Anda di halaman 1dari 7

Microeconomics, History of

Paola Tubaro, University of Greenwich, Greenwich, UK


2015 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

Abstract

This article provides a brief overview of the history of microeconomics, starting from the late eighteenth century when its key
foundations were laid. Without intending to be comprehensive, the article outlines landmarks and milestones in the building
of the basic principles of todays knowledge, highlighting challenges faced and open questions. Focus is on the contribution
of each historical phase to the understanding of two foundational issues in microeconomics the theory of individual
economic decision making and the market mechanism as a coordinating device. At the end, the article discusses the current
state of microeconomics and recent tendencies.

Introduction system taken in its entirety (Frisch, 1933: p. 2). The work of
John M. Keynes (1936) in those same years, with its strong
Microeconomics stands as one of the two main pillars of focus on aggregate relations and an extremely simplied
todays economic science, the other being macroeconomics. representation of individual behaviors, popularized the belief
Microeconomics seeks to understand how individuals, house- that the macro level of analysis differs in nature from the
holds, and companies make decisions; the factors that shape microlevel, and contributed to further differentiating the two
these decisions; and how these decisions affect others. Its object subdisciplines.
is decision making at low, or micro, level, in contrast to Since then, it took another 50 years before economists
macroeconomics, whose focus is the behavior of national formally acknowledged the micromacro taxonomy. In the
aggregates such as gross domestic product, ination, and classication of subject elds of the Journal of Economic Litera-
unemployment. ture, a reference for the profession worldwide, micro- and
At the heart of microeconomics is a social and scientic macroeconomics were subsets of a broad theory category in
mystery. In modern market economies characterized by the original 1960 version, and were brought up a level and
private property and freedom, decisions to produce, sell, work, highlighted as major independent categories in a substantial
buy, and consume are made by multiple individuals, house- revision of the system in 1991 (Barreto, 2012). They remain
holds, and companies autonomously and independently from two major areas today, allowing the development of new or
one another; each actor chooses under limited, or even inex- renewed subelds within them. The teaching of economics has
istent, knowledge of the choices of others. Yet someones followed suit, with current curricula typically separating micro-
decision to buy, say, a pint of milk can only translate into an and macroeconomics courses, both being part of the core
actual purchase if someone else simultaneously decides to sell training of new economists.
a pint of milk. So if buyer and seller do not coordinate ex ante, Perhaps ironically, a parallel movement has been increas-
how can their decisions engender actual, mutually benecial ingly blurring the distinction between the micro and macro
transactions, rather than result in disappointment and frustra- approaches. Economists have grown more and more uncom-
tion? The market mechanism is the device that accomplishes fortable with the idea that different theoretical principles apply
this result: by establishing the relative price of goods and to the study of individual decisions and the aggregates that
factors, it informs individual decisions, adjusts the quantities (ultimately) result from them. Since the late 1980s the
traded, and achieves ex post coordination. Microeconomics, microfoundations movement in macroeconomics, champ-
through the supply-and-demand framework of analysis, looks ioned by Robert Lucas (born 1937), aims to reconcile these
at how this happens. It also studies the effects of institutions two traditions and rebuild macroeconomics so as to make it
such as government regulation and taxation on individual consistent with the principles of microeconomics.
choices and market outcomes. This article provides a brief overview of the history of
In essence, microeconomics is as old as economic thought microeconomics, starting from the time in which its key
itself: Classics in the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries laid foundations were laid, although the micro terminology was
out the theoretical elements that have progressively molded not yet in use. Despite the interest of the early literature, which
economists understanding of individual decision making and dates as far back as antiquity and the Middle Ages (see, e.g.,
the market mechanism. Yet the micro label and the repre- Hutchison, 1988), a detailed account of it would be beyond the
sentation of microeconomics as a separate enterprise, explicitly scope of this article, and the more traditional convention of
distinct from macroeconomics, emerged much later. According starting from the late eighteenth century is followed. The article
to Humberto Barreto (2012), its rst traces are in a 1933 article overviews historical developments since then, without
by Ragnar Frisch for whom the micro approach would try to intending to be comprehensive, but aiming only to outline
explain in some detail the behavior of a certain section of the landmarks and milestones in the building of the basic princi-
huge economic mechanism, while the macro would instead ples of todays knowledge, highlighting the challenges faced
give an account of the uctuations of the whole economic and the questions that remain open. Focus is on what each

International Encyclopedia of the Social & Behavioral Sciences, 2nd edition, Volume 15 http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/B978-0-08-097086-8.03060-9 331
332 Microeconomics, History of

historical phase contributed to the understanding of the two Incidentally, the Smithian model of individual behavior
foundational issues in microeconomics namely, the theory of had the merit of supporting an egalitarian perspective in the
individual economic decision making and the market mecha- nineteenth-century political debates. If the same scheme holds
nism as a coordinating device. At the end, the article discusses for all individuals, they are all equal and have the same capacity
the current state of microeconomics and recent tendencies, for decision making; observed differences, if any, depend on
again distinguishing between the study of individual behaviors chance and history. This egalitarian view was shared by most
and the market mechanism. economists of the time and strongly contrasted the (then also
widespread) hierarchical stance that regarded the lower classes
of society and supposedly inferior ethnic/racial groups as less
The Origins: Self-Interest and the Invisible Hand capable of making decisions and thus in need of guidance
in Adam Smith (Peart and Levy, 2005). Interestingly, the infamous dismal
science designation of economics was originally an accusation
The Scottish philosopher Adam Smith (172390) is widely against economists antislavery orientation, resulting from their
regarded as one of the founders of economics; though not belief that all humans are equal (Levy, 2001).
alone in this enterprise, he exemplies at best the novelty and Smiths work also contributed to shaping economists view
relevance of eighteenth-century thought in dening what of the market as a coordinating device that ensures, ex post, that
would become the basic principles of microeconomics. In his individual decisions are consistent with one another and
Wealth of Nations (1776), Smith was the rst to explicitly generate an orderly result. Smiths invisible hand metaphor
characterize individual economic behavior as self-interested has often been recognized as an effective representation of this
behavior, admitting that it is peoples desire for a gain that mechanism:
explains work, production, and ultimately the existence of an
economic system: by directing [.] industry in such a manner as its produce may be of
the greatest value, he [man] intends only his own gain, and he is in
this, as in many other cases, led by an invisible hand to promote an
It is not from the benevolence of the butcher, the brewer, or the end which was no part of his intention. By pursuing his own interest
baker that we expect our dinner, but from their regard to their own he frequently promotes that of the society more effectually than
interest. We address ourselves, not to their humanity but to their self- when he really intends to promote it.
love, and never talk to them of our own necessities but of their (Smith, 1776/1981: p. 456)
advantages.
(Smith, 1776/1981: pp. 2627)
Because individuals are not isolated but part of a larger
human community, their actions have unexpected or unin-
The idea that businesspeople act to satisfy their self-interest tended consequences at the system level. Individuals take into
may seem dauntingly simple, and to some extent brutal in its account only their self-interest, yet their choices affect others
apparent amorality. Yet over time, it has proven fertile in and trigger a chain of interactions that eventually affect the
informing economists imagination and their capacity to society as a whole, well beyond their original intentions.
explain individual decision making. It is not a sheer defense of Strikingly enough, Smith argues that this spontaneous process
selshness in present-day parlance, one would simply say does not lead to chaos but to harmony: Self-interest may not
that people respond to incentives, that is, advantages or gains seem a noble motivation, yet it triggers consequences that
that can derive from given decisions or actions. By and large, benet society even more than those arising from benevolence.
modern microeconomics assumes that individuals motiva- Thus, there is no need for a strong state power that would
tions when they make decisions are their expected gains by impose social order from above, as had been argued by Thomas
those decisions. Hobbes (15881679). The idea of unintended consequences
But Smith, a moral philosopher, could not neglect motiva- and the possible reconciliation of individual self-interest and
tions other than self-interest in shaping economic decision- social good, rst articulated by Smith, have been at the core of
making. Indeed his self-interest must be understood in subsequent microeconomic reection which is another
conjunction with another behavioral principle, that of sympathy reason why Smith is credited as a founder of the discipline.
between human beings who, by putting themselves imagina-
tively in the place of others, understand their feelings and
expectations and are moved to act accordingly (e.g., to give to Early Developments: Marginalism,
those who are in need). While Smiths critics initially opposed Supply-and-Demand, Formalization
sympathy and self-interest, todays scholarship sees them as two
instances of a common framework for thinking about human To further develop Smiths approach, economists faced the
behavior, in which the individually centered, self-interested formidable problem of how to operationalize the principle of
component is accompanied by an interpersonal dimension, so self-interested action so as to apply it to the solution of concrete
that it becomes possible to account for various forms of behavior, economic problems. They rst thought about it in terms of the
from gain-seeking actions to philanthropy. Reconciliation of self-interested businessperson who makes production-related
these two aspects of Smiths thought makes him the father of decisions: In his On the Principles of Political Economy and Taxa-
microeconomics in a broader sense: A recent trend in todays tion (1817/2004), the highly inuential British writer David
research on economic decision making (see below) tends to Ricardo (17721823) discussed how cost-effective substitution
explicitly integrate forms of prosocial behavior into the analysis. of machinery for workers, or of imports for nationally produced
Microeconomics, History of 333

goods through international trade, affects a rms prots and On the coordinating mechanism, emphasis was increas-
workers welfare. Ricardos writings hardly touched on the study ingly placed on the symmetry of supply-and-demand factors
of household and consumer behavior, though: As many econ- and on the resulting market equilibrium. While Ricardo had
omists of the time, he was mainly interested in production stressed supply factors in the determination of prices and
forces, working conditions, and their differential impact on quantities traded, the mid-nineteenth century developed a view
income distribution. Emphasis was on the effects of the whole according to which individual demand and supply are derived,
economic system on individual behavior, rather than the respectively, from agents calculations of utility (for consumers)
reverse, and a fundamental heterogeneity distinguished and prot/cost (for rms), and market supply and demand are
economic agents consumers vs rms. While the latter were obtained by aggregating all individual values. When market
already envisaged as cost-minimizers or prot-maximizers, supply equals demand, the market is in equilibrium that is,
placing emphasis on how they acted for their own advantage, the decisions of all households and all rms are consistent with
less attention was drawn to the individual decisions of the one another. The French mathematician Antoine-Augustin
former, and demand was mainly seen as an aggregate rather Cournot (180177) was the rst, as early as 1838, to illus-
than an individual construct, for example, by assuming that trate these principles with the help of pricequantity diagrams
population growth largely determines demand for food. in which the demand of a good decreases, and the supply
Even the authors who, following developments in philos- increases, with its price; The intersection of the supply-and-
ophy and psychology, introduced the notion of utility to demand schedules identies equilibrium, that is, a price at
account for the pleasure and pain that consumers derive from which supply equals demand and the market clears. This
goods, found it difcult to integrate it into economic models. partial equilibrium approach, focusing on the study of a single
Utility initially appeared as a qualitative, subjective construct competitive market, was further developed and popularized
devoid of any objective, quantiable attributes very different a few decades later in England by Alfred Marshall (1842
then from the rms prot or income, which centuries-long 1924); it is now a standard part of undergraduate microeco-
advances in accounting enabled to measure in straightfor- nomics education.
ward way. The solution came in the mid-nineteenth century, The advantage of Marshalls partial equilibrium approach is
from reinterpreting utility not as an absolute but as a relative that it provides a tractable framework to study the relationship
magnitude, varying from one individual to another and for between price and quantity; however, it is based on the
each individual, depending on the available quantity of a good. restrictive assumption that changes in the price of a good affect
It turned out that measurability and quantication were not the quantity of that good only, disregarding the possibility that
even necessary, insofar as utility could be expressed as a vari- a variation in the price of a good will impinge on the demand
able or a function of other variables, allowing comparisons and supply of substitutes and complements of that good too.
(larger/smaller, more/less, positive/negative, etc.). One could Hence, it can be taken at most as an approximation, not as
thus distinguish the total amount of utility from marginal a rigorous analytical device. A rival view focusing on interde-
utility namely, the change in the level of utility that results pendencies among markets was simultaneously developed by
from a given increase in the quantity of the good. Marginal Walras (1874/1977), who represented economic agents that
utility was thought to diminish with the quantity consumed, allocate their budgets to the purchase of multiple goods so that
reecting the capacity of individuals to order the possible uses changes in the market price and/or quantity of one good are
of successively acquired units: For instance, one would reserve likely to have repercussions on the markets for other goods. His
the rst gallons of water for drinking and the successive ones notion of general equilibrium which would inform large parts
for personal hygiene, for housekeeping, and nally for watering of microeconomics, is directly derived from this view and
plants. In passing, this assumption solved what earlier thinkers corresponds to a situation in which supply equals demand on
considered a paradox the fact that useful goods such as water each market, so that all clear simultaneously.
or air have low market value: The reason is their abundance, A derived question is whether and how actual trade prac-
which means that the last increment in quantity generates an tices will drive prices and quantities toward equilibrium.
extremely small increase in utility. These results suggested an Marshall and Walras provided different answers, consistent
interpretation of self-interested behavior in terms of attempts with their respective views. Walras (1874/1977) proposed
to raise ones utility to its highest possible level and were a model of auctions in which at given prices, all traders declare
obtained independently, in 187174, by William S. Jevons the quantity of each good that they wish to buy or sell at those
(183582) in Britain, Carl Menger (18401921) in Austria, prices; if with these quantities, supply equals demand on each
and Lon Walras (18341910) in Switzerland. market, then this is the general equilibrium and trade takes
The importance of thinking in terms of marginal variations place; if not, prices are adjusted in such a way that they
rather than total magnitudes proved so useful to account for diminish where supply exceeds demand and increase in the
utility and demand that it was subsequently extended to opposite case; at the new prices, traders announce again the
supply. In fact, notions of marginal productivity and marginal quantities that they wish to buy or sell, and the process
cost of production, as opposed to total productivity/cost, had (ttonnement) starts again, until equilibrium is reached. In
already been introduced, but in a patchy fashion; they were short, transactions take place simultaneously, at equilibrium
rened and generalized in the 1890s by, among others, John B. only, so that the same prices apply to all traders. Instead,
Clark (18471938), Philip H. Wicksteed (18441927), and Marshall (1920) had in mind a sequence of bilateral trans-
Knut Wicksell (18511926). Marginal reasoning seemed so actions on a single market, in which each pair of traders
important that the economic thought of this time period is negotiates a price and each transaction withdraws some units
often referred to as marginalism. from the market so that lesser quantities are available for later
334 Microeconomics, History of

trades in other words, the conditions under which traders the demand and the supply side of the market, becoming the
negotiate are altered at every step. Such changes gradually basis of all analyses of individual economic behavior. The
dampen price adjustments until they reach the level that contribution of Paul Samuelson (19152009) was essential to
corresponds to the intersection of supply and demand. Here, these developments and mainly consisted in rewriting many
transactions occur sequentially, in disequilibrium, at prices that problems of economics as maximization problems, with
may differ from a pair of traders to the other. These different extensive use of mathematics. Samuelsons effort to show that
approaches strongly affected later developments (see below). apparently diverse subjects have the same underlying structure
These theoretical developments, often referred to as neo- and can be treated with the same mathematical tools dened
classical economics (in contrast to Ricardos classical theory), the core of what came to be known as microeconomics, and
accompanied a growing tendency to formalization. Deeply gave it unprecedented unity and coherence. Higher abstraction
intertwined with the development of microeconomic thought and technical difculty, however, were the price to pay for
since its early phases, formalization is an approach to theory- increased scope and greater logical coherence making the
building which, starting from the denition of theoretical eld inaccessible to wide audiences and hard to communicate
constructs and of linkages between them, derives logical outside a narrow circle of specialists.
conclusions from given premises. In this sense, formalization is With time, these revisions proved successful in that they
an abstract process and must be distinguished from quanti- made constrained maximization so powerful that it began to be
cation, or the systematic effort to measure reality for purposes of thought of as a basis for understanding all human behaviors
business or policy intervention, rather than theory-building, for not just those traditionally regarded as falling within the realm
instance by counting the population in a census. While quan- of market transactions. The work of Gary Becker (19302014),
tication was already well under way at this time, it was in particular, is founded on the idea that individual behavior
formalization that needed to be advanced. Writing in its follows the same fundamental principles in different areas, so
defense, Jevons claimed that The data are almost wholly that the same explanatory model microeconomic optimiza-
decient for the complete solution of any one problem, yet tion should always be applicable. Becker thus extended the
we have mathematical theory without the data requisite for sphere of microeconomic analysis to the study of new areas,
precise calculation (Jevons, 1965/1871). Yet despite its ranging from crime and discrimination to marriage and the
growing importance, formalization was still far from being family (Becker, 1992). Beckers analysis initially raised many
prominent at the end of the nineteenth century, when many eyebrows, but gradually came to exert a huge inuence on the
economists still privileged the verbal form and some overtly economics profession as well as on neighboring disciplines.
criticized the use of mathematics, the most prominent example The optimization model was not beyond dispute, though:
being the German Historical School. It was only in the mid- At least since the 1950s, Herbert Simon (19162001) and
twentieth century, after the emergence of microeconomics as others contended that actual decision makers lack the cognitive
a distinct theoretical enterprise, that formalization became capacities to solve maximization problems and rather content
a standard practice. themselves with satiscing behavior, choosing options that
are not optimal but make them happy enough. Along these
lines, they developed a bounded rationality approach as an
Maturity: Constrained Optimization and Market alternative to the seemingly strong rationality requirements of
Equilibrium the individual maximization model. Yet it was difcult to
identify universal principles enabling to devise general models
The theoretical elements laid out in the nineteenth century of nonmaximizing behavior, so that bounded rationality
went through further elaboration and systematization in the assumptions often maintained an ad hoc, hardly generalizable
rst half of the twentieth century, when neoclassical micro- character. Partly for this reason, the optimization model
economics blossomed and eventually arose as a major retained its prominence for long.
subdiscipline in conjunction with macroeconomics. The More recently, a current of thought known as behavioral
concept of utility was rened and utility gradually came to be economics has provided abundant evidence against the indi-
understood as rational, purposeful behavior choosing the vidual optimization model. Starting from a seminal contribu-
best possible means to achieve ones ends, an interpretation tion (1979) by Amos Tversky (193796) and Daniel
that deprives utility of any identication with self-interest Kahnemann (born 1934), it has been shown that people make
narrowly interpreted, and even with pleasure, pain or any decisions based on simplied heuristics such as routines and
other emotions and feelings. Consistency in choices turned out habits rather than rigorous logic, and use mental emotional
to be all that was needed, and the microeconomic paradigm lters to respond to changing circumstances. In contrast to the
that eventually emerged refrained from making psychological microeconomic paradigm that aims at a value-neutral, highly
assumptions. This more neutral interpretation of utility came abstract representation of decision making, behavioral
to dominate economics, notably through the revealed preference economics reintegrates psychological elements into the anal-
approach (Samuelson, 1938) which enabled application of the ysis, explicitly investigates pro-social behavior, and compares
model to a variety of settings and behaviors (including non- and contrasts it with self-interest and selshness renewing, in
selsh ones and altruism). a sense, with the older tradition initiated at the time of Adam
Consistency involves the optimizing behavior of agents Smith.
under some constraints (budget for consumers, technology for Regarding market models, after World War II it was the
rms). Progressively, the constrained maximization model was general equilibrium model that most attracted the attention
extended to the study of all individual decision units, on both of economic theorists, largely due to the introduction into
Microeconomics, History of 335

economics of highly advanced formal tools and of a new way of markets appeared as a monolithic bloc a standard, more and
thinking about mathematics, based on topology, convex set more rmly established mainstream allowing less and less
theory, and xed-point theorems (Weintraub, 2002). The new different perspectives. The micro-foundations movement, in its
tools allowed for a sophisticated renement of Walrass effort to integrate core microeconomic principles into macro,
approach, named the ArrowDebreuMcKenzie model after its seemed to further reinforce the mainstreams primacy. Micro-
main contributors. A major achievement in the 1950s was economics seemed at the same time successful, and stagnating,
a formal proof of existence of equilibrium. The difculty was unable to move any further.
that it was not enough to show that the system of simultaneous Yet a closer look reveals that the evolution of microeco-
equations representing equality between supply and demand nomics in the decades that followed World War II was more
in all markets has a solution: For this solution to be meaningful diverse than may seem at rst sight. Alternative and heterodox
economically, and not only mathematically, it was also economic theories, explicitly challenging neoclassical micro-
necessary to prove that equilibrium prices and quantities are economics, have never ceased to exist even though their place,
nonnegative. By demonstrating that it is indeed the case, it was relevance, and visibility seemed to somehow shrink over time.
established that the notion of a set of prices that clear all A complete review of their approaches is beyond the scope of
markets is consistent (i.e., the notion of equilibrium of this article; But it is worth briey mentioning two key devel-
a system of interrelated competitive markets is not void). opments which, initially not among the most vocally critical of
Another success for general equilibrium theory was the the state of microeconomics, have been highly successful and
mathematical proof of the so-called two theorems of welfare over time, have progressively grown to be integrated into the
economics a modern reinterpretation of Smiths invisible mainstream as it is today. First, the general-equilibrium image
hand. The rst theorem states that a general equilibrium of individuals making decisions in isolation from one another,
corresponds to a socially optimal allocation of resources, and letting an impersonal market mechanism establish the prices
the second states that, under some conditions, any socially that will guide their decisions, progressively gave way to a more
optimal allocation of resources can be sustainable by a general active view of decisions as strategic reactions to other agents
equilibrium. These results amounted to rigorously establishing own actions. In contexts in which interdependencies are strong,
the desirable properties of the free market mechanism that such as imperfectly competitive markets, economic agents
earlier economists like Adam Smith had put forward only anticipate the direct repercussions of their choices on others,
intuitively or metaphorically. In sum, the new approach and of others choices on themselves. Game theory has proven
completely transformed general equilibrium theory, allowing to be the appropriate technique to explore the structure of
to make it rigorous, to generalize it, to simplify it, and to strategic interactions and the direct effects of individual deci-
extend it in new directions (Debreu, 1984: p. 267). sions on one another. Initiated in the 1940s with, among
In the 1950s and 1960s, such progresses put the Arrow others, a seminal contribution of Oskar Morgenstern and John
DebreuMcKenzie model at the center of the stage and von Neumann (1944), game theory experienced a rapid
increased condence in its potential to provide the whole of development and an extraordinary expansion of its application
economics with rigorous mathematical foundations. However, to economics since the 1980s.
problems started with attempts at proving two other key Second, Marshalls partial equilibrium remained in the
properties of equilibrium namely, stability and uniqueness. shadow for a while, largely due to a devastating critique from
The question of stability was meant to ensure that after an Piero Sraffa (1925) who questioned its logical consistency; But
exogenous shock, the market mechanism is capable of gener- it did not entirely disappear. The static supply-and-demand
ating endogenous forces that bring it back to equilibrium; if diagram was used in some applied studies, while the
equilibrium exists but the market cannot nd it, then argu- dynamic conception of sequential transactions between pairs
ments for free markets are harder to make. In addition, if of buyers and sellers, underdeveloped in Marshalls own time,
uniqueness is not guaranteed, it is unclear where an adjustment was rened with the help of novel, nonmathematical tech-
process might drive the system after a shock; besides, some niques. It underpinned the pioneering laboratory experiments
equilibriums may be unstable. It became soon clear, though, on markets that were implemented by Edward Chamberlin
that formal proofs of stability and uniqueness could be ob- (1948) and Nobel Prize Vernon L. Smith (1962). Although
tained only under excessively restrictive, unrealistic assump- experimental research remained a tiny niche within economics
tions. Critics stressed that these results reveal that with all its for long, it kept alive the Marshallian approach, in its dynamic
mathematical underpinnings, general equilibrium theory did connotation. Partial equilibrium experimental markets gained
not truly succeed in improving knowledge of how the market renewed interest in the 1990s, and the properties of the
mechanism works and how prices adjust in response to varia- exchange dynamics that they generate are sometimes referred
tions of supply-and-demand conditions (Kirman, 1989; Ingrao to in the literature as Marshallian dynamics (Friedman and
and Israel, 1990). Despite these shortcomings, general equi- Rust, 1993).
librium theory remained central for long, and is still in the core Interestingly, the rst experimental markets inspired by
of economists education; the publication in 1995 of a cele- Marshalls dynamic orientation were being devised at the same
brated graduate textbook by Mas-Colell et al. (1995) time in which set-theoretical mathematical techniques were
condensed and systematized the essence of the knowledge being implemented to model Walrasian systems. These tools
available at the highest level. were rudimentary at the beginning (Chamberlin simply relied
At this point, the consolidation of the microeconomic on his students and a blackboard to perform his market
paradigm founded on constrained optimization of the indi- experiment), but they became more sophisticated over time
vidual economic agent and the general equilibrium of all with the increased availability of software for computer-based
336 Microeconomics, History of

experiments, and are thriving today. They embody a view of price-inelastic side faces a high mark-up (Rochet and Tirole,
economics that gives less weight to the logical rigor of 2003, 2006). Research in this area is booming and top
formalization than to the theorys t with empirical data, microeconomic theorists are increasingly often consulted by, or
assessed with objective, well-dened, and replicable (labora- serve as chief economists of, major Internet companies.
tory-based) measures. These examples bring to light a second major tendency in
todays renewal, that for microeconomics to become
much more practically oriented and empirically informed. If
State of the Art and Future Perspectives nineteenth- and twentieth-century microeconomics left aside
quantication to adopt formalization (an approach that
The mainstream edice of neoclassical microeconomics erected purports to develop hypotheses and explanatory arguments
throughout the twentieth century is still largely in place, and is independently of, or prior to, confrontation with empirical
still the basis of most economics teaching; yet its scientic data), recent research uses empirical investigation methods to
underpinnings have undergone a process of profound test theories against data, thereby typifying a third and more
rethinking and revision. Both general equilibrium analysis and recent use of mathematics, namely validation and verication,
the individual optimization paradigm have come under re testing (formal) theory against (quantitative) data according
from critics of diverse obedience, including (but not limited to) to some version of the scientic method. To do so, new
behavioral economists. Research in general equilibrium theory sources of information are being exploited, notably
now experiences a slow but neat decline; and studies of the experimentation and analysis of survey and administrative
principles of individual decision making tend to follow the data with the help of increasingly sophisticated
behavioral rather than the neoclassical approach. microeconometric techniques. These techniques are now
Yet far from languishing, the eld is renewing itself at an recognized parts of the eld and attract an increasing number
unprecedented pace. The current tendency is to increasing of young economists.
diversication of approaches, methods, and topics, seemingly The future of microeconomics is, in sum, still open, with
reversing the trend toward unication of the different parts of promising developments in several subelds and still greater
microeconomics observed in the twentieth century. Against the potential for further success, and with access to an ever-wider
decline of once dominantgeneral equilibrium theory, and more diverse set of tools, techniques, theories, and
partial-equilibrium and experimental approaches are on the datasets. Yet the precise directions of its future developments
rise, and game theory has become the essential mathematical are still unclear many paths can be taken, and the major
structure and support of a broad range of economic analysis. A task of choosing which ones to take lies ahead of
case in point is market design the study of how to dene, microeconomists in the near future.
enforce, and monitor trading rules that maximize the efciency
of exchange, for example in auctions. Part of the motivation for See also: Behavioral Economics, History of; Capital: History of
these studies in the 1990s and early 2000s was the need to the Concept; Equilibrium: History of the Concept; Prospect
design trading mechanisms that would help governments to Theory.
privatize companies or state infrastructures, or to allocate
property rights the 3G auction in the United Kingdom being
regarded as one of the most successful examples (Binmore and
Bibliography
Klemperer, 2002). The design of an auction for the Bank of
Englands liquidity insurance operations is another case in
Barreto, H., 2012. Microeconomics: Past, Present, and Future. Speech at the 2012
point (Klemperer, 2010). These studies depart from the general Conference of the History of Economics Society: http://www.econrx.org/htdocs/
equilibrium tradition by, rst, using insight from game theory hes/barreto_microeconomics_past_present_future.pdf (accessed 01.09.13.).
to highlight the importance of trading institutions to yield Becker, G.S., 1992. The economic way of looking at life. Journal of Political Economy
socially desirable outcomes, instead of abstracting them away; 101 (3), 383409.
Binmore, K., Klemperer, P., 2002. The biggest auction ever: the sale of the British 3G
and second, by concentrating on single markets rather than
telecom licences. Economic Journal, 7496.
global interdependencies Marshalls partial equilibrium Chamberlin, E.H., 1948. An experimental imperfect market. Journal of Political
perspective. Economy 56 (2), 95108.
Partial equilibrium approaches also underlie a growing Debreu, G., 1984. Economic theory in the mathematical mode. American Economic
body of research on Internet markets, especially with the study Review 74 (3), 267278.
Friedman, D., Rust, J. (Eds.), 1993. The Double Auction Market: Institutions, Theories,
of so-called two-sided markets. This expression designates and Evidence. AddisonWesley, Reading, MA.
markets in which two different sets of agents interact through Frisch, R., 1933. Propagation problems and impulse problems in dynamic economics.
an intermediary or platform, and the decisions of each set of In: Economic Essays in Honor of Gustav Cassel. George Allen and Unwin, Ltd,
agents affect the outcomes of the other set of agents, typically London.
Hutchison, T.W., 1988. Before Adam Smith: The Emergence of Political Economy
through an externality (Rysman, 2009). Internet and media
16621776. Blackwell, Oxford, UK.
companies operating between advertisers and consumers are Ingrao, B., Israel, G., 1990. The Invisible Hand: Economic Equilibrium in the History of
a typical example, along with the payment card industry Science. MIT Press, Cambridge.
(between merchants and customers). Pricing is usually asym- Jevons, W.S., 1965. The Theory of Political Economy. Kelley, New York (Original work
metric, and depends on the price sensitivity the elasticity published 1871).
Kahneman, D., Tversky, A., 1979. Prospect theory: an analysis of decisions under risk.
of demand of each side; it often turns out that one side Econometrica 47, 313327.
does not pay, or is even rewarded for using a service (with cash- Keynes, J.M., 1936. The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money.
back for credit card use for example), while the other, more Macmillan, London.
Microeconomics, History of 337

Kirman, A.P., 1989. The intrinsic limits of modern economic theory: the emperor has Rochet, J.C., Tirole, J., 2006. Two-sided markets: a progress report. The RAND
no clothes. Economic Journal 99 (395), 126139. Journal of Economics 35 (3), 645667.
Klemperer, P., 2010. The product-mix auction: a new auction design for differentiated Rysman, M., 2009. The economics of two-sided markets. Journal of Economic
goods. Journal of the European Economic Association 8, 526536. Perspectives 23 (3), 125143.
Levy, D.M., 2001. How the Dismal Science Got Its Name: Classical Economics and the Samuelson, P., 1938. A note on the pure theory of consumers behavior. Economica 5,
Ur-text of Racial Politics. University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor, MI. 6171.
Mas-Colell, A., Whinston, M., Green, J., 1995. Microeconomic Theory. Oxford Smith, A., 1981. In: Campbell, R.H., Skinner, A.S. (Eds.), An Inquiry into the Nature
University Press, Oxford. and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, 2 vols. Liberty Fund, Indianapolis, IN (Original
Morgenstern, O., von Neumann, J., 1944. Theory of Games and Economic Behaviour. work published 1776).
Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ. Smith, V.L., 1962. An experimental study of competitive market behaviour. Journal of
Peart, S.J., Levy, D.M., 2005. The Vanity of the Philosopher: From Equality to Political Economy 70 (2), 111137.
Hierarchy in Post-classical Economics. University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor, MI. Sraffa, P., 1925. Sulle relazioni fra costo e quantit prodotta. Annali di economia 2,
Ricardo, D., 2004. In: Sraffa, P., Dobb, M. (Eds.), On the Principles of Political 277328.
Economy and Taxation. Liberty Fund, Indianapolis, IN (Original work pub- Walras, L., 1977. Elements of Pure Economics: Or the Theory of Social Wealth
lished 1817). (W. Jaff, Trans.). A. M. Kelley, Faireld, NJ (Original work published 1874).
Rochet, J.C., Tirole, J., 2003. Platform competition in two-sided markets. Journal of Weintraub, E.R., 2002. How Economics Became a Mathematical Science. Duke
the European Economic Association 1 (4), 9901029. University Press, Durham, NC.

Anda mungkin juga menyukai