Anda di halaman 1dari 24

Chapter 16: Capital Structure Some Basic

Concepts
The Capital-Structure Question and The Pie Theory
Maximizing Firm Value versus Maximizing
Stockholder Interests
Financial Leverage and Firm Value: An Example
Modigliani and Miller: Proposition II (No Taxes)
Taxes
Summary and Conclusions
16.1 The Capital-Structure Question and The Pie Theory

The value of a firm is defined to be the sum of the


value of the firms debt and the firms equity.
V=B+S

If the goal of the


management of the firm is to
make the firm as valuable as S B
possible, then the firm should
pick the debt-equity ratio that
makes the pie as big as
possible.
Value of the Firm
16.2 The Capital-Structure Question
There are really two important questions:
1. Why should the stockholders care about
maximizing firm value? Perhaps they should be
interested in strategies that maximize shareholder
value.
2. What is the ratio of debt-to-equity that maximizes
the shareholders value?

As it turns out, changes in capital structure benefit the


stockholders if and only if the value of the firm
increases.
16.3 Financial Leverage, EPS, and ROE

Consider an all-equity firm that is considering going into


debt. (Maybe some of the original shareholders want to cash
out.)
Current Proposed
Assets $20,000 $20,000
Debt $0 $8,000
Equity $20,000 $12,000
Debt/Equity ratio 0.00 2/3
Interest rate n/a 8%
Shares outstanding 400 240
Share price $50 $50
16.4 EPS and ROE Under Current Capital
Structure

Recession Expected Expansion


EBIT $1,000 $2,000 $3,000
Interest 0 0 0
Net income $1,000 $2,000 $3,000
EPS $2.50 $5.00 $7.50
ROA 5% 10% 15%
ROE 5% 10% 15%

Current Shares Outstanding = 400 shares


16.5 EPS and ROE Under Proposed Capital
Structure

Recession Expected Expansion


EBIT $1,000 $2,000 $3,000
Interest 640 640 640
Net income $360 $1,360 $2,360
EPS $1.50 $5.67 $9.83
ROA 5% 10% 15%
ROE 3% 11% 20%

Proposed Shares Outstanding = 240 shares


16.6 EPS and ROE Under Both Capital
Structures
All-Equity
Recession Expected Expansion
EBIT $1,000 $2,000 $3,000
Interest 0 0 0
Net income $1,000 $2,000 $3,000
EPS $2.50 $5.00 $7.50
ROA 5% 10% 15%
ROE 5% 10% 15%
Current Shares Outstanding = 400 shares

Levered
Recession Expected Expansion
EBIT $1,000 $2,000 $3,000
Interest 640 640 640
Net income $360 $1,360 $2,360
EPS $1.50 $5.67 $9.83
ROA 5% 10% 15%
ROE 3% 11% 20%

Proposed Shares Outstanding = 240 shares


16.7 Assumptions of the Modigliani-Miller
Model
Homogeneous Expectations
Homogeneous Business Risk Classes
Perpetual Cash Flows
Perfect Capital Markets:
Perfect competition
Firms and investors can borrow/lend at the same rate
Equal access to all relevant information
No transaction costs
No taxes
16.8 Homemade Leverage: An Example
Recession Expected Expansion
EPS of Unlevered Firm $2.50 $5.00 $7.50

Earnings for 40 shares $100 $200 $300


Less interest on $800 (8%) $64 $64 $64
Net Profits $36 $136 $236
ROE (Net Profits / $1,200) 3% 11% 20%

We are buying 40 shares of a $50 stock on margin. We get the


same ROE as if we bought into a levered firm.
Our personal debt equity ratio is: B $800 2
= =
S $1,200 3
16.9 Homemade Unleverage: An Example
Recession Expected Expansion
EPS of Levered Firm $1.50 $5.67 $9.83

Earnings for 24 shares $36 $136 $236


Plus interest on $800 (8%) $64 $64 $64
Net Profits $100 $200 $300
ROE (Net Profits / $2,000) 5% 10% 15%

Buying 24 shares of an other-wise identical levered firm along


with the some of the firms debt gets us to the ROE of the
unlevered firm.
This is the fundamental insight of M&M
16.10 The MM Propositions I & II (No
Taxes)
Proposition I
Firm value is not affected by leverage
VL = VU
Proposition II
Leverage increases the risk and return to stockholders
rs = r0 + (B / SL) (r0 - rB)
rB is the interest rate (cost of debt)
rs is the return on (levered) equity (cost of equity)
r0 is the return on unlevered equity (cost of capital)
B is the value of debt
SL is the value of levered equity
16.11 The MM Proposition I (No Taxes)
The derivation is straightforward:
Shareholders in a levered firm receive Bondholders receive
EBIT rB B rB B
Thus, the total cash flow to all stakeholders is
( EBIT rB B ) + rB B
The present value of this stream of cash flows is VL
Clearly
( EBIT rB B ) + rB B = EBIT
The present value of this stream of cash flows is VU

VL = VU
16.12 The MM Proposition II (No Taxes)
The derivation is straightforward:
B S
rWACC = rB + rS Then set rWACC = r0
B+S B+S
B S B+S
rB + rS = r0 multiply both sides by
B+S B+S S
B+S B B+S S B+S
rB + rS = r0
S B+S S B+S S
B B+S
rB + rS = r0
S S

B B B
rB + rS = r0 + r0 rS = r0 + (r0 rB )
S S S
16.13 The Cost of Equity, the Cost of Debt, and
the Weighted Average Cost of Capital: MM
Proposition II with No Corporate Taxes
Cost of capital: r (%)

B
rS = r0 + (r0 rB )
SL

B S
r0 rWACC = rB + rS
B+S B+S

rB rB

Debt-to-equity Ratio B
S
16.14 Taxes
The MM Propositions I & II (with Corporate Taxes)
Proposition I (with Corporate Taxes)
Firm value increases with leverage
VL = VU + TC B
Proposition II (with Corporate Taxes)
Some of the increase in equity risk and return is offset by
interest tax shield
rS = r0 + (B/S)(1-TC)(r0 - rB)
rB is the interest rate (cost of debt)
rS is the return on equity (cost of equity)
r0 is the return on unlevered equity (cost of capital)
B is the value of debt
S is the value of levered equity
16.15 The MM Proposition I (Corp. Taxes)
Shareholders in a levered firm receive Bondholders receive
( EBIT rB B) (1 TC ) rB B
Thus, the total cash flow to all stakeholders is
( EBIT rB B ) (1 TC ) + rB B
The present value of this stream of cash flows is VL
Clearly ( EBIT rB B ) (1 TC ) + rB B =
= EBIT (1 TC ) rB B (1 TC ) + rB B
= EBIT (1 TC ) rB B + rB BTC + rB B
The present value of the first term is VU
The present value of the second term is TCB
VL = VU + TC B
16.16 The MM Proposition II (Corp. Taxes)
Start with M&M Proposition I with taxes: VL = VU + TC B
Since VL = S + B S + B = VU + TC B
VU = S + B(1 TC )
The cash flows from each side of the balance sheet must equal:
SrS + BrB = VU r0 + TC BrB
SrS + BrB = [ S + B (1 TC )]r0 + TC rB B
Divide both sides by S
B B B
rS + rB = [1 + (1 TC )]r0 + TC rB
S S S
B
Which quickly reduces to rS = r0 + (1 TC ) (r0 rB )
S
16.17The Effect of Financial Leverage on the
Cost of Debt and Equity Capital with Corporate
Taxes
Cost of capital: r B
(%)
rS = r0 + (r0 rB )
SL

B
rS = r0 + (1 TC ) (r0 rB )
SL

r0

B SL
rWACC = rB (1 TC ) + rS
B+SL B + SL
rB

Debt-to-equity
ratio (B/S)
16.18 Total Cash Flow to Investors Under
Each Capital Structure with Corp. Taxes
All-Equity
Recession Expected Expansion
EBIT $1,000 $2,000 $3,000
Interest 0 0 0
EBT $1,000 $2,000 $3,000
Taxes (Tc = 35% $350 $700 $1,050

Total Cash Flow to S/H $650 $1,300 $1,950

Levered
Recession Expected Expansion
EBIT $1,000 $2,000 $3,000
Interest ($8000 @ 8% ) 640 640 640
EBT $360 $1,360 $2,360
Taxes (Tc = 35%) $126 $476 $826
Total Cash Flow $234+640 $468+$640 $1,534+$640
(to both S/H & B/H): $874 $1,524 $2,174
EBIT(1-Tc)+TCrBB $650+$224 $1,300+$224 $1,950+$224
$874 $1,524 $2,174
16.19 Total Cash Flow to Investors Under
Each Capital Structure with Corp. Taxes

All-equity firm Levered firm

S G S G

The levered firm pays less in taxes than does the all-
equity firm.
Thus, the sum of the debt plus the equity of the levered
firm is greater than the equity of the unlevered firm.
16.20 Total Cash Flow to Investors Under
Each Capital Structure with Corp. Taxes

All-equity firm Levered firm

S G S G

The sum of the debt plus the equity of the levered firm is
greater than the equity of the unlevered firm.
This is how cutting the pie differently can make the pie
larger: the government takes a smaller slice of the pie!
16.21 Summary: No Taxes
In a world of no taxes, the value of the firm is unaffected by
capital structure.
This is M&M Proposition I:
VL = VU
Prop I holds because shareholders can achieve any pattern of
payouts they desire with homemade leverage.

In a world of no taxes, M&M Proposition II states that


leverage increases the risk and return to stockholders

B
rS = r0 + (r0 rB )
SL
16.22 Summary: Taxes
In a world of taxes, but no bankruptcy costs, the value of the
firm increases with leverage.
This is M&M Proposition I:
VL = VU + TC B
Prop I holds because shareholders can achieve any pattern of
payouts they desire with homemade leverage.

In a world of taxes, M&M Proposition II states that leverage


increases the risk and return to stockholders.

B
rS = r0 + (1 TC ) (r0 rB )
SL
16.23 Prospectus: Bankruptcy Costs
So far, we have seen M&M suggest that financial
leverage does not matter, or imply that taxes cause
the optimal financial structure to be 100% debt.
In the real world, most executives do not like a
capital structure of 100% debt because that is a state
known as bankruptcy.
In the next chapter we will introduce the notion of a
limit on the use of debt: financial distress.
The important use of this chapter is to get
comfortable with M&M algebra.

Anda mungkin juga menyukai