Anda di halaman 1dari 6

Global Food Security ∎ (∎∎∎∎) ∎∎∎–∎∎∎

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Global Food Security


journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/gfs

Growing advantage of large farms in Asia and its implications for


global food security
Keijiro Otsuka a,n, Yanyan Liu b, Futoshi Yamauchi c
a
National Graduate Institute for Policy Studies, Tokyo, Japan
b
International Food Policy Research Institute, Washington, DC, United States of America
c
World Bank, Washington, DC, USA

art ic l e i nf o a b s t r a c t

Article history: When the wage rate is low, a labour-intensive production method is chosen. Since it is costly to monitor
Received 5 November 2015 hired labourers in agriculture, small-scale farms dependent on family labour are more efficient than large
Accepted 6 March 2016 farms relying on hired labour. This leads to the inverse relationship between farm size and productivity, if
land markets do not reallocate land. When the wage rate increases, labour-saving and machine-using
production methods become efficient. If machinery and land are complementary and machines are in-
divisible to some extent, large-scale mechanized farms become more efficient, which tends to weaken
the inverse farm size-productivity relationship. This article argues that if small-scale farms continue to
dominate in the face of the increasing wage rate in Asia, many countries in this region will lose their
comparative advantage in agriculture.
& 2016 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.

1. Introduction observed (Otsuka, 2007).


Although small farms in Asia achieved higher productivity than
Since first observed in Russian agriculture (Chayanov, 1926/ their larger counterparts in the past, they are facing more and
1986), the inverse relationship between farm size and productivity more challenges as structural transformation has been occurring
has been widely observed in developing countries (for example, in most developing countries in Asia. In these countries, the rapid
Bardhan, 1973; Sen, 1975; Heltberg, 1998; Lipton, 2009; Hayami, growth of the non-farm sector has created more lucrative em-
2001, 2009). Such observations point to small farms' higher pro- ployment opportunities, which has resulted in a higher real wage
duction efficiency compared with large farms, which is caused by in both farm and nonfarm sectors. Coupled with technological
intensification of farming systems and the low cost of family la- advances in manufacturing industries, the price ratio of labour to
bour. Recently, such a relationship seems to have emerged in sub- machine use is increasing, which renders the substitution of la-
Saharan Africa, with the gradual intensification of farming systems bour by machine profitable. The rapidly growing machine rental
(Barrett et al., 2010; Carletto et al. 2013; Larson et al., 2014). markets in China and Vietnam represent a response to such trends
In order to operate large farms, hired labour must be employed, in recent decades (Liu et al., 2013; Zhang et al., 2011). As farming
whereas small farms mainly rely on family labour. Thus, the lower systems gradually change from labour-intensive to capital-in-
production efficiency of large-scale farms in Asia can be attributed tensive systems, the advantage of small farms relying on family
to the high monitoring cost of hired workers in spatially dispersed labour is declining, while large farms' advantages are enhanced by
agricultural environments (Feder, 1985; Hayami and Otsuka, 1993). the use of farm machinery. Indeed, large farms were more pro-
However, the higher production efficiency of small farms does not ductive than small farms in agriculturally advanced regions of
necessarily imply the existence of the inverse relationship because India, such as Punjab and Haryana, by the early 1980s (Jha and
land markets, if functioning effectively, will reallocate land from Rhodes, 1999; Jha et al., 2000). A more recent study by Foster and
large inefficient farms to small efficient farms, so that the in- Rosenzweig (2010) also finds that large farms have become more
efficiency associated with farm size will be eliminated. Indeed,
productive than small farms in India with the introduction of farm
land rental markets generally function effectively in Southeast
machinery as a response to rising labour costs. Cross-country
Asian countries because of the absence of distortive land reform
programs, so that the inverse relationship has seldom been

n
Corresponding author.

http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.gfs.2016.03.001
2211-9124/& 2016 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.

Please cite this article as: Otsuka, K., et al., Growing advantage of large farms in Asia and its implications for global food security. Global
Food Security (2016), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.gfs.2016.03.001i
2 K. Otsuka et al. / Global Food Security ∎ (∎∎∎∎) ∎∎∎–∎∎∎

4 2. Factors affecting optimum farm size


Average operational farm size (ha)

3
If one of three markets – land rental, land sale, or labour – is
perfectly competitive, an equally efficient allocation of resources
among farming households can be achieved in equilibrium.3 In
2 this case, land-labour ratios will be equalized among farms in all
three cases (Kevane, 1996). For instance, if labour markets work,
1 members of labour-abundant and land-scarce households will
work for land-abundant households. In contrast, if either land
sales or land rental markets work, labour-abundant households
0
will either purchase or rent in land from land-abundant house-
1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 holds. In practice, however, it is likely that labour and land sales
Year
markets do not function efficiently.
China Japan Large farmers employ hired labour because of the limited en-
Bangladesh India
dowment of family labour relative to owned land. According to
Indonesia Philippines
Thailand Feder (1985) and Eswaran and Kotwal (1986), hired wage la-
bourers do not work diligently without incurring high supervision
Fig. 1. Change in operational farm size in selected countries in Asia. costs by landowners, because fixed daily wages do not give strong
work incentives to hired labourers. While piece-rate labour con-
panel-data analyses of the impacts of farm size on productivity by tracts (for example, based on area ploughed and amount of pro-
Otsuka et al. (2013) also indicate the growing efficiency of large ducts harvested) are common, they may induce quality shirking, as
farms, where real wages are high. Thus, it seems reasonable to the quality of work is not amenable to easy supervision in spatially
hypothesize that larger farms are currently more efficient than dispersed agricultural environments. This is the case particularly
smaller farms in some parts of Asia.1 for the tasks that require care and judgment, such as land pre-
This article undertakes a comprehensive literature review in paration, fertilizer application, and water and pest control (Hayami
order to identify factors that explain the changing relative ad- and Otsuka, 1993). Furthermore, the supervision cost of hired la-
vantage of small vs. large farms. It is shown that the existing bour contracts is expected to increase more than proportionally
studies pay attention primarily to static effects of soil quality dif- with farm size. Imperfect supervision leads to inefficiency of large-
scale farm operations dependent on hired labour employment. To
ferences, measurement errors, and factor market imperfection.
avoid the high monitoring cost of hired labour, some landowners
Unlike our previous study which reports the changing relationship
may adopt labour-saving and machine-using production methods.
between farm size and crop yield in selected countries in Asia
This often involves machines that are not divisible into smaller
(Otsuka et al., 2016), this study emphasizes institutional changes scales, which tend to entail scale economies. However, such
responding to the increasing wage rate and growing advantage of technology choice is obviously costly in low-wage economies
larger farms, (e.g., development of machinery service markets and where labour is relatively cheap. Therefore, the high enforcement
consolidation of small farms by county governments in China). cost of hired labour will lead to the lower production efficiency of
Obviously, whether farm size increases in Asia is a serious is- large farms.4
sue. Fig. 1 shows changing operational farm size in seven selected It is well known that land sales markets are inactive in many
Asian countries: Bangladesh, India, Indonesia, Philippines, Thai- places. Binswanger and Rosenzweig (1986) argue that since land
land, China, and Japan. The average operational farm size was al- can be used as collateral for obtaining credit, the price of land
ready small in the 1970s, ranging from one hectare in Indonesia exceeds the present value of future agricultural profits accrued to
and Japan to three or four hectares in the Philippines and Thailand. land by the amount of benefit accrued from the collateral value.
It has declined in subsequent periods in all these countries except Thus, buyers of land cannot cover the cost of land purchases solely
from future agricultural profits. In order for land transactions to
in Japan, because of rapid population growth in rural areas. Farm
take place, buyers must have sufficient funds to purchase land.
size increased in Japan but it is far below the average farm size in
Land prices may be also higher than justified by their agricultural
high-income economies in Europe and North America where
returns if people expect land values to rise because of increasing
farms of more than 100 ha are common. If small farms continue to nonagricultural land demand and subsidy policies (Robison et al.,
dominate and become a major constraint on large-scale mechan- 1985; Brandao and Rezende, 1992; Gunjal et al., 1996). Moreover,
ization in high-wage Asian economies, the continent could be- some farmers regard their land as a family heirloom; something to
come a gigantic importer of food grains. This has already hap- be kept in the family and not traded.
pened in high-income economies in Asia, such as Japan, Taiwan, Thus, in practice, land rental through tenancy contracts is the
and South Korea (Otsuka, 2013).2 most common way of adjusting the allocation of land among rural
The next section reviews theoretical studies that explain the households with different factor endowments, given the relatively
small farm advantage and identifies critical conditions under less efficient functioning of land sales and labour market trans-
which small farms can be more efficient than large farms. In actions (Skoufias, 1995). However, land rental also entails trans-
Section 3, we review recent evidence on the increasing efficiency action costs associated with the search for contracting partners,
of large farms, mainly reported from Asian countries. In Section 4, negotiation of the terms and conditions, their monitoring, and
we conclude by drawing policy implications. sanctions against breach of contractual agreements. The transac-
tion costs are substantially higher with the existence of insecure
land tenure, because there is no assurance that rented land will be
1
Large-scale corporate farms have emerged in land-abundant countries in
Latin America, Eastern Europe, and Central Asia, where scale economies prevail
3
(Deininger and Byerlee, 2012). To be strict, we need the assumption that the production function is subject
2
Other compelling reasons that contributed to the change observed in the self- to constant returns to scale.
4
sufficiency ratio of cereals in Japan include the massive appreciation of the yen and Production on large farms is technically and allocatively inefficient due to
the dietary diversification. high monitoring costs and socially excessive use of agricultural machineries.

Please cite this article as: Otsuka, K., et al., Growing advantage of large farms in Asia and its implications for global food security. Global
Food Security (2016), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.gfs.2016.03.001i
K. Otsuka et al. / Global Food Security ∎ (∎∎∎∎) ∎∎∎–∎∎∎ 3

returned to landowners (Holden et al., 2013). Some land reform arrangements are facilitated online by county governments in
laws, such as land-to-the-tiller programs in which the owned land some provinces such as Chongqing. In some areas, land banks are
in excess of a ceiling is supposed to be transferred from the also established to facilitate borrowing and lending (renting-in
landowners to the tenants, suppress land rental transactions. and renting-out) of farmland. In this way, farm size expansion is
Consequently, Asian agriculture is dominated by owner-cultivated taking place in China (Huang and Ding, 2015).
family farms operating alongside relatively small areas of rented In sum, when the real wage rate is low, the optimum farm size
land (Hayami and Otsuka, 1993). Feder (1985) and Eswaran and is small and the inverse correlation between farm size and pro-
Kotwal (1986) also attribute the prevalence of self-sufficient ductivity tends to emerge. When the wage rate increases, me-
owner-cultivated farms, that neither rent in nor rent out land, to chanization will take place to save labour. If machines and land are
the inefficiency of credit markets in which poor but potentially complementary and machines are indivisible to some extent, the
productive tenants cannot obtain sufficient funds to pay for pur- optimum farm size tends to increase. If farm size adjustments take
chased inputs for rented land.5 place smoothly through market transactions and institutional ar-
We implicitly assume that there is no information asymmetry rangements, only efficient large farms survive. In practice, land
about the quality and safety of products. In the case of high-value markets may not function smoothly, so a positive relationship can
agricultural products, such as vegetables, fruits, and livestock arise between farm size and productivity in high-wage economies.
products, retailers and consumers may not be able to identify their
quality and safety easily. In such cases, contract farming is often
adopted, which is designed to guarantee the quality and safety of 3. Emerging advantage of large farms in Asia
products by the provision of inputs and technical services by the
contractor. Since the transaction cost is lower for the buyer to This section examines the validity of our arguments developed
contract with a small number of large farms than a large numbers in the previous section by drawing on recent empirical evidence
of small farms, large farms would have advantage over small-scale mainly available from Asian countries. They include case studies in
farms. This article, however, focuses on the production of food Indonesia (Yamauchi, 2016), Vietnam (Liu et al., 2013), India
grains, whose quality variations are relatively small and so spot- (Deininger et al., 2014), and China (Wang et al., 2014a). These re-
market transactions are common.6 cent studies explicitly look at the impact of rising real wages on
When the wage is sufficiently low, the labour-intensive and land and machine service transactions and the dynamically
family labour-based cultivation method is more efficient. Thus, the changing advantage of small farms (or the emerging advantage of
inverse relationship between farm size and productivity will be large farms). This is a major departure from the earlier literature
observed where efficient small-scale farms and inefficient large that assessed factors that were considered to explain the inverse
farms coexist. When the wage rate increases substantially relative relationship between farm size and productivity observed in cross-
to machine rental, however, the efficient production method sectional data.
changes from the labour-intensive to the labour-saving method by The existing empirical tests on the inverse relationship are
substituting labour by machines. However, it is uneconomical for grouped into several types. The first type investigates whether the
small farms to introduce large machinery, which is most likely advantage of small farms can be attributed to imperfect factor
indivisible and, therefore, cannot be used efficiently on small markets, particularly labour market. Our primary hypothesis is
farms. Large farms can also have easier access to credit and savings related to this. The second test inquires whether unobserved fac-
and therefore enjoy lower costs of funds for purchasing and/or tors such as soil quality can explain the inverse relationship if such
leasing machinery (Feder, 1985). As a result, small farms face factors are unevenly distributed between small and large farms
higher costs of mechanization due to credit market imperfections.7 (Benjamin, 1995). The third is concerned with the impact of
As labour becomes more costly, small farms' advantage of effi- measurement errors of farm size on the inverse correlation be-
ciently using family labour declines and large farmers' advantage tween farm size and productivity (Lamb, 2003).
arising from scale economies due to machine use increases. Con- Classical studies basically support the first hypothesis. For ex-
sequently, the inverse relationship is weakened or may even be ample, Carter (1984) found the inverse relationship in Haryana in
reversed as the optimum farm size becomes larger. 1969/70–1971–72 using household data, even after controlling for
Recently, we also observed an evolution of machine service village fixed effects and possible selection bias. Deolalikar (1981)
providers as an institutional response to reduce the user cost of also observed the inverse relationship between yields and farm
machine use. For example, in China (Yang et al., 2013), small farms size using district level data in India 1969/70–1971–72, particularly
can contract with the provider to use machine services, rather in districts without the adoption of new green revolution tech-
than renting in or purchasing machines, in order to save on labour nology. Barrett et al. (2010) simultaneously tested two hypotheses:
costs. By contracting with a large number of small farms, the the imperfection of the labour market and unobserved soil quality
provider can enjoy scale economies, provided that the transaction using rice production data from Madagascar. Employing precise
cost of machine service provision is sufficiently low. If it is high, soil quality measurements and including hired labour as a control
small farms cannot save labour as much as large farms. variable in their production function specifications, their empirical
It is still also possible that farmland consolidation can be fa- results show that only a small portion of the inverse productivity-
cilitated by market transactions as well as institutional arrange- size relationship is explained by labour market imperfections and
ments. Historically, consolidation was largely achieved through none of it seems attributable to the omission of soil quality mea-
market transactions in many of the Organisation for Economic Co- surements. Carletto et al. (2013) used geospatial and self-reported
operation and Development (OECD) countries. Recently in China data on plot size to identify the magnitude of measurement error
where land transactions are seriously constrained by the in- attenuation bias related to farm size. Their results show that such
security in farmers' individual land rights, farm land rental bias alone is not significant enough to generate the inverse re-
lationship. By using a precise measurement of plot size, the inverse
relationship becomes even more robust in their study. Note that
5
However, landlords often provide credit to their tenants, particularly under both studies use data from Africa, where measurement error is
share tenancy (Otsuka et al., 1992).
6
See Otsuka et al. (2016a) for a recent literature review of contract farming.
likely be large and tasks carried out by hired labourers are rela-
7
A similar argument holds in the discussion of industrial duality observed tively simple.
between large and small firms. Since the existing studies analyze the static effects of factor

Please cite this article as: Otsuka, K., et al., Growing advantage of large farms in Asia and its implications for global food security. Global
Food Security (2016), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.gfs.2016.03.001i
4 K. Otsuka et al. / Global Food Security ∎ (∎∎∎∎) ∎∎∎–∎∎∎

market imperfections, soil quality, and measurement error, they do 1.4 ha in 2009 in the Mekong Delta region.
not pay attention to possible changes in the relationship between Using data from three-rounds of nationally representative
farm size and productivity over time. Most parts of Asia today are household surveys in India, Deininger et al. (2014) examine the
experiencing rapidly rising real wages even in the rural areas due change in the inverse relationship between farm size and land
to rural-urban migration and resultant labour shortages. Such a productivity from 1982 to 2008. During this period, the real agri-
dramatic change in the real wage in the region offers a quasi- cultural wage rose from 20 rupees per day to 47 rupees per day.
natural experiment to test our hypotheses that the wage rate plays Their major finding is that the inverse farm size-productivity re-
a pivotal role in the relationship between farm size and lationship significantly weakened.10 Further analyses exploring
productivity. the mechanism underlying the changing relationship suggest that
Some recent studies explicitly use a change in the real wage to increases in real wages cause farmers to use more machines and
look at changes in land and machine inputs and the relationship employ less labour input. Similar to the cases of Indonesia and
between farm size and productivity.8 Indonesia is an interesting Vietnam, larger farmers are more responsive to increases in wages
case for the purpose of our study due to the coexistence of small and actively substitute labour by machines.
farms in Java and relatively large farms in the outer islands. Ya- Furthermore, the authors test for separation of labour supply
mauchi (2016) examines the dynamically changing patterns of and labour demand decisions of farm households following Ben-
land use, capital investments, and real wages by using farm jamin (1992) and find that the labour market became more effi-
household panel data from seven provinces collected in 2007 and cient over time. They also examine the relative effectiveness of
2010. His regression analyses show that an increase in real agri- family labour and hired labour. They find that while family labour
cultural wages induced the substitution of labour by machines, was more efficient than hired labour in the early period (1982–99),
either through machine rentals or machine service providers, the efficiency difference disappeared in the later period (1999–
notably among relatively large farmers. The total amount of pay- 2007). They attribute this to the ease of supervising hired labour in
ments for hired-in machines (and/or services) has increased sig- mechanized farming systems. First, compared with a traditional
nificantly in response to rising real agricultural wages, especially labour-intensive farming system, a capital-intensive farming sys-
among relatively large farms. They tend to increase the scale of tem likely requires a smaller number of skilled labourers, whose
operation by renting in more land when real agricultural wages task is to operate machines. Second, wage increases lower the ratio
increase. Furthermore, the effect of an increase in farm size on of hired labour to family labour, which in turn leads to more ef-
crop productivity becomes positive among relatively large farms.9 fective supervision of hired labour.
Thus, the Indonesian case study clearly supports our hypothesis In China, the economy has been rapidly growing over the last
that the efficiency of large farms increases with rising real agri- three and a half decades, and the wage rate has been rising shar-
cultural wage rates. ply, particularly since 2003 (Zhang et al., 2011). Correspondingly,
The case of Vietnam is similar to that of Indonesia. Liu et al. the use of riding tractors and combine harvesters is increasing
(2013) use data from 1992 and 1998 Vietnam Living Standards (Yang et al., 2013). Yet the average farm size remained at 0.6 ha in
Surveys (VLSS) and from four rounds of Vietnam Household Living 2010, increasing only by 0.05 ha per year since 2000, even though
Standards Surveys (VHLSS) between 2002 and 2008 to investigate land rental markets have become increasingly active (Kimura et al.,
machine use and the farm size-productivity relationship from the 2011; Huang et al., 2012). More recently, Huang and Ding (2015)
1990s to the 2000s. Descriptive analysis suggests that tractor point out that farm size in China is somewhat underestimated.
rental has become more common. In 2008 more than 60% of farms Using farm household panel data from China, collected in six
rented in machines, whereas less than 20% did so in 1992. Rapid provinces in 2000 and 2008, Wang et al. (2014a) analyze the dy-
increase in tractor use would be associated with an increase in the namic changes in land transactions, machine investments, and the
relative advantage of large farms. Consistent with such an ex- use of machine services. Their study looks at the effects of non-
pectation, large farmers are more likely to use agricultural ma- agricultural and agricultural wage growth, changes in the migra-
chines, pointing to the scale economies arising from machine use. tion rate, and the proportion of non-agricultural income, all of
Interestingly, machine use is not responsive to the real agricultural which are estimated at the village level, on changes in self-culti-
wage in 1992/98 but becomes significantly responsive in 2006/08, vated farm size, rented-in land areas, machine services used, and
suggesting the emergence of clear substitution effects between machine investments. The regression results show that increases
machine and labour in recent years when the wage rate increases. in non-agricultural wages, the proportion of non-agricultural in-
Such differences may be attributed to the development of machine come and the migration rate lead to the expansion of the opera-
rental markets over time. The estimation results of the paddy yield tional farm size. Consistently, the demand for machine services
regression demonstrate that the inverse relationship between also increased along with increases in agricultural wages and
farm size and land productivity has significantly lessened: when migration rates. This effect is larger for relatively large farms.
farm size doubles, the expected paddy yield is estimated to have As shown in the Indonesia study, the regression results of crop
decreased by 15.6% in the 1990s but only by 6.1% in the late 2000s. income equations support the hypothesis of complementarities
Thus, the inverse relationship is lessened but not reversed. Yet, between rented-in land and machine services demanded, espe-
another interesting finding is that the inverse relationship may be cially among relatively large landholders. In other words, the
reversed in areas where farm size is larger and the wage rate is possibility of renting in land and the availability of machine ser-
higher. This indicates that a positive relationship has emerged vice providers led to expansion of farm size to take advantage of
between farm size and productivity in advanced areas where the scale economies.
wage rate is higher. This result is also consistent with the ob- Wang et al. (2014b) used province-level crop-wise panel data
servation of Estudillo and Otsuka (2016) that the average farm size to investigate the substitutability between agricultural labour and
among their sample households increased from 1.0 ha in 1996 to machine use. They provided evidence that supports the conjecture
that machines are increasingly used to substitute for agricultural
8
The rest of this section draws on Otsuka et al. (2016a).
9 10
Crop productivity is measured by the value of production of a mixture of Yield refers to the total output value per hectare, which is deflated by the
crops. Using the panel data, the estimated equation is first differenced, so that fixed output price index using 1999 as the base year. The output price index is generated
components are controlled for. The same approach is applied to the analysis in using a weighted average of prices of all types of outputs in the sample using the
China. quantities as weights.

Please cite this article as: Otsuka, K., et al., Growing advantage of large farms in Asia and its implications for global food security. Global
Food Security (2016), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.gfs.2016.03.001i
K. Otsuka et al. / Global Food Security ∎ (∎∎∎∎) ∎∎∎–∎∎∎ 5

labour under the circumstances where the real wage has been be politically difficult to justify the transfer of land from small-
rapidly increasing. To know more about the relationship between holders to large farmers. In fact, the government of Japan at-
the availability of machine service providers and/or machine tempted to expand farm size without notable success (Hayami,
rentals and the activation of land rental markets, Wang et al. 1988) and the result was loss of comparative advantage in agri-
(2015) used the same household panel as in Wang et al. (2014a), culture due partly to policy induced market distortions. The self-
collected from six provinces. Interestingly, land rental markets sufficiency ratio of cereals decreased from 70% to 80% to around
seem to be more active if machines, either from rental arrange- 30% for the last several decades, even though cereal production
ments or service providers, are available. Farmers' willingness to has been heavily protected (Otsuka, 2013). Ironically a series of
rent in and out land is more responsive to actual demand and econometric studies on the production structure of Japanese
supply conditions if machines are accessible. That is, the possibility agriculture by Kuroda (1987, 1988a, 1988b, 1995) report the
of renting in land and the availability of machine service providers emergence of significant scale economies.
are jointly important to the possible realization of scale In China, although land rental markets have developed sig-
economies. nificantly, the remaining insecurity of land rights may deter farm
Two recent movements deserve special attention. First, in size expansion. The government has taken several measures to
northeast China, machine service providers directly attempt to facilitate land rental transactions, land consolidation, and farm
consolidate farmland by renting in land from smallholders to size expansion. Rada et al. (2015), however, point out that sub-
realize scale economies. However, such land rental contracts with sidies for farm size expansion are distortive and do not lead to
small farmers are mainly short term and often subject to annual efficiency gains at this stage. Land registration, titling and the es-
renewals, because small farmers feel insecure renting out their tablishment of rural land banks are two recent prominent mea-
land under long-term contracts due to the lack of private land sures. All rural land, including residential and collectively-owned
ownership. They also expect the land rent to increase over time land, was registered and titled in Sichuan Province beginning in
and thus hesitate to sign long-term contracts. Second, recently, 2008, and the process appears to have contributed to higher land
farmland rental arrangements are facilitated through the internet security and increased land rental transactions (Deininger et al.,
by county governments in some provinces such as Chongqing. The 2015). Rural land banks have been piloted in several provinces
internet-based land rental platform seems to be increasingly in- since the late 2000s. They have the potential to improve land
troduced in other provinces too. In all likelihood, these new in- market efficiency and increase operational farm size by con-
stitutional arrangements are induced by increasing the optimum solidating fragmented land plots deposited by small farmers and
size of farm operation in China. lending them to large farming or agricultural enterprises (Wang
In contrast to the conventional view of the small-farm ad- et al., 2014).
vantage, the evidence shown above supports the hypothesis of Demand for agricultural products in high-performing countries
dynamic changes in the relative advantage between small and in Asia has been shifting from cereals to livestock products, which
large farms in Asia. That is, the inefficiency of small farms in- require larger amounts of cereals for animal feeds. If farms size
creases with rising real wages, whereas large farms increase their expansion does not take place in these Asian countries, the supply
productivity by utilizing large-scale machines efficiently, saving of cereals will fall short of demand. Thus, they are likely to become
increasingly costly labour, and thereby realizing scale economies. major importers of cereals. Since China, India, and Indonesia are
gigantic countries, the absolute amount of imported cereals can be
huge. This in turn implies a significant imbalance of global food
4. Concluding remarks demand and supply, which would result in large increases in
cereal prices, which will disproportionately affect the poor
It is clear that, in Asia, responding to rising wages, labour has throughout the world. In order to avoid or mitigate such an im-
been substituted by machines primarily through the machinery
balance, there is an urgent need to change land polices so as to
rental market. This, in turn, stimulates farm size expansion,
facilitate farm size expansion in Asia.
usually through land rental markets. It is likely that these changes
have weakened the inverse relationship between farm size and
productivity, or even reversed it, especially on large farms, because
References
mechanization confers scale advantages. If the real wage rate
continues to increase in high-performing countries in Asia, as it
Bardhan, P.K., 1973. Size, productivity, and returns to scale: an analysis of farm-level
certainly will, eventually a clear positive relationship between data in Indian agriculture. J. PoliticaL Econ. 81 (6), 1370–1386.
farm size and farming efficiency will emerge, as in the case of Barrett, C.B., Bellamare, M.F., Hou, J.Y., 2010. Reconsidering conventional explana-
Japan (Otsuka, 2013). This means that these countries need to tions of the inverse productivity-size relationship. World Dev. 38 (1), 88–97.
Benjamin, D., 1992. Household composition, labour markets, and labour demand:
expand farm size in order to maintain competitiveness in
testing for separation in agricultural household models. Econometrica 60 (2),
agriculture. 287–322.
A major constraint on farm size expansion is land reform pro- Benjamin, D., 1995. Can observed land quality explain the inverse productivity
grams and land laws which tend to suppress functioning of land relationship? J. Dev. Econ. 46 (1), 51–84.
Binswanger, H.P., Rosenzweig, M.R., 1986. Behavioral and material determinants of
markets (Hayami and Otsuka, 1993; Otsuka, 2007; Holden et al., production relations in agriculture. J. Dev. Stud. 22 (3), 503–539.
2013). A good example is land-to-the-tiller programs implemented Brandao, A.S.P., Rezende, G.C.D., 1992. Credit Subsidies, Inflation and the Land
in India, Nepal, and the Philippines, which are designed to transfer Market in Brazil: A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis. World Bank, Wa-
shington DC.
land from large landowners to landless or near landless tenants. Carletto, C., Savastano, S., Zezza, A., 2013. Fact or artifact: the impact of measure-
Given the inverse relationship between farm size and productivity, ment errors on the farm size – productivity relationship. J. Dev. Econ. 103 (C),
the transfer of land under a land-to-the-tiller program could en- 254–261.
Carter, M.R., 1984. Identification of the inverse relationship between farm size and
hance both efficiency and equity. But this program reduces in-
productivity: an empirical analysis of peasant agricultural production. Oxf.
centives for a large number of small landowners to rent out land to Econ. 36 (1), 131–145.
a small number of large farmers so as to facilitate land con- Chayanov, A.V., 1926/1986. The Theory of Peasant Economy. University of Wis-
solidation (Otsuka, 2007). consin Press, Madison.
Deininger, K., Byerlee, D., 2012. The rise if large farms in land abundant countries:
It is now time for policymakers in Asia to consider ways to Do they have a future? World Dev. 40 (4), 701–714.
facilitate farm size expansion. This is a major challenge as it may Deininger, K., Jin, S., Liu, Y., Singh, S., 2014. Labour Market Efficiency and Inverse

Please cite this article as: Otsuka, K., et al., Growing advantage of large farms in Asia and its implications for global food security. Global
Food Security (2016), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.gfs.2016.03.001i
6 K. Otsuka et al. / Global Food Security ∎ (∎∎∎∎) ∎∎∎–∎∎∎

Productivity-Farm Size in India. International Food Policy Research Institute, Kuroda, Y., 1995. Labor productivity measurement in Japanese agriculture. Agric.
Washington, DC (Unpublished manuscript). Econ. 12 (1), 55–68.
Deininger, K., Jin, S., Liu, S., Shao, T., Xia, F., 2015. Impact of Property Rights Reform Lamb, R.L., 2003. Inverse productivity: Land quality, labor markets and measure-
to Support China's Rural-Urban Integration: Village-Level Evidence from the ment error. J. Dev. Econ. 71 (1), 71–95.
Chengdu National Experiment. the World Bank, Washington, DC, Policy Re- Larson, D., Matsumoto, T., Kilic, T., Otsuka, K., 2014. Should African rural develop-
search Working Paper Series 7389. ment strategies depend on smallholder farms? an exploration of the inverse
Deolalikar, A.B., 1981. The inverse relationship between productivity and farm size: productivity hypothesis. Agric. Econ. 45 (3), 355–367.
a test using regional data from India. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 63 (2), 275–279. Lipton, M., 2009. Land Reform in Developing Countries: Property Rights and
Estudillo, J.P., Otsuka, K., 2016. Moving out of Poverty: An Inquiry into Inclusive Property Wrongs. Routledge, Oxford, UK.
Growth in Asia. Routledge, London, UK. Liu, Y., Violette, W., Barrett, C., 2013. Real Wage, Machine Use, and Inverse Farm Size
Eswaran, M., Kotwal, A., 1986. Access to capital and agrarian production organi- – Productivity Relationship in Vietnam. International Food Policy Research In-
zation. Econ. J. 96 (382), 482–498. stitute, Washington, DC (Unpublished manuscript).
Feder, G., 1985. The relation between farm size and productivity. J. Dev. Econ. 18 (2– Otsuka, K., 2007. Efficiency and equity effects of land markets. In: Pingli, P., Even-
3), 297–313. son, R.E. (Eds.), Handbook of Agricultural Economics 3. Elsevier, Amsterdam.
Foster, A.D., Rosenzweig, M.R., 2010. Barriers to Farm Profitability in India: Me- Otsuka, K., 2013. Food insecurity, income inequality, and the changing comparative
chanization, Scale and Credit Markets. (Unpublished manuscript). advantage in world agriculture. Agric. Econ. 44 (S1), S7–S18.
Gunjal, K., Williams, S., Romain, R., 1996. Agricultural credit subsidies and farmland Otsuka, K., Chuma, H., Hayami, Y., 1992. Land and labor contracts in agrarian
values in Canada. Can. J. Agric. Econ. 44 (1), 39–52. economies: theories and facts. J. Econ. Lit. 30 (4), 1965–2018.
Hayami, Y., 1988. Japanese Agriculture under Siege: The Political Economy of Otsuka, K., Nakano, Y., Takahashi, K., 2016a. Contract farming in developed and
Agricultural Policies. St. Martin's Press, New York, NY. developing countries. Annu. Rev. Resour. Econ. (forthcoming)
Hayami, Y., 2001. Ecology, history, and development: a perspective from rural Otsuka, K., Liu, Y., Yamauchi, F., 2013. Factor endowments, wage growth, and
Southeast Asia. World Bank. Res. Obs. 16 (2), 169–198. changing food self-sufficiency: evidence from country-level panel data. Am. J.
Hayami, Y., 2009. Plantations agriculture. In: Pingli, P., Evenson, R.E. (Eds.), Hand-
Agric. Econ. 95 (5), 1252–1258.
book of Agricultural Economics 4. Elsevier, Amsterdam.
Otsuka, K., Liu, Y., Yamauchi, F., 2016b. The future of small farms in Asia. Dev. Policy
Hayami, Y., Otsuka, K., 1993. The Economics of Contract Choice: An Agrarian Per-
Rev. (Forthcoming)
spective. Clarendon Press, Oxford, UK.
Rada, N., Wang, C., Qin, L., 2015. Subsidy or market reform? rethinking China's farm
Heltberg, R., 1998. Rural market imperfections and the farm size-productivity re-
consolidation strategy. Food Policy 57 (1), 93–103.
lationships: evidence from Pakistan. World Dev. 26 (10), 1807–1826.
Robison, L.J., Lins, D.A., Venkatraman, R., 1985. Cash rents and land values in U.S.
Holden, S., Otsuka, K., Deininger, K., 2013. Land Tenure Reforms in Asia and Africa:
agriculture. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 67 (4), 794–805.
Assessing Impacts on Poverty and Natural Resource Management. Palgrave
Sen, A.K., 1975. Employment, Technology, and Development. Oxford University
Macmillan, Hampshire, UK.
Press, London.
Huang, J., Ding, J., 2015. Institutional innovation and policy support to facilitate
Skoufias, E., 1995. Household resources, transaction costs, and adjustment through
small-scale farming transformation in China. In: Proceedings of Paper pre-
land tenancy. Land Econ. 71 (1), 42–56.
sented at 29th International Conference of Agricultural Economists in Milan.
Wang, H., Tong, Y., Guan, S., 2014. Establishment and risk analysis of Chinese rural
Huang, J., Wang, X., Qui, H., 2012. Small-Scale Farmers in China in the Face of
Modernization and Globalization. International Institute for Environment and land bank. In: Wang, Y., Ye, H., Shen, G.Q.P., Bai, Y. (Eds.), ICCREM 2014: Smart
Development, London. Construction and Management in the Context of New Technology. American
Jha, R., Chitkara, P., Gupta, S., 2000. Productivity, technical and allocative efficiency Society of Civil Engineers, Reston.
and farm size in wheat farming in India: a DEA approach. Appl. Econ. Lett. 7 (1), Wang, X., Yamauchi, F., Otsuka, K., Huang, J., 2014a. Wage Growth, Landholding and
1–5. Machine Services in China. Cent. Chin. Agric. Policy World Bank. (Unpublished
Jha, R., Rhodes, M.J., 1999. Some imperatives of the green revolution: technical manuscript)
efficiency and ownership of inputs in Indian agriculture. Agric. Resour. Econ. Wang, X., Yamauchi, F., Huang, J., 2014b. Rising wages, mechanization and the
Rev. 28 (1), 57–64. substitution between capital and labor: evidence from small scale farm system
Kevane, M., 1996. Agrarian structure and agricultural practice: typology and ap- in China. Agric. Econ. (Forthcoming)
plication to Western Sudan. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 78 (1), 236–245. Wang, X., Yamauchi, F., Huang, J., Rozelle, S., 2015. Wages, Machine Services and
Kimura, S., Otsuka, K., Sonobe, T., Rozelle, S., 2011. Efficiency of land allocation Land Rental Markets in Chinese Agriculture. Center for Chinese Agricultural
through tenancy markets: evidence from China. Econ. Dev. Cult. Chang. 59 (3), Policy. World Bank, and Stanford University (Unpublished manuscript).
485–510. Yamauchi, F., 2016. Rising real wages, mechanization and growing advantage of
Kuroda, Y., 1987. The production structure and demand for labor in postwar Japa- large farms: evidence from Indonesia. Food Policy 58, 62–69.
nese agriculture, 1952–82. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 69 (2), 328–337. Yang, J., Huang, Z., Zhang, X., Reardon, T., 2013. The rapid rise of cross-regional
Kuroda, Y., 1988a. Biased technological change and factor demand in postwar Ja- agricultural mechanization services in China. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 95 (5),
panese agriculture, 1954–84. Agric. Econ. 2 (1), 101–122. 1245–1251.
Kuroda, Y., 1988b. The output bias of technological change in postwar Japanese Zhang, X., Yang, J., Wang, S., 2011. China has reached the Lewis turning point. China
agriculture. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 70 (3), 663–673. Econ. Rev. 22 (4), 542–554.

Please cite this article as: Otsuka, K., et al., Growing advantage of large farms in Asia and its implications for global food security. Global
Food Security (2016), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.gfs.2016.03.001i

Anda mungkin juga menyukai