Anda di halaman 1dari 9

Canadian Water Resources Journal

ISSN: 0701-1784 (Print) 1918-1817 (Online) Journal homepage: http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/tcwr20

The Value of Water as a Commodity

Bruce Mitchell

To cite this article: Bruce Mitchell (1984) The Value of Water as a Commodity , Canadian Water
Resources Journal, 9:2, 30-37, DOI: 10.4296/cwrj0902030

To link to this article: https://doi.org/10.4296/cwrj0902030

Published online: 23 Jan 2013.

Submit your article to this journal

Article views: 1503

View related articles

Citing articles: 6 View citing articles

Full Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at


http://www.tandfonline.com/action/journalInformation?journalCode=tcwr20
The Value of Water as a Commodity
Bruce Mitchelll

Abstract:
North Amencan society has traditionally undervalued water as a commodity. This
policy has led to wastefuland inefficient use, as wellas difficulties in determining
compensation when third parties are negatively afiected. A variety of methods exist
to place a value on water. None are perfect. However, bargaining has been used to
establish the intrinsic value of water and rllustrates clearly that an in-source value
can be established.
lf water were given a more realistic value, an rncentive would be provided for
more efficienl use. In addition, the traditional approach of supply management
could be complemenled with demand management practices. In combination,
these straleoies could lead to a more rational alloCation and use Of water.
Economic efficiency is only one criterion deserving attention. However, il other
criteria are to be used, society should be aware of the ineff icrencies that are being
accepted. Only in that way can reasonable trade-ofts and compromises be
reacneo.

Rdsume.
Notre soci6t6 nord-am6ricaine a traditionnellement sous-estim6 la valeur mar-
chande de l'eau. Cet 6tat d'esprit s'est traduit par une mauvaise utilisation, voire le
gaspillage, de cet6l6menl, ainsi que pardes difficult6s au niveau de l'estimation
des compensations lorsque des tiers sont l6s6s. llexiste diverses m6thodes aiin
d'estimer la valeur de I'eau, bien qu'aucune ne soit id6ale. Cependant, c'esl par le
marchandage qu'on 6tablit la valeur intrinsbque de I'eau et I'on sait donc que
I'estrmation est possible.
En accordant une valeur plus r6aliste qu gaspillage, on encouragerait une
utilisation plus efficace de I'eau. De plus, l'approche tradrtionnelle de gestion de
I'ollre pourrait 6tre compl6t6e par une gestion de la demande. L'association de ces
deux proc6d6s pourrait conduire d une r6partition et d une utilisation plus
rationnelles de I'ea-.
Un bon fonctionnement 6conomique n'est que I'un des critbres qui doivent 6tre
pris en consid6ration. Cependant, si d'autres critbres sont utilis6s, notre soci6t6
devrait se rendre compte des insuff isances qui sont couramment admises. Ce n'est
que de cette fagon que des 6changes et des compromis acceptables seront
effectu6s.
lntroduction generally has not treated water as a valued
The concept that water as a commodity has commodity. Indeed, as Environment Canada
value is not new. In 1 966, the Royal Society oI (1 983, 1 0) reported, "traditionally, water has
Canada designated water resources as the been considered a free good, and charges for
main theme for its annual meeting in Sher- its use have been related to the costs of
brooke, Quebec. Dolman (1 967, x) wrote that treatment prior to use, distribution and pol-
"Complacent attitudes about water resources lution abatement. In contrast to most other
cannot be justified anywhere today, for most natural resources, no commodity charge js
parts of the world are either threatened by or attached to water itself".
are already suffering from inadequate re- To illustrate, consider some water con-
serves of clean fresh water. . .". sumption levels. An American study indicated
Despite this longstanding recognition of that the average person in the United States
the value of water, North American societv uses 300 to 380 litres of water per day for
drinking and in-home use (Dewane and
Holthusen, 1982, S-3). Figures for Canadian
rDeparlmenl of Geography, University of consumption levels are similar. lf a price per
Waterloo, Waterloo, Ontario. litre srmilar to gasoline (48 cents/litre) were

30 Canadian Water Resources Journal / Vol. 9, No. 2,1984


used to price water, the cost wou ld be $1 45 to instance they discovered a statement in a
$1 B0 fora one day supply of water Ior each Canada-United States University Seminar
person io each household. These figures (1973, 1 1 ) addressing the management of the
suggest that the real value of water is sub- Great Lakes in which itwas stated that: "There
stantial reiative to a commodity such as gas- are a number of common f actors lnat account
oline which most of us rely upon every day. for our inability to respond more effectivelyto
One wonders if we would have the "com- the challenge to managing not only our water
placent attitude" towards water which was and land resources, but other social prob-
mentioned by Dolman if water were priced to lems as well. A listing of a few of the more
reflect its actual value. significant factors affecting resource man-
The consequences of undervaluing water agement include: the diffused public interest;
as a commodity have been significant and differing views about national priorities; in-
deserve more altention. As Bocking (1972,ix) adequate legislation and enforcement; spe-
commented: "The whole field of water de- cral interest politics; fragmentation of respon-
velopment, long viewed as the embodimentof sibilities within and among governments;
man's mastery over nature for the good ot organizational iealousies; and lack of under-
society. turned out to be rargely 2 5l6ry of standing of man-environment relationships "
political manipulation of mind-boggling pro- The scholars are intrigued at how complex
portions, Amazing engineering work is fre- ano cumbersome water management had
quently lustif ied by a strange kind of economics become by the early 19BO's. The number of
that is remarkable for its lack of relationship to inter-related variables i nf uencing water man-
I

reality." Continuing, Bocking (1 972, B9) ob- agement decisions was large, emphasizing
served that a Derson ". . . with even a modest that it would be unrealistic to expect con-
understanding of modern economlc thought centration upon a single factor to resolve
must expect to feel sometlring like Alice in problems, Even if water as commodity were
Wonderland as he tries to find logical eco- given greater value, they agreed that other
nomic procedures underlytng many of our aspects would need attention if improved
great water projects of both past and future" management were to be realized.
This paper witl examine 11 ) the background A major dilemma for the scholars was the
against which to consider the value of water contradictory evidence they found regarding
as a commodity, (2) the rationale for estab- the time perspective used in water manage-
lishing a more realistic value for water, (3) ment. On the one hand, they noted that in
alternative approaches for identifying a value Naisbitt's (1 984, B1 -101\ Megatrends one oi
for water, and (4) the general implications of ten basic patterns identif ied in the 1 980's was
an increased value for water management that we are restructuring f rom a society run by
and development stralegies. sho1Lterm consideratrons and rewards in
Since the wisdom of hindsight is often tavourof dealing with things in a much Ionger-
more profound than the wrsdom of foresight, term time frame" (Naisbitt, 1984, xxii) The
to realize these four obiectives let us ioin in the scholars were impressed and encouraged by
year 2010, when a group of scholars are the suggestion of such a general trend in
meeting as part of an ongoing review of the North American society, On the other hand,
evolution of water management stralegies. when they'ooked for evidence of such a trend
They already have held several such meets in water management, they could find rela-
ings, and at this one are focusing upon the tively little to verify its existence. They spec-
major events and decisions of the 1 970's and u lated as to whether the Iow value assigned to
1 980's. We join them as they are reviewing the water contributed to the persistence of short-
general background for water management term thinking as well as a reliance upon a
in the 1 970's and 1980's. relatively narrow range of strategies.
Despite the large number of issues de-
Contextforwater management in the serving analysis, the scholars decided to
197O's and 198O's concentrate upon the attitudes and ap-
The scholars are surprised at several things proaches towards wateras a commodity. As a
First, they are amazed at the number of ob- start, they reviewed the prevailing ideas con-
stacles frustraling attempts to improve water cerning the rationale for establishing a value
resource management. Second, they are in- for water.
trigued that most of the obstacles have been
identified and recognized but that relatively Establishing A Value For Water
little has been done to resolve them. For In reviewing the literature for the 1 970's and

Revue Canadienne des,gessources en Eau / Vol. 9, No. 2, 1984 31


the 1980's, the scholars identified two ideas taxes down by subsidizing other municipal
which had been offered to support arguments services from the water revenues. However,
that the value of water should be rncreased. from the viewpoint of encouraging efficient
The points were efficiency and externalities. water use, this practice has disadvanlages.
Regarding efficiency, Environment Can- As Gill and Leitch (1 983,21) remarked: "... the
ada (1983, 10) noted that economic prin- traditional approach to rate setting has re-
ciples indicate that when a good is under- sulted in improper price signals being sent to
valued it tends to be overused. A most strikinq consumers, Rate design must translate ac-
example of the implications of this for rJ tual water/sewer costs into prices. These
source management was described by Hardin prices... are signals sent to consumers... Onlv
(1 968. 1 2441 regarding the 'tragedy
of the with proper pricing can consumers make
commons", Hardin described a common oas- economically efficient use of these resources.',
ture in Britain which became overgrazed as a The "irratronal muddle" regarding water
result of each herdsman only considering pricing also applies to agricultural use, As
himself and steadily adding more animals to Tate (1 984, 4) explained: " ln agriculture, mas-
the pasture. The end result was ruin for all as sive subsid jes lead to over-expansion of acre-
the common pasture became destroved age, the growing of crops which cou ld be best
through overuse, supplied more cheaply in other areas or by
Tate 984, 3-4) observed that oolicv mak-
(1 other areas, and ultimately to "demands,, for
ers have allowed water to be unpriced, or at more water, reallocation of water from per-
least underpriced. With water pricing being in 'haps higher valued users and finallv to
aoi-
what he called an "irrational muddle,,, ihe tation lor water transfers. lrrigation is a lric-ky
implications are overuse. In Tate's (j 984, 4) and potentially explosive topic to address in
words. 'ln municipatities average water use this manner in some parts of the country.
is artif icially high. H igh system peaking is also "Regional development" is frequenily put
experienced. . . . Exaggerated dernands vyiil forth to meet this criticism. Yet, . . . we must
Inevitably cause watei systems tc be over- !'ecognize that the end product of agriculture
built, This leads to an unnecessariiv hioh is f ood, not irrigated land, and that perhaps we
burden on public treasuries. ln the ireantrm'e. si.rould do analyses aimed at the cheapest
abundant (and cheap) watei. ieads to arti- pcssible production, not at massively funded
flcially high demands. and the cii.cie stans |!'i-i gation sch emes,"
again." To substantiate these arguments, Tate
Experience in several areas ;iiusirates the ir 984, 3) indicated that irrigation throughout
effect of undervaluing water. Edmonron has i.,iortn America receives heavy subsidies. To
metered all residential water lsers, anc ccn- i iusirate. in Alberta the government policy is
sumes half as much water as Oalgar-,-. Twc tc subsidize irrigation up1o75o/o to 85026 of the
pflcrng systems exist in Calgary for resi- ccst. and in the United States, irrigation sub-
dences: a flat rate and a declining biock rate sicjies often are higher (Bocking, 1972, 102:
based upon metering. The unmetered i.esr Hcwe and Easter, 1971, 168-171). For ex-
dences use 46 percent more water than ampie, MacGregor(1 982, S-20) reported that
metered users (Thompson, j 983, 52). Fur.- irrigators utilizing water from U.S. Water and
thermore. Gysi (1981) has calculated thal ir Power Resources Service projects pay from
Calgary the savings due to metering were $35 to$1 35 less peracreperyearthan itcosts
approximately 18,200 litres oer month oer to provide water to them. Confirming the low
household. Much of this saving resulted f rom value placed on irrigation water in the United
the reduction of use in peak periods as a States, Pope(1 983 S-25) has notedthatsince
result of people being sensrlive to the value of the 1902 Bureau of Reclamation Act, "water
water when it is metered and charged for on for irrigation has been provided at one-tenth
the basis of actual use (Furst, Robinson and or less of real cost, or pennies per thousand
Benninger, 1 981). gallons". lt was on this type of evidence that
In Ontario, Gilland Leitch (1 983) reviewed Armitage (1983, S-1 B) concluded that in the
the water and sewer rates in the Reqional United States "politics and not economics
Municipality ol Durham. They docum-ented has been the driving force behind national
that water pricing policies were desjgned to water policy. In the West, federal reclamation
cover water system operations. In addition, a policy gave federal subsidies to develop
politicaldecision had been taken to transfer a agriculture and promote settlement".
portion of water system revenues to general Tate, Reynolds and Dossett(1 984,3) high-
funds. This procedure helps to keep general lighted some of the problems that emerge

32 Canadian Water Resources Journal / Vol. g, No. 2,1984


from undervaluing water as a commodity. Approaches To Placing A Value
Their comments apply to Canada, but the On Water
remarks have validity when applied to the The scholars noted that pricing waterto give it
United States as well. In their words: ", .. it is a value was perceived to be fraught with
apparent that water pricing . . . has failed to act problems. As Armitage (1 983 S-1 B) had re-
as an Incentive for water conservation oi as a marked: "Placing avalue on water is hardlyan
means of encouraging sociallyoptimal levels easy task. All life forms depend upon it
of supply. Ralher water use has traditionally Putting a dollar f igure on the value of ensuring
been viewed as cost-free, with charges being an adequate and safe supply of water raises
levied to recover system construction and ethical and political questions . . . . For better
operating costs. The result has often been the and for worse, water programs developed for
over-building of systems, waste ol public reasons far removed from economic effr
funds and sub-optimal water use practices." ciency." For such reasons, water usually has
The ser:nnd cnn.trnt whiCh the scholars been treated as a free good (DeWane and
identified was that of externalities. In the Holthusen, 1982, S-4; Schroeder, 1 983, S-5;
jargon of economists, "an externality occurs Tate, 1 984, 3). As a result, the value of water
when the action of an individual or group of has been determined with reference to the
individuals has economic consequences costs of pumping, treatment and distribution.
which are not priced bythe market" (Hartman The water itsell, unlike oil, minerals, fish,
and Seastone, 1970, 2). In addition to illus- timberorotherresources, was given no intrin-
trating inetficiency, Hardin's story about the sic value. Indeed, as illustrated previously by
"tragedy of the commons" also is an example the significant subsidies given to agricultural
regardrng externalities, ln other words, each water users, consumers often have not even
herdsman did not consider the consequen- paid the full cost of delivering water to them.
ces for the larger group. And, as seen, evenlu- Some consequences of this approach have
ally the entrre commons was destroyed. been ineff icient use, over-building of supply
Similar issues and concerns may arise systems, and subsidies from some sectors in
when water resources are undervalued. Thus, society to other sectors.
an area which is facing shortages of water Although no perfect mechanism was avaiF
may look to areas of water surplus as sources able for establishing a value for water, the
of supply. However, while the receivrng area scholars discovered that several alternatives
will realize many direct and indirect benefits had been ideniified. The first procedure in-
f rom the transfer of water, the source area and volved assigning value with regard to the cost
the area through which the water is trans- of the "next best alterrrative". This approach
ferred may experience most of the direct and would reflect the cost of obtaining and de-
indirect costs. When water is undervalued or livering alternative supplies (DeWane and
not given any inherent value, there is diff iculty Holthusen. 1 982, S-1 1). EnvironmentCanada
in realizing equitable compensation for the (1983, 10) has illustrated how this procedure
areas incurring the costs. In contrast. des- could be applied to hydroelectric production
ig nation of a value for water provides a mech- for which water is a primary input. lf Canada's
anism for f inancial comoensation or for some hydroelectric production in 1980 had had to
comoarable comoensation in kind. be produced in oiFiired plants, the expense
The scholars concluded from their ex- incurred for fuel alone would have ranged
amination of prevailing ideas in the 1970's between $9 billion and $1 2 billion depending
and 1 980's that at least some ind ividuals were upon whether domestic or world oil prices
well aware of the serious problems being were utilized, Calculating the value ol non-
created through conscious decisions to un- withdrawal uses (boating, fishing) presents
dervalue water. In brief, the two major prob- numerous difficulfies, but ball park figures
lems were ineificient use of water and nega- can be generated for them as well.
tive impacts for third parties. lt seemed to The second procedure established value
them that manyof those problems could be at with reference to the value added to the
least partially resolved if a higher value were consume/s products or saiisfaction. Using
given to water. For that to occur, however, a agriculture as an example, rhe difference in
method to value water was required. As a value of agricultural output with and without
result, they decided to examine the alternative irrigation in an area could be calculated.
ways which were used or which might have Recreation also could be handled in this way,
been used to price water. Environment Canada (1 983, 1 0) reported that
data showed that during 1 981 Canada had

Revue Canadienne des Fessources en Eau / Vol. 9, No. 2' 1 984 JJ


$21 0 billion in lamily income. About 7 percenl the construction of these reservoirs? ... While
ol that was spent on recreatron, and about 75 the loss at 530,000 acres (214,500 hectares)
percent of recreation was water-onented. On of land in South Dakota is providing sub-
that basis, $1 1 billion would have been soenl stantial navigation, flood control and power
on wateroriented recreatron in 1 980. This benefits for our neighboring states, South
procedure has a majorf law in that the derived Dakota is receiving little or no benefit in a
ligures reflect the costs of all factors of pro- substantial economic sense from the con-
duction or salisfaction. As a result, the value of struction of the reservoirs" (Smith, no date).
water is overstated. Nevertheless, both "value The bargaining for the water began when
added" and "next best alternative" approach- Energy Transportation Systems, Inc. (ETSI)
es help to emphasize the substantial value of recognized that if coal could betransported in
waler as a commodlty. The actual figures will a slurryform the firm would realize substantial
always be open to debate, but the relative savings. The reason centered upon the capF
magnitude of the value is suggested and tal intensive nature of coal slurry pipelines
could be used for discussing compensation relative to railroad transportation, ETSI cal-
when negative externalities arise. culated that 70 percent of the operating costs
A third procedure wou ld involve assigning lor a coal slurry pipeline are fixed, leaving only
an explicit value to water belore it is de 30 percent as variable and therefore subject
veloped, as is done with oil, timber or other to inflation. In contrast, ETSI estimated that85
resources. The cost to the user would then percent of the operating cosls for ratlroads
ref lectthe intrinsicvaiue of water plus the cost are variable and subject to inflation. During a
of pumping, trealing, and distnbuting. Eco- period of inflation, the form of transportation
nomists do not have any magic formula to with the highest ratio of fixed costs has a
establish the in-source value of water, but a compelitive advantage. ETSI's calculations
timehonoured procedure is available: bar showed that with only a 5 percent rate of
gaining between or among inlerested parties. inflation, the cumulative savings in operating
Schroeder (1 983 S-3) has reminded us costs by using the coal slurry over a 30 year
that using this procedure South Dakota "has period would be $32 billion (Smith, no date).
put a price on water at the source - a pre Against this background, the bargaining
viously unheard-of precedenl . . .". The agree began between South Dakota and ETSI and
ment to which Schroeder referred was with a carried on over a period of four or five years.
private corporation to provide 1.98 cubic Neufeld (1 982, 127) described the bargain-
metres per second (70 cubic ieet per second ing process in thelollowing manner "Ali I can
or 50,000 acre-feet o1 water per year) of say about the economics of interbasin trans-
Missouri Riv€rwater, In return for$1.4 billion fer with respect to ETSI is that we sat down at
in payment over a 50 year agr€ement, water the bargaining table with those people and
lrom the Missouri Fliver in South Dakota will we had certain economic and political cards
be available to be piped to Wyoming, a dis- in our hands and they had certain economic
tance of 445 kilometres where it would be and political cards in therr hand. Every time
mixed with pulverized coal to make a slurry. they made an offer we just kept saying "no"
The coal slurry then would be piped 2,66b until we were afraid that they were going to
kilometres to markets in Oklahoma, Arkansas walk away from the table and then we said
and Louisiana (Morrisette, 1983 $29). "yes". lt was just a very straight business Ceal
How was the value oJ the water estab- with each side holding certain advantages
lished? South Dakota noted that six reservoirs over the other."
had been builtonthe mainstem oJthe Missouri The end result was that ETSI obtained a 50
River, four ol which are located in South year agreement for a supply of water and
Dakota. The dams were multiple purpose in South Dakota will receive indexed payments
design, serving navigation, flood control, ir- which could total $.1 .4 billion over the life of
rigation, hydropower, industrial and recrea- the contract.
tional development. Most of these benefits Thus, the group of scholars concluded
were received by downstream states, even that bythe early 1 980's society had a number
though South Dakota gave up 214,500 hec- of procedures to place a value on water: (1)
tares of farmland when the reservoirs were next best alternative, (2) value added, (3)
created. As the Director of the Department of intrinsic or in-source value. None of these
Waler and Natural Resources in South Dakota procedures was perfect, but each moved
observed: "The question arises lrom South water away from being handled as a "free"
Dakota's standpoint Who is benefiting from good with the associated problems of in-

34 Canadian Water Resources Journal / Vol. 9, No. 2,1984


eff iciency and negative externalities. With this no publicized ribbon-cutting ceremonies for
in mind, the experts considered the impli- fixing pipes, roots, wiring and plumbing". In
cations of water as a"f ree" good or as a valued contrast, "large-scale diversion projects re-
commodity for water management and de- main politically fashionable" (Thomas, 1983,
velopment strategres. s-r0).
Neverlheless, the scholars were puzzled
I plications For Water Management
m that by the 1980's water managers had not
And Development learned more from the "energy crisis" of the
The scholars concluded that by the early 1970's. Shortfalls of energy supplies in the
19BO's amole evidence was available to doc- mid 1970's led to increase in prices and to
ument the numerous problems whtch were introduction of conservation measures. The
partially attributable to water being under- result was a drop in demand by the early
valued. Societywas often wastef ul in its use of 1 9BO s, and in some instances the creation ot

water, usually because there was little in- surpluses. While the demand for water is not
centive to improve efficiency. lt was this situ- as elastic or price sensitive as it is for energy'
ation which led DenUyl and Nickle (1 982, decreased use ol water could be expected if
124) Io conclude that scope existed for sub- more realistic pricing were introduceC with
stantial improvement in the elficiency of ir- other demand management strategtes (Tate,
rigation systems, especially in the American 1 984, 6).
West. Indeed they remarked thal "conserv- The scholars agreed that too often con-
ation of water, both in agriculture and other servation and development are wrongly per-
uses, has been set back by the relatively low ceived to be in opposition to one another. In
subsidized prices paid in the west". As a that regard, they supported the arguments of
result, they suggested that it ". . . was highly the International Union for Conservation of
unlikely that an interbasin transfer of water Natureand Natural Resources(1 980) thatthe
from the Great Lakes lor the purpose of goal shou ld be to use conservation to support
supplyin g irrigation water to the west could be long-term sustainable development. In that
justified by any economic criteria." sense, demand and supply management
The scholars also concluded that by the become complementary tools. lf water re
1 980's there was a good understanding of the sources are depleted, then Hardin's "tragedy
negative externalities associated with the of the commons" will be repeated and there
undervaluing of water. Thus, while the im- will not be a resource to develop and maniF
porting area could receive many benefits ulate.
from a water diversion, the exporting area The scholars concluded that in the 1 970's
could experience many costs. Using the and 1980's North American society had con-
Great Lakes as an example, changes in lake sciously created water management strate-
levels as a result o1 diversions could affect gies that led to wastefuland inefficient use of
hydropower generation, navigation and coast- water. However, those experts recognized
al zone interests (erosion and inundation that economic efficiency ls only one criterion
affects on shore property) (DeCooke et al, to consider in iudging alternatives. Society
1983, 1 1-121. ff those groups and interests might well decide to emphasize other as-
were to be compensated for negative im- pects, such as to promote certain kinds of
pacts, a realistic appraisal of the value of activity, or to benefit certain groups in pref-
water had to be established. Establishing erence to others, or to favour certain areas
such a value would not eliminate the extern- (Campbell, Pearse, Scott and Uzelac, 1974,
alities, but it would lacilitate compensation. 477). These are all legitimate objectives, but
Undervaluing water also contributed to a the scholars concluded that in pursuing
preoccupation with structural or technologF them, governments should be aware of the
cal manipulation of supply systems, rather economic inefficiency costs being incurred,
than combining a mix of strategies to manage especiallywhen third parties receive negative
demand and supply. Demand management tmpacts.
focuses upon reducing the quantities of water Castle (1 983) has confirmed that objec-
required by society through rational water tives other than economic efficiency have
pricing, irrigation canal lining, promotion of dominated water management His comments
industrial water recirculation, retrofitting ex- refer to the United States, but they also are
isting waterusing fixtures, and public edu- applicable to Canada. In his view: "Histor
cation (Tate and Reynolds, 1983, 1B). How- ically, many major water development pro'
ever, as Lang (1 983, 5-6) remarked, "There are iects in the United States were undertaken to

Revue Canadienne des Fessources en Eau / Vol. 9, No. 2, 1 984 35


provrde economic opportunity and to develop consin Coastal Management Council, Mil-
particular geographic areas. Water develog waukee. oo. 1 1 9-1 25.
ment became a wayof transferring income or
wealth from group to group and region to DeWane, M,L. and T.L. Holthusen. .]982.
"Water: The NewCurrenc/'.Journal of Fresh-
region, and efficient or economical use of
warer rarety was a central issue of water wafer. Special Report, Vol. 6 S-3-S.1 4.
development policy''(Casile 1 983, 59). Dolman, C.E. 1967. "lntroduction". In C.E.
Related to that conclusion he also re- Dolman, Editor, Water Resources of Canada.
marked that: , .. "research makes clear.. . that University of Toronto Press, Toronto pp ix-
water often becomes a convenient political xviii,
tool for doing something for one's constit:
uents. In a political sense, it really is income Environment Canada. 1983. Canada Water
rather than water that is being transferred,, Year Book 1981-1982. M inister of Suppty and
(Castle, 1 983, 63). Services Canada, Ottawa,
lf we are to understand the nature of such Furst, J., J. Robinson, and B. Benninger. 1 981 .
Income redistributions and the potential Preliminary Evaluation olExcess IJse Charge.
trade-offs or compromises, it is essential that Municipal Working Group on Water Conser-
we have better understanding of the actual vation Alternatives, Working Paper No. B,
value of water as a commodity. Whatever University of Waterloo, Waterloo, Or.rtario.
society identif ies as overall ob jectives, it is not
realistic to continue treating water as a free Gill, G,W. and A.W. Leitch. 1 983. Municipal
gooo. Water/Sewer Rate Design, Regional Muni-
cipality of Durham Case Study. Regional
Municipality of Durham, Whitby.
References Gysi, M. 1981. "The Cost of Peak Capacity
Watel'. Water Resources Bulletin. Vol. 1 7, No,
Armitage, A. 1983. "The Pricing ol Water: The 6, 956-961 .

New Economics". Journal of Freshwater.


Special Report, Vol. 7, S-1 B-S-20. Hardin, G. 1968. "The Tragedy of the Com-
mons . Sclence. Vol. 162 f)enemher nn
Bocking, R.C. I972. Canada's Water: For 1 243-1 248.
Sa/e? James Lewis and Samuel, Toronto.
Hartman, L.M. and D. Seastone. 1970. Water
Campbell, R.S., P.H, Pearse, A. Scott, and M. Transfers: Economrc Efficiency and Altern-
Uzelac. 1 974. "Water Management in Ontario: ative lnstitutions. Johns Hopkins press.
An Economic Evaluation of public policV', Baltimore.
Osgoode Hall LawJournai.Vol. l2, No.3.475-
526. Howe, C.W. and K.W, Easter.
1 971. lnterbasin
Transfers of Water: Economic /ssues and
Canada-United States University Seminar. lmpacts. Johns Hopkins Press, Baltimore.
1973. A Proposat for Improving the Man-
agement of the Great Lakes of the United International Union for Conservation of
Sfates and Canada, Department of Man- Nature and Natural Resources. 1980. World
Environment Studies, Universitv-of Waterloo, Conservation Strategy: Living Resource Con-
Waterloo, Ontario. servation for Sustainabte Development. ln-
ternational Union of Conservation of Nature
Castle, E.N. 1983, "Water Avaitability: The and Natural Resources, Gland, Switzerland.
Crisis of the Eighties". Canadian Water Re-
sources Journal. Vol. 8, No. 4, 57-66. Lang, M. 1983. "Water Management in a
Democracy: Understanding the lssue". Jour-
DeCooke, B.G,, J.W. Bulktey, and S.J. Wright. nal of Freshwafer. Special Report, Vol.7, 5-6-
1983. "Great Lakes Diversions: preliminary s-7.
Assessment of Economic lmpacts". paoer
Presented at the 36th Annual Conference ol MacGregor, |\/. 1982. "lrrigation Farming:
the Canadian Water Resources Association, Subsidizing Mother Nature". Journal of Fresh-
Saskatoon, June 21 -23. waler Special Report, Vol. 6, S-1 8-S-21 .

DenUyl, R.B. and P. Nickel. 19B2. "Economic Morrisette, M. 1983. "Looking for More or
Aspects of Inter-basin Water Transfers from Living with Less: The Interbasin Water lssue".
the G reat Lakes". lnThe lnterbasin Trcnsfer of Journal of Freshwater. Special Report, Vol. 7,
Water: The Great Lakes Connection. Wis- s-28-S-31.

36 Canadian Water Resources Journat / Vol. 9, No. 2, igB4


Naisbitt, J. 1 984, Megatrends. Warner Books, Tate, D.M. and P,J. Reynolds. 19B3. "Meeting
New York, the Demand f or I nd ustrial Water: I ntermed iate
Water Transfers" , Canadran Water Resources
Neufeld, W. 19B2. "The Economics of Selling
Journal. Vol. 8, No. 4, I 0-1 9.
Water: The South Dakota Perspeclrve . In lhe
lnterbasin Transler of Water: The Greal Lakes Tate, D.M., P.J. Reynolds, and P.A. Dossett.
Connection. Wisconsin Coastal Manage- '1
984. "The Role of Water Pricing in Canadian
ment Council, Milwaukee. Water Management". Unpublished Pape;
lnland Waters Directorate, Environment Can-
Opie, J, 1983. "Desalination: Tapping the ada. Ottawa.
Endless Supply". Journal of Freshwater,
Special Report, Vol. 7, S-25-S-27. Thomas, W.A. 1983. "Water Law: Facing a
New Reality", Journal of Freshwater. Special
Schroeder, L. 1982. ' lntroduction to Special
Report, Vol. 7,, S-8-S-1 O.
Report on Supplying the Demand: The Water
Management Challenge". Journal of Fresh- Thompson, D. 1983, "Water Allocation Sys-
wafer. Special Report, Vol, 7, S-3-S-5. tems and Their lmplications for Manage-
ment", ln. B, Sadler, EdiIor, Water Policy for
Smith, J.J. Allocation of Water in the Missouri
Western Canada: Ihe i ssues of the Eighties.
River Basin: South Dakota and the ETSI
University of Calgary Press, Calgary. pp, 46-
Expe r ien ce. Department of Water and N atural
64.
Resources, Pierre, South Dakota. n.d,
Viessman, W. 1983. "Cooperation or Crisis:
Tate, D.M. 1984. "Water Management in lnstitutions in Transition". Journal of Fresh-
Canada: A One-Armed Giant". Unpublished wafer. Special Report. Vol. 7, S-B-S.1 0.
Paper. Inland Waters Directorate, Environ-
ment Canada, Ottawa.

Revue Canadienne des Bessources en Eau / Vol. 9, No. 2, 1 984 JI

Anda mungkin juga menyukai