Anda di halaman 1dari 24

Journal of Business Ethics (2011) 103:143165  Springer 2011

DOI 10.1007/s10551-011-0859-0

Institutional Interest in Corporate


Responsibility: Portfolio Evidence Paul Cox
and Ethical Explanation Patricia Gaya Wicks

ABSTRACT. This study examines the extent to which dramatically in recent years. These investors have
corporate responsibility influences the demand for shares by evolved as major holders of public company shares
institutions. The study follows Bushee (Account Rev within many developed economies (Allen and Gale,
73(3):305333, 1998) in categorising institutions as dedi- 2001; Davis and Steil, 2001). These developments
cated or transient. The demand for shares is organised have prompted researchers to examine the charac-
according to three factors: a long-term factor, corporate
teristics of different types of institutional investor
responsibility; a short-term factor, market liquidity; and a
time-independent factor, portfolio theory. The rank and
(Ryan and Schneider, 2002) as well as the associa-
importance of the factors for the different types of institu- tion between institutional holdings and corporate
tional investor are analysed. For one of two types of dedi- behaviour (Bushee, 1998; Coffey and Fryxell, 1991;
cated institution, corporate responsibility is as important as David et al., 1998, 2001; Graves and Waddock,
portfolio theory in influencing the demand for shares. For all 1994; Johnson and Greening, 1999; Tihanyi et al.,
dedicated institutions, corporate responsibility influences 2003).
the demand for shares more than market liquidity. For two One viewpoint is that the growth in institu-
of the three types of transient institution, market liquidity is tional holdings of corporate stock has led to a more
the most important factor in share selection. For all transient concentrated and hence powerful owner base to
institutions, the least important factor is corporate respon- counter managerialism (Brown, 1998). For example,
sibility. Findings suggest that corporate responsibility posi- in 2008, UK-domiciled financial institutions owned
tively and significantly influences the demand for shares by
40% of the shares of UK public companies (Office
dedicated institutions. The discussion considers the extent
to which these trends are constitutive of significant shifts in
for National Statistics, 2010). Such high levels of
ethicality within the context of institutional investment. domestic ownership may have reduced the flexibility
Looking at this from within a highly institutionalised Anglo of institutions to sell investments without adversely
market model, dedicated institutions commitment to affecting their value, and resulted in a greater focus
broader and longer-term concerns could be interpreted as a on long-term outcomes such as shareholder activism,
small but significant step towards a more axiologically corporate governance and corporate social perfor-
informed ethical business practice. Such a form of engage- mance (CSP) (Graves and Waddock, 1994; Johnson
ment calls for sensitive attention to a fuller range of features and Greening, 1999; Ryan and Schneider, 2002).
deemed to be relevant to investment decisions, as opposed This has given rise to the phenomenon of patient,
to more narrow reliance on legislation, codes of practice and dedicated investors who buy and hold based on
fiduciary principles. long-term corporate attributes and developments
(Bushee and Noe, 2000; Porter, 1992).
KEY WORDS: share ownership, corporate responsibil-
ity, institutional investment, business ethics
A different viewpoint is that the rise in interna-
tional investment has reduced the importance of any
single market or subset of stocks and increased the
Introduction spread of holdings. For example, the proportion of
shares held by UK pension funds in UK public
The ownership of large corporations by institutions, companies has fallen from 31.7% in 1990 to 12.8% in
such as pension funds and mutual funds, has risen 2008, whilst over the same period, overseas own-
144 Paul Cox and Patricia Gaya Wicks

ership of UK public companies has grown from 11.8 porate responsibility ranks in importance within
to 41.5% (Office for National Statistics, 2010). share selection as compared to portfolio theory and
Furthermore, clauses in fund management contracts market liquidity factors. The proposal that corporate
often constrain the maximum that a single stock can responsibility is a mainstream investment consider-
comprise within a portfolio, as well as the percent of ation for at least some institutional shareholders is
shares held in any one company. Keeping these to a outlined in the Discussion section. In that section,
low proportion prevents a concentration of holdings we highlight some of the controversies involving
and improves the ability to trade portfolio holdings claims of corporate social responsibility relevant to
quickly and at low cost. Thus, internationalisation this article, which centre on debates as to the actual
and a greater spread of portfolio holdings may have and/or perceived motivations and purposes under-
reduced the commitment to long-term investment lying such trends, and the extent to which these
decisions and encouraged corporate managers to do represent significant shifts towards more ethical
the same. This has given rise to the phenomenon of practice.
transient investors that trade intensively (Bushee and The second innovation is that the research applies
Noe, 2000). an institutional share selection model to a UK con-
Which of these two perspectives best fits the text. The concept of an institutional share selection
evidence, and given this, what are the implications model is not new, and has been used by Badrinath
for our understanding of business ethics within the et al. (1989, 1996), Bushee (1998), Coffey and
context of a highly institutionalised market model? Fryxell (1991), Creedy (1994), Del Guercio (1996),
This study seeks to answer these questions by Eatkins et al. (1998), Falkenstein (1996), Gompers
drawing on detailed institutional share ownership and Metrick (2001), Graves and Waddock (1994),
data for UK public companies that include both Hessel and Norman (1992), Johnson and Greening
domestic and overseas shareholders. The data set is (1999) and OBrien and Bhushan (1990). However,
used to categorise institutional shareholders as ded- all this work is performed from a US perspective,
icated or transient. The study hypothesises that and only includes US shareholders in US companies.
different categories of institutional shareholder The focus here is all institutional shareholders of UK
will hold different types of shares. A three-factor companies.
share-selection model is constructed in which the Third, the UK financial market is both highly
determinants are a long-term factor, corporate institutional and international. For example, the
responsibility; a short-term factor, market liquidity; importance of US investment company branch
and a time-independent factor, portfolio theory. A offices in the UK and their holdings of UK shares are
number of expectations are empirically confirmed. evidenced in the data. Five-hundred US institutions
For one of two categories of dedicated institution are recorded as owning 15% of all UK shares. The
investigated, corporate responsibility is as important results of this study therefore speak to other insti-
as portfolio theory in influencing the demand for tutionalised market places, and perhaps the US
shares. For all categories of dedicated institution, market in particular. We highlight some of the
corporate responsibility influences the demand for limitations to ethical practice imposed by a highly
shares more than market liquidity. The situation institutionalised market model, and explain how
with transient institutions is the opposite. For two of such a model serves to constrain the ways and extent
three categories of transient institution, market to which it is possible for investors to critically attend
liquidity is the most important factor. For all tran- to the ethical dimensions of financial markets.
sient institutions, the lowest ranking factor in the The article is structured as follows: The next
demand for shares is corporate responsibility. section discusses the conceptual background to the
This study makes three innovations, two of which study and outlines the hypotheses. The third section
can be further analysed through an ethical perspec- introduces the data and methods. The fourth section
tive. First, the use of a three-factor model that discusses the findings, including the ethical impli-
incorporates corporate responsibility places it at the cations and controversies raised by the study, and the
centre of the analysis. It effectively asks how cor- fifth section concludes.
Institutional Interest in Corporate Responsibility 145

Conceptual background and hypotheses term behaviour adopted by corporate managers is


development associated with the extent to which the firm is
owned by transient (short-term), or dedicated
The capital asset pricing model (CAPM) uses a single (long-term) institutions. Transient institutions have a
factor, beta, to explain the risk and return relation- propensity to sell a firm based on short-term cor-
ship. If the only stock characteristic that matters is porate developments. This might lead corporate
beta, then stocks with similar betas will be close managers to underinvest in long-term expenditures
substitutes. This should mean there will be no rela- such as research and development and corporate
tionship between the level of demand for a stock responsibility. Why might such institutions have a
and characteristics specific to the corporate issuer propensity to sell a firm based on short-term cor-
(Eatkins et al., 1998). Some studies have found that porate developments? One explanation is that if
characteristics specific to corporate issuers do con- institutions hold a broad spread of investments so
tribute to an explanation of long-run returns. These that there is a small stake in each, research on the
include small versus large capitalisation stocks, value long-term prospects and fundamentals of each line of
versus growth and momentum factors (Carhart, stock is not cost effective. Trading becomes driven
1997; Fama and French, 1993). by short-term news and earnings (Froot et al., 1992).
Studies have also found that factors other than A second explanation is the characteristics of the
beta influence the demand for shares. OBrien and financial products transient institutions create and
Bhushan (1990) establish a relationship between the manage. These often offer immediate liquidity e.g.
number of analysts following a stock and the level mutual funds or involve their investment managers
of institutional ownership in the stock. Del Guer- in competition with others e.g. external fund
cio (1996), Gompers and Metrick (2001) and management of pension fund assets (Acker and
Badrinath et al. (1989) identify a positive associa- Duck, 2006; Chen and Penacchi, 2001; Chevalier
tion between the demand for shares and variables and Ellison, 1997; Ehrenberg and Bognanno, 1990;
that have appeared in prudence case law. These Goriaev et al., 2000; Khorana, 2001; Meyer and
include firm size, firm age, dividend yield, stock Vickers, 1997). A propensity to sell a firm based on
price volatility and membership of an index such as short-term developments indicates preferences for
the S&P 500. The suggestion is that institutional low-cost fulfilment of trades and high market
fund managers guided by these factors can later use liquidity.
them to demonstrate investment suitability in case Dedicated institutions have a propensity to see-
of client criticism or class actions. Hessel and through short-term developments, and prefer invest-
Norman (1992) report that debt and profitability ment in shares of firms that allocate greater corporate
ratios predict the level of institutional ownership. resources to research and development, long-range
Falkenstein (1996) and Creedy (1994) find that planning, and meeting the expectations of a multi-
certain institutional shareholders prefer high beta plicity of stakeholders (Bushee, 1998; Hoskisson
and idiosyncratic risk. Eatkins et al. (1998) and et al., 2002; Porter, 1992). One interpretation is that
Gompers and Metrick (2001) evidence higher these institutions are managing investments for
institutional ownership in stocks with higher trad- realisation in future decades, for example, charities,
ing volume. Coffey and Fryxell (1991), Graves and endowment and pension funds (Acharya and
Waddock (1994) and Johnson and Greening (1999) Dimson, 2007).
find a positive relationship between corporate so- If there are time horizon differences between
cial and environmental performance and the level types of institution, then this indicates a relationship
of institutional ownership. Thus, investment suit- between time horizon related firm-specific factors
ability appears not to be guided solely by the and the level of institutional ownership. This study
marginal effect of an investment on the overall examines this question by developing and extend-
portfolio. ing earlier studies by Bushee (1998) and Bushee
In related work from a corporate perspective, and Noe (2000). Institutional shareholders are
Bushee (1998) investigates whether short or long- categorised as dedicated or transient and a share
146 Paul Cox and Patricia Gaya Wicks

selection model used to examine the demand for that more of the stock is tradable as there is more
long-term and short-term firm-specific characteris- opportunity to trade large amounts at low cost.
tics within their equity portfolios. The long-term Institutions with long investment horizons are
characteristic is corporate responsibility, and the expected to be less influenced by the cost and speed
short-term characteristic is market liquidity. of trading. When spread over a longer holding
The institutional framework in which these period, the costs of trading are not so important in
investors function, we suggest, severely limits the relation to the potential accumulation of financial
ways and extent to which they can engage with distributions and capital gain. This suggests that such
ethical dilemmas and quandaries in their decision- institutions may not be averse to higher holdings in
making. From this perspective, some institutional firms with lower market liquidity, which are often
investors inclusion of longer-term considerations in small and mid-size firms (Bushee, 1998). Long-term
share selection could be interpreted as a form of and significant holdings may also enrich relations
experimentation with the possibilities for ethical with corporate managers, create opportunities for
engagement open to them within the bounds of the monitoring and influence, and provide valuable
existing system. This points to the need to critically private information for the improvement of long-
examine the extent to which experimentation term portfolio risk and expected return (Hendry
within micropolitical contexts (i.e. within individual et al., 2006; Holland, 1998).
investment decisions) succeeds in shifting and even
transforming macropolitical realities (i.e. the over- Portfolio theory: time independent
arching market system). This is crucial, since it is the Institutional investors, in their role as investment
macropolitical system, by virtue of its regulatory fiduciaries, are held to the tenets of portfolio theory
power, which broadly organises possibilities for (Ignatius, 1999; New Prudent Investor Rule, 2006).
ethically informed business practice into a limited As a result, all institutional shareholders, regardless of
range (Gatens, 2000). their investment time horizon, can be expected to
The next section discusses the share-selection incorporate portfolio theory within portfolio con-
model based on a short-term factor, market liquidity; struction.
a time-independent factor, portfolio theory; and a One tenet of portfolio theory is investment risk
long-term factor, corporate responsibility. This is which cannot be eliminated by diversification across
followed by a discussion of transient and dedicated different stocks because it is composed of broad
institutions. market factors (Rosenberg and Guy, 1995). This risk
is measured by beta, the responsiveness of the price of
a security to a percent change in the overall market of
Determinants of corporate ownership which it is resident. Portfolio theory predicts that
exposure to beta is necessary to earn a positive
Liquidity: short-term financial return, and so a positive relationship is
Institutional shareholders with short investment expected between investment demand and beta.
horizons can be expected to prefer low transaction Other common factors within portfolio theory
costs. Profits are made from after-cost returns, and a which have in the past explained long-run returns
short investment time horizon provides a short time include value stocks, small capitalisation stocks, and
period over which to recover the costs of buying and stocks with greater momentum1 (Carhart, 1997;
selling. Low buying and selling costs are associated Fama and French, 1993). These additional variables
with a high volume of trades (Chan and Lakonishok, arguably result in at least some degree of higher
1995; Falkenstein, 1996). Some institutions also expected risk, and so institutional shareholders
keep the price impact of trading low by setting a relationship with these will depend on their appetite
limit on the maximum ownership in any one for risk and expected return and on their investment
company of no more than the equivalent of a few beliefs about such factors as sources of expected
normal days trading volume (Dyl and Anderson, return.
2002). Both of these lead to more investment in Another source of investment risk used to explain
more liquid lines of stock. It is often in larger firms the relationship between risk and expected return is
Institutional Interest in Corporate Responsibility 147

stock price volatility, measured by standard devia- tutions. This might involve dedicated institutions
tion. The relationship between the demand for seeking both financial returns and also a certain type
shares and stock price volatility may be positive or of CSP. Significantly, a position on responsible
negative, depending on institutional beliefs about the investment is not considered of itself a violation of
variability of returns as an additional source of fiduciary duty if it is part of an approach to valuation,
investment return. The general expectation is that risk and expected return (Cox, 2009; Kurtz, 2005).
investors will be averse to this risk. This is because Of course, the above analysis necessarily assumes
there is no general consensus concerning whether that when taking into consideration the corporate
the market rewards investors for holding higher responsibility, institutional investors are guided by a
standard deviation stocks (Falkenstein, 1996). costbenefit analysis, largely centred on the prospect
of future economic gains. This raises questions
Corporate responsibility: long-term concerning the extent to which such a motivation
The European Union (EU, 2002) defines corporate represents significant shifts towards more ethical
social responsibility as a concept whereby compa- practice, to which we now turn.
nies integrate social and environmental concerns in
their business operations and in their interactions The ethics of corporate responsibility motivations
with their stakeholders. Interest in corporate As suggested by Fukukawa et al. in a recent special
responsibility is based on the principle that business issue (Fukukawa et al., 2007), questions about the
and society are inter-woven. As such, the environ- foundations, triggers and motives of corporations
ment, society, workplace, business values and gover- processes of the so-called ethicalisation constitutes a
nance may impact corporate fundamentals, valuation key line of inquiry in the business ethics field. Such
and investment performance. questions seem particularly germane in relation to
An exemplar of the long time horizon associated responsible investment trends of the kind examined
with corporate responsibility is climate change. The through this study. Given existing findings which
2006 Stern Review on the economics of climate suggest that performance is fairly equal between
change illustrated the likely impact of not pursuing socially responsible and conventional portfolios (Benson
corporate responsibility. According to the Stern et al., 2006), what might be the motivations and
Review, if the world does not act to limit carbon purposes of investing responsibly? The interest in such
dioxide emissions, then the overall costs and risks of questions is unsurprising, given that the nature of
climate change will be equivalent to losing at least 5% underlying purposes and motivations may be under-
of global GDP each year, now and forever (Stern, stood to define the extent to which such shifts are
2006, p. vi). Future climate change policy is likely to perceived as significant. Indeed, debates on corpo-
reform inefficient energy systems and remove dis- rate responsibility often focus on the extent to which
torting energy subsidies on which governments this trend is representative of either business as usual
worldwide currently spend around $250bn a year. or of a fundamental reconceptualisation of the busi-
Businesses that address climate change through ac- ness model.
tions around their corporate responsibility may help Fukukawa et al. (2007) point out that there is some
mitigate future risk, capitalise on forthcoming oppor- consensus on the perceived underpinnings of pro-
tunities, reduce existing inefficiencies and draw cesses of ethicalisation, with the three key driving
attention to money-saving opportunities (Stern, forces understood to include altruism on the part
2006). However, these factors operate over a long of leaders, strategic attempts to gain competitive
time horizon; it can take 3040 years for a change in advantage and profit, and external forces such as
carbon dioxide emissions to presage a change in cli- changes in legislation and societal norms. The per-
mate (Climate Change Business Forum, 2010). ceived importance given by firms to the second of the
It requires investment patience to position a above, namely, a desire for competitive advantage, is
portfolio based on risks that are in the system some regularly identified as a limitation of the CSR
time before they impact. As such, corporate movement by commentators interested in prob-
responsibility can be expected to attract dedicated lematising the relative amorality (and sometimes
institutions more than it will attract transient insti- immorality) of prevailing business models (see, e.g.
148 Paul Cox and Patricia Gaya Wicks

Doane, 2005; Kleinberg Neimark, 1995). The aims of horizons, i.e. transient, and those with long
alleged moves towards corporate responsibility have investment horizons, i.e. dedicated. Ryan and
been problematised for some time, as characterised by Schneider (2002) and Johnson and Greening (1999)
a critical reading of Carrolls (1991, p. 43) landmark produce similar typologies of institutional investors,
article in which CSR is famously framed as good and the typology of transient and dedicated institu-
business sense and enlightened self-interest, involv- tional shareholders below draws on these.
ing doing well by doing good. Debates focusing on
whether this is a sufficiently significant reframing of Transient institutions
the responsibility of business are, to a large extent, Open-end mutual funds. Mutual funds are one class of
axiological ones, dealing with fundamental questions short time horizon institution. In a mutual fund,
about what matters and what we value in modern shares or units may be redeemed on any business
societies. day by the investor selling them back to the fund.
As many moral theorists, ethical philosophers and Investors in mutual funds are also usually able to
business ethics commentators are at pains to show, switch at low cost from one fund to another within
such axiological assumptions and foundations are the same fund family. This detail is important because
themselves constructs, and thus open to problemati- to meet redemptions and switching between funds,
sation and deconstruction (Hekman, 1995; Jones, the portfolio manager either has to have sufficient
2003; Lewis and Mackenzie, 2000; Tappan, 2006). cash in the fund or be able to sell assets quickly.
For instance, the criterion of maximum profits is not Immediate redemption and switching means that
only an enduring value, but is often presented as a mutual fund manager cannot know when a secu-
absolute and non-negotiable: All other business rity purchased may need to be sold. There can be
responsibilities are predicated upon the economic significant money flows into and out of mutual funds
responsibility of the firm, because without it the others as a result of the latest investment return perfor-
become moot considerations (Carroll, 1991, p. 41). mance, so this possibility is very real (Del Guercio
More to the point, fiduciary duty is such that where and Tkac, 2002).
there are significant trade-offs between economic and A need to buy and sell securities quickly and at
other responsibilities, pension fund managers as low cost may encourage investment in more liquid
investors are legally obliged to prioritise the former. securities and securities whose value is expected to
It is not the intention of the present discussion to crystallise in the short-term (Droms and Walker,
dispute the fiduciary principle per se. Rather, the aim 1996). Ryan and Schneider (2002) report that mu-
is to highlight that the ethicality of the trends tual funds have the highest portfolio turnover of any
investigated in this article is necessarily constrained institutional investor. Based on the above, and an
by the willingness and ability of the various actors absence of legislation, regulation or industry pressure
who form part of the market system to engage in for long-term factors such as CSP within share
serious, critical, and explicit debate about what selection, a preference for market liquidity is above
matters. We return to this question in the Findings all expected.
and discussion section, when we analyse our find-
ings in the light of some of the constraints and Life insurance funds. Insurance company funds,
opportunities for ethical engagement faced by play- comprising mostly life funds, are a second class of
ers within the highly institutionalised Anglo market short time horizon institution. Many insurance
system. Next, we introduce the range of institutional companies are either publicly listed in their own
actors relevant to our study. right or divisions of insurance companies or banks
that are publicly listed. As a result, the market for
corporate control may discipline these compa-
Investment institutions as corporate owners nies should their investment holdings substantially
underperform index and peer group benchmarks.
This section discusses transient and dedicated insti- Competition, and the need to take commercial
tutions. Bushee (1998) argues that institutions can be decisions for profit, may shorten the time horizon
categorised according to those with short investment associated with portfolio investment decisions.
Institutional Interest in Corporate Responsibility 149

Life funds and mutual funds also share several companies selected for their long-term outcomes
investment similarities. In the UK and continental (Ryan and Schneider, 2002). On the other hand,
Europe, many of the best-known mutual fund man- external managers confront investment mandates
agers are insurance companies. A life fund often links that initially run for 3 years, but with a notice period
to units in a mutual fund so that the investment vehicle of 3 months, and portfolio evaluation each quarter
is often the same. Mutual and life funds are mostly and year end (Davis and Steil, 2001; Lakonishok
retail products. As a result, investors, both institutional et al., 1991). Based upon these evaluations, assets
and retail, are able to compare mutual and life fund either remain with the manager or are reallocated to
performance cheaply and quickly by browsing widely other money managers. Replacement of managers
published league tables that reveal past fund perfor- following underperformance is a normal part of
mance over measured time periods and attach an external portfolio management and mandates are
overall fund rating (Myners, 2001). Money flow into often terminated prior to 3 years (Del Guercio and
mutual and life funds is then associated with the Tkac, 2002; Ennis, 2001; Lakonishok et al., 1991).
ranking revealed by these league tables. Since external managers are uncertain as to when a
As with mutual funds, liquidity is also important to mandate may be lost, they may rationally assume that
life funds. For example, the UK Financial Services dismissal could be after any quarters performance,
Authority (FSA) requires unit-linked life policies to and thus invest in stocks that have low trading costs
hold securities that are readily realisable, i.e. liquid and whose investment value is expected to crystallise
(FSA, 2007). This may lead to a preference for larger in the short-run (Myners, 2001).
stocks with greater trading liquidity, which are listed There is occupational pension scheme legislation
on main exchanges. Greater market liquidity may concerning responsible investment. An amendment
also be preferred to cover trades needed to meet early in the year 1999 to the 1995 Pensions Act (Statutory
surrender of policies and switching between funds. Instrument 1999 No. 1849 and 3259), commencing
This discussion suggests a preference for more July 2000, requires that trustees of occupational and
liquid securities and securities more likely to perform local government pension schemes disclose in the
well in the short-term. This fits with the US evi- Statement of Investment Principles the extent (if at
dence that portfolio turnover of life funds is more all) to which social, environmental and ethical con-
frequent than pension funds but less frequent than siderations are taken into account in the selection,
mutual funds (Ryan and Schneider, 2002). Whilst retention and realisation of investments (Pensions
the insurance industry trade body in the UK has set a Act, 1999a, b). This represents a disclosure legislation
best practice agenda for corporate responsibility, this only but not a requirement to invest responsibly, and
does not have the force of law, and may therefore so short-term factors are still expected to have the
have less influence on the demand for shares than greater influence on the demand for shares.
short-term liquidity.
Hypothesis 1: Corporate ownership by transient
Externally managed pension plans. Pension plan institutions will be greater in companies with
investment managers who prefer not to expend time more liquid stocks than in companies with high
and resources acquiring the knowledge and staff to corporate social performance.
invest their own money delegate the management of
plan assets to external investment managers. These
professional managers may also be investing in mu- Dedicated institutions
tual fund, life insurance, proprietary, foundation, Other pension plans expend time and resources
church and charity funds. Professional managers are acquiring the knowledge and staff to invest their own
therefore likely to hold many of the same stocks money. Over time, inhouse-managed pension plans
across the different portfolios they manage, and have gradually reduced in number, mostly among
possibly apply the same investment timing and smaller plans with fewer assets over which to appor-
trading. On the one hand, this suggests larger overall tion fixed costs. Many of the largest schemes still
investment positions and a greater price impact of manage their assets inhouse because their scale makes
trading, so that trading will be infrequent and it less expensive to do so (Herman, 1963). By value,
150 Paul Cox and Patricia Gaya Wicks

approximately one-third of European pension plans Inhouse-managed private sector pension plans. There is
invest their own assets (Davis and Steil, 2001). In- often executive presence from the sponsoring em-
house investment management is fundamentally ployer on the board of private sector pension plans.
different to contracted-out external management Since many private sector plans are corporate, this
because assets managed inhouse are invested by sala- suggests pressure from at least one quarter to maximise
ried employees that are typically responsible only for the current market performance of the fund. This may
their employers money. There are no conflicts of be true regardless of the benefit type, whether defined
interest with corporate finance divisions, no man- benefit or defined contribution. In a defined benefit
dates to win, and no mandates to suddenly lose. With (final salary) plan, the company (sponsor) will draw on
inhouse staff, the long-term culture and values of the its own income to make additional contributions to
pension plan can more easily align with the invest- correct a plan deficit. In a defined contribution plan,
ment philosophy on which asset allocation and whilst there is no legal duty to make additional con-
security selection are based. There is less job tenure tributions in an instance of poor plan performance,
risk, and remuneration is typically lower and less unions and plan members may engage with the firm
linked to short-term profit. The nature of the asset to such an extent that, to avoid conflict, the company
management contract is therefore long term, with is pressed to increase employer contributions. Com-
underperformance leading to neither loss of mandate panies are therefore not isolated from existing pension
nor job. This more stable and permanent investment arrangements they have put in place. Other things
context is well suited to a long investment horizon. being equal, greater contributions reduce corporate
This is evidenced by the lower portfolio turnover and profit, and therefore executive presence on the pen-
investment risk of the inhouse-managed pension sion plan board may mean greater priority given to
funds (Brown, 1998; Davidson, 1971). Based on the risk, expected return and portfolio performance than
study by Ryan and Schneider (2002), this institutional public sector pension plans. This argues that inhouse-
class is sub-divided into public and private sector. managed private sector pension assets are a second
type of dedicated institution, but one in which long-
Inhouse-managed public sector pension plans. Inhouse- term outcomes may be tempered relative to inhouse-
managed public sector plans are expected to have the managed public sector pension assets.
longest investment horizon (Ryan and Schneider,
2002). These pension plans include local authority Hypothesis 2: Corporate ownership by dedicated
employers, nationalised and previously nationalised institutions is greater in companies with higher
industries, and some federal (central government) corporate social performance than in companies
plans. Inhouse public sector plans are free from with high market liquidity
competitive pressure and commercial constraint be-
and in addition
cause their funding is solved at a public level through
the tax system. Long-term strategies, such as those Hypothesis 3:Corporate responsibility is a more
associated with CSP, are widely evidenced, and important factor in share selection for inhouse-
portfolio turnover is lower than any other type of managed public sector pension plans than for
institutional investor (Monks and Minow, 2001; inhouse-managed private sector pension plans.
Ryan and Schneider, 2002). Some researchers argue
that these pension schemes may serve a range of social,
political, and geographic goals, for example, having
dialogue with large employers to press for better Methods
neighbourhoods in which pension plan members live
(Monks and Minow, 2001; Murphy and Van Nuys, Sample
1994; Romano, 1993). This suggests a range of
motivations and broader values beyond those due to The sample of firms chosen for data collection is that
a strict adherence to fiduciary principles. For this type of the FTSE AllShare index, a market-value-weigh-
of dedicated institution, then, corporate responsibility ted index representing 9899% of the UK market and
is expected to be relatively important. the most widely used UK institutional benchmark.
Institutional Interest in Corporate Responsibility 151

Ownership data for sample firms was drawn in June transient institutions. First, all shares held by mutual
2002 from a corporate ownership database main- funds were pooled per sample firm. Next, all shares
tained by one of the UKs largest company regis- held by life insurance funds were pooled per sample
trars. The registrar continuously updates shareholder firm. Greater attention was paid to pension plans. If
account information for 2000 UK firms via daily the pension plan was in the public sector, then it was
changes in ownership, as recorded by equity trans- coded public, if a private sector plan, then it was
action information on the London Stock Exchange. coded private. If the name of the pension plan and
The data are used by investor relations departments to the name of the asset manager were equal or related,
understand investor demographics and by investment then it was coded inhouse, (e.g. British Airways
professionals to monitor ownership changes and to and British Airways Pension Fund), and external in
source stock for trading. The database allows for the the absence of any similarity or relationship, (e.g.
creation of investor clienteles. For example, the BBC and Deutsche Asset Management). To calcu-
database showed that some 2300 different pension late the dependent variables, the pooled number of
funds held shares in FTSE AllShare companies. It lists shares held by each category of institution to the
the investor name, country of origin, appointed fund total number of shares outstanding per sample firm is
managers and the number of shares held in each UK computed. The calculation method is presented in
company. Variables for the market liquidity factor are Table I. The following dependent variables were
drawn from The London Stock Exchange and FTSE. created: mutual funds, life insurance funds, exter-
Variables for the portfolio theory factor are drawn nally managed pension plans, inhouse-managed
from BARRA, an investment software and research public sector pension plans, and inhouse-managed
company. Variables for the corporate responsibility private sector pension plans.
factor are drawn from Factiva, a Dow Jones & Reuters
product and The Ethical Investment Research Ser-
vice (EIRIS). Almost all non-ownership data are Independent factors
collected for the prior 18 months and then averaged.
This is relevant because share ownership as at June Market liquidity
2002 is a reflection of investment decisions made Three variables are used to represent the market
weeks and months before this date. Missing data re- liquidity factor: firm size, trading volume and free
duced the firm sample number from the initial of 746 float. Firm size (Size) is an indicator of market
to a final of 514. Almost all narrowing of the initial to liquidity because it enables institutions to trade large
final sample occurred as a result of missing informa- blocks of shares without significantly affecting mar-
tion about smaller firms. ket price (Roth and Saporoschenko, 2001). Short
investment horizon institutions are expected to
prefer a company whose stock has high trading
Dependent variable definition volume (Trading Volume). Free float (Free Float) is
the proportion of shares tradable within the market
The dependent variables are designed to capture the place for a given stock. A higher free float reflects
proportion of a company owned by dedicated and high stock availability that supports trading in larger

TABLE I
Calculation method of institutional share holding in a firm

P
X
Shares owned by institutionin firmi at timet
Mean Percent Holdingi Shares outstanding in firmi at timet
x1
Mean Percent Holding is the proportion of firm i owned by a category of investment institutions, e.g. mutual funds,
where X is the total number of institutions in the specified category, and firm i is a FTSE All Share security
Shares outstanding are adjusted for free float. Adjusting firms share capital for free float overcomes situations where an
investor owns a proportion of a line of stock that is unlikely to be for sale and so ensures an accurate representation of the
proportion of a firms stock that is available for portfolio investors
152 Paul Cox and Patricia Gaya Wicks

blocks. Firm size is computed as the dollar value of Corporate responsibility


company assets. Trading volume is computed as Four variables are used to represent the corporate
shares traded per month divided by the free float- responsibility factor: health and safety (Health &
adjusted number of shares outstanding. Free float Safety), equal opportunities (Equal Opportunities),
varies from 0 to 1, with 1 being complete stock environment (Environment), and non-financial news
availability, and 0 no stock availability. stories (Non-financial News). The first three variables
are selected because they represent major stakeholder
Portfolio theory categories and follow the theoretical and empirical
Three variables are used to represent the portfolio CSP literature (Griffin and Mahon, 1997; Wood,
theory factor: total risk, systematic risk and value. 1991). The fourth variable, non-financial news sto-
Each of the proxies is widely used within previ- ries, is included to capture all other stakeholder cat-
ous research on share selection (Creedy, 1994; egories. A significant body of research contributes
Falkenstein, 1996; Gompers and Metrick, 2001; evidence to the case for some degree of systematic
Hessel and Norman, 1992; OBrien and Bhushan, early positioning of an investment portfolio around
1990). All institutions are expected to be averse to CSP.
total risk (Stock Price Volatility), though heteroge- Equal opportunities and health and safety both
neously so. Systematic risk (Beta) is the risk which offer perspectives on the work environment. Hansen
cannot be diversified away for it comprises aspects and Wernerfelt (1989) and Berman et al. (1999) find
that all firms are exposed to, for example, the price a positive relationship between work environment
of oil and gas. Since it cannot be off-loaded, inves- quality and financial performance. Dennison (1984)
tors are expected to only be prepared to take on this finds that work environment quality is positively
risk if they are rewarded for doing so. The exact associated with firm profitability and that changes in
relationship with systematic risk depends on insti- firm profitability follow changes in work environ-
tutional investors tolerance for risk. More risk- ment quality by 23 years. In their respective studies
tolerant investors will tolerate a higher beta, less Turban and Greening (1997), Albinger and Freeman
risk-tolerant investors will demand a lower beta. (2000), Greening and Turban (2000), and Backhaus
Empirical studies have so far tended to reveal a po- et al. (2002) find a positive relationship between
sitive relationship between investment institutions more responsible firms and employer attractiveness,
holdings of shares and systematic risk (Badrinath suggesting that more responsible firms draw on a
et al., 1989; Eatkins et al., 1998; OBrien and deeper and more talented pool of prospective
Bhushan, 1990). Fama and French (1993) suggest employees.
that long-run returns can also be explained by small Regarding the natural environment, Buhr (1994),
capitalisation and value factors. Firm size is already Orlitzky and Benjamin (2001) and Al-Tuwaijri et al.
included within the Liquidity factor. Value investing (2004) find that high environmental performance
involves identifying efficient firms that are over- firms have better financial performance. Nehrt
looked or unfashionable, and therefore inexpensive (1996) demonstrates that early timing of environ-
and undervalued. Yardsticks are used to identify mental strategies significantly contributed to sub-
inexpensive securities with adequate safety margins sequent profit growth in firms. Bragdon and Marlin
versus their intrinsic value. A positive relationship is (1972) and Riahi-Belkaoui (1976) find a positive
expected with Value for it suggests greater return. relationship between pollution disclosure and excess
Stock price volatility is measured as the variance of return. Spicer (1978a, b) discovers some support for
stock price returns over the previous 60 months. Beta a positive relationship between financial perfor-
is the slope of 60-month stock returns regressed on the mance and environmental performance in the pulp
market. There is no theoretical basis to suggest the best and paper industry. Shane and Spicer (1983) and
time period for the calculation of beta; however, the Holman et al. (1985) find a negative relationship
most frequently used beta estimate in share selection between pollution and rates of return.
research has been 60 months (see, e.g. Badrinath et al., The inclusion of non-financial news stories is
1989, 1996; Eatkins et al., 1998; Falkenstein, 1996). designed to capture other stakeholder categories. This
The BARRA Value variable is used. might include, for example, corporate community
Institutional Interest in Corporate Responsibility 153

involvement, family-friendly employer policies, and equal opportunities and health and safety news cat-
human rights and associated supply chain issues. egories were also deselected.
There is a mix of relationships between such vari- Finally, a set of industry dummy variables is de-
ables and financial performance. Orlitzky et al. fined to account for the possibility that the demand
(2003) find a positive relationship between corporate for shares across different industries may be influ-
community involvement and financial performance. enced by the general relationships industries have
Altman (1998) and Saiia et al. (2003) find that cor- with needs for diversification, risk, and expected
porate community involvement is strategic, and return. Industry dummies were created using the
undertaken to enhance financial success. Levy and FTSE Global Industry Classification System which
Shatto (1980), Fry et al. (1982), Useem (1988), File groups listed stocks into ten economic groups: Basic
and Prince (1998) and Brammer and Millington industries, general industries, resource extraction
(2005) find that corporate community involvement industries, cyclical consumer good industries, cyclical
is underpinned, at least in part, by public relations services, non-cyclical goods, non-cyclical services,
motives which may indirectly benefit financial per- utilities, financials, and information technology
formance. In a research on the United Nations (UN) industries. The general industry sector is chosen as
Declaration of Human Rights, Patten (1990) fails to the comparator sector.
find a relationship between corporate signing of the Table II presents a summary of the hypothesised
Global Sullivan Principles2 and financial perfor- relationships for the key factors and variables.
mance. In research on family-friendly policies, Diltz
(1995) finds that the market penalises family-related
benefits such as parental leave and dependent care Estimation technique
assistance. Preece and Filbeck (1999) find lower risk-
adjusted returns on a high family-orientated firm A multiple regression was performed that estimated
portfolio relative to a comparator benchmark, and the relationship between the percent of shares held
Filbeck and Preece (2003) report negative abnormal by a particular class of institutional investor in a
stock returns to family orientated award announce- particular firm and the variables corresponding to the
ments. On balance, there exists more non-negative market liquidity, portfolio theory and corporate
evidence than negative evidence, and therefore a
positive relationship is expected between non-financial
TABLE II
news stories and the demand for shares by dedicated
institutions. Summary of expected relationships on factors
Health and safety, equal opportunities, and envi- and variables
ronment are drawn from the EIRIS. Using the ap-
proach of Graves and Waddock (1994) and Cox Factor and variable Hypothesised relationship
et al. (2007), each text-grade rating for health and Market liquidity
safety, equal opportunities and environment per Size More positive and
sample firm is translated into a number-grade rating Free float significant for
starting at 1 and increasing with greater perfor- Trading volume institutional shareholders
mance. To arrive at a single measure for health and with short time horizons
safety, equal opportunities, and the environment, the Portfolio theory
score on each is normalised so as to give them equal Beta + Extent depends on fund
weight. This generates a possible range of scores Stock price volatility - management style
from 3 to 12. Non-financial news stories data are Value +
drawn from Factiva, a product covering nearly 8000 Corporate responsibility
news sources including Dow Jones and Reuters Non-financial news More positive and
Health and safety significant for institutional
newswires and The Wall Street Journal. Financial
Equal opportunities shareholders with
accounting and earnings-based news categories were Environment long time horizons
deselected. To avoid double counting, environment,
154 Paul Cox and Patricia Gaya Wicks

responsibility factors, including the economic con- at these levels, it is unlikely to present significant
trols. The data as used in the multiple regression statistical difficulties (Greene, 1993). Variance infla-
model are summarised and presented in Table III. tion factors are estimated and in no instance do these
The estimation model used is: exceed 3. In the lower half of Table V, the corre-
lation coefficients reported provide good justifica-
COi a bXi; ei;
tion for the consolidation of variables into three
where COi is the proportion of shares in company i distinct factors. This is because the average correla-
held by a class of institutional shareholder and Xi are tion between factors is considerably lower than the
the factors that explain the share holding. Institu- average correlation within factors. Looking at the
tional constraints on short positions and a maximum within-factor correlations, the average correlation of
long position of 100% cause CO to vary between 0 the three market liquidity variables is 0.26, the three
and 1 and imply that a censored model is the most portfolio theory variables 0.41, and the four corpo-
appropriate form. When data are censored, instead rate responsibility variables 0.25. Looking among
of observing y*, we actually observe y, of the form: the factors, the average correlation coefficient of
the liquidity to portfolio theory variables is 0.17, the
y0 if y  0
portfolio theory to corporate responsibility variables
y y if y  0
0.12, and the liquidity to corporate responsibility
To avoid the biased and inconsistent parameter variables 0.24.
estimates that can be associated with ordinary least Tables VI and VII document Tobit estimates for
squares (OLS) estimation, a truncated regression the independent variables regressed on the extent of
technique is necessitated. A commonly adopted shares held by transient and dedicated institutions in
solution is to estimate a Tobit model: the sample firms. Both tables have the same layout.
On average, the model explains approximately one-
yi bXi ei
quarter of the variation in the extent of shares held
where an observed dependent variable, yi (which is by transient institutions and approximately one-fifth
equal to yi*) is generated if bXi, + ei > 0 and is of the variation in the extent of shares held by
otherwise equal to zero. An OLS model, not dedicated institutions. This finding compares favour-
reported, using heteroskedasticity-consistent (White) ably with existing studies in finance and in man-
standard errors with intercept included is also esti- agement (Coffey and Fryxell, 1991; Del Guercio,
mated and has similar results. 1996; Graves and Waddock, 1994).
Moving from the top to the bottom of Tables VI
and VII, the first section documents the importance
Findings and discussion of each of the three share selection factors in terms of
their contribution to adjusted R2. The next portion,
The discussion of results begins by presenting Rank by Size of Contribution, reveals the rank
descriptive statistics for the sample data. importance of the factors. This orders and ranks the
Table IV reveals that 4700 different institutional factors according to the size of the contribution to
shareholders are recorded in the 514 sample firms. adjusted R2. The adjusted R2 is presented because
Looking at the mean fund holding per sample firm, corporate responsibility has one more variable than
which reveals the mean ownership for a single insti- market liquidity and portfolio theory factors. In or-
tutional shareholder in a single line of stock, those that der to determine the contribution to adjusted R2 due
are inhouse-managed public sector pension plans hold to each of the factors, the industry controls were
twice as much in each sample firm as any other class of first of all entered as a block on their own and the
institution, and those that are externally managed adjusted R2 noted. Next, the three market liquidity
pension plans half as much as any other class. variables were entered in addition to the industry
Table V presents correlation coefficients for the controls and the adjusted R2 noted. Following this,
independent variables. In the top half of Table V, the three market liquidity variables were removed,
the magnitudes of the correlation coefficients suggest and the three portfolio theory variables added
some very limited evidence of multicollinearity, but alongside the industry controls. The adjusted R2 was
TABLE III
The data as used in the multiple regression model

Factor Share Liquidity (independent Portfolio theory Corporate responsibility Industries


holding variable) (independent variable) (independent variable) (independent
(dependent variable)
variable)
Definition Proportion Free float Trading Firm Systematic Share Value News Health Equal Environment Industry
of shares volume size risk price stories and safety opportunities dummies
held by type (beta) volatility
of institution
Source Computershare FTSE London Datastream Barra Barra Barra Reuters EIRIS EIRIS EIRIS FTSE
stock factiva
exchange

Companies
Abbey National x x x x x x x x x x x x
Anglo American x x x x x x x x x x x x
Astrazeneca x x x x x x x x x x x x

= 514 companies
Institutional Interest in Corporate Responsibility

Notes. The purpose served by each variable is noted in the row titled Factor. The definition of each variable is noted in the row titled Definition. The data source for each
variable used is listed in the row titled Source.
The dependent variable is the proportion of shares outstanding held by a class of institution in each company. The share ownership data were obtained from Computershare
Analytics, now part of Thomson Financial.
155
156 Paul Cox and Patricia Gaya Wicks

TABLE IV
Summary statistics on share holdings

Total institutions Transient institutions Dedicated institutions

Mutual Life Externally Inhouse- Inhouse-managed


funds insurance managed managed private sector
funds pension public sector pension funds
funds pension funds

Maximum (%) 1.00 1.00 0.30 0.56 0.10 0.27


Minimum (%) 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00
SD 0.16 0.11 0.05 0.05 0.01 0.03
Mean fund holding per 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.005 0.02 0.01
sample firm (%)
No. of funds in sample 4700 1601 746 1840 66 448

TABLE V
(A) Correlation coefficients and (B) within and between factor mean correlation coefficients

(A)

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9)

(1) Size
(2) Free float 0.202**
(3) Trading volume 0.365** 0.202
(4) Value 0.162** 0.155** 0.030
(5) Stock price volatility -0.439** -0.191** 0.077* -0.245**
(6) Stock beta 0.126** -0.020 0.348** -0.246** 0.735**
(7) Non-financial news items 0.005 -0.096* 0.009 -0.127** -0.038 0.003
(8) Health and safety 0.223** 0.083* 0.185** 0.063 -0.031 0.103* -0.006
(9) Equal opportunities 0.603** 0.190** 0.329** 0.181** -0.274** 0.049 0.047 0.396**
(10) Environment 0.631** 0.205** 0.343** 0.249** -0.345** -0.017 -0.057** 0.328** 0.682**

(B)

(1) (2) (3)

(1) Market liquidity 0.26a


(2) Portfolio theory 0.17d 0.41b
(3) Corporate responsibility 0.24f 0.12e 0.25c

*Significant at the 5% level, **significant at the 1% level.


a
Computed as the absolute mean of the three market liquidity coefficients.
b
Computed as the absolute mean of the three portfolio theory coefficients.
c
Computed as the absolute mean of the four corporate responsibility coefficients.
d
Computed as the absolute mean of the nine cross correlation coefficients for market liquidity and portfolio theory.
e
Computed as the absolute mean of the 12 cross correlation coefficients for portfolio theory and corporate responsibility.
f
Computed as the absolute mean of the 12 cross correlation coefficients for market liquidity and corporate responsibility.
Institutional Interest in Corporate Responsibility 157

TABLE VI
Transient institutions: institutional share selection due to market liquidity, portfolio theory and corporate responsibility

Mutual funds Life assurance funds Externally managed pension funds

Contribution of share selection factor to adjusted R2


Industry 0.01 0.02 0.03
Industry and market liquidity 0.32 0.08 0.17
Industry and portfolio theory 0.14 0.07 0.20
Industry and corporate responsibility 0.10 0.05 0.08
Total Adj. R2 0.36 0.13 0.19
Rank by size of contribution
1st Liquidity Liquidity Portfolio theory
2nd Portfolio theory Portfolio theory Liquidity
3rd Responsibility Responsibility Responsibility
4th Industry Industry Industry
Independent variables
Constant 0.588 (0.076)*** 0.258 (0.042)*** 0.180 (0.043)***
Size 0.003 (0.005) 0.003 (0.003) -0.0001 (0.003)
Free float -0.051 (0.026)** -0.020 (0.003) 0.008 (0.015)
Trading volume 0.044 (0.005)*** 0.014 (0.003)*** 0.005 (0.003)***
Value -0.007 (0.005) 0.002 (0.003) 0.007 (0.003)***
Stock price volatility 0.128 (0.105) -0.330 (0.058)*** -0.365 (0.060)***
Stock beta -0.053 (0.034) 0.083 (0.019)*** 0.123 (0.019)***
Non-financial news -0.005 (0.006) 0.009 (0.003)*** 0.003 (0.003)
Health and Safety -0.004 (0.007) 0.004 (0.004) 0.007 (0.004)*
Equal opportunities 0.015 (0.006)*** 0.005 (0.003) -0.001 (0.004)
Environment 0.003 (0.006) 0.001 (0.004) 0.001 (0.004)

*Significant at the 10% level, **significant at the 5% level, ***significant at the 1% level.

again noted. Finally, the three portfolio theory life insurance funds. For all types of transient insti-
variables were removed, and the four corporate tution analysed in this study, the long-term corpo-
responsibility variables entered alongside the indus- rate responsibility factor is lowest in rank, providing
try controls, and the adjusted R2 noted. strong support for hypothesis 1. The implication is
that the short time horizon by which transient
institutional investors are constrained for instance,
Transient institutions findings by virtue of their vulnerability to short-term moni-
toring and assessments severely limits the extent to
Moving from left to right in Table VI, along the which more complex, longer-term, ethical consid-
rows associated with Rank by Size of Contribution, erations are factored into investment decisions.
for two of the three types of transient institution, The lower half of Table VI reports the coeffi-
market liquidity contributes most to adjusted R2. cients when the control and independent variables
This is surprising in that all the institutions examined are entered at once. Industry variables are excluded
in this study are investment fiduciaries, and thus, in a for reasons of space. All of the three classes of tran-
neutral setting, one might expect portfolio theory to sient institution have greater holdings in companies
rank the highest. This indicates greater investment whose stock has greater market liquidity (Trading
demand for firms whose stock has low transaction Volume p < 0.01). These preferences point to a
costs and in which positions can be rapidly bought short investment horizon. Externally managed pen-
and sold. Most of all, this is the case for mutual and sion plans have greater holdings in value stocks at
158 Paul Cox and Patricia Gaya Wicks

TABLE VII
Dedicated institutions: institutional share selection due to market liquidity, portfolio theory and corporate responsibility

Inhouse-managed public sector Inhouse-managed private


pension funds sector pension funds

Contribution of share selection factor to adjusted R2


Industry 0.01 0.03
Industry and market liquidity 0.03 0.09
Industry and portfolio theory 0.05 0.17
Industry and corporate responsibility 0.05 0.11
Total Adj. R2 0.08 0.20
Rank by size of contribution
1st Responsibility/portfolio theory Portfolio theory
2nd Liquidity Responsibility
3rd Liquidity
4th Industry Industry
Independent variables
Constant 0.010 (0.007) 0.140 (0.028)***
Size -0.0003 (0.0004) -0.004 (0.002)**
Free float 0.006 (0.002)** 0.018 (0.010)*
Trading volume 0.000009 (0.0005) 0.001 (0.002)
Value 0.0003 (0.0004) -0.001 (0.002)
Stock price volatility -0.028 (0.010)*** -0.267 (0.039)***
Stock beta 0.007 (0.003)** 0.077 (0.013)***
Non-financial news 0.001 (0.0006)* 0.008 (0.002)***
Health and safety 0.001 (0.0006) 0.004 (0.002)
Equal opportunities 0.001 (0.0005)** 0.002 (0.002)
Environment -0.0005 (0.0006) 0.005 (0.002)**

*Significant at the 10% level, **significant at the 5% level, ***significant at the 1% level.

the 1% level of significance. Mutual funds are institution. Possibly environmental strategies are the
economically different from the other institutions in most forward looking. For each of the three classes
the sense that the coefficients on Value, Beta and of transient institution, one of the corporate
Stock Price Volatility have the opposite sign to responsibility variables other than Environment is
expectations, though none are statistically significant. always significant and positive. The fact that short-
An absence of aversion to stock price volatility in the term orientated institutions are at all interested in
mutual fund industry confirms previous work that any aspect of CSP highlights the value in disaggre-
mutual funds take relatively high risk (Falkenstein, gating the construct. At least some components are
1996). The result is also consistent with evidence perceived to have benefit even to short-term, trad-
that mutual fund managers adapt their portfolio ing-intensive institutions.
holdings over time to either consolidate or win When the UK FTSE AllShare index constituent
performance relative to results posted by other weights were entered into the model, not reported,
portfolio managers, including increasing exposure to there is no statistical significance on the four cor-
stock price volatility when underperforming (Brown porate responsibility variables. This is relevant to the
et al., 1996; Lakonishok et al., 1991). analysis because it means that if statistical significance
Turning to the rows associated with corporate is found it indicates that institutional investors are
responsibility, the coefficient on Environment is tilting their portfolio equity holdings either towards
insignificant for all the three classes of transient or away from these variables.
Institutional Interest in Corporate Responsibility 159

Dedicated institutions findings Turning to the rows associated with corporate


responsibility, for each class of dedicated institution
Table VII reports results for dedicated institutions two out of the four variables are always positive and
according to a categorisation of institutions set out in significant. Only one was significant for each of the
prior conceptual work by Ryan and Schneider transient institutions. The coefficients on Non-
(2002). financial News are positive and significant (p < 0.1
Looking at the rows associated with Rank by Size and p < 0.01), indicating preferences by dedicated
of Contribution, and moving from left to right, institutions for firms that communicate to their
corporate responsibility and portfolio theory are multiplicity of stakeholders. Inhouse-managed pub-
equal first in importance as determinants of the de- lic sector pension plans also invest more in firms
mand for shares by inhouse-managed public sector with better Equal Opportunities (p < 0.05), sug-
pension plans. Corporate responsibility is as impor- gesting preferences for a less liable firm. Finally, the
tant as portfolio theory in determining holdings of relationship between corporate ownership by dedi-
shares. For both categories of dedicated institution, cated institutions and the environment is not
corporate responsibility is more important than straightforward. Inhouse-managed private sector
market liquidity, providing support for hypothesis 2. pension plans prefer it, whilst inhouse-managed
The rank of corporate responsibility is higher for public sector pension plans are neutral towards it. It
inhouse public sector pension plans than inhouse may be that, at present, the relationship between a
private sector pension plans, so hypothesis 3 is also firms environmental record and its financial per-
confirmed. This also supports conceptual work by formance is complex, and interpreted by investors,
Ryan and Schneider (2002), which suggests that even those with long investment planning horizons,
public sector pension plans have the longest invest- in different ways.
ment horizons and greatest interest in long-term Of course, the extent to which the pursuit of
corporate outcomes. corporate responsibility can ultimately be reduced to
Turning to the lower half of Table VII, the rows discussions involving investment risk and return
associated with the Independent Variables report raises some pertinent questions about the signifi-
that both classes of dedicated institution have greater cance of such trends with respect to movements
holdings in firms with higher free float (p < 0.05 and towards ethical business practice. We now turn to a
p < 0.10). This facilitates trading larger holdings of discussion of such questions, as perceived through an
shares, about which there is supporting evidence in axiologically informed critical lens.
Table III. The negative coefficients on Size suggest
that inhouse-managed private sector pension plans
hold proportionately less in larger firms and pro- Towards ethical business practice?
portionately more in smaller firms (p < 0.05). The
coefficients on Trading Volume are not significant. The findings of this study highlight two key trends
This is significantly different to the result for tran- particularly relevant to debates on ethical business
sient institutions, all of which invested more in firms practice. The first is the elaboration of some insti-
whose stocks had high trading volume at the 1% tutional investors positioning as patient and dedi-
level of significance. It may be that dedicated insti- cated, in differentiation to those transient investors
tutions have higher holdings in smaller firms due to driven primarily by short-term considerations. The
preferences for more active ownership. Both Size second is the apparent growing importance of cor-
and Trading Volume suggest that market liquidity is porate responsibility as a determinant of share
not as important to dedicated institutions. The ownership, and yet, as argued earlier, it is possible to
coefficient on Value is not significant, indicating no question the extent to which these trends can be
systematic preference for value or growth fund understood as meaningful movements towards eth-
management styles. The coefficients on the other ical business practice. Our contention is that any
portfolio theory variables confirm prior evidence of such movements are necessarily constrained by the
aversion to Stock Price Volatility and a preference willingness and ability of the various actors who
for greater systematic risk (Beta). form part of the institutionalised market system to
160 Paul Cox and Patricia Gaya Wicks

engage in axiological debates, addressing questions and subtle, rather than formalised. Indeed, delays in
about underpinning values and motivations. This is a legitimising any such shifts are only to be expected,
fundamental aspect of the theory and study of ethics. given that codified ethics, in the form of legal
Indeed, some critics argue that the popular rhetoric responsibilities, are always behind the times and/or
pertaining to business ethics serves not to illuminate, playing catch up (Carroll, 1991, p. 41). Hence,
but to distract from thorny questions regarding value alongside its concern with the extent to which trends
choices, priorities, and conflicts of interests: of dedicated versus transient institutional investment
may be indicative of significant shifts in ethical
As much as one would like to believe that all the talk business practice, this article also speaks to broader
about business ethics today reflects an increased desire
alterations in how the relationship between the
by business executives and political leaders to examine
function of markets and issues of ethics is conceived.
the ethical foundations of their activities criti-
cally[by] its very construction, the official discourse
of business ethics precludes such an engagement Boundaries and limitations of highly institutionalised
[Instead,] it presents as universal the partisan interests market models
of corporations, by masking the frequent incompati-
bility of social and corporate interests under a rhe-
Despite some of the trends highlighted in this study,
torical gloss that allows the comfortable cohabita-
tion of social responsibility and corporate profitability. the fact remains that within a highly institutionalised
(Kleinberg Neimark, 1995, p. 88) market model, the ability of individual investors to
engage fully, actively, and/or creatively with ques-
Through this critical lens, it is possible to question tions of ethics and morality is seriously constrained.
the extent to which this studys findings contribute As shifting conceptualisations of morality-and-the-
to such a rhetorical gloss, by positing corporate market show, social responsibility is a moving tar-
responsibility as a significant factor in share selection get (Churchill, 1974, p. 266). And yet, the
and a vehicle for improving long-run financial assumption implicitly made by a deontological,
rewards for fund management firms and their clients. legalistic approach to ethical decision-making of
Given this, it is necessary to consider the extent to the kind which underpins the fiduciary principle and
which the trends evidenced through this study are the legalities of institutional investment is that such
enabling and/or constitutive of shifting (if not considerations can, in fact, be pinned down, at least
wholly transformative) forms of ethical engagement in the short and medium terms. The bureaucratic
within the context of institutional investment. and regulatory infrastructure in which institutional
When dedicated institutions, in opposition to tran- investors operate is likely to be experienced, for all
sient ones, make the decision to focus on long-term intents and purposes, as largely solid and indisputable
rather than short-term goals, this begins to shift the (see also Rose, 2007). As this study demonstrates,
parameters within which investors can work, and this would especially appear to be the case for
what they can value. If, as is often claimed, one of transient investors who are more vulnerable to the
the failures of the business case for corporate short-term demands and assessments of their clients.
responsibility is its dependence on short and med- In contrast, under certain conditions and against
ium-term financial rewards (Carter and Huby, the odds, it may be possible to understand the
2005), then the move to include longer-term and market not just as an arena for ethically engaged
broader concerns as an aspect of the practice of social action, but as a source of moral consciousness
modern portfolio theory could be perceived as a and a site for the development of ethical sensibilities
welcome, if not sufficient, shift. (Zwick et al., 2007, p. 191). Significantly, the spe-
Moreover, the fact that institutional investors cific conditions which make this possible are absent
appear able to make decisions which take into ac- from institutional, mediated forms of investment. As
count factors other than portfolio theory and Zwick et al. (2007) explain, private individuals in-
liquidity may be representative of a shift in collective volved in do-it-yourself, online trading increasingly
conceptualisations of the role, place, and nature of seek to question and learn about the causal, ethical
morality in the market. Such shifts may be tentative effects of their investment choices. Thus, these types
Institutional Interest in Corporate Responsibility 161

of investors are legitimately able to bring greater portfolio theory; and a long-term factor, corporate
critical awareness to bear on their investment responsibility. The rank and importance of the fac-
decisions. Instead, mediated investment forces the tors for the different types of institutional investor
institutional investor, by virtue of fiduciary respon- are analysed.
sibilities, to focus on evaluating economic dimen- This study uncovers evidence consistent with a
sions like percentage growth and return on focus on long-term outcomes and a focus on short-
investment, while [in the process]conceal[ing] the term outcomes. The study firstly finds that for two
type of causeeffect relationships that a direct of three types of transient institution investigated,
experience of market discipline provides (Zwick market liquidity is the most important factor in the
et al., 2007, p. 193). demand for shares. For all three types of transient
The dominance of prescriptive, legalistic institu- institution, corporate responsibility is the least
tional frameworks is not surprising, given such important of the three factors. The study secondly
governance models grounding in ethical perspec- finds that for one of two types of dedicated institu-
tives which advocate the utility of rules, procedures, tion, corporate responsibility is as important as
laws and codes as moral standards (Jones, 2003; portfolio theory in influencing the demand for
Kjonstad and Willmott, 1995; Ladkin, 2006). As shares. For all dedicated institutions, corporate
Jones (2003, p. 238), following Rancie`re (1995), responsibility influences the demand for shares more
points out, the elimination of uncertainty and than market liquidity. This suggests that for dedi-
equation of solid ground with the good are central to cated institutions, corporate responsibility is as much
political thought at least since Aristotle. To the an input into the investment process as market
extent that such codified frameworks seek to liquidity and portfolio theory are. Thirdly, dedicated
eliminate ethical quandaries (Jones, 2003, p. 238, institutions invest more in companies with more
original emphasis), arguably their usefulness is non-financial news flow, but not necessarily more in
dubious at worst and limited at best. Indeed, as Jones firms with better environmental performance.
(2003, p. 238) asserts: we must ask if the goal of a We conclude by summarising the implications of
business ethics worthy of the name should be to offer this research for business ethics. To the extent that
comfort or whether it should be to call into the highly institutionalised Anglo market model
question the self-satisfying rules, excuses and alibis necessitates strict adherence to a codified set of
that produce a reassuring sense of comfort. fiduciary principles, institutional investors are limited
in their ability to engage more critically and crea-
tively with the ethical dilemmas, contradictions, and
Conclusions trade-offs inherent to prevailing business and finan-
cial models. Working within these constraints,
This study examines market liquidity, portfolio dedicated institutions commitment to broader and
theory, and corporate responsibility as determinants longer-term concerns, such as corporate responsi-
of the demand for shares for the following classes of bility, may be understood as a small but significant
transient institution: mutual funds, life insurance step towards the kind of engagement with ethical
funds, and externally managed pension plans; and the dilemmas that Ladkin (2006), for one, advocates.
following classes of dedicated institution: inhouse- Such a form of engagement calls for sensitive
managed public sector pension plans, and inhouse- attention to a fuller range of features deemed to be
managed private sector pension plans. The study relevant to particular decisions, as opposed to more
hypothesises that a principal difference between narrow, if often more straight-forward, reliance on
transient and dedicated institutions lies in the iden- legislation and codes of practice. Further research is
tification of their investment time horizon and the indicated into any opportunities for shifting the
trading patterns that link to this. The study suggests boundaries of what is possible within an institu-
that this is revealed by differences in their demand tionalised market system, and also into the barriers to
for shares. The demand for shares is organised doing so. The phenomenon of dedicated, patient
according to three factors: a short-term factor, investors, and the growing importance of corporate
market liquidity; and a time-independent factor, responsibility as a determinant of share ownership,
162 Paul Cox and Patricia Gaya Wicks

would appear to signify such an expansion in Badrinath, S. G., G. D. Gay and J. R. Kale: 1989, Pat-
boundaries. Future studies might critically examine terns of Institutional Investment, Prudence, and the
the extent to which these trends are representative of Managerial Safety-Net Hypothesis, The Journal of Risk
substantial shifts to the ethical underpinnings of and Insurance 56(4), 605629.
markets, beyond serving as a form of rhetorical gloss. Badrinath, S. G., J. R. Kale and H. E. Ryan: 1996,
Characteristics of Common Stock Holdings of
Insurance Companies, The Journal of Risk and Insurance
63(1), 4976.
Notes Benson, K. L., T. J. Brailsford and J. E. Humphrey: 2006,
1
Do Socially Responsible Fund Managers Really
This might involve buying stocks with high recent Invest Differently?, Journal of Business Ethics 65, 337
returns and selling those with low returns over the same 357.
period. Berman, S. L., A. C. Wicks, S. Kotha and T. M. Jones:
2
These are based on the UN Declaration of Human 1999, Does Stakeholder Orientation Matter? The
Rights. Relationship Between Stakeholder Management
Models and Firm Financial Performance, Academy of
Management Journal 42(5), 483506.
Bragdon, J. H. and J. T. Marlin: 1972, Is Pollution
Acknowledgement Profitable?, Risk Management 19(4), 918.
Brammer, S. and A. I. Millington: 2005, Corporate
The authors would like to thank two anonymous refer- Reputation and Philanthropy: An Empirical Analysis,
ees for their very helpful comments during the period Journal of Business Ethics 61(1), 2944.
of revision of this article. Brown, C.: 1998, Rise of the Institutional Equity Funds:
Implications for Managerialism, Journal of Economic
Issues 32, 803821.
Brown, K. C., W. V. Harlow and L. T. Starks: 1996, Of
References Tournaments and Temptations: An Analysis of Man-
agerial Incentives in the Mutual Fund Industry, Journal
Acharya, S. and E. Dimson: 2007, Endowment Asset of Finance 51(1), 85110.
Management: Investment Strategies in Oxford and Cam- Buhr, N.: 1994, Environmental Disclosure: An Empirical
bridge (Oxford University Press, Oxford). Study of Corporate Communication in Canada and
Acker, D. and N. W. Duck: 2006, A Tournament Model the Role of Accounting, Ph.D. Dissertation, The
of Fund Management, Journal of Business Finance & University of Western Ontario.
Accounting 33(9&10), 14601483. Bushee, B. J.: 1998, The Influence of Institutional
Albinger, H. S. and S. J. Freeman: 2000, Corporate Investors on Myopic R&D Investment Behaviour,
Social Performance and Attractiveness as an Employer The Accounting Review 73(3), 305333.
to Different Job Seeking Populations, Journal of Busi- Bushee, B. J. and Noe, C. F.: 2000, Corporate
ness Ethics 28(3), 243253. Disclosure Practices, Institutional Investors, and Stock
Allen, G. and D. Gale: 2001, Comparing Financial Systems Return Volatility, Journal of Accounting Research
(MIT Press, Cambridge). 38(Supplement), 171202.
Altman, B. W.: 1998, Corporate Community Relations Carhart, M. M.: 1997, On Persistence in Mutual Fund
in the 1990s: A Study in Transformation, Business & Performance, Journal of Finance 52(1), 5782.
Society 37(2), 221227. Carroll, A. B.: 1991, The Pyramid of Corporate Social
Al-Tuwaijri, S. A., T. E. Christensen and K. E. Hughes Responsibility: Toward the Moral Management of
II: 2004, The Relations Among Environmental Dis- Organizational Stakeholders, Business Horizons July
closure, Environmental Performance, and Economic August, 3948.
Performance: A Simultaneous Equations Approach, Carter, N. and M. Huby: 2005, Ecological Citizenship
Accounting, Organizations and Society 29, 447471. and Ethical Investment, Environmental Politics 14(2),
Backhaus, K. B., B. A. Stone and K. Heiner: 2002, 255272.
Exploring the Relationship Between Corporate Social Chan, L. K. and J. Lakonishok: 1995, The Behaviour of
Performance and Employer Attractiveness, Business & Stock Prices Around Institutional Trades, Journal of
Society 41(3), 292318. Finance 50(4), 11471174.
Institutional Interest in Corporate Responsibility 163

Chen, H. and G. G. Penacchi: 2001, Does Prior Per- Droms, W. G. and D. A. Walker: 1996, Mutual Fund
formance Affect Mutual Fund Choice of Risk? Theory Investment Performance, The Quarterly Review of
and Further Empirical Evidence, Financial Intermedia- Economics and Finance 36(3), 347363.
tion Research Society (November) 29(1), 135. Dyl, E. A., and A. M. Anderson: 2002, Market Structure
Chevalier, J. and G. Ellison: 1997, Risk Taking by and Trading Volume, University of Arizona Working
Mutual Funds as a Response to Incentives, Journal of Paper, August.
Political Economy 105(6), 11671200. Eatkins, S. G., S. R. Stansell and J. F. Buck: 1998,
Churchill, N.: 1974, Toward a Theory of Social Analyzing the Nature of Institutional Demand for
Accounting, Sloan Management Review 15(3), 117. Common Stocks, The Quarterly Journal of Business and
Climate Change Business Forum: 2010, Understanding Economics 37(2), 3348.
Climate Change, http://www.climatechangebusinessf Ehrenberg, R. G. and M. L. Bognanno: 1990, Do
orum.com/en-us/understanding. Tournaments Have Incentive Effects?, Journal of
Coffey, B. S. and G. E. Fryxell: 1991, Institutional Political Economy 98(6), 13071324.
Ownership of Stock and Dimensions of Corpo- Ennis, R. M.: 2001, The Case for Whole Stock Port-
rate Social Performance: An Empirical Examination, folios, Journal of Portfolio Management 27(3), 1726.
Journal of Business Ethics 10, 437444. European Union: 2002, Corporate Social Responsibility:
Cox, P.: 2009, Responsible Investment in Fund Man- A Business Contribution to Sustainable Development,
agement: It Works, But When?, Department For http://ewindows.eu.org/Industry/Reporting/cec__
Work and Pensions Research Report, http://www. corporate_responsibility/csr_eu_strategy.pdf.
nestpensions.org.uk/investment.aspx. Falkenstein, E. G.: 1996, Preferences for Stock Charac-
Cox, P., S. Brammer and A. Millington: 2007, Pension teristics as Revealed by Mutual Fund Portfolio Hold-
Fund Manager Tournaments and Attitudes Towards ings, Journal of Finance 51(1), 111135.
Corporate Characteristics, Journal of Business Finance & Fama, E. F. and K. R. French: 1993, Common Risk
Accounting 34(7/8), 13071326. Factors in the Returns on Stocks and Bonds, Journal of
Creedy, W. M.: 1994, Determinants of Relative Investor Financial Economics 33(1), 356.
Demand for Common Stocks, Journal of Accounting, Filbeck, G. and D. C. Preece: 2003, Announcement
Auditing and Finance 9(3), 487507. Effects of the Working Mother Annual Survey of
David, P., M. A. Hitt and J. Gimeno: 2001, The Influ- Family-Friendly Firms, Journal of Investing 12(3), 87
ence of Activism by Institutional Investors on R&D, 95.
Academy of Management Journal 44, 144157. File, K. M. and R. A. Prince: 1998, Cause Related
David, P., R. Kochhar and E. Levitas: 1998, The Effects Marketing and Corporate Philanthropy in the Pri-
of Institutional Investors on the Level and Mix of vately Held Enterprise, Journal of Business Ethics
CEO Compensation, Academy of Management Journal 17(14), 15291539.
41, 200207. Froot, K. A., A. F. Perold and J. Stein: 1992, Shareholder
Davidson, H. A.: 1971, Investing College Endowment Trading Practices and Corporate Investment Hori-
Funds, Financial Analysts Journal JanuaryFebruary, zons, Continental Bank Journal of Applied Corporate
6974. Finance 5(2), 4258.
Davis, P. E. and B. Steil: 2001, Institutional Investors (MIT Fry, F. L., G. D. Keim and R. E. Meiners: 1982, Cor-
Press, Cambridge). porate Contributions: Altruistic or for Profit?, Acad-
Del Guercio, D.: 1996, The Distorting Effect of the emy of Management Journal 25(1), 94106.
Prudent-Man Laws on Institutional Equity Invest- FSA: 2007, Permitted Links for Long Term Insurance
ments, Journal of Financial Economics 40(1), 3162. Business, CP07/7, March, http://www.fsa.gov.uk/
Del Guercio, D. and P. A. Tkac: 2002, The Determi- pubs/cp/cp07_07.pdf.
nants of the Flow of Funds of Managed Portfolios: Fukukawa, K., J. M. T. Balmer and E. R. Gray: 2007,
Mutual Funds Versus Pension Funds, Journal of Mapping the Interface Between Corporate Identity,
Financial and Quantitative Analysis 37(4), 523557. Ethics and Corporate Social Responsibility, Journal of
Dennison, D. R.: 1984, Bringing Corporate Culture to Business Ethics 76(1), 15.
the Bottom Line, Organizational Dynamics 13(2), 522. Gatens, M.: 2000, Feminism as Password: Rethinking
Diltz, J. D.: 1995, Does Social Screening Affect Portfolio the Possible with Spinoza and Deleuze, Hypatia
Performance?, The Journal of Investing 4(1), 6469. 15(2), 5975.
Doane, D.: 2005, Beyond Corporate Social Responsi- Gompers, P. A. and A. Metrick: 2001, Institutional
bility: Minnows, Mammoths and Markets, Futures 37, Investors and Equity Prices, The Quarterly Journal of
215229. Economics 116(1), 229259.
164 Paul Cox and Patricia Gaya Wicks

Goriaev, A., F. Palomino and A. Prat: 2000, Mutual Jones, C.: 2003, As If Business Ethics Were Possible,
Fund Tournament: Risk Taking Incentives Induced Within Such Limits, Organization 10(2), 223248.
by Ranking Objectives?, Tilberg University Center Khorana, A.: 2001, Performance Changes Following
Discussion Paper, 129. Top Management Turnover: Evidence from Open-
Graves, S. B. and S. A. Waddock: 1994, Institutional End Mutual Funds, Journal of Financial and Quantitative
Owners and Social Performance, Academy of Manage- Analysis 36(3), 371393.
ment Journal 37(4), 10341046. Kjonstad, B. and H. Willmott: 1995, Business Ethics:
Greene, W. H.: 1993, Econometric Analysis (Macmillan, Restrictive or Empowering?, Journal of Business Ethics
New York). 14(6), 445464.
Greening, D. W. and D. B. Turban: 2000, Corporate Kleinberg Neimark, M.: 1995, The Selling of Ethics:
Social Performance as a Competitive Advantage in The Ethics of Business Meets the Business of Ethics,
Attracting a Quality Workforce, Business & Society Accounting, Auditing & Accountability Journal 8(3), 81
39(3), 254280. 96.
Griffin, J. J. and J. F. Mahon: 1997, The Corporate Kurtz, L.: 2005, Answers to Four Questions, The Journal
Social Performance and Corporate Financial Perfor- of Investing 14(3), 125139.
mance Debate, Business and Society 36(1), 531. Ladkin, D.: 2006, When Deontology and Utilitarianism
Hansen, G. S. and B. Wernerfelt: 1989, Determinants of Arent Enough: How Heideggers Notion of Dwell-
Firm Performance: The Relative Importance of Eco- ing Might Help Organisational Leaders Resolve
nomic and Organizational Factors, Strategic Manage- Ethical Issues, Journal of Business Ethics 65(3), 8798.
ment Journal 10(5), 399411. Lakonishok, J., A. Shleifer, R. Thaler and R. Vishny:
Hekman, S. J.: 1995, Moral Voices, Moral Selves: Carol 1991, Window Dressing by Pension Fund Managers,
Gilligan and Feminist Moral Theory (Polity Press and American Economic Review 81(2), 227231.
Pennsylvania State University Press, Cambridge and Levy, F. K. and G. M. Shatto: 1980, Social Responsi-
University Park). bility in Large Electric Utility Firms: The Case for
Hendry, J., P. Sanderson, R. Barker and J. Roberts: 2006, Philanthropy, in L. E. Preston (ed.), Research in Cor-
Owners or Traders? Conceptualizations of Institu- porate Social Performance and Policy, Vol. 2 (JAI Press,
tional Investors and Their Relationship with Corpo- Greenwich, CT), pp. 237249.
rate Managers, Human Relations 59(8), 11011132. Lewis, A. and C. Mackenzie: 2000, Morals, Money,
Herman, E. S.: 1963, Growth and Impact of Mutual Ethical Investing and Economic Psychology, Human
Funds. Some Analytical and Public Policy Issues, Relations 53(2), 171191.
Journal of Finance 18(2), 360376. Meyer, M. A. and J. Vickers: 1997, Performance
Hessel, C. A. and B. Norman: 1992, Financial Charac- Comparisons and Dynamic Incentives, Journal of
teristics of Institutionally Held Stocks, Journal of Political Economy 105(3), 547581.
Accounting, Auditing and Finance 7(3), 313330. Monks, R. A. G. and N. Minow: 2001, Corporate Gov-
Holland, J.: 1998, Influence and Intervention by ernance (Blackwell, Cambridge, MA).
Financial Institutions in Their Investee Companies, Murphy, K. and K. Van Nuys: 1994, State Pension
Corporate Governance 6(4), 249264. Funds and Shareholder Inactivism, Harvard Business
Holman, W. R., J. R. New and D. Singer: 1985, The School Working Paper.
Impact of Corporate Social Responsiveness on Myners, P.: 2001, Institutional Investment in the United
Shareholder Wealth, Research in Corporate Social Per- Kingdom: A Review, HM Treasury, http://archive.
formance and Policy 7, 137152. treasury.gov.uk/pdf/2001/myners_report.pdf.
Hoskisson, R. E., M. A. Hitt, R. A. Johnson and Nehrt, C.: 1996, Timing and Intensity of Environmental
W. Grossman: 2002, Conflicting Voices: The Effects Investments, Strategic Management Journal 17(7), 535
of Institutional Ownership Heterogeneity and Internal 547.
Governance on Corporate Innovation Strategies, New Prudent Investor Rule: 2006, Restatement of the
Academy of Management Journal 45(4), 697716. Law Third, Trusts (Prudent Investor Rule), www.ali.
Ignatius, R.: 1999, Trustee Investment and Management org.
Responsibilities Under the Uniform Prudent Investor OBrien, P. C. and R. Bhushan: 1990, Analyst Follow-
Act, CFA Digest 29(3), 34. ing and Institutional Ownership, Journal of Accounting
Johnson, R. D. and D. W. Greening: 1999, The Effects Research 28(Supplement), 5576.
of Corporate Governance and Institutional Ownership Office for National Statistics: 2010, Share Ownership
Types on Corporate Social Performance, Academy of Survey 2008, http://www.statistics.gov.uk/pdfdir/
Management Journal 42(5), 564576. share0110.pdf.
Institutional Interest in Corporate Responsibility 165

Orlitzky, M. and J. D. Benjamin: 2001, Corporate Social Shane, P. B. and B. H. Spicer: 1983, Market Response to
Performance and Firm Risk: A Meta-Analytical Re- Environmental Information Produced Outside the
view, Business & Society 40(4), 369396. Firm, The Accounting Review 58(3), 521538.
Orlitzky, M., F. L. Schmidt and S. L. Rynes: 2003, Spicer, B. H.: 1978a, Investors, Corporate Social Per-
Corporate Social and Financial Performance: A Meta- formance, and Information Disclosure: An Empirical
Analysis, Organization Studies 24(3), 403441. Study, The Accounting Review 53, 94111.
Patten, D. M.: 1990, The Market Reaction to Social Spicer, B. H.: 1978b, Market Risk, Accounting Data and
Responsibility Disclosures: The Case of the Sullivan Companies Pollution Control Records, Journal of
Principles Signings, Accounting, Organizations and Society Business Finance and Accounting 5(1), 6783.
15, 575587. Stern, N.: 2006, Stern Review: The Economics of Cli-
Pensions Act 1999a: 1999, The Occupational Pension mate Change, http://www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/stern
Schemes (Investment, and Assignment, Forfeiture, review_index.htm.
Bankruptcy etc.) Amendment Regulations, http:// Tappan, M. B.: 2006, Moral Functioning as Mediated
www.opsi.gov.uk/si/si1999/19991849.htm. Action, Journal of Moral Education 35(1), 118.
Pensions Act 1999b: 1999, The Local Government Tihanyi, L., R. A. Johnson, R. E. Hoskisson and M. A.
Pension Scheme (Management and Investment of Hitt: 2003, Institutional Ownership Differences and
Funds) (Amendment) Regulations, http://www.opsi. International Diversification: The Effects of Boards of
gov.uk/si/si1999/uksi_19993259_en.pdf. Directors and Technological Opportunity, Academy of
Porter, M. E.: 1992, Capital Disadvantage: Americas Management Journal 46, 195211.
Failing Capital Investment System, Harvard Business Turban, D. B. and D. W. Greening: 1997, Corporate
Review 70(5), 6582. Social Performance and Organizational Attractiveness
Preece, D. C. and G. Filbeck: 1999, Family Friendly to Prospective Employees, Academy of Management
Firms; Does It Pay to Care, Financial Services Review Journal 40(3), 658672.
8(1), 4760. Useem, M.: 1988, Market and Institutional Factors
Rancie`re, J.: 1995, On the Shores of Politics (L. Heron, in Corporate Contributions, California Management
Trans.). Verso, London. Review 30(2), 7788.
Riahi-Belkaoui, A.: 1976, The Impact of the Disclosure Wood, D. J.: 1991, Corporate Social Performance
of the Environmental Effects of Organizational Revisited, Academy of Management Review 16(4),
Behavior on the Market, Financial Management 5(4), 691718.
2631. Zwick, D., J. Denegri-Knott and J. Schroeder: 2007,
Romano, R.: 1993, Public Pension Fund Activism in The Social Pedagogy of Wall Street: Stock Trading as
Corporate Governance Reconsidered, Columbia Law Political Activism?, Journal of Consumer Policy 30(3),
Review 93(4), 795853. 177199.
Rose, J. M.: 2007, Corporate Directors and Social
Responsibility: Ethics Versus Shareholder Value, Paul Cox
Journal of Business Ethics 73, 319331. Birmingham Business School,
Rosenberg, B., and J. Guy: 1995, Prediction of Beta University of Birmingham,
from Investment Fundamentals, Financial Analysts University House, Edgbaston Park Road,
Journal JanuaryFebruary, 101112. Birmingham B15 2TT, U.K.
Roth, G. and A. Saporoschenko: 2001, Institutional
E-mail: p.cox@bham.ac.uk
Ownership of Bank Shares, Financial Analysts Journal
July/August, 2736.
Patricia Gaya Wicks
Ryan, L. V. and M. Schneider: 2002, The Antecedents
Department of Management,
of Institutional Investor Activism, Academy of Man-
agement Review 27(4), 554573. School of Economics, Finance, and Management,
Saiia, D. H., A. B. Carroll and A. K. Buchholtz: 2003, University of Bristol,
Philanthropy as Strategy: When Corporate Charity 8 Woodland Road, Bristol BS8 1TN, U.K.
Begins at Home, Business Society 42(2), 169201. E-mail: patricia.gayawicks@bristol.ac.uk
Copyright of Journal of Business Ethics is the property of Springer Science & Business Media
B.V. and its content may not be copied or emailed to multiple sites or posted to a listserv
without the copyright holder's express written permission. However, users may print,
download, or email articles for individual use.

Anda mungkin juga menyukai