Anda di halaman 1dari 12

International Journal of Cultural Policy

ISSN: 1028-6632 (Print) 1477-2833 (Online) Journal homepage: http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/gcul20

The disappearing arts: creativity and innovation


after the creative industries

Kate Oakley

To cite this article: Kate Oakley (2009) The disappearing arts: creativity and innovation
after the creative industries, International Journal of Cultural Policy, 15:4, 403-413, DOI:
10.1080/10286630902856721

To link to this article: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/10286630902856721

Published online: 16 Nov 2009.

Submit your article to this journal

Article views: 1981

View related articles

Citing articles: 23 View citing articles

Full Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at


http://www.tandfonline.com/action/journalInformation?journalCode=gcul20

Download by: [Panteion University] Date: 03 March 2017, At: 03:48


International Journal of Cultural Policy
Vol. 15, No. 4, November 2009, 403413

The disappearing arts: creativity and innovation after the creative


industries
Kate Oakley*

City University, London, UK


International
10.1080/10286630902856721
GCUL_A_385844.sgm
1028-6632
Original
Taylor
402009
15
Professor
kate.oakley@btinternet.com
000002009
and
& Article
Francis
KateOakley
(print)/1477-2833
Francis
JournalLtd
of Cultural
(online)
Policy

Since the birth of the creative industries a decade ago, there has been a series of
attempts to link the cultural sectors with innovation policy and to downplay the
connection between them and traditional arts or cultural policy. The theory appears to be
that innovation is where the big money is, and that the cultural sectors can only benefit
by being rescued from the ghetto of arts funding. This paper seeks to query this notion
and to draw attention to some of the problems that have resulted and may result from it.
Keywords: creativity; innovation; creative industries

1. Introduction
Since the birth of creative industries as a discourse and a policy construct in the late 1990s,
there has been a series of increasingly enthusiastic attempts to link the cultural sectors with
innovation policy (Cox 2005, Cunningham 2006, NESTA 2006), and to downplay the
connection between them and traditional arts or cultural policy. The theory appears to be
that innovation is where the big money is, and that the cultural sectors can only benefit by
being rescued from the ghetto of arts funding.
As Stuart Cunningham argues,

The price to be paid for a creative economy is that the case for arts and culture will become
less about their special or exceptional difference, and become diffused into the need for creativ-
ity across the economy and society. (2006, p. 4)

In this formulation, the development of the creative industries discourse (as opposed to the
arts, or cultural industries) was the first to break free (Hartley 2005) from traditional
cultural policy concerns, ranging from market failure to issues of identity politics (Potts
et al. 2008). Thus liberated, the new non-political creative industries cease to be industrial
sectors producing cultural products or services, let alone the refuge of the uncommodifiable,
and become markets for novelty conveying and organising the production and dissemina-
tion of new ideas across the economy.
This paper seeks to interrogate and query this notion and to draw attention to some of
the problems that have resulted, and may result from it in the future. The shift in terminol-
ogy from cultural to creative and from creativity to innovation captures the drift of
this discourse and, I would argue, reflects a changing set of priorities. The paper considers,
somewhat unusually for a paper on the cultural and creative industries these days, the
effects of this shift on arts policy, and in particular the renewed debate about excellence and

*Email: kate.oakley@btinternet.com

ISSN 1028-6632 print/ISSN 1477-2833 online


2009 Taylor & Francis
DOI: 10.1080/10286630902856721
http://www.informaworld.com
404 K. Oakley

innovation in the arts that followed the publication of the McMaster Review (McMaster
2008). The context of the paper is the UK, and while other places have embraced the notion
of creative industries, it does not attempt to speculate on whether similar trajectories are
being followed elsewhere in terms of innovation or arts policy.

2. Culture to creative industries


In order to speculate on the future of cultural policy under an innovation regime, we have
to, of necessity, have some history. The DCMS delineation of 13 creative industry sectors
back in the late 1990s (DCMS 1998) has been globally exported (Cunningham 2002) with
a rapidity and effectiveness that many UK-based creative industry firms would envy. The
shift from cultural industries to creative industries has been well examined elsewhere, not
least in the last special issue of IJCP (Garnham 2005) so I do not intend to dwell on it too
much here, other than to make the point that while the creative industries moment
undoubtedly represented a shift in the role that culture was expected to play, and a ramping
up of the focus on their potential for economic growth; there were also continuities between
cultural industries policy and creative industries policy, continuities that have been broken
with the birth of the creativity and innovation discourse.
The rebranded creative industries extended the definition of the cultural sectors beyond
the traditional arts and media and into the creative services (NESTA 2006), where the UK
was perceived to have some competitive advantages, namely, design, architecture and
advertising. But actual public interventions did not diverge as far from the cultural industries
paradigm as a simple analysis of the rhetoric would suggest. Policy retained a concern with
local economic development, not least because most of the policy development and support
was done by local authorities and regional development agencies (RDAs), and with job
creation (Evans and Shaw 2004, Oakley 2009). In particular, public funding for dedicated
workspaces, for specialised advice networks and for skills training and education initiatives,
supported interventions that were not so different from those which could have been pursued
under a cultural industries framework. And the concern of many cultural industries advo-
cates with access for marginalised groups ethnic minorities and women in particular still
found itself reflected in specific interventions, though the ability of those interventions to
counter wider market and social forces was limited, to say the least (Oakley 2006).
Most importantly, for the argument of this paper, the concern of creative industries
policy was, initially at least, to support the development of particular industrial sectors
(Garnham 2005), primarily concerned with producing cultural products and services.

3. The discourse of creativity


The impact of the work of Richard Florida (2002) on local economic development more
generally and policies around the creative industries specifically, has been analysed exten-
sively elsewhere (Markusen 2005, Nathan 2005, Peck 2005, Lloyd 2006, Oakley 2009) and
there is no need to rehearse all the arguments here. But it does represent an important step
in the decoupling of the use of the term creativity from specifically cultural activities.
Floridas adoption of the term creative, for his class of knowledge workers, and
professionals, which as Garnham (2005) points out, derives from Daniel Bell (1973),
enabled his work to become entangled with existing debates about creative industries,
creative cities and the creative economy, and thus to gain wider currency, despite the
fact that his focus is largely on high technology growth, rather than the cultural or creative
industries (Pratt 2008).
International Journal of Cultural Policy 405

Although artists, writers, musicians and so on are included in Floridas core creative
class, the primary function of cultural activities is as amenities, part of the urban infrastruc-
ture that serves to attract a mobile, professional labour force and provides an outlet for their,
highly focused and purposeful, leisure time (Banks 2008).
Creativity in Floridas construct is the production of new ideas, a force which is power-
ing the great ongoing changes of our time (2002, p. 21), and comes suitably loaded with
expectations; economic, moral and political.
As Pope has pointed out (Pope 2005), in its form as an abstract noun, the term creativ-
ity did not appear in the Oxford English Dictionary until 1933 and was not in widespread
use until the 1940s and 1950s. Having emerged in educational and psychological circles, in
the 1920s, Pope argues that it is a specifically modern response to rapid social and techno-
logical change. He quotes one of the pioneers of creativity research, J.P. Guilford, as claim-
ing that the upsurge in interest in creativity, was the result of specifically modern dilemmas,
including space travel, global communications and the population explosion.
As Pope comments, it is not clear whether, in this conception, creativity is the force driv-
ing these changes, or what is needed to help people readjust to them, and certainly this dual
role has continued in more contemporary discourse, including Floridas work. In the UK,
the influential UK National Advisory Committee on Creative and Cultural Education
(NACCCE) report, All Our Futures (Robinson 1999), argued that the reasons for fostering
a creative curriculum in schools, were that it enabled young people to be able to participate
in global markets, feed the fast-growing creative industries and adapt to technological and
social change.
It is clear from this description that we are a long way from creativity as a synonym
for culture, or even from the idea that creativity is a particular quality associated with the
arts or with those of us with artistic talent. If, as Craft (2001) has argued, there have been
two waves of conceptualising creativity: firstly a Romantic notion of personal creativity,
and secondly a strong emphasis on social systems, we are by now firmly in the latter
camp. The NACCCE notion of creativity, one that has become widespread internationally,
since its publication (Schlesinger 2007), is that creativity is essentially democratic, in
that everyone can learn it; is a co-operative activity and best learned via collective activ-
ity; and it is essentially pro-social, in that it encourages communication and feelings of
empathy.
Such a notion of creativity clearly has widespread appeal to those in the community arts
and education worlds who see more elitist notions of creativity, which focus on individual
talent, as setting up barriers to personal development. But as Banaji et al. (2006) argue, there
are dangers in this broad but bland definition of creativity. Most obviously there is a danger
that by mainstreaming creativity in this way, and stressing its pro-social elements, we risk
excluding creative expression that is marginal, radical, counter-cultural or in some way
deemed to be anti-social.
Creativity no longer undermines or challenges social norms, now it is the key to social
cohesion; dynamic enough to bring us lots of new products in the marketplace, but not so
dynamic that it has much to say about the operation of markets themselves. Indeed, we now
have a term that is designed not only to cover both economic growth and social good; but
to suggest that there is never any conflict between them.
Secondly, the problem solving idea of creativity, the notion that it is the application
of knowledge and skills in new ways to achieve a valued goal (Seltzer and Bentley 1999,
p. 10), stresses the instrumental utility of creativity, while diminishing notions of fantasy,
play or uselessness, which have a long history in discussions of artistic creativity, and which
are often stubbornly clung to by cultural practitioners themselves (Oakley et al. 2008).
406 K. Oakley

Crucially, it also fails to highlight what might be the distinctive features of creativity as
practised in the arts. However, in practice, particularly for policy-makers in economic
development and education, this decoupling of creativity from culture, is partial rather than
total, with resulting confusion about the relationship between culture, creativity and inno-
vation (Garnham 2005, Pratt and Jeffcut, 2009).

4. Creativity becomes innovation


An example of this confusion can be seen in the Cox Review of Creativity in British
Business (Cox 2005). As Schlesinger argues, Cox is unusually clear in its attempt to
define the terminology, defining creativity as the generation of new ideas, and innovation
as the successful exploitation of those ideas (2007). But in arguing that design is what links
these two and in concentrating its recommendations on improving the take up of design,
particularly in manufacturing industry, the Cox Review does not depart as far from aesthetic
considerations as it seems to want to.
Nor is Coxs desire to use a broad notion of creativity to argue for an increase in design
training and education, a new approach. As Garnham points out, it was a feature of 1980s
policy to see manufacturing failures as essentially design failures (2005) and the intervening
years have seen at best mixed results in addressing this, despite the rather over-heated claims
for the importance of design as an input into the wider economy (Design Council 2004).
What was less clear was what, if any, was the relationship envisaged by Cox between
creativity as the generation of new ideas in general, and the particular performance of the
UKs creative industries. While a number of research projects are underway to try and
capture spillovers or model the relationship between culture and creativity (Andari et al.
2007, Stoneman 2007, Bakhshi et al. 2008, Higgs et al. 2008), policy-makers are keen to
assert this relationship, even where no clear idea of what it is, exists.
A Department of Trade report (DTI 2005) accompanying the Cox Review, claimed that
the creative industries can serve as proxy for creativity in the economy in general; but it
is unclear within this argument, how the economic performance of advertising or the tele-
vision industry, can act as a proxy for the generation of new ideas in the pharmaceutical
industry, or in financial services.
Another attempt to model the relationship of the creative and cultural sectors to the rest
of the economy (Andari et al. 2007) formed part of the UK Department of Cultures
Creative Economy review. It was based on Throsbys concentric circle model of the
cultural sectors (Throsby 2001), which sees the creative arts as the source and generator of
ideas that are later picked up by other cultural industries such as the media industries (film,
TV and radio). But importantly, and somewhat stretching Throsbys argument, it extends
this influence of expressive value beyond the cultural and creative industries and firmly
into those areas which produce non-cultural outputs, such as the Dyson vacuum cleaner, or,
the retailainment of Virgin Atlantic flights (Andari et al. 2007)
This is a variant of the culturisation thesis, that cultural objects themselves proliferate
in a variety of forms, as information, as communications, as branded products, as media
products, as transport and leisure services, cultural entities are no longer the exception: they
are the rule (Lash and Lury 2007, p. 4), and are therefore no longer primarily symbolic. But
if Lash and Lury are keen to take, in part at least, a critical look at how culture, as they
argue, has moved from symbol to brand, and how cultural value has become enmeshed with
use and exchange value; innovation enthusiasts see the process as somewhat less problem-
atic. If culture can be thingified, as Lash and Lury argue that it can (p. 4); innovation
enthusiasts are simply keen to thingify it as speedily and efficiently as possible.
International Journal of Cultural Policy 407

However, in its enthusiasm to demonstrate that this process is happening, much of this
literature tends to assert rather than provide evidence for the link between culture, creativity
and innovation. Andari et al. (2007) argue that,

The creative industries can be conceived as a pioneer sector of the economy, trailblazing
approaches, and fostering an attitude towards creativity and innovation from which the rest of
the economy and society can benefit. This critically depends on whether effective transmis-
sion mechanisms are in place. (p. 14)

This is a little clearer than simply suggesting that the creative industries are a proxy for
wider creativity, but the nature of the transmission mechanisms, let alone whether they are
effective or not, is not made apparent. It seems entirely plausible that the creative arts are a
source of ideas, stories and images that are reproduced in other forms in other parts of the
economy; but the mechanisms by which this happens remain frustratingly elusive.
Recent attempts to look at input-output tables (Bakhshi et al. 2008) find weak evidence
that firms with supply chain links to firms in the creative industries are more innovative than
those without them, but there is no evidence about what takes place in these engagements,
and hence no clues as to causality. It may simply be that more innovative firms buy more
creative industry inputs, namely design, branding or advertising.
Other work (Howkins 2001, Florida 2002) claims that human capital is the mechanism
of transmission, in essence that there are more people working in creative occupations in the
wider economy than in the cultural sectors (Higgs et al. 2008). But this calculation depends
on accepting the notion that town planners, software professionals and library assistants are
creative workers, which stretches the definition way beyond any reasonably cultural occu-
pation and therefore turns into a slightly circular argument. On what basis are these creative
occupations, creative? Is it because many of them are cultural occupations such as dancers,
actors or photographers? In which case why include town planning, which is not a cultural
activity? And if creative simply means works with new ideas or some such, why include
musicians, but not research chemists?
In other words, why sometimes use cultural notions of creativity and at other times not?
This confusion poses a problem for those who would argue that the primary importance of
cultural activities is their effect on the wider economy (Cunningham 2006, Potts et al.
2008) and therefore now need to provide evidence for these wider economic effects of
cultural activities; but it poses a greater problem for cultural policy-makers and advocates,
who, having appropriated the term creativity, must now show how cultural creativity is
different from other kinds of creativity, and the basis for any claims of prominence in the
debate.

5. The price of a creative economy


One price to be paid for a creative economy, therefore, is the downgrading of efforts to
develop the cultural and creative industry sectors themselves, however half-hearted this
attempt has sometimes appeared (Hesmondhalgh and Pratt 2005), in favour of seeing them
primarily as an input into other economic activities.
As Pratt and Jeffcut argue (2009)

For many policy makers it is this innovation or creativity spill-over, and not the intrinsic or
substantive economic and cultural value, that is the prize to be gained from the promotion of
the cultural economy. Such a view rests on the assumption that culture and entertainment are
necessarily inferior and dependent upon the real economy.
408 K. Oakley

The current recession may demonstrate how far and in what ways, culture and entertainment
depend on the real economy, and one could hypothesise that business-to-business creative
sectors such as advertising or design, much favoured by innovation enthusiasts, may actu-
ally suffer more than business-to-consumer cultural products and services, such as films or
music. If so, we may see a switch back to arguments about the viability of cultural products
and services as themselves, not as inputs. But in some cases, it will have come too late.
Perhaps the best example of an organisation that has moved in concert with the times is
NESTA, set up with lottery money in the wake of the 1997 election and initially committed
to funding individuals in the sciences, arts and technology, who have traditionally struggled
in the UK, where funding tends to go to firms and institutions. Poets such as Carol Ann
Duffy and Tom Paulin, theatre directors Katie Mitchell and James MacDonald and the
novelist W.G. Sebald were among recipients of NESTA awards in the early years. More
recently the organisation has switched focus entirely and under the strapline, making inno-
vation flourish, now informs and shapes innovation policy, with its arts stand of work,
other than in connection to innovation, generally regarded as moribund.
Economic development agencies that previously backed creative industry interventions
are now reducing this support. The London Development Agency has closed its Creative
Industry team, in favour of generalised Business Development, and Skills teams, and
ended the funding for many of the interventions it supported as part of its Creative London
initiative (see http://www.london.gov.uk/mayor/creativeindustries.jsp), a practice that may
be repeated across the UK, especially as EU structural funding diminishes.
And at the same time, the UKs creative industries seem to have been undergoing some-
thing of a decline. From measuring 8% of Gross Value Added (GVA) in 2003 (DCMS
2005), the latest estimates put the figure at 6.4% (DCMS 2009). While allowing for changes
in methodology in what is notoriously unreliable statistical area, this still suggests dimin-
ished competitiveness on the part of these industries, an issue which one might have thought
would be of concern to policy-makers. But the creativity bandwagon appears to have moved
from a focus on the creative industries, to one on creativity, leaving the culture and
creative industries, somewhat sidelined.

6. The policy echo chamber excellence, risk and innovation in the arts
As Pratt and Jeffcut (2009) argue one of the problems associated with the creative industries
label, let alone the creative economy, was that it glossed over real differences between the
constituent parts of the creative industries, with their different business models, markets and
relationship to public funding. Even if we accept that an innovation discourse offers some-
thing to design or advertising, the effect on the arts, far from rescuing them from the ghetto
of shrinking public funds, is to consign them to a residual role as heritage, social ameliora-
tion or enablement (Cunningham et al. 2008). If the cultural industries and even the creative
industries, offered an enhanced role for the arts within a growing economic sector, innova-
tion discourse puts them firmly back in their place.
In an attempt to combat this extreme instrumentalism, either of a social or an economic
bent, the Arts Council of England (ACE) has been engaged in recasting a new set of argu-
ments and justifications, based around notions like public value, public consultation and
the re-birth of peer review (Keaney et al. 2007, McMaster 2008).
In an example of the way the policy echo chamber works, innovation has also been
adopted as a buzzword by the Arts Council, albeit in reference to artistic innovation, rather
than economic innovation in general. In the same way that associating the cultural sectors
with creativity was seen as bringing them new friends, but ended up reducing them to an
International Journal of Cultural Policy 409

input, innovation looks set to be even more problematic (Cunningham 2006, Pratt and
Jeffcut, 2009).
In an almost perfect piece of public policy prose, Brian McMaster in his review of ACE
funding and decision-making states,

It has been argued that culture does not always need to innovate to be excellent, but if it is to
be truly relevant to our society, it absolutely must. Innovation is understood to be the introduc-
tion of something new, where old methods and systems are insufficient. Innovation is therefore
an integral part of the search for excellence, and should be encouraged if we are to encourage
excellence. (2008, p. 10)

Innovation is thus related to excellence, which is related to relevance, all of which are vital
in ways that are continually stated, but never entirely made clear (McMaster 2008).
However, although McMasters concern is with artistic innovation, his echoes of innovation
enthusiast language runs the risk of over-stating the importance of novelty in discussion of
what is valuable about the arts; not to mention getting into rather deep waters about what
counts as artistic innovation.

7. Are artists innovators?


Artists may seem like natural innovators: they work in highly uncertain, inherently risky
markets where originality is prized and imitation often disparaged. But discussions of
cultural production are rarely that simple. As Becker (1982) argued,

Every art work creates a world in some respects unique, a combination of vast amounts of
conventional materials with some that are innovative. Without the first, it becomes unintelligi-
ble; without the second it becomes boring and featureless (p. 63)

This standing on the shoulders of giants is hardly unique to the arts (Edgerton 2006), but
the degree to which contemporary production does not substitute for historical works in the
arts is pronounced. A living painter or poet does not supplant his or her predecessors; old
plays and dramatic styles are regularly performed and rediscovered, forming the majority of
the repertoire for some theatre companies. At a more fundamental level, while you are
unlikely to treat yourself with seventeenth century medicine if you fall ill; if you fall in love,
you may find that John Donne has as much to say to you as Simon Armitage or the Arctic
Monkeys.
Both the need for innovation, and what constitutes innovation in the arts therefore, is
somewhat contested. Castaer and Campos (2002) define artistic innovation as something
that is new to the field. Thus, they argue that a new piece of music by John Cage is not an
innovation in the musical world, as minimalism is already a well-known musical form. This
rather strict definition however suggests that one cannot innovate within a genre or form,
something that most people would find puzzling. The Beatles Sergeant Pepper may have
been innovative in musical arrangement, use of recording technology and even cover art
work; but it was still recognisably within the genre of popular music; it did not create an
entirely new field.
At the same time, few would be comfortable with the notion that every new cultural
product; each book, film, song or videogame produced, is an innovation (Stoneman 2007).
Michael Palins New Europe is one of a series of books he has written to accompany his
BBC TV programmes. The book may not have been written before, but it uses a well-known
format and very few would regard it as an innovation in travel writing.
410 K. Oakley

Crucially, nor should innovation be seen as a cultural products only desirable quality
(Bunting 2007): tradition, heritage, memory and ritual influence the value that consumers
get from cultural products, even in popular culture. Few fans at a Rolling Stones concert
want to see the Stones take an entirely new musical direction; most come to hear old favou-
rites and relive youthful memories. They are taking part in a communal ritual, not seeking
novelty. Closeness to the consumer may be part of the way in which the cultural sectors
innovate, but it is far from being an uncomplicated relationship (MacDonald 2003).
While it seems reasonable to argue that public funding for the arts should support the
risky, rather than the tried and tested, leaving the development of successful formats to the
market, a strict interpretation of the innovation mantra would ignore much craft production,
however high a level; would leave very little room for non-Western arts forms, which are
often less enamoured of the shock of the new; and would marginalise genre works which
depend on their collective, historical development, for much of their meaning. To argue that
all great art is an innovation is to argue for Picasso but not Lucian Freud; Orson Welles but
not Howard Hawks; Dashiell Hammett but not John Le Carre. Its an exciting cultural
world; but not necessarily one you would want to inhabit all the time.
Nor does applying an innovation framework to cultural funding get you off the hook
of having to make judgements. As Hesmondhalgh and Pratt argue, the question of aesthetics
never really goes away in cultural policy (2005) and the Arts Council is now beginning a
lengthy process of operationalising its commitment to innovation1 with a public consulta-
tion on the best methods of self-assessment and peer review for its regularly funded organ-
isations. It is unlikely that echoing the language of innovation will make those judgements
any less problematic or contested.
For arts organisations, used to negotiating the twists and turns of policy language, it may
simply be a case of re-stating their value in another context. Like the discourse of public
value, some may embrace it, others may use it opportunistically to re-brand their current
activities (Oakley et al. 2006). It is probably too early to say, and tracing the effect of inno-
vation discourse on funding practice is outside the scope of this paper, but the danger is less
to individual arts organisations and more to the ecology as whole. A desire to fund only the
new and innovation-friendly risks producing a sort of perpetual present; a culture without
memory.

8. Conclusion: arts policy after the creative industries


In contrast to Garnhams arguments that the arts lobby welcomed the notion of creative
industries, because it signalled a return to an artist-centred, supply-side type of cultural
policy (Garnham 2005) and away from a focus on distribution and consumption; it has
always seemed to me that the arts lobby has had a rather ambivalent relationship to the idea
of creative industries. Although, to adapt Markusens argument about Floridas work
(Markusen 2005), the discourse of creative industries temporarily made the arts seem visible
to policy-makers who had never thought to notice them before, and at the regional level, it
secured funding for regeneration projects that often involved the arts (Evans and Shaw
2004); it did so at the cost of collapsing several, carefully constructed arguments for public
cultural funding into essentially one: its good for the economy.
The way that the arts were understood to be good for the economy changed between
creative industries, creativity and innovation from a focus on the growth of the arts and
media sectors as growing providers of employment to the disappearance of the arts them-
selves into a host of knowledge-based activities. This is sometimes presented teleologically,
in the shape of four models of culture (Cunningham et al. 2008), which move us from a
International Journal of Cultural Policy 411

welfarist or subsidy model of arts funding, via the cultural/creative industries, to an innova-
tion model, where creative industries value lies in the development and adoption of new
knowledge, and so is focused on experimentation and difference, rather than conservation
and equality (2008, p. 9).
In this account, past cultural forms no longer inform new the development of new ones
in a fruitful dialogue across time, but instead fracture into old and new cultures (Potts
et al. 2008), where the historical built environment, museums (and their collections), and
the classic performing arts, require only maintenance and continuity (2008, p. 11); some-
thing that might come as a shock to anyone who works in these worlds and is continually
engaged in a process of reinterpretation and re-creation. Not to mention the odd property
developer who has realised the value of heritage buildings as contemporary cultural
spaces.
Culture as innovation goes much further than creative industries discourse, not only in
stating cultural value solely in terms of economic impact, but in breaking up cultural activ-
ities themselves into the novel and innovative (videogames, good) and the heritage and
educational (opera, almost certainly bad). The complex symbiosis that informs the cultural
ecology of any town or city with its mix of funding models, cultural forms and working
practices that links a performance of the Tempest, with a TV cop show and voiceovers for
advertisements (the staple working life of a successful actor, for example) is too messy, too
wasteful and simply too hard to understand.
In the face of this, traditional arts advocates seem ready to beat a hasty retreat into more
comfortable terrain. They rage at meddling philistines (Tusa 2007), and worry that ill-
informed cultural diversity officers are now in charge of what hangs in our galleries, rather
than say, curators (Appleton 2004), though it must be said that there is scant evidence for
this one. Social instrumentalism seems to raise more concern than economic instrumental-
ism, at least on the political Right; but even a former Secretary of Stare for Culture worries
that, between the two, we have ceased to value culture in its own terms (Jowell 2004).
The gains made in decades of cultural and media studies-informed policy work in
collapsing distinctions between high and low culture, market and non-market, dominant and
other are real, if fragile. The difficulty for an innovation framework is that they need
defending in terms of meaning, not of impact.
When the recently elected Mayor of London, Boris Johnson addresses the Royal Society
of Arts, one hears some arts advocates in full retreat from much the argument of cultural
policy over the last 40 years.

I get pretty steamed up about the general mushy-minded cultural relativism of our age, and
I assert the total superiority of Homer over the epic of Gilgamesh, and I think the artistic
output of 15th century Italy was much better than the artistic output of 15th century meso-
America, and I congratulate Neil McGregor on getting the Terracotta army to London, but
when you compare those universal imperial henchmen with the Panathenaic frieze you can see
why democracy and individualism got going in western Europe, rather than in East Asia.
(Johnson 2008)

This is not to suggest that the arts lobby, assuming we think it a coherent force, would line
up behind any such crude assertion of the superiority of European high culture. And indeed
the Mayors proposed cultural strategy for London, while displaying a somewhat naive faith
in the transformative power of unused musical instruments, steers well clear of such
emotive language or content (London 2008). But it is to make the point that discussions of
cultural policy ultimately become entwined with question of aesthetics, politics, identity and
meaning.
412 K. Oakley

Stuart Cunningham (2006) doubts that we have enough agreement about cultural values
to make a robust and enduring case for public funding. But surely that is the point. Debates
about culture take place in a contested space and so they should, as they are essentially polit-
ical debates. Alan Finlaysons (2003) critique of New Labour, as wanting, a permanent
consensus under its permanent management, (p. 11) seems to be apt here, and as he goes
on to say,

It sometimes seems to be dreaming of a world of pure individuals, permanently innovating new


products, and managing social relations through the terms and practices of trade. (Finlayson
2003, p. 11)

The collapse of culture into an innovation discourse fits this aspiration entirely, and as such
it may simply be part of the waning political moment of New Labour. But the price to be
paid for it is a thin notion of cultural value, declining cultural sectors and a crude version of
innovation, which conflates it with novelty. As such, it seems a fairly high price.

Note
1. The Arts Council is consulting on the best method of doing this, the consultation ended 23
January 2009 (http://www.artscouncil.org.uk/consultation).

References
Andari, R., et al., 2007. Staying ahead: the economic performance of the UKs creative industries.
London: The Work Foundation.
Appleton, J., 2004. Art for inclusions sake. Spiked. Available from: http://www.spiked-online.com/
Articles/0000000CA4BC.htm [Accessed 22 August 2009].
Bakhshi, H., et al., 2008. Creating innovation. London: NESTA.
Banaji, S., Burn, A., and Buckingham, D. 2006. Rhetorics of creativity. London: Creative Partner-
ships.
Banks, M., 2008. The instrumental leisure of the Creative Class (CRESC working paper series).
Oxford: Open University.
Bell, D., 1973. The coming of post-industrial society. London: Penguin.
Bunting, C. 2007. Public value and the arts in England: discussion and conclusions of the arts
debate. London: Arts Council.
Castaer, X., and Campos, L., 2002. The determinants of artistic innovation: bringing in the role of
organisations. Journal of cultural economics, 26, 2952.
Cox, G., 2005. Creativity in British business. London: HM Treasury.
Craft, A., 2001. An analysis of research and literature on creativity in education. UK: Qualification
and Curriculum Authority.
Cunningham, S., 2003. The evolving creative industries [online]. Available at: http://
www.creativeindustries.qut.com/research/cirac/reading.jsp.
Cunningham, S., 2006. What price a creative economy? Platform Papers, Currency House.
Cunningham, S., et al., 2008. Cultural economy: the shape of the field. In: H.K. Anheier and Y.R.
Isar, eds. The cultural economy. Thousand Oaks, CA/London: Sage, 1315.
DCMS (Department for Culture, Media and Sport), 1998. Creative industries mapping document.
London: Department for Culture, Media and Sport.
DCMS, 2005. Creative industries economic estimates statistical bulletin. London: Department for
Culture, Media and Sport.
DCMS, 2009. Creative industries economic estimates statistical bulletin 2009. London: Department
for Culture, Media and Sport.
Design Council, 2004. The impact of design on stock market performance. London: Design Council.
DTI (Department of Trade and Industry), 2005. Creativity, design and business performance (DTI
Economics Paper No. 15). London: Department of Trade and Industry.
Edgerton, D., 2006. The shock of the old: technology and global history since 1900. London: Profile
Books.
International Journal of Cultural Policy 413

Evans, G., and Shaw, P., 2004. The contribution of culture to regeneration in the UK: a review of
the evidence. London: Department for Culture, Media and Sport.
Finlayson, A., 2003. Making sense of New Labour. London: Lawrence & Wishart.
Florida, R., 2002. The rise of the creative class. New York: Basic Books.
Garnham, N., 2005. From cultural to creative industries. International journal of cultural policy, 11
(1), 1529.
Hartley, J., ed., 2005. Creative industries. Oxford: Blackwell.
Hesmondhalgh, D., and Pratt, A., 2005. Cultural industries and cultural policy. International journal
of cultural policy, 11 (1), 113.
Higgs, P., Cunningham, S., and Bakhshi, H., 2008. Beyond the creative industries: mapping the
creative economy in the United Kingdom. London: NESTA.
Howkins, J., 2001. The creative economy: how people make money from ideas. London: Penguin.
Johnson, B., 2008. The Mayors speech at the Royal Academy annual dinner. Available from:
http://www.london.gov.uk/mayor/speeches/20080603-ra.jsp [Accessed 10 December 2008].
Jowell, T., 2004. Government and the value of culture. London: DCMS.
Keaney, E., et al., 2007. The arts debate: summary and analysis of consultation responses. London:
Arts Council England.
Lash, S., and Lury, C., 2007. Global culture industry. Cambridge: Polity.
Lloyd, R., 2006. Neo-Bohemia, arts and commerce in the post-industrial city. New York: Rout-
ledge.
London, M.O., 2008. Cultural metropolis. London: GLA.
MacDonald, I., 2003. Wild Mercury: a tale of two Dylans. The peoples music. London: Pimlico.
Markusen, A., 2005. Urban development and the politics of a creative class: evidence from the study
of artists. Paper presented at the RSA Conference on Regional Growth Agendas, 2831 May,
Aalborg, Denmark.
McMaster, B., 2008. Supporting excellence in the arts: from measurement to judgement. London:
Department for Culture, Media and Sport.
Nathan, M., 2005. The wrong stuff, creative class theory, diversity and city performance. London:
Centre for Cities.
NESTA, 2006. Creating growth: how the UK can develop world-class creative businesses.
London: NESTA.
Oakley, K., 2006. Include us out: economic development and social policy in the creative industries.
Cultural trends, 14, 283296.
Oakley, K., 2009. Getting out of place: the mobile creative class takes on the local. A UK perspec-
tive on the creative class. In: L. Kong and J. OConnor, eds. Creative economies, creative cities:
Asian-European perspectives. Berlin: Springer, 121134.
Oakley, K., et al., 2006. Giving them what they want: the construction of the public in public value.
Paper presented at the 2nd annual CRESC Media Change and Social Theory Conference, 68
September, Oxford, UK.
Oakley, K., et al., 2008. The art of innovation. London: NESTA.
Peck, J., 2005. Struggling with the creative class. International journal of urban and regional
research, 20 (4), 740770.
Pope, R., 2005. Creativity: theory, history and practice. London: Routledge.
Potts, J., et al., 2008. Social network markets: a new definition of the creative industries. Journal of
cultural economics, 32 (3), 167185.
Pratt, A.C., 2008. Creative cities: the cultural industries and the creative class. Geografiska annaler:
Series B Human geography, 90 (2), 107117.
Pratt, A.C., and Jeffcut, P., eds., 2009. Creativity and innovation in the cultural industries. London:
Routledge.
Robinson, K., 1999. All our futures: creativity, culture and education. London: Department for
Education and Employment.
Schlesinger, P., 2007. Creativity: from discourse to doctrine? Screen, 48 (3), 377387.
Seltzer, K., and Bentley, T., 1999. The creative age. London: Demos.
Stoneman, P., 2007. An introduction to the definition and measurement of soft innovation (NESTA
working paper). London: NESTA.
Throsby, D., 2001. Economics and culture. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Tusa, J., 2007. Im stick to death of meddling philistines. The Times. London, 7 April.

Anda mungkin juga menyukai