Anda di halaman 1dari 7

Undertaking Emission Reduction Projects

Prototype Carbon Fund and Clean


Development Mechanism
The ratification of the Kyoto Protocol will pave the way for developed countries to
embark on emissions trading by setting up emission reduction projects in developing nations,
which do not have emission reduction commitments. This article studies the potential
costs, risks and returns involved in such projects and looks at the advantages of setting up
large projects.
HARIPRIYA GUNDIMEDA, YAN GUO

each project will need more than one investor. The entrepreneur
I is also transferred some technology for this indivisible invest-
Introduction ment project (or the emission reduction projects) with stochastic

I
f the Kyoto Protocol (KP) is ratified, then the Annex I returns.
countries1 will face emission reduction targets. However, The product of the project at the end of the period is emission
these emission reductions can be partly offset by the three reduction credits (carbon credit), which is of interest to the
flexible mechanisms of the Kyoto Protocol – the joint imple- investor. Here the carbon credits are the difference between the
mentation (JI) in Article 6, clean development mechanism (CDM) hypothetical baseline emissions and effective emissions. The
in Article 12 and emissions trading (ET) in Article 17 respec- entrepreneur is interested in other direct benefits provided by the
tively. Emissions trading allows the Annex I countries to trade project as well as indirect benefits like employment, increased
emission reduction units that are above or below their emission power production or improved environmental quality. For ex-
quotas agreed in the protocol in supplement to the domestic ample, in the case of the Latvia project the benefits to the host
actions. The application of ET requires a full international country are low public health risk, waste disposal and landfill
agreement and a well-established trading market. JI allows trans- gas-fired power. However, the entrepreneurs have no direct
fer of emission reduction units (ERUs) resulting from emission rights over the carbon reductions (carbon credits) and so
reduction or removal projects (carbon offset projects) among the cannot market them. The project would be undertaken only if
Annex I countries. The CDM allows transfer of ERUs resulting the entrepreneur has enough capital inputs and if the return from
from carbon offset projects (like afforestation and forest the project at least equals the opportunity cost of capital. Investors
preservation) between Annex I and non-Annex I (developing) agree to finance this project only if it fetches at least the carbon
countries (which do not have emission reduction commitments). credits which they would have obtained if they had invested on
If the Annex I countries decide to benefit through JI or CDM, their own.
there will be a large group of firms (henceforth called investors)
interested in investing in projects abroad and several firms in II
developing countries (henceforth called entrepreneurs or Risks in JI/CDM Projects
implementers or agents), who are interested in taking up these
emission reduction projects through initial capital financing. JI and CDM seem quite flexible, but in reality they can be risky
There can be small projects as well as large projects but the and very costly for various reasons making the mechanisms
investors’ investment is limited to projects that would not have shaky. There are mainly three kinds of risks associated with the
occurred without co-financing or the additionality component of projects, which may lead to project failure: non-performance,
the baseline project and would be limited to the cost of carbon non-cooperation and exogenous risk [Mitchell and Parson 2001].
offsets generated. This would increase the internal rate of return The non-performance risk arises because of the project parti-
(IRR) of the project and make it profitable.2 For example, cipants’ intentional non-performance of their obligations. For
consider the case of the Latvia-Liepaja gas recovery project. example, implementers of a reforestation project might plant
The baseline project objective is to implement modern waste less land than promised or plant it badly; investors might fail
management system, the funds for which are raised in the to provide promised funding, training or other resources. Second,
entrepreneurs’ own country. The additional feature of this project projects may fail due to lack of expected cooperation from
is installing energy cell technology for enhanced degradation of non-participants. To succeed, many projects require coop-
biodegradable waste, collecting landfill gas containing 50 per eration from actors not involved in project negotiations and not
cent methane and generating electricity using this captured bound by explicit obligations to the project, particularly host-
methane gas.3 The investor would invest only in this additional country government agencies (if they are not involved in project
feature of the project. Also in some large projects like hydro negotiation). These risks may result in emission reductions below
projects the scale of inputs for the project exceeds the personal expectations despite the participants’ efforts. Such situations are
wealth of any single investor. This implies that in such cases particularly likely in the resource-poor contexts of non-Annex I

Economic and Political Weekly October 11, 2003 4331


Figure 1: Threats to Successful CDM Project Performance conditions such as haze and sandstorms may affect the perfor-
Project Risk mance of critical components of the power plant. Also, the
High maintenance and operation of critical solar equipment and control
may prove to be too complex. Third, there is the economic risk
that the application of the technology in India may be more costly
Medium risks with High risks that are than anticipated, making it completely unaffordable. Fourth,
limited emission acceptable only if
reductions but participants
there is the replicability risk where, even if the demonstration
significant learning assume risk project works as planned, the project may not lead to its rep-
lication in India. This may be due to lack of proper policy
instruments or economic resources, or simply because the
conditions do not bring about a sufficiently large decrease in
Participant Risk the production costs.4
Low High Apart from the costs arising due to project and participant risk,
transaction costs can also arise due to a cumbersome regulatory
approval process in the host and investor countries for foreign
Low risk with Identifiable risks investment. Further, complex, non-transparent processes govern-
reliable emission that require
reductions management
ing the approval and implementation of investment by both sides
can invite opportunistic rent-seeking by host-country officials,
or even raise the troublesome issue of corruption [Powell et al
Low
1997]. Thus transaction costs may take different forms but in
this paper by transaction costs we mean the costs associated with
Source: Mitchell and Parson (2001) the process of obtaining JI or CDM recognition for a project and
obtaining the resulting emission credits as defined in OECD
countries. For example, projects may fail because a government (2001). Hence the transaction costs can be split into the pre-
agency does not provide water, energy or transport infrastructure implementation and implementation phases. The pre-implemen-
that implementers had assumed would be available. Third, projects tation costs include search costs, negotiation costs, validation
may fail due to risks that have nothing to do with such causes. costs and approval costs. Project-based implementation costs
The desire for innovation in project technology, organisation or include monitoring costs, certification costs and enforcement
application makes CDM projects particularly vulnerable to in- costs [Stronzik 2001].5 Thus in the context of CDM, transaction
herent project-related risks [Mintzer 1994:44]. Required project costs are important because they may influence the scope and
inputs may be higher than expected and higher than the concerned extent of the use of flexibility mechanisms.
actor is able or willing to provide. Parties to a project might accept
technical assumptions about the relationship between inputs and III
emission effects that turn out to be mistaken. Both uncertain
knowledge and random events may make the actual context for
Prototype Carbon Fund
project implementation quite different from that assumed during Keeping in view the risks and complications involved in
negotiations. A reforestation project may fail because difficult successful implementation of CDM projects, the World Bank
site conditions demand more time or resources than participants has launched a prototype carbon fund (PCF) to understand and
predicted; because a planted species takes up carbon more slowly test the processes and procedures for creating a market in project-
than predicted; or because of fire, drought, etc [Metz 1995:170]. based emission reduction under the joint implementation (JI) and
Based on these sources of project failure, Mitchell and Parson the clean development mechanism (CDM). Contributors to the
(2001) identify two distinct types of threats to project perfor- PCF include both companies and governments (‘PCF parti-
mance: project-related risk and participant-related risk (Figure 1). cipants’). The fund resources are used to support projects de-
Project-related risk consists of uncertainty in performance even signed to produce emission reductions fully consistent with the
if project participants implement it perfectly, because of tech- Kyoto Protocol and the emerging framework for JI and the CDM.
nological risk, external events, or reliance on non-participants. The contributors, or ‘participants’ in the PCF receive a pro rata
For low-risk projects, the relationship of effort to outcome is share of the emission reductions, verified and certified in accor-
sufficiently well known that shortfalls in outcome can be readily dance with carbon purchase agreements reached with the respec-
attributed to failures of the project participants. For example, tive countries ‘hosting’ the projects. The mechanism of this PCF
projects involving established technologies come under this is illustrated in Figure 2.
category. For high-risk projects, the relationship of effort to Some of the potential projects include wind, small hydro, solar
outcome may be either intrinsically stochastic or poorly under- direct, solar photovoltaic, landfill gas, refuse-derived fuel,
stood, so that identifying causes of failure requires considerable geothermal power and heat, and biomass fuels, including
investigation. For example, consider the case of a project in crop-residue fuels such as bagasse, rice-husks, coffee husks
India which harnesses solar power to generate energy. There and wood fuels. Energy-efficiency projects include demand-side
are at least four areas of project risks. First, there is the financial management such as manufacturing processes, building and
and operational risk that the project may fail to attract people appliance efficiency measures, and supply-side efficiency such
financially and technically capable of completing it and to manage as transmission, distribution efficiency and gas flaring reduction.
the plant efficiently so as maintain sound financial operations. PCF funds are limited to projects that would not have occurred
Second, there is a technical risk that the technology may not work without PCF co-financing and would be limited to the cost of
properly in the Indian context. For instance, climatological carbon offsets generated. The PCF will attempt to negotiate

4332 Economic and Political Weekly October 11, 2003


Figure 2: Mechanism of Prototype Carbon Fund to delegate the monitoring to an intermediary (in this case invest
in a fund like a prototype carbon fund) and pay a delegation fee
$ $ to the intermediary. Hence, a critical issue is whether it is
worthwhile to introduce an intermediary not only in the context
of PCF but also such intermediaries in the future to make the
Industries, Economies in in
JI and CDM more efficient. What are the incentives to be provided
Economies
Industries,
Governments PP Transition
transition andand in various projects and under what conditions is it necessary to
governments
and Companies and C Developing go in for an intermediary? In the next section, we analyse these
companies
CF developing
Countries
countries issues in a non-technical way.
F

CO2 2
CO CO2 2
CO
IV
ΩΩ Contracting, Monitoring or Delegation?
ΩΩ
As both participant as well as project risk underlie CDM, the
$ -–Money
Money – Technology CO2 ––Carbon
Carboncredits
credits
final outcome depends on the type of contracting, that is, con-
- Technology tracting with no monitoring, just monitoring, or both or using
an intermediary. In the context of multiple investors and
Source: www.prototypecarbonfund.org multiple implementers, using an intermediary might be an
efficient way to diversify the project portfolio risk, given that
financing where the price for offsets is paid on delivery of the the return in individual project is independent across different
offset after the periodic verification of the offsets achieved. In projects. In the real world scenario, entrepreneurs take up all
case the projects require initial capital financing, the PCF will project risks, including risks that cannot be controlled such as
attempt to limit the initial financing to the cost of generating technical uncertainty or non-cooperation of non-participants.
the emission reduction. The launch of the PCF has raised hope However, in the context of CDM such an approach will deter
for these project-based reductions under CDM and JI. participation and innovation in the programme, as new and riskier
If the KP or similar protocols are in place in future, the scope technology will never be encouraged. Further, in instances when
for such carbon trading or carbon projects can be substantial. project failure is unambiguously due to project risk, such sanc-
It is estimated that the gross annual demand for ERUs between tions (that entrepreneur takes all the risk) are likely be difficult
2008 and 2012 is 1400-2400 Mt CO2 (without the US) of which to impose, and may not have the desired effect. Hence, the only
the demand for Annex B sinks is around 330 Mt CO2 [Lecocq way out is to design proper incentives in order to avoid the failure
2000]. As the carbon credits are the difference between the of projects. In this section, we will see how to implement the
hypothetical baseline and effective emissions, they depend on projects efficiently using the basic principal-agent model. The
the effort put in by the agent and also some external factors. Here investor can either contract with entrepreneurs to provide incen-
the main difficulty arises from the investor’s inability to perfectly tives or monitor to prevent the entrepreneur shirking or do both
observe the actions of the agent due to high monitoring costs to get carbon credits given the entrepreneur’s participation
and technical non-feasibility. The investors therefore face two constraint and the investor’s budget constraint. The expected
types of asymmetric information. The entrepreneurs have private carbon credit depends on the entrepreneur’s performance and also
information about their baseline emissions and the impact on the on some stochastic variables which cannot be controlled by the
production function of this investment; and private information entrepreneur. When there are multiple principals and agents to
about their own actions (from now on referred to as effort) during implement JI and CDM, an intermediary can be introduced to
the project period. To simplify it further, if the projects fetch diversify independent risk, save transaction and monitoring cost,
a high return to the agent (and carbon reductions are directly and strengthen bargaining power in contract renegotiation. We
related to the output) then it can be win-win for both investor discuss below the incentives under vaious heads.
as well as entrepreneur. However, if the projects are not that Contracting with entrepreneurs: The type of contract depends
profitable from the entrepreneur’s point of view (that is, if carbon on whether the projects are of high return or low return from
credit is the main outcome and no by-products, which yield the entrepreneurs’ point of view. High-return projects are defined
monetary benefits to the agent), the investor has to induce the as those that can fetch direct benefits for hosting countries’
entrepreneur to put in full effort and avoid shirking (as a lower entrepreneur or manager without much risk. This kind of project
target is not of interest to the investor; it delays compliance). not only produces carbon reduction, but also produces other
Here the investor is interested in effort rather than output because products, which are economically attractive to the entrepreneur
carbon reduction is dependent on hypothetical baseline emis- (that is, they enjoy a good rate of return even without funding
sions. If the agent claims that the baseline emissions are low and from the investor). For example, consider the case of a power
show higher offset potential, it is not of interest as lower targets plant operated by a firm using waste rice husk or waste peanut
are reached and the investor has over-invested. To ensure that shells as fuel, to produce electricity using the conventional
the agent is acting responsibly with full commitment, the investor Rankine steam cycle technology. As this technology has been
has to use a compensation scheme to optimise the agent’s com- in use for more than 100 years and is commercially competitive
pliance effort, so that his behaviour is in line with the investors’ with existing sources of electricity, this fetches direct returns to
targeted output (that is, the emission reductions are really achieved). the entrepreneur (if not, it at least saves the cost of electricity).
Only with a properly designed scheme can the agent put in This is an ideal project in which both parties are better off.
appropriate levels of effort and meet the target. If the number However, the principal may incur higher transaction costs to
of projects and investors is large then it may be more efficient verify the baseline carbon emissions. For instance, renewable

Economic and Political Weekly October 11, 2003 4333


energy projects, such as wind and photovoltaic projects, though ratio). Similarly, he offers less compensation for outcomes that
risky require less effort in absolute terms than for large-scale are relatively more likely when low effort is chosen. In this case
fossil projects. This is due to the fact that projects with zero the investor pays the agent a fixed amount plus an additional
emissions require minimal verification effort in the implemen- motivational amount that is incentive-compatible. Therefore the
tation phase. Because of the comparative cost advantage in the motivational amount renders the agent’s compensation dependent
host country and the positive externality from the investment on the emission reduction credits and effort via this likelihood
project, social welfare is increased. But optimal effort of entre- ratio. This is significant because compensation, the traditional
preneur doesn’t mean that the project can perfectly achieve the and most significant behavioural control mechanism employed
targeted carbon reduction as we mentioned earlier. Each project’s by management, becomes in part a function of the ability to
outcome can also depend on some stochastic variables, for measure output and effort. If this relationship were to break down,
example, states of nature, which cannot be controlled by investor managerial control is weakened and improper risk sharing would
or entrepreneur. In this case the project is low in participants result [Goldsmith and Basak 2001]. However, output being
risk, but may not be low in project related risk. As neither investor highly stochastic, if it does not depend on effort but depends
nor entrepreneur can control the uncertainty of states of nature, on the state of nature, the optimal payment scheme reverts to
there always exists some risk that a low outcome may occur, fixed wage compensation.
implying that the targeted carbon reduction is not achieved, which Monitoring: Earlier we said that the final output of the project
is not of much interest to the investor. also depends on the state of nature, any deviation from the first
The above scenario is more interesting in the case of a multiple- best solution representing the social welfare loss. How can the
investor and single-project setting. The scenario won’t change investor know that the deviation from the first best is because
except that there may be some cooperation problem and dupli- of state of nature and other exogenous factors and not because
cated contract-writing costs. If the investors can make a coalition of intentional non-commitment? So an important issue to be
or delegate an intermediary to write the contract and pay the considered is if there is any way to reduce the deviation by
service fee, then both parties can reduce the contracting cost. So minimising information asymmetry in order to mitigate social
is the situation with multiple profitable projects. Here delegation welfare loss. Monitoring is often adopted in principal-agent
to an intermediary can be profitable because the intermediary problems to improve the agent’s effort by punishing shirking.
not only saves the transaction cost in writing a contract with Any imperfect information about the agent’s action or states of
multiple principals and agents, but can also diversify the risk nature can be used to improve the contract, as long as the marginal
among different independent projects. If the states of nature faced benefit of getting information is greater than its marginal cost
by each project are independent, then, as the number of projects [Holmstrom 1979]. Given that effort is unobservable, choosing
goes to infinity the whole risk of the project portfolio can be an appropriate signal or choosing a good performance measure
largely diversified. which includes information about the agent’s effort becomes the
Now consider the case when the project does not fetch a high key issue in monitoring. Apparently the more information in-
return from the entrepreneur’s point of view (can yield good IRR cluded in the signal about the agent’s effort, the better off the
only with funding from the investor). For example, consider the parties are by monitoring. However, monitoring is costly. Hence,
case of a reforestation project. The benefits of forests as a source the investor will balance the gains and costs from monitoring
of timber, fuelwood, fodder and other non-timber forest products to get maximum profit. Milgrom and Roberts (1992) endogenise
along with environmental services provided by them are well monitoring into incentive contract, showing how much should
known. Though the project provides valuable environmental be spent on monitoring for principal. Earlier, under the observable
services now, as the forest can no longer generate direct economic effort case, the risk-averse agent gets constant wage without
benefits in the form of timber and fuelwood (due to using trees sharing any risk, and under unobservable case, the incentive
for storing carbon) this is economically unattractive for the contract imposes some risk on the agent to induce high effort.
entrepreneur. Another example is the case of the Liepaja solid In this case too, the incentive wage package can be decomposed
waste management project in Latvia. Without funding from the into a certain constant amount of wage and the marginal gain
investor, the project IRR is only around 1 per cent and with from more effort for agent (incentive intensity). As the effort
funding the IRR is around 5 per cent. So the project becomes cannot be observed, the agent has to take some risk along with
economically unattractive and has too much of risk. There are the cost of effort.
three major areas of potential risk namely: technical risk arising
due to the design, construction, operation and reuse of the energy V
cells; difficulties in realising the expected gas generation rates Delegated Monitoring
and yields (which is a critical component in supporting, through
energy sales, the financial viability of the project); and a shortfall Diamond (1984) provides a financial intermediary theory from
in revenue through sales of electrical power.6 As the entrepre- the point of delegated monitoring. He proves that as long as the
neurs cannot make direct profits, it is always feasible for them monitoring costs are less than the contracting costs the delegated
to put in less than optimal amount of effort than the case of high monitoring pays. For the financial intermediary to be viable,
return projects. In order to ensure that the entrepreneur chooses Diamond argued that three conditions must be fulfilled. The
a high level of effort, he must be provided with incentives as investors must receive an expected return R per unit deposited.
well as be monitored. In the former case, the only option for The intermediary must receive an expected return net of monitoring
the investor is to pay enough compensation to induce agent’s costs and any dead weight penalties incurred which is at least
high effort. Here the optimal compensation scheme pays more zero. Finally, each entrepreneur must retain an expected return
for outcomes that are statistically relatively more likely to occur at least as high as he would be by contracting directly with
under high effort than under low effort (referred to as likelihood investors. Given that the CDM system is highly risky, it requires

4334 Economic and Political Weekly October 11, 2003


attracting a diverse collection of projects and participants and In low-risk projects it is easier to measure the agent’s perfor-
tuning implementation approaches to respond to these differ- mance, but as the agent’s risk is high he has to be given strong
ences: for example, rewarding low-risk projects that generate incentives. But the discounted profitability and responsiveness
near-term reductions while also encouraging high-risk projects to incentive will offset the outcome from the incentives. Thus,
that may involve innovations resulting in large future reductions. in this case contracting with incentive would work. He should
The diversification can reduce the project risk. However, as it be given some incentive not to shirk work and to put in optimal
is too difficult for an individual investor to monitor different effort. High-risk participants would be allowed to undertake low-
projects with different levels of project risk, it is useful to have risk projects, but would have to bear the costs of extensive
an intermediary to reduce the transaction costs. The importance monitoring to ensure their full performance. Here contracting
of the intermediary is not simply a way for investors to hold well- would dominate monitoring.
diversified portfolios, but also a way to strengthen the bargaining When the project risk is high and agent risk is low, the project
power of investors when renegotiation happens. The asymmetric might have high expected profit, but the profitability from in-
information may warrant a renegotiation of the contract. When cremental effort may be limited due to the low-risk of the agent.
renegotiation happens, delegated renegotiation is more efficient In this case it is very difficult to identify the agent’s performance
in a situation with dispersed multiple investors and multiple because of the high variance of measurement. Minimal incentive
projects [Bolton and Freixas 1994]. In CDM and JI programmes intensity and minimal monitoring can be optimal. This kind of
where each project involves some non-participant risk also, like compensation scheme holds good even in projects which yield
sovereign risk, PCF, as an intermediary to renegotiate with good return to the entrepreneur. In such cases the performance
sovereign countries is more efficient than the investors to guar- can be awarded based on behavioural standards. Behavioural
antee the carbon reduction target. standards would award credits for performing specified actions
and defending against eventualities specified at the time of project
VI approval [Kerr 1997:2]. Here the participant can be given con-
Discussion and Conclusions stant wage but some bonus may be promised if the participants
meet expectations despite unfavourable circumstances, to en-
Based on the analysis in earlier sections, we would try to courage and reward project success. However, if the projects fail,
summarise the incentives to be provided in the four cases: (1) low still they get constant wage and the investor takes the risk.
participant-low project risk; (2) low participant-high project risk; However, in order to judge that the effort is genuine, the par-
(3) high participant-low project risk and (4) high participant-high ticipant needs to be monitored (though minimally). In this case
project risk. The incentive mechanism is summarised in Figure the cost of monitoring can be borne by the investor. The extent
3. When project risk is low (expected profit is low and the of monitoring chosen depends on the type of project. Projects
profitability from incremental effort is low as well), the incentive like reforestation require only intermittent monitoring. Power
intensity is low as well. In such cases it is also reasonable to plant projects require more continuous and consistent monitoring
say that agent’s performance can be identified very easily, as there to ensure that the power plant is operated and maintained in ways
are few variables which are outside control to affect the outcome, that minimise emissions.
implying higher incentive. Low-risk agents are usually more risk When the participant’s risk is high and project risk is high as
averse and hence less responsive to incentives, and as seen from well, high profitability can be expected from incremental effort
Figure 3 the incentive intensity is low. Due to the high precision though it is ambiguous. High-risk agents are less-risk averse than
of performance measurement, though it appears that incentive low-risk agents. If more discretion is given to the agent in high-
should be high, in reality this is offset by the low profitability, risk projects, less-risk averse agents may have more incentive
strong risk aversion and low responsiveness to incentive. There- to find innovative ways to improve performance in order to get
fore, principal can save monitoring cost because of low incen- more payoff, which means stronger responsiveness to incentives.
tives. For these low-risk projects the contract can be written based However in case of high-risk projects, it is very difficult to
on a set of minimum standard criteria for all the projects (the measure the agent’s performance precisely thereby, lessening the
criteria can be adjusted after project initiation to meet the par- incentive intensity. Hence, in such cases, higher incentives need
ticular exigencies of the project). If feasible the projects can also to be provided to the agent, which implies that the investor has
be evaluated on completion based on performance criteria (for to put in more effort to monitor to improve efficiency. Such
instance using emission reductions or effectiveness of standards projects are quite risky and are generally not favoured but they
as criteria), thereby granting entrepreneurs maximum flexibility. can be quite promising sometimes due to high returns. Rewarding
In this case, the initially agreed contract should provide adequate these risky projects through careful design and implementation
incentives and compensation. Here there may be expectations promotes innovations that may improve system efficiency over
on the part of entrepreneur that they will be rewarded if they the longer term. In such cases, monitoring crucial behaviour,
perform as per expectations. Such entrepreneurs may be encour- interim progress evaluations, and identification and responses
aged through subsidies of monitoring costs to undertake inno- to precursors of failure is essential. Otherwise it is difficult to
vative projects and linked with some incentives. However, if the know the reasons why a project failed (whether it is because of
entrepreneur fails to perform in low-risk projects, there can be the risky project or because of the low effort). Here, such high-
additional sanctions on them like publicising poor performance, risk performers may be asked to submit performance reports
and restricting future CDM participation, etc, [Mitchell and regularly. In such cases, the monitoring costs have to be borne
Parson 2001]. by the entrepreneur. This would impose some additional cost and
In case of low project risk and high participant risk, profitability inconvenience on responsible entrepreneurs, but this is the only
from incremental effort will be discounted by the low expected way to screen fraudulent entrepreneurs who plan to shirk their
profit and so is the responsiveness of the agent to the incentive. responsibilities, as they are likely to reject such provisions at the

Economic and Political Weekly October 11, 2003 4335


Figure 3: Monitoring and Incentive Strategy
Project Risk
High
Profitability from incremental effort is Profitability from incremental
low ⇒ incentive intensity (ΙΙ)↓ effort is high ⇒ incentive
Absolute risk aversion high ⇒ ΙΙ↓ intensity (ΙΙ) ↑

Precision of performance Absolute risk aversion low ⇒ ΙΙ ↑


measurement high ⇒ ΙΙ↓ Precision of performance
Agent’s risk tolerance high ⇒ ΙΙ↓ measurement high ⇒ ΙΙ↓

Investor takes risk Agent’s risk tolerance


ambiguous ⇒ ΙΙ↓or ↑
Constant wage
High incentive with careful
Minimal monitoring monitoring

Low High Participant


Risk

Profitability from incremental effort Profitability from incremental effort


is low ⇒ incentive intensity (ΙΙ)↓ is high ⇒ ΙΙ↑
Absolute risk aversion high ⇒ ΙΙ↓ Absolute risk aversion low ⇒ ΙΙ↑
Precision of performance Precision of performance
measurement low ⇒ ΙΙ↑ measurement low ⇒ ΙΙ↓
Agent’s risk tolerance high ⇒ β↓ Agent’s risk tolerance low ⇒ ΙΙ↑
Low incentive contracting Very high incentive/careful
With low cost monitoring monitoring

Not much space to give Let the agent take the risk. There is
much space to give incentive to the
Incentives to agent because of agent but limited by project risk
participating constraint

Low

beginning of the project. To verify that self-reporting is reliable measures should be explored so that the ERUs from small deals
the investor has to incur second-party and third-party monitoring can compete with high-volume low-cost projections
if necessary. If the project failed due to unforeseen factors despite (www.prototypecarbonfund.org). Given this heterogeneity of
good performance, the agents are required to demonstrate full transactions, determining a price for the ERUs is also a challenge
performance before credits are disbursed [Goldsmith and Basak due to the absence of a public liquid market. The prices also
2001]. vary from contract to contract, depending on the level of risk
In the above cases, the design of incentives is under the standard inherent in the transaction and the underlying project. Prospective
CDM project model involving an exchange in which a single market prices will depend largely on evolution of demand and
investor receives credits and a single entrepreneur is paid for supply. This makes the whole mechanism quite risky and com-
generating them. However, as the CDM develops, some projects plex. As the intermediary is risk-neutral he can bear all the risks
may involve multiple participants on the investor side, with and give a pro rata share of emissions to all the investors according
credits being allocated among them as part of the project design. to their investments in the fund.
Such large emission reduction projects are ideal as they have As discussed in the introduction there is some non-participant
low transaction costs.7 However, larger projects would also require risk (from governments) associated with the CDM mechanism.
managing a mixed portfolio of projects, including innovative and Projects in different sovereign states may face different risk
high-risk ones, of which some – or many – fall short of expec- premia owing to the perceived level of risk of default or project
tations. This is similar to diversification of risk of individual failure due to the general nature of the economy or the nature
stocks in a stock portfolio. As discussed earlier, this would be of the government. So using an intermediary with reputation and
extremely costly for the investors and in such cases using an bargaining power would minimise risks. The intermediary in this
intermediary would be highly beneficial to both the parties. case can be powerful in influencing governments in undertaking
There are several other reasons in support of the use of in- projects and subsequently contribute to the overall system suc-
termediary apart from diversifying the portfolio. As discussed cess. Further a large intermediary like the World Bank can ensure
earlier though it is ideal to have large projects because of low successful screening of the participants due to its experience by
transaction costs, many countries have small-scale renewable linking current or future participation to past performance. EPW
energy and energy efficiency opportunities that can enhance their
rural economies and provide clean technology in manufacturing Address for correspondence:
and infrastructure. Financing tiny projects of hundreds of watts haripriya@mse.ac.in
to a few KW of installed power, or to mass distribution of single
energy-efficient appliances, such as air conditioners/solar water
Notes
heaters, is very difficult (involving high transaction costs)8 and 1 Most of the developed and industrialised countries.
also challenging. The costs rise with the number of operational 2 Assuming a revenue stream based on emission reduction (at US $3 /t
Co2e) the change in IRR for some of the projects are given below:
entities involved and significantly for smaller projects. However, Energy efficiency – district heating (2–4), wind (0.9–1.3), hydro (1.2–
as the benefits of CDM should reach smaller countries, such 2.6), bagasse (0.5–3.5), biomass projects (upto 5.0), municipal solid waste
projects need to be encouraged. This implies that cost reduction (75.0) (www.prototypecarbonfund.org).

4336 Economic and Political Weekly October 11, 2003


3 See www.prototypecarbonfund.org/document library/project idea Notes/ Franck, Lecocq (2000): States and Trends of the Carbon Market – DECRG/
Latvia PIN PCF Plus Research, http://econ.worldbank.org
4 http://wbln0018.worldbank.org/essd/kb.nsf. India Solar power. Holmstrom, B (1979): ‘Moral Hazard and observability’, Bell Journal of
5 For example, the typical average costs of the PCF projects for negotiation, Economics, 10: 74-91.
approval, validation and contingency are 2,50,000, 40,000, 20,000 and Kerr, S (1997): ‘Towards a Theory of Compliance Institutions for International
31,000 euro respectively [Stronzik 2001]. Traceable Permit Markets: Joint Implementation of the Framework
6 Technical Review and Assessment of the proposed Liepaja Solid Waste Convention on Climate Change’, (Report WP 96-25). College Park:
Management Project, May 2000 University of Maryland.
(www.prototypecarbonfund.org/documents) Metz, B (1995): ‘Joint Implementation as a Financing Instrument for Global
7 For instance, the transaction costs for small projects (i e, carbon reduction Reductions in Greenhouse Gas Emissions’ in K Ramakrishna (ed),
of < 50 t/annum) is 1,000 USD/tC while for large projects (with carbon Criteria for Joint Implementation under the Framework Convention on
reduction of 5,000 – 50,000 t/annum), the transaction costs are only 1$/ Climate Change, Woods Hole Research Centre, Woods Hole MA, pp 25-34.
t C [Stronzik 2001]. Milgrom, P and J Roberts (1992): Economics, Organisation and Management,
8 According to [Pricewaterhousecoopers 2000], the transaction costs for Prentice-Hall, Inc.
a new combined cycle gas turbine (CCGT) plant varies from 0.09 to 0.20$/ Mintzer, I (1994): ‘Institutional Options and Operational Challenges in the
t C for different levels, for retrofit project from 0.08 to 0.17 $/tC, for Management of a Joint Implementation Regime’ in K Ramakrishna (ed),
wind project the transaction costs vary from 0.77 to 1.27$/tC, for 1 MW Criteria for Joint Implementation Under the Framework Convention
PV project the costs vary from 67.4-111.0 $/tC, for 1,000 KW PV project, on Climate Change, Woods Hole Research Centre, MA, pp 25-34.
the costs vary from 674 – 1119$/TC for different levels. Mitchell, R B and E A Parson (2001): ‘Implementing the Climate Change
Regime’s Clean Development Mechanism’, Journal of Environment and
Development, 20 (2): 125-46.
References OECD (2001): ‘Kyoto Mechanisms, Monitoring and Compliance from Kyoto
to The Hague’, http://www.oecd.org/env/cc/
Bolton, P and Freixas, S (1994): ‘Direct Bond Financing, Financial Powell, M, Lile, R and M Toman (1997): ‘Assessing the Constraints
Intermediation and Investment’, Universitat Pompeu Fabra, Bacxelona, and Opportunities for Private-Sector Participation in Activities
Mimeograph as quoted in: Diamond, D W (1984), ‘Financial Inter- Implemented Jointly: Two Case studies from the US Initiative for Joint
mediation and Delegated Monitoring’, The Review of Economic Studies, Implementation’, discussion paper 97-38-REV, Resources for Future,
51(3): 393-414. Washington, DC.
Diamond, D W (1984): ‘Financial Intermediation and Delegated Monitoring’, Price Water House Coopers (2000): ‘A Business View on Key Issues Relating
The Review of Economic Studies, 51(3): 393-414. to Kyoto Mechanisms’, Funded by UK DETR. London.
Goldsmith, P D, and R Basak (2001): ‘Incentive Contracts and Environmental Stronzik, M (2001): ‘Transaction Costs of the Project-Based Kyoto
Performance Indicators’, Environmental and Resource Economics, 20: Mechanisms’, EC Energie Project Number ENG2-CT1999-00004,
259-79. Manheim.

Ashoka Trust for Research in


Ecology and the Environment Ashoka Trust for Research in Ecology and the Environment
www.atree.org

Positions for ecologically oriented social scientist and an outreach coordinator


ATREE invites applications from motivated and qualified persons for the following two positions:
1. Social Scientist: The applicant should have a Ph. D and/or have a credible publication and research record in sociology,
anthropology, political science or related discipline, with demonstrable research experience in applying an interdisciplinary
approach to ecological and environmental issues. Familiarity with public policy, legal, and governance issues associated with
conservation of biological resources and management of natural resources. Candidate should have the ability to initiate and
manage projects independently and to work as a member of an interdisciplinary team.
This position is at the level of Fellow, and will be based in Bangalore. A Fellow position at ATREE is equivalent to that of Assistant
Professor at an academic institution. This position is endowed, with a modest budget for annual operating costs. The candidate
will be appointed for a renewable 5-year term. Our emoluments are competitive with other academic institutions in India.
2. Outreach Coordinator: The position is based out of Bangalore, but requires extensive travel to project sites in South India,
working closely with our Field coordinator to implement community based developmental activities and participatory research in
the area of Natural resource conservation and management. Master’s degree required in any relevant discipline with 3 years experience
in coordinating and implementing relevant community based activities. Must have demonstrated abilities to work with communities
and plan interventions that have a sustained impact. Will be responsible for all written inputs and outputs for this program. Excellent
oral and written skills in English a must. Oral communications in South Indian languages with knowledge of Kannada preferred.
Salary will be commensurate with qualifications and experience. The appointment will be renewed annually.
Applicants should write to the address below, enclosing their CVs, names of three references, and a letter describing how their
profile fits ATREE’s mission and how they plan to contribute to ATREE’s programs. Applicants must be Indian citizens. For more
information on ATREE please look at www.atree.org
Deadline for application: November 15, 2003 or until suitable candidates are found.

The Director, ATREE, 659, 5th A Main Rd, Hebbal, Bangalore 560024
Phone: 80-3533942, 3530069 Fax: 80-3530070, Email: director@atree.org or info@atree.org

Economic and Political Weekly October 11, 2003 4337

Anda mungkin juga menyukai