Anda di halaman 1dari 15

Available online at www.sciencedirect.

com

Decision Support Systems 44 (2008) 606 – 620


www.elsevier.com/locate/dss

Customer-centric marketing with Internet coupons


Hsing Kenneth Cheng a,b,⁎, Kutsal Dogan c
a
Department of Information Systems and Operations Management, Warrington College of Business Administration,
University of Florida, Gainesville, FL 32611, USA
b
Visiting Professor, Department of Industrial and Information Management, National Cheng Kung University, Taiwan, ROC
c
Information Systems and Operations Management, School of Management, University of Texas at Dallas, Richardson, TX 75080, USA
Received 20 June 2006; received in revised form 2 August 2007; accepted 3 September 2007
Available online 12 September 2007

Abstract

We develop an analytical framework to examine customer-centric marketing with Internet coupons. We show that mass
distribution of Internet coupons without a customer-centric information system to identify customers' profile will have adverse
consequences that defeat the price discrimination effect of couponing. We analyze alternative strategies including distributing
Internet coupons to targeted customers with perfect and imperfect profile information of customers. The targeted coupons with
perfect information case amounts to dynamic pricing, but without customers' backlash. In the targeted customers with imperfect
information scenario, we consider Internet coupons with fixed face value as well as changing face value cases. We derive the
condition under which the firm should opt for the changing face value Internet coupons. As the firm's customer-centric information
system improves in terms of enhanced targeting accuracy at a lower cost, the changing face value Internet coupons will become
more prevalent.
© 2007 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.

Keywords: Customer-centric information systems; Customer-centric marketing; Internet coupons; Electronic commerce

1. Introduction centric” in the e-business era [2]. The resulting


fundamental shift in business and customer behavior
The proliferation of the Internet has led to heightened entailed by the ubiquitous Internet has never been more
global competition for businesses large and small. In pronounced in marketing — a core component of a
response, it has become fashionable or even essential for company's value chain that interfaces with customers
corporations to become “customer-centric” organiza- [27]. Hence, the goal of becoming a “customer-centric”
tions [14]. This translates to making their company web organization cannot be achieved without the presence of
sites “sticky”, their customers' “touch points” seamless- the “customer-centric” marketing.
ly integrated, and, above all, their businesses “customer- Customer-centric marketing refers to the practice in
which “marketers assess each customer individually and
make a determination of whether to serve that customer
⁎ Corresponding author. Department of Information Systems and
directly or via a third-party,” and customer-centric
Operations Management, Warrington College of Business Adminis-
tration, University of Florida, Gainesville, FL 32611, USA. Tel.: +1
marketing “focuses on the needs, wants, and resources
352 392 7068. of customers as the starting point of the planning
E-mail address: hkcheng@ufl.edu (H.K. Cheng). process.” [p.57, 28]. Customer-centric marketing is
0167-9236/$ - see front matter © 2007 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/j.dss.2007.09.001
H.K. Cheng, K. Dogan / Decision Support Systems 44 (2008) 606–620 607

different from one-to-one marketing in that one-to-one firm's optimal choice is to not provide coupons at all in
marketing adopts a product-centric approach by making this case as any level of coupon distribution hurts the
product the starting point of the planning process and firm's profitability. To benefit from distributing coupons
providing a customized product for each individual randomly over the Internet, the firm should make sure
customer. A good example of applying information consumers incur some disutility when they use these
technology to achieve one-to-one marketing is to use Internet coupons by requiring registration with the site,
consumers' online browsing and shopping-cart data to downloading software, printing the coupon and so on,
arrive at better product bundles [18]. Sheth et al. [28] which are practices adopted by such Internet coupons
also point out a clear distinction between customer- firms as Coolsavings.com, Coupons Inc, and ValuPage.
centric marketing and relationship marketing since Next, we present the model of a firm that provides a
customer-centric marketing needs to emerge first in fixed face value Internet coupon to targeted customers
order to have the practice of relationship marketing, but identified by customer profiling technologies. Using
not necessarily the other way around. fixed face value Internet coupons, firms benefit from the
This paper addresses various interesting issues low cost of distributing coupons over the Internet.
arising in customer-centric marketing with Internet However, this approach does not fully exploit the
coupons, an increasingly popular marketing mechanism customer-centric marketing ability afforded by the
made possible only by the Internet technologies. Internet. With the advent of tracking and personalization
Internet coupons, in essence, are those coupons technologies, firms can individually target each con-
distributed through the Internet. There are a variety of sumer and tailor its coupons according to individual
different ways to deliver coupons to consumers over the consumer's preferences and willingness to pay. In this
Internet. Interested readers are referred to Ref. [9] for an paper, we explore the models of changing face value
extensive review of Internet couponing firms, their Internet coupons involving two cases where the firm has
business models, as well as advantages and disadvan- perfect information or imperfect information about the
tages of Internet coupons.1 Firms benefit from using consumers.
Internet coupons as they provide customer-centric We find that it is more profitable for the firm to
marketing capability, easy tracking and measure, introduce the changing face value Internet coupons
flexible couponing process with short lead-time for when the cost of improving targeting accuracy of the
coupon drop, low coupon distribution costs, and higher firm's customer-centric information systems decreases.
observed redemption rates (reaching up to 20%).2,3 The consumer profiling cost is also an important factor
The objective of this research is to provide insights in choosing between a changing face and a fixed face
into such critical questions involved in implementing value Internet coupon. The impact of the customer
customer-centric marketing system with Internet cou- profiling cost, however, is not as significant as that of
pons as “How does mass customization and personal- the targeting accuracy cost.
ization affect business performance?” and “What are the This paper is structured as follows. In Section 2, we
economic effects of the customer-centric system?”. To first review the literature most relevant to our work. Then,
the best of our knowledge, this study is among the first we provide a critical review of Salop's original spatial
to provide analytical insights into customer-centric model to be extended later to examine various issues of
marketing with Internet coupons. customer-centric marketing with Internet coupons. In
In this paper, we first show that mass distribution of Section 3, we look at the mass distribution of Internet
Internet coupons will defeat the price discrimination coupons. Section 4 presents targeted Internet couponing
purpose of using coupons. Our model indicates that the models. The discussion of profits and prices as well as the
comparison of different Internet coupon models is given
1
There are four major players currently in the US Internet in Section 5. Section 6 provides concluding remarks and
Couponing Market: CoolSavings®.com, ValuPage® (owned by Super- describes some useful future extensions of our models.
Markets Online®, Inc. which is a subsidiary of Catalina Marketing
Inc.), Planet U™ and Coupons Inc. (formerly Storecoupon). Other
players include DirectCoupons.com, H.O.T.! Coupons.com, Coupon- 2. Review of literature and Salop's spatial model
Surfer.com, MyCoupons.com, Save.com. The first four represent the
majority and distinct ways to distribute Internet coupons. 2.1. Literature review
2
“Best Practices for Best Results in Internet Consumer Incentives.”
Planet U™ website.
3
“The ACP Guide to Internet Coupons,” The Association of
Extensive research has been devoted to examining the
Coupon Professionals, 2001, available online at the ACP website effectiveness of coupons in achieving objectives set forth
www.eden.rutgers.edu/boyden. by coupon providers. Blattberg and Neslin [6] provide an
608 H.K. Cheng, K. Dogan / Decision Support Systems 44 (2008) 606–620

excellent review of the literature on coupons, identifying model does not incorporate individual consumers'
“price discriminate” and “reach the appropriate target coupon use decision. A constant fraction of consumer
group” as two major objectives of coupons. Levedahl [20] population is assumed to be coupon users and the rest is
lends support to the price discrimination objective of assumed to be nonusers. Therefore, the face value of the
coupons. White [31] posits that manufacturers use coupon and the disutility of using coupon are not
coupons as a price discrimination tool to segment considered in Ref. [26] to determine coupon users and
consumers into two classes — those who comparison nonusers. Our models allow individual consumers to
shop and those who do not. Recent research by Gopal et decide whether or not to use a coupon when they receive
al. [13] discovers that Internet technologies help segment the coupon with a certain face value.
consumers into those who actively seek out coupons from Another stream of literature on coupons examines the
fatwallet.com and those who don't. Those consumers who objective of using coupons as a targeting tool. Refs.
actively seek out coupons and promotional materials often [3,24,29,33] give examples of coupon targeting through
engage in reselling at eBay. Narasimhan [21] theorizes direct mail programs such as Donnelly Marketing's Carol
that the consumers with lower opportunity cost for their Wright program. Shaffer and Zhang [26] state that
time are most likely to use coupons. He finds empirical coupons should be targeted to competitive firm's
evidence that coupon users are more price-sensitive. consumers to increase brand sales. With the advent of
Babakus et al. [4] offer further empirical evidence Internet tracking technologies, firms can now target each
supporting the price sensitivity argument. Our analyses individual consumer and tailor its coupons according to
focus on the price discrimination dimension of coupons in individual consumers' preferences and willingness to pay.
the dichotomy of [6]. Instead of one same coupon, different coupons for
Narasimhan [21] develops the model for individual different consumers can be issued for immediate online
consumer's decision to use coupons and finds that the use. Kumar et al. [17] construct an Internet coupon
trade-off between the value of coupons and the disutility distribution prototype to assure a smooth and secure
of using coupons determines which decision is made. couponing process. Rangachari et al. [23] describe how a
Chiang [11] endogenizes consumers' decision to use consumer's online behavior can be analyzed in order to
coupons in the overall demand decision and bases this determine her desire for a product. Adomavicius and
decision on consumers' utility maximization to measure Tuzhilin [1] present a data mining model that can be used
the impact of coupons on the category sales. Our study to develop personal profiles of consumers from their
analyzes a firm's couponing decision which takes into transactional histories. The firm can then decide on the
account individual consumers' decision process of Ref. coupon and the terms of the coupon according to the
[21]. information gathered.
There is a body of research that looks at the firm's In the next section, we provide a critical review of
decision process to use coupons as a strategic tool in a Salop's spatial model [25]. Using Salop's spatial model
competitive environment. Refs. [5,7,11,26] and most as the underlying model, we present several extensions
recently [22] analyze competitive effects of coupons. and generalizations to address issues related to Internet
Houston and Howe [16] provide a theoretical analysis of coupons in subsequent sections.
coupons as price discrimination tool under monopolistic
competition, while Ref. [22] finds support for price 2.2. Review of Salop's spatial model [25]
discrimination models in oligopoly settings.
The model developed in Ref. [26] is closest to the Consider the market for a single product where the
models developed in this paper. They develop a two-stage monopolist produces the product with constant returns
game theoretic model of pricing and coupon distribution to scale and at a constant marginal cost. Without loss of
to compare conventional mass-media coupon drop with generality, the marginal cost of production is normalized
targeted coupons based on consumers' past purchases. to zero. We use the product characteristics approach to
They use a linear spatial model to compare two types of product differentiation introduced in Ref. [19] and
coupon drop methods. They find that coupon targeting is developed by Ref. [25]. The market is modeled as a unit
not necessarily a replacement to mass media distribution circle. The customers are uniformly distributed over the
of coupons as the two methods work differently in unit circle. The total number of consumers is assumed to
segmenting the market. Our model differs from theirs as be constant and normalized to one. Consumers have the
we allow for different levels of mass media coupon drop same maximum willingness to pay for the product under
and calculate the optimal level of mass media coupon consideration. That is, consumers have a common
drop intensity. Another important difference is that their reservation price for the product, and this reservation
H.K. Cheng, K. Dogan / Decision Support Systems 44 (2008) 606–620 609

Table 1 Thus, d ¼ rp t . The marginal consumers who are distance


Summary of notation d away from their ideal product determine the size of the
r Common reservation price of consumers market.
p Price All consumers whose distance to their ideal product
t Fit cost
d Distance of the marginal consumer from the available product
is less than d will buy the product at price p since r − p −
di Distance of consumer i from the available product dit N 0 for all di b d. That is, all consumers along the arc
k Firm's total market coverage (share) from A to C will have a positive surplus. Since
k Coupon distribution intensity (fraction of consumers who get a consumers within distance d of point B will buy, the
mass distributed coupon) total market size of buyers is 2d. Let Π denote   the profit
C(.) Cost of coupon distribution
a1 Fixed cost of mass distribution of coupons
of the firm. Then, one has P ¼ 2dp ¼ 2 rp t p.
b1 Marginal cost of mass distribution of coupons The monopolist solves the following maximization
f Face value of the coupon problem.
fi Face value of the coupon given to consumer i h  r  p i
fm Maximum possible face value of the coupon Max P ¼ Max 2 p
x Distance of the marginal consumer in coupon segment from the p p t
marginal consumer in the no coupon segment  
r2p*
xi Distance of consumer i in coupon segment from the marginal First order condition requires dP dp ¼ 2 t ¼ 0. Since
d2 P
consumer in the no coupon segment dp2 ¼  4
t b0 for all t N 0, the second order condition for
x̂i Firm's estimate of the distance of consumer i in coupon segment maximization is also met. Hence, we find the solution as
from the marginal consumer in the no coupon segment
xm Maximum distance of the marginal consumer who is given
r r2 r  p* r
firm's changing face value coupon p* ¼ ; P* ¼ ; and d* ¼ ¼ :
b2 Cost of consumer profiling 2 2t t 2t
q Targeting accuracy
a2 Targeting accuracy cost Let k be the percentage of the market that is covered, or
simply the market coverage. Then, k* ¼ 2d* ¼ rt. When
r ≥ t, it is optimal for the monopolist to serve all
price is denoted by r. Each consumer is assumed to consumers. If r b t, some consumers are not served at the
purchase at most a single unit of the product, and all equilibrium. We assume that r b t so that the monopolist
consumers have perfect information about different has incentive to introduce coupons to those customers
market offerings and prices. A summary of the notation who would not purchase otherwise.
used in the paper is given in Table 1.
Consumers have heterogeneous preferences and are 3. Mass distribution of Internet coupons with no
uniformly distributed along the unit circle according to targeting
their preferences for the product. Each consumer's
location on the unit circle represents her ideal product. When a firm does not have a customer-centric
Consumers incur a fit cost t per unit distance, as they fall information system to acquire individual consumers'
away from their ideal product. The fit cost represents preferences, it cannot differentiate its coupon provision
consumers' dissatisfaction due to the difference between among consumers according to consumers' locations in
the characteristics of the product supplied by the firm
and those of consumers' ideal product. A product is
represented by a point on the unit circle. The product is
provided at price p. All of these assumptions are
commonly made in the economics, marketing, and
information systems literature, see Ref. [8,12,15].
In Fig. 1, the monopolist markets the product at point
B. We define the “marginal” consumers, located at points
A and C in Fig. 1, as those who are indifferent between
buying and doing without the product offered at point B.
These two marginal consumers (A and C) are indifferent
between buying and not buying, and the following
equation holds.

r  p  dt ¼ 0 ð1Þ Fig. 1. Salop's spatial model [25].


610 H.K. Cheng, K. Dogan / Decision Support Systems 44 (2008) 606–620

the market, or some proxy thereof. The firm's only buy the product without a coupon will not buy if they do
choice is to distribute coupons randomly, either through not receive a coupon. If this latter segment of customers
traditional coupons distribution methods or over the receives a coupon, their purchase decision will depend
Internet. As the cost of distributing coupons over the on the face value of the coupon. Let the “marginal”
Internet is lower than the traditional distribution consumers of this group, represented by D and E in
channels, the firm will naturally choose to distribute Fig. 2, be those who receive the coupon with the face
them over the Internet. Using traditional paper coupons value f and are indifferent between buying and not
requires certain effort on the consumers' part to clip, buying. Then, one has
organize, and use them. This required effort is what
allows firms to use traditional coupons as price r  p  dt  xt þ f ¼ 0; ð2Þ
discrimination tools. Cheng et al. [10] model this effort where x denotes this segment of consumers who will
and find that this effort is very critical to the success of a buy the product only with coupon.
couponing campaign. However, for some mechanisms Since r−p−dt= 0 describes the decision of marginal
of Internet couponing that we describe earlier, this consumers A and C of the segment of consumers who will
consumer's effort on using the coupons distributed over buy the product with or without the coupon, we have x ¼ ft .
the Internet is negligible. In this section we show the Therefore, the expected value of x can be found as
undesirable consequence to the firm when the disutility
of using Internet coupons becomes essentially zero. kf
E ð xÞ ¼ P
x ¼ PrfReceiving a coupong  x ¼ :
Assume that the firm will give coupons to λ fraction t
of consumers randomly. Furthermore, we assume that The same result can be derived if we look at the
each consumer is equally likely to receive a coupon problem from a different perspective. Assume that the
from the firm. Therefore, the probability that a consumer marginal consumers get the coupon for sure but the face
will get a coupon is λ. The costs of distributing coupons value of the coupon is a random variable. The face value
in this case will be linear in this fraction (or probability). of the coupon is f with probability λ, and 0 with
This is because the marginal cost of distributing probability 1 − λ. Therefore, the expected value of the
coupons over the Internet is constant in the number of coupon face value is E( f ) = f¯= λf + (1 − λ)0 = λf. Hence
consumers that receive the coupons. Our cost function C the expected value of x can be calculated as follows.
(λ) will take the following form:
  P
P f Eð f Þ f kf
C ðkÞ ¼ a1 þ b1 k: x ¼ E ð xÞ ¼ E ¼ ¼ ¼ :
t t t t
In this case, consumers who would buy without a
The total revenue of the firm consists of two parts.
coupon will still buy using the coupon, if they receive
The first part of the revenue, denoted by Π1, is derived
one, since there is no disutility associated with using the
from the segment of consumers who will buy the
coupon. This segment of consumers is represented by
product even without a coupon. For this segment
the arc AC in Fig. 2 with λ proportion of them receiving
of consumers, the λ fraction of consumers who get
and using the coupon. The consumers who would not
the coupon and use it will pay ( p − f ) whereas the others
1 − λ fraction pay the full price p. Hence, Π1 = 2[(1 − λ)
dp + λd( p − f )]. The second part of the revenue, denoted
by Π2, results from the segment of consumers who will
not buy the product without a coupon. Thus, P2 ¼
P
2 xð p  f Þ ¼ 2kft ð p  f Þ. Taking all revenues and cost
into consideration, the firm's total profit equals ΠTotal =
Π1 + Π2 − C(λ). That is,
2kf
PTotal ¼ 2½ð1  kÞdp þ kd ð p  f Þ þ ð p  f Þ  a1  b1 k:
t

After some algebra, we have the following profit


function for the monopolist.

2 
PTotal ¼ rp  p2  krf þ 2kpf  kf 2  a1  b1 k:
Fig. 2. Internet coupons with negligible disutility of using coupons. t
H.K. Cheng, K. Dogan / Decision Support Systems 44 (2008) 606–620 611

Then the firm solves the following problem. Cheng et al. [10] examine the case for mass media
 distributed paper coupons that impose disutility of usage to
2 
Max rp  p  krf þ 2kpf  kf  a1  b1 k
2 2 consumers. They find similar conclusions for paper
p;f ;k t coupons. Using the Internet for mass distribution of
ð3Þ coupons without targeting prevents the firm from realizing
all the benefits the Internet has to offer. In the next section,
Subject To we analyze the targeted distribution of Internet coupons as
0VkV1 ð4Þ an alternative to mass distribution.

0VpVr ð5Þ 4. Models of targeted Internet coupons

0Vf Vp ð6Þ Internet coupons are revolutionary mechanisms for the


firm to achieve customer-centric marketing capabilities as
rp 1 the Internet technology enables the firm to target
0V V ð7Þ individual consumers. This section models a monopolist's
t 2
decision to use Internet coupons to target consumers
f 1 rp according to their preferences for the product with an aim
0V V  ð8Þ to improve its profits. In Section 4.1, we first analyze a
t 2 t
benchmark case where a firm can target consumers
The constraints given in inequalities (4), (5), and (6) perfectly without incurring any costs. This model is rather
guarantee nonnegative and feasible values for the unrealistic and is used only as the base model for
decision variables λ, p, and f. Inequality (7) makes comparison with more realistic models that include costs
sure that the size of the segment d is between 0 and one of consumer profiling and imperfect targeting introduced
half. Finally, inequality (8) ensures that the size of the x in Section 4.2. With imperfect targeting and costs of
segment is nonnegative and not greater than the consumer profiling, the firm has two alternatives to induce
remaining market size 1/2 − d. The solution of this customers to buy the product by providing them with
model leads to4 either a coupon with fixed face value or a different coupon
ð1  k* Þf * ¼ 0: with changing face value for each individual consumer.
For both models in Section 4.2, we follow a two-period
This implies two cases — either f ⁎ is 0 and λ⁎ is pricing and couponing process. In the first period, the firm
free, or λ⁎ is 1 and f ⁎ is free. In the first case, the model introduces the product and makes the pricing decision.
suggests no issuance of coupon, as zero face value The firm's customer-centric information system records
implies no coupon distribution. In the second case those consumers who buy the product without a coupon in
where λ⁎ = 1, we have P*Total ¼ r2t  a1  b1 : This profit
2
the first period. The firm targets those consumers with a
figure is less than that of the no coupon issuance case. high fit cost who would not be able to buy the product at
Therefore, the firm's optimal choice will be to provide the regular price by introducing coupons in the second
no coupons at all. Without a customer-centric informa- period. The firm's objective in the second period is to find
tion system to help targeting consumers, a mass the most effective form and optimal face value of Internet
distribution of Internet coupons does not help the pro- coupons. We ignore the discount factor in our two-period
fitability of the firm. This results from the fact that the model for simplicity.
firm will not be able to price discriminate when the
disutility (i.e. effort) to use the Internet coupons 4.1. Targeted coupons with free perfect information
becomes negligible.
In order for the firm to still be able to price discriminate, When the firm has detailed information regarding
it needs a mechanism to impose certain effort for the consumers' shopping behavior and preferences, it can
consumers to use coupons, even with Internet coupons. estimate their willingness to pay. With the flexibility
For instance, Coolsavings.com and Coupons Inc. require a afforded by customer-centric information systems, firms
software download. ValuPage grants no immediate cash can change the face value of their coupon offerings
discount, the reward can only be redeemed at the next visit. according to individual consumers' preferences and
shopping behavior. Instead of one same coupon,
4
The solution details to this model as well as the solutions to customized coupon for each consumer can be issued
subsequent models in this paper have been delegated to the Appendix. for immediate online use. We assume that the coupon is
612 H.K. Cheng, K. Dogan / Decision Support Systems 44 (2008) 606–620

given for one product and it is instantaneous as soon as Both A and C are distance d away from the product and
the face value is determined. Coupons distributed this hence incur fit cost dt. For these consumers, r− p − dt= 0
way will not impose any disutility of usage. holds and we have d ¼ rp t . The profit for this
 no  coupon
With the help of coupons, a monopolist can charge (NC) segment is given by PNC ¼ 2dp ¼ 2 rp t p.
higher prices to some consumers and lower prices to To entice those consumers who did not buy the product
others and segment consumers effectively. However, with at price p in the first period, the firm decides to issue them
traditional paper coupons the firm is limited to very small coupons in the second period. Instead of distributing one
number of different coupons. In practice, a conventional fixed face value Internet coupon, the firm can tailor the
firm generally uses one coupon with the same face value coupon for each individual consumer. The firm's choice
for all consumers. Customer-centric information systems of the coupon face value for individual i, denoted by fi, is
enable firms to target their consumers in ways that were just enough to induce consumer i to buy the product.
considered infeasible before. Since r − p − dt = 0, r − p − dit b 0 for all di N d. If we let xi
We again consider a monopolistic market for a single denote consumer i's distance from the closest marginal
product with the exact same characteristics described in consumer at point A or C, we have di = d + xi. Thus,
Section 3 — zero marginal production cost, product consumer i's net utility for the product is
characteristics approach to product differentiation, unit
circle model with the total number of consumers uniformly r  p  ðd þ xi Þt ¼ r  p  dt  xi t ¼ xi t:
distributed and normalized to one, a common reservation
price r, and heterogeneous consumer preferences repre- Then, the following condition should hold to make
sented by the fit cost t. consumer i buy the product: − xit + fi ≥ 0. As we assume
In the model of targeted coupons with perfect infor- that the consumers who are indifferent will buy the
mation, we assume that each consumer's true location on product, the firm should set the face value of the coupon
the unit circle can be identified perfectly with an infor- for consumer i equal to the incremental fit cost this
mation gathering mechanism. The firm may offer Internet consumer incurs compared to the closest marginal
coupons to interested customers only if they provide rele- consumer A or C. That is, at optimality we have fi = xit.
vant information to the firm. For instance, the users of Since we assume no cost of producing an extra unit of
ValuPage.com Internet coupons need to register their pref- the product, the firm is willing to provide coupon face value
erences along with zip code information in order to receive up to p, i.e., fi ≤p. Let m denote the consumer with the
the desired coupons. We assume that the cost of the perfect largest negative net utility for the product before receiving a
information is fixed and normalized to zero. This unrealistic coupon, and let xm denote her distance from the closest
assumption will be relaxed in subsequent models. marginal consumer. This implies fm =p or similarly xmt =p.
Fig. 3 describes the essence of the model of targeted Hence, xm ¼ pt. Therefore, the firm will provide coupon
coupons with perfect information. The firm's product is face value, fi =xit for all xi V pt. The firm's profit from the
marketed at point B. Assume that the two marginal coupon segment can be calculated accordingly.
consumers located at points A and C are indifferent In this benchmark model we assume that the process
between buying and not buying the product at price p. of learning consumers' location can be done without any
costs. The firm's profit from the coupon segment is
Z xm Z p
t
PC ¼ 2 ð p  f ð xÞÞdx ¼ 2 ð p  xt Þdx:
0 0

Hence, the total profit is given by


 r  p Z p
t
PTotal ¼ PNC þ PC ¼ 2 p þ 2 ð p  xt Þdx
t 0
2rp  p2
¼ :
t
Then, the firm' problem can be formulated as follows.


2rp  p2
Max ð9Þ
Fig. 3. Targeted Internet coupons with perfect information. p t
H.K. Cheng, K. Dogan / Decision Support Systems 44 (2008) 606–620 613

Subject To One possible reason for consumers' more favorable


reactions to achieving the same outcome of dynamic
0VpVr ð10Þ pricing by dynamic coupons may be the fact that the price
is announced and known by all consumers. All consumers
rp 1 observe the same disclosed price but not necessarily the
0V V ð11Þ
t 2 face value of coupons when they visit the firm's online
establishment. With the use of dynamic coupons,
p 1 rp consumers might very well feel that they are getting a
0V V  ð12Þ
t 2 t good deal on the product. Much research is needed to
uncover the exact psychological reasoning of consumers.
The constraint in inequality (10) is straightforward. However, it is beyond the scope of this study. We are not
Inequalities (11) and (12) are the same as inequalities (7) interested in why consumers react differently, but rather
and (8) presented earlier. what the firm should do, given these different reactions, to
We find the solution to this problem as (see the effectively price discriminate, serve more consumers, and
Appendix) improve its profits with Internet coupons along the way. In
the next section, we relax some of the assumptions made
* ¼ r2
p* ¼ r; PTotal ; and d* ¼ 0: in the benchmark model and analyze Internet coupon
t targeting with imperfect and costly information.
The market coverage k* ¼ 2rt. When rz 2t , it is optimal
for the monopolist to serve all consumers. If rb 2t , some 4.2. Targeted coupons with imperfect information
consumers are not served at the monopolist's optimal price.
The results of this basic model amounts to perfect (first- With imperfect and costly information, the firm can
degree) price discrimination. Each individual consumer is choose between providing a fixed face value coupon or
charged her true reservation price for the product. However, changing face value coupons to different consumers. In
this is not achieved through dynamic pricing but through the following two subsections, we present models for
the use of the changing face value coupons. The end results these two alternatives. We first analyze the fixed face
in these two alternatives are virtually the same; however, value coupons case.
they generate different perceptions among consumers.
When Amazon.com was found to use its enormous 4.2.1. Fixed face value Internet coupons to targeted
consumer information database to price discriminate, consumers
charging higher prices to loyal consumers that are frequent We model the couponing process as a two-period
purchasers and supposedly less price sensitive, the decision process. As the consumers who buy without the
consumers' reaction was nothing short of a backlash coupon reveal themselves in the first period, the firm has
[30]. Amazon.com denied the allegations of implementing no interest in targeting these consumers. It will not give
dynamic pricing and claimed that it was merely running coupons to those consumers who would buy its product at
price tests. Even though dynamic pricing has been price p and let them buy the product without a coupon in
effectively used in such industries as airline and travel the first period. The firm will issue its Internet coupon in
industries, its use by an online firm to sell DVDs stirred up the second period. Fig. 4 displays the dynamics of this
a lot of negative emotion among consumers. couponing model.
The situation is rather different with coupons. The The marginal consumers in the no coupon segment are
use of coupons as price discrimination tool does not located at points A and C, and thus r − p − dt = 0 holds at
seem to have the same adverse effect that dynamic these two points. In the segment where the coupon is
pricing has on consumers. Jupiter Media Metrix analyst provided, the marginal consumers who are indifferent
Jared Blank support this view point [32]. between buying and not buying are located at points D
and E (see Fig. 4). We model the case of Internet coupons,
“…Merchants that want to price a new product such as Planet U™'s paperless coupons, where the
dynamically (especially one that consumers will discuss disutility of collecting and using the coupon is negligible.
in chat rooms) should send coupons of differing values Therefore, r − p − dt − xt + f = 0 holds for the marginal
to customers, rather than adjusting the price of the item coupon users at points D and E where x is described as
on the site. Consumers are not offended when others in Section 4, the segment of consumers who will buy the
receive coupons of differing values; this happens often product only if they receive the coupon. As r − p − dt = 0,
with consumer packaged goods…” we have x ¼ rpdtþf
t ¼ ft .
614 H.K. Cheng, K. Dogan / Decision Support Systems 44 (2008) 606–620

where
PNC ¼ 2dp; PC ¼ 2xð p  f Þ; and C ð xÞ ¼ 2b2 x:

After some algebra, we have PTotal ¼ 2t ðrp  p2 þ


pf  f 2  b2 f Þ. Therefore the firm's profit maximiza-
tion problem can be formulated.
2 
Max rp  p2 þ pf  f 2  b2 f ð13Þ
p;f t

Subject To
0VpVr ð14Þ

0Vf Vp ð15Þ

rp 1
0V V ð16Þ
t 2

f 1 rp
0V V  ð17Þ
t 2 t
The constraints given in Inequalities (14)–(17) and
their interpretations are the same as those in Inequalities
(5)–(8). The solution to this problem is characterized by
(see the Appendix)
Fig. 4. Targeted Internet coupons with imperfect information. r  2b2 2r  b2 r  2b2
f* ¼ ; p* ¼ ; and x* ¼ :
3 3 3t

Additionally, d* ¼ rþb 3t : Hence the market coverage


2
In this section the firm maximizes its profit by taking
is k* ¼ 3t2 ð
2r  b2 Þ. And finally the total profit is
both the price and the face value of the coupon as * ¼ 2 r2  rb þ b2 .
PTotal 3t 2 2
decision variables. We would like to see if the optimal
The following proposition summarizes the results of
price changes with the provision of coupons. Further-
this model.
more, the firm will want to have the flexibility to change
its pricing structure anticipating that it will provide Proposition 1. Only if 2b2 brb 3t2b 2
2
will a firm introduce
coupons later on. We assume that the consumer profiling fixed face value Internet coupons. When this is the case, the
technology of customer-centric information systems has face value of the coupon is r2b 3 and the firm will distribute
2

2ðr2b2 Þ
constant returns to scale as Amazon.com and Yahoo can coupons to 3t percent 2
of the consumers, increasing
acquire consumers' “purchasing and preference profile” the total profit by ðr2b
6t

. Otherwise, it is not profitable for
information at a constant marginal cost for all the firm to introduce coupons.
consumers [12]. Therefore the firm providing Internet
coupons will incur the cost of consumer profiling as a In this model it is optimal for the firm to increase its
linear function of the coupon segment x. The firm will price for the no coupon segment and provide coupons to
have to observe consumers to decide whether or not the the rest of the consumers. In contrast, [10] shows that the
consumers would buy the product with Internet coupons conventional paper coupon provider did not have to
if it sets the face value at f. We assume that the firm increase its price to maximize its profits with paper
incurs consumer profiling cost b2 per unit distance of coupon promotions. It is optimal for the conventional
observed market segment. Then, the firm's total net coupon provider to charge the same price with or without
profit equals coupons. However, with Internet coupons, firms should
increase the price for consumers with lower fit cost for the
PTotal ¼ PNC þ PC  C ð xÞ; product, i.e. the consumers that are not given a coupon
H.K. Cheng, K. Dogan / Decision Support Systems 44 (2008) 606–620 615

will need to bear higher prices. Not only is this price Thus, the expected profit from consumer i is E(πiC) =
higher than what the consumer receiving the coupon pays q(p − x̂it). The total profit of the firm from the entire
but also higher than the price that would be charged if no coupon segment can be calculated by simply integrating
coupons are provided at all. Comparisons of results from its profit from individual consumers over the interval
this model with those from others are given in Section 5. x̂i ∈ [0,xm]. In this case the firm may not be willing to
In the next subsection, we introduce the changing face provide coupons with a face value up to the price as
value coupons in the case of imperfect targetability. there are costs associated with changing the face value
of the coupon. The total profit within this range is
4.2.2. Changing face value Internet coupons to targeted Z xm
consumers PC ¼ 2 qð p  x̂t Þd x̂:
We now analyze the provision of the changing face 0
value coupons when the firm's targeting ability is less
The cost of consumer profiling with accuracy q is
than perfect. Our aim is to find conditions under which the
given as follows:
firm will choose the changing face value coupons over the
fixed face value coupons in the presence of imperfect C ð x; qÞ ¼ 2b2 xm þ a2 q2 :
information. If the firm estimates consumer i's location in
terms of her distance to the closest marginal consumer to The firm incurs a linear consumer profiling cost b2
be x̂i and the true location of the consumer i turns out to be similar to the fixed face value coupon case. We assume
xi, one of the three possible cases arises: (1) xi N x̂i, i.e., the that the accuracy level of the technology to estimate
firm underestimates the consumer's fit cost, and the consumers' locations on the unit circle is exogenous to
consumer will not buy as the coupon face value she is our model. This assumption reflects the fact that these
given is not enough to offset her fit cost; (2) xi = x̂i, i.e., the technologies are not available in the entire spectrum of
firm estimates the consumer's fit cost perfectly, the accuracy levels from 0 to 1. The firm's choice of
consumer will be indifferent and we assume she will buy; accuracy is not continuous. The firm solves its
and finally (3) xi b x̂i, i.e., the firm overestimates the optimization problem for a set of given technologies
consumer's fit cost, and the consumer will buy and enjoy with associated accuracy levels and picks the best one.
some surplus as the face value of the coupon is larger than We assume that the firm incurs a quadratic cost for
the minimum required amount to induce her into buying. achieving accuracy level q, which represents the
Suppose that consumer profiling of the firm's increasing marginal cost of accuracy provision. Hence,
customer-centric system works imperfectly. It under- the firm's total profit is given by
estimates or overestimates consumers' fit cost from time
to time. Assume that the system's accuracy of identifying PTotal ¼ PNC þ PC  CZð x; qÞ
a consumer's true fit cost is independent of her preference r  p xm
¼2 pþ2 qð p  xt Þdx
for the firm's product (i.e., her true fit cost). Suppose also
 t 0
that the system either overestimates or perfectly estimates  2b2 xm þ a2 q :
2

a consumer's fit cost with probability q, i.e. q = Pr{xi ≤ x̂i}


for all consumers xi's in [0, xm]. Chen, el al. [8] employ a After some algebra we have PTotal ¼ 2rp2p þ2tqpx qxt t 2tb x ta q .
2 2 2 2
m m 2 m 2

similar probability measure to model imperfect target- Therefore the firm solves the following problem.
ability in individual marketing setting. Given this
 
probability, we can reformulate the firm's maximization 2rp  2p2 þ 2tqpxm  qx2m t 2  2tb2 xm  ta2 q2
problem. Let πiC denote the firm's profit from consumer i Max
p;xm t
in the coupon segment. The value πiC, given the face
ð18Þ
value of the coupon, fi, is given by
Subject To
p  fi with probability q
piC ¼ :
0 with probability 1  q
0VpVr ð19Þ
Or, if we write the same value in terms of the
consumer's location on the unit circle, 0Vf Vp ð20Þ

p  x̂i t with probability q rp 1
piC ¼ : 0V V ð21Þ
0 with probability1  q t 2
616 H.K. Cheng, K. Dogan / Decision Support Systems 44 (2008) 606–620

1 rp “no coupon segment” appears for all r N 0. Because the


0 V xm V  ð22Þ
2 t firm is not giving coupons to some consumers, it cannot
The constraints given in Inequalities (19)–(21) and perform first degree price discrimination. There are some
their interpretations are the same as Inequalities (5)–(7) consumers who are charged the same price, p. Proposition
and their interpretations. Inequality (22) is similar to (12). 2 summarizes the results of this section.
The profit maximizing solution gives p* ¼ rb ⁎
2q and xm ¼
2

qr2b2 pffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi
qtð2qÞ (see the Appendix). The profit for this case is Proposition 2. Only if 2bq2 þ 2a2 t ð2  qÞb r b tð2q Þ2b2
2ð1qÞ
* ¼ a2 tq4 2a2 tq3 2rb2 qþr2 qþ2b22
PTotal 2tqð2qÞ : Further, we have d* ¼ will a firm introduce the changing face value Internet
rqrþb2
t ð2qÞ: The market coverage is equal to k* ¼ 2tððrb 2Þ
2qÞ :
coupons. When this is the case, the firm will distribute
When r z tð2q2Þþ2b2 , it is optimal for the monopolist to coupons to 2ðqtqr2b2Þ
ð2qÞ percent of the consumers, increasing
2a tq4 4a tq3 þr2 q2 4rbqþ4b2
serve all consumers. If r b tð2q2Þþ2b2 , some consumers are the total profit by 2 2
2tqð2qÞ
2
. Otherwise, it
not served at the equilibrium. With imperfect information, is not profitable for the firm to introduce coupons.

5. Discussion of customer-centric marketing with Internet coupons


In this section, we analyze the Internet couponing models in detail and gives comparative statics of the two models
presented in the previous section.

5.1. Profit and price analysis of the Internet couponing models

A summary of Internet couponing models for a monopolist, including the no coupon model, is given in Table 2.
The most important result in this section describes the impact on the price of the product when a firm chooses to
provide Internet coupons, whether they are fixed face value or changing face value. This result is stated in the following
proposition.

Proposition 3. When an Internet couponing method is more profitable than providing no coupons, the monop-
olistic firm will increase its price to the segment of the consumers who will buy the firm's product without coupons.

When issuing Internet coupons, the firm always prefers to increase its price for the segment of consumers who have
lower fit costs and thus will buy the firm's product without coupons. Moreover, there is another noteworthy
result of Internet couponing models of the previous section. The price is a decreasing function of the consumer
profiling cost.

Table 2
Comparison of the Internet couponing models
No coupons Internet Coupons with free Fixed face value Internet Changing face value Internet
perfect information coupons coupons
Price, p⁎ r r 2rb2 rb2
2 3 2q
xt h i r2b2  xt
Coupon Value, f ⁎ 0 p qr  2b
xa 0; 3 xa 0;
t qtð2  qÞ
No Coupon Segment, d⁎
r rþb2 rqrþb2
2t 0
3t tð2qÞ
r2b2
Coupon Segment, x⁎
2r qr2b2
0 t 3t qtð2qÞ
Market Coverage, k⁎
r 2r 2 2ðrb2 Þ
t t 3tð2r  b2 Þ tð2qÞ
r2 r2 2 2  a2 tq4  2a2 tq3  2rb2 q þ r2 q þ 2b22
Firm's Profit, π⁎ r  rb2 þ b22
2t t 3t 2tqð2  qÞ
 2  –
Consumers' Surplus r2 0 2r  2rb2 þ 5b22
4t
9t
 2  –
3r2 r2 8r  8rb2 þ 11b22
Total Welfare
4t t 9t
H.K. Cheng, K. Dogan / Decision Support Systems 44 (2008) 606–620 617

Proposition 4. The improvements in consumer profiling technologies that lead to decreased profiling cost will
make the monopolistic firm charge more for its product.

Proposition 4 implies that the firm is going to increase its price if the cost of customer profiling decreases. The
advancement of profiling technology will actually make the monopolist charge more for the product. This is true
for both Internet couponing models, see Table 2. A follow up result is that the firm will also increase the face value
of its coupon in the fixed coupon case with lower costs of profiling. Similarly, in the changing face value coupons,
the firm will give more consumers coupons if the profiling technology becomes cheaper.

5.2. Comparison of targeted Internet couponing models

The comparison of the prices, the size of the no coupon segments, and the market coverage of the two targeted
Internet coupons models presented in Sections 4.2.1 and 4.2.2 is summarized by the following proposition.
rþb2
Proposition 5. If qb 2rb 2
we have
i) The price with the fixed face value Internet coupons is greater than the price with the changing face value
Internet coupons,
ii) The size of the no coupon segment with the fixed face value Internet coupons is less than the size of the no coupon
segment with the changing face value Internet coupons,
iii) The size of the coupon segment with the fixed face value Internet coupons is larger than the size of the coupon
segment with the changing face value Internet coupons,
iv) The market coverage of the fixed face value Internet coupons is larger than the market coverage of the changing
face value Internet coupons.

Which of the two targeted Internet couponing models yields more profits depends heavily on the parameters
of the models. Conditions on which targeted couponing model generates more profit than the other can be
derived in terms of parameter values but they are rather complicated and hence do not allow easy interpretation.
For example we have the following condition for the value of the common reservation price.
pffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi
2b2 q þ 2b2 q2 þ 2 6a2 tq6 þ 15a2 tq5  6a2 tq4  3b22 q4 þ 12b22 q3  15b22 q2 þ 6b22 q
rN
2ð2q2  qÞ
If this condition holds, the changing face value Internet coupons will always provide higher profit than the fixed face
value Internet coupons. Therefore, in this subsection we give a numerical example to show how the profitability of the
two models change with respect to three important parameters of the model — the consumer profiling cost b2, the
targeting accuracy cost a2 and the accuracy level q. Fig. 5 shows the effect of parameter changes on the profits of the
two models.

Fig. 5. Profit comparison of the Internet couponing models.


618 H.K. Cheng, K. Dogan / Decision Support Systems 44 (2008) 606–620

The vertical axis represents the profit difference between the changing face value Internet coupons and the fixed face
value Internet coupons. A positive value indicates higher profits for the changing face value case. The parameter values are
r = 1 and t = 2. The consumer profiling cost coefficients, b2, are 0.01 for the figure on the left, and 0.1 for the figure on the
right. The targeting accuracy cost parameter a2 increases from 0.01 to 0.15 from left to right (one value for each curve) in
both figures in shown increments. The feasible values of q for the first figure are in the interval [0.01, 1.00] and for the
second figure they are in the interval [0.10, 1.00]. Outside these two intervals, coupon provision is not a feasible option.
The first result of interest is the effect of the targeting accuracy cost parameter a2. Ceteris paribus, as a2 decreases
and makes the curves in Fig. 5 moving toward above the x-axis, it becomes more profitable for the firm to choose the
distribution of the changing face value Internet coupons over the fixed face value ones. In the event of increasing cost
of targeting accuracy, however, the targeting accuracy has to become higher to justify the use of changing face value
Internet coupons. For some value of targeting accuracy cost, no accuracy level is large enough to make the changing
face value Internet coupons a viable option. The firm is better off with the fixed face value coupons.
The effect of the consumer profiling cost b2 is also an important decision factor but its impact is not as significant as
that of the targeting accuracy cost. If the consumer profiling cost decreases, ceteris paribus, the changing face value
Internet coupons will be more desirable.
As reported in Ref. [10], changing face value Internet coupons are not widely used in practice, although
technologies to do so are already in place. Our models suggest that as the cost of targeting accuracy improves, we
would observe more prevalent use of changing face value Internet coupons.

6. Conclusions, limitations and future extensions valuation and discount factor are arguably correlated, it
should be a worthy future research to examine whether the
We develop an analytical framework to analyze main results of the paper still apply in this case.
different Internet couponing strategies for a monopolis- This research studies the implications of Internet
tic firm providing a single product. Our models show coupons issued by the manufacturer. It should be of interest
that the distinct characteristics of Internet coupons call to analyze the retailer-based coupons such as those for 10%
for a careful selection of a firm's couponing strategy of all apparel. The retailer-based coupons scenario will not
that suits the firm's technological capabilities. The firm satisfy a fundamental assumption of the Salop model [25]
that does not have the ability of a customer-centric and extensions thereof — the product under consideration
information system to identify and profile individual being a single product, not multiple products. Intuitively,
consumers will not be able to benefit from Internet the general predictions of the propositions in this paper
couponing through mass distribution of their coupons should still hold. However, the parameters conditions in
over the Internet. We find that the firm will increase its Propositions 2 and 5 will be difficult to ascertain.
price to the segment of the consumers who have lower A natural extension to our work is to examine the
fit costs and will buy the firm's product without coupons firm's decision to use coupons as a strategic tool in a
when it is more profitable to distribute targeted Internet competitive environment. One possible extension to this
coupons even though the information gathered about the study is to consider the case of multiple products where
firm's customers is not perfect with the implementation of the effects of substitution and complementarity among a
a customer-centric information system. A decreasing cost firm's products are analyzed. Another possible future
of customer profiling technologies will result in a higher work is to consider repeat purchases. Our models assume
price for the firm's product. As the firm's customer- that consumers are in the market for a unit quantity of the
centric information system improves in terms of enhanced product. If we allow for repeat purchases, the benefits of
targeting accuracy at a lower cost, the changing face value consumer profiling will be even greater. First, the firm will
Internet coupons will become more prevalent. be able to collect more information. Second, it will use the
This research is not without limitations. This paper same information to target consumers multiple times,
assumes that consumers are not aware of the two stage which will result in cost savings.
process used for identifying purchasers at the regular
price and the potential coupon users. One possible Acknowledgement
approach to relax this critical assumption is to introduce
a discount factor for consumers where the consumers The authors gratefully acknowledge the very detailed
with high discount factor would buy in the first stage at the and constructive comments and suggestions from three
regular price while those with low discount factor would anonymous reviewers, which greatly help improve the
wait for the coupons in the second stage. Since the paper. We thank seminar participants of Georgia Institute
H.K. Cheng, K. Dogan / Decision Support Systems 44 (2008) 606–620 619

of Technology, Penn State University, University of rr


t ¼ 0. The market coverage is k* ¼ 2d* þ 2xm ¼
Arizona, University of Connecticut, University of Illinois 0 þ 2 pt ¼ 2rt.
at Chicago, University of Texas at Dallas, and Workshop
on Information Systems and Economics 2002 for their A.3. Internet fixed face value coupons
useful comments. Needless to say, any remaining errors
belong to the authors. First order conditions lead to
dPTotal ðr  2p* þ f * Þ
Appendix A. Model solutions ¼2 ¼ 0;
dp t
A.1. Internet mass distribution of coupons and

First order conditions require dPTotal ð p  2f *  b2 Þ


¼2 ¼ 0:
dPTotal ðr  2p* þ 2k*f * Þ df t
¼2 ¼ 0;
dp t The Hessian matrix for this model is negative definite.
Therefore the second order condition is satisfied. From
dPTotal ðk*r þ 2k*p*  2k*f * Þ rþf ⁎
¼2 ¼ 0; dp ¼ 0 we have p* ¼ 2 . From df ¼ 0 we have
dPTotal dPTotal
df t
p⁎ = 2f ⁎ + b2. Hence, f * ¼ r2b 3
2
, p* ¼ 2rb
3
2
and
and x* ¼ t ¼ 3t . Additionally, d* ¼ t ¼ 3t : Hence
f r2b2 rp rþb2

  the market coverage is


k* ¼ 2x þ 2d ¼ 3t2 ð2r  b2 Þ.
dPTotal rf * þ 2p*f *  f *2 * ¼ 2 r2  rb þ b2 .
Total profit is PTotal
¼2  b1 ¼ 0: 3t 2 2
dk t
The Hessian matrix for this model is negative semi- A.4. Changing face value Internet coupons to targeted
definite, satisfying the second order condition.
⁎ ⁎
consumers
From dPdpTotal ¼ 0 we have p* ¼ rþ2k2 f . From dPdfTotal ¼ 0
⁎ ⁎
⁎ rþ2k⁎ f ⁎
we have p* ¼ rþ2f 2 provided λ ≠ 0. Hence, 2 ¼ rþ2f
2 ,
First order conditions require
leading to (1−λ⁎)f ⁎ = 0. dPTotal 2r  4p* þ 2tqx⁎m
There are two cases — either f ⁎ is 0 and λ⁎ is free, or ¼ ¼ 0;
dp t
λ⁎ is 1 and f ⁎ is free. If the first case is true, the model
reduces to the no coupon case, as zero face value implies and
no coupon distribution. If the second case is true, i.e. dPTotal 2tqp*  2qx⁎m t 2  2tb2
λ⁎ = 1, we have the following: p* ¼ rþ2f

¼ ¼ ¼ 0:
2 þ f *.
r
2
4 4 4 42
dxm t
From dPdkTotal ¼ 0, we have 2 ðrf þ2pt f f Þ ¼ b1 or
The second order condition is met since the Hessian
rf * þ 2p*f *  f *2 ¼ tb21 . Substituting p* ¼ 2r þqfffiffiffiffi*
matrix is negative semi-definite.
gives rf * þ 2 2r þ f * f *  f *2 ¼ tb21 , hence f * ¼ qtb2ffiffiffi.ffi 1

qffiffiffiffi ⁎ The profit maximizing solution gives p* ¼ rb 2q and


2

So, p* ¼ 2r þ f * ¼ 2r þ tb2 Additionally, x* ¼ ft ¼ b2t1


1

xm ¼ qtð2qÞ.
qr2b2
qffiffiffiffi
rp⁎
and d* ¼ ¼ 2tr  b1
. Hence the market coverage is P* ¼ 2
a tq4 2a2 tq3 2rb2 qþr2 qþ2b22
t qffiffiffiffi
2t qffiffiffiffi Total 2tqð2qÞ . We additionally have
k* ¼ 2x þ 2d ¼ 2ð x þ d Þ ¼ 2 b1
þ r
 2t ¼ t .
b1 r
the following: d* ¼ rqrþb 2
2t 2t t ð2qÞ .
The market coverage is then
Total profit becomes P* ¼ r  a  b : equal to k* ¼ 2d* þ 2qx⁎m ¼ 2tððrb2Þ
2
Total 2t 1 1 2qÞ .

A.2. Internet changing value coupons with free perfect References


information
[1] G. Adomavicius, A. Tuzhilin, Expert-driven validation of rule-
based user models in personalization applications, Data Mining
First order condition requires and Knowledge Discovery 5 (2001) 33–58.
[2] C. Allen, Mediation — the missing ingredient in the marriage of
dPTotal 2r  2p*
¼0¼ : people and technology, 2005 http://www.torontoadr.com/labour.shtml.
dp t [3] R. Alsop, Companies seek ways to put coupons where they will
2
PTotal count, Wall Street Journal 25 (1985) (August 8).
Since d dp2 ¼  2t b0 for all t N 0, the second order [4] E. Babakus, P. Tat, W. Cunningham, Coupon redemption: a
condition for maximization is met. Hence we find ⁎the motivational perspective, Journal of Consumer Marketing 5 (2)
solution as p⁎ = r and P*Total ¼ rt . We have d* ¼ rp
2
t ¼ (1988) 37–43.
620 H.K. Cheng, K. Dogan / Decision Support Systems 44 (2008) 606–620

[5] H. Bester, E. Petrakis, Coupons and oligopolistic price [29] A. Stern, New marketing game: Stealing customers, Dun's
discrimination, International Journal of Industrial Organization Business Month 125 (2) (1985) 48–50.
14 (1996) 227–242. [30] D. Streitfeld, On the web, price tags blur, Washington Post
[6] R.C. Blattberg, S.A. Neslin, Sales promotion: Concepts, methods, (September 27 2001) A01.
and strategies, Prentice Hall, Englewood Cliffs, NJ, 1990. [31] B.A. White, Comparison shopping and the economics of
[7] R. Caminal, C. Matutes, Endogenous switching costs in a duopoly manufacturers' coupons, Discussion Paper, vol. 517, Department
model, International Journal of Industrial Organization 8 (1990) of Economics, State University of New York, Buffalo, 1983.
353–373. [32] E. Zaret, Different prices for different folks, , July 17 2001 www.
[8] Y. Chen, C. Narasimhan, Z.J. Zhang, Individual marketing with msnbc.com.
imperfect targetability, Marketing Science 20 (1) (2001) 23–41. [33] N. Zeldis, Targeted coupons hit non-users, Advertising Age
[9] H.K. Cheng, K. Dogan, E. Warner, Internet coupons: clicking not (April 27 1987) S–26.
clipping, Department of Information Systems and Operations
Management Working Paper, The University of Florida, 2005. Hsing Kenneth Cheng received the Ph.D.
[10] H.K. Cheng, K. Dogan, G.J. Koehler, Conventional coupons: degree in computers and information systems
spatial models of price discrimination, Department of Informa- from William E. Simon Graduate School of
tion Systems and Operations Management Working Paper, The Business Administration, University of Roche-
University of Florida, 2005. ster in 1992. He is Associate Professor of
[11] J. Chiang, Competing coupon promotions and category sales, Information Systems and the American Eco-
Marketing Science 14 (1) (1995) 105–122. nomic Institutions Faculty Fellow at the
[12] R. Dewan, B. Jing, A. Seidmann, Adoption of internet-based Department of Information Systems and Op-
product customization and pricing strategies, Journal of Man- erations Management of Warrington College of
agement Information Systems 17 (2) (2000) 9–28. Business Administration, The University of
[13] R.D. Gopal, B. Phatak, A. Tripathi, F. Yin, From fatwallet to ebay: Florida. Prior to joining UF, he served on the
an investigation of online deal forums and sales promotions, faculty at The College of William and Mary from 1992 to 1998. His
Journal of Retailing 82 (2) (2006) 155–164. research interests focus on modeling the impact of Internet technology on
[14] B. Gomolski, Are you really customer-centric? Computerworld software development and marketing, and information systems policy
39 (8) (2005) 33. issues. His work has appeared in Computers and Education, Computers
[15] G.M. Grossman, C. Shapiro, Informative advertising with differenti- and Operations Research, Decision Support Systems, European Journal
ated products, The Review of Economic Studies 51 (1) (1984) 63–81. of Operational Research, IEICE Transactions, IEEE Transactions on
[16] D.A. Houston, J.S. Howe, An economic rationale for couponing, Engineering Management, Information Technology and Management,
Quarterly Journal of Business and Economic 24 (1985) 37–50. International Journal of Electronic Commerce, International Journal
[17] M. Kumar, A. Rangachari, A. Jhingran, R. Mohan, Sales of Web Services Research, Journal of Business Ethics, Journal of
promotions on the Internet, Proceedings of the Second Usenix Information Systems and e-Business Management, Journal of Manage-
Conference on E-commerce, Boston, MA, 1998. ment Information Systems, and Socio-Economic Planning Sciences. Dr.
[18] H.C. Lai, T.C. Yang, Comparison of product bundling strategies Cheng has co-edited several special issues in various information
on different online shopping behaviors, Electronic Commerce systems journals. He has served on the program committee of many
Research and Applications 5 (4) (2006) 295–304. information systems conferences and workshops, and is a program co-
[19] K. Lancaster, Socially optimal product differentiation, American chair for the Workshop on E-Business (2003).
Economic Review 65 (4) (1975) 567–585.
[20] W.J. Levedahl, Profit maximizing pricing of cents off coupons:
Promotion or price discrimination, Quarterly Journal of Business Kutsal Dogan is an Assistant Professor at the
and Economics (Fall, 1986) 56–70. Information Systems and Operations Manage-
[21] C. Narasimhan, A price discrimination theory of coupons, ment department, University of Texas at
Marketing Science 3 (2) (1984) 128–147. Dallas. He holds a Ph.D. degree in decision
[22] A. Nevo, C. Wolfram, Why do manufacturers issue coupons? an and information sciences from University of
empirical analysis of breakfast cereals, Rand Journal of Florida. Dr. Dogan's research interests are
Economics 33 (2) (2002) 319–339. diverse and lie broadly in marketing, econom-
[23] A. Rangachari, M. Kumar, A. Jhingran, distributing e-coupons ics and information systems. Specifically, he
on the internet, Proceedings of the 9th Annual Conference of the is interested in the analysis and development
Internet Society, San Jose, CA, 1999. of pricing and promotion models; particularly
[24] M. Raphel, how am I gonna fight the competition blues, Direct those apply to Internet businesses. His
Marketing 51 (1988) 142–146. research tries to quantify the effects of promotions, dynamic pricing
[25] S. Salop, Monopolistic competition with outside goods, Bell and second-degree price discrimination tools on consumers and
Journal of Economics 10 (1) (1979) 141–156. competition. He is also interested in the development, planning and
[26] G. Shaffer, Z.J. Zhang, Competitive coupon targeting, Marketing pricing issues for information products and services such as software.
Science 14 (4) (1995) 395–416. Dr. Dogan serves on the editorial boards of Decision Sciences Journal
[27] A. Sharma, J.N. Sheth, Web-based marketing: the coming and International Journal of E-business Research. He is a member of
revolution in marketing thought and strategy, Journal of Business Institute for Operations Research and Management Science (IN-
Research 57 (2004) 696–702. FORMS), Association for Information Systems (AIS) and Decision
[28] J.N. Sheth, R.S. Sisodia, A. Sharma, The antecedents and Sciences Institute (DSI).
consequences of customer-centric marketing, Journal of Acad-
emy of Marketing Science 28 (1) (2000) 55–66.

Anda mungkin juga menyukai