Anda di halaman 1dari 58

Lecture 11:

The Greeks and Risk Management

This lecture studies market risk management from


the perspective of an options trader. First, we show how
to describe the risk characteristics of derivatives. Then,
we construct portfolios that eliminate these risks.

I. Motivation
II. Partial Derivatives of Simple Securities
III. Partial Derivatives of European Options
IV. The Gamma-Theta Relationship
V. Popular Options Strategies and the Greeks
VI. Risk Management
A. Portfolio Hedging
B. Delta Hedging
C. Gamma Hedging
D. Simultaneous Delta and Gamma Hedging
E. Theta, Vega, and Rho Hedging
VII. The Cost of Greeks
VIII. Other Risk Management Approaches
Risk Management with Options

I. Motivation

Traders who write derivatives must hedge their risk


exposure.
 Wed like to simply characterize the main risks
associated with a complicated portfolio of positions
on an underlying.
Ultimately, thats where were headed.

Example: Suppose youre trading options for


Goldman-Sachs, and you just wrote, for $5, a 10-
week, ATM European call.

 The underlyings trading at $50, and  D 50%.


 The risk-free rate is 3.0%.

Black-Scholes tells you that the call option is worth


$4.50. How can you make the profit of $0.50 per
option without risk?

 Buy the same option for $4.50 elsewhere.


 Spend $4.50 on a replicating portfolio (i.e., buy a
synthetic option) that has the same payoff.

Bus 35100 Page 2 Robert Novy-Marx


Risk Management with Options

Question 1 : can you really perfectly replicate the


options payoff?

 That is, can you perfectly hedge away all of the risk
associated with the call you wrote?

 You can if both:


The binomial tree model perfectly describes the
stock price dynamics.
You can trade without transaction costs.

 You can if both:


The log-normal model perfectly describes the
stock price dynamics.
You can trade continuously and without transaction
costs.

But in the real world:

 We cant trade continuously.


 Transaction costs can be substantial.
 The volatility of the underlying and the risk-free
rate arent constant.

Bus 35100 Page 3 Robert Novy-Marx


Risk Management with Options

Question 2: So what should you do, if you cant


perfectly hedge the risk of the call youve written?
1. Identify the different sources of risk.
 The value of the call changes if any of the
following factors changes:

S D Stock Price
t D Time
 D Volatility
r D Interest Rate

2. Form an approximate replicating portfolio for the


written call option.
 The value of this portfolio should change by
about the same amount as that of the option.
At least for small changes in the factors.

But how do we figure out how sensitive the option is


to the factors?

Bus 35100 Page 4 Robert Novy-Marx


Risk Management with Options

The Greeks

To construct the approximate replicating portfolio, we


have to know how much the value of the option
changes as the various factors change.
 That is, the sensitivity of the call to each factor.
 Using calculus (i.e., a linear approximation), for
small changes in the factors, the value of the call
option changes by:

@C 1 @2 C 2 @C @C @C
dC D dS C 2
(dS ) C dt C d C dr,
@S 2 @S @t @ @r

Delta Gamma Theta Vega Rho

or, using the symbols , , ,  and ,

2
dC D c dS C 12 c (dS ) C c dt C c d C c dr.

These Greeks characterize the market risk


associated with the option.

Bus 35100 Page 5 Robert Novy-Marx


Risk Management with Options

II. Example: Stocks, Bonds, and Forwards


 Before we consider the sensitivity of an options
price to each of the factors that determine an
options value, well do some simpler securities.
To get a feel.

 First, what are , , ,  and  for a stock?

@S t
S D D 1
@S t

@S
S D D 0
@S t

@S t
S D D 0
@t
@S t
S D D 0
@
@S t
S D D 0.
@r

Bus 35100 Page 6 Robert Novy-Marx


Risk Management with Options

 What about a bond?


r (T t)
Bt,T D e , so

@Bt
B D D 0
@S t
@B
B D D 0
@S t
@Bt
B D D rBt,T
@t
@Bt
B D D 0
@
@Bt
B D D (T t )Bt,T .
@r

 B D rBt,T > 0 )
Bond becomes more valuable as time passes.

 B D (T t )Bt,T < 0 )
Bond looses value when interest rates rise.
 Note: B D DB Bt,T .

Bus 35100 Page 7 Robert Novy-Marx


Risk Management with Options

 What about a forward contract?


r (T t)
Replication ) f t D S t Ke , so

@f t
f D D 1
@S t
@f
f D D 0
@S t
@f t r (T t)
f D D rKe
@t
@f t
f D D 0
@
@f t r (T t)
f D D (T t )Ke .
@r

 A long forward position is worth more (ceteris


paribus)
If the underlying goes up.
If interest rates rise.
With more time to maturity.

Note: f D 1 and f D 0 explains why we can


replicate a forward statically.

Bus 35100 Page 8 Robert Novy-Marx


Risk Management with Options

III. The Greeks for European Options

How does the price of a derivative change when we


vary one factor and hold all others fixed?

 Delta ()
Delta measures a derivatives sensitivity to the
price of the underlying security.

@C
c D D N(d1) > 0
@S
@P
p D D N( d1 ) < 0.
@S

Note that:

c ! 0 as S ! 0
c ! 1 as S ! 1

Important: In the Black-Scholes model, delta tells


us how many shares of the stock to buy for the
replicating portfolio.

Bus 35100 Page 9 Robert Novy-Marx


Risk Management with Options

 What does c look like?

Delta vs. Underlying price


T = 1 week, 1 month, and 1 quarter

Delta HDL
1

0.8

0.6

0.4

0.2

Spot HSL
60 80 100 120 140 160

Delta as a function of the spot price of the underlying, for


three different time-to-expirations [T D 0.02 (solid line),
T D 0.0833 (dashed line) and T D 0.25 (dotted line)].
Figure depicts the case when K D 100,  D 0.56 and
r D 0.05.

Bus 35100 Page 10 Robert Novy-Marx


Risk Management with Options

 How about c and moneyness?

Delta vs. Time-to-Expiration


ITM, ATM, OTM

Delta HDL
1

0.8

0.6

0.4

0.2

Time HTL
0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5

Delta as a function of time-to-maturity, for three different


levels of moneyness [K D 100 (solid line, ATM), K D
90 (dashed line, ITM) and K D 110 (dotted line, OTM)].
Figure depicts the case when S D 100,  D 0.56 and
r D 0.05.

Bus 35100 Page 11 Robert Novy-Marx


Risk Management with Options

 Gamma ( )
Gamma measures a derivatives convexity.

@c
c D
@S
@d1 0 N 0 (d1)
D @S
N (d1) D p > 0
S T t
@( d1)
p D @S
N 0 ( d1) D c.

Note that:

! 0 as S ! 0
! 0 as S ! 1
is high when S  K.

What does gamma tell us?


 It tells us how much  we gain as the
underlying rises.
 It also tells us how quickly a delta-hedged
derivative becomes unhedged.

Bus 35100 Page 12 Robert Novy-Marx


Risk Management with Options

 What does c look like?

Gamma vs. Underlying price


T = 1 week, 1 month, and 1 quarter

Gamma HGL
0.05

0.04

0.03

0.02

0.01

Spot HSL
80 100 120 140

Gamma as a function of the spot price of the underlying,


for three different time-to-expirations [T D 0.02 (solid
line), T D 0.0833 (dashed line) and T D 0.25 (dotted
line)]. Figure depicts the case when K D 100,  D 0.56
and r D 0.05.

Bus 35100 Page 13 Robert Novy-Marx


Risk Management with Options

 How about c and moneyness?

Gamma vs. Time-to-Expiration


ATM, OTM, ITM

Gamma HGL

0.035
0.03
0.025
0.02
0.015
0.01
0.005
Time HTL
0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5

Gamma as a function of time-to-maturity, for three


different levels of moneyness [K D 100 (solid line, ATM),
K D 80 (dashed line, ITM) and K D 120 (dotted line,
OTM)]. Figure depicts the case when S D 100,  D 0.56
and r D 0.05.

Bus 35100 Page 14 Robert Novy-Marx


Risk Management with Options

 Theta ()
Theta measures the derivatives sensitivity to the
passage of time. It captures time-decay.

@C
c D
@t
@ r (T t)

D @(T t)
SN(d1) Ke N(d2)
@N(d1 ) r (T t) @N(d2 ) r (T t)
D S @(T t)
C Ke @(T t)
rKe N(d2)

This can be simplified using


p
(d2 C T t)2 =2
0 Se
SN (d1) D p
2
p
0  ( T t )d2  2 (T t)=2
D SN (d2)e
r (T t)
D Ke N 0 (d2)

and
p 
@ (d1 d2) @  T t 
D D p
@(T t) @(T t ) 2 T t

Bus 35100 Page 15 Robert Novy-Marx


Risk Management with Options

 Taken together, these imply

N 0(d1 )S r (T t)
c D p rKe N(d2)
2 (T t )

< 0.

 c < 0 ) the value of a call decreases as time


goes by, ceteris paribus.

 As time-to-expiration decreases:
The variance of the stock price at maturity
decreases.
 Less value in the right to not exercise.
The time discounting of the exercise price
decreases.
 Expected cost of exercise is higher.

Important: the fact that c is negative does not


imply that the call price is expected to fall.
Remember, the stock price, on average, rises
over time.

Bus 35100 Page 16 Robert Novy-Marx


Risk Management with Options

 By put-call parity,

P D C f,

we have

@(C f)
p D
@t
@f
D c C
@(T t )

N 0 (d1) S r (T t)
D p C rKe N( d2 ).
2 (T t )

 The first term is again because the variance of


the stock price at maturity decreases as time-to-
maturity decreases.
 The second term is positive.
The PV of the strike grows over time.
 I.e., with less time-to-maturity.
Put receive the strike, so this tends to make the
put more valuable as time passes.

Bus 35100 Page 17 Robert Novy-Marx


Risk Management with Options

 What does c look like?

Theta vs. Underlying price


T = 1 week, 1 month, and 1 quarter

Theta HQL
Spot HSL
80 100 120 140 160 180

-20

-40

-60

-80

Theta as a function of the spot price of the underlying, for


three different time-to-expirations [T D 0.02 (solid line),
T D 0.0833 (dashed line) and T D 0.25 (dotted line)].
Figure depicts the case when K D 100,  D 0.56 and
r D 0.05.

Bus 35100 Page 18 Robert Novy-Marx


Risk Management with Options

 How about c and moneyness?

Theta vs. Time-to-Expiration


ATM, OTM, ITM

Theta HQL
Time HTL
0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5
-10

-20

-30

-40

-50

Theta as a function of time-to-maturity, for three different


levels of moneyness [K D 100 (solid line, ATM), K D
80 (dashed line, ITM) and K D 120 (dotted line, OTM)].
Figure depicts the case when S D 100,  D 0.56 and
r D 0.05.

Bus 35100 Page 19 Robert Novy-Marx


Risk Management with Options

 Vega ()
Vega measures the derivatives sensitivity to the
volatility of the underlying security.
Youll occasionally see it called Kappa ().

@C p
c D DS T t N 0 (d1) > 0
@
@P
p D D c
@

Note that:

  0 for S  K
 is largest for S  K e r (T t)

  0 for S  K

Important: Vega is important to traders who worry


about changes in the volatility of the underlying
security.

Bus 35100 Page 20 Robert Novy-Marx


Risk Management with Options

 What does  c look like?

Vega vs. Underlying price


T = 1 week, 1 month, and 1 quarter

Vega HL
20

15

10

Spot HSL
80 100 120 140 160 180 200

Vega as a function of the spot price of the underlying, for


three different time-to-expirations [T D 0.02 (solid line),
T D 0.0833 (dashed line) and T D 0.25 (dotted line)].
Figure depicts the case when K D 100,  D 0.56 and
r D 0.05.

Bus 35100 Page 21 Robert Novy-Marx


Risk Management with Options

 How about  c and moneyness?

Vega vs. Time-to-Expiration


ATM, OTM, ITM

Vega HL
17.5
15
12.5
10
7.5
5
2.5
Time HTL
0.05 0.1 0.15 0.2

Vega as a function of time-to-maturity, for three different


levels of moneyness [K D 100 (solid line, ATM), K D
80 (dashed line, ITM) and K D 120 (dotted line, OTM)].
Figure depicts the case when S D 100,  D 0.56 and
r D 0.05.

Bus 35100 Page 22 Robert Novy-Marx


Risk Management with Options

The Gamma-Vega Relationship


 Remember:

N 0 (d1)
c D p
S T t

 So:
p
c D S T t N 0 (d1)

D S 2(T t) c

or
c
D S 2(T t)
c

They always come together


 Closely related; sensitivities to expected and
realized volatilities
Come in fixed proportion, for a given series
Calender spreads allow you to bet more on one
than the other

Bus 35100 Page 23 Robert Novy-Marx


Risk Management with Options

 Rho (c )
Rho measures the derivatives sensitivity to the
risk-free interest rate.

@ r (T t)

c D @r
SN(d1) Ke N(d2)

D S @N(d
@r
1)
Ke r (T t) @N(d2 )
@r
r (T t)
C (T t )Ke N(d2).

Now

@N(d1 ) @d1 0
@r
D @r
N (d1)
p
@N(d2 ) @(d1  T t) 0
@r
D @r
N (d2 )
@d1 0
D @r
N (d2)

and

r (T t)
SN 0(d1) D Ke N 0 (d2).

Bus 35100 Page 24 Robert Novy-Marx


Risk Management with Options

 So

r (T t)
c D (T t )Ke N(d2) > 0.

 Put-call parity gives

r (T t)
@(C S C Ke )
p D
@r
r (T t)
D c (T t )Ke

r (T t)
D (T t )Ke N( d2 ) < 0.

 The value of the call always goes up with the


interest rate.
The P V of S (T ) is always S (t ).
The P V of K drops.

 The opposite is true for puts.


The value of a put falls with the interest rate.

Bus 35100 Page 25 Robert Novy-Marx


Risk Management with Options

 What does c look like?

Rho vs. Underlying price


T = 1 week, 1 month, and 1 quarter

Rho HL

20

15

10

Spot HSL
80 100 120 140 160 180

Rho as a function of the spot price of the underlying, for


three different time-to-expirations [T D 0.02 (solid line),
T D 0.0833 (dashed line) and T D 0.25 (dotted line)].
Figure depicts the case when K D 100,  D 0.56 and
r D 0.05.

Bus 35100 Page 26 Robert Novy-Marx


Risk Management with Options

 How about c and moneyness?

Rho vs. Time-to-Expiration


ATM, OTM, ITM

Rho HL

25

20

15

10

Time HTL
0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5

Rho as a function of time-to-maturity, for three different


levels of moneyness [K D 100 (solid line, ATM), K D
80 (dashed line, ITM) and K D 120 (dotted line, OTM)].
Figure depicts the case when S D 100,  D 0.56 and
r D 0.05.

Bus 35100 Page 27 Robert Novy-Marx


Risk Management with Options

Other Greeks

Much less common; just mentioning their existence


 Lambda
Delta per dollar invested

c
c D
C

 Volga (or Vega-Gamma)


Second-order sensitivity to volatility

@2 C @c
D
@ 2 @

 Vanna
Sensitivity of Delta to volatility

@2 C @c
D
@ @S @

Moneyness changes with underlying price, and


implied volatilities change with moneyness

Bus 35100 Page 28 Robert Novy-Marx


Risk Management with Options

IV. The Gamma-Theta Relationship

 Remember the Black-Scholes partial differential


equation:

1 2 2 @2 C @C @C
2
 S @S 2 C rS @S
C @t
rC D 0.

 Using the Greeks we can rewrite this as

1 2 2
2
 S c C rSc C c rC D 0.

 That is, the Black-Scholes PDE implies a relation


between C , , , and  for a European call
option.
They are not determined independently.
This is true in general, not just for calls.

 How can we interpret this constraint?

Bus 35100 Page 29 Robert Novy-Marx


Risk Management with Options

 First, rewrite the constraint as

rC D rSc C 12  2S 2 c C c .

 Now remember: r C is the expected, risk-neutral


yield to the call.
Here yield = price  rate of return.

 The equation says that yield comes from three


sources.

 If you own a call youre:

Long the underlying stock.


 And earning a return on that.

Youre also Earning c .


 Because youre long volatility.

And youre Paying  c .


 Remember: c < 0.
 Time-to-expiration runs backwards.

Bus 35100 Page 30 Robert Novy-Marx


Risk Management with Options

rC D rSc C 12  2S 2 c C c .

 This equation also says that if two calls are:


1. Priced the same, and
2. Have the same sensitivity to the underlying,
I.e., if C D C 0 and C D C 0 , then:

1 2 2 1 2 2
2
 S c C c D 2
 S c0 C c 0 .

 That is, the call with the higher Gamma also has
a higher Theta.
You pay for Gamma by taking on Theta.

 Traders care about this!


A lot.
Having this answer in an interview is the kind of
thing that can get you a job.

Bus 35100 Page 31 Robert Novy-Marx


Risk Management with Options

 It also gives us another way to understand this:

Theta vs. Time-to-Expiration


ATM, OTM, ITM

Theta HQL
Time HTL
0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5
-10

-20

-30

-40

-50

Theta as a function of time-to-maturity, for three


different levels of moneyness. Solid line, ATM: K=S D
1; dashed line, ITM: K=S D 0.8; dotted line, OTM:
K=S D 1.2. Other parameters:  D 0.56 and r D 0.05.

 How so?
Well what happens to Gamma ATM, ITM, and
OTM as T ! 0?

Bus 35100 Page 32 Robert Novy-Marx


Risk Management with Options

V. Popular Options Strategies and the Greeks

 We can also recast option portfolio strategies in


terms of the Greeks.
Traders tend to think about them this way.

 For example, what are you buying when you buy


a straddle?
That is, when you buy both a put and a call with
the same strike.

py g ( ) y

Straddle:
C=f(S,t) ATM CALL + ATM PUT

S = 100 Profit
K = 100 (BUY ATM CALL @ $18.84)
(BUY ATM PUT @ $5.80)
t =1
r = 1.15
25
d = 1.00
V = . 3
50 75 125 150

Future Asset Price

-25 Strategy:
Strategy: Believe
Believevolatility
volatilityof
of
Straddle Value = $18.84 + $5.80 = $24.64 asset
asset price will be high,but
price will be high, buthave
have
no
noclue
clueabout
aboutdirection.
direction.
Loss

Bus 35100 Page 33 Robert Novy-Marx


Risk Management with Options

 Youre not buying Delta.


At least not very much:

pCc D c C p
D N(d1 ) N( d1)  0.

2=2)T
 pCc D 0 if d1 D 0 , K D Se (r C .

 But youre definitely buying Gamma.

pCc D c C p D 2 c.

And the Gamma of the call is high, if its near the


money.

 Youre paying for it with Theta.


Strike-discounting isnt the problem.
 Youre paying on the put, earning on the call.
But the premia on both options shrinks with time.
 Each moment, your exposure to Gamma costs
you Theta.

Bus 35100 Page 34 Robert Novy-Marx


Risk Management with Options

 What happens to the straddle price as (T t ) ! 0?


Assuming everything else is unchanged.

Straddle Price
T = 1 day, 1 week, and 1 month

Price H$L

20

15

10

Spot HSL
90 100 110 120

Straddle prices (P100 CC100) as a function of the spot price


of the underlying, for three different time-to-expirations
[T D 0.004 (solid line), T D 0.02 (dashed line) and
T D 0.0833 (dotted line)]. Figure depicts the case when
 D 0.56 and r D 0.05.

Bus 35100 Page 35 Robert Novy-Marx


Risk Management with Options

 Butterfly spreads do more or less the opposite.


BS: Buy one ITM, sell two ATM, buy one OTM.
 But near the money:
Delta is linear w.r.t. moneyness (more or less).
Gamma is convex w.r.t. moneyness.

Delta HDL Gamma HGL


1
0.05

0.8 0.04

0.6 0.03

0.4 0.02

0.2 0.01

Spot HSL Spot HSL


60 80 100 120 140 160 80 100 120 140

 That is,
1
K  2
(K C KC )
1
K > 2
( K C KC ) ,

so
BFS D K 2K C KC  0
BFS D K 2 K C KC < 0.

Bus 35100 Page 36 Robert Novy-Marx


Risk Management with Options

 What happens to the Butterfly price at the central


strike as (T t ) ! 0?
Assuming everything else is unchanged.

Butterfly Price
T = 1 day, 1 week, and 1 month

Price H$L
10

Spot HSL
85 90 95 100 105 110 115 120

Butterfly prices (C90 2C100 C C110) as a function of the


spot price of the underlying, for three different time-to-
expirations [T D 0.004 (solid line), T D 0.02 (dashed line)
and T D 0.0833 (dotted line)]. Figure depicts the case
when  D 0.56 and r D 0.05.

Bus 35100 Page 37 Robert Novy-Marx


Risk Management with Options

VI. Risk Management


A. Portfolio Hedging
 The basic idea of portfolio hedging is that the
value of a portfolio can be made invariant to the
factors affecting it, such as S ,  and r .
 For example, suppose a portfolio consists of
three assets:

V D n1 A1 C n2 A2 C n3 A3

where:
V is the value of the portfolio,
ni is the number of shares of asset i, and
Ai is the market value of one share of asset i.

 Then the sensitivity of the portfolio to some


arbitrary factor, x, is

@V @A1 @A2 @A3


D n1 C n2 C n3 .
@x @x @x @x

Bus 35100 Page 38 Robert Novy-Marx


Risk Management with Options

 The objective of x-hedging is to pick the ni such


that the value of the portfolio stays constant
when x changes.
That is, pick n1, n2, and n3 so that:

@V @A1 @A2 @A3


D n1 C n2 C n3 D 0.
@x @x @x @x

 Then the value of the portfolio stays approximately


constant when x changes by a small amount:

@V
dV D dx  0.
@x

Important: It takes n securities to hedge against


n 1 sources of uncertainty.
 For example, with two assets you can only
hedge one risk.
E.g., you could pick the relative weights so that
the portfolio is Delta-neutral.
All the other exposures are determined by
these weights.

Bus 35100 Page 39 Robert Novy-Marx


Risk Management with Options

B. Delta Hedging

A portfolio is Delta neutral (i.e., Delta hedged) if


the  of the portfolio is zero.
 For example, take our portfolio of three assets,
and let x D S :

@V
portfolio D
@S
@A1 @A2 @A3
D n1 C n2 C n3
@S @S @S
D n1 1 C n2 2 C n3 3.

 The portfolio will be Delta-hedged if we pick the


ns so that this is zero.
 Then the portfolio value will be insensitive to
small changes in S :

dV  portfolio  dS D 0.

Bus 35100 Page 40 Robert Novy-Marx


Risk Management with Options

More concretely:
 Remember the call you wrote for Goldman-
Sachs:

S D 50
K D 50
10
T t D 52
 D 0.50
r D 0.03.

Questions: how many share of the stock should


we buy to Delta hedge the option?
 Were short the call, and c D 0.554.
 S of a share is one, so we buy nS shares such
that:

nS  1 0.554 D 0.

 So, we buy nS D S D 0.554 shares of the stock.

Bus 35100 Page 41 Robert Novy-Marx


Risk Management with Options

C. Gamma Hedging

A portfolio is Gamma neutral (i.e., Gamma


hedged) if the of the portfolio is zero.
 Take the portfolio of three assets and let x D S :

@2 V
portfolio D
@S 2
@portfolio
D
@S
@1 @2 @3
D n1 C n2 C n3
@S @S @S

D n1 1 C n2 2 C n3 3.

Question:
If a portfolio is already Delta hedged, so its value
stays approximately constant for small changes in
S , why do we want to Gamma hedge it?

Bus 35100 Page 42 Robert Novy-Marx


Risk Management with Options

Example continued ...


We just learned that the portfolio
1. Short the ATM call, and
2. Long 0.554 shares of the stock,
is Delta hedged.

 How stable is the value of this portfolio if S


changes?

 Small change in S:
Suppose S increases from 50 to 51.

C (50, 50, 10
52
, 0.50, 0.03) D 4.498
C (51, 50, 10
52
, 0.50, 0.03) D 5.070.

Then 0.554(51 50) (5.070 4.498) D 0.018.


 A loss of less than 2 cents for a $1 increase in
the stock price.
 Not too bad.
But what about bigger moves in the underlying?

Bus 35100 Page 43 Robert Novy-Marx


Risk Management with Options

 Large change in S :
Suppose S increases from 50 to 60.

C (50, 50, 10
52
, 0.50, 0.03) D 4.498
C (60, 50, 10
52
, 0.50, 0.03) D 11.541.

Then 0.554(60 50) (11.541 4.498) D 1.54.


 A loss of $1.54 for a $10 increase in the stock
price.
 Not so good. Our hedged position still had
an effective 15% exposure the large move in
the underlying.

Lesson from the Example:


 Delta hedging works well for small changes in S
only.
 Gamma hedging can improve the quality of the
hedge.

Bus 35100 Page 44 Robert Novy-Marx


Risk Management with Options

 To understand why, look at the Taylor series


expansion for the change in the call price

2
C (S C dS ) C (S )  c dS C 12 c (dS )

D 0.554 dS C 0.018 (dS )2.

 Buying 0.554 shares hedges the first term.


 Were still exposed to the second term.
Wed need to Gamma hedge as well to
eliminate that exposure.
 For the large change in S (dS D 10), the second
term is $1.80, which explains our $1.55 loss.
Any discrepancy is due to the missing 3rd-,
4th-, and higher- order terms.

Questions:
 Is Gamma hedging alone more effective than
Delta hedging alone?
 Can we use stock to Gamma hedge an option?

Bus 35100 Page 45 Robert Novy-Marx


Risk Management with Options

D. Simultaneous Delta and Gamma Hedging


 What if we wanted to hedge our writhen call such
that our net position was both Delta-neutral and
Gamma-neutral?
For that ATM call 1 D 0.554 and 1 D 0.0361.

 We need another asset


One that has Gamma.
 So any call should do
 Well consider the call struck at 55.

 Delta-hedging requires that

nS S C nC55 C55 C nC50 C50 D 0.

 Gamma-hedging requires that

nS S C nC55 C55
C nC50 C50
D 0.

Bus 35100 Page 46 Robert Novy-Marx


Risk Management with Options

 We already know

C50 D 0.554
C50
D 0.0361.

 And S D 1, S D 0.

 Black-Scholes gives

C55 D 0.382
C55
D 0.0348.

 Finally, nC50 D 1, so need to buy nS shares of


the stock and nC55 calls at 55 such that:

nS C 0.382 nC55 0.554 D 0

0 C 0.0348 nC55 0.0361 D 0.

 Solving these yields nS D 0.158 and nC55 D 1.037.

Bus 35100 Page 47 Robert Novy-Marx


Risk Management with Options

How stable is the value of this portfolio to changes


in S ?

 Small change in S:
Suppose S increases from 50 to 51.

C50(51) C50(50) D 5.067 4.498


D 0.569
C55(51) C55(50) D 3.002 2.602
D 0.400

and

0.158  1 C 1.037  0.400 1  0.569 D 0.001.

The value of the portfolio changes (increases)


by less than 0.1 cent.
 Thats pretty good hedging.

Bus 35100 Page 48 Robert Novy-Marx


Risk Management with Options

 Large change in S :
Suppose S increases from 50 to 60.

C50(60) C50(50) D 11.581 4.498


D 7.084
C55(60) C55(50) D 8.104 2.602
D 5.501

and

0.158  10 C 1.037  5.501 1  7.084 D 0.201.

The value of the portfolio changes (increases)


by 20 cents.
 Thats much less than a change of $1.55
change for the Delta hedged portfolio.

Important: We needed three securities to form a


portfolio hedged in both Delta and Gamma.
 In general we need n securities to form a
portfolio that is insensitive to small variations in
n 1 factors.

Bus 35100 Page 49 Robert Novy-Marx


Risk Management with Options

E. Theta, Vega, and Rho Hedging

 These dont get worried about as much


Theyre still important, but not as important.

 The mechanics of these hedging strategies are


similar to Delta or Gamma hedging.
For example, a portfolio is Theta hedged, or is
Theta neutral, if its  is zero.

Some questions:

 How does the  of a portfolio relate to the s of


the securities that form the portfolio?

 Can a bond be used for Theta hedging?

 Can a stock be used to Theta hedge an option?

Bus 35100 Page 50 Robert Novy-Marx


Risk Management with Options

VII. The Cost of Greeks

 We can construct pure exposures to individual


Greeks
By hedging all the other risks away

 This allows us to price the exposures


Figure what it costs to take on a pure exposure
to a given Greek

 The easiest Greek to price is delta


How do you get a pure exposure to ?
Whats the cost of a unit exposure to ?

 The underlying is a pure exposure to delta


So cost of a unit exposure:

P D S

Bus 35100 Page 51 Robert Novy-Marx


Risk Management with Options

 Rho is also easy to price


What does duration cost?

Nothing!

 Remember, for a bond B D B D B D 0, and

@Bt
B D D rBt,T
@t
@Bt
B D D (T t )Bt,T
@r

 So buy $1 of a long bond, sell $1 of a short bond


Its free
l=s D l=s D l=s D 0, and

l=s D r r D 0

l=s D (Tl t ) C (Ts t)

D (Tl Ts )

 So P D 0

Bus 35100 Page 52 Robert Novy-Marx


Risk Management with Options

 Now its easy to price theta

 Again, for a bond B D B D B D 0, and

@Bt
B D D rBt,T
@t
@Bt
B D D (T t )Bt,T
@r

 Rho is free

 So buy a bond, at a cost of Bt,T


Hedge the Rho risk
 using a zero-cost portfolio of bonds
Hedging Rho is free

 Your pure theta exposure of rBt,T cost you Bt,T

 Unit price is (price paid) / (total exposure), so

Bt,T 1
P D D
rBt,T r

Bus 35100 Page 53 Robert Novy-Marx


Risk Management with Options

 Gamma and Vega are slightly harder


 Lets start by summarizing what we know
Cost of , , and :

P D S
P D 0
P D 1=r

r (T t)
C D SN(d1) Ke N(d2 ) and

c D N(d1)
N 0(d1)
c D p
S T t
N 0 (d1)S r (T t)
c D p rKe N(d2)
2 (T t )

c D S 2(T t) c

r (T t)
c D (T t )Ke N(d2)

 Cost of a delta/rho/theta-hedged call?

Bus 35100 Page 54 Robert Novy-Marx


Risk Management with Options

 Cost and Greeks of the hedged call:

P  C P C P C P C

r (T t)

D SN(d1) Ke N(d2) SN(d1)
!
0
1 N (d1)S r (T t)
p rKe N(d2)
r 2 (T t )

N 0(d1)S
D p
2r (T t )

and
P  D 0
N 0 (d1)
P D p
S T t
P  D 0

P  D S 2(T t) c

P  D 0

Bus 35100 Page 55 Robert Novy-Marx


Risk Management with Options

 Now note that


 
N 0(d1)S
p
P  2r (T t)  2S 2
D   D
P N 0(d1 )
p 2r
S T t

 
  2S 2
i.e., P D 2r P

 This is independent of all contractual parameters


$1 of any delta/rho/theta-hedged call gives you
the same amount of gamma: P  =P  D 2r= 2S 2
 So a long/short portfolio of delta/rho/theta-hedged
calls is gamma-neutral
Its also delta/rho/theta-neutral
Its not generally Vega-neutral
 Unless same maturity on both sides
 I.e., pure Vega-exposure is free ) P D 0
 So ame equation gives us the price of gamma:

P  2S 2
P D D
P 2r

Bus 35100 Page 56 Robert Novy-Marx


Risk Management with Options

 Summarizing:
P D S
 2S 2
P D
2r
P D 0
P D 0
P D 1=r

 So the value of any derivative V on S , in terms of


its exposures to the risk factors, is

V D P  C P C P  C P  C P 
 2 2 
 S 1
D S C 2r C r 

We can also write this as

rV D rS CS C 12  2S 2CS S C C t

 The Black-Scholes PDE!

Bus 35100 Page 57 Robert Novy-Marx


Risk Management with Options

VIII. Other Risk Management Approaches

 Stop-Loss Rules.

 Scenario Analysis:
1. Monte Carlo Simulations.
2. Stress Testing.
3. Value at Risk (VAR).

Bus 35100 Page 58 Robert Novy-Marx

Anda mungkin juga menyukai