Anda di halaman 1dari 7

Applied Economics

ISSN: 0003-6846 (Print) 1466-4283 (Online) Journal homepage: http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/raec20

Bid dispersion, competition and wage regulation:


some field evidence from public contract bidding
in British Columbia

Cihan Bilginsoy

To cite this article: Cihan Bilginsoy (2000) Bid dispersion, competition and wage regulation:
some field evidence from public contract bidding in British Columbia, Applied Economics, 32:6,
717-722, DOI: 10.1080/000368400322336

To link to this article: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/000368400322336

Published online: 04 Oct 2010.

Submit your article to this journal

Article views: 25

View related articles

Citing articles: 1 View citing articles

Full Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at


http://www.tandfonline.com/action/journalInformation?journalCode=raec20

Download by: [Jordan Univ. of Science & Tech] Date: 23 February 2016, At: 22:29
Applied Economics, 2000, 32, 717 722

Bid dispersion, competition and wage


regulation: some eld evidence from public
contract bidding in British Columbia
C I H A N B I L G I N S OY
University of Utah, Department of Economics, 1645 E Central Campus Dr Front, Salt
L ake City, UT 84112-9300 , USA
Downloaded by [Jordan Univ. of Science & Tech] at 22:29 23 February 2016

The paper uses data from British Columbia to show that bid dispersion (the di er-
ence between the winning and next-lowest bids) in public school construction con-
tract bidding is very compact, and that it varies inversely with the degree of
competition. It also examines the impact of the Skill Development and Fair Wage
Law (SDFWP), which promulgated wage scales and required contractors to pay
them in public construction projects, on the bid dispersion. Multivariate analysis
shows that bid dispersion declined after SDFWP. One possible interpretation of this
result is that the contractors became less prone to the winners curse following the
SDFWP.

I . I N T R OD U C T I ON `fair wage on public construction projects in order to pre-


vent competition for contracts on the basis of wages, and
The bid dispersion is a critical indicator of the distribution determines the wage scales for the construction trades. The
of information signals of bidders in an auction. In a recent existing literature on prevailing or fair wage laws has
article Dyer and Kagel (1996) analysed bid dispersions focused on their impact on construction costs. Here, the
measured as the di erence between the winning and the focus is directed elsewhere, to their impact on the bidding
next-lowest bids in contract bidding for various types behaviour. The SDFWP changes the information content
of construction projects to infer how prone contractors of the auction because the bidding contractor faces less
are to the `winners curse. They compared these with bid uncertainty concerning his/her own labour costs and has
dispersions of the outer continental shelf (OCS) hydrocar- more information on the competitors labour costs. The
bon lease auctions reported by Hendricks et al. (1987) and paper examines whether the changing regulatory environ-
concluded that the potential for adverse selection is much ment that reduces the degree of common uncertainty over
smaller in the construction industry. They also found that the true value of the project a ects the bidding behaviour
the bid dispersion varied with the degree of competition of contractors and competition over contracts.
and the average bid. In this paper, data from British Approximately half of the projects under study are auc-
Columbia (BC) is used to present some new evidence on tioned before the passage of the SDFWP, providing a
the bidding behaviour of contractors under alternative unique opportunity to carry out this `before after compar-
wage regulation regimes. ison. Bid dispersion is measured by the di erence between
The paper has two objectives. First, the within-tender the winning and the next-lowest bids.
bid dispersion in a sample of BC school projects and the The following section brie y summarizes the theoretical
e ect of the number of bidders and the project size on the framework. The data are described in Section III. Section
bid dispersion are analysed. The second objective concerns IV presents descriptive statistics on tenders and bids.
the Skill Development and Fair Wage Policy (SDFWP) Section V focuses on the determination of the bid disper-
established by the BC provincial government on 31 sion and the impact of the SDFWP on the bid dispersion in
March 1992. The SDFWP is similar to the prevailing a multivariate context. The concluding section summarizes
wage laws of the US. It requires contractors to pay the the ndings.
Applied Economics ISSN 0003 6846 print/ISSN 1466 4283 online # 2000 Taylor & Francis Ltd 717
http://www.tandf.co.uk/journals/tf/00036846.htm l
718 C. Bilginsoy
I I . B I D D I N G , C OM PE TI T I ON A N D author found that the relationship between the number
I N F OR MA T I ON of bidders and the bid levels in BC school construction
projects was positive prior to the SDFWP and negative
In public construction auctions, contractors submit sealed afterwards (Bilginsoy, 1999). This result was attributed to
bids for the project by a xed deadline and the owner the transformation of nature of uncertainty facing the bid-
awards the contract to the lowest bidder, provided that ders, whereby elements of the common values model
s/he is a reputable contractor. Auction theory proposed a became less and private values model became more import-
series of hypotheses on the determination of the optimum ant after the establishment of the SDFWP. In the present
bid in one-shot rst-prize auctions under alternative paper, the question is how the dispersion of bids changes
information structures. These studies generally assume with the degree of competition and the changing regula-
that bidders are symmetric, risk neutral expected pro t- tions. Wilson (1977) and Holt (1979) predict that the bid
maximizers, and that information on the competitors and dispersion would decline as the number of bidders increases
their bidding history is common knowledge. Let xj stand under the independent private and common values
for the independently distributed information signal assumptions. Numerical illustrations by Dyer and Kagel
received by contractor j, and c be the cost of construction, (1996) also yield an inverse relationship between the bid
Downloaded by [Jordan Univ. of Science & Tech] at 22:29 23 February 2016

unknown prior to the completion of the project. Then dispersion and the degree of competition under both the
contractor js expected pro t is bxj Ecj jxj , where common and private value assumptions. The following sec-
bxj is the optimal bid and Ecj jxj is the estimated cost tions explore if evidence from BC supports this hypothesis
of construction. In determining the nal o er, the and whether the magnitude of this inverse relationship is
contractor estimates the cost of construction conditional a ected by the change in labour market regulation.
on the sample information, and then adds a mark-up to
obtain the optimum bid. The nal o er must be high
enough to yield a positive expected pro t, but low enough III. THE DA TA
to beat competitors.
Under the so-called independent private values model cj The data for the present study come from tenders received
and xj are identical. Any di erences between the estimated for 54 new public school construction projects in six dis-
and the true cost are attributable exclusively to the indi- tricts in BC between August 1989 and December 1995. Of
vidual contractor, such as its relationship with its foreman, the 54 projects, 25 were tendered before 31 March 1992 and
crew, or subcontractors. This individual nature of uncer- 29 were tendered afterwards. All post-SDFWP projects
tainty is the hallmark of the earlier bidding models, which were covered by the new regulation. Thirty-nine of the
followed the work of Friedman (1956). One implication of projects are for elementary and 15 for secondary schools.
the private values model is that the nal o er will be nega- Tenders for 17 elementary schools were received before the
tively related to the number of competitors. SDFWP and the remaining 22 afterwards. For the second-
The alternative is the common values model in which ary schools these gures are seven and eight, respectively.
case bidders face some collective source of uncertainty in Thus, the number and the type of schools are distributed
estimating the cost of construction, such as weather con- approximately evenly across the two periods.
ditions, physical characteristics of the land, or the state of The dataset lists individual general contractors and their
the labour market. In this case all bidders make unbiased bids for each project. In order to standardize bids across
estimates of the true cost of construction. By the nature of projects, bids are expressed in square-metre prices (in 1989
the auction mechanism, however, the winning bid has the prices). Table 1 summarizes basic statistics on bids and the
lowest information signal value, and is therefore biased number of bidders. A total of 452 bids were made on 54
downward. Unless the adverse selection e ect is fully projects, 197 before the SDFWP and 255 afterwards. The
accounted for by bidders, the winner is prone to less than mean bid value is $1461. The mean value increased signi -
anticipated or even negative pro ts. This problem is known cantly across the two periods, however, from $1362 to
as the `winners curse. Economic theory suggests that an $1538. This di erence is statistically highly signi cant (t-
experienced contractor should add a surcharge to its bid in value 8:85;p 0:00). The standard deviation, however,
order not to fall victim to the winners curse (Milgrom, is lower in the post-SDFWP period, declining from 222 to
1989). In this case the impact of an increase in the number 199. The di erence in standard deviations is also statisti-
of bidders is the outcome of two con icting factors: an cally signi cant, albeit at a lower level (F-value 3:77;
experienced bidder is forced to lower the bid as a result p 0.05:
of competitive forces, and to raise it in order to avoid the The average number of bidders per tender for the whole
prospect of adverse selection. period is 8.37. The number of bidders for each project
Independent private and common values models are varied between four and 17. There is some di erence
polar cases, and the real world lies somewhere in between, between the number of bidders per auction in the pre-
incorporating elements of both models. Elsewhere the and post-SDFWP periods. The mean number of bidders
Bid dispersion, competition and wage regulation 719
Table 1. Summary statistics

All tenders Before SDFWP After SDFWP

Bid Mean 1461 1362 1538


Stand. Dev. 227 222 199
Range 965 2094 965 1938 1167 2094
N 452 197 255
Number of bidders Mean 8.37 7.88 8.79
Median 8.00 8.00 9.00
Stand. Dev. 2.55 2.11 2.85
Range 4 17 4 15 5 17
N 54 25 29

Table 2. Bid dispersion


Downloaded by [Jordan Univ. of Science & Tech] at 22:29 23 February 2016

All tenders Before SDFWP After SDFWP

Money left on the table (level) Mean 18.54 23.46 14.31


Stand. Dev. 16.20 3.28 15.04
Min-max 0.01 71.24 1.71 52.94 0.01 71.24
Money left on the table (per cent) Mean 1.38 1.91 0.93
Stand. Dev. 1.26 1.36 0.99
Min-max 0.00 4.87 0.14 4.57 0.00 4.87
Number of observations 54 25 29

increased by 0.9 after the change in the regulatory environ- comparison with the OCS lease auctions, the potential
ment. The median, perhaps the more appropriate measure for the winners curse is much smaller in construction.
of the central tendency since the distribution of the number Mean values of MLOT declined after the establishment
of bidders is non-normal, increased by one. The hypotheses of the policy. Average absolute MLOT declined from
of equality of the pre- and post-SDFWP means and med- $23.46 to $14.31. The null hypothesis that the mean values
ians are tested and neither are rejected. The data also of dispersion are equal across periods is rejected for both
rejected the hypothesis that the standard deviations of the absolute ( p 0:04) and the relative ( p 0:01) MLOT.
the number of bidders are equal across the two periods These ndings suggest rising compactness in bids at the low
( p 0:07). end of the bid distribution. It is observed from Table 2 that
the standard deviations were also lower in the post-
SDFWP period.
Pearson correlation coe cients between bid dispersion
I V . B I D D I S PE R S I ON and the number of bidders and the average bid size (a
proxy for the true cost of construction) across tenders are
The di erence between the winning and the next-lowest bid reported in Table 3. The two statistically signi cant corre-
money left on the table (MLOT) focuses on the left- lations in Table 3 suggest that, for the whole sample, both
hand tail of the bid distribution. MLOT was measured in measures of the MLOT varied inversely with the number of
both absolute and relative terms, as the di erence between bidders. For sub-periods, the correlation coe cients are
the two bids and as the percentage of the winning o er. A also negative but not statistically signi cant. Correlation
large value of MLOT indicates that the bidders underlying coe cients between MLOT and the average bid price sug-
signal values exhibit high variation and may also suggest gest that the relationship between the two variables were
higher likelihood of winners curse (Dyer and Kagel, 1996). altered after the SDFWP. They are most strongly negative
Table 2 presents summary statistics of the MLOT. The for the pre-SDFWP period. For the whole sample, the
mean values of the absolute and relative MLOT are $18.54 coe cient is still negative but much smaller in value.
and 1.38%, respectively. The relative MLOT is even lower Post-SDFWP coe cients are even smaller with positive
than the 2.10% Dyer and Kagel (1996) observed in the case and negative signs for the absolute and relative measures
of new public school and public facility construction in of the MLOT, respectively.
Houston, TX. In the OCS lease auctions, MLOT was on The preceding statistical analysis shows that distribu-
average 50% (Hendricks et al. , 1987). Hence, the present tions of bids across tenders were somewhat a ected by
gures corroborate Dyer and Kagels conclusion that in the SDFWP. No signi cant patterns emerge, however,
720 C. Bilginsoy
Table 3. Correlation coe cients

Number of bidders Average bid

Money left on the table (level) All tenders 0:266 0:059


(0.05) (0.67)
Pre-SDFWP 0:213 0:189
(0.31) (0.37)
Post-SDFWP 0:245 0.038
(0.20) (0.85)
Money left on the table (per cent) All tenders 0:267 0:094
(0.04) (0.50)
Pre-SDFWP 0:246 0:226
(0.23) (0.28)
Post-SDFWP 0:233 0:003
(0.22) (0.99)
Note: Signi cance levels in parentheses.
Downloaded by [Jordan Univ. of Science & Tech] at 22:29 23 February 2016

from the correlation coe cients between the bid disper- where ML OT stands for either measure of the money left
sion, on the one hand, and the number of bidders and on the table; SDFW P is a dummy variable equal to one in
the average bid, on the other. In the next section, the the post-SDFWP period and zero otherwise; Average bid is
impact of the SDFWP on the bid dispersion is explored the mean bid value of the project ; Construction cycle is the
in more detail in a multivariate context. percentage di erence between the trend and the actual
value of non-residential building permits; Secondary school
is a dummy variable that takes the value of one for sec-
V . M U L T I V A R I A T E A N A L Y S I S OF TH E ondary schools and zero for elementary; " is the error
T E N D E R S PR E A D term. 2
The critical variable in Equation 1 is the SDFW P
Auction theory predicts that bid dispersion declines with dummy. If 1 < 0, then the after-SDFWP bid dispersion,
the rising degree of competition, i.e. the number of at any level of competition, is lower by a constant amount.
bidders. 1 Wage regulation is also expected to reduce dis- The regulation dummy also enters the equation in inter-
persion at all levels of competition , by reducing the com- action with the number of bidders because the SDFWP has
mon uncertainty related to the labour market, on the one been observed to a ect the relationship between of the
hand, and by reducing any di erences in wages paid by degree of competition and bid prices (Bilginsoy, 1999).
contractors, on the other. These hypotheses are tested in Ignoring 1 , if 2 is positive, as predicted by auction
this section using a regression model explaining variations theory, and 3 is negative, then the post-SDFWP bid dis-
the MLOT by the regulatory environment, the number of persion will be lower than the pre-SDFWP dispersion at
bidders, the average bid, the construction sector business any level of competition.
cycle, and school type. The estimated equation is: Estimates of four versions of Equation 1 are presented in
ML OT 0 1 SDFW P Table 4. In estimation, the e ect of the SDFWP is initially
ignored by restricting coe cients 1 and 3 to zero.
2 1=N
Regressions (1) and (5) report the ordinary least squares
3 SDFW P 1=N estimates of this speci cation using relative and absolute
MLOT as the dependent variable, respectively. In both esti-
4 Average bid mations only a small fraction of the variation in the bid
5 Construction cycle dispersion is explained. The coe cients of determination
are 11 and 9%, respectively, which are one-quarter and
6 School type " 1 one-half of the R2 s of the corresponding Dyer Kagel regres-

1
Note that if contractors with high estimated costs do not submit bids, then the number of bidders is an endogenous variable, and not an
appropriate measure of the degree of competition. While this is a signi cant problem in the OCS auctions where rms who already drill
in the neighbouring tracks have more information on the value of the auctioned tracks (Gilley and Karels, 1981 ; Hendricks et al. , 1987) .
School construction projects are relatively standard and the scope of such informational advantage is likely to be far smaller than is
observed in the OCS lease auctions.
2
Initial regressions included district dummies as control variables and, in light of the relatively strong correlation between the MLOT and
the average bid in the pre-SDFWP period, the interaction term for the SDFW P and Average bid. These variables were subsequently
dropped because their coe cients turned out to be statistically insigni cant in all estimations.
Bid dispersion, competition and wage regulation 721
Table 4. Determinants of bid dispersion

MLOT (%) MLOT (level)

Variable (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

Constant 0.29 0.61 0.92 0.37 4.03 8.99 9.86 4.70


(0.43) (0.62) (1.37) (0.58) (0.46) (0.68) (1.10) (0.55)
SDFW P 70.41 70.96 77.34 78.84
(0.33) (2.80) *** (0.43) (1.93)*
1/N 10.28 11.67 9.58 13.18 124.20 123.47 117.64 150.23
(2.13)** (1.77)* (2.11) ** (2.84)*** (1.99)* (1.39) (1.93)* (2.41) **
SDFW L (1/N) 74.08 76.97 711.32 762.54
(0.66) (2.82)*** (0.09) (1.88) *
Average bid 72.4E-08 73.9E-08 1.2E-07 73.5E-08 77.6E-08 72.5E-07 72.6E-07 71.8E-07
(0.34) (0.59) (1.53) (0.54) (0.09) (0.28) (0.30) (0.21)
Downloaded by [Jordan Univ. of Science & Tech] at 22:29 23 February 2016

Construction cycle 71.3E-02 71.4E-02 71.6E-02 1.2E-02 79.2E-02 0.17 0.17 0.13
(0.69) (0.43) (0.17) (0.67) (0.22) (0.38) (0.40) (0.30)
School type 76.7E-02 0.12 0.15 8.7E-02 73.00 71.13 71.05 71.62
( 1 if secondary) (0.95) (0.12) (0.15) (0.09) (0.23) (0.09) (0.08) (0.13)
R2 0.11 0.24 0.23 0.24 0.09 0.16 0.16 0.15
Adj-R2 0.04 0.14 0.15 0.16 0.02 0.05 0.07 0.06
F 1.48 2.42** 2.92** 2.94** 1.21 1.44 1.76 1.72

Notes: t-statistics in parentheses. ***, ** and * indicate statistical signi cance at the 1%, 5% and 10% levels, respectively.

sions (which were based on a signi cantly larger sample). declines. This is the outcome of high degree of collinearity
The most important nding reported in these regressions is between 1=N, SDFW P and SDFW P 1=N. 4
that both the relative and absolute MLOT decline with the The remaining four equations drop SDFW P and
number of bidders. According to regression (1), an incre- SDFW P 1=N alternatively in response to the multicolli-
mental increase in the number of bidders, say from eight nearity problem. In all four equations the regulatory change
to nine, lowers the relative MLOT by 0.14 percentage points is observed to have a notable e ect on the bid dispersion. In
(or about 10% of the mean relative MLOT). If the depen- regression (3), MLOT is still inversely related to the number
dent variable is the absolute MLOT (regression 5) , the same of bidders and this relationship is statistically signi cant
change in the degree of competition reduces the di erence ( p 0:04). After the establishment of the SDFWP, there
between the lowest two bids by approximately $1.70. Both of was also a sharp decline in bid dispersion, and this impact
these ndings are statistically signi cant ( p 0:04 and has an even higher statistical signi cance ( p 0:01). At any
p 0:05, respectively), and are consistent with the correla- given level of competition, the predicted MLOT is lower by
tion coe cients reported in Table 3. They also conform with approximately one percentage point after the SDFWP.
the results obtained by Dyer and Kagel,3 but contradict Regression (4) yields a similar result, although this time
some of the ndings of Hendricks et al. who observed that the SDFWP is hypothesized to a ect the bid dispersion via
the absolute MLOT rises with the number of bidders in OSC the degree of competition. Following the SDFWP, there is
lease auctions. Other explanatory variables included in the still an inverse relationship between the MLOT and the
regression do not have any statistically signi cant e ect on degree of competition, but the magnitude of this relationship
the bid dispersion. is smaller. At any given number of bidders, the post-
In regressions (2) and (6), the SDFWP slope and inter- SDFWP bid dispersion is smaller.
cept dummies are introduced simultaneously. Although the In order to underscore this nding the predicted relative
explanatory powers of both regressions rise appreciably, MLOTs from regression Equations 3 were plotted under
neither of the dummies is statistically signi cant and, the assumptions that School type 0, Average bid $1400
although the inverse relationship is preserved, the signi - and Construction cycle 0. The number of bidders is
cance level of the coe cient of the number of bidders allowed to vary between two and 17. The predicted relative

3
The estimated coe cient and its standard error in the relative MLOT regression are surprisingly close to Dyer and Kagels estimates of
10.1 and 4.1, respectively. Dyer and Kagels sample size is 295 projects.
4
Variance proportions of the three variables are 0.81, 0.86 and 0.84, respectively, with the condition index equal to 23.
722 C. Bilginsoy
SDFWP, established in 1992, determined and implemented
wage scales to construction trades. Change in regulations
may a ect the nature of uncertainty, reducing the relative
weight of the common values model elements a ecting the
bidding behaviour, and also reduce one potentially signi -
cant source of di erence wages paid across contractors.
Both factors would cause the bid dispersion to become
more compact. Evidence from BC supports this hypothesis.
Dyer and Kagel (1996) suggested that although there is
no necessary relationship between the two, the MLOT is a
potential indicator of the likelihood of winner s curse in
common value auctions. Noting that the MLOT of the
construction projects is far smaller than that of the OCS
lease auctions (by an order of seven), for instance, they are
able to state that the likelihood of adverse selection is far
Downloaded by [Jordan Univ. of Science & Tech] at 22:29 23 February 2016

smaller in the former. By the same token, comparison of


Fig. 1. Predicted values of relative money-left on-the-table the pre- and post-SDFWP MLOTs of the BC projects
(ML OT ) (from regression (4))
reveals that the bid spread declined after establishment of
the law and the potential for the winners curse has become
MLOT values are plotted on Fig. 1. This chart rst illus- lower. This impact of regulation on the nature of uncer-
trates that as the number of bidders increases, bid disper- tainty must be of interest to policy-makers because avoid-
sion declines. Secondly, bid dispersion in the post-SDFWP ing the winner s curse bene ts both the contractors and the
period is lower at any degree of competition. MLOT for owners of public construction. Losses by a contractor who
the pre- and post-SDFWP periods are 6.96 and 3.47%, is unable to nish a construction project below the contract
respectively, if there are only two bidders. This 3.5 per- price may ultimately spill over to owners as scheduling
centage point di erence in MLOT declines gradually as delays, lower construction quality, higher change order
the number of bidders increases. With 17 bidders, the prices, legal expenses and, ultimately, more tax dollars.
MLOT of post-SDFWP tender is 0.73%, 0.4 percentage
points lower than the pre-SDFWP value.
Regression (6) and (7) carry out the same exercise for the A C K N OW L E D G E ME N T S
absolute MLOT. The explanatory power of these regres-
sions and statistical signi cance of the coe cient turn out I am indebted to Clyde Scollan and Greg Sewell for pro-
to be lower in this case but these regressions yield results viding the raw data and detailed information on the British
similar to those reported in columns (3) and (4). The abso- Columbia construction industry, and an anonymous
lute bid dispersion varies inversely with the number of bid- referee for comments. I am responsible for all errors.
ders, and is lower during the post-SDFWP period than in
the pre-SDFWP period.
R EFER ENCES
Bilginsoy, C. (1999) Labor market regulation and the winner s
V I . C ON C L U S I ON curse, Economic Inquiry, 37, 387 400.
Dyer, D. and Kagel, J. H. (1996) Bidding common value auctions:
how the commercial construction industry corrects for the
This paper attempts to contribute to the growing empirical winners curse, Management Science, 42, 1463 75
literature on eld evidence on auctions. It calculated the Friedman, L. (1956) A competitive bidding strategy, Operations
di erence between the winning and the next-lowest bids Research, 4, 104 112.
for BC public school construction projects tendered between Gilley, O. W. and Karels, G. V. (1981) The competitive e ect in
1989 and 1995, and explored the relationship between the bonus bidding: new evidence, Bell Journal of Economics, 12,
637 48.
bid spread and number of bidders, average bid price, school Hendricks, K., Porter, R. H. and Boudreau, B. (1987)
type and business cycle. The calculated MLOT shows that Information, returns, and bidding behavior in OCS auctions:
the construction project auctions bids are very compact, far 1954 1969, Journal of Industrial Economics, 35, 517 42.
smaller than is observed in OCS lease auctions, and it is an Holt, C. A. Jr. (1979) Uncertainty and the bidding for incentive
inverse function of the number of bidders. contracts, American Economic Review, 69, 697 705.
Milgrom, P. (1989) Auctions and bidding: a primer, T he Journal
One unique advantage of the BC data set is that it allows of Economic Perspectives, 33, 3 21.
experiments to be carried out on the behaviour of the con- Wilson, R. (1977) A bidding model of perfect competition, Review
tractors under alternative regulatory environments. The of Economic Studies, 44(138) , 511 18.

Anda mungkin juga menyukai