78 It
would also be wrong to have a test that focuses on the survival of a particular
competitor as opposed to whether it was generally economically viable for any
competitor to survive without access to the facility. The test can only be
objective.79
Accordingly, as clarified in Bronner,80 any alternative technology must be
assessed on the assumption that comparable assets would be invested for its
development, even if they are less advantageous for competitors.81
In addition, certain factors may be taken into account in the determination of
essentiality. For example, whether the facility has become an industry standard,82
U.S. Dist. LEXIS 12049; 1970 Trade Cas. (CCH) P73,170, 16th April, 1970, would seem
to be that duplication of the facility would be economically infeasible and the denial of
use inflicts severe handicap on potential entrants in the market. See also A.B. Lipsky,
J.G. Sidak, (1999) op. cit. who believe that inherent in the notion of essentiality lies the
premise that the owner of the facility possesses monopoly power. They identify three
requirements: a. some uniqueness and market control; b. the lack of feasible alternative
or ability to reproduce; and c. the facility connotes an integrated physical structure or
large capital asset with the unique character that usually confers monopoly power and
control by virtue of the superiority of its intended purpose. They also believe that the
EFD is inappropriate in the following situations: where there is no monopoly power; the
facility is not an indivisible unit; an IPR is involved; and it is necessary to expand the
capacity of the facility to accommodate for the new user.
See M.A. Bergman, The Bronner Case A Turning Point for the Essential Facilities
Doctrine? [2000] 2 ECLR 59, who believes that the requirement of a market share
equivalent to the dominant firm in Oscar Bronner is too strict. However, the EFD should
not be applied simply if a firm finds it impossible to establish an EF. Ideally, it is argued,
that the criterion should be able to distinguish between situations in which investments
and other desirable behaviour might be jeopardised by its application, and situations in
which such significant risk is at hand and the application of the doctrine can potentially
result in substantial efficiency gains.
77
Stena Sealink (1994) op. cit.
78
Lipsky and Sidak (1999) op. cit.
79
In general, Art. 82 applies an objective concept of abuse. It is only in the context
of dependence and cases that reflect the estoppel rationale that one may argue that
abuse has acquired a subjective character.
80
Case C-7/97 Bronner, [1998] ECR I-7791.
81
Ibid, paras. 43-45.
82
This has influenced the Commission in IMS in deciding that the product was indispensable and in favour of granting a compulsory licensing order. It is believed that
once a service or product develops into a standard, then access should be available to all
competitors as it is impossible without it to compete. The Commission reasoned that as
the 1860 brick structure had developed into an industry standard, according to consumer
preferences, the dominant undertaking was not allowed to refuse access to it. Hence, in
this sense the industry standard consideration could militate in favour of finding of
indispensability.

The duty to deal under Art. 82 EC

137

or whether the intellectual property (IP) in question does not require or merit
any incentive might militate (whether expressly or impliedly) in favour of a
ruling of essentiality.83 On the other hand, the threshold of essentiality may be
higher, where there are significant sunk costs involved, or if the incentives to
innovate are very important.
In IMS84 the ECJ confirmed that the test for determining the indispensability
of a facility or input relates to whether there are products or services which
constitute alternative solutions, even if they are less advantageous, and whether
there are technical, legal or economic obstacles capable of making it impossible
or at least unreasonably difficult for any undertaking seeking to operate in the
market to create, possibly in cooperation with other operators, the alternative
products or services.85

83
This is an unspoken consideration that seems to have influenced the EU Courts
and Commission in the Magill and IMS case. It is interesting that both cases involved a
national IP law that did not exist in the rest of the EU countries, and was viewed with
disbelief as failing to warrant IP protection. The dominant positions in both cases successfully invoked the national copyright law to drive the complainant out or prevent him
from entering the business. The perception that the laws in question were of limited value,
may have been a consideration that influenced the Courts to find the refusals abusive.
Admittedly if an IP of no merit is concerned, this should be remedied in the IP provisions, and competition law should not be seen as correcting perceived IP regulatory
failures.
If it was controlled by competition law, it would be seen as addressing IP failures and
not treating IP like other cases. If competition law did not control it, it would be seen as
exempting IP from something, unjustifiably, as argued in Chapter 5. However, if competition law merely controls it, then, because of the effect of these laws on the market as
they eliminate downstream competition, there would arguably be no objection.
Accordingly, the IP in question is not relevant in determining the effects of exclusion,
but may be relevant as a matter of fact in the determination of essentiality/indispensability
of the facility. The weaker the rationale for protecting the exclusivity of the facility,
stemming from IP or otherwise, the easier it may be for a facility to be deemed indispensable. In this sense, the weak nature of the IP in question may be relevant after all.
This would also be consistent with the AG Jacobs opinion in Glaxosmithkline on taking
the regulatory context and other factors into account in the determination of abuse and
objective justification. See below.
However see also G. Lunney, Re-examining Copyrights Incentive/ Access Paradigm,
49 Vanderbuilt L. Rev. 483 (1996), on the incentive/access paradox, who posits that
access is more likely to be precipitated in exactly those cases where the invention involved is important and deserving of the incentives.
84
Case C-418/01 29 April 2004
85
Ibid. para 28. See however, the Commission Decision in Case COMP/C-3/37.792
Microsoft [2004] where a lower standard for indispensability was adopted. While it was
recognised that there may be less advantageous alternatives, it was argued that those
were not in reality alternatives.

138

Antitrust as a complement to the patent system

6.2.3.2 Two-market requirement


Opinion is divided with regard to the question of whether there is a need for
two markets. Some argue against the need for two markets and focus instead on
the competitive relationship between parties,86 while others stress the necessity
of the existence of two markets arguing that there is no obligation to create
competition in ones own market.87
It would appear that the effect of the denial of access is the same regardless
of whether the firm is vertically integrated or not.88 If a firm is vertically integrated and unable to price discriminate, it would be inclined to deny access as
part of a predatory practice. If it is not vertically integrated it would again be
inclined to limit downstream competition in order to reap a downstream price.
Hence, the denial might be present in both cases, either to increase market power
or to maximise profits. The harmful effects on welfare are also present in this
case. Thus whether the dominant firm is present on the downstream market also
does not seem to be decisive for the purposes of the essential facilities doctrine,

86
R. Pitofsky, The Essential Facilities Doctrine under US Antitrust Law, Paper
submitted to the European Commission in support of National Data Corporation in its
essential facilities case against IMS. 2002; The courts require only that the plaintiff
prove that the facility is indispensable for competition in a relevant product market, is
controlled by a monopolist who could practically make access available, and is not capable of duplication. The policy concern is simply to ensure competition in the market
where the two parties could compete but for the refusal to provide access to the essential
asset the vital issue is whether a plaintiff has a competitive relationship with the alleged monopolist in the relevant product not what the relationship is between the
plaintiff and the defendant with regard to the asset alleged to be essential. pp.234. R.
Pitofsky, D. Patterson, J. Hooks, The Essential Facilities Doctrine under US Antitrust
Law, 70 Antitrust L. J. 443 (2002).
87
P. Marquandt, M. Leddy, The Essential Facilities Doctrine and Intellectual
Property Rights: A Response to Pitofsky, Patterson and Hooks, 70 Antitrust L. J. 847
(2002).
88
Given that the essential facilities doctrine refers to a situation where the users
production or access to a market is impeded by the lack of access to the essential facility, it would appear that it refers to a factual situation in which the important
relationship is a vertical one between the monopolist and the user, and so emphasis
should not be placed on the horizontal relationship. Viewing the doctrine from this
perspective directs attention to the situations, irrespective of vertical integration, in
which it is either desirable to impose judicial regulation, as the facility concerns an
unregulated natural monopoly for which overly high returns are not warranted (as they
have not been achieved by merit or skill) and would lead to an inefficient allocation
of resources (as it would attract too much investment to the detriment of regulated
goods), or the refusal to deal would be anticompetitive from a dynamic point of view.
Accordingly, a competitive relationship would not be necessary and the issue of
whether two markets are necessary is avoided; the focus is placed on the essentiality
of the input. D.J. Gerber (1988) op. cit.

The duty to deal under Art. 82 EC

139

as it would lead to the same effect if there was another sole downstream
supplier.89
The conclusions drawn by the ECJ on the two market requirement in IMS
should be seen in light of these considerations. It is determinative that two different stages of production may be identified and that they are interconnected,
the upstream is indispensable in as much as for supply of the downstream
product.90
Therefore, it adopted a wider definition which does not require two markets
in the traditional antitrust sense: it is sufficient that a potential market or even
hypothetical market can be identified. Such is the case where the products or
services are indispensable in order to carry on a particular activity.91 If the
criterion of a secondary market is the hypothetical one then effectively the
threshold has been significantly lowered and it will be met in all or almost all
cases.92
6.2.3.3 Objective justification
The third contentious issue relates to the scope of an objective justification. A
legitimate justification generally includes situations such as: the lack of capacity
to supply or grant access; inability to pay (the foreclosed party is unable or unwilling to bear the monopolists costs of doing business that include not only
the actual expenses, but also a reasonable return for the investment); and cases
where access would interfere with the service of other customers.93
Furthermore, the analysis undertaken in the previous chapter supports the
conclusion that IP, in itself, would not constitute an objective justification as
this would amount to the exemption of IP from antitrust control.94
89
J. Ratner, Should there be an Essential Facilities Doctrine, 21 UC DAVIS L.
REV. 327 (1988) p.382. In addition, it is sometimes impossible to characterise some
markets as separate markets in an antitrust sense, but nonetheless there is a dependence
situation as in the case of IMS, and also in the case for research tools.
90
IMS Case (2004) op. cit. para 45.
91
Ibid. para 44.
92
See J. Killick (2004) op. cit.
93
D.E. Troy (1983) op. cit.
94
See Chapter 5. As it was contended earlier, the existence of unwarranted IPRs
that lead to unreasonable monopolisations of the market may constitute an unspoken
consideration in the determination of essentiality. In cases where weak IP laws are involved which grant an extra advantage in the market without justification, the
essentiality benchmark may effectively be lowered. This should not be seen as competition law adopting a different threshold for IP, but rather as similar to the case in which
an industry standard is involved as it will affect the application of the essentiality/ indispensability requirement. This effectively involves taking the specific regulatory and
other contexts into account in determining indispensability. See also Dutch Telegraaf
case (Decision of director-general Dutch Competition Authority 10 September 1998,

140

Antitrust as a complement to the patent system

The recent opinion of Advocate-General Jacobs in GlaxoSmithKline95 sheds


some light on the objective justification. First, he stated that the question of
abuse and justification should be dealt with together as a single issue.96 Secondly, and most importantly, he considered that the specific and regulatory
context can be taken into account in the determination of abuse and objective
justification.97
In this case, the Advocate-General took the pervasive regulation of price and
distribution in the pharmaceutical industry into account, as well as the likely
impact of unmoderated parallel trade upon pharmaceutical undertakings, and
the effect of such trade upon consumers and purchasers of pharmaceutical
products.98 Based on the particularities of these factors in the pharmaceutical
industry, he concluded that a refusal to license which was intended to restrict
parallel trade, did not constitute an abuse and was capable of justification as a
reasonable and proportionate measure in defence of that undertakings commercial interests.99
The Advocate-Generals opinion is illuminating insofar as it takes consideration of the broader context and specificities involved in line with the
characteristics of the industry. In addition, insofar as he considers abuse and
objective justification one question, consideration of the economic and regula-

1/501.o119 (Telegraaf v NOS/HMG); Trade and Industry Appeals Tribunal, 15th July,
2004, www.rechtspraak.nl, LJN-number: AQ1727) in which the Rotterdam District
Court decided that the existence of IPRs could not be used to establish an objective
justification.
See also Commission Decision in Case COMP/C-3/37.792 Microsoft [2004] Microsofts refusal cannot be objectively justified merely by the fact that it constitutes a refusal
to license intellectual property (recital 712).
95
AG Opinion in Glaxosmithkline (2004) op. cit.
96
Ibid. para. 72.
97
Ibid. para. 68.
98
Ibid. para. 76.
99
Ibid. para. 100. The AG considered that this was the case due to the particularities
of the industry as well as the fact that the case dealt with: a. the pervasive and diverse
measures of State intervention in the pricing of pharmaceutical products, which is responsible for price differentials between the Member States; b. the regulation of the
distribution of products which establishes nationally demarcated obligations upon pharmaceutical undertakings and wholesalers to ensure the availability of adequate stocks of
those products; c. the potentially negative consequences of parallel trade for competition,
the common market and incentives to innovate, given the economic characteristics of
the pharmaceutical industry; d. the fact that end consumers of pharmaceutical products
may not benefit in all cases from parallel trade and that public authorities in Member
States, as the main purchasers of such products, cannot be assumed to benefit from lower
prices, given that they are themselves responsible for fixing prices within their territories
(para. 105).

The duty to deal under Art. 82 EC

141

tory context should also be taken into account in determining abuse and its
individual elements, including indispensability.100
6.2.4 New Product Innovation
In the IMS case, the Court further referred to the circumstances in which a refusal by a dominant undertaking to grant a licence (to use its IP) might constitute
an abuse under Art. 82 EC. Following Magill, the Court stated that in order for
the refusal to give access to an indispensable product or service to be treated as
abusive three cumulative conditions must be satisfied: the refusal prevents the
emergence of a new product for which there is potential consumer demand; it
is unjustified; and it amounts to the exclusion of any competition on a secondary
market.101

100
In the case of IP, this again does not amount to an exemption but rather to a consideration of the regulatory context that may include IPRs. This is likely to be crucial in
finding in favour of a duty to deal where a weak IP is concerned.
101
IMS (2004) op. cit. para. 38 of judgment. See also Magill op. cit.
This differs from the Magill case, as although the product was not yet in existence
there was certitude as to its development and what it would involve. On the other hand,
it is only required here that there should be an intention to produce a new product which
one may also argue negates the very requirement itself. In biotechnology and specifically
in the case of research tools, as it will be shown in Chapter 7 this is important in view
of the fact that access is sought at a stage where it is not known whether a new product
will be developed.
Other cases however have not made reference to the new product rule or found it not
to be decisive. The Bronner case made no reference to the new product rule in its interpretation of the duty to deal. See Bronner (1998) op. cit. para 41:

Therefore even if that case-law on the exercise of an intellectual property right were
applicable to the exercise of any property right whatever, it would still be necessary,
for the Magill judgment to be effectively relied upon in order to plead the existence
of an abuse within the meaning of Article 86 of the Treaty in a situation such as that
which forms the subject-matter of the first question, not only that the refusal of the
service comprised in home delivery be likely to eliminate all competition in the daily
newspaper market on the part of the person requesting the service and that such refusal be incapable of being objectively justified, but also that the service in itself be
indispensable to carrying on that persons business, inasmuch as there is no actual or
potential substitute in existence for that home-delivery scheme.
Hence, while Magill identified the new product requirement, Bronner did not perceive
it as an essential element of the test. Similarly, the Commission Decision in Microsoft
(2004) op. cit. did not make any reference to the new product rule.
See also, however, Ladbroke (1997) op. cit. para. 131. The Court in Ladbroke interpreted the prohibition on the refusal to deal as applying either in cases where the product
or service is essential or in cases where a new product might be prevented despite spe-

142

Antitrust as a complement to the patent system

This new product rule alludes to both consumer preferences and also to innovation and the need to promote new and efficient products.
Therefore, the refusal by an undertaking in a dominant position to allow access to a
product protected by copyright, where that product is indispensable for operating on
a secondary market, may be regarded as abusive only where the undertaking which
requested the licence does not intend to limit itself essentially to duplicating the goods
or services already offered on the secondary market by the owner of the copyright,
but intends to produce new goods or services not offered by the owner of the right
and for which there is a potential consumer demand.102

There are two fundamental issues which should be noted with regard to the
new product rule. First, this may be seen as the departure from the essential facilities doctrine as this emphasis is not only placed on indispensability but
also on the new product. The EFD did not contain a requirement relating to
the new product. Hence, strict adherence to the requirement would imply that
the EFD is insufficient to capture the essence of the duty to deal under Art. 82;
the emphasis should not only be on the indispensability of the facility but also
on the creation of a new product.
Secondly, it should be noted that the ECJ adopted a liberal definition of the
new product, as it refers to intention to produce new goods as distinct from
their actual production. There may be significant implications arising from this
broad definition, particularly in the biopharmaceutical industry, as there may
be a duty to deal where access to an input is required as a basis for further research and development, to enable further innovation, even if it is as yet
impossible to identify the new products that would be developed, or even to
state with certainty that new products would be developed.103 Taking this argument to the extreme, one could also argue that the reference to an intention to
produce actually negates the very requirement of a new product.

cific, constant and regular potential demand on the part of consumers. The new product
rule would accordingly be a sufficient ground for liability, but not a necessary one.
102
IMS (2004) op. cit. para. 51.
103
Unfortunately, the Commission did not address the issue of this requirement in
its Microsoft decision. See Commission Decision in Microsoft (2004) op. cit. para.
693701, in which the Commission briefly discusses whether the refusal limits technical
development to the prejudice of consumer, without analysing the new product
requirement.
See however the Dutch Telegraaf case (1998) op. cit. in which the Trade and Industry
Appeals Tribunal found that a refusal to license did not amount to an abuse of a dominant
position as the television guide which Telegraaf sought to publish did not qualify as a
new product as required in EC case law, thus applying the considerations of the ECJ in
IMS.

The duty to deal under Art. 82 EC

143

6.3 Conclusions
As recently confirmed in EC case law, the duty to deal under Art. 82 remains
exceptional and only sanctioned within narrow limits.104 It is applicable where
the refusal to license leads to harm to competition, rather than to a specific
competitor105 or to the restriction of parallel trade.106
Determining whether there are exceptional circumstances which amount to
a risk of harm to competition requires a comprehensive examination.107 In
addition, the regulatory and economic context needs to be considered.108 This
is important, as industry-specific characteristics may be decisive in establishing
indispensability and objective justification.
The case law clarifies that the duty to deal remains limited to situations in
which:
1. the product or service is indispensable for carrying on a particular
business;
2. the refusal prevents the emergence of a new product with a potential consumer demand;
3. the refusal is not objectively justified;
4. the refusal effectively excludes all competition on the secondary
market.109
The aftermath to the Sealink decision underlines the importance of considering
alternatives and avoiding an over-eagerness in finding something essential.110
It should be recalled that the decision provided that the defendant should make
the port available to the rival ferry service, Sea Containers. The events that followed showed that the latter did not avail of this option and instead chose to

104

AG opinion in Glaxosmithkline (2004) op. cit. para. 53; IMS (2004) op. cit.
See Bronner (1998) op. cit.
106
See Glaxosmithkline (2004) op. cit.
107
Microsoft Commission decision (2004) op. cit. para. 555558.
108
AG opinion Glaxosmithkline (2004) op. cit. para. 53 any obligation to deal pursuant to Article 82 EC can be established only after a close scrutiny of the factual and
economic context.
109
IMS case (2004) op. cit. It confirmed that in order for the refusal by an undertaking which owns copyright to give access to a product or service indispensable for carrying
on a particular business to be treated as abusive, it is sufficient that three cumulative
conditions be satisfied, namely that the refusal is preventing the emergence of a new
product for which there is a potential consumer demand, that it is unjustified and such
as to exclude any competition on a secondary market.
110
N/e/r/a, Competition Brief, Oscar Bronner: Legitimate Refusal to Supply, 1999,
at www.nera.com, p.3.
105

144

Antitrust as a complement to the patent system

operate a service to Ireland from Liverpool rather than Holyhead. At the time,
the Commission had dismissed this as an alternative, being too readily persuaded
by the claimant claims as to the essentiality of the facility.111
It therefore becomes clear that in imposing any obligation to deal, it is important not to dismiss the alternatives too easily. It is likely that the essential
nature of a product is overstated and thereby found essential, even though it
might not have been more than an inconvenience to the competitor. It is also
important not to encourage competitors to rely on the dominant firms facilities
but rather to encourage them to develop new and innovative services
themselves.112
In conclusion, the introduction of the new product rule as a prerequisite for
liability113 leads to a reconsideration of the applicability of the EFD in this
context and the extent to which it is the appropriate term to capture to the essence of the duty to deal under Art. 82. It would rather seem to be more
appropriate in this case to refer to a more generally phrased duty to deal in cases
of indispensable facilities/inputs which also prevent potential new products
from entering the market. It should be noted, however, that it is not yet clear
whether the conditions laid down by the Court in IMS are necessary or merely
sufficient to impose liability for refusal to deal. 114

111

Ibid. p.4.
Ibid.
113
IMS Case (2004) op. cit.
114
This debate is reflected in the Order of the President of the CFI 22 December
2004 (1) (Proceedings for interim relief Article 82 EC) Competition Microsoft v Commission Case T-201/04 para. 206: Clearly, that question cannot be resolved at the interim
relief stage. It should be pointed out, however, that the Court of Justice has held, in the
words of paragraph 38 of the judgment in IMS Health, that it is sufficient, in order for
the refusal by an undertaking which owns a copyright to give access to a product or
service indispensable for carrying on a particular business to be treated as abusive, that
that refusal is preventing the emergence of a new product for which there is a potential
consumer demand, that it is unjustified and [that it is] likely to exclude all competition
on a secondary market.
112

The duty to deal under Art. 82 EC

145

Appendix The Refusal to Deal Cases under


Art. 82
Box 6.1 Commercial Solvents:Refusal
to supply input to downstream
competitor in vertically related
market/ to preserve power in
market B
The first case in which a refusal to supply was found to constitute
an abuse of a dominant position contrary to Art. 82 EC was Commercial Solvents.115 The defendant, Commercial Solvents (CS),
was the worlds only producer of an industrial scale raw material
which was used to produce ethambutol, an important drug in the
treatment of tuberculosis, which required a high level of know-how
and for which barriers to entry were high. Zoja was one of the three
main manufacturers of ethambutol in the common market and had
asked to be released from the contract. However, when it became
impossible to buy the drug elsewhere, Zoja requested CS to begin
supplying the raw materials again.
The latter refused to supply Zoja with the raw material and instructed the other companies who received the supplies not to sell
it on to Zoja. Finally, CS took the decision to integrate down the
market vertically and produce the drug itself. Zoja complained to
the Commission, who ordered minimum quantities be supplied,
however, it was not clarified whether this order was made to protect
the interests of Zoja or the consumer.
The ECJ upheld the finding of abuse, as it was particularly concerned about vertical integration. It held that the decision by a
dominant firm to vertically integrate did not justify the refusal to
supply a long-standing customer, even if he was a competitor, as
it would eliminate competition from one of the principal manufacturers in the market.
Market A: Raw material

Long-standing customer Vertical Integration

Market B: Ethambutol P

115

Case 7/73 ICI and Commercial Solvents v Commission [1974] ECR 223.

146

Antitrust as a complement to the patent system

The ruling in this case thus imposes an obligation to grant a licence to existing customers, if the failure to supply would lead to
the elimination of a significant competitor in the market. The ECJ
seems to have been particularly wary of vertical integration, fearing
that dominant firms in the production of raw material would use
their power in an upstream market to gain power in a related downstream market, with the possibility of also monopolising that
market.
Therefore, it took an interventionist approach, shaping the market
in line with its structural objectives, beyond its mandate to protect
the interests of customers and competitors.116 The case supports
the view that consumer interests are served by having as much
competition as possible in the final market.117 The decision, however, makes a clear appeal to the need to protect the interests of
consumers so that conduct that may directly or indirectly prejudice
them by impairing the competitive structure will be found abusive.
How would the court have ruled if CS had not chosen to integrate
vertically, but had none the less refused to supply Zoja, in response
to the latters initial preference of another upstream supplier? It is
probable that, even in this case, CS would have been forced to
supply as it would have been found to have been a disproportionate
response to the conduct of Zoja, and an unreasonable means to
protect its own interests.118 If the conduct of CS were to be deemed
to be proportionate and reasonable, then it could have also qualified as an objective justification for the refusal to supply. However,
what constitutes a legitimate objective justification and in what
cases is it proportionate?119
The Court did not provide any guidance on the latter questions,
as it was believed that CS would have refused to license, even

116
R. Grosvenor, To what Extent can Art 86 be used to compel dominant undertakings to supply competitors? at www.jumper.demon.co.uk/comm8a.htm, p.3.
117
Ibid.
118
See also Case 27/76 United Brands v Commission [1978] ECR 207, on the issue
of proportionality.
119
See BP, Case 77/77, Benzine en Petroleum Handelsmaatschappik BV and others
v Commission [1978] ECR 1513, in which the Court held that BP had not abused its
dominant position during the 1973 oil crisis, when it reduced supplies significantly more
to the complainant than to its regular customers. This conduct was justified as reductions
were relative to the oil shortage. See, however, also Boosey & Hawkes OJ [1987]
L286/36, where the Commission stated that a dominant undertaking may always take
reasonable steps to protect its commercial interests, but such measures must be fair and
proportional to the threat.

The duty to deal under Art. 82 EC

147

without the initial cancellation of Zoja and stressed that vertical integration cannot be used to justify the elimination of a principal
manufacturer.

Box 6.2 United Brands:Refusal to deal


with a distributor promoting a
competing brand to reserve
market power in A
The next case that arose involving a refusal to deal was United
Brands.120 The defendant had reduced supplies to Olesen, a longstanding customer (distributor/ ripener) of bananas, because he
had taken part in an advertising campaign for a rival brand, Dole.
United Brands (UB) argued that the complainant was pushing Dole
bananas at the expense of Chiquita bananas.
The Commission was concerned that if such conduct were permitted, it would discourage other distributors from advertising and
promoting other brands. In this manner UBC succeeds in keeping
its principle distributor/ripeners within its own marketing network
and in preventing competitors from having access to them, thus
denying to such competitors the essential facilities which they may
require in order to ripen their bananas before sale.
The ECJ advised that an undertaking in a dominant position
cannot stop supplying a long-standing customer who abides by
regular commercial practice, if the orders placed by this customer
are in no way out of the ordinary.121
Market A: banana production

D and Competitors

Long-standing customer

Market B: distributors/ripeners P
The argument that Olesen was selling a competitors product
and neglecting the sale of UBs product did not justify a failure to
supply. The reduction of supplies was found to violate Art. 82. The
ECJ stressed that a dominant undertaking can only take reasona-

120

Case 27/76 United Brands v Commission [1978] ECR 207.


Ibid. para. 182.

121

148

Antitrust as a complement to the patent system

ble steps to ensure that its produce is properly sold. Hence, the
Court seems to be raising proportionality requirements again in
this case, as the right to protect ones own commercial interests is
only justified if the action taken is reasonable and appropriate. In
considering the proportionality of this type of sanction, the economic strength of the undertakings at stake will be taken into
consideration. Any attempt to extend and abuse the dominance of
the firm will be found to have violated Art. 82.
This is also in line with the requirement that the justification must
be objective. It is unclear, however, what steps UB could have taken
in this instance to defend its legitimate interests. It is important to
distinguish between the requirement of equal treatment in relation
to a distributors sales policy,122 and the actual restriction of competitors from access to the distributors marketing networksthe
so-called essential facilities to ripen the bananas. However, had
UB crossed this line?
It appears that the Court was also concerned about the independence of SMEs, which allows them to preserve their business
interests and determine their own sales policy. A restriction upon
a firms right to participate in the advertising of a supplier would
effectively hamper the actual sales of other brands, as well as the
buyers freedom to decide its business interests. The arbitrary interference in the management of Olesens business had resulted
in serious damage, and if the Court had found in favour of the behaviour of UB, it would have strengthened its bargaining position
even further and effectively allowed UB to indirectly discourage the
promotion of competing brands.
However, would this factor not exist in most cases? One might
argue that the Court chose to uphold the business interests of
Olesen, but denied UB the right to enforce its respective business
interests. Nevertheless, as it has been repeatedly recognised,
dominant undertakings are under more onerous obligations,123 as
they also have more potential for abuse, and more commercial

122
In effect, it could be argued that it was as if the Court was applauding the actions
of Dole leading to Olesen treating him favourably, but not those of UB wanting to be
treated equally.
123
See Case 322/81 Michelin v Commission [1983] ECR 3461 on special responsibility. See also Case C-333/94 Tetra Pak v Commission [1997] 4 CMLR 602, where the
dominance in one market and the close links with another market gave the latter a freedom of independence of conduct compared to the other economic operators such as to
impose on it a special responsibility under Art. 82 to maintain genuine and undistorted

The duty to deal under Art. 82 EC

149

bargaining power. In this light, the Court sought to encourage SMEs


to make their own commercial decisions, uninfluenced by threats
of large and more powerful companies, and to discourage the latter
companies from exerting this type of pressure in the first place. The
Commission and Court seem to have paid particular attention to
the fact that the market for bananas had many barriers to entry; as
UB was vertically integrated to a large degree, from plantation to
marketing, it controlled the sources of supply and was able to
guarantee regular supplies to competitors.
It is also worth noting, moreover, that by providing a requirement
to supply long-standing customers, the Court was in effect setting
a general rule prohibiting a refusal to supply unless justified, irrespective of the fact that competitors were not an issue and that
there was no possibility for leverage as in the Commercial Solvents
case.124
Hence, this case seems to provide a more general and broader
obligation not to go against a pattern of dealing, by refusing to license a long-standing customer, regardless of the rationale. Hence,
in the case of a refusal to supply, an objective justification would
seem to be necessary in order to escape liability, and while the
Court did not provide guidelines on what constitutes such a justification, it appears that the requirements of reasonableness and
proportionality will be strictly applied.
It should be remembered, however, that the behaviour of UB was
also found abusive, as there was evidence of price discrimination
and a restriction on the resale of green bananas, resulting in the
segmentation of the market in practice. As integration was an important consideration at stake, the Court was determined not to
allow any possibility for discrimination along national boundaries,
and therefore its strict ruling against the refusal to supply may have
been influenced by its condemnation of price discrimination and its
desire to prevent any perceived barriers to integration.125

competition on those markets. V. Korah, Competition Law of the European Communities, 2nd edn, Lexis Nexis (2001).
124
In this case, the parties only had a vertical relationship, and not a horizontal one
of competition as in the ICI and Commercial Solvents v Commission 7/73 [1974] ECR
223.
125
For a critique of the unclear economic rationale of the Courts condemnation of
price discrimination, see L. Zanon di Valgiurate, Price Discrimination Under Art 86 of
the EEC Treaty: The United Brands Case [1982] Internatl and Comparative Law Quar-

150

Antitrust as a complement to the patent system

Box 6.3 Hugin:No effect on trade


The Hugin126 case involved Hugins refusal to supply spare parts
to its former exclusive distributor in the UK which were needed to
repair and maintain the large numbers of Hugin cash registers that
it rented out. The Commission ruled against Hugin, using a similar
rationale to the previous case, as it was concerned for the interests
of consumers and the preservation and independence of SMEs.
The Court, however, did not find any infringement of Art. 82, as the
firm only operated locally and therefore there was no effect on
trade.

Box 6.4 IGR:Refusal to license an


essential facility?
IGR Stereo-Television127 involved the refusal of a firm, IGR, the
proprietor of patents for stereo receivers which were necessary for
providing German television sets with stereo reception, to license
non-members (or the plans to license at a later stage along with
restrictions on quantity), and the use of the patent rights to prevent
a Finnish company, Salora, from supplying stereo TV sets which
required a patent licence.
The Commission found that the conduct constituted an abuse of
a dominant position that could not be justified on the basis of patent
rights. Compulsory licensing was not imposed, however, despite
the Commissions willingness to impose it, as IGR agreed to grant
a licence to Salora without limitations after the initiation of
proceedings.
Market A: Patents for stereo receivers

New entrant

Market B: TV manufacturing P

terly 37. The author states that that the judgment appears more akin to those laws aiming
at the protection of existing competitors rather than of competition itself. p.53.
126
Hugin v Commission Case 22/78 [1979] ECR 1869.
127
IGR Stereo Television EC, Comm XIth Competition Policy Report, 1982, p.63.

The duty to deal under Art. 82 EC

151

In this case, the Commission was concerned with the control by


a firm in an upstream market of a downstream market, regardless
of the rationale behind this control, or whether it was due to an IPR
or otherwise. This case is similar to the previous cases, and again,
it concerned a vertical relationship. It differs, however, from the
previous cases as there was no previous relationship between the
parties, and therefore there was no consideration of the long-standing relationship or the pattern of behaviour. The refusal to license
the Finnish company effectively prevented a new entrant into the
German market of TV manufacturing. The obligation to license or
supply was hence extended by the Commission, to situations beyond those involving existing dealers, requiring dominant firms to
take affirmative action to ensure that competition is allowed to take
place in all markets on which they have an influence.128

Box 6.5 Telemarketing:Tying/ Refusal


to deal with suppliers dealing
with competitors/ to preserve
market power in B
In the Telemarketing case,129 a subsidiary of Radio and TV Luxembourg refused to accept advertisements from advertisers who had
not used the telemarketing services of its associated phone-in
marketing company when it sought to enter the field.
The Commission treated this as a case of tying, and held that
there is an abuse of a dominant position where an undertaking
which occupies a DP on a market and which is thus able to control
the activities of other undertakings on a neighbouring market decides to establish itself on the second market and for no good
reason refuses to supply the product or service in question on the
market where it already occupies a DP to the undertakings whose
activities are centred on the market which it is penetrating.
The ECJ treated the case as a refusal to supply and found that
Art. 82 applies even where dominance is due to some legal provi-

128
R. Subbiotto, The Right to Deal with Whom One Pleases Under EC Competition
Law: A Small Contribution to a Necessary Debate, 9 ECLR 234 (1992).
129
Case 311/84 Centre Belge dEtudes du March-Tlmarketing SA (CBEM) v
Companie Luxembourgeoise de Tldiffusion [1985] ECR 3261.

152

Antitrust as a complement to the patent system

sions providing for limited or no competition, as it refers to a factual


situation. An abuse is committed where an undertaking holding a
dominant position on a particular market reserves an ancillary activity without objective necessity to itself or to an undertaking
belonging in the same group which might be carried out by another
undertaking as part of its activities on a neighbouring but separate
market, with the possibility of eliminating all competition from such
undertaking. It also stated that the same applies where an undertaking has a dominant position on the market for a service that is
indispensable for another undertaking on another market.
The case might also be seen as a refusal to deal with suppliers
(for example advertising as in this case) which dealt with competitors on a secondary market (such as answering services) to
preserve market power in the latter market.
Market A: TV
D

Vertical integration
Market B: Answering services

D Competitors

Market C: Telemarketing P
The judgment is significant for several reasons. First, it held that
Art. 82 applies even where dominance arises from provisions enshrined in law. While the case the Court referred to liberalised
companies by virtue of Art. 90(2), in the present case, this also
implies the same attitude for IPRs, which are also granted by law.
Secondly, it appears that in the present case, the Court and
Commission were particularly concerned about the existence of
related markets, and the possibility of extending market power from
an upstream to a downstream market with the possibility of eliminating competition. The requirements for an abuse would hence,
thus far, seem to include: (a) the existence of a dominant position;
(b) the reservation of an ancillary activity; (c) with the possibility of
eliminating all competition from such undertaking; and (d) with no
objective necessity.

153

The duty to deal under Art. 82 EC

Box 6.6 Volvo:Refusal to share spare


parts with independent
providers of aftermarket
support
Another case which involved a refusal to supply was Volvo v
Veng.130 Volvo had used its design rights in the UK to restrain Veng
from importing wing panels of Volvo cars from another Member
State. It alleged that there had been an infringement of its registered design. Veng, in its defence, argued that Volvos refusal to
license spare parts for Volvo motor carts constituted an abuse of
a dominant position.
The ECJ refused to rule against the injunction imposed on Veng.
Advocate-General Mischo concluded that the right to restrain third
parties from exploiting the design constitutes the very subject matter of the exclusive right. Consequently, the ECJ held that an order
for the granting of a licence would deprive the right of the substance
of its exclusivity and that a refusal to license did not constitute an
abuse of that right. Nevertheless, it added that the exercise of a
holders exclusive right might be prohibited by Art. 82 if it involved
certain abusive conduct such as the arbitrary refusal to supply
spare parts to independent repairers, the fixing of prices for spare
parts at an unfair level or a decision no longer to produce spare
parts for a consumer model even though many cars of that model
are still in circulation provided that such conduct may affect trade
between Member States. Whilst the Court emphasised that, in the
absence of harmonisation the determination of the conditions and
procedures under which protection of designs is granted is a matter
for national law, it also clarified that their exercise could be limited
by Art. 82 in certain cases.
Market A: Car manufacturer and spare parts

Registered design rights on replacement body panels

Market B: Repair of car/replacement parts P


The case highlighted that a dominant position does not arise only
by virtue of the existence of exclusive rights; rather, this would also

130

Volvo v Veng (UK) Ltd Case 238/87 [1988] ECR 6211.

154

Antitrust as a complement to the patent system

depend on the absence of substitutes, clarifying that the existence


of an IPR is not concomitant with dominance. However, the Courts
reference to arbitrary refusal to supply spare parts does not address the question of when such a refusal will be deemed
arbitrary.

Box 6.7 Sabena: Denial of access to a


facility to downstream
competitors which is necessary
to compete/ to preserve market
power in market B
In London European/Sabena,131 Sabena, as the dominant firm in
the market for computer reservation services (CRS) in Belgium,
refused access to its CRS to London European, as it sought to
enter the LondonBrussels route, competing with it on the fare
rates. The refusal prevented London European from covering this
route, and it was therefore treated by the Commission as an abuse,
which consisted of refusing access to an essential service.
Market A: Computer reservation services

Market B: Flights/London-Brussels route

D P

The Commission was paving the way for the essential facilities
doctrine. It also took consideration of the fact that the refusal to
grant access was not based on a lack of capacity, but on a desire
to prevent the competitor from entering the market. Sabenas operations on both markets opened the possibility for leverage, in
particular as the CRS was essential for operating in the market and
its access would have to be granted on the basis of objective criteria and of the competitive (or anti-competitive for this matter)
strategies of the controlling company.

131

Commission Decision London European-Sabena, OJ 1988 L 317/47.

155

The duty to deal under Art. 82 EC

Box 6.8 Decca:Essential Facilities?


Denial of access to a facility to
downstream competitors that is
necessary to compete/to
preserve market power in
market B
In Decca Navigation Systems,132 Decca refused to grant access to
its navigation signals that were protected by copyright to users of
non-Decca receivers. The Commission found that this constituted
an abuse of a dominant position, as navigation signals were essential to all receivers, and hence Decca was under a positive duty
to grant access to other receivers. As in the case of IGR TV, the
emphasis seems to be on the exclusionary behaviour on a secondary market, regardless of whether dominance was due to or
associated with the IPR.
The recurring pattern seems to involve a firm which is dominant
on the upstream market and is also present on the downstream
market in which another firm seeks to enter or continue to operate;
access to the upstream product or service is necessary to compete
in the downstream market.
Market A: Navigation signals

Essential for operation on downstream market

Market B: Receivers

D P

In this case, other considerations might also have influenced the


Commission, as Racal had entered into an agreement with competitors to partition the market for commercial and pleasure boat
receivers. There was no potential competition on the market for the
signals, whereas with the agreement and the change of frequencies in the signals, DNS-compatible receivers for commercial use
enjoyed a de facto monopoly. The Commission believed that such
action would lead to a negative impact on consumers as it would
limit their freedom of choice.
Abuse was therefore found on the basis of use of power on the
market for signals to foreclose and limit the access of third parties

132

Commission Decision Decca Navigator System, OJ 1989 L 43/27.

156

Antitrust as a complement to the patent system

to the market for receivers, thereby also affecting consumer


interest.
The Commission also found that Racal (DNS) did not have any
legitimate property interests, as its patents on the receivers had
lapsed and there was no legal property in the transmission of signals, which is the service supplied but only in the equipment
(chains).133 It seems that the Commission was also concerned
about the possibility of extending the legal monopoly (of the patents) after they had lapsed. Regarding the copyright in question
which aimed to partition the market, it was not found to justify farreaching restrictions on competition.
It also clarified that IPR do not enjoy immunity from the competition provisions: The Community system of competition does not
allow the improper use of rights under national copyright laws which
frustrate Community competition law.134
Hence, in its finding of abuse, the Commission seems to have
been influenced by the following factors: (a) there was an agreement between competitors allocating the markets; (b) it impeded
competing receivers resulting in a de facto monopoly; (c) it was
acting against the interests of the consumers; and (d) there was
no justification for this conduct as it eliminated innovative competition and limited technological and economic progress, rather than
fostering innovation.

Box 6.9 Aer Lingus:Refusal to continue


joint venture with competitor. A
disproportionate sanction?
In British Midland/Aer Lingus,135 the two companies had an interlining agreement, which involved issuing tickets reciprocally on behalf
of the other airlines. When BM began to compete on a specific
route with AL (the DublinLondon route), the latter decided to end
the interlining agreement, which rendered BM flights less attractive.
The Commission found that such a withdrawal constituted an abuse

133

Ibid. para. 104.


Ibid. para. 104.
135
Commission Decision British Midland/ Aer Lingus, OJ 1992 L 96/34.
134

The duty to deal under Art. 82 EC

157

and fined AL.136 It stated that refusing to interline is not normal


competition on the merits the argument that interlining would
result in a loss of revenue would not of itself make the refusal legitimate. Both the refusal to grant new interline facilities and the
withdrawal of existing interline facilities may, depending on the circumstances, hinder the maintenance of competition.
The Commission also referred to objectively likely to have a
significant impact on the other airlines ability to start a new service
or sustain an existing service in account of its effects on the other
airlines costs and revenue. The Commission, however, recognised that new entrants should not be allowed to operate on their
competitors networks forever, but instead should be encouraged
to develop their own and therefore only imposed the interlining
agreement for a period of two years.137
It has been suggested that it might be more helpful to characterize Aer Lingus, Boosey & Hawkes and United Brands as cases of
dependence rather than essential facilities. They were all cases of
retaliation by dominant firms against customers who either entered
into, or joined with competitors to enter into competition with their
supplier. In such a situation Art. 86 can apply even if the degree
of dominance is such that there are some alternative sources of
supply and the legal test is one of objective justification and proportionality for the dominant undertakings use of the sanction of
refusal to supply as a punishment.138

136
See Commission Speeches on short-term benefits, in http://europa.eu.int/comm/
competition/speeches/text/sp1996_0542_en.html which refers to cooperation between
competitors that might be essential to carry out certain operations, specifically referring
to airlines interlining, where more participants is considered better as there is usually
only scope for one system. Network externalities magnify disadvantages of exclusion,
and reduce the viability of otherwise essential competitors. Exclusion would be hard to
justify, as it would create a category of second-class competitors, unless admission would
reduce the efficiency of the network. p.17.
137
R. Grosvenor, To what extent can Art 86 be used to compel dominant undertakings to supply competitors? at www.jumper.demon.co.uk/comm8a.htm, pp.45.
138
Anderman, EC Competition Law and IPRs: The Regulation of Innovation, 1998,
p.202. See also T. Nacke Abuse of Dominant Positions, 1995 at http://europa.eu.int/
comm/competition/speeches/text/sp1995_025_en.html. He refers to the notion of economic dependence of some Member States, in which a company has market power but
is not dominant. The author proposes that we should develop a concept of partenaire
obligatoire so that there is an abuse if the dependent company cannot substitute, if it is
likely to deter new competitors and if the companys behaviour is not constrained by
competition in the wider downstream market.

158

Antitrust as a complement to the patent system

Box 6.10 Sea Containers:Essential


facilities? Refusal to grant
access to a facility to a
competitor/to preserve market
power in B
Sea Containers v Stena Sealink139 also seems to follow the same
pattern of the previous cases. This involved a port owner who refused to give access to a new ferry service, as it competed with its
own ferry service from Holyhead to Ireland. For the first time, the
Commission explicitly referred to the essential facilities doctrine,
holding that the port constituted an essential facility, and that the
denial of access was not based on an objective justification, and
that the owner had to offer access to competitors and customers
on a non-discriminatory basis.
Market A: Port owner

Market B: Ferry service

D P

In the present case, it appears that here the requirements for an


obligation to grant access on a non-discriminatory basis would include: (a) an essential facility controlled by a dominant undertaking;
(b) denial of it to a competitor or access on less favourable terms;
(c) no objective justification.
It would seem again that the rationale was the fear of extending
power from an upstream market in which the defendant is dominant
to the downstream market. The Commission imposed a strict duty
of non-discrimination as the owner of the facility had to satisfy the
dual role as administrator and operator of the facility. The Commission therefore imposed more onerous obligations on the owner of
the facility who had to negotiate as an independent standard operator, and not just on reasonable grounds.140

139

Commission Decision Sea Containers v Stena Sealink, OJ 1994 L15/08.


It should be noted, however, that the standard of an independent operator was
perhaps imposed here as the case involved a natural monopoly. There was indeed a double
monopoly as both the upstream and the downstream market were monopolised by the
defendant and not through his skill and merit, J.S. Venit and J.J. Kallaugher, Essential
140

The duty to deal under Art. 82 EC

159

Box 6.11 Magill:Essential facilities/


Refusal to supply input to
downstream competitor/to
preserve market power in
market B
The next case that led to significant debate on the dominant firms
obligations to deal with competitors and the compulsory licensing
of IPRs was the Magill case.141 The case involved the monopolisation of the weekly TV programme magazines. Three channels, RTE,
BBC and ITP, each published their respective weekly listings for
their TV programmes. These were sent to newspapers and magazines free of charge who were allowed to publish daily TV
programmes one day in advance during the week and two days in
advance at weekends. The TV listings were protected by copyright
law. There was no comprehensive weekly guide published for all
channels and injunctions restrained Magill from publishing a comprehensive weekly TV magazine. As a result, a complaint was
made to the Commission.
In this case, the ECJ stated that although mere ownership of an
IPR cannot confer a dominant position, the broadcasters had a
factual monopoly over the basic information that was required by
a third party; they had complete control over the raw material for
weekly TV guides. Therefore, they were deemed to be in a dominant position.
The ECJ also held that the exclusive rights of reproduction form
part of the rights of a copyright holder and that a refusal to grant a

Facilities: A Comparative Law Approach, in Hawk ed., 1994, Fordham Corp. L. Inst.
315 (1995).
Hence, it might reflect concerns about liberalised industries and the possibility for leverage and extension of power on secondary markets, with the possibility of eliminating
competition on such markets, or to evade regulation in the upstream market by extending
power in other unregulated markets. In Europe important sectors of industry are being
deregulated or at least liberalized by the EU. These measures would be of little value if the
companies concerned, most of which are dominant in their own areas, were free to integrate
forward and to discriminate in favour of their own downstream operations. Regulated or
state-owned companies often own facilities that are essential for all or most of their downstream competitors. The essential facilities principle is in effect the follow-up of Art 90 of
the EEC Treaty. J.T. Lang, Defining Legitimate Competition: Companies Duties to Supply
Competitors and Access to Essential Services, 1994, Fordham Law Inst. 245.
141
Case C-241 and 242/91P Magill [1995] ECR I-743.

160

Antitrust as a complement to the patent system

licence cannot in itself constitute an abuse. However, the exercise


of exclusive rights may amount to an abuse in exceptional circumstances. It was relevant that the refusal to supply the raw
information prevented the emergence of a new product for which
there was substantial demand. Secondly, the refusal was not justified and, thirdly, through their conduct, the broadcasters had
reserved to themselves a secondary market excluding all competition on that market, as they had denied access to the basic
information to the public, the raw material that was indispensable
for the creation of such a guide.
The Court also highlighted that the case was not concerned by
the differences in granting IPRs by Member States, but at the same
time it emphasised that it was wrong to assume that conduct consisting of the exercise of copyright which is legitimate under national
law cannot be reviewed under Art. 82. It confirmed that the Commission had the power to impose compulsory licensing (as it was
the only way to bring an end to infringement), and that for effect on
trade potential effect is enough.
Market A: TV listings/ programme information

Market B: Weekly programme listings and weekly D P


TV publications

(including non-listings material)
The impact of Magill largely depends on its interpretation. Two
interpretations may be made of the ECJs requirement of exceptional circumstances. The narrow requires both the prevention of a
new product for which there is significant demand, and that IPRs
are linked to essential inputs for a secondary market. The broad
interpretation states that the essential input in a secondary market
is sufficient, thus placing positive duties on IPR holders.142 Thus,
on the position regarding a refusal to license, the impact of Magill
depends on whether one views the exceptional circumstances as
consisting of two separate rules (the new product rule and the essential facility rule) or as one cumulative one. Evidence of the fact
that it constitutes one rule can be found in para. 57 of the judgment

142
S. Anderman, EC Competition Law and IPRs: The Regulation of Innovation,
Oxford University Press (1998).

161

The duty to deal under Art. 82 EC

in which the Court found that in the light of all those circumstances
the Court of First Instance (CFI) did not err in law in finding that the
appellants conduct was an abuse of a dominant position within the
meaning of Art. 86 of the Treaty.143

Box 6.12 Ladbroke:The absence of a


competitive relationship/
Refusal to license input/
Essential facilities
In the case of Tierce Ladbroke v Commission,144 the CFI held that
the judgment in Magill did not apply to the refusal by the copyright
holders of French horse racing to grant Ladbroke a licence to show
the races in its Belgian betting shops.
The relevant market was defined as the sound and picture of
horse racing in general in Belgium. Ladbroke argued that the conduct of the copyright holders was discriminatory as it had licensed
the French horse racing to other countries. The CFI rejected this
argument, however, as the refusal could not have been discriminatory in the absence of competition in the relevant market, notably
Belgium. It also believed that this did not result in the partitioning
of the common market as the pattern of demand showed that the
markets were divided along national lines and not as a result of the
right holders licensing policy. Furthermore, the latter did not operate nor had they granted a licence to other operators in Belgium.
Market A: Broadcasting coverage of horse racing

Market B: Operation of betting shops P


The Court also strictly distinguished the case from Magill, as in
the present case, Ladbroke was not even present on the market let
alone enjoyed a monopoly. The CFI explained that for a duty to deal
to arise the product must either be essential or it must involve a new
product. While the broadcasting was an additional and suitable

143

Magill case, op. cit., Judgment of the Court, para. 57.


Case T-504/93 Tierce Ladbroke v Commission [1997] ECR II 923.

144

162

Antitrust as a complement to the patent system

service for bettors, it was not indispensable to the main activity, in


other words, to the taking of bets, nor did it constitute a new product.
Ladbroke showed other races on screen, and its betting activity was
very strong even without a licence to the French horse races.
The case is important as it offered a broad interpretation of Magill
in the wider way, holding that the new product rule and the leverage
rule were separate, rather than cumulative. However, it should be
noted that this is not an authoritative interpretation of Magill, as it
was discussed obiter dicta. The case also reflects how market
definition is crucial in deciding whether an IPR holder has abused
its dominant position by refusing to license a product.145

Box 6.13 Bronner:Refusal to grant


access to a distribution system
to an upstream competitor/
Refusal to share methods to
reach customers/Essential
facilities?/To preserve market
power in market A
Oscar Bronner v Mediaprint146 involved the obligations of a dominant newspaper firm to grant access to its nation-wide home-delivery
service of daily newspapers to Mediaprint, a newspaper of smaller
circulation. It was held that the access to the home-delivery system
was not indispensable and, therefore, it was found that no abuse
had occurred. The case displays a narrow interpretation of the
doctrine of a refusal by a firm that was not in the public sector to
grant access to an essential facility.147
Market A: Newspapers

D P

Market B: Home delivery service

145
The CFI spoke in terms of ancillary markets that were not independent of the
main market and not of sub-markets as in Magill, but it is not clear what the term signifies. See Fitzgerald, Magill Revisited EIPR 154, 1998.
146
Case C-7/97 [1998] ECR I-7791.
147
V. Korah, Competition Law of the European Communities, 2nd edn, Lexis Nexis
(2001).

The duty to deal under Art. 82 EC

163

The Advocate-General explained the doctrine applied in cases


where a dominant firm in the provision of facilities for the supply of
goods or services on another market abuses its dominant position
by refusing access to those facilities without objective justification.
This involves cases in which a dominant firm is obliged not merely
to refrain from anti-competitive activity, but also must actively promote competition by allowing potential competitors to have access
to the facilities that it has developed. He also acknowledged the
importance of the right to choose ones trading partners, the need
to preserve the incentive for a dominant position to invest, and that
the primary purpose of Art. 82 is to prevent distortion of competition
and to safeguard the interests of the consumers rather than protect
the position of particular competitors. He observed that reserving
oneself to the downstream market will not have an adverse impact
on consumers unless the dominant position is sufficiently insulated
from competition to give it market power.148
With regard to IPRs, the Advocate-General stated that in the absence of other factors, the refusal to license does not in itself
constitute an abuse, and recognised that a wide duty to provide
access would have a harmful effect on the incentive to make the
original investment, particularly bearing in mind that duplication of
the facility was possible and the difficulty of the courts in establishing
the amount of compensation. There should be a real stranglehold
on a related market before a duty to license is imposed, for example
if duplication of the facility is impossible or extremely difficult owing
to physical, geographical or legal constraints or is highly undesirable
for reasons of public policy. It is not sufficient that the undertakings
control over a facility gives it a competitive advantage.149
He also noted that the test must be objective: it must be extremely difficult not merely for the undertaking demanding access,
but for any other undertaking to compete.150
The Court upheld the Advocate-Generals decision in the sense
that the refusal must be likely to eliminate all competition in the
market, it must be incapable of being objectively justified, and the
service in question must be indispensable to carrying on that persons business, inasmuch as there is no actual or potential
substitute in existence for that home-delivery scheme. For such

148

C 7/97 Oscar Bronner, A-G Jacobs Opinion, ECR [1998] I-07791, para. 58.
Ibid. para. 65.
150
Ibid. para. 66.
149

164

Antitrust as a complement to the patent system

access to be capable of being regarded as indispensable it would


be necessary at the very least that it is not economically viable to
create a second home-delivery scheme for the distribution of daily
newspapers with a circulation comparable to that of the daily newspapers distributed by the existing scheme.151 In this way, the facility
should not only be desirable, it must also be necessary.
On the facts of the case, the ECJ found that the home-delivery
system was not essential and access was not indispensable, even
if an alternative system would not be economically viable due its
small circulation. It viewed Magill as an exceptional case, in which
the information was indispensable to the publication as: Magill
could not publish a magazine for which there was consumer demand at all without it; there was no objective justification for refusal;
and the refusal would result in the elimination of all competition in
the secondary market of TV guides. In the present case, however,
the facility was not indispensable, as the question of whether it
could be expected to establish a second such system was not
judged from the position of Bronner but that of an undertaking of
comparable position to Mediaprint.152

151

Oscar Bronner op. cit., Judgment of the Court, para. 46.


R. Whish, Recent Developments in Community Competition Law, 2000 E.L. Rev.

152

219.
For a criticism of this see M. Bergman, The Bronner CaseA turning point for the
Essential Facilities Doctrine? 21 ECLR 59 (2000) who believes that if such a high
standard is applied without consideration of the specific circumstances, only natural/inevitable monopolies will qualify as EF. The author also believes that although the strict
criterion encourages strong firms to take risks and invest, it hampers competition (at least
in the short run) and reduces incentives for small firms to invest. He also believes that
the ECJ replaced the circumstance approach of economic analysis for legal certainty,
thus undermining the flexibility of the notion of abuse which is perceived by many commentators to be its virtue. This case has also been criticised for confusing the issues of
dominance and abuse. See Stothers, Refusal to Supply as Abuse of a Dominant Position:
Essential Facilities in the EU, 7 ECLR 256 (2001). The author shows that two out of the
three requirements laid down by the Court for abuse involve dominance. He concludes
that in the end the traditional test of Commercial Solvents and the modern approach of
Magill and Oscar Bronner are the same. This test involved the question of whether there
was a dominant position on the market, and if there was, whether it had been abused.
The author further argues that the essential facilities doctrine involves the importation
of an unnecessary concept in EC law and that refusal to supply cases may be sufficiently
and better dealt with under Art. 82. Regarding the need to preserve incentives for investment, refusal to supply will only constitute abuse if it is determined that there is no
sufficient possibility of substitutes to prevent dominance. It is unnecessary to show
dominance in a downstream market as, if this is not the case, the dominant firm will not
be able to take monopoly rent at that level in any case. Finally, the author believes that

The duty to deal under Art. 82 EC

165

Therefore, the requirements for liability in this case appear to


include: (a) refusal to license; (b) likely to eliminate all competition
in market; (c) no objective justification; (d) service indispensable to
carrying business/no substitutes. The ECJ treated the obligation to
license as much narrower than in previous cases such as United
Brands and Commercial Solvents, as the service should be indispensable, and a real stranglehold must exist before compulsory
licensing is imposed.

Box 6.14 IMS:Refusal to license input


(format) to competitors/
Essential facilities/To preserve
market power in market A
In the IMS case153 NDC complained to the Commission that IMS
had refused to license its 1860 brick structure for reporting German
sales data in the pharmaceutical industry. Within this structure,
Germany was divided into the maximum number of geographical
the transaction costs of enforcing this aspect of competition law would outweigh its
benefits. Hence the solution he proposes involves the use of Art. 82, but without readily
finding dominance. Once dominance is established, refusal to supply should be seen as
abusive unless an objective justification is given. IP should be considered as an objective
justification for all cases, apart from the most exceptional ones. Hence, it directs criticism
to the definition of dominance rather than abuse. It is submitted that such an approach
would then redirect attention in IP cases of which exceptional circumstances negate the
justification. Indeed the essential facilities doctrine may not be necessary to analyse refusal to supply cases. It may, however, none the less be desirable, as limiting the
situations in which a dominant firm will be under a duty to supply/license. Furthermore,
this assumption of an obligation on dominant firms to license, at the very least imposes
an obligation on IPR holders, and any dominant firm in general, to give reasons for their
refusal to supply to avoid interference on the grounds that the refusal was arbitrary, and
therefore abusive. Although jurisdictional requirements remain, any IP owner in more
than one EC Member State will be capable of satisfying them. See Robertson, Compulsory Licensing Under EC Law? 1992 LQR 39.
See also Case T-374/94 European Night Services [1998] ECR II-3141 in which the
Court took the view that train crews could not constitute an EF; and Info-Lab/Ricoh
(Competition Policy Newsletter (1999)) in which the Commission referred to the restrictive approach of Oscar Bronner and rejected a claim that Ricoh was under an obligation
to supply the complainant with new empty toner cartridges to enable him to compete
with Ricohs filled cartridges.
153
IMS Health Inc v Commission, 10 August 2001, Order of President of CFI, 26
October 2001, Order of President of CFI, 11 April 2002, Order of President of Court.

166

Antitrust as a complement to the patent system

units permitting data collection, while not enabling users to match


the data to a specific pharmacy, as that would contravene German
data protection rules.154 IMS which collects and sells regional data
services for sales data collection and analysis, used its copyright
on the brick structure to prevent competitors from marketing data
services using the same or similar reporting formats. NDC argued
that the refusal to license the structure prevented it from effectively
competing, as an alternative structure would not serve the customers needs and would be unmarketable. In this instance, their
complaint was effectively based on the essential facilities doctrine.
Market?

Brick structure standard?

Market A: Selling regional data services

D (brick structure) P

Market B: Sales data collection and analysis


Wholesalers using input data of Service Provider

Service provider (IMS, NDC) check and format using


brick structure
Regional Sales Report
The Commission found that the relevant market was the German
regional sales data service, and that there were exceptional circumstances in this instance, as it became clear that the brick
structure had developed into a de facto industry standard and that
an alternative standard would not be economically viable. It hence
ordered interim measures, consisting of a licence on a non-discriminatory basis in return for a reasonable royalty.
In its decision, the Commission greatly expanded the ambit of
third party rights of access.155 It effectively did away with the requirement of a new product, based on its reading of Ladbroke, and
it also neglected the requirement of a secondary market. It is also
argued that while access to the information was vital in Magill as

154
D. Hull, J. Atwood, J. Perrine, Intellectual Property Compulsory Licensing, 2002
European Antitrust Review 36, at www.Global-Competition.com.
155
Ibid.

The duty to deal under Art. 82 EC

167

there was no alternative and Magill could not invent or develop the
listings, nor could it publish the non-listings material without this
information. In the IMS case, access to medical data was not at issue, but the use of the format developed to present this information
to the pharmaceutical companies.156
In reaching its conclusion on the indispensability of the structure
particular attention was paid to whether customers would buy data
formatted in other structures. This might be criticised, as although
consumers interests are an important consideration, it is only natural that they prefer a higher product developed with a significant
level of skill and merit. However, the Commission based its decision
on the fact that the brick structure had been developed by a working
group, and pharmaceutical companies had participated in this
process; the brick structure was therefore built to suit their interests
over a long period of time and there were many disincentives in
switching. It therefore found that it had evolved into a de facto industry standard.
The fact that the pharmaceutical companies were economically
dependent on the brick structure was also relevant in this decision,
as switching would be an unviable economic option in light of the
comparability and compatibility of data, the change of sales territories and the costs of modifying the software applications. In reaching
its conclusion on the indispensability of the brick structure, the Commission was also concerned that it would not be likely for competitors
to create an alternative structure due to technological and legal
constraints.157 These included administrative boundaries, data protection constraints and uncertainty surrounding the sale of data and
whether it would infringe the copyright of the 1860 brick structure.
The Commissions willingness to impose compulsory licensing
and to find that the brick structure constituted an essential facility
raises many questions regarding the need for two markets, along
with whether IP is treated or should be treated differently from other
cases.
The decision of the Commission was suspended by Order of the
President of the CFI on 10 August 2001, as IMS argued that the
156

Ibid. p.37.
It might also have been relevant that there was a low margin of creativity in the
brick structure of 35%, which means that any alternative is bound to be similar and,
therefore, likely to lead to an infringement of the data. This was also confirmed by the
practice in other countries that showed that the brick structures were either similar, or
identical.
157

168

Antitrust as a complement to the patent system

competitive advantage was the essence of copyright, and that


compulsory licensing was incompatible with Art. 295. On 26 October 2001, the President referred to the question at issue: whether
the application of German copyright law may be affected by Art. 82
EC. The arguments of the parties are important, as they illuminate,
first, when there is an obligation to deal is uncertain, and secondly,
that the position regarding IP is also a matter of debate.
IMS argued that a refusal to license an IPR can only constitute
an abuse if there is some additional behaviour that is in itself abusive, or when an essential facility is at stake, which presupposes
the existence of two markets.158 The applicants further argued that
Magill was exceptional, as there was leverage from the upstream
to the downstream market and the copyright from broadcasting was
used to extend dominance in the weekly TV guides. In the present
case, IMS was not seeking to exploit market power in a separate
market.
On the other hand, the Commission argued there was no separate product in Magill either, and that in both cases the supply of
service was indispensable. While there was no new product in IMS,
there was no such requirement, adopting the broad interpretation
of Magill. Hence, it argued that there is no precondition for two
markets. In accordance with Magill, it found that there were exceptional circumstances (such as that it had been developed in
cooperation with pharmaceutical companies and constituted an
industry standard with no likelihood of alternative), and in accordance with Oscar Bronner, the refusal was likely to eliminate all
competition, access to it was necessary to compete and there was
no justification for such refusal.
The President of the CFI interpreted Magill as highlighting the
exceptional circumstances in which the exercise of exclusive rights
would constitute an abuse; when it is exercised in such ways and
circumstances as in fact to pursue an aim manifestly contrary to
Art. 82. He found, however, that the balance of interests weighed
in favour of the preservation of copyright and therefore suspended
the Commission decision until the CFI judgment had been given.
The ECJ gave its Art. 234 reference opinion relatively recently
in the IMS case.159 It adopted a cumulative reading of the Magill

158
IMS Health Inc v Commission, 10 August 2001, Order of President of CFI, 26
Oct 2001, Order of President of CFI, 11 April 2002, Order of President of Court. p.15.
159
Case C-418/01, not yet reported, 29 April 2004.

The duty to deal under Art. 82 EC

169

requirements by stating that the refusal must prevent the emergence of a new product. It adopted a broad definition of a new
product, however, as it referred to the intention to produce new
goods as distinct from the actual production.
As regards the presence of two markets in an antitrust sense,
the Court concluded that it is determinative that two different
stages of production may be identified and that they are interconnected, the upstream is indispensable in as much as for supply of
the downstream product.160 It hence adopted an expanded definition that did not require two markets in the traditional antitrust
sense: it is sufficient that a potential market or even hypothetical
market can be identified. Such is the case where the products or
services are indispensable in order to carry on a particular
activity.161

Box 6.15 Microsoft162 refusing to


provide interoperating
information
In March 2004 the Commission adopted a decision finding that
Microsoft had abused its quasi-monopoly in desktop operating
systems by, inter alia, refusing to provide interface information
necessary for competitors to create their own desktop operating
systems that could interoperate with Microsoft. The Commission
amongst other things imposed an obligation on Microsoft to license
the interface information to competitors on reasonable and nondiscriminatory terms and to provide an unbundled version of
Windows without the media player.

160

Ibid. para. 45.


Ibid. para. 44.
162
Commission Decision in Case COMP/C-3/37.792 Microsoft [2004], not yet
reported.
161

170

Antitrust as a complement to the patent system

Box 6.16 GlaxoSmithKline, Syfait


refusal to fully meet supply
requests to prevent parallel
imports163
The Greek Competition Commission made a preliminary reference
under Art. 234 EC in relation to the extent to which a dominant
company may refuse to fully meet orders placed by pharmaceutical
wholesalers with the intention of limiting parallel trade. The ECJ
found that it could not rule on the case as the Greek authority is
not a court or tribunal for the purposes of Art. 234, however, Advocate-General Jacobs gave his opinion on the matters.
The Advocate-General found that due to the particular features
of the pharmaceutical sector, mostly relating to the high level of
regulation and sunk costs of R&D, pharmaceutical companies may
be objectively justified in refusing to fully supply wholesalers with
the intention of limiting parallel trade. He suggested that Courts
should take a flexible, economics-based approach in applying Art.
82 to the pharmaceutical sector, taking into account the whole
context (economic, regulatory and otherwise) and the particularities
of the industry.
In 2006 the Greek Competition Commission followed the Advocate-Generals Opinion allowing GlaxoSmithKline to implement its
strategy to combat parallel imports.

163
Case C-53/03 Synetairismos Farmakopoion Aitolias and Akarnanias (Syfait) and
Others v Glaxosmithkline AEVE, Opinion of the A-G Jacobs, 28 October 2004.

The duty to deal under Art. 82 EC

171

Table 6.1 An overview of the main case law


Cases

Principles

Considerations

Commercial
Solvents:

1. existence of a longstanding customer


2. elimination of
important competitor
in market

Leverage. Vertical
integration (VI)
proportionate sanction

United Brands:

1. long-standing
customer
2. regular commercial
practice

SMEs, dependence
proportional sanction
Price discrimination
and market
segmentation

Hugin:

No effect on trade

IGR Stereo-TV:*
COM

1. new entrant
2. essential for downstream research

Leverage. Vertical
integration
Essential Facilities
Doctrine (EFD)?
same standard for IP

Telemarketing:

1. reservation of
ancillary activity
2. possibility of eliminating all competition
from such
undertaking
3. no objective
necessity

Leverage. Vertical
integration
long-standing customer

1. indispensable
2. for another market
3. no objective
justification

EFD

Volvo v Veng:*

additional abusive
conduct

same for non IP cases


also?

London European:
COM

1. essential service
New entrant

Vertical integration,
Leverage
EFD?

172

Antitrust as a complement to the patent system

Table 6.1 concluded


Cases

Principles

Considerations

Decca Navigation:*
COM

1. essential
New entrant

Leverage. Vertical
integration, EFD?
same for IP and non-IP

British Midland:
COM

1. long standing
2. Significant impact on
firm even if new
entrant
No indispensabilityno
EF

No leverage
dependence?
Proportionality of
sanction

Sea Containers:
COM

1. essential facility
2. denial
3. no objective
justification

Leverage, EFD
New entrant

Magill:*

1. new product
2. no objective
justification
3. indispensable for
secondary market
IPRs exceptional
circumstances

New entrant
Leverage
EF
In practice same for
non-IP?

Tierce Ladbroke:

not essential nor betting


shop new

Oscar Bronner:

1. indispensable
2. likely to eliminate all
competition
3. no objective
justification

No leverage?
Not EF
IP same as non-IP?

IMS:

2 markets or one?
EF?

indispensable no
alternatives
industry standard
dependence of
customers

Note: * and Italics for IP cases and considerations.

173

The duty to deal under Art. 82 EC

Table 6.2 The outcome of the main case law


Abuse

No Abuse

IP

Non IP

IP

Non IP

Decca
Navigation

Commercial
Solvents

Volvo (on
facts/in theory
can be abuse)

Ladbroke

Magill

United Brands

IMS

Telemarketing

Microsoft

Sabena

AstraZeneca

Sea Containers

GlaxoSmith
Kline

Bronner

PART IV

A more innovation sensitive approach to the


interface of competition law and patents?

7. The duty to deal as applied to address


technology access problems in the
biopharmaceutical industry
Compulsory licensing is not an absence of patent protection but merely a lessening
of that protection. While compulsory licensing may weaken the incentives to invest
in pharmaceutical research the trend of rapid and significant increases in investment
in pharmaceutical research demonstrates that the present incentives to invest are so
strong that they would have to be weakened considerably before there would be any
reduction in the amount of pharmaceutical research.

7.1 Conclusions on the patent system in the


case of research tools
7.1.1 The Particularity of Research Tools: Pre-commercial Stage
Patents
The nature of biopharmaceutical research and of the industry in general is such
as to potentially give rise to concerns related to refusals to deal or lack access
in certain cases. The specific case of research tools was examined in this
context.

T.C. Bailey, Innovation and Access: The Role of Compulsory Licensing in the
Development and Distribution of HIV/AIDS Drugs, 2001 U. Ill. J. L. Tech. & Poly 193,
p.207.

The latter consists of the full range of resources that scientists use in laboratories,
recognising that one institutions research tool may be anothers end product. NIH Report
on Research Tools (1998) op. cit.. They are used to find, refine or design and identify
something else that is sold in the marketplace. R. Blackburn in DOJ/FTC Proceedings
on the Pharmaceutical Industry: Business Perspectives on the Use and the Role of Patents
in the Biotechnology Industry, 26 February 2002.
Many research tools are expensive to develop and have significant competitive value
to the companies that own them. If institutions wish to gain a competitive advantage
from their exploitation, they are likely to limit access and restrict their use and disclosure.
This trend is also accompanied by the increasing use of the patent system to obtain proprietary rights for the research tools. There may be competing interests among those who
control the tools depending on whether they are scientists, university technology transfer

177

178

The interface of competition law and patents

While concerns relating to access are not new in the area of antitrust law, research tools are more complicated as they are not only end products whose
dissemination/distribution effects can readily be measured or witnessed, but
they are also tools for research, which are important in the pre-commercial stage
when the impact of the restricted access cannot be easily determined.
The problem in the case of research tools does not relate to the restriction of
a product or technology market, but rather the hindering of the innovation
process. The concern is that the lack of access may lead to reduced research
which would, in turn, lead to less innovation. Therefore, we are not concerned
with something that may already crystallise in a product or technology market,
but rather with something in even earlier stages of research and development.

professionals or private firms, and whether they are importers or exporters. See Chapters
2 and 3.
However, research tools are merely an example of what might be a general problem.
For example there may be similar exclusionary concerns in cases involving Pharmacy
Benefits Management (PBM) networks. See R. Levy, The Pharmaceutical Industry: A
Discussion of Competition and Antitrust Issues in an Environment of Change, Bureau
of Economic Staff Report, FTC March 1999. While until recently the doctors prescriptions were the most crucial factor in determining which drugs would be dispensed by
pharmacists, today pharmacies are usually part of PBM networks that administer the
drug benefits as part of health insurance plans to employers and others. This could give
rise to some concerns as drug companies now may acquire PBMs and the exchange of
information may allow for the monitoring of deviations of coordination in the prescription drug markets. In addition, this could raise the marginal costs of unintegrated drug
companies and lead to higher prices and lower level in prescription drug markets. A refusal to deal scenario may exist where C, an unintegrated pharmaceutical manufacturer,
has no substitutes for the marketing services of A and Bs downstream PBMs and A and
B have the incentive to coordinate to limit a companys ability to undermine collusion.
Foreclosure effects might also occur with regard to the exclusion of unintegrated PBMs
from the market, depending on the availability of ways for the unintegrated company to
avoid the exclusion.

For more information on pre-commercial stage patents see R.A. Epstein, Steady
the Course: Property Rights in Genetic Material, The Law School of Uni of Chicago,
working paper no 152, 2003 at http://ssrn.com/abstract_id=317101.
See In The Matter Between Mpho Makhathnini, Nelislwe Mthethwa, Musa Msomi,
Elijah Paul Musoke, Tom Myers, AIDS Healthcare Foundation Limited, and GlaxoSmithKline (Pty) Ltd, Glaxo Group Limited, Case Number 34/CR/Apr04, where the South
African courts found GlaxoSmithKlyne to have abused its dominant position by virtue
of excessive prices of drugs. See also South African Competition Tribunals decision and
order in Pharmaceutical Wholesalers and Glaxo Wellcome, case 68/IR/Jun00, 18 June
2003 at www.comptrib.co.za/decidedcases/pdf/68IRJUN00kinesis.pdf, and Case No.
15/CAC/Feb02.

Technology access problems in the biopharmaceutical industry

179

7.1.2 A Gap in the Patent System?


As shown in Chapter 3, the patent laws do not adequately provide for this possibility. While there are provisions on compulsory licensing and other limitations
on the breadth of the patent permitting use, such as the experimental use exemption, these are rarely used and usually address other concerns.
Compulsory licensing provisions, for example, as it was demonstrated, are
drafted to deal with more developed stages of research that have already led
to the development of products or technology which already warrant a patent.
The experimental use exemption is again usually concerned with experimenting on an invention in the sense of improvements, as opposed to experimenting
with.
In addition, while the right to health does have implications for patent law as
it affects access to drugs, it is unlikely that the right to health would be helpful
in the context of the innovation process as it is too far removed from the actual
results and overly speculative about the innovation process.
7.1.3 The More the Better? Optimal Market Structure for Innovation
It should also be noted that the desire to have broader access to fundamental
research tools is also based to some extent on the assumption that the more research paths undertaken the better.
While the economics of innovation and whether concentration or competition
is more conducive to innovation is far from clear, it is assumed that access would
be more desirable in some cases where it has been refused. When more risky
investment is required until there is a useful product, it may be socially desirable
to have many firms engaging in the next innovative step. Because this approach
involves some duplication of effort, it is not necessarily cost effective. However,
there may well be situations in which the patent owner would like to be the sole

See Chapter 3.
See Chapter 4.

See Commission Decision in Microsoft (2004) op. cit. para. 782 in which the
Commission stated that a refusal to supply would have the consequence of stifling innovation in the impacted market and of diminishing consumers choices by locking them
into a homogeneous Microsoft solution. As such it is particularly inconsistent with the
provisions of Art. 82(b) of the Treaty, hence, effectively endorsing a view of innovation
which suggests that technical development in the IT industry is best promoted by a
number of different firms innovating rather than one. S. Anderman, Does the Microsoft
Case offer a New Paradigm for the Exceptional Circumstances Test and Compulsory
Copyright Licenses under EC Competition Law? Presented at the Clasf Conference on
9 September 2004.


180

The interface of competition law and patents

developer of the final product but society would be better off if this were not
the case.
A significant amount of economic research has focused on the issue of
whether competition and potential competition are capable of increasing innovative activity. The findings are ambiguous in this regard. Some commentators
have argued that firms which are insulated from competition may choose a quiet
life. Yi has found that in the case of process innovations, as long as they are
not drastic, their benefit decreases in line with the number of firms under certain
conditions.10 Boone has concluded that if competition is intense and innovations
lead to major technological changes then small increases in competition may
quicken innovation as they force the leading firm to innovate in order to refrain
from losing its competitive advantage.11
On the other hand, other economic studies seem to support innovation by
large firms in concentrated markets. Schumpeter found that large firms are more
innovative than smaller firms, which could mean that in concentrated markets
there was more innovation taking place. This may be due to two factors.12 First,
innovative activity may be less costly for large firms as there are significant
economies of scale in innovation. Large firms may have more specialised resources undertaking many R&D projects which reduce the marginal costs of
innovation. As innovation involves significant fixed costs, these companies are
able to incur less average total costs, and they may have larger portfolios of
R&D, increasing the likelihood of success. Secondly, it might be the case that
firms obtain higher benefits from innovative effort as they diversify products,


R. Aoki and J. Small, Compulsory licensing of technology and the essential facilities doctrine, 16 Information Economics and Policy 23 (2004).

W.M. Cohen and R.C. Levin, Empirical Studies on Innovation and Market Structure, in R. Schmalensee and R.D. Willig (eds), Handbook of Industrial Organization,
North-Holland, Amsterdam (1989), p.1078; J. Lerner, An Empirical Exploration of a
Technology Rate, 28(2) Rand J. Econcs 228 (1997).

See K. Arrow, Economic Welfare and the Allocation of Resources for Innovation,
in pp.60926, R.R. Nelson (ed.), The Rate and Direction of Inventive Activity, New York:
New York, Princeton University Press (1962); S. De Santi and W. Cohen, Competition
to Innovate: Strategies for Proper Antitrust Assessments, in R. Dreyfuss et al. ed., Expanding the Boundaries of Intellectual Property, Oxford, Oxford University Press (2001);
ABA (2002) op. cit.
10
S. Yi (1999) op. cit.
11
J. Boone (2001) op. cit.
12
Ibid. See also F. Parisi, B. Depoorter (2002) op. cit. on oligopoly in complementary as opposed to substitutable products. See also R.A. Epstein, Steady the Course:
Property Rights in Genetic Material, The Law School of Uni. of Chicago, Working Paper
No. 152 (2003) on the marginal cost and double marginalisation problem. R.C. Dreyfuss,
Varying the Course in Patenting Genetic Material: A Counter-Proposal to Richard Epsteins Steady Course, NYU Law School, Public Law Research Paper No. 59 (2003).

Technology access problems in the biopharmaceutical industry

181

thus increasing the likelihood of discovery, and even the more effective marketing of new products.
Empirical evidence shows that large firms have developed a significant share
of innovation but in recent years small firms have also done so.13 Early studies
showed that R&D rose more than proportionately with firm size, however,
Scherer14 has shown that was up to some size level. Recent studies suggest that
large firms may actually be generating less innovation per dollar of R&D than
small firms.

7.2 Two possible avenues for increased


access to essential research tools
Increasing access to patented research tools could either be achieved through
patent law or through antitrust law.
7.2.1 Patent Law
Several proposals have been made as to how the patent system itself could be
changed to account for the problem of research tools.15 Professor Eisenberg had

13

ABA (2002) op. cit.


F.M. Scherer, Firm Size, Market Structure, Opportunity and the Output of Patented
Inventions, 55 American Economic Review 1097 (1965).
15
On open source proposals see R.X. Cringely, The True Believer: Can Mike Doyle
do to Microsoft what the rest of the computer industry and the Department of Justice
couldnt do? The Pulpit, 7 November, 2002; D. Burk, Open Source Genomics, 8 Boston
University Journal of Science and Technology Law 254 (Symposium on Bioinformatics
and Intellectual Property Law, 27 April, 2001, Boston, Mass. (Winter 2002)). S. Maurer,
Promoting and disseminating knowledge: the public/private interface, Washington DC,
National Research Council (2002). See specifically in the case of agricultural biotechnology: J.L. Kind, Concentration and Technology in Agricultural Input Industries, 2001,
US Department of Agriculture Economic Research Serve; Benkler, Coases Penguin, or,
Linux and The Nature of the Firm. 112 Yale L. J., Winter 20023; S. Maurer, New Institutions for Doing Science: From Databases to Open Source Biology, conference paper,
European Policy for Intellectual Property, University of Maastricht, November 2003,
available at http://ist-socrates.berkeley.edu/~scotch/maurer.htm.
On the interpretation of the term relating to in the experimental use exemption see
the European Commissions proposed Council Regulation on the Community Patent, 1
August 2000 (exempting acts done privately and for non-commercial purposes and
acts done for experimental purposes relating to the subject-matter of the patented invention); J.M. Mueller (2001) op. cit. p.38 refers to the possibility of interpreting the term
relating to broadly to include the ordinary use of patented research tools to research
downstream.
14

182

The interface of competition law and patents

proposed the expansion of the experimental use doctrine based on a distinction


between three types of cases.16
First, in cases involving use of a patented invention to verify that the requirement of enabling disclosure has been satisfied, the use should be exempt. This
situation is the least contentious and most countries allow such use.17 This type
of use, however, is unrelated to the problem of access to essential research
tools.
Secondly, in cases involving use of an invention having a primary or significant market among research users who are ordinary consumers of the
invention, the exemption should be inapplicable. In such cases, it was felt that
there should be a licence prior to use, as there should not normally be any access
problems.18
Finally, in cases where an improvement in the technological field of the patent
is concerned, there should not be a need for any licence in order to encourage
designing around patents. While the users would be infringers, there would be
limitations in the remedies available against them. The patent holder would not
be able to prevent use in such cases but would be entitled to a reasonable royalty
in some instances.
This situation is a variation of the compulsory licensing provisions as applicable to improvements and secondary dependent patents, although there is
usually no need for a licence or to petition for a compulsory licence in the
first place in the case of the experimental use exemption. From the start, the
remedies of the patentee are limited to a liability rather than a property
rule.19
This interpretation of the experimental use exemption, however, would still
not cover cases where access is needed to the research tool for research on

Others contend, however, that research tools should be excluded entirely from patenting. See public comments received from USPTO in response to its first round of Interim
Written Description Guidelines, published in June 1998 asserting that ESTs are genomic
research tools that should be available for unencumbered research to advance the public
good. Department of Commerce, Patent and Trademark Office, Revised Utility Examination Guidelines, 64 Fed. Reg. 71 (1999) 440.
16
R.S. Eisenberg, Patents and the Progress of Science: Exclusive Rights and Experimental Use, 56 U. Chi. L. Rev. 1017 (1989), pp.107478.
17
See Chapter 3.
18
It was believed that these tools could be readily licensed or bought on the open
market. The patentee will want to sell to these users they fall squarely within the
market for the patented invention. Ibid. p.1085.
19
On this distinction see G. Calabresi and D. Melamed, Property Rules, Liability
Rules and Inalienability: One View of the Cathedral, 85 Harv. L. Rev. 1089 (1972); I.
Ayres, E. Talley, Solomonic Bargaining: Dividing a Legal Entitlement to Facilitate
Coasean Trade, 104 Yale L. J. 1027, (1995).

Technology access problems in the biopharmaceutical industry

183

downstream products. They would fall into the second category of Professor
Eisenbergs model of the ordinary consumers.
The extension of the doctrine was also considered by the NIH Working Group,
who concluded that:
It is difficult to imagine how a broader research exemption could be formulated
without effectively eviscerating the value of patents on research tools. Researchers
are ordinary consumers of patented research tools, and if these consumers were exempt from patent infringement liability, the patent holder would have nowhere else
to turn to collect patent royalties. An excessively broad research exemption could
eliminate incentives for private firms to develop and disseminate new research tools
which could on the balance do more harm than good to the research enterprise.20

The difficulty with such a view, however, is that the assumption that such
workers are truly ordinary consumers of the tool is called into question. When
it becomes increasingly difficult for these consumers of the tool to obtain access, then to the extent the experimental use doctrine is based on that distinction,
it becomes questionable. When research tool transaction costs are severe
enough to impede or stop the development of new biomedical products, line
drawing between experimenting on and experimenting with is no longer
justified. In such cases access to the experimental use doctrine should not turn
on the relatively fine distinction between experimenting on or experimenting
with the patented invention.21
The arguments against an expanded experimental use exemption mirror to a
large extent the general arguments against a reduced patent scope. In this context, it is felt that any reduction in patent protection would lead to a reduction
in innovation.22 As argued in Chapter 5, however, the optimal balance between
initial and follow-on innovation is not known to any degree of precision. Although there may be some reduction in the development of new research tools
by forcing wider access, there may equally be more products developed by virtue of the broader access to those tools. The trade-off ultimately is an empirical
one.23
20

NIH Report on Research Tools (1998) op. cit. App. D-8.


J.M. Mueller, No Dilettante Affair: Rethinking the Experimental Use Exception to
Patent Infringement for Biomedical Research Tools, 76 Wash. L. Rev. 1 (2001), p.40.
22
See, for example, J.P. Karp, Experimental Use as Patent Infringement: The Impropriety of a Broad Exception, 100 Yale L. J. 2169 (1991), p.2181. The author contends
that an expansive experimental use exception, which threatens the patentees potential
for economic returns, would reduce inventive activity, particularly in those industries
that rely on patent protection.
23
See R.S. Eisenberg (1989) op. cit. pp.103031 who states that it is difficult to
determine the impact of a reduction in the breadth of patents on the incentives for investment, either through the research exemption or other limitations.
21

184

The interface of competition law and patents

In response, Mueller proposes the endorsement of a development use rule


which makes no distinction as to the type of use that is contemplated for the
tool.24 The only limitation would be that it must relate to the use of the patented
research tool, rather than the sale of which products physically incorporate the
patented invention.25
In such cases, he suggests that a reach-through royalty scheme should be applied whereby the user would be allowed to infringe the patents but then would
have to pay a royalty according to the ultimate commercial value of the products
developed. The research tool patent owner would acquire the right to a potentially commercially significant future royalty stream, while the tool user would
avoid the burdens of pre-use license negotiations, up-front payments and
blocked access to the proprietary research tools.26
According to Mueller, royalties should be paid for no longer than the total
period of the effective patent life, beginning on the first date of the sale of the
product developed.27 In addition, in cases where no product is developed, he
argues that a standardised schedule of royalty fees could be drawn up, similar
to the musical works model.28 He contends that calculating the royalty rate may
be more of a problem in theory than in practice.29
Similarly, Gilat claims that the experimental use doctrine may not be sufficient in the area of biotechnology industry, and for this reason a liability rule
might be required.
Indeed the fact that patents are granted on biotech basic research inventions seems
to require a more liberal experimental use exemption than that provided by traditional
patent law, as the effect of enforcing a patent right against research competitors might
be detrimental to progress, and it therefore appears that, in addition to the exemption
from infringement liability provided by the experiment exception, a specific liability
rule in respect of research use of patented inventions may be appropriate.30

24

J.M. Mueller (2001) op. cit. pp.5864.


Ibid. p.58. The author distinguishes between use and selling as the latter is not
exempted from liability.
26
Ibid. p.58.
27
Ibid. p.62.
28
See 17 USC 115 (Supp. IV 1998) (Scope of exclusive rights in non-dramatic
musical works: Compulsory License for making and distributing phonorecords). Once
the owner of a copyright for a non-dramatic musical work has sold the work to the public,
any other person has a compulsory license to record and sell the phonorecords of the
same work. See M. Leaffer, Understanding Copyright Law, New York, Bender, 8.7
(2nd edn, 1995) 4th edn (2004). A monthly statutory ceiling price must be paid for each
record distributed under the licence.
29
J.M. Mueller (2001) op. cit. p.65.
30
D. Gilat (1995) op. cit. p.81.
25

Technology access problems in the biopharmaceutical industry

185

In this context, antitrust may be a desirable safety net. It imposes a liability


rule in certain cases, while not requiring any change of the law.
7.2.2 A Role for Art. 82?
As a policy matter, antitrust limitations should be desirable unless they result
in a net decrease in innovation.31 The problem lies in the fact that there is no
clear formula to decide how much innovation is due to patent law and how much
can be attributed to antitrust law.
In some ways, antitrust law addresses the same concerns as the patent system,
namely the breadth of the exclusivity only, in light of the market conditions. In
the case of a controlling upstream innovation that impairs the progress of the
downstream innovation by virtue of limited licensing practices or a refusal to
deal, it would seem that it is possible to use antitrust law to judge when access
to such upstream innovation should be granted, and to compel it.32
A blanket antitrust exemption for all unilateral refusals to license IP, including refusals
used to prevent competition in complementary markets, may discourage innovation,
not only in the unprotected complementary markets, but also in the patented market.
This is because it would require entry at two levels if there is no viable competition
in the complementary market.33

As shown in Chapter 3, the TRIPS Agreement provides that compulsory licensing (CL) may be used to remedy cases in which a practice has been
determined anti-competitive in a court of law. In accordance with economic
theory, this was interpreted to mean that there is no justification for applying a
different antitrust threshold for cases involving IPRs, and that the application
of the competition law provisions remains intact.34

31
M. Lao, Unilateral Refusals to Sell or License IP and the Antitrust Duty to Deal,
9 Cornell J. L. & Pub. Policy 193 (1999).
32
While it is true that antitrust law presumes that the market will fix failures, it is
contemplated here that antitrust should work as a safety valve if the market fails to fix
an imperfection and in the absence of a patent mechanism to correct it.
33
M. Lao (1999) op. cit. p.201.
34
Whether one chooses to interpret this as the use of antitrust to address patent regulatory failures or merely to be a co-determinant of patent scope, makes little difference
in practice. See D.S. Karjala, Copyright Protection of Operating Software, Copyright
Misuse ad Antitrust, 9 Cornell J. L. & Pub. Poly 161 (1999), who states in the context
of copyright and the relation with antitrust: Although the copyright courts have correctly
concluded that an antitrust violation is not a predicate of copyright misuse, there is no
reason in principle why the courts could not treat copyright misuse by someone with
market power as an antitrust violation the courts tailor the scope of copyright protection all the time in an effort to further the underlying copyright policies. This is not

186

The interface of competition law and patents

Article 82 has been used to condemn unilateral refusals to deal in several


cases, some even involving IPRs. There has not yet been any case before the
ECJ, however, regarding early pre-commercial biopharmaceutical patents.
Nevertheless, this provision may still be helpful.
In Chapter 6, the duty to deal under Art. 82 was analysed. CL was analysed
in terms of four factors: indispensability, the introduction of a new product, the
elimination of competition on a downstream market, and the absence of objective justification.
7.2.2.1 Indispensability
It was shown that the Court has placed particular emphasis on whether access
to the product or process is indispensable to carry on business.35 The test is
whether there are products or services which constitute alternative solutions,
even if they are less advantageous, and whether there are technical, legal or
economic obstacles capable of making it impossible or at least unreasonably
difficult for any undertaking seeking to operate in the market to create, possibly
in cooperation with other operators, the alternative products or services.36
In the specific case of research tools, the test will focus on whether access to
the former is truly indispensable/essential to conduct research on the downstream market.37 In addition, the high threshold should be preserved if the duty
to deal is to remain exceptional. The threshold should be set high enough to
ensure that the resulting static gains are large enough to outweigh such dynamic
losses.38
While indispensability ultimately is to be judged on the facts of the case, there
may be certain factors, as seen in Chapter 6, which will militate in favour or
against such a finding. The existence of high sunk costs and/or incentives to innovate may be two such factors.39 Furthermore, the good in question must really
be unique, central to the operation on the market and without any feasible
alternative.

necessarily easy but the only fundamentally new aspect suggested here is that antitrust
rather than copyright supplies the hook for devising remedies p.189.
35
See Chapter 6.
36
Case C-418/01 IMS, 29 April 2004, para. 28.
37
There may be many instances in which IP products or technologies could be regarded as indispensable as traditionally judged under the essential facilities doctrine.
This is because it may not make economic sense to duplicate them and they may be of
national economic significance, similar in some ways to land facilities. R. Aoki and J.
Small (2004) op. cit. p.27.
38
Ibid. p.28.
39
See Chapter 6.

Technology access problems in the biopharmaceutical industry

187

7.2.2.2 Preventing the emergence of a new product for which there is


potential consumer demand
In IMS, the liberal position adopted by the Court can be seen from the following
statement:
Therefore, the refusal by an undertaking in a dominant position to allow access to a
product protected by copyright, where that is indispensable for operating on a secondary market, may be regarded as abusive only where the undertaking which requested
the license does not intend to limit itself essentially to duplicating the goods or services already offered on the secondary market by the owner of the copyright, but
intends to produce new goods or services not offered by the owner of the right and
for which there is a potential consumer demand.40

Following the broad interpretation of IMS, the new product requirement


would easily be met in cases where access to research tools is required to research on the downstream market in an attempt to develop technology further.
The reference to the intention to produce new goods or services, as distinct from
their actual production, may hence be of particular significance to the biopharmaceutical industry, where it is felt that access may be warranted in the
pre-commercial stage in some cases even if the research is in its early stages
and possibly even still in the pipeline.
This would allow for a CL to be ordered for certain indispensable research
tools while taking into account that a more extensive use would most likely lead
to more products but not necessarily so. Hence this will provide access to research tools to be used for further research irrespective of what that later leads
to. This effectively involves endorsing a wider definition of new product to
include potential innovation,41 and indispensability, which would be viewed
from the perspective of enabling further innovation. In addition, as clarified by
the Commission in Microsoft, demand for that potential new product also only
needs to be potential.42
7.2.2.3 Elimination of competition on a downstream or neighbouring
market/two-market requirement
As regards the two-market requirement, as shown in Chapter 6, the Court
adopted a wide interpretation: it is sufficient that a potential market or even

40

IMS Case (2004) op. cit. para. 49.


This rests on the assumption that more research lines may be more conducive to
innovation. See section 7.1.3 on the relationship between market structure and
innovation.
42
See Commission reference to Ladbroke and the essential facilities doctrine in para.
552 where reference is made to specific, constant and regular potential demand.
41

188

The interface of competition law and patents

hypothetical market can be identified. Such is the case where the products or
services are indispensable in order to carry on a particular activity .43
Hence, it would seem that this case can be used as a precedent that two markets in an antitrust sense are not required, and an obligation to deal will be based
on the essentiality of an input for the operation of a market. Therefore, it effectively extended harm to competition to potential or hypothetical markets.
In the example of research tools which require access to potentially develop
some downstream product, the doctrine remains applicable, and if truly indispensable the research tools could be the object of a CL. In IMS, the Court stated
that it is determinative that two different stages of production may be identified and that they are interconnected, the upstream product is indispensable in
as much as for supply of the downstream product.
This is also consistent with the innovation markets approach, in the sense that
the court extended its interpretation of the elimination of competition not only
to existing or potential product or technology markets, but also to innovation
markets not yet in existence.44
7.2.2.4 The absence of an objective justification
In the Microsoft case, the Commission confirmed that intellectual property
rights are not in a different category to property rights as such45 and, therefore,
they could not amount to an objective justification. Hence, the fact that research
tools are protected by patents of itself would not negate the duty to deal if it
arose. This is in line with recent competition findings, whereby the fact that
something involves IPRs does not exempt conduct from competition control.46

43

IMS (2004) op. cit. para. 44.


See IMA at section 7.2.3.2. See also J.T. Lang, European Community Antitrust
Law: Innovation Markets and High Technology Industries, 20 Fordham International L.
J. 717 (1997).
45
Microsoft (2004) op. cit. para. 550.
46
See, for example, the recent Commission decision fining AstraZeneca (Commission press release IP/05/737) for abusing its dominance by misusing the patent system.
Patent misuse is a known defence in the USA according to which a patent holder might
be prevented from asserting its patent if such have been obtained by breaching antitrust
laws or illegally extending the term of the patent. AstraZeneca in this instance abused
its dominance by making misrepresentations to certain national patent offices with a
view to obtaining supplementary protection certificates, as well as strategically misusing
procedures to block the entry of generic products or parallel traders. Similarly, a UK
court judge stated that the enforcement of patent rights could constitute abusive conduct
in certain cases, where a dominant undertaking brings action which: cannot reasonably
be considered as an attempt to establish its rights and can only serve to harass the opposite party, and is conceived to eliminate competition: Sandisk Corporation v Koninklijke
Phillips Electronics NV and Others [2007] EWHC 332 Ch.
44

Technology access problems in the biopharmaceutical industry

189

7.2.3.1 The impact of Art. 82 duty to deal with case-law on the patent
system
Article 82 can effectively be used to grant access to an indispensable input for
further research where this has been refused. In this way, it can address problems
associated with the hindrance of potential technology and potentially restricted
access to necessary inputs. It involves recognition of the importance of potential
innovation, and bases the remedy on treating IP just as any other case, while
adopting a broader definition of a new product and of secondary markets.
Although the economics of cumulative innovation fail to provide a clear formula, none the less, they affirm that concentration may not necessarily lead to
more innovation; the granting therefore of an unqualified exclusive right (and
thereby immunising IP) may not actually be conducive to innovation.47 In the
same way as the patent system attempts to balance initial innovation with follow-on innovation through the patent length and breadth, competition law may
also be used to achieve this objective.
In this way, antitrust can be seen as interchangeable as a remedy with patent
CL provisions, only with a difference in threshold; one requiring a patent of
significant technological advance of considerable economic interest, and the
other requiring the existence and abuse of a dominant position by virtue of a
refusal to grant access to an indispensable/essential input as set against the
market conditions, respectively.
Noticeably, the new product rule imports in Art. 82 also the consideration of
ensuring some advantage from access. None the less, the definition of the new
product is much broader than the one in patent law, as it is not limited to patented
products or processes constituting a significant technological advance, and it
can even relate to potential goods. It is not restricted to dependent patents, but
may be applied to downstream innovation as distinct from improvements.48
It should be noted, however, that market definition will preserve its centrality
as it will in turn determine the availability of substitutes, the risk of elimination
of competition and hence also the indispensability of the product or process in
question. The application of antitrust control would be limited to cases in which
the monopoly is effectively over a variety of product lines and in which there
is a series of dependent inventions, without a real alternative in the market.
The advantage of the antitrust application of a duty to deal is that it is set
against the market conditions in order to ascertain: the extent to which access
to the input is indeed necessary in view of the alternatives and substitutes; the

47
See also the endorsement of this view with the introduction of the innovation
markets approach in the USA discussed below, at section 7.2.2.2.
48
See above at section 7.2.2 on the new product requirement and the IMS definition.
See also Chapter 3 on patent CL provisions.

190

The interface of competition law and patents

extent to which the consumers will benefit by virtue of access; and the extent
to which the market has proven that the patent controls not only a specific
product or process but indeed a whole area of endeavour.
This approach effectively advocates a more explicit consideration of followon innovation in the application of antitrust analysis and this may apply not only
for the application of the duty to deal provisions, but also for investigations of
cross-licences and patent pools, and potentially for mergers.49 Indeed, in the
EU, unilateral restraints on innovation have been condemned on several occasions,50 either because they involved the acquisition of control over potentially
competitive innovations,51 the prevention of downstream innovation,52 or the
foreclosure of innovation by raising barriers to entry.53
In brief, the issue of research tools introduces a new element into the analysis
of refusals to deal or to grant access. The new element centres on the fact that
it is not concerned with the restriction of a downstream existing product or
technology market, either by virtue of distribution or otherwise, but rather it is
concerned with downstream research which may or may not lead to new products which could either be seen as future product markets or, in some cases, as
new innovation markets.
In the case of research tools, access is mandated for potential innovation and
this, similar to the traditional cases where access is mandated to a facility, contains assumptions about the type of structure that is more conducive to market
developments (whether product, technological or innovation).54

49
See, for example, innovation markets approach in merger review and the consideration paid to potential competition. J.H. Barton, Patents and Antitrust: A rethinking in
light of patent breadth and sequential innovation, 65 Antitrust L. J. 44 (1997), who proposes that attention should also be paid to technology lines and not only product market
or technology or innovation markets. Clearly there are antitrust issues when a license
or merger concentrates control over product lines or combines into one management
several patents covering complementary ways of manufacturing a specific product.
50
See M. Dolmans, Antitrust and the Suppression of Technology in the US and Europe: Is there a Remedy? Restrictions on Innovation: An EU Antitrust Approach, 66
Antitrust L. J. 455 (1998).
51
Case 88/501 Tetra Pak I (BTG license) [1988] OJ I.272/27.
52
Magill (1995) op. cit.
53
Microsoft decision (2004) op. cit.
54
In conventional antitrust enforcement there is a broad consensus on the relationship between market structure and market performance. In contrast, this is seen as more
contentious in innovation market enforcement and, for this reason, these structural assumptions are seen as being more dangerous. In view of the role of technological change,
however, in todays economy conventional enforcement may even require judges to
predict the inherently unpredictable course of future technology and so the differences
between the two approaches should not be exaggerated. R.W. Davis, Innovation Markets
and Merger Enforcement: Current Practice in Perspective, 71 Ant. L. J. 677 (2003),

Technology access problems in the biopharmaceutical industry

191

7.2.3.2 An innovation sensitive approach: innovation markets in


Art. 82?
A similar approach considering innovation and the type of structure that is more
conducive to it can be seen in the application of other antitrust provisions, specifically in the application of the Technology Transfer Block Exemption
Regulation (TTBER) and in merger analysis.55

p.681. See also J. Kattan, Antitrust Considerations in Innovation-Driven Markets, 21


Can.-US L. J. 115 (1995), p.117; D. McGowan, Innovation, Uncertainty, and the Stability in Antitrust Law, 16 Berkeley Tech. L. J. 729 (2001); I. Knable Gotts and J.G. Kraus,
Antitrust Review of New Economy Acquisitions, Antitrust, Fall 2000, p.59.
55
The innovation markets approach has been discussed most extensively in the USA
where it was formally recognised as an enforcement tool for the first time in the IP Licensing Guidelines (1995) op. cit. This was then extended to a broader variety of
competitor collaborations by the FTC/DOJ, Antitrust Guidelines for Collaborations
Among Competitors (2000), reprinted in 4 Trade Reg. Rep (CCH). Since then it has been
the subject of many enforcement actions of the Antitrust Division in conjunction with
the conventional potential competition analysis such as US v General Motors Corp. No.
93-530 (D. Del. Filed 23 March 1998), US v Lockheed Martin and Northrop Grumman
(D.D.C. filed 23 March, 1998). In addition, the innovation effects have been the key
factor of the decisions in several FTC enforcement records, especially concerning the
pharmaceutical industry in view of the FDA collaboration in assessing the likely effect
of each innovation effort. See J. Kattan, After the IP Guidelines: Trends in Intellectual
Property Antitrust Enforcement, Antitrust, Summer 1997, p.26. See, for example, FTC
innovation markets enforcement actions Roche/Genentech, Roche Holding Ltd, 113 FTC
1086 (1990); American Home Products/American Cyanamid, American Home Prods.
Corp. FTC Docket No. C-3557 (1995); Sensormatic/Knogo, Sensormatic Elec. Corp.,
FTC Docket No. C- 3572 (1995); Glaxo/Burroughs Wellcome, Glaxo Inc., 119 FTC 815
(1995); Upjohn/Pharmacia, The Upjohn Co. 121 FTC 44 (1996); Ciba-Geigy/Sandoz,
Ciba-Geigy Ltd, 123 FTC 842 (1997); Baxter/Immuno, Baxter Intl, Inc., 123 FTC 904
(1997); Pfizer/Warner-Lambert, Pfizer Inc., FTC Docket No. C-3957 (2000); Hoechst/
Rhone-Poulenc, Hoechst AG, FTC Docket No. C-3929 (2000).
In the EU, the European Commission has two main concerns in the area of innovation:
first, patents may pose considerable entry barriers to competitors on future markets; and
secondly, mergers between firms that are active in similar R&D projects must not become
dominant actors that are capable of eliminating future competition in related markets,
and thus slowing the innovation process itself. J. Pons, Innovation and Competition, A
View from the European Commission, speech for the 50th anniversary of the Japan Trade
Commission in Tokyo 1st December 1997, published in the EC Competition Policy /
DGIV/speech/eight/en/sp980xx.htm February 1998.
Hence, Commission Regulation 772/2004, on the application of article 81(3) of the
Treaty to categories of technology transfer agreements, 2004 OJ L213/11, allows the
Commission to withdraw the benefit of block exemption where the licensed products are
not exposed to effective competition in the licensed territory. This principle was applied
in Case 88/501 Tetra Pak I (BTG license) [1988] OJ I.272/27 where the licensee was
found to have abused its dominant position and was forced to give up the exclusive rights
attached to its licence.

192

The interface of competition law and patents

In the context of mergers, the innovation markets approach aims to assess the
effects of a merger on the incentive for R&D and innovation. It assesses the extent to which an output in the upstream R&D market may be restrained and
whether the latter may lead to adverse competitive effects on the downstream
product market at a later stage.
The approach is based on two factors:
First that antitrust ought to be concerned about agreements and transactions that are
likely to result in a reduction in resources devoted to research and development in
definable lines of research, or in the elimination of one or more parallel research
tracks, when such a reduction of resources, or elimination of a line of research, is
likely to have an adverse effect on price or non-price competition in a product market at some time in the future (whether or not the product market in question exists
or does not exist at the time when enforcement action is taken); and second, that
the doctrine of potential competition does not suffice to address the adverse competitive effects of many agreements and transactions that reduce competition in
innovation.56

The concerns of the innovation markets approach are similar to those found
in CL as it seeks to encourage multiple research paths by ensuring that essential
innovation tools remain de-concentrated even if this is only to protect innovation
on a research/pipeline level as distinct from commercialisable products.
This approach is contentious,57 as unlike traditional oligopoly theory applied
to markets for existing products, there is no firm basis in economics to support
the presumption that an anti-competitive reduction in innovation would result
from a reduction in the number of competitors attempting to innovate.58
Similarly, there have been several cases where mergers have raised concerns in the
field of R&D and innovation. Commission Decisions Shell-Montedison, OJ 1994 L.
332/49, M.555 Glaxo-Wellcome and others, OJ 1995 L. 2985, Crown Cork OJ 1995 L
75/39, Ciba-GeigySandoz OJ 1996 C.102/737, M.984 DuPont-ICI, OJ 1997 L. 2985,
M.468 MSG-Media Services OJ 1994 L. 364/01, M.877 Boeing-McDonnell-Douglas OJ
1997 C.59/877. In all of these cases, a divestiture or licence remedy was imposed. However, the Commission has also allowed collaborations where the agreements contained
some efficiencies, such as Konsortium OJ 1990 L. 228/31.
56
R.W. Davis, Innovation Markets and Merger Enforcement: Current Practice in
Perspective, 71 Ant. L. J. 677 (2003) pp.6778
57
Criticism and more extensive analysis of the use of the approach is beyond the
scope for present purposes. For alternative views on the approach see T.N. Dahdoud and
J.F. Mongoven, The Shape of Things to Come: Innovation Market Analysis in Merger
Cases, 64 Antitrust L. J. 405, 1996; M.H. Morse, The Limits of Innovation Markets, at
www.dbr.com; E. Kwoka, Non-Incumbent Competition: Mergers Involving Constraining
and Prospective Competitors, 52 Case W. Res. L. Rev. 173 (2001).
58
D.L. Wald and D. L. Feinstein, Merger Enforcement in Innovation Markets: The
Latest Chapter Genzyme/Novazyme, The Antitrust Source, July 2004, p.4. On a debate
between the optimal market structure for innovation see section 7.1.3. above. See also

Technology access problems in the biopharmaceutical industry

193

The novelty of the approach, as confirmed in the recent Genzyme/Novazyme59


merger, lies in the fact that there may be an antitrust violation despite the absence
of an existing goods market and the lack of clarity on the link between market
structure and innovation. In theory, it is possible that a merger may not injure
actual or potential competition in any relevant product market but nevertheless
it harms consumers by reducing competition in innovation.60 For example, this
may occur if the parties in the merger are among the few or only likely potential
entrants into a product market that does not exist at the time of the merger.61
However, the innovation markets approach should be subject to a strict factual
analysis to establish whether innovation is likely to be adversely affected or
R. Gilbert and W. Tom, Is Innovation King at the Antitrust Agencies? The Intellectual
Property Guidelines Five Years Later, 69 Antitrust L. J. 43 (2001), p.83, who concludes
that there is only anecdotal evidence to support the view that competition enhances R&D
efforts. See also D. Carlton and R. Gertner, Intellectual Property, Antitrust and Strategic
Behaviour, University of Chicago, National Bureau of Economic Research, Working
Paper No. W8976, May 2002, p.10 , reprinted in A. Jaffe and J. Lerner, Innovation Policy
and the Economy, Vol.3, MIT Press (2003); neither theory nor empirical work provides
any general justification for an antitrust merger policy aimed at preserving competition
in R&D markets. R. Rapp, The Misapplication of the Innovation Market Approach to
Merger Analysis, 64 Antitrust L. J. 19 (1995); R.J. Gilbert and S.C. Sunshine, The Use
of Innovation Markets: A Reply to Hay, Rapp and Hoerner, 64 Antitrust L. J. 75 (1994);
who argue that the lack of clarity regarding the link between market structure and innovation is not as important as Rapp contends; D. Mc Gowan, Innovation, Uncertainty, and
Stability in Antitrust Law, 16 Berkeley Tech. L. J. 729, (2001).
59
See FTC 13 January 2004 closing the investigation of Genzyme Corporations
acquisition of Novazyme Pharmaceuticals in 2001. FTC Press Release, FTC Closes its
Investigation of Genzyme Corporations 2001 Acquisition of Novazyme Pharmaceuticals,
Inc., at www.ftc.gov/opa/2004/01/genzyme.htm; Statement of Chairman T.J. Muris, in
the Matter of Genzyme Corporation/Novazyme Pharmaceuticals, Inc., at www.ftc.gov/
os/2004/01/murisgenzymestmt.pdf; Dissenting Statement of Commissioner M.W.
Thompson, Genzyme Corporations Acquisition of Novazyme Pharmaceuticals, at www.
ftc.gov/os/2004/01/thompsongenzymestmt.pdf; Commissioner P.J. Harbour Statement
available at www.ftc.gov/os/2004/01/harbourgenzymestmt.pdf. For an analysis, see D.
L. Wald and D.L. Feinstein, Merger Enforcement in Innovation Markets: The Latest
chapter Genzyme/Novazyme, The Antitrust Source, July 2004; P. Balto and S. Sher,
Refining the Innovation Focus: The FTCs Genzyme Decision, Antitrust magazine, 2004,
p.28.
60
R.J. Gilbert and S.C. Sunshine, Incorporating Dynamic Efficiency Concerns in
Merger Analysis: The Use of Innovation Markets, 63 Antitrust L. J. 567 (1995); G.A.
Hay, Innovations in Antitrust Enforcement, 64 Antitrust L. J. 7 (1995).
61
This corresponds to the case of Genzyme/Novazyme, FTC Press Release, FTC
Closes its Investigation of Genzyme Corporations 2001 Acquisition of Novazyme Pharmaceuticals, Inc., at www.ftc.gov/opa/2004/01/genzyme.htm. See also R.W. Davis
(2003) op. cit. For further examples, see also R. Gilbert, Should Antitrust Enforcers Rely
on Potential Analysis or the Concept of Innovation Markets? at www.ftc.gov/opp/global/gilbert1.htm.

194

The interface of competition law and patents

enhanced by consolidation. This involves recognising that collaborations are


often pro-competitive and that it is paramount in determining whether independent R&D efforts are close substitutes. In making this determination, attention
should be paid to the nature, scope and magnitude of their R&D efforts; their
access to financial support; their access to intellectual property, skilled personnel, or other specialized assets; their timing; and their ability, either acting alone
or through others, to successfully commercialize innovations.62
Merger control, in this case, is used as means to ensure that R&D is not overly
concentrated so that downstream potential markets may develop, and remedies
such as divestiture and CL are used to achieve this result. In a similar way, Art.
82 duty to deal case-law could be used to ensure that R&D is not suppressed
by the control of essential inputs in the R&D process by a few dominant firms
with the discretion and possible motive to deny or reduce access to such
inputs.
Antitrust law aims to promote not only price competition and output maximisation of existing products, but also industrial progress, therefore, practices
which limit such progress pose problems for antitrust, either in the application
of Arts 81 and 82 or in merger analysis.63 As in the case of mergers, the use of
innovation markets analysis assesses the likelihood of delay in or elimination
or reduction in quality or diversity of innovation as a result of decreased levels
of competition in innovation. A corollary of this is that unilateral practices with
the same effect will also be reviewed under Art. 82.64
In addition, this approach is particularly appealing in biopharmaceutical industry in view of the tight regulatory requirements. These permit competition
authorities in cooperation with the regulatory authorities, to forecast the effects
of exclusion or consolidation. For example in the USA the cooperation between
the FDA and the FTC provides extensive information on the status, approach
and likely effect of each innovation effort that might have been difficult to
obtain otherwise.65 Therefore, it may be more feasible to determine on a factual
basis which research tools are truly indispensable.
62
FTC/DOJ Guidelines for Collaboration Among Competitors (2000) op. cit. 4.3
These may also be the relative considerations in determining indispensability under Art.
82.
63
R.W. Davis (2003) op. cit., p.682.
64
In the same way that a merger may lead to increased consolidation, similarly a
refusal to deal may lead to the elimination of all competition as prohibited in certain
cases by Art. 82. This application of Art. 82 may also be seen as the other side of the
TTBER (2004) op. cit., which exempts certain types of agreements between competitors
under Art. 81.
65
FTC, Office of Policy Planning, Anticipating the 21st Century: Competition Policy
in the New High-Tech Global Marketplace, 1996, available at www.ftc.fov/opp/hitech/
global.htm.

Technology access problems in the biopharmaceutical industry

195

7.2.3.3 Conclusions on compulsory licensing as a safety net


While it would seem that much uncertainty surrounds fundamental questions
in this area, the importance of CL as a means of addressing follow-on innovation
considerations should not be underestimated. To the extent that neither statutory
nor case law establishes clearly the legal scope of an IP grant, one should also
look to policy concerns in determining whether a unilateral refusal to license
should ever be considered an antirust violation.66 As it is questionable whether
innovation incentives are sensitive to the narrow refusal to deal liability, the
benefits may far outweigh the cost.67
The recognition of the existence of CL under antitrust law to remedy a situation of blocked follow-on innovation as a last resort safety net (whether this is
seen as remedying a perceived patent failure or simply balancing the system as
initially contemplated) would seem to be a more feasible and indeed more desirable option. While competition law is not the only instrument to improve the
balance, it does provide a means of enhancing the innovation/access balance.68
A major disadvantage of this approach is the fact that it relies on courts to
determine what constitutes a reasonable royalty. None the less, it would seem
that this is more problematic in theory, rather than in practice, as the courts are

66
There is no definitive test for dividing the optimal level of protection for IP.
Logically the law should not place antitrust constraints on a monopolists right to refuse
to license if such constraints would undermine the IP laws. Conversely, the law should
not give IP holders the carte blanche to refuse to license if that would result in frustrating
the very objectives that IP laws seek to achieve. M. Lao (1999) op. cit. p.210.
67
See Chapter 5 on alleged harm to incentives to innovate. See also C. Springman,
Competition and IP Law and Policy in the Knowledge-Based Society: Is there a Cause
for Concern about Unilateral refusals to Deal? 1 May 2002, DOJ/FTC Hearings on IP
and Competition Law. The author questions whether innovation incentives are sensitive
to narrow refusal to deal liability, leading to a significant reduction in incentives across
industries. He also refers to Klemperers model (P. Klemperer, How Broad Should the
Scope of Patent Protection Be? 21 Rand J. Econcs 113 (1990)) that suggests that a small
reduction in the patent holders right to profit may reduce deadweight loss even more.
Hence, the assumption that the IP right to exclude is complete may prove to be incorrect.
A similar argument is levelled with regard to the commensurability and proportionality
of the incentive to innovate and the benefit form immunity. See A. Arora, Competition
and IP Law and Policy in the Knowledge-Based Society: Is there a Cause for Concern
about Unilateral Refusals to Deal? 1 May, 2002, DOJ/FTC Hearings on IP and Competition Law, and D.J. Gerber (1988) op. cit.
See also T.C. Bailey (2001) op. cit. p.12 Pointing to the fact that compulsory licensing
will lead to a less-than-maximum level of research and development is not dispositive
because the social cost of providing those additional units of research may outweigh
their social utility. There is no reason to assume that the present level of research activity is in fact the socially optimal level.
68
An alternative may be a patent compulsory licensing provision in the case of
necessary inputs for follow-on or downstream innovation.

196

The interface of competition law and patents

used to determining infringement damages on a regular basis.69 In general, it is


left up to the parties to reach an agreement within a specific period, however,
failing this, the royalty fee may be set by an expert.70
A reasonable royalty fee covers costs as well as a reasonable profit taking the
market value of the innovation into account amongst other things.71 It is believed
that royalty payments, particularly in the case of information goods, allow
greater choice [than fixed fees] among profits and consumer welfare in the final
good market72 and permit flexibility so as to prevent as far as possible the potential to cause unreasonable loss of income to the copyright owner.73 So, for
example, in a case involving whether the level of royalties charged for an IP licence were excessive, the Advocate-General indicated that the cost/price
analysis would not be appropriate in the context of copyright licensing as the
cost of creating a work of the imagination is impossible to determine; the ECJ
simply compared the rates with those charged by other copyright management
societies in other Member States.74
The shortcoming of such an approach may be that the enforcement costs are
so high and the procedure so lengthy that it effectively discourages parties from
pursuing a compulsory licensing action, and instead diverts research to other
areas.75 If this proves to be the case in practice, then the alternative of enacting
a specific patent provision for research tools should be considered.76
7.2.4 Conclusion: A Human Rights Approach to Competition Law?
In conclusion, it should be noted, that the right to health not only affects patent
law but may also increasingly affect the interpretation and application of competition law. For example, in South Africa, the Competition Commission found
69

J. H. Barton (1997) op. cit.


See Check List for Fast Track Compulsory Licensing, in J. Love, Implementing
TRIPS Safeguards with Particular Attention to Administrative Models for Compulsory
Licensing of Patents, WHO Meeting in Harare, Zimbabwe, 21 August 2001.
71
However, the royalty may not be at discriminatory rates that would violate Art.
82(c) prohibiting dissimilar conditions for equivalent transactions. None the less, in
considering which rates are discriminatory consideration is paid to, amongst other things,
the differences in the costs of licensing, lost profits, other business relations, and different
end-uses.
72
R. Aoki and J. Small (2004) op. cit. p.28.
73
WTO, US Section 110(5) of the US Copyright Act, Panel Report of 15 June 2000,
WT/DS160/R, para. 6.229.
74
Case 402/85 Basset v SACEM [1987] ECR 1747.
75
See, for example, in the USA where it is estimated that parties spend more than
$1 million to litigate a patent dispute. See J. Love (2001) op. cit.
76
An alternative to this may be the endorsement of a rebuttable presumption in favour of compulsory licensing.
70

Technology access problems in the biopharmaceutical industry

197

GlaxoSmithKline and Boehringer Ingelheim to have abused their dominant


position by virtue of excessive pricing in respect of ritonavir, lamivudine,
ritonavir+lamivudine and neviparine.77
More specifically, the parties were found to have violated the provisions of
the Competition Act of 1998 which prohibit excessive pricing (s. 8(a)), refusing access to essential facilities (s. 8(b)) and exclusionary acts that have an
anti-competitive effect that outweighs technological efficiency or other procompetitive gains (s. 8(c)).78 Hence, the abuse also consisted of refusal to
grant licences to generic manufacturers in return for a reasonable royalty. It
was found that this would have been feasible and also beneficial to consumers
as it would lead to lower prices.
The South African case shows that competition law may be interpreted in line
with the human rights obligations and, more specifically, with the goal of striving towards the highest attainable standard of health. Excessive pricing and
anti-competitive refusals to deal, amongst other things, should therefore be examined within the context of the health implications at stake. If access to drugs
is disproportionately restricted due to pricing measures, private companies may
be found to be in violation of the competition provisions.79

77
In The Matter Between Mpho Makhathnini, Nelislwe Mthethwa, Musa Msomi,
Elijah Paul Musoke, Tom Myers, AIDS Healthcare Foundation Limited, and GlaxoSmithKline (Pty) Ltd, Glaxo Group Limited, Case Number 34/CR/Apr04, in which the South
African courts found GlaxoSmithKlyne to have abused its dominant position by virtue
of the excessive pricing of drugs. See also South African Competition Tribunals decision
and order in Pharmaceutical Wholesalers and Glaxo Wellcome, case 68/IR/Jun00, 18
June 2003 at www.comptrib.co.za/decidedcases/pdf/68IRJUN00kinesis.pdf.
See Competition Commission finds pharmaceutical firms in contravention of the
Competition Act, 16 October 2003, available at http://www.cptech.org/ip/health/sa/
cc10162003.html and Competition Commission concludes an agreement with pharmaceutical firms, 10 December 2003, available at http://www.cptech.org/ip/health/sa/
cc12102003.html.
78
Ibid. The terms of the settlement included: (1) extend the voluntary licence granted
to Aspen Pharmacare in October 2001 in respect of the public sector to include the private
sector; (2) grant up to three more voluntary licences on terms no less favourable than
those granted to Aspen Pharmacare, based on reasonable criteria which include registration with the Medicines Control Council and the meeting of safety and efficacy
obligations; (3) permit the licensees to export the relevant antiretroviral drugs to subSaharan African countries; (4) where the licensee does not have manufacturing capability
in South Africa, GSK will permit the importation of the drugs for distribution in South
Africa; (5) permit licensees to combine the relevant ARV with other antiretroviral medicines; and (6) charge royalties of no more than 5 per cent of the net sales of the relevant
ARVs
79
See Statement by Consumer Project on Technology Concerning an alleged prohibited practice in terms of section 49B(2)(a) of the Competition Act 89 of 1998, at www.
cptech/ip/health/cl/recent-examples.html.

198

The interface of competition law and patents

In this way, specific health concerns associated with the effect of patents in
the biopharmaceutical industry may be mitigated by competition law and the
obligations relating to the right to health.
This interpretation of competition law, however, is more likely in cases involving dissemination concerns where the effect on health would be apparent,80
rather than in cases such as research tools where the effects on health are more
indirect and can only be speculated.81 None the less, they may affect the compulsory licensing provisions in the sense of lowering the indispensability
threshold and may lead more easily to a finding that access to certain research
tools should be mandated.
In the IMS case, the interpretation of the new product requirement as extending to intention to produce new goods, and the interpretation of a market as
including a potential or even hypothetical market could be seen as a step in
this direction. Adopting a more innovation sensitive approach to competition
law and the particularities of certain innovation-based industries such as biopharmaceuticals could in this sense also be seen as in line with the obligation of
states to strive towards the highest attainable standard of health.
Consistent with the above, in the Discussion Paper on the application of Art.
82 to exclusionary abuses it is stated that when it comes to refusal to deal with
IPR: a refusal to licence an IPR protected technology which is indispensable
as a basis for follow-on innovation by competitors may be abusive even if the
80
See, for example, in 1973 when the Monopolies Commission in the UK required
Roche to lower the price of its patented Librium and Valium to the NHS. Chlordiazepoxide and Diazepam (H.C. 197, 1973). The Monopolies and Mergers Commission was the
forerunner of the present Competition Commission.
81
As explained above, the crucial element in the case of research tools is the indispensability of the input for downstream innovation. Classical antitrust cases in the
biopharmaceutical industry, however, have rather been concerned with products which
were present on the market. In this context, the Commission has distinguished between
the markets for the production and sale of approved products, R&D into new therapeutic
compounds and wholesale distribution of medicines. Drug markets usually correspond
to the therapeutic classes, although reimbursement policies are also relevant. In the case
of research tools however, the novel element of the analysis is the future potential innovation element. In addition, unlike traditional antitrust cases where markets are still quite
fragmented along national lines in this industry, with prices differing according to the
pricing policies of each Member State, in the case of research tools, the market may
consist of the global innovation market. See J. Gatti, Mergers, Mergers, Joint Ventures
and the Pharmaceutical Industry, 1996 EU Pharmaceutical Forum 1996 at http://europa.
eu.int. See also S.A. Singham, Competition Policy and the Stimulation of Innovation:
TRIPS and the Interface Between Competition and Patent Protection in the Pharmaceutical Industry, 26 Brooklyn J. Intel L 363, 2000; K. Maskus, Parallel Important in
Pharmaceuticals: Implications for Competition and Prices in Developing Countries,
Report to WIPO 2001, at http://www.wipo.org/about-ip/en/studies/pdf/ssa_maskus_pi.
pdf.

Technology access problems in the biopharmaceutical industry

199

licence is not sought to directly incorporate the technology in clearly identifiable


new goods and services.82

82
Commission Discussion Paper on the Application of Art. 82 to Exclusionary
Abuses, December 2005, para. 240.

Bibliography
Legislation and Guidelines
European Legislation, Guidelines, Proposals
COM(2000) 412 final Commission Proposal for a Council Regulation on the
Community Patent, 1 August, 2000, COM(2000) 412 final.
COM(2004) 7119 Doc. 7119/04 PI 18, Revised Proposal for Council Regulation on the Community Patent, 8 March 2004, COM(2004) 7119.
COM(2004) 737 Commission Proposal for Regulation of the European Parliament and Council on Compulsory Licensing of patents relating to the
manufacture of pharmaceutical products for export to countries with public
health problems, COM (2004) 737.
Commission Discussion Paper 2005 Commission Discussion Paper on the
Application of Art. 82 to exclusionary abuses, December 2005.
Commission Regulation 2659/2000 Commission Regulation on the application of Art. 81(3) of the Treaty to categories of research and development
agreements (R&D Regulation), OJ 2000 L. 304/7.
Council Directive 2004/27 Council Directive amending Directive 2001/83 on
the Community code relating to medicinal products for human use, OJ 2004
L. 36/34.
Council Directive 98/79/EC Council Directive on in-vitro diagnostic medical
devices, OJ 1998 L. 331/1.
Council Directive 98/44 Council Directive on the legal protection of biotechnology inventions, OJ 1998 L. 213/13.
Council Directive 91/250 Council Directive on the legal protection of computer programs, OJ 1991 L. 122/ 42.
Council Directive 141/2000 Council Directive on the orphan medicinal product, OJ 2000 L. 18/1.
Council Directives 92/26, 92/28, 92/27, 92/23 Council Directive on the rational use of medicines, OJ 1992 L. 113/13.
Council Regulation 2349/84 Council Regulation on the application of Article
85(3) of the Treaty to certain categories of patent licensing agreements (Patent Regulation), OJ 1984 L. 84/219.
Council Regulation 556/89 Council Regulation on the application of Article

200

Bibliography

201

85(3) of the Treaty to certain categories of Know-How Licensing Agreements


(Know-How Regulation), OJ 1989 L. 61/1.
Council Regulation 1768/92 Council Regulation concerning the creation of
a supplementary protection certificate for medicinal products, OJ 1992 L.
182.
Council Regulation 2309/93 Council Regulation laying down Community
Procedures for the authorization and supervision of medicinal products for
human and veterinary use and establishing a European Agency for the Evaluation of Medicinal Products, OJ 1993 L. 214/01.
European Charter Charter of Fundamental Rights of the European Union OJ
2000 C. 364/01.
European Parliament Resolutions B5-0633, 0641, 0651 and 0663/2001 European Parliament resolution on the patenting of BRCA1 and BRCA2 (breast
cancer) genes OJ 2002 C. 87/265.
Technology Transfer Block Exemption Commission Regulation 772/2004, on
the application of article 81(3) of the Treaty to categories of technology
transfer agreements, 2004 OJ L. 213/11.
National Legislation
Austrian Patent Law (Patentgesetz 1970) last amended by the Law No. 234 of
23 May 1984.
Banjul Charter, African [Banjul] Charter on Human and Peoples Rights,
adopted 27 June, 1981, OAU Doc. CAB/LEG/67/3 rev. 5, 21 I.L.M. 58 (1982
entered into force 1986).
Danish Consolidate Patents Act, Patents Act No. 479 1967 last amended by Act
No 733, 27 November 1989.
Dutch Patent Act 1910 last amended by the Act of the Kingdom of 29 May
1987.
Finnish Patents Act, Patent Law (Patenttilaki) No. 550 1967 last amended by
Act No. 243, 21 March 1997.
French Patent Act, Intellectual Property Code, Law No. 92-597 (last amended
by Law No. 96-1106 1996).
German Act Against Restraints of Competition 1958.
German Patent Act, Patent Law of 16 December 1980 last amended by Law of
25 October 1994.
Greek Technology Transfer, Inventions and Technological Innovation Law
1733/1987 last amended by Law No. 17/39 1987 and Presidential Decrees
No. 54/1992.
Italian Law on Patents for Inventions; Royal Decree No. 1127 1939 last amended
by Legislative Decree No. 198 1996.

202

Bibliography

Nordic Patents Act No. 9 1967 last amended by Act No. 104, 20 December
1996.
Portuguese Industrial Property Code Decree Law No. 16/95 1995.
Spanish Law on Patents No. 11 (20 March 1986) last amended by Law 50,
1998.
Swedish Patents Act No. 837 1967 last amended by Act No. 1406 of 1998
(Patentlag).
Swiss Federal Law on Patents for Inventions 1954 (last amended on 24 March
1995).
UK Patents Act 1977 last amended by the Copyright, Designs and Patents Act
1988.
UK SI 2002/247, Patents and Plant Variety Rights (Compulsory Licensing)
Regulations 2002.
US Legislation and Guidelines
Affordable Drugs Act 2001 Affordable Prescription Drugs Act HR 1708, 27
April 2001.
Affordable Drugs Act 1999 Affordable Prescription Drugs Act, HR 2927 23
September 1999.
Bayh Dole Act 1980 Bayh Dole Act Pub. L. No. 96-517, 6 (a), 94 Stat. 3019,
3019-28 (1980) (codified at 35 U.S.C. 200212 (1994)).
Collaboration Guidelines 2000 FTC/DOJ, Antitrust Guidelines for Collaborations Among Competitors, (2000) Reprinted in 4 Trade Reg. Rep (CCH).
DPCPTRA 1984 Drug Price Competition and Patent Term Restoration Act
1984 Public Law 98417.
IP Licensing Guidelines 1995 FTC/DOJ Antitrust Guidelines for the Licensing
of Intellectual Property (6 April 1995), reprinted in 4 Trade Reg. Rep.
(CCH).
Orphan Drug Act 1992 Orphan Drug Regulations (57 FR 62076) 29 December
1992 and CFR Part 316 et seq.
Public Health Act 2001 Public Health Emergencies Act HR 3235, 6 November
2001.
Revised Utility Guidelines 1999 Department of Commerce, Patent and Trademark Office, Revised Utility Examination Guidelines, 64 Fed. Reg. 71 (1999)
440.
Sherman Act Sherman Act 1890.
International treaties, legislation, guidelines
Berne Convention (1886) Berne Convention for the Protection of Literary and
Artistic Works, 9 September 1886.

Bibliography

203

Convention against Discrimination (1979) Convention on the Elimination of


All Forms of Discrimination against Women of 1979, GA Res. 34/180 UN
GAOR 34 Sess., Supp/No. 44 at 193, UN Doc. A/34/36 91980 (entered into
force 3 September 1981).
Convention on Elimination of Racial Discrimination (1965) International
Convention on the Elimination of All Forms of Racial Discrimination of 1965,
UN GAOR Res. 2106 A(XX).
Convention on Rights of Child (1989) Convention on the Rights of the Child,
No. 20 1989 GA Res. 44/25, UN GAOR 44 Sess., Supp. No. 49, at 167, UN
Doc. A/44/49 (1989).
Doha Declaration (2001) Doha Declaration on Pubic Health, WT/MIN(01)/
DEC/1 November 2001.
EPO Examination Guidelines Guidelines for Examination in the European
Patent Office, available at http://www.european-patent-office.org/legal/
gui_lines/e/.
European Charter of Patients Rights (2002) Active Citizenship Network.
European Charter of Patients Rights, 2002, available at http://www.activecitizenship.net/health/european_charter.pdf.
European Patent Convention (EPC) (1973) Convention for the grant of European Patents, entered into force in 1977, also known as the Munich
Convention, available at http://www.european-patent-office.org/legal/epc/.
European Social Charter (1961) European Social Charter, ETS 35 Social
Charter, 18.X.1961, 18 October, 1961, available at www.conventions.coe.
int/Treaty/en/treaties/hetml/035.htm.
General Comment 14 on Right to Health (2000) E/C.12/2000/4, The Right to
the Highest Attainable Standard of Health, CESCR General Comment 14, 11
August 2000.
ICESCR (1966) International Covenant on Economic, Social and Cultural
Rights, G.A. Res. 2200 (XXI), UN GAOR, Supp. (No. 16) 49, UN Doc.
A(6316) 1966 999 UNTS 171 (entered into force 23 March, 1976).
ICCPR (1966) International Covenant on Civil and Political Rights. United
Nations General Assembly Resolution 2200A [XXI], 16 December 1966.
Paris Convention (1883) Paris Convention for the Protection of Industrial
Property of 20 March 1883 as revised at Brussels on 14 December 1900, at
Washington on 2 June 1911, at the Hague on 6 November 1925, at London
on 2 June 1934, at Lisbon on 31 October 1958 and at Stockholm on 14 July
1967, and as amended on 2 October 1979.
South Africa Medicines Act (1997) Medicines and Related Substances Control
Amendment Act, 1997, Republic of South Africa, Government Gazette, 12
December 1997.
TRIPS Agreement (1994) Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual
Property Rights (TRIPS) 1997, Annex 1C of the Marrakesh Agreement Es-

204

Bibliography

tablished by the World Trade Organization, signed in Marrakesh, Morocco


on 15 April 1994.
UDHR (1948) Universal Declaration on Human Rights GA Res. 217 A(III),
UN Doc. A/810 (1948).
UN Human Rights Resolution (2001) United Nations resolution of the SubCommission on Human Rights 2001/21.
UN Right to Property (1993) The Right of Everyone to Own Property Alone
as well as in Association with Others, UN Commission on Human Rights,
49 Sess., Provisional Agenda Item 7, at 25, UN Doc. E/CN.4/1993/15.
Vienna Declaration (1993) Vienna Declaration and Program of Action, World
Conference on Human Rights, 25 June 1993.
WHO Constitution (1945) World Health Organization Constitution, 1945
available at http://www.who.int/rarebooks/official_records/constitution.pdf.
WHO Declaration of Alma-Ata (1978) Declaration of Alma-Ata, adopted at
the International Conference on Primary Health Care, 12 September 1978,
World Health Organization, Geneva.

Reports and Studies


AAAS on Science and Human Rights (2002) Report on Science and Human
Rights, AAAS Science and Human Rights Program, Vol. XXII, No. 1, 2002
available at http://shr.aaas.org/report/xxii/ip.htm.
ABA Survey on Innovation (2002) ABA, The Economics of Innovation: A
Survey, ABA, available at http://www.ftc.gov/opp/intellect/0207salabasrvy.
pdf, July 2002.
ACIP Issues on Experimental Use (2004) ACIP, Issues and Options Papers,
Patents and Experimental Use, December 2004 available at http://www.acip.
gov.au/library/Experimental%20Use%20Options%20Paper%20A.pdf.
BIO Statistics Biotechnology Industry Organization, Biotech Statistics; available at http://www.bio.org/er/statistics.asp.
BIO (2000) Biotechnology Industry Organization, The Economic Contributions of the Biotechnology Industry to the US Economy, 2000.
BIO (2000a) Biotechnology Industry Organization, Medicare modernization,
Genomics, Issues and Policies, Primer: Genome and Genetic Research, Patent Protection and the 21st Century Medicine, 2000 available at www.bio.
org/genomics/primer.html.
BIO (2000b) Biotechnology Industry Organization: Editors and Reporters
Guide to Biotechnology, February 2000, available at www.bio.org/aboutbio/
guide2000/facts.html.
BIO (2002) Testimony of the Biotechnology Industry Organization on Com-

Bibliography

205

petition and IP law and Policy in the Knowledge Based Economy, FTC/DOJ
Proceedings on the Pharmaceutical Industry, 26 February 2002.
BIO (2003-4) Biotechnology Industry Organization, Biotechnology: A New
Link to Hope, Editors and Reporters Guide to Biotechnology, 200304.
CESCR on Human Rights and IP, (2001) E/C.12/2001/15, Human Rights and
Intellectual Property Issues, Statement by the Committee on Economic, Social and Cultural Rights, 26 November 2001, Intellectual Property and
Human Rights.
Commission Speeches on antitrust (1996) Commission Speeches on shortterm benefits, available at http://europa.eu.int/comm/competition/speeches
/text/sp1996_0542_en.html.
CPTech (1998) CPTech, Compulsory Licensing and the Resolution of the
Revised Drug Strategy 51st World Health Assembly, March 1998 available
at http://www.cptech.org/pharm/cl.html .
CPTech (2001) CPTech comments on H.R. 3235, the Public Health Emergency Medicines Act, 7 November 2001, http://lists.essential.org, p.1.
CPTech (2002) CPTech on Collective Management of IPRS: Patent Pools, L.
Sung, Greater predictability may result in patent pools, 8 February 2002
available at http://www.cptech.org/cm/patentpool.html.
CPTech (2003) Statement by consumer project on technology, concerning an
alleged prohibited practice in terms of section 49B(2)(a) of the Competition
Act 89 of 1998, February 2003 available at http://www.cptech.org/ip/health/clcases/rsa-tac/cptech-statement-3feb2003.doc.
Derwent on Pharmaceutical Research (2000) Derwent Information, New Patent Research Shows SMES in the Pharmaceutical Sector Lead the Field, 2000
available at www.derwent.com/press/2000/smes_pharma.html.
DOJ/FTC Proceeding on Competition and IPRs (2002) DOJ/FTC Proceedings
on Competition and IPRS: A. Diverse perspectives on patents. B. Business
perspectives on patents. Biotechnology and pharmaceuticals, 19 March
2002.
DOJ/FTC Proceedings on Pharmaceutical Industry (2002) DOJ/FTC Proceedings on the pharmaceutical industry: Business perspectives on the use and
the role of patents in the biotech industry, 26 February 2002.
DOJ/FTC on Innovation (2003) FTC/DOJ, To Promote Innovation: The Proper
Balance of Completion and Patent Law and Policy, Executive Summary,
2003.
EGE Opinion No. 3 (1993) Report of the European Group on Ethics in Science
and New Technologies, on ethical questions arising from the EC Commission
Proposal for a Council Directive on Legal Protection for Biotechnological
Inventions, 30 September,1993.
EGE Opinion No. 4 (1994) Report of the European Group on Ethics in Science

206

Bibliography

and New Technologies, on the ethical implications of gene therapy, 13 December 1994.
EGE on Charter (2000) Report of the European Group on Ethics in Science
and New Technologies on the Charter on Fundamental Rights Related to
Technological Innovation, 23 May 2000.
EGE Opinion No. 15 (2000a) Report of the European Group on Ethics in
Science and New Technologies, on Stem Cells, 14 November 2000.
EGE Opinion No. 16 (2000b) Report of the European Group on Ethics in
Science and New Technologies, on ethical aspects of patenting inventions
involving human stem cells, 7 May 2000.
ETSI on Standards (2000) ETSI, Legal Considerations when drafting a standard in ETSI, October 2000.
EU on IP and Access to Medicines (2001) EUs Position Paper Submitted to
TRIPS Council for special discussion of IP and Access to Medicines, 20 June
2001.
EUROPE on Pharmaceutical Products (1996) EUROPE, Pharmaceutical
Products, Single Market Review, 1996.
Europe Economics on Health (2001) Europe Economics, Global Public Goods
in Health, May 2001, available at www.europe-economics.com/.
European Competitiveness Report (2001) European Competitiveness Report,
Chapter V: The Competitiveness of European Biotechnology: A Case study
of Innovation, 2001.
Eversheds on Swiss Type Claim (2000) Eversheds National Bioscience Group,
2nd Pharmaceutical use the Swiss type claim, 21 December 2000 available
at http://atlas.pharmalicensing.com.
Freshfields on Compulsory Licensing (2001) Freshfields Bruckhaus Deringer,
Market Leader Forced to License IP, July 2001.
FTC on Competition Policy (1996) FTC, Office of Policy Planning, Anticipating the 21st Century: Competition Policy in the New High-Tech Global
Marketplace, 1996, available at www.ftc.fov/opp/hitech/global.htm.
FTC on Genetic Entry (2001) FTC, Generic Entry Prior to Patent Expiration,
an FTC Study, July 2001.
FTC on Pharmaceuticals (2003) FTC, FTC Antitrust Actions in Pharmaceutical Services and Products, October 2003.
FTC Press Release on Innovation Markets (2004) FTC Press Release, FTC
Closes its Investigation of Genzyme Corporations 2001 Acquisition of Novazyme Pharmaceuticals, Inc., available at www.ftc.gov/opa/2004/01/genzyme.
htm; Statement of Chairman T.J. Muris, in the Matter of Genzyme Corporation/Novazyme Pharmaceuticals, Inc., available at www.ftc.gov/os/2004/
01/murisgenzymestmt.pdf; Dissenting Statement of Commissioner M.W.
Thompson, Genzyme Corporations Acquisition of Novazyme Pharmaceuticals, at www.ftc.gov/os/2004/01/thompsongenzymestmt.pdf; Commissioner

Bibliography

207

P.J. Harbour Statement available at www.ftc.gov/os/2004/01/harbourgenzyme


stmt.pdf.
High Commissioner Report (2000) E/CN.4/SUB.2/RES.2000/7 United Nations High Commissioner for Human Rights, Intellectual Property and
Human Rights, Sub-Commission on Human Rights, 2000.
High Commissioner Report (2001) E/CN.4/Sub.2/2001/27, United Nations
High Commissioner for Human Rights, The Impact of the Agreement on
Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights on Human Rights, 27
June 2001.
High Commissioner Report (2002) E/CN.4/Sub.2/2002/9, United Nations
High Commissioner for Human Rights, Economic, Social and Cultural
Rights, Liberalization of trade in services and human rights, 25 June 2002.
IACHR Report (1993) Status of Human Rights in Several Countries: Nicaragua, Annual report of the Inter-American Commission on Human Rights
1993, OEA/Ser.L/V/II.85, Doc. 9 Rev. (1994) at 465, available at www.cidh.
org/annualrep/93span/cap.IVe.htm.
IIHRS (1990) International Institute for Human Rights Studies. Le mdecin
face aux droits de lhomme. Padova: CEDAM, 1990.
Ladas and Parry on Competition and IP (1994) Ladas and Parry, EU Interface
Between Competition Law and IP Law, 1995 available at http://www.ladas.
com/BULLETINS/1994/0694Bulletin/EU_COmpetitionIPInterface.html.
National Academies of Sciences on Research Tools (1997) National Academies of Sciences, Intellectual Property Rights and the Dissemination of
Research Tools in Molecular Biology, Summary of a Workshop Held at the
National Academies of Sciences, 1516 February, 1996, 1997.
N/e/r/a on refusal to supply (1999) N/e/r/a, Competition Brief, Oscar Bronner:
Legitimate Refusal to Supply,1999 available at www.nera.com.
NIH Report on Research Tools (1998) Report of the National Institutes of
Health NIHWorking Group on Research Tools, Presented to the Advisory
Committee to the Director, 4 June 1998.
Nuffield Council on Bioethics (2002) Nuffield Council on Bioethics, The
Ethics of Patenting DNA, available at http://www.nuffieldbioethics.org/fileLibrary/pdf/nuffield_annual_report_2002.pdf 2002.
OECD (1985) OECD, The Pharmaceutical Industry, Paris, 1985.
OECD (1989) OECD, Competition Policy and IPRs, Paris, 1989.
OECD (1996) OECD, Essential Facilities Doctrine, Paris, 1996.
OECD (1998) OECD Competition Policy and IPRs, Paris, 1998, including
articles:
l Shiraishi, Refusals to License Intellectual Property.
l J. Barton, The Balance between IPRs and Competition.
l J. Barton, The Impact of Contemporary Patent Law on Biotechnology
Research.

208

Bibliography

J. Barton, A hypothetical case where competition policy perhaps should


be applied to curtail the exercise of IPRs.
l N. Gallini and M. Trebilcock, IPRs and Competition Policy: A Framework
for Analysis of Economic and Legal Issues.
l V. Korah, Compulsory Licenses and Incentives to Invest in Innovation.
l V. Korah, Patents and Antitrust.
OECD (2001) OECD Report, Competition and Regulation Issues in the Pharmaceutical Industry, Paris, 2001.
OECD (2001a) OECD, The Pharmaceutical Industry, Paris, 2001.
OECD (2001b) OECD, The New Economy Beyond the Hype, Paris, 2001.
OECD (2001c) OECD, Towards a Knowledge-based Economy, Paris 2001.
OECD (2002) OECD, Genetic Inventions, IPRs and Licensing Practices:
Evidence and Policies, Paris, 2002.
Oxfam on Patents Oxfam, Patent Injustice: How that World Trade Rules
Threaten the Health of Poor People; available at www.oxfam.org.uk.
Oxfam on Public Health Oxfam: Dare to Lead: Public Health and Company
Wealth, at www.oxfam.org.uk.
PhRMA (2002) PhRMA, Delivering on the Promise of Pharmaceutical Innovation: The Need to Maintain Strong and Predictable Intellectual Property
Rights, White Paper on the Intersection of IP and Antitrust Law in the Pharmaceutical Industry, submitted to the FTC and the DOJ Antitrust Division,
22 April 2002.
S-G ESCR Report on IPRs and Human Rights (2001) Report of the SecretaryGeneral on Economic, Social and Cultural Rights, IPRs and Human Rights,
E/CN.4/Sub.2/2001/12, 14 June 2001.
Special Rapporteur Report on right to health (2003) Report of the Special
Rapporteur, P. Haunt, The Right of Everyone to the Highest Attainable Standard of Physical and Mental Health, submitted in accordance with Commission
Resolution 2002/31, UN ESCOR, 59th Sess., Agenda Item 23, 20, UN Doc.
E/CN.4/2003/58 (2003).
UN Press Release on Right to Health (1993) Day of General Discussion on
the Right to Health on 6 December 1993, the right to the enjoyment of the
highest attainable standard of physical and mental health, UN Information
Service, Press Release HR/3604, 6 December 1993.
Vossius and Partner on Research Tools Vossius and Partner, The Patenting
andEnforcement of Inventions Relating to Research Tools: Chances and
Problems, at www.vossiusandpartner.com/eng/publication/pub-patenting_
and_enforcement.html.
WHA on Compulsory licensing World Health Assembly Compulsory Licensing and the Resolution of the Revised Drug Strategy, 51st World Health
Assembly, at www.cptech.org.
WHO (1993) World Health Organization. Indicators to Measure the Realiza-

Bibliography

209

tion of the Right to Health, Background Paper for Seminar on Appropriate


Indicators to Measure Achievements in the Progressive Realization of Economic, Cultural and Social Rights. Geneva, 2529 January 1993. HR/Geneva/
1993/Sem/BP. Jan. 1993.
WHO (2001) World Health Organization, Globalization, TRIPS and Access
to Pharmaceuticals, WHO Policy Perspectives on Medicines, 3 March
2001.
WHO (2001a) World Health Organization, More equitable pricing for essential drugs: What do we mean and what are the issues?, Background Paper
for the WHO-WTO Secretariat Workshop on Differential Pricing and Financing of Essential Drugs, Hosbjor, Norway, 811 April 2001.
WHO/WTO (2001b) World Health Organization World Trade Organization
Secretariat Workshop, on Differential Pricing and Financing of Essential
Drugs, Hosbjor, Norway, 811 April 2001.
WHO/WTO (2002) WTO/WHO, WTO Agreements and Public Health, A Joint
Study by WHO and the WTO Secretariat, 2002.
WHO Press release WHO/61 (2002) World Health Organization, Press Release
24 July 2002, New WHO publication explores important links between health
and human rights an area drawing increased attention.
WIPO Conference on Patent System (2002) WIPO Conference, on the International Patent System, Geneva, 2527 March, 2002.
l E. Kitch, The Patent System: A design for all Seasons?
l M. Kirk, Competing Demands on Public Policy.
l J. Straus, Patents and Health Issues.
l E. Hoen, Patents and Health Issues.
l J. Bambridge, Impact of IT on Patent System.
l S. Fukushima, Impact of IT on Patent System.
l A. Roach, Impact of IT on Patent System.
l Delphion, The Valuation of patents and patents as financial
instruments.
l C. Correa, Internalization of the patent system and new technology.
l B. Lehman, Need for Stronger PCT.
l J. Nieuwenhuis, IP and Innovation Policy.
WIPO on Pliva WIPO, Azythromocin: A world best-selling antibiotic Pliva,
at www.wipo.int.
WTO (2000) WTO, US Section 110(5) of the US Copyright Act, Panel Report of 15 June 2000, WT/DS160/R, para. 6.229.

210

Bibliography

Authors
Abbott, F.M. (2001), The TRIPS Agreement, Access to Medicines and the WTO
Doha Ministerial Conference, Quaker United Nations Office, 8 September.
Abbott, F. (2002), Compulsory Licensing for Public Health Needs: The TRIPS
Agenda and the WTO after the Doha Declaration on Public Health, Quaker
United Nations Office, February.
Abbott, F. (2002a), The Doha Declaration on the TRIPS Agreement and Public
Health: Lighting a Dark Corner at the WTO, Journal of International Economic Law 439.
Acharya, R. (1999), The Emergence and Growth of Biotechnology, Experiences
in Industrialized and Developing Countries, Cheltenham, UK and Northampton, MA, USA, Edward Elgar.
Ackiron, E. (1991), The Human Genome Initiative and the Impact of Genetic
Testing and Screening Technology: Patents for Critical Pharmaceuticals: The
AZT Case, 17 Am. J. L. and Med. 145.
Addanki, S. (1995), The DOJs Draft Intellectual Property Guidelines: An
Economists First Look [1995] ECLR 221.
Adelman, M.J. (1977), Property Rights Theory and Patent Antitrust: The Role
of Compulsory Licensing, 52 NYUL Rev. 977.
Aguilera, M.C. (1995), Local Institutes Named in Lawsuit, San Diego Daily
Transcript, 25 May.
Ahern, P.J. (1994), Refusals to Deal After Aspen, 93 Antitrust L. J. 153.
Ahlborn, C., Evans, D.S. and Padilla, A.J. (2001), Competition Policy in the
New Economy: Is European Competition Law Up to the Challenge? [2001]
ECLR 156.
Allansdottir, A., Bonaccorsi, A., Gambardella, A., Mariani, M., Orsenigo, L.,
Pammolli, F., Riccaboni, M. (2002), Innovation and Competitiveness in European Biotechnology, Enterprise papers for DG EU Commission.
Anderman, S. (1996), The Aftermath of Magill [1996] Yearbook of Media and
Entertainment Law 235.
Anderman, S. (1998), EC Competition Law and IPRs: The Regulation of Innovation, Oxford, Oxford University Press.
Anderman, S. (2004), Does the Microsoft Case offer a New Paradigm for the
Exceptional Circumstances Test and Compulsory Copyright Licenses under
EC Competition Law?, presented at the Clasf Conference on 9th September.
Anderson, R.D. and Gallini, N.T. (1998), Competition Policy and IPRs in the
Knowledge-Based Economy, Calgary, University of Calgary Press.
Anderson, R.D. (1998a), The Interface between Competition Policy and IP in
the Context of International Trading System, 1(4) Jnl of Intl Econ. Law
655.

Bibliography

211

Anthony, S.F. (2000), Antitrust and Intellectual Property Law: From Adversaries
to Partners, 28(1) AIPLA Quarterly Review 1.
Aoki, R. and Small, J. (2004), Compulsory Licensing of Technology and the
Essential Facilities Doctrine, 16 Information Economics and Policy 23.
Areeda, P. (1989), Essential Facilities: An Epithet In Need of Limiting Principles, 58 Antitrust Law Jnl 841.
Arora, A. (2002), Competition and IP Law and Policy in the Knowledge-Based
Society: Is there a Cause for Concern about Unilateral Refusals to Deal?,
DOJ/FTC Hearings on IP and Competition Law, 1 May.
Arrow, K.J. (1971), Economic Welfare and the Allocation of Resources for Invention, in Essays in the Theory of Risk-Bearing, Chicago, Markham
Publishing Co.
Austin, D. (2000), Patents, Spillovers and Competition in Biotechnology, Resources for the future, Discussion Paper 00-53, Nov. 2000 available at
http://www.rff.org.
Ayres, J. and Talley, E. (1995), Solomonic Bargaining: Dividing a Legal Entitlement to Facilitate Coasean Trade, 104 Yale L. J. 1027.
Bailey, T.C. (2001), Innovation and Access: The Role of Compulsory Licensing
in the Development and Distribution of the HIV Drug, U. Ill. J. L. Tech. &
Poly 193.
Baily, M. (1972), R&D Costs and Returns: The US Pharmaceutical Industry,
80 Journal of Political Economy 70.
Balance, R., Pogany, J. and Forstner, H. (1992), The Worlds Pharmaceutical
Industries: An International Perspective on Innovation, Competition and
Policy, UNIDO.
Baldwin, J.R., Hanel, P. and Sabourin, D. (2000), Determinants of Innovative
Activity in Canadian Manufacturing Firms: The Role of IPRs, Statistics Canada,
Analytical Studies Branch series Research Papers No. 11f0019mie2000122.
Balto, D.A. and Mongoven, J.F. (1999), Antitrust Enforcement in Pharmaceutical Industry Mergers, 54 Food and Drug Law Journal 255.
Balto, P. and Sher, S. (2004), Refining the Innovation Focus: The FTCs Genzyme Decision, 2004 Antitrust Magazine 28.
Balto, D.A. and Wolman, A.M. (2003), Intellectual Property and Antitrust:
General Principles, 43 IDEA 395.
Barinaga, M. (1995), Scientists Named in PCR Suit, 268 Science 1273.
Barounos, H.J. (1975), EEC Anti-trust Law, London, Butterworths.
Barton, J. (1993), Adapting IP System to New Technology, in Global Dimensions
of IPRs in Science and Technology, National Research Council, edited by M.
Wallerstein, M. Mogee, R. Schoen, Washington, National Academy Press.
Barton, J.H. (1997), Patents and Antitrust: A Rethinking in Light of Patent
Breadth and Sequential Innovation, 65 Antitrust L. J. 44.

212

Bibliography

Barton, J.H. (2002), Antitrust Treatment of Oligopolies with Mutually Blocking


Patent Portfolios, 69 Antitrust L. J. 851.
Battcock, R., IPRS, Software Copyright and Competition Law: Restricting the
Rights of Intellectual Property Owners in the Wider Public Interest, available
at http://www.cptech.org/ip/health/cl/cl-eu.html.
Bebchuk, L.A. (2001), Property Rights and Liability Rules: The Ex Ante View
of the Cathedral, 100 Mich. L. Rev. 601.
Becker, L. (1993), Deserving to Own Intellectual Property, 68 Chi-Kent L. Rev.
609.
Beier, F.K. (1980), The Significance of the Patent System for Technical, Economic and Social Progress [1980] IIC 563.
Beier, F.K. (1990), Industrial Property and Internal Market [1990] 2 IIC 131.
Beier, F.K. (1991), The Future of IP in Europe [1991] IIC 157.
Bendekgey, L. and Hamlet-Cox, D. (2002), Gene Patents and Innovation, 77
Academic Medicine 1373.
Benkler, Y. (2001), Free as the Air to Common Use: A Political Economy of the
Public Domain, in Expanding the Boundaries of Intellectual Property, R.
Dreyfuss et al. (eds), Oxford, Oxford University Press.
Benkler, Y. (2001a), A Political Economy of the Public Domain: Markets in Information Goods Versus the Marketplace of Ideas, in Expanding the
Boundaries of Intellectual Property, R. Dreyfuss et al. (eds), Oxford, Oxford
University Press.
Benkler, Y, (2002), Coases Penguin, or, Linux and The Nature of the Firm, 112
Yale L. J.
Bergman, M.A. (2000), The Bronner Case A Turning Point for the Essential
Facilities Doctrine? [2000] 2 ECLR 59.
Bhatnager, M.P. (1992), GATT Intellectual Property Protection Proposals in
Context with Developing Countries and the Paris Convention, 40 Patent
World 33.
Birdsall, N. and James, E. (1993), Health, Government and the Poor: The Case
for the Private Sector, in J.N. Gribble and S.H. Preston (eds), The Epidemiological Transition Policy and Planning Implications for Developing Countries,
Washington DC, National Academy Press.
Blackburn, R. (2000), Chief Patent Counsel, Chiron Corporation, remarks at
the National Academies Board of Science, Technology and Economic Policys
Conference on Intellectual Property Rights: How Far Should They Be Extended?, Washington, DC, 3 Feb.
Blackburn, R. (2002), in DOJ/FTC Proceedings on the Pharmaceutical Industry:
Business Perspectives on the Use and the Role of Patents in the Biotechnology Industry, 26 February.
Blair, M.M., Hoffman, G.H. and Tamburo, S.P. (2002), Clarifying IPRs for the

Bibliography

213

New Economy, in Bruce Berman (ed.), From Ideas to Assets: Investing Wisely
in Intellectual Property, John Wiley & Sons.
Bloche, M.G. (2002), WTO Deference to National Health Policy: Toward an
Interpretive Principle, 5(4) Journal of International Economic Law 825.
Blumenthal, W. (1990), Three Vexing Issues Under the Essential Facilities
Doctrine: ATM Networks as Illustration, 58 Antitrust Law Journal 855.
Boone, J. (2001), Intensity of Competition and Incentives to Innovate, 19 Interl
J. Ind. Org.n 705.
Boseley, S. (2002), EU loophole sends drug prices soaring, Guardian Weekly,
24 June.
Boyle, J. (2000), Law and Economic of IPRs: Cruel, Mean, or Lavish? Economic Analysis, Price Discrimination and Digital Intellectual Property, 53
Vand. L. Rev. 2007.
Brennan, T.J. (1993), Copyright, Property and the Right to Deny, 68 Chi. Kent
L. Rev. 675.
Brimelow, A. (2001), Does IP Need a New Set of Wheels? [2001] EIPR 44.
Burk, D. (2002), Open Source Genomics, 8 Boston University Journal of Science and Technology Law 254.
Burling, J.C., Lee, W.F. and Krug, A.K. (1999), Antitrust Duty to Deal and IPRs,
24 Iowa J Corp 527.
Burtis, M.M. and Kobayashi, B.H. (2001), Why an Original Can be Better than
a Copy: IP, the Refusal to deal and the ISO Antitrust Litigation, 9 Supr. Ct.
Econ. Rev.
Calabresi, G. and Melamed, A.D. (1972), Property Rules, Liability Rules and
Inalienability: One View of the Cathedral, 85 Harvard Law Rev 1089.
Calabresi, G. (1997), Property Rules, Liability Rules and Inalienability: The
Simple Virtues of the Cathedral, 106 Yale L. J. 2201.
Cambell, E.G., Clarridge, B.R., Gokhale, M., Birenbaum, L., Hilgartner, S.,
Holtzman, N.A.and Blumenthal, D. (2002), Data Withholding in Academic
Genetics: Evidence from a National Survey. 287(4) Journal of the American
Medical Association 473.
Carl, P. et al. (1991), AIDS and Human Rights in the European Communities,
Utrecht, Netherlands Institute of Human Rights.
Carlson, S.C. (1999), Patent Pools and the Antitrust Dilemma, 6 Yale J. on Reg.
369.
Carlton, D.W. (2001), Antitrust at the Millennium: A General Analysis of Exclusionary Conduct and Refusal to Deal, 68 Antitrust L. J. 659.
Carlton, D. and Gertner, R. (2003), Intellectual Property, Antitrust and Strategic
Behaviour, University of Chicago, National Bureau of Economic Research,
Working Paper No. W8976, May 2002, at 10, reprinted in A. Jaffe and J.
Lerner, Innovation Policy and the Economy, Vol. 3, MIT Press.
Caves, R., Whinston, M. and Hurwitz, M. (1991), Patent Expiration, Entry and

214

Bibliography

Competition in the US Pharmaceutical Industry, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Microeconomics.


Cawthra, B. (1973) Industrial Property Rights in the EEC, London, Gower Press
Ltd.
Chambers, S.A. (1995), Comments on the Patentability of Certain Inventions
Associated with the Identification of Partial cDNA Sequences, 23 AIPLA Q.J.
53.
Chang, H.F. (1995), Patent Scope, Antitrust Policy and Cumulative Innovation,
26 RAND Journal of Economics 3457.
Chapman, A.R. (2001), Approaching IP as a Human Right, Obligations related
to Art. 15(1)(c), Copyright Bulletin, Vol. XXXV No. 3, UNESCO Publishing,
E/C.12/2000/12.
Chapman, A.R. (2002), The Human Rights Implications of Intellectual Property
Protection, in 5 Journal of International Economic Law 861, Mini-Symposium on Health and the WTO.
Chetley, A. (1990), A Healthy Business? World Health and the Pharmaceutical
Industry, London, Zed Books.
Chien, C.V. (2003), Cheap Drugs at What Price to Innovation: Does the Compulsory Licensing of Pharmaceuticals Hurt Innovation?, 18 Berkl. Tech. L.
J. 853.
Chien, R.I. (ed.) (1979), Issues in Pharmaceutical Economics, Lanham, Lexington Books.
l H. Grabowski and J. Vernon, New Studies on Market Definition, Concentration, Theory of Supply, Entry and Promotion.
l W. Comanor, Competition in the Pharmaceutical Industry.
l J. Weston, Pricing in the Pharmaceutical Industry.
l O. Brownlee, Rates of Return to Investment in the Pharmaceutical Industry: A Survey and Critical Appraisal.
l W. Wardell, The Impact of Regulation on New Drug Development.
Chin, Y.W. (1998), Antitrust and the Suppression of Technology in the US and
Europe: Is there a Remedy? Unilateral Technology Suppression: Appropriate
Antitrust and Patent Law Remedies, 66 Antitrust L. J. 441.
Cho, M.K. (1998), Ethical and Legal Issues in the 21st Century, in Preparing
for the Millennium: Laboratory Medicine in the 21st century, Washington
DC, AACC Press, 2nd edition.
Clark, J., Piccolo, J., Stanton, B. and Tyson, K. (2000), Patent Pools: A Solution
to the Problem of Access in Biotechnology Patents? US PTO, 5 December at
http://www.uspto.gov/web/offices/pac/dapp/opla/patentpool.pdf.
Cohen, W.M. and Levin, R.C. (1989), Empirical Studies on Innovation and
Market Structure in R. Schmalensee and R.D. Willig (eds), Handbook of Industrial Organization, Amsterdam, North-Holland.

Bibliography

215

Cohen, J.E. (1998), Lochner in Cyberspace: The New Economic Orthodoxy of


Rights Management, 97 Mich L. Rev. 462.
Cohen, L.J. and Suddards, H. (1998), Limits on Enforcement of Intellectual
Property Rights, S. Meek (ed.) Center for Interl Legal Studies, Austria.
Cohen, J. and Lemley, M. (2001), Patent Scope and Innovation in the Software
Industry, 89 California L. Rev. 1.
Cohler, C.B. and Pearson, H.E. (1994), Software Interfaces, Intellectual Property and Competition Policy [1994] EIPR 434.
Cole, D.H. and Grossman, P.Z. (2000), The Meaning of Property Rights: Law
vs. Economics? 78 Land Econ. 317.
Colston (1996), Principles of IP Law, London, Cavendish Publishing Ltd.
Comanor, W. (1979), Competition in the Pharmaceutical Industry, in R.I. Chien,
Issues in Pharmaceutical Economics, Lanham, Lexington Books.
Conigliaro, M.J., Greenberg, A.C. and Lemley, M.A. (2001), Foreseeability in
Patent Law, 16 Berkeley Tech L. J. 1045.
Contractor, F.J. (1982), Technology Licensing Practices in US Companies:
Corporate and Public Policy Implication, Col. Jnl of World Business 80.
Cook, R.J. (1989), Human Rights in Relation to Womens Health, The Promotion
and Protection of Womens Health through International Human Rights Law,
WHO/DGH/93.l, H.L. Fuenzalida-Puelma/S.S. Connor, eds, The Right to
Health in the Americas, Pan-American Health Organization, Scientific Publication No. 509, Washington, DC, 1989.
Cornish, W.R. (1996), Intellectual Property, London, Sweet & Maxwell, 3rd
edn.
Cornish, W.R. (1998), Experimental Use of Patented Inventions in European
Community States, 29(7) IIC 736.
Cornish, B., Llewelyn, M. and Adcock, M. (2003), Intellectual Property Rights
and Genetics. A Study into the Impact and Management of Intellectual Property Rights within the Healthcare Sector, at http://www.phgu.org.uk/about_
phgu/resources/word/s-ipr1.doc.
Correa, C. (2002), Internalization of the Patent System and New Technology in
WIPO Conference on the International Patent System, Geneva, 2527
March.
Craig, P. and de Burca, G. (2003), EU Law, Oxford, Oxford University Press,
3rd edn.
Crespi, R.S. (2003), Patenting and Ethics, A Dubious Connection, Bio-Science
Law Review, 26 February.
Cringely, R.X. (2002), The True Believer: Can Mike Doyle do to Microsoft what
the Rest of the Computer Industry and the Department of Justice couldnt
do? The Pulpit, http://www.pbs.org/cringely/pulpit, 7 November.
Cullem, G. (1999), Panning for Biotechnology Gold: Reach-Through Royalty

216

Bibliography

Damage Awards for Infringing Uses of Patented Molecular Sleeves, 29 IDEA


533.
Cullet, P. (2001), Patents Bill, TRIPS and the Right to Health, XXXVI/43 Economic and Political Weekly, 27 October.
Cunningham, J.P. (1973), The Competition Law of the EEC, London, Kogan
Page.
Cunningham, N. (1999), How Far can a Patent Holder Go? [1999] EIPR
469.
Curti, A. (2001), The WTO Dispute Settlement Understanding: An Unlikely
Weapon in the Fight Against AIDS, 27 Am. L. J. and Med. 468.
Dahdoud, T.N. and Mongoven, J.F. (1996), The Shape of Things to Come: Innovation Market Analysis in Merger Cases, 64 Antitrust L. J. 405.
Dalp, R., Bouchard, L., Houle, A-J. and Bdard, L. (2002), Watching the race
to find the breast cancer genes, 28(2) Science, Technology, and Human Values
187216.
Danzon, P. and Chao, L. (2000), Does Regulation Drive Out Competition in
Pharmaceutical Markets?, 43 J. Law & Econ. 311.
David, P.A. (1993), Intellectual Property Institutions and Pandas Thumb: Patents, Copyrights and Trade Secrets in Economic Theory and History, in
Global Dimensions of IPRs in Science and Technology, National Research
Council, M. Wallerstein, M. Mogee and R. Schoen (eds), Washington: National Academy Press.
Davies, D. (1986), Industrial Biotechnology in Europe: Issues for Public Policy,
London, Frances Pinter Publishers.
Davis, J. (2001), Intellectual Property Law, London, Butterworths.
Davis, R.W. (2003), Innovation Markets and Merger Enforcement: Current
Practice in Perspective, 71 Ant. L. J. 677.
Delavelle, C. (2001), Analysis of CIS Data on the Impact of Innovation on
Growth in the Chemical Sector, at ftp://ftp.cordis.lu/pub/eims/docs/eims_
summary_98_186.pdf.
De Leon, I. (2001), The Enforcement of Competition Policy on IP and its Implication on Economic Development: The Latin American Experience, New
York, New York University.
Demsetz, H. (1964), The Exchange and Enforcement of Property Rights, The
Journal of Law and Economics 11.
Demsetz, H. (1966), Some Aspects of Property Rights, 1966 The Journal of Law
and Economics 61.
De Santi, S. and Cohen, W. (2001), Competition to Innovate: Strategies for
Proper Antitrust Assessments, in R. Dreyfuss et al. (eds), Expanding the
Boundaries of Intellectual Property, Oxford, Oxford University Press.
Dolmans, M. (1998), Antitrust and the Suppression of Technology in the US and

Bibliography

217

Europe: Is there a Remedy? Restrictions on Innovation: An EU Antitrust


Approach, 66 Antitrust L. J. 455.
Dolmo, B.C. (2001), Examining Global Access to Essential Pharmaceuticals
in the Face of Patent Protection Rights: S. African Example, 7 Buff. Hum.
Rts L. Rev. 13763.
Domeij, B. (2000), Pharmaceutical Patents in Europe, Deventer, Kluwer Law
International.
Domeij, B. (2001), Patent Claim Scope: Initial and Follow-on Pharmaceutical
Inventions [2001] EIPR 326.
Dommering, E.J., Hugenholtz, P.B. and Kabel, J.J. (1992), Information Law
Towards the 21st Century, Deventer, Kluwer.
l E. Mackaay, Economic View of Information Law.
l J.C. Arnbak, Economic and Policy Issues in Regulation Conditions for
Subscriber Access and Market Entry to Telecommunications.
l H. Burkert, The Commercial Use of Government Controlled Information
and its Information Law Environment in EEC.
l J.H. Reichman, Legal Hybrids Between Patent and Copyright
Paradigm.
l J.H. Spoor, Standardization and Exclusivity in IP.
Drahos, P. (1996), A Philosophy of Intellectual Property, Darmouth, Darmouth
Publishing Co.
Drahos, P. (1999), Biotechnology Patents, Markets and Morality, 21(9) EIPR
441.
Dreyfuss, R.C. (1989), The Federal Circuit: A Case Study in Specialized Courts,
64 NYUL Rev. 1.
Dreyfuss, R.C. (2003), Varying the Course in Patenting Genetic Material: A
Counter-Proposal to Richard Epsteins Steady Course, NYU Law School,
Public Law Research Paper No. 59.
Drlica, K. (1997), Understanding DNA and Gene Cloning: A Guide for the
Curious, New York, Wiley edn, 3rd edn.
Ducor, P. (1999), Research Tool Patents and the Experimental Use Exemption
A no-win situation?, 17 Nature Biotechnology 1027.
Dupuy, R.J. (1979) (ed.), The Right to Health as a Human Right, Workshop,
The Hague Academy of International Law and the United Nations University,
Sijthoff & Noordhoff, Alphen aan den Rijn, The Netherlands.
Dutfield, G. (2003), IPRs and the Life Science Industries, A 20th Century History, Aldershot, Ashgate.
Eisenberg, R.S. (1987), Proprietary Rights and the Norms of Science in Biotechnology Research, 97 Yale L. J. 177.
Eisenberg, R.S. (1989), Patents and the Progress of Science: Exclusive Rights
and Experimental Use, 56 Univ. Chi. Law Rev. 1017.

218

Bibliography

Eisenberg, R. (1994), Technology Transfer and the Genome Project: Problems


with Patenting of Research Tools, 5 RISK 163.
Eisenberg, R.S. and Merges, R.P. (1995), Opinion Letter as to the Patentability
of Certain Inventions Associated with the Identification of Partial cDNA Sequences, 23 AIPLA Q.J. 1.
Eisenberg, R. (1996), Patenting Research Tools and the Law, in IPRs and Research Tools in Molecular Biology, Summary of Workshop Held at the
National Academies of Sciences, 1516 February.
Eisenberg, R. (2001), Bargaining over the Transfer of Proprietary Research
Tools: Is this Market Failing or Emerging, in R. Dreyfuss et al., Expanding
the Boundaries of Intellectual Property, Oxford, Oxford University Press.
Elhauge, E. (2003), Defining Better Monopolization Standards, 56 Stanford
Law Review 253.
Elliot, R. (2002), Realizing the right to health: access to HIV/AIDS-related
medication, 3 April 2002 at http://www.aidslaw.ca/Maincontent/issues/cts/
righttohealth.doc.
Endeshaw, A. (2001), Treating Intellectual Capital as Property: The Vexed Issues [2001] EIPR 140.
Epstein, R.A. (1997), A Clear View of the Cathedral: The Dominance of Property Rules, 1-6 Yale L. J. 2091.
Epstein, R.A. (1997), Transaction Costs and Property Rights: Or Do Good
Fences Make Good Neighbours?, The Law School of University of Chicago,
Working Paper No. 38.
Epstein, R.A. (2003), Steady the Course: Property Rights in Genetic Material,
The Law School of University of Chicago, Working Paper No. 152.
Erickson, S. (1999), Patent Law and the New Product Development: Does Priority Claim Basis Make a Difference?, 36 Am. Bus. L. J. 327.
Evenson, R.E. and Kanwar, S. (2001), Does IP protection Spur Technological
Change? Yale Uni. Discussion Paper 831, at http://www.edu.econ.yale.
edul~egcenter/research.htm.
Farmer, P. (2003), Pathologies of Power. Health, Human Rights and the New
War on the Poor, Berkeley, University of California Press.
Farr, S. (1992), Abuse of a Dominant Position The Hilti Case [1992] ECLR
175.
Fauver, C.M. (1988), Compulsory Patent Licensing in the US: An Idea Whose
Time Has Come, 8 J Intl L. Bus. 666.
Feit, I.N. (1989), Biotechnology Research and the Experimental Use Exception
to Patent Infringement, 71 J. Pat. & Trademark Off. Socy 819.
Fitzerald, D. (1998), Magill Revisited [1998] EIPR 154.
Flint, D. (1995), Magill Case Comment, MacRoberts Solicitors, 1995 at http://
www.jurisdiction.com/flin0002.htm.

Bibliography

219

Flores, M.A. (1999), Taking the Profits out of Biomedical Research Tools, 17
Nature Biotechnology 819.
Flynn, J. (1998), Antitrust and the Suppression of Technology in the US and
Europe: Is there a Remedy?, 66 Antitrust L. J. 487.
Flynn, J. (1992), Intellectual Property and Antitrust: EC Attitudes [1992] EIPR
53.
Forrester, I.S. (1992), Software Licensing in the Light of Current EC Competition Law Considerations [1992] ECLR 5.
Friden, G. (1989), Recent Developments in the EEC IP Law: The Distinction
Between the Existence and Exercise Revisited,[1989] CML Rev. 193.
Fuenzalida-Puelma, H.L. and Connor, S.S. (eds) (1989), The Right to Health in
the Americas, Pan-American Health Organization, Scientific Publication No.
509, Washington, DC.
Furse, M. (1995), The Essential Facilities Doctrine in Community Law, ECLR
469.
Furse, M. (2000), Competition Law of EC and UK, London, Blackstone Press
Limited, 2nd edn.
Fysh, M. (2002), Supplementary Certificate Legal Issues in Exploiting Drug
Patents in Europe, Milan, LES-Italy Conference.
Gallini, N.T. (1992), Patent Policy and Costly Imitation, 23 The RAND Journal
of Economics 52.
Gallini, N.T. and Trebilcock, M. (1996), IPRs and Competition Policy, Paris,
OECD.
Gambardella, A., Orsengo, L. and Pammoli, F. (2002), Global Competitiveness
in Pharmaceutical Industry. A European Perspective, for DG Enterprise of
European Commission.
Gana, R.L. (1996), The Myth of Development, The Progress of Rights: Human
Rights to IP and Development, 1996 Law and Policy 315.
Garg, R. et al. (1996), Four Opportunities in Indias Pharmaceutical Market, 4
McKinsey Q. 132.
Gatti, J. (1996), Mergers, Mergers, Joint Ventures and the Pharmaceutical Industry, 1996 EU Pharmaceutical Forum 1996.
Gelijns, A.C. and Halm, E.A. (eds) (1991), The Changing Economics of Medical
Technology, Institute of Medicine, Medical Innovation at the Crossroads Vol.
II, Washington, National Academies Press.
l E. Halm and A. Gelijns, An Introduction to the Changing Economics of
Technology Innovation in Medicine.
l P. Neumann and M. Weinstein, The Diffusion of New Technology: Cost
and Benefits to Health Care.
l H. Grabowski, The Changing Economics of Pharmaceutical R&D.
l L. Morteson, Public Policy and Access to New Drugs: The Case of Cancer
Chemotherapy.

220

Bibliography

European Policies Influencing Pharmaceutical Innovation.


P. Barton Hitt, Appendix A: The Impact of Regulation and Reimbursement
on Pharmaceutical Innovation.
l F. Spiegel, Appendix B: The Economics of Pharmaceutical R&D: an Industry Perspective.
Genevaz, S. (2004), Against Immunity for Unilateral Refusals to Deal in Intellectual Property: Why Antitrust Law should not Distinguish Between IP and
Other Property Rights, 19 Berkeley Tech. L. J. l 741.
Gerber, D.J. (19878), Law and the Abuse of Economic Power in Europe,
19878 Tulane L. Rev. 57.
Gerber, D.G. (1988), Rethinking the Monopolists Duty to Deal: A Legal and
Economic Critique of the Doctrine of Essential Facilities, 74 VA. L. Rev.
1069.
Gilat, D. (1995), Experimental Use and Patents, 16 IIC 1.
Gilbert, R. and Shapiro, C. (1990), Optimal Patent Length and Breadth, 21 The
RAND Journal of Economics 106.
Gilbert, R.J. and Sunshine, S.C. (1994), The Use of Innovation Markets: A Reply
to Hay, Rapp and Hoerner, 64 Antitrust L. J. 75.
Gilbert, R.J. and Sunshine, S.C. (1995), Incorporating Dynamic Efficiency
Concerns in Merger Analysis: The Use of Innovation Markets, 63 Antitrust
L. J. 567.
Gilbert, R. (1995a), Should Antitrust Enforcers Rely on Potential Analysis or
the Concept of Innovation Markets? at www.ftc.gov/opp/global/gilbert1.
htm.
Gilbert, R. (2001), Economics, Law and History of Patent Pools & Cross-Licensing Agreements, Franco-American Conference on Economics, Law and
History of IPRs, 6 Oct.
Gilbert, R. and Tom, W. (2001), Is Innovation King at the Antitrust Agencies?
The Intellectual Property Guidelines Five Years Later, 69 Antitrust L. J. 43.
Gitter, D. (2001), International Conflicts over Patenting Human DNA Sequences
in the US and the EU: An Argument for Compulsory Licensing and the Fair
Use Exemption, 76 NYUL Rev. 1623.
Glasl, D. (1994), Essential Facilities Doctrine in EC Antitrust Law: A Contribution to the Current Debate [1994] ECLR 307.
Glazer, K.L. and Lipsky, A.B. (1995), Unilateral Refusal to Supply under section 2 of the Sherman, 63 Antitrust Law Journal 749.
Glenken, J. (2002), Competition and IP Law and Policy in the Knowledge-Based
Society: Is there a Cause for Concern about Unilateral Refusals to Deal? in
DOJ/FTC Hearings on IP and Competition Law, 1 May.
Glover, G. (2002), Competition in the Pharmaceutical Marketplace before the
FTC, Proceedings on Competition and IPRS: A. Diverse perspectives on
patents. B. Business perspectives on patents. Biotechnology and pharmaceul

Bibliography

221

ticals, 19 March, see also http:www.ftc.gov/opp/intellect/020319gregoryjglover.


pdf..
Goh, A.T. and Olivier, J. (2002), Free Trade and Protection of IPRs: Can we
have one without the other?, Center for Econ. Policy Research, Discussion
Paper No. 3127.
Gohring, N. (2005), Qualcomm Accused of Anticompetitive Conduct in EU, 28
October 2005, available at www.infoworld.com.
Goldstein, J.A. (2001), Patenting the Tools of Drug Discovery, 2001 Drug Discovery World 9.
Gordon, H.S. (1954), The Economic Theory of a Common-Property Research:
The Fishery, 62 Journal of Political Economy 124.
Gordon, W.J. (1982), Fair Use as Market Failure: A Structural and Economic
Analysis of the Betamax Case and its Predecessors, Colum. L. Rev. 1600.
Gordon, W.J. (1984), An Inquiry Into the Merits of Copyright, 41 Stan. L. Rev.
1343.
Gordon, W.J. (1993), A Property Right in Self-Expression: Equality and Individualism in Natural Law of IP, 102 Yale L. J. 1533.
Gordon, W.J. (1994), Assertive Modesty: An Economic of Intangibles, 94
Colum. L. Rev. 2579.
Gordon, W.J. (1998), Intellectual Property as Price Discrimination: Implications for Contract, 73 Chic. Kent L. Rev. 1367.
Gorinson, S.M. (198990), Essential Facilities and Regulation, 58 Antitrust L.
J. 871.
Gorner, P. (2001), Parents Suing Over Patenting of Genetic Test, Chi. Trib., 19
Nov., p.1.
Gostin, L. and Mann, J. (1994), Towards the Development of a Human Rights
Impact Assessment for the Formulation and Evaluation of Health Policies,
1(6) Health and Human Rights: An International Journal 58.
Gould, D.M. and Cruben, W.C. (19956), The Role of IPRs in Economic
Growth, 48 Journal of Development Economics 323.
Govaere, I. (1996), The Use and Abuse of IPRs in EC Law, London, Sweet &
Maxwell.
Grabowski, H. and Vernon, J. (1979), New Studies on Market Definition, Concentration, Theory of Supply, Entry and Promotion, in R.I. Chien (ed.), Issues
in Pharmaceutical Economics, Massachusetts, Lexington Books.
Grabowski, H. and Vernon, J. (1987), Pioneers, Imitators and Generics A
Simulation Model of Schumpeterian Competition, 102 Quarterly Journal of
Economics 491.
Grabowski, H. (1991), The Changing Economics of Pharmaceutical R&D, in
A.C. Gelijns and E.A. Halm (eds), The Changing Economics of Medical
Technology, Institute of Medicine, Medical Innovation at the Crossroads Vol.
II, Washington, National Academies Press.

222

Bibliography

Grabowski, H. (2002), Patents, Innovation and Access to New Pharmaceuticals,


Mini-Symposium: Health and the WTO in 5(4) Journal of International Economic Law 829.
Grabowski, H. (2002), Patents and New Product Development in the Pharmaceutical and Biotechnology Industries, Science and Cents (April) (Federal
Reserve Bank of Dallas).
Greaves, R. (1995), Magill Est Arrive RTE and ITP v Commission of the EC
[1995] ECLR 244.
Greaves, R. (1998), The Herchel Smith Lecture 1998: Article 86 of the EC Treaty
and IPRs [1998] EIPR 379.
Green, J. and Scotchmer, S. (1995), On the Division of Profit between Sequential
Innovators, 26 Rand J. of Econcs 20.
Grossman, G.M. and Helpman, E. (1992), Innovation and Growth in the Global
Economy, Boston, MIT Press.
Grosvenor, R., To what Extent can Art 86 be used to compel dominant undertakings to supply competitors?, available at www.jumper.demon.co.uk/comm8a.
htm.
Groves, P. (1989), The Use of Registered Designs to Protect Car Body Panels,
1989 Bus. Law Rev. 117.
Gutterman, A. (1997), Innovation and Competition Policy, London, Kluwer
Law International.
Guy, D. and Leigh, G. (1981), The EEC and Intellectual Property, London,
Sweet & Maxwell.
Haddock, D.D., McChesney, F. and Spiegel, M. (1990), An Ordinary Economic
Rationale for Extraordinary Legal Sanctions, 78 Calif. L. Rev. 1.
Hahn, R.W. (2001), A Primer on Competition Policy and the New Economy,
AEI-Brookings Joint Center Working Paper No. 01-3.
Hahn, R. (2001), Cyber Rights, Protection, and Markets, 32 U. West L. A. L.
Rev. 159.
Haines, S. (1994), Copyright Takes the Dominant Position [1994] EIPR 401.
Halm, E. and Gelijns, A. (1991), An Introduction to the Changing Economics
of Technology Innovation in Medicine, in A.C. Gelijns and E.A. Halm (eds),
The Changing Economics of Medical Technology, Institute of Medicine,
Medical Innovation at the Crossroads Vol. II, Washington, National Academies Press.
Hammond, R.G. (1984), Theft of Information [1984] Law Quarterly Review
252.
Handley, L.A. (1991), Refining the Graver Tank Analysis with Hypothetical
Claims: A Biotechnology Exemplar, 5 Harvard J. Law & Tech. 31.
Hantman, R.D. (1985), Experimental Use as an Exception to Patent Infringement, 67 JPTOS 617.
Hardin, R. (1993), Valuing Intellectual Property, 68 Chi. Kent L. Rev. 659.

Bibliography

223

Harrelson, J.A. (2001), TRIPS, Pharmaceutical Patents and the HIV/AIDS


Crisis: Finding the Proper Balance between IPRs and Compassion, 7 Wid.
L. Symp. J. 175.
Harris, G. (2001), Bayers Cipro Will Be Profitable, Even on Discount Deal with
US, 26 October 2001 at http://lists.essential.org/pipermail/ip-health/2001october/002261.html.
Harris, J.W. (1996), Property and Justice, Oxford, Clarendon Press, 1996.
Harz, M.H. (1997), Dominance and Duty in the EU: A Look through Microsoft
Windows at the Essential Facilities Doctrine, 11 Emory Intl Rev. 189.
Hawk, B.E. (1988), The American (Antitrust) Revolution: Lessons for the EEC?,
[1988] ECLR 53.
Hawker, N.H. (1999), Open Windows: The Essential Facilities Doctrine and
Microsoft, 25 Ohio NUL Rev. 115.
Hawn, R.W. (2001), A Primer on Competition Policy and New Economy, Working Paper, AEI-Brookings Joint Center for Regulatory Studies.
Hay, G.A. (1995), Innovations in Antitrust Enforcement, 64 Antitrust L. J. 7.
Heller, M.A. (1998), The Tragedy of the Anti-commons: Property in the Transition from Marx to Markets, 111 Harv. L. Rev. 621.
Heller, M.A. and Eisenberg, R. (1998a), Can Patents Deter Innovation? Anticommons in Biomedical Research, 280 Science 698, 1 May.
Hogerzeil, H. (2003), Access to Essential Medicines as a Human Right, 33 Essential Drugs Monitor 25.
Holzapfel, J. and Lindenmeir, M. (2002), Empirical Survey on Genetic Inventions and Patent Law, OECD expert workshop on Genetic Inventions,
Intellectual Property Rights and Licensing Practices, Berlin.
Hovenkamp, H. (1999), IPRs and Federal Antitrust Policy Introduction, 24 Iowa
J. Corp. L. 977.
Hovenkamp, H., Janis, M.D. and Lemley, M.A. (2003), Intellectual Property
and Antitrust: An Analysis of Antitrust Principles Applied to IP Law, New
York, Aspen Law and Business, c. 2002, 2003 Supplement.
Hughes, J. (1988), The Philosophy of IP, 77 Geo. L. J. 287.
Hull, D., Atwood, J. and Perrine, J. (2002), Intellectual Property Compulsory
Licensing, 2002 European Antitrust Review 36.
Israelsen, N.A. (19889), Making, Using and Selling Without Infringement: An
Examination of 35 U.S.C.Sec.271(e) and the Experimental Use Exception to
Patent Infringement, 16 AIPLA Q.J. 457.
Jaffe, A.J. and Louziotis, D. (1996), Property Rights and Economic Efficiency:
A Survey of Institutional Factors, 4(2) J. of Real Estate Literature 137.
Jehoram, H.C. (2004), Copyright and Freedom of Expression, Abuse of Rights
and Standard Chicanery: American and Dutch Approaches, 26(7) EIPR
275.

224

Bibliography

Jensen, E. (1987), Research Expenditures and the Discovery of New Drugs, 36


Journal of Industrial Economics 83.
Jones, N. (1998), Euro-Defences: Magill Distinguished [1998] EIPR 352.
Jorde, T.M., Sidak, G. and Teece, D. (2000), Innovation and Unbundling, 17
Yale J. on Reg. 1.
Julian-Arnold, G. (1993), International Compulsory Licensing: The Rationales
and the Reality, 1993 IDEA 349.
Junnarkar, S. (1997), GeneChip Encodes DNA on Silicon, New York Times 15
March.
Kadidal, S. (1993) S. Kadidal, Plants, Poverty and Pharmaceutical Patents,
103 Yale L. J. 223.
Kahn, A. (19912), The Cutting Edge of Antitrust: Market Power: Market Issues
in Deregulated Industries, 60 Antitrust L. J. 857.
Kaiser, G. (1981), Competition in Telecommunications: Refusal to Supply Facilities by Regulated Common Carriers, 13 Ottawa L. Rev. 1.
Kamien and Schwartz (1982), Market Structure and Innovation, Cambridge,
Cambridge University Press.
Kamperman Sanders, A. (1997), Unfair Competition Law Some Economic
Considerations, in J.A.L. Sterling (ed.), Perspectives on Intellectual Property
Intellectual Property and Market Freedom, London, Sweet & Maxwell.
Kanwar, S. and Evenson, R.E. (2001), Does IP Protection Spur Technological
Change?, Economic Growth Center, Yale University, Center Discussion Paper
No. 831, June.
Kaplow, L. (198384), The PatentAntitrust Intersection: A Reappraisal, 97
Harvard Law Rev. 1813.
Kaplow, L. (1985), Extension of Monopoly Power through Leverage, 85 Colum
L. Rev. 515.
Karjala, S. (1999), Copyright Protection of Operating Software, Copyright
Misuse and Antitrust, 9 Cornell J. L. and Pub. Poly 161.
Karp, J.P. (1991), Experimental Use as Patent Infringement: The Impropriety
of a Broad Exception, 100 Yale L. J. 2169.
Kass, L.R. (1975), Regarding the End of Medicine and the Pursuit of Health,
40 The Public Interest 11.
Kassirer, J. (2001), Financial Conflict of Interest: An Unresolved Ethical Frontier, 27 Am. L. J. and Med. 149.
Kattan, J. (1994), Efficiencies and Merger Analysis, 62 Antitrust L. J. 513.
Kattan, J. (1995), Antitrust Considerations in Innovation-Driven Markets, 21
Can.-US L. J. 115.
Kattan, J. (1997), After the IP Guidelines: Trends in Intellectual Property Antitrust Enforcement, 1997 Antitrust 26.
Kauper, T.E. (1990), Art 86, Excessive Prices, and Refusals to Deal, 59 Antitrust
Law Journal 441.

Bibliography

225

Kelley, D. (1993), Is there a right to health care, The Objectivist Center, 1993
available at http://www.objectivistcenter.org/articles/delley_right-to-healthcare.asp.
Kenney, P.J. (1988), The Orphan Drug Act Is it a Barrier to Innovation? Does
it Create Unintended Windfalls?, 43 Food Drug Cosmetic Law Journal
667.
Kern, M. (1996), Recent Federal Supreme Court Decision on Experimental Use
and Compulsory Licensing, 3 (2) CASRIP Newsletter 2, Summer 1996.
Kezsbron, A. and Goldman, A.V. (1996), No Shortcut to Antitrust Analysis: The
Twisted Journey of the Essential Facilities Doctrine, 1996 Colum. Bus. L.
Rev. 1.
Kieff, F.S. (2001), Property Rights and Property Rules for Commercializing
Inventions, 85 Minnesota Law Review 697.
Killick, J. (2004), IMS and Microsoft judged in the cold light of IMS, presented
in the Competition Law Scholars Forum Workshop, Assessing the Boundary:
Intellectual Property and Competition Law, 9 September.
Kind, J.L. (2001), Concentration and Technology in Agricultural Input Industries, US Department of Agriculture Economic Research, AIB-763, U.S.
Dept. of Agr., Econ. Res. Serv. March.
Kirk, M. (2002), Competing Demands on Public Policy in WIPO Conference
on the International Patent System, Geneva, 2527 March.
Kitch, E.W. (1977), The Nature and Function of the Patent System, 20 Journal
of Law and Economics 265.
Klefenz, H. (2002), Industrial Pharmaceutical Biotechnology, New York,
Wiley-VCH.
Klemperer, P. (1990), How Broad Should the Scope of Patent Protection Be?,
21 Rand J. of Econ. 113.
Knable Gotts, I. and Kraus, J.G. (2000), Antitrust Review of New Economy Acquisitions, 2000 Antitrust 59.
Knieps, G. (2000), Deregulation in Contestable and non-Contestable Markets,
23 Fordham Intl L. J. 90.
Ko, Y. (1992), An Economic Analysis of Biotechnology Patent Protection, 102
Yale Law Journal 777.
Kobayashi, B. and Burtis, M. (2001), Intellectual Property and Limitations on
Contract: Antitrust, Pre-emption and the First Sale Doctrine, in J. Ellig (ed.),
Dynamic Competition and Public Policy, Cambridge, Cambridge University
Press.
Kolasky, W.J. and Dick, A.R. (2003), Celebrating 20 years of Merger Guidelines: The Merger Guidelines and the Integration of Efficiencies into Antitrust
Review of Horizontal Mergers, 71 Antitrust L. J. 207.
Korah, V. (1972), Dividing the Common Market through National Industrial
Property Rights [1972] Modern Law Rev. 634.

226

Bibliography

Korah, V. (1998), Compulsory Licenses and Incentives to Invest in Innovation


and Compulsory Licenses, Paris, OECD.
Korah, V. (1999), EC Competition law, London, Hart Publishing.
Korah, V. (2001), Competition Law of the European Communities, 2nd edn,
New York, Lexis Nexis.
Krummenacker, M., Are Intellectual Property Rights Justified?, http://www.na-n-o.com/ipr/extro2/extro2mk.html.
Kubalski, J. (2002), Comments on Patent Pools and Standards, for the FTC
Hearings on IP and Antitrust, January.
Kwoka, E. (2001), Non-Incumbent Competition: Mergers Involving Constraining and Prospective Competitors, 52 Case W. Res. L. Rev. 173.
Ladas, S.P. (1975), Patents, Trademarks and Related Rights: National and International Protection, Cambridge, Harvard University Press.
Hugh Laddie, Sir (2001), National IP Rights: A Moribund Anachronism in a
Federal Europe?, [2001] EIPR 402.
Laddies, J. (1996), Copyright: Over-strength, Over-regulated, Over-rated?,
[1996] EIPR 253.
Laherty, C. and Shibata, Y. (2001), Harmonization of Patent Term Extension
and Experimental Use Laws Related to Drug Development and Testing,
Comparative Patent law Seminar, Spring 2001 at http://www.law.washington.
edu/casrip/Harmonization/PDF/ExperimentalUse.pdf.
Lang, J.T. (1994), Defining Legitimate Competition: Companies Duties to Supply Competitors and Access to Essential Services, 1994 Fordham Law Inst.
245.
Lang, J.T. (1997), European Community Antitrust Law: Innovation Markets and
High Technology Industries, 20 Fordham International L. J. 717.
Lanjouw, J. (1998), Patent Protection in the Shadow of Infringement: Simulation
Estimations of Patent Value, Review of Econ. Studies 671.
Lao, M. (1999), Unilateral Refusals to Sell or License IP and the Antitrust Duty
to Deal, 9 Cornell J. L. & Pub. Policy 193.
Lawson, C. (2002), Patenting Genes and Gene Sequences and Competition:
Patenting at the Expense of Competition, 30 Federal Law Review 97.
Leaffer, M. (2004), Understanding Copyright Law, New York, Bender, 2nd edn,
1995; 4th edn, 2004.
Leary, V.A. (1994), The Right to Health in International Human Rights Law,
1(1) Health and Human Rights: An International Journal 1.
Lehmann, M. (1989), Property and Intellectual Property Property Rights as
Restrictions on Competition in Furtherance of Competition, 1989 IIC 1.
Lemley, M. (1997), The Economics of Improvements in Intellectual Property
Law, 75 Texas L. Rev. 993.
Lerner, J. (1997), An Empirical Exploration of a Technology Rate, 28(2) Rand
J. Econ. 228.

Bibliography

227

Lessig, L. (1999), Code and Other Laws of Cyberspace, New York, Basic
Books.
Lester, D., Implications of Magill a Fresh Perspective, at www.iael.org/newsletter/D2Lester.html.
Levy, R. (1999), The Pharmaceutical Industry: A Discussion of Competition
and Antitrust Issues in an Environment of Change, Bureau of Economic Staff
Report, FTC March 1999.
Li, J.J. (1998), Intellectual Property: Infringement: Doctrine of Equivalents:
Warner-Jenkinson Co. Inc. v Hilton Davis Chemical Co., 13 Berkeley Technology L. J. 199.
Libling, D.F. (1978), Property in Intangibles [1978] Law Quarterly Rev. 103.
Lichtenberg, F. (2002), Benefits and Costs of Newer Drugs: An Update, 2002
at http://www.nber.org/papers/w8996.
Lie, R.K. (2004), Health, human rights and mobilization of resources for health,
4 BMC International Health and Human Rights 4.
Linday, C.M. (ed.) (1978), The Pharmaceutical Industry, New York, Wiley.
l J. Schnee, Government Control of Therapeutic Drugs: Intent, Impact, and
Issues.
l J. Schnee and E. Caglarcan, Economic Structure and Performance of the
Ethical Drug Industry.
l D. Siskind, Contributions of the Pharmaceutical Industry to Improved
Health.
l Campbell and R. Smith, Profitability and the Pharmaceutical Industry.
Lipinski, T.A., Pekari, J.C. and Britz, J. (2000), Rethinking the Ownership of
Information in the Twenty First Century: Ethical Implications, 2 Ethics and
Information Technology 49.
Lipsky, A.B. (1981), Current Antitrust Division Views on Patent Licensing
Practices, Remarks before the ABA Antitrust Section, 56 Nov.
Lipsky, A.B. and Sidak, J.G. (1999), Essential Facilities, 51 Stan. Law Rev.
1187.
Litman, J. (2001), Digital Copyright, Amherst, Prometheus Books.
Loewenheim, U. (1995), IP Before the ECJ, 1995 IIC 829.
Lopatka, J.E. (2000), Antitrust at the Millenium: US v IBM, 68 Antitr. L. J.
145.
Loughlan, P. (2002), Looking at the Matrix: Intellectual Property and Expressive
Freedom [2002] EIPR 30.
Loury, G.C. (1979), Market Structure and Innovation, 93 Quarterly J. of Econ.
345.
Love, J. (1998), Bolar Exemption, at http://lists.essential.org/1998/pharm-policy/msg00004.html.
Love, J. (2001), Implementing TRIPS Safeguards with Particular Attention to

228

Bibliography

Administrative Models for Compulsory Licensing of Patents, WHO meeting


in Harare, Zimbabwe, 21 August.
Love, J. (2002), Perspectives on Competition and IP Law and Policy in the
Knowledge-Based Economy, FTC, http://www.ftc.gov/opp/intellect/020319
jameslove.pdf, 19 March.
Lugard, H.P. (1995), ECJ Upholds Magill: It Sounds Nice in Theory, But How
Does IT Work In Practice?, 1995 EBL Rev. 231.
Lunney, G. (1996), Re-examining Copyrights Incentive/Access Paradigm, 49
Vanderbuilt L. Rev. 483.
Machlup, F. (1958), An Economic Review of the Patent System, Study No. 15 of
the Subcomm. on Patents, Trademarks and Copyrights of the Senate Comm.
on the Judiciary, 85th Cong., 2nd Sess.
Mackaay, E. (1992), Economic View of Information Law in E.J. Dommering,
P.B. Hugenholtz and J.J. Kabel, Information Law towards the 21st century,
Deventer/Boston, Kluwer Law and Taxation Publishers.
Mackie-Mason, J.K. (2002), What about Unilateral Refusal to Deal?, in FTC/
DOJ Hearings on IP and Competition Policy.
MacLaren, M. (2001), Patently Unsatisfactory? Community Legislative Competence and the ECJ Biotech Decision, 2 German Law Journal 18.
MacFarlane, N., Wardle, C. and Wilkinson, J. (1994), The Tension Between
National IPRs and Certain Provisions of EC Law, 12 EIPR 525.
Mansfield, E. (1986), Patents and Innovation: An Empirical Study, 32 Management Science 173.
Mansfield, E. (1993), Unauthorized Use of IP: Effects on Investment, Technology Transfer and Innovation, in Global Dimensions of IPRs in Science and
Technology, National Research Council, M. Wallerstein, M. Mogee, R.
Schoen (eds), Washington, National Academy Press.
Marenco, G. and Banks, K. (1989), IP and the Community Rules on Free Movement: Discrimination Unearthed, 15 E.L. Rev 224.
Marquandt, P. and Leddy, M. (2002), The Essential Facilities Doctrine and Intellectual Property Rights: A Response to Pitofsky, Patterson and Hooks, 70
Antitrust L. J. 847.
Marshall, E. (2000), A Deluge of Patents Creates Legal Hassles for Research,
288 Science 255.
Maskus, K. (2001), Parallel Important in Pharmaceuticals: Implications for
Competition and Prices in Developing Countries, Report to WIPO 2001; at
http://www.wipo.org/about-ip/en/studies/pdf/ssa_maskus_pi.pdf.
Maurer, S. (2002), Promoting and disseminating knowledge: the public/private
interface, Washington DC, National Research Council.
Maurer, S. (2003), New Institutions for Doing Science: From Databases to Open
Source Biology, Conference Paper, European Policy for Intellectual Property,

Bibliography

229

University of Maastricht, November, at http://ist-socrates.berkeley.edu/


~scotch/maurer.htm.
McChesney, F.S. (2000), Antitrust and Property: First Principles, 2000 U. Chi.
Legal Forum 23.
McFetridge, D.G. (1998), Intellectual Property, Technology Diffusion, and
Growth in the Canadian Economy, in Competition Policy and Intellectual
Property Rights in the Knowledge Based Economy, R.D. Anderson and N.T.
Gallini (eds), Calgary, University of Calgary Press.
McGee, J.S. (196667), Patent Exploitation: Some Economic and Legal Problems, 910 Jnl of Law and Econ. 135.
McGowan, D. (2001), Innovation, Uncertainty, and the Stability in Antitrust
Law, 16 Berkeley Tech. L. J. 729.
Van Melle, A. (1997), Refusal to License IPRs: The Impact of RTE v EC Comm
(Magill) on Australian and New Zealand Competition Law, 25 Austr. Bus. L.
Rev. 4.
Merges, R. and Nelson, R.R. (1990), On the Complex Economics of Patent
Scope, 90 Colum. L. Rev. 839.
Merges, R. (1994), IPRs and Bargaining Breakdown: The Case for Blocking
Patents, 62 Ten. L. Rev. 75.
Merges, R.P. (1994), Toward a Third IP Paradigm, Rules Coase and IP, 94
Colum. L. Rev. 2655.
Merges, R. (1998), Commercial Success and Patent Standards: Economic Perspectives on Innovation, 76 Calif. L. Rev. 805.
Merges, R.P. (1999), As many as Six Impossible Patents Before Breakfast:
Property Rights for Business Concepts and Patent System Reform, 14 Berkeley Tech. L. J. 577.
Merges, R.P. (2001), Institutions for Intellectual Property Transactions: The
Case of Patent Pools, in R. Dreyfuss, D.L. Zimmerman and H. First, Expanding the Boundaries of Intellectual Property, Oxford, Oxford University
Press.
Merkin, R.M. (1995), The Interface Between Anti-trust and Intellectual Property
[1995] ECLR 377.
Metz, J.F., Kriss, A.G., Leonard, D.G.B. and Cho, M.K. (2002), Diagnostic
testing fails the test, 415 Nature 5779.
Michelman, F.I. (1987), Possession v Distribution in the Constitutional Idea of
Property, 72 Iowa Law Rev. 1319.
Miller, C.G. (1994), Magill: Time to Abandon the Specific Subject-Matter Concept [1994] EIPR 415.
Montgomery, J. (1992), Rights to Health and Health Care, in A. Coote (ed.),
The Welfare of Citizens, Developing New Social Rights, London, Institute for
Public Policy Research/ Rivers Oram Press.

230

Bibliography

Morse, M.H. (2001), The Limits of Innovation Markets, Antitrust and IP Newsletter, ABA Antitrust Section Intel. Prop. Comm., Spring.
Morse, M.H. (2003), Symposium: Antitrust Issues in the Pharmaceutical Industry: Product Market Definition in the Pharmaceutical Industry, 71 Antitrust
L. J. 633.
Mossinghoff, G. and Bombelles, T., IP Protection and the Pharmaceutical Industry, at www.oblon.com/pub/display.php?mossing- 7072.html.
Mossinghoff, G. (2005), Progress in the Pharmaceutical Industry, 14 March at
http://usinfo.state.gov/products/pubs/intelprp/progress.htm.
Motta, M. (2003), Competition Policy: History, Objectives and the Law, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
Mueller, J.M. (2001), No Dilettante Affair: Rethinking the Experimental Use
Exception to Patent Infringement for Biomedical Research Tools, 76 Wash.
L. Rev. 1.
Muir, I., Brandi-Dohrn, M. and Gruber, S. (2002), European Patent Law: Law
and Procedure under the EPC and PCT, 2nd edn, Oxford, Oxford University
Press.
Mully, T. (2004), Intellectual Property, Fundamental Rights (and Competition
Law): Do They Interoperate?, International Conference, Intellectual Property
Beyond Rights, Hanasaari Cultural Centre, Finland, 2526 October.
Mwalimu, U. (2002) U. A. Mwalimu, Implications of WTO/TRIPS in East
Africa With Special Emphasis on Pharmaceutical Patents, Economics and
Social Research Foundation, Workshop on Globalization and East Africa,
1516 April.
Myrick, M.E. (1992), Will IP on Technology still be Viable in a Unitary Market
[1992] EIPR 9.
Nacke, T. (1995), Abuse of Dominant Positions, at http://europa. eu.int/
comm/competition/speeches/text/sp1995_025_en.html.
Nelsen, L. (1998), The Rise of Intellectual Property Protection in the American
University, 279 Science 1460.
Nicol, D. and Nielsen, J. (2003), Patents and Medical Biotechnology: An Empirical Analysis of Issues Facing Australian Industry, Centre for Law and
Generics Occasional Paper No. 6.
Nimmer, M.B. (1970), Does Copyright Abridge the First Amendment Guarantees of Free Speech and Press?, UCLA Law Rev. 1180.
Nunziato, D.C. (2002), Intergenerational Justice Between Authors in the Digital
Age, 9(2) J. IP. Law 1.
Ordover, J. (1991), A Patent System for Both Diffusion and Exclusion, 5 J. of
Econ. Perss 212.
Osadci, A.V. (2001), General Description of the Property Rights Imperfections,
available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=270419.

Bibliography

231

Ostrom, E. (1990), Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for


Collective Action, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
Pate, G.N. (2002), Analysis of the Experimental Use Exception, 3(2) North
Carolina J. of L. and Tech. 253.
Patterson, M.R. (2000), When is Property Intellectual? The Leveraging Problem,
73 S. Cal. L. Rev. 1133.
Parisi, F. and Depoorter, B. (2003), The Market for Intellectual Property: The
Case for Complementary Oligopoly, in W. Gordon and R. Watt (eds), The
Economics of Copyright: Developments in Research and Analysis, Cheltenham, UK and Northampton, MA, USA, Edward Elgar.
Paulre, B. (2000), Is the New Economy a useful concept?, Universit Paris
Pantheon Sorbonne.
Pekari, C. (2004), Intellectual Property and Human Rights: Where to after the
first WSIS? at http://www.eumap.org/journal/features/2004/infohr1/infohr/
ipandhr/.
Perritt, H. (1996), Property and Innovation in the Global Information Infrastructure, 1996 U. Chi. Legal Forum 261.
Petersmann, E. (2003), Constitutional Economics, Human Rights and the Future
of the WTO, Aussenwirtschaft, 58. Jahrgang Heft. I, Zurich, Ruegger, S.
4991.
Phillips, J. and Firth, A. (1995), Introduction to IP Law, London, Butterworths,
3rd edn.
Pinto (2002), The Influence of the European Convention on Human Rights,
[2002] EIPR 217.
Piropato, M.A. (2000), Open Access and the Essential Facilities Doctrine:
Promoting Competition and Innovation, 2000 U. Chi. Legal Forum 369.
Pitofsky, R. (2001), Antitrust and Intellectual Property: Unresolved Issues at
the Heart of the New Economy, at Antitrust, Technology and Intellectual
Property Conference, Berkeley Center for Law and Technology, 2 March.
Pitofsky, R. (2001a), Antitrust at the Millennium: Challenges of the New
Economy: Issues at the Intersection of Antitrust and IP, 68 Antitrust L. J.
913.
Pitofsky, R. (2002), The Essential Facilities Doctrine under US Antitrust Law,
Paper Submitted to the European Commission in support of National Data
Corporation in its essential facilities case against IMS.
Pittofsky, R., Patterson, D. and Hooks, J. (2002), The Essential Facilities Doctrine under US Antitrust Law, 70 Antitrust L. J. 443.
Pons, J. (1998), Innovation and Competition, A View from the European Commission, speech at the 50th Anniversary of the Japan Trade Commission in
Tokyo, 1st December 1997, published in the EC Competition Policy /DGIV/
speech/eight/en/sp980xx.htm February 1998.
Posner, P. (2000), The Economic Effects of the Law Approach of Effects of De-

232

Bibliography

regulation on Competition: The Experience of the US, 23 Fordham Intl L. J.


7.
Price, D.R. (1990), Abuse of a Dominant Position the Tale of Nails, Milk
Cartons, and TV Guides, [1990] ECLR 81.
Rabinow, P. (1996), Making PCR: A Story of Biotechnology, Chicago, University of Chicago Press.
Rai, R.K. (2001), Fostering Cumulative Innovation in the Biopharmaceutical
Industry: The Role of Patents and Antitrust, 16 Berkeley Tech. L. J. 813.
Rapp, R. (1995), The Misapplication of the Innovation Market Approach to
Merger Analysis, 64 Antitrust L. J. 19.
Ratner, J. (1988), Should there be an Essential Facilities Doctrine, 21 UC Davis
L. Rev. 327.
Reagan, T.D. (1996), The Ascendancy of EC Law The Implications of the
Court of Justice decisions in Magill on the Balance Between National and
EC IP Law, 25 GA J. Intl and Comp. L. 681.
Reichman, J.H. (1998), Legal Hybrids between the Patent and Copyright Paradigm, in E.J. Dommering, P.B. Hugenholtz and J.J. Kabel, Information Law
towards the 21st century, Deventer/ Boston, Kluwer Law International.
Reichman, J.H. (2000), Taking Stock: The Law and Economics of IPRs, 53 Vand.
L. Rev. 1743.
Reichman, J. and Hasenzahl, C. (2003), Non-Voluntary Licensing of Patented
Inventions: Historical Perspective, Legal Framework under TRIPS and an
Overview of the Practice in Canada and the USA, UNCTAD-ICTSD Project
on IPRs and Sustainable Development, Issue Paper No 5, also available at
http://www.ictsd.org/pubs/ictsd_series/iprs/CS_reichman_hasenzahl.pdf.
Reiffen, D. and Ward, M. (2002), Generic Drug Industry Dynamics, FTC,
February, available at http://www.ftc.gov/be/workpapers/industrydynamicsreiffenwp.pdf.
Reindl (1993), The Magic of Magill: TV Program Guides as a Limit of Copyright Law?, [1993] IIC 60.
Rey, P. (2002), Competition and IP Law and Policy in the Knowledge-Based
Society: Is there a Cause for Concern about Unilateral Refusals to Deal? in
DOJ/FTC Hearings on IP and Competition Law, 1 May.
Richardson, D.M. (1987), The Orphan Drug Tax Credit: An Inadequate Response to An Ill-Defined Problem, 6 Amer. J. of Tax Poly 135.
Ridyard, D. (1996), Essential Facilities and the Obligation to Supply Competitors under UK and EC Competition Law, 17 ECLR 438.
Rifkin, J. (2000), The Age of Access, London, Penguin Putman.
Robertson, A. (1992), Compulsory Copyright Licensing Under EC Law?, [1992]
LQR 39.
Robertson, A. (1995), The Existence and Exercise of Copyright: Can it Bear
the Abuse?, [1995] LQR 588.

Bibliography

233

Robinson, C.O. (2002), On Refusing to Deal with Rivals, 87 Cornell L. Rev.


1177.
Rose, C.M. (1997), Property Rules, Liability Rules and Inalienability: The
Shadow of the Cathedral, 106 Yale L. J. 2175.
Rubenstein, B. (1996), La Roche and Promega in Tug of War Over Enzyme;
DNA-Testing Tool Patent at Issue, Corp. Legal Times, January.
Samuelson, P. (1989), Information as Property: Do Ruckelshaus and Carpenter
Signal a Changing Direction in IP Law?, 38 Cath U. L. Rev. 365.
Samuelson, P. Davis, R., Kapor, M.D. and Reichman, J.H. (1994), Manifesto
Concerning the Legal Protection of Computer Programs, 1994 Colum. L.
Rev. 2308.
Scherer, F.M. (1965), Firm Size, Market Structure, Opportunity and the Output
of Patented Inventions, 55 American Economic Review 1097125.
Scherer, F.M. (1972), Nordhaus Theory of Optimal Patent Life: A Geometric
Reinterpretation, 62(3) American Economic Review 422.
Scherer, F.M. (1977), The Economic Effects of Compulsory Patent Licensing,
New York, New York University Monograph Series in Finance and
Economics.
Scherer, F.M. (1984), Innovation and Growth, Boston, MIT Press.
Scherer, F.M. and Ross, D. (1990), Industrial Market Structure and Economic
Performance, Boston, Houghton Mifflin Co., 3rd edn.
Scherer, F.M. (1993), Pricing, Profits and Technological Progress in thePharmaceutical Industry, 7(3) Journal of Economic Perspectives 97.
Scherer, F.M. and Weisburst, S. (1995), Economic Effects of Strengthening
Pharmaceutical Patent Protection in Italy, 26 IIC 1009.
Scherer, F.M. (1998), The Patent System and Innovation in Pharmaceuticals,
Harvard University.
Scherer, F.M. (1999), New Perspectives on Economic Growth and Technological
Innovation. Washington, DC, Brookings Institution Press.
Scherer, F.M., Harhoff, D. and Kukies, J. (2000), Policy Implications of a World
Skew-Distributed Returns on Innovation, 29 Research Policy 559.
Scherer, F.M., Harhoff, D. and Kukies, J. (2000) F.M. Scherer, D. Karhoff, J.
Kukies, Uncertainty and Size Distribution of Returns from Technological
Innovation, 10 J. Evoly Econ. 17.
Scherer, F.M. (2000b), The Law and Economics of IPRS: The Pharmaceutical
Industry and World IP Standards, 53 Vand. L. Rev. 2245.
Schroeder, R.G. and Papas, P. (2001), Protecting the Balance of Hatch-Waxman:
Understanding the Industrys New Dynamics for the 21st Century, 56 Food
and Drug L. J. 19.
Schumpeter, J. (1942), Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy, New York, NY
Harper.

234

Bibliography

Schotchmer, S. and Green, J. (1990), Novelty and Disclosure in Patent Law, 21


Rand Journal of Economics 131.
Scotchmer, J. (1991), Standing on the Shoulders of Giants: Cumulative Research
and the Patent Law, 1 J. of Econ. Perss 29.
Scotchmer, S. (1999), Cumulative Innovation in Theory and Practice, Goldman
School of Public Policy Working Paper 240, University of California (Berkeley), February.
Seelen, C.M. (1997), The Essential Facilities Doctrine: What does it Mean to
be Essential?, 8 Marq. L. Rev. 117.
Seide, R.K. and McLeod, J.M., Response to Policy Commentary, Science at
www.sciencemag.org/feature/data/980465/seide.shl.
Semerano, S. (2003), The Efficiency and Fairness of Enforced Sharing: An Examination of the Essence of Antitrust, 52 Kansas Law Rev. 57.
Shah, S. (1999) S. Shah, Illuminating the Possible in the Developing World:
Guaranteeing the Human Right to Health in India, 32 Vand. J. Transnatl L.
435.
Shapiro, C. (2002), Competition and IP Law and Policy in the Knowledge-Based
Society: Is there a Cause for Concern about Unilateral Refusals to Deal? in
DOJ/FTC Hearing on IP and Competition Law, 1 May.
Shapiro, C. (2004), Navigating the Patent Thicket: Cross Licenses, Patent Pools
and Standard-Setting, UCLA Department of Economics in its series Levines
Working Paper Archive No. 122247000000000539, at http://haas.berkeley.
edu/~shapiro/thicket.pdf.
Sharp, M. and Patel, P. (2002), EIMS Studies, Europes Pharmaceutical Industry: An Innovation Profile, at www.cordis.lu/eims.
Shavell, S. (2002), Economic Analysis of Property Law, Harvard Law and
Economics Discussion Paper No. 399, Dec.
Shaw, J. (1999), The Specific Subject-Matter of Design Rights, 14 Eur. L. Rev.
99.
Shulman, S. (1999), Owning the Future, Boston, Houghton Mifflin Company.
Sidak, J.G. and Lipsky, A.B. (1999), Essential Facilities, 51 Stan. Law Rev.
1187.
Siebrasse, N. (2001), A Property Rights Theory and the Limits of Copyright, 51
Uni. of Toronto L. J. 1.
Singham, S.A. (2000), Competition Policy and the Stimulation of Innovation:
TRIPS and the Interface Between Competition and Patent Protection in the
Pharmaceutical Industry, 26 Brooklyn J. Intl L. 363.
Skinner, T. (1994), The Oral Hearing of the Magill Case, [1994] ECLR 103.
Smith, J. (1992), Television Guides: The European Court Doesnt Know Theres
So Much In It, [1992] ECLR 135.
Smith, S. (1997), The Changing Approach of the European Court to Intellectual
Property, at www.solent.ac.uk/law/ssmith2.html.

Bibliography

235

Snyder, E.A. (2002), in FTC/DOJ Proceedings on Competition and IPRs: A.


Diverse perspectives on patents. B. Business perspectives on patents. Biotechnology and Pharmaceuticals, http://www.ftc.gov/opp/intellect/020319
edwardasnyder.pdf, 19 March.
Soma, J.T., Forkner, D.A. and Jumps, B.P. (1998), The Essential Facilities
Doctrine in Deregulated Telecommunications Industry, 13 Berkeley Tech. L.
J. 565.
Springman, C. (2002), Competition and IP Law and Policy in the KnowledgeBased Society: Is there a Cause for Concern about Unilateral refusals to
Deal? 1 May, DOJ/FTC Hearings on IP and Competition Law.
Sterling, A. (1997), Perspectives on Intellectual Property, London, Sweet &
Maxwell.
Stern, R.H. (1998), Refusal to License IPRs and Monopoly Leverage [1998]
EIPR 390.
Stiglitz, J.E. (1995), Testimony of J.E. Stiglitz before the FTC Hearings on
Global and Innovation-Based Competition, 12 October.
Stothers, C. (2001), Refusal to Supply as Abuse of a Dominant Position: Essential Facilities in the EU, 7 ECLR 256, (2001).
Strauss, J. (2002), Genetic Inventions and Patent Law, in presentation at OECD
Workshop on Genetic Inventions, IPRs and Licensing Practices: Evidence
and Policies.
Strauss, J. (2002a), Patents and Health Issues, in WIPO Conference on the International Patent System, Geneva, 2527 March.
Subbiotto, R. (1992), The Right to Deal with Whom One Pleases Under EC
Competition Law: A Small Contribution to a Necessary Debate, 9 ECLR
234.
Sullivan, R. (1994), Estimates of the Value of Patent Rights in Great Britain and
Ireland, 18521876, 61 Economica 37.
Sung, L. (2002), Greater predictability may result in patent pools, 8 Feb., in
CPTech on Collective Management of IPRS: Patent Pools at http://www.ftc.
gov/opp/intellect/020417lawrencemsung1.pdf.
Tandon, P. (1982), Optimal Patents with Compulsory Licensing, 90(3) J. of
Politl Econy 47086.
Taylor, C.T. and Silberston, Z.A. (1973), The Economic Impact of the Patent
System, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
Toebes, C.A. (1999), The Right to Health as a Human Right in International
Law, Oxford, Intersentia-Hart.
Tom, W.K. and Newberg, J.A. (1997), Antitrust and IP: From Separate Fields
to a Unified Field, 66 Antitrust L. J. 167.
Topping, S. (1994), Finally Nailed Down, [1994] EIPR 543.
Treacy, P. (1998), Essential Facilities Is the Tide Turning?, [1998] ECLR
501.

236

Bibliography

Tritton, G. (1994), Articles 30 to 36 and IP: Is the Jurisprudence of the ECJ


now of an Ideal Standard?, 10 EIPR 422.
Tritton (1995), Intellectual Property in Europe, London, Sweet & Maxwell.
Troy (1983), Unclogging the Bottleneck: A New Essential Facilities Doctrine,
83 Colum. L. Rev. 441.
Trumm, T. (1998), Expansion of Compulsory Licensing Doctrine?, 24 Iowa J.
Corp. L. 157.
Tuffery, D.E. (1992), Experimental Use as a Defense to Infringement in New
Zealand, Patent World, Oct., p.22.
Tushnet, R. (2000), Copyright as a Model for Free Speech Law, 2000 Boston
College Law Rev. 1.
Ullrich, H. (2001), Intellectual Property, Access to Information and Antitrust:
Harmony, Disharmony and International Harmonization, in Expanding the
Boundaries of Intellectual Property: Innovation Policy for the Knowledge
Society, Oxford, Oxford University Press.
Ullrich, H. (2001a), Legal Protection of Innovative Technologies: Property or
Policy? in O. Grandstrand, The Swedish Intellectual Property Symposium.
Ullrich, H. (2002), Patent Protection in Europe: Integrating Europe into the
Community or the Community into Europe?, 8(4) ELJ 433.
Ungerer, H. (2000), Access Issues under EU Regulation and Antitrust Law the
case of telecommunications and Internet Markets, 5 Intl L. J. Comm. L. and
Poly 1.
Valentine, D.A. (1999), Abuse of Dominance in Relation to Intellectual Property: US Perspectives and the Intel Cases, at the Israel International Antitrust
Law Conference, 15 November, at http://www.ftc.gov/speeches/other/dvisraelin.htm.
Van Boven, T.C. (1979), The Right to Health, in R-J. Dupuy, ed. The Right to
Health as a Human Right, Workshop, The Hague Academy of International
Law and the United Nations University, Sijthoff & Noordhoff, Alphen aan
den Rijn, The Netherlands.
Van Der Kerckhove, M. (1994), The Advocate General Delivers his Opinion on
Magill, [1994] ECLR 277.
Van der Wal, M. (1994), Art 86: The Limits of Compulsory Licensing, [1994]
ECLR 231.
Velasquez, G. and Boulet, P. (1997), Globalization and Access to Drugs: Implications of the WTO/TRIPS Agreement, Health Economics and Drugs DAP
Series No. 7, Action Programme on Essential Drugs, WHO, Geneva,
November.
Venit, J.S. and Kallaugher, J.J. (1994), Essential Facilities: A Comparative Law
Approach, in B. Hawk (ed.), International Antitrust Law & Policy, Fordham
Corp. L. Institute 315.

Bibliography

237

Vicien, C.F. (1996), Why Parallel Imports of Pharmaceutical Produces Should


be Forbidden, [1996] ECLR 17.
Vignes, D. (1990), The Harmonization of National Legislation and the EEC,
[1990] EL Rev. 358.
Vinje, T.C. (2002), Magill: Its Impact on the IT industry, [1992] EIPR 397.
Wald, D.L. and Feinstein, D.L. (2004), Merger Enforcement in Innovation
Markets: The Latest chapter Genzyme/Novazyme, The Antitrust Source,
July.
Waldron, J. (1993), From Authors to Copiers: Individual Rights and Social
Values in IP, 68 Chic. Kent L. Rev. 841.
Wallerstein, M., Mogee, M. and Schoen, R. (1993), Global Dimensions of IPRs
in Science and Technology, National Research Council, National Academy
Press 1993:
l Global Dimensions of IPRs in Science and Technology.
l P.A. David, IP Institutions and Pandas Thumb: Patents, Copyrights and
Trade Secrets in Economic Theory and History.
l E. Mansfield, Unauthorized Use of IP: Effects on Investment, Tech. Transfer and Innovation.
l J. Armstrong, Trends in Global Science and Tech. and What they mean
for IP systems.
l O. Stamm, IPRs and Competitive Strategy: A Multinational Pharmaceutical Firm.
l J. Barton, Adapting IP System to New technology.
l G. Rathmann, Biotech Case Study.
l M. Borrus, Global IPR Issues in Perspective.
Walter, W.G. (1990), Compulsory Licenses and Dependent Patents, 21 IIC
532.
Walsh, J.P., Arora A. and Cohen, W.M. (2002), The Patenting and Licensing of
Research Tools and Biomedical Innovation, Washington, National Academies
Science, Technology and Economic Policy Board.
Walsh, J. and Cohen, J. (2003), Research Tool Patenting and Licensing and Biomedical Innovation, in Cohen and S. Merill (eds), Patents in the
Knowledge-Based Economy, Washington DC, National Academies Press.
Weatherall, K. (2002), Intellectual Property and Freedom of Expression, From
Speakers to Audience: Copyright and the Conditions for Speech, EUI Seminar
Sadurski.
Weatherill, S. and Beaumont, P. (1995), EC Law: The Essential Guide to the
Legal Workings of the EC, London, Penguin Books, 2nd edn.
Weissbrod, D. and Schoff, K. (2003), Human Rights Approach to Intellectual
Property Protection: The Genesis and Application of Sub-Commission Resolution 2000/7, 5(1) Minnesota Intellectual Property Review 1.

238

Bibliography

Welch, L.T. (1989), The Experimental Use Exception to Patent Infringement in


the USA, 19 Patent and Licensing 17.
Whish, R. (2000), Recent Developments in Community Competition Law, [2000]
EL Rev. 219.
Whitehead, M. (1990), The Concepts and Principles of Equity and Health, Copenhagen, WHO Regional Office for Europe.
Whitener, M. (2002), Competition and IP Law and Policy in the KnowledgeBased Society: Is there a Cause for Concern about Unilateral Refusals to
Deal? in DOJ/FTC Hearings on IP and Competition Law, May 1.
Wilson, A.M. (2000), Harmonizing Regulation by promoting facilities-based
competition, 8 Geo. Mason L. Rev. 729.
Wong, T. (2000), Intellectual Property [2000] EIPR 585.
Worthy, J. (1994), Intellectual Property Protection After GATT, [1994] EIPR
195.
Wright, R. (1991), Injunctive Relief in Cases of Refusal to Supply, 19 Austr.
Bus. L. Rev. 65.
Yamin, A.E. (2003), Not Just A Tragedy: Access to Medications as a Right under
International Law, 21 Boston University Interl Law J. 178.
Yi, S. (1999), Market Structure and Incentives to Innovate: The Case of Cournot
Oligopoly, 65 Economics Letters 379.
Yoo, C.S. (2002), Vertical Integration and Media Regulation in the New Economy, 19 Yale Journal on Regulation 171.
Yosick, J.A. (2001), Compulsory Patent Licensing for Efficient Use of Inventions, 2001 U. Ill. L. Rev. 1275.
Zanon di Valgiurate, L. (1982), Price Discrimination Under Art 86 of the EEC
Treaty: The United Brands Case, [1982] Internatl and Comparative Law
Quarterly 37.
Newspaper articles
P. Gorner, Parents Suing Over Patenting of Genetic Test, Chicago Tribune, 19
November 2000 p.1.
Hoffman-La-Roche Challenges Freedom of Researcher; List of Infringers Includes Hundreds of Researchers and Dozens of Government-Supported
Laboratories, Bus. Wire, 24 May, 1995.
S. Junnarkar, GeneChip Encodes DNA on Silicon, New York Times, 15
March1997.
P. Rabinow, Making PCR: A Story of Biotechnology, Chicago, University of
Chicago Press, 1996.
Should Congress Liberate Gene Data?, Chicago Tribune, 16 September
1999.
Striking a Balance on Patent Rights, Herald Tribune, 30 October 2001.

Index
AAAS (American Academy of Arts and
Sciences) 85
ABA (American Bar Association) 21, 22,
26, 126, 181
Abbott, F.M. 32, 58, 64
abuse of dominance
compulsory licensing and 150, 15961
essential facilities doctrine and 1678
proportionality and 1478, 1567
refusal of access to essential services
and 1546, 158, 1625
refusal to license and 15051, 1534,
163, 169
refusal to supply and 1479, 1514
requirements for 152, 1534, 156, 165
Treaty of Rome and 103
vertical integration and 1457, 149,
151
acceptability
right to health and 78
access
essential services, to, refusal of 1546,
158, 1625
see also technology access
accessibility
right to health and 78
ACIP (Advisory Council on Intellectual
Property) 47, 51, 52, 53, 54
Adcock, M. 88
agreement see MTA; TRIPS
Aguilera, M.C. 9
ancillary activity
reservation of, leverage cases and duty
to deal 13033
Anderman, S. 101, 106, 116, 129, 157,
160, 179
anti-commons
property rights and 10910
research fragmentation and 5, 6
anti-competitive conduct
remedy for, compulsory licensing as 63

antitrust
aims 101
compulsory licensing as interchangeable remedy with 189
control
effect on incentives to innovate,
IPRs and competition law
11619
recent recognition of, IPRs and
competition law 11921
essential facilities doctrine and 1334
intellectual property and, transition
from separate to unified fields
115
law see competition law; duty to deal
technology access problems and 1856
Aoki, R. 180, 186, 196
Areeda, P. 134, 135
Arora, A. 195
Arrow, K.J. 49, 117, 180
Attwood, J. 166
Austin, D. 22
Australia
compulsory licensing 64
experimental use exemption 47
Australian Department of Health and
Ageing 47
Austria
compulsory licensing and experimental use exemption provisions 66
see also EU
availability
right to health and 78
Ayres, I. 117, 182
Bailey, T.C. 55, 56, 177, 195
Baily, M. 28
Balto, P. 193
Banks, K. 104
Barinaga, M. 9
Barton, J.H. 32, 190, 196

239

240

Index

Battcock, R. 65
Belgium
duty to deal 154, 1612
see also EU
Bendekgey, L. 10
Benkler, Y. 23, 181
Bergman, M.A. 135, 164
Bhatnager, 59
Biotechnology Industry Organization 4
Birdsall, N. 71
Blackburn, R. 8, 177
Bloche, M.G. 83, 94
blocking patents doctrine
patent protection and 37, 49
see also patent
Boone, J. 126, 180
Boyle, J. 108
Brazil
compulsory licensing 59
right to health 94
Britain see UK
Britz, J. 90
Calabresi, G. 182
Campbell, E.G. 6
Carl, P. 78, 81
Carlson, S.C. 34
Carlton, D.W. 123, 124, 131, 193
case law
essential facilities doctrine cases, duty
to deal 122
intellectual property 946
patent system, technology access
problems impact on 18990
public health 934
refusal to deal under Art 82 EC 1479,
1512, 1713
denial of access 1546, 158, 1625
no effect on trade 150
refusal to continue joint venture
with competitor 1567
refusal to fully meet supply requests
to prevent parallel imports 170
refusal to license 15051, 1612,
1659
refusal to provide interoperating
information 169
refusal to share spare parts with
independent provider of
aftermarket support 1534

refusal to supply input to preserve


power in market B 1457,
15961
see also courts; dependence cases;
essential facilities doctrine;
leverage cases
Chambers, S.A. 8
Chapman, A.R. 85, 90, 91
Chetley, A. 73
Chien, C.V. 567, 118
Cho, M.K. 10
CL (compulsory licensing)
abuse of dominance and 150, 15961
antitrust as interchangeable remedy
with 189
blocking patents doctrine and 49
incentives to innovate and 118
new product for which potential
consumer demand and, preventing emergence of 187
patent protection and 37, 635
definition and history 54
EU Member State provisions for
669
grounds for 578
role of 5863
support and opposition for 546
public health case law and 94
research tools and, access through
patent law 182, 184
right to health and 70, 87, 913, 967
safety net, as, technology access
problems and 177, 1956
two-market requirement and 188
see also licensing
Clark, J. 51, 52, 53
Cohen, C. 3
Cohen, J. 6, 17
Cohen, W.M. 180
Cohen-Boyer Patents
research tool, as 8
Colombia
right to health 80
commensurability
compulsory licensing role in balancing
58
competition
IPRs and see IPRs, competition law and
potential harm to, refusal to deal and
1236

Index

Competition Commission (South Africa)


63, 1967
competition law
human rights approach to, technology
access problems and 1969
see also duty to deal; IPRs, competition law and
Conigliaro, M.J. 34
Connor, S.S. 72
Cornish, B. 88, 97
Cornish, W.R. 39
Correa, C. 32
courts
practice, IPRs and competition law
1036
see also case law
Cringely, R.X. 181
Cullem, G. 7
Cullet, P. 93
cumulative innovation
biopharmaceutical see R&D
patent breadth and 24
see also invention; patent
Dahdoud, T.N. 192
Dalp, R. 4
David, P.A. 212, 24, 107, 108, 109,
111
Davis, R.W. 190, 192, 194
De Santi, S. 180
deadweight loss
compulsory licensing desirability and
556
property rights and 111
demand see product, demand
Denmark
compulsory licensing and experimental use exemption provisions 66
see also EU
Department of Commerce, Patent and
Trademark Office (USA) 182
dependence cases
characterization unhelpful 157
duty to deal 122, 12830
see also case law
Depoorter, B. 126, 180
direct effect
patenting and right to health 878
Directives
Biotechnology 12, 37, 60, 945

241

Community Code Relating to Medicinal Products for Human Use,


amending 40
Database 119
In-Vitro Diagnostic Medical Devices
37
Legal Protection of Biotechnology
Inventions 27
Legal Protection of Computer
Programs 119
Rational Use of Medicines 27
Rental and Lending Rights 95
see also EU; legislation
DNA sequences
biomedical research tools and 912
patent trends effect on patent
balance for 13, 14
see also genetic diagnostics
Dolmans, M. 190
Domeij, B. 34, 41, 48
Drahos, P. 88
Dreyfuss, R.C. 180
Drlica, K. 9
Ducor, P. 42
Dupuy, R.-J. 73, 76, 79, 81
Dutfield, G. 31, 33
duties
right to health, under 79
duty to deal (Art 82 EC)
refusal to deal under 1223, 1434
cases see case law, refusal to deal
under Art 82 EC
competition and, potential harm to
1236
state of law on 1268
dependence cases 12830
essential facilities doctrine (EFD)
cases, indispensability
requirement and 13341
new product innovation 1412
leverage cases, reservation of
ancillary activity 13033
technology access problems and 1856
impact on patent system case-law
18990
indispensability 186
innovation markets in 1914
new product for which potential
consumer demand, preventing
emergence of 187

242

Index

objective justification, absence of


188
two-market requirement 1878
EC Treaty see Treaty of Rome
EFD (essential facilities doctrine)
abuse of dominance and 1678
access refused to essential services and
154, 158
antitrust and competition and 115
cases, duty to deal 122
exceptional circumstances and 166
indispensability requirement and 1335
indispensability 1357
objective justification 13941
two-market requirement 1389
refusal to license and 1659
Eisenberg, R. S.
experimental use exemption and 45,
46, 47
research fragmentation and 56
research tools and 8, 13, 14, 15
technology access problems and 16,
1812, 183
El Salvador
right to health 88
Elliott, R. 89
EMEA (European Medicines Evaluation
Agency) 267
EPO (European Patent Office) 367
Epstein, R.A. 178, 180
ESCRC (Committee on Economic Social
and Cultural Rights) 73
ESTs (expressed sequence tags)
research tool, as 8, 182
EU (European Union)
competition law 101, 103, 119, 121
compulsory licensing 60, 669
experimental use exemption provisions
669
intellectual property cases 946
patent protection provisions 38
patent systems and sources 25
reverse doctrine of equivalents 48, 49
right to health 745, 94, 97
right to health as human right, status in
law 714
right to property and IP 84, 86
Supplementary Protection Certificate
30

see also individually named Member


States
EUE (experimental use exemption)
patent protection and 37, 3943, 467
EU Member State provisions for
669
US experience 446
relating to in, interpretation of 181
research tools and, access through
patent law 1813, 184
European Commission
antitrust and IP and 115
antitrust control recognition and 120
duty to deal and 144, 157
existence/exercise distinction and 104
experimental use exemption and 181
innovation markets and 191
IPRs and competition law and 103,
121
technology access problems and
1989
European Group on Ethics in Science
and New Technologies 37, 70, 87
exceptional circumstances
essential facilities doctrine and 166
exclusive rights exercise and, interpretation 16061, 166
exclusivity
patronage, procurement and property
and, IPRs and competition law
10912
existence/exercise distinction
antitrust and competition and 115
IPRs and competition law and 1036
Fauver, C.M. 55
Feinstein, D.L. 192, 193
Feit, I.N. 12
Finland
compulsory licensing and experimental use exemption provisions 66
duty to deal 15051
see also EU
Fitzgerald, D. 162
follow-on innovation
compulsory licensing desirability and
55
patent protection and 367
blocking patents doctrine 37, 49
compulsory licensing see CL

Index

experimental use exemption see


EUE
patent pools 37, 513
reverse doctrine of equivalents 37,
489, 50
see also invention; patent
France
compulsory licensing and experimental use exemption provisions 66
patents importance, overstating 33
see also EU
FTC (Federal Trade Commission) (USA)
32, 193, 194
FTC/DOJ
Antitrust Guidelines for Collaboration
Among Competitors 191, 194
Antitrust Guidelines for the Licensing
of Intellectual Property 119, 120
Hearings on IP and Competition Law
195
Proceedings on Competition and IPRs
29, 118
Proceedings on the Pharmaceutical
Industry 29
Fuenzalida-Puelma, H.L. 72
Fysh, M. 43
Gambardella, A. 26, 27
Gwrg, R. 33
Gatti, J. 198
Gelijns, A.C. 26
genetic diagnostics
biopharmaceutical R&D and cumulative innovation 45, 6
research tools and 8, 9
patent pools and 52
see also DNA sequences
Genevaz, S. 116
Gerber, D.G. 131
Gerber D.J. 135, 138
Germany
compulsory licensing 61, 645, 67
duty to deal 129, 15051, 1659
experimental use exemption 40, 42, 67
patent pools 53
research tools, patent trends effect on
patent balance for 14
see also EU
Gertner, R. 193
Gilat, D. 39, 40, 41, 42, 46, 184

243

Gilbert, R.J. 24, 193


Gitter, D. 12
Glenken, J. 129
Glover, G. 28, 29
Goldman, A.V. 134
Goldstein, J.A. 15
goods see information goods; public
goods
Gordon, H.S. 113
Gorner, P. 97
Gostin, L. 78
Grabowski, H. 23, 27, 28, 29
Greece
compulsory licensing and experimental use exemption provisions 67
duty to deal 170
see also EU
Green, J. 24
Greenberg, A.C. 34
Grosvenor, R. 146, 157
Hahn, E.A. 26
Hamlet-Cox, D. 10
Handley, L.A. 48
Hantman, R.D. 41
Hardin, R. 110
Harhoff, D. 26, 29
Harvard oncomouse
research tool, as 8
Harz, M.H. 134
Hasenzahl, C. 54, 59
Hawker, N.W. 132, 135
health
emergencies, compulsory licensing
role in addressing 613
see also public health; right to health
healthcare
implications, biopharmaceutical R&D
and 45
Heller, M.A. 5
Hogerzeil, H. 97
Holzapfel, J. 6
Hooks, J. 138
horizontal dilemma
patent balance and 23
Hovenkamp, H. 56, 58
Hull, D. 166
human rights
approach to competition law, technology access problems and 1969

244

Index

right to life 80
see also right to health; right to
property
IACHR (Inter-American Commission on
Human Rights) 80
ICESCR (International Covenant on
Economic, Social and Cultural
Rights)
property rights and, public interest
limitations 86
right to health elements and 78
right to health sources and 756
right to health strengthening and 81
right to property and IP as human right
and 84, 85
see also legislation
incentive reduction
compulsory licensing desirability and
56
India
generic products and drug prices 82
indirect effect
patenting and right to health 889
indispensability
duty to deal and technology access
problems and 186
essential facilities doctrine and
1337
objective justification 13941
two-market requirement 1389
information
access see technology access
goods, IPRs and competition law
10912
see also knowledge
innovation
nature of biopharmaceutical 268
new product, duty to deal 1412
patenting and 2831
see also cumulative innovation;
follow-on innovation; patent
innovation incentives
antitrust control effect on 11619
compulsory licensing and 118
innovation markets
duty to deal and technology access
problems and 1914
optimal structure 17981
see also market

invention
commercialization, as patent system
rationale 223
dissemination
patent system goals and 234
patent system rationale, as 22
motivation, as patent system rationale
212
orderly cumulative development of, as
patent system rationale 23
see also patent
IP (intellectual property)
European cases on, fundamental rights
analysis and 946
human right, as, right to property and
846
system, competition embedded in
114
see also property
IPRs (intellectual property rights)
competition law and 101, 103, 121
antitrust control 11621
competition embedded in IP system
114
courts practice 1036
EC Treaty provisions 102
exclusivity, patronage, procurement
and property and 10912
information goods, patronage,
procurement and property and
10912
IPRs like other property rights for
purposes of competition
11213
public goods
market failure and 1079
patronage, procurement and
property and 10912
transition from separate to unified
fields 11416
see also rights
Ireland
duty to deal 1567, 15961
see also EU
Israelsen, N.A. 41
Italy
compulsory licensing and experimental use exemption provisions 67
see also EU


James, E. 71
Japan
compulsory licensing 61
Jehoram, H.C. 923
Jensen, E. 28
Julian-Arnold, G. 57, 59, 60, 62, 64
Junnarker, S. 8
Kallaugher, J.J. 134, 1589
Karjala, D.S. 1856
Karp, J.P. 183
Kass, L.R. 77
Kattan, J. 191
Kelley, D. 72
Kenney, P.J. 87
Kenya
generic products and drug prices 82
Kern, M. 39, 60, 645
Kezsborn, A. 134
Killick, J. 139
Kind, J.L. 181
Kitchm E.W. 21, 23, 24
Klemperer, P. 24, 117, 195
Knable Gotts, I. 191
knowledge
public good, as 1078
see also information
Ko, Y. 11
Korah, V. 56, 1489, 162
Kraus, J.G. 191
Kubalski, J. 51
Kukies, J. 26, 29
Kwoka, E. 192
Ladas, S.P. 59
Laherty, C. 42
Lang, J.T. 159
Lao, M. 185, 195
Lawson, C. 6
Leaffer, M. 184
Leary, V.A. 72, 73
Leddy, M. 138
legislation
Act Against Restraint of Competition
(Germany) 129
Affordable Prescription Drugs Act
(USA) 623
African Charter on Human and
Peoples Rights (Banjul Charter)
72

Index

245

Berne Convention for the Protection of


Literary and Artistic Works 119
Charter of Fundamental Rights of the
European Union 745, 84, 86
Civil Code (Netherlands) 92
Community Patent Convention (CPC)
39
Community Patent Regulation (CPR)
38, 39, 61
Competition Act (South Africa) 63, 197
Convention on the Elimination of All
Forms of Discrimination Against
Women 72, 76
Convention on the Rights of the Child
72, 76
Intellectual Property Code (France) 62
Drug Price Competition and Patent
Term Restoration Act (USA) 40,
46
European Charter of Patients Rights 75
European Convention on Human Rights
(ECHR) 84, 86
European Patent Convention (EPC) 15,
35, 36, 38, 39
European Social Charter 72
General Agreement on Trade and
Services 91
International Convention on the
Elimination of All Forms of
Racial Discrimination 72, 76
International Covenant on Civil and
Political Rights (ICCPR) 74, 86
Medicines and Related Substances
Control Amendment Act (South
Africa) 93
Orphan Drugs Act (EU) 30
Orphan Drug Act (USA) 3031, 87
Paris Convention for the Protection of
Industrial Property 54
Patent Act (Germany) 1516, 39, 62
Patent Law (Switzerland) 60
Patent Law Including Modifications
(France) 39
Patents Act (UK) 39, 60, 119
Patents and Plant Variety Rights
(Compulsory Licensing) Regulations 60
Public Health Emergencies Act (USA)
62
San Salvador Protocol 88

246

Index

Technology Transfer Block Exemption


Regulation (TTBER) 191
Universal Declaration of Human
Rights (UDHR) 734, 75, 84, 85
Vienna Convention on the Law of
Treaties 89
see also Directives; EPC; ICESCR;
Treaty of Rome; TRIPS
Lemley, M.A. 24, 34, 49, 56, 58
Lerner, J. 180
leverage cases
duty to deal 122, 13033
see also case law
Levin, R.C. 180
Levy, R. 178
license stacking
patent trends effect on patent balance
for research tools and 1314
technology access and innovation and
56
licensing
broad, compulsory licensing as
mechanism to induce 589
compulsory see CL
refusal
abuse of dominance and 15051,
1534, 163, 169
essential facilities doctrine and
1659
refusal to deal, as 124
Lichtenberg, F. 30
Lie, R.K. 73
Lipinski, T.A. 90
Lipsky, A.B. 134, 135
Llewelyn, M. 88
Loury, G.C. 24
Love, J. 46, 64, 196
Lunney, G. 137
Luxembourg
duty to deal 1512
see also EU
Machlup, F. 21, 24
Mackaay, E. 110, 114
Mackie-Mason, J.K. 124, 125, 126
MacLaren, M. 95
Mann, J. 78
Mansfield, E. 29, 30
Marenco, G. 104
Mark, J. 56, 58

market
failure, public goods and, IPRs and
competition law 1079
structure, optimal for innovation,
technology access problems and
17981
see also innovation markets; twomarket requirement
market-oriented experiments
experimental use exception and 40
Marquandt, P. 138
Marshall, E. 13
Maskus, K. 198
Maurer, S. 181
McFetridge, D.G. 56
McGowan, D. 191, 193
McLeod, J.M. 8
Melamed, D. 182
Merges, R.
IPRs and competition law and 110, 111
patent balance and 24
patent protection and 48, 4950, 51,
52, 53
research tools and 8
Merkin, R. 101
Metz, J.F. 10
Miller, C.G. 1056
Mongoven, J.F. 192
Montgomery, J. 77, 79
Morse, M.H. 192
MTA (material transfer agreement)
research tools and 7
Mueller, J.M.
duty to deal and technology access
problems and 181, 183, 184
patent protection and 36, 47
research tools and 7, 8, 9, 11, 13, 17
Mully, T. 83, 856, 95
Mwalimu, U.A. 82
Myrick, M.E. 104, 105
Nacke, T. 12930, 157
National Institutes of Health (NIH)
(USA) 13, 183
Nelson, L. 1213
Nelson, R.R. 24, 111
Netherlands
compulsory licensing and experimental use exemption provisions 69
see also EU


new product
innovation, duty to deal 1412
potential consumer demand existing,
preventing emergence of, duty to
deal and technology access
problems and 187
see also product
Newberg, J.A. 115
Nicol, D. 6
Nielsen, J. 6
Nigeria
right to health 80
NIH (National Institutes of Health)
(USA) 4, 7, 17, 177, 183
non-use
compulsory licensing role for 59
Norway
compulsory licensing and experimental use exemption provisions 67
Nuffield Institute of Biotechnology 4, 5,
910, 11, 13, 14, 17
objective justification
absence of, duty to deal and technology access problems 188
abuse of dominance and 148
essential facilities doctrine and
indispensability requirement and
13941
parallel trade restrictions and 170
refusal to supply and 149
obligations see duties
OECD (Organisation for Economic
Cooperation and Development) 3,
13, 27, 29, 52, 134
Ordover, J. 24
ordre public
right to health and 70, 87, 96
Orsengo, L. 26, 27
Oxfam 31
Pammoli, F. 26, 27
Parisi, F. 126, 180
Pate, G.N. 46
patent
blocking, doctrine, patent protection
and 37, 49
breadth, patent system goals and 24
dependent 49, 65
importance, overstating 313

Index

247

length, patent system goals and 24


pools, patent protection and 37, 513
pre-commercial stage 4, 1778
see also innovation; invention
patent balance
patent system as balancing system and
21, 235
research tools, for, patent trends effect
on 1215
right to health implications see right to
health
patent law
right to health and
effect of patent law on right to
health 823
effect of right to health on patent
law 83
interpretive principle, as 7071,
9093, 968
public-health case-law 934
technology access problems and 1815
patent protection
compulsory licensing as, technology
access problems and 177, 1956
European law provisions for 38
follow-on innovation and 367
blocking patents doctrine 37, 49
compulsory licensing (CL) 37, 635
definition and history 54
EU Member State provisions for
669
grounds for 578
role of 5863
support and opposition for 546
experimental use exemption (EUE)
37, 3943, 467
EU Member State provisions for
669
US experience 446
patent pools 37, 513
reverse doctrine of equivalents 37,
489, 50
impeding information access and
1415
patent system
balancing system, as 345
biopharmaceutical innovation
nature of 268
patenting and 2831
patent balance 21, 235

248

Index

patents importance, overstating


313
biopharmaceutical industry and 256
case-law, technology access problems
impact on 18990
EU existing 25
importance of, factors in 2930
main rationales 213
research tools and, technology access
problems 17781
safety nets see patent protection
patenting
biopharmaceutical innovation and
2831
increase in, healthcare implications
45
privatization and 5
right to health and 879
patronage
public goods, exclusivity and information goods and, IPRs and
competition law 10912
Patterson, D. 138
PBM (Pharmacy Benefits Management)
networks
refusal to deal and 178
PCR (polymerase chain reaction)
technology
biomedical research tools and 9
research tool, as 8
see also technology
Pekari, J.C. 90
Perrine, J. 166
Perritt, H. 108, 110
Pitofsky, R. 138
Pons, J. 191
Portugal
compulsory licensing and experimental use exemption provisions 68
see also EU
privatization
biopharmaceutical R&D and 5
procurement
public goods, exclusivity and information goods and, IPRs and
competition law 10912
product
demand not met, compulsory licensing
desirable where 545
see also new product

property
public goods, exclusivity and information goods and, IPRs and
competition law 10912
see also IP; right to property
property rights
specific subject matter doctrine and
115
see also IPRs; rights
proportionality
abuse of dominance and 1478, 1567
public goods
market failure and, IPRs and competition law 1079
patronage, procurement and property
and, IPRs and competition law
10912
public health
case law, patent law and right to health
934
compulsory licensing and 70
see also health
public interest
IP as human right and right to property
84, 86
quality
right to health and 78
R&D (research and development)
cumulative innovation and 37, 1618
biomedical research tools 912
defining research tools 78
patent trends effect on patent
balance for research tools
1215
see also research
Rabinow, P. 9
Rai, R.K. 4
Rapp, R. 193
Ratner, J. 139
Reichman, J. 54, 59
remedy
anti-competitive conduct, for, compulsory licensing as 63, 185
interchangeable, compulsory licensing
and antitrust 189
research
fragmentation, biopharmaceutical
R&D and 57

Index

nature of, recent changes in 3


see also R&D
research tools
biomedical, cumulative innovation and
R&D and 912
compulsory licensing usefulness and
58
defining, cumulative innovation and
R&D and 78
essential, technology access problems
and 1815
experimental use exemption and 40,
467
patent pools and 53
patent system and, technology access
problems 17781
patent trends effect on patent balance
for, cumulative innovation and
R&D and 1215
reverse doctrine of equivalents and 50
reverse doctrine of equivalents
patent protection and 37, 489, 50
Rey, P. 132
Richardson, D.M. 87
right to heath
elements 778
human right, as, status in European
law and 714
implications 767
obligation to respect, protect and fulfil
79
strengthening, international efforts for
80
sources 746
IP 846, 946
patent law and 7071, 823, 9094,
968
patenting and 879
right to property
IP as human right and 846
rights
exclusive, exercise of and exceptional
circumstances interpretation
16061, 166
see also IPRs; property rights
Robertson, A. 165
Robinson, C.O. 134
Ross, D. 118
Scherer, F.M.

249

duty to deal and technology access


problems and 181
IPRs and competition law and 116,
118
patent balance and 24, 26, 32, 33
patent protection and 56, 64
Schoff, K. 90
Schumpeter, J. 24, 180
Scotchmer, S. 23, 24
Seelen, C.M. 135
Seide, R.K. 8
Semerano, S. 118
Shah, S. 81
Shapiro, C. 24, 51, 52, 129
Shavell, S. 1089, 111
Sher, S. 193
Shibata, Y. 42
Sidak, J.G. 134, 135
Siebrasse, N. 112
Silberston, Z.A. 56
Sing, L. 52
Singham, S.A. 29, 33
Small, J. 180, 186, 196
SMEs (small- and medium-sized
enterprises)
independence, abuse of dominance and
1489, 150
Smith, S. 1045
Snyder, E.A. 30
South Africa
compulsory licensing 63
right to health 934, 98
technology access problems 1967
Spain
compulsory licensing and experimental use exemption provisions 68
see also EU
Springman, C. 195
SSM (specific subject matter) doctrine
existence/exercise distinction and 104,
1056
property rights and 115
see also access
Stiglitz, J.E. 3
Stothers, C. 1645
Strauss, J. 14, 53
Subbiotto, R. 151
Sunshine, S.C. 193
supply
refusal to 1479, 1514

250

Index

Sweden
compulsory licensing and experimental use exemption provisions 68
see also EU
Switzerland
compulsory licensing 60, 61, 69
experimental use exemption provisions
69
patents importance, overstating 33
Talley, E. 182
Tandon, P. 55
Taq (Thermus aquaticus YTI DNA
polymerase)
research tool, as 9
Taylor, C.T. 56
technology
PCR 8, 9
significant advances, CL role in 5961
technology access
competition law, human rights
approach to 1969
compulsory licensing as safety net
177, 1956
duty to deal (Art 82 EC) and see duty
to deal, technology access
problems and
impeded, patent protection and 1415
innovation and 1617
license stacking and 56
research tools and patent system,
conclusions
antitrust law see duty to deal
innovation, optimal market structure
for 17981
patent law 1815
patent system gap 179
research tool particularity 1778
see also access
Thailand
generic products and drug prices 82
Toebes, C.A. 71, 73, 74
Tom, W.K. 115, 193
Treaty of Rome (EC Treaty)
abuse by dominant undertaking and 103
Art 82 see duty to deal
existence/exercise distinction and 104,
105, 106
IPRs and competition law and,
relevant provisions 102

see also legislation


TRIPS (Trade-Related Aspects of
Intellectual Property Rights)
Agreement
antitrust control and 119, 120
blocking patents doctrine and 49
compulsory licensing and 57, 58,
185
property rights and, public interest
limitations 86
right to health as interpretive principle
in patent law and 90, 93, 94
right to health indirect effect and 889,
96
see also legislation
Troy, D.E. 134, 135, 139
two-market requirement
duty to deal and technology access
problems and 1878
essential facilities doctrine and
indispensability requirement and
1389
refusal to license and 169
see also market
Tuffery, D.E. 41
UK (United Kingdom)
compulsory licensing provisions 69
duty to deal 150, 1534, 15961
experimental use exemption 43, 69
patents importance, overstating 33
see also EU
Ullrich, H. 23, 112, 113, 11415
UN (United Nations) 80, 89, 90
UNDP (United Nations Development
Programme) 82
USA (United States of America)
antitrust control 119
biopharmaceutical innovation in,
nature of 28
Bolar exception 40
compulsory licensing 623, 64, 65
essential facilities doctrine 133, 134
experimental use exemption 446
innovation markets and 191
research tools, patent trends effect on
patent balance for 15
reverse doctrine of equivalents 35, 48,
49
right to health 94


technology access problems 194
two-tier R&D system, cumulative
innovation and 3
use see EUE; non-use
Van Boven, T.C. 73
Venit, J.S. 134, 1589
vertical dilemma
patent system goals and 23
vertical integration
abuse of dominance and 1457, 149,
151
leverage cases and 1312
Vinje, T. 104, 106
Voissiues and Partner 12
Walsh, J. 3, 6, 17
Walter, W.G. 61
Weissbrod, D. 90
Weisburst, S. 33
Welch, L.T. 41

Index

251

Whish, R. 164
Whitehead, M. 77, 88
Whitener, M. 131
WHO (World Health Organization)
compulsory licensing and health
emergencies and 62
Constitution 71, 73, 76
Declaration of Alma-Ata on Primary
Health Care 74
innovation and patenting and 31
right to health and 778, 79, 82, 87
WIPO (World Intellectual Property
Organization) 33
WTO (World Trade Organization) 312,
889, 89, 90, 94, 96
Yamin, A.E. 77, 78, 79, 81, 83, 88
Yi, S. 126, 180
Yoo, C.S. 133
Zanon di Valgiurate, L. 14950

Anda mungkin juga menyukai