Anda di halaman 1dari 841

The SAGE

Handbook of

Organizational
Institutionalism
The SAGE
Handbook of

Organizational
Institutionalism

Edited by
Royston Greenwood
Christine Oliver
Roy Suddaby
and Kerstin Sahlin

SAGE
Los Angeles • London • New Delhi • Singapore
© Sage Publications 2008

First published 2008

Apart from any fair dealing for the purposes of research or


private study, or criticism or review, as permitted under the
Copyright, Designs and Patents Act, 1988, this publication may
be reproduced, stored or transmitted in any form, or by any
means, only with the prior permission in writing of the publishers,
or in the case of reprographic reproduction, in accordance with the
terms of licences issued by the Copyright Licensing Agency.
Enquiries concerning reproduction outside those terms should be
sent to the publishers.

SAGE Publications Ltd


1 Oliver’s Yard
55 City Road
London EC1Y 1SP

SAGE Publications Inc.


2455 Teller Road
Thousand Oaks, California 91320

SAGE Publications India Pvt Ltd


B1/I 1, Mohan Cooperative Industrial Area
Mathura Road
New Delhi 110 044

SAGE Publications Asia-Pacific Pte Ltd


33 Pekin Street # 02-01
Far East Square, Singapore 048763

Library of Congress Control Number: 2007932329

British Library Cataloguing in Publication data

A catalogue record for this book is available from the British Library

ISBN 978-1-4129-3123-6

Typeset by CEPHA Imaging Pvt. Ltd., Bangalore, India


Printed in Great Britain by The Cromwell Press, Trowbridge, Wiltshire
Printed on paper from sustainable resources
Contents

Notes on Contributors viii

Introduction 1
Royston Greenwood, Christine Oliver, Kerstin Sahlin and Roy Suddaby

SECTION I FOUNDATIONAL THEMES 47

1 Legitimacy in Organizational Institutionalism 49


David L. Deephouse and Mark Suchman

2 Isomorphism, Diffusion and Decoupling 78


Eva Boxenbaum and Stefan Jonsson

3 Institutional Logics 99
Patricia H. Thornton and William Ocasio

4 Organizational Fields: Past, Present and Future 130


Melissa Wooten and Andrew J. Hoffman

SECTION II INSTITUTIONAL DYNAMICS 149

5 The Work of Meanings in Institutional Processes and Thinking 151


Tammar B. Zilber

6 Power, Institutions and Organizations 170


Thomas B. Lawrence

7 Institutional Entrepreneurship 198


Cynthia Hardy and Steve Maguire

8 Circulating Ideas: Imitation, Translation and Editing 218


Kerstin Sahlin and Linda Wedlin

9 Organizational Implications of Institutional Pluralism 243


Matthew S. Kraatz and Emily S. Block
vi CONTENTS

10 Microfoundations of Institutional Theory 276


Walter W. Powell and Jeannette A. Colyvas

11 Institutions and Transnationalization 299


Marie-Laure Djelic and Sigrid Quack

SECTION III APPLICATIONS 325

12 Traditions as Institutionalized Practice: Implications


for Deinstitutionalization 327
M. Tina Dacin and Peter A. Dacin

13 New Forms as Settlements 352


Hayagreeva Rao and Martin Kenney

14 Social Movements and Failed Institutionalization:


Corporate (Non) Response to the AIDS Epidemic 371
Gerald F. Davis and Peter J.J. Anderson

15 Institutions and Corporate Governance 389


Peer C. Fiss

SECTION IV INTERFACES 411

16 Beyond Constraint: How Institutions Enable Identities 413


Mary Ann Glynn

17 Institutionalism and the Professions 431


Kevin T. Leicht and Mary L. Fennell

18 Institutionalism and Globalization Studies 449


Gili S. Drori

19 Organizational Institutionalism and Sociology: A Reflection 473


C.R. Hinings and Pamela S. Tolbert

20 Coalface Institutionalism 491


Stephen R. Barley

21 New Sociology of Knowledge: Historical Legacy and Contributions


to Current Debates in Institutional Research 519
Renate E. Meyer

22 Systems Theory, Societal Contexts, and Organizational Heterogeneity 539


Raimund Hasse and Georg Krücken

23 Charting Progress at the Nexus of Institutional Theory and Economics 560


Peter W. Roberts
CONTENTS vii

24 Ecologists and Institutionalists: Friends or Foes? 573


Heather A. Haveman and Robert J. David

25 Networks and Institutions 596


Jason Owen-Smith and Walter W. Powell

26 Institutional-Level Learning: Learning as a Source of Institutional Change 624


Pamela Haunschild and David Chandler

27 Social Movements and Institutional Analysis 650


Marc Schneiberg and Michael Lounsbury

28 Examining ‘Institutionalization’: A Critical Theoretic Perspective 673


David J. Cooper, Mahmoud Ezzamel and Hugh Willmott

29 Taking Social Construction Seriously: Extending the Discursive


Approach in Institutional Theory 702
Nelson Phillips and Namrata Malhotra

30 Institutional Leadership: Past, Present and Future 721


Marvin Washington, Kimberly B. Boal and John N. Davis

SECTION V REFLECTIONS 737

31 Is the New Institutionalism a Theory? 739


Donald Palmer, Nicole Biggart and Brian Dick

32 How to Misuse Institutions and Get Away with It: Some Reflections
on Institutional Theory(ies) 769
Barbara Czarniawska

33 Been There, Done That, Moving On: Reflections on Institutional


Theory’s Continuing Evolution 783
Paul Hirsch

34 Reflections on Institutional Theories of Organizations 790


John W. Meyer

Index 813
Notes on Contributors
Peter Anderson is a former doctoral student in management and organization at the Ross
School of Business at the University of Michigan. His research is focused on the relationship
between shared leadership and members’ perceptions of their value to an organization. He is
currently pursuing his Masters in Education to teach social studies at the secondary level.

Stephen R. Barley is Charles M. Pigott Professor of Management Science and Engineering,


Co-Director of the Center for Work, Technology and Organization at Stanford’s School of
Engineering and Co-Director of the Stanford/General Motors Collaborative Research
Laboratory. He has previously edited the Administrative Science Quarterly, and was founding
editor of the Stanford Social Innovation Review. He edited Between Craft and Science:
Technical Work in the United States (Cornell University Press, 1997), and recently published
(with Gideon Kunda) the book Gurus, Hired Guns and Warm Bodies: Itinerant Experts in the
Knowledge Economy (Princeton University Press).

Nicole Woolsey Biggart is Professor of Management and Sociology, and holds the Jerome J.
and Elsie Suran Chair in Technology Management at the University of California, Davis. She
is currently serving as Dean of the Graduate School of Management. Nicole is interested in the
institutional structure of economic relations and has studied the direct selling industry, family
firms and business groups in Asia, and microcredit lending. While her empirical interests have
been varied she has largely approached analysis from a Weberian institutional perspective and
grounds her work historically. She has also written extensively on institutional theory.

Emily Block is a Ph.D candidate at the University of Illinois at Champaign-Urbana. Her


research focuses on how organizations actively shape institutions and promote field-level
change. Her doctoral dissertation explores the process through which industry associations
and non-governmental organizations facilitate and direct the emergence of self-regulatory
governance institutions related to sustainable forestry practices.

Kimberly B. Boal is Rawls Professor of Management at the Rawls College of Business,


Texas Tech University. He was Co-Editor-in-Chief of the Journal of Management Inquiry
(1997–2006). He served on the Board of Governors of the Academy of Management from 2001
to 2004, and as President of the Western Academy of Management in 1998–2000. He was twice
awarded the Joan G. Dahl Presidential Award by the Western Academy of Management. His
research on worker attitudes and motivation, leadership, organizational change, strategic plan-
ning, mergers and acquisitions, and corporate social responsibility has been published in
Academy of Management Executive, Academy of Management Review, Administrative Science
Quarterly, Journal of Management, Leadership Quarterly, and Strategic Management Journal,
and books.

Eva Boxenbaum is Assistant Professor in the Department of Organization at Copenhagen


Business School, where she is also a member of the Centre for Management Studies of the
Building Process. The focus of her research is on the institutionalization of innovative management
practices, in particular, how management practices are translated, implemented, and sometimes
NOTES ON CONTRIBUTORS ix

decoupled when they are brought into new national contexts. Her regional areas of expertise
are Canada, Denmark, France, Quebec and the United States. Most of her empirical work is
comparative in scope and spans multiple levels of analysis, the aim being to shed light on
processes of institutionalization. She has published in Strategic Organization, Journal of
Business Strategies, American Behavioral Scientist and in several international anthologies.

David Chandler is a Ph.D candidate in organization theory and strategy at the University
of Texas at Austin. His broad area of research interest lies at the intersection between the
organization and its institutional environment. Specifically, he is interested in change processes
of organizational adoption, learning, and imitation. He is also interested in the strategic impli-
cations of corporate social responsibility and firm/stakeholder relations. His publications in this
area include the textbook Strategic Corporate Social Responsibility (Sage, December 2005).

Jeannette A. Colyvas is an assistant professor in learning and organizational change at


Northwestern University's School of Education and Social Policy. Her research interests
include organizations and entrepreneurship, comparing public, private, and non-profit forms
of organizing, and institutional change. Colyvas' work examines the relationship between insti-
tutions and resources, practices and their meanings, and how social and technical categories
develop and become institutionalized. Her current research examines university–industry
interfaces, focusing on the translation of basic science into commercial application and its
ramifications for careers, identities, and public science.

David J. Cooper is the CGA Chair in Accounting at the University of Alberta and Director of
the Ph.D program for the School of Business. He has written or edited seven books and over
70 articles (in journals such as Accounting, Organizations and Society, Administrative Science
Quarterly, and Organization Studies). He is a joint editor of Critical Perspectives on
Accounting, and serves on the editorial boards of seven other journals. His current research
examines the development and implementation of strategic performance measurement
systems in multinational organizations, as well as the emerging systems of global regulation
of professional accountants.

Barbara Czarniawska holds a Chair in Management Studies at GRI, School of Business,


Economics and Law, Göteborg University, Sweden. Her recent publications in English are
A Tale of Three Cities (2002), Narratives in Social Science Research (2004) and A Theory
of Organizing (2008). She edited Global Ideas (with Guje Sevón, 2005), ANT and Organizing
(with Tor Hernes, 2005), Organization Theory (2006) and Management Education
& Humanities (with Pasquale Gagliardi, 2006).

Peter A. Dacin is Kraft Professor of Marketing at the Queen’s School of Business, Queen’s
University, Canada. His research areas include corporate reputation and identity, consumer judg-
ment formation, and sociological approaches to understanding communication and consumption.
He is currently working on several projects focused on understanding communication and coordi-
nation effects between marketing organizations and various types of consumption communities.
His work has been published in a variety of academic journals, including the Journal
of Marketing, Journal of Marketing Research, Journal of Consumer Research, Journal of the
Academy of Marketing Science, and the Journal of Business Research.

M. Tina Dacin is the E. Marie Shantz Professor of Strategy and Organizational Behavior in
the Queen’s School of Business, Queen’s University, Canada. Her research interests include
x NOTES ON CONTRIBUTORS

institutional change, organizational traditions, social entrepreneurship and partner selection in


alliances. She is currently working on several projects that examine the intersection between
culture and institutions. Her work has been published in the Academy of Management Journal,
Academy of Management Review, Accounting, Organizations, and Society, Journal of Management,
Journal of World Business, Organization Science, and the Strategic Management Journal.

Robert David (Ph.D, Cornell University) is Associate Professor of Strategy & Organization
and Cleghorn Faculty Scholar at the Desautels Faculty of Management of McGill University.
He is also Director of the Center for Strategy Studies in Organization at McGill. He studies the
evolution of industries and organizational forms from an institutional perspective. Robert has
published articles in Research Policy, Strategic Management Journal, Academy of
Management Journal, and Organization Science.

Gerald Davis is Wilbur K. Pierpont Collegiate Professor of Management at the Ross School
of Business and Professor of Sociology, the University of Michigan. His research examines the
influence of politics and social networks on the institutions of corporate governance and the
effects of financial globalization on social structure and politics. Recent books include
Organizations and Organizing: Rational, Natural, and Open System Perspectives (with
W. Richard Scott) and Social Movements and Organization Theory (co-edited with Doug
McAdam, W. Richard Scott, and Mayer Zald).

John N. Davis recently completed his Ph.D in leadership at Texas Tech University and is
currently on the faculty at Coastal Carolina University. In June 2008, he will move to the Kelley
College of Business at Hardin-Simmons University to become an assistant professor of manage-
ment. His research examines how leaders change over time, with special emphasis on charisma.

David Deephouse is an Associate Professor in the Department of Strategic Management and


Organization at the University of Alberta School of Business. He received his Ph.D from the
Carlson School of Management at the University of Minnesota. His research interests include
legitimacy, reputation, and organizational similarity, especially on the media’s role in them.

Brian Dick is a Ph.D candidate in the Department of Sociology at the University of California,
Davis. His research interests include social theory, the philosophy of the social sciences, organ-
ization studies, and science and technology studies. He is currently working on his dissertation,
which consists of a historical and sociological analysis of the proliferation of superstring theory
among physics departments. This work develops the concept of scientific legitimacy drawing
on ideas current in organization studies and science and technology studies.

Marie-Laure Djelic is Professor at ESSEC Business School, Paris. Her research interests
range from the role of professions and social networks in the transnational diffusion of rules
and practices to the historical transformation of national institutions. She is the author of
Exporting the American Model (Oxford University Press, 1998), which obtained the 2000 Max
Weber Award from the American Sociological Association. She has edited, together with Sigrid
Quack, Globalization and Institutions (Edward Elgar, 2003) and together with Kerstin
Sahlin-Andersson, Transnational Governance (Cambridge University Press, 2006).

Gili S. Drori is a lecturer in Stanford University’s International Relations Program and Director
of the IR Honors Program. Her research interests include the comparative study of science,
social progress and rationalization, globalization, and governance. Her interests on world
NOTES ON CONTRIBUTORS xi

culture, global health, technology entrepreneurship, and higher education have appeared in her
books: Science in the Modern World Polity: Institutionalization and Globalization (2003,
co-authored with John W. Meyer, Francisco O. Ramirez and Evan Schofer), Global E-litism:
Digital Technology, Social Inequality, and Transnationality (2005), and World Society and the
Expansion of Formal Organization (2006, co-edited with John W. Meyer and Hokyu Hwang).

Mahmoud Ezzamel is Cardiff Professorial Fellow, Cardiff University. His main research
interests are in the areas of the interface between social theory and organization analysis, with
particular emphasis on accounting practice. He has published papers in Administrative Science
Quarterly, Academy of Management Journal, Accounting, Organizations and Society,
Organization Studies, Journal of Management Studies, Organization, as well as in other
leading accounting and management journals.

Mary L. Fennell is Professor and Chair of the Department of Sociology at Brown University.
She coauthored (with Richard Warnecke) the book The Diffusion of Medical Innovation:
An Applied Network Approach (Plenum, 1988). Her work has been published in Health
Affairs, Health Services Research, Administrative Science Quarterly, the Journal of Health and
Social Behavior, and the Academy of Management Journal. Her current research continues in
areas of nursing home quality of care differences (with Vince Mor), cultural competence in
nursing home care (with Melissa Clark), and studies of change over time in professional work,
professional labor markets, and professional organizations (with Kevin Leicht; Professional
Work, Blackwell 2001). She served Brown University as Dean of the Faculty from 2000 to
2004.

Peer C. Fiss is an assistant professor of strategy at the Marshall School of Business at the
University of Southern California. His current research interests include corporate governance,
framing and symbolic management, and the use of set-theoretic methods such as Qualitative
Comparative Analysis (QCA) in management and the social sciences. His articles have
appeared in journals such as the Administrative Science Quarterly, American Sociological
Review, Academy of Management Journal, Academy of Management Review, and the Strategic
Management Journal.

Mary Ann Glynn is Professor of Organization Studies, Professor of Sociology, and Fellow
and Research Director for the Winston Center for Leadership and Ethics at Boston College.
She is the nationally elected Program Officer for the Academy of Management, Managerial
and Organizational Cognition Division. Her research has been published in Academy of
Management Journal, Academy of Management Review, Organization Science, Strategic
Management Journal, Journal of Applied Psychology, Journal of Management Studies, Journal
of Marketing, and Poetics: International Journal of Empirical Research on Art, Media, and
Literature, and edited books.

Royston Greenwood (Ph.D, University of Birmingham, UK) is TELUS Professor of Strategic


Management in the Department of Strategic Management and Organization, School of
Business, University of Alberta. His research focuses upon the dynamics of institutional
change, especially at the field-level of analysis. His favored empirical settings involve profes-
sional service firms. Recently, his research has explored how and why large professional service
firms developed new organizational forms, with particular reference to how they are ‘theorized’
and thus legitimated. One paper from this research stream won the Academy of Management
Journal’s 2006 Best Paper Award. His work has appeared in Administrative Science Quarterly,
xii NOTES ON CONTRIBUTORS

Academy of Management Journal, Academy of Management Review, Organization Science, and


Organization Studies. He is a founding co-editor of Strategic Organization.

Cynthia Hardy is Professor of Management at the University of Melbourne and co-director


of the International Centre for Research on Organizational Discourse, Strategy & Change.
Her recent research includes a focus on institutional entrepreneurship and institutional change
from a discursive perspective, and has been published in Academy of Management Journal,
Academic of Management Review. She has also co-edited a special issue of Organization
Studies on institutional entrepreneurship. Other research interests revolve around the study
of power and politics in organizations, organizational discourse theory, and critical
discourse analysis. She has published Discourse Analysis: Investigating Processes of
Social Construction, as well as co-editing a special issue of Organization Studies on
organizational discourse and the Sage Handbook of Organizational Discourse. In total, she
has written over 60 journal articles and book chapters; and published twelve books and edited
volumes.

Raimund Hasse is associate professor for Sociology, Organization and Knowledge at the
University of Lucerne, Switzerland. His research interests include organization theory and new
institutionalism. His book Wohlfahrtspolitik und Globalisierung (2003) deals with the interplay
of organizational and political changes. Other publications have dealt with changes in
the organization of work, with organizational impacts of new technologies, and with issues
of innovation. Currently, Raimund Hasse is conducting a research project that investigates the
formation of new organizations.

Pamela Haunschild is the Herbert D. Kelleher/MCorp Professor of Business as well as


Chair of the Department of Management at the McCombs School of Business, University
of Texas-Austin. Her research involves studying organizational (and inter-organizational)
learning processes, especially how and under what circumstances organizations learn from
their errors. She is also interested in issues related to networks and corporate governance as
well as how governance decisions are affected by network information and influence. Her work
has been published in several key management journals, including Administrative Science
Quarterly, Organization Science, and Management Science.

Heather A. Haveman is Professor of Sociology and Organizational Behavior at the University


of California, Berkeley. Her research investigates organizations’ responses to shifting internal
and external conditions, the impact of organizational change on performance and survival, and
the consequences of organizational structures and dynamics for employees’ careers and the
composition of organizations’ work forces. She has published in Administrative Science
Quarterly, the American Sociological Review, the American Journal of Sociology, the Academy
of Management Journal, and Organization Science.

Bob Hinings is Professor Emeritus in the Department of Strategic Management and


Organization and Senior Research Fellow in the Center for Entrepreneurship and Family
Enterprise, School of Business, University of Alberta. He is currently carrying out research into
health care organization. He is also involved in research into the organization of the Canadian
wine industry. All of his research is concerned with organizational change.

Paul Hirsch is the Allen Professor of Strategy and Organization at Northwestern University’s
Kellogg School of Management. He has received the “Distinguished Scholar” award from the
NOTES ON CONTRIBUTORS xiii

Academy of Management’s Division of Organization and Management Theory. He has also


served as Chair of this division, and on the boards of the American Sociological Association’s
Sections on Economic Sociology, and Organizations, Occupations and Work. His early study
of “Organizational Effectiveness and the Institutional Environment” helped expand the field’s
traditional focus on firms, to include industries and organizational fields, political economy and
regulation. He remains interested in the changes wrought by deregulation and similar insti-
tutional failures as the collapse of the Savings and Loan industry and, more recently, the large-
scale losses suffered by lenders and borrowers connected to the wide-spread failure of
subprime mortgage loans.

Andrew (Andy) Hoffman is Holcim (US) Professor of Sustainable Enterprise at the


University of Michigan. He has published five books and over fifty articles and book chapters
on environmental and social issues as they relate to business. He recently published the report
Getting Ahead of the Curve: Corporate Strategies that Address Climate Change with the Pew
Center on Global Climate Change. His book From Heresy to Dogma was awarded the 2001
Rachel Carson Prize. He serves on the editorial board of Organization & Environment. His
research deals with the nature and dynamics of change within institutional and cultural systems
and he applies that research towards understanding the cultural and managerial implications of
environmental protection and sustainability for industry.

Stefan Jonsson is currently a researcher at Uppsala University, Sweden. His research centers
on the interaction of norms, the spread of ideas and market structures. His earlier work centers
on norms that guide competitive behavior across firms and how these can lead to a systematic
undervaluation of the use of some new practices. More recently, he has focused on the role that
media plays in the structuring of markets and the spread of bad reputation.

Martin Kenney is a professor in the Department of Human and Community Development at


the University of California, Davis, and a senior project director at the Berkeley Roundtable on
the International Economy. He has been interested in the processes by which entrepreneurs
commercialize new technical developments, and through this process, enact new industries. Of
particular interest to him are the mechanisms by which regions develop institutions to support
entrepreneurial activity and the geography and dynamics of these support networks. His recent
research is in three areas: the evolution of the venture capital industry in the U.S. and globally,
the entrepreneurial support networks and genealogies of entrepreneurship in regions, and the
emergence of India as a leader in offshore service provision.

Matt Kraatz (Ph.D, Northwestern University) is an associate professor in the Department


of Business Administration at the University of Illinois. His scholarly interests include
organizational adaptation, governance, identity, leadership, and other institutional processes.
His research has been published in the Academy of Management Journal, the Strategic
Management Journal, Organization Science, and the American Sociological Review.

Georg Krücken (Ph.D, Bielefeld University, Germany) is professor of Science Organization,


Higher Education and Science Management at the German University of Administrative Sciences
in Speyer. After studying sociology, philosophy, and political sciences at Bielefeld University
and the University of Bologna, he worked as an associate professor at Bielefeld until 2006. From
1999 to 2001 he was a visiting scholar at the Department of Sociology at Stanford University.
He taught as a guest professor at the Institute for Science Studies, University of Vienna, and
at the Centre de Sociologie des Organisations, Sciences Po, Paris. His research interests include
xiv NOTES ON CONTRIBUTORS

science studies, organizational studies, the management of higher education, and neo-institutional
theory.

Thomas B. Lawrence (Ph.D, University of Alberta) is Weyerhaeuser Professor of Change


Management, and Director of the CMA Center for Strategic Change and Performance
Measurement at Simon Fraser University in Vancouver, Canada. After receiving his doctorate
in 1993 he was on the faculty of the University of Victoria until 2002. His research focuses on
the dynamics of power, change and institutions in organizations and organizational fields.

Kevin T. Leicht is Professor of Sociology, Director of the Social Science Research Center, and
co-Director of the Institute for Inequality Studies at The University of Iowa. He is editor of
Research in Social Stratification and Mobility. His research examines the relationship between
globalization and economic development, and their relationship to the production of social
inequality. His work has appeared in The American Sociological Review, American Journal of
Sociology, Social Forces, and The Academy of Management Journal.

Michael Lounsbury is Associate Professor of Strategic Management and Organization


at the University of Alberta School of Business and the National Institute of Nanotechnology.
His research focuses on the relationship between organizational and institutional change, entre-
preneurial dynamics, and the emergence of new industries and practices. He has published
research on topics such as social movement activism and the construction of the recycling
industry, and the professionalization of money managers in the mutual fund industry.
He is currently investigating the co-evolution of nanoscience and nanotechnology.
Professor Lounsbury serves on a number of editorial boards and his work has been published
in Administrative Science Quarterly, Academy of Management Journal, Academy of
Management Review, Strategic Management Journal, and Organization Studies. In addition, he
is the series editor of Research in the Sociology of Organizations, and co-editor in-chief of
Journal of Management Inquiry.

Steve Maguire is Associate Professor of Strategy and Organization in the Desautels Faculty
of Management at McGill University. His research focuses on institutional and technological
change resulting when commercial, scientific and political struggles intersect around social
or environmental issues. His doctoral dissertation draws lessons from society’s experience
with the insecticide DDT and was awarded the Academy of Management’s ‘Organization
and Natural Environment (ONE)’ Best Doctoral Dissertation Award in 2001. He has also
studied the pharmaceutical industry, analysing the impact of the empowerment of people
living with HIV/AIDS on the commercialization, availability and accessibility of HIV/AIDS
treatments.

Namrata Malhotra is on faculty in the Tanaka Business School, Imperial College, London,
UK. Her research is focused on understanding processes of organizational change, especially
in professional service organizations. She has been involved in projects investigating change
processes in Australian, British, and Canadian law firms. Currently, she is pursuing research
examining institutional change processes in law firms.

John W. Meyer is Professor of Sociology, emeritus, at Stanford. He has contributed to


organizational theory, comparative education, and the sociology of education, developing lines
of thought now called sociological institutional theory. Recently, he completed a collaborative
study of worldwide science and its impact on national societies (Drori, et al., Science in the
NOTES ON CONTRIBUTORS xv

Modern World Polity, Stanford, 2003). Another collaborative project, on the impact of global-
ization on organizational structures, has just been published (Drori et al., eds., Globalization
and Organization, Oxford 2006). He now studies the rise and impact of the world human
rights regime, world curricula of mass and higher education, and the global expansion of higher
education.

Renate E. Meyer is Professor for Public Management at Wirtschaftsuniversität Wien, Austria.


Her research interests include the communicative construction of institutions and related framing
processes, the role of meaning in processes of institutional maintenance and change, and the
conceptualization of time. Her recent work addresses translations and alignments of global
management concepts to local opportunity structures, social identities, and the development
of communicative institutions. Renate is particularly interested in combining qualitative and
quantitative research. She is currently co-editing a volume on institutions and ideology.

William Ocasio is the John L. and Helen Kellogg Distinguished Professor of Management and
Organizations at the Kellogg Graduate School of Management, Northwestern University. His
research integrates institutional, cognitive, and political perspectives to explain organizational
decision making and organizational change. Current research projects include examining the
role of vocabularies of organizing in shaping decision making, and developing a political
capital perspective on power in organizations.

Christine Oliver is the Henry J. Knowles Chair of Organizational Strategy in the Schulich
School of Business at York University, Toronto. Her work has appeared in Administrative
Science Quarterly, Academy of Management Review, Organization Studies, Academy of
Management Journal, Advances in Strategic Management, Journal of Management Studies,
Strategic Management Journal, and American Sociological Review. Christine is on the
editorial board of the Journal of Management Studies, and is a past Representative-At-Large
on the Academy of Management Board of Governors. Christine is past Associate Editor
(1993–1996) and Editor (1996–2003) of the Administrative Science Quarterly.

Jason Owen-Smith is Assistant Professor of Sociology and Organizational Studies at the


University of Michigan in Ann Arbor. He is interested in institutional and organizational change,
innovation, the dynamics of complex social and economic networks and the commercialization
of academic research. His current project focuses on the intersection of science, technology,
and commerce in academe with particular emphasis on the ramifications of patenting,
licensing, and university–industry collaborations.

Donald Palmer is Professor of Organizational Behavior and Associate Dean for Research in
the Graduate School of Management at the University of California, Davis. He is also Editor
of Administrative Science Quarterly. He has conducted quantitative empirical studies on
corporate strategy, structure, and inter-organizational relations. And he is currently embarked
on a series of qualitative empirical studies of organizational wrongdoing, the first of which
appeared in Management Inquiry and the second of which is in press at Research in
Organizational Behavior.

Nelson Phillips is Professor of Strategy and Organizational Behaviour at Tanaka Business


School, Imperial College London. His research interests include knowledge management,
technology strategy, institutional theory, social entrepreneurship, management in cultural
industries, and international management. He has published over 60 academic articles and book
xvi NOTES ON CONTRIBUTORS

chapters, including articles in the Academy of Management Journal, Academy of Management


Review, Management Science, Sloan Management Review, Organization Science, Journal
of Management Studies, Journal of Business Ethics, and Organization Studies. He has also
written two books: one with Cynthia Hardy, Discourse Analysis (2002) and a second with
Stewart Clegg and David Courpasson, Power and Organizations (2006).

Walter W. Powell is professor of education and affiliated professor of sociology, organizational


behavior, management science and engineering, and communication at Stanford University.
He is also an external faculty member at the Santa Fe Institute. He works in the areas of organ-
ization theory, social networks, and economic sociology. He is particularly interested in the
processes through which knowledge is transferred across organizations, and the role
of networks in facilitating and hindering innovation processes. With Jeannette Colyvas, he is
studying the origins of organizational practices that eventually become codified and institution-
alized. With Hokyu Hwang, he is studying the consequences of increased professionalization
in the nonprofit sector, and its impact on civil society organizations. With Jason Owen-Smith,
he is studying the evolving network and institutional structures of the life sciences field and the
reshaping of the boundaries of public and private science.

Sigrid Quack is a research fellow at the Max Planck Institute for the Study of Societies in
Cologne. Her books include National Capitalisms, Global Competition and Economic
Performance, which she edited together with Glenn Morgan and Richard Whitley,
Globalization and Institutions, edited with Marie-Laure Djelic and Grenzüberschreitungen –
Grenzziehungen (Edition Sigma 2006, edited in German with Ariane Berthoin Antal). She has
also published articles in Cambridge Journal of Economics, Environment and Planning,
International Journal of Human Resource Management, Organization, Organization Studies
and Theory and Society.

Hayagreeva Rao is the Atholl McBean Professor of Organizational Behavior at the


Graduate School of Business, Stanford University. He studies the social and cultural causes
of organizational change.

Peter Roberts’ primary research interests relate to how the behavior and performance of
organizations evolve over time. He has studied these issues in diverse settings, including the
pharmaceutical industry, the retail banking industry, the hotel industry, and the global wine
industry. His research has been published in Academy of Management Review, American
Journal of Sociology, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, Organization Science,
and Strategic Management Journal. Peter has also served on the faculties of Columbia
University, Carnegie Mellon University, and the Australian Graduate School of Management.

Kerstin Sahlin is professor of management at Uppsala University. Her research interests


include transnational governance, transformed public-private relations, governance of health
care and universities, and the travels of management ideas. She recently edited Transnational
Governance: Institutional Dynamics of Regulation (Cambridge University Press, 2006, with
Marie-Laure Djelic) and The Expansion of Management Knowledge: Carriers, Flows and
Sources (Stanford University Press, 2002, with Lars Engwall). She is currently the Deputy
Vice-Chancellor of Uppsala University

Marc Schneiberg is the John C. Pock Professor of Sociology at Reed College. He researches
variety and change in economic organization, with particular emphasis on collective and public
alternatives to for-profit corporations in the American economy. He is currently completing an
NOTES ON CONTRIBUTORS xvii

NSF-funded study of private, public, and cooperative enterprise. His research on alternatives,
organizational form, and social movements appears in Politics and Society, American Journal
of Sociology, American Sociological Review, Research in the Sociology of Organizations, and
Socio-Economic Review.

Mark Suchman is professor of Sociology at Brown University. His research interests center
on the relationship between law and organizations, particularly the role of legal institutions
in formally and informally legitimating innovation and entrepreneurship in the information
technology, nanotechnology, and healthcare sectors. In addition to his work on legitimacy,
he has also written on inter-organizational disputing, on the “internalization” of law within
corporate bureaucracies, and on contracts as social artifacts.

Roy Suddaby is an associate professor at the Alberta School of Business. His theoretical focus
is on processes of institutional change. His research has been published in Administrative
Science Quarterly, Academy of Management Journal, Journal of Organizational Behavior,
Accounting, Organizations and Society and Human Relations. Roy serves on the editorial
boards of Administrative Science Quarterly, Academy of Management Review, Academy of
Management Journal, Organization Studies, Journal of Management Studies and the
Scandinavian Journal of Management. He is currently studying corporate art collections.

Patricia H. Thornton is Associate Professor of Management at Duke University Fuqua School


of Business and Visiting Associate Professor at Stanford University Department of Sociology.
Her interests are in organization theory, economic sociology, and entrepreneurship. Her book
Markets from Culture: Institutional Logics and Organizational Decisions (2004) shows how
institutional logics influence executives’ discovery and development of market opportunities.
She has authored reviews of entrepreneurship literature in the Annual Review of Sociology and
the Handbook of Entrepreneurship Research. Currently, she is researching on how institutional
logics affect innovation discovery and the strategic decision to use network relations in
product development and distribution and also is comparing the long-term survival rates of
internal corporate ventures with ventures founded independently.

Pamela S. Tolbert is a professor and chair of the Department of Organizational Behavior


in the ILR School at Cornell University. Her research is broadly focused on processes
of organizational change, the role of organizations in social stratification, and the impact of
occupations on organizational structures. She has served on the editorial boards of
Administrative Science Quarterly, American Sociological Review, Organization Science,
Journal of Engineering and Technology Management and Sociological Forum, as the book
review editor for Administrative Science Quarterly, and as an associate editor for Management
Science and the Academy of Management Review.

Marvin Washington is an Associate Professor of Physical Education and Recreation with


a joint appointment with the Faculty of Business at the University of Alberta. His research
interest focuses on the creation and evolution of institutions and organizational fields. He has
recently examined the creation and evolution of U.S. collegiate athletics and this work has been
published in Academy of Management Journal, Organization Science, Organization Studies,
and Journal of Sport Management.

Linda Wedlin is assistant professor and lecturer at the Department of Business Studies,
Uppsala University. Her current research includes a project on transnational regulatory reform
in higher education and research, a study on local academic governance in practice, and a study
xviii NOTES ON CONTRIBUTORS

on the restructuring of interest representation in public rule-making. Recent publications


include a book, Ranking Business Schools (Edward Elgar, 2006), analyzing the role of ranking
practices, as new means of evaluation and monitoring, in the structuring of the international
management education field.

Hugh Willmott is Research Professor, Cardiff Business School. He has previously held full
professorial appointments at the Universities of Cambridge and Manchester and visiting
appointments at the Universities of Copenhagen, Lund and Cranfield. His books include
Making Quality Critical, The Re-engineering Revolution, Managing Knowledge, Management
Lives, Studying Management Critically and Fragmenting Work. He is interested in developing
critical analyses of diverse aspects of management and has published widely in social
science and management journals. He currently is a member of the editorial boards of the
Academy of Management Review, Organization Studies and Journal of Management Studies.
Further details can be found on his homepage: http://dspace.dial.pipex.com/town/close/hr22/
hcwhome.

Melissa Wooten is assistant professor in Sociology at the University of Massachusetts


Amherst. She received her doctorate in Management and Organization from the University of
Michigan in 2006. Her dissertation research focuses on change in historically black colleges
after the American Civil Rights Movement. She uses institutional theory to investigate the
processes leading to homogenization among historically black colleges, private Northeastern
liberal art colleges, and public universities located in the American South.

Tammar B. Zilber is a lecturer in Organization Theory at the School of Business


Administration, the Hebrew University of Jerusalem, Israel. She is interested in cultural worlds
within and without organizations. Using qualitative methods like ethnography, narrative analysis
and discourse analysis, she explores symbolic aspects of institutional processes. Among the
issues she examined in recent years were the translation of institutional meanings over time and
across social spheres; the role of stories in institutional entrepreneurship; and institutional
maintenance as narrative work.
Introduction
Royston Greenwood, Christine Oliver, Kerstin Sahlin
and Roy Suddaby

The motivation for this Handbook arose from 2. We focus upon ‘organizational institutionalism’.
a conversation with Don Palmer, who raised Several variants of institutional analysis have
the question of whether organization theories been identified. Hall and Taylor (1996) propose
in general have life cycles. Given the prolif- three basic schools of thought: rational choice
eration of theoretical paradigms, do organi- institutionalism, historical (comparative) institu-
tionalism, and organizational (sociological)
zation theories build into coherent
institutionalism. The material covered in this
conceptual frameworks supported by dili- Handbook does centre upon organizational insti-
gently conducted empirical work, or do they tutionalism, but we are less sure of the accuracy
fragment into proliferated confusion? That of the depictions provided by Hall and Taylor
conversation never proceeded to a compara- (1996) or Campbell (2004). In fact, we propose to
tive assessment of organization theories. But show how institutionalist research applied to
it did lead to the present volume. It seemed, organizational behaviour has evolved over time
in late 2004, when the idea of a Handbook and that much of this work does not fit neatly
was mooted, an appropriate moment to take into the classifications offered by Hall or
stock of the institutional perspective on Campbell. Our stance is not to ask, what is dis-
organizations because we were approaching tinctive of ‘organizational institutionalism’? But,
instead: ‘What does the institutional perspective
the thirtieth anniversary of seminal papers
tell us about organizational behaviour?’
that not only triggered revitalization of inter- 3. Our timeframe emphasizes contributions made
est in the role of institutions but became since 1977. The late 1970s were great years for
known as the new institutionalism. organization theory. In a very short span of years,
It is important at the outset to set down at least three of the enduring perspectives within
certain scope conditions for this volume: organizational theory were initiated: resource
dependence theory, ecology theory, and institu-
1. Our interest is in understanding organizations. tional theory. In 1977, two papers (Meyer &
How and why do organizations behave as they Rowan, 1977; Zucker, 1977) introduced what
do, and with what consequences? These are the became known as new institutionalism. We do
overarching questions of organization theory. not deny that institutions and institutional
‘Organizational institutionalism’ is the applica- processes had been examined prior to that date
tion of the institutional perspective to those (see Hirsch, Chapter 33 this volume). On the con-
questions. trary, the study of institutions has a long and
2 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

respected tradition (see DiMaggio & Powell, In this section we review how the ‘so-called
1991; Hinings & Tolbert, Chapter 19 this volume; institutional perspective’ (Carroll, Goodstein &
and Barley, Chapter 20 this volume). However, Gyenes, 1988: 238) has evolved since 1977.
the body of institutional work post-1977 has a By doing so we are, in one sense, retrospec-
focus that warrants our treatment of 1977 as a tively tracing the social construction of insti-
starting point.
tutional theory over the past three decades. We
review how the term has been used in the
main organization theory journals. We examine
how theorists and researchers have understood
THE SOCIAL CONSTRUCTION OF the term and we uncover the organizational
‘INSTITUTIONAL THEORY’ issues and questions to which the theory has
been applied. We suggest certain pivotal
Institutional theory is perhaps the dominant moments when either the definition or the
approach to understanding organizations. Its application of the theory shifted. Our motiva-
popularity is shown in Figure 1.1, which tion is to understand what makes an institu-
reports the number of citations to Meyer and tional story different from other theoretical
Rowan (1977). The steady rise in citations is perspectives. This is not an easy task given
impressive. And it is clear from these statis- institutional theory’s ‘definitional thicket’
tics that institutional theory is an entrenched (Zucker, 1987: 457). Moreover, any attempt
and prevalent approach. Moreover, as to arrange nearly 30 years of research and
Haveman and David (Chapter 24 this volume) theorizing can be challenged. Ours, we admit,
point out, institutional theory has dominated is a subjective arrangement and our procedure
submissions to the Organization and Manage- means we may miss hidden nuggets.
ment Theory Division of the Academy of Nevertheless, there are some reasonably obvi-
Management. ous temporal signposts. Thus, we begin by
But what is it? And why is it so popular? examining the period between 1977 and
What aspects of organizational behaviour 1983, when several papers established the
does it address? And how well does it do so? foundations of the ‘new’ institutionalism.

300

250
Number of citations

200

150

100

50

0
78

80

82

84

86

88

90

92

94

96

98

00

02

04

06
19

19

19

19

19

19

19

19

19

19

19

20

20

20

20

Years
Meyer & Rowan DiMaggio & Powell Hannan & Freeman Pfeffer & Salancik

Figure 1.1 Citations to Meyer & Rowan (1977), DiMaggio & Powell (1983), Hannan & Freeman
(1977) and Pfeffer & Salancik (1978)
INTRODUCTION 3

Foundations: 1977–83 Following Weber, Meyer and Rowan were


interested in the rationalization and diffusion
The conceptual foundations of modern orga- of formal bureaucracies in modern society,
nizational institutionalism were established which they saw as arising from two condi-
in the works of Meyer and Rowan (1977), tions: ‘the complexity of networks of social
Zucker (1977), Meyer and Rowan (1983), organization and exchange’ and ‘the institu-
DiMaggio and Powell (1983), Tolbert and tional context’ (1977: 346). Most attention,
Zucker (1983), and Meyer and Scott (1983). both in their paper and in subsequent work,
Collectively, these papers set the course for was given to the institutional context, but it is
much of the next three decades, although, as worth remembering that ‘relational’ net-
we shall note, many of the works that fol- works were seen as important influences.
lowed were sometimes selective in their Meyer (1977) and Scott (1983), for example,
interpretations. anticipated that complex networks of
In the late 1970s, prevailing perspectives interactions between organizations would
within organization theory largely portrayed increase the occurrence of rationalized
organizations as agentic actors responding to myths, that complex and conflicted fields
situational circumstances. Senior managers would give rise to a greater variety of organi-
steered organizations by interpreting their zational forms, and that field complexity
contexts and taking appropriate actions. would increase the likelihood of myths
Structural-contingency theory saw organiza- becoming codified into formal regulations
tions adapting to circumstances of scale, and laws. Finally, they pointed out that
task uncertainty and strategic scope by appro- rationalized myths are diffused through rela-
priate selection of structural arrangements. tional networks. Networks/fields are thus
Resource-dependence theory analyzed how both antecedents of rationalized myths and
organizations sought to affect the supply of vehicles for their transmission (most clearly
critical resources by managing their depend- set out by DiMaggio & Powell, 1983 – see
encies on other organizations (e.g. by careful below).1
placement of directors). Even the behavioural Nevertheless, the idea that captured the
theory of the firm assumed adaptation to imagination was that organizations are influ-
market and performance circumstances, enced by their institutional context, i.e. by
albeit within the limits of bounded rationality. widespread social understandings (rational-
Ecological theory was the exception, empha- ized myths) that define what it means to be
sizing the inability of organizations to be rational. Elsewhere, and less prosaically,
adaptively managed, although even in this Meyer and Rowan (1983: 84) referred to the
case the problem was not that managers could institutional context as ‘the rules, norms, and
not effect organizational adaptation, but that ideologies of the wider society’. Zucker (1983:
they could not do so quickly enough. Each of 105) looked to ‘common understandings of
these theoretical perspectives focused on the what is appropriate and, fundamentally, mean-
relationship between an organization and its ingful behaviour’. And Scott (1983: 163)
environment and examined how organiza- offered ‘normative and cognitive belief sys-
tions adapted – or attempted to adapt – so as tems’. The underlying focus of early institu-
to secure an appropriate ‘fit’. The environ- tional theorists, in short, was the role of shared
ment, moreover, was the ‘technical’/market meanings, institutional processes (such as
setting, much as assumed in accounts pro- cultural prescriptions, Zucker, 1977) and insti-
vided by economists, and the behaviour of tutional conformity.2
executives (organizations) was intendedly Because organizations are expected to
(if boundedly) rational. It was against this behave rationally, Meyer and Rowan pro-
context that Meyer and Rowan’s (1977) cele- posed that rationalized myths are accepted
brated paper appeared. as prescriptions of appropriate conduct.
4 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Organizations conform to them – i.e. become equated institutionalized organizations with


isomorphic with their institutional context – the not-for-profit and governmental sectors,
in order to signal their social fitness and gain precipitating a particular stream of research
legitimacy in the eyes of critical constituen- (see below) that contrasted organizations in
cies. It is by ‘appearing to be rational’ (Scott, highly institutionalized settings with those
1983: 160) that organizations avoid social where institutional influences were pre-
censure, minimize demands for external sumed to be much weaker. Later, institutional
accountability, improve their chances of ideas would be unapologetically applied
securing necessary resources and raise their to all organizations, and technical con-
probability of survival. texts would be treated as institutional
However, it was believed that conforming constructions.
to institutional rules might conflict with the Given the originality of Meyer and
requirements of technical efficiency (Meyer Rowan’s (1977) paper, it inevitably con-
& Rowan, 1977: 310; Zucker, 1987: 445). tained underdeveloped themes and some
Therefore, conformity may be ceremonial, conceptual ambiguities. There was, for
‘a form of confidence game’ (Pfeffer, 1982: example, no definition of ‘institution’.
246) producing ‘surface isomorphism’ Instead, the reader is left to assume that insti-
(Zucker, 1987: 672). Ceremonial conformity tutions are taken-for-granted rationalized
is achieved by deliberately decoupling sym- myths. Other definitions of ‘institution’
bolic practices from the organization’s tech- appeared early in the institutional literature,
nical core. Decoupling occurs, in other with inevitable later confusion. One defini-
words, if the prescriptions of institutional tion referred to institutions as types of organ-
contexts are contradictory to the exigencies izations, such as prisons, mental hospitals,
of technical contexts. Ceremonial conformity nursing homes, and orphanages. Another
may also occur because institutional contexts definition referred to institutions as sectors
are often pluralistic and inconsistent (an (see Hasse & Krücken, Chapter 22 this
observation of some theoretical significance, volume), such as ‘education’, ‘büsiness’, and
as will be shown later). The idea set out in the ‘armies’. A final definition echoed antecedent
1977 paper, that institutional prescriptions work (e.g. Hirsch, 1975), equating institu-
run counter to efficiency considerations, was tions with the major agencies of the political
qualified by Meyer and Scott (1983), who economy (e.g. unions, the professions, regu-
referred to institutional and technical latory agencies of the State). It is thus not
exigencies as dimensions that can vary in surprising that Haveman and David (Chapter
their relative salience within a given setting. 24 this volume) should challenge institution-
A more fundamental challenge would come alists ‘to reach agreement on the meaning of
from Carroll, Lee and Rao, (1986; see also central constructs and wean themselves from
Meyer, Scott & Strang, 1987; Zucker, 1987; using the vapid term institution, which means
Powell, 1991) who pointed out that technical everything and therefore nothing’. (For a
contexts (e.g. markets) are themselves insti- contrary view, see Czarniawska, Chapter 32
tutionally defined. this volume.).
All organizations were envisaged as sub- Our purpose here is not to provide the or
ject to institutional influences, but not to the even a definition of institution; rather, we are
same extent. Organizations whose technolo- interested in tracing how others defined it
gies are not clearly linked to given outcomes over the past 30 years. Nevertheless, and for
and whose outputs are difficult to evaluate are the record, we understand the term to refer to
particularly sensitive to the need to appear more-or-less taken-for-granted repetitive
rational (Meyer & Rowan referred to them as social behaviour that is underpinned by nor-
institutionalized organizations). Perhaps not mative systems and cognitive understandings
surprisingly, much early institutional work that give meaning to social exchange and
INTRODUCTION 5

thus enable self-reproducing social order. ‘Institutionalization’ and ‘institutional-


Institutions are characterized by lack of overt ized’ were defined by Meyer and Rowan.
enforcement, their survival resting upon ‘rel- Institutionalization is the process by which
atively self-activating social processes’ ‘social processes, obligations, or actualities
(Jepperson, 1991: 145; see also Zucker, come to take on a rule-like status in social
1977). Although institutions exist at the level thought and action’ (Meyer & Rowan, 1977:
of the individual (e.g. a handshake in western 341). Something is ‘institutionalized’ when it
societies), the organization (e.g. the use of has that rule-like status. In a famous turn of
formal accounting controls, particular struc- phrase, Zucker concluded that institutional-
tures, and impersonal personnel practices), ization means that ‘alternatives may be liter-
the field (e.g. hierarchies of status between ally unthinkable’ (1983: 5). Tolbert and
categories of occupations or between organi- Zucker (1983: 25) suggested three indicators
zations that affect hiring patterns and of institutionalized practices: they are widely
alliances), or society (e.g. a legal system followed, without debate, and exhibit
based upon due process), organizational permanence.
institutionalism is primarily interested in The notion of institutionalized behaviour
institutions and institutional processes at the as something widely practiced and taken-
level of the organization and the organiza- for-granted, however, was not entirely unam-
tional field (although not exclusively – see, biguous. On the one hand, Meyer and Rowan
for example, Djelic & Quack, Chapter 11; referred to ‘binding’ and ‘powerful institu-
Drori, Chapter18; and J. Meyer, Chapter 34 tional rules’ that are ‘in some measure
this volume). beyond the discretion of any individual par-
Meyer and Rowan also omitted to provide a ticipant or organization’ (1977: 344).
formal definition of ‘institutional context’, Similarly, Tolbert and Zucker (1983: 22)
other than that it contains rationalized myths. referred to organizations as ‘captives of the
Tolbert (1985: 2) followed suit: ‘widespread institutional environment in which they
social conceptions of appropriate organiza- exist’. In this imagery, institutions are ‘envi-
tional form and behaviour constitute the insti- ronments’ that are ‘out there’ and to which
tutional environment of organizations’. As we organizations respond (Zucker, 1987).
note below, over the next two decades ‘institu- Zucker (1977), in a perceptive and rigorous
tional context’ would continue to prove a trou- application of Berger and Luckman’s (1967)
blesome concept, partly because the term was ideas, insisted that ideas and practices are
used to cover two very different ideas – con- institutionalized when they have achieved the
text as symbolic/cultural influences (as in the attributes of exteriority and objectivity. As
Tolbert quote), and context as the regulatory such (and this is a distinctive feature of
framework of state and professional agencies Zucker’s account), institutionalized acts
(e.g. Scott & Meyer, 1983). The latter require no monitoring or enforcement but
approach is closer to that of institutional econ- persist solely through transmission from one
omists than to our reading of Meyer and generation to another.
Rowan (1977). To us, accounts of how regu- Yet, on the other hand, notions of ceremo-
latory agencies (institutions) shape organiza- nial adoption and decoupling imply foresight
tional behaviour are incomplete institutional and choice. Even more striking are state-
explanations unless they show how regulatory ments that ‘organizations … often play active
frameworks embody, enact or transmit societal roles in shaping [institutional] contexts’ and
norms and values. Otherwise, referring to reg- that ‘powerful organizations attempt to build
ulatory frameworks as ‘the institutional con- their goals and procedures directly into soci-
text’ risks confusing institutional theory with ety as institutional rules’ (Meyer & Rowan,
resource-dependence or political-economy 1977: 29–30). Similarly, when Meyer and
explanations.3 Rowan advise that in highly institutionalized
6 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

contexts managers need to exercise ‘saga- That idea arose from DiMaggio and Powell
cious conformity’ if they are to understand (1983), who began from the same motivation
‘changing fashions and governmental pro- as Meyer and Rowan, namely, to understand
grammes’, they imply a level of active man- the rationalization of modern society. But
agement as organizations adapt to their DiMaggio and Powell reframed this question
institutional environments. Rao and Kenney’s into: ‘why is there such startling homogene-
examination (Chapter 13 this volume) of ity of organizational forms and practices?’
new forms as settlements is a compelling (1983: 147). The answer, they proposed,
illustration of this active management as an resides in the structuration of organizational
antecedent to institutionalization. This recip- fields. As fields mature, ‘there is an inexorable
rocal tension between institutions as cultur- push towards homogenization’ as ‘powerful
ally hegemonic (with organizations ‘bound’ forces emerge that lead them (organizations)
by taken-for-granted rationalizations) and to become more similar to one another’ (1983:
institutions as enacted and reconstructed 148). Homogenization, point out DiMaggio
(with organizations responding ‘strategically’ and Powell, is field or sector-specific,
to institutional pressures) is a ‘long-standing although this does not preclude ideas diffus-
tension’ (Hinings & Tolbert, Chapter 19 this ing across sectors because fields have their
volume) within sociology and thus, not sur- own histories and institutional processes.
prisingly, would become a central theme in Boxenbaum and Jonsson (Chapter 2 this
institutional thinking. volume) suggest that DiMaggio and Powell’s
In outline, then, the basic elements of the emphasis upon field-level structuration
institutional thesis put forward in the late processes was a nuanced advance from the
1970s and early 1980s were as follows: initial institutional statements, because it
‘represented a move towards a more cogni-
1. organizations are influenced by their institutional tive and constitutive view of organizations’.
and network contexts.The institutional context con- However, DiMaggio and Powell’s framing of
sists of rationalized myths of appropriate conduct; the problem was often misinterpreted by later
2. institutional pressures affect all organizations but researchers, who treated homogeneity as
especially those with unclear technologies and/or synonymous with institutional isomorphism,
difficult to evaluate outputs. Organizations when in fact homogeneity is only one possi-
especially sensitive to institutional contexts are ble effect of institutional pressures and one
institutionalized organizations; that is not, in our view, a definitional one.4
3. organizations become isomorphic with their
We elaborate upon this point later.
institutional context in order to secure social
approval (legitimacy), which provides survival
The most cited contribution of the 1983
benefits; paper was its discussion of how institutional-
4. because conformity to institutional pressures ization actually occurs. DiMaggio and
may be contrary to the dictates of efficiency, Powell proposed three ‘mechanisms of diffu-
conformity may be ceremonial, whereby symbolic sion’: coercive, which occur when external
structures are decoupled from an organization’s constituents – typically powerful organiza-
technical core; tions, including the State – cajole or force
5. institutionalized practices are typically taken-for organizations to adopt an organizational ele-
granted, widely accepted and resistant to ment; normative, which arise primarily from
change. professionalization projects; and mimetic,
which occur when uncertain organizations
These elements awaited empirical verifi- copy others either because others’ actions are
cation. believed to be rational and/or because of a
The above summary contains no statement desire to avoid appearing deviant or back-
that organizations converge upon the same ward. These mechanisms of diffusion are
response to their institutional environments. usefully considered as explaining the
INTRODUCTION 7

motivation for adoption. Coercive isomor- narrowly whereas later work embraced a widen-
phism occurs because organizations are ing array of issues and concerns. Thus, the initial
motivated to avoid sanctions available to line of inquiry looked at the adoption of the
organizations on which they are dependent. bureaucratic organizational form within a given
Normative isomorphism occurs because sector or field (i.e. at the process of rationaliza-
tion), whereas later inquiries looked at a wider
organizations are motivated to respect social
range of organizational forms, practices and
obligations. And mimetic isomorphism behaviours, and at the construction of the field
occurs because organizations are motivated itself. But the central focus is the organization
by their interpretation of others’ successful and its relationship with its context.
behaviours.5 As Mizruchi and Fein (1999) 2. the essential answer provided by institutional
and Boxenbaum and Jonsson (Chapter 2 this theory emphasized (and still emphasizes) the
volume) note, most empirical studies have play of widely-shared and taken-for-granted
been portrayed (often erroneously) as studies social values and ideas. As Meyer and Rowan
of mimetic isomorphism, although, as we (1977: 346) famously put it: ‘institutional theo-
note momentarily, this is not necessarily ries in their extreme forms define organizations
indicative of institutional processes. Hasse as dramatic enactments of the rationalized myths
pervading modern societies’. Critically, the insti-
and Krücken, (Chapter 22 this volume)
tutional explanation is not derived from the cal-
return to European scholars – such as culated self-interest of organizational actors, nor
Luhman and Giddens – who inspired early from the imperatives of instrumental functional-
institutional theorists, in order to show how ity. Instead, the institutional explanation empha-
institutional theory could overcome simpli- sizes that organizations seek legitimacy and
fied notions of homogeneity and instead survival not efficiency, and highlights the role of
develop better explanations of heterogeneity cognition and obligation, not self-interest.
and variation.
One insight in the DiMaggio and Powell
paper that was much less influential was the Early years: 1983–91
connection between institutional processes and
‘the influence of elite interests’ (1983: 147). Immediately following publication, most
This insight was largely inspired by Bordieu’s citations to Meyer and Rowan (1977) and
notion of fields (e.g. Mohr, 1998). The same Zucker (1977) were incidental rather than
theme is evident in Tolbert and Zucker (1983), substantive. Authors simply acknowledged
and would be raised again by DiMaggio that social values affect organizations and/or
(1988). However, attention to the political that organizations adopt structures in order to
consequences of institutional processes would legitimize themselves.6 Often, these ideas
be largely lost in subsequent institutional were juxtaposed against those of structural
work (and in much of organization theory in contingency theory. Few attempts were made
general – see Stern & Barley, 1996; Perrow, to actually test institutional ideas and, over-
2002; Hinings & Greenwood, 2002). all, Meyer and Rowan’s influence was rather
To take stock. By 1983 the initial founda- modest.7 North American reviews of organi-
tions of organizational institutionalism had zation theory that appeared in the early to
been established. Two features are worth mid 1980s gave sparse attention to institu-
emphasizing because they are defining tional work (e.g. Van de Ven & Joyce, 1981;
themes of our subject matter: Zey-Ferrell, 1981; Astley & Van de Ven,
1983; Galaskiewicz, 1985). The very term
1. the central question addressed by early formula-
tions of institutional theory was: Why and with ‘institutional’ was not established. Fligstein,
what consequences do organizations use partic- for example, referred to ‘organiza-
ular organizational arrangements that defy tradi- tional homogeneity theory’ (1985: 377).
tional rational explanations? As we will show, Galaskiewicz (1985) wrote of the literature
this question was initially interpreted somewhat ‘on legitimation’. Only Scott (1981) and
8 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Pfeffer (1982) were sufficiently prescient to (means of transmission) explored how ideas
seriously acknowledge the institutional are transmitted across organizations.
perspective.
Outside of North America, Meyer and Processual studies
Rowan’s ideas caught the interest of Swedish The most systematic and nuanced approach to
scholars who showed especial interest in the the institutional literature was initiated by
notion of decoupling (e.g. Brunsson, 1985, Tolbert & Zucker (1983) who looked at the
1989). Public sector reforms were observed diffusion of civil service employment prac-
to be primarily rhetorical in form and the tices across US local governments over an
goal of ‘modernization’ was found to have extended period. Adoption reflected incorpo-
little effect upon operational practices. These ration of practices ‘modelled after the business
empirical observations confirmed the Meyer corporation, where personnel selection
and Rowan thesis of decoupling. But and promotion were presumably based on
Scandinavian researchers also recognized merit …’ (Tolbert & Zucker, 1983: 25).
that organizations confront and handle multi- A point worth emphasizing is that Tolbert and
ple and contradictory institutions and expec- Zucker explicitly identified the ‘rationalized
tations. Brunsson (1989), in particular, myth’ – business efficiency via hiring based
theorized on ‘organizational hypocrisy’ on expertise – to which municipalities were
whereby organizations ‘talk’ in one way yet responding. The logic of Tolbert and Zucker’s
act in another in order to cope with contra- study is that diffusion involves two stages,
dictory contextual pressures. Scandinavian each defined by the motivation for adoption.
research also discerned what would later Early adopters of an idea are motivated to
be referred to as the ‘translation’ process improve operations, ‘for example, by stream-
(see Boxenbaum & Johnsson, Chapter 2; lining procedures or reducing conflict’
Czarniawska, Chapter 32; and Sahlin & (Tolbert & Zucker, 1983: 26), whereas later
Wedlin, Chapter 8 this volume). Despite these adopters are motivated to secure social legiti-
emerging themes, the impact of Scandinavian macy by appearing ‘modern, efficient and
research upon North American thinking was rational’ even though the procedures were not
initially rather slight. especially functional. Tolbert and Zucker
Gradually, the institutional thesis received interpret the second stage of diffusion to
fuller treatment and was ‘confronted with mean that, as increasing numbers of organiza-
data’ (Scott, 2004: 464). But very quickly, tions adopt an innovation, the innovation itself
studies claiming to be within the institutional becomes ‘progressively institutionalized, or
perspective showed a diversity of approaches widely understood to be a necessary compo-
and a rather casual use of the term institu- nent of rationalized organizational structure.
tional. We begin, however, with four sets of The legitimacy of the procedures themselves
studies that clearly reflected the idea of insti- serves as the impetus for the later adopters’
tutions as rationalized myths. The first set (1983: 35). An important insight, here, is that
(which we label processual) demonstrated it is the justification underlying adoption that
that organizations are motivated to achieve signals whether an institutional effect is being
legitimacy by adopting practices widely observed. (Tolbert & Zucker did not actually
believed to be rational. The second (cross- measure whether late adopters were moti-
category) examined the proposition that vated by legitimacy concerns, or whether they
institutionalized organizations converge secured it. They concluded that, because the
around practices assumed to be rational. functional imperatives that explained early
The third (cross-national) compared prac- adoptions did not explain later adoptions,
tices in different countries, testing whether institutional processes must have been at
distinct cultural values result in different work. This is treating institutional theory as
organizational behaviours. The fourth the default option).
INTRODUCTION 9

The Tolbert and Zucker study was pivotal, (legitimated) ideas (myths) within an organi-
for three reasons. It was the first large-scale, zational field are associated with adoption of
quantitative, historical analysis of institu- particular organizational strategies and struc-
tional effects. It focused upon cognitive tures. Third, Fligstein is not addressing the
forms of legitimacy. And it set in train a Weberian question of why society is becom-
series of studies seeking to confirm the two- ing increasingly rationalized. Fligstein dis-
stage model of diffusion. This model was connected the study of institutional processes
largely but by no means always found in from the study of rationalization. Thereafter,
other studies, but is often treated as one of the study of institutional processes was free
the basic insights of institutional theory. to examine any aspect of organizational
Zilber (Chapter 5 this volume), however, form. Finally, Fligstein offers an alternative
raises the important caution that, by focusing to the two-stage model of change, showing
upon the diffusion of structures rather than how disruptive changes in legal frameworks
upon underlying motivations, there is a enable shifts in organizational behaviours by
high risk that erroneous conclusions will altering patterns of incentives and opportuni-
be drawn. ties (see also Baron et al., 1986; Edelman,
A second diffusion study with a historical 1990, 1992). This model of change, the
perspective9 was conducted by Fligstein exogenous-shock model, became the domi-
(1987). Fligstein showed that the back- nant portrayal for the next two decades
grounds of those holding top positions in (see below).
large corporations changed over the course of
60 years. From 1919 to 1939, manufacturing Cross-category comparisons
personnel dominated but thereafter were A series of studies, mostly from researchers
increasingly displaced, first by sales and from Stanford University (Pfeffer & Cohen,
marketing personnel and from 1959 onwards 1984; Tolbert, 1985; Baron & Bielby, 1986;
by finance personnel. Manufacturing person- Fennell & Alexander, 1987; Pfeffer & Davis-
nel dominated initially because firms were Blake, 1987; Eisenhardt, 1988) examined
largely non-diversified. But the emergence of Meyer and Rowan’s (1977) idea that govern-
the multidivisional form led to the rise of the ment and non-profit organizations were more
sales and marketing function because that likely than commercial organizations to use
function was believed to have the appropriate employment practices presumed (by the
skill set for the new strategy. Then, anti-trust researchers) to be exemplary practices. By
legislation, which curtailed opportunities for and large, these studies supported the idea
vertical and horizontal diversification, pro- that not-for-profit organizations are espe-
vided the conditions for unrelated diversifi- cially sensitive to institutional influences.
cation to emerge as the dominant strategy A different observation was made by Baron,
and the ascendance of finance officers. Jennings and Dobbin (1988), who tracked
Fligstein’s analysis is thus a broad one, but it the diffusion of modern personnel from man-
contains a mimetic explanation of diffusion: ufacturing industries to service industries
‘once new actors established themselves in (i.e. from a setting low in institutional sensi-
one set of firms, their counterparts in other tivity to one with high institutional sensitiv-
firms were able to use that fact as a basis of ity). Baron et al. explained their findings by
gaining power’ (1985: 56). saying that once practices were extensively
Three features of Fligstein’s study deserve used in manufacturing they became the stan-
recognition. First, he links control of the dard of good practice. Another extension of
organization to intra-organizational power cross-category research was provided by
struggles. Second, he never uses the terms Sheets and Ting (1988) who showed that dif-
‘rationalized myths’ or ‘legitimacy’, but fusion even within a category of institution-
his study traces how generally accepted alized organizations is dependent not only
10 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

upon the need for legitimacy, but upon appropriate structures. Yet, in some ways,
whether organizations are within networks this explanation is the closest to the ideas of
that ‘transmit normatively expected employ- Meyer and Rowan.
ment practices’ (610). These cross-category
studies were discontinued by the end of the Other themes
decade. Other themes were explored but to a lesser
extent. Pfeffer and Davis-Blake (1987), in a
Cross-national comparisons rare study of consequences, examined how
A third approach hypothesized that social stereotypes of ‘women’s work’ and its worth
values in different countries (especially those results in patterns of compensation that
that are relatively cohesive and isolated, such disadvantage women. Torres (1988) showed
as Japan), would use different organizational how professions shape regulatory structures
practices (for a review, see Lincoln & so as to preclude organizational forms
McBride, 1987). This approach directly chal- inconsistent with their interests. Imershein
lenged the structural-contingency assump- and Rond (1989), in a strangely neglected
tion of culture-free ‘laws’ of organizations. paper, traced how competing societal values –
Lincoln et al. (1981) compared the attitudes ‘altruism’ and ‘efficiency’ – precipitated
of Japanese and US workers in 28 Japanese- struggles between interest groups who
owned organizations located in the United promote different organizational forms
States. They found that the two groups of and how state regulators resolved these
employees preferred different organizational disputes.
arrangements. Organizations with ‘inappro- Not all studies were entirely supportive of
priate’ structures, i.e. that did not reflect the institutional argument (see for example,
employee preferences, experienced employee Pfeffer & Cohen, 1984; DiPrete, 1987; Finlay,
dissatisfaction. Lincoln et al.’s study was the 1987; Oliver, 1988). But most were. Moreover,
first in a series of studies through the 1980s evidence was collected from an array of prac-
that analyzed the effects of national culture tices, including personnel procedures (Tolbert
(e.g. Birnbaum & Wong, 1985; Lincoln et al., & Zucker, 1983), boundary-spanning strate-
1986; Carroll et al., 1988; Hamilton & gies (Fennell & Alexander, 1987), corporate
Biggart, 1988). Evidence of cultural (institu- committee structures (Harrison, 1987) and
tional) effects was usually found, but see accounting practices (Covaleski et al., 1986).
Birnbaum and Wong (1985). Furthermore, evidence was taken from a range
of settings, including universities (Pfeffer &
Means of transmission Davis-Blake [add 1987]), hospitals (Fennell
Showing the spread of practices per se does & Alexander, 1987), school districts (Strang,
not explain how institutional influences pen- 1987), publicly traded corporations (Baron
etrate organizations, a question that began to et al., 1986), municipalities (Tolbert &
be addressed late in the 1980s (and even Zucker, 1983), the long-shore industry
more in the 1990s). Several means or agents (Finlay, 1987), Hungarian agricultural co-
of diffusion were observed, including operatives (Carroll et al., 1988), US federal
professional networks (Baron et al., 1986; bureaucracies (DiPrete, 1987), social welfare
Sheets & Ting, 1988), government agencies agencies (Oliver, 1988), and even the funeral
(Baron et al., 1986), management consultants industry (Torres, 1988). The sheer range and
(Ghoshal, 1988) and senior executives diversity of practices and settings was
(Harrison, 1987). Each of these means of dif- impressive, leading Zucker (1987: 443) to
fusion would be extensively examined in the comment that: ‘institutional theories have
1990s. But one thesis not picked up was spread rapidly, a testimony to the power of
Lincoln et al.’s (1981) idea that structures are the imaginative ideas developed in theoreti-
adopted because of employee expectations of cal and empirical work’.
INTRODUCTION 11

One reason for the expanding scope and organizations respond in similar fashion to
diversity of institutional ideas was their suc- institutional processes. Given this finding,
cessful juxtaposition with other theoretical Fombrun (1989: 439) rightly asked: ‘If
perspectives. Initially, institutional accounts isomorphism obtains, how then are we
were largely contrasted with structural- to explain the apparent variety of organiza-
contingency theory because of that theory’s tions that nonetheless co-exist within indus-
assumption of efficiency as the key dynamic tries …?’ This question, we believe, points to
driving organizational behaviour. But, later, the confusion raised earlier over the idea of
institutional approaches were linked, often in isomorphism. As initially proposed, isomor-
a complementary way10 to resource depend- phism refers to the relationship between an
ence and population ecology (for a review of organization and its institutional context.
the 1980s, see Singh & Lumsden, 1990). Not But, isomorphism was (and still is, unfortu-
all observers were impressed by these nately) often taken to mean that all organiza-
theoretical overlaps (Zucker, 1989, 1991, tions will respond in the same way. Yet,
pp. 104–5). Nevertheless, insights achieved organizations confront institutional contexts
by combining institutional and ecological containing multiple and inconsistent myths
analysis (see Haveman & David, Chapter 24 that allow for multiple yet equally legitimate
this volume) and resource dependence theory responses (a feature explicitly recognized by
continue to be productive. Meyer & Rowan, 1977: 356 and by Scott,
1983: 161). By the late 1980s, increasing
references were being made to the ‘substan-
Taking stock: 1987–91 tial discord’ within institutional environ-
ments rather than the ‘effortless evolution of
By the end of the 1980s, ambiguities in the common sense understandings’ implicit in
institutional story were becoming apparent, earlier work (DiMaggio, 1991: 268; see also
as were issues that were not receiving ade- Imershein & Rond, 1989; Baxter & Lambert,
quate attention (Perrow, 1986; Neilson & 1990). Further, it was recognized that
Rao, 1987; Scott, 1987; Zucker, 1987, 1988; ‘institutionalized myths differ in [their]
DiMaggio, 1988; Fligstein & Dauber, 1989; completeness’ (Meyer & Rowan, 1977: 354),
Oliver, 1991; Powell & DiMaggio, 1991). providing scope for strategic choice in how
One concern was that the majority of studies they are interpreted (Scott, 1991). Finally,
had been of the public sector and not-for- Fligstein (1985) had shown that complex
profit organizations. Meyer and Rowan’s def- organizations constitute arenas of struggle
inition of ‘institutionalized organizations’ as where groups compete for power and selec-
those with weak market forces had naturally tively appeal to institutional pressures to
turned attention to governmental and not-for- legitimate their claims. For all these reasons,
profit organizations. Towards the end of the the idea that organizations would become
decade, however, this overly narrow under- aligned with their institutional contexts in the
standing of where institutional processes same way became less acceptable.
would occur was being discarded as scholars Even if the institutional context is very
recognized that ‘markets’ were institutions. clear and uniform in its demands, it is not
We pointed out above that the first authors to clear that diffusion of any practice per se sig-
make this point were Carroll et al. (1986) but nifies an institutional effect. If a firm believes
Zucker (1987) and Powell (1991) strength- another to have superior knowledge and to
ened the call for examination of all types of have acted rationally, copying that firm is
organizations.11 an act of vicarious learning, and, arguably,
A second ambiguity surrounded the a purposely ‘rational’ decision. In contrast, if
concept of isomorphism. We noted earlier a firm adopts an innovation because it
that several studies reported that not all believes that doing so provides legitimacy,
12 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

that behaviour is an institutional effect. hiring of expert staff, and use of personnel
(Several leading researchers – see Haveman practices of a bureaucratic form. (Here we
& David, Chapter 24 this volume, for see, again, the academic interest in rationali-
example – view legitimacy as a defining zation). After the War, personnel practitioners
element of institutional explanations). shifted their focus and claimed (successfully)
Convergence around a similar set of prac- that they had expertise relevant to the
tices, in other words, could signal competi- immediate post-War problems of labour-
tive or institutional isomorphism12 (see management relations such as productiv-
Haunschild & Chandler, Chapter 26 this ity measurement. Moreover, personnel
volume, for an elaboration of this argument). officers mobilized themselves and began
But few diffusion studies conducted in the their professionalization ‘project’ (Abbott,
1980s made this distinction (neither did those 1988).
conducted in the following decade). Instead, Baron et al.’s paper is a rich story of insti-
‘institutionalization’ became associated with tutional processes, embracing mimetic, coer-
diffusion irrespective of the (unexamined) cive and normative mechanisms. But we
motivations for adoption. Moreover, it was wish to highlight that it uses ‘institution’ in
assumed (wrongly) that a lack of conver- two ways. On the one hand, institutions are
gence indicates the absence of institutional ‘models’ that become cultural prescriptions.
processes. As such, institution is being used in the same
A third ambiguity concerned the nature of way as it was by Meyer and Rowan (1977).
an institutional explanation. We illustrate this On the other hand, institutions are the regula-
ambiguity by summarizing an excellent tory agencies of the political economy. In this
paper (Baron et al., 1986) that used ‘institu- second usage the institutional context is not
tional’ in a rather different way to that put one of ideas and symbols but of agencies and
forward by the core foundational papers. policies. By the end of the 1980s, Baron
Baron et al. set out to ‘sketch an institutional et al. thus illustrate how the term institution
explanation’ (1986: 352) of the spread of had acquired two meanings: as rationalized
modern personnel administration in the US myths within a cultural context; and as a
during and after World War II. The explana- framework of (primarily State) regulatory
tion provided is that new personnel methods agencies and policies. The former is the
were adopted when ‘certain institutional pres- focus of Meyer and Rowan (1977). The latter
sures’ favoured adoption. What were these would become the focus of the confusingly
‘institutional pressures’? During World War termed ‘new institutionalism’ (see, for exam-
II, there was increased federal intervention in ple, Ingram & Inman, 1996; Ingram & Clay,
labour markets, especially through the War 2000; Ingram & Silverman, 2002). But, this
Production Board and the War Labour Board. latter form of ‘institutional explanation’ need
These agencies sought to stabilize employ- not (and in some later studies, did not)
ment and reduce turnover in industries criti- explicitly embrace socio-cultural elements.
cal to the War effort by encouraging firms to Instead, institutions would be defined,
adopt particular employment practices. simply, as the regulatory framework. The dif-
Moreover, the War Manpower Commission ficulty with this usage is that it fails to
placed responsibilities upon firms for provid- separate an institutional from a resource-
ing data on their manpower needs, which led dependence perspective. For us, inclusion of
to increased use of job analysis and job eval- regulatory frameworks as ‘institutions’ is
uation. In effect, federal agencies were pro- appropriate only if it is made clear that those
viding ‘models for personnel management’ institutions embody taken-for-granted socie-
(1986: 371) underwritten by ‘strong incen- tal norms and values, and if these values are
tives’ (1986: 373). These models included the explicitly identified. This distinction between
creation of personnel departments and the institutions as cultural prescriptions, and
INTRODUCTION 13

institutions as regulatory frameworks, would ‘strategic’, depending on various contingen-


recur over the next decade and beyond. cies in the organization and its environment.
A fourth ambiguity concerned the basic Oliver’s analysis identified possible strategic
questions that institutional theory seeks to responses and the likely antecedents of their
answer. The foundational papers ask why adoption.
there is an increasing rationalization of soci- Paradoxically, others believed that much
ety and use of bureaucratic organizational institutional work held an oversimplified
forms. But organization theorists are (more?) approach to agency. Neilson and Rao (1987)
interested in institutionalized patterns of criticized existing work for: ‘treating legiti-
behaviour, irrespective of whether those macy as something to be managed in a func-
practices are indicators of rationalization. We tional sense by dominant coalitions. This
referred earlier to Fligstein’s (1985) tracking creates the serious risk of oversimplifying
of the use of the multidivisional form, which legitimacy into a matter of marketing and
is an interesting question to organization the- effective presentation rather than approach-
orists. But it is not an application of the ing it as a complex process of socially con-
Weberian question of increasing rationaliza- structing reality’ (1987: 525).13 (This
tion. The multidivisional form (M-form) is observation, curiously, is particularly appro-
no more an indicator of rationalization than priate today.) A key difference between these
is, say, the functional form that the M-form different standpoints is that Neilson and Rao
displaced, or the network form that followed. were criticizing images of agency carried out
This turning away from Weber’s (and Meyer within an existing institutional setting,
& Rowan’s and DiMaggio & Powell’s) focus whereas DiMaggio was interested in how
upon rationalization would be increasingly that setting might be changed. For us, both
characteristic in the 1990s and would criticisms had merit. Nevertheless, it was
serve to expand the scope of institutional widely assumed at the beginning of the
applications. 1990s that institutional theory did not take
sufficient account of how actors (i.e. organi-
New directions? zations) were able to work on their institu-
DiMaggio (1988) complained that institu- tional context in order to promote their
tional work risked being marginalized unless interests. This imagery, however, increas-
it could incorporate ‘the reality of purposive, ingly sees institutional contexts as ‘out
interest-driven, and conflictual behaviour’ there’, as constraints on an organization,
(1988: 5). Organizations, he rightly com- rather than as something with which the
plained, were portrayed as caught within the organization interacts and thus constructs.
constraints of institutionalized norms. Another proposed new direction, put for-
Consequently, institutional theory could not ward by Powell (1991), concerned the conse-
explain fundamental change. To progress, quences of institutional behaviour. A core
DiMaggio argued, institutional theory would assumption of the institutional story is that if
have to incorporate an account of agency and organizations conform to institutionalized
address a series of critical questions: How are norms, they gain legitimacy and improve
new organizational forms created and legiti- their survival prospects. But few studies in
mated? Who has the power to legitimate a the 1980s, other than those adopting the eco-
novel form? Who are the ‘institutional entre- logical perspective, examined whether con-
preneurs’? How are ‘core institutions’ dele- formity did generate legitimacy, and, if so,
gitimized? Building on DiMaggio (1988), with whom; nor did they examine whether
Oliver (1991) incorporated resource-depend- legitimacy led to organizational survival.
ence theory and suggested that organiza- One exception was Singh et al. (1986), who
tional responses to their institutional observed that endorsement by external agen-
environment may be proactive or even cies (an indicator of legitimacy) reduced the
14 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

liabilities of newness of social service organ- institutional perspective. For example,


izations. Little attention was also given to the Richard Daft’s best-selling organization
broader political consequences of institu- theory textbook referred to institutional
tional structures, even though, as we noted theory for the first time in the sixth edition,
earlier, the connection between institutional published in 1997. Admittedly, most text-
processes and elite interests was raised in books referred to institutional theory more as
several of the original formulations. This gap an interesting aside than as a core construct,
in research (exceptions included Baron et al., but by the middle of the decade the perspec-
1986; Imershein & Rond, 1989; Baxter & tive was firmly established as one of the cen-
Lambert, 1990) prompted DiMaggio and tral approaches of organization theory (see
Powell (1991: 30) to lament that ‘power and for example, Aldrich, 1999). Moreover, in
interests have been slighted topics in institu- terms of research, the 1990s was a theoreti-
tional analysis’. cally rich period with an expanding agenda
There was, however, growing awareness of applications and greater systematization
towards the end of the 1980s that organizations of ideas. Initially, there was a focus on show-
are not unitary entities and that their responses ing isomorphism and its dynamics. But, by
to institutional processes may be less homoge- the middle of the decade, attention had turned
neous and less automatic than originally envis- to the examination of legitimacy, typically
aged (e.g. Fligstein, 1985, 1987; Hinings & accompanied by a more agentic approach.
Greenwood, 1988). Looking back, Powell A further line of research examined institu-
commented that: ‘… much of the imagery of tional change, again often with an agentic
institutional theory portrays organizations too approach (as indicated by adoption of ‘insti-
passively and depicts environments as overly tutional entrepreneurship’ as a central organ-
constraining. There is a wide range of institu- izing term). Finally, there was a renewed
tional influences, and internal responses to interest in the notion of ‘institutional logics’,
these pressures are more varied than is sug- which represented a welcome return to the
gested by our initial arguments.’ (1991: 194; importance of cultural symbols. In other
see also, DiMaggio, 1991). words, several of the challenges raised at the
In summary, as the decade turned institu- end of the 1980s were being addressed, but,
tional theory was clearly established within as we shall see, not all of them.
organization theory as a productive lens Before reviewing these research themes, it
through which to understand organization- is worth noting that the concept of institution
context interactions. But if the promise of continued to be troublesome and used in sev-
institutional theory was to be realized there eral different ways. As before, some
was a need to show the underlying motiva- researchers referred to cultural models,
tions of institutional effects (rather than treat others to the State or its policies, some
them as the default option), to pay greater simply avoided the term and pointed instead
attention to (and explain) the variability of to presumed institutional effects (e.g.
responses to conflicting institutional pres- mimetic behaviour). Godard (1999: 683),
sures, to incorporate more agentic and politi- rather politely, thought the theory had
cal dimensions, and to explicitly look at how become ‘increasingly amorphous’. Davis
institutions arise, change and with what con- et al. (1994: 550), in similarly diplomatic
sequences. Did this happen? tones, found the meaning of institution
‘somewhat unclear’. Scott’s (1995: xiv) mas-
terful review noted that ‘institution’ had
Expanding horizons: 1991–2007 acquired new meanings ‘much like barnacles
on a ship’s hull’. For most theorists, however,
Most textbooks that appeared after 1991 would the problem was put aside. Much like the early
include some (albeit limited) discussion of the days of organization theory, when a tacit
INTRODUCTION 15

agreement occurred to stop attempting to on instrumental grounds’ (Davis et al. 1994:


define ‘organization’, there emerged an 551). This latter condition, however, is rarely
unwritten assumption that we intuitively insisted upon in empirical work (although,
know what we mean by institution and thus see Brunsson, 2006). Instead, institutional-
have no further need to define it. ization has become accepted as the process
Scott (1995) brought order to the various whereby things become institutionalized,
strands of institutional analysis by distin- which, in turn, simply means that things are
guishing between the regulative, normative more or less taken for granted.14
and cultural-cognitive ‘pillars’ or elements
that underpin institutions. Analytically, these Institutional isomorphism
are separate elements and have been selec- Studies of isomorphism were salient in the
tively emphasized by different theorists. One early to mid 1990s and elaborated upon
consequence has been the crystallization of the processual and transmission studies of
the two nascent approaches of the 1980s the previous decade. The two-stage model
(institutions as cultural models, institutions was examined, with mixed results. Despite
as regulatory frameworks), and, worryingly, this inconsistent support, the model began to
an increasing disconnect between them. In be treated as having ‘canonical status’
practice, as Scott later acknowledged, the (Schneiberg & Lounsbury, Chapter 27 this
three pillars are often found together but the volume). However, research in the 1990s
cultural-cognitive pillar provides ‘the deeper increasingly recognized that institutional
foundations of institutional forms … the infra- contexts were complex, often consisting of
structure on which not only beliefs, but norms competing institutional demands (see
and rules rest’ (Scott, 2004: 5). For this reason, Boxenbaum & Jonsson, Chapter 2; Hasse &
Phillips and Malhotra (Chapter 29 this Krücken, Chapter 22; and Kraatz & Block,
volume) would prefer that researchers focus Chapter 9 this volume). There was thus
exclusively upon the cultural-cognitive, growing interest in why and how organiza-
which they declare as the distinctive insight tions interpret and respond differently to
of organizational institutionalism. Scott, their contexts.
however, urges researchers to specify which Three approaches developed to explain
pillars are operant in which settings, how why organizations in general are more or less
they unfold, and with what effects. Few receptive to institutional pressures. The dom-
researchers, however, have satisfactorily inant approach was structural and examined
operationalized the three pillars (Mizruchi & how institutional prescriptions are mediated
Fein, 1999) and in some instances (e.g. by an organization’s position in a social (net-
Kostova & Roth, 2002) they are deliberately work) structure, with position defined by the
blended to form a composite ‘institutional degree of centrality, status, or simply by ties
profile’. Nevertheless, Scott’s pillars have to other organizations. Where you are, in this
become one of the most-cited contributions approach, determines what you do. Interest
in the institutional literature. was shown in which organizations serve as
The notion of ‘institutionalized’ was less models for others to copy, and in the means
troublesome, typically interpreted to mean by which information and/or expectations are
something that is widely used and more or transmitted. Board interlocks, ‘perhaps the
less taken-for-granted. Davis et al. (1994), most-studied social structure in organization
following Zucker (1977), offered a useful but theory’ (Davis & Greve, 1997: 12), were
tough definition, proposing that a practice or extensively examined. (A smaller number of
belief is institutionalized if it is widely studies examined the role of spatial proxim-
accepted without recourse to analysis as the ity but recognition of the role of geographic
best way of meeting technical requirements, communities became rather lost and has only
and, ‘is able to withstand challenges based recently resurfaced).
16 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

An intriguing twist was provided by approaches. R. Meyer (Chapter 21, this


Westphal and Zajac (2001) who observed that volume) adds that US dominated institutional
network ties are not only conveyers of institu- theory lost contact with some of its European
tional pressures but conduits for knowledge theoretical ‘forefathers’.
of how to avoid them. Another interesting A second approach to understanding orga-
study (Davis & Greve, 1997) compared the nizational responses to institutional pres-
diffusion of two practices – the poison pill, sures looked at intraorganizational factors.
and golden parachutes for CEOs – and found Greenwood and Hinings (1993) emphasized
that, although both practices diffused, they that organizations are coalitions of diverse
did so in very different ways. One diffused professional interests that contest which of
rapidly, the other more slowly. One diffused several institutional models (archetypes)
in linear form, the other in the classic S-curve. should be adopted. Han (1994) identified the
Further, the dynamics driving diffusion were importance of status, observing that high and
also different. This study, in other words, low status firms are less likely than interme-
highlighted the complexities of diffusion diate status firms to engage in mimetic
(which were thrown into relief by the com- behaviour. Kossek et al. (1994) demonstrated
parative method) and considered the social the effects of demographics and gender in
processes whereby practices are actively jus- shaping organizational responses. Beck and
tified to particular constituencies. Both stud- Walgenbach (2005) turned attention to more
ies noted that organizations can act upon their traditional contingency variables, such as
institutional contexts (see also Davis & organizational size (which increases the like-
Anderson, Chapter 14 this volume). lihood of adoption) and technology (cus-
Although we are including the diffusion tomization decreases adoption). These and
studies of the early and mid 1990s as part of similar studies confirmed that organizations
the institutional story, these studies would are unlikely to respond uniformly to institu-
often combine institutional with organiza- tional processes, although the ‘choice-set’
tional learning theory or network theory – (Greenwood & Hinings, 2006) of options is
Young, Charns & Shortell (2001) actually institutionally defined.
referred to the ‘network/institutional per- Towards the end of the 1990s, a third
spective’ – and it was not always clear approach, as yet not fully developed, turned
whether the authors’ focal interest was diffu- attention to notions of organizational iden-
sion or isomorphism. Few studies, moreover, tity. How organizations respond to their con-
went beyond rates of adoption as indicative texts is affected by how far institutional
of whether practices had become established pressures are consistent with the history and
and taken-for-granted, even though, as Rao broader norms that define an organization to
et al. point out, ‘adoption is sometimes fol- its members (Elsbach & Kramer, 1996; Fox-
lowed by regret and abandonment’ (2001: Wolfgramm et al., 1998; Labianca et al.,
503). Nevertheless, the diffusion of pre- 2001; Kostova & Roth, 2002). The relation-
sumed institutional effects began to be ship between institutional processes and
treated as evidence of institutional processes, organizational identity is complex and recip-
even though the motivation and meanings rocal (see Glynn, Chapter 16 this volume)
underlying adoption were not established, with institutionalized social categories and
and even though it was rarely established that symbols providing the materials from which
adoption was permanent (‘internalized’, to a claimed identity is constructed (who we
use Kostova & Roth’s term, 2002). Zilber are is defined by whom we profess to be
(Chapter 5, this volume) attributes the neg- like) and by which identity is displayed.
lect of meaning and process to the preference Organizational identity, in other words,
for quantitative, macro-level methodologies mediates how organizations interpret and
rather than more interpretive, qualitative respond to institutional expectations.15
INTRODUCTION 17

Implicit in the above three approaches, to mid 1990s (e.g. Scott, 1995; Christensen,
a greater or lesser degree, was the idea that Karnoe, Pedersen & Dobbin, 1997; Hirsch &
institutional models or prescriptions are ‘out Lounsbury, 1997; Stinchcombe, 1997), was
there’. This assumption is clearest in the being answered. Research in the 1990s had
structural approach to diffusion, which basi- turned decidedly agentic and remained so,
cally tested whether a particular structural perhaps too much so, into the 2000s.17
form or technique was adopted or not. A very
different imagery, referred to earlier, is pro- Legitimacy
vided by the Scandinavian school, which If the motivating question of the 1980s had
emphasizes the diffusion of ideas through a been ‘Why is there such startling homogene-
process of ‘translation’ (see Czarniawska, ity of organizational forms and practices?’
Chapter 32 and Sahlin & Wedlin, Chapter 8 (DiMaggio & Powell, 1983: 147), one of the
this volume). Instead of treating institution- two motivating questions from the mid 1990s
ally prescribed structures and practices as became ‘How do organizations acquire,
‘out there’ and as adopted more or less ‘as manage and use legitimacy?’ (the second
is’, translation assumes that ideas and prac- was, How do institutional arrangements
tices are interpreted and reformulated during change? – see below). We attribute this shift
the process of adoption. Several studies in in attention, at least partly, to the growing
this tradition focused on the interplay of acceptance that neither institutional contexts
translated ideas and transformed organiza- nor organizations are homogeneous. But it
tional identities (Sahlin-Andersson, 1996; may also have been a response to the ampli-
Sevón, 1996; Hedmo et al., 2006; Wedlin, fied appeal for inclusion of interests and
2006). Inevitably, translation implies deliber- agency. For example, one approach drew
ate and accidental or unintended transforma- upon impression management theory to show
tions of ideas as they transfer from one how organizations acquired and sustained
setting to another, and the potential for con- social approval (e.g. Elsbach & Sutton, 1992;
tinuous adjustment and change, much as Elsbach, 1994; Arndt & Bigelow, 2000).
anticipated in Giddens’ notion of structura- A rather different and interesting example of
tion. The Scandinavian approach was thus agentic behaviour is Westphal and Zajac’s
more faithful to the social constructionist (2001) study of why some organizations that
principles of institutional thought. Early announce stock repurchase plans (announce-
Scandinavian contributions had been rela- ments favourably received by investors) fail
tively ignored, but pivotal statements by to implement them (with the result that CEOs
Czarniawska and Sevón (1996) and Sahlin- retain discretion over the allocation of corpo-
Andersson (1996) generated increased atten- rate resources). According to Westphal and
tion in North America.16 These works Zajac, the decoupling of announcements
observed that imitators are often motivated to from implementation was especially likely in
become similar to other organizations and corporations with powerful CEOs. In other
yet seek to distinguish themselves. words, ‘powerful actors mediate institutional
Studies of diffusion and translation clearly effects’ (2001: 207; see also Zajac &
allowed for agentic action. Organizations Westphal, 2004). Again, we see the recogni-
were no longer presented as conforming to tion of agency and the role of interests in how
institutional demands, but as making sense of organizations respond to institutional pres-
them, adapting them, enacting them, and sures. (More recently, we see ‘embedded
working upon them (e.g, Glynn, Chapter 16 agency’ featured as a core characteristic of
this volume). This is a very different image to institutional logics – see Thornton & Ocasio,
that conveyed at the beginning of the decade, Chapter 3 this volume.)
indicating that DiMaggio’s call for inclusion Renewed interest in legitimacy went hand
of agency and interest, a call amplified in the in hand with two developments. First, there
18 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

were attempts to give greater precision to Only a minority of studies during this
what the term means. Suchman’s (1995) period explicitly examined whether conform-
classic statement distinguished between ity to cultural prescriptions delivered social
pragmatic, moral, and cognitive legitimacy, legitimacy and/or improved organizational
and identified the various audiences who survival chances and/or affected performance
confer it. Aldrich and Fiol (1994) separated in other ways. Early in the 1990s, studies that
sociopolitical from cognitive legitimacy. examined the consequences of conformity
Ruef and Scott (1998: 877) and Scott largely concluded that legitimacy did,
et al. (2000) crystallized (and in our view indeed, follow conformity, but were less
raised the standard of the research bar) by clear on whether performance was affected.
declaring the need to specify much more Later, several studies connected legitimacy
clearly which organizational elements are positively with performance (see Deephouse
affected by institutional processes, which & Suchman, Chapter 1). Higgins and Gulati
audiences confer legitimacy, and what form (2003), for example, provided an insightful
of legitimacy is being conferred. Interestingly, account of how legitimacy affects the ability
most studies that followed would point to of young firms to attract prestigious invest-
external audiences, such as the media and ment banks as lead underwriters for initial
professional associations; only a minority public offerings. Arthur (2003; see also
noted the role of internal audiences (e.g. Deeds, Mang & Frandsen, 2004) showed that
Staw & Epstein, 2000; Pollock & Rindova, legitimacy gained from adoption of work-
2003). The important point is that greater family human resource initiatives affected a
specificity was being introduced (see company’s share price. Zimmerman and
Deephouse & Suchman, Chapter 1 this Zeitz (2002) traced how legitimacy enabled
volume). new ventures to grow by assisting their
Interest in legitimacy also led to a call for acquisition of resources. In sharp contrast,
better empirical measures. Zucker (1989) Kitchener’s (2002: 411) study of academic
had questioned the use of density (the health centres in the US revealed that ‘uncrit-
number of organizations with a particular ical adoption of managerial innovations can
arrangement) and called for better proxies of prove to be more malignant than benign in
cognitive legitimacy. In the mid 1990s, this their implications’ and Denrell (2003) pro-
argument flared into a spirited debate vided a theoretical explanation for why
between Baum and Powell (1995) and mimetic behaviour will result in poorer per-
Hannan and Carroll (1995) with the former formance. A rather different take on the role
advocating use of richer and multiple meas- of legitimacy was provided by Sherer and
ures, such as certification contests, creden- Lee (2002), who note that high legitimacy
tialing mechanisms, training programmes, enables organizations to deviate from estab-
and so forth. Despite these attempts to obtain lished practices. Overall, these results
greater conceptual precision and more credi- demonstrate the complexity of the relation-
ble empirical indicators, Foreman and ship between legitimacy and performance.
Whetten would later complain that ‘there is
little agreement on how it (legitimacy) is Institutional entrepreneurship and change
defined and/or measured’ (2002: 623). DiMaggio’s (1988) challenge that institu-
Deephouse and Suchman (Chapter 1) reaf- tional theory should provide an account of
firm this complaint, but also note, encourag- deinstitutionalization and institutional
ingly, that efforts are being made to use change was met by a flurry of work. A piv-
richer empirical indicators, such as media otal expression was the Special Issue of the
statements, certification and licensing, Academy of Management Journal (Dacin,
endorsements, and links to prestigious Goldstein & Scott, 2002). Later, institutional
organizations. entrepreneurship emerged as a key term and
INTRODUCTION 19

became almost synonymous with institu- analogies, i.e. existing cognitive frameworks
tional change. In fact, from the later 1990s are used to make sense of ambiguous or
the focus of institutional change was the con- novel events. Few studies have replicated
struction and legitimation of new practices this theme.
(see Hardy & Maguire, Chapter 7 this In contradiction to Leblebici et al.’s idea of
volume). Such was the appeal of this pro- endogenously driven change, most North
posed research agenda that understanding American19 studies followed the assumption
institutional entrepreneurship became a cot- of the 1980s that institutional change is trig-
tage industry from about 2000 and indicates, gered by an exogenous shock or ‘jolt’
again, the currently strong agentic emphasis (Meyer, 1982), whereby change happens as a
within institutional work. Organizations consequence of external factors ‘smacking
became treated as the independent rather into stable institutional arrangements and
than the dependent variable in processes of creating indeterminancy’ (Clemens & Cook,
institutional change. 1999: 447). The exogenous shock model
An important early study of institutional retains the image of highly institutionalized
change focused upon the organizational field. settings exhibiting stability and relative iner-
Leblebici, Salancik, Copay and King (1991) tia over long periods. Gradually, however,
took account of the variety of actors typically institutional fields came to be seen as more
embraced within the definition of field conflicted and pregnant with suppressed
(actors too often neglected in later studies interests (see Hasse & Krücken, Chapter 22,
that claimed to be field-level analyses) and and Wooten & Hoffman, Chapter 4 this
provided an insightful account of how inter- volume). And, as the 1990s ended, the exoge-
actions between them evolved within the US nous model was revitalized by the inclusion
radio broadcasting industry from its incep- of social movement theory (see Davis &
tion in the early 1900s to the mid 1960s. The Anderson, Chapter 14; Schneiberg &
paper explicitly addressed the conundrum of Lounsbury, Chapter 27; and Rao & Kenney,
agency, asking how actors can reflect upon Chapter 13 this volume). Social movement
and change institutionalized practices in theory not only provides a language for
which they are embedded. Leblebici and his understanding how radically new ideas are
colleagues provided four important contribu- framed and theorized in order to further their
tions, three of which shaped the trajectory of acceptance, but assumes explicit contestation
subsequent research. First, they explicitly between actors whose interests are disadvan-
theorized at the level of the organization taged and repressed. All of these depictions
field, which became the level for institutional contrasted sharply with the portrayals of the
analysis (see Wooten & Hoffman, Chapter 4 1980s. Instead of institutional settings being
this volume). Second, they argued that the seen as highly stable, permanent and charac-
locus of change within a field is likely to be terized by conformity, they were now treated
‘fringe’ or peripheral actors because these as contested terrains contoured by variation,
organizations are less embedded within, and struggles and relatively temporary truces (or
less privileged by, existing institutional ‘settlements’, Rao & Kenney in Chapter 13).
arrangements.18 Third, they emphasized the This new imagery raised the profile of power
importance of ‘internal contradictions’ relations (see Lawrence, Chapter 6 and
(Leblebici et al., 1991: 337) that emerge as R. Meyer, Chapter 21 this volume).
fields develop, thus providing the starting One worry about the attention given to
point for an endogenous explanation of political struggles is that the institutional
change, an idea that remained largely ignored dimension sometimes recedes into the back-
until it was revisited by Seo and Creed ground. A critical contribution of institu-
(2002). Finally, Leblebici et al. (1991) tional analysis is its recognition that actors
noted how new technologies invoke use of are not motivated solely by self-interest.
20 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Yet, at times, studies that analyze the strate- personnel professionals theorize responses in
gies used by actors/entrepreneurs to achieve ways that persuade managers to see the poli-
institutional change often ignore how and cies not as onerous ‘red-tape’, but as technical
why institutional forces shape the strategies ways of improving efficiency (for example,
accepted as appropriate and the choice of by securing a better fit between employee
strategies made by particular actors. Unless skills and job requirements). Theorizing com-
political processes are explicitly couched pliance in this way achieves two things. It
within an institutional context, the resultant enhances the value and status of the personnel
story becomes premised upon actors behav- profession (by reinforcing their interests); and,
ing quasi-rationally and knowingly pursuing it links compliance to perceived efficiency,
their interests. For us, this would be a politi- giving it the status of ‘rational’ behaviour.
cal or resource dependence account, not an Through these processes, in other words, prac-
institutional one. tices become rationalized myths.
A very different and important approach to Four features of the above studies deserve
institutional change followed the definition highlighting. First, they offer a rich account
of institution as the apparatus and policies of of the dynamics of change. They show how
the State (Edelman, 1990, 1992; Dobbin, legislation creates interests (e.g. the profes-
1992, 1993; Edelman, Abraham & Erlanger, sions, or new industries) which construct
1992; Dobbin, Sutton, Meyer & Scott, 1993; compliance behaviours. They show how pro-
Edelman, Erlanger & Lande, 1993; Dobbin fessions use legislation to enhance their
& Dowd, 1997, 2000; Edelman & Suchman, influence and scope of activity. They look at
1997; Edelman, Uggen & Erlanger, 1999). the role of power both within and between
A sub-emphasis within this perspective was organizations and industries. Second, these
the relationship between organizations and studies began to show that legislation is not
the law. There is much to admire in these simply a structure of incentives and opportu-
papers. One theme is that laws and regula- nities but a reflection of cognitive schema
tions create and/or enhance interests. Dobbin that are historically contingent. As Edelman
(1992), for example, showed how legislation and Suchman (1997: 482) put it, ‘organiza-
encouraged development of the private insur- tions instrumentally invoke or evade the law’
ance industry. Edelman (1992) linked legisla- and ‘look to the law for normative and cog-
tion on ‘due practice’ to the evolution of the nitive guidance, as they seek their place in a
personnel profession. Once established, socially constructed cultural reality’. As
these interests/agencies make it difficult to such, these studies began to combine the two
reverse public policy (a point initially made definitions of institutions (i.e. institutions as
by Baron et al., 1986). Another theme is that regulatory frameworks, and institutions as
professionals interpret public policy and cultural models). Third, these studies dis-
develop responses that, after legal testing in cussed how policies and practices become
the courts, diffuse across the profession. In constructed as enhancing efficiency and thus
this way, organizational responses converge as ‘rational’ behaviour, and thus eventually
and become reproduced through professional taken-for-granted. Finally, these studies do
networks and enforced by the mechanisms of not assume that new practices/models
professional discipline. Interpretations of, already exist. Instead, they point to the recip-
and responses to, public policy are in part rocal relationships involving professions,
constituted by the implicit models embedded regulators and organizational managers in
within the legal system (e.g. conceptions of constructing business models in response to
fair treatment, due process, etc.). Such ambiguous legislation. As Scott (2004: 9)
interpretations resonate with legal institu- notes, ‘this implies a transmutation over time
tions such as the Courts, enhancing their of regulative into normative and cultural-
acceptance and thus legitimation. Further, cognitive elements’.
INTRODUCTION 21

Much of this work failed to become incor- Dobbin work, to draw upon institutions as
porated into the majority of studies that have regulatory structures (although not coer-
appeared in the organization and manage- cively enforced) and institutions as cultural
ment journals. For example, of the 12 articles expressions. Second, much of the work
on institutional change published in the points to transnational agencies as the source
Special Issue on Institutional Change of the of soft laws and traces the diffusion of
Academy of Management Journal (Dacin practices across societies.20
et al., 2002), only four refer to either Dobbin
or Edelman and none provides a full account Institutional logics
of how those authors combined regulatory The introduction of institutional logics into
and cultural notions of institutions. Most contemporary institutional theory is com-
work has continued to treat the regulatory monly attributed to Friedland and Alford
institutional processes as synonymous with (1991), who were concerned to move institu-
coercive processes arising from the power of tional thinking forward by incorporating an
state agencies or from organizational hierar- explanation for institutional change. They
chies, and thus has basically collapsed this proposed that modern capitalist societies
component of institutional analysis into have ‘central institutions’ that have ‘poten-
resource dependence theory, ignoring the tially incompatible’ institutional logics. It is
more nuanced approach of Edelman. In the incompatibility of logics that provides the
short, two discrete institutional communities dynamic for potential change. The picture is
have developed, each drawing on different of actors recognizing opportunities for
predecessor works and each being cited by change because of their location at the inter-
different colleagues. stices of conflicting logics and instigating
There is a risk of a third discrete commu- change by ‘appealing’ to these logics.
nity. Scandinavian research over the last Thornton (2004) developed these ideas
decade has focused not upon the role of the furthest and refined the list of central
State, but upon the emergence of ‘soft’ regu- institutions.
lations (e.g. Mörth, 2004; Djelic & Sahlin- Thornton and Ocasio (Chapter 3, this
Andersson, 2006). For these theorists, the volume) caution that the term ‘institutional
institutional change of interest is the dis- logic’ is in danger of becoming ‘a buzz
placement of coercive, state-level regulations word’. Moreover, and as is usual in institu-
by more voluntary regulations such as stan- tional work, definitions and usage vary. An
dards (Brunsson & Jacobsson, 2000), rank- important distinction is between those, such
ings (Wedlin, 2006), and accreditations as Thornton, who retain the idea that logics at
(Hedmo, 2004). These softer regulatory the field level are nested within higher-order
structures are developed and applied by non- societal institutional logics, and others (the
governmental agencies (note, for example, majority) who identify logics within a field
the influence of The Financial Times and of without referencing their societal patronage.
accreditation bodies such as the AACSB Despite these differences, as the century
upon business schools!) and elicit compli- turned, exploration of how institutional
ance because they provide legitimacy (Djelic logics shape organizational behaviours and
& Sahlin-Andersson, 2006). Two features of how those logics are historically dependent
this work are worth noting. First, it repre- became a vibrant research theme. As
sents another attempt to bridge the two defi- Thornton and Ocasio (Chapter 3 this volume)
nitions of institution. Because of their point out, a clear implication of the logic
voluntary nature, soft regulations only work construct is that there will be variation across
in conjunction with relative cultural homo- sectors, fields and historical periods, contrary
geneity. There is, therefore, in this work, the to the later ideas of Meyer (e.g. see Drori,
same attempt observed in the Edelman and Chapter 18 this volume).
22 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

TAKING STOCK political actors, operate upon their environ-


ments for either instrumental or social gain.
Tracing the historical developments of insti- In the third period (1991 to the present),
tutional theory from 1977 to the present, we we have argued that the most conspicu-
have sought to reflect on the most prominent ous theoretical developments surrounded
themes and constructs that continue to define institutional isomorphism (as a more
the distinctive substance of the theory’s con- complex phenomenon inclusive of network-,
tribution. To that end, we analyzed three time intra-organizational-, identity- and transla-
periods. The foundations period, from 1977 tion-based responses to institutional pres-
to 1983, laid the substratum of important sures); legitimacy as agency (together with
constructs – institution, institutional context, clarification of the construct by Suchman,
institutionalization, and isomorphism – upon 1995); institutional entrepreneurship and
which the initial articulations of the theory change (embracing the characterization of
were built. Where construct definition was organizations and their fields as conflicting,
lacking in the literature during this period, contested, or legally constituted terrain); and
we have offered our own. Five basic elements institutional logics. Furthermore, empirical
of institutional theory during this period were work had broadened to include a wider range
summarized, together with our interpretation of industries and practices (although hospi-
of the overall questions and potential tals were a favoured site!). By the end of the
answers which institutional theory examined period, much of the theoretical story had
and, importantly, continues to examine, been confirmed by the detailing of previ-
thereby giving coherence and continuity to a ously inferred steps (e.g. by showing how
perspective which has otherwise proliferated ideas move between organizations and which
in multiple directions across diverse empiri- organizations serve as models). The com-
cal settings and topics. plexity of institutional effects had been rec-
The second time period, 1983 to 1991, ognized (e.g. that not all organizations
revealed the development of four areas of succumb easily to institutional processes,
study – processual, cross-category, cross- that the dynamics and pacing of diffusion can
national, and means of transmission – vary by type of innovation, that the dynamics
encompassing, respectively, diffusion, com- of adoption are different to those of abandon-
parisons between State or nonprofit agencies ment, and that the intensity of institutional
and commercial organizations, national cul- processes varies over time). Insights into
ture, and the role of networks, consultants institutional change had been much
and executives in transmitting or communi- advanced, although emphasis primarily
cating institutional values and beliefs. remained on exogenous explanations. These
During this period, researchers also initiated were all important elaborations. Moreover,
combinations or juxtapositions of institu- attention had begun to turn towards highly
tional theory with other perspectives significant issues: the emergence (and disap-
(resource dependence theory, population pearance) of organizational forms; the cre-
ecology, for example). Ambiguities emerged ation of markets; the adoption and
around the meaning of isomorphism (occa- abandonment of market strategies; the inter-
sionally misapplied as inevitable homogene- action of organizational behaviour and finan-
ity) and institutional context (as cultural cial markets; the adoption of affirmative
prescriptions versus regulatory policies, the action in organizations and the determinants
latter being defensible as an institutional con- of workplace violence; the institutional
struct only insofar as they reflect societal antecedents of environmental management
norms and values). Nonetheless, this period, and sustainability. These are important issues
we suggest, also spawned material insights within organization theory. Aldrich (1999:
into how organizations, as active agents and 53), for one, concluded that: ‘Despite
INTRODUCTION 23

pressures from applied fields to focus on same point, accusing researchers of ‘measur-
narrow issues such as efficiency and intraor- ing only the outcome while assuming the
ganizational problems, institutional theory process’. Mizruchi and Fein (1999) also
has succeeded in expanding organizational noted that most researchers report their find-
studies’ scope and vision’. Clearly, there has ings as evidence of mimetic effects but use
been no withering of institutional effort. empirical measures that could just as easily
As the literature of the 1990s and the be interpreted as reflecting normative and/or
present decade gave expression to a startling coercive processes. These criticisms, unfor-
outgrowth of the theory’s explanatory possi- tunately, still apply (cf. R. Meyer, Chapter 21
bilities, the introduction of Scott’s (1995: this volume). Nevertheless, mimetic behav-
2001) three pillars and his accompanying iour is assumed (wrongly) within organiza-
magisterial review of the field brought an tional theory as indicative of institutional
impressive (and influential) integrative focus processes and as empirically confirmed.
to the most generative period of institutional Haunschild’s (1993) study, for example, is
theory’s development. Nevertheless, the extensively cited as evidence of institutional
broadening scope of institutional applica- mimesis but only a minority of those doing
tions heightens the risk of theoretical inco- so have acknowledged Haunschild’s own
herence. However, before drawing our own cautious interpretation of her results.
conclusions about the current status of insti- For this reason, future research might ben-
tutional theory, let us first suggest directions efit from more nuanced explanations of the
(the whithering) for future research and then processes behind, and reasons for, mimetic
reflect in the Conclusions on our level of behaviour. Research should attempt to inter-
optimism around the question initially posed pret and identify the institutional logics
about the extent of coherence versus prolifer- (Thornton, 2002; Thornton & Ocasio,
ation in the theory’s future. Chapter 3 this volume) or structures of shared
values and beliefs that induce and propel
imitation (cf. Czarniawska, Chapter 32 and
Sahlin & Wedlin, Chapter 8 this volume).
New directions?
Another approach might be to contrast
We suggest eight directions for future the literature on bandwagon effects
research. These reflect both our concerns (Abrahamson, 1996; Henderson & Cool,
about the state of institutional theory and our 2003) with current knowledge of mimetic
reading of the recent growth in interest of isomorphism to illuminate with more sub-
particular research areas. tlety and accuracy the distinction between
First, although some progress has been technically rational and legitimating motiva-
made, studies still struggle to relate institu- tions of organizational imitation. In the inter-
tional processes to learning and to clearly ests of broadening attention beyond mimetic
separate institutional effects from vicarious processes, further elaboration of coercive
learning (competitive isomorphism). By and and normative mechanisms also appears war-
large, diffusion studies have continued to ranted (Kock, 2005; Haunschild & Chandler,
assume that convergent behaviour indicates Chapter 26 this volume). For example,
the functioning of institutional processes (see recent theory development applying an insti-
Haveman & David, Chapter 24 and Zilber, tutional perspective to government and
Chapter 5 this volume) even though, at the policy making has begun to illuminate gov-
beginning of the 1990s, Haunschild had ernment efforts to overturn or reinterpret bar-
pointedly remarked that: ‘[w]e know that gains with foreign investors (Henisz &
acquisitions are imitated, but we don’t know Zelner, 2005). The institutional literature’s
why’ (1993: 588). Later in the decade, rather selective emphasis on imitative or
Mizruchi and Fein (1999: 664) made the vicarious learning also invites a broader
24 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

application of the theory to other forms of processes’ (Zilber, 2006: 281). Translation,
organizational learning, and it may be partic- as previously noted, refers to the transforma-
ularly relevant to the current emphasis in the tion of ideational and material objects within
organizational learning literature on learning and during the process of adoption, diffusion,
through exploitation (replication or refine- and/or institutionalization (Czarniawska &
ment of existing routines) versus exploration Joerges, 1996; Czarniawska & Sevón, 2005;
(concerted variation and experimentation) Zilber, 2006). Its emphasis on the symbolic
(March, 1991; Gupta, Smith & Shalley, aspects of institutionalization (Sahlin-
2006). Just as the replication of existing rou- Andersson, 1996), the complexities sur-
tines may be partially explicable by institu- rounding the construction of rational myths,
tionalized, legitimized or taken-for-granted and the travel of ideas across organizational
understandings, so too may learning through fields (Rao, 2004; Djelic & Sahlin-
exploration occur along entirely new trajec- Andersson, 2006; Thornton & Ocasio,
tories through the intervention of institu- Chapter 3 this volume), offers the promise of
tional entrepreneurs (Maguire, Hardy, & more rich and detailed insights into how
Lawrence, 2004; Greenwood & Suddaby, institutional practices and processes migrate
2006). These theoretical conjectures, how- and diffuse across fields and over time.
ever, await empirical validation. Another timely extension to future
Second, many studies have been parsimo- research on diffusion might draw inspiration
nious in their account of institutional from Sanders and Tuschke’s (2007: 33) study
processes. Meyer and Rowan’s (1977) of diffusion across distinct fields, particularly
emphasis upon taken-for-granted cultural in cases where practices spread ‘from one
models has become somewhat reduced in institutional environment, where it is widely
some accounts to mapping the diffusion of prevalent and taken-for-granted, to another
highly specific managerial practices, or, in environment, where its introduction violates
later studies, to organizational foundings. all three of Scott’s pillars of legitimacy’. The
Many of the earlier diffusion studies, in par- possibility of viral institutional diffusion that
ticular, tended to tell a less expansive story, jumps from one institutional field to another,
deploying large-scale analysis to rigorously where its spread is unexpected, offers a more
examine very narrowly drawn hypotheses. rigorous test of the power and limits of insti-
Stinchcombe (1997) was particularly critical tutional diffusion and the coercive, normative
of the tendency to ‘mathematize’ institutional and cognitive forces underlying diffusion
effects, accusing its proponents of missing trajectories that are sufficiently powerful
‘the guts’ of institutional influences. to infiltrate unexpected terrain. As Sanders
Not all diffusion researchers have and Tuschke (2007) observe, we may also
restricted their attention to specific manage- generate new understanding about how
rial practices. D’Aunno, Sutton and Price organizations learn from multiple or differ-
(1991), for example (see also Schneider, ing institutional contexts. Leicht and Fennel
1993), compared the adoption and the conse- (Chapter 17 this volume) examine an
quences of competing mental-health care instance of ‘viral diffusion’ in their analysis
models. These models have broad implica- of the diffusion of managerial logics and
tions, including the choice of organizational practices from the corporate sector to the
form, the scope of professional status, and professions.
the kinds of technologies to be deployed. As Third, for the most part, institutional work
such, this study is very different in its scope has remained stubbornly silent on issues of
than most diffusion studies. It is also note- social power, although, as we noted above,
worthy that ‘recent theoretical developments incorporation of social movement theory holds
have moved from a “diffusion” to a “transla- considerable promise (e.g. Rao & Kenney,
tion” model for understanding institutional Chapter 13 this volume). There have also
INTRODUCTION 25

been some attempts to examine issues of An inviting door into the dark side of insti-
stratification and entrenched patterns of dis- tutional processes comes from researchers
crimination (e.g. Lucas, 2003), social posi- who have applied institutional theory to sus-
tion (e.g. Battilana, 2006) and the tainability and environmental issues (e.g.
relationship between institutionalized beliefs Jennings & Zandbergen, 1995; Hoffman,
and patterns of intraorganizational privilege 1999; Hoffman & Ventresca, 2002; Bansal &
(e.g. Zilber, 2002). Suddaby et al. (2007) Clelland, 2004; Bansal, 2005; Davis &
analyzed the link between the Big Four Anderson, Chapter 14 this volume). To the
accounting firms and non-governmental extent that sustainability researchers see
transnational organizations such as the World unresolved tensions between instrumental
Trade Organization, and cautioned against and moral solutions to environmental
the loss of professional accountability. But destruction, institutional theory’s refutation
these remain rare exceptions. Two examples, of exclusively rational economic motives of
both of which refer to the functioning of organizational behaviour may serve as a
financial markets, illustrate the relative neg- useful bridge to less instrumentally reasoned
lect of elite interests and social power. and more socially justified bases for studying
Hayward and Boeker (1998) documented societal-level harm. In a suggestive case
how security analysts rate their firm’s clients’ study of ISO standard adoption, Boiral
securities more favourably than other ana- (2007), for example, examined corporate
lysts rating the same securities. These biases greening as an institutionalized rational myth
were concealed through symbolic acts (codes and revealed the extent to which the adoption
of ethics, Chinese walls) that legitimated of environmental standards was a ceremonial
investment banks as trustworthy and beyond and potentially hypocritical environmental
reproach. (This façade of legitimacy surround- strategy.
ing the operations of professional service Overall, however, we have limited under-
firms would collapse some years later follow- standing of how power, conflict and funda-
ing the Enron affair). Westphal and Zajac mental social interests affect and are affected
(1998, 2001) analyzed how corporations by institutional processes. There have been
adopt but fail to implement symbolic practices clarion calls for giving attention to the sys-
(such as long-range incentive plans for chief temic structures of power and domination
executives) in order to appease shareholders that define institutions and that privilege their
and manipulate share values. On the one hand, ruling elites. Useful frameworks have been
this can be seen (as it was by Westphal & advanced (e.g. Lawrence, Winn & Jennings,
Zajac) as an example of decoupling. On the 2001; Hargrave & Van de Ven, 2006; Cooper,
other, it could be seen as willful manipulation Ezzamel & Willmott, Chapter 28 and
of shareholder perceptions in order to affect Lawrence, Chapter 6 this volume). But
share prices. Both of these studies, in other empirical work is badly needed. As sug-
words, uncovered the dark side of symbolic or gested by Hasse and Krücken (Chapter 22,
legitimating behaviour – namely, the use of this volume) and R. Meyer (Chapter 21, this
symbols to adversely affect certain societal volume) issues of power and conflict could
interests while privileging others – but illus- be more thoroughly understood if current
trate how we too often neglect to assess the conceptual tools of organizational institu-
societal consequences of institutionalized cor- tionalism were to be combined with the
porate behaviour. Fiss (Chapter 15 this closely related European sociology of knowl-
volume) extends this perspective by analyzing edge and system theories.
corporate governance through an institutional Fourth, most studies have portrayed insti-
lens, observing how coalitions of actors con- tutional processes as fully formed (Aldrich,
struct ‘moral orders’ that determine the power 1999: 52) and underplayed Meyer and
structure of corporations. Rowan’s (1977) emphasis that institutional
26 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

contexts are socially constructed. Barley and with whom) change as fields mature
Tolbert (1997: 93) attempted to redress this (see also Owen-Smith & Powell, Chapter 25
imbalance, first by criticizing institutional this volume). Anand and Watson (2004)
theory’s neglect of how institutional arrange- demonstrated the role of ‘tournament ritu-
ments are ‘created, altered, and reproduced’, als’, such as the Grammy Awards, in field
and second by proposing incorporation of construction. Greenwood and Suddaby
Giddens’ theory of structuration (for an early (2006) looked at professional associations as
attempt to do so, see Phillips, Lawrence & forums within which members of a profes-
Hardy, 2000). Barley and Tolbert’s (1993) sion define and theorize its appropriate
central concern, that most researchers had boundaries. Fligstein (2002) looked at how
simply assumed the existence of institutions, regulatory institutions and economic activity
was largely correct, although there were develop symbiotically and coalesce into
exceptions. Edelman’s work, for example, as stable fields. Garud, Jain and Kumaraswamy
described above, clearly addressed institu- (2002) traced the tensions and political
tional creation, albeit at a much more socie- dynamics involved in adoption of field-wide
tal level than perhaps intended by Barley and common technological standards. Brunsson
Tolbert (1997). Suchman and Cahill (1996) and Jacobsson (2000) looked at emerging
had traced how interactions between Silicon standardization procedures. Wedlin (2006)
Valley lawyers and their clients constructed looked at rankings of business schools and
and then reproduced normative models of Djelic and Sahlin-Andersson (2006)
appropriate behaviour in the venture capital explained the institutional dynamics of new
industry. Bacharach, Banberger and regulations (cf. Sahlin & Wedlin, Chapter 8
Sonnenstuhl (1996) had analyzed the this volume). All of these studies are steps
micropolitics of dissonance reduction that towards understanding processes of institu-
enabled transformational change within an tional construction. Powell and Colyvas
organization (see also Johnson, Smith & (Chapter 10, this volume) and Colyvas and
Codling, 2000). At a more macro-level, Powell (2006) elaborate key questions of
Ingram and Inman (1996) had tracked how this research agenda, including how cate-
regulatory ‘institution building’ arose from gories and routines emerge, and illustrate
collective action. By and large, however, how archival materials may be used to
institutional studies had not been overly con- address them.
cerned with how institutions arise. Separating institutional construction (how
Following publication of Barley and institutions and fields emerge) from institu-
Tolbert’s paper, various developments tional reproduction, is not easy and more
addressed their concerns. The late 1990s saw attention has been given to the former than
early stirrings of interest ‘discourse theory’ the latter. But an important and imaginative
(Phillips & Hardy, 1997; see Phillips & line of research is Zuckerman’s exploration
Malhotra, Chapter 29 in this volume), ‘narra- of ‘categorical imperatives’ (Zuckerman,
tives’ (Czarniawska, 1997 and Chapter 32, this 1999, 2000; Zuckerman & Kim, 2003; see
volume), and the role of ‘rhetoric’ (Zbaracki, also Rao, Monin & Durand, 2003; Durand,
1998; Suddaby & Greenwood, 2005). Related Rao & Monin, 2007). Zuckerman’s work has
work by Lawrence et al. (2002) examined a broader theoretical purpose, but it rightly
how ‘proto-institutions’ (institutions in the identified the failure of institutionalists to
making) can evolve from interorganizational demonstrate ‘that defying classification’ (i.e.
collaboration. Powell, White, Koput and deviating from socially accepted cognitive
Owen-Smith’s (2005) award-winning study frameworks) ‘invites penalties’ (1999: 1399).
of network structures in the US biotechnol- A core theme of organizational institutional-
ogy industry provided a complex account of ism is that deviation from socially defined
how the bases of affiliation (who partners expectations of appropriate conduct are,
INTRODUCTION 27

often subtly, projected onto social actors who useful analysis of the conditions conducive
are cajoled into conforming by self- to institutional entropy, deinstitutionalization
activating mechanisms of disapproval. has remained largely neglected (see Dacin &
Zuckerman’s work is a rare, early examina- Dacin, Chapter 12 this volume). As Scott
tion of this social process. More work in this put it, institutional work has failed to capture
area is clearly warranted. the ‘arc of institutionalization’ (2005: 472),
Interestingly, current work on cognition in focusing instead upon ‘the middle moment’
the strategy literature has remained divorced (2005: 471). Ahmadjian and Robinson’s
from Scott’s well-recognized (2001) cogni- (2001: 647) remark that ‘deinstitutionalization
tive pillar and from the scope of institutional is not simply institutionalization’s converse’
research on the construction and transmis- raises the call for better understanding of
sion of organizational practices as shared how institutions decline.
cognitions and logics (Daniels, Johnson & de As a means of introducing more integration
Chernatony, 2002). Roberts (Chapter 23, this to the literature on institutional change and to
volume) makes the similar point that ‘much push for its fuller theoretical treatment,
less in the way of published work seems to be Hargrave and Van de Ven (2006) developed a
integrating Scott’s (1995) cognitive pillar typology that identifies four internally consis-
with economic perspectives on organiza- tent and distinct models of institutional
tions’. Notwithstanding work by Porac and change, which they label institutional design,
his colleagues (Porac, Thomas, Wilson & institutional adaptation, institutional diffu-
Kanfer, 1995), the strategic management lit- sion, and collective action models. Stated
erature has confined its work on cognition briefly, the institutional design model
primarily to cognitive biases and to the infor- ‘focuses on the intentional behaviours of an
mation processing limitations and effects of individual entrepreneur engaged in the cre-
actors’ cognitive maps (‘mental models’) in ation or revision of an institution to achieve
making strategic decisions (Huff, 1997; his or her goals’; the institutional adaptation
Tripsas & Gavetti, 2000). By juxtaposing model ‘explains how and why organizations
notions of cognitive maps and schemas with conform to forces in the institutional environ-
Scott’s (2001) characterization of the cogni- ment’; the institutional diffusion model
tive pillar in institutional theory, we may ‘focuses on how and why specific institu-
learn more about how such cognitive maps tional arrangements are adopted (selected)
become taken-for-granted as appropriate or and diffused (retained) among institutional
legitimated mental models in the first place actors in a population’; and the collective
(Hasselbladh & Kalinikos, 2000) and how action model ‘examines the construction of
these models become shared across decision new institutions through the political behav-
makers confronting similar challenges and iors of many actors who play diverse and par-
environments (cf. also Czarniawska, Chapter tisan roles in the organizational field or
32 this volume). network that emerges around a social move-
Fifth, the study of institutional change ment or technical innovation’ (Hargrave &
brought forward several attempts to identify Van de Ven, 2006: 867–8). These authors call
the stages of institutionalization. Tolbert and for further theorizing around the collective
Zucker (1995) identified three stages, but action model, which they view, correctly, as
ignored how arrangements might erode and the most recent of the four models of institu-
be displaced. Greenwood et al. (2002) sug- tional change, and the one least understood.
gested five stages, from deinstitutionalization Overall, their work brings a welcome move-
through to diffusion/translation and subse- ment toward integration in the literature on
quent re-institutionalization. But despite change and provides a set of categories for
early attention from Oliver (1992) and Davis distinguishing among widely different types
et al. (1994), and Clemens and Cook’s (1999) and stages of institutional change.
28 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Nevertheless, ‘much theorizing remains to be (e.g. Djelic, 1998; Guler, Guillen &
done’ (Hargrave & Van de Ven, 2006: 884). MacPherson, 2002; Sahlin-Andersson &
Sixth, there is a growing interest in cross- Engwall, 2002; Djelic & Quack, 2003; Djelic
national studies. Until recently, there was a & Sahlin-Andersson, 2006; Drori, Chapter
concern that institutional work was becom- 18 this volume). Frenkel’s (2005) study of
ing distilled through the lens of US cultural how state-level institutional power structures
and social dynamics. Such an ethnocentric imported two management models – scien-
perspective risked missing interesting and tific management and human relations –
important institutional effects (Biggart & from different cultures demonstrated how
Hamilton, 1990; Orru, Biggart & Hamilton, cross-national translation occurs and how
1991; Guillen, 2001). Mizruchi and Fein these management models changed their
had speculated that the myopic focus of social meaning as they moved from one
US scholars is a consequence of ‘the domi- culture to another. Some researchers have
nantly held view among leading North examined how ‘institutional distance’
American organizational researchers that (Kostova, 1999) between parent MNCs
emphasizes cognitive decision-making (almost always, US corporations) and for-
processes at the expense of inter-organiza- eign countries affect investment and expan-
tional power and coercion’ (1999: 677). In sion decisions.
short, Mizruchi and Fein feared that North Seventh, institutional theory has gained
American researchers were reproducing a enormously for many years from its combi-
world-view (rationalized myth?) that nation with, or incorporation of, other theo-
provides ‘a limited picture of the world’ ries (see the Interfaces section of this volume
(1999: 680). for the most current examples of this impor-
The concern about an ethnocentric focus tant work). Somewhat surprisingly, a particu-
may have been premature. Recent work larly pronounced growth in the application of
reveals that a significant number of studies institutional theory to mainstream strategy
are applying institutional theory to an inter- topics has not been accompanied by the
national context and, in doing so, are opening explicit juxtaposition of institutional theory
up the relevance of the theory to new topics, and specific strategy theories, apart from a
such as foreign entry mode (Yiu & Makino, limited and selective combination of institu-
2002), foreign investment and the impact tional theory with the resource-based view
of host country governments (Henisz & (Oliver, 1997), transaction cost theory (Yiu
Zelner, 2005), capital structures in foreign & Makino, 2002), and agency theory
economies (Keister, 2004), the choice of (Young, Stedham & Beekun, 2000).
international alliance partner (Hitt, Ahlstrom, Institutional theory has been increasingly
Dacin, Levitas & Svobodina, 2004), and firm applied to topics in strategy as diverse as
turnaround (Bruton, Ahlstrom & Wan, 2003). mergers (Krishnan, Joshi & Krishnan, 2004),
Several theorists gained insight into these firm heterogeneity (Walker, Madsen &
and similar practices by combining organiza- Carini, 2002), firm diversification (Peng, Lee
tional with comparative institutionalism & Wang, 2005), the effects of corporate
(e.g. Djelic & Quack, 2003). For us, it is boards on firm performance (Peng, 2004),
especially interesting to note the growing firm reputation (Rhee & Haunschild, 2006),
application of institutional theory to emerg- the legitimacy of strategic alliances (Dacin,
ing economies (e.g. Peng, 2003; Keister, Oliver & Roy, 2007), and managers’ mental
2004; Vaaler & McNamara, 2004; Child & models of competition (Daniels et al., 2002).
Tsai, 2005; Chang, Chung & Mahmood, The literature has witnessed almost no
2006; Dobrev, Ozdemir & Teo, 2006). Work attempts, however, to combine, more
on the politics of institutional translation comprehensively, a strategy theory with
across cultures also holds future promise institutional theory.
INTRODUCTION 29

An exciting direction for future research environment is the level of analysis (see
may be the juxtaposition of institutional Wooten & Hoffman, Chapter 4 this volume).
theory and the dynamic capabilities frame- Other levels of analysis have been rarely con-
work (Teece, Pisano & Shuen, 1997; Helfat sidered. For example, few studies treat the
& Peteraf, 2003; Helfat, Finkelstein, organization as the level of analysis (Ocasio,
Mitchell et al., 2007), arguably one of the 1994) or examine how the organization
more prominent perspectives in current strat- might be treated as an institutional context
egy theory. This framework focuses on firms’ for understanding intraorganizational behav-
capabilities to ‘integrate, reconfigure, and iour. An interesting exception was Goodrick
release resources to match and even create and Salancik’s (1996) study of how cesarean
market change’ (Eisenhardt & Martin, 2000: section surgeries varied by type of hospital
1107). Specifically, dynamic capabilities and the ambiguity of institutional standards
refer to the capacity for rent appropriation within them. Using hospital-level data, they
and profit stemming from an organization’s found that when uncertainty was greatest,
‘capability to effectively coordinate and hospital characteristics significantly influ-
redeploy internal and external competences enced cesarean section rates. Their work
… to achieve congruence with the changing showed how technical practices become
business environment’ (Teece, Pisano & embedded in institutional frameworks at the
Shuen, 1997: 515). To our knowledge, no organizational level, and how these frame-
one has addressed institutional theory’s works come to define the ways in which
implications for this strategic perspective (or technical forces operate. We see considerable
vice versa). In examining an organization’s promise in this change to an intraorganiza-
existing routines and the factors that tional level of analysis for expanding insights
facilitate or impede organizational change, into institutional processes. Recent scholars
the theory of dynamic capabilities shares have made a compelling case for an intraor-
institutional theory’s interest in how organi- ganizational level of analysis by combining
zational practices become entrenched in the an institutional perspective with such micro-
cognitive repertoire of organizational rou- theories as prospect theory and the threat-
tines, and the ways in which the changing rigidity hypothesis (George, Chattopadhyay,
environment molds them. Further research, Sitkin & Barden, 2006). Washington, Boal &
therefore, might extend dynamic capabilities Davis (Chapter 30, this volume) adopt an
theory to consider the ways in which the explicitly intraorganizational perspective as
adoption and diffusion of norms and values they integrate institutional and leadership
in the institutional environment impede theories.
rent appropriation or, alternatively, how insti- While any number of intraorganizational
tutional legitimacy sustains or even acceler- phenomena might be informed by an institu-
ates the flow of resources and informa- tional perspective (see for example, Quaid’s
tion to organizations for developing their 1993 article on job evaluation as an institu-
capabilities. tional myth), we are particularly intrigued by
Eighth, and finally, institutional theory Weber and Glynn’s (2006) call for an explo-
evolved as an antidote to the overly rational- ration of the connections between institu-
ist and technocratic perspectives of the tional and sense-making perspectives. Weber
1960s. It emphasized the role of cultural and Glynn (2006: 1639) note that a recurrent
forces within an institutional context and criticism of Weick’s (1995) influential
homed in on the organizational field as the work, specifically its ‘neglect of the role of
level at which such cultural pressures are larger social and historical contexts in
more evident. As a consequence, the sense-making’, can be partially addressed
overwhelming majority of studies now take by showing how the institutional context
for granted that the organizational field or may be an important part of sense-making
30 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

within organizations. Treating the organiza- they are also located within communities.
tion as the institutional context for sense- Only recently has institutional work begun to
making would also go far, we believe, in acknowledge that communities may influ-
adding to institutional theory. In its own neg- ence the particular expression of rationalized
lect of the more micro-dynamics of sense- myths and institutional logics to which
making, institutional theory has relinquished organizations have to respond. Marquis
the opportunity to develop a richer theory of (2003), Marquis et al. (2007), Magan Diaz,
the intersubjective processes of perception, Greenwood, Li and Lorente (2007), and
interpretation and interaction that establish Marquis and Lounsbury (2007), have each
the core of a micro-level understanding of recognized that local or regional communi-
institutionalization. Therefore, like DiMaggio ties are part of the institutional context.
and Powell (1991) and Zucker (1987) we Marquis (2003), for example, traced the elite
continue to see value in amending institu- social organizations and cultural associations
tional theory to include more elaborated that connect organizations within a bounded
micro-foundations and we propose that theo- geographical setting. Magan et al. (2007)
rists might begin with Weick’s (1995) formu- suggested that connections between organi-
lation of sense-making in organizations. This zations and local political elites influence
focus on sensemaking also accords with decisions on the utilization of human
recent criticisms of institutional theory that resources.
have suggested the need for more emphasis These studies imply that the concept of
on ‘the various ways by which ideas are organizational field may have been consid-
objectified i.e. developed and embedded into ered unduly narrowly, and the roots of the
solid and durable social artifacts’ within field concept may prove helpful in order to
organizations (Hasselbladh & Kallinikos, make it into a more elaborate conceptual tool
2000: 699). A rare example of this theoretical (Martin, 2003; Mohr, 2005; Djelic & Sahlin-
purpose underlies Johnson, Smith and Andersson, 2006). Although it has proved,
Codling’s (2000) conceptualization of priva- and will continue to be, a useful level of
tization as a series of individual actors’ analysis, it may have become too abstract
attempts to enact and make sense of a change and thus divorced from the socio-political
from a ‘public’ to a ‘privatized’ institutional community within which institutional and
template through micro-level processes of organizational processes occur. As Magan
script development. In this volume (Chapter et al. put it: ‘Analytical abstraction, intended
32) Czarniawska calls for an elaborate under- to better capture contextual influences, has
standing of how ideas are objectified, resulted in blindness to how communities
but also of how they form in relation to new affect organizations. The relationship
technologies. between communities and organizations was,
Unlike the call for better understanding of of course, integral to early institutional work
intraorganizational processes, a second chal- (Selznick, 1949) but that focus has largely
lenge to the dominance of field-level analysis disappeared. A return to the traditional
emphasizes how the abstractness of the field emphasis upon community would be timely’.
concept may have inadvertently disembed- We agree.
ded institutional analysis. The field concept
originally developed (see Wooten &
Hoffman, Chapter 4 this volume) because of
dissatisfaction with the term ‘industry’, CONCLUSIONS
which neglects the role of agencies such as
professional and trade associations, regula- If institutional theory is decidedly not wither-
tors, the media and the State. However, ing over time in its use and migration within
organizations are not only set within a field, and across the discipline of organization
INTRODUCTION 31

theory (as the sheer number of recent journal Our eight foregoing directions for future
articles bears witness), we still need to ask research reveal our own position on the
whether its power to explain organizational theory’s strengths, limitations, and opportuni-
phenomena is withering in light of its rather ties. We see that there is still much for institu-
splintered proliferation. Our answer is a tional theory to address. More broadly, we
somewhat emphatic no, not only because we have three reasons to feel that the overarching
see thematic cohesion around its basic theo- strengths and contributions of institutional
retical question and ‘answer’, but because we theory far outweigh our few lingering but by no
continue to find its questions infinitely inter- means irrevocable misgivings about the theory.
esting, its capacity to contextualize organiza- First, a review of institutional theory from
tional phenomena beneficial, and its tolerance its early foundations to its current applica-
for theoretical and methodological pluralism tions reveals an impressive tradition of inter-
advantageous to knowledge sharing within facing with numerous other theories (e.g.
organization analysis. We began this network theory, resource dependence theory,
Introduction by identifying the central ques- ecology theory) to explain a correspondingly
tion of institutional theory that we felt gave broad range of organizational phenomena
value to its perspective as originally developed (e.g. organizational structure, change, iden-
by early institutional theorists: why and with tity, alliances, foreign entry). The use of
what consequences do organizations exhibit institutionalism with so many other theories
particular organizational arrangements that and topics rather than in relative isolation is,
defy traditional rational explanation? We see we believe, a conspicuous and significant
the perpetuation of this central question to the strength. For as Nobel prizewinner Erwin
present day as the intellectual stimulus that Schrodinger (1951: 6) observed: ‘… [i]t
gives coherence to a theory that in other seems plain and self-evident, yet it needs to
respects has expanded its applications to an be said: the isolated knowledge obtained by a
impressively wide array of topics. Similarly, group of specialists in a narrow field has in
we identify the ‘answer’ emphasized by insti- itself no value whatsoever but only in its syn-
tutional theory as laying claim to unique thesis with all the rest of knowledge’.
insights into the play of widely shared or Institutionalism’s proliferation, however,
taken-for-granted social values and ideas that comes at the expense of linguistic specificity.
complement, if not defy, calculative rational- Even the term ‘institutional’ defies precise
ity and instrumental functionality. Perhaps definition, leaving it open to alternative con-
the most notable shift in emphasis and inter- ceptual constructions that are adapted to the
pretation over the past three decades has been topic at hand. It is for this reason, among
from treating the context of social values and others, that we encourage a greater focus on
ideas as influences upon organizations, developing a more common vocabulary in
towards recognition of the interplay of organ- future developments of the theory. Thus,
izations with their contexts. It is our position while we are delighted by the theory’s range
that the endurance of institutional theory’s of application, we continue to hope for fur-
fundamental question and answer is a testa- ther consensus around construct definition.
ment to the resilience and robustness of the We also believe that the underspecification
perspective. In answering the query stated at of institutional theory’s constructs is not alto-
the outset of the Introduction, we reject the gether an incontestable impediment to theory
notion that theories invariably fragment into building and research. We share Barbara
proliferated confusion. The coherence and Czarniawska’s view (Chapter 32, this volume)
endurance of institutional theory’s core ques- that ‘the strength of institutional theory lies in
tion and answer run through most institutional the tolerance of its propagandists.’21 We view
work, bringing a surprising semblance of the present scope of contributors to institu-
order to a literature that exhibits rich variety. tional theory’s growth as an indication of an
32 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

epistemological pluralism that tends to dis- discourse, power elites, history and the ‘iron
courage polarizing styles of arguments or the- cage’ of conformity pressures. Therefore,
matic quests for a monopoly on truth. It is not while not asserting that institutional theorists
that all elements of institutional theory are are ideologically agnostic, either individually
inevitably reconcilable with all approaches or or in the aggregate, we nonetheless do not
perspectives; indeed, this is far from the truth see the institutional theorists that populate
(see Cooper et al., Chapter 28 this volume). our journals and bookshelves as pre-oriented
Rather, the stunning variety of topics and toward contempt for the persistence of
methodologies drawing on institutional phenomena or the status quo, even when
theory that we now witness in the literature is such persistence is unjust or dysfunctional.
itself evidence, in our opinion, of the inven- Our disdain (we hope) is for the injustices of
tiveness and flexibility of the many who practices and not for the stability of a
apply it. In the interests of guarding this plu- practice per se.
ralism, we tend, therefore, to favour the It is our hope as well that indicators of
broader construct definition of ‘institutions’ institutionalization be sufficiently neutral to
put forward by Scott (1995: 33): avoid foreclosing on avenues of research into
Institutions consist of cognitive, normative, and
different manifestations of institutionaliza-
regulative structures and activities that provide sta- tion. Rather than insistence on a single
bility and meaning to social behaviour. Institutions measure of institutionalization as that which
are transported by various carriers – culture, struc- is strictly socially embedded, taken-
tures, and routines – and they operate at multiple for-granted, or, alternatively, rooted in power,
levels of jurisdiction.
we favour Selznick’s (1996) notion of institu-
Such a definition increases specificity but tionalization as a comparatively neutral
encourages continued application of institu- concept, receptive to whatever arguments
tional theory to multiple levels, topics, and best explain it, depending on the context in
settings. which it occurs. Building on his early charac-
Second, a distinct advantage of institu- terization of institutionalization as indicative
tional theory, we would argue, is its singular of that which is infused with value beyond
refusal to accept reality at face value, and to the technical requirements at hand, Selznick
do so without the accompanying baggage of (1996: 271) suggests that we judge the
cynicism. Institutional theory throws open degree to which a phenomenon is institution-
the possibility that any cherished aspect of alized as the extent to which it is expendable:
organizational life may be nothing more than ‘[t]he test is expendability, that is, the readi-
a theoretical artifact, but the theory’s implicit ness with which the organization or practice
agenda is not to heap ex ante scorn on the is given up or changed in response to new
causes of misguided or overly-rationalized circumstances or demands’. This position is
behaviour. Agnostic about the reasons for the consistent with Scott’s (2001: 213) exhorta-
taken-for-granted understanding or social tion that ‘we try to avoid and, to the extent
consensus surrounding institutionalized possible, eliminate theoretical arguments
structures and behaviours, institutional based on exclusivist (often, dichotomous)
researchers have been free to roam in the the- thinking’, (e.g. if the cause of persistence
oretical territory of political domination, is social then it cannot be political, or
unconscious reasoning, or social acceptabil- vice versa).
ity to stake out their claim for theoretical Third, institutional theory has an important
superiority in explaining institutionalization. capacity to stimulate contextualization. Just
Thus, institutional researchers have been able as we cannot make feasible improvements in
to trace the source of institutionalization and knowledge of market economies by wishing
persistence to factors as varied as interorga- away their social context (see Roberts,
nizational collaboration, shared norms, Chapter 23 this volume), so it is the case that
INTRODUCTION 33

we cannot understand such knowledge with- and extended. The last section, Reflections,
out recognizing that it is socially constructed presents essays from leading intellectuals,
within a broader context. Institutional theory who reflect on the past and future of organi-
has aided us in contextualizing the phenom- zational institutionalism, offering sometimes
ena we study, whether that context encom- provocative but always engaging insights
passes regulatory, historical, political, and observations. An important feature
cognitively tacit, or socially embedded set- of the five sections as a whole is that the
tings. Indeed, such contextualization is a contributors are distinctly international and
distinguishing (and distinguished) feature of include not only many of the leading
institutional theory and research. contributors to institutional thinking of
Notwithstanding its capacity to stimulate the past three decades, but exciting new
the contextualization of many phenomena, voices.
institutional theory is simultaneously under Overall, on the w(h)ithering of institu-
threat of serving the role of ‘default option’ in tional theory we remain fervent optimists,
the development of organization theory. We and the quality and richness of this volume’s
see limited but somewhat alarming use of contributions bear strong witness to this
institutional theory by other theorists who point of view. Institutional theory is wither-
engage institutional theory as a convenient but ing neither in its scope nor its relevance, and
under-theorized catch-all for what their own we see no obstacles to a lively and productive
theories cannot readily explain. The distinc- growth in the theory’s future. Perhaps Dick
tive aspect of institutional-theory-as-default Scott is correct in predicting that ‘the
research is not necessarily its inaccuracy, but, major contributions of institutional theory to
rather, the meagreness with which institu- organizational studies may still lie ahead’
tional theory is applied; that is, the lack of (2005: 473). If there is a danger, perhaps
depth or richness in its use and the rather it lies in the suppleness of the theory’s
perilous distance from institutional theory’s fit to so many topics, and the corresponding
core concepts, assumptions, and arguments. temptation to assume that it explains
Our intent is not to discourage interfacing everything:
between theories, but to urge a more
comprehensive application of institutional None of us can go a little way with a theory. When
it once possesses us, we are no longer our own
explanations to the topics they inform. masters. It makes us speak its words, and do vio-
To that end, all the chapters in this book lence to our nature. (Newman, 1907: 222)
are outstanding models for future engage-
ment with the theory. The chapters are Let us not, therefore, become blind adher-
grouped into five distinct sections: Section I ents. Institutional theory’s seeming inclusive-
reviews the Foundational Themes, recount- ness may lure us into believing we possess a
ing the initial ideas that excited attention and relatively comprehensive tool for explaining
showing how those ideas have been tested the social character of organizations and
and enhanced. Section II, Institutional environments, that is, at best, incomplete
Dynamics, contains a series of insightful and, at worst, distinctly myopic. The size
reviews of current scholarships and agendas (and enthusiasm) of institutional theory’s fol-
for future work. Section III, Applications, lowing is arguably the most insidious threat
illustrates the extensive range of significant to its capacity to reflect creatively and criti-
issues and contemporary problems to which cally on its limitations and thus to keep
institutional theory can be applied. Section developing constructively as a theory of
IV, Interfaces, explores points of intersec- organizations. Moreover, an institutional
tion with other theories, illustrating how the perspective starts from a good question that
relevance and potential of organizational remains only partially answerable within the
institutionalism continues to be sharpened limits of its own assumptions (see Kraatz &
34 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Zajac, 1996; Bowring, 2000). We remain, the phrase ‘logic of appropriateness’. March empha-
nonetheless, optimistic about its future sized that many decisions are not based on the cal-
culation of future consequences but are the outcome
because it has been relatively robust across
of decision ‘rules’ or routines. March was developing
different epistemological styles and differing a view of organizations as institutionally embedded
disciplinary expertise, finding commensu- and, even though his ideas were anchored in deci-
rable justification for both political and sion-making studies of bounded rationality (e.g.
social rationales, and for both reflexive and March & Simon, 1958; Cyert & March, 1963), deci-
sion-making ambiguity (e.g. March & Olsen, 1976)
more reductionist explanations of organi-
and, more broadly, political science (e.g. March &
zational action. If institutional theory Olsen, 1989), these ideas did not develop in isolation
becomes too institutionalized, however, its from other contributions to institutional theory.
own legitimacy may exert an isomorphic or Sahlin and Wedlin (Chapter 8 this volume) review the
homogenizing effect on the richness and influence of this line of research, especially on
Scandinavian institutionalism. It is notable that three
breadth of explanations it currently con-
of the primary theorists of institutional theory – John
tributes to our understanding of organiza- Meyer, Dick Scott and Jim March – were based at
tional processes and phenomena. And that, Stanford.
should it happen, would be a signal of a 4 Scott (1983: 161) explicitly qualified any ten-
withering theory. dency towards homogeneity: ‘While there may be
some convergence in the general overall pattern
exhibited by organizations, we are more impressed
by the variety of forms and practices encountered.
We see organizational environments as becoming
NOTES more highly organized but not necessarily in the
same manner; and the cultural beliefs governing
1 As we note below, Mohr (2005) showed that organizational practice, while similar in promoting
institutionalist theories have evolved essentially in rationalization, still vary in their particular specifica-
two directions. The dominant trend has directly fol- tions for differing types of organizations’.
lowed DiMaggio and Powell (1983) and privileged 5 Before progressing, we wish to make the fol-
studies and explanations of networks and interac- lowing comment. Meyer and Rowan (1977) and
tions. The other trend, centring around John Meyer’s Zucker (1977) were clearly influenced by Berger and
work, has privileged studies and explanations of Luckman (1967). Berger and Luckman proposed that
meaning. Mohr finds this division unfortunate and social stability occurs in three stages: actors interact
sees great potentials in bringing the two aspects of and, over time, their interactions become ‘habitual-
field back together (Djelic & Sahlin-Andersson, 2006 ized’. Conforming to habitualized patterns makes
argue in the same direction). social interactions predictable and thus orderly.
2 Emphasis upon social values and cognitive Subsequently, habitualized actions become ‘recipro-
systems differentiates ‘organizational institutionalism’ cal typifications of action’, i.e. the habits are recipro-
(not a term used by Meyer & Rowan) from other cally reflected upon and conceptualized as roles (i.e.
versions of institutionalism. Historical institutional- they become ‘objectified’). Once reciprocal typifica-
ism, for example, betraying its origins in comparative tions are passed on to third parties, especially new
political science, focuses upon structures (institu- generations, then reciprocal typifications become
tions) of the state (e.g. state agencies, corporate eco- regarded as ‘real’ and natural, i.e. they acquire ‘exte-
nomic actors such as unions and trade associations) riority’ (Berger & Luckman, 1967: 58) or, in Tolbert
and traces how those structures enable and shape and Zucker’s terms, they become ‘sedimented’ and
the access of organized interests in decision-making taken-for-granted. A recurrent criticism of institu-
processes. Rational choice institutionalism, similarly, tional theory is that much research focuses upon the
also treats (self-) interest as the key driver of behav- objectification stage (Tolbert & Zucker refer to it as
iour within a context of incentives and opportunities. ‘semi-institutionalization’) rather than the sedimenta-
The sociocultural approach to organizational institu- tion (full-institutionalization) stage. In this volume,
tionalism, in contrast, does not see motivation as Renate Meyer argues that the legacy from Berger
exclusively (or even primarily) interest-driven and in and Luckman has largely become less visible in later
doing so provides ‘an important corrective’ to other developments of organizational institutionalism, and
organizational perspectives (DiMaggio, 1988). she shows that many of the recent questions posed
3 A related but more micro approach to the insti- by theoreticians in the field could find much inspira-
tutional context emerged from the research pro- tion and clarification from Berger and Luckman’s
gramme of Jim March, also at Stanford. March coined work.
INTRODUCTION 35

6 For example, Alan Meyer (1982), in discussing been created (e.g. Bacharach et al., 1996; Djelic &
how hospitals responded to a doctors’ strike referred Quack, Chapter 11, this volume). This latter usage
to Meyer and Rowan as follows: ‘Hospitals inhabit clearly connects more closely to the definition of
highly institutionalized environments that may foster ‘institution’ as regulation.
the construction of superficial structural facades. 15 An interesting application of identity theory
Meyer and Rowan (1977) argue that ceremonial would be to connect institutional theory with con-
structures harmonizing with societal ideologies cepts of ‘celebrity firms’. Rindova, Pollock and
attract resources and promote the survival of such Hayward (2006) propose that celebrity firms (firms
organizations. But this study suggests that ceremo- that attract a high level of public attention and posi-
nial structures may also promote survival and tive emotional appeal from being different) are
resource conservation by harmonizing with organiza- socially constructed primarily by the media, and that,
tional ideologies’. once having achieved celebrity status, a firm behaves
7 Most empirical work came from Stanford so as to retain that status. From our point of view,
University (in addition to Meyer & Scott, there was a the conferring of celebrity upon non-conforming
stream of papers from Jeffrey Pfeffer, Kathy firms may serve to legitimate deviance and thus con-
Eisenhardt and Jim Baron). tribute to the prospect of institutional entrepreneur-
8 The idea of translation involved the movement ship and change.
of ideas across organizations. An interesting parallel 16 More recent studies have extended the trans-
is Barley’s (1986) interest in the ‘slippage’ within lation theme to the movements of ideas across
organizations as individuals draw upon institutional- national institutions (e.g. Djelic, 1998; Sahlin-
ized norms to enact their roles. Andersson & Engwall, 2002).
9 These early studies applied a long historical 17 See J. Meyer (Chapter 34, this volume), for a
perspective on institutionalization. They were critical discussion of this development. Meyer (1996)
designed around – and reinforced the notion – used the term ‘soft’ actor to emphasize actors as cul-
that institutionalization involves long historical and turally constrained and dependent.
inert processes. Even though calls for more historical 18 Earlier, we commented upon Bourdieu’s
studies are often heard, many of the later diffusion influence on the early institutional theorists.
studies applied a much shorter time span. This defi- Very soon direct references to his work largely
ciency means, among other things, that the long ceased, at least in North American studies. Later,
term consequences (e.g. are they retained) of adopt- however, some of the main assumptions and results
ing new organizational elements have been largely from Bourdieu’s work on fields reappeared (e.g.
neglected. Wedlin, 2006). One such finding is that changes in
10 But not always. Oliver (1988) for example, fields develop as so called pretendents – trying to
deliberately contrasted institutional theory with pop- enter and exact influence over the field – challenge
ulation ecology and strategic choice theory, in order dominating incumbents. Dominating actors seek
to assess its validity (it failed the test!) to defend the status quo and protect their own cen-
11 An excellent statement on this issue is Biggart tral role in the field. This framework directs the theo-
& Delbridge (2004). rist’s attention to the periphery of organizational
12 Abrahamson (1991: see also, Abrahamson & fields as the likely source of change (cf. Bourdieu,
Rosenkopf, 1993) distinguished institutional from 1977, 1984).
competitive ‘bandwagon’ pressures and showed 19 Because of its focus on translation, European
how the latter also produces the two-stage diffusion research was more inclined to view change as the
model from which institutionalists erroneously infer consequence of endogenous and exogenous forces.
institutional processes. Early and late adopters in the 20 A very influential work underpinning much of
diffusion curve can be motivated by managerial per- this work is Power (1997).
ceptions of the competitive risks of non-adoption. 21 This observation was reinforced by a heavily
13 Broadly speaking, Neilson and Rao were cor- attended 2006 conference on institutional theory
rect. But a small number of studies did contribute to hosted by the University of Alberta, which brought
better understanding of the reciprocal interaction together quant jocks, interpretivists, critical theorists,
between organization and context, both at the level organizational theorists, strategy theorists, dis-
of the strategic group (e.g. Porac et al., 1989), and at course analysts, ecologists, and micro-organizational
the level of the organization (e.g. Barley, 1986). behaviour theorists, applying institutional theory to
14 Even the term institutionalized, however, had everything from identity to political mobilization. The
subtle variations of usage. As noted here, for most most striking aspect of this conference was the rela-
people it meant that something is taken for granted: tive ease and pronounced tolerance with which par-
i.e. objectified as the natural order of things (Tolbert ticipants were able to converse across widely
& Zucker, 1995). But, in some instances, institution- differing ontological assumptions, interests, and
alized meant that a formal organization or rule had methodologies.
36 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

REFERENCES Bansal, P., and Clelland, I. 2004. Talking trash,


legitimacy, impression management and
Abbott, A. 1988. The System of Professions. unsystematic risk in the context of the natu-
Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press. ral environment. Academy of Management
Abrahamson, E. 1996. Management fashion. Journal, 47: 93–103.
Academy of Management Review, 16: Barley, S.R. 1986. Technology as an occasion
254–284. for structuring: Evidence from observations
Abrahamson, E. 1991. Managerial fads and of CT scanners and the social order of radiol-
fashions: The diffusion and rejection of inno- ogy departments. Administrative Science
vations. Academy of Management Review, Quarterly, 31 (1): 78–108.
16 (3): 586–612. Barley, S.R., and Tolbert, P.S. 1997.
Abrahamson, E., and Rosenkopf, L. 1993. Institutionalization and structuration: Studying
Institutional and competitive bandwagons: the links between action and institution.
Using mathematical modeling as a tool to Organization Studies, 18 (1): 93–117.
explore innovation diffusion. Academy of Baron, J.N., and Bielby, W.T. 1986. The prolifer-
Management Review, 18 (3): 487–517. ation of job titles in organizations.
Ahmadjian, C.L., and Robinson, P. 2001. Safety Administrative Science Quarterly, 31 (4):
in numbers: Downsizing and the deinstitution- 561–586.
alization of permanent employment in Japan. Baron, J.N., Davis-Blake, A., and Bielby, W.T.
Administrative Science Quarterly, 46: 622–654. 1986. The structure of opportunity:
Aldrich, H.E. 1999. Organizations Evolving. How promotion ladders vary within and
London: Sage Publications. among organizations. Administrative Science
Aldrich, H.E., and Fiol, C.M. 1994. Fools rush in? Quarterly, 31 (2): 248–273.
The institutional context of industry creation. Baron, J.N., Jennings, P.D., and Dobbin, F.R.
Academy of Management Review, 19 (4): 1988. Mission control: The development of
645–670. personnel systems in United States industry.
Anand, N., and Watson, M.R. 2004. Tournament American Sociological Review, 53 (4):
rituals in the evolution of fields: The case 497–514.
of the Grammy Awards. Academy of Battilana, J. 2006. Agency and institutions: The
Management Journal, 47 (1): 59–80. enabling role of individuals’ social position.
Arndt, M., and Bigelow, B. 2000. Presenting Organization, 13: 653–676.
structural innovation in an institutional envi- Baum, J.A.C., and Powell, W.W. 1995.
ronment: Hospitals’ use of impression man- Cultivating an institutional ecology of organ-
agement. Administrative Science Quarterly, izations: Comment. American Sociological
45 (3): 494–522. Review, 60 (4): 529–538.
Arthur, M.M. 2003. Share price reactions to Baxter, V., and Lambert, C. 1990. The national
work-family initiatives: An institutional per- collegiate athletic association and the gover-
spective. Academy of Management Journal, nance of higher education. Sociological
46 (4): 497–505. Quarterly, 31 (3): 403–421.
Astley, W.G., and Van de Ven, A.H. 1983. Central Beck, N., and Walgenbach, P. 2005. Technical
perspectives and debates in organizational efficiency or adaptation to institutionalized
theory. Administrative Science Quarterly, 28: expectations? The adoption of ISO 9000 stan-
245–273. dards in the German mechanical engineering
Bacharach, S.B., Banberger, P., and industry. Organization Studies, 26 (6): 841–866.
Sonnenstuhl, W.J. 1996. The organizational Berger, T., and Luckmann, P. 1967. The Social
transformation process: The micropolitics of Construction of Reality. New York: Doubleday
dissonance reduction and the alignment of Anchor.
logics of action. Administrative Science Biggart, N.W., and Delbridge, R. 2004. Systems
Quarterly, 41 (3): 477–506. of exchange. Academy of Management
Bansal, P. 2005. Evolving sustainability: A longi- Review, 29 (1): 28–49.
tudinal stud of corporate sustainable devel- Biggart, N.W., and Hamilton, G.G. 1990.
opment. Strategic Management Journal, 26: Explaining Asian business success: Theory no.
197–218. 4. Business and Economics Review, 5: 11.
INTRODUCTION 37

Birnbaum, P.H., and Wong, G.Y.Y. 1985. and institutional constraints in emerging
Organizational structure of multinational economies: Evidence from China and Taiwan.
banks in Hong Kong from a culture-free per- Journal of Management Studies, 42: 177–196.
spective. Administrative Science Quarterly, Christensen, S., Karnoe, P., Pedersen, J.S., and
30 (2): 262–277. Dobbin, F. 1997. Actors and institutions:
Boiral, O. 2007. Corporate greening through Introduction. American Behavioral Scientist,
ISO 14001: A rational myth? Organization 40 (4): 392–396.
Science, 18: 127–146. Clemens, E.S., and Cook, J.M. 1999. Politics
Bourdieu, P. 1984. Distinction. Cambridge, and institutionalism: Explaining durability
MA: Harvard University Press. and change. Annual Review of Sociology,
Bourdieu, P. 1977. Outline of a Theory of Practice. 25: 441–466.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Colyvas, J.A., and Powell, W.W. 2006. Roads to
Bowring, M.A. 2000. De/constructing theory: institutionalization: The remaking of bound-
A look at the institutional theory that posi- aries between public and private science.
tivism built. Journal of Management Inquiry, Research in Organizational Behavior, 27:
9: 258–270. 305–353.
Brunsson, N. 2006. Mechanisms of Hope: Covaleski, M., Aiken, M., and Birnberg, J.G.
Maintaining the Dream of the Rational 1986. Accounting and theories of organiza-
Organization. Malmö: Liber. tions: Some preliminary considerations/dis-
Brunsson, N. 1989. The Organization of cussion. Accounting, Organizations and
Hypocrisy: Talk, Decisions and Actions in Society, 11 (4, 5): 297–324.
Organizations. Chichester: John Wiley and Cyert, R.M., and March, J.G. 1963. A Behav-
Sons. ioral Theory of the Firm. Englewood Cliffs,
Brunsson, N. 1985. The Irrational Organization. NJ: Prentice-Hall.
Chicester: John Wiley and Sons. Czarniawska, B. 1997. Narrating the Organiza-
Brunsson, N., and Jacobsson, B. (eds.) 2000. tion: Dramas of Institutional Identity.
A World of Standards. Oxford: Oxford Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.
University Press. Czarniawska, B., and Joerges, B. 1996. The
Bruton, G.D., Ahlstrom, D., and Wan, J.C.C. travel of ideas. In B. Czarniawska-Joerges
2003. Turnaround in east Asian firms: and G. Sevón (eds.), Translating Organiza-
Evidence from ethnic overseas Chinese com- tional Change, pp. 13–48. Berlin: de Gruyter.
munities. Strategic Management Journal, 24: Czarniawska, B., and Sevón, G. (eds.) 2005.
519–540. Global Ideas: How Ideas, Objects and Prac-
Campbell, J.L. 2004. Institutional Change and tices Travel in the Global Economy. Lund:
Globalization. Princeton, NJ: Princeton Liber and Copenhagen Business School Press.
University Press. Czarniawska, B., and Sevón, G. 1996.
Carroll, G.R., Goodstein, J., and Gyenes, A. Introduction. In B. Czarniawska and
1988. Organizations and the State: Effects of G. Sevón (eds.), Translating Organizational
the institutional environment on agricultural Change. Berlin: de Gruyter.
cooperatives in Hungary. Administrative D’Aunno, T., Sutton, R.I., and Price, R.H. 1991.
Science Quarterly, 33 (2): 233–256. Isomorphism and external support in con-
Carroll, V.P., Lee, H.L., and Rao, A.G. 1986. flicting institutional environments: A study of
Implications of salesforce productivity het- drug abuse treatment units. Academy of
erogeneity and demotivation: A navy Management Journal, 14: 636–661.
recruiter case study. Management Science, Dacin, T., Goldstein, J., and Scott, W.R. 2002.
32 (11): 1371–1389. Institutional theory and institutional change:
Chang, S., Chung, C., and Mahmood, I.P. Introduction to the special research forum.
2006. When and how does business group Academy of Management Journal, 45:
affiliation promote firm innovation? A tale of 45–56.
two emerging economies. Organization Dacin, M.T., Oliver, C., and Roy, J. 2007. The
Science, 17: 637–656. legitimacy of strategic alliances: An institu-
Child, J., and Tsai, T. 2005. The dynamic tional perspective. Strategic Management
between firms’ environmental strategies Journal, 28: 169–187.
38 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Daft, R. 1997. Organization Theory and Design Djelic, M.-L., and Quack, S. 2003. Globalisation
(6th ed.). Nashville, TN: South-Western and Institutions: Redefining the Rules of the
Publishing. Economic Game. London: Edward Elgar.
Daniels, K., Johnson, G., and de Chernatony, L. Djelic, M.-L., and Sahlin-Andersson, K. 2006.
2002. Task and institutional influences on Transnational governance, 1st edn.
managers’ mental models of competition. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Organization Studies, 23: 31–62. Dobbin, F.R. 1993. The social construction of
Davis, G.F., Diekmann, K.A., and Tinsley, C.H. the Great Depression: Industrial policy during
1994. The decline and fall of the conglomer- the 1930s in the United States, Britain, and
ate firm in the 1980s: The deinstitutionaliza- France. Theory and Society, 22 (1): 1–56.
tion of an organizational form. American Dobbin, F.R. 1992. The origins of private social
Sociological Review, 59 (4): 547–570. insurance: Public policy and fringe benefits in
Davis, G.F., and Greve, H.R. 1997. Corporate America, 1920–1950. American Journal of
elite networks and governance changes in Sociology, 97 (5): 1416–1450.
the 1980s. American Journal of Sociology, Dobbin, F., and Dowd, T.J. 2000. The market
103 (1): 1–37. that antitrust built: Public policy, private
Deeds, D.L., Mang, P.Y., and Frandsen, M.L. coercion, and railroad acquisitions,
2004. The influence of firms’ and industries’ 1825–1922. American Sociological Review,
legitimacy on the flow of capital into 65: 631–657.
high-technology ventures. Strategic Organi- Dobbin, F., and Dowd, T.J. 1997. How policy
zation, 2 (1): 9–34. shapes competition: Early railroad foundings
Denrell, J. 2003. Vicarious learning, under- in Massachusetts. Administrative Science
sampling of failure, and the myths of Quarterly, 42 (3): 501–529.
management. Organization Science, 14 (3): Dobbin, F., Sutton, J.R., Meyer, J.W., and Scott,
227–243. W.R. 1993. Equal opportunity law and the
DiMaggio, P.J. 1991. Constructing an organiza- construction of internal labor markets.
tional field as a professional project: US art American Journal of Sociology, 99 (2):
museums, 1920–1940. In W.W. Powell and 396–427.
P.J. DiMaggio (eds.), The New Institutionalism Dobrev, S.D., Ozdemir, S.Z., and Teo, A.C.
in Organizational Analysis, pp. 267–292. 2006. The ecological interdependence of
Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press. emergent and established organizational
DiMaggio, P.J. 1988. Interest and agency in populations: Legitimacy transfer, violation by
institutional theory. In, L.G. Zucker (ed.), comparison, and unstable identities.
Institutional Patterns and Organizations: Organization Science, 17: 557–597.
Culture and Environment, pp. 3–22. Durand, R., Rao, H., and Monin, P. 2007. Code
Cambridge, MA: Ballinger. and conduct in French cuisine: Impact of
DiMaggio, P.J., and Powell, W.W. 1991. code changes on external evaluations.
Introduction. In W.W. Powell and P.J. Strategic Management Journal, 28: 455–472.
DiMaggio (eds.), The New Institutionalism Edelman, L.B. 1992. Legal ambiguity and sym-
in Organizational Analysis. Chicago, IL: bolic structures: Organizational mediation of
University of Chicago Press. civil rights law. American Journal of
DiMaggio, P.J., and Powell, W.W. 1983. The Sociology, 97 (6): 1531–1576.
iron cage revisited: Institutional isomorphism Edelman, L.B. 1990. Legal environments and
and collective rationality in organizational organizational governance: The expansion of
fields. American Sociological Review, 48: due process in the American workplace.
147–160. American Journal of Sociology, 95 (6):
DiPrete, T.A. 1987. Horizontal and vertical 1401–1440.
mobility in organizations. Administrative Edelman, L.B., Abraham, S.E., and Erlanger,
Science Quarterly, 32 (3): 422–444. H.S. 1992. Professional construction of law:
Djelic, M.-L. 1998. Exporting the American The inflated threat of wrongful discharge.
Model: The Postwar Transformation of Law and Society Review, 26 (1): 47–83.
European Business. Oxford: Oxford University Edelman, L.B., Erlanger, H.S., Lande, J. 1993.
Press. Internal dispute resolution: The transformation
INTRODUCTION 39

of civil rights in the workplace. Law and Society Fligstein, N., and Dauber, K. 1989. Structural
Review, 27 (3): 497–534. change in corporate organization. Annual
Edelman, L.B., and Suchman, M.C. 1997. The Review of Sociology, 15: 73–96.
legal environments of organizations. Annual Fombrun, C.J. 1989. Convergent dynamics in
Review of Sociology, 23: 479–515. the production of organizational configura-
Edelman, L.B., Uggen, C., and Erlanger, H.S. tions. Journal of Management Studies, 26
1999. The endogeneity of legal regulation: (5): 458–475.
Grievance procedures as rational myth. Foreman, P., and Whetten, D.A. 2002.
American Journal of Sociology, 105 (2): Members’ identification with multiple-
406–454. identity organizations. Organization Science,
Eisenhardt, K.M. 1988. Agency-theory and 13 (6): 618–635.
institutional theory explanations: The case of Fox-Wolfgramm, S.J., Boal, K., and Hunt, J.G.
retail sales compensation. Academy of 1998. Organizational adaptation to institu-
Management Journal, 31 (3): 488–511. tional change: A comparative study of first-
Eisenhardt, K.M., and Martin, J.A. 2000. order change in prospector and defender
Dynamic capabilities: What are they? banks. Administrative Science Quarterly, 43:
Strategic Management Journal, Special Issue 87–126.
21: 1105–1121. Frenkel, M. 2005. The politics of translation:
Elsbach, K.D. 1994. Managing organizational How state-level political relations affect the
legitimacy in the California cattle industry: cross-national travel of management ideas.
The construction and effectiveness of verbal Organization, 12: 275–301.
accounts. Administrative Science Quarterly, Friedland, R., and Alford, R.R. 1991. Bringing
39 (1): 57–88. society back in: Symbols, practices, and
Elsbach, K.D., and Kramer, R.D., 1996. institutional contradictions. In W.W. Powell
Members’ responses to organizational iden- and P.J. DiMaggio (eds)., The New Institution-
tity threats: Encountering and countering the alism in Organizational Analysis. Chicago, IL:
business week rankings. Administrative University of Chicago Press.
Science Quarterly, 41: 442–476. Galaskiewicz, J. 1985. Professional networks
Elsbach, K.D., and Sutton, R.I. 1992. Acquiring and the institutionalization of a single mind
organizational legitimacy through illegiti- set. American Sociological Review, 50:
mate actions: A marriage of institutional and 639–658.
impression management theories. Academy Garud, R., Jain, S., and Kumaraswamy, A. 2002.
of Management Journal, 35 (4): 699–738. Institutional entrepreneurship in the spon-
Fennell, M.L., and Alexander, J.A. 1987. sorship of common technological standards:
Organizational boundary spanning in institu- The case of Sun Microsystems and Java.
tionalized environments. Academy of Academy of Management Journal, 45 (1):
Management Journal, 30 (3): 456–476. 196–214.
Finlay, W. 1987. Industrial relations and firm George, E., Chattopadhyay, P., Sitkin, S.B., and
behavior: Informal labor practices in the west Barden, J. 2006. Cognitive underpinnings of
coast longshore industry. Administrative institutional persistence and change: A fram-
Science Quarterly, 32 (1): 49–67. ing perspective. Academy of Management
Fligstein, N. 2002. The twenty-first century Review, 31: 347–365.
firm: Changing economic organization in Ghoshal, S. 1988. Environmental scanning in
international perspective. American Journal Korean firms: Organizational isomorphism in
of Sociology, 107 (4): 1114–1116. action. Journal of International Business
Fligstein, N. 1987. The intraorganizational Studies, 19 (1): 69–86.
power struggle: Rise of finance personnel to Godard, J. 1999. Do implementation processes
top leadership in large corporations, and rationales matter? The case of work-
1919–1979. American Sociological Review, place reforms. Journal of Management
52 (1): 44–58. Studies, 36 (5): 679–704.
Fligstein, N. 1985. The spread of the multidivi- Goodrick, E., and Salancik, G.R. 1996.
sional form among large firms, 1919–1979. Organizational discretion in responding to
American Sociological Review, 50: 377–391. institutional practices: Hospitals and caesarean
40 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

births. Administrative Science Quarterly, 29 Hasselbladh, H., and Kalinikos, J. 2000. The
(2): 232–237. project of rationalization: A critique and re-
Greenwood, R., and Hinings, C.R. 2006. Radical appraisal of neo-institutionalism in organiza-
organizational change. In, S. Clegg, C. Hardy, tion studies. Organization Studies, 21:
W.W. Nord and T. Lawrence (eds.), Handbook 697–720.
of Organization Studies. Haunschild, P. 1993. Interorganizational imita-
Greenwood, R., and Hinings, C.R. 1993. tion: the impact of interlocks on corporate
Understanding strategic change: The acquisition activity. Administrative Science
contribution of archetypes. Academy of Quarterly, 38: 564–592.
Management Journal, 36: 1052–1081. Hayward, M.L.A., and Boeker, W. 1998. Power
Greenwood, R., and Suddaby, R. 2006. and conflicts of interest in professional
Institutional entrepreneurship in mature firms: Evidence from investment banking.
fields: The Big Five accounting firms. Administrative Science Quarterly, 43 (1): 1–22.
Academy of Management Journal, 49: Hedmo, T. 2004. Rule-making in the Transna-
27–48. tional Space: The Development of European
Greenwood, R., Suddaby, R., and Hinings, C.R. Accreditation of Management Education.
2002. Theorizing change: The role of profes- Unpublished doctoral thesis #109. Department
sional associations in the transformation of of Business Studies, Uppsala University.
institutional fields. Academy of Management Hedmo, T., Sahlin-Andersson, K., and Wedlin,
Journal, 45 (1): 58–80. L. 2006 [a]. The emergence of a European
Guillen, M.F. 2001. The Limits of Convergence. regulatory field of management education.
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. In M.-L. Djelic and K. Sahlin-Andersson (eds.),
Guler, I., Guillen, M.F., and MacPherson, J.M. Transnational Governance: Institutional
2002. Global competition, institutions, and Dynamics of Regulation. Cambridge University
the diffusion of organizational practices: The Press, pp. 308–328.
international spread of ISO 9000 quality cer- Hedmo, T., Sahlin-Andersson, K., and Wedlin,
tificates. Administrative Science Quarterly, L. 2006 [b]. Fields of imitation: The global
47 (2): 207–232. expansion of management education. In
Gupta, A.K. Smith, K.G., and Shalley, C.E. B. Czarniawska and G. Sevón (eds.), Global
2006. The interplay between exploration Ideas: How Ideas, Objects and Practices
and exploitation. Academy of Management Travel in the Global Economy. Liber and
Journal, 49: 693–706. Copenhagen Business School Press, Lund,
Hall, P.A., and Taylor, R.C.R. 1996. Political sci- pp. 190–212.
ence and the three new institutionalisms. Helfat, C.E., Finkelstein, S., Mitchell, W.,
Political Studies, 44 (5): 936–957. Peterak, M.A., Singh, H., Teece, D.J., and
Hamilton, G.G., and Biggart, N.W. 1988. Winter, S.G. 2007. Dynamic Capabilities.
Market, culture, and authority: A compara- Blackwell Publishing.
tive analysis of management and organiza- Helfat, C.E., and Peteraf, M.A. 2003. The
tion in the Far East. American Journal of dynamic resource-based view: Capability life-
Sociology, 94: S52–S94. cycles. Strategic Management Journal, 24:
Han, S.K. 1994. Mimetic isomorphism and its 997–1010.
effect on the audit services market. Social Henderson, J., and Cool, K. 2003. Corporate
Forces, 73 (2): 637–664. governance, investment bandwagons and
Hannan, M.T., and Carroll, G. (eds.) 1995. overcapacity: An analysis of the worldwide
Organizations in Industry. Oxford, UK: petrochemical industry, 1975–95. Strategic
Oxford University Press. Management Journal, 24: 349–373.
Hargrave, T.J., and Van de Ven, A.H. 2006. A Henisz, W.J., and Zelner, B.A. 2005. Legitimacy,
collective action model of institutional inno- interest group pressures, and change in emer-
vation. Academy of Management Review, gent institutions: The case of foreign investors
31: 864–888. and host country governments. Academy of
Harrison, J.R. 1987. The strategic use of Management Review, 30: 361–382.
corporate board committees. California Higgins, M.C., and Gulati, R. 2003. Getting off
Management Review, 30 (1): 109–125. to a good start: The effects of upper echelon
INTRODUCTION 41

affiliations on underwriter prestige. Jepperson, R.L. 1991. Institutions, institutional


Organization Science, 14 (3): 244–263. effects, and institutionalization. In
Hinings, C.R., and Greenwood, R. 2002. W.W. Powell and P.J. DiMaggio (eds.), The
Disconnects and consequences in organiza- New Institutionalism in Organizational Analy-
tion theory? Administrative Science sis. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.
Quarterly, 47 (3): 411–421. Johnson, G., Smith, S., and Codling, B. 2000.
Hinings, C. R., and Greenwood, R. 1988. The Microprocesses of institutional change in the
Dynamics of Strategic Change. Oxford, UK: context of privatization. Academy of
Basil Blackwell. Management Review, 25 (3): 572–580.
Hirsch, P.M. 1975. Organizational effective- Keister, L.A. 2004. Capital structure in transi-
ness and the institutional environment. tion: The transformation of financial strate-
Administrative Science Quarterly, 20: 327–344. gies in China’s emerging economy.
Hirsch, P.M., and Lounsbury, M. 1997. Putting Organization Science, 15: 145–158.
the organization back into organization Kitchener, M. 2002. Mobilizing the logic of
theory: Action, change, and the ‘new’ insti- managerialism in professional fields: The
tutionalism. Journal of Management Inquiry, case of academic health centre mergers.
6 (1): 79–88. Organization Studies, 23 (3): 391–420.
Hitt, M.A., Ahlstrom, D., Dacin, M.T., Levitas, Kock, C.J. 2005. When the market mis-
E., and Svobodina, L. 2004. The institutional leads: Stock prices, firm behavior, and
effects on strategic alliance partner selection industry evolution. Organization Science, 16:
in transition economies: China vs. Russia. 637–660.
Organization Science, 15: 173–185. Kossek, E.E., Dass, P., and Demarr, B. 1994. The
Hoffman, A.J. 1999. Institutional evolution and dominant logic of employer-sponsored work
change: Environmentalism and the U.S. and family initiatives: Human resource man-
chemical industry. Academy of Management agers’ institutional role. Human Relations, 47
Journal, 42: 351–371. (9): 1121–49.
Hoffman, A.J., and Ventresca, M.J. (eds.) 2002. Kostova, T. 1999. Transnational transfer of
Organizations, Policy, and the Natural Envi- strategic organizational practices: A contex-
ronment. Stanford: Stanford University Press. tual perspective. Academy of Management
Huff, A.S. 1997. A current and future agenda for Review, 24 (2): 308–324.
cognitive research in organizations. Journal of Kostova, T., and Roth, K. 2002. Adoption of an
Management Studies, 34: 947–952. organizational practice by subsidiaries of
Imershein, A.W., Rond III, P.C. 1989. Elite frag- multinational corporations: Institutional and
mentation in health care: Proprietary and relational effects. Academy of Management
nonproprietary hospitals in Florida. Social Journal, 45 (1): 215–233.
Science Quarterly, 70 (1): 53–71. Kraatz, M.S., and Zajac, E.J. 1996. Exploring
Ingram, P., and Clay, K. 2000. The choice the limits of the new institutionalism: The
within constraints new institutionalism and causes and consequences of illegitimate
implications for sociology. Annual Review of organizational change. American Sociological
Sociology, 26: 525–546. Review, 61: 812–836.
Ingram, P., Inman, C. 1996. Institutions, inter- Krishnan, R.A., Joshi, S., and Krishnan, H. 2004.
group competition, and the evolution of The influence of mergers in firms’ product-mix
hotel populations around Niagara Falls. strategies. Strategic Management Journal, 25:
Administrative Science Quarterly, 41 (4): 587–611.
629–658. Labianca, G., Fairbank, J.F., Thomas, J.B., Gioia,
Ingram, P., and Silverman, B.S. 2002. D.A., and Umphress, E.E. 2001. Emulation in
Introduction: The new institutionalism in academia: Balancing structure and identity.
strategic management. New Institutionalism Organization Science, 12 (3): 312–330.
in Strategic Management, 19: 1–30. Lawrence, T., Hardy, C., and Phillips, N. 2002.
Jennings, P.S., and Zandergen, P.A. 1995. Institutional effects of interorganizational
Ecologically sustainable organizations: An collaboration: The emergence of proto-
institutional approach. Academy of institutions. Academy of Management
Management Review, 20: 1015–1052. Journal, 45: 281–291.
42 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Lawrence, T., Winn, M.I., and Jennings, P.D. contingency of professional counter-
2001. The temporal dynamics of institutional- mobilization in U.S. banking. Academy of
ization. Academy of Management Review, Management Journal, 50(4): 799–820.
25: 624–644. Martin, J.L. 2003. What is field theory?
Leblebici, H., Salancik, G., Copay, A., and King, American Journal of Sociology, 109 (1):
T. 1991. Institutional change and the trans- 1–49.
formation of the U.S. radio broadcasting Meyer, A.D. 1982. Adapting to environmental
industry. Administrative Science Quarterly, jolts. Administrative Science Quarterly, 27
36: 333–363. (4): 515–537.
Lincoln, J.R., Hanada, M., and McBride, K. 1986. Meyer, J.W. 1996. Otherhood: The pro-
Organizational structures in Japanese and mulgation and transmission of ideas in
United States manufacturing. Administrative the modern organizational environment.
Science Quarterly, 31 (3): 403–421. In B. Czarniawska and G. Sevón (eds.),
Lincoln, J.R., Hanada, M., and Olson, J. 1981. Translating Organizational Change. DeGruyter,
Cultural orientations and individual reactions pp. 241–252.
to organizations: A study of employees Meyer, J.W., and Rowan, B. 1983. The struc-
of Japanese-owned firms. Administrative ture of educational organizations. In J.W.
Science Quarterly, 26 (1): 93–115. Meyer and W.R. Scott (eds.), Organizational
Lincoln, J.R., and McBride, K. 1987. Japanese Environments: Ritual and Rationality. Beverly
industrial organization in comparative per- Hills: Sage Publications.
spective. Annual Review of Sociology, 13: Meyer, J.W., and Rowan, B. 1977.
289–312. Institutionalized organizations: Formal struc-
Lucas, J.W. 2003. Status processes and the insti- ture as myth and ceremony. American
tutionalization of women as leaders. American Journal of Sociology, 83: 440–463.
Sociological Review, 68 (3): 464–480. Meyer, J.W., and Scott, W.R. 1983.
Magan Diaz, A., Greenwood, R., Li, S.X., and Organizational Environments. Beverly Hills,
Lorente, J.C. 2007. Adapting to institutional CA: Sage Publications.
complexity: Spanish firms in the post-Franco Meyer, J., Scott, W.R., and Strang, D. 1987.
era. To be presented at the Academy of Centralization, fragmentation, and school
Management Conference in Philadelphia, district complexity. Administrative Science
August, 2007. Quarterly, 32 (2): 186–201.
Maguire, S., Hardy, C., and Lawrence, T.B. Mizruchi, M.S., and Fein, L.C. 1999. The social
2004. Institutional entrepreneurship in construction of organizational knowledge: A
emerging fields: HI/AIDS treatment advocacy study of the uses of coercive, mimetic, and
in Canada. Academy of Management normative isomorphism. Administrative
Journal, 47: 657–679. Science Quarterly, 44 (4): 653–683.
March, J.G. 1991. Exploration and exploitation Mohr, J.W. 2005. Implicit terrains: Meaning,
in organizational learning. Organization measurement, and spatial metaphors in
Science, 2: 71–87. organizational theory. In M. Ventresca and
March, J.G., and Olsen, J.P. 1989. Porac (eds.), Constructing Industries and
Rediscovering Institutions: The Organiza- Markets. New York: Elsevier.
tional Basis of Politics. New York: Free Press. Mohr, J.W. 1998. Measuring meaning struc-
March, J.G., and Olsen, J.P. 1976. Ambiguity tures. Annual Review of Sociology, 24:
and Choice in Organizations. Bergen, 345–370.
Norway: Universitetsforlaget. Mörth, U. (ed.). 2004. Soft Law in Governance
March, J.G., and Simon, H.A. 1958. and Regulation. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Organizations. New York: John Wiley. Neilson, E.H., and Rao, M.V.H. 1987. The strat-
Marquis, C. 2003. The pressure of the past: egy-legitimacy nexus: A thick description.
Network imprinting in intercorporate com- Academy of Management Review, 12 (3):
munities. Administrative Science Quarterly, 523–533.
48 (4): 655–689. Newman, J.H.C. 1907. Essays Critical and
Marquis, C., and Lounsbury, M. 2007. Vive la Historical. London: Longmans, Green and
résistance: Consolidation and the institutional Co., Vol. II.
INTRODUCTION 43

Ocasio, W. 1994. Political dynamics and the circu- resources in the UK refugee system.
lation of power: CEO succession in U.S. indus- Organization, 4 (2): 159–185.
trial corporations, 1960–1990. Administrative Phillips, N., Lawrence, T.B., and Hardy, C. 2000.
Science Quarterly, 39: 285–314. Inter-organizational collaboration and the
Oliver, C. 1997. Sustainable competitive advan- dynamics of institutional fields. Journal of
tage: Combining institutional and resource- Management Studies, 37 (1): 23–43.
based views. Strategic Management Journal, Pollock, T.G., and Rindova, V.P. 2003. Media
18: 697–713. legitimation effects in the market for initial
Oliver, C. 1992. The antecedents of deinstitu- public offerings. Academy of Management
tionalization. Organization Studies, 13: Journal, 46: 631–642.
563–588. Porac, J.F., Thomas, H., and Baden-Fuller, C.
Oliver, C. 1991. Strategic responses to institu- 1989. Competitive groups as cognitive com-
tional processes. Academy of Management munities: The case of Scottish knitwear man-
Review, 16: 145–179. ufacturers. Journal of Management Studies,
Oliver, C. 1988. The collective strategy frame- 26 (4): 397–416.
work: An application to competing predic- Porac, J.F., Thomas, H., Wilson, and Kanfer, A.
tions of isomorphism. Administrative Science 1995. Rivalry and the industry model of
Quarterly, 33 (4): 543–561. Scottish knitwear producers. Administrative
Orru, M., Biggart, N.W., and Hamilton, G.G. Science Quarterly, 40: 203–227.
1991. Organizational isomorphism in East Powell, W.W. 1991. Expanding the scope of insti-
Asia. In W.W. Powell and P.J. DiMaggio tutional analysis. In W.W. Powell, W.W. and
(eds.), The New Institutionalism in Organiza- P.J. DiMaggio (eds.), The New Institutionalism
tional Analysis. Chicago, IL: University of in Organizational Analysis, pp. 183–203.
Chicago Press. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.
Peng, M.W. 2004. Outside directors and firm Powell, W.W., and DiMaggio, P.J. 1991. The
performance during institutional transitions. New Institutionalism in Organizational Analy-
Strategic Management Journal, 25: 453–471. sis. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.
Peng, M.W. 2003. Institutional transitions and Powell, W.W., White, D.R., Koput, K.W., and
strategic choices. Academy of Management Owen-Smith, J. 2005. Network dynamics and
Review, 28: 275–296. field evolution: The growth of interorganiza-
Peng, M.W., Lee, S., and Wang, D.Y.L. 2005. tional collaboration in the life sciences.
What determines the scope of the firm over American Journal of Sociology, 110 (4):
time? A focus on institutional relatedness. 1132–1205.
Academy of Management Review, 30: Power, M. 1997. The Audit Society. Oxford:
622–633. Oxford University Press.
Perrow, C. 2002. Organizing America. Quaid, M. 1993. Job evaluation as institutional
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. myth. Journal of Management Studies, 30:
Perrow, C. 1986. Complex Organizations: A Crit- 239–260.
ical Essay, 3rd edn. New York: Random House. Rao, H. 2004. Institutional activism in the early
Pfeffer, J. 1982. Organizational demography. In American automobile industry. Journal of
L.L. Cummings and B.M. Staw (eds.), Business Venturing, 19: 359–384.
Research in Organizational Behavior, vol. 5. Rao, H., Greve, H.R., and Davis, G.F. 2001.
Greenwich, CT: JAI Press. Fool’s gold: Social proof in the initiation and
Pfeffer, J., and Cohen, Y. 1984. Determinants abandonment of coverage by Wall Street
of internal labor markets in organizations. analysts. Administrative Science Quarterly,
Administrative Science Quarterly, 29 (4): 46 (3): 502–526.
550–572. Rao, H., Monin, P., and Durand, R. 2003.
Pfeffer, J., and Davis-Blake, A. 1987. The effect Institutional change in Toque Ville: Nouvelle
of the proportion of women on salaries: cuisine as an identity movement in French
The case of college administrators. gastronomy. American Journal of Sociology,
Administrative Science Quarterly, 32 (1): 1–24. 180 (4): 795–843.
Phillips, N., and Hardy, C. 1997. Managing Rhee, M., and Haunschild, P.R. 2006. The liabil-
multiple identities: Discourse, legitimacy and ity of good reputation: A study of product
44 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

recalls in the U.S. automobile industry. Organizational Environments: Ritual and


Organization Science, 17: 101–117. Rationality. Beverly Hills: Sage Publications.
Rindova, V.P., Pollock, T.G., and Hayward, Scott, W.R. 1981. Developments in organization
M.L.A. 2006. Celebrity firms: The social con- theory, 1960–1980. American Behavioral
struction of market popularity. Academy of Scientist, 24 (3): 407–422.
Management Review, 31 (1): 50–71. Scott, W.R., and Meyer, J. 1983. The organiza-
Ruef, M., and Scott, W.R. 1998. A multidimen- tion of societal sectors. In J.W. Meyer and
sional model of organizational legitimacy: W.R. Scott (eds.), Organizational Environ-
Hospital survival in changing institutional ments: Ritual and Rationality. Beverly Hills,
environments: Administrative Science CA: Sage.
Quarterly, 43 (4): 877–904. Scott, W.R., Ruef, M., Mendel, P.J., and
Sahlin-Andersson, K. 1996. Imitating by editing Caronna, C.A. 2000. Institutional Change and
success: The construction of organizational Healthcare Organizations: From Professional
fields. In B. Czarniawska and G. Sevón (eds.), Dominance to Managed Care. Chicago, IL:
Translating Organizational Change, pp. University of Chicago Press.
69–92. Berlin: de Gruyter. Selznick, P. 1996. Institutionalism ‘old’ and
Sahlin-Andersson, K., and Engwall, L. 2002. ‘new.’ Administrative Science Quarterly, 41:
The Expansion of Management Knowledge. 270–277.
Stanford: Stanford University Press. Selznick, P. 1949. TVA and The Grass Roots.
Sanders, W.G., and Tuschke, A. 2007. The Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.
adoption of institutionally contested organi- Seo, M.G., and Creed, W.E.D. 2002.
zational practices: The emergence of stock Institutional contradictions, praxis and insti-
option pay in Germany. Academy of tutional change: A dialectical perspective.
Management Journal, 50: 33–57. Academy of Management Review, 27:
Schneider, S.C. 1993. Conflicting ideologies: 222–247.
Structural and motivational consequences. Sevón, G. 1996. Organizational imitation in
Human Relations, 46 (1): 45–64. identity transformation. In B. Czarniawska
Schrodinger, E. 1951. Science and Humanism, and G. Sevón (eds.), Translating Organiza-
quoted in Goleman, D. Vital Lies, Simple tional Change. DeGruyter, pp. 49–68.
Truths. London: Bloomsbury. Sheets, R.G., and Ting, Y. 1988. Determinants
Scott, W.R. 2005. Institutional theory: of employee termination benefits in organi-
Contributing to a theoretical research program. zations. Administrative Science Quarterly, 33
In K.G. Smith and M.A. Hitt (eds.), Great Minds (4): 607–624.
in Management. Oxford: Oxford University Sherer, P.D., and Lee, K. 2002. Institutional
Press. change in large law firms: A resource depend-
Scott, W.R. 2004. Reflections on a half-century ency and institutional perspective. Academy
of organizational sociology. Annual Review of Management Journal, 45 (1): 102–119.
of Sociology, 30: 1–21. Singh, J.V., House, R.J., and Tucker, D.J. 1986.
Scott, R.W. 2001. Institutions and Organiza- Organizational change and organizational
tions, 2nd edn. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage. mortality. Administrative Science Quarterly,
Scott, W.R. 1995. Institutions and Organiza- 31 (3): 338–364.
tions, 1st edn. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage. Singh, J.V., and Lumsden, C.J. 1990. Theory
Scott, W.R. 1991. Unpacking institutional argu- and research in organizational ecology.
ments. In W.W. Powell and P.J. DiMaggio Annual Review of Sociology, 16: 161–195.
(eds.), The New Institutionalism in Organiza- Staw, B.M., and Epstein, L.D. 2000. What band-
tional Analysis, pp. 164–182. Chicago, IL: wagons bring: Effects of popular manage-
University of Chicago Press. ment techniques on corporate performance,
Scott, W.R. 1987. The adolescence of institu- reputation, and CEO pay. Administrative
tional theory. Administrative Science Science Quarterly, 45 (3): 523–556.
Quarterly, 32 (4): 493–511. Stern, R.N., and Barley, S.R. 1996. Organizations
Scott, W.R. 1983. The organization of environ- and social systems: Organization theory’s
ments: Network, cultural and historical neglected mandate. Administrative Science
elements. In J.W. Meyer and W.R. Scott (eds.), Quarterly, 41 (1): 146–162.
INTRODUCTION 45

Stinchcombe, A.L. 1997. On the virtues of the Tripsas, M., and Gavetti, G. 2000. Capabilities,
old institutionalism. Annual Review of cognition, and inertia. Strategic Management
Sociology, 23: 1–18. Journal, 21: 1147–1161.
Strang, D. 1987. The administrative transfor- Vaaler, P.M., and McNamara, G. 2004. Crisis
mation of American education school district and competition in expert organizational
consolidation, 1938–1980. Administrative decision making: Credit-rating agencies and
Science Quarterly, 32 (3): 352–366. their response to turbulence in emerging
Suchman, M.C. 1995. Managing legitimacy: economies. Organization Science, 15:
Strategic and institutional approaches. 687–703.
Academy of Management Review, 20: Van de Ven, A.H., and Joyce, W.F. 1981.
571–611. Perspectives on Organization Design and
Suchman, M.C., and Cahill, M.L. 1996. The Behaviour. New York: John Wiley and Sons.
hired gun as facilitator: Lawyers and the sup- Walker, G. Madsen, T.L., and Carini, G. 2002.
pression of business disputes in Silicon Valley. How does institutional change affect hetero-
Law and Social Inquiry: Journal of the geneity among firms? Strategic Management
American Bar Foundation, 21 (3): 679–712. Journal, 23: 9–104.
Suddaby, R., and Greenwood, R. 2005. Weber, K., and Glynn, M.A. 2006. Making
Rhetorical strategies of legitimacy. sense with institutions: Context, thought and
Administrative Science Quarterly, 50: 35–67. action in Karl Weick’s theory. Organization
Suddaby, R., Cooper, D.J., Greenwood, R. Studies, 27: 1639–1660.
2007. Transnational regulation of profes- Wedlin, L. 2006. Ranking Business Schools:
sional services: Governance dynamics of field Forming Fields, Identities and Boundaries in
level organizational change. Accounting, International Management Education.
Organizations and Society, 32: 333–362. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Teece, D.J. Pisano, G., and Shuen, A. 1997. Weick, K. 1995. Sensemaking in Organizations.
Dynamic capabilities and strategic management. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.
Strategic Management Journal, 18: 509–533. Westphal, J.D., and Zajac, E.J. 2001.
Thornton, P. 2004. Markets from Culture: Decoupling policy from practice: The case of
Institutional Logics and Organizational stock repurchase programs. Administrative
Decisions in Higher Education Publishing. Science Quarterly, 46 (2): 202–228.
Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press Westphal, J.D., and Zajac, E.J. 1998. The
Thornton, P. 2002. The rise of the corporation symbolic management of stockholders:
in a craft industry: Conflict and conformity in Corporate governance reforms and share-
institutional logics. Academy of Management holder reactions. Administrative Science
Journal, 45: 81–101. Quarterly, 43 (1): 127–153.
Tolbert, P.S. 1985. Institutional environments and Yiu, D., Makino, S. 2002. The choice between
resource dependence: Sources of administra- joint venture and wholly owned subsidiary:
tive structure in institutions of higher educa- An institutional perspective. Organization
tion. Administrative Science Quarterly, 30 Science, 13 (6): 667–683.
(1): 1–13. Young, G.J., Charns, M.P., and Shortell, S.M.
Tolbert, P.S., and Zucker, L.G. 1995. The institu- 2001. Top manager and network effects on
tionalization of institutional theory. In the adoption of innovative management
S.R. Clegg, C. Hardy and W.R. Nord (eds.), practices: A study of TQM in a public hospi-
Handbook of Organization Studies, pp. tal system. Strategic Management Journal,
175–190. London: Sage. 22 (10): 935–951.
Tolbert, P.S., and Zucker, L.G. 1983. Young, G.J. Stedham, Y., and Beekun, R.I. 2000.
Institutional sources of change in the formal Boards of directors and the adoption of a CEO
structure of organizations: The diffusion of performance evaluation process: Agency- and
civil service reform, 1880–1935. Administrative institutional-theory perspectives. Journal of
Science Quarterly, 30: 22–39. Management Studies, 37: 277–295.
Torres, D.L. 1988. Professionalism, variation, Zajac, E.J., and Westphal, J.D. 2004. The social
and organizational survival. American construction of market value: Institutional-
Sociological Review, 53 (3): 380–394. ization and learning perspectives on stock
46 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

market reactions. American Sociological no history. American Sociological Review, 54


Review, 69 (3): 433–457. (4): 542–545.
Zbaracki, M.J. 1998. The rhetoric and reality of Zucker, L.G. 1988. Institutional Patterns and
total quality management. Administrative Organizations: Culture and Environment.
Science Quarterly, 43 (3): 602–636. Cambridge, MA: Ballinger.
Zey-Ferrell, M. 1981. Criticisms of the domi- Zucker, L.G. 1987 [b]. Institutional theories of
nant perspective on organizations. The organization. Annual Review of Sociology,
Sociological Quarterly, Spring: 181–205. 13: 443–464.
Zilber, T.B. 2006. The work of the symbolic in Zucker, L.G. 1983. Organizations as institu-
institutional processes: Translations of tions. Research in the Sociology of
rational myths in Israel high tech. Academy Organizations, 2: 1–47.
of Management Journal, 49: 281–304. Zucker, L.G. 1977. The role of institutionaliza-
Zilber, T.B. 2002. Institutionalization as an inter- tion in cultural persistence. American
play between actions, meanings and actors: The Sociological Review, 42: 726–743.
case of a rape crisis center in Israel. Academy of Zuckerman, E.W., and Kim, T. Y. 2003. The crit-
Management Journal, 45 (1): 234–254. ical trade-off: Identity assignment and box-
Zimmerman, M.A., and Zeitz, G.J. 2002. office success in the feature film industry.
Beyond survival: Achieving new venture Industrial and Corporate Change, 12 (1):
growth by building legitimacy. Academy of 27–67.
Management Review, 27 (3): 414–431. Zuckerman, E.W. 2000. Focusing the corporate
Zucker, L.G. 1991. Postscript: Microfoundations product: Securities analysts and de-diversifi-
of institutional thought. In W.W. Powell and cation. Administrative Science Quarterly, 45
P.J. DiMaggio (eds.), The New Institutionalism (3): 591–619.
in Organizational Analysis, pp. 103–107. Zuckerman, E.W. 1999. The categorical imper-
Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press. ative: Securities analysts and the illegitimacy
Zucker, L.G. 1989. Combining institutional discount. American Journal of Sociology,
theory and population ecology: No legitimacy, 104 (5): 1398–1438.
SECTION I

Foundational Themes
1
Legitimacy in Organizational
Institutionalism
David L. Deephouse and Mark Suchman

INTRODUCTION concept formation is always simultaneously


the process of concept transformation,’ and
Legitimacy is a central concept in organiza- legitimacy has been no exception. Nonetheless,
tional institutionalism. The term ‘legiti- despite its diversity, the literature on legitimacy
macy’ dates back to the dawn of displays more than enough coherence and com-
organization theory; however, for most of monality to merit an integrative review.
the past century, research on legitimacy This chapter is organized as follows. Our
emerged only slowly and was fragmented exploration begins with an overview of past
across several distinct social science theoretical and empirical research on legiti-
literatures. Since 1995, however, the body of macy. This discussion includes some basic
relevant scholarship has grown rapidly and in suggestions on the dimensions, sources, and
a variety of directions. Much of this new subjects of legitimation, as well as on key
literature (like much of the literature that legitimation processes, antecedents and con-
preceded it) has been highly theoretical, sequences.1 Second, we consider the rela-
invoking legitimacy as an explanatory tionship between legitimacy and two other
concept rather than examining it as an empir- types of social evaluation that have recently
ical property. Empirical accounts, to date, gained prominence in organization studies,
have focused on exploratory case studies of namely status and reputation. Finally, we
legitimacy being gained or lost, while only a conclude with several recommendations for
handful of investigations have employed advancing legitimacy research in the future.
legitimacy as a variable in hypothesis testing.
Perhaps because of this heavy skew toward
theory development versus theory testing, the
legitimacy concept has exhibited substantial THE EVOLUTION OF
plasticity as it has evolved from its earliest ORGANIZATIONAL LEGITIMACY
institutionalist usages (e.g., Meyer & Rowan,
1977; Meyer & Scott, 1983). As Wright Over the years, the conceptualization and
(1985: 292) has observed, ‘the process of explication of organizational legitimacy has
50 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

displayed substantial elasticity. Taken as a New institutional theory started develop-


whole, this elasticity has resulted in some ing in 1977 with the articles by Meyer and
productive conceptual evolution but more Rowan (1977) and Zucker (1977). Although
conceptual stretching (Osigweh, 1989). As a Zucker only mentioned legitimacy once in
result, the existing literature offers a plethora passing, Meyer and Rowan made it a central
of definitions, measures, and theoretical focus of their analysis, invoking the term at
propositions, not all of which are fully com- least 43 times in some form. Their summary
patible with one another. While some might graphic (1977: 353, figure 2) placed ‘legiti-
argue that this intellectual thicket is overdue macy’ and ‘resources’ together in the same
for a wholesale pruning, here we limit our- box, and suggested that both of these
selves to the more modest task of mapping survival-enhancing outcomes may result not
the underlying terrain, seeking to identify only from being efficient but also from
both the features that have become increas- conforming to institutionalized myths in the
ingly well established and widely accepted organizational environment. Although
over time, and the features that have remained Meyer and Rowan (1977) did not offer an
relatively ambiguous and contested. explicit definition of legitimacy, they
presaged many of the dimensions explicated
in the mid-1990s by stating that legitimacy
The development of legitimacy can result from suppositions of ‘rational
theory in organizational effectiveness’ (later termed pragmatic legiti-
macy), ‘legal mandates’ (regulatory or
institutionalism
sociopolitical legitimacy), and ‘collectively
Most reviewers credit Weber with introducing valued purposes, means, goals, etc.’ (norma-
legitimacy into sociological theory and thus tive or moral legitimacy). They also
into organization studies (Johnson et al., 2006; highlighted how legitimacy insulates the
Ruef & Scott, 1998; Suchman, 1995). Weber’s organization from external pressures. ‘The
analysis of the legitimacy of different author- incorporation of institutionalized elements
ity types is well known to many organization provides an account (Scott & Lyman,
theorists. More generally, however, his writ- 1968) … that protects the organization from
ings also discuss the importance of social having its conduct questioned. The organiza-
practice being oriented to ‘maxims’ or rules tion becomes, in a word, legitimate …. And
and suggest that legitimacy can result from legitimacy as accepted subunits of society
conformity with both general social norms protects organizations from immediate sanc-
and formal laws (Weber, 1978). Parsons tions for variations in technical performance’
(1956, 1960) applied Weber’s ideas and (Meyer & Rowan, 1977: 349, 351).
viewed legitimacy as congruence of an In 1983, Meyer and Scott discussed legiti-
organization with social laws, norms and macy in much more depth, including offering
values. This formulation was later embraced a more thorough definition:
by many organization theorists, including
Dowling and Pfeffer (1975), Pfeffer and We take the view that organizational legitimacy
refers to the degree of cultural support for an
Salancik (1978), and Czarniawska-Joerges
organization – the extent to which the array of
(1989). Ironically, however, the early institu- established cultural accounts provide explanations
tionalist literature was more enthusiastic in for its existence, functioning, and jurisdiction, and
embracing Weber’s concept than in adopting lack or deny alternatives … In such a[n] instance,
his conceptualization. Meyer and Scott legitimacy mainly refers to the adequacy of an
organization as theory. A completely legitimate
(1983: 201), for example, commented that
organization would be one about which no ques-
the many references to Weber as a defining tion could be raised. [Every goal, mean, resource,
account of legitimacy were ‘unfortunate, and control system is necessary, specified, com-
given Weber’s lack of clarity on the point.’ plete, and without alternative.] Perfect legitimation
LEGITIMACY IN ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM 51

is perfect theory, complete (i.e., without uncer- resonates with Child’s (1972) strategic
tainty) and confronted by no alternatives (p. 201) choice perspective, which holds that
One noteworthy feature of this definition legitimate organizations enjoy substantial
is its emphasis on legitimacy’s ‘cognitive’ latitude to choose their structures, products,
aspects – explanation, theorization, and the markets, factors of production, etc. That is, a
incomprehensibility of alternatives. This legitimate organization has largely unques-
focus continues to enjoy substantial currency, tioned freedom to pursue its activities:
especially within neo-institutional sociology ‘legitimate status is a sine qua non for easy
(cf. DiMaggio & Powell, 1991). access to resources, unrestricted access to
Some theorizing expanded on Meyer and markets, and long term survival’ (Brown,
Scott’s (1983) formulation, embracing the 1998: 35).
basic proposition that legitimacy can be con- In addition to offering these foundational
ceptualized as the presence or absence of definitions, early legitimacy research also
questioning, but suggesting that questioning built on the work of Pfeffer and Salancik
is as likely to arise when a familiar organiza- (1978) to examine how organizations gain or
tion is unsatisfactory as when a satisfactory lose legitimacy. Galaskiewicz (1985) found
organization is unfamiliar. Along these lines, that organizations often sought to enhance
Hirsch and Andrews (1984) considered two their legitimacy by donating to charities,
types of questions: forming director interlocks, and obtaining
external endorsements. Ashforth and Gibbs
Performance challenges occur when organizations (1990) proposed two general approaches,
are perceived by relevant actors as having failed
‘substantive’ and ‘symbolic,’ and a total of
to execute the purpose for which they are char-
tered and claim support. The values they serve are ten specific actions, many drawn from
not at issue, but rather their performance in ‘deliv- impression management theory. They also
ering the goods’ and meeting the goals of their highlighted three purposes for legitimation
mission are called into serious question … Value efforts: Gaining, maintaining, or defending
challenges place the organization’s mission and
legitimacy. Both of Ashforth and Gibbs’ con-
legitimacy for existence at issue, regardless of how
well it has fulfilled its agreed-upon goals or tributions proved fertile: Elsbach (1994;
function. … [Both] entail fundamental challenges Elsbach & Sutton, 1992) further integrated
to the legitimacy of an organization’s continued impression management and institutional
existence. Each places the target in an inherently theories in her studies of the Act Up,
more unstable situation than is addressed in com-
EarthFirst!, and the California cattle indus-
parative or longitudinal examinations of adminis-
trative efficiency. try; and Suchman (1995) further explored the
distinct purposes (or, as he relabeled them,
Pfeffer and Salancik’s foundational state- ‘challenges’) of gaining, maintaining, and
ment of resource-dependence theory (1978) repairing legitimacy.
adopted a similar ‘negative definition’ of The year 1995 could be viewed as a pivotal
legitimacy, asserting that ‘Legitimacy is point in the development of legitimacy
known more readily when it is absent than theory. Scott published his review book
when it is present. When activities of an Institutions and Organizations. He wrote:
organization are illegitimate, comments and ‘Legitimacy is not a commodity to be
attacks will occur’ (1978: 194). Knoke (1985: possessed or exchanged but a condition
222) restated this in the affirmative, defining reflecting cultural alignment, normative
legitimacy (in the context of political associ- support, or consonance with relevant rules
ations and interest groups) as ‘the acceptance or laws’ (1995: 45). And Suchman published
by the general public and by relevant elite his comprehensive ‘Managing legitimacy:
organizations of an association’s right to Strategic and institutional approaches’
exist and to pursue its affairs in its chosen in the 1995 Academy of Management
manner.’ The ability to pursue its own affairs Review. He observed that legitimacy was
52 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

‘an anchor-point of a vastly expanded theoret-


Dimensions of legitimacy
ical apparatus addressing the normative and
cognitive forces that constrain, construct, and The conceptual dimensions of legitimacy
empower organizational actors,’ but he also received much attention in the mid-1990s.
cautioned that the existing literature provided Stryker (1994) distinguished between behav-
‘surprisingly fragile conceptual moorings. ioral consent to rules, attitudinal approval of
Many researchers employ the term legitimacy, rules, and cognitive orientation to rules.
but few define it. Further, most treatments Aldrich and Fiol (1994: 648) distinguished
cover only a limited aspect …’ (1995: 571, between cognitive and sociopolitical legiti-
italics in the original). To remedy these macy. ‘Cognitive legitimation refers to the
weaknesses, Suchman offered the following spread of knowledge about a new venture …
inclusive, broad-based definition: ‘Legitimacy Sociopolitical legitimation refers to the
is a generalized perception or assumption process by which key stakeholders, the
that the actions of an entity are desirable, general public, key opinion leaders, or
proper, or appropriate within some socially government officials accept a venture as
constructed system of norms, values, beliefs, appropriate and right, given existing norms
and definitions’ (1995: 574). Within this and laws.’ Scott (1995), in effect, subdivided
scope, he delineated two basic perspectives, Aldrich and Fiol’s ‘sociopolitical’ category
an institutional view emphasizing how to arrive at three dimensions of legitimacy –
constitutive societal beliefs become embed- regulative, normative, and cognitive – linked
ded in organizations, and a strategic perspec- to his three pillars of institutions. Suchman
tive emphasizing how legitimacy can be (1995) proposed a broadly similar
managed to help achieve organizational trichotomy using the labels ‘pragmatic,’
goals. ‘moral’ and ‘cognitive’ legitimacy;
These two publications raised the visibility however, he went on to combine this basic
of legitimacy, especially among management framework with two temporal textures
researchers studying for-profit organizations. (episodic versus continual) and two substan-
Aldrich and Fiol (1994) had already high- tive foci (organizational actions versus orga-
lighted the importance of legitimacy to entre- nizational essences), in order to arrive
preneurs, and within a few years, Kostova at a typology containing twelve distinct legit-
and Zaheer (1999) reconsidered legitimacy imacy types: pragmatic legitimacy compris-
in the context of the multinational enterprise. ing exchange, influence, interest, and
Meanwhile, at a more theoretical level, character; moral legitimacy comprising
Oliver (1997) drew heavily on arguments consequences, procedures, persons, and
about legitimacy to integrate institutional structures; and cognitive legitimacy compris-
theory with the resource-based view of the ing predictability, plausibility, inevitability,
firm, and Deephouse (1999) developed and permanence. Together, these efforts to
strategic balance theory to address the explicate the various dimensions of legiti-
tension between differentiating to attain macy allowed more researchers to become
profitability and conforming to attain legiti- involved in the development of institutional
macy. This period also witnessed a sharp theory at both theoretical and empirical
upsurge in references to legitimacy with the levels.
broader management literature. And this There has been some effort recently to
heightened attention led to a number of reconsider these dimensions. Archibald
significant refinements in the field’s under- (2004) equated sociopolitical legitimacy with
standings of the dimensions, subjects, and regulative legitimacy and combined norma-
sources of legitimacy, as well as of the tive and cognitive legitimacy in a new cate-
processes, antecedents, and consequences of gory called cultural legitimacy. Cultural
legitimation. legitimacy accrued over time in professional
LEGITIMACY IN ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM 53

and cultural contexts, whereas sociopolitical relationships (pragmatic legitimacy), and


legitimacy was more directly managed fundamental meanings (cognitive legiti-
within political contexts. Bitekhtine (2006) macy), as well as norms and values of the
began to disentangle the concepts by drawing profession and the larger social system
on one of the fundamental tools of construct (moral legitimacy) (cf., Greenwood, Suddaby,
validity, the nomological network (Cronbach & Hinings, 2002; Suchman, 1995). Perhaps
& Meehl, 1955). Bansal and Clelland for this reason, some recent institutional
(2004) brought forth a contextually focused studies of professional associations
dimension called corporate environmental (Greenwood et al., 2002; Jones & Manev,
legitimacy. 2002) have avoided the term normative legiti-
In surveying this terrain, we note two per- macy, emphasizing instead that professions
sistent sources of confusion. The first centers often seek to influence many different dimen-
on the term ‘normative legitimacy.’ In gen- sions of legitimacy at once. We applaud this
eral sociological usage, ‘normative culture’ trend and propose that future researchers use
connotes the shared value premises that professional legitimacy to refer to legitimacy
structure collective assessments of the good conferred by professional endorsement (on
and the bad, that which is to be desired and any grounds), whereas normative legitimacy
that which is to be shunned, right and wrong should refer to legitimacy conferred by any
(Suchman, 1997). Norms, in this sense, are audience (including but not limited to profes-
everywhere – within people, groups, organi- sionals) on primarily normative grounds (cf.,
zations, and social systems. Congruence with Suchman, 1995, 1997).
such norms lies at the heart of legitimacy as A second significant source of confusion
conceptualized by early institutional sociolo- in the current literature involves the nature
gists (e.g., Weber, 1978; Parsons, 1956, 1960; and measurement of the ‘taken-for-granted’
see also DiMaggio & Powell, 1991); and component of cognitive legitimacy. As
such norms motivate most of the ‘value chal- Aldrich and Fiol (1994: 648) note, ‘The
lenges’ identified by Hirsch and Andrews highest form of cognitive legitimation is
(1984). In contemporary organizational achieved when a new product, process, or
institutionalism, however, ‘normative legiti- service is taken for granted.’ Taken-for-
macy’ is often equated with DiMaggio and grantedness – an absence of questioning – is
Powell’s (1983) concept of ‘normative iso- not, however, easy to measure, especially
morphism,’ which has come to connote not because asking one’s research subjects about
congruence with general social values, but it is, in itself, a form of questioning. One
rather congruence with the particular ethics increasingly popular measurement strategy
and worldviews of formal professions.2 involves counting the number of organiza-
These competing usages are highly problem- tions or the number of media articles, with
atic. To restrict normative legitimacy to greater numbers indicating greater legiti-
‘professional endorsement’ marginalizes the macy (Archibald, 2004; Carroll & Hannan,
sorts of broader societal norms and values 1989a; Hybels, Ryan, & Barley, 1994).
that have been seen as important since Although promising in some contexts, this
Weber. At the same time, it also marginalizes approach may be more appropriate for
the less normative, more instrumental and/or emerging industries, organizations, or prac-
cognitive aspects of professionalization. tices, than for more established ones. There
Meyer and Scott (1983: 202), for example, are fewer automobile companies and media
argue that professional groups, such as articles about automobile quality today than
‘lawyers, accountants, intellectuals,’ convey there used to be (Abrahamson & Fairchild,
legitimacy by virtue of their ‘collective 1999; Hannan, Dundon, Carroll, &
authority over what is acceptable theory’; but Torres, 1995), but the automobile industry
‘acceptable theory’ involves cause and effect remains deeply taken-for-granted. Perhaps as
54 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

industries become increasingly established, The possible subjects of legitimation are


population counts become decoupled from almost innumerable. Johnson (2004: 10–11)
taken-for-grantedness, in part because the offers a partial list, including: ‘an act, a rule,
taken-for-grantedness of existing firms a procedure, a routine, a distribution, a
reduces the legitimacy of entrepreneurship position, a group or team, a group’s status
more than it reduces the legitimacy of structure, teamwork, a system of positions,
consolidation. Similarly, with regard to an authority structure, an organization,
media articles, the taken-for-grantedness of a organizational symbols, an organization’s
well-established activity may be reflected in form, practices, services, programs, a
the complete absence of press coverage, regime, a system of power, and a system of
because the subject has blended into the inequality (to name a few).’ Two additional
cultural landscape and is no longer seen as subjects of legitimation that have drawn
requiring social scrutiny or as being attention in management research recently
‘newsworthy’ according to prevailing jour- are company founders and top management
nalistic practices (Itule & Anderson, 1994; teams (Certo, 2003; Cohen & Dean, 2005;
Shoemaker, 1996). Deeds, Mang, & Frandsen, 2004; Higgins &
Gulati, 2003, 2006). Indeed, at this point, it
appears that almost anything can be a subject
of legitimation. In the future, researchers
Subjects of legitimation
may face the challenge of aggregating lower-
‘Subjects of legitimation’ are those social level subjects of legitimacy in order to assess
entities, structures, actions, and ideas whose legitimacy of a higher-level subject, such as
acceptability is being assessed. Alternative evaluating the legitimacy of a new venture by
terms include ‘levels’ (Ruef & Scott, 1998), the legitimacy of its products, structure, and
‘focuses’ (Suchman, 1995: 583), or ‘objects’ top management team. Such an effort may
of legitimation (Johnson, 2004). Here, we run into the problem of aggregation, such as
use ‘subjects’ for several reasons. First, this described in stakeholder research (Rowley &
term is both familiar and encompassing. Berman, 2000; Wartick, 2002). Alternatively,
Second, it reflects the idea that legitimacy researchers may decide that only a limited
is socially constructed and emerges out of selection of attributes can be valid subjects of
the subject’s relation to other rules, laws, legitimation – that is, the research community
norms, values, and cognitive frameworks might seek to specify legitimate subjects of
in a larger social system. Third, it serves legitimation. Given the real-world complexity
as a reminder that legitimacy can be quite and plasticity of legitimacy dynamics, how-
subjective at times, particularly when an ever, we do not particularly advocate this
organization is seeking to gain or defend latter, artificially exclusive strategy.
legitimacy in the face of opposition
(Ashforth & Gibbs, 1990; Suchman, 1995).
Finally, subjects aren’t necessarily passive Sources of legitimacy
but instead may be active in creating legiti-
macy (Ashforth & Gibbs, 1990; Suchman, ‘Sources of legitimacy’ are the internal and
1995); examples include the European busi- external audiences who observe organiza-
ness schools who created the legitimating tions and make legitimacy assessments (Ruef
agencies that would then accredit them & Scott, 1998: 880). Meyer and Scott (1983:
(Durand & McGuire, 2005), and the Big 201–2) focused on those ‘who have the
5 accounting firms who were actively legiti- capacity to mobilize and confront the organ-
mating the multidisciplinary practice at the ization,’ not so much in terms of power but in
same time that they were adapting it for use authority over cultural theory. They classified
(Greenwood et al., 2002). these sources into two basic groups. The first
LEGITIMACY IN ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM 55

are those who ‘have standing and license, Empirical support for this relationship has
derived from the organization’s legitimating been found in many organizational forms,
account of itself’, most commonly the State. such as newspapers, automobiles, and British
The second are those who have collective motorcycle manufacturers (Carroll &
authority over what is acceptable theory Hannan, 1989a; Hannan & Carroll, 1992;
(e.g., lawyers, accountants, intellectuals). Hannan et al., 1995; Wezel, 2005). Although
These may not be the only relevant sources, some institutionalists (e.g., Zucker, 1989;
however. In Suchman’s definition (1995: Baum & Powell, 1995) argued that density
574), legitimacy implies congruence with fails to capture the richness of the institu-
‘some socially constructed system of norms, tional environment, Carroll and Hannan
values, beliefs, and definitions,’ but, as the (1989a, b), Hannan and Carroll (1995) and
word ‘some’ suggests, the possible sources of Hannan et al. (1995) rebutted that density is
such legitimating accounts are not a parsimonious indicator of legitimacy that
inherently restricted to any fixed set of enjoys predictive validity for a remarkably
gatekeepers. Thus, a central issue for legiti- wide array of organizational populations.
macy research is identifying who has collec- Other researchers in both the institutionalist
tive authority over legitimation in any given and ecological camps responded by incorpo-
setting. The answer depends to a large extent rating additional indicators of society-wide
on the focus of the research question. For legitimacy, most notably time-period vari-
instance, when Suddaby and Greenwood ables based on institutional regime changes
(2005) examined the debate between the US or stages of the adoption cycle (e.g., Arthur,
law and accounting professions about what a 2003; Ruef & Scott, 1998). For further dis-
professional services firm should be, the cussion of these developments, see the
issue was fairly specialized and the social companion Chapter 2 by Boxenbaum and
system narrowly drawn. In contrast, an Jonsson and 24 by Haveman in this volume.
examination of the legitimacy of the global Somewhere between specific legitimacy-
energy industry after the Exxon Valdez oil granting authorities and society-at-large as a
spill would need to encompass popular source of legitimacy stand the media. As
opinion, state regulators, industry analysts, suggested by Baum and Powell (1995; see
political activists, and expert ‘epistemic com- also Dowling & Pfeffer, 1975), the media
munities’ (Adler & Haas, 1992) throughout are one institutionally rich indicator of
the world system. society-wide legitimacy, and researchers
Many researchers have finessed these dis- have been working with media data since the
tinctions by treating society-at-large as a 1990s. At the population level of analysis,
source of legitimacy, especially over long Hybels, Ryan, and Barley (1994) measured
periods of time. This approach is particularly the legitimacy of the US biotech population
common in institutional studies of diffusion by counting newspaper articles about the
(e.g., Strang & Soule, 1998; Tolbert & population in each year. Concurrently,
Zucker, 1983), which build on the linkage Deephouse (1996) used media data to
between cognitive legitimacy and mimetic measure the public legitimacy of individual
isomorphism3 to argue that the more organizations in the financial sector. Media
numerous the adopters of a practice, the reports were subsequently used to measure
more widespread its acceptance and the legitimacy by Lamertz and Baum (1998),
greater its legitimacy. Similarly, ‘density Abrahamson and Fairchild (1999), Pollock
dependence’ research in organizational and Rindova (2003), Bansal and Clelland
ecology has treated the number of organi- (2004), and Deeds et al. (2004), etc.
zations in a population as a determinant However, as Deephouse (1996) pointed out,
of the organizational form’s legitimacy evidence from journalism and mass commu-
within the external social environment. nications strongly suggests that media
56 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

reports not only reflect but also influence the the legitimacy of a voluntary social service
opinion of the general public (Fombrun & organization by whether it was listed in the
Shanley, 1990; McCombs & Shaw, 1972; community directory of Metropolitan
Schramm, 1949). Thus, the media should Toronto, registered as a bona fide charity
rightfully play a dual role in legitimacy with Revenue Canada, and endowed with a
research, serving both as an indicator of large (and therefore presumably interorgani-
legitimation by sociey-at-large and as a zationally embedded) board of directors.
source of legitimacy in their own stead. Later papers enumerated similar connections
This duality is particularly noteworthy in to government, industry leaders, and other
the case of ‘prestige media,’ such as The authorities in the institutional environment
New York Times or The Wall Street Journal, (Baum & Oliver, 1991; Baum & Oliver,
which have figured prominently in legiti- 1992; D’Aunno, Sutton, & Price, 1991).
macy studies. Empirically, prestige media Thus, charitable donations, interlocking
provide appealing indicators of society-wide directorships, and strategic alliances with
legitimacy because they are now readily prestigious partners have all been identified
available in electronic form, reducing the as important sources of legitimacy for the
often prohibitive burden of selecting and firms involved (Cohen & Dean, 2005; Deeds
coding a media sample (Carroll, 2004; et al., 2004; Galaskiewicz, 1985; Higgins
Conway, 2006). Their presence in libraries & Gulati, 2003, 2006; Miles, 1982; Oliver,
makes them amenable to historical research 2001).
(Mezias & Boyle, 2005). Theoretically, how- Three important interrelated issues emerge
ever, prestige media are particularly likely to from this review of the sources of legitimacy.
influence that which they are taken as meas- The first is a recognition that many common
uring, because they are produced by and for sources of legitimacy are themselves organi-
societal elites, aspirants to elite status, and zations. For instance, regulatory legitimacy
other participants in the cultural mainstream. results from rulemaking and enforcement
Prestige media often set the agenda for less activities within the agencies of the State.
prestigious media outlets (Boyle, 2001; Legitimacy-enhancing interorganizational
Gans, 1979), and they are routinely targeted relationships, too, arise from decisions by
by organizations and institutional entrepre- other organizations to affiliate with the
neurs seeking to build or repair legitimacy. subject entity. And media stories, whether
Further, with a few significant exceptions, legitimating or de-legitimating, do not appear
prestige media tend to be culturally conser- out of a vacuum, but instead are produced
vative, acting as a stabilizing force in society, by organizations, as Hirsch (1977) reminded
and perhaps exacerbating the disparities us thirty years ago. Thus, the granting of
between legitimate and illegitimate actors legitimacy is as amenable to organizational
(e.g., Gitlin, 1980). analysis as is the pursuit.
Beyond society-at-large and the media, a We frame the second issue as a question:
third often-mentioned source of legitimacy Are there legitimate sources of legitimacy?
derives from interorganizational relations: A This depends in part on the research question
subject becomes legitimate when it is con- and the social system(s) of interest. Consider
nected to legitimate others (Galaskiewicz, whether organized crime or official
1985). Pfeffer and Salancik (1978), for corruption is legitimate. Jepperson (1991:
example, explain how the American Institute 149) stated that some elements, such as
for Foreign Study burnished its legitimacy by fraud, bribery, organized crime, and political
obtaining endorsements from prominent corruption, can be institutionalized without
political figures. And in perhaps the first sta- being legitimate. Nonetheless, within some
tistical study of organizational legitimacy, social systems, be they networks of
Singh, Tucker, and House (1986) measured organized criminals or particular national
LEGITIMACY IN ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM 57

polities, even these ‘social pathologies’ may rejections – rather than on positive accounts,
in fact be accepted as legitimate – certainly in endorsements and adoptions (Hirsch &
the pragmatic sense of being seen as useful Andrews, 1984; Meyer & Scott, 1983). Many
and the cognitive sense of being taken- case studies, for example, examine organiza-
for-granted, and at least occasionally in the tions such as Nike and Exxon that have faced
moral sense of being ethically permitted, as legitimacy challenges. Deephouse (1996)
well. Thus, an individual might be willing to was perhaps the first to apply this approach
bribe a police officer in one nation but not in statistical research by measuring the extent
another, and an organization might be willing to which commercial banks were constrained
to bribe a regulator in one nation but not by regulators and challenged in the media.
another. The legitimacy of criminal One of his measures was the presence of a
punishment varies; for instance, many regulatory decision that explicitly limited the
jurisdictions ban capital punishment. One strategic choices of the bank in question. For
group’s terrorist is often another group’s this approach, the absence of legitimacy
freedom fighter. Given this ‘legal pluralism’ challenges is an indicator of whether the
(Merry, 1988), can researchers meaningfully organization is ‘accepted’ in the sense of
distinguish between conventionally legiti- being left to pursue its activities without
mate sources such as public authorities and interference from cultural authorities.
formal professions (the two groups listed However, the presence of questioning may
by Meyer and Scott, 1983) and unconven- sometimes be as ambiguous as the absence of
tional but often potent competitors such as endorsement, given that in some domains
criminal underworlds, ethnic enclaves, and (academic meetings and presidential press
rejectionist sects? conferences come to mind) questioning can
The third issue is the nature of the assess- be a ritualized display of attentiveness rather
ments that sources make in determining than a genuine challenge to legitimacy.
whether to grant or withhold legitimacy. We close our discussion of legitimacy
Most statistical studies focus on the pres- sources with a statement from the resource-
ence, absence or intensity of support from dependence perspective: ‘We suspect that
any given source. But while it may be fairly legitimacy need not be conferred by a large
clear that the presence of an endorsement or segment of society for the organization (or
the occurrence of an adoption implies subject) to prosper.’ (Pfeffer & Salancik,
support (Galaskiewicz, 1985; Hannan & 1978: 194). The survival of many structures,
Carroll, 1992; Tolbert & Zucker, 1983), what organizations and organizational forms
does the absence of an endorsement or an without ringing cultural endorsement
adoption indicate? In some cases, such as suggests that there may be some truth to this.
charitable registration in an organizational But in the absence of broad-based cultural
field where non-profit status matters and support, the characteristics of those particu-
registration is open to all, unregistered lar sources that do grant endorsement may
organizations would certainly appear to lack matter quite a bit.
legitimacy (Baum & Oliver, 1991; Baum &
Oliver, 1992; Singh et al., 1986). In contrast,
the absence of a board interlock with a Legitimation
prestigious firm conveys much less informa-
tion about whether the subject organization is Generalizing from Maurer (1971), Ashforth
acceptable, desirable, or culturally and Gibbs (1990), and Walker and Zelditch
supported, except perhaps from the perspec- (1993), (de-)legitimation is the process by
tive of the prestigious firm. which the legitimacy of a subject changes
Some researchers focus on negative over time. Following Van de Ven (1992), we
assessments – questions, challenges, and use the term process narrowly as the order or
58 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

sequence in which things happen. The more (1997) found that conformity to Total
general use of the term process includes a set Quality Management practices enhanced the
of explanations for explaining a variance likelihood that a hospital would earn
theory and as a category of concepts; these endorsement from the Joint Commission on
are discussed elsewhere in this and other Accreditation of Healthcare Organizations
reviews. (JCAHO), a major source of legitimacy in
Legitimation is closely related to diffusion the US healthcare sector. And Glynn and
and institutionalization, and there is Abzug (2002) found that conformity in orga-
sufficient research to specify a general nizational names increased their under-
process. For instance, Johnson et al. (2006) standibility to a wide range of business and
integrated research in social psychology and non-business audiences. Findings like these
organizational sociology to develop a reinforce Suchman’s (1995: 587) prescrip-
four-stage model of legitimation consisting tion that the best way to gain legitimacy is
of innovation, local validation, diffusion, and often simply to ‘conform to environments.’
general validation. In general, we expect the Suchman, however, also notes that
dynamics of legitimation to parallel those organizations sometimes gain legitimacy by
of institutionalization (Lawrence, Winn, & manipulating, rather than conforming to,
Jennings, 2001), but exceptions to our environments. Along these lines, a large
expectations may make interesting case number of studies have examined how texts,
studies. Moreover, there is greater need for generally construed, can be used to gain
research on the order in which different legitimacy for some subjects and challenge
sources confer legitimacy and the different the legitimacy of other subjects (Phillips,
dimensions of legitimacy are conferred. Lawrence, & Hardy, 2004). In an early study
A notable example of this is by Greenwood of organizational impression management,
et al. (2002). They offered a six-stage model for example, Elsbach (1994) found that
of institutional change in highly profession- accounts that acknowledge failings or make
alized fields. They proposed that moral and reference to the institutional environment are
pragmatic legitimacy was theorized in stages superior to accounts that deny responsibility
four and five and cognitive legitimacy or make reference to the technical
occurred in stage six. environment. More recently, Suddaby and
Greenwood (2005) examined the discursive
struggle between proponents and opponents
Antecedents of legitimacy of multidisciplinary partnerships in profes-
sional services, and Vaara, Tienari, and
Meyer and Rowan (1977) suggest that both Laurila (2006) identified five ‘discursive
technical efficiency and conformity to insti- legitimation’ strategies, which they labeled
tutional myths can be precursors of legiti- normalization, authorization, rationalization,
macy.4 Deephouse (1996) was perhaps the moralization, and narrativization.
first to test these relationships directly. He
found that conformity and efficiency
increased banks’ legitimacy in the eyes of Consequences of legitimacy
regulators, consistent with the regulators’
interest in the stability of the banking system; The consequences of legitimacy have
in contrast, he found that only conformity also received considerable attention. At least
had a positive effect on legitimacy in the eyes since Meyer and Rowan (1977: 353), institu-
of the media, assumed to be both a leader and tionalists have argued that legitimacy
a recorder of the public’s norms and values enhances organizational survival. Supportive
(Dowling & Pfeffer, 1975; Fombrun evidence abounds: Legitimacy measured
& Shanley, 1990). Similarly, Westphal et al. by endorsements and interorganizational
LEGITIMACY IN ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM 59

relationships increased survival rates among legitimacy studies. Legitimacy continues to


Toronto non-profits (Baum & Oliver, 1991, appear most frequently in theoretical analy-
1992; Singh et al., 1986), and both manage- ses; however, the number of descriptive case
rial and technical legitimacy reduced exit studies has increased substantially, and efforts
rates for US hospitals (Ruef & Scott, 1998). at confirmatory hypothesis testing (although
Organizational ecology, too, has lent support still relatively rare) seem to be on the rise.
to this claim, finding that legitimacy (meas-
ured by the density of firms in an industry)
increases survival rates across a wide range
of organizational populations (Hannan & LEGITIMACY AND OTHER SOCIAL
Carroll, 1992). EVALUATIONS
Other, more proximate consequences have
been examined as well. The strategic view of These developments have brought legitimacy
legitimacy sees it as something that can be research into overlap with a variety of other
manipulated to achieve organizational goals ways of describing the social evaluation of
(Suchman, 1995), and researchers have long organizations. In recent years, the most
posited that ‘[l]egitimacy affects the compe- prominent of these kindred concepts have
tition for resources,’ (Pfeffer & Salancik, been ‘status’ (e.g., Podolny, 1993; Phillips &
1978: 201; see also Parsons, 1960). More Zuckerman, 2001) and ‘reputation’ (Fombrun
recently, as an interest in legitimacy has & Shanley, 1990; Fombrun, 1996). Although
spread into the strategic management litera- a full synthesis of these largely independent
ture, researchers have developed and tested literatures would go well beyond the scope of
hypotheses predicting how various types of the present chapter, one might productively
legitimacy would affect other performance ponder to what extent and in what ways legit-
measures, such as the value of initial public imacy, status, and reputation are either equiv-
offerings (IPOs) (Cohen & Dean, 2005; alent or distinct. In this section, we briefly
Deeds et al., 2004; Higgins & Gulati, 2006; compare and contrast what we see as the key
Pollock & Rindova, 2003), stock prices connotations of each term.
(Zuckerman, 2000), stock market risk
(Bansal & Clelland, 2004), and stakeholder
support (Choi & Shepherd, 2005).
Definitions and distinctions
The definitions of status and reputation are at
Summary least as diverse, ambiguous, and contested as
the definition of legitimacy. We will explore
As the preceding discussion demonstrates, some of the sources of this ambiguity and
research on legitimacy has expanded in many contestation below, but as provisional work-
directions over the past three decades. Initial ing definitions, we offer the following,
concern with the effect of legitimacy on sur- adapted from the literature:
vival has expanded to include effects on other
types of organizational success. Legitimacy – Status is ‘a socially constructed, intersubjectively
has been dimensionalized into as many as agreed-upon and accepted ordering or ranking’
of social actors (Washington & Zajac, 2005: 284),
twelve types, and the recognized sources of
based on the esteem or deference that each actor
legitimacy have been extended well beyond can claim by virtue of the actor’s membership in
the two enumerated by Meyer and Scott a group or groups with distinctive practices,
(1983) – those with standing and license and values, traits, capacities or inherent worth (cf.,
those with authority over what constitutes Benjamin & Podolny, 1999; Weber, 1946).5
acceptable theory. These developments have – Reputation is a generalized expectation about a
created opportunities for a wide variety of firm’s future behavior or performance based on
60 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

collective perceptions (either direct or, more by obeying norms instrumentally as long as
often, vicarious) of past behavior or performance the benefits of doing so exceed the costs; and
(cf., Ferguson, Deephouse, & Ferguson, 2000; by cynically displaying the outward indicia
Fombrun, 1996; Rindova et al., 2005).6 of conformity, while making as few substan-
To illustrate the potential for overlap among tive accommodations as possible. Thus, all
legitimacy, status, and reputation, consider three literatures also, at least implicitly,
the following two examples from recent engage two central questions: (a) how
empirical research: Higgins and Gulati successful can cynical displays of conformity
(2003) report that the prior job histories of a be, absent internalization?7 and (b) to what
firm’s upper echelon employees, such as extent does surface conformity lead over
affiliations with certain prominent industries time to internalization, despite initial
like pharmaceuticals, increase the likelihood cynicism? Fundamentally, to what extent can
that the firm can garner endorsements from legitimacy, status, or reputation, be feigned
leading investment banks; Deeds et al. without either being internalized by organi-
(2004) similarly report that US high tech zational participants or being discovered by
firms with founders or managers from top ten curious outsiders, such as competitors, the
research universities and Master of Business media, or the state?
Administration (MBA) programs receive The similarities between these literatures
higher IPO valuations. In both studies, the arise because legitimacy, status, and reputa-
employee-background variables are charac- tion share many antecedents, consequences,
terized as measures of legitimacy – a plausi- measures, and processes. Indeed, one could
ble claim, given that past affiliations could no doubt find instances in the prior literature
indicate managerial competence and hence where different authors use different mixes
pragmatic legitimacy, managerial propriety of the three terms for essentially the same
and hence moral legitimacy, or managerial empirical referents. Given this, any progress
conventionality and hence cognitive legiti- toward precision and parsimony will
macy. But prominence and prestige are also inevitably come at the cost of contradicting
often associated with status; and a track at least some prior usages; we doubt that
record of experience, training and visibility anyone could prune this conceptual thicket
might easily foster reputation. Is the choice while leaving every branch fully intact.
among these labels merely stylistic, or do Nonetheless, we believe that researchers
their implications differ? throughout these intertwined literatures
Certainly, the literatures on legitimacy, would benefit from clarifying and, where
status, and reputation have many traits in possible, disentangling the three focal
common. They all focus on cultural factors in concepts. Juxtaposing legitimacy, status, and
organizational life. They all suggest that reputation reveals important connotations of
organizations can garner resources by each that would remain largely invisible if
conforming to prevailing social norms. And the three were considered only in isolation.8
they all emphasize that ‘objective’ perform- Goring our own oxen first, we can begin
ance criteria are not always salient or even by suggesting that legitimacy, in contrast
evident, and that organizational behaviours to status and reputation, is fundamen-
may be social signals as well as technical tally dichotomous. Despite some usages to
operations. Thus, all three literatures depict the contrary (see below), legitimation is
social perceptions of conformity as being largely a question of ‘satisficing’ to
central determinants of organizational an acceptable level, and the absence of
success. Moreover, all three recognize that negative ‘problems’ is more important
organizations can create such ‘social percep- than the presence of positive achievements.
tions of conformity’ in at least three different Legitimacy is also fundamentally non-rival:
ways: by embracing and internalizing norms; it is rarely a zero-sum game within any given
LEGITIMACY IN ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM 61

population; indeed, positive feedback loops ostracism, and individuals move between
and a ‘logic of confidence’ (Meyer & groups primarily through sponsorship, not
Rowan, 1977) tend to produce win-win competitive performance. From this, it
ceremonies of mutual affirmation among follows that, whereas legitimacy is
legitimate actors. Further, legitimacy is fundamentally homogenizing, status is fun-
fundamentally homogenizing, producing damentally segregating: Lower-status groups
herd-like conformity along whichever tend to imitate higher-status groups as a way
dimensions the prevailing rational myths of earning group honour; however, higher-
establish as legitimacy-defining. Further, status groups tend to jettison status markers
precisely because legitimacy is non-rival as soon as those markers become contami-
and homogenizing, it paints with a broad nated by imitation. Significantly, because
brush and tends to attach to all entities that status is group-rival and segregating, it tends
share a given form. Although firms, struc- to attach to self-aware cliques or ‘status
tures and even individuals can achieve groups,’ rather than to individual social
legitimacy on their own, the more common actors or entire populations. Entry into these
pattern is for each instance to be legitimated cliques is usually based on a mixture of
by conformity with a collectively legitimated ascription and achievement (or, one might
template.9 Finally, legitimacy is fundamen- say, legitimacy and reputation), but entry is
tally political. Because it is linked to more a matter of favor than dessert –
authority, legitimacy generally produces a objective performance and legitimacy in the
taken-for-granted right to act and command eyes of outsiders matter far less than accept-
within a particular sphere of activity. This ance by the status group itself. Finally, status
political aspect is embedded within the is fundamentally honorific; it reflects cultural
etymological roots of legitimacy in the Latin capital and habitus (Bourdieu, 1986), and it
lex or legis, meaning law. It is also consistent elicits deference and tribute: ‘Status gener-
with the central place of the state – as both ates social esteem and special, unearned (i.e.,
licensor and enforcer – in much legitimacy non-merit-based) benefits known as privi-
research. Indeed, state certification is leges, which are granted to and enjoyed by
arguably the core archetype of legitimation, high-status actors in a social system’
to which most other legitimation mecha- (Washington & Zajac, 2005: 284). Status
nisms are linked by either implication or also implies an ability to valorize (or contam-
analogy. inate) by association – as illustrated by
Status reflects the relative position of admission into an elite club, or rejection by
social groups within a hierarchy of collective the ‘in’ crowd.
honour (cf., Weber, 1946). Consequently, in More so than either legitimacy or status,
contrast to legitimacy, status is fundamen- reputation involves an explicit extrapolation
tally ordinal and categorical, varying less from past to future behavior. Thus, strictly
within groups than across groups. This speaking, reputations can be as multidimen-
allows empirical distinctions between, sional and idiosyncratic as the behaviors
for example, the upper-, middle-, and lower- that they summarize.10 Certainly, reputation
status tiers in an industry (Podolny, 1993; can extend beyond product and ser-
Deephouse & Carter, 2005; Phillips & vice quality (the focus of most economic
Zuckerman, 2001). Further, whereas legiti- discussions of reputation), to include being a
macy is fundamentally non-rival, status is tough competitor, a good place to work, an
fundamentally ‘group-rival.’ That is, status is environmentally sensitive manufacturer, etc.
positive sum within status groups, but (e.g., Shapiro, 1983; Weigelt & Camerer,
negative sum across groups. Groups compete 1988; Benjamin & Podolny, 1999; Carter &
for status through solidarity displays, Deephouse, 1999; Washington & Zajac, 2005;
collective mobility projects, and out-group Rindova, Pollock, & Hayward, 2006).
62 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Nonetheless, in contrast to both legitimacy fundamentally dichotomous, legitimacy can


and status, reputation is fundamentally a con- appear continuous (or at least ordinal) by
tinuous measure, placing each actor on a virtue of what might be termed ‘pointalism’:
continuum from best to worst – or, more Because legitimacy is always assessed by
often, on many such continua. As a ranking multiple audiences and with respect to
of actors, reputation is fundamentally rival: multiple activities, an organization can
On any given continuum, reputation is con- become ‘more legitimate’ by becoming legit-
tingent on relative standing, and hence a imate to more audiences in more of its activ-
firm’s position can usually only increase ities. Second, legitimacy can vary in its
at the expense of competitors. Reputation certainty and security. Thus, a firm can
is also fundamentally differentiating: become ‘more legitimate’ by becoming more
Reputation dynamics encourage organiza- clearly legitimate, more firmly legitimate, or
tions to distinguish themselves from their both.
peers either substantively or by advancing Another source of confusion involves the
claims to uniqueness, often despite assertion that legitimacy is fundamentally a
minimal outward differences. Because property of forms or populations, rather than
reputation is rival and differentiating, it tends of self-defined groups (à la status) or individ-
to attach to individual actors, ranking each ual firms ( à la reputation). A casual perusal
firm even when the distinctions involved are of the empirical literature would turn up
substantively trivial.11 Finally, if legitimacy many instances when this assertion seems
is political and status is honorific, reputation not to hold, and when legitimacy, instead,
is fundamentally economic: In effect, reputa- appears quite similar to group-level status or
tion becomes an input into potential firm-level reputation. Upon closer inspec-
exchange partners’ expected utility functions. tion, however, most of these counter-exam-
Given that boundedly rational actors can ples prove to be special cases, such as when
never know the actual outcomes of transac- a form has only one real-world instantiation
tions in advance, would-be exchange (e.g., the United Nations) or when a group
partners must turn to reputation in order to erects such high status barriers that it
map one another’s past performances onto becomes virtually a population unto itself,
present preferences. This means that favor- incommensurable with other organizations in
able reputation is often a strategic resource its domain (e.g., the ‘Big 8, 6, 5, or 4’
that firms can exploit for competitive advan- accounting firms). Moreover, even in these
tage (cf., Barney, 1991; Deephouse, 2000; special cases, legitimacy’s underlying conno-
Roberts & Dowling, 2002). tation of being a population-level property
seeps through: One hallmark of legitimacy is
the (mythological) assumption that legitima-
Confusions and conflations tion arises from alignment with universal
principles, rather than from the idiosyncratic,
Despite these differences in connotation, the culturally-specific maneuverings of a partic-
prior literature frequently confuses and ular firm or group of firms; hence, in claim-
conflates legitimacy with both status and rep- ing legitimacy, unique entities tend to present
utation.12 One common source of difficulty is themselves as exemplars of an abstract form,
reflected in the recurrence of phrases like even if they are the only exemplar in
‘more (or less) legitimate’: In the past, existence. (An attack on the UN becomes an
researchers have often treated legitimacy as a attack on world government; an appeal for
continuous variable, obscuring an important the international space station becomes a
distinction between legitimacy and both tribute to the human spirit of exploration.)
status and reputation. The sources of this A third cause of confusion is the fact that
usage are two-fold: First, despite being observers (both academics and practitioners)
LEGITIMACY IN ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM 63

often rely on overlapping information inputs frequently identified a favorable reputation


to assess legitimacy, reputation, and status. as a resource that can yield significant com-
Sometimes these inputs are simply too petitive advantages (e.g., Barney, 1991;
generic and multivocal to be characterized as Deephouse, 2000; Roberts & Dowling,
indicators of one form of social evaluation 2002).
versus another. This, for example, is clearly The situation becomes more complicated,
true of charitable donations and directorship however, when one reverses the causal arrow,
interlocks, two of the most common legiti- to make success an independent rather than a
macy/status/reputation measures in organiza- dependent variable. Reputation, legitimacy
tion studies (Davis & Greve, 1997; Fombrun, and status can each be bolstered by success-
1996; Galaskiewicz, 1985). But even when ful performance – but in decidedly different
well-established ‘reputational intermedi- ways. Success enhances reputation directly,
aries’ purport to be distilling objective data by demonstrating an ability to perform.
about past performance (as is the case, for Indeed, the link between past performance
example, in the US News and World Report and future potential is arguably reputation’s
rankings of educational programs), confla- defining element. Success enhances
tion remains almost inevitable (cf., Sauder legitimacy, too, but mostly indirectly:
& Lancaster, 2006). Evaluators, like all Success often signals cultural acceptance and
social actors, have cognitive limitations an ability to deliver on commitments, both
(Simon, 1976), and as a result, unique, of which affect whether an organization
infinitely multidimensional reputations get can sustain a self-confirming ‘logic of
reduced, in practice, to a small number of confidence’ (Meyer & Rowan, 1977). But
socially constructed ranking criteria. And success, in itself, is not enough. Legitimacy
significantly, both the choice of criteria and rarely attaches to organizational forms, such
the methods of measurement are heavily as criminal gangs or ‘pirate’ radio stations,
shaped by the same institutional logics and that ‘succeed’ in culturally inappropriate
honor-markers that determine legitimacy and endeavors or by taking short-cuts around
status. culturally prescribed practices. Finally,
A fourth reason for confusion is that legit- while success may enhance status as well, it
imacy, reputation, and status are all related to does so only obliquely at best. Success may
success. As discussed above, each of these provide currency (literal or figurative) for
favorable social evaluations can enhance per- procuring the indicia of status-group mem-
formance: Legitimacy can be crucial to gar- bership; but status groups tend to be resistant
nering resources from external audiences, to to the success of arrivistes, interposing new
commanding the loyalty of internal partici- bases of distinction (i.e., ‘moving the bar’)
pants, and (in its cognitive forms) to avoiding in order to maintain group boundaries
misunderstandings and miscues among (Weber, 1946). Given these different
external and internal constituencies alike. mechanisms, the relative impact of success
Copious evidence also links status to success. on reputation, legitimacy, and status may
For instance, Benjamin and Podolny (1999) vary. For instance, Deephouse and Carter
found that the status of a winery led to higher (2005: 355) showed that financial perform-
prices, even after controlling for the winery’s ance had a stronger effect on reputation than
product quality. it did on legitimacy.
And the impact of reputation on subse- Figure 1.1 depicts our nested conceptual-
quent outcomes has been well-known, at ization of legitimacy, reputation, and status,
least since Merton (1968) famously identified and their relationships to resource flows.
the ‘Matthew Effect’ in the sociology of Stakeholders (on the left) exchange resources
science.13 In organizational studies, research with organizations in a focal industry,
on the resource-based view of the firm has population, or sector (on the right); the lines
64 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Stakeholders Resource flows Organizations

R1,H,L, R2,H,L... High status

R1,M,L, R2,M,L... Middle status Legitimate


organizations

R1,L,L, R2,L,L... Low status

R1,H,I, R2,H,I... High status

Illegitimate
R1,M,I, R2,M,I... Middle status organizations

R1,L,I, R2,L,I... Low status

Ri,S,L denotes reputation of organization i in status group S in legitimacy class L

Figure 1.1 The effects of legitimacy, reputation, and status on resource flows between
stakeholders and organizations

represent bi-directional resource flows of words, no matter what the components of the
inducements and contributions, such as marketing mix illegitimate organizations
employee effort and compensation (Barnard, offer, a substantial group of stakeholders will
1938: 94; March & Simon, 1958: 84).14 For not transact with them. Thus, as many
illustrative purposes, we can group stake- authors have suggested in the past, legiti-
holders dichotomously, although stakeholder macy affects market access: ‘An organization
research offers ample evidence of more fine- which can convince relevant publics that its
grained differentiation (Clarkson, 1995; competitors are not legitimate can eliminate
Mitchell, Agle, & Wood, 1997). Consistent some competition’ (Pfeffer & Salancik,
with our discussion above, organizations in 1978: 194; see also Brown, 1994, 1998;
the figure are grouped into two legitimacy Deephouse & Carter, 2005). A few examples
classes (legitimate and illegitimate), and may be enlightening: One is gambling,
within each class organizations are clustered divided into state-sanctioned and other
by status (high, medium, and low). In addi- forms. Many customers who would happily
tion, each organization possesses a unique buy a state lottery ticket would never con-
reputation, subscripted by the organization’s sider placing wagers with a bookie, even at
rank within its legitimacy and status cohort. substantially more favorable odds. Another
The essence of the figure is that certain example is petroleum marketing. Certain
stakeholders will exchange resources only stakeholders who are concerned about the
with legitimate organizations and will not environment may refuse to patronize Exxon
engage in transactions with others. In other and Shell in reaction to the Exxon Valdez and
LEGITIMACY IN ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM 65

Brent Spar incidents, although some of those (Home winemakers who sell their product
same stakeholders may have forgotten less outside of state-licensed facilities might
de-legitimating accidents caused by other exemplify an illegitimate group, with limited
producers. A third example comes from the market access regardless of either reputation
British Columbia forestry industry, where the or status.) In general, within a legitimacy
province recently decided to grant timber class and status group, stakeholders will
access only to contractors who could demon- favor those organizations with the strongest
strate acceptable safety standards, not only in reputations. The literature suggests at least
their own operations but also in the opera- two noteworthy caveats, however: First,
tions of their sub-contractors. In announcing some stakeholders may have idiosyncratic
the new policy, the provincial Forests preferences, leading them to weight certain
Minister nicely captured the importance aspects of reputation differently from the
of legitimacy for market access: ‘no one is norm among stakeholders as a whole; this
going to get one of those tenders unless they allows organizations to adopt niche strategies
have safety procedures applied through their that cater to specific subsets of the stake-
operation … they are a safe company holder pool. Second, stakeholders will often
and they meet our standards.’ (Kennedy, give more credence to (or be more cognizant
2006: S3). of) reputational hierarchies within ‘core’
As Figure 1.1 suggests, each legitimacy versus ‘peripheral’groups; this suggests that
class may contain several status groups. For the impact of reputation may be moderated
visual simplicity, we depict a simple ‘low,’ by legitimacy and status, such that legiti-
‘medium,’ and ‘high’ division. This tri- mate, high-status actors will enjoy the great-
chotomy is fairly common in the recent est returns on their past achievements (cf.,
status literature, and for some industries, Phillips & Zuckerman, 2007; Beck, Horan, &
such as automobile manufacturing, these Tolbert, 1978).
three broad status groups may suffice. In As the preceding paragraphs suggest, the
other industries, however, status distinctions interrelationships among legitimacy, status,
are likely to be much more fine-grained; for and reputation offer numerous research
instance, Benjamin and Podolny (1999: 574) opportunities. One empirical approach would
identified 41 distinct status groups among be to cross-classify legitimacy classes
California wineries. Although not illustrated (e.g., Yes/No), status groups (e.g., High/
in the figure, stakeholders may also be Middle/Low) and reputational ranks (e.g.,
divided into status groups. When this is the High/Low), and then examine the size, char-
case, and when organizations and stakehold- acteristics, and consequences of each of the
ers recognize one another’s status hierar- resulting 12 categories. Past research has
chies, entities in each population may seek to adopted essentially this approach: For
avoid contamination by limiting their contact instance, studies of top business schools
with lower status entities in the other. suggest that this sector possesses relatively
This dynamic tends to reproduce the status clear status groupings (at least at the high
hierarchies on both sides of the exchange. end), many rankings systems, and a few
Within any given status group, each organ- legitimating agencies (Corley & Gioia, 2000;
ization has a reputation based on many Durand & McGuire, 2005; Elsbach &
dimensions, such as product quality, work- Kramer, 1996; Gioia & Thomas, 1996;
place practices, community involvement, etc. McKee, Mills, & Weatherbee, 2005; Wedlin,
(Fombrun, 1996). In the case of winemaking, 2006). Looking at the California wine indus-
such components might include a reputation try, Benjamin and Podolny (1999) attempt to
for producing award-winning wine, for being differentiate the effect of product quality and
a good place to work, for having great winery status affiliations on success. And looking at
tours, or for donating generously to charities. architectural services, Jones and Manev
66 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

(2002) explore how legitimacy and status reputations are often taken into consideration
affect reputation. (at least formalistically) when legitimacy
At a theoretical level, much work remains sources make endorsement and affiliation
to be done on how the processes of legitima- decisions. Finally, as mentioned previously,
tion, reputation-building, and status-seeking status affects reputation by increasing the
intersect and overlap (Rao, 1994; Vidaver- returns to past achievements; and reputation
Cohen, 2006). Figure 1.2 suggests a few of affects status both by determining an actor’s
the most plausible interconnections: At their standing within a particular status group and
cores, legitimacy, status, and reputation stem by conditioning the likelihood of sponsored
from fundamentally different sources, with mobility from one status group to another.
legitimacy reflecting conformity to various At the risk of oversimplification, much of
social guidelines, while status reflects ascrip- this discussion might be encapsulated in the
tion and group mobility, and reputation following equation:
reflects achievement and self-presentation.
Prestige = Legitimacy + Legitimacy *
However, the three also influence one
(Status + Reputation + [Status * Reputation])
another. Legitimacy affects status because a
commitment to avoid illegitimate activities ‘Prestige,’ here, denotes an organization’s
may be a criterion for status-group member- capacity to achieve objectives by virtue of
ship; and status affects legitimacy because enjoying a favorable social evaluation.
membership in a high-status group may Without legitimacy, prestige will be low,
create presumptions of proprietary that cush- regardless of the organization’s status or rep-
ion the impact of minor rule violations – utation. However, legitimacy alone is rarely
while at the same time increasing the penalty enough to achieve much beyond the most
for breaches that are so egregious as to mundane tasks. Rather, legitimacy empowers
threaten the honor of the group as a whole. the organization to enunciate claims based on
Legitimacy affects reputation because both status and reputation – and status
legitimate actors are often both more visible and reputation further augment one another
and more credible in their self-presentations; through the visibility, credibility, and mobil-
and reputation affects legitimacy because ity effects described above.

Conformity to
social guidelines

Legitimacy

Presumption of Visibility and


propriety credibility
Criterion for Evaluation by
status-group legitimation
membership sources

Standing and
mobility
Status Reputation
Increased returns
Ascription and to performance Achievement and
group mobility self-presentation

Figure 1.2 The interrelation of legitimacy, reputation, and status


LEGITIMACY IN ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM 67

Before closing, we should perhaps note and Kotha (2007) demonstrated that
that legitimacy, status and reputation are Amazon.com became the exemplar of e-
hardly the only social evaluations to appear commerce in the 1990s; and Bowen (2004)
in recent organizational literature. Others highlighted a US pharmaceutical firm as an
include accreditation, certification, credibil- exemplar of ethical decision making.
ity, and accountability, as well as the related Somewhat similarly, celebrities are entities
concepts of the ‘exemplar’ and the ‘that attract a high level of public attention
‘celebrity.’ To a large extent, these terms and generate positive emotional responses
simply re-district and re-label the terrain that from stakeholder audiences’ (Rindova et al.,
we have explored above. For instance, busi- 2006: 51; Hayward, Rindova, & Pollock,
ness school accreditation associations have 2004). Celebrities (and possibly exemplars)
been described as legitimating agencies benefit disproportionately from their posi-
(Durand & McGuire, 2005), and accountabil- tion, based on the economics of superstars
ity and credibility are linked to trust, a central (Rosen, 1981). These benefits could be com-
component of both legitimacy and reputa- pared to the privileges of high-status actors,
tion. Certification, too, could be incorporated discussed above (Washington & Zajac,
into models of either legitimacy, status, or 2005).
reputation (cf., Schnatterly, Ward, & Lee,
2006). Some of the most well-known certifi-
cations are those of the International
Standards Organization (e.g., ISO 9000 and INTEGRATIVE DISCUSSION
ISO 14000), which – consistent with our
view of legitimacy – are open to any com- We conclude by presenting several integra-
pany that meets a set of predetermined crite- tive recommendations. The first is to recog-
ria (Beck & Walgenbach, 2005; Boiral, 2003; nize that legitimacy and its dimensions are
cf., Guler, Guillen, & MacPherson, 2002; analytic concepts, not fully separable empir-
ISO 9000 News, 1996).15 This type of ical phenomena. The second is to further
dichotomous, non-rival certification can be investigate the workings of various sources
distinguished from a ‘certification contest,’ of legitimacy and the workings of legitimacy
defined as ‘a competition in which actors in at multiple levels of analysis. The third is to
a given domain are ranked on the basis of embrace diverse perspectives, improving our
performance criteria that key stakeholders understanding of organizational legitimacy
accept as credible and legitimate’ (Rao, by drawing on the work of other disciplines
1994; Wade, Porac, Pollock, & Graffin, such as law, mass communications, and
2006: 644). ‘Certification contests legitimate political science.
organizations, generate status orderings, and As a starting point, we urge legitimacy
create favorable reputations’ (Rao, 1994: 29; researchers not to become fixated on defend-
Wade et al., 2006); however, whether they ing the purity and independence of the differ-
accomplish each of these tasks better or ent dimensions of legitimacy. As suggested
worse than other evaluation mechanisms above, the assertion that a legitimate organi-
largely remains to be determined. zation must offer an ‘acceptable theory’ of
Finally, exemplars and celebrities are itself (Meyer & Scott, 1983: 202) is broad
migrating into organizational studies. An enough to encompass a variety of such legiti-
exemplar is a singular subject that sets the mating accounts – from claims about cause
standard for a certain social act, form, and effect (pragmatic legitimacy), to invoca-
or actor. For instance, Greenwood and tions of collectively valued ends (moral legit-
Empson (2003) proposed that profes- imacy), to constitutive suppositions about
sional partnerships may be an exemplary definitions and meanings (cognitive legiti-
governance mechanism; Rindova Petkova, macy) (Greenwood et al., 2002; Meyer &
68 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Scott, 1983; Stryker, 1994; Suchman, 1995). for the legitimation of certain subjects and
Early in the development of organizational the de-legitimation of others (Elsbach &
institutionalism, Meyer and Scott (1983: Sutton, 1992; Rao, Morrill, & Zald, 2000;
214) observed that ‘the literature on legiti- Strang & Soule, 1998). These efforts and
macy tends to distinguish sharply between its counter-efforts are often adjudicated (albeit
cognitive and normative aspects. This may not always fully resolved) by courts and
overemphasize Western dualism.’ More other public authorities as a corollary of the
recently, Scott (1995: 143–4) has written that state’s ostensible monopoly of legitimate
‘distinctions … among [the three pillars of force (Edelman & Suchman, 1997; Suddaby
institutions] are analytical in the sense that & Greenwood, 2005).
concrete institutional arrangements will be Overall, then, we see a growing role for
found to combine regulative, normative, and research on institutional politics, which
cognitive processes together in varying Stryker (2000: 190) defined as the ‘strategic
amounts.’As applied to legitimacy, any act of mobilization and counter-mobilization of
legitimation may operate on a variety of diverse institutional logics.’ Without
dimensions. For instance, regulatory prejudging the findings of such research, the
approval of a new pharmaceutical not only literature to date suggests a central position
confers regulatory legitimacy but also (a) for rhetorical, discursive, and technical strug-
enhances the ‘cognitive’ comprehensibility gles over what is legitimate and who is
and taken-for-grantedness of the new com- authorized to theorize and certify (e.g.,
pound, (b) indicates that the entity is consis- Hensmans, 2003; Lounsbury, 2007; Phillips
tent with the ‘moral’ value of good health, et al., 2004; Suddaby & Greenwood, 2005;
and (c) confirms the entity’s demonstrable Vaara et al., 2006). Future research might
‘pragmatic’ benefits. Similarly, Rao (1994) also consider the evolution and ecology
reasoned that certification contests in the of entire populations of legitimacy sources.
early days of automaking provided both nor- Given that concepts from legitimacy research
mative justification and cognitive validation have been used to study the births and
for the young industry – as well as pragmatic deaths of organizations, future research
promotion for those fortunate firms that could examine the births and deaths of legit-
could demonstrate superior capabilities. imating agencies or rule systems (Jennings,
Instead of further reifying analytic distinc- Schulz, Patient, Gravel, & Yuan, 2005).
tions among the various dimensions of legit- Along these lines, Durand and McGuire
imacy, researchers might do well to attend (2005), McKee, Mills, and Weatherbee
more closely to the workings of various (2005), and Wedlin (2006) examined the cre-
sources of legitimacy.16 The sources and sub- ation and expansion of business school
jects of legitimacy are embedded in complex accreditation agencies, and one could imag-
networks of social influence and communi- ine a similar approach to studying the prolif-
cation (Carter & Deephouse, 1999; eration of business-school reputation
Granovetter, 1985; Rowley, 1997): Subjects rankings. In this way, one might arrive at a
seek endorsement from various sources and ‘community ecology’ of legitimacy, in which
are pleased when they receive it, but certain the legitimacy, competition, and population
sources may have a larger impact than others. density of subjects and sources – as well as
For instance, regulatory approval of a new of advocates and activists – might interact
pharmaceutical usually means more than and coevolve.
publication of a non-refereed research study We also believe that future research should
funded by the drug’s developer. Meanwhile, examine legitimation at multiple levels –
subjects may not be the only entities seeking within organizations, among organizations,
to affect a given source’s deliberations: and within organizational fields – and that these
Social movements often actively advocate investigations should include the interactions
LEGITIMACY IN ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM 69

among the levels.17 For example, Holm lacks an overarching theory of legitimation
(1995) presented a ‘nested systems’ view, to to guide inquiry.’ Since that time, researchers
examine how various sources contributed have made progress in developing not a
to the legitimation and de-legitimation of single overarching theory, but multiple theo-
mandated sales organization in Norwegian ries matched to particular dimensions and
fisheries. More recently, Rubtsova and Dowd sources of legitimation. Increasingly these
(2004) examined cultural capital at the theories have drawn on other disciplines, a
macro-, meso-, and micro-levels, Sine, David, trend which we believe will and should
and Mitsuhashi (2007) examined the effects continue. For instance, Stryker (1994),
of firm and sector legitimacy on new Suchman and Edelman (1996), Edelman and
ventures, and Crumley, Lounsbury, and Suchman (1997) and Edelman, Fuller, &
Greenwood (2006) examined how social MaraDrita (2001) have extended arguments
actors attempted to legitimate and delegiti- from the ‘law and society’ tradition to
mate the role of acupuncture within the insti- explore the impact of institutional ambiguity
tutionalized western healthcare system. Such and contestation. Analogously, Carter and
cross-level studies are still in their infancy; Deephouse (1999), Deephouse (1996),
however, eventually research on how individ- Deephouse & Carter (2005), Kennedy
uals within groups within organizations grap- (2005), and others have adapted mass com-
ple with particular subjects of legitimation, munication theory to explore the role of the
such as equal employment opportunity guide- media and public opinion. In the future, bor-
lines (Edelman, 1992), may yield useful rowings from political science and public
insights into the legitimation of authority administration may similarly enrich the
systems in general, a central topic in social legitimacy literature’s depiction of regulators
psychology (Berger, Cohen, & Zelditch, and other public sector legitimation sources.
1972; Johnson et al., 2006). Equally important, though, will be exchanges
As researchers begin to explore the work- with other branches of organization theory
ings of various sources of legitimacy, impor- itself. After all, many sources of legitimation
tant differences in kind are likely to emerge. To are organizations in their own right (Hirsch,
facilitate productive dialog, we propose the 1977; Scott, 1987), and their actions need to
following tentative distinctions: Legitimacy be understood in organizational terms.
agents are those organizations, such as accred- The development of an overarching theory
itors and regulators, specifically established to of legitimation remains unfinished business.
confer legitimacy on a certain set of subjects More than a decade after Suchman’s 1995
(Durand & McGuire, 2005). Legitimacy medi- review, we still find that ‘most treatments
ators are other social actors, such as the media, cover only a limited aspect’ (1995: 571) of
who make or convey implicit or explicit legiti- this complex but crucial subject. A more
macy assessments as a side-effect of their rou- adequate formulation would contain careful,
tine operations. And legitimacy guidelines are widely-accepted definitions, would examine
abstract legitimacy-relevant constructs embed- more aspects of the concept, and would incor-
ded in society at large, such as language, porate both strategic and institutional views.
values, norms, social rules, etc. We use the One practical challenge on the road to this
term ‘guidelines’ to highlight the fact that these destination arises from the norms of the
constructs may be in flux, may vary according business school world, in which many legiti-
to local conditions, and may not be enforced as macy researchers now work. Rewards there
strictly, as consistently, or as formally as might increasingly favor journal publications
be implied by the more commonly used phrase over longer works, arguably impeding the
‘social rules.’ construction of comprehensive explanations
In an early review, Galaskiewicz (1985: for phenomena that are too complex to be
298) stated ‘this literature [on legitimacy] explicated in the space of 30–40 pages.
70 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Nonetheless, recent years have seen the efficiency and institutional conformity as two largely
arrival of several exemplary books, such as distinct attributes.
5 Here, we focus on organizational status. Thus,
Scott et al.’s (2000) examination of healthcare
the ‘ranked social actors’ in question are organiza-
organizations and Wedlin’s (2006) examina- tions, and the ‘groups’ are, for example, the upper,
tion of European business schools. And other middle and lower tiers of an industry or the federal,
research programs have yielded impressively state, and local levels of a government.
cumulative sequences of journal articles, such 6 This definition is consistent with reputation’s
etymological roots in Latin as re-putare, ‘to think
as the work on professional service firms con-
back upon.’ In managerial and economic usages,
ducted by scholars at the University of however, this ‘thinking backward’ is often associated
Alberta (e.g., Suddaby & Greenwood, 2005; with ‘acting forward.’ For instance, if a company has
Greenwood et al., 2002; Hinings, Brown, & a reputation for product quality, then customers are
Greenwood, 1991). These efforts represent more likely to pay extra for its products; if a company
has a reputation for being a bad place to work, then
a solid start, but whether they will lead to a
recruits will avoid it and employees will seek new jobs
more comprehensive and holistic understand- elsewhere (Fombrun, 1996; Weigelt & Camerer,
ing remains to be seen. Hinings (2006) has 1988).
advocated the pursuit of ambitious, large- 7 For obvious reasons, questions like this link all
scale research programs to reach new heights three literature to a fourth literature (not reviewed
here) on organization impression management (e.g.
in our understanding of complex organiza-
Elsbach, 1994; Elsbach & Sutton, 1992).
tional phenomena. Legitimacy is clearly one 8 Readers who quail at constraining their
of those complex phenomena, and we agree favorite term should take comfort from our focus on
that a large-scale research program may be in connotations rather than denotations. We see no
order. We note, however, that this program need to narrow the permissible usages of any partic-
ular term at this time; however, much can be learned
would require the efforts of many people over
from exploring how legitimacy, status, and reputation
many years. Can such concerted endeavors may carry differing overtones even when applied to
become legitimate again? similar phenomena.
9 This is self-fulfilling to some extent: Entities
that manage to achieve legitimacy on their own
often become the templates for legitimate forms. As
the original instance is imitated, its initially idiosyn-
NOTES cratic claim to legitimacy becomes reinstitutionalized
at the level of the form as a whole.
1 Given the large volume of relevant research, our 10 In this sense, organizational reputation is quite
coverage here is necessarily only partial. Other close to organizational identity – with the caveat that
informative reviews of legitimacy scholarship include reputation emphasizes identity as assessed by trans-
recent essays by Stryker (1994, 2000), Suchman action partners, rather than identity as internalized
(1995), Ruef and Scott (1998), and Johnson, Dowd, by representatives of the organization itself.
and Ridgeway (2006). 11 Reputation can also apply to groups of firms
2 Arguably, DiMaggio and Powell, themselves, (Ferguson, Deephouse, & Ferguson, 2000; Wry,
may have intended their arguments about profes- Deephouse, & McNamara, 2006). But the strategic
sionals merely to illustrate one way in which any groups that sometimes appear in reputation research
norms, whether general or specific, might generate are not necessarily equivalent to status groups, since
isomorphism in an organizational field. Be this as it the former are united by shared performance
may, the linkage between normative isomorphism profiles, while the latter are united by collective
and professionalization has now become so firmly honor claims.
rooted in the organizational literature as to be virtu- 12 Here, we confine ourselves to addressing over-
ally a matter of definition. laps between legitimacy and status and between
3 DiMaggio (1995) has expressed caution about legitimacy and reputation. Overlaps between status
the facile assumption that cognitive legitimacy and and reputation, although equally common, are left
mimetic isomorphism necessarily go hand in hand. for another day.
However, few others in this tradition have taken his 13 The label refers to a verse from the biblical
concerns to heart. Book of Matthew: ‘For unto every one that hath shall
4 One might argue that prevailing definitions of be given, and he shall have abundance: but from him
efficiency are, themselves, institutional myths. Most that hath not shall be taken away even that which he
institutionalist scholarship, however, treats technical hath’ (Matthew XXV: 29, King James Version).
LEGITIMACY IN ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM 71

14 Here, the size of the boxes is arbitrary; how- Barney, J. 1991. Firm Resources and Sustained
ever, future research might empirically assess the rel- Competitive Advantage. Journal of Manage-
ative magnitudes of various sub-groups. ment, 17: 99–120.
15 Over 127,000 firms worldwide had met ISO Baum, J. A. C., & Oliver, C. 1991. Institutional
9000 targets by 1996.
linkages and organizational mortality.
16 These two endeavors are not mutually exclu-
sive, of course. We mean merely to indicate which of
Administrative Science Quarterly, 36:
the two we would give priority. 187–218.
17 Stryker (2000: 187, 191) and Scott (1995) Baum, J. A. C., & Oliver, C. 1992. Institutional
have both noted that despite the potential for both embeddedness and the dynamics of organi-
top-down and bottom-up approaches to institutions, zational populations. American Sociological
most cross-level work to date has taken a top-down Review, 57: 540–559.
approach. Baum, J. A. C., & Powell, W. W. 1995.
Cultivating an institutional ecology of organ-
izations: Comment on Hannan, Carroll,
Dundon, and Torres. American Sociological
REFERENCES Review, 60: 529–538.
Beck, E. M., Horan, P. M., & Tolbert II, C. M.
Abrahamson, E., & Fairchild, G. 1999. 1978. Stratification in a dual economy:
Management fashion: Lifecycles, triggers, A sectoral model of earnings determination.
and collective learning processes. American Sociological Review, 43(5):
Administrative Science Quarterly, 44: 704–720.
708–740. Beck, N., & Walgenbach, P. 2005. Technical
Adler, E. & Haas, P. M. 1992. Epistemic commu- efficiency or adaptation to institutionalized
nities, world-order, and the creation of a expectations? The adoption of ISO 9000
reflective research-program - Conclusion. standards in the German mechanical engi-
International Organization, 46: 367–390. neering industry. Organization Studies, 26:
Aldrich, H. E., & Fiol, C. M. 1994. Fools rush in? 841–866.
The institutional context of industry creation. Benjamin, B. A., & Podolny, J. M. 1999. Status,
Academy of Management Review, 19: quality, and social order in the California
645–670. wine industry. Administrative Science
Archibald, M. E. 2004. Between isomorphism Quarterly, 44: 563–589.
and market partitioning: How organizational Berger, J., Cohen, B., & Zelditch, M., Jr.
competencies and resources foster cultural 1972. Status characteristics and social inter-
and sociopolitical legitimacy, and promote action. American Sociological Review, 37:
organizational survival. In C. Johnson (Ed.), 241–255.
Research in the Sociology of Organizations, Bitekhtine, A. B. 2006. Building a Nomological
Volume 22, pp. 171–211. Amsterdam: Net Around the Organizational Legitimacy.
Elsevier JAI. Paper presented at the Administrative
Arthur, M. M. 2003. Share price reactions to Sciences Association of Canada, Banff, AB.
work-family initiatives: An institutional per- Boiral, O. 2003. ISO 9000: Outside the iron
spective. Academy of Management Journal, cage. Organization Science, 14: 720–737.
46: 497–505. Bourdieu, P. 1986. The forms of capital. In J. G.
Ashforth, B. E., & Gibbs, B. W. 1990. The Richardson (Ed.), Handbook of Theory and
double-edge of organizational legitimation. Research for the Sociology of Education:
Organization Science, 1: 177–194. 241–258. New York: Greenwood.
Bansal, P., & Clelland, I. 2004. Talking trash: Bowen, S. A. 2004. Organizational factors
Legitimacy, impression management, and encouraging ethical decision making: An
unsystematic risk in the context of the natu- exploration into the case of an exemplar.
ral environment. Academy of Management Journal of Business Ethics, 52: 311–324.
Journal, 47: 93–103. Boyle, T. P. 2001. Intermedia agenda setting
Barnard, C. I. 1938. The Functions of the in the 1996 presidential election.
Executive. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Univer- Journalism & Mass Communication
sity Press. Quarterly, 78: 26–44.
72 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Brown, A. D. 1994. Politics, symbolic action Cronbach, L. J., & Meehl, P. E. 1955. Construct
and myth making in pursuit of legitimacy. validity in psychological tests. Psychological
Organization Studies, 15: 861–878. Bulletin, 52: 281–302.
Brown, A. D. 1998. Narrative, politics and legit- Crumley, E., Lounsbury, M., & Greenwood, R.
imacy in an IT implementation. Journal of 2006. Managing Knowledge Boundaries:
Management Studies, 35: 35–58. Incorporating Acupuncture into Biomedicine.
Carroll, C. E. 2004. How the Mass Media Paper presented at the Beyond Knowledge
Influence Perceptions of Corporate Reputa- Management: Advancing the Organizational
tion: Exploring Agenda-Setting Effects within Knowledge Research Agenda, Durham, UK.
Business News Coverage. Unpublished doc- Czarniawska-Joerges, B. 1989. The wonder-
toral dissertation, The University of Texas at land of public administration reforms.
Austin, Austin, TX. Organization Studies, 10: 531–548.
Carroll, G. R., & Hannan, M. T. 1989a. D’Aunno, T., Sutton, R. I., & Price, R. H. 1991.
Density dependence in the evolution of Isomorphism and external support in con-
populations of newspaper organizations. flicting institutional environments: A study of
American Sociological Review, 54: drug abuse treatment units. Academy of
524–541. Management Journal, 34: 636–661.
Carroll, G. R., & Hannan, M. T. 1989b. On Davis, G. F., & Greve, H. R. 1997. Corporate
using institutional theory in studying organi- elite networks and governance changes in
zational populations – Reply. American the 1980s. American Journal of Sociology,
Sociological Review, 54: 545–548. 103: 1–37.
Carter, S. M., & Deephouse, D. L. 1999. ‘Tough Deeds, D. L., Mang, P. Y., & Frandsen, M. L.
talk’ or ‘soothing speech’: Managing 2004. The influence of firms’ and industries’
reputations for being tough and for being legitimacy on the flow of capital into high-
good. Corporate Reputation Review, 2: technology ventures. Strategic Organization,
308–332. 2: 9–34.
Certo, S. T. 2003. Influencing initial public Deephouse, D. L. 1996. Does isomorphism
offering investors with prestige: Signaling legitimate? Academy of Management
with board structures. Academy of Journal, 39: 1024–1039.
Management Review, 28: 432–446. Deephouse, D. L. 1999. To be different, or to
Child, J. 1972. Organizational structure, envi- be the same? It’s a question (and theory) of
ronment and performance: The role of strategic balance. Strategic Management
strategic choice. Sociology, 6: 2–21. Journal, 20: 147–166.
Choi, Y. R., & Shepherd, D. A. 2005. Deephouse, D. L. 2000. Media reputation as a
Stakeholder perceptions of age and other strategic resource: An integration of mass
dimensions of newness. Journal of communication and resource-based theories.
Management, 31: 573–596. Journal of Management, 26: 1091–1112.
Clarkson, M. B. E. 1995. A stakeholder Deephouse, D. L., & Carter, S. M. 2005. An
framework for analyzing and evaluating examination of differences between organi-
corporate social performance. Academy of zational legitimacy and organizational repu-
Management Review, 20: 92–117. tation. Journal of Management Studies, 42:
Cohen, B. D., & Dean, T. J. 2005. Information 329–360.
asymmetry and investor valuation of IPOs: DiMaggio, P. J. 1995. Comments on ‘What
Top management team legitimacy as a capi- theory is not’. Administrative Science
tal market signal. Strategic Management Quarterly, 40: 391–397.
Journal, 26: 683–690. DiMaggio, P. J., & Powell, W. W. 1983. The iron
Conway, M. 2006. The subjective precision of cage revisited: Institutional isomorphism and
computers: A methodological comparison collective rationality in organizational fields.
with human coding in content analysis. American Sociological Review, 48: 147–160.
Journalism & Mass Communication DiMaggio, P. J., & Powell, W. W. 1991.
Quarterly, 83: 186–200. Introduction. In W. W. Powell, & P. J.
Corley, K., & Gioia, D. 2000. The rankings DiMaggio (Eds.), The New Institutionalism in
game: Managing business school reputation. Organizational Analysis: 1–38. Chicago, IL:
Corporate Reputation Review, 3: 319–333. University of Chicago Press.
LEGITIMACY IN ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM 73

Dowling, J., & Pfeffer, J. 1975. Organizational Glynn, M. A., & Abzug, R. 2002.
legitimacy: Social values and organizational Institutionalizing identity: Symbolic isomor-
behavior. Pacific Sociological Review, 18: phism and organizational names. Academy
122–136. of Management Journal, 45: 267–280.
Durand, R., & McGuire, J. 2005. Legitimating Granovetter, M. 1985. Economic action
agencies in the face of selection: The case of and social structure: The problem of
AACSB. Organization Studies, 26: 165–196. embeddedness. American Journal of
Edelman, L. B. 1992. Legal ambiguity and sym- Sociology, 91: 481–510.
bolic structures: Organizational mediation of Greenwood, R., & Empson, L. 2003. The pro-
civil rights law. American Journal of fessional partnership: Relic or exemplary
Sociology, 97: 1531–1576. form of governance? Organization Studies,
Edelman, L. B., Fuller, S. R., & MaraDrita, I. 24: 909–933.
2001. Diversity rhetoric and the managerial- Greenwood, R., Suddaby, R., & Hinings, C. R.
ization of law. American Journal of 2002. Theorizing change: The role of profes-
Sociology, 106: 1589–1641. sional associations in the transformation of
Edelman, L. B., & Suchman, M. C. 1997. The institutionalized fields. Academy of
legal environments of organizations. Annual Management Journal, 45: 58–80.
Review of Sociology, 23: 479–515. Guler, I., Guillen, M. F., & MacPherson, J. M.
Elsbach, K. D. 1994. Managing organizational 2002. Global competition, institutions, and
legitimacy in the California cattle industry: the diffusion of organizational practices:
The construction and effectiveness of verbal The international spread of ISO 9000
accounts. Administrative Science Quarterly, quality certificates. Administrative Science
39: 57–88. Quarterly, 47: 207–232.
Elsbach, K. D., & Kramer, R. M. 1996. Hannan, M. T., & Carroll, G. R. 1992. Dynamics
Members’ responses to organizational iden- of Organizational Populations: Density,
tity threats: Encountering and countering the Legitimation, and Competition. New York:
Business Week rankings. Administrative Oxford University Press.
Science Quarterly, 41: 442–476. Hannan, M. T., & Carroll, G. R. 1995. Theory
Elsbach, K. D., & Sutton, R. I. 1992. Acquiring building and cheap talk about legitimation –
organizational legitimacy through illegiti- Reply. American Sociological Review, 60:
mate actions: A marriage of institutional and 539–544.
impression management theories. Academy Hannan, M. T., Dundon, E. A., Carroll, G. R., &
of Management Journal, 35: 699–738. Torres, J. C. 1995. Organizational evolution
Ferguson, T. D., Deephouse, D. L., & Ferguson, in a multinational context: Entries of auto-
W. L. 2000. Do strategic groups differ in rep- mobile manufacturers in Belgium, Britain,
utation? Strategic Management Journal, 21: France, Germany, and Italy. American
1195–1214. Sociological Review, 60: 509–528.
Fombrun, C., & Shanley, M. 1990. What’s in a Hayward, M. L. A., Rindova, V. P., & Pollock,
name? Reputation building and corporate T. G. 2004. Believing one’s own press:
strategy. Academy of Management Journal, The causes and consequences of CEO
33: 233–258. celebrity. Strategic Management Journal,
Fombrun, C. J. 1996. Reputation: Realizing 25: 637–653.
Value from the Corporate Image. Boston, Hensmans, M. 2003. Social movement organi-
MA: Harvard Business School Press. zations: A metaphor for strategic actors in
Galaskiewicz, J. 1985. Interorganizational rela- institutional fields. Organization Studies, 24:
tions. Annual Review of Sociology, 11: 355–381.
281–304. Higgins, M. C., & Gulati, R. 2003. Getting off
Gans, H. J. 1979. Deciding What’s News. New to a good start: The effects of upper echelon
York: Pantheon Books. affiliations on underwriter prestige.
Gioia, D. A., & Thomas, J. B. 1996. Institutional Organization Science, 14: 244–263.
identity, image and issue interpretation: Higgins, M. C., & Gulati, R. 2006. Stacking the
Sensemaking during strategic change in aca- deck: The effects of top management back-
demia. Administrative Science Quarterly, 41: grounds on investor decisions. Strategic
370–403. Management Journal, 27: 1–25.
74 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Hinings, C. R. 2006. Keynote address – Service Firms’ reputation. Paper presented at


Reaching new heights. Canadian Journal of the Academy of Management, Denver.
Administrative Sciences, 23: 175–182. Kennedy, M. T. 2005. Behind the one-way
Hinings, C. R., Brown, J. L., & Greenwood, R. mirror: Refraction in the construction of
1991. Change in an autonomous product market categories. Poetics, 33:
professional organization. Journal of 201–226.
Management Studies, 28: 375–393. Kennedy, P. 2006. Forestry union denounces
Hirsch, P. M. 1977. Occupational, organiza- safety initiatives, The Globe and Mail: S.3.
tional, and institutional models in mass Toronto.
media research: Towards an integrated Knoke, D. 1985. The political economies of
framework. In P. M. Hirsch, P. V. Miller, & F. G. associations. In R. G. Braungart, & M. M.
Kline (Eds.), Strategies For Communication Braungart (Eds.), Research in Political
Research: 13-40. Beverly Hills, CA: Sage. Sociology, Vol. 1: 211–242. Greenwich, CT:
Hirsch, P. M., & Andrews, J. A. Y. 1984. JAI Press.
Administrators’ response to performance Kostova, T., & Zaheer, S. 1999. Organizational
and value challenges: Stance, symbols, and legitimacy under conditions of complexity:
behavior. In T. J. Sergiovanni, & J. E. Corbally The case of the multinational enterprise.
(Eds.), Leadership and Organizational Academy of Management Review, 24:
Culture: 170–185. Urbana, IL: University of 64–81.
Illinois Press. Lamertz, K., & Baum, J. A. C. 1998. The
Holm, P. 1995. The dynamics of institutionaliza- legitimacy of organizational downsizing
tion: Transformation processes in Norwegian in Canada: An analysis of explanatory
fisheries. Administrative Science Quarterly, media accounts. Canadian Journal of
40: 398–422. Administrative Sciences, 15: 93–107.
Hybels, R. C., Ryan, A. R., & Barley, S. R. 1994. Lawrence, T. B., Winn, M. I., & Jennings, P. D.
Alliances, Legitimation, and Founding Rates 2001. The temporal dynamics of institution-
in the U.S. Biotechnology Field, 1971–1989. alization. Academy of Management Review,
Paper presented at the annual meeting of 26: 624–644.
the Academy of Management, Dallas. Lounsbury, M. 2007. A tale of two cities:
ISO 9000 News. 1996. More than 127000 ISO Competing logics and practice variation in
9000 certificates, Vol. 5. the professionalizing of mutual funds.
Itule, B. D., & Anderson, D. A. 1994. News Academy of Management Journal, 50:
Writing and Reporting For Today’s Media 289–330.
(3rd ed.). New York: McGraw-Hill. March, J., & Simon, H. 1958. Organizations.
Jennings, P. D., Schulz, M., Patient, D., Gravel, New York: John Wiley and Sons.
C., & Yuan, K. 2005. Weber and legal rule Maurer, J. G. 1971. Readings in Organization
evolution: The closing of the iron cage? Theory: Open-System Approaches. New
Organization Studies, 26: 621–653. York: Random House.
Jepperson, R. L. 1991. Institutions, institutional McCombs, M. E., & Shaw, D. L. 1972. The
effects, and institutionalism. In W. W. Powell, agenda setting function of the mass media.
& P. J. DiMaggio (Eds.), The New Institutio- Public Opinion Quarterly, 36: 176–187.
nalism in Organizational Analysis: 143–163. McKee, M. C., Mills, A. J., & Weatherbee, T.
Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press. 2005. Institutional field of dreams: Exploring
Johnson, C. 2004. Introduction: Legitimacy the AACSB and the new legitimacy of
processes in organizations. In C. Johnson (Ed.), Canadian business schools. Canadian
Research in the Sociology of Organizations, Journal of Administrative Sciences, 22:
Vol. 22: 1–24. Amsterdam: Elsevier JAI. 288–301.
Johnson, C., Dowd, T. J., & Ridgeway, C. L. Merry, S. E. 1988. Legal pluralism. Law &
2006. Legitimacy as a social process. Annual Society Review, 22: 869–896.
Review of Sociology, 32: 53–78. Merton, Robert K. 1968, ‘The Matthew Effect
Jones, C., & Manev, I. M. 2002. The Social in science: The reward and communcation
Construction of Expertise: Status and systems of science considered,’ Science,
Legitimacy as the Cornerstones of Professional 159 (3810): 56–63.
LEGITIMACY IN ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM 75

Meyer, J. W., & Rowan, B. 1977. Podolny, J. 1993. A status-based model of


Institutionalized organizations: Formal struc- market competition. American Journal of
ture as myth and ceremony. American Sociology, 98: 829–872.
Journal of Sociology, 83: 340–363. Pollock, T. G., & Rindova, V. P. 2003. Media
Meyer, J. W., & Scott, W. R. 1983. Centralization legitimation effects in the market for initial
and the legitimacy problems of local govern- public offerings. Academy of Management
ment. In J. W. Meyer, & W. R. Scott (Eds.), Journal, 46: 631–642.
Organizational Environments: Ritual and Rao, H. 1994. The social construction of repu-
Rationality: 199–215. Beverly Hills, CA: Sage. tation: Certification contests, legitimation,
Mezias, S. J., & Boyle, E. 2005. Blind trust: and the survival of organizations in the
Market control, legal environments and the American automobile industry: 1895–1912.
dynamics of competitive intensity in the early Strategic Management Journal, 15: 29–44.
American film industry 1893–1920. Rao, H., Morrill, C., & Zald, M. 2000. Power plays:
Administrative Science Quarterly, 50: 1–34. How social movements and collective action
Miles, R. H. 1982. Coffin Nails and Corporate create new organizational forms, Research
Strategies. Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey: in Organizational Behavior, Vol. 22: 237–281.
Prentice-Hall, Inc. Rindova, V. P., Pollock, T. G., & Hayward, M. L.
Mitchell, R. K., Agle, B. R., & Wood, D. J. 1997. A. 2006. Celebrity firms: The social construc-
Toward a theory of stakeholder identification tion of market popularity. Academy of
and salience: Defining the principle of who Management Review, 31: 1–22.
and what really counts. Academy of Rindova, V., Petkova, A. P., & Kotha, S. 2007.
Management Review, 22: 853–886. Standing out: how new firms in emerging
Oliver, A. L. 2001. Strategic alliances and the markets build reputation. Strategic
learning life-cycle of biotechnology firms. Organization, 5: 31–70.
Organization Studies, 22: 467–489. Rindova, V. P., Williamson, I. O., Petkova, A. P.,
Oliver, C. 1997. Sustainable competitive advan- & Sever, J. M. 2005. Being good or being
tage: Combining institutional and resource- known: An empirical examination of the
based views. Strategic Management Journal, dimensions, antecedents, and consequences
18: 697–713. of organizational reputation. Academy of
Osigweh, C. A. B., YG. 1989. Concept fallibil- Management Journal, 48: 1033–1050.
ity in organizational science. Academy of Roberts, P. W., & Dowling, G. R. 2002.
Management Review, 14: 579–594. Corporate reputation and sustained
Parsons, T. 1956. Suggestions for a sociological superior financial performance. Strategic
approach to the theory of organizations – I. Management Journal, 23: 1077–1093.
Administrative Science Quarterly, 1: 63–85. Rosen, S. 1981. The economics of superstars.
Parsons, T. 1960. Structure and Process in American Economic Review, 71: 845–858.
Modern Societies. New York: Free Press. Rowley, T., & Berman, S. 2000. A brand new
Pfeffer, J., & Salancik, G. R. 1978. The External brand of corporate social performance.
Control of Organizations: A Resource Depen- Business & Society, 39: 397.
dence Perspective. New York: Harper & Row. Rowley, T. J. 1997. Moving beyond dyadic ties:
Phillips, D. J., & Zuckerman, E. W. 2001. Middle- A network theory of stakeholder influences.
status conformity: Theoretical restatement and Academy of Management Review, 22:
empirical demonstration in two markets. 887–910.
American Journal of Sociology, 107: 379–429. Rubtsova, A., & Dowd, T. J. 2004. Cultural cap-
Phillips, D. J., & Zuckerman, E. W. 2007. High- ital as a multi-level concept: The case of an
status deviance or conformity? Silicon Valley advertising agency. In C. Johnson (Ed.),
law firms’ engagement in family and per- Research in the Sociology of Organizations,
sonal injury law. Paper presented at the Vol. 22: 117–146. Amsterdam: Elsevier JAI.
annual meeting of the American Sociological Ruef, M., & Scott, W. R. 1998. A multidimen-
Association, in New York City, NY. sional model of organizational legitimacy:
Phillips, N., Lawrence, T. B., & Hardy, C. 2004. Hospital survival in changing institutional
Discourse and institutions. Academy of environments. Administrative Science
Management Review, 29: 635–652. Quarterly, 43: 877–904.
76 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Sauder, M., and Lancaster, R. (2006). Do rank- Stryker, R. 2000. Legitimacy processes as insti-
ings matter? The effects of U.S. news and tutional politics: Implications for theory and
world report rankings on the admissions research in the sociology of organizations,
process of law schools. Law & Society Research in the Sociology of Organizations,
Review, 40(1): 105–134. Vol. 17: 179–223. Greenwich, CT: JAI.
Schnatterly, K., Ward, A., & Lee, P. M. 2006. Suchman, M. C. 1995. Managing legitimacy:
Certification, Reputation and Legitimacy: Strategic and institutional approaches. Academy
Concentric Concepts. Paper presented at the of Management Review, 20: 571–610.
Academy of Management, Atlanta, GA. Suddaby, R., & Greenwood, R. 2005. Rhetorical
Schramm, W. 1949. The nature of news. In W. strategies of legitimacy. Administrative
Schramm (Ed.), Mass Communications: Science Quarterly, 50: 35–67.
288–303. Urbana, IL: University of Illinois Tolbert, P. S., & Zucker, L. G. 1983. Institutional
Press. sources of change in the formal structure of
Scott, W. R. 1987. Organizations: Rational, organizations: The diffusion of civil service
Natural, and Open Systems (2nd edn). reforms 1880–1935. Administrative Science
Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall. Quarterly, 23: 22–39.
Scott, W. R. 1995. Institutions and Vaara, E., Tienari, J., & Laurila, J. 2006. Pulp
Organizations. Thousands Oaks, CA: Sage. and paper fiction: On the discursive legitima-
Scott, M. B., & Lyman, S. M. 1968. Accounts. tion of global industrial restructuring.
American Sociological Review, 33: 46–62 Organization Studies, 27: 789–810.
Scott, W. R., Ruef, M., Mendel, P.J., & Caronna, Van de Ven, A. H. 1992. Suggestions for study-
C. 2000. Institutional Change and Healthcare ing strategy process: A research note. Strategic
Organizations: From Professional Dominance Management Journal, 13: 169–188.
to Managed Care. Chicago, IL: University of Vidaver-Cohen, D. 2006. Institutional Change,
Chicago Press. Legitimacy, and Reputation: A Model of
Shapiro, C. 1983. Premiums for high quality Reciprocal Processes. Paper presented at the
products as returns to reputations. Quarterly Florida International University Faculty
Journal of Economics, 98: 659–679. Research Symposium, Miami.
Shoemaker, P. J. 1996. Hardwired for news: Wade, J. B., Porac, J. F., Pollock, T. G., &
Using biological and cultural evolution to Graffin, S. D. 2006. The burden of celebrity:
explain the surveillance function. Journal of The impact of CEO certification contests on
Communication, 46: 32–47. CEO pay and performance. Academy of
Simon, H. A. 1976. Administrative Behavior Management Journal, 49: 643–660.
(3rd edn). New York: Free Press. Walker, H. A., & Zelditch, M., Jr. 1993. Power,
Sine, W. D., David, R. J., & Mitsuhashi, H. 2007. legitimacy, and the stability of authority: A
From plan to plant: Effects of certification on theoretical research program. In J. Berger, &
operational start-up in the emergent inde- M. Zelditch, Jr. (Eds.), Theoretical Research
pendent power sector. Organization Science, Programs: Studies in the Growth of Theory:
18: 578–594. 364–381. Stanford, CA: Stanford University
Singh, J. V., Tucker, D. J., & House, R. J. 1986. Press.
Organizational legitimacy and the liability of Wartick, S. L. 2002. Measuring corporate repu-
newness. Administrative Science Quarterly, tation: Definition and data. Business &
31: 171–193. Society, 41: 371–392.
Strang, D., & Soule, S. A. 1998. Diffusion in Washington, M., & Zajac, E. J. 2005. Status
organizations and social movements: From evolution and competition: Theory and evi-
hybrid corn to poison pills. Annual Review of dence. Academy of Management Journal,
Sociology, 24: 265–290. 48: 282–296.
Stryker, R. 1994. Rules, resources, and legiti- Weber, M. (1946 [1922]). ‘Class, status, party.’
macy processes: Some implications for social Pp. 180–95 in From Max Weber Essays in
conflict, order and change. American Journal Sociology, ed. H. H. Gerth and C. Wright
of Sociology, 99: 847–910. Mills. New York: Oxford University Press.
LEGITIMACY IN ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM 77

Wedlin, L. 2006. Ranking Business Schools: Wright, E. O. 1985. Practical strategies for
Forming Fields, Identities and Boundaries in transforming concepts. In E. O. Wright (Ed.),
International Management Education. Classes: 292–302. London, UK: Verso.
Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar. Wry, T. E., Deephouse, D. L., & McNamara, G.
Weigelt, K., & Camerer, C. 1988. Reputation 2007. Substantive and evaluative media rep-
and corporate strategy: A review of utations across and within cognitive strategic
recent theory and applications. Strategic groups. Corporate Reputation Review, 9:
Management Journal, 9: 443–454. 225–242.
Westphal, J. D., Gulati, R., & Shortell, S. M. Zucker, L. G. 1977. The role of institutionaliza-
1997. Customization or conformity? An tion in cultural persistence. American
institutional and network perspective on Sociological Review, 42: 726–743.
the content and consequences of TQM adop- Zucker, L. G. 1989. Combining institutional
tion. Administrative Science Quarterly, 42: theory and population ecology: No legiti-
366–394. macy, no history. American Sociological
Wezel, F. C. 2005. Location dependence and Review, 54: 542–545.
industry evolution: Founding rates in the Zuckerman, E. W. 2000. Focusing the corpo-
United Kingdom motorcycle industry, rate product: Securities analysts and de-
1895–1993. Organization Studies, 26: diversification. Administrative Science
729–754. Quarterly, 45: 591–619.
2
Isomorphism, Diffusion
and Decoupling
Eva Boxenbaum and Stefan Jonsson

questions and dimensions to the original


INTRODUCTION propositions. Our aim in this chapter is to
bring clarity to this body of literature by first
A longstanding question in organization establishing the state of the art and then
research is what makes organizations more identifying important areas in need of further
or less similar to each other. Early organiza- research.
tion theorists pointed out that organizations A central idea of institutional isomor-
that share the same environment tend to phism is that organizations conform to
take on similar forms as efficiency-seeking ‘rationalized myths’ in society about what
organizations seek the optimal ‘fit’ with constitutes a proper organization. These
their environment. Institutional theories of myths emerge as solutions to widely
organization have added two related claims. perceived problems of organizing and
First, organizations adapt not only to techni- become rationalized when they are popularly
cal pressures but also to what they believe believed to constitute the proper solutions
society expects of them, which leads to to these problems. As more organizations
institutional isomorphism. Organizations conform to these myths they become more
need a societal mandate, or legitimacy, deeply institutionalized, which subsequently
to operate and this is gained by conforming leads to institutional isomorphism (Meyer
to societal expectations. Second, when and Rowan 1977). Institutional isomorphism
adaptations to institutional pressures contra- is facilitated by processes that further the
dict internal efficiency needs, organizations diffusion of ideas, practices and prescribed
sometimes claim to adapt when they in organizational structure among organizations
reality do not; they decouple action from (DiMaggio and Powell 1983). While
structure in order to preserve organizational diffusion was introduced as a mechanism
efficiency. A large number of empirical that led to isomorphsim, many empirical
studies have subsequently refined the related researchers have implicitly reversed this
propositions of institutional isomorphism causal link. The result is that there has been
and decoupling, and also introduced new little empirical work with isomorphism as the
ISOMORPHISM, DIFFUSION AND DECOUPLING 79

outcome of diffusion, while there is a wealth We begin the chapter with an outline of
of empirical studies that invoke institutional the early theoretical formulations, where we
isomorphism as the cause of diffusion. explicate the initial core theoretical
Furthermore, we notice a recent shift in insti- statements of isomorphism and decoupling
tutional literature toward the acknowledge- and proceed to trace how decades of empiri-
ment of heterogeneity in the institutional cal research have contributed to the refine-
environment (cf. Dacin, Goodstein and Scott ment of these statements. This refinement
2002). An emphasis on isomorphism as a has taken place against the backdrop of a
driver of diffusion rather than an outcome wider shift within institutional theory
coupled with a growing sensitivity to hetero- towards a greater recognition of heterogene-
geneity of institutional environments is prob- ity in the institutional environment and in
ably why we find surprisingly little empirical organizational response to institutional pres-
evidence of institutional isomorphism; extant sures. We discuss how this shift has impacted
evidence is simply not conclusive. on our understanding of isomorphism and
The second claim about organizational decoupling and end the chapter with a
similarity is that organizations decouple their discussion of what we identify as neglected
formal structure from their production areas of research, as well as the relationship
activities when institutional and task environ- between institutional isomorphism and
ments are in conflict, or when there are con- decoupling. It is our hope that this juxtaposi-
flicting institutional pressures. Decoupling tion of empirical findings with our reflection
enables organizations to seek the legitimacy on the interaction among isomorphism,
that adaptation to rationalized myths diffusion and decoupling catalyzes new and
provides while they engage in technical exciting research questions that can propel
‘business as usual’. While decoupling is a institutional theory forward.
core idea in institutional theory, it has
received relatively little scholarly attention
(see e.g. Scott 1995), although this trend
seems to be reversing. We review the empiri- EARLY THEORETICAL STATEMENTS
cal research that has refined the notion of
decoupling and the factors that have been
Isomorphism
found to predict or mediate this response to
institutional pressure for conformity. Why are organizations so strikingly similar?
Despite the centrality of isomorphism DiMaggio and Powell (1983) proposed that
and decoupling within institutional theory institutionalized ideas pressure organizations
and their close theoretical ancestry, little to adopt similar structures and forms, and as
attention has been devoted to examine a result they become increasingly similar. It
how they relate to each other. We recognize was not a new idea in organization theory that
that this absence provides for several organizations in the same environment over
interesting future research avenues; for time also come to share their appearance.
instance whether or not the ease of decou- Already Weber argued that the ‘iron cage of
pling within an organizational field influ- rationality’ and that competitive forces in
ences the likelihood and speed of society would pressure organizations to
institutional isomorphism, or whether similarity in structure and action. Rational
decoupling is more likely in a heterogeneous adaptation theorists then claimed that organi-
or mature institutionalized environment. A zational similarity results from efficiency-
fruitful empirical and theoretical research seeking organizational adaptation to a similar
agenda is to clarify the relationship between task environment (Scott 1995). Playing down
isomorphism and decoupling under different the aggregate effects of organization-level
field conditions. adaptation, population ecology theorists have
80 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

subsequently argued that environmental com- similar practices and structures (for instance
petitive selection forces leave the surviving Galaskiewicz and Burt 1991; Mezias 1990).
organizational population structurally similar. These three pressures can also be thought
Institutional isomorphism was distinct from of in terms of topographical directions from
these perspectives in its assertion that organi- where isomorphic pressures emanate in an
zations became similar not through adaptation organizational field: regulative pressures
to an external or technically demanding normally come from above (the state)
environment or through the ‘weeding out’ of whereas mimetic and normative pressures
technical and social misfits, but through adap- often stem from horizontally positioned peer
tation to a socially constructed environment. organizations or groupings. Strang and Soule
The timing of the statement about institutional (1998) also liken the three pressures to a
isomorphism should be understood against the mapping of diffusion channels in terms of
backdrop of a longstanding interest within external diffusion pressure on the organiza-
organizational sociology in the structure of tion, such as the state, peer pressure across
organizations, a heritage from open-systems firms, or internal diffusion pressure from
theories of the 1960s, and the development of professional information networks.
the population ecology school from 1977 and DiMaggio and Powell then propose a
onwards (Scott 2004). dozen hypotheses relating to how organiza-
DiMaggio and Powell outlined three pres- tions subject to isomorphic pressures respond
sures that lead organizations to become to an increasingly institutionalized environ-
increasingly similar: coercive, mimetic and ment. These hypotheses, which set the arena
normative pressures. Coercive pressures result for much of the subsequent empirical work on
from power relationships and politics; proto- isomorphism, range from predictions about
typically these are demands of the state or the degree of isomorphism at the level of an
other large actors to adopt specific structures or organizational field to the rate by which
practices, or else face sanctions. Coercive pres- different kinds of organizations are expected
sures are not only by fiat but can also result to morph to similarity within the field. The
from resource dependence, such as demands to hypotheses relate to questions that were, at
adopt specific accounting practices to be eligi- the time, topical in organization theory, most
ble for state grants or requirements of ISO cer- notably questions about organizational
tification to become a supplier (see for instance structure, implications of resource depend-
work by Edelman 1992; Guillen 2001; Sutton ence across organizations, the effects of orga-
et al. 1994). Mimetic pressures arise primarily nizational and field goal ambiguity, and the
from uncertainty. Under conditions of uncer- level of professionalization of the workforce.
tainty organizations often imitate peers that are While these theoretical statements and
perceived to be successful or influential propositions were meant to further our
(Haveman 1993; Palmer, Jennings and Zhou understanding of how organizations became
1993). Normative pressures pertain to what is increasingly similar over time, empirical
widely considered a proper course of action, or research fairly soon re-directed their use to
even a moral duty (Suchman 1995), such further our understanding of the diffusion of
as when there are signals from the organiza- practices and ideas, which means that some
tional environment that the adoption of a of the fundamental ideas of institutional
particular practice or structure is a correct isomorphism still await confirmation.
moral choice. Normative pressures are often
associated with professions because the
similar education and training instil similar Decoupling
professional values of what is ‘proper’, which
is then carried into organizations with profes- When organizations are pressured to adapt to
sionals who then tend to favour the adoption of societal rationalized myths about what
ISOMORPHISM, DIFFUSION AND DECOUPLING 81

organizations should look like and do, they without actually adapting relies critically on
face two problems: First, the rationalized the ‘logic of confidence and good faith’, i.e.
myths may not comprise an efficient solution that people trust that the organization does
for the organization, and second, competing what it says it will (Meyer and Rowan 1977:
and internally inconsistent rational myths 357), which means that organizations that
can exist simultaneously. Meyer and Rowan decouple must avoid close inspection or else
(1977) proposed that organizations decouple they are exposed as frauds. A corollary to the
their practices from their formal or espoused decoupling proposition is that when institu-
structure to solve these two problems of tional pressures lead to decoupling, organiza-
institutional pressures. In effect, decoupling tions will do their best to avoid scrutiny or at
means that organizations abide only superfi- least to control the process of scrutiny.
cially by institutional pressure and adopt new
structures without necessarily implementing
the related practices.
The idea of organizations decoupling EMPIRICAL EXAMINATION
structure and action reflected the perspective
of organizations as loosely coupled systems Given the voluminous research on institu-
that became popular in the mid-1970s. tional isomorphism and decoupling, it was
A group of organizational sociologists and necessary to structure the review of empirical
social psychologists proposed loose coupling work according to themes that emerged as
as a solution to problems of change and salient after a first reading of the literature.
reform in US public schools (Hallet and These themes are partially chronological. In
Ventresca 2006). In a challenge to the the discussion section, we touch on the
dominant system theory where organizations development of these themes in relation to
were seen as coherent units composed of the wider theoretical developments within
densely linked and interdependent elements, institutional theory.
they proposed instead that organizational
elements are loosely coupled to one another.
Drawing on this insight they investigated Isomorphism
different kinds of couplings and how these
are created (e.g. Weick 1979) also in relation Similar to what?
to decision-making processes (March and A central question with respect to isomor-
Olsen 1976). In contrast to the more general phism is what the relevant environment is to
idea of organizations as loosely coupled which organizations are thought to become
systems, Meyer and Rowan refer specifically (or not become) isomorphic? While this is a
to a form of loose coupling that is a discon- question that is not often discussed, a broad
nect between organizational practice and dividing line can be drawn between empirical
organizational structure, where the former is studies that conceptualize the institutional
determined by perceived efficiency concerns environment in terms of technical and goal-
and the latter results from institutional setting features, i.e. societal sectors (Scott and
pressure for conformity. Meyer 1983), and studies that consider the
In its original statement, decoupling can environment to be a socially constructed
be a rational response to demands for organi- ‘field’ (DiMaggio and Powell 1983). The
zational adaptation that are inconsistent or social sector approach differs from an organi-
harmful to the organization; by decoupling, zational field perspective in the conceptual-
organizations achieve legitimacy through ization of the institutional environment as
espoused action but remain efficient or con- external and exogenous to organizations; it is
sistent through actual action, which enhances the technical nature of the production task
their survival prospects. Gaining legitimacy that determines the nature of the institutional
82 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

environment, a factor that changes through we direct the interested reader to the work by
technical development rather than organiza- John Mohr (2005).
tional action. Seeing the institutional environ-
ment as a field, in contrast, positions the Similar in what?
institutional environment as a result of a Another important question about isomor-
structuration process that involves all field phism is in what respect organizations are
actors (Powell and DiMaggio 1991; Zucker supposed to become similar. The early theo-
1987). A further difference is that the concept retical statement by DiMaggio and Powell is
of institutional sectors is hierarchical in ambiguous on this topic, suggesting that iso-
nature, with clear distinctions between hori- morphism can be detected by ‘the lessening
zontal and vertical ties (Scott and Meyer in variance around some central dimension’.
1983), whereas the field essentially represents This ambiguity essentially left subsequent
a relational non-topographical space that empirical researchers to their own devices
stems from its ideational roots within network (Oliver 1988; Scott and Meyer 1994). The
theory (Mohr 2005). few studies that have investigated isomor-
The perspective on the environment is phism as an outcome emphasize different
important to our understanding of how iso- dimensions and levels in their measurements
morphic pressures can be thought to operate of similarity. Meyer, Scott and Strang (1987)
on organizations. An organizational sector investigated isomorphism in the structure of
approach, which broadly defines the relevant U.S. schools and found more evidence of iso-
environment as input–output relations, morphism at higher levels of the administra-
makes technological shifts important drivers tive system, levels that were further removed
of changes in isomorphic pressures. If, in from the local task environment of education.
contrast, the arena for isomorphic pressures Meyer and colleagues (1997) also investi-
is thought of as socially constructed by gated the structure of national educational
organizations, then the source of isomorphic systems in a large-scale empirical study of
pressures is instead partly endogenous to world systems, and they show that educa-
the organizations. An important point is that tional systems are becoming increasingly
this theoretical dividing line between two similar across the globe, especially so in
perspectives on the nature of the institutional countries that are more tightly integrated into
environment is seldom reflected in empirical the ‘western cultural account’.
studies (see, however, Scott 1987; Zucker Other studies have focused more closely
1987). What we see instead are empirical on isomorphism in what organizations do.
definitions of ‘organizational fields’ that are Levitt and Nass (1989) investigated isomor-
largely coterminous with the theoretical con- phism in the output of college text book pub-
cept of societal sectors (for instance the typi- lishing, where they found isomorphism to be
cal ‘industry’ definition of a field), which are more prevalent in the mature academic field
then matched with DiMaggio and Powell’s of physics than in sociology. Kraatz and
theoretical apparatus of isomorphism in a Zajac (1996) showed that in a maturing field
socially constructed field. Very few, if any, of U.S. higher education, the scope of college
studies of institutional isomorphism match programs decreased in homogeneity, instead
DiMaggio and Powell’s idea of isomorphic of increased, suggesting that isomorphism
forces with a constructionist definition of the did not occur, at least not in the programs
organizational field. This may be unproblem- that colleges offered. Lifting the level of
atic, we do not know, but it needs further the- analysis to that of national economic sys-
oretical and empirical work. As it is beyond tems, Orru, Biggart and Hamilton (1991)
the scope of this chapter to focus on the showed that corporate governance structures
thorny issue of the relevant definition of what are more similar within, than across, national
organizations are supposed to morph with, economies in the Far East.
ISOMORPHISM, DIFFUSION AND DECOUPLING 83

The common feature of these empirical isomorphic pressures. Early studies found
studies is the ambiguity of the relevant that mimetic pressures emanated most
dimension and level of analysis where simi- strongly from actors that are considered sim-
larity should or should not occur in order to ilar (Greve 1998), successful and prestigious
confirm the presence of institutional isomor- (Haveman 1993). In addition, Haunschild
phism. This ambiguity makes it difficult, (1993) found mimetic pressures to operate
even after three decades of research, to deter- through networks of board members. Other
mine the degree of empirical support for the studies found normative pressures to
proposition of institutional isomorphism, influence the manner in which large U.S.
including its limitations. More theoretical firms adopted new accounting standards
work clearly needs to be done in this area to (Mezias 1990) and the multidivisional
render institutional isomorphism an empiri- form (Palmer, Jennings and Zhou 1993).
cally falsifiable theoretical proposition. Empirical support was also found
for the claim that legal measures lead to
Similarity as diffusion? coercive diffusion pressure. Edelman
Even if the above studies on isomorphism are (1992) showed that coercive employment
not always directly comparable, at least they equity laws made organizations change
try to measure isomorphism as an outcome their structure and subsequently their
variable, which is not the case with the practice even if organizations were quite
majority of studies that invoke institutional influential in interpreting what it meant to
isomorphism. Rather than test isomorphism comply.
as an empirical outcome, these studies have Among the three isomorphic pressures,
typically turned to the mechanisms through mimesis has received the most attention
which isomorphism supposedly happens, (Mizruchi and Fein 1999). One reason for
i.e. the three isomorphic pressures outlined this focus on mimetic pressures, as Mizruchi
by DiMaggio and Powell. In studying these and Fein argue, is that power perspectives are
mechanisms without also investigating out of vogue among North American social
the resulting isomorphism, institutionalists scientists, which is why coercive and norma-
have often drifted very close to the prolific tive isomorphic pressures have received less
field of diffusion studies. An example of the attention. Another plausible explanation is
confluence of institutional and diffusion that mimesis is easier to study with
studies is the investigation of the spread of quantitative methods while it is more
administrative reforms by Tolbert and Zucker difficult to collect data on normative
(1983). They tested coercive pressures pressures or to illuminate the exercise of
against mimetic pressures and found that coercion in large quantitative studies. A third
coercive pressures were more effective than possible explanation is that normative and
mimetic pressures in spreading a new coercive processes receive attention in other
practice. It is a typical research strategy theoretical traditions or in specific
within diffusion studies that invokes institutional literatures, such as European
institutional theory and test one (or more) of institutional schools (cf. Mizruchi and Fein
the isomorphic pressures against an effi- 1999).
ciency or resource dependence perspective, These empirical studies that invoke institu-
in order to explain the diffusion of certain tional isomorphism do not investigate the
practices and structures (for instance Kraatz resulting level of isomorphism in the
and Zajac 1996; Palmer, Jennings and Zhou field, but instead elaborate on the mechanism
1993). by which practices spread. They do so under
The various diffusion studies that invoke the implicit assumption that diffusion
theories of isomorphic pressures can be equals isomorphism, an assumption that
organized according to the focal type of the certainly needs verification.
84 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Similarity in a heterogeneous environment isomorphism (Boxenbaum and Battilana


The very idea of institutional isomorphism 2005; Schneiberg 2002; Townley 2002;
presupposes an institutional environment Zilber 2002).
with which the organization can morph.
A crucial question is how institutional Similarity and heterogeneous
isomorphism can occur where the institu- organizational response
tional environment is not homogenous. Apart from an increasing attention to hetero-
Part of the answer may be ambiguities in geneous institutional pressures, serious orga-
the original theoretical formulation of insti- nizational thinkers have also challenged the
tutional isomorphism, in particular with assumption that, once subjected to institu-
respect to how the institutional environment tional pressures, organizations either con-
(i.e. the organizational field or social sector) form or die (cf. DiMaggio 1988; Perrow
and its effects can be identified and delimited 1986; Scott 1991). This topic evokes the
(cf. Mohr 2005). larger question within institutional theory of
Early studies of isomorphism in organiza- whether or not institutions are fully internal-
tional fields conceptualized the organiza- ized in actors (i.e. ‘social facts’) or if actors
tional field as unitary and examined how can comprehend and thereby ‘game’ them
institutional pressures affected organizations, (Zucker 1987). The division between institu-
presumably in an equal manner (Scott 2001). tions as social fact and institutions as visible
In more recent studies the field has increas- limitations on action splits empirical work on
ingly become conceptualized as ambiguous the effect of isomorphic pressures. One line
and heterogeneous with multiple institutional of research adopts the more agentic approach
pressures that often result in conflicting pres- where actors can strategize and manipulate
sures for conformity. Isomorphic pressures institutional pressures; in this research it is
have been found to interact with competitive organizational similarity and not difference
pressures and space (D’Aunno, Succi and that needs to be explained, organizations
Alexander 2000; Dacin 1997) and vary over have choice. This form of institutionalism
time (Dacin 1997; Ruef and Scott 1998). An received a boost after Powell and DiMaggio
example of the effects of variation in the (1991) argued that institutional analysis
local competitive context is provided in a needs to do away with the organization as an
study of isomorphism in U.S. higher educa- ‘institutional dope’. A key issue within this
tion, where Kraatz and Zajac (1996) show literature is whether isomorphism is attrac-
that the increasing maturity of the field does tive when all organizations occupy the same
not lead to homogeneity (isomorphism) in strategic and resource space (Deephouse
educational programmes because of a simul- 1999; Greenwood and Hinings 1996). The
taneous increase in competitive pressure to other line of research is a less agentic
differentiate student programmes. The struc- approach where organizations internalize
ture of networks through which the ‘markers institutional pressures to a greater extent. As
of similarity’ travel, i.e. how entities diffuse, institutions constitute actors and actions,
can also limit the resulting isomorphism there is no consciousness involved in follow-
within an organizational field. Greve (1996) ing norms; conformity comes naturally and
studied the spread of new competitive strate- deviance is almost unthinkable. Here it is not
gies among radio stations and found that similarity, but difference, that needs to be
mimetic pressure led to practice polymor- explained. Isomorphism is not guaranteed,
phism (islands of homogeneity) because and will, for instance, not happen when there
imitation networks were geographically are cognitive or capability limitations on
bounded in markets. Similar findings are also becoming isomorphic (Goodrick and
reported in a number of qualitative studies of Salancik 1996). This latter direction is most
the spread of practices and the resulting clearly articulated in European books on
ISOMORPHISM, DIFFUSION AND DECOUPLING 85

translation, editing and globalization (for self-evident and desirable. When a practice or
instance Djelic and Quack 2003; Sahlin and structure is implicitly adapted to local institu-
Engwall 2003). tions, it is broadly referred to as translation or
Within an agentic perspective, organiza- editing (see the chapter on translation). We
tions are seen as active agents that can thus see the larger division between institu-
respond differently, within certain bound- tion and actorhood reflected in studies on
aries, to institutional pressure (Ingram and institutional isomorphism; after 1991 there
Clay 2000). Oliver (1991) argued that are relatively fewer studies of isomorphism as
organizations under certain circumstances an outcome presumably because of a greater
have leeway to act strategically in the face of emphasis on actorhood in institutional theory
isomorphic pressures. She proposed five in general. It would be interesting to follow
strategic responses that are available to up on this preliminary observation with a
organizations that face institutional pressure meta-study that relates the larger shifts in
to conform. The first one, acquiescence institutional theory to how institutional
(conformity), is essentially the response that isomorphism is studied empirically.
leads to isomorphism while the second one,
compromise, can manifest as decoupling Decoupling
(Scott 2001). The third and fourth, avoidance
and defiance, are two forms of resistance that Does decoupling occur?
organizations display when they disagree Several empirical studies have sought to con-
with the objectives of the constituents who firm the existence of decoupling. For
put pressure on them to adopt a new organi- instance, in a study of affirmative action
zational element. Manipulation, the fifth policies in a small liberal arts college in the
response, is akin to institutional entrepre- United States, Edelman et al. (1992) found
neurship in the sense that it implies a deliber- that the affirmative action officer exercised
ate attempt to change institutions in a certain significant flexibility in the hiring process
direction. Oliver’s theoretical argumentation although he had issued policies that reflected
has triggered a number of empirical studies affirmative action legislation. By means of
(see for instance Goodrick and Salancik decoupling, he conferred legitimacy upon the
1996; Ingram and Simons 1995) that relate college while simultaneously attending to
strategic considerations to isomorphism. divergent concerns related to its teaching
In the non-agentic tradition, where staff. Similarly, Brunsson and Olsen (1993)
institutions are ‘social facts’, organizations found that a radical reform at Swedish Rail
may also respond heterogeneously, but for a was formally implemented without
different reason. Several studies link organi- significant impact on daily operations. While
zational responses to environmental management thought that the reform would
contingencies, demonstrating how time, result in near chaos, they discovered to their
space and local competition introduce varia- surprise that rail traffic and operational
tion in organizational response to isomorphic supervisors were virtually undisrupted
pressures, even where the institutional pres- by the reform. Decoupling made it easier for
sures are fully internalized (Beck and management to make decisions on reform
Walgenbach 2005; D’Aunno, Succi and since operational departments were collabo-
Alexander 2000; Dacin 1997; Jonsson 2003). rative as long as the reform did not affect
At other times organizations are simply not their work in any significant way.
able to perfectly replicate an institutionally Collectively, these studies provided some
sanctioned structure or practice. That is the empirical support for Meyer and Rowan’s
case even if institutional pressures have proposition that formal structure can be,
been internalized to such an extent that adop- and often is, decoupled from production
tion of a structure or practice is perceived as activities.
86 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Why do organizations decouple? efficiency, whereas recent studies suggest


Institutional decoupling carries with it a risk that decoupling is a result of heterogeneous
of detection where it would no longer confer organizational fields with multiple and often
legitimacy, but probably shame, on the contradictory pressures on the organization
organization. So why do organizations (cf. Heimer 1999; Ruef and Scott 1998).
decouple? One suggestion is that organiza- Faced with simultaneous contradictory pres-
tions decouple if they experience strong sures, organizations survive by engaging in
coercive pressure to implement a new prac- decoupling. For instance, George et al.
tice (Seidman 1983), and all the more so if (2006) proposed that decision makers resort
they distrust the actor that asserts pressure on to decoupling when they face ambiguity in
them (Kostova and Roth 2002). Another pos- their reading of the environment. They may
sibility is that decoupling increases as an respond to heterogeneous pressure for
organizational field becomes more homoge- conformity by conforming to select institu-
neous. Investigating the introduction of long- tional pressures and ignoring others. Aurini
term CEO compensation plans, Westphal and (2006) found, for instance, that educational
Zajac (1997) showed that early adopters institutions routinely shed some of the most
were more likely than late adopters to imple- sacred schooling scripts, but flourished
ment adopted incentive plans. Their research anyway because they responded to new
(Westphal and Zajac 1994, 1997) indicates pressures, such as consumer demands for
that decoupling is most likely among reluc- individualized education programmes. They
tant (later) adopters that respond to norma- decoupled some institutions to be able to
tive pressure, a finding that is corraborated implement others, recognizing that there
by a study of financial analysts who initiated were several ways to obtain legitimacy in this
coverage of firms. Analysts who initated cov- heterogenous field.
erage late were also more likely to abandon Decoupling structure from practice can
their actions earlier (Rao, Greve and Davis take multiple forms simultaneously. Nils
2001). First movers and adopters are eager to Brunsson (2002) suggests that organizations
implement while late movers more readily solve the dilemma of contradictory demands
decouple, a response that they hide behind by meeting some demands by talk, others by
seeming enthusiasm. A study by Fiss and decisions, and yet others by action. They are
Zajac (2006) concluded, for instance, that required to do so, he argues, because if they
organizations that fervently proclaim their act consistently with what is said and what is
conformity to demands for strategic change decided in a situation of conflicting
are less likely to be the ones that actually demands, then they will satisfy only one
implement structural changes. This intrigu- interest at the expense of the others. In resort-
ing question of how isomorphism relates to ing to decoupling, organizations increase
decoupling is one that deserves careful atten- their chance of survival as they prevent
tion in future research. conflicts from escalating. A study of the
Danish Red Cross came to a similar conclu-
Decoupling as a response to field sion, showing that the organization became
heterogeneity more robust when it decoupled ideology and
In their initial formulations, Meyer and structure from concrete programmes and
Rowan suggested that decoupling was a activities (Christensen and Molin 1995).
response to two organization-level problems: Decoupling thus turned out to be a safe-
contradictions with internal organizational guarding mechanism in a heterogenous field,
efficiency and contradictions among multiple an attempt to compose with conflicting
institutionalized pressures. Early studies demands in a way that minimizes risk.
focused primarily on decoupling as a The move to embrace heterogeneity in
response to save internal organizational empirical studies has not been accompanied
ISOMORPHISM, DIFFUSION AND DECOUPLING 87

by a commensurate theoretical elaboration. organizations to decouple for proactive


Researchers have noted, however, that organ- reasons rather than for defensive reasons.
izations in the same organizational field do
not respond similarly to the same pressures, What predicts decoupling?
an observation that indicates that decoupling Even when subjected to similar institutional
may be related to factors in the individual pressures, some organizations decouple
organization. while others do not. The interesting question
in this regard is which organizational vari-
Decoupling as a strategic response? ables affect whether an organization engages
In their initial formulation, Meyer and in decoupling. One suggestion is that decou-
Rowan proposed that decoupling consists in pling follows naturally from a realization that
adopting a structure for legitimacy purposes, the organization may derive financial bene-
but not implementing it in practice because fits from it. In one of the first quantitative
of a (perceived) conflict with technical studies of decoupling, Westphal and Zajac
efficiency concerns. Oliver (1997) found (1998) found that the market price of
empirical evidence for the proposition that corporations increased when they adopted a
decoupling is critical to an organization’s legitimate practice, regardless of whether
success. This relationship was particularly they implemented it or not. This finding
strong when resource stringency was high validates Meyer and Rowan’s proposition
and organizations depended on constituents that decoupling is a pragmatic response to
in the task environment who held control conflicting pressures to ensure both legiti-
over land, labour, capital and suppliers. macy and technical efficiency. Others have
Stringent regulation made organizations refined their theoretical proposition by inves-
engage in less decoupling. tigating which variables mediate the act of
Recent developments in the decoupling decoupling. Naturally, the prerequisite is
literature has broadened the scope of decou- here that organizations are aware of the pos-
pling from a defensive action, which Meyer sibility of decoupling and consider it to have
and Rowan wrote about, to something akin to a strategic advantage.
impression management. For instance, brand Power dynamics has been identified as an
managers of up-market wineries deliberately important variable that mediates the desire to
decoupled projected images from internal decouple and the action of decoupling. In a
practices to create powerful brand images, longitudinal study of the response of large
which apparently increased their profits U.S. corporations to pressure from external
(Beverland and Luxton 2005). In another sources to adopt stock repurchase pro-
example of the proximity to impression man- grammes, Westphal and Zajac (2001) found
agement, Elsbach and Sutton (1992) investi- that organizational power dynamics medi-
gated how radical social movement ated the ability of organizations to decouple.
organizations acquired legitimacy and mobi- While organizations derived legitimacy from
lized constituent support. They found that adopting the stock repurchase programme,
spokespersons shifted attention away from top executives had a personal interest in not
controversial actions toward socially desir- implementing these programmes in practice.
able goals that were endorsed by broader Decoupling occurred more frequently when
constituents. They simultaneously decoupled top executives had power over boards to
their illegitimate activities from their legiti- resist external pressure for change. There is
mate organizational structures. There is further evidence for external pressure as a
much room to investigate the strategic mediating variable between the desire to
aspects of decoupling in future research. decouple and the act of doing it. A survey of
It may be fruitful, for instance, to map 302 senior financial executives showed that
the motivations and conditions that lead executives were less likely to decouple the
88 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

company’s ethics code from strategic deci- effects of such pretence. It is not always
sions when they experienced strong pressure possible to sustain a purely ceremonial adop-
from market stakeholders like suppliers, cus- tion. For instance, Edelman’s (1992) study of
tomers or shareholders (Stevens et al. 2005). organizations that initially decoupled the
Decoupling also became infrequent when Employment Equity and Affirmative Action
the ethics code was already integrated into Legislation revealed that the adopted struc-
daily activities through ethics code training ture eventually affected practice, leading to
programmes. real structural change. Employees that were
Finally, empirical research suggests that hired into the formal structure tried to fulfill
networks and coalitions also mediate the their mandate even if it was meant to be
decoupling response. Westphal and Zajac entirely symbolic. They elaborated formal
(2001) found that top executives who had structures and created visible symbols of
prior experience with decoupling or who had compliance in an effort to interpret what it
social ties to organizations that did, were meant to comply. This finding poses new
more likely to engage in decoupling them- interesting questions about whether or not
selves. A consensus on decoupling formed decoupling is sustainable over time.
among top executives who had no personal Decoupling may lead to full implementation
interest in implementing a new practice, after some time simply because most
which facilitated the decision to decouple. individuals refuse to see themselves as only
On the other side of the equation, Fiss and ceremonial props (Scott 2001). It seems
Zajac (2004) found that decoupling was least that an organizational image that is persist-
likely in companies where powerful and ently inconsistent with how organizational
committed actors cared strongly about members see themselves will eventually
implementation and could influence the provoke a corrective action (Dutton and
organizational response. This finding came Dukerich 1991; Fiss and Zajac 2006).
from a study of over 100 of the largest However, if the adopted structure employs
publicly traded German companies in the no people, e.g. a stock-option programme,
period 1990–2000. Social networks also then time passed may not affect the likeli-
prevented decoupling in a study of recycling hoood of actual implementation. Decoupling
(Lounsbury 2001) and made organizations in may persist over very long periods of time.
another study imitate each others’ corporate It could be fruitful to investigate the condi-
acquisition activities independently of institu- tions under which organizations can continue
tional pressure from the field (Haunschild to decouple their structures from their
1993). These findings are intriguing. They not practices. This is all the more relevant for
only confirm that strategic alliances have a organizations that rely on time to overcome
legitimating effect (Dacin, Oliver and Roy the tendency to decouple, such as in adopting
2007), but they also point to new areas of quotas to eliminate gender or race bias in
investigation in the interface between institu- recruitment.
tional theory and social network studies. One
topic that could be interesting is the effect that
coalitions, networks and strategic alliances
have on the desire and ability of organizations
to engage in decoupling. DISCUSSION –
CAUSAL RELATIONSHIPS
Sustainable over time?
While the idea that actors sometimes only Our review of empirical studies on isomor-
pretend to do something that is socially phism and decoupling revealed that some
desirable is theoretically powerful, it is also aspects of the initial theory formulations
limited because it overlooks the dynamic have received empirical verification, while
ISOMORPHISM, DIFFUSION AND DECOUPLING 89

others have been refined or qualified. The the process of diffusion for the outcome of
past decades of empirical research have isomorphism provides at best a limited test of
consolidated and sharpened the sometimes institutional isomorphism. Moreover, as
initially vague formulations of institutional others have pointed out, the outcome of
theory, but there are also important aspects similarity may also be explained by compet-
that have escaped scrutiny altogether. Most ing theoretical frameworks, particularly
striking is the limited research attention resource dependence theory (Scott 1987;
that has gone into confirming some of the Zucker 1987). It is important to the theoreti-
core causal relationships of institutional cal development of institutional theory that
theory. A number of empirical studies have the relationship between diffusion and iso-
in a piecemeal manner investigated theoreti- morphism be sharpened significantly, both
cal concepts and mechanisms without ques- theoretically and empirically.
tioning or verifying whether these generate A closely related point is that the causal
the theorized outcomes. One case in point is relationship between legitimacy and diffu-
that empirical examinations of institutional sion also needs better articulation. Citing
isomorphism and decoupling have developed Meyer and Rowan (1977), DiMaggio and
along separate lines of inquiry, even though Powell (1983) explained that ‘as an innova-
these concepts are tightly coupled theoreti- tion spreads, a threshold is reached beyond
cally. Somewhat simplistically, inquiries which adoption provides legitimacy rather
associated with institutional isomorphism than improves performance’. While institu-
have explored the external consequences of tional isomorphism presupposes that legiti-
institutional pressures, i.e. organizational macy is the driving force behind diffusion
similarity, whereas decoupling research has (cf. Meyer and Rowan 1977), diffusion
investigated how organizations deal inter- may also occur without any legitimacy-
nally with institutional pressure for conform- seeking behaviour. Not everything that
ity. Before we discuss the relationship diffuses enhances organizational legitimacy.
between the two terms, let us point out For instance, organizations may replace an
some other causal relationships within each existing structure with another one if they
line of inquiry that merit careful attention receive a substantial state subsidy to do so.
in the future. They are neither forced, uncertain, or under
any moral obligation to do so, they simply
see an opportunity to control costs, and it
leads to isomorphism. While many organiza-
Isomorphism
tions may adopt this structure, it is far-
Although institutional isomorphism has fetched to argue that their adoption is an
attracted much research attention, a number example of institutional isomorphism when
of causal relationships have not received the it is not driven by legitimacy concerns.
careful empirical attention that they deserve. Similarly, the causal relationship between
First, there is the relationship between iso- institutionalization and diffusion could bene-
morphism and diffusion. There is a natural fit from more clarification. In the widely
empirical affinity between isomorphism and popular ‘two-stage model’ suggested by
diffusion, but this empirical affinity can be Tolbert and Zucker (1983), diffusion is
theoretically treacherous. The majority of the assumed to lead to institutionalization. This
studies that invoke the concept of institu- finding subsequently became established
tional isomorphism has treated the diffusion within institutional theory as the ‘two-stage
of a particular practice or structure as the out- model’ of institutionalization, which sug-
come variable of interest, under the implicit gests that a practice is introduced as the
assumption that diffusion leads to isomor- result of an efficiency search, and then, as it
phism. A research strategy that substitutes is adopted by others over time, it becomes
90 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

institutionalized and adoption efficiency and core causal relationships to avoid that
ceases to predict further spread (see for institutional theory becomes an ambiguous
instance Westphal, Gulati and Shortell 1997). umbrella-term for assorted organization
However, as pointed out by Scott (1995), a theory. There is currently a tendency for
sharp increase in the rate by which an inno- institutional theory to expand into dimen-
vation is adopted need not reflect more insti- sions of organizational life that have
tutionalization. The two-stage model of traditionally been associated with other theo-
institutionalization thus closely resembles ries. While such expansion may enrich
the standard two-stage diffusion model from institutional theory by making it more com-
the 1950s (Katz, Levin and Hamilton 1963), prehensive, it also draws attention away from
the main difference being that the contagion clarifying core causal relationships. The
phase is renamed institutionalization phase. causal relationships among isomorphism,
An important point is that there are plausible diffusion, legitimacy, and institutionalization
alternative explanations to the second stage need to be strengthened significantly. Herein
in the diffusion phase, such as social- lies an important challenge for future
level learning (Levitt and March 1988) theoretical and empirical research, one that
or other general ‘bandwagon’ processes we think should take precedence over expan-
(Abrahamson and Rosenkopf 1993). To con- sion of the scope of institutional theory.
vincingly demonstrate that a practice diffuses
quickly because it becomes institutionalized,
empirical research must provide other indica-
Decoupling
tors of institutionalization than a simple
increase in the number of adopters Although there is less empirical research on
(Schneiberg and Clemens 2006). It should be decoupling than there is on institutional iso-
shown that adoption is associated with morphism, isomorphic pressures and diffu-
changing norms, collective beliefs or laws, sion, we have seen a surge in attention to
and studies should identify the conditions decoupling in recent years. There is reason to
under which diffusion is causally related to believe that this trend will continue as insti-
institutionalization. tutionalists pay increasing attention to orga-
Future research should also address the nizational and individual factors in the
relationship between isomorphism and field processes of institutionalization and deinsti-
heterogeneity. The growing recognition of tutionalization. Decoupling research may
heterogenity in the institutional environment reveal the seeds of an endogenous model of
calls for reflection on how isomorphism fits institutional change, but first the notion of
with the core claims of institutional theory. If decoupling needs clarification and alignment
organizations become isomorphic with the with isomorphism.
total complexity of their institutional Meyer and Rowan defined decoupling as a
environment, as some studies suggest deliberate disconnection between organiza-
(Goodrick and Salancik 1996; Heimer 1999), tional structures that enhance legitimacy and
then the notion of isomorphism resonates organizational practices that are believed
with predictions of ‘requisite variety’ in within the organization to be technically effi-
early population ecology and systems- cient. Some empirical studies have inter-
oriented theories (Scott 2004). This possi- preted structure to include organizational
bility prompts the provocative (and evoca- elements such as programmes, policies,
tive) question of whether institutional images and decisions. In so doing they came
isomorphism still has a place as a distinct very close to confounding decoupling with
theoretical and empirical concept (cf. Kraatz the more general notion of ‘loose couplings’
and Zajac 1996). We think it does, but insti- (cf. Weick 1979). The theoretical idea of
tutionalists need to sharpen core concepts organizations as loosely coupled systems is
ISOMORPHISM, DIFFUSION AND DECOUPLING 91

more comprehensive in scope than the idea though the pattern is still obscure. Late
of decoupling in institutional theory. Studies adopters seem more likely to engage in
that examine weak links between changing decoupling than early adopters, but why is
organizational practice and organizational this the case? Perhaps organizational or indi-
decision making (e.g. Child, 1972) are thus vidual variables explain this pattern, perhaps
better characterized as studies of loose power relations within a field influence the
coupling than of institutional decoupling. likelihood of decoupling. Is there a ‘middle-
Studies of decoupling need to be distinguish- status conformity’ situation (Philips and
able from studies of loosely coupled organi- Zuckerman 2001) or does a central position
zations in a similar manner to the need for in the field makes it more illegitimate for an
empirical studies of institutional isomor- organization to engage in decoupling? Or is
phism to be distinguishable from diffusion decoupling directly correlated with isomor-
studies. phism in such a way that decoupling
The aspect of decoupling that has received becomes more common once the field
most attention so far is what predicts or reaches a certain point of maturity? Attention
mediates the act of decoupling. As our to the causal relationship between isomor-
review revealed, some organizational vari- phism and decoupling has been almost
ables have already been identified; they entirely neglected so far and should be given
include perceived advantages of decoupling, priority in future research.
internal power dynamics, and concerns The neglect of how isomorphism and
about the organizational image. In addition, decoupling relate to each other may well
empirical research has identified inter- contribute to widening the gap between
organizational variables such as external agentic and non-agentic approaches in insti-
network formations and the power of exter- tutional theory. This gap also increases when
nal stakeholders. We think more attention empirical studies investigate only one level
should be devoted to investigating the of analysis at a time. Individual and organi-
interaction among the already identified zational levels of analysis are most common
variables that seem to predict or mediate in agentic studies whereas non-agentic stud-
institutional decoupling, though it may also ies are more likely to use the field, the indus-
prove fruitful to consider other organiza- try, or the nation as the level of analysis.
tional or inter-organizational variables. The Naturally, the gap will decrease if more
unintended effects of decoupling, such as empirical studies use a multi-level approach
whether it affects morale and fosters cyni- (cf. Schneiberg and Soule 2004). Perhaps the
cism within the organization, certainly merits first step is to theoretically formulate how
attention as well. Furthermore the central isomorphism and decoupling relates to one
prediction of decoupling that organizations another in light of the initial theory formula-
actively avoid evaluation would imply that tions and the past decades of empirical
entire groups of (isomorphic) organizations research. The variables that correlated with
collectively embrace opaqueness in structure decoupling in empirical studies can certainly
and actions. Such a broad prediction would inform this research agenda, in addition to
be interesting to verify empirically, perhaps representing an area where our knowledge of
also to contrast with recent movements decoupling needs to be furthered in future
towards greater transparency and accounta- research.
bility, not least in public management. As
there has been virtually no scholarly atten-
tion paid to this topic, this is an area of Other institutional perspectives
research that should be particularly fruitful.
Some field-level variables also seem to Our review is based on ‘journal institutional-
influence the likelihood of decoupling, ism’, or what can be called mainstream
92 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

institutional organization analysis, where Sahlin-Andersson and Engwall 2003). For


there is a predominance of U.S. research and instance, a historical analysis of Copenhagen
researchers (cf. Mizruchi and Fein 1999). Business School showed that the organiza-
Other incarnations of organizational institu- tion gradually absorbed elements of different
tionalism have developed in parallel to main- myths from their institutional environment,
stream institutionalism, although these are which resulted in an organization that
often less widely known and accessible as embodies five different models that are
they tend to be written in languages other loosely coupled to one another (Borum and
than English. We want to recognize these Westenholz 1995). What appears as
writings because they address some of the decoupling may simply be a multi-faceted
shortcomings of mainstream institutional organization that has conformed to changing
theory, such as an excessive focus on isomorphic pressures over a long period of
mimetic processes, insufficient attention to time while not fully discarding the old insti-
the study of practice, and limited use of qual- tutional elements.
itative methods. As we know of one specific The focus on organizational practice has
type, Scandinavian institutionalism (for an led Scandinavian institutionalism to engage
overview see Czarniawska and Sevón 1996; more readily with practice-oriented litera-
Czarniawska and Sevón 2003), we briefly tures. The notions of loose couplings,
review some of the main points where we see sense-making, actants and translation,
that Scandinavian institutionalism can offer which are drawn from the work of Jim
interesting and complementary perspectives March, Karl Weick, Bruno Latour and
on the core themes of our review. Michel Callon, have importantly influenced
A Scandinavian tradition of institutional- Scandinavian institutionalism. Decoupling
ism emphasizes the study of organizational and translation have received much attention
practice and engages researchers in reflective in local research, perhaps accentuated by the
theorizing that also takes into account the formation in 1988 of the Scandinavian
role of the observer. One line of argument is Consortium for Organizational Research
that isomorphism is an illusory effect of (Scancor) at Stanford University.
particular research strategies that create Another line of inquiry in Scandinavian
distance between the observer and the institutionalism is to apply an interpretive
phenomenon. For instance, when researchers angle to the study of institutions. According
use archival data to study institutional change to interpretivism, practice is always mediated
over a period of several decades, they are by an interpreter, whether the interpreter is
more likely to see something that looks like the object of study or the researcher conduct-
isomorphism than if they had collected ing the study. For instance, research showed
observational data in a contemporary organi- that maverick film directors rely on their own
zation. In other words, the further distanced strategic interpretations when they decide to
the observer is, in terms of abstracting or differentiate themselves from other film
simplifying the object under study, the more directors in the organizational field of film-
isomorphism there will seem to be (Forssell making (Alvarez et al. 2005). Similarly, key
and Jansson 2000). This stance would players in the organizational field of Danish
explain the observation that the clearest evi- hospitals strategically reinterpreted the same
dence of isomorphism is found within the institutionalized belief to fit their own
world systems literature, where the unit of political preferences (Borum 2004). The
analysis is highly aggregated. In contrast, act of interpretation is not always conscious
case-based research provides excellent evi- and strategic, it is often implicitly governed
dence for the variation in organizational by institutionalized beliefs and norms. A
response to institutional pressures non-Scandinavian study on school teachers
(for instance Djelic and Quack 2003; or in California showed, for instance, that
ISOMORPHISM, DIFFUSION AND DECOUPLING 93

teachers’ preexisting beliefs and practices that merit careful attention in future research.
implicitly mediated the nature of the message Disproportionate attention has been devoted
that teachers delivered in the classroom to studying the relationship between isomor-
(Coburn 2004). The non-strategic approach phic pressure and diffusion, to the neglect of
to interpretation, which is informed by Actor the associated outcomes of decoupling
Network Theory, is evident in the literature and/or isomorphism. An effect of this is that
on translation, which posits that ideas and some of the causal relationships that define
practices undergo change every time they institutional theory have largely escaped
are applied in a new organizational con- empirical inquiry. This limitation weakens
text (Czarniawska and Joerges 1996; institutional theory and restricts its extension
Sahlin-Andersson 1996). These interpretive into other levels of analysis that carry with
studies suggest that decoupling is an act of them new independent and intervening
interpretation that is shaped by contextual variables. The greatest risk, as we see it, is
and institutionalized factors. This line of that institutionalism becomes a catch-all
inquiry has gained international recognition phrase for various organization theories.
in recent years in parallel to increased Institutionalists put the explanatory power of
interest in how organizations respond to institutional theory at risk if they do not
institutional pressures. prioritize to validate the core claims of insti-
tutional theory before adding new layers of
complexity to its core claims.
An interesting discovery was that surpris-
CONCLUSION ingly little attention has been devoted to
examining how isomorphism and decoupling
This chapter presented the theoretical formu- interact with each other. Organizations sup-
lations of isomorphism and decoupling and posedly adopt new organizational structures
carefully reviewed the empirical research to enhance their legitimacy, and then decou-
that has been conducted on these two central ple these same structures from their practices
theoretical concepts in institutional theory. to maintain technical efficiency in a compet-
These are central concepts because they set itive quest for survival. We see real potential
institutional theory apart from other organi- in combining and juxtaposing what we know
zation theories. Isomorphism plays an about isomorphism and decoupling to
important role in organization theory as an develop a stronger and more dynamic theory
alternative to efficiency-based explanations of institutions. As we noted in our review,
of organizational change (Scott 1987; Zucker many interesting questions have never been
1987), and decoupling provides an explana- asked. For instance, does decoupling become
tion for why organizations seem to be more frequent when a field becomes more
constantly reforming (Brunsson and Olsen isomorphic or mature? Perhaps the possibil-
1993). In a more general sense, these two ity of decoupling is crucial for obtaining a
concepts have also moved structuralist and high level of isomorphism in an organization
cultural/symbolical understandings of organ- field. It is certainly possible that such
ization closer to one another (Lounsbury and insights could provide answers to the vexing
Ventresca 2003; Scott 2001). question of how best to measure isomor-
The first contribution of this chapter was phism. It may also open an intriguing avenue
to delineate how empirical studies have for studying endogenous institutional change
carved out the initial formulations of isomor- processes without resorting to methodologi-
phism and decoupling respectively. A related cal individualism.
contribution was to highlight some ambigu- Another striking finding of this review of
ous causal relationships that pertain to empirical studies is the conflation between
theories of isomorphism and decoupling and institutional studies and diffusion studies.
94 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

We noted that there is a close but compli- Will the organizational field level become
cated relation between diffusion (i.e. the depopulated, or will other research commu-
spread of things) and isomorphism. In many nities migrate to this area of inquiry and take
cases diffusion is a prerequisite for isomor- on the challenging task of clarifying the link
phism, but diffusion need not always lead to between different levels of analysis?
isomorphism; conversely all that looks simi- A related fundamental question is whether
lar need not be the result of diffusion isomorphism is a useful and distinct theoret-
(cf. Zucker 1987). Isomorphism and diffu- ical concept if we believe in a world of
sion have often been conflated in empirical fragmented institutional environments. For
studies where the spread of something is instance, is institutional isomorphism a more
treated as an outcome synonomous with iso- useful concept than that of ‘requisite variety’
morphism. It is commonplace to contrast that was proposed in the 1960s? If this
mimetic isomorphic pressure with efficiency question is answered in the negative, then we
and/or resource dependence theory as an need to reflect upon how important the theo-
explanation for the spread of a particular retical concept of isomorphism is to institu-
form or practice (see for instance the well- tional theory. Conversely, would the notion
cited studies of Fligstein 1985; Haveman of legitimacy still have meaning and be
1993; Palmer, Jennings and Zhou 1993). The sufficiently distinct without the assumption
conflation of institutionalism and diffusion is of some form of homogeneity in the
unfortunate because diffusion studies include organizational field?
a larger set of phenomena where practices
are not necessarily adopted for legitimacy
gains. In contrast, legitimacy is central to the
kind of diffusion that pertains to institution- REFERENCES
alism, whether the outcome is isomorphism
or decoupling. We thus argue that the rela- Abrahamson, E., and Rosenkopf, L. 1993.
tionship between institutionalism and diffu- ‘Institutional and competitive bandwagons:
sion needs more careful empirical and Using mathematical modeling as a tool to
theoretical parsing. explore innovation diffusion.’ Academy of
A final topic that is worth noting is the Management Review 18: 487–517.
growing recognition that institutional envi- Alvarez, J. L., Mazza, C., Pedersen, J. S., and
Svejenova, S. 2005. ‘Shielding idiosyncrasy
ronments are heterogeneous, just as are orga-
from isomorphic pressures: Towards optimal
nizational responses to institutional pressure. distinctiveness in European filmmaking.’
This trend makes for a lot of heterogeneity, Organization 12: 863–888.
possibly more than the theory can sustain. Aurini, J. 2006. ‘Crafting legitimation projects:
While there are a number of good studies that an institutional analysis of private education
argue forcefully for the need to include het- businesses.’ Sociological Forum 21: 83–111.
erogeneity in institutional analysis, we find Beck, N., and Walgenbach, P. 2005. ‘Technical
precious little work that steps back from this efficiency or adaptation to institutionalized
argument and considers the implications of expectations? The adoption of ISO 9000
heterogeneity at various levels. One question standards in the German mechanical engi-
that arises is what will happen to studies of neering industry.’ Organization Studies 26:
841–866.
organizational fields as the gap widens
Beverland, M., and Luxton, S. 2005.
between agentic and non-agentic institution- ‘Managing integrated marketing communi-
alists. The former are migrating ‘down’ to the cation (IMC) through strategic decoupling:
organizational level or the individual level of How luxury wine firms retain brand
analysis, while the latter group is migrating leadership while appearing to be wedded
‘up’ into higher levels of analysis like institu- to the past.’ Journal of Advertising:
tional logics and national business systems. 103–116.
ISOMORPHISM, DIFFUSION AND DECOUPLING 95

Borum, F. 2004. ‘Means-end frames and the norms.’ Academy of Management Journal
politics and myths of organizational fields.’ 40: 46–81.
Organization Studies 25: 897–922. Deephouse, D. L. 1999. ‘To be different, or to
Boxenbaum, E. and Battilana, J. 2005. be the same? It’s a question (and theory) of
‘Importation as innovation: Transposing strategic balance.’ Strategic Management
managerial practices across fields.’ Strategic Journal 20: 147–166.
Organization 3: 355–383. DiMaggio, P. J. 1988. ‘Interest and agency in
Brunsson, N. 2002. The Organization of institutional theory.’ Pp. 3–23 in Institutional
Hypocrisy. Oslo: Abstract Liber. Patterns and Organizations: Culture and
Brunsson, N., and Olsen, J. P. 1993. The Reform- Environment, ed. L. G. Zucker. Cambridge,
ing Organization. London and New York: Mass: Ballinger Publishing Company.
Routledge. DiMaggio, P. J., and Powell, W. W. 1983. ‘The
Child, J. 1972. ‘Organization structure and iron cage revisited: Institutional isomorphism
strategies of control: A replication of the and collective rationality in organizational
Aston study.’ Administrative Science fields.’ American Sociological Review 48:
Quarterly 17(2): 163–178. 147–160.
Christensen, S., and Molin, J. 1995. ‘Origin and Djelic, M.-L., and Quack, S. 2003. Globalization
transformation of organizations.’ In The and Institutions: Redefining the Rules of the
Institutional Construction of Organizations: Economic Game. Cheltenham, UK: Edward
International and Longitudinal Studies, ed. Elgar.
R. W Scott and S. Christensen. Thousand Dutton, J., and Dukerich, J. 1991. ‘Keeping an
Oaks: Sage. eye on the mirror: Image and identity in
Coburn, C. E. 2004. ‘Beyond decoupling: organizational adaptation.’ Academy of
Rethinking the relationship between the Management Journal 34(3): 517–554.
institutional environment and the class- Edelman, L. B. 1992. ‘Legal ambiguity and sym-
room.’ Sociology of Education 77: 211–244. bolic structures: Organizational mediation of
Czarniawska, B., and Joerges, B. 1996. ‘Travels civil rights law.’ American Journal of
of ideas’ Pp. 13-47 in Translating Organi- Sociology 6: 1531–1576.
zational Change, ed. B. Czarniawska and G. Edelman, L. B., Abraham, S. E., and Erlanger, H.
Sevo– n. Berlin: Walter de Gruyter. S. 1992. ‘Professional construction of law:
Czarniawska, B., and Sevón, G. 1996. The inflated threat of wrongful discharge.’
‘Introduction.’ Pp. 1–13 in Translating Law and Society Review 26: 47–94.
Organizational Change, ed. B. Czarniawska Elsbach, K,, and Sutton, R. I. 1992. ‘Acquiring
and G. Sevón. New York: Walter de Gruyter. organizational legitimacy through illegiti-
Czarniawska, B., and Sev ón, G. (Eds.). 2003. mate actions: A marriage of institutional
The Northern Lights: Organization Theory in and impression management theories.’
Scandinavia. Copenhagen: Copenhagen Academy of Management Journal 35:
Business School Press. 699–738.
D’Aunno, T., Succi, M., and Alexander, J. A. Fiss, P., and Zajac, E. J. 2004. ‘The diffusion of
2000. ‘The role of institutional and market ideas over contested terrain: The (non)adop-
forces in divergent organizational change.’ tion of a shareholder value orientation
Administrative Science Quarterly 45: 679–703. among German firms.’ Administrative
Dacin, M. T., Oliver, C., and Roy, J.-P. 2007. Science Quarterly 49: 501–534.
‘The legitimacy of strategic alliances: An insti- Fiss, P., and Zajac, E. J. 2006. ‘The symbolic
tutional perspective.’ Strategic Management management of strategic change: Sense-
Journal 28(2): 169–187. giving via framing and decoupling.’
Dacin, M. T., Goodstein, J., and Scott, W. R. Academy of Management Journal 49(6):
2002. ‘Institutional theory and institutional 1173–1193.
change: Introduction to the special research Fligstein, N. 1985. ‘The spread of the multidivi-
forum.’ Academy of Management Journal sional form among large firms 1919–1979.’
45: 45–58. American Sociological Review 50: 377–391.
Dacin, T. 1997. ‘Isomorphism in context: the Forssell, A., and Jansson, D. 2000. Idéer Som
power and prescription of institutional Fängslar. Recept För En Offentlig Reformation.
96 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

(trans.: Ideas that imprison: a recipe for Ingram, P., and Simons, T. 1995. ‘Institutional
reform of public management). Malmö: Liber. and resource dependence determinants of
Galaskiewicz, J., and Burt, R. S. 1991. responsiveness to work-family issues.’
‘Interorganizational contagion in corporate Academy of Management Journal 38:
philantropy.’ Administrative Science 1466–1482.
Quarterly 36: 88–105. Jonsson, S. 2003. ‘Trickle-up and trickle-down:
George, E., Chattopadhyay, P., and Sitkin, S. B. Institutionalized norms and the spread of
2006. ‘Cognitive underpinnings of institu- new ideas.’ Academy of Management Best
tional persistence and change: A framing Paper Proceedings 2003.
perspective.’ Academy of Management Katz, E., Levin, M. L. and Hamilton, H. 1963.
Review 31: 347–365. ‘Traditions of research in the diffusion of
Goodrick, E., and Salancik, G. R. 1996. innovation.’ American Sociological Review
‘Organizational discretion in responding to 28: 237–252.
institutional practices: Hospitals and Kostova, T., and Roth, K. 2002. ‘Adoption of
cesarean births.’ Administrative Science an organizational practice by subsidiaries of
Quarterly 40: 1–28. multinational corporations: Institutional and
Greenwood, R., and Hinings, C. R. 1996. relational effects.’ Academy of Management
‘Understanding radical organizational Journal 45(1): 215–233.
change: Bringing together the old and the Kraatz, M. S., and Zajac, E. J. 1996. ‘Exploring
new institutionalsm.’ Academy of the limits of the new institutionalism: the
Management Review 21: 1022–1054. causes and consequences of illegitimate
Greve, H. R. 1998. ‘Managerial cognition and organizational change.’ American
the mimetic adoption of market positions: Sociological Review 61: 812–836.
What you see is what you do.’ Strategic Levitt, B., and March, J. G. 1988. ‘Organizational
Management Journal 19: 967–988. learning.’ Annual Review of Sociology 14:
Greve, H. R. 1996. ‘Patterns of competition: 319–340.
The diffusion of a market position in radio Levitt, B., and Nass, C. 1989. ‘The lid on the
broadcasting.’ Administrative Science garbage can: Institutional constraints on
Quarterly 41: 29–60. decision making in the technical core of col-
Guillen, M. F. 2001. ‘Is globalization civilizing, lege-text publishers.’ Administrative Science
destructive or feeble? A critique of five key Quarterly 34: 190.
debates in the social science literature.’ Lounsbury, M. 2001. ‘Institutional sources of
Annual Review of Sociology 27: 235–260. practice variation: Staffing college and uni-
Hallet, T., and Ventresca, M. 2006. ‘How insti- versity recycling programs.’ Administrative
tutions form: Loose coupling as mechanism Science Quarterly 46: 29–56.
in Gouldner’s patterns of industrial bureau- Lounsbury, M., and Ventresca, M. 2003. ‘The
cracy.’ American Behavioral Scientist 49: New structuralism in organizational theory.’
908–924. Organization 10: 457–480.
Haunschild, P. R. 1993. ‘Interorganizational imi- March, J. G., and Olsen, J. P. 1976. Ambiguity
tation: The impact of interlocks on corporate and Choice in Organizations. Bergen:
acquisition activity.’ Administrative Science Universitetsforlaget.
Quarterly 38: 564–592. Meyer, J. W., Boli, J., Thomas, G., and Ramirez,
Haveman, H. A. 1993. ‘Follow the leader: F. 1997. ‘World society and the nation state.’
Mimetic isomorphism and entry into new American Journal of Sociology 103:
markets.’ Administrative Science Quarterly 144–181.
38: 593–627. Meyer, J. W., and Rowan, B. 1977. ‘Institutionalized
Heimer, C. A. 1999. ‘Competing institutions: organizations: Formal structure as myth and
Law, medicine, and family in neonatal inten- ceremony.’ American Journal of Sociology
sive care.’ Law and Society Review 33: 17–66. 83: 340–363.
Ingram, P., and Clay, K. 2000. ‘The choice- Meyer, J., Scott, R. W., and Strang, D. 1987.
within-constraints new institutionalism and ‘Centralization, fragmentation, and school
implications for sociology.’ Annual Review of district complexity.’ Administrative Science
Sociology 26: 525–546. Quarterly 32(2): 186–202.
ISOMORPHISM, DIFFUSION AND DECOUPLING 97

Mezias, S. J. 1990. ‘An institutional model of Sahlin-Andersson, K. 1996. ‘Imitating by edit-


organizational practice: Financial reporting ing success: The construction of organiza-
at the Fortune 200.’ Administrative Science tional fields and identities.’ Pp. 69–92 in
Quarterly 35: 431–457. Translating Organizational Change, ed. B.
Mizruchi, M., and Fein, L. C. 1999. ‘The social Czarniawska and G. Sevón. Berlin: De
construction of organizational knowledge: A Gruyter.
study of the uses of coercive, mimetic and Sahlin-Andersson, K., and Engwall, L. 2003.
normative isomorphism.’ Administrative Expansion of Management Knowledge:
Science Quarterly 44: 653–683. Carriers, Flows and Sources. Stanford:
Mohr, J. W. 2005. ‘Implicit terrains: Meaning, Stanford University Press.
measurement, and spatial metaphors in Schneiberg, M. 2002. ‘Organizational hetero-
organizational theory,’ in Constructing geneity and the production of new forms:
Industries and Markets, ed. J. F. Porac and Politics, social movements and mutual com-
M. Ventresca. New York: Elsevier. panies in American fire insurance,
Oliver, C. 1988. ‘The collective strategy frame- 1900–1930.’ Pp. 39–89 in Research in the
work: An application to competing predic- Sociology of Organizations, ed. M. Lounsbury
tions of isomorphism.’ Administrative and M. Ventresca: JAI Press.
Science Quarterly 33: 543–561. Schneiberg, M., and Clemens, E. S. 2006. ‘The
Oliver, C. 1991. ‘Strategic responses to institu- typical tools for the job: Research strategies
tional processes.’ Academy of Management in institutional analysis.’ Sociological Theory
Review 16: 145–179. 3: 195–227.
Orru, M., Biggart, W. N., and Hamilton, G. G. Schneiberg, M., and Soule, S. A. 2004.
1991. ‘Organizational isomorphism in East ‘Institutionalizaiton as a contested, multi-
Asia.’ Pp. 361–389 in The New level process: The case of rate regulation in
Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis, American fire insurance,’ in Social Move-
ed. W. W. Powell and P. J. DiMaggio. ments and Organization Theory: Building
Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press. Bridges, ed. J. Davis, D. McAdam, R. W. Scott,
Palmer, D., Jennings, D. and Zhou, X. 1993. and Z. Mayer. Cambridge: Cambridge
‘Late adoption of the multidivisional form by University Press.
large U.S. corporations: institutional, political Scott, R. W. 1987. ‘The adolescence of institu-
and economic accounts.’ Administrative tional theory.’ Administrative Science
Science Quarterly 38: 100–131. Quarterly 32: 493–511.
Perrow, C. 1986. Complex Organizations: A Scott, R. W. 1991. ‘Unpacking institutional
Critical Essay. Glenview, Ill: Scott Foresman. arguments.’ Pp. 164–183 in The New
Philips, D. J., and Zuckerman, E. W. 2001. Instituionalism in Organizational Analysis,
‘Middle-status conformity: Theoretical ed. W. W Powell and P. J. DiMaggio.
restatement and empirical demonstration in Chicago, IL: The University of Chicago Press.
two markets.’ American Journal of Sociology Scott, R. W. 1995. Institutions and Organi-
107: 379–429. zations. London: Sage.
Powell, W. W., and DiMaggio, P. J. 1991. Scott, R. W. 2001. Institutions and Organi-
‘Introduction.’ Pp. 1–38 in The New Institu- zations. Newbury Park, CA: Sage.
tionalism in Organizational Analysis. Chicago, Scott, R. W. 2004. ‘Reflections on a half-cen-
IL: University of Chicago Press. tury of organizational sociology.’ Annual
Rao, H., Greve, H. R., and Davis, G. F. 2001. Review of Sociology 30: 1–21.
‘Fool’s gold: social proof in the initiation and Scott, R. W., and Meyer, J. W. 1983. ‘The
abandonment of coverage by wall street organization of societal sectors.’ Pp. 1–16 in
analysts.’ Administrative Science Quarterly Organizational Environments: Ritual and
46: 502–526. Rationality. Beverly Hills, CA: Sage.
Ruef, M., and Scott, R. W. 1998. ‘A multidi- Scott, R. W. 1994. ‘Environmental linkages and
mensional model of organizational legiti- organizational complexity: Public and private
macy: hospital survival in changing schools.’ Pp. 137–159 in Institutional Envi-
institutional environments.’ Administrative ronments and Organizations: Structural
Science Quarterly 43: 877–904. Complexity and Individualism, ed. R. W. Scott
98 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

and J. W., Meyer. London, New Delhi: Sage Weick, K. 1979. The Social Psychology of
Publications. Organizing. New York: McGraw-Hill.
Seidman, W. H. 1983. ‘Goal ambiguity and Westphal, J. D., Gulati, R., and Shortell, S. M.
organizational decoupling: The failure of 1997. ‘Customization or conformity? An insti-
‘rational systems’ program implementation.’ tutional and network perspective on the con-
Educational Evaluation and Policy Analysis 5: tent and consequences of TQM adoption.’
399–413. Administrative Science Quarterly 42: 366–394.
Stevens, J. M., Steensma, H. K., Harrison D. A., Westphal, J. D., and Zajac, E. J. 1994.
and Cochran, P. L. 2005. ‘Symbolic or sub- ‘Substance and symbolism in CEOs’ long-
stantive document? The influence of ethics term incentive plans.’ Administrative Science
codes on financial executives’ decisions.’ Quarterly 39(3): 367–390.
Strategic Management Journal 26: 181–195. Westphal, J. D., and Zajac, E. J., 1997. ‘Defections
Strang, D., and Soule, S. A. 1998. ‘Diffusion in from the inner circle: Social exchange, reci-
organizations and social movements: From procity and the diffusoin of board independ-
hybrid corn to poison pills.’ Annual Review ence in U.S. corporations.’ Administrative
of Sociology 24: 265–290. Science Quarterly 42: 161–183.
Suchman, M. C. 1995. ‘Managing legitimacy: Westphal, J. D., and Zajac, E. J. 1998. ‘The sym-
Strategic and institutional approaches.’ bolic management of stockholders: Corporate
Academy of Management Review 20: governance reforms and shareholder reac-
571–610. tions.’ Administrative Science Quarterly 43:
Sutton, J. R., Dobbin, F., Meyer, J., and Scott, 127–153.
R. W. 1994. ‘The legalization of the work- Westphal, J. D., and Zajac, E. J. 2001. ‘Decoup-
place.’ American Journal of Sociology 99: ling policy from practice: The case of stock
944–971. repurchase programs.’ Administrative Science
Tolbert, P. S., and Zucker, L. G. 1983. Quarterly 46(2): 202–228.
‘Institutional sources of change in the formal Zilber, T. B. 2002. ‘Institutionalization as an
structure of organizations: The diffusion of interplay between actions, meanings, and
civil service reform.’ Administrative Science actors: The case of a rape crisis center in
Quarterly 28: 22–39. Israel.’ Academy of Management Journal 45:
Townley, B. 2002. ‘The role of competing 234–254.
rationalities in institutional change.’ Zucker, L. G. 1987. ‘Institutional theories of
Academy of Management Journal 45: organization.’ Annual Review of Sociology
163–179. 13: 443–464.
3
Institutional Logics
Patricia H. Thornton and William Ocasio

INTRODUCTION findings. Last, we critique the literature on


institutional logics and suggest how the
The phrase, ‘institutional logic’ has become approach can be used to further advance the
somewhat of a buzz-word. Buzz words are study of organizations and institutions.
over used; as a result their meanings often get The research on institutional logics repre-
distorted and overextended and they burn-out sents an impressive variety of empirical con-
of existence. Mizruchi and Fein (1999) texts, from thrifts (Haveman and Rao, 1997),
showed in the institutional theory literature higher education publishing (Thornton and
how meanings get distorted and then taken Ocasio, 1999), health care organizations
for granted. To avoid misunderstandings of (Scott et al., 2000), colleges and universities
the institutional logic concept and to build on (Gumport, 2000), consumer research
research in this genre, now is the time to (Moorman, 2002), mutual funds (Lounsbury,
reflect on definitions and the theoretical and 2002), French cuisine (Rao, Monin, and
methodological contributions this perspec- Durand, 2003), equity markets (Zajac and
tive brings to the analysis of institutions. Westphal, 2004), accounting firms (Thornton,
We begin by defining the concept of an Jones, and Kury, 2005), occupational prestige
institutional logic and how it emerged as part rankings (Zhou, 2005), and architects (Jones
of the development of institutional theory and Livne-Tarandach (Forthcoming), among
since the 1970s. Second, we illustrate the others. Given the incredible diversity of
institutional logics approach as both a meta- research topics, what are institutional logics?
theory and a method of analysis. Third, we
present a select review of the literature
emphasizing how the institutional logics
approach makes headway in addressing sev- DEVELOPMENT OF INSTITUTIONAL
eral limitations and tensions identified by THEORY
scholars of institutional analysis. In this
review we focus on an analysis of the To understand the concept of institutional
implicit and explicit social mechanisms logics we must first place it within the con-
employed in these studies, not on the text of institutional theory and institutional
description or strength of their empirical analysis. The study of institutions has a long
100 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

history in organizational analysis, beginning legitimacy rather than efficiency as an


with Selznick’s (1948, 1949, 1957) empirical explanation for the success and survival of
analyses of organizations and the institu- organizations (Tolbert and Zucker, 1983).
tional environment, and Parson’s (1956) Friedland and Alford’s (1991) seminal
theorizing, which emphasized how institu- essay, together with empirical work by
tions function to integrate organizations with Haveman and Rao (1997), Thornton and
other organizations in society through uni- Ocasio (1999), and Scott et al. (2000),
versalistic rules, contracts, and authority. created a new approach to institutional analy-
In the 1970s a new approach to institu- sis which posited institutional logics as
tional analysis emerged with Meyer and defining the content and meaning of institu-
Rowan (1977) and Zucker (1977), who high- tions. While the institutional logics approach
lighted the role of culture and cognition in shares with Meyer and Rowan (1977),
institutional analysis. From a macro perspec- Zucker (1977), and DiMaggio and Powell
tive, Meyer and Rowan (1977) emphasized (1983, 1991) a concern with how cultural
the role of modernization in rationalizing rules and cognitive structures shape
taken-for-granted rules, leading to isomor- organizational structures, it differs from them
phism in the formal structures of organiza- in significant ways. The focus is no longer on
tions. Organizations had to conform to the isomorphism, whether in the world system,
requirements of external environments for society, or organizational fields, but on the
legitimacy, meaning that parts of organiza- effects of differentiated institutional logics
tions had to be loosely coupled from their on individuals and organizations in a larger
technical core. Meyer and his colleagues variety of contexts, including markets, indus-
were concerned with the importance of tries, and populations of organizational
rationality in the account of western culture, forms. Institutional logics shape rational,
and viewed the development of formal orga- mindful behavior, and individual and organi-
nizational structures as part of world society zational actors have some hand in shaping
and its cultural system (Meyer, Boli, and and changing institutional logics (Thornton,
Thomas, 1987; Meyer, Boli, Thomas, and 2004). By providing a link between
Ramirez, 1997). From a micro perspective, institutions and action, the institutional
Zucker (1977) also emphasized the taken- logics approach provides a bridge between
for-granted nature of institutions, and the role the macro, structural perspectives of Meyer
of cultural persistence as a measure of insti- and Rowan (1977) and DiMaggio and
tutionalization. Powell (1983) and Zucker’s more micro,
DiMaggio and Powell (1983) extended process approaches. Situated forms of
Meyer and Rowan’s (1977) focus on isomor- organizing are linked with beliefs and prac-
phism from the societal level to the level of tices in wider institutional environments in
organizational fields. With their emphasis on ways that address the critique of isomor-
coercive, normative, and mimetic sources of phism and diffusion studies (Hasselbladh and
isomorphism, DiMaggio and Powell’s Kallinikos, 2000).
approach led to an explosion of empirical
analysis. In DiMaggio and Powell (1983),
the effects of cognition are mainly viewed
through mimetic isomorphism – focusing on DEFINITIONS OF INSTITUTIONAL
mindless behavior in response to cultural LOGICS
rationalization. Subsequently, what they
termed ‘the new institutionalism’ also We present definitions of the institutional
became largely identified with a rejection logics approach and then return to how it dif-
of rationality as an explanation for organiza- fers from the new institutionalism. The term
tional structure, and an emphasis on institutional logics was introduced by Alford
INSTITUTIONAL LOGICS 101

and Friedland (1985) to describe the contra- thereby contingent set of rules, premiums
dictory practices and beliefs inherent in the and sanctions that men and women in partic-
institutions of modern western societies. ular contexts create and recreate in such a
They describe capitalism, state bureaucracy, way that their behavior and accompanying
and political democracy as three contending perspective are to some extent regularized
institutional orders which have different and predictable. Put succinctly, an institu-
practices and beliefs that shape how individ- tional logic is the way a particular social
uals engage political struggles. world works.’ Jackall, like Friedland and
Friedland and Alford (1991) further devel- Alford, views institutional logics as embod-
oped the concept in the context of exploring ied in practices, sustained and reproduced by
the interrelationships between individuals, cultural assumptions and political struggles.
organizations, and society. They view But the emphasis for Jackall is on the norma-
institutions as supraorganizational patterns of tive dimensions of institutions and the
activity rooted in material practices and intra-institutional contradictions of contem-
symbolic systems by which individuals and porary forms of organization; in contrast the
organizations produce and reproduce their focus for Friedland and Alford is on
material lives and render their experiences symbolic resources and the inter-institutional
meaningful. Rejecting both individualistic, contradictions of the inter-institutional
rational choice theories and macro structural system, for example between the market and
perspectives, they posited that each of the the family and the professions and the
institutional orders has a central logic that corporation.
guides its organizing principles and provides Building on the developments of the
social actors with vocabularies of motive and concept by both Jackall (1988) and Friedland
a sense of self (i.e., identity). These practices and Alford (1991), Thornton and Ocasio
and symbols are available to individuals, (1999: 804) defined institutional logics as
groups, and organizations to further elabo- ‘the socially constructed, historical patterns
rate, manipulate, and use to their own advan- of material practices, assumptions, values,
tage (Friedland and Alford, 1991: 232, 248, beliefs, and rules by which individuals
251–252). produce and reproduce their material subsis-
For Friedland and Alford (1991) the core tence, organize time and space, and provide
institutions of society – the capitalist market, meaning to their social reality.’ According to
the bureaucratic state, families, democracy, this definition institutional logics provide a
and religion – each has a central logic that link between individual agency and
constrain both the means and ends of individ- cognition and socially constructed institu-
ual behavior and are constitutive of individu- tional practices and rule structures. While
als, organizations, and society. However, Friedland and Alford’s approach is both
while institutions constrain action they also structural and symbolic, and Jackall’s is both
provide sources of agency and change. The structural and normative, Thornton and
contradictions inherent in the differentiated Ocasio’s (1999) approach to institutional
set of institutional logics provide individuals, logics integrates the structural, normative,
groups, and organizations with cultural and symbolic as three necessary and comple-
resources for transforming individual identi- mentary dimensions of institutions, rather
ties, organizations, and society. than separable structural (coercive), norma-
A separate, albeit related, conception of tive, and symbolic (cognitive) carriers, as
institutional logics was developed by Jackall suggested by alternative approaches
(1988). In his ethnographic analysis of ethi- (e.g., Scott, [1995] 2001).
cal conflicts in corporations, Jackall (1988: While varying in their emphasis, the vari-
112) defines institutional logic as ‘the ous definitions of institutional logics all
complicated, experientially constructed, and presuppose a core meta-theory: to understand
102 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

individual and organizational behavior, it The eventual result was that first manufactur-
must be located in a social and institutional ing, then marketing succumb in power and
context, and this institutional context both control to those in finance. Updating his data
regularizes behavior and provides opportu- on corporate control, Fligstein (2001) devel-
nity for agency and change. The various oped a shareholder value conception of
dimensions of the meta-theory are further control as distinct from the earlier finance
elaborated in Section IV. conception – shifting influences away from
the corporate venue to that of the market.
For Fligstein (1985, 1987, 1990), individ-
Precursors ual executives are the primary carriers of the
contending conceptions of control. However,
Research sometimes referred to as logics of these conceptions may not be explicitly
action provides precursors to the institutional institutionalized. For example, Ocasio and
logics approach – similarly being based on Kim (1999) suggest that the alternative
an interdependent set of logics that provide conceptions of control were never institu-
some context for social influence on actors’ tionalized in the organizational field, as none
actions in a domain. We highlight the exam- of them became dominant. While Fligstein’s
ples that illustrate different logics of action work is similar to the institutional logics
operating either within or between institu- approach because of its implicit interplay of
tional orders – Fligstein’s (1987, 1990) three institutional sectors – the professions, the
conceptions of control within corporate gov- corporation, and the State, the emphasis on
ernance, DiMaggio’s (1991) two conflicting the utilitarian individual and the power-
models to organize the field of art museums, oriented organization motivated subsequent
and Boltanski and Thevenot’s ([1986] 1991) work leading to the institutional logics
multiple modes of justification to evaluate approach that more systematically integrated
agreements situated between six different conflict and cultural perspectives.
worlds. In reviewing these examples note the In another example of logics of action,
relatively early and similar dates of publica- DiMaggio (1991) develops ideal types of
tion and that all the examples involve an organizing the organizational field of art
analysis of conflicting logics without focus- museums, the Gilman and the Data models,
ing on isomorphism. to understand how competing cultural
Fligstein (1990) identified three competing models formed the basis of a power struggle
conceptions of control that guide the gover- to redefine the field; a struggle between the
nance of large industrial firms: the manufac- elite upper classes and their social circle of
turing, marketing, and finance conceptions. collectors and curators and the new class of
For Fligstein, both intra-organizational power museum professionals fueled by the expan-
struggles (Fligstein, 1987) and field-level sion of higher education in the fine arts. The
struggles to control market competition and case reveals the structuration of organiza-
contest state legislation shaped the formation tional fields is a contested process between
of these competing conceptions, or logics of these two cultural models. However, there is
action. Executives’ views on how to best run an evolutionary ordering with the creation of
the corporation were selectively influenced a standardized body of knowledge, the
by their experience in the corporation. organization of professional associations,
Employees’ ability to fight it out among each and the collective definition of a field, being
other in the rise to the top of the corporation historically prior to the diffusion of the Data
occurs in a Chandlerian (Chandler, 1962) Model.
world of significant economic and industrial Boltanski and Thevenot (1991) apply a
change, organizational and professional inno- taxonomy of cultural repertoires that present
vation, coupled with a powerful State. different justifications of worth to understand
INSTITUTIONAL LOGICS 103

how people disagree, compromise, and role of institutions and institutionalization in


conclude more or less lasting agreements. shaping logics than the approaches of
Identified with the tool kit school, they view Friedland and Alford (1991) or Jackall
culture as a social resource that individuals use (1988). While sharing with the institutional
strategically, culture is more than motivating logics perspective a focus on culture as a
action – it also justifies it. Boltanski and source of agency (Swidler, 1986; DiMaggio,
Thevenot illustrate in a variety of scenarios of 1997), these precursors differ from an institu-
interactions that what is legitimate changes tional logics approach by deemphasizing the
depending on the context in which it is negoti- structural and normative constraints imposed
ated and evaluated, the ideal types being six by institutional logics.
different worlds – the inspired, domestic, fame,
civic, market, and industrial. Compromises are
less fragile when there is groundwork to
embed them in the specific arrangements of META-THEORY OF INSTITUTIONAL
these worlds assuming that the embedding is LOGICS
congruent with the worlds. Transposing or
putting together elements extracted from the The institutional logics approach incorpo-
descriptions of the various worlds of worth can rates a broad meta-theory on how institu-
cause actors to be placed in incongruent or tions, through their underlying logics of
compromising situations, depending on the action, shape heterogeneity, stability and
particular scenario. An intuitively awkward change in individuals and organizations. Not
example illustrates their point. ‘At home, to get all aspects of the meta-theory have been
his children’s attention, a father presents a incorporated into every application of the
glowing picture of his ability to direct a project institutional logics perspective, due to differ-
at work …. The first combines elements bor- ences among authors in emphasis, and par-
rowed from the domestic world (a father and tially to the limitations of the journal
his children), from the world of fame (attract publication process. Here we propose five
attention, present a glowing picture), and from principles that in our judgment underlie the
the industrial world (ability to direct a project) meta-theory and provide opportunities for
(Boltanski and Thevenot, 1991: 227). This is an theoretical development and refinement.
incongruous transfer of worth from different
worlds since fathers do not receive attention
based on industrial worth through the eyes of Embedded agency
their children.
Fligstein’s (1985, 1987, 1990), DiMaggio’s Perhaps the core assumption of the institu-
(1991) and Boltanksi and Thevenot’s tional logics approach is that the interests,
([1986] 1991) approaches all posit the identities, values, and assumptions of indi-
existence of conceptions, models, or logics viduals and organizations are embedded
at a supraorganizational level, and either within prevailing institutional logics.
implicitly or explicitly emphasize the role Decisions and outcomes are a result of the
of culture in shaping and interpreting indi- interplay between individual agency and
vidual and organizational activities. These institutional structure (Jackall, 1988;
examples also illustrate the interrelationship Friedland and Alford, 1991; Thornton and
between individuals, organizations, and the Ocasio, 1999). While individual and organi-
environment and how logics interpenetrate zational actors may seek power, status, and
multiple levels of analysis from the social economic advantage, the means and ends of
psychological to the levels of the organi- their interests and agency are both enabled
zational field and societal sector. These and constrained by prevailing institutional
approaches are less focused, however, on the logics (Giddens, 1984; Sewell, 1992).
104 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

This assumption, which over time has levels as an important mechanism for organi-
become known as embedded agency (Seo zational and institutional change.
and Creed, 2002; Battilana, 2006;
Greenwood and Suddaby, 2006), distin-
guishes an institutional logics approach from Society as an inter-institutional
rational choice perspectives on institutions
system
(North, 1990; Ingram and Klay, 2000) which
presume individualistic interests. This The main innovation of Friedland and Alford
assumption also distinguishes an institutional (1991) is to conceptualize society as an inter-
logics approach from macro structural institutional system. To locate behavior in a
perspectives which emphasize the primacy of context requires theorizing an inter-institu-
structure over action (DiMaggio and Powell, tional system of societal sectors in which
1983; Meyer et al., 1987; Meyer et al., 1997; each sector represents a different set of
Schneiberg and Clemens, 2006) and expectations for social relations and human
Parsonian (Parsons 1956) perspectives on and organizational behavior. In Friedland
institutions, which posit a separation of insti- and Alford’s words, the capitalist market,
tutional from economic or technical sectors bureaucratic state, democracy, nuclear
(e.g., Meyer and Scott, 1983). family, and Christian religion are key institu-
The embeddedness of agency presupposes tional sectors, each with its own distinct logic.
the partial autonomy of individuals, organi- Thornton (2004: 44–45) elaborated this
zations, and the institutions in society in any typology in a review of a series of empirical
explanation of social structure or action studies to include six sectors – markets,
(Friedland and Alford, 1991). Society corporations, professions, states, families,
consists of three levels – individuals compet- and religions.
ing and negotiating, organizations in conflict Viewing society as an inter-institutional
and coordination, and institutions in contra- system allows sources of heterogeneity and
diction and interdependency. All three levels agency to be theorized and to be observed
are necessary to adequately understand soci- from the contradictions between the logics of
ety; the three levels are nested (embedded) different institutional orders. There is not just
when organizations and institutions specify one source of rationality, as in world systems
progressively higher levels of constraint and approaches (Meyer et al., 1997), but multiple
opportunity for individual action. sources. Rather than positing homogeneity
Rather than privileging one level over and isomorphism in organizational fields, the
another, this perspective suggests that while institutional logics approach views any con-
individual and organizational action is text as potentially influenced by contending
embedded within institutions, institutions are logics of different societal sectors. For exam-
socially constructed and therefore consti- ple, the health care field is shaped by the
tuted by the actions of individuals and organ- institutional logics of the market, the logic of
izations (Berger and Luckmann, 1967). This the democratic state, and the professional
suggests that cross-level effects are critical. logic of medical care (Scott et al., 2000).
One limitation, however, is that most The inter-institutional system enables two
research, whether theoretical or empirical, advances in institutional analysis. First, it is
tends to emphasize one level over another. non-deterministic, that is no institutional
Friedland and Alford (1991), despite their order with its accompanying principles of
direct call for multiple levels, emphasized the organization and logics of action is accorded
role of the societal level. Recent work on causal primacy a priori. Second, the inter-
institutional entrepreneurship (Battilana, institutional system provides researchers
2006; Greenwood and Hinnings, 2006) with an understanding of the institutional
has incorporated the relationship between foundations of categories of knowledge.
INSTITUTIONAL LOGICS 105

Key constructs in the analysis of organiza- utilities – and these values and utilities cannot
tion, such as efficiency, rationality, participa- be traded off as simple economic alternatives.
tion, and values are not neutral, but are Thus, an important underlying assumption is
themselves shaped by the logics of not whether motivation and action are rational
inter-institutional system. As posited by or irrational; instead the argument is how the
Friedland and Alford (1991: 260) ‘Categories comparative conflict and conformity of insti-
of knowledge contribute to and yet depend tutional logics (which are both material and
upon the power of institutions which make cultural) influence human and organizational
them possible. Without understanding the behavior (Thornton, 2002).
historical and institutional specificity of the This assumption reflects a cultural turn in
primary categories of analysis, social scien- the study of conflict and agency. This
tists run the risk of elaborating the rationality cultural turn is motivated by the thorny ques-
of institutions they study, and as a result tion of how individual agents know they have
become actors in their reproduction.’ economic or political struggles on their
hands and what is an appropriate way to
respond to them. For example, Thornton and
The material and cultural Ocasio (1999) and Thornton (2004) showed
that resource competition was actually
foundations of institutions
greater in higher education publishing in the
A key assumption of an institutional logics era of the editorial logic – but this competi-
perspective is that each of the institutional tion was interpreted differently and
orders in society has both material and cul- responded to in a non-conflictual manner.
tural characteristics (Friedland and Alford, With the rise of a market logic, resource
1991). For example, both the family and reli- competition, although less significant, had
gion, while typically not considered part of greater effects on organizational actions and
the economic sphere, are directly involved in decisions. Stinchcombe (2002: 429) has
the production, distribution, and consump- commented around this issue – needing
tion of goods and services (Becker, 1976). culture to define the meaning of power and
Similarly, markets, while often not consid- competition – viewing it as a causal sequenc-
ered part of the cultural sphere, are directly ing problem. His argument is that if power is
shaped by culture and social structure, theorized as a first-order construct in
including networks of social relationships as explaining change, independently of culture,
well as structures of power, status, and dom- two problems need to be addressed. First,
ination (Granovetter, 1985). Rather than power is created in the course of action: it
privileging material or cultural explanations does not occur prior to the action that it
of institutions, an institutional logics per- explains. Second, the decision to use power
spective recognizes that institutions develop is an intentional, strategic choice; however, it
and change as a result of the interplay is not always possible for actors to know the
between both of these forces. cultural framing or menus of available
In explaining human behavior and organi- options in advance of any action. Thus,
zational structure, Friedland and Alford instrumental political theories of action may
(1991) argued that theories which ‘retreat be incomplete explanations because the
from society,’ – emphasizing market mecha- necessary sequence of events is unlikely
nisms to aggregate individual utilities and to occur. Consequently, cultural explana-
preferences, organizational competition, tions are necessary adjuncts to structural
technology, and resource dependence – begin explanations.
to fail. Instead, institutional sectors, for In making way for the role of culture
example families, professions, states, and in shaping action, institutional logics
religions locate the origins of values and incorporate both the symbolic and the
106 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

normative components of culture. Following on resource dependencies and political


Geertz (1973) and Douglas (1986), interests.
DiMaggio and Powell (1991) and Friedland An institutional logics approach views
and Alford (1991) highlighted the symbolic norms as drawn from experience and exem-
and cognitive dimensions of institutions and plars of the institution (Jackall, 1988; Ocasio,
institutional logics. But symbolic and cogni- 1999). Norms imply ambivalence about uni-
tive explanations of institutions and institu- versalistic principles, with both dominant and
tional logics are incomplete without also subsidiary norms co-existing. This suggests a
incorporating the normative dimensions probabilistic, rather than a deterministic view
(Hirsch, 1997; Mizruchi and Fein, 1999). of adherence to dominant norms of behavior,
Sociologists, rejecting the strong view of and the identification of specific contingen-
internalization of universalistic values and cies where subsidiary norms prevail.
cultural norms proposed by Parsons (1951)
and early Merton (1957), have been reluctant
to rely on social norms as an explanation for
Institutions at multiple levels
behavior. Even DiMaggio and Powell (1983),
in discussing the normative forces driving The institutional logics approach as meta-
isomorphism, emphasized the role of formal theory provides tremendous capacity to
education, legitimating authorities, and develop theory and research across multiple
professional networks, with an unclear role levels of analysis. For Friedland and Alford
for social norms, per se. An institutional (1991) the focus was on societal-level logics
logics approach, in contrast, emphasizes how and their effects on individuals and organiza-
institutions provide social actors with a tions. But the meta-theory that has emerged
highly contingent set of social norms is broader, and institutional logics may
(Jackall, 1988), where behavior is driven develop at a variety of different levels, for
not by a logic of consequences but by a example organizations, markets, industries,
logic of appropriateness (March and inter-organizational networks, geographic
Olsen, 1989). communities, and organizational fields. This
The requirement of norms as a critical flexibility allows for a wide variety of mech-
dimension of institutions and their underly- anisms to be emphasized in research and
ing logics does not imply universalism, theoretical development and may be one
moral behavior by individuals, nor deeply reason the term institutional logics has
internalized values, all part of Parson’s caught on among scholars (Kuhn, 1962).
(1951) conceptions of norms. An institu- Theoretical mechanisms are elements of
tional logics approach shares with theory that operate at a different level of
Granovetter (1985) and others the over- analysis (e.g., individuals or organizational
socialized critique of Parsons, while at the fields), than the main phenomenon being the-
same time suggesting that ignoring norms orized about (e.g., organizations or groups).
implies an under-socialized view of individ- To identify the effects of mechanisms across
ual and organizational behavior. A focus on levels of analysis makes the theory more pre-
identification (see below) as the mechanism cise as well as more general (Stinchcombe,
by which cultural norms exert their effects 1991). Therefore, to apply the institutional
over individuals and organizations logics meta-theory it is critical that the level
(Kelman, 1956, 2006; O’Reilly and of analysis at which institutionalization
Chatman, 1996) distinguishes an institutional occurs be clearly specified, whether at a
logics approach from an over-socialized societal level (Friedland and Alford, 1991),
conception of institutions that focuses on or at other levels.
internalization and value commitments and For example, Haveman and Rao (1997), in
an under-socialized conception that focuses their study of the coevolution of institutions
INSTITUTIONAL LOGICS 107

and organizations in the California thrift societal level. Jackall argues that the formal
industry, studied how with the rise of bureaucratic logic, as characterized by Weber
Progressivism, changes in institutional logics ([1922] 1978), had little affinity with
at the societal level affected the formation of American individualistic affinities and
distinct organizational forms at the industry cultural values, with the hybrid logic of
level. In particular, their analysis shows how patrimonial bureaucracy thereby emerging.
plans that embodied bureaucratic logics and Thornton and Ocasio (1999) focus on the
rational decision making were more likely to formation of industry-level institutional
thrive than those that embodied a community logics in higher education publishing. They
logic and mutual cooperation among actors. propose that industries are a relevant bound-
The emphasis here is on institutional logics ary for establishing institutional logics
at the societal level affecting the selection of because producers in an industry establish a
alternative forms at the organizational level. common identity through social compar-
A secondary, and less developed, aspect of isons, status competition, and structurally
the coevolutionary process in the paper sug- equivalent network positions (White, 1992).
gests that as organizational forms that Their analysis and the subsequent research
embody a particular institutional logic evolve by Thornton (2001, 2002) focus on the
and become institutionalized at the industry effects of shifts, at the industry level, from an
level, the corresponding societal-level insti- editorial logic to a market logic. While focus-
tutional logics further evolves and becomes ing on industry-level logics that both emerge
further institutionalized. from and sustain market competition, these
The emphasis on societal-level institutions logics do not emerge in the industry de novo,
is illustrated by the work of Bhappu (2000), but are shaped by higher-order societal
which draws on anthropological analysis of professional and market logics. The link
the ancient Japanese family system to argue between industry-level logics and the logics
how the institutional order of the family is of the inter-institutional system is further
the origin of the institutional logic of developed by Thornton (2004).
Japanese corporate networks. Scott et al. Research on institutional logics adopting a
(2000) examine how societal-level profes- field-level perspective has emphasized the
sional, government, and managerial-market existence of competing logics within the
logics shape the transformation of the health field. For example, in a qualitative analysis
care organizational field, from one domi- of U.S. academic health centers, Kitchener
nated by professional logics to one where (2002) explores the effects of competing
the three logics co-exist and no single one managerial and professional logics on the
dominates. responses to merger initiatives. Reay and
In Jackall’s (1988) ethnographic analysis, Hinings (2005) adopt a similar approach in
the emphasis is on institutionalization at the their analysis of structural change in
organizational level. Here the focus in on the Canadian health care organizations.
structures of managerial careers and how Greenwood and Suddaby (2006) focus
they shape the formation of a managerial instead on contradictions between institu-
ethos that shapes decision making and action tional logics in organizational fields and
in organizations. The formal structures of the suggest that boundary bridging organiza-
organizations combine with institutionalized tions are sources of change in institutional
practices of fealty and patronage to create an logics (see below). Lounsbury (2007)
institutional logic termed patrimonial examines competing trustee and professional
bureaucracy. While clearly focusing on orga- logics in the mutual fund industry. In his
nizational-level institutionalized practices, analysis geographic communities are also a
Jackall’s analysis suggests how these source of institutionalization of logic, as
practices also reflect cultural forces at the Boston and New York are centers of the
108 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

trustee and professional logics respectively, Zajac and Westphal’s analysis of historical
leading to different patterns of organizational contingency in financial markets (2004) is
change in the two areas. notable in viewing markets themselves as
The variety of levels of analysis studied shaped by institutional forces. The paper
suggests the fecundity of the institutional finds that the emergence of an agency
logics perspective. The breadth of the meta- perspective in the 1980s led to historical
theory may have encouraged imprecision in shifts in stock market response to stock
research, and it could be inferred that any repurchases, from an unfavorable reaction,
logic or interpretive scheme, at any level of consistent with a professional logic, to a
analysis, may be characterized as an institu- favorable one, consistent with an agency
tional logic. We suggest otherwise. logic. The paper suggests that the market’s
Institutional logics are more than strategies reaction to particular corporate practices are
or logics of action as they are sources of not, as financial economists contend, simply
legitimacy and provide a sense of order and a function of the inherent efficiency of such
ontological security (Giddens, 1984: Seo and practices, but are influenced by the prevail-
Creed, 2002). Research on competing ing institutional logic.
institutional logics, as some of the work on However, note with the current rise of reli-
organizational fields described above, often is gion in world discourse that institutional
not precise on the level of which logics logics, both in their elaboration and relative
become institutionalized, or whether they pattern of dominance between institutional
should be considered institutional logics at all. orders, are not simply an evolutionary or
linear model of development driven by scien-
tific progress or market rationalization. Here
the institutional logics approach departs dis-
Historical contingency
tinctly from Meyer and his colleagues’ work
Historical contingency is a key meta-theoret- noted earlier on modern rationalization. For
ical assumption of the institutional logics example, Thornton, Jones, and Kury (2005)
approach. In general this assumption is con- illustrate other models of the historical
sistent with institutional theory, which focuses contingency of institutional logics that show
attention on how larger environments affect cyclical or punctuated equilibrium functional
individual and organizational behavior. While forms in their comparison of the cases of
the six institutional orders of the inter-institu- accounting and architecture.
tional system in western societies previously Many studies reveal findings that are valid
identified have remained influential, empiri- in one historical time period but not in others.
cal observation also informs us that they Thornton (2004: 127) presents a meta-analy-
differed in development and importance over sis partitioning the findings on the higher
time. For example, modern societies have education publishing studies by universal
greater emphasis on corporate and state influ- and particular effects. Founder and owner-
ences and earlier societies in general empha- ship effects were found to be universal across
sized family and religion to a larger extent. In time, whereas relational and structural effects
particular, during the last 30 years the promi- were particular to a historical period in which
nence of market logics has been found in an institutional logic prevailed. Many find-
multiple studies in various contexts, including ings typically predicted by resource depend-
Thornton and Ocasio (1999) in higher educa- ence and economic theories are found to be
tion publishing, Scott et al. (2000) in health historically contingent. Note that the models
care, Lounsbury (2002) in financial interme- in this meta-analysis controlled for differ-
diation, Zajac and Westphal (2004) in equity ences in organization age, size, and resource
markets, and Meyer and Hammerschmidt competition and other macro economic
(2004) in public management. variables. Note also that the meta-analysis
INSTITUTIONAL LOGICS 109

design controls for differences in industry, contingency is a focus of the analysis


product market, data set, population and (Thornton, 2004: 126–127). They also can
sampling methods, and statistical modeling accommodate data at multiple levels of
procedures. The universal founder effect analysis, for example at the individual, orga-
suggests the persistence of individual entre- nizational, and environmental – making it
preneurs or leaders to hang tough on a logic possible to partition material from cultural
of action, regardless of contradictory logics effects (DiMaggio, 1994). The challenge of
prevailing in their surrounding environment. measuring cultural effects is often
The objective of recognizing historical approached by examining how one or more
contingency as a meta-theoretical assump- of the institutional orders of the inter-institu-
tion is to explore if the effects of economic, tional system are changing in its strength of
political, structural, and normative forces influence on individual and organizational
affecting individuals and organizations are behavior. These types of studies require
indeed historically contingent. Moreover, the identifying a scientific boundary to draw a
goal is not to develop universal theories of population or sample for hypothesis testing –
organizational behavior and structure but to such as an industry, market, or profession.
examine whether such theories, often Note that the organizational field concept is
assumed to be universal through time and problematic in this sense, unless it can be
space, are instead particular to historical time defined, for example as a geographic
and cultural environments (Thornton, 2004: community, positional community, i.e. CEOs
130–133). of Fortune 500, or inter-organizational
network.
The development of interpretive methods
enriches the possibilities of the types of data
INSTITUTIONAL LOGICS AS and data gathering methods available for
METHOD OF ANALYSIS researchers to examine the content and
meaning of institutions. Scott et al. (2000),
Theory and methods go hand-in-hand and the for example. used content analysis of publi-
meta-theoretical principles reviewed in the cations to identify the key terms important to
preceding section have been examined the actors of the professions and corporate
through the creative development of meth- institutional orders of the health care system
ods. While many social science researchers and then measured the frequency of vocabu-
have been skeptical of cultural effects laries associated with the institutional orders,
(DiMaggio, 1994), in our view researchers signaling the emergence and decline of these
are rising to the challenges of measuring the alternative institutional logics.
effects of content, meaning, and change in Phillips and Hardy (2002: 55) define
institutions using the institutional logics methods from discourse theory and describe
perspective. In this endeavor, we comment how they have been borrowed to further
on the use of event history analysis, interpre- develop institutional theory and methods.
tive methods, triangulation, and ideal types. Data sources include, for example, inter-
Foundational studies have combined event views, focus groups, archival documents and
history (Tuma and Hannan, 1984) and inter- records, naturally occurring conversations,
pretive methods, for example from archival political speeches, newspaper articles,
records (Haveman and Rao, 1997), personal novels, stories, cartoons, and photographs.
interviews (Thornton and Ocasio, 1999), and Methods of analysis include, for example,
content analysis of professional journals genealogy, ethnography, conversation analy-
(Scott et al., 2000). Event history models typ- sis, content analysis, narrative analysis,
ically use historical time (not organization critical discourse analysis, and rhetorical
age) as the clock, particularly when historical analysis that make use of a variety of ‘texts,’
110 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

including spoken words, pictures, symbols, Swedberg (2005: 3), in drawing from
and cultural artifacts among others. Suddaby Weber, gives an example. ‘When the wood-
and Greenwood (2005), for example, used cutter brings down his axe on the wood, it
rhetorical analysis of vocabularies (words) to can be a case of wage labor, provision for
expose contradictory institutional logics one’s household, or form of recreation – and
embedded in historically different which one it is depends on the meaning with
understandings of professionalism to explain which the action is invested.’ In the Appendix
the multidisciplinary partnership as a new we include examples of ideal types devel-
organizational form. oped from the analysis of the effects of insti-
While this vibrant resurrection and devel- tutional logics in three industries, higher
opment of qualitative methods strengthens education publishing, accounting, and
the capacity to interpret meanings, we architecture.
caution that the strength of the foundational DiMaggio’s (1991: 271) analysis of the
studies of the institutional logics perspective two models of organizing art museums is a
has been on triangulation of types of data and precursor to bringing back the use of ideal
methods of analysis – being reliant on both types in institutional analysis. His categories
qualitative and quantitative methods. One on the Y axis focused on the mission, defini-
method that integrates interpretive and tion of art, legitimate perception, education,
hypothesis testing approaches is the use of major publics, control, strategy, building, and
ideal types. living artists – showing how the X axis spec-
Ideal types are a method of interpretive ifies the Gilman and Data models varied on
analysis for understanding the meaning that these universal dimensions. Rao et al. (2003)
actors invest their actions with. They were also used ideal types in their characterization
first developed by the classic theorists as a of classical and nouvelle French cuisine to
theoretical tool to facilitate intelligible understand how new logics displaced old and
comparisons (Weber, 1922). Researchers ushered in new role identities. Their
have further developed this method of analy- categories on the Y axis examine the dimen-
sis to suggest testable hypotheses (Thornton sions of culinary rhetoric, rules of cooking,
and Ocasio, 1999). archetypal ingredients, role of the chef, and
In theory building, ideal types require the organization of the menu – showing how the
development of formal typologies composed X axis defined the two characteristics of
of two parts: (a) the description of ideal types classical and nouvelle cuisines. However,
and (b) the set of assertions that relate the what is the causal connection between
ideal types to the dependent variable (Dotty DiMaggio’s and Rao et al.’s ideal types and
and Glick, 1994). While often derived from the inter-institutional system? Should we, for
empirical observation, ideal types are not for example, intuit that the Gilman Model was
describing an organizational field, but influenced by the institutional logics of the
instead are theoretical models for comparing family and the Data Model by the logics of
the effects of various meanings in a location the professions and the state?
with a definable boundary. They do not Thornton and Ocasio (1999: 808–809) and
precisely conform to reality because of Thornton (2004) explicitly anchor the higher
deliberate simplification to afford compara- education publishing ideal types in the
tive analysis and multidimensional classifi- domains (orders) of the inter-institutional
cation of phenomena not restricted by the system – revealing their origins. Their
events of the selected cases. Ideal types categories on the Y axis examined form of
assign a hypothetical meaning that can be capitalism, organizational identity, legiti-
used as a yardstick to compare and contrast macy, authority structures, mission, focus of
hypothesized and actual meaning and attention, strategy, logics of investment, and
behavior. rules of succession – showing how the X axis
INSTITUTIONAL LOGICS 111

specifying the editorial and market logic 1991). Collective identities also emerge
varied on these general elements. among populations of organizational
Once derived from interview and archival forms (Haveman and Rao, 1997; Carroll
data they pushed the standards further and Hannan, 2000), market competitors
by externally validating the ideal types (Porac et al., 1989; White, 1992; Peteraf
with publishers’ experiences and their use and Shanley, 1997; Thornton and
in the Stanford University Publishers Ocasio, 1999), and industry associations
College.1 (Aldrich and Fiol, 1994; King and Lenox,
2000).
As collective identities become institution-
alized, they develop their own distinct insti-
HOW LOGICS SHAPE INDIVIDUAL tutional logic, and these logics prevail within
AND ORGANIZATIONAL ACTION the social group (Jackall, 1998). These
effects of institutional logics are emphasized,
Collective identities and identification among others, in the work of Haveman and
A mechanism by which institutional logics Rao (1997), on the theory of moral senti-
exert their effects on individuals and organi- ments embodied in the collective identities of
zations is when they identify with the collec- organizational forms; in Thornton and
tive identities of an institutionalized group, Ocasio (1999)’s shift from an editorial logic
organization, profession, industry or popula- to a market logic in the collective identity of
tion (Tajfel and Turner, 1979; March and competitors in the higher education
Olsen, 1989). A collective identity is the publishing market; in Jones and Livne
cognitive, normative, and emotional connec- Tarandach’s (Forthcoming) rhetorical
tion experienced by members of a social strategies of architects based in the institu-
group because of their perceived common tional logics of business, profession, and
status with other members of the social group state that focus attention on distinct
(Polleta and Jasper, 2001). Collective competencies – servicing clients, building
identities emerge out of social interactions great architecture, or managing facilities, and
and communications between members of in Lounsbury’s (2002) analysis of collective
the social group (White, 1992). As individu- identities embodied in professional
als identify with the collective iden- associations in the field of finance. In
tity of the social groups they belong to all of these cases, albeit at different
they are likely to cooperate with the levels of analysis, identification with the
social group (Tyler, 1999; Brickson, 2000), respective institutional logics occurs
abide by its norms and prescriptions directly, as the identification with the
(March and Olsen, 1989; Kelman, 2006), collective is equivalent to the identifi-
and seek to protect the interests of the collec- cation with the institutional logic prevailing
tive and its members against contending in the collective, whether they are organiza-
identities (Tajfel and Turner, 1979; tional forms, market competitors, or profes-
White, 1992). sional associations, or any other social
Individuals are members of multiple social grouping.
groups with a collective identity, including
professions and occupations (Abbott, 1988; Contests for status and power
Fine, 1996; Glynn, 2000), gender, racial and The contests for status and power are rela-
ethnic groups (Cerulo, 1997; Lamont and tively universal mechanisms for individual
Molnar, 2002), social movements (Benford and organizational actions. However, an
and Snow, 2000; Rao et al., 2003), and indi- institutional logics perspective suggests that
vidual organizations (Selznick, 1957; Albert these mechanisms are conditioned by pre-
and Whetten, 1985; Dutton and Dukerich, vailing institutions (Fligstein, 1996;
112 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Thornton and Ocasio, 1999; Lounsbury and a market logic created a shift from status
Ventresca, 2003). While power and status driven by reputation within business practice
differences are present in all organizations, to reputation driven by normative conformity
researchers can identify the sources of power to increasingly mathematical economics.
and status, their meaning and consequences Professional finance associations led the
by understanding how these power and status transformation to a market logic in this field.
differences are associated with the prevailing New professions such as money management
institutional logic. Institutional logics shape and securities analysis helped diffuse
and create the rules of the game, the means- new financial theories such as portfolio and
ends relationships by which power and status risk management, and status within the
are gained, maintained, and lost in organiza- field became increasingly determined by
tions (Jackall, 1988; Ocasio, 1999; familiarity and expertise with new financial
Lounsbury and Ventresca, 2003). Social theories. As social actors gained status and
actors rely on their understandings of institu- position by their reliance on financial theo-
tional logics in the competition for power ries, the market logic gained prominence in
and status and in doing so generate the the field.
conditions for the reproduction of prevailing Zhou (2005) relies on an institutional logic
logics. perspective to explain occupational prestige
For Jackall (1988), competition for power, ranking. Building on Weber’s argument that
status, and position in organizations shapes social statuses or social honors are related,
the creation and reproduction of a patrimo- but distinct from one’s economic resources
nial bureaucratic logic in U.S. corporations. or structural positions, Zhou is searching for
Managers, driven by career concerns, estab- an explanation of how a hierarchical ordering
lish and maintain a system of patronage and of occupations must be recognized through a
fealty, where strong social ties to those in meaning system shared by members of the
position of authority determine power and same community. He proposes an institu-
privilege in organizations. Achieving career tional logic of social recognition to explicate
success requires social actors to play by the the causal mechanisms. What is appropriate
rules, with language use and symbolic and legitimate must be seen as transcend-
management serving to reproduce the formal ing self-interests and group boundaries, and
structure, while promotion patterns parallel be accepted by a large audience. Overall,
the patrimonial structure, serving to occupation prestige should vary system-
reproduce the informal status hierarchies and atically with the basis for making legitimate
power structures. claims and with group membership
Thornton and Ocasio (1999) focus on the as a function of their inclusion into the
link between institutional logics and power realm of a shared institutional logic (Zhou,
structures. They find that under an editorial 2005: 98).
logic, publishers’ means and ends are shaped
by author-editor relationships, and power Classification and categorization
structures are determined by organization A key mechanism by which institutional
size and structure. Under a market logic, logics shapes individual cognition is through
publishers’ means - end relationships are social classification and categorization
shaped by resource competition and acquisi- (DiMaggio, 1997). Cognitive psychologists
tions, and power structures are determined by emphasize the importance of categories in
competition in the product market and the shaping individual cognition (e.g., Rosch,
market for corporate control. 1975; Medin, 1989). While psychologists
Lounsbury (2002) focuses on status who study categories typically emphasize the
competition and status mobility in the field study of categories of objects occurring in
of finance. A shift from a regulatory logic to nature, the classification and categorization
INSTITUTIONAL LOGICS 113

of social and organizational categories is Categorization processes have been partic-


determined by social institutions (Douglas, ularly central to work on institutional logics
1986; Searle, 1995). Given the institutional- that focuses on logics residing in competing
ization of categories, individuals take for organizational forms (Haveman and Rao,
granted that the categories of organizing 1997; Rao et al., 2003). Distinct categories of
activity such as CEO, return on assets, forms are shaped by changes in societal level
human resources, corporate governance, institutional logics (Haveman and Rao,
multidivisional structures, patents, 1997). At the organizational field level,
restaurants, to name but a few common sub- Rao et al. (2003) explore how changes in
jects of study, are not categories that exist in the categories of French cuisine led to
nature but socially constructed, institutional self-categorization by industry entrepreneurs
categories (Berger and Luckmann, 1967). and triggered institutional transformation.
Institutional logics provide agents within Rao et al. (2005) explored how organiza-
organizations with socially constructed tional change occurs through bricolage
systems of classifications that constitute among categories of organizational products
categories of social actors (Mohr and associated with alternative institutional
Duquenne, 1997), organizational forms logics.
(Haveman and Rao, 1997), products Research has also explored how changing
(Lounsbury and Rao, 2004), and organiza- logics lead to changes in the meaning of
tional agendas (Ocasio and Joseph, 2005). existing categories. Ruef (1999) explores the
Changes in institutional logics lead to the shift to a market logic in the heath care field
creation of new categories (Rao et al., 2003) by examining the changing systems of
and to changes in meaning of existing cate- categories that underlie discourse among
gories (Ruef, 1999; Ocasio and Joseph, technical, managerial, and policy-oriented
2005). Categories, as a basic unit of cogni- health care professionals. Ruef’s analysis
tion, do not imply mindless cognition, as do focuses on the relationships among linguistic
schemas and scripts, but are a necessary categories and finds that a historical shift
component of all mindful, agentive behavior. in logics results in changes in the meaning
Mohr and his collaborators have of underlying categories of organ-
emphasized the link between systems of izational forms. With the rise of a market
categories and institutional logics. Mohr and logic there is increased integration of
Duquenne (1997) analyze the changing insti- issues of financing and risk bearing across
tutional logics in poverty relief by examining the various forms in the organizational field,
how they provide a different system of and less focus across the spectrum on
classification of the poor (distressed, desti- issues of access. With the rise of a market
tute, fallen, deserving, homeless, indigent, logic the meaning of a hospital or a
misfortunate, needy, poor, stranger, and health maintenance organization shifts, as do
worthy) and the categorization of organiza- other organizational forms, with less differ-
tional practices (giving advice, giving food, entiation among forms in their focus on
giving money, paying a person to chop wood, financing.
placing a relief applicant in an asylum,
and so on). Mohr and Guerra-Pearson Attention
(Forthcoming) studied how categories of Contemporary perspectives on organiza-
actors, organizational forms, and organizing tional attention emphasize how organiza-
activities varied by competing institutional tional responses to economic and social
logics. Breiger and Mohr (2004) develop factors are mediated by the attention of
network methodologies among systems of organizational decision makers (Ocasio,
categories to empirically measure institu- 1995, 1997). Theoretical and empirical
tional logics. research provides key mechanisms to explain
114 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

how institutions moderate organizational organizational attention to market forces that


attention. are salient under a market logic, but not
In a theoretical analysis of how organiza- under an editorial logic. Thornton (2004:
tions respond to economic adversity, Ocasio 44–45) further developed the role of institu-
(1995) proposed that institutional logics tional logics in structuring attention by
affect the allocation of attention to alternative linking these organization and industry level
schemas for perceiving, interpreting, evaluat- analyses to societal-level institutional logics.
ing, and responding to environmental Relying on content analysis, Glynn and
situations. According to theory of allocation Lounsbury (2005) examine the shifts in focus
of attention, institutional logics provide indi- of attention by newspaper critics of the
viduals and organizations with a set of rules Atlantic Symphony Orchestra from an
and conventions – for deciding which prob- aesthetic logic prior to a strike at the orches-
lems get attended to, which solutions get tra to a market logic post-strike. Consistent
considered, and which solutions get linked to with the effects of institutional logics on
which situtations (March and Olsen, 1976). attention, they find that pre-strike newspaper
Ocasio (1997) suggests two mechanisms by critics, in their reviews, focus attention on the
which institutions structure attention: (1) by virtuosity and musical interpretation (associ-
generating a set of values that order the legit- ated with an aesthetic logic) and post-strike
imacy, importance, and relevance of issues critics increased their attention to ticket
and solutions; and (2) by providing decision sales, production of recordings, and audience
makers with an understanding of their reactions (consistent with a market logic).
interests and identities. These interests and The ascendancy of the market logic did not
identities generate in turn a set of decision imply, however, a rejection of aesthetic con-
premises and motivation for action. cerns, but the blending of the two logics.
Thornton and Ocasio (1999) developed the In his study of competing logics in the
role of industry-level institutional logics in mutual funds industry, Lounsbury (2007)
structuring attention in organizational relies on attention as a mechanism to show
decisions on executive succession. The how non-growth funds and Boston-based
theory was further developed in application funds focus attention on the issue of product
to decisions on acquisitions (Thornton, costs, while growth funds and New York-
2001), and the rise of multidivisional based funds focus attention on the issue of
structures (Thornton, 2002) in the higher fund performance. The empirical results sup-
education publishing industry. The core of port this argument, demonstrating how the
the argument in these empirical studies is effects of market forces are contingent on
that institutional logics focus the attention of prevailing organizational logics, as mediated
decision makers on issues and solutions that through processes of attention.
are consistent with prevailing logics.
Institutional logics focus attention on issues
and solutions through a variety of mecha-
nisms, including determining their appropri- CHANGE IN INSTITUTIONAL
ateness and legitimacy, rewarding certain LOGICS
forms of political behavior in organizations,
shaping the availability of alternatives, and ‘How can actors change institutions if their
selectively focusing attention on environ- actions, intentions, and rationality are all
mental and organizational determinants of conditioned by the very institution they wish
change. A key finding of these empirical to change’ (Holm, 1995: 398). The institu-
analyses is that the effects of resource tional logics approach sheds light on this
competition and resource dependencies are problem of embedded agency by conceptual-
not universal effects, but are contingent on izing society as an inter-institutional system
INSTITUTIONAL LOGICS 115

in which logics are characterized by cultural also symbolic. To use an analogy to the
differentiation, fragmentation, and contradic- bricoler (Levi-Strauss, 1966), institutional
tion (DiMaggio, 1997). This differentiation, entrepreneurs creatively manipulate social
fragmentation, and contradiction is relationships by importing and exporting
evident both within and between institu- cultural symbols and practices from one
tional orders (Friedland and Alford, 1991). institutional order to another. In theory, the
We focus on three mechanisms of change: different social locations of the institutional
institutional entrepreneurs, structural orders bring to light different cultural tools
overlap, event sequencing, and a fourth for institutional entrepreneurs (Thornton,
topic, often an antedecent or conse- 2004). Note the focus on cultural resources
quence of change – competing institutional as distinct from material resources; culture
logics. being something people strategically use,
deploy, and mobilize. This focus is consistent
Institutional entrepreneurs with the meta-theory of the institutional
Institutional entrepreneurs are the agents that logics approach which views culture as both
create new and modify old institutions a motivation as well as a justification of
because they have access to resources that action.
support their self-interests (DiMaggio, There are several mechanisms that institu-
1988). By definition, institutional entrepre- tional entrepreneurs use to manipulate cul-
neurs can play a critical role in perceiving tural symbols and practices, for example
institutional differentiation, fragmentation, story telling (Zilber, 2006), rhetorical
and contradiction by virtue of the different strategies (Suddaby and Greenwood 2005;
social locations they may occupy in the inter- Jones and Livne-Tarandach, forthcoming),
institutional system and in taking advantage and tool kit approaches (Swidler 1986;
of the opportunities it presents for institu- Boltanski and Thevenot 1991).
tional change (Thornton, 2004). Fligstein Suddaby and Greenwood (2005) showed,
(1997), for example, describes how entrepre- for example, in their study of organizational
neurs perceive and exploit contradictions in forms in the accounting industry, how institu-
institutional logics to further their self- tional entrepreneurs used ‘rhetorical strate-
interest. DiMaggio (1988: 14–15) argues that gies’ to reinterpret and manipulate prevailing
the creation of institutions requires an symbols and practices. Rhetorical strategies
institutionalization project in which the or ‘institutional vocabularies’ were used by
claims of institutional entrepreneurs are sup- entrepreneurs to affirm or discredit the dom-
ported by existing or newly mobilized actors inant institutional logic which defined the
who stand to gain from the success of the legitimacy of organizational forms. To
institutionalization project (DiMaggio, discredit an institutional logic and bring
1991). The challenge for the institutional about institutional change, entrepreneurs
entrepreneur is to create an environ- exposed the contradictions or ameliorated the
ment to successfully enact the claims of a contradictions by associating them with
new public theory. Sometimes this involves broader cultural analogies (Douglas, 1986;
institutional entrepreneurs organizing from Strang and Meyer, 1994).
the center of an established environment In returning to Holm’s (1995) concern
(Suddaby and Greenwood, 2005) and at with embedded agency, Leca and Naccache
other times it may stem from the periphery (2006) argue from a critical realist
of emerging fields (Maguire, Hardy, and perspective that the concept of institutional
Lawrence, 2004). entrepreneur does not completely address
However, the environments that institu- the paradox of embedded agency because the
tional entrepreneurs enact to garner control concept by definition does not take
of resources are not just material, they are into account the interrelated sequencing of
116 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

structures and actions and the causal emer- interesting because it is inconsistent with
gent properties of both structures and extant theory which would predict
actions. They argue for a critical realist change from the periphery, not the center
approach in which actors use the causal of the field. They argue that contact
powers of pre-existing structures to with institutional logics in multiple and
create new institutions or challenge exist- different organizational fields increases
ing ones. We highlight their important the awareness of and experiences with
insight as it motivates our subsequent discus- contradictions in logics, which lowers con-
sion of structural overlap and event straints and embeddedness of actors and
sequencing. enables central actors to become institutional
entrepreneurs.
Structural overlap
Structural overlap occurs when individual Event sequencing
roles and organizational structures and func- Event sequencing is defined as the temporal
tions that were previously distinct are forced and sequential unfolding of unique events
into association (Thornton, 2004). Mergers that dislocate, rearticulate, and transform the
and acquisitions are an example of structural interpretation and meaning of cultural sym-
overlap when organizational actors from bols and social and economic structures
divergent cultures are forced into associat- (Sewell, 1996: 844). For example, this can be
ion, triggering a change in institutional changes in cultural schemas, shifts of
logics guiding the firm. Structural over- resources, and the emergence of new sources
lap across systems with differentiated of power. As noted above, because structures
logics creates contradiction in organiza- are often overlapping, any rupture has the
tions and organizational fields, creating potential of cascading into multiple changes,
entrepreneurial opportunities for institutional particularly when the events are character-
change. ized by heightened emotion, collective
For example, Stovel and Savage (2005) creativity, and ritual. The accumulation
showed how a merger wave exposed compet- of events can result in a path-dependent
ing institutional logics and triggered the elab- process in which shifts in the symbolic inter-
oration of the modern, mobile, bureaucratic pretation of events are locked in place by
career in the financial sector. Thornton, simultaneous shifts in resources. Such
Jones, and Kury (2005) illustrated how the sequencing produces more events that
structural overlap when accounting firms reinforce or erode the dominance of the
incorporated management consultants into incumbent logic.
their organizations brought professional and Event sequencing has been used as an ana-
market logics head to head and conflicted the lytical method to address the problem of
focus of attention of accountants from over- embedded agency or what Barley and Tolbert
seeing the accuracy of client’s books to using (1997) term conflation and the problem of
exposure to accounting ledgers to identify reducing structure to action or action to
consulting clients. Greenwood and Suddaby structure. (How such event sequences inter-
(2006), in their analysis of a pioneering new sect to reveal causation has been extensively
organizational form, the multidisciplinary examined in the literature on historical com-
practice (MDP) within the field of business parative methods of analysis (Abbott, 1990;
services, theorize a case of structural overlap Griffin, 1992; Sewell, 1992, 1996)). There
in which elite organizations are more likely are several ways to assess the impact of event
to come into contact with competing and sequencing on institutional change –
contradictory logics because they bridge for example, nominal and ordinal compar-
different organizational fields. They point isons and narrative analysis (Mahoney,
out that this case of institutional change is 1999). These are different strategies of
INSTITUTIONAL LOGICS 117

macro-causal analysis – ways that culture a monolithic and coherent influence on


researchers iterate between theory and his- actors that results from socialization (Parsons,
tory in identifying the causes of an outcome. 1951). Instead, conceptualizing society as an
The narrative analysis method is used to inter-institutional system implies that the insti-
understand the ordering of circumstantial tutional orders have modularity and decom-
detail in searching for analogies that are the posable elements. The decomposable nature
foundation for new and convincing accounts. of institutional logics allows for theorizing the
In the institutional logics literature, it is the fragmented and contradicted nature of cultural
institutional orders of the inter-institutional influences, revealing this not only at different
system that provide the meta-theory which levels of analysis, for example individuals and
points to these analogies and that prevent the organizations, but also in specific contexts in
analysis from getting bogged down in the which individuals actively import and export
minutia of historical details. elements of institutional logics across institu-
For example, the case of the change in tional orders (Thornton, 2004). Thus, the
institutional logics in higher education decomposability of the elements of the inter-
publishing from 1958 to 1990, from an institutional system makes it possible to
editorial (based in the logics of the family observe the influence of cultural institutions
and the professions) to a market logic, from the standpoint of the vertical coherence
reveals the causally linked events that inter- and fragmentation of different levels of
acted to produce a shift in the prevail- analysis, not only bottom up or top down
ing institutional logic (Thornton, 2004). (Schneiberg and Clemens, 2006), but also
Event sequencing is also shown to play from the horizontal blending and segregating
a role in institutional change in the account- of the elements of different orders of the
ing profession (Thornton, Jones, and inter-institutional system. This, for example,
Kury, 2005). Hoffman and Ocasio (2001) enables theorizing institutional change
theorize what determines public attent- processes such as bricolage, which is the
ion to events that trigger institutional creation of new practices and institutions
change. from different elements of existing institutions
So what are the implications of individuals (Levi-Strauss, 1966). Thus, in returning to the
and organizations in a sea of cultural fragmen- question of embedded agency, the institutional
tation and contradiction? It means that to entrepreneur does not disembed from the
study cultural institutions researchers need a social world to create change – structures and
theoretical framework that can accommodate actions are separable (Leca and Naccache,
how individuals’ norms may deviate from 2006), allowing institutional entrepreneurs to
norms at higher levels of analysis, for example hop and bridge from one social world to
at the level of individuals as distinct from cor- another. Our review leads us to be encouraged
porate management or professional associa- that literatures on organizations and culture
tions (DiMaggio, 1997: 265). This multi-level are converging, creating these fresh views on
and multi-contextual requirement calls for a the topic of agency.
theory that conceptualizes how to partition
‘units of cultural analysis’ and the relations Competing logics
among them (Holm, 1995). We argue that the A focus on competition between alternative
inter-institutional system is well suited to this institutional logics has guided research on
task because each institutional order has dis- institutional change. This diverse literature
tinct organizing principles, cultural symbols, encompasses a wide variety of mechanisms
and logics of action that clarify how to define to explain the effects of competing logics on
units of cultural analysis. Culture is not just change, including environmental selection
amorphously out there in ‘thin air’ as per the pressures, political contestation, and social
critique of culture as a world system, nor is movements. We emphasize that competing
118 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

logics are not, by themselves, an explanation Other studies on competing institutional


for change in institutional logics but an logics highlight power struggles among pro-
antecedent or a consequence. Moreover, ponents of alternative logics. Reay and
competing logics can facilitate resistance to Hinings’ (2005: 375) description of the
institutional change as in the case of the con- Alberta Canada case of health care services
test between the institutional logics of global bears similarities. Their lens focuses on a
corporate and local professional banking recomposition of an organizational field in
(Marquis and Lounsbury, 2007). The causal which competing institutional logics of med-
mechanisms for institutional change reside ical professionalism versus business-like
not in competition per se, but on a combina- health care is driving a radical change
tion of the effects of market selection pres- process. They conceptualize the organiza-
sures, power of institutional actors, tional field as a battlefield where power
and changes in the relative prevalence of struggles motivated by competing institu-
societal-level institutional logics, which tional logics get played out. The structure of
unfortunately in many studies is typically the field and the dominant institutional logic
unspecified. changed, but the previously dominant logic
Much work has utilized both case and of medical professionalism was only sub-
quantitative studies of competing logics in dued rather than eliminated. The power
professional and occupational domains, for ended up being distributed between the two
example finance, health care, accounting, powerful actors – the physicians and the gov-
and culinary. Comparing and contrasting ernment – creating a countervailing or stabi-
studies across professional and occupational lizing tension.
contexts reveals the vibrant ecology of Meyer and Hammerschmid (2006: 1012)
competing institutional logics of the inter- analyze to what extent an old administrative
institutional system. orientation is being replaced with a new
Early research by Haveman and Rao managerial logic in the Austrian public
(1997) on mutual funds, described above, sector. They trace institutional change by
adopted a selection meta-theory, positing observing how state bureaucrats make use of
how environmental selection pressures social identities that are derived from com-
favored organizational forms more congruent peting institutional logics. They have found
with their institutional environments. evidence of the formation of a new manage-
Similarly, the Scott et al. (2000) historical rial identity created by individuals who
account of the Bay Area health care system is mixed a new orientation with more orthodox
exemplary in describing institutional change beliefs on public administration.
from a setting once dominated by the institu- Research on competing logics has also
tional logics of the medical professions to incorporated a social movement perspective.
one greatly influenced by the logics of the For example, Rao, Monin, and Durand
state, the corporation, and the market. Their (2003) show how social identity movements
study shows how the logics of the state in underpin reinstitutionalization in the culinary
terms of new regulatory systems disempow- professions by contrasting the institutional
ered those of the professions, in particular logics of the classic and nouvelle cuisine
the more powerful and higher priced MDs, movements. Change in logics and change in
creating an avenue for managers of corporate the adherence to a logic take place through
logics in the form of managed care and new four mechanisms, the sociopolitical legiti-
organizational forms such as Health macy of food critics as activists, the theoriza-
Maintenance Organizations (HMOs), Point tion of new roles, prior defections by peers
of Provider Organizations (PPOs), and surgi- and gains to peers, and gains to defectors as
centers to become commonplace in the identity-discrepant cues. In essence, institu-
health care system. tional logics and professions undergo change
INSTITUTIONAL LOGICS 119

when activists gain control of professional A market in one historical and cultural con-
societies, critique the traditional logic, and text is not the same as a market in another
proffer a solution hinging on a new institu- (Fligstein, 1996). Similarly non-market
tional logic. Note, the theory doesn’t fore- institutions, such as professions, the family,
shadow why critic activists chose to engage and religion are also economic structures and
in an institutional deconstruction project. are not independent from market forces
One can surmise the influence of other social of demand and supply (Friedland and Alford,
movements that are supported by other 1991).
domains in the professions and even other Second, institutional logics do not emerge
institutional orders, for example the more from organizational fields – they are locally
generic health movement. instantiated and enacted in organizational
Overall, the studies of competing institu- fields as in other places such as markets,
tional logics focus either on strategies of industries, and organizations. Institutional
action at a lower level of analysis, for exam- logics stem from the institutional orders of
ple an organizational field, for example Reay the inter-institutional system (Friedland and
and Hinings (2005), or on how a higher- Alford, 1991), not as commonly miscon-
level institutional logic at the societal-sector strued from an organizational field (Scott,
level transforms strategies of action in a 2001: 139). Institutional logics through
lower-level domain, for example Haveman various mechanisms may get reshaped and
and Rao (1997) and Meyer and customized in an organizational field.
Hammerschmid (2006). This difference may However, an organizational field is a level of
be partly reflected in the research design, for analysis; it is a place where institutional
example the qualitative study of a case versus logics get played out, but not by itself a
the quantitative analysis of a specific instan- theoretical mechanism. Friedland and Alford
tiation of an institutional order. These differ- (1991: 244) have commented around this
ences may also be reflected in how the issue:
camera lens is focused. That is, if you get
defining the boundaries of an organizational field,
close to the action as qualitative researchers within which there are strong pressures for
are able to do, one is more likely to interpret conformity, is difficult and potentially tautological.
the action as a power struggle when indeed it The approach seems to assume that formal
may also reflect the operation of higher-level attributes of organizational fields can be specified
independently of the institutional arena in which
institutional forces.
they are located. But, we would argue, it is the
content of an institutional order that shapes the
mechanisms by which organizations are able to
conform or deviate from established patterns.
MISCONCEPTIONS REGARDING These institutional orders, and the specific relations
between them, delimit types of organizational
INSTITUTIONAL LOGICS
fields.

With respect to the institutional logics Third, ideal types are not a description of
approach there are several misconceptions in what happens in an organizational field. Ideal
our view that we feel compelled to comment types are formal analytical models by which
on. One is a continued juxtaposition between to compare empirical observations across
institutional and market structures (e.g., institutions. Therefore, ideal types are best
Greenwood and Suddaby, 2006). While mar- developed at least in pairs, if not multiple
kets are economic structures – they are also characterizations. Instead, often what are
institutions. They function because of a set of often mischaracterized as ideal types are a
formal laws and normative expectations description of a particular case study rather
about them and these normative expectations than a set of findings that can be refuted or
have changed through time and space. generalized and aggregated.
120 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Fourth, most studies of institutional logics theory requires increased attention to its
do not in some way tie their analyses back to microfoundations. DiMaggio’s (1997) paper
the institutional orders of the inter- on culture and cognition is a start, providing
institutional system. This is partly due to a link between the microfoundations of
page limitation requirements of the journals cognitive processes and the cultural
and a focus on other alternative units of structures inherent in institutional logics. But
analysis. In other cases it appears due to the cognitive theory is only part of the story. The
authors who do not focus on causal relation- Carnegie School is another source and the
ships both up and down stream. To simply recent call for a neo-Carnegie perspective
and briefly recognize these multi-level may also yield answers (Gavetti, Levinthal,
relationships is important to further the and Ocasio, 2007). Given the rejection of
development of the institutional logics rational choice theory, how embedded inter-
approach as it systematically advances and ests, identity and commitments play a role is
foreshadows questions for future study. For an important topic for further theoretical
example, why do culinary critics, the lynch development and empirical research.
pin of the four mechanisms that begin the New methodologies that make use of
shift in chef identities, decide to favor web-based experiments show promise in
nouvelle over classic cuisine? Are these research linking levels of analysis and also in
critics, for example, increasingly under partitioning causes and effects by level of
market pressures or have professional pres- analysis, helping to specify the underlying
sures changed in some way? theoretical mechanisms (Thornton, 2004).
For example, Salganik, Dodds, and Watts
(2006) show the micro-macro linkages in
SUGGESTIONS FOR FUTURE how people select songs. This partitioning
RESEARCH also should address the meta-theoretical
assumption of incorporating both the
The main intellectual hurdle in institutional material and cultural. However, incorporating
analysis is in many respects the same as it is both is not enough – what is needed is theory
for sociological theory more generally. We and methods to partition these effects – that is
need to better understand how macro-level to understand the autonomy of culture from
states at one point in time influence individ- economy (DiMaggio, 1994).
uals’ orientations to their actions, prefer- Future research needs to move beyond
ences, beliefs; how these orientations to implicit assumptions and to engage explicit
action influence how individuals act; and discussion of the underlying theoretical
how the actions of individuals constitute the mechanisms, that is the clear identification of
macro-level outcomes that we seek to the ‘gears and ball bearings behind the statis-
explain. Moreover, how does the stability of tical models’ (Davis and Marquis, 2005).
institutional logics change systematically by Without formalization of the theory and
level of analysis – is it more stable or change- methods, studies of institutions cannot build
able at the top or bottom, macro- or micro- upon or invalidate one another and the social
level of analysis? This is a big theoretical science of institutions cannot grow systemat-
question. ically (Pfeffer, 1993). Instead, it will be
We need more work on the microfounda- forgotten as it was in the past (Hughes, 1939;
tions of institutional logics. Work on institu- Selznick, 1949, 1957).
tional logics is inherently cross-level, Most research on institutional analysis has
highlighting the interplay between individu- revealed the effects of market rationalization
als, organizations, and institutions. While the or state regulation; the latter is more about
embedded agency of actors is a key meta- resource dependence than institutional analy-
theoretical assumption, as discussed above, a sis. In theory, other underlying patterns of
fully developed perspective on institutional institutional change should exist. Given the
INSTITUTIONAL LOGICS 121

interpenetration of institutions across levels in institutional change, we need work on


this raises the question of what implications institutional logics, at various levels, organi-
this has for the rise of market logics in soci- zations, industries, fields, societies, and
etal sectors where you would not expect to world systems can themselves be institution-
see markets operating, such as in the case of alized and deinstitutionalized. In examining
families and the rising salience of religions in this issue it is important to distinguish
a world system. between changes in logics and changes in
Institutional change occurring in the practices. What constitutes an institution
global multi-national context provides fertile remains an unresolved conceptual issue
ground for new research. Contrary to for the field. How and why actors manipulate
Friedland and Alford's (1991) formulation, and switch institutional logics and in
the institutional logics perspective and in particular cases in which manipulations and
particular the inter-institutional system is an switches are not supported by cultural
analytical tool not limited to expectations of analogy are important empirical papers to
Western culture. It is also useful in analyses anticipate.
of international contexts as evidenced by
recent applications examining the influence
of cross-national institutional logics on CONCLUSION
employee training (Luo, 2007) and business
group restructuring in emerging economies With the exception of DiMaggio and
(Chung and Luo, forthcoming). Powell’s (1983) theory of isomorphism,
We think there is a healthy growth of institutional theory has lacked coherence.
measurement strategies of institutional logics Subsequently, two papers have affected the
on the horizon. Most quantitative research on abandonment of isomorphism theory and the
institutional logics has relied on indirect cognitive meta-theory espoused by
measures of institutional logics, attempting DiMaggio and Powell (1991), namely that of
to bolster this approach by combining Kraatz and Zajac (1996) and Hirsch’s (1997)
research methodologies and triangulating (in our judgment inaccurate) critique of
historical and interview methodologies with Scott’s ([1995] 2001) emphasis on the cogni-
quantitative methodologies. Content analytic tive perspective. The impact of these papers
methodologies by Scott et al. have been left institutional theory adrift with Scott’s
attempted, albeit these have not been ‘carriers’ perspective. As a result, much of
incorporated directly into the literature. what is called institutional theory these days
Research on vocabularies and cultural is not very institutional at all. Instead it is
structures provide opportunities in this area about resource dependencies, political strug-
and the use of techniques employed in mar- gles, social movements, and other mecha-
keting such as focus groups and the field test- nisms which, while important, are really
ing of ideal types. More cross-over research about non-institutional forces driving institu-
is needed between network and institutional tional change. Within this political sociolog-
scholars as network methodologies offer a ical vein, culture is relegated to the narrower
well-established set of methods that can be topic of how groups and social movements
used for direct measurement of the meaning make use of rhetoric and framing to be
of cultural categories (Breiger and persuasive (Suddaby and Greenwood, 2005).
Mohr, 2004). The institutional logics approach provides an
How institutional logics become institu- important remedy to this theoretical drift
tionalized and deinstitutionalized continues away from institutional effects, by highlight-
to be a vibrant vein of work. Synthesis of the ing how the cultural dimensions of institu-
state of what we know in this realm is tions both enable and constrain social action.
needed. While work on institutional change We review how the institutional logics
has focused on the role of competing logics approach is a systematic way to theorize and
122 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

measure the influence of institutions on indi- REFERENCES


vidual and organizational behavior. Without
positing isomorphism or organizational sta- Abbott, A. 1988. The System of Professions:
bility, the institutional logics approach offers An Essay on the Division of Expert Labor.
precision in understanding how individual Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.
and organizational behavior is located in a Albert, S. and D. Whetten. 1985.
social context and the social mechanisms that ‘Organizational Identity,’ Research on
influence that behavior. By categorizing soci- Organizational Behavior, Vol. 7, 263–295.
JAI Press.
etal influences as an inter-institutional
Aldrich, H., and C. M. Fiol, 1994. ‘Fools Rush
system, previously tractable issues such as
in? The Institutional Context of Industry
embedded agency and institutional change Creation,’ Academy of Management Review
can be better addressed. Through the use of 19 (4): 645–670.
increasingly sophisticated methods of inter- Alford, R. R. and R. Friedland, 1985. Powers
pretive analysis, most notably the use of ideal of Theory: Capitalism, the State, and
types and discourse analysis coupled with Democracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University
quantitative modeling techniques, the institu- Press.
tional logics approach is well positioned to Barley, S. R. and Tolbert, P. S. 1997.
continue to address the questions of the cog- ‘Institutionalization and Structuration: Studying
nitive meaning of culture and institutions. the Links Between Action and Institution,’
Organization Studies 18 (1): 93–117.
An important advantage of the institu-
Battilana, J. 2006. ‘Agency and Institutions:
tional logics approach as meta-theory is its
The Enabling Role of Individuals’ Social
systematic means to associate various theo- Position,’ Organization, Forthcoming.
ries (explanations) of organization and action Becker, Gary, S. 1976. ‘On the Relevance of the
in which institutions and their effects and New Economics of the Family,’ The American
how actors constitute institutions can be Economic Review, August.
understood and measured objectively – they Benford, R. D. and D. A. Snow, 2000. ‘Framing
can be heard, recorded, classified, and asso- Processes and Social Movements: An
ciated with a set of actors and strategic Overview and Assessment,’ Annual Review
actions. of Sociology, Vol. 26, 611–639.
In this review we focused on an analysis of Berger, P. and Thomas Luckmann. 1967. The
Social Construction of Reality. New York:
the implicit and explicit social mechanisms
Doubleday Anchor.
in a variety of studies, not on the description
Bhappu, Anita D. 2000. ‘The Japanese Family:
or strength of their empirical findings. Our An Institutional Logic for Japanese
approach was guided by believing that the Corporate Networks and Japanese
advancement of institutional analysis in the Management,’ Academy of Management
social sciences requires an analytic, not a Review 25 (2): 409–515.
descriptive approach, that ‘explains’ Boltanski, Luc and Laurent Thevenot. [1986]
observed associations between individuals, 1991. On Justification: Economies of Worth.
organizations, and societies. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Breiger, Ronald and John Mohr. 2004.
‘Institutional Logics from the Aggregation of
NOTES Organizational Networks,’ Computational
and Mathematical Organization Theory 10:
17–43. Kluwer Academic.
1 Publishers included among others, Len
Louchow, former CEO of Jossey-Bass, and John
Brickson, Shelley. 2000. ‘The Impact of Identity
Davis, former head of the Prentice-Hall College Orientation on Individual and Organizational
Division. Louchow used the ideal types in teaching Outcomes in Demographically Diverse
the leadership course for the Stanford University Settings,’ Academy of Management Review,
Publishers College. 25 (1): 82–101.
INSTITUTIONAL LOGICS 123

Carroll, Glenn and Michael Hannan. 2000. The Dutton, Jane E. and J. Dukerich. 1991. ‘Keeping
Demography of Corporations and Industries. an Eye on the Mirror: Image and Identity in
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. P. 43. Organizational Adaptation,’ Academy of
Cerulo, Karen. 1997. ‘Identity Construction: Management Journal 34 (3): 517–554.
New Issue, New Directions,’ Annual Review Fine, Gary Alan. 1996. Difficult Reputations:
of Sociology, vol. 23, 385–409. Collective Memories of Evil, Inept, and
Chandler, Alfred D. 1962. Strategy and Controversial. University of Chicago Press.
Structure. New York: Doubleday. Fligstein, Neil. 1985. ‘The Spread of the
Chung, Chi-Nien, and Xiaowei Luo forthcom- Multidivisional Form among Large Firms,
ing. 'Institutional Logics or Agency Costs: 1919–1979,’ American Sociological Review
The Influence of Corporate Governance 50 (3): 377–391.
Models on Business Group Restructuring in Fligstein, Neil. 1987. ‘The Interorganizational
Emerging Economies,' Organization Science. Power Struggle: The Rise of Finance
Davis, Gerald F., and Christopher Marquis. Personnel to Top Leadership in Large
2005. ‘Prospects for Organization Theory in Corporations, 1919–1979,’ American
the Early Twenty-First Century: Institutional Sociological Review 52: 44–58.
Fields and Mechanisms,’ Organization Fligstein, Neil. 1990. The Transformation of
Science 16 (4): 332–343. Corporate Control. Cambridge, MA: Harvard
DiMaggio, Paul J. 1988. ‘Interest and agency University Press.
in institutional theory,’ in Institutional Fligstein, Neil. 1996. ‘Market as Politics: A
Patterns and Organizations: Culture and Political-Cultural Approach to Market
Environment, ed. Lynne G. Zucker, 3–21. Institutions,’ American Sociological Review
Cambridge, MA: Ballinger. 61 (4): 656–673.
DiMaggio, Paul J. 1991. ‘Constructing an organi- Fligstein, Neil. 2001. The Architecture of
zational field as a professional project: U.S. art Markets: An Economic Sociology of Twenty-
museums, 1920–1940,’ in The New Institu- First-Century Capitalist Societies. Princeton,
tionalism in Organizational Analysis, ed. Walter NJ: Princeton University Press.
W. Powell and Paul J. DiMaggio, 267–292. Friedland, Roger and Alford, R. Robert. 1991.
Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press. ‘Bringing society back in: Symbols, practices,
DiMaggio, Paul. 1994. ‘The challenge of com- and institutional contradictions,’ in The New
munity evolution,’ in Evolutionary Dynamics Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis,
of Organizations, ed. Joel A. C. Baum and ed. Walter W. Powell and Paul J. DiMaggio,
Jitendra V. Singh, pp. 444–456. New York: pp. 232–263. Chicago, IL: University of
Oxford University Press. Chicago Press.
DiMaggio, Paul. 1997. ‘Culture and Cognition,’ Gavetti, Daniel Levinthal, and William Ocasio.
Annual Review of Sociology 23: 263–287. (2007). ‘Neo-Carnegie: The Carnegie School’s
DiMaggio, Paul J. and Walter W. Powell. 1983. Past, Present, and Reconstructing for the
‘The Iron Cage Revisited: Institutional Future.’ Organization Science 20: 523–536.
Isomorphism and Collective Rationality in Geertz, Clifford. 1973. The Interpretation of
Organizational Fields,’ American Sociological Cultures: Selected Essays. New York: Basic
Review 48: 147–160. Books.
DiMaggio, Paul and Walter W. Powell. 1991. Giddens, Anthony. 1984. The Constitution of
‘Introduction,’ in The New Institutionalism in Society. Berkeley: University of California Press.
Organizational Analysis, ed. Walter W. Glynn, Mary Ann. 2000. ‘When cymbals
Powell and Paul J. DiMaggio, pp.1–38. become symbols: Conflict over organiza-
Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press. tional identity within a symphony orchestra.
Dotty and Glick. 1994. ‘Typologies as a Unique Organization Science 11 (3): 285–298.
Form of Theory Building: Toward Improved Glynn, Mary Ann and Michael Lounsbury. 2005.
Understanding and Modeling,’ Academy of ‘From the Critics’ Corner: Logic Blending,
Management Review 19 (2): 230–251. Discursive Change and Authencity in a
Douglas, Mary. 1986. How Institutions Think. Cultural Production System,’ Journal of
Syracuse, NY: Syracuse University Press. Management Studies 42 (5): 1031–1055.
124 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Granovetter, Mark. 1985. ‘Economic Action Jackall, Robert. 1988. Moral Mazes: The World
and Social Structure: The Problem of of Corporate Managers. New York: Oxford
Embeddedness,’ American Journal of University Press.
Sociology 91: 481–510. Jones, Candace and Reut Livne-Tarandach
Greenwood, Royston, and Robert Hinnings. (Forthcoming). ‘Designing a Frame: Rhetorical
2006. Understanding Strategic Change: The Strategies of Architects,’ Journal of
Contribution of Archetypes. Academy of Organizational Behavior.
Management Journal 36 (5): 1052–1081. Kelman, Herbert C. 1956. ‘Compliance,
Greenwood, Royston, and Roy Suddaby. 2006. Identification, and Internalization: A
‘Institutional Entrepreneurship in Mature Theoretical and Experimental Approach to
Fields: The Big Five Accounting Firms,’ the Study of Social Influence,’ unpublished
Academy of Management Journal 49 (1): manuscript.
27–48. Kelman, Herbert C. 2006. Interests,
Griffin, Larry J. 1992. ‘Temporality, Events, and Relationships, and Identities: Three Central
Explanation in Historical Sociology: An Issues for Individuals and Groups in
Introduction,’ Sociological Methods and Negotiating Social Environment,’ Annual
Research 20: 403–427. Review of Psychology, vol. 55: 1–26.
Gumport, Patricia, J. 2000. ‘Academic King, Andrew and Michael Lenox. 2000.
Restructuring: Organizational Change and ‘Industry Self Regulation Without Sanctions:
Institutional Imperatives, Higher Education,’ The Chemical Industry’s Responsible Care
The International Journal of Higher Education Program,’ Academy of Management Care
and Educational Planning 39: 67–91. Program,’ Academy of Management Journal
Hasselbladh, Hans and Jannis Kallinikos. 2000. 43(4): 698–716.
‘The Project of Rationalization: A Critique Kitchener, Martin. 2002. ‘Mobilizing the Logic
and Reappraisal of Neo-Institutionalism in of Managerialism in Professional Fields: The
Organization Studies,’ Organization Studies Case of Academic Health Centers Mergers,’
21: 691-. Organization Studies 23 (3): 391–420.
Haveman, Heather A., and Hayagreeva Rao. Kraatz, Matthew and Edward Zajac. 1996.
1997. ‘Structuring a Theory of Moral ‘Exploring the Limits of the New Institu-
Sentiments: Institutional and Organizational tionalism: The Causes and Consequences
Coevolution in the Early Thrift Industry,’ of Illegitimate Organizational Change,’
American Journal of Sociology 102 (6): American Sociological Review 61 (5):
1606–1651. 812–836.
Hirsch, Paul M. 1997. ‘Review Essay: Sociology Kuhn, Thomas. 1962. The Structure of Scientific
Without Social Structure: Neo-Institutional Revolutions. Chicago, IL: University of
Theory Meets Brave New World,’ American Chicago Press.
Journal of Sociology 91: 800–837. Lamont, Michele and Virag Molnar. 2002.
Hoffman, Andrew and William Ocasio. 2001. ‘The Study of Borundaries in the Social
‘Not all Events are Attended to Equally: Sciences,’ Annual Review of Sociology 28:
Toward a Middle Range Theory of Industry 167–195.
Attention to External Events,’ Organization Leca, Bernard and Philippe Naccache. 2006.
Science 12 (4): 414–434. ‘A Critical Realist Approach to Institutional
Holm, Peter. 1995. ‘The Dynamics of Entrepreneurship,’ Organization 13 (5):
Institutionalization: Transformation Processes 627–651.
in Norwegian Fisheries,’ Administrative Levi-Strauss, Claude. 1966. The Savage Mind.
Science Quarterly 40: 398–422. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.
Hughes, Everett C. 1939. ‘Institutions,’ pp. Lounsbury, Michael. 2002. ‘Institutional
281–330 in Robert E. Park, ed., An Outline Transformation and Status Mobility: The
of the Principles of Sociology. New York: Professionalization of the Field of Finance,’
Barnes and Noble. Academy of Management Journal 45:
Ingram, Paul and Karen Klay. 2000. The Choice- 255–266.
Within-Constraints New Institutionalism and Lounsbury, Michael. 2007. ‘A Tale of Two
Implications for Sociology Annual Review of Cities: Competing Logics and Practice
Sociology 26: 525–546. Variation in the Professionalization of Mutual
INSTITUTIONAL LOGICS 125

Funds,’ Academy of Management Journal Society, and the Individual, edited by George M.
50: 289–307. Thomas, John W. Meyer, Francisco O. Ramirez,
Lounsbury, Michael and Hayagreeva Rao. and John Boli. Newbury Park, CA: Sage.
2004. Sources of Durability and Change in Meyer, John W., John Boli, Geoerge M. Thomas,
Market Classificiation: A Study of the and Francisco O. Ramirez. 1997. ‘World
Reconstruction of Product Categories in the Society and the Nation-State,’ American
American Mutual Fund Industry, 1944–1985. Journal of Sociology 103: 144–181.
Social Forces 82: (3): 969–999. Meyer, John W. and Brian Rowan 1977.
Lounsbury, Michael and Marc Ventresca. 2003. ‘Institutional Organizations: Formal Structure
The New Structuralism in Organization as Myth and Ceremony,’ American Journal of
Theory, Organization 10 (3): 457–480. Sociology 83: 340–363.
Lounsbury, Michael, Marc Ventresca and Paul Meyer, John W. and W. R. Richard Scott (eds).
M. Hirsch. 2003. ‘Social Movements, Field 1983. Organizational Environments: Ritual
Frames, and Industry Emergence: A and Rationality, Beverly Hills, CA: Sage.
Cultural–Political Perspective on U.S. Meyer, Renate E. and Gerhard Hammerschmid.
Recycling. Socio-Economic Review 1(1): 2006. ‘Changing Institutional Logics and
71–104. Executive Identities: A Managerial Challenge
Luo, Xiaowei 2007. 'Continuous Learning: The to Public Administration in Austria,’
Influence of National Institutional Logics American Behavioral Scientist 49 (7):
on Training Attitudes,' Organization Science 1000–1014.
18 (2): 280–296. Mizruchi, Mark S. and Lisa C. Fein. 1999. ‘The
Maguire, S. C. Hardy, and Thomas Lawrence. Social Construction of Organizational
2004. ‘Institutional Entrepreneurship in Knowledge: A Study of the Uses of Coercive,
Emerging Fields: HIV/AIDS Treatment Mimetic, and Normative Isomorphism,’
Advocacy in Canada,’ Academy of Administrative Science Quarterly 33:
Management Journal 75 (5):1–23. 194–210.
Mahoney, James. 1999. ‘Nominal, Ordinal, and Mohr, John W. and V. Duquenne. 1997. ‘The
Narrative Appraisal in Macrocausal Analysis,’ Duality of Culture and Practice: Poverty
The American Journal of Sociology 104 (4): Relief in New York City, 1988–1917,’ Theory
1154–1196. and Society 26 (2–3): 305–356.
March, James G. and Johan P. Olsen. 1976. Mohr, John W. and Francesca Guerra-Pearson
Ambiguity and Choice in Organizations. (Forthcoming). The Duality of Niche and
Bergen, Norway, Universitetsforlaget. Form: The Differentiation of Institutional
March, James and Olsen. 1989. Rediscovering Space in New York City, 1999–1917. In How
Institutions: The Organizational Basis of Institutions Change, Walter Powell and
Politics. New York: Free Press. Dan Jones (Eds). Chicago, IL: University of
Marquis, Christopher and Michael Lounsbury. Chicago Press.
2007. Vive La Resistance: Competing Logics Moorman, Christine. 2002. ‘Consumer Health
and the Consolidation of the U.S. under the Scope,’ Journal of Consumer
Community Banking. Academy of Research 29: 152–158.
Management Journal 50 (4): 799–820. North, Douglas C. 1990. Institutions,
Martin, Joanne. 1992. Cultures in Organizations: Institutional Change, and Economic
Three Perspectives. New York: Oxford Performance. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge
University Press. University Press.
Medin, Douglas L. 1989. ‘Concepts and Ocasio, William. 1995. ‘The Enactment of
Conceptual Structure,’ The American Economic Adversity: A Reconciliation of
Psychologist, Dec. 1, vol. 44, no. 12, 1469. Theories of Failure-Induced Change and
Merton, Robert K. 1949, 1957, 1968. Social Threat-Rigidity,’ Research in Organizational
Theory and Social Structure. Glencoe, IL: Free Behavior 17: 287–331.
Press. Ocasio, William. 1997. ‘Toward an Attention-
Meyer, John W., John Boli, and George M. Based View of the Firm,’ Strategic
Thomas. 1987. ‘Ontology and Rationalization in Management Journal 18: 187–206.
the Western Cultural Account.’ Pp. 12-37 in Ocasio, William. 1999. ‘Institutionalized Action
Institutional Structure: Constituting State. and Corporate Governance: The Reliance on
126 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Rules of CEO Succession,’ Administrative Reay, Trish, and C. R. Hinings. 2005. ‘The
Science Quarterly 44 (2): 384–416. Recomposition of an Organizational Field:
Ocasio, William, and Hyosun Kim. 1999. ‘The Health Care in Alberta,’ Organization Studies
Circulation of Corporate Control: Selection of 26 (3): 351–384.
Functional Backgrounds of New CEOs in Rosch, Eleanor. 1975. ‘Cognitive Repre-
large U.S. Manufacturing Firms, 1981–1992,’ sentations of Semantic Categories,’ Journal
Administrative Science Quarterly 44 (2): of Experimental Psychology-General 104 (3):
384–416. 192–233.
Ocasio, William, and Joseph 2005. ‘Cultural Ruef, Martin. 1999. ‘The Dynamics of
adaptation and institutional change: The Organizational Forms: Creating Market
evolution of vocabularies of corporate gover- Actors in the Health Care Field,’ Social Forces
nance, 1972–2003,’ Poetics 33 (3–4). 77 (4): 1405–1434.
O’Reilly, Charles and Jennifer A. Chatman. 1996. Salganik, M. J., P. S. Dodds, and D. J. Watts.
‘Culture as social control: Corporations, cults, 2006. ‘Experimental study of inequality and
and commitment,’ Research in Organizational unpredictability in an artificial cultural
Behavior 18: 157–200. market. Science 311 (5762): 854-856.
Parsons, Talcott. 1951. The Social System. New Schneiberg, Marc and Elizabeth S. Clemens.
York: Free Press. 2006. ‘The Typical Tools for the Job: Research
Parsons, Talcott. 1956. ‘Suggestions for a Strategies in Institutional Analysis,’
Sociological Approach to the Theory of Sociological Theory 24 (3): 195–227.
Organizations,’ Administrative Science Scott, W. Richard. [1995] 2001. Institutions and
Quarterly 1: 63–85. Organizations, 2nd edn. Thousand Oaks, CA:
Peteraf, Margaret, and Mark Shanley. 1997. Sage.
‘Getting to know you: A theory of strategic Scott, W. Richard, Martin Ruef, Peter Mendel,
group identity,‘ Strategic Management and Carole Caronna. 2000. Institutional
Journal 18: 165–186. Change and Health Care Organizations:
Pfeffer, Jeffrey. 1993. ‘Barriers to the Advance From Professional Dominance to Managed
of Organizational Science: Paradigm Care. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Development as a Dependent Variable,’ Searle, John R. 1995. The Social Construction
Academy of Management Journal 19 (4): of Reality. New York: The Free Press.
599–620. Selznick, Phillip. 1948. ‘Foundations of the
Phillips, Nelson, and Cynthia Hardy. 2002. Theory of Organization,’ American Sociological
Discourse Analysis: Investigating Processes Review 13: 25–35.
of Social Construction. Thousand Oaks, CA: Selznick, Phillip. 1949. TVA and the Grass Roots.
Sage. Berkeley: University of California Press.
Polleta, F. and J. M. Jasper. 2001.’Collective Selznick, Phillip. 1957. Leadership in Administ-
Identity and Social Movements,’ Annual ration. Berkeley: University of California Press.
Review of Sociology 27: 283–305. Seo, M. G. and W. E. Douglas Creed. 2002.
Porac, Joseph, Howard Thomas, and Charles ‘Institutional Contradictions, Praxis and
Baden-Fuller. 1989. ‘Competitive Groups as Institutional Change: A Dialectical
Cognitive Communities: The Case of Perspective,’ Academy of Management
Scottish Knitwear Manufacturers,’ Journal of Review 27 (2): 222–247.
Management Studies 26 (4): 397–416. Sewell, William H. Jr. 1992. ‘A Theory of Struct-
Rao, Hayagreeva, Philippe Monin, and ure: Duality, Agency, and Transfor-
Rodolphe Durand. 2003. ‘Institutional mation,’ American Journal of Sociology
Change in Toque Ville: Nouvelle Cuisine as 98: 1–29.
an Identity Movement in French Sewell, William H. Jr. 1996. ‘Historical Events as
Gastronomy,’ American Journal of Sociology Transformations of Structures: Inventing
108 (4): 795–843. Revolution at the Bastille,’ Theory and
Rao, Hayagreeva, Phillipe Monin, and Rudolph Society 25, 841–881.
Durand. 2005. ‘Border Crossing: Bricolage Stinchcombe, Arthur L. 1991. ‘The Conditions of
and the Erosion of Categorical Boundaries in Fruitfulness of Theorizing about Mechanisms
French Gastronomy, American Sociological in Social Science,’ Philosophy of the Social
Review 70: 968–991. Sciences 21, 3 (September): 367–387.
INSTITUTIONAL LOGICS 127

Stinchcombe, Arthur L. 2002. ‘New Sociological Sociology of Organizations, ed. Candace


Microfoundations for Organizational Theory: Jones and Patricia H. Thornton, 125–170.
A Postscript.’ In Social Structures and Organi- London: JAI.
zations Revisited, vol. 19, ed. M. Lounsbury Thornton, Patricia, and William Ocasio. 1999.
and M. Ventresca, 415–433. Amsterdam: ‘Institutional Logics and the Historical
Elsevier Science. Contingency of Power in Organizations:
Stovel, Katherine and Mike Savage. 2005. Executive Succession in the Higher
‘Mergers and Mobility: Organizational Education Publishing Industry, 1958–1990.’
Growth and the Origins of Career Migration American Journal of Sociology 105 (3):
at Lloyds Bank,’ American Journal of 801–843.
Sociology 111 (4): 1080–1121. Tolbert, Pamela S. and Lynne G. Zucker. 1983.
Strang, David and John W. Meyer. 1994. ‘Institutional Sources of Change in the
‘Institutional conditions for diffusion,’ in Formal Structure of Organizations: The
Institutional Environments and Organi- Diffusion of Civil Service Reform,
zations: Structural Complexity and Individ- 1880–1935,’ Administrative Science
ualism, ed. W. Richard Scott and John W. Quarterly 28: 22–39.
Meyer, 100–112. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage; Tuma, Nancy B. and Michael Hannan. 1984.
reprinted from Theory and Society 22(4): Social Dynamics: Models and Methods.
487–511, August 1993. Orlando: Academic Press.
Suddaby, Roy, and Royston Greenwood. 2005. Tyler, Tom R. 1999. ‘Why people cooperate
‘Rhetorical Strategies of Legitimacy,’ with organizations: An identity-based per-
Administrative Science Quarterly 50: 35–67. spective,’ Research in Organizational
Swedberg, Richard. 2005. Economic Sociology Behavior 21: 201–246.
Section Newsletter, American Sociological Weber, Max. [1922] 1978. Economy and
Association. Society: An Outline of Interpretive
Swidler, Ann. 1986. ‘Culture in Action: Sociology, ed. Guenther Roth and Claus
Symbols and Strategies,’ American Wittich. Berkeley, CA: University of California
Sociological Review 51: 273–286. Press.
Swidler, Ann. 1997. Talk of Love: How White, Harrison. 1992. Identity and Control:
Americans Use their Culture. Chicago: A Structural Theory of Social Action. Princeton,
University of Chicago Press. NJ: Princeton University Press.
Tajfel, H. and J. C. Turner. 1979. ‘An Integrative Zajac, Edward J. and James D. Westphal.
Theory of Intergroup Conflict,’ in S. Worche, 2004. ‘The Social Construction of Market
W. G. Austins, (eds.) The Social Psychology Value: Institutionalization and Learning
of Intergroup Relations. Monterey, CA: Perspectives on Stock Market Reactions,’
Brooks/Cole Publishing Co. American Sociological Review, vol. 69,
Thornton, Patricia. 2001. ‘Personal versus 433–458.
Market Logics of Control: A Historically Zhou, Xueguang. 2005. ‘The Institutional
Contingent Theory of the Risk of Acquisition,’ Logic of Occupational Prestige Ranking,’
Organization Science 12: 294–311. American Journal of Sociology 111 (1):
Thornton, Patricia. 2002. ‘The Rise of the 90–140.
Corporation in a Craft Industry: Conflict and Zilber, Tamar, B. 2006. ‘The Work of the
Conformity in Institutional Logics,’ Academy Symbolic in Institutional Processes: Translations
of Management Journal 45: 81–101. of Rational Myths in Israeli High Tech,’
Thornton, Patricia. 2004. Markets from Culture: Academy of Management Journal 49 (2):
Institutional Logics and Organizational 281–303.
Decisions in Higher Education Publishing. Zucker, Lynne G. 1977. ‘The Role of
Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. Institutionalization in Cultural Persistence,’
Thornton, Patricia, Candace Jones, and American Sociological Review 42:
Kenneth Kury. 2005. ‘Institutional 726–743.
Logics and Institutional Change: Zucker, Lynne G. 1983. ‘Organizations as
Transformation in Accounting, Architecture, Institutions,’ Research in the Sociology of
and Publishing,’ in Research in the Organizations 2: 1–47.
128 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

APPENDIX

Table 3.1 Ideal types of institutional logics in public accounting


Characteristic Fiduciary logic Corporate logic
Economic system Personal capitalism Managerial capitalism
Sources of identity Accounting as a profession Accounting as an industry
Sources of legitimacy Reputation of CPAs Scale and scope of firm
Standardization & conservatism
Sources of authority Professional association Management committee
Government regulation Managing partners
Government regulation
Basis of mission Build legitimacy of public corporation Build seasonal stability of firm
Build prestige of partnership Build status position of firm through growth
Basis of attention Selling legitimacy Selling services
Generating profits
Basis of strategy Standardize and authenticate Growth through mergers and acquisitions
client financial statements Differentiate on client service
Logic of investment Build legitimacy of profession Build wealth & career of partners
Governance mechanism CPA partnership Private corporation
CPA ownership Majority CPA ownership
Institutional entrepreneurs British: Waterhouse, Big 8 accounting firms
Young, Niven
American: Haskels, Sells, Andersen
Event sequencing 1896–1921 State CPA World War II
legislation 1965–1975 Consolidation to Big 8
1933, 1934 Securities Acts Corporate merger wave
1938 SEC Accounting Series 1970s–1980s FTC ruling on open competition
Release no. 4 1980s–1990s Consolidation to Big 5
2001 Enron collapse
2001 Andersen bankruptcy
Structural overlap Intentional reduction of overlap CPA – Consulting
CPA – Lawyers in tax practice CPA – Lawyers in tax practice

Table 3.2 Ideal types of institutional logics in architecture


Characteristic Aesthetic logic Efficiency logic
Economic system Personal capitalism Managerial capitalism
Sources of identity Architect as artist–entrepreneur Architect as engineer–manager
Sources of legitimacy Reputation of architect Scale and scope of firm
Aesthetics of design Efficiency and economics of design
Sources of authority Design prowess Managing partner or supervisor
Basis of mission Build personal reputation Build multidisciplinary firm
Build prestige of firm Build market position of firm
Basis of attention Resolve design problems and Resolve technological and organizational
entrepreneurial challenges challenges
Basis of strategy Increase prestige of patron or Increase number of corporate clients
government sponsor Build recurring clientele
Win design competitions Increase markets for services
Logic of investment Build wealth and prestige of Build wealth of partners
entrepreneurs
Continued
INSTITUTIONAL LOGICS 129

Continued
Table 3.2 Ideal types of institutional logics in architecture
Characteristic Aesthetic logic Efficiency logic
Governance mechanism Entrepreneurial firm (atelier) Partnership ownership
Profession Private global multidisciplinary
corporation
Institutional entrepreneurs H. H. Richardson, R. M. Hunt, Louis Sullivan, Wm Le Baron Jenney,
R. R. Ware, Robert Venturi Walter Gropius, Mies Van der Rohe
Event sequencing 1857 Founding of Increased immigration and industrialization
Architecture profession 1871 Chicago Fire provides commercial
1893 Chicago Fair reinforces building opportunities
aesthetic of Beaux Art tradition World War I provides building
1967 Postmodernism treatise rejects opportunities and implementation of
aesthetic of minimalism new aesthetic which rejects history
World War II immigration of modernist
architects to U.S.
Structural overlap Professions – architects, Professions – architects, engineers, and
engineers, and contractors contractors
Clients – government and Clients – real estate speculators and
wealthy individuals as patrons corporations

Table 3.3 Ideal types of institutional logics in higher-education publishing


Characteristic Editorial logic Market logic
Economic system Personal capitalism Market capitalism
Sources of identity Publishing as a profession Publishing as a business
Sources of legitimacy Personal reputation Market position of firm
Education value Share value
Sources of authority Founder–editor CEO
Personal networks Corporate hierarchy
Private ownership Public ownership
Basis of mission Build prestige of house Build competitive position of
Increase sales corporation
Increase profits
Basis of attention Author–editor networks Resource competition
Basis of strategy Organic growth Acquisition growth
Build personal imprints Build market channels
Logic of investment Capital committed to firm Capital committed to market return
Governance mechanism Family ownership Market for corporate control
Trade association
Institutional entrepreneurs Prentice Hall Thomson
Richard Prentice Ettinger Michael Brown
Event sequencing Increased public funding to education Founding of boutique investment
Increased college enrollments bankers
Wall St. announces good investment Founding of publishing finance
newsletters
Structural overlap 1950–1960s Prentice Hall internal 1980s acquisitions wave
corporate ventures and spin-offs
1960s acquisitions wave
4
Organizational Fields: Past,
Present and Future
Melissa Wooten and Andrew J. Hoffman

external environment, institutional theory


INTRODUCTION asks questions about how social choices are
shaped, mediated and channeled by the insti-
The term ‘institutional theory’ covers a broad tutional environment. Organizational action
body of literature which has grown in promi- becomes a reflection of the perspectives
nence and popularity over the past two defined by the group of members which
decades. But consistency in defining the comprise the institutional environment; out
bounds of this activity has not always been of which emerge the regulative, normative,
easy. The lament of DiMaggio and Powell in and cultural-cognitive systems that provide
1991 still holds true today: ‘it is often easier meaning for organizations (Scott, 1995,
to gain agreement about what it is not than 2001). Action is not a choice among unlim-
about what it is’ (1991: 1). There are a great ited possibilities but rather among a narrowly
number of issues that have and continue to defined set of legitimate options. As an
remain divisive within this literature and organization becomes more profoundly
among related literatures that apply institu- aware of its dependence on this external
tional arguments (i.e. economics, political environment, its very conception of itself
science, and history). What these literatures changes, with consequences on many levels.
have in common, however, is an underlying As this happens, Selznick states, ‘institution-
skepticism towards atomistic accounts of alization has set in’ (1957: 7). Hence,
social processes, relying instead on a convic- institutionalization represents both a process
tion that institutional arrangements and and an outcome (DiMaggio, 1988).
social processes matter in the formulation While not highly emphasized in early
of organizational action (DiMaggio and institutional analyses (i.e. Selznick, 1949,
Powell, 1991). 1957), the central construct of neo-
At its core, the literature looks to institutional theory has been the organiza-
the source of action as existing exogenous tional field (Scott, 1991). Strictly speaking,
to the actor. More than merely suggesting the field is ‘a community of organizations
that action is a reaction to the pressures of the that partakes of a common meaning system
ORGANIZATIONAL FIELDS: PAST, PRESENT AND FUTURE 131

and whose participants interact more fre- where an organization’s actions were struc-
quently and fatefully with one another than tured by the network of relationships within
with actors outside the field’ (Scott, 1995: which it was embedded (Warren, 1967).
56). It may include constituents such as the Warren used the example of community
government, critical exchange partners, organizations such as banks, welfare organi-
sources of funding, professional and trade zations, churches, businesses, and boards of
associations, special interest groups, and the education, working in conjunction with one
general public – any constituent which another to elucidate the importance of taking
imposes a coercive, normative or mimetic the ‘interorganizational’ field as a unit of
influence on the organization (DiMaggio and analysis. By focusing attention on this level
Powell, 1991; Scott, 1991). But the concept of analysis, researchers could better under-
of the organizational field encompasses stand the decision making processes among
much more than simply a discrete list of con- distinct organizations that, while having
stituents; and the ways in which the institu- dissimilar goals, felt it necessary and advan-
tional literature has sought to capture this tageous to interact with one another to
complexity has evolved over the past accomplish a given task.
decades, and continues to evolve. In this As studies of interorganizational relations
chapter, we present this evolution, discussing evolved, scholars broadened the field to
the past, present and future of this important include organizations that were not necessar-
construct. We illustrate its early conceptual- ily bound by geography or goals, but instead
ization and present its progression in a way made up a recognized area of institutional
that invites scholars to both consider their life. These could include organizations that
work within this historical trajectory and produced similar services or products,
contribute to its further development. We suppliers, resource and product consumers,
conclude the chapter with our thoughts on regulatory agencies, and others (DiMaggio
promising avenues for future research within and Powell, 1983). What these organizations
this domain. had in common was that they comprised a
community of organizations that partook of a
common meaning system and whose partici-
pants interacted more frequently and
ORGANIZATIONAL FIELDS: fatefully with one another than with other
EARLY INCARNATIONS organizations (Scott, 1995). Such evolving
definitions focused on the organizational
For early neo-institutional theory, the central field as a means to understand the impact of
unit of analysis was variously referred to as rationalization on organizations.
the institutional sphere (Fligstein, 1990), The behavior of organizations within
institutional field (Meyer and Rowan, 1977; fields was said to be guided by institutions:
DiMaggio, 1991), societal sector (Scott and the cultural-cognitive, normative, and regula-
Meyer, 1992), and institutional environment tive structures that provided stability and
(Orru, Biggart and Hamilton, 1991; Powell, collective meaning to social behavior (Scott,
1991). But the term organizational field 1995). These structures acted as ‘social facts’
(Scott, 1991) has become the accepted term which organizational actors took into
for the constellation of actors that comprise account when determining appropriate action
this central organizing unit. Like Bourdieu’s (Zucker, 1977; Meyer and Rowan, 1983).
field (1990, 1993), where an agent’s actions The transmission of social facts from one set
within the political, economic, or cultural of actors to another caused them to take on a
arena were structured by a network of social rule-like and taken-for-granted status and
relations, institutional theorists conceptual- thus become institutionalized (Zucker,
ized the organizational field as the domain 1977). Once a social fact had become
132 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

institutionalized, it provided actors with tem- Zucker (1983) looked to the spread of civil
plates for action which created unified or service reforms at the turn of the twentieth
monolithic responses to uncertainty that led century as resulting from the pressure of
to isomorphism; a commonality in form and legal requirements or the examples set by
function (DiMaggio and Powell, 1983). fellow cities.
The central notions of organizational field Early field-level analyses allowed some
research focused on understanding the degree of diversity in action, based on
processes that guided the behavior of field primacy in institutional adoption. For exam-
members in unconscious ways. ple, first adopters within a community of
Meyer and Rowan (1977) suggested that organizations tended to take action out of
the incorporation of elements (i.e. structures, concerns for efficiency. But, later adoptions
practices, procedures, etc.) from the institu- followed a different diffusion process with
tional environment imbued an organization adoption of structures and practices designed
with legitimacy. Thus, for example, ‘admin- to mimic the behavior of prior adopters.
istrators and politicians champion programs Tolbert and Zucker’s (1983) study of the
that are established but not implemented; adoption of civil reforms by cities provides
managers gather information assiduously, an exemplar of this phenomenon. Their study
but fail to analyze it; experts are hired not for found that characteristics such as the percent-
advice but to signal legitimacy’ (DiMaggio age of foreign-born residents and the size of
and Powell, 1991: 3). An organization that the city influenced the adoption of civil serv-
appeared legitimate increased its prospects ice reforms thought to improve city function-
for survival because constituents would not ing in the early phases of the municipal
question the organization’s intent and pur- reform movement. However, over time the
pose. As increasing numbers of organizations city demographics no longer influenced the
incorporated common institutional elements, adoption of such reforms. The authors
most (if not all) organizations at the field concluded that, in the later periods, civil
level became homogeneous in structure, service reforms had taken on a legitimated
culture, and output (DiMaggio and Powell, status and as such, became viewed as a nec-
1983). Much of the research using this notion essary signal of a properly functioning
of the organizational field centered on the municipal system.
premise that organizations sought survival Much work in the organizational field
and legitimacy as opposed to efficiency arena sought to identify institutionalization
(Orru, Biggart and Hamilton, 1991). by contrasting the adoption of practices for
For example, Fligstein (1990) depicted the rational or institutional motives, and by
industry-wide transformation of executive detecting how the quest for collective ration-
leadership in America as resulting from shift- ality led to homogeneity within field-level
ing pressures from the government. populations. Of particular interest was the
DiMaggio (1991) cited the causes for the role of the state and the influence of
accepted form of art museums in American the legal/regulatory environment in leading
cities in the 1920s and 1930s as the result of organizations to collectively develop appro-
efforts by museum workers to define a pro- priate responses that ultimately led to unifor-
fession through conformity to demands from mity in organizational form or structure.
foundations, particularly the Carnegie For instance, Edelman (1992) studied
Foundation. Leblebici, Salancik, Copay and organizations subject to affirmative action
King (1991) argued that the generation and and equal employment opportunity legisla-
acceptance of practices and technologies tion. This legislation required organizations
within the American radio broadcasting to incorporate members from historically
industry were the result of the actions of underrepresented groups into their hierarchy.
influential industrial actors. And Tolbert and Yet, the ambiguity of the legislation did not
ORGANIZATIONAL FIELDS: PAST, PRESENT AND FUTURE 133

specify how an organization should demon- logic dominated the industry. When a market-
strate its compliance (i.e. how an organiza- logic dominated the industry, publishers that
tion could demonstrate that it had indeed followed an imprint strategy and those with
incorporated women, racial/ethnic, and reli- distribution contracts faced a greater risk of
gious minorities into its operations). In acquisition than other publishers. Yet, when an
response to this uncertainty, field-level actors editorial-logic dominated the industry, imprint
pushed for the creation of Affirmative Action and distribution strategies had no significant
and Equal Employment Opportunity effect on a publisher’s likelihood of being
(AA/EEO) offices as a way to demonstrate acquired, suggesting that, as the field-level
their compliance with the new regulations. logic changed, the acquisition behavior of the
As other field members – namely the govern- organizations within the field changed as well.
ment – took the establishment of an AA/EEO While the Marquis and Thornton studies
office as evidence of compliance, the adop- highlighted the temporal dimension of cogni-
tion of these offices became widespread. A tive processes, another study by Davis and
similar process also led to the implementa- Greve (1997) highlighted the corresponding
tion of grievance systems (Sutton and spatial dimensions by noting that cognitive
Dobbin, 1996), internal job markets (Dobbin, perceptions regarding the legitimacy of a cor-
Sutton, Meyer and Scott, 1993) and mater- porate practice varied based on the social and
nity leave policies (Kelly and Dobbin, 1999). geographic distance among managers and
After focusing on the mimetic and regula- board of director members. The implementa-
tive forces which led to adoption and isomor- tion of the golden parachute, a practice that
phism within an organizational field, provided protection to top managers in the
institutional research took the so-called ‘cog- event of a hostile takeover, spread among
nitive turn’ (Lindenberg, 1998; Meindl, firms within the same region, whereas the
Stubbart and Porac, 1994). Work within the adoption of a poison pill, a practice that made
organizational field domain turned towards hostile takeover prohibitively expensive,
understanding the cultural and cognitive spread among firms that shared a board of
processes that guided field members’ director tie. Their investigation suggested
behavior. Researchers sought to uncover the that the proximity of actors affected the dif-
material practices and symbolic construc- fusion of firm behavior within a field.
tions that served as organizing templates for Throughout this early stream of research,
field members (Friedland and Alford, 1991). the overarching emphasis on similarity
These field-level ‘logics’ provided organiza- remained a constant. The organizational field
tions with schemas to guide their behavior. was conceived as predominantly static in its
For example, Marquis (2003) highlighted configuration, unitary in its makeup and
the cultural-cognitive templates that guided the formed around common technologies, indus-
construction of inter-corporate network ties. tries, or discrete network ties (DiMaggio,
Firms located in communities that began before 1995; Greenwood and Hinings, 1996).
the era of auto and air travel had more locally Regulative, normative and cognitive influ-
based director connections than firms located ences bred homogeneity in the aggregate.
in communities that began after auto and air But this emphasis within the literature soon
travel became prevalent. Moreover, this logic became the subject of criticism.
of locally based network ties continued to guide
the behavior of the firms in older communities
long after auto and air travel became prevalent. ORGANIZATIONAL FIELDS:
In other work, Thornton (2001) studied PRESENT CONFIGURATIONS
the evolution of logics within the higher
education publishing industry and found that Beginning in the late 1990s, scholars argued
acquisition patterns varied according to which that the institutional literature placed too
134 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

much emphasis on the homogeneity of orga- 1995; Kraatz and Zajak, 1996; Greenwood
nizational populations and not the processes and Hinings, 1996). This new line of reason-
that created this outcome (Hirsch, 1997). ing attended to several key aspects of
This focus on isomorphism as the ‘master field-level processes: moving beyond stabil-
hypothesis’ (Hoffman and Ventresca, 2002) ity and inertia to introduce notions of change
was seen by many as an unfortunate outcome within the field; considering the role of
of early theory development and the misrec- organizational self-interests and agency
ognized empirical insights possible from within that context (Covaleski and Dirsmith,
institutional analyses. Critics contended that 1988; DiMaggio, 1988; Perrow, 1985) and
it facilitated a popular misconception of the advancing the view that some firms can
theory as embodying stability and inertia as respond strategically to institutional
its defining characteristics. Homogeneity of pressures (Oliver, 1991) to become what
form and practice was treated as evidence of might be called institutional entrepreneurs
institutional theories of organization (Kraatz (DiMaggio, 1988; Fligstein, 1997; Zucker,
and Zajac, 1996). DiMaggio, reflecting on 1988; Lawrence, 1999).
‘what theory is not’ (1995) suggested that The first target for reconfiguring concep-
core institutional claims in his oft-cited 1983 tions of the field addressed the notion of
paper (DiMaggio and Powell, 1983) suffered change. As observers of the social world,
asymmetric attention: scholars knew that change happened even
Somewhat to my surprise, … papers … cited our within highly institutionalized contexts. Yet
paper as support for the proposition that all organ- prevailing theory did not handle such
izations become like all others, regardless of field. occurrences adequately, in part because of
Somehow the network argument that we authors the way in which scholars defined and
regarded as so central had been deleted in the
operationalized organizational fields. Where
paper’s reception. Within a few more years, the
paper had turned into a kind of ritual citation, previous definitions of the field centered
affirming the view that, well, organizations are around organizations with a common tech-
kind of wacky, and (despite the presence of ‘collec- nology or market (i.e. SIC classification), the
tive rationality’ in the paper’s subtitle) people are field began to be seen as forming around
never rational (DiMaggio, 1995: 395).
the issues that became important to the
Scholars called for efforts to ‘end the interests and objectives of a specific collec-
family quarrel’ between old and new institu- tive of organizations (Hoffman, 1999).
tionalism (Hirsch and Lounsbury, 1997) and Issues defined what the field was, drawing
to bring agency, politics and change ‘back’ linkages that may not have been previously
into the institutional literature (DiMaggio, present.
1988; Brint and Karabel, 1991; Hirsch and This important clarification led to a con-
Lounsbury, 1997; Perrow, 1986; DiMaggio, ception of the organizational field that would
1995; Greenwood and Hinings, 1996), bring together various field constituents with
resurrecting it from the earlier traditions of incongruent purposes, not common technolo-
macro-organizational literature (i.e. Selznick, gies or industries that assured some com-
1947). In all, these criticisms were aimed monality of interests. Rather than locales of
at redressing the over-socialized view isomorphic dialogue, the field became con-
(Granovetter, 1985), that depicted recipients tested; a ‘field of struggles’ (Bourdieu and
of field-level influence as a homogenous col- Wacquant, 1992) where constituents engaged
lection of organizational actors, each behav- in ‘a war or, if one prefers, a distribution of
ing according to a social script designed by the specific capital which, accumulated in the
the social environment. course of previous wars, orients future strate-
In response, emergent studies examined gies’ (Calhoun, 1993: 86). Organizations
organizational field member actions in light engage in field-level conflict, out of which
of their institutional contexts (i.e. Holm, they gain skills and capital for future conflict.
ORGANIZATIONAL FIELDS: PAST, PRESENT AND FUTURE 135

Thus, the organizational field became seen Seo and Creed (2002) highlighted an impor-
as dynamic and capable of moving towards tant interest that served as an impetus for
something other than isomorphism; evolving change: field members’ need to reconcile
both through the entry or exit of particular contradictory institutional arrangements.
organizations or populations (Barnett and According to the authors, organizational
Carroll, 1993; Hoffman, 1999; Scott, Reuf, fields were connected to and embedded
Mendel and Caronna, 2000) and through an within other and conflicting institutional
alteration of the interaction patterns and systems. As field members tried to reconcile
power balances among them (Brint and these differences by bringing the various
Karabel, 1991; Greenwood and Hinings, institutional rules in line with their needs and
1996). Others added that fields remained interests, the fields inevitably changed.
conflicted even when institutional norms Most recently, Schneiberg (2007) has
were apparently ‘settled’ because powerful suggested that change and variation comes
actors were continually working to maintain from within fields. If fields are indeed places
their legitimacy (Lounsbury and Glynn, where struggle and contestation take place,
2001). With the field defined more in terms then inevitably these struggles leave behind
of contestation and debate, institutions were organizational practices and forms that suffer
seen more as ‘the products of human design, defeat. These ideas may lay dormant for a
[and] the outcomes of purposive action by time, but field members often resurrect these
instrumentally oriented individuals’ expired forms of organization and practice
(DiMaggio and Powell, 1991: 8), such that which in turn, leads to increased variation
we may expect to find more opportunity for within the field.
deviance and agency among field members These theoretical accounts of change were
(Hirsch, 1997). used to develop new empirical insights.
Several authors developed theoretical Emergent research looked not at homogene-
accounts of the sources of agency, change, ity but at variation and change among organ-
and variety within institutions and organiza- izations within a field as signs of institutional
tional fields. Oliver (1991) suggested that processes. For instance, by investigating the
organizations crafted strategic responses and decline of the conglomerate organizational
engaged in a multitude of tactics when con- form among the 500 largest American indus-
fronted with the pressures presented by the trial firms, Davis, Diekmann and Tinsley
institutional environment. She argued that an (1994) studied the abandonment of a
organization’s willingness and ability to well-institutionalized practice among organi-
conform to institutional pressures depended zations within a field rather than the adoption
on why these pressures were being exerted of such practices. Lounsbury (2001)
(cause), who was exerting them (con- provided an explanation of the institutional
stituents), what these pressures were factors that influenced variation in the adop-
(content), how or by what means they were tion of two recycling practices among U.S.
exerted (control), and where they occurred colleges and universities. The study high-
(context). From this perspective, all organi- lighted the internal organizational dynamics
zations within a field did not march quietly of colleges that chose to incorporate recy-
down the path towards homogeneity. cling duties into current waste management
Greenwood and Hinings (1996) pushed policies in relation to those colleges that
further to combine thoughts from both the chose to create a new recycling administrator
old and new institutionalism literatures by position.
developing a framework for understanding This newfound emphasis on institutional
how the internal interests and conflicts of an change culminated with the publication of a
organization’s members influenced the orga- special issue of the Academy of Management
nization’s response to institutional pressures. Journal, with each article in this volume
136 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

seeking to interpret change and agency importance, and organizational responsibility


within an organizational field through the for recycling were interpreted within these
lens of institutional theory (Dacin, Goodstein networks helped account for variation in
and Scott, 2002). organizational response to this issue. By link-
But, despite the insights that this new area ing theory and argument from cognitive strat-
of research brought to bear on organizational egy theory on issue interpretation to
fields, early notions which implied that institutional analysis, the authors provided an
individual organizations can respond strate- explanation of heterogeneity in field-level
gically to field pressures (Oliver, 1991) or behavior.
may strategically influence the process of Other work focused on the interconnected-
field change (Lawrence, 1999) treated the ness of organizations and the field by analyz-
organization and the field as separate and ing the role of institutional entrepreneurs
distinct. The firm ‘responded’ to pressures by (DiMaggio, 1988; Fligstein, 1997;
either adapting to or resisting those Lawrence, 1999) in shaping the discourse,
pressures. Critics argued that the interaction norms and the structures that guide organiza-
between firm and field was not unidirectional tional action (Maguire, Hardy and Lawrence,
nor was it free from interpretation and filter- 2004). As in all field-level debates, certain
ing processes. This introduced concerns for organizations have the ability to influence the
sense-making, issue interpretation, selective rules of the game (Fligstein, 1990). Yet, even
attention, and cognitive framing among field powerful actors cannot simply impose new
members (Dutton and Dukerich, 1991; Scott, logics and norms on a field. At some level,
1994; Hoffman and Ocasio, 2001; Hoffman the norms must be accepted by other actors
and Ventresca, 2002). The demands of the (Beckert, 1999). The actors that lobby for the
field were not uniformly understood by all acceptance of these new logics, norms, and
members. Organization-level dynamics practices illustrate the work that institutional
caused field members to filter and alter envi- entrepreneurs engage in to create and build
ronmental demands. Further, members trans- legitimacy.
mitted their interests back towards the field. Suddaby and Greenwood’s (2005) study of
The process of interaction became recursive the creation of multidisciplinary practices
as the social structure of the field became provided insight into this process. The estab-
both the ‘medium and outcome of the lishment of practices that included both
reproduction of practices. Structure enters accountants and lawyers threatened the
simultaneously into the constitution of social previously agreed upon boundaries between
practices, and “exists” in the generating the accounting and legal professions. Thus,
moments of this constitution’ (Giddens, creating a firm that included both lawyers
1979). and accountants within the same hierarchy
Scott (1994) claimed that the essence of required institutional entrepreneurs to
the field perspective was its ability to analyze provide a legitimating account for this orga-
the ways in which organizations enact their nizational form. To build legitimacy
environment and are simultaneously enacted entrepreneurs developed rhetorical strategies
upon by the same environment. The work of which served two purposes. First, they
Bansal and Penner (2002) illustrated this included institutional vocabularies that
process by investigating the interpretive articulated the logic behind new organiza-
processes among four newspaper publishers. tional practices and forms. Second, these
The authors highlighted the importance of rhetorical strategies included language which
regional networks in influencing the frames accounted for the pace and necessity of
and enactment processes developed to change within the organizational field.
address the recycled newsprint issue. They Recent discussions have taken the notion
found that the way in which feasibility, of the institutional entrepreneur further by
ORGANIZATIONAL FIELDS: PAST, PRESENT AND FUTURE 137

acknowledging that institutional entrepre- in highly-structured fields of activity


neurs do not act alone or in isolation. (Edelman, 1990; Guthrie and Roth, 1999;
Individual agents form political networks Washington and Ventresca, 2001). For exam-
and coalitions to act as ‘important motors of ple, Zilber’s (2006) study highlighted the
institution-building, deinstitutionalization, ways in which Israeli society, culture, and
and reinstitutionalization in organizational fields are intertwined. High technology was
fields’ (Rao, Monin and Durand, 2003: 796). mythologized as a tool, enabling the creation
This conception provided a bridge between of useful products, an area where gifted indi-
institutional theory and social movement viduals excelled, and as a vehicle for national
theory (Davis, McAdam, Scott and Zald, development and societal progress within the
2005), focusing attention on the ability of Israeli popular press. Each of these myths was
social movements to give rise to new organi- found at the level of the organizational field
zational fields and change the demography of as high technology companies incorporated
existing organization fields (Rao, Morrill and elements of these myths in the job descrip-
Zald, 2000). tions contained within employment advertise-
Social movement scholars have long rec- ments. As a result, rationalizations of the
ognized the connection between their work benefits and purposes of high technology to
and organizations (McCarthy and Zald, 1977; Israeli society were incorporated within the
Strang and Soule, 1998; Campbell, 2005). employment activities of the high technology
McCarthy and Zald (1977) incorporated con- organizational field.
cepts from organization theory to develop In sum, the critiques of new institutional
their resource mobilization perspective. theory led to streams of field-level research
According to this perspective, the availability that focused on change, variation, and
and accumulation of resources served as an agency discussed above. But, while the past
impetus for the formation of social movement and present of organizational research dif-
organizations that bear a remarkable resem- fered from one another in terms of the out-
blance to other goal-directed, hierarchical come studied, they were connected by their
organizations. Moreover, those social move- conceptualization of fields as ‘things’ that
ment organizations with similar preferences produced outcomes. More recent critiques
for change constituted the social movement have suggested that the future of field
industry, a unit of analysis not unlike the research lies not in the further emphasis on
organizational field. Organizational change outcomes but instead in conceptualizing
agents became parts of these collective move- fields as mechanisms (Hoffman and
ments, using shared and accumulated Ventresca, 2002; Davis and Marquis, 2005).
resources and power to ‘overcome historical This refocus allows for the specification of
inertia, undermine the entrenched power collective rationality and the possibility that
structures in the field or triumph over alterna- fields serve as mechanisms for bringing
tive projects of change’ (Guillen, 2006: 43). about phenomena other than similarity
These actions were often conducted in oppo- (DiMaggio and Powell, 1983; Washington
sition to others in similarly configured collec- and Ventresca, 2001). We address these
tive movements (Zald and Useem, 1987; themes in the third section of this chapter.
Meyer and Staggenborg, 1996).
Other work sought to understand the bidi-
rectional influence of organizations and fields
built on the linkages between organizational ORGANIZATIONAL FIELDS:
fields, culture, and societal institutions. In THE FUTURE
particular, researchers sought to explain how
ideas and beliefs about organizational strate- In the final portion of this paper, we offer our
gies and practice became standard and spread thoughts on the future of organizational field
138 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

research. We develop our arguments regard- proximity of actors (Warren, 1967) or


ing future directions based on the critiques of issues (Hoffman, 1999), fields as relational
past and present research as focusing on the spaces stresses the notion that organizations
outcomes of field membership as opposed to become connected within the same field
the processes that hold the members of a when they begin to take note of one
field together. We encourage those involved another. This does not mean that actors
in organizational field research to focus on formalize their relations via hierarchical
collective rationality within fields: how it is arrangements or network ties (Djelic and
developed, which field members contribute Sahlin-Andersson, 2006). Instead, one actor
to its development and maintenance, how it takes note of another and through this
is transmitted to other actors, and how it process of referencing one another, actors
changes over time. bring a field into existence. Out of a rela-
Scott (2001) defined the field as a commu- tional notion of the field emerge several
nity of organizations that partake in a critical issues concerning formation, evolu-
common meaning system and whose partici- tion, and boundaries.
pants interact more frequently and fatefully
with one another than with actors outside the ● Why does one relational space with this set of
field. DiMaggio and Powell (1983) defined actors form and not another? Why do disparate
organizations and populations come together at
the field as those organizations that in the
the field level? How and why do fields form?
aggregate represent a recognized area of What processes drive some organizations to
institutional life. While both of these defini- interact more frequently and fatefully with one
tions treat the field as a collective of organi- another than with other organizations, thus
zations, they also present an underlying creating the boundaries of a field?
notion that represents a future conception of
the field; one where the field is a locale in Research must highlight the organizational
which organizations relate to or involve dynamics that lead actors to engage one
themselves with one another. A definition another and start the field-level structuring or
that in some ways brings us back to the restructuring process. It is not evident, for
influence of Bourdieu – where a field is as example, why petrochemical companies
much about the relationship between the would willingly engage environmental
actors as it is about the effect of the field on groups without understanding the dynamics
the actors. of field-level engagement in field studies
To move away from the current focus on (i.e. Hoffman, 1999). Future research should
field outcomes and towards an understand- investigate the dynamics that lead to field
ing of why field-level interactions remain creation and the contextual factors that lead
vital to organizations, fields must be seen, to one field form over another. For example,
not as containers for the community of relations that form around a common tech-
organizations, but instead as relational nology, say coal production, are not likely to
spaces that provide an organization with the be similar to those relations that form around
opportunity to involve itself with other an issue such as environmental protection.
actors (Wooten, 2006). Fields are richly Such differences will undoubtedly influence
contextualized spaces where disparate the character of the field (Stinchcombe,
organizations involve themselves with one 1965) and the specification of collective
another in an effort to develop collective rationality.
understandings regarding matters that are Entrance to or engagement within the field
consequential for organizational and field- is often precipitated by disruptive events
level activities. such as exogenous shocks that provide the
Moving beyond the notion of fields as impetus for organizations to make sense of a
being constructed around the physical reconfigured environment. Disruptive events,
ORGANIZATIONAL FIELDS: PAST, PRESENT AND FUTURE 139

such as the threat of a hostile takeover become contested. Thus, the Grammy
(Davis, 1991), regulatory changes (Edelman, Awards represent the site where conflicts
1992), environmental catastrophes (Hoffman among members are engaged and resolved.
and Ocasio, 2001) or rituals (Anand and The petition for new categories represents a
Watson, 2004) create contradictions within disruptive event and the current members
the environment (Seo and Creed, 2002) and engaging with the relational space of the
force organizations to (re)analyze their sur- field (i.e. the Grammy Awards) develop a
roundings. Fields serve as the sites in which new collective rationality about which artists
organizations come together to do this sense- belong within the field and which do not.
making work. Future research will address An actor’s attempt to gain membership
what drives organizations to interact with one strains the existing order within an estab-
another and how those configurations are lished field. Field members that once had
formed. It will also hold open the possibility limited interactions with one another may
that the field is not always in use. Instead, the band together because of a common interest
field comes alive when organizations decide in locking a particular actor out of the field,
to interact with one another and this is the thus changing the pre-existing coalitions.
moment that researchers are encouraged to Under such circumstances, every aspect of a
direct their attention towards as it provides field’s character is challenged. As new actors
tentative answers to the questions now being push for admittance, the interorganizational
posed. structures and coalitions that once supported
the field no longer make sense and the
● Once formed, how do fields evolve and change? mutual awareness among the field members
What are the dynamics by which engagement that they are involved in a common enter-
takes place? prise must be revisited.
This leads to an appreciation for con-
The essence of a field is its ability to serve as tending logics as a force for institutional
the meeting place where organizations have change (Seo and Creed, 2002; Suddaby and
the opportunity to involve themselves with Greenwood, 2005). Reay and Hinings
one another. Positioning fields in this (2005), for example, develop a theoretical
manner brings scholarship back to the core model to explain change in mature organi-
concepts of the literature, refocusing on the zational fields by emphasizing the role of
development of ‘collective rationality’ competing institutional logics as part of a
(Scott, 2001), rather than the impact that col- radical change process. Rather than
lective rationality has on the field. But that explaining the sources of change, they
field structure is not static. It evolves in investigate how a field becomes re-estab-
makeup, interconnections and conceptual lished after the implementation of a radical
frames. structural change. Studying fields at these
For example, Anand and Watson’s (2004) moments of restructuring increases our
study of the Grammy Awards illuminates this understanding of how collective rationality
emerging conception of the organizational is developed.
field. In addition to providing the music
industry’s members with an opportunity to ● How can the activities within field-level popula-
meet annually and celebrate one another’s tions be identified and defined? How do field
accomplishments, the music industry as a members relate to one another?
field is engaged at this event. Artists fight for
the creation of categories particular to their While field constituents’ actions may be
genre to legitimate their status as field mem- initially conducted in opposition to one
bers. The addition of new genres to the music another (Zald and Useem, 1987; Meyer and
industry causes the boundaries of the field to Staggenborg, 1996; Davis, McAdam, Scott
140 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

and Zald, 2005), protracted institutional creation stage of the field, it is highly
engagement can yield a gradual merging of unlikely that all members of an organiza-
interests with a concurrent alteration in the tional field would need to advocate on the
structure of the field itself. However, until field’s behalf. A more feasible scenario
that happens, the field is not a collective of would involve a select number of field mem-
isomorphic actors, but an intertwined bers devoting their time and energy towards
constellation of actors who hold differing this task while other field members focus
perspectives and competing logics with their attention on other activities also vital to
regard to their individual and collective the field’s emergence. With greater focus on
purpose (McCarthy and Zald, 1977). As the different types of work that actors
such, an appreciation for the diversity of perform comes a need for a language to
activities and beliefs must be incorporated articulate these distinct institutional roles.
into field-level arguments, directing atten- Labels for each member of the community
tion towards the development of a terminol- of organizations become necessary accord-
ogy for the differing roles that field ing to the type of institutional activities per-
members play. formed. General terminology like buyer,
Every social group has roles that members supplier, or regulatory agency will no longer
must adopt to perpetuate the group’s exis- provide a sufficient explanation of the role
tence. Moreover, these roles typically confer organizations adopt or the work they
different responsibilities for the actors perform within the field.
within them. For instance, the role of Labeling organizations in this manner
‘mother’ has a different set of behavioral will provide deeper clarity on the collective
expectations than the role of ‘brother.’ understanding held by each field member
Within field research, we have been neglect- regarding which actors perform what roles
ful of the differing roles that field members within the field. Just as organizational
have. The exceptions may be our focus on members can reduce uncertainty over work
entrepreneurs or change agents. Yet, even in roles by developing agreement about the
this case, we label a member as an entrepre- responsibilities that come with organiza-
neur or not, a change agent or conversely a tional roles, field members can also reduce
protector of the status-quo. Conceptualizing the level of uncertainty they face by devel-
the field as a relational space dictates that we oping a corresponding understanding of
take a closer look at the way in which actors what type of work each field member is
relate to one another, especially the roles responsible for given their role within the
that certain members adopt to advance the field.
field. Though we strongly encourage scholars to
Lawrence and Suddaby’s (2005) review of move away from the focus on outcomes
institutional theory provides a typology of within field research, we recognize that it
the different types of activities that actors may be difficult to wean ourselves off of this
engage in to create, maintain, and disrupt line of inquiry. Therefore, we highlight
institutions. For example, during the cre- several avenues of research based on the
ation stage actors advocate on behalf of an relational space perspective on fields.
institution by mobilizing political and regu-
latory support. During the maintenance ● Beyond discerning appropriate behavior, what do
stage, advocacy becomes less important and the disparate organizations hope to gain from
actors instead aim to police the activities of their involvement with one another?
others to ensure the institution’s continua-
tion. This suggests that at the level of the As we move beyond the depiction of
organizational field, different actors engage organizations as mere recipients of institu-
in various tasks. For example, during the tional pressures, it is also time to advance
ORGANIZATIONAL FIELDS: PAST, PRESENT AND FUTURE 141

conceptions of what organizations take ● How is field-level interaction affected by mecha-


away from field membership. If we take the nisms and structures internal to the individual
field as a relational space, we can envision organization, and how does this interaction
other uses for the field beyond discerning change those mechanisms and structures?
appropriate behavior. Field-level interac-
tions are best understood as mechanisms by Future organizational field research will
which other organizational phenomena focus on the processes of participating in a
occur. For example, some have begun to field and what this participation ultimately
investigate the field-level processes by means for the inner workings of an organiza-
which organizational identities are formed. tion (Hoffman, 2001). To date, field research
Within the organizational literature, identity has largely provided an explanation of
is typically presented as an organizational- macro to macro transitions; field-level inter-
level property developed internally by the actions lead to changes in structure, culture,
members of an organization. While research and output at the aggregate field levels.
has suggested that organizational identity is Moving forward, field research will serve as
influenced by outside parties (Dutton and a bridge between the macro and micro by
Dukerich, 1991; Elsbach and Kramer, providing detailed explanations of how
1996), the general consensus holds that an field-level interactions influence internal
organization’s identity is what members see organizational phenomena. This direction
as central, distinctive, and enduring about acknowledges that the field is made up of
the organization (Albert and Whetten, various actors that constitute a community
1985). Wedlin (2006) challenges this con- of organizations (DiMaggio and Powell,
ception of organizational identity formation 1983; Scott, 1995, 2001) while simultane-
by positioning the organizational field ously acknowledging that organizational and
as the site in which organizations develop field-level factors are interconnected in a
their identity. In this view, identity forma- reciprocal relationship.
tion is seen as an inherently social and Future research will continue to bridge
interorganizational process and the field is the old and new institutionalisms in an
the place in which organizations take on this effort to understand how field membership
task. aids other intra-organizational processes. As
Other work has sought to understand discussed earlier, prior attempts to connect
how field membership influences phenom- these literatures imported the concepts of
ena such as hiring (Williamson and Cable, agency and interests from the old-institu-
2003) and collaborative tie formation tionalism to explain how organizational
(Kenis and Knoke, 2002), both processes that field members resisted isomorphic pres-
had been thought to be reflective of sures. While this represents progress on one
dynamics internal to the organization. This is front, problems still remain with the way in
not to suggest that scholars recast every which agency and interests are conceptual-
organizational process as being dependent ized in the institutional domain. Currently,
upon field-level membership, as this both the old and new institutionalisms pres-
would push the literature towards an over- ent the concepts of agency and interests in
socialized view once again. However, it an atomistic fashion. Each holds that an
does suggest that envisioning organizational organization’s self-interests are developed
fields as influential to the development of internally and cause the organization to
intra-organizational processes exposes a undertake some action such as cooptation or
host of possibilities for research projects that resistance (Oliver, 1991). Yet, Scott (1991)
shed light on the institutional factors insisted that institutions define the ends and
that influence an organization’s daily shape the means by which interests are
functioning. determined and pursued. The formation and
142 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

pursuit of interests must be seen as the prod- 2006). In the process of translation, the
uct of field-level engagement. Just as original meaning of an organizational practice
research has recast organizational identity changes as individual field members incorpo-
formation as a field-level process, so too rate these items into their own organization.
will research reconceptualize organizational Much like literal translations from one lan-
agency and self-interests by focusing on the guage to another often have no meaning,
possibility that field-level engagement incorporating a prevailing practice ‘as-is’ into
enables an individual organization’s pursuit an organization may not yield the intended
of self-interests. This will redirect more consequences. Instead, field members must
attention to the way in which the field pro- determine how to bend and shape a prevailing
vides an organization with a context to enact organizational practice such that it will hold
agency. meaning for their own organization and the
field facilitates this translation process. As
● How do institutions spread or diffuse within field- organizations relate to one another within the
level populations? field, they can determine how other members
incorporated the predominant practices and
Just as institutional scholars (particularly use this knowledge to determine how best to
within North America) emphasized mimetic mold these practices for use within their own
or taken-for-granted forces as the primary organization.
mechanism by which organizational field Another byproduct of the emphasis on the
members became homogeneous to one diffusion model has been that theoretical and
another (Mizruchi and Fein, 1999), we have empirical work using this model leaves the
also emphasized the diffusion model as an impression that the widespread adoption
explanation for how institutional rules are of a practice within an organizational field
adopted and spread throughout an organiza- equals institutionalization. Zeitz, Mittal and
tional field. Theoretical and empirical works McAulay (1999) caution us to reconsider.
in the institutional literature imply that orga- The authors suggest that, just as organiza-
nizational practices spread through fields like tions adopt a practice en masse, they may
wild-fires, with members succumbing to also abandon the practice with the same
pressures to adopt these practices. Moreover, vigor in a short amount of time. Instead of
field members adopt these practices intact focusing on the presence of a practice at a
without adjusting or manipulating them to fit finite moment in time, the authors implore
their specific needs or context. Yet, more researchers to focus on the micro-processes
recent research suggests that the uncritical that allow a practice to take hold and become
adoption of practices encouraged by the dif- ‘entrenched’ within an organizational field
fusion process accounts for the failure of (Zeitz et al., 1999). Future research will draw
these practices to deliver the promised benefit attention to the relational dynamics which
to organizational functioning (Kitchener, facilitate not only the widespread adoption
2002). of certain practices over others, but also
As we begin to view the field as a highly provide greater understanding of the intra-
interactive relational space, relying so heavily organizational processes (i.e. identity, inter-
upon the diffusion model will no longer suf- ests, agency) that facilitate the entrenchment
fice. Work within the European tradition pro- of certain practices over others.
vides an alternative understanding of how
institutional norms and rules take hold at the
field level. Instead of diffusing through a field, CONCLUSION
organizational practices are translated from
the institutional level to the organizational This chapter offers views on how the
level (Czarniawska and Joerges, 1996; Zilber, central concept of institutional theory – the
ORGANIZATIONAL FIELDS: PAST, PRESENT AND FUTURE 143

organizational field – has changed over the ACKNOWLEDGMENTS


past three decades. It presents a trajectory
that began by focusing on the dynamics that We would like to thank John Campbell, Marie-Laure
led to conformity in behavior among organi- Djelic, and the editors for helpful comments on pre-
zations and evolved towards understanding vious drafts. The first author would like to thank
Dartmouth College's Sociology Department and
the dynamics that allow for heterogeneity, Policy program for their support during the writing of
variation, and change. The chapter ends with this chapter.
thoughts on where the future of organiza-
tional field research lies, suggesting that
scholars orient their research towards the REFERENCES
processes that encourage field formation and
collective rationality. The future of organiza- Albert, Stuart, and David A. Whetten. 1985.
tional field research is linked to the future of ‘Organizational Identity.’ Pp. 263–295 in
organization theory in general. Research in Organizational Behavior, edited by
In speculating about the prospects for Robert Sutton and Barry Staw. JAI Press Inc.
organization theory in the twenty-first cen- Anand, N., and Mary R. Watson. 2004.
tury, Davis and Marquis (2005) suggest that ‘Tournament Rituals in the Evolution of Fields:
research in this area has moved away from The Case of the Grammy Awards.’ Academy
being paradigm driven to being problem of Management Journal 47: 59–80.
driven. As such, field-level research is ready Bansal, Pratima, and Wendy J. Penner. 2002.
‘Interpretations of Institutions: The Case of
to make the transition from testing the core
Recycled Newsprint.’ Pp. 311–326 in
ideas of the new institutional theory para- Organizations, Policy, and the Natural
digm to investigating fields as sites where Environment: Institutional and Strategic
problems of organizing are debated among Perspectives, edited by Petter Holm and
disparate actors. The domain of organiza- Marc Ventresca. Stanford, CA: Stanford
tional fields is now ready to move away from University Press.
the simple outcomes of institutional Barnett, Willam, and Glenn Carroll. 1993.
processes, to instead explain why the field ‘How Institutional Constraints Affected the
remains integral to understanding how organ- Organization of Early US Telephony.’ Journal
izations construct solutions to the problems of Law, Economics and Organizations 9.
of the twenty-first century. This moves Bourdieu, Pierre. 1990. The Logic of Practice.
Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.
beyond notions of institutions as barriers, as
Bourdieu, Pierre, and Loic Wacquant. 1992.
always taken-for-granted and as leading Invitation to Reflexive Sociology. Chicago:
towards isomorphism and, instead, refocuses University of Chicago Press.
on field-level dynamics, collective rationality Bourdieu, Pierre. 1993. The Field of Cultural
within these fields and the behavior of indi- Production: Essays on Art and Literature.
vidual organizations as integral parts of these New York: Columbia University Press.
processes. Researchers will return to a focus Brint, Steven, and Jerome Karabel. 1991.
on the structuration processes with a particu- ‘Institutional Origins and Transformations:
lar interest in understanding how the struc- The Case of American Community
turing of fields contributes to intra- and Colleges.’ Pp. 337–360 in The New
interorganizational processes. While not a Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis,
edited by Paul J. DiMaggio and Walter W.
complete agenda for future research, this
Powell. Chicago: The University of Chicago
represents a starting point for researchers Press.
wishing to understand the processes that Calhoun, Craig. 1993. ‘Habitus, Field,
lead organizations to relate to one another and Capital: The Question of Historical
and to ultimately do so within the space we Specificity.’ Pp. 61–88 in Bourdieu:
have come to know as an organizational Critical Perspectives, edited by Craig
field. Calhoun, Edward LiPuma, and Moishe
144 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Postone. Chicago: University of Chicago DiMaggio, Paul J. 1988. ‘Interest and Agency
Press. in Institutional Theory.’ Pp. 3–21 in
Campbell, John L. 2005. ‘Where Do We Institutional Patterns and Organizations,
Stand? Common Mechanisms in edited by Lynne Zucker. Cambridge, MA:
Organizations and Social Movements Ballinger.
Research,’ in Social Movements and DiMaggio, Paul J., and Walter W. Powell. 1991.
Organization Theory, edited by Gerald F. ‘Introduction.’ Pp. 1–40 in The New
Davis, Doug McAdam, W. Richard Scott, and Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis,
Mayer N. Zald. New York: Cambridge edited by Paul J. DiMaggio and Walter W.
University Press. Powell. Chicago: The University of Chicago
Covaleski, Mark A., and Mark W. Dirsmith. Press.
1988. ‘An Institutional Perspective on the DiMaggio, Paul J. 1995. ‘Comments on ‘What
Rise, Social Transformation and Fall of a Theory is Not’.’ Administrative Science
University Budget Category.’ Administrative Quarterly 40: 391–397.
Science Quarterly 33: 562–587. Djelic, Marie-Laure, and Kerstin Sahlin-
Czarniawska, Barbara, and Bernward Jorges. Andersson. 2006. ‘Introduction: A World of
1996. ‘Travels of Ideas.’ Pp. 13–48 in Governance: The Rise of Transnational
Translating Organizational Change, edited by Regulation.’ Pp. 1–28 in Transnational
Barbara Czarniawska and Guje Sevon. Berlin: Governance: Institutional Dynamics of
Walter de Gruyter. Regulation, edited by Marie-Laure Djelic and
Dacin, M. Tina, Jerry Goodstein, and W. Kerstin Sahlin-Andersson. Cambridge:
Richard Scott. 2002. ‘Institutional Theory Cambridge University Press.
and Institutional Change: Introduction to the Dobbin, Frank, John R. Sutton, John W. Meyer,
Special Research Forum.’ Academy of and W. Richard Scott. 1993. ‘Equal
Management Journal 45: 45–57. Opportunity and the Construction of Internal
Davis, Gerald F. 1991. ‘Agents Without Labor Markets.’ American Journal of
Principles? The Spread of the Poison Pill Sociology 99.
Through the Intercorporate Network.’ Dutton, Jane E., and Janet M. Dukerich. 1991.
Administrative Science Quarterly 36: 583–613. ‘Keeping an Eye on the Mirror: Image and
Davis, Gerald F., Kristina A. Diekmann, and Identity in Organizational Adaptation.’
Catherine H. Tinsley. 1994. ‘The Decline Academy of Management Journal 34:
and Fall of the Conglomerate Firm in the 517–554.
1980s: The Deinstitutionalization of an Edelman, Lauren. 1990. ‘Legal Environments
Organizational Form.’ American Sociological and Organizational Governance: The
Review 59: 547–571. Expansion of Due Process in the American
Davis, Gerald F., and Henrich R. Greve. 1997. Workplace.’ American Journal of Sociology
‘Corporate Elite Networks and Governance 95: 1401–1440.
Changes in the 1980s.’ American Journal of Edelman, Lauren. 1992. ‘Legal Ambiguity
Sociology 103: 1–37. and Symbolic Structures: Organizational
Davis, Gerald F., Doug McAdam, W. Richard Mediation of Civil Rights Law.’ American
Scott, and Mayer N. Zald (Eds.). 2005. Journal of Sociology 97: 1531–1576.
Social Movements and Organization Elsbach, Kimberly D., and Roderick M. Kramer.
Theory. New York: Cambridge University Press. 1996. ‘Members’ Responses to Organiza-
Davis, Gerald F., and Christopher Marquis. tional Identity Threats: Encountering the
2005. ‘Prospects for Organization Theory in Countering the Business Week Rankings.’
the Early Twenty-First Century: Institutional Administrative Science Quarterly 41:
Fields and Mechanisms.’ Organization 442–476.
Science 16: 332–343. Fligstein, Neil. 1990. The Transformation of
DiMaggio, Paul J., and Walter W. Powell. Corporate Control. Cambridge, MA: Harvard
1983. ‘The Iron Cage Revisited: Institutional University Press.
Isomorphism and Collective Rationality Fligstein, Neil. 1997. ‘Social Skill and
in Organizational Fields.’ American Institutional Theory.’ American Behavioral
Sociological Review 48: 147–160. Scientist 40: 397–405.
ORGANIZATIONAL FIELDS: PAST, PRESENT AND FUTURE 145

Fligstein, Neil. 2001. The Architecture of to External Events.’ Organization Science 12:
Markets: An Economic Sociology of 21st 414–434.
Century Capitalist Societies. New York: Hoffman, Andrew, and Marc Ventresca (Eds.).
Cambridge University Press. 2002. Organizations, Policy, and the Natural
Friedland, Roger, and Robert R. Alford. 1991. Environment: Institutional and Strategic
‘Bringing Society Back In: Symbols, Practices, Perspectives. Stanford, CA: Stanford
and Institutional Contradictions.’ Pp. University Press.
232–266 in The New Institutionalism in Holm, Petter. 1995. ‘The Dynamics of
Organizational Analysis, edited by Paul J. Institutionalization: Transformation Process
DiMaggio and Walter W. Powell. Chicago: in Norwegian Fisheries.’ Administrative
The University of Chicago Press. Science Quarterly 40: 398–422.
Giddens, Anthony. 1979. Central Problems in Kelly, Erin, and Frank Dobbin. 1999. ‘Civil Rights
Social Theory: Action, Structure, and Law at Work: Sex Discrimination and the Rise
Contradiction in Social Analysis. Berkeley, of Maternity Leave Policies.’ American
CA: University of California Press. Journal of Sociology 105: 455–492.
Granovetter, Mark. 1985. ‘Economic Actions Kenis, Patrick, and David Knoke. 2002. ‘How
and Social Structure: The Problem of Organizational Field Networks Shape Interorga-
Embeddedness.’ American Journal of nization Tie-Formation Rates.’ Academy of
Sociology 91: 481–510. Management Review 27: 275–293.
Greenwood, Royston, and C.R. Hinings. 1996. Kitchener, Martin. 2002. ‘Mobilizing the Logic
‘Understanding Radical Organizational of Managerialism in Professional Fields: The
Change: Bringing Together the Old and the Case of Academic Health Centre Mergers.’
New Institutionalism.’ Academy of Organization Studies 23: 391–420.
Management Review 21: 1022–1054. Kraatz, Matthew S., and Edward J. Zajac. 1996.
Guillen, Mauro. 2006. The Taylorized Beauty of ‘Exploring the Limits of the New
the Mechanical: Scientific Management and Institutionalism: The Causes and Conse-
the Rise of Modernist Architecture. quences of Illegitimate Organizational
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Change.’ American Sociological Review 61:
Guthri, Doug, and Louise Roth. 1999. ‘The 812–836.
States, Courts, and Maternity Leave Policies Lawrence, Thomas B. 1999. ‘Institutional
in the US: Specifying Institutional Strategy.’ Journal of Management 25:
Mechanisms.’ American Sociological Review 161–188.
64: 41–63. Lawrence, Thomas B., and Roy Suddaby. 2006.
Hirsch, Paul. 1997. ‘Sociology without Social ‘Institutions and Institutional Work,’ in The
Structure: Neo-institutional Theory Meets a SAGE Handbook of Organization Studies,
Brave New World.’ American Journal of edited by Stewart Clegg. SAGE Publications.
Sociology 102: 1702–1723. Leblebici, Huseyin, Gerald R. Salancik, Anne
Hirsch, Paul, and Michael Lounsbury. 1997. Copay, and Tom King. 1991. ‘Institutional
‘Ending the Family Quarrel: Toward a Change and the Transformation of
Reconciliation of ‘Old’ and ‘New’ Interorganizational Fields: An Organizational
Institutionalisms.’ American Behavioral History of the U.S. Radio Broadcasting
Scientist 40: 406–418. Industry.’ Administrative Science Quarterly
Hoffman, Andrew J. 1999. ‘Institutional 36: 331–363.
Evolution and Change: Environmentalism Lindenberg, Siewart. 1998. ‘The Cognitive Turn
and the U.S. Chemical Industry.’ Academy of in Institutional Analysis: Beyond NIE, and
Management Journal 42: 351–371. NIS?,’ Journal of Institutional and Theoretical
Hoffman, Andrew. 2001. ‘Linking Organizational Economics 154: 716–727.
and Field-level Analyses: The Diffusion of Lounsbury, Michael, and Mary Ann Glynn.
Corporate Environmental Practice.’ 2001. ‘Cultural Entrepreneurship: Stories,
Organization & Environment 14: 133–156. legitimacy, and the acquisitions of resources.’
Hoffman, Andrew, and William Ocasio. 2001. Strategic Management Journal 22: 545–564.
‘Not All Events are Attended Equally: Toward Lounsbury, Michael. 2001. ‘Institutional
a Middle-Range Theory of Industry Attention sources of practice variation: Staffing college
146 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

and university recycling programs.’ Rao, Hayagreeva, Calvin Morrill, and Mayer
Administrative Science Quarterly 46: 29. N. Zald. 2002. ‘Power Plays: How Social
MaGuire, Steve, Cynthia Hardy, and Movements and Collective Action
Thomas B. Lawrence. 2004. ‘Institutional Create New Organizational Forms.’
Entrepreneurship in Emerging Fields: Research in Organizational Behavior 22:
HIV/AIDS Treatment Advocacy in Canada.’ 239–282.
Academy of Management Journal 47: Rao, Hayagreeva, Phillipe Monin, and Rodolphe
657–679. Durand. 2003. ‘Institutional Change in Toque
Marquis, Christopher. 2003. ‘The Pressure Ville: Nouvelle Cuisines an Identity Movement
of the Past: Network Imprinting in in French Gastronomy.’ American Journal of
Intercorporate Communities.’ Adminis- Sociology 108: 795–843.
trative Science Quarterly 48: 655–689. Reay, Trish, and C.R. Hinings. 2005. ‘The
McCarthy, John D., and Mayer N. Zald. 1977. Recomposition of an Organizational Field:
‘Resource Mobilization and Social Health Care in Alberta.’ Organization Studies
Movements: A Partial Theory.’ American 26: 351–384.
Journal of Sociology 82: 1212–1240. Schneiberg, Marc. 2007. ‘What’s on Path? Path
Meindl, James, Charles Stubbart, and Joseph Dependence, Organizational Diversity and
Porac. 1994. ‘Cognition Within and the Problem of Institutional Change in the
Between Organizations–5 Key Questions.’ US Economy, 1900–1950.’ Socio-Economic
Organization Science 5: 289–293. Review 5: 47–80.
Meyer, John W., and Brian Rowan. 1977. Scott, W. Richard. 1991. ‘Unpacking
‘Institutionalized Organizations: Formal Institutional Arguments.’ Pp. 164–182 in The
Structure as Myth and Ceremony.’ American New Institutionalism in Organizational
Journal of Sociology 83: 41–62. Analysis, edited by Paul J. DiMaggio and
Meyer, David S., and Suzanne Staggenborg. Walter W. Powell. Chicago: The University of
1996. ‘Movements, Countermovements, Chicago Press.
and the Structure of Political Opportunity.’ Scott, W. Richard, and John W. Meyer. 1992.
American Journal of Sociology 101: ‘The Organization of Societal Sectors.’ Pp.
1628–1660. 129–154 in Organizational Environments:
Mizruchi, Mark, and Lisa Fein. 1999. ‘The Rituals and Rationality, edited by John W.
Social Construction of Organizational Meyer and W. Richard Scott. Newbury Park,
Knowledge: A Study of the Uses of Coercive, CA: Sage Publications.
Mimetic, and Normative Isomorphism.’ Scott, W. Richard. 1994. ‘Conceptualizing
Administrative Science Quarterly 43: Organizational Fields: Linking Organizations
257–292. and Societal Systems.’ Pp. 203–221 in
Oakes, Leslie S., Barbara Townley, and David Systems Rationality and Partial Interests,
J. Cooper. 1998. ‘Business Planning edited by Hans-Ulrich Derlien, Uta Gerhardt,
as Pedagogy: Language and Control and Fritz W. Scharpf. Baden-Baden,
in a Changing Institutional Field.’ Germany: Nomos Verlagsgesselschaft.
Administrative Science Quarterly 43: Scott, W. Richard. 1995. Institutions and
257–292. Organizations. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage
Oliver, Christine. 1991. ‘Strategic Responses to Publications.
Institutional Processes.’ Academy of Scott, W. Richard, Martin Ruef, Peter Mendel,
Management Review 16: 145–179. and Carol Caronna. 2000. Institutional
Orru, Marco, Nicole Woolsey Biggart, and Gary Change and Healthcare Organizations: From
C. Hamilton. 1991. ‘Organizational Professional Dominance to Managed Care.
Isomorphism in East Asia.’ Pp. 361–389 in Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
The New Institutionalism in Organizational Scott, W. Richard. 2001. Institutions and
Analysis, edited by Walter W. Powell and Organizations. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage
Paul J. DiMaggio. Chicago: University of Publications.
Chicago Press. Selznick, Philip. 1949. TVA and the Grass
Perrow, Charles. 1986. Complex Organizations: Roots. Berkeley, CA: University of California
A Critical Essay. New York: McGraw-Hill, Inc. Press.
ORGANIZATIONAL FIELDS: PAST, PRESENT AND FUTURE 147

Selznick, Philip 1957. Leadership in The Role of Institutional Support


Administration: A Sociological Interpre- Mechanisms in the Incorporation of Higher
tation. Berkeley, CA: University of California Education Visibility Strategies, 1874–1995.’
Press. Organization Science 15: 82–97.
Seo, Myeong-Gu, and W.E. Douglass Creed. Wedlin, Linda. 2006. Ranking Business Schools:
2002. ‘Institutional Contradictions, Praxis, Forming Fields, Identities, and Boundaries in
and Institutional Change: A Dialectical International Management Education.
Perspective.’ Academy of Management Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar Publishing,
Review 27: 222–247. Inc.
Stinchcombe, Arthur L. 1965. ‘Social Structure Williamson, Ian O., and Daniel M. Cable. 2003.
and Organizations.’ Pp. 142–193 in ‘Organizational Hiring Patterns, Interfirm
Handbook of Organizations, edited by James Network Ties, and Interorganizational
G. March. Chicago: Rand McNally. Imitation.’ Academy of Management Journal
Strang, David, and Sarah A. Soule. 1998. 46: 349–358.
‘Diffusion in Organizations and Social Wooten, Melissa E. 2006. ‘The Evolution of the
Movements: From Hybrid Corn to Poison Black Higher Education Field, 1854–1996.’
Pills.’ Annual Review of Sociology 24: Unpublished Dissertation. Ann Arbor, MI:
265–290. University of Michigan.
Suddaby, Roy, and Royston Greenwood. 2005. Zald, Mayer N., and Bert Useem. 1987.
‘Rhetorical Strategies of Legitimacy.’ ‘Movement and Countermovement
Administrative Science Quarterly 50: 35–67. Interaction: Mobilization, Tactics, and State
Sutton, John R., and Frank Dobbin. 1996. ‘The Involvement,’ in Social Movements in an
Two Faces of Governance: Responses to Organizational Society, edited by Mayer N.
Legal Uncertainty in U.S. Firms, 1955 to Zald and John D. McCarthy. New Brunswick,
1985.’ American Journal of Sociology 61: NJ: Transaction Publishers.
794–811. Zeitz, Gerald, Vikas Mittal, and Brian McAuly.
Thornton, Patricia H. 2001. ‘Personal Versus 1999. ‘Distinguishing Adoption and
Market Logics of Control: A Historically Entrenchment of Management Practices:
Contingent Theory of the Risk of A Framework Analysis.’ Organization Studies
Acquisition.’ Organization Science 12: 20: 741–776.
294–311. Zilber, Tamar. 2006. ‘The Work of the Symbolic
Tolbert, Pamela S., and Lynne G. Zucker. 1983. in Institutional Processes: Translation of
‘Institutional Sources of Change in the Rational Myths in Israeli High Tech,’
Formal Structure of Organizations: The Academy of Management Journal 49:
Diffusion of Civil Service Reform, 281–303.
1880–1935.’ Administrative Science Zucker, Lynne G. 1977. ‘The Role of
Quarterly 28: 22–39. Institutionalization in Cultural Persistence.’
Warren, Ronald L. 1967. ‘The Interorganiza- American Sociological Review 42: 726–743.
tional Field As a Focus for Investigation.’ Zucker, Lynne (Eds.). 1988. Institutional
Administrative Science Quarterly 12: 396–419. Patterns and Organizations. Cambridge, MA:
Washington, Marvin, and Marc Ventresca. Ballinger.
2004. ‘How Organizations Change:
SECTION II

Institutional Dynamics
5
The Work of Meanings in
Institutional Processes and
Thinking
Tammar B. Zilber

The interest in the role of meanings in institu- conceptual formulations, I will argue that
tional theory is both old and new. While mean- studies that examine the dynamics of mean-
ings were at the heart of early neo-institutional ings in institutionalization reinterpret the
thinking (e.g. Meyer & Rowan, 1977; Zucker, social constructionist approach from which
1977; DiMaggio & Powell, 1983), and while institutional theory had originated, and offer
they constitute much of its unique contribution a unique perspective that complements the
vis-á-vis other open-system theories (Scott, mainstream studies. Specifically, the focus
2007), the very exploration of meaning was on meanings highlights the particular, con-
somewhat neglected later on, especially in the textual, the political, and the on-going
empirical inquiry of institutions. Thus, our processes involved in institutionalization.
understanding of the work of meaning in insti- My aim is twofold: Offering a reading of
tutional processes had been limited (Dobbin, institutional processes as depicted by studies
1994a; Friedland & Alford, 1991; Hasselbladh that deal with meanings; and, on another
& Kallinilos, 2000). level of analysis, point to the institutionaliza-
Lately, however, we have seen a renewed tion of the study of meanings within our dis-
empirical and theoretical interest in the cipline. I start with a short exposition of what
ideational aspects of institutional processes. I mean by ‘meaning’ and the procedure I fol-
What do these studies tell us about institu- lowed in gathering those works which consti-
tional processes that we have not known tute the data set for this review. I will then
before based on studies that focus on the offer a reading of this collection of empirical
more tangible – structural and practical – and theoretical works, mainly by analyzing
aspects of institutions? Answering this ques- the notion of institutional processes they
tion will be my main concern in this chapter. offer. Finally, I will discuss a few directions
Based on a review of empirical studies and for further research.
152 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

THE MEANING OF ‘MEANING’ the term ‘meaning’ to denote those aspects of


institutions that are ideational and symbolic,
While the role of meanings was central to to distinguish them from the material aspects
early theoretical formulations of neo-institu- of institutions. Of course, meaning and the
tional thinking, to date we do not have an material are intertwined, constituting each
agreed upon terminology for ‘meaning.’ other. Meanings are encoded in structures
Following Meyer and Rowan’s (1977) and practices, while structures and practices
‘rational myths’ – the shared meanings and express and affect those meanings. And still,
understandings associated with social struc- for analytical purposes, it is worthwhile to
tures – other related concepts abound in the focus our attention on meaning alone, and
literature, including ‘analogies’ (Davis, take stock of our understanding of its dynam-
Diekmann & Tinsley, 1994), ‘discourse’ ics, and implications, for institutional
(Phillips, Lawrence & Hardy, 2004), ‘legiti- processes and theory.
mating accounts’ (Creed, Scully & Austin, I collected empirical studies and theoreti-
2002), ‘linguistic framing’ (Hirsch, 1986), cal formulations that explicitly deal with
‘management rhetoric’ or ‘rationales’ meanings in institutional processes. Many, if
(Kelly & Dobbin, 1998), ‘rationalities’ or not most, publications in the area of institu-
‘institutional myths’ (Townley, 2002), and tional theory pay respect to meaning, as part
‘theorizing’ (Greenwood, Suddaby & of the institutional explanatory model, with-
Hinings, 2002; Strang & Meyer, 1993). out directly measuring it or dealing with its
Given this polyphony of terms (apparently dynamics (Mohr, 1998: 347). I looked
with some nuanced yet important differences instead for papers that treat ‘meanings’ –
between them), I chose to craft this review broadly defined – as their main concern.
using a bottom-up approach. Rather than These include theoretical conceptualizations
offer a clear-cut definition of ‘meaning’ and that deal with the role of meanings in institu-
point to its implications to institutional tional processes, as well as empirical investi-
theory, I follow the way meanings were dealt gations that explore meanings and their
with by researchers in the field of institu- dynamics. I started my search with a central
tional theory – publishing and presenting database of journals, the ‘Web of
their work within the community of institu- Knowledge’, using the key word ‘institu-
tional scholars. Through a content analysis of tion*’ and looking for papers that were
published works that deal with ‘meaning’ published in the various outlets included in
and institutionalization, I came to (one possi- this database in the field of organizational
ble) understanding of what institutional theory (e.g. Academy of Management
scholars consider as ‘meaning’ and its role in Journal, Academy of Management Review,
institutional processes. Administrative Science Quarterly, Organi-
But, obviously, there is no logical way of zation Studies, Organization Science, Human
totally avoiding some initial definition that Relations, Journal of Management, Journal
directs what is to be included in the review. of Management Inquiry, Journal of
Hence, to begin with, meaning is defined as Management Studies) as well as in sociology
‘what is intended to be, or actually is, (American Journal of Sociology, American
expressed or indicated’ (Random House Sociological Review). Next, since works that
Webster’s 1998: 1191), and in our context, deal with meanings are somewhat peripheral
meaning is what is signified in institutional in our field (using qualitative research
structures and practices. I try to analytically methods,1 and often carried out by European
concentrate on ‘meanings’ as a separate scholars), I tried to be more inclusive by fol-
object of inquiry. ‘Meaning’ refers then to lowing the bibliographies of journal articles,
that which is not structure or practice per-se – trying thus to tracing also relevant books and
that is to the untangible. Accordingly, I use book chapters in a snowball manner.
THE WORK OF MEANINGS IN INSTITUTIONAL PROCESSES AND THINKING 153

Once the data set was compiled, I used the sharp contrast to functionalist theories of
tools of my trade to analyze it. I conducted organizational structure, Meyer and Rowan
a content analysis of these works (Lieblich, (1977) claimed that organizations are ‘dra-
1998), looking for the more specific ways matic enactments of the rationalized myths
they define and use ‘meaning’, and the way pervading modern societies’ (346). The main
they portray its role in institutional pro- idea was that while the adoption of
cesses. After reading each paper, noting its institutionalized elements may not ensure the
theoretical question, methodological approach, effective operation of an organization, it will
findings and contributions, I asked myself confer legitimacy upon it, and this legitimacy
what depiction of institutionalization the is critical to its survival: ‘vocabularies of
paper offers. I then analyzed the collection of structure which are isomorphic with institu-
papers, looking for similarities between these tional rules provide prudent, rational, and
depictions. As I was interested in what is legitimate accounts. Organizations described
unique about meanings in institutional in legitimated vocabularies are assumed to be
processes, I chose to frame my review vis- oriented to collectively defined, and often
á-vis studies of the structural and practical. collectively mandated, ends’ (349).
Thus, I will highlight those aspects that are Zucker, in her study of cultural persistence
common to the different approaches towards (1977), highlighted the specific role of mean-
meaning, rather than exploring detailed ing in institutionalization. Treating institution-
nuances within them. alization as a dependent variable and looking
for independent variables to explain it, she
claimed that it is the meaning of an act – the
degree to which it is ‘perceived to be more or
EARLY BEGINNINGS less exterior and objective’ (728) – that deter-
mines the degree of its institutionalization.
The emphasis on meaning was at the heart of Moreover, she also studied the effect of
neo-institutional thinking in its very early institutionalization on the transmission,
formulations in the 1970s. We find much ref- maintenance and resistance of cultural
erence to shared meanings, culture and understandings.
myths in the work of various early theoreti- In their quest to define the isomorphic
cians of neo-institutionalization. To begin forces at play in institutionalization,
with, institutions were understood as social DiMaggio and Powell (1983) followed suit
constructions (Berger & Luckmann, 1966), with an emphasis on the central role of
that is, structures, practices and meaning sys- ideational elements in structuring organiza-
tems that come to be taken for granted tions (and organizational fields). Each of the
through their repeated social enactment – isomorphic pressures (the coercive, mimetic
which involves, first and foremost, language and normative) can thus be extracted from,
and other symbolic expressions and artifacts. and in any case is built upon, cultural expec-
More specifically, Meyer and Rowan termed tations, shared cognitions and beliefs. The
the notion of ‘institutionalized myths’, relat- isomorphic forces were described then as
ing to ‘rationalized and impersonal prescrip- ‘great rationalizing’ forces in action.
tions that identify various social purposes as And finally, in his ‘omnibus’ conceptual-
technical ones and specify in a rule-like way ization of institutions, Scott (most lately
the appropriate means to pursue these techni- 2007) argued that institutions have regula-
cal purposes rationally … [These myths are] tive, normative and cultural-cognitive ele-
beyond the discretion of any individual par- ments. The latter ‘involves the creation of
ticipant or organization … [they are] taken shared conceptions that constitute the nature
for granted as legitimate, apart from evalua- of social reality and the frames through
tions of their impact’ (1977: 343–344). In which meaning is made’ (Scott, 2003: 880).
154 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

The cultural-cognitive pillar directs attention processes as involving the travel of ideas.’
to the taken for granted meanings that under- Rational actors are in full control over their
lie the institutional order. The theoretical actions, motivated by goals that they pursue
emphasis on meaning is further reflected in through the use of technologies and the
Scott’s (2007) conceptualization of ‘institu- resources at their disposal. Meanings and
tional carriers’ in which he distinguishes symbolism, depicted as potentially having
between four types – artifacts (material cul- power of their own, have no place in this pic-
ture), routines (habitualized behavior), rela- ture. Second, since neo-institutionalists hold
tional systems (personal and organizational that ‘institutional beliefs, rules and roles
networks) and symbolic systems. Institutions come to be coded into the structure’ of organ-
are carried through ‘various types of izations (Scott, 1987: 506), in most institu-
symbolic schemata into which meaningful tional studies, the very institutionalization of
information is coded and conveyed’ (Scott, a structure or practice is taken to testify that
2003: 882). it won legitimacy, without probing into the
Meaning, then, had a central place in the meanings and cultural processes involved.
development of early neo-institutional think- Researchers studied structural and practical
ing. In fact, it is the attention to meanings, dimensions of institutions, assuming – rather
culture and symbols – the non-technical than directly studying – their symbolic,
environment, as it was termed – that is con- meaningful character. Third, methodological
sidered to distinguish the neo-institutional preferences may be responsible as well
school from its ‘old’ predecessor, as well as (Bowring, 2000; Schneiberg & Clemens,
from other open system theories in our disci- forthcoming). Again, in the lingo of institu-
pline (Scott, 2007). Notwithstanding this the- tional theory itself, longitudinal, quantitative
oretical emphasis on meaning, most studies are the taken-for-granted procedure
empirical studies of institutionalization in the in our discipline. They serve as a social
past 30 years focused on structures and resource that wins legitimacy, whereas quali-
practices, relegating meaning to the back- tative studies do not fit within ‘the way
ground (Farashahi, Hafsi & Molz, 2005; things are done.’ Meanings elude quantifica-
Hasselbladh & Kallinikos, 2000; Glynn tion, do not allow for causal inferences and
& Abzug, 2002; Jepperson, 1991; Zilber, explanations in the form of correlations
2002). between clear causes and effects. Instead,
Three main explanations to this state of meanings call for ‘after the fact’ interpreta-
affairs come to mind, and they can all be con- tions, and for case studies with thick
ceptualized in neo-institutional terms. The accounts rather than broad generalizations –
first has to do with the taken-for-granted all of which do not fit nicely with the posi-
assumption about the social carrier of institu- tivistic paradigm current in our discipline.
tions, the second is the outcome of a taken-
for-granted epistemological assumption, and
the third is related to the taken-for-granted
method for exploring institutions. Thus, TAKING STOCK
Meyer (1996: 241–242) ascribes this ten-
dency to the ‘typical American version’ of Recently, however, we see a renewed empir-
institutional theory, which assumes the ical and theoretical interest in meanings in
‘rational actor’: ‘These actors have prior pur- institutionalization. The linguistic turn in
poses, clear boundaries, definite technolo- organization studies (Alvesson & Karreman,
gies, unified sovereignty, clear internal 2000), and the growing acceptance of quali-
control systems, and definite and discrete tative research methods (Van Maanen, 1998)
resources to employ. This starting point and of critical approaches (Alvesson &
makes it difficult to think about institutional Deetz, 1996) within our discipline, all partly
THE WORK OF MEANINGS IN INSTITUTIONAL PROCESSES AND THINKING 155

as a result of the influence of European- they employ were central to the diffusion of
based scholars (Usdiken & Pasadeos, 1995) a new institutional logic within the field.
contributed to this change. Taken together, Townley (2002) offers a rare inquiry into the
this body of works highlights four various meanings of institutionalized myths
dimensions of the institutional order – being and their effect on the process of institution-
particular, contextual, conflictual and ever alization. Based on interviews and archival
dynamic. These attributes are of course data, Townley shows how the introduction of
interconnected, but for the sake of analytical a new practice of business planning and per-
clarity I will differentiate between them in formance evaluation to a division of the
the following discussion, and exemplify each provincial government in Alberta, Canada,
separately. was affected by the meanings relevant actors
saw in them. Using Weber’s typology of four
types of rationality as an interpretative
The particularities of schema, she follows the ways her informants
made sense of the changes, and how these
institutionalization
different understandings shaped their
Recent studies have emphasized the ways in reactions thereof.
which institutionalization occurs in relation Indeed, once the particularities of institu-
to the specific content of the meaning tionalization are explored, it was found that
systems involved. Rather than depicting the seemingly ‘same’ institutional practices
institutionalization as governed by universal and structures may be infused with different
laws, studies of meaning highlight the partic- meanings by different actors, and hence have
ularities of the process, and the importance differential institutional effects. Zilber
of specific meanings in explaining the micro- (2002), in her study of a rape crisis center
processes of (de)institutionalization, both on that evolved under the dual, sometimes com-
the organizational (Prasad & Prasad, 1994; peting, institutional pressures of a feminist
Ritti & Silver, 1986; Wicks, 2001; Zilber, ideology and a therapeutic worldview,
2002) and field levels (e.g. Clark & Jennings, showed how the very same institutionalized
1997; DiMaggio & Mullen, 2000; Ferguson, practices were understood differentially by
1998; Hargadon & Douglas, 2001; Quaid, different members. Practices which origi-
1993; Rao, Monin & Durand, 2003; Scheid- nated from a feminist ideology and were
Cook, 1992; Townley, 2002). understood as such by members who carried
For example, Wicks’ (2001) study of a the feminist institution, were reinterpreted by
mine explosion highlights the crucial role of therapeutically oriented members as
the institutionalization of what he calls the reflecting a therapeutic rationale. Based on
‘mindset of invulnerability’ that, among this ethnographic study, Zilber claims that
other factors, allowed the accident to happen. the difference in interpretation – the work of
Based on textual analysis of secondary data, meaning – allowed for the co-existence of the
Wicks shows specifically the crucial role of two quite different institutions in one organi-
meanings – embodied in the masculine zation. At the field level as well, DiMaggio &
identity of coal miners and the embrace of Mullen (2000) showed how the very ‘same’
risk as part of their job – in overlooking dan- practice – the ritual of ‘music week’ – was
gers and acting in ways that raised the risks. celebrated differentially in different commu-
Rao, Monin & Durand (2003), in their study nities across the USA. DiMaggio & Mullen
of the rise of the Nouvelle Cuisine in French (2000) connected the various construction of
gastronomy, highlight the role of meanings the ‘music week’ as a civic ritual to various
as embodied in identity at the field level as characteristics of the local adopting
well. They show that the meanings ascribed communities. These studies show, then,
to the role of chefs and the various practices that to fully understand the dynamics of
156 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

institutionalization, one must attend not only anti-whaling and popular culture discourses,
to institutionalized structures and practices, and charted the changes in the discursive
but to their (specific) meanings as well. construction of whales and human–whale
interaction. The change in this case is dra-
matic, from the negative to the positive,
Institutionalization in context which they term the change from Moby Dick
to Free Willy. While 150 years ago whales
Current studies of meaning in institutional were depicted as dangerous animals, these
processes underscore the contextuality of days they are perceived as endearing crea-
institutions. They attest to the complex tures to be respected and enjoyed. If not for
connections and interactions occurring this depiction, whale-watching could not
between the institutionalized and the have developed as a commercial field.
meaningful environment within which it is However, this change in the macro-cultural
embedded. Thus they argue that institutional- depiction of whales, apparent in North
ization occurs in relation to the ways America in general, dramatic as it was, was
meanings are contextualized within systems only a precondition for the emergence of the
of meanings at the field and societal levels field of commercial whale-watching. For a
(e.g. Holm, 1995; Lawrence & Phillips, new institutional field to emerge, entrepre-
2004; Zilber, 2006a; Zilber, 2006b). For neurial action was needed. This entrepre-
example, in her study of Israeli hi-tech indus- neurial activity included the local use and
try, Zilber (2006a) followed the imagery of manipulation of macro-cultural discourses.
Israeli hi-tech in two social arenas (the For example, when the field of commercial
societal versus the field level), and through whale-watching grew, it encountered the
time (the boom and bust of the hi-tech indus- critic that the many boats surrounding the
try world-wide). Based on the analysis of whale’s habitats were ‘harassing’ the whales.
newspaper articles and want-ads, Zilber Whale-watchers reacted by building on the
connects the prevalent rational myths of humanization and anthropomorphization of
Israeli hi-tech to generic rational myths in the whales, apparent in the popular and in the
Israeli society more generally, showing how anti-whaling discourses. They thus argued
the same cultural building blocks were used that the whales were ‘urban whales’, that is
differentially in different institutional arenas that they had already habitualized to the
and in different points of time to construct presence of humans, so that the heightened
the meaning of hi-tech and its importance. commercial activity did not harass them.
Zilber claims that this process of translation This study shows the embeddedness of an
of generic into specific rational-myths in the emerging institutional field, and of entrepre-
process of institutionalization is related to neurial activity, within various meaningful
material fluctuations over time and to the contexts. If we were to study the institution-
dynamics of the different institutional arenas. alization of whale-watching in Canada by
Lawrence and Phillips’ (2004) study of the following only the structural and practical
emergence of commercial whale-watching in dynamics, we would have missed the impor-
Canada exemplifies the importance of tant role played by meanings at both the
reference of actors to the meaningful socio- broad cultural and local levels.
cultural environment for the emergence of a That institutions are sensitive to their
new institutional field. They show how meaningful context is especially apparent in
changes in what they call ‘macro-cultural comparative studies that follow the travel of
discourse’ concerning the nature of whales institutional structures and practices across
created the very opportunity for commercial national borders (e.g. Boxenbaum, 2006;
whale-watching. Based on the analysis of Frenkel, 2005; Mazza, Sahlin-Andersson &
various texts, they followed the regulatory, Pedersen, 2005; Meyer & Hammerschmid,
THE WORK OF MEANINGS IN INSTITUTIONAL PROCESSES AND THINKING 157

2006; Saka, 2004). For example, Meyer and have picked up this emphasis and showed
Hammerschmid (2006) studied the transla- how power and power relations are articu-
tion of market managerialism in the Austrian lated through meanings. They show that
public sector. Based on managers’ answers to since relevant institutional meanings are like
open questions in a survey, the authors ana- cultural building blocks that are multiple
lyzed their social identities as reflections of (Friedland & Alford, 1991) and nested within
institutional logics. They found that Austrian each other (Holm, 1995), actors must choose
executives used both old administrative logic and manipulate them in the process of inter-
and new market managerialist logic in pretation. And actors do so in relation to
constructing their social identities, thus re- conflicting interests and in lieu with their
defining and translating the seemingly global different subject positions (Maguire, Hardy
logic of market managerialism into the local & Lawrence, 2004). Instilling institutional
context. In the same vein, based on an structures and practices with meaning is thus
ethnographic study of the translation of the interest-driven and carried out through power
American practice of diversity management relations dynamics.
in Denmark, Boxenbaum (2006) highlighted These dynamics are especially apparent in
the importance of the strategic framing of the the context of institutional change (e.g. Arndt
practice to its implementation in a new & Bigelow, 2000; Borum, 2004; Carruthers
context. & Babb, 1996; Creed et al., 2002;
Studies of the meaningful aspects of Greenwood et al., 2002; Munir & Phillips,
institutionalization call our attention to the 2005; Oakes, Townley & Cooper, 1998;
peculiarities and embeddedness of institu- Suddaby & Greenwood, 2005), as well as in
tionalization. Rather than viewing it as a uni- the creation of new institutions (e.g. Dejean,
versal process, they highlight its particularity Gond & Leca, 2004; Lounsbury & Pollack,
and contextuality: the specific contents of 2001; Maguire et al., 2004; Maguire &
institutional structures and practices affect Hardy, 2006). For example, Munir and
their institutionalization, and those contents Phillips (2005) explore the efforts made by
are embedded within larger meaning systems. Kodak to transform the depiction of photog-
Thus, to understand institutionalization, we raphy as a way to push forward its new tech-
need to explore its meaningful particularities nology. Based on the analysis of texts created
and its context, both at the organizational and and disseminated by Kodak (advertisements,
interorganizational levels. company documents and annual reports), as
well as industry reports, trade journals,
newspapers, historical accounts of photogra-
Institutionalization as phy and photographic technology and the
historical period more generally, they offer
a political process
an account of Kodak’s introduction of the
Power relations were always part of the insti- roll-film camera in 1882. They show how
tutional model. However, early formulations Kodak, as an institutional entrepreneur,
highlighted the overwhelming, deterministic ‘engage(d) in discursive strategies to
power of the institutional order over anyone transform the “meaning” embodied by par-
operating within it. Only with Oliver’s paper ticular technologies, by producing new
on strategic responses (1991) we see a move concepts, objects and subject positions’
to ‘empower’ the actors vis-à-vis the institu- (p. 1666).
tionalized structure. And only after Similarly, Oakes, Townley and Cooper
DiMaggio’s (1988) call for a perspective (1998), in their study of the introduction of
which takes politics into account, do we start business planning to the provincial museums
to see explorations of power and politics by and cultural heritage sites of Alberta,
and between various actors. Recent studies Canada, explore the way business planning is
158 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

a political tool, by virtue of its ‘monopoly of The struggle over meaning involved in
legitimate naming’, that is by its ability to institutionalization is especially apparent in
define meanings: ‘They actively construct studies that follow discursive efforts of
the seeable and the sayable by specifying competing institutional actors. Creed, Scully &
what will be documented and what will be Austin (2002) follow the way various
ignored … Through a process of naming, actors offer different ‘legitimating accounts’
categorizing, and regularizing, business plan- for and against policies that rule out work-
ning replaced one set of meanings, defined place discrimination on the basis of sexual
by the producers within the field, with orientation and identity. Based on the analy-
another set that was defined in reference to sis of public testimonies, media accounts,
the external market’ (p. 273, 277). As well, position papers and interviews with relevant
Greenwood, Suddaby and Hinings (2002), workplace activists, they identify five differ-
studying the change in the jurisdiction of ent frames used by different parties to the
accounting firms in the field of professional debate, each connected to different cultural
business services in Alberta, Canada, explore building blocks, and invoking different social
the way professional associations actors aim identities. Suddaby and Greenwood (2005)
at legitimating change by theorizing it – that follow the various rhetorical strategies used
is by interpreting, representing and translat- by competing parties in their efforts to
ing relevant issues in a way that justifies the (de)legitimate an institutional change. Using
change. Based on the analysis of archival and the emergence of a new organizational form –
interview data, they offer a model of multidisciplinary partnership – as their case
institutional change that highlights the role of study, they explore the jurisdictional struggle
such theorization in the diffusion of new between proponents and opponents of the
institutional practices. innovation. They show that this struggle was
The very ability to theorize, or offer theo- taking place on a rhetorical level. The two
rizations for public consumption, is political parties – each comprising a multitude of
in nature. Maguire, Hardy and Lawrence organizational actors – made up two
(2004), who highlight the role of theorizing discursive communities. They used different
in the entrepreneurial activity behind the institutional vocabularies (arguments and
emergence of the field of HIV/AIDS treat- words) and relied upon different texts to
ment advocacy in Canada, explore the way invoke two different logics of professional-
entrepreneurs work to occupy subject posi- ism, according to which legitimacy should be
tions that will allow them to engage in such established. As well, each party relied upon
theorization and confer legitimacy over the and invoked different understandings of
new practices they advocate. change. Proponents and opponents of the
These studies exemplify then the power of new organizational form used, then, various
language and of actors in the processes of insti- institutional vocabularies, and relied upon
tutional change and emergence, as language various understandings of change as part of a
constructs reality in lieu of the agenda of insti- political effort to further their interests
tutional actors. This is not a simple process. through this discursive struggle.
Institutional entrepreneurs need to balance nov- Hence, rather than seeing institutions as
elty and tradition, as they try to frame new (or all-encompassing, deterministic and hege-
changing) practices in ways that will provide monic forces, the exploration of meanings
them legitimacy and will not raise too much highlights the political nature of institution-
resistance (Lounsbury & Pollack, 2001). Such alization (Phillips et al., 2004). Studies of
framing may involve some manipulations of meanings (re-framing, re-packaging,
meaning, creatively tailoring accounts that theorizing, etc.) all ‘highlight the often
(hopefully) serve actors’ interests (Arndt & contested and incomplete character of insti-
Bigelow, 2000; Hargadon & Douglas, 2001). tutionalization projects, often neglected in
THE WORK OF MEANINGS IN INSTITUTIONAL PROCESSES AND THINKING 159

standard accounts of new practice diffusion’ designed to regulate’ (p. 406–7). Based on
(Lounsbury & Pollack, 2001: 321). Meanings the analysis of professional personnel litera-
are thus understood as an institutional ture, survey of organizational practices, and
resource (Rao, Morrill & Zald, 2000), relevant legal cases, they follow the develop-
offered as well as constrained by the institu- ment of a shared definition of compliance
tional context (Lounsbury & Pollack, 2001). with civil rights law. Many parties took part
Various parties strive to further their interests in this process of construction of the law,
by manipulating this resource (thus offering among them organizations, personnel profes-
an interpretation of existing, changing or new sionals, and the courts. Central to this
structures and practices that suit their process of constructions were the meanings
interests). No less important, the study of the infused into organizational practices that
interface of power and meanings joins the were constructed as singling compliance
recent interest in agency in institutional with the law and thus sheltering organiza-
process, as it shows how interpretation tions from legal intervention. While at the
(meaning making) is a form of agency beginning these meanings were ‘myths,’ that
(Zilber, 2002), and it calls our attention to is they had no foundation in legal reality,
what Lounsbury and Glynn (2001) termed with time they became rational as the courts
‘cultural entrepreneurship’: Interpretative adopted them. This and other studies of the
and symbolic work that aims at legitimating institution of law (e.g. Christensen &
new structures and practices. Westenholz, 1997; Edelman, 1992; Edelman,
Abraham & Erlanger, 1992) testify then to
the on-going process of institutionalization,
Institutionalization as and the important role of meaning in it. In the
same vein, Grattet and Jenness (2001) follow
a work in progress
the construction of ‘hate crimes’ as a policy
The emphasis on specificity, contexts and domain in the US in the past four decades,
politics brings to the fore the multiplicity of highlighting the interrelations of multiple
the institutional order. We have multiple actors in the process. Based on an historical
meaning systems, multiple actors who hold analysis, they chart the roles of social
multiple interests and who work in relation to movements and interest groups in bringing
multiple contexts. They may or may not the idea of hate crime to social attention, the
share the same understandings, and they role of legislatures in translating it into
instill institutional structures and practices federal and state legislation, the role of the
with meanings, at least part of the time, to courts in the interpretation of these laws, and
further their own interests. Thus, institution- of the police and prosecution in enforcing it.
alization is understood as fluid and dynamic, Their analysis highlights, once again, the role
as an on-going process rather than an end of meaning in institutionalization: ‘In its
point (DiMaggio, 1988). Meanings are cen- journey from social movement frame to leg-
tral to our understanding of institutionaliza- islative concept to judicial theory to law
tion as work-in-progress. One very enforcement practice, the meaning and
well-documented area in this regard is the policy significance of hate crime have under-
institutionalization of law. As Edelman, gone a series of transformations. … each
Uggen and Erlanger (1999) show in their change reflects the unique demands placed
study of the institutionalization of grievance on the concept in the different institutional
procedures, ‘the meaning of law regulating arenas that compose the American policy
organizations unfolds dynamically across process. Its meaning has been pushed and
organizations, professional, and legal fields pulled in new directions both within and
… the content and meaning of law is deter- across each new context, mutating in ways
mined within the social field that it is that ensure constancy as well as innovation’
160 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

(p. 691). Specifically, their analyses show institutionalization of structure and prac-
that in each institutional arena, policy tices, influencing the very process of
concepts like ‘hate crime’ go through a institutionalization.
common process of solidification, by which Recent studies go further, trying to unpack
its definition becomes, at the same time, the underlying processes. For example,
more specific and restricted, as well as Ocasio and Joseph (2005) followed the evo-
expanding to new circumstances. More lution of vocabularies of ‘corporate gover-
generally, then, these and other studies nance’ in the past three decades. Based on the
(e.g. Anand, 2005; Anand & Peterson, 2000; analysis of media coverage in the New York
Phillips & Hardy, 1997) explore the central Times, a multitude of documents, and popu-
role of meanings and interpretations in the lar and academic literature on corporate gov-
on-going construction of organizational ernance, they construct an historical account
fields. of the developments in the meanings of the
Moreover, institutions are not fixed, but term. Based on this case study, they offer an
may change, in response to field-level or evolutionary model of vocabulary change,
environmental changes (e.g. Reay & one that depicts mechanisms of
Hinings, 2005). Changes call for more inter- variation, selection and retention on the
pretations and theorizing, as the reshuffling linguistic level. For example, linguistic
of the institutional order needs to be legiti- variation stems from non-routine events that
mated (e.g. Greenwood et al., 2002). need to be interpreted and cannot be
‘Change’ itself need to be constructed as explained using current vocabularies.
such (Munir, 2005). While the meaningful Selection is partially based on the resonance
dynamics of institutionalization are espe- of new or diffusing terms with already
cially apparent in the emergence of new insti- accepted concepts. And retention is achieved
tutions or change of existing ones, many through theorization that stabilizes and
studies show that even after structures and reproduces the meanings and vocabularies
practices are institutionalized, their meaning in use.
still undergoes changes. In an early study that Interestingly, it seems that the very process
set the path to many ideational explorations of institutionalization changes the relevant
of institutionalization, Hirsch (1986) showed – field in ways that require further changes
based on business periodicals, interviews in the framing of those institutionalized
and transcripts of congressional reports and structures and practices. Lounsbury’s and
hearings and other publications – how the Pollack’s (2001) study of service learning
‘normative framing’ of corporate takeovers in US higher education exemplifies this
changed in tandem with the growing spread complicated dynamics. Based on interviews
of the practice. With time, the depiction of and the analysis of primary and secondary
takeovers – ‘the language used, the rituals documents and trade periodicals, they
followed, and the meanings attributed to the follow the institutionalization of a new way
event sequence by participants and close of learning and knowing – through personal
observers’ (Hirsch, 1986: 802) turned from experience in the community, termed
negative to positive. This linguistic framing, service-learning. They show how the packag-
Hirsch argued, served various cognitive, ing of service-learning in US higher educa-
social-psychological, and institutional tion was changed through the years. Whereas
functions, all facilitating the diffusion of the early on, in the 1960s, service-learning was
practice. This and other studies (e.g. Baron, portrayed in revolutionary terms, as a means
Dobbin & Jennings, 1986; Baron, Jennings to transform higher education, in the 1980s it
& Dobbin, 1988; Dobbin, Sutton, was framed within a functional discourse that
Meyer & Scott, 1993; Kelly & Dobbin, 1998) highlighted its capacity to improve students’
show how cultural framings change with the learning. They explain this change in relation
THE WORK OF MEANINGS IN INSTITUTIONAL PROCESSES AND THINKING 161

to the dialectics of a change in the broader Thinking of meaning and


higher-education field, as well as the specific institutionalization: theorization,
field of service-learning itself. The field of
translation and discourse
service-learning is embedded within the field
of higher education in which a change from Many of the institutional studies of the 1980s
closed to open-system logic took place, thus and early 1990s were based on, and con-
creating the space for institutional change, tributed to, the conceptualization of institu-
enabling the institutionalization of the tionalization as diffusion (Creed et al., 2002;
innovative service-learning. But the very Czarniawska & Joerges, 1996; for a review,
institutionalization of service-learning see Strang & Soule, 1998). They followed
entailed a change in its packaging. In its early the diffusion of structures and practices
days, a revolutionary framing made sense, across an institutional field, using quantita-
and was in line with the norms of the era. But tive, longitudinal and macro-level method-
as service-learning became the mainstream, ologies based on a positivistic paradigm. The
such framing became too threatening, and imagery of institutionalization created by
thus the transformation into a more func- this set of studies was of a universal and
tional framing, which again was also more deterministic process, made of clearly
in line with the spirits of the time. Thus, defined and clear-cut steps (Sahlin-
meanings are essential not only to the initia- Andersson, 1996): More and more firms
tion of institutional change, but also to its adopted – sooner or later – a certain institu-
constant maintenance. tionalized structure or practice. Adoption
Indeed, the recent interest in institutional itself was measured in clear-cut terms. So,
work and especially institutional while institutionalization was understood as
maintenance (Lawrence & Suddaby, 2006) a dynamic process, the process itself, once
draws attention to the continuous processes set forth, was not problematized. It was con-
of construction that are part of institutional- sidered a question of volume (how many
ization. The on-goingness of institutions may firms adopted) rather than quality (what does
be especially apparent in its meaningful it mean to adopt, what is exactly adopted).
dimensions, as it is argued that symbols and Moreover, the focus on diffusion ‘across a
meanings themselves are never stable: ‘the single community’ (Strang & Soule, 1998:
essence of a sign is that its meaning can never 279) created a sense of a universal, homoge-
be determined once and for all by a given lin- neous process of diffusion, one that is
guistic system, but always has the capacity to affected by characteristics of the population
break with a context and take on different con- and its interrelations, no matter where it
notations. The sign is thus overflowed by a resides. Finally, since those were macro-level
plurality of signification, which cannot be studies, usually focusing on the field level,
finally stabilized’ (Howarth, 1998: 273, and they neglected micro processes, including
see Derrida, 1982: 320–321). The meaning of issues of power and politics (DiMaggio,
institutional structures and ractices – like laws, 1988).
higher education or economic practices – Empirical studies of ideational aspects of
evolves dynamically, with various actors institutionalization, which highlighted the
engaged in negotiations and power plays, all particular, contextual, conflictual and
embedded within multiple fields and contexts on-going processes constituting the institu-
(Edelman, Uggen & Erlanger, 1999; Zilber, tional order, were coupled by more explicit
2008). Institutionalization is thus not only theoretical formulations of the dynamics of
about outcomes, but about the very process meaning. These theoretical formulations sug-
(Zucker, 1987) of how it is worked out con- gest at times alternative conceptualizations
stantly, and the important role of meanings in of the very notion of institutionalization.
that process. Thus, to begin with Strang and Meyer (1993)
162 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

offered the concept of ‘theorization’ as a crit- structures, practices and meanings as they
ical component for diffusion, whereas move across various boundaries, we are deal-
Czarniawska and Joerges (1996) and Sahlin- ing with adaptation, the transformations of
Andersson (1996) suggested we should ideational and material objects in the process
depart from ‘diffusion’ and use ‘translation’ of their movement. Sahlin-Andersson (1996)
and ‘editing’ instead as depictions of the highlighted especially the role of meaning in
institutionalization process. Most recently, this process. Since most organizations do not
Phillips, Lawrence and Hardy (2004) have a direct experience with the structures
conceptualized institutions as ‘discourse’ and or practices they implement, what they actu-
thus once again offered a new way to under- ally imitate are ‘rationalizations – stories
stand institutionalization. constructed by actors in the “exemplary”
While early studies of institutionalization organization, and their own translation of
as diffusion were ‘rich in structural mecha- such stories. The distance between the
nisms’ (Strang & Soule, 1998: 270), Strang supposed source of the model – a practice or
and Meyer (1993: 492) argued that social an action pattern – and the imitating organi-
practices are always accompanied by zation forms a space for translating, filling in
‘theorized accounts’ which play a central and interpreting the model in various ways’
role in the very process of diffusion. (Sahlin-Andersson, 1996: 78–79).
‘Theorized accounts’ chart abstract Phillips, Lawrence and Hardy (2004)
categories and outline the relationships offered a conceptualization of institutions as
between them (e.g. cause-and-effect). They discourse, thus complementing the
are produced as part of the efforts to make translation metaphor with a more general
sense of the world, and are the result of both theoretical foundation, that of discourse
individual-specific theorizing, and the influ- analysis (Phillips & Hardy, 2002).
ence of globally available theories and Institutions, they argue, are ‘social construc-
models, promoted by ‘culturally legitimated tions constituted through discourse … the
theorists’ (Strang & Meyer, 1993: 494–495) structured collections of texts that exist in a
– like scientists, intellectuals and profession- particular field and that produce the social
als. Strang and Meyer (1993) hypothesized categories and norms that shape the under-
that theorizing is a diffusion mechanism so standings and behaviors of actors’ (p. 638).
that the more theorization is complex and Thus, the production of texts is viewed as
rich, diffusion will be more rapid, and less central to any institutional action. As actors
dependent on social relations (for empirical strive to make sense of reality and gain legit-
examples, see Greenwood et al., 2002; Kelly imacy, they produce texts. In order for these
& Dobbin, 1998). texts to affect institutional processes, they
Building on Latour (1986), Czarniawska need to become part of the relevant
and Joerges (1996) went a step further by discourse. The genre of the texts, as well as
suggesting an explicit new metaphor to the their producers, and the links between the
very process of the spread of practices and focal text and other relevant texts all influ-
structures across organizations, that of ence their institutional impact. Once texts are
‘translation.’ The ‘diffusion’ metaphor embedded in discourse, and as much as that
comes from physics and connotes a transmis- discourse is structured, coherent and
sion of a given entity from one sphere to supported by other discourses, it produces
the other. The ‘translation’ metaphor, by con- institutions, which in their turn enable and
trast, comes from linguistics and constrain the production of more action,
connotes transformation so that whatever is texts, discourses and institutions in a cyclic
translated is being reshaped in a specific process. This conceptualization of institu-
context (Czarniawska & Sevon, 1996). tionalization as discourse highlights the role
Thus, instead of thinking of adoption of fixed of language and meanings in the process, and
THE WORK OF MEANINGS IN INSTITUTIONAL PROCESSES AND THINKING 163

offers new ways to conceptualize and study institutional processes ‘do not have the theo-
institutional fields and institutional entrepre- retical tools by which to understand the insti-
neurship (see, for example, Maguire & tutional content whose diffusion they do
Hardy, 2006; Munir & Phillips, 2005). analyze’ (Friedland & Alford, 1991: 243–244).
Theorization, translation and discourse all Finally, the meaningful environment within
offer then complementary new ways to think which institutions reside was left unexplored:
about the role of meaning, language and ‘the social and cultural processes that make
interpretation in institutional processes, and up the project of rationalization and shape
about institutionalization itself. the structure and functioning of work
organizations have either been bypassed or
given an exogenous status, reified to “real-
ity,” “society” or “environment” and treated
DISCUSSION as independent variables in cross sectional or
longitudinal empirical research’ (Hasselbladh
Meanings were at the heart of the neo- & Kallinikos, 2000: 697–698).
institutional argument and contribution Recently, however, we have seen a surge of
(Farashahi, Hafsi & Molz, 2005; Hasselbladh studies of meaning in institutional process.
& Kallinikos, 2000; Glynn & Abzug, 2002; Taken together, these studies help in adding
Jepperson, 1991; Zilber, 2002). However, pluralism and variety back into institutional
early treatments of meaning were partial and theory (Glynn, Bar & Dacin, 2000) by setting
somewhat naïve. Meanings were mainly forth a new formulation of institutions and
understood in their formal characteristic. institutionalization – that of a local and partic-
Institutionalization meant that some ularistic process, context-sensitive, conflictual
structures, practices and understandings have and on-going. They highlight anew the social
come to be taken for granted. The content of constructionist dimension of institutional
institutions and the dynamic of such processes, thus reconnecting to the roots of the
contents were not at center stage. It might be neo-institutional school (though with modifi-
even argued that many early neo-institutional cations). They remind us that neo-institutional
formulations were precisely saying that, theory ‘seeks to grasp not the universal laws
regardless of the content of institutions, that generate social practice, but the social
certain processes will take place (the same practices that generate universal laws’
disregard to particularities was evident in the (Dobbin, 1994b: 123, emphasis in original).
treatment of structures and practices). Early Following Lawrence and Suddaby’s
theorists were talking then about meanings, (2006) notion of ‘institutional work,’ the
but in the abstract (or as a variable), regard- studies reviewed above highlight the ‘work
less of their specific content or dynamics. In of meaning’ in institutional processes.
lieu of these depictions of meaning, most Meanings do not reside ‘out there,’ but
empirical studies of institutionalization rather are socially constructed, and as such
focused on structural or practical aspects, they take part in the social construction of
using them as proxies of meaning, rather institutions themselves (Berger & Luckman,
than exploring meaning directly (Farashahi, 1966). The work of meaning refers to the
Hafsi & Molz, 2005; Hasselbladh & interpretations, understandings and shared
Kallinikos, 2000; Glynn & Abzug, 2002; beliefs that are produced and processed
Jepperson, 1991; Zilber, 2002). Thus, the through social action, and specifically
meaning of rationality itself was overlooked, through the efforts of institutional actors
as rationality was treated as ‘transparent and engaged in power relations and political
self-evident rather than meaningful’ (Dobbin, negotiations, as these are all embedded
1994a: 218). The very content of institutions within particular sociocultural and historical
was neglected as well, as students of moments.
164 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

To further develop these understandings of them perfectly. Still, the two models or
institutional processes, students of meaning metaphors represent two different ontologi-
need to make more efforts at building upon cal, epistemological and methodological
existing theoretical formulations and further approaches and result in different research
exploring the theoretical implications of their agendas, and thus in different understandings
findings; bridge the current division of labor and depictions of the subject matter itself –
between studies of the material and that is of institutionalization. The division of
ideational aspects of institutionalization; labor between them is quite reasonable in
explore meaning in action; and renew our terms of paradigmatic consistency, yet it
interest in organizations as meaning systems. limits the field as a whole. We know much
Qualitative, linguistic and discursive about the ways structures and practices dif-
inquiries in organization studies have been fuse within a field. In recent years we also
blamed for being anecdotal, for concentrat- came to know much on how meanings are
ing ‘on symbols per se rather than on their translated as they travel a field. However,
relationship to other aspects of organiza- what about the interrelations between them?
tional life. It is, therefore, perhaps unsurpris- Is it possible to account, within one model,
ing that what was originally hoped would be for the dynamics of the material and the
a means of enriching our understanding of ideational? Are there ways to bridge this con-
organizational processes has effectively been ceptual as well as methodological
isolated from the mainstream of organiza- dichotomy, and explore the interrelations
tional studies’ (Brown, 1994: 874). Indeed, in between practices/structures and meanings?
writing this review I was struck by the gap Whether positivistic or constructivist in
between the implicit theoretical implications approach, researchers of institutionalization
of the collection of studies reviewed above, should be sensitive to the dynamics of
taken as a whole, and the deficiency in meaning in the process, and find proxies and
explicit theoretical articulations within them. measures that more closely adhere to both
Specifically, while many of these studies meaning systems and structural indicia of
offer rich and thick descriptions of interest- institutional processes. To date, there are
ing case studies, they by and large do not only a few attempts at doing so (e.g. Rao,
build upon or correspond with current Monin & Durand, 2003).
conceptualizations of the work of meanings While the integration of positivistic and
(e.g. theorizing, translation, discourse). To constructionist approaches may yield
make a difference within the field of institu- interesting insights into institutional
tional theory, studies of meanings must processes, studies of meanings may also gain
explore the dynamics and micro-processes of insights from more sophisticated research
theorizing, translation and discourse, and, designs. Studies of the discursive tend to
once again, explicitly articulate their focus on archival data, using various kinds of
implications for our understanding of the texts that are relatively accessible, like
social construction of institutions and the proceedings, professional and general media
institutional order. coverage and interviews. Fewer studies
Another potential avenue for further devel- treated the dynamics of the discursive as a
opment of institutional theory through the collective, on-going phenomenon. Thus, we
study of meanings is by integrating the study are still lacking an understanding of ‘the
of the structural and practical with that of the enactment of beliefs over time’ (Porac,
ideational and meaningful. To date, there is a Ventresca & Mishina, 2002: 595). We are
division of labor between the diffusion and still missing in-situ and in-vivo studies of
translation/discursive models. Of course, meanings ‘in action,’ the way meanings are
these are two ideal types (in the Weberian enacted (e.g. Zilber, 2007). Studying
sense) and no individual study fits any of the on-going and unfolding processes of
THE WORK OF MEANINGS IN INSTITUTIONAL PROCESSES AND THINKING 165

institutionalization will allow us to overcome NOTES


a serious bias in the study of institutional
processes – the fact that most studies are 1 However, this was not a criteria in my search, as
retrospective and examine successful institu- there are studies of meaning which use quantitative
tional processes. We do not know what hap- methods (e.g. Edelman, Uggen & Erlanger, 1999;
Rao, Monin & Durand, 2003), and some qualitative
pens in attempts at institutionalization that studies of institutional processes that do not explore
fail. Specifically, in regards to meaning, what meanings and their dynamics (e.g. Child & Tsai,
happens when one party tries to instill a 2005; Edwards, Almond, Clark, Colling & Ferner,
certain institutional order or change of mean- 2005).
ings, and fails? How do other parties reject
those meanings, and how can we account for
the reasons and dynamics of that process?
This may help us achieve a better and deeper REFERENCES
understanding of the micro-processes
involved in the theorization or translations of Alvesson, M. & Deetz, S. 1996. Critical theory
meanings. Furthermore, in-vivo and in-situ and postmodernism approaches to organiza-
studies that will combine institutional theory tional studies. In S. Clegg & C. Hardy & W. R.
with insights from other relevant research Nord (Eds.), Handbook of Organization
Studies: 191–217. London: Sage.
streams, like organizational sense-making
Alvesson, M. & Karreman, D. 2000. Varieties of
(Weick, 1995) and interorganizational
discourse: On the study of organizations
cognition and interpretation (Porac, through discourse analysis. Human
Ventresca & Mishina, 2002) may yield new Relations, 53(9): 1125–1149.
understandings of institutionalization. Anand, N. & Peterson, R. A. 2000. When
Finally, studies of meaning may gain much market information constitutes fields:
from re-focusing our attention, as institutional Sensemaking of markets in the commercial
scholars, on the organizational level of analy- music industry. Organization Science, 11(3):
sis. While the early (‘old’) institutional school 270–284.
dealt with the organizational level, later works Anand, N. 2005. Charting the music business:
tended to focus on the interorganizational Billboard magazine and the development of
(field) and above (societal, world-polity) levels the commercial music field. In J. Lampel &
J. Shamsie & T. Lant (Eds.), The Business of Cul-
(DiMaggio & Powell, 1991). While these
ture: Strategic Perspectives on Entertainment
studies offer many valuable insights re the
and Media. Mahwah, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum.
dynamics of meaning in the field and wider Arndt, M. & Bigelow, B. 2000. Presenting
environments (as reviewed above), we are left structural innovation in an institutional envi-
to wonder how these dynamics affect life ronment: Hospitals’ use of impression man-
within organizations. We need to analyze more agement. Administrative Science Quarterly,
the core meanings of organizations and organ- 45(3): 494–522.
izing: How goals are set, strategic plans Baron, J. N., Dobbin, F. R., & Jennings, P. D.
defined, and resources depicted. How evalua- 1986. War and peace: The evolution of
tion and control systems are formalized and modern personnel-administration in United
how decisions are taken to make sense – and States industry. American Journal of
how these intense processes of meaning- Sociology, 92(2): 350–383.
Baron, J. N., Jennings, P. D., & Dobbin, F. R. 1988.
making are embedded within wider, institu-
Mission control: The development of personnel
tional dynamics of meaning. Re-connecting systems in United-States industry. American
institutional theory with the organizational Sociological Review, 53(4): 497–514.
level may yield not only insights about mean- Berger, P. L. & Luckmann, T. 1966. The Social
ing, but rejuvenate institutional theory itself, Construction of Reality: A Treatise in the
by making it more relevant to other theoretical Sociology of Knowledge. Garden City,
schools and to practitioners as well. New York: Doubleday.
166 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Borum, F. 2004. Means-end frames and the fields. American Sociological Review, 48:
politics and myths of organizational fields. 147–160.
Organization Studies, 25(6): 897–921. DiMaggio, P.J. & Powell, W.W. 1991.
Bowring, M. A. 2000. De/Constructing theory: Introduction. In W.W. Powell & P.J. DiMaggio
A look at the institutional theory that posi- (Eds.), The New Institutionalism in Organi-
tivism built. Journal of Management Inquiry, zational Analysis: 1–38. Chicago: University
9(3): 258–270. of Chicago Press.
Boxenbaum, E. 2006. Lost in translation: The DiMaggio, P. J. 1988. Interest and agency in
making of Danish diversity management. institutional theory. In L. G. Zucker (Ed.),
American Behavioral Scientist, 49(7): 939–948. Institutional Patterns and Organizations:
Brown, A. D. 1994. Politics, symbolic action Culture and Environment: 3–21. Cambridge,
and myth making in pursuit of legitimacy. MA: Ballinger.
Organization Studies, 15(6): 861–878. DiMaggio, P. & Mullen, A. L. 2000. Enacting
Carruthers, B. G. & Babb, S. 1996. The color of community in progressive America: Civic rit-
money and the nature of value: Greenbacks uals in national music week, 1924. Poetics,
and gold in postbellum America. American 27: 135–162.
Journal of Sociology, 101(6): 1556–1591. Dobbin, F., Sutton, J. R., Meyer, J. W., & Scott, W.
Child, J. & Tsai, T. 2005. The dynamic between R. 1993. Equal opportunity law and the con-
firms’ environmental strategies and institu- struction of internal labor-markets. American
tional constraints in emerging economies: Journal of Sociology, 99(2): 396–427.
Evidence from China and Taiwan. Journal of Dobbin, F. R. 1994a. Forging Industrial Policy.
Management Studies, 42(1): 95–125. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Christensen, S. & Westenholz, A. 1997. The Dobbin, F. R. 1994b. Cultural models of organ-
social/behavioral construction of employees ization: The social construction of rational
as strategic actors on company boards of organizing principles. In D. Crane (Ed.), The
directors. American Behavioral Scientist, Sociology of Culture: Emerging Theoretical
40(4): 490–501. Perspectives: 117–141. Oxford: Blackwell.
Clark, V. & Jennings, P. D. 1997. Talking About Edelman, L. B. 1992. Legal ambiguity and sym-
the Natural Environment: A Means for bolic structures: Organizational mediation of
Deinstitutionalization? American Behavioral civil-rights law. American Journal of
Scientist 40 (4): 454–464. Sociology, 97(6): 1531–1576.
Czarniawska, B. & Sevon, G. 1996. Edelman, L. B., Abrahama, S. E., & Erlanger, H.
Introduction. In B. Czarniawska & G. Sevon 1992. Professional construction of law: The
(Eds.), Translating Organizational Change: inflated threat of wrongful discharge. Law &
1–12. Berlin: de Gruyter. Society Review, 26(1): 47–83.
Czarniawska, B. & Joerges, B. 1996. The travel Edelman, L. B., Uggen, C., & Erlanger, H. S.
of ideas. In B. Czarniawska & G. Sevon 1999. The endogeneity of legal regulation:
(Eds.), Translating Organizational Change: Grievance procedures as rational myth.
13–48. Berlin: de Gruyter. American Journal of Sociology, 105(2):
Davis, G. F., Diekmann, K. A., & Tinsley, C. H. 406–454.
1994. The decline and fall of the conglomer- Edwards, T., Almond, P., Clark, I., Colling, T., &
ate firm in the 1980s: The deinstitutionaliza- Ferner, A. 2005. Reverse diffusion in US
tion of an organizational form. American multinationals: Barriers from the American
Sociological Review, 59(4): 547–570. business system. Journal of Management
Dejean, F., Gond, J. P., & Leca, B. 2004. Studies, 42(6): 1261–1286.
Measuring the unmeasured: An institutional Farashahi, M., Hafsi, T., & Molz, R. 2005.
entrepreneur strategy in an emerging Institutionalized norms of conducting research
industry. Human Relations, 57(6): 741–764. and social realities: A research synthesis of
Derrida, J. 1982. Margins of Philosophy. empirical works from 1983 to 2002.
Brighton. International Journal of Management
DiMaggio, P. J. & Powell, W. W. 1983. The Reviews, 7(1): 1–24.
iron cage revisited: Institutional isomorphism Ferguson, P. P. 1998. A cultural field in the
and collective rationality in organizational making: Gastronomy in 19th-century France.
THE WORK OF MEANINGS IN INSTITUTIONAL PROCESSES AND THINKING 167

American Journal of Sociology, 104(3): Approaches: 268–293. Oxford: Oxford


597–641. University Press.
Frenkel, M. 2005. The politics of translation: Jepperson, R. L. 1991. Institutions, institutional
How state level political relations affect the effects, and institutionalism. In W. W. Powell
cross-national travel of management ideas. & P. J. DiMaggio (Eds.), The New
Organization, 12: 275–301. Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis:
Friedland, R. & Alford, R. R. 1991. Bringing 143–163. Chicago: The University of
society back in: Symbols, practice, and Chicago Press.
institutional contradictions. In W. W. Kelly, E. & Dobbin, F. 1998. How affirmative
Powell & P. J. DiMaggio (Eds.), The New action became diversity management:
Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis: Employer response to antidiscrimination law,
232–263. Chicago: The University of 1961 to 1996. American Behavioral
Chicago Press. Scientist, 41(7): 960–984.
Glynn, M. A., Barr, P. S., & Dacin, M. T. 2000. Latour, B. 1986. The powers of association. In
Pluralism and the problem of variety. J. Law (Ed.), Power, Action and Belief:
Academy of Management Review, 25(4): 264–280. London: Routledge and Kegan
726–734. Paul.
Glynn, M. A. & Abzug, R. 2002. Institutionalizing Lawrence, T. B. & Phillips, N. 2004. From Moby
identity: Symbolic isomorphism and organi- Dick to Free Willy: Macro-cultural discourse
zational names. Academy of Management and institutional entrepreneurship in emerg-
Journal, 45(1): 267–280. ing institutional fields. Organization, 11(5):
Grattet, R. & Jenness, V. 2001. The birth and 689–711.
maturation of hate crime policy in the United Lawrence, T. B. & Suddaby, R. 2006. Institutions
States. American Behavioral Scientist, 45(4): and institutional work. In S. R. Clegg & C.
668–696. Hardy & W. R. Nord & T. Lawrence (Eds.),
Greenwood, R., Suddaby, R., & Hinings, C. R. Handbook of Organization Studies.
2002. Theorizing change: The role of profes- Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.
sional associations in the transformation of Lieblich, A. 1998. Categorical-content perspec-
institutionalized fields. Academy of tive. In A. Lieblich & R. Tuval-Mashiach &
Management Journal, 45(1): 58–80. T. Zilber. Narrative Research: Reading,
Hargadon, A. B. & Douglas, Y. 2001. When Analysis and Interpretation: 112–126.
innovations meet institutions: Edison Newbury Park, CA: Sage.
and the design of the electric light. Lounsbury, M. & Glynn, M. A. 2001. Cultural
Administrative Science Quarterly, 46(3): entrepreneurship: Stories, legitimacy, and the
476–501. acquisition of resources. Strategic Management
Hasselbladh, H. & Kallinikos, J. 2000. The Journal 22: 545–564.
project of rationalization: A critique and Maguire, S., Hardy, C., & Lawrence, T. B. 2004.
reappraisal of Neo-institutionalism in organi- Institutional entrepreneurship in emerging
zation studies. Organization Studies, 21(4): fields: HIV/AIDS treatment advocacy in
697–720. Canada. Academy of Management Journal,
Hirsch, P. M. 1986. From ambushes to golden 47(5): 657–679.
parachutes: Corporate takeovers as an Maguire, S. & Hardy, C. 2006. The emergence
instance of cultural framing and institutional of new global institutions: A discursive per-
integration. American Journal of Sociology, spective. Organization Studies, 27(1): 7–29.
91: 800–837. Mazza, C., Sahlin-Andersson, K., & Pedersen, J.
Holm, P. 1995. The dynamics of institutionaliza- S. 2005. European constructions of an
tion: Transformation processes in Norwegian American model: Developments of four MEA
fisheries. Administrative Science Quarterly, programs. Management Learning, 36(4):
40(3): 398–422. 471–491.
Howarth, D. 1998. Discourse theory and Meyer, J. W. & Rowan, B. 1977. Institutiona-
political analysis. In E. Scarbrough & lized organizations: Formal structure as myth
E. Tanenbaum (Eds.), Research Strategies in and ceremony. American Journal of
the Social Sciences: A Guide to New Sociology, 83: 340–363.
168 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Meyer, J. W. 1996. Otherhood: The promulga- Quaid, M. 1993. Job evaluation as institutional
tion and transmission of ideas in the modern myth. Journal of Management Studies,
organizational environment. In B. 30(2): 239–260.
Czarniawska & G. Sevon (Eds.), Translating Random House Webster’s 1998. Random
Organizational Change: 240–252. Berlin: House Webster’s Unabridged Dictionary
Walter de Gruyter. (2nd edn). New York: Random House.
Meyer, R. E. & Hammerschmid, G. 2006. Rao, H., Morrill, C., & Zald, M. N. 2000. Power
Changing institutional logics and executive plays: How social movements and collective
identities: A managerial challenge to public action create new organizational forms.
administration in Austria. American Research in Organizational Behavior, 22:
Behavioral Scientist, 49(7): 1000–1014. 237–281.
Mohr, J. W. 1998. Measuring meaning Rao, H., Monin, P., & Durand, R. 2003.
structures. Annual Review of Sociology, 24: Institutional change in Toque Ville: Nouvelle
345–370. cuisine as an identity movement in French
Munir, K. A. 2005. The social construction of gastronomy. American Journal of Sociology,
events: A study of institutional change in the 108(4): 795–843.
photographic field. Organization Studies, Reay, T. & Hinings, C. R. 2005. The recomposi-
26(1): 93–112. tion of an organizational field: Health care in
Munir, K. A. & Phillips, N. 2005. The birth of the Alberta. Organization Studies, 26(3):
‘Kodak moment’: Institutional entrepreneur- 351–384.
ship and the adoption of new technologies. Ritti, R. R. & Silver, J. H. 1986. Early processes
Organization Studies, 26(11): 1665–1687. of institutionalization: The dramaturgy of
Oakes, L. S., Townley, B., & Cooper, D. J. 1998. exchange in interorganizational relations.
Business planning as pedagogy: Language Administrative Science Quarterly, 31(1):
and control in a changing institutional field. 25–42.
Administrative Science Quarterly, 43(2): Sahlin-Andersson, K. 1996. Imitating by editing
257–292. success: The construction of organization
Ocasio, W. & Joseph, J. 2005. Cultural adapta- fields. In B. Czarniawska & G. Sevon (Eds.),
tion and institutional change: The evolution Translating Organizational Change: 69–92.
of vocabularies of corporate governance, Berlin: de Gruyter.
1972–2003. Poetics, 33: 163–178. Saka, A. 2004. The cross-national diffusion of
Oliver, C. 1991 Strategic responses to institu- work systems: Translation of Japanese oper-
tional processes Academy of Management ations in the UK. Organization Studies,
Review 16 145–179. 25(2): 209–228.
Phillips, N. & Hardy, C. 1997. Managing multi- Scheid-Cook, T. L. 1992. Organizational enact-
ple identities: Discourse, legitimacy and ments and conformity to environmental pre-
resources in the UK refugee system. scriptions. Human Relations, 45(6): 537–554.
Organization, 4(2): 159–185. Schneiberg, M. & Clemens, E. S. 2006
Phillips, N. & Hardy, C. 2002. Discourse Forthcoming. The typical tools for the job:
Analysis. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage. Research strategies in institutional analysis.
Phillips, N., Lawrence, T. B., & Hardy, C. 2004. In D. D. Powell & D. L. Jones (Eds.), How
Discourse and institutions. Academy of Institutions Change. Chicago: University of
Management Review, 29(4): 635–652. Chicago Press.
Porac, J. F., Ventresca, M. J., & Mishina, Y. Scott, W. R. 1987. The Adolescence of
2002. Interorganizational cognition and Institutional Theory. Administrative Science
interpretation. In J. A. C. Baum (Ed.), Quarterly, 32(4): 493–511.
Blackwell Companion to Organizations: Scott, W. R. 2003. Institutional carriers: review-
579–598. Oxford: Blackwell. ing modes of transporting ideas over time
Presad, P. & Prasad, A. 1994. The ideology and space and considering their conse-
of professionalism and work computeri- quences. Industrial and Corporate Change,
zation: An institutionalist study of 12(4): 879–894.
technological-change. Human Relations, Scott, W. R. 2007. Institutions and Organi-
47(12): 1433–1458. zations. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.
THE WORK OF MEANINGS IN INSTITUTIONAL PROCESSES AND THINKING 169

Strang, D. & Meyer, J. 1993. Institutional con- actors: The case of a rape crisis center in
ditions for diffusion. Theory and Society, 22: Israel. Academy of Management Journal,
487–511. 45(1): 234–254.
Strang, D. & Soule, S. A. 1998. Diffusion in Zilber, T. B. 2006a. The work of the symbolic
organizations and social movements: From in institutional processes: Translations of
hybrid corn to poison pills. Annual Review of rational myths in Israeli High Tech.
Sociology, 24: 265–290. Academy of Management Journal, 49(2):
Suddaby, R. & Greenwood, R. 2005. Rhetorical 281–303.
strategies of legitimacy. Administrative Zilber, T. B. 2006b. Mythologies of speed and
Science Quarterly, 50(1): 35–67. the shaping of Israeli hi-tech industry. In
Townley, B. 2002. The role of competing P. Case, S. Lilley & T. Owens (Eds.), The Speed
rationalities in institutional change. Academy of Organization. Copenhagen: Copenhagen
of Management Journal, 45(1): 163–179. University Press.
Usdiken, B. & Pasadeos, Y. 1995. Organizational Zilber, T.B. 2007. Stories and the discursive
analysis in North-America and Europe – A dynamics of institutional entrepreneurship:
comparison of cocitation networks. The case of Israeli high-tech after the burst
Organization Studies, 16(3): 503–526. of the bubble. Organization Studies, 28(7):
Van Maanen, J. (Ed.). 1998. Qualitative Studies 1035–1054.
of Organizations. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage. Zilber, T.B. 2008 (Forthcoming). Institutional
Weick, K. E. 1995. Sensemaking in Organi- Maintenance as Narrative Acts. In:
zations. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage. T.B. Lawrence, R. Suddaby & B. Leca (Eds.),
Wicks, D. 2001. Institutionalized mindsets of Institutional work. Cambridge: Cambridge
invulnerability: Differentiated institutional University Press.
fields and the antecedents of organizational Zucker, L. G. 1987. Institutional theories of
crisis. Organization Studies, 22(4): 659–692. organizations. Annual Review of Sociology,
Zilber, T. B. 2002. Institutionalization as an 13: 443–464.
interplay between actions, meanings and
6
Power, Institutions and
Organizations
Thomas B. Lawrence

relationship between power and institu-


INTRODUCTION tions (DiMaggio, 1988), and has been exam-
ined primarily under the rubric of
The relationship between power and institu- institutional entrepreneurship (see Chapter 7
tions is an intimate one. Institutions exist to in this volume for an overview of this
the extent that they are powerful – the extent literature), and increasingly also in terms
to which they affect the behaviors, beliefs of the role of social movements in
and opportunities of individuals, groups, institutional change (see Chapter 27 in this
organizations and societies. Institutions are volume).
enduring patterns of social practice (Hughes, The relationship between power and insti-
1936), but they are more than that: institu- tutions was ignored in early neo-institutional
tions are those patterns of practice for which theory but has been addressed in more recent
‘departures from the pattern are counteracted institutional studies of organization. The first
in a regulated fashion, by repetitively acti- wave of neo-institutional research in the late
vated, socially constructed, controls – that is 1970s and 1980s focused primarily on insti-
by some set of rewards and sanctions’ tutions as myths and ceremony (Meyer &
(Jepperson, 1991: 145). Thus, power, in the Rowan, 1977), and in so doing tended to
form of repetitively activated controls, is avoid language that would associate institu-
what differentiates institutions from other tions and power. The research in this period
social constructions (Phillips, Lawrence & concentrated significantly on demonstrating
Hardy, 2004). The relationship between that enduring organizational structures and
power and institutions is also bi-directional. practices were often the result of institutional
A significant stream of research has docu- processes, and especially mimetic processes
mented the processes through which actors, whereby organizations adopted practices
individual and collective, affect the based on a need for legitimacy or to avoid
institutional contexts within which they work uncertainty, rather than some ‘rational’
(Lawrence & Suddaby, 2006). This search for efficiency or effectiveness
brings agency and interests directly into the (DiMaggio & Powell, 1983; Hinings &
POWER, INSTITUTIONS AND ORGANIZATIONS 171

Greenwood, 1988; Tolbert & Zucker, 1983). agency, and institutional resistance – each of
More recent work on institutions has moved which describes an aspect of how institutions
away from the focus on demonstrating the, and actors relate to each other in terms of
usually isomorphic, effects of institutions to power relations. Institutional control involves
exploring the roles of conflict, politics and the effects of institutions on actors’ beliefs
agency in the evolution of organizational and behavior; institutional agency describes
fields. This includes work that examines the the work of actors to create, transform and
political effects of competing institutional disrupt institutions; and, institutional resist-
logics (Thornton, 2002; Thornton & Ocasio, ance represents the attempts of actors to
1999), the role of institutional arrangements impose limits on institutional control and
in creating political opportunities and medi- institutional agency. Although each of these
ating the influence of political actors dimensions has been the subject of significant
(Amenta & Halfmann, 2000; Amenta & study, either within the institutional literature
Zylan, 1991; Bartley & Schneiberg, 2002), or, in the case of institutional resistance, out-
the intersection of social movements and side that literature, there has been little
institutional change (Lounsbury, 2001; recognition either of the fundamental role of
Lounsbury, Ventresca & Hirsch, 2003), and power in each case, or in their status as ele-
the role of institutional entrepreneurs in ments of an interlocking system of institu-
creating and transforming institutional tional politics.
conditions (DiMaggio, 1988; Garud, Jain & I develop and explore this framework in
Kumaraswamy, 2002; Maguire, Hardy & four steps. First, I outline the notion of insti-
Lawrence, 2004). tutional politics and each of its three dimen-
These recent streams of research point to sions. The second and third sections examine
the importance of considering power and institutional control and institutional agency,
politics when examining institutions and respectively. In each of those sections, I first
institutional change. They demonstrate that discuss relevant institutional research, and
incorporating power is critical to understand- then turn to forms of power that might under-
ing how institutions operate in society and pin each dimension – discipline and domi-
their relationship to organizations. Drawing nation in the case of institutional
principally on case studies of organizational control, and influence and force in the case of
fields or instances of social policy, this work institutional agency. I conclude each of those
has provided significant insights with respect sections with a discussion of resistance.
to the dynamics of institutional politics I argue that the dynamics of institutional resist-
(Bartley & Schneiberg, 2002; Stryker, 1994, ance depend on the form of power to which it
2000) and the institutional strategies associ- is a reaction, and so embed my discussion of
ated with different kinds of actors or different institutional resistance within the sections on
contexts (Greenwood & Suddaby, 2006; institutional agency and institutional control,
Lawrence, 1999; Maguire et al., 2004). rather than treating it separately. I conclude the
Missing in this work, however, is a paper with an exploration of a set of issues that
systematic, theoretical consideration of the emerge from the framework and point to some
relationship between power and institutions. future directions for research on power, organ-
In this chapter, I begin to address this issue izations and institutions.
by developing an organizing framework
for understanding the multi-dimensional THE POLITICS OF INSTITUTIONS
relationship between power and institutions,
and exploring some of the implications of that Overview
framework. I argue that the relationship
between power and institutions has three Holm’s (1995) study of institutional change in
dimensions – institutional control, institutional Norwegian fisheries highlights the potential
172 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

analytical power of adopting an explicitly This institution effected a set of power rela-
political stance on institutions and institu- tions, directly between the rules and the
tional change, as well as suggesting the fishermen, and indirectly between the fisher-
contours of what a political perspective on men and the fish merchants who now faced a
institutions might look like. Holm’s (1995: powerful, organized collective actor, rather
398) analysis explains the ‘rise and fall of a than a set of relatively weak, unorganized
specific institutional form, the mandated sales individual fishermen.
organization (MSO), in Norwegian fisheries’, In further describing this example,
focusing on the ‘interconnection between the Holm (1995:405) points to a second
practical and political levels of action’, type of relationship between power and
and the ‘interaction of practices, interests, and institutions.
ideas’. This work highlights the power of a
A rule making all fishermen sell their catch through
number of institutions and a range of politi- the organization, enforced by police and the
cal/institutional strategies. I draw on it here to legal apparatus of the Norwegian state, would
illustrate the theoretical framework for immediately solve the free-rider problem.
connecting power and institutions that I Mobilizing the state’s power behind the fisher-
develop in the rest of the chapter. men’s institutional project in this way was not a
simple matter, however. It would require, first, that
The central institutional battle (Hoffman, the fishermen’s problem could be made so
1999) in Holm’s (1995) story is between the important that it warranted a place on the
fishers and the fish merchants of Norway. political agenda; second, that the fishermen’s
Holm’s (1995: 404) first example of institu- solution would survive through the various
tional change in this battle provides a clear stages of the decision-making process; and
third, that the required number of votes be cast in
example of the relationship between power their favor.
and institutions:
The fishermen’s common interest lay in restricting Thus, the system of rules that would bind
the supply of herring, which would bring better the fishermen together and unite them
prices. As long as they acted individually, this option against the fish merchants did not just appear,
was not available. To solve their dilemma, the fish- but required significant, complex forms of
ermen had to set up a rule system that allowed institutional work (Lawrence & Suddaby,
them to market their herring collectively. … If we
simply assume that the fishermen in this situation 2006). In order to institutionalize the rule in
were rational and acted individually, we cannot law, the fishermen would need to engage in
account for the fact that [the rule system] was discursive strategies intended to frame the
established and successfully organized the herring problem as important, as well as building and
trade for two years without legal protection. leveraging relationships with governmental
To explain this, we must look into the pattern of
interaction among the fishermen. The herring actors who could shepherd the project
fishery in question was largely concentrated both through the bureaucracy. Thus, as much as
in time and geographically, and the fishermen institutions are connected to power through
largely came from the same area, had the same their impact on the beliefs and behaviors of
social background, and operated the same type of actors, they are also connected to power
technology.
through the strategies of actors that are
The rule system enacted by the fisher- intended to transform institutional arrange-
men is a classic example of an institution – ments through political means.
a set of practices, for which com- The contours of power and institutions in
pliance is enforced through social and Holm’s (1995) study illustrate the theoretical
cultural mechanisms, in this case implicitly framework that guides the exploration of
through mechanisms of surveillance and power and institutions in the rest of this chap-
shaming that are made possible by ter. These contours represent what I refer to as
dense patterns of interaction and common the ‘institutional politics’ of a situation.
cultural backgrounds (Douglas, 1973). The concept of institutional politics, I argue,
POWER, INSTITUTIONS AND ORGANIZATIONS 173

has three dimensions which need to be taken collective actors to create, transform, and
into account in order to understand how and disrupt institutions. Research that has high-
why institutional arenas are shaped and lighted this role has made power explicit,
changed in the way they are (see Figure 6.1). highlighting the connection between power
Each of these dimensions describes a role that and agency, and the influence of actors on
power plays in shaping the relationship institutional arrangements (DiMaggio, 1988;
between institutions and actors. I describe the Greenwood et al., 2002; Maguire et al., 2004;
first role of power as ‘institutional control’, Greenwood & Suddaby, 2006).
and illustrate it with the solid-line arrow The third, and least well-understood role of
pointing from ‘Institutions’ to ‘Actors’ in power with respect to institutions is what I
Figure 6.1. Institutional control describes the refer to as ‘institutional resistance’ – the work
impact of institutions on the behaviors and of actors to impose limits on both institutional
beliefs of individual and organizational agency and institutional control. Although
actors. In research that has highlighted this this role of power was highlighted by Oliver
role, power is present but usually appears (1991), its dynamics have been relatively neg-
only indirectly, observable primarily through lected in most institutional studies of organi-
the compliance of organizational actors to zation. The interplay of these three roles in an
institutional rules and norms (DiMaggio & organizational field can be described as the
Powell, 1983; Meyer & Rowan, 1977; Tolbert ‘institutional politics’ of a situation.
& Zucker, 1983).
The second role of power is ‘institutional
agency’, represented in Figure 6.1 by the
Power and institutional politics
solid-line arrow pointing from Actors
to Institutions. Institutional agency is con- Before exploring each dimension of institu-
ceived of here as the work of individual and tional politics in the rest of this section,

Institutional control
Institutions The impact of
institutions on the
beliefs and
behaviors of actors.

Institutional resistance
Systemic power
Episodic power The work of actors to
- Discipline
- Influence resist institutional
- Domination
- Force control
and agency.

Institutional agency
The work of actors to
create, transform,
maintain and disrupt Actors
institutions.

Figure 6.1 Institutional politics – the interplay of institutional control, agency and resistance
174 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

I want to first provide an overview of the that works through routine, ongoing practices
approach I take to power in this chapter, and to advantage particular groups without those
the specific terminology I adopt. The study groups necessarily establishing or maintaining
of power has long been a central element of those practices (Clegg, 1989; Foucault, 1977;
organization studies, with a large and long- Hardy, 1994; Laclau & Mouffe, 1985).
standing literature on what leads to individu- Systemic forms of power are associated with a
als, groups and organizations gaining power wide range of phenomena, including social-
relative to others (Bachrach & Lawler, 1980; ization and accreditation processes (Covaleski
Brass, 1984; Clegg & Dunkerly, 1984; et al., 1998), technological systems (Noble,
Hickson, Hinings, Schneck & Pennings, 1984; Shaiken, 1984), and insurance and tax
1972; Jermier, Knights & Nord, 1994; regimes (Simon, 1998). These forms of power
Mintzberg, 1983; Pfeffer, 1981; Pfeffer & tend to work in an ongoing, prosaic fashion
Salancik, 1978). The variety of approaches that are often not apparent as forms of power
and theories has meant that the concept of (Covaleski et al., 1998; Townley, 1993).
power has been defined in a wide range of As illustrated in Figure 6.1, I argue that
ways. In this chapter, I adopt the view that institutional agency is underpinned by
power is a property of relationships such that episodic forms of power. Institutional agency
the beliefs or behaviors of an actor are requires actors to mobilize resources, engage
affected by another actor or system. Thus, in institutional contests over meanings and
power is a relational phenomenon, rather practices, develop, support or attack forms of
than a commodity (Clegg, 1989; Clegg, discourse and practice – all involving discrete,
Courpasson & Phillips, 2006; Foucault, strategic acts of mobilization. In this chapter,
1977): it is understood here as an effect of I explore two forms of episodic power that
social relations, rather than something an I argue are fundamental to institutional
actor can ‘have’, ‘hold’ or ‘keep in reserve’. agency – influence and force. I further argue
So, when I talk about power in this chapter, I that institutional control is associated with
do not refer to a capacity for effect, but rather systemic forms of power. As discussed above,
the aspect of relationships in which there is Jepperson (1991) argues that institutions are
an effect.1 associated with automatic forms of regulation
This definition of power leads to a distinc- that enforce compliance, without involving
tion between two basic modes in which power episodes of action on the part of interested
operates and which corresponds in large part actors. Regulations, norms and taken-
to the dimensions of institutional politics for-granted understandings have their roots, of
described above. The first mode of power is course, in self-interested behavior, but once
‘episodic’, which refers to relatively discrete, established and associated with sets of social,
strategic acts of mobilization initiated by self- cultural or cognitive ‘stakes’ (Bourdieu,
interested actors (Clegg, 1989). Historically, 1993), institutional control operates as if
this mode of power has dominated the study significantly independent of any particular
of power in organizations through the devel- agent, or at least independent of the interests
opment of two streams of theory (Hardy & of such an agent. In examining the relation-
Clegg, 1996); one focusing on power as dom- ship between institutional control and sys-
ination through ownership and control of the temic forms of power, I concentrate here on
means of production (Braverman, 1974; two such forms – discipline and domination.
Buroway, 1979; Clegg, 1975; Clegg &
Dunkerly, 1980); and one focusing on the role
of power as an alternative to formal authority INSTITUTIONAL CONTROL
in organizations (Hickson et al., 1972;
Mintzberg, 1984; Thompson, 1956). The The concept of institutional control parallels
second mode of power is ‘systemic’ – power the classic sociological notion of ‘social
POWER, INSTITUTIONS AND ORGANIZATIONS 175

control’, which ‘referred to the capacity of a resource interdependence, whether it is an


society to regulate itself according to desired institutional phenomenon or an ad hoc,
principles and values’ (Janowitz, 1975: 82). momentary negotiation (Pfeffer & Salancik,
Working from an institutional perspective, 1978). Thus, institutional and resource
our concern is not with the ability of societies dependence theories constitute overlapping
to regulate themselves, but with the ways in domains of concern rather than competing
which institutions organize, encourage explanations; both approaches deal with
and diminish particular forms of thought and resource-based institutional control, but each
action in organizational fields. Thus, there also includes other non-overlapping areas of
are two important conceptual shifts in interest.
moving from a focus on social control to
institutional control. First, consistent with
the more general shift in discussions of Studies of institutional control
power (Clegg et al., 2006), institutional
control is not understood as a capacity but as Early neo-institutional writing on organiza-
a relational effect of institutions on actors. tions, beginning with Meyer and Rowan’s
The second shift is toward an understanding (1977), and DiMaggio and Powell’s (1983)
of social systems as fragmented, contested classic pieces, focused significantly on insti-
arenas in which coherent sets of ‘desired tutional control, but left out an explicit
principles and values’, are less likely than are consideration of power. Meyer and Rowan’s
competing and conflicting principles and (1977) discussion of ‘formal structure as
values enacted in discourse and action (Dyck myth and ceremony’ provided a powerful set
& Schroeder, 2005; Hoffman, 1999). of images for understanding the nature of
In order to clarify the nature and scope of institutional control. Meyer and Rowan’s
institutional control, we can contrast it with (1977) central argument was that ‘organiza-
resource dependence as a basis for inter- tions are driven to incorporate the practices
organizational control. Drawing on exchange and procedures defined by prevailing ration-
theory (Emerson, 1962), Pfeffer and Salancik alized concepts of organizational work and
(1978) argue that the critical determinant of institutionalized in society’ (Meyer
power among organizations is the control of & Rowan, 1977: 340). Most critical to how
the flow of resources, such as money, research on institutional control developed is
physical resources, capital, and human their idea that organizational environments
resources. Institutional theories also recog- are constituted by powerful myths that are
nize the importance of resource flows as a ‘highly institutional, and thus in some meas-
control mechanism (Meyer & Rowan, 1977; ure beyond the discretion of any individual
W. R. Scott, 2001), but resource dependence participant or organization’ (Meyer & Rowan,
theory is not a theory of institutional control: 1977: 344). DiMaggio and Powell’s (1983)
theories of institutional control focus on examination of institutional isomorphism and
those aspects of a field which regulate behav- collective rationality extended the focus on
ior on an ongoing basis, and set ‘the rules of compliance with powerful institutions, which
the game’ (Holm, 1995; Lawrence, 1999), led both to compliance and the homogeniza-
including coercive and resource-based forms tion of organizational fields. DiMaggio and
of control, but also including many other Powell’s (1983) three sources of institutional
forms of control, such as social and control – mimetic, normative, coercive – have
professional norms, and taken-for-granted become a taken-for-granted feature of institu-
assumptions about the world. Resource tional theories of organization. Each of these
dependence arguments also go beyond describes a class of mechanisms which regu-
institutional concerns, dealing with any late the behavior of actors in a field through
actor-to-actor relationship shaped by mutual social and cultural systems rather than
176 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

through enforcement by a self-interested Oakes et al. (1998) argue that the most effec-
actor. tive forms of power with respect to maintain-
The first stream of empirical research that ing institutional control are those which are
emerged out of these theoretical discussions associated with little or no visible conflict
focused on the diffusion of innovation within (Covaleski et al., 1998; Lawrence et al.,
fields, and also largely ignored the role of 2001; Townley, 1997).
power (Baron, Dobbin & Jennings, 1986;
Leblebici, Salancik, Copay & King, 1991;
Mezias & Scarselletta, 1994; Slack Power and institutional control
& Hinings, 1994; Strang & Soule, 1998;
Tolbert & Zucker, 1983; Westphal, Gulati Looking across the theoretical and empirical
& Shortell, 1997). This work demonstrated writing on institutional control, it is clear that
that the adoption of innovations depends sig- much of this work has left out any explicit
nificantly on the influence of social and cul- consideration of power. There is, however,
tural systems which reduce uncertainty and an image of power that is consistent with,
provide legitimacy and other resources to though often implicit in, this work. Both the
adopting organizations. The classic institu- earlier institutional discussions of control
tional argument regarding the diffusion of which largely ignored power and the more
innovation has been that, as new practices are recent work that brings it in directly are con-
adopted for technical reasons by leading sistent with a conception of power as vested
organizations, the practices gain legitimacy in social and cultural systems, rather than in
which spurs adoption by other organizations, individual actors. This approach to power is
which avoid cognitive uncertainty and consistent with recent work in the sociology
normative sanction by mimicking the early of power that describes it as ‘systemic’ –
adopters (Tolbert & Zucker, 1983). power that works through routine, ongoing
A second stream of work has brought practices to advantage particular groups
power more directly into institutional discus- without those groups necessarily establishing
sions, examining the relationship between or maintaining those practices (Clegg, 1989;
institutions and control in organizations and Foucault, 1977; Laclau & Mouffe, 1985).
inter-organizational networks. This work These forms of power tend to work in an
connects institutional research to the work of ongoing, prosaic fashion that are often not
Foucault and Bourdieu, through its focus on apparent as forms of power (Covaleski et al.,
cultural and social systems that effect institu- 1998; Townley, 1993). Understanding power
tional control within and across organiza- as potentially systemic is not intended to
tions (Covaleski et al., 1998; Oakes, Townley attribute ‘will’ or ‘agency’ to systems (social
& Cooper, 1998; Lawrence et al., 2001; or technological), but rather to break any
Townley, 1997; Townley, 2002). Oakes et al. simple association between agency and
(1998), for instance, draw on the work of power (Clegg, 1989; Foucault, 1977). From
Bourdieu to examine business planning as a an institutional perspective, it seems impor-
mechanism of institutional control in a tant to embrace a definition of power that
government department. Central to their recognizes the power of the courts, profes-
findings is the idea that the effectiveness of sional associations, language, and social
institutional control comes from ‘both redi- customs, as well as the actors that occupy
recting work and changing the identity of roles within these structures and who enact
producers’; in their case, business plans are these routines. Indeed, a cornerstone of an
described as a ‘pedagogic practice that can institutional perspective is the idea that
fundamentally change organizational identi- actors are subject to forms of power that are
ties’ (Oakes et al., 1998: 257). Consistent disconnected from the interests and actions
with other work in this stream of research, of specific others (Meyer & Rowan, 1977).
POWER, INSTITUTIONS AND ORGANIZATIONS 177

When considering systemic forms of he was particularly aware of the need to


power, it is useful to differentiate between embed power in institutions which could
two major forms, one of which has received control the behavior of employees (and
attention in the institutional literature, and others) without direct episodes of managerial
one which has largely been ignored. The con- agency. The Ford Motor Company’s use of
cept of power that is most closely connected discipline as a means of institutional control
to studies of institutional control is stemmed from the problems it was facing
Foucault’s (1977) notion of discipline; with respect to its employees that were cre-
although not explicitly evoked in most insti- ated in part by the assembly line technology.
tutional research, the idea of power exerc In 1914, the company’s annual turnover rate
ised through mundane practices that revolve was 416 percent and daily absenteeism ran
significantly around the constitution of iden- between 10 percent and 20 percent. In
tity is core to much, and especially recent, response, Ford established another corporate
writing on institutional control (Oakes et al., institution, when it launched the ‘Five Dollar
1998; Thornton & Ocasio, 1999). Discipline Day’ – a profit-sharing plan that would apply
as a form of power involves an ongoing, to 90 percent of its workforce, a plan so out
systemic engagement with the target of of the ordinary that the Wall Street Journal
power, and relies on the agency of that target accused Ford of promoting socialism. A cen-
to have an effect (Clegg, 1989; Covaleski et tral aspect of the program was the set of con-
al., 1998; Jacques, 1995; Knights & Wilmott, ditions that dictated who was eligible to
1989). Discipline works through the benefit from it. Ford would only
micro-techniques, practices and procedures provide the profit sharing to those it deemed
of everyday life (Sewell, 1998; Sewell & to be living a moral life, including ‘every
Wilkinson, 1992; Townley, 1993), and conse- male employee over 22 years of age who
quently is often overlooked as a form of leads a clean, sober and industrious life, and
power in organizations. An aspect of disci- who can prove he has thrifty habits’, and
pline that is critical for its role as a basis for ‘[a]ll women employed by the company who
institutional control is its capacity to provide are deserving and who have some relatives
a basis for agency through the formation of solely dependent upon them for support’.
identity (Knights & Wilmott, 1989). Alongside these rules, Ford established a
Discipline is concerned with shaping the Sociological Department, which investigated
actual formation of the subject, such that: the home lives of Ford workers in order to
‘subjects come to recognize themselves as ascertain eligibility, and actively intervened
discrete and autonomous individuals whose with training and advice intended to lift stan-
sense of a clear identity is sustained through dards of morality and living conditions.
participation in social practices which are a The Sociological Department focused partic-
condition and consequence of the exercise of ularly on Ford’s newly immigrated workers,
power’ (Knights & Wilmott, 1989: 538). who, as Henry Ford expressed, ‘must be
Thus, disciplinary practices involve a form of taught American ways, the English language,
power that can be understood as positive in and the right way to live’. To that end, com-
its provision of identity and motivation to pulsory courses at the Ford English School
organizational actors (Foucault, 1984). included, ‘industry and efficiency’, ‘thrift
A wonderful example of discipline as a and economy’, ‘domestic relations’, and
basis for institutional control comes from its ‘community relations’.
use in the Ford Motor Company in the early Although disciplinary power is an impor-
20th century, as recounted in Stephen Meyer tant and pervasive mechanism underpinning
III’s (1981), The Five Dollar Day. Although institutions, other important forms of
Henry Ford ran the Ford Motor Company systemic power have been largely overlooked
and was responsible for many of its effects, in institutional studies of organization.
178 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

In particular, institutional research has other life chances, and the definition of
tended to ignore systemic power that works demographic categories (Simon, 1988).
by altering the range of options available to While these familiar practices seem
actors – a form of power I describe as domi- relatively banal and benign, they repre-
nation2 (Lawrence et al., 2001). This form of sent a significant shift in the production
power can be embedded in a wide variety of and structuring of power relations in
social systems including material technolo- societies:
gies (Noble, 1984; Shaiken, 1984), informa- Through the lens of representations thrown off by
tion systems, and actuarial practices (Simon, these practices, individuals, once understood as
1988). In the context of institutional control, moral or rational actors, are increasingly
systems of domination often take the form of understood as locations in actuarial tables of
variations. This shift from moral agent to actuarial
physical and social technologies that provide
subject marks a change in the way power is exer-
the context for action. The physical layouts cised on individuals by the state and other large
of office building, factories and universities, organizations. Where power once sought to
for example, institutionalize particular pat- manipulate the choice of rational actors, it
terns of interaction among workers, and are now seeks to predict behavior and situate sub-
jects according to the risks they pose. (Simon,
often overlooked as political mechanisms
1988: 772)
(Brown, Lawrence & Robinson, 2005).
Winner’s (1986) examination of the politics Thus, actuarial practices involve a form of
of artifacts examines numerous instances of restrictive institutional control in which the
this, with the most famous being the many lives of individuals are transformed, not
overpasses on Long Island, New York, which through their own actions, but through their
are so low that they do not permit 12-foot placement in a social order abstracted from
high public buses to use the parkways over their lived experiences.
which those overpasses go. Winner (1986: Although discipline and domination both
23) argues that this effect is not happen- work though routine practices and systems,
stance, but rather that it was an intentional there is a critical difference between the two.
control strategy of Robert Moses, the chief Whereas disciplinary practices involve
architect of New York public works from the ‘knowing’ the individual through regimes of
1920s to the 1970s. Winner argues that surveillance and training (Foucault, 1977;
Moses specified the overpasses in this way Townley, 1993), systems of domination work
because: ‘Poor people and blacks, who nor- by ‘knowing’ the population. Disciplinary
mally used public transit were kept off the mechanisms of surveillance, normalization
roads because the twelve-foot tall buses and examination all work to construct an
could not handle the overpasses’ and were image of the ‘normal’ subject in any defined
consequently limited in their access to ‘Jones social space, move actors toward uniformity
Beach, Moses’ widely acclaimed public and punish deviants. In contrast, systems of
park’ (Winner, 1986: 23). domination ‘map out the distribution and
A more subtle form of institutional control arrange strategies to maximize efficiency of
through domination is that which is embed- the population as it stands’ (Simon, 1988).
ded in systems that restrict the effects of While the disciplinary practices replaced
action, rather than restrict action itself, as techniques of coercion and intimidation that
illustrated by a wide range of actuarial were less precise and engendered overt
practices. Actuarial practices involve the conflict (Clegg, 1989; Foucault, 1977),
use of statistics to represent the characteris- systems of domination draw on our knowl-
tics of a population, including the use of edge of populations to extend this process
standardized tests of intelligence, aptitude or even further, constructing even more precise
personality, the construction of probability systems of institutional control which
tables reflecting life expectancies and engender even less overt conflict.
POWER, INSTITUTIONS AND ORGANIZATIONS 179

Resisting institutional control remainder of this section, I explore this


middle ground first in relation to the
Studies of resistance in the social sciences potential for institutional resistance to
are not rare. They tend, however, to focus on discipline and then to domination.
either resistance to broad, societal norms and
values (Kirsch, 2000), or on resistance to Resisting discipline
managerial control in organizations (Jermier, Just as different forms of institutional control
Knights & Nord, 1994). Much less studied is are associated with distinct dynamics and
the resistance of individuals and organiza- effects, they are also associated with differ-
tions to field-level rules, norms, and beliefs. ent forms of resistance. When looking at
In this chapter, I adopt Barbalet’s (1985: 531) resistance to discipline as a form of institu-
position, that ‘resistance imposes limits on tional control, space for potential resistance
power. Indeed, it is through its limitations on strategies is opened up by two key require-
power that resistance contributes to the ments of discipline: enclosure and surveil-
outcome of power relations’. Thus, institu- lance. A key aspect of disciplinary systems is
tional resistance is understood as the work of that they are ‘inward’ looking: discipline
actors to impose limits on institutional works through routine practices and struc-
control and institutional agency. tures that shape the choices of actors by
The first prominent recognition of institu- establishing boundaries of appropriate and
tional resistance is in Oliver’s (1991) discus- inappropriate behavior, but only for actors
sion of the wide range of potential responses who understand themselves as members of
to institutional pressures in which actors the community, society or field within which
might engage: ‘organizational responses [to those norms apply (DiMaggio & Powell,
institutional pressures] will vary from con- 1983; Douglas, 1986). In the Ford example,
forming to resistant, from impotent to influ- the Sociological Department developed pow-
ential, and from habitual to opportunistic’ erful systems and routines that shaped the
(Oliver, 1991: 151). Oliver argues that actors identities and actions of Ford employees, but
potentially respond to institutional pressures for the most part it only affected Ford
with five basic strategies that range from the employees (and perhaps their families), and
most passive to the most active: ‘acquiesce’, in fact only those who were both eligible for
‘compromise’, ‘avoid’, ‘defy’, and ‘manipu- and desirous of the Five Dollar Day. So, to
late’. All but the end points of this set involve the extent that Ford employees were profes-
attempting to impose limits on institutional sionally mobile (based on skills or family
control and thus constitute forms of institu- connections), they would have been able to
tional resistance. Despite Oliver’s (1991) avoid or deny the control of the Five Dollar
clear and influential statement regarding the Day and its associated disciplining systems.
importance of institutional resistance, it has A second requirement of discipline is con-
remained the most neglected aspect of tinuous surveillance or members’ perceptions
institutional politics. The ‘acquiesce’ strat- of continuous surveillance (Barker, 1993;
egy has been the dominant response Sewell, 1998). The range of forms and
described in studies of institutional control intensities of surveillance associated with
(e.g., Hinings & Greenwood, 1988; Tolbert institutions is wide, but consistent across the
& Zucker, 1983); and the ‘manipulate’ range is the potential for noncompliance to
strategy has been the focus of research on be registered by systems which will automat-
institutional agency (e.g. DiMaggio, 1988; ically punish, shame, embarrass, or penalize.
Garud et al., 2002; Maguire et al., 2004). In describing the role of surveillance in the
There is, however, a relative dearth of historical development of discipline,
research on the ‘middle ground’ strategies of Foucault (1977: 175) argues that, as large
‘compromise’, ‘avoid’ and ‘defy’. In the factories developed, it became ‘a decisive
180 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

economic operator both as an internal part of regulations, it reverted to old routines once it
the production machinery and as a specific had passed the regulatory inspection associ-
mechanism in the disciplinary power’. The ated with the new laws. The prospector bank
importance of surveillance in effecting also initially resisted the new regulation,
institutional control has only become more again minimally complying with the letter of
important and more effective since the indus- the law, and largely carrying on with busi-
trial revolution described by Foucault. As ness as usual. The motivation for this resist-
Sewell (1988: 401) argues, ance, however, differed significantly from
that of the defender bank: in the case of the
New technology has enabled the erection of a sur-
veillance superstructure throughout society that prospector bank, it ‘seemed to resist change
unobtrusively influences almost all aspects of daily because top management believed that the
life, especially work life. … The impact of this bank was already fulfilling institutional
surveillance, especially its ability to instill a pro- expectations consistent with its “first to lead
found sense of self-discipline and self-control in
the way” identity and thus did not think
many social settings, is so subtle that it often goes
unnoticed. change was needed’ (Fox-Wolfgramm et al.,
1998: 117). The prospector bank’s approach
Sewell’s argument notwithstanding, sur- to the legislation changed significantly, how-
veillance cannot be taken for granted in sys- ever, when it failed a formal test of its com-
tems of institutional control. It must be pliance: ‘management interpreted the
effected in some manner, and to the degree examination performance as an indication of
that actors can avoid or ignore it, institutional identity and image incongruence … [and]
control will be undermined. An example of responded by internalizing the changes
this dynamic and the potential for institu- needed to pass the test and incorporating
tional resistance it raises comes from Fox- these into [the bank’s] ideology, strategy and
Wolfgramm, Boal and Hunt’s (1998) other organizational and issue aspects of
examination of the reaction of two West its “community leadership” so as to be
Texas banks with distinct strategic orienta- isomorphic with institutional forces’
tions (one defender, one prospector) to new (Fox-Wolfgramm et al., 1998: 120).
regulation, which demanded the banks not The resistance of the banks described by
‘discriminate against any so-called red-lined Fox-Wolfgramm et al. (1998) illustrates the
areas considered high risk in terms of loan limits of surveillance in many institutional
repayment’ (Fox-Wolfgramm et al., 1998: systems, and especially those which are
91). Both banks resisted the institutional highly distributed and involve large
pressure associated with the new law, but in numbers of actors. In this case, managers in
different ways and seemingly with distinct both banks were able to simply avoid making
motivations. Fox-Wolfgramm et al. (1998) any substantive changes in their operations
argue that the defender bank initially for significant time periods with no signifi-
engaged in ‘identity resistance’ – an attempt cant repercussions, largely because the
to ignore the new regulation, operating on a processes through which compliance was
‘business as usual’ basis, because of a lack of monitored occurred only periodically and
congruence between the regulation and the with substantial prior warning.
bank’s current and envisioned identity and
image. The bank resisted by adopting a strat- Resisting domination
egy of ‘minimal technical compliance’, so Resistance to domination has distinctly
that ‘the bank complied with the letter of the different dynamics than does resistance to
law’, spending ‘minimal time and effort’ discipline. These differences stem from the
(Fox-Wolfgramm et al., 1998: 104). differential effects of discipline and domina-
Although the bank then moved some way tion on actors, and particularly groups of
toward accepting and implementing the new actors. When systems of domination are
POWER, INSTITUTIONS AND ORGANIZATIONS 181

effective, the potential for actors to resist, at theft from the organization, insubordination, inten-
least directly, may be significantly reduced in tional mistakes, sabotaging machinery or equip-
ment, whereby the employee seeks to cause harm
comparison to disciplinary systems. Taking
to the organization and/or its property.
actuarial practices as an example illustrates
this dynamic. The most central technique in Institutional resistance to systems of dom-
the development of actuarial practices is the ination, thus, present a paradox – although
classification of the individual within a the ability of actors to compromise, avoid,
population based on some set of relevant and defy institutional control based on dom-
variables. The relevance of these variables is ination may be less than it is under systems
dependent, however, on the task at hand, of discipline, the resistance that actors
rather than on any phenomenological signifi- engage in is likely to be more severe, and
cance for the individuals so classified. The potentially more destructive. It may be diffi-
same is true for physical and technological cult to avoid the effects of overpass heights,
infrastructures, which effect power relations but it is possible to vandalize overpasses and
based on ‘objective’ characteristics of popu- buses. This dynamic is an unexplored one in
lations, which may or may not connect to institutional studies of organization, but
their lived experiences. Simon (1988: 744) could be a major issue when trying to
argues that this aspect of actuarial practices understand the effects and side-effects of
has significant consequences for our politics forms of institutional control that might seem
and our identities: ‘By placing people in benign to the designers and implementers of
groups that have no experienced meaning for those systems.
their members, and therefore lack the capac-
ity to realize common goals or purposes, …
[people] may be stripped of a certain quality
of belongingness to others that has long INSTITUTIONAL AGENCY
played a role in our culture’. These classifi-
cations provide little basis for political The second role of power in institutional
action, and even potentially work to usurp theory is ‘institutional agency’ – the work of
the political foundations of existing groups. actors to create, transform, or disrupt institu-
Lawrence and Robinson (In press) argue that tions. Power and agency have been tied
an important effect of this dynamic is the tightly to each other in organization theory,
potential to provoke more significant, and more generally in the social sciences
destructive resistance, because in contrast to (Giddens, 1976, 1984). The capacity of
discipline, it can ‘entail a greater loss of individual and collective actors to attempt to
autonomy, pose more serious threats to orga- realize their own interests was centrally
nizational members’ identities, and may be important to the ‘old institutionalism’ (see
perceived as less procedurally just.’ Because Washington, Boal and Davis, Chapter 30 in
direct, assertive resistance is problematic in this volume), and has re-emerged as an
reaction to systems of domination, Lawrence important focus for institutional research,
and Robinson (2007) argue that domination particularly with respect to institutional
will be associated with relatively severe, entrepreneurship and social movements.
‘deviant’ forms of resistance directed at Significant findings in this literature include
organizations or society as a whole, what the importance of relational and discursive
Robinson and Bennett (1995) refer to as strategies in effecting institutional change
‘property deviance’: (Garud et al., 2002; Lawrence & Suddaby,
2006; Maguire et al., 2004; Suddaby &
The distinctive quality of property deviance is that it
involves what might be described as very harmful Greenwood, 2006), the impact of field devel-
behavior directed at the organization as a whole. opment (Greenwood & Suddaby, 2006;
This type of deviance includes such behaviors as Lawrence & Phillips, 2004; Maguire et al.,
182 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

2004; Munir & Phillips, 2005), the role of Research on social movements has many
actors’ identities in effecting their institu- similarities to the work on institutional entre-
tional strategies (Fligstein, 1997; Greenwood preneurship, particularly in their shared
et al., 2002; Hensmans, 2003), and the focus on the role of agents in effecting
processes through which practices move changes in institutional arrangements, and a
across space and time (Boxenbaum & tendency to examine this role through the
Battilana, 2005; Czarniawska & Joerges, deep analysis of individual cases of institu-
1996). Research on both institutional tional agency. What separates the two litera-
entrepreneurship and social movements is tures, however, is their understandings of the
reviewed in other chapters in this form and the roots of that agency
volume (see Chapters 7 and and 27, (Schneiberg & Lounsbury, Chapter 27 this
respectively), and so I briefly summarize the volume). Whereas institutional agency
broad contours of this work and then focuses significantly on the traits, strategies
focus on the role of power in institutional and positions of individual actors (Battilana,
agency. 2006; Maguire et al., 2004), social
movements research highlights the role of
collective action motivated by structural
Studies of institutional agency – inequalities (Clemens, 1993; McAdam,
institutional entrepreneurship 1988). The strategies that each literature
highlights differ in ways that reflect their
and social movements
emphasis on individual versus collective
The concept of institutional entrepreneurship action. While institutional entrepreneurship
(DiMaggio, 1988; Eisenstadt, 1980) describes research highlights strategies focused specif-
the process through which new institutions ically on institutional rules (Garud et al.,
are created when ‘organized actors with suf- 2001; Greenwood & Suddaby, 2006;
ficient resources (institutional entrepreneurs) Lawrence, 1999; Maguire et al., 2004),
see in them an opportunity to realize interests research on social movements focuses on
that they value highly’ (DiMaggio, 1988: 14). strategies aimed at fostering and leveraging
Power in this stream of research is tied to the collective action, such as framing (Snow &
ability of actors to create new institutions, Benford, 1988; Snow, Rochford, Worden &
through the mobilization of resources. This Benford, 1986) and resource mobilization
work has examined the processes and prac- (Jenkins, 1983; McCarthy & Zald, 1977).
tices associated with the creation of practices What is common across studies of institu-
(Boxenbaum, 2006; Lawrence, 1999; Munir tional entrepreneurship and social move-
& Phillips, 2005), technologies (Aldrich & ments is a concern for how interested actors
Fiol, 1994; Hargadon & Douglas, 2001; work to affect the institutions and fields that
Leblebici, Salancik, Copay & King, 1991), provide the institutional context within
and forms of organizing (Greenwood, which they operate. More clearly than in the
Suddaby & Hinings, 2002; Suddaby & case of institutional control, the study of
Greenwood, 2005) that go against the institu- institutional agency is the study of a set of
tional norms or rules within which they are political processes and practices in which
embedded. Research on institutional power in many forms is necessarily and obvi-
entrepreneurship has shown that actors effect ously implicated.
institutional agency in a broad set of ways,
including technical and market leadership,
lobbying for regulatory change and discur-
Power and institutional agency
sive action (Fligstein, 1997; Garud, Jain &
Kumaraswamy, 2002; Hoffman, 1999; Most research and writing on institutional
Maguire et al., 2004). agency is explicitly political in its accounts
POWER, INSTITUTIONS AND ORGANIZATIONS 183

of how actors create, transform and disrupt interests’, ‘trying five things to get one’,
institutions (Beckert, 1999; DiMaggio, 1988; ‘convincing people one holds more cards
Hensmans, 2003). The dominant image of than one does’, ‘making others think they are
power in this work is as an ‘episodic’ phe- in control’, and ‘networking to outliers’.
nomenon, constituted in relatively discrete, Fligstein (1997: 403) goes on to argue that
strategic acts of mobilization initiated by the use of these influence tactics will depend
self-interested actors (Clegg, 1989). significantly on how ‘organized’ the fields
Research on institutional entrepreneurship are in which they operate. He argues that:
and social movements both describe actors
When fields are less organized, their tactics are to
mobilizing resources, engaging in institu- bring together disparate groups in a large number
tional contests over meanings and practices, of ways. As a frame begins to cohere to organize
developing, supporting or attacking forms of the field, they act to propagate that frame and the
discourse and practice – all practices involv- social order it implies. Once in place, skilled strate-
gic actors defend a status quo by deftly manipulat-
ing discrete, strategic acts of mobilization.
ing accepted meanings and making sure that the
Similar to institutional control, however, ‘goods’ are being delivered to those who domi-
research on institutional agency has nate the organizational field. Under situations of
maintained a relatively narrow focus with crisis, actors committed to the status quo will con-
respect to forms of power, in this case tinue to try to use dominant understandings to
focusing primarily on influence. structure action as long as they can. Skilled strate-
gic actors in challenger groups will offer new
Influence is typically described as the abil- cultural frames and rules to reorganize the field.
ity of one actor to persuade another actor to
do something they would not otherwise do Studies of institutional entrepreneurship
(Clegg, 1989; French & Raven, 1959; Lukes, (e.g., Garud et al., 2002; Maguire et al.,
1974). It potentially involves a wide range of 2004) have demonstrated the importance of
tactics, including moral suasion, negotiation, influence tactics similar to, or a subset of,
rational persuasion, ingratiation, and those delineated by Fligstein (1997).
exchange (Clegg, 1989; Lawrence et al., Moreover, the issue of field development has
2001; Maslyn, Farmer & Fedor, 1996). The become an important theme in examining
literatures on institutional entrepreneurship different forms of institutional agency and
and social movements provide numerous the question of what kinds of actors will
examples of influence as a basis for institu- engage in such action (Greenwood &
tional agency. Fligstein’s (1997: 398) essay Suddaby, 2006; Lawrence & Phillips, 2004;
on the importance of social skills in institu- Maguire et al., 2004).
tional entrepreneurship, for example, The study of institutional agency has main-
positions influence as central to institutional tained a relatively narrow focus in terms of
entrepreneurship, which, as a form of ‘skilled the forms of power it examines, particularly
social action’, ‘revolves around finding and overlooking the use of force, which works by
maintaining a collective identity of a set of directly overcoming another actor’s inten-
social groups and the effort to shape and tions or behavior (French & Raven, 1959;
meet the interests of those groups’. Fligstein Lukes, 1974). The legitimate use of physical
goes on to articulate a list of tactics available force is generally restricted by communities
to ‘strategic actors’, most of which are and societies to specific agencies, such as
examples of either influence or establishing prisons, psychiatric hospitals, the military and
conditions under which influence is possi- police forces. Other organizations, however,
ble: ‘agenda setting’, ‘framing action’, also use what might be described as ‘bureau-
‘wheeling and annealing’, ‘brokering’, cratic force’ on a regular basis: corporations
‘asking for more, settling for less’, ‘main- fire employees; bars forcibly remove disrup-
taining goallessness and selflessness’, tive patrons; schools confiscate contraband
‘maintaining ambiguity’, ‘aggregating substances; universities expel poorly
184 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

performing students; and editors reject the on Seattle. The protestors were effectively
submissions of aspiring authors. organized into two main factions. The first,
The use of force, and especially of physi- and largest group was the ‘paraders’, who
cal force, is perhaps the most under-exam- were organized primarily by the AFL-CIO,
ined aspect of institutional politics in the and whose intention was to mount a large
organizational literature. Although explicit march to draw attention to their concerns.
physical force may be relatively rare in many The second group, the Direct Action
of the institutional settings we study, this Network (DAN), was an alliance of groups
may be more of a reflection of the con- including the Rainforest Action Network, Art
strained empirical focus we have adopted in & Revolution, and the Ruckus Society,
organization studies than the relative impor- whose aim was to ‘shut down the WTO’. The
tance of force in creating, maintaining and main strategy of the DAN was to take over
disrupting institutions. If we consider institu- key intersections, making it impossible for
tional change from an historical perspective, delegates to reach the convention centre
it is clear that force has been a critically where the WTO talks were to be held. Early
important means by which states and state in the morning on the first day of the talks,
institutions have been created, maintained groups of protesters lock[ed] themselves together
and disrupted (Mann, 1993), and not only in with bicycle locks or tubes, covering their linked
the past (Mann, 2003). In a broad array of arms to prevent police from removing them indi-
institutional arenas, including healthcare, vidually. By 8 a.m., most of the key intersections
education, and more obviously policing and had been seized by the protesters, now reinforced
by their second wave.
the prison system, the use of force by the
state or state-sanctioned agencies maintains The next three days saw a range of force
many contemporary institutions. and influence tactics used by protestors and
The use of force as a basis for institutional law enforcement agencies. By 10 a.m. on the
agency is associated both with attempts to first morning, police were using tear gas, and
disrupt institutionalized practices and with then later rubber and wooden bullets, pepper
attempts to maintain institutions. Disrupting spray, and mass arrests to try to disperse the
institutions through force is most vividly protestors. For their part, protestors relied
associated with protests in which protestors primarily on non-violent, passive forms of
attempt to shut down some kind of institu- resistance, using their numbers to overwhelm
tionalized activity by making it impossible police. From the protestors’ perspective,
for it to proceed. Perhaps the most famous however, their key use of force was in terms
recent example of the use of force to both of their effect not on police agencies, but on
disrupt and maintain institutional arrange- the WTO and its delegates: at 1pm on the
ments was in the ‘Battle of Seattle’ that first day, the WTO cancelled its opening
occurred around the 1999 World Trade ceremonies, and ultimately cancelled the
Organization (WTO) meetings in Seattle, talks completely. The strategy of the DAN
Washington.3 On November 30, 1999, protestors in this respect was to make it
Seattle was meant to host the WTO talks that impossible for the WTO to proceed, in par-
would involve representatives from the ticular by controlling Seattle streets and thus
Western industrialized countries, including a forcing WTO delegates to stay at their hotels
visit from then President Clinton, the Asian rather than proceed to the convention centre.
industrialized countries, and, for the first
time, developing countries in the South. In
response to these meetings, tens of thousands
Resisting institutional agency
of protestors, representing a diverse set of
interests including labour, the environment, Resistance to institutional agency involves
the arts, and anti-poverty groups, converged reaching compromises with institutional
POWER, INSTITUTIONS AND ORGANIZATIONS 185

agents, avoiding their gaze or their ability to In the remainder of this section, I explore
punish non-compliance, or defying their the issue of resistance to institutional agency,
aims. Although its basic nature is similar to focusing first on institutional resistance to
resistance to institutional control, the flux influence and then on institutional resistance
and uncertainty that is tied to institutional to force. As with institutional resistance in
agency opens up more room for resistance, response to institutional control, the different
and more potential for creativity in effecting forms of power that might underpin
forms of resistance. Dirsmith, Heian and institutional agency engender different possi-
Covaleski (1997) provide a detailed descrip- bilities for resistance, and different resistance
tion of resistance to institutional agency in strategies.
their study of forms of control in the Big Six
accounting firms. This study focused on the
attempt by large, professional accounting Resisting influence
firms to shift internal power relations by
importing ‘a legitimated form of formal orga- The potential for resistance to institutional
nizational practice, Management by objec- agency based on influence stems signifi-
tives (MBO) … in the hope of legitimating the cantly from the uncertainty and complexity
actual application of control to the firm’s pro- of attempts to create or transform institu-
fessional cadre’ (Dirsmith et al., 1997: 20). tional arrangements. Attempts to create,
Dirsmith et al. (1997: 20) argue that the use of maintain or disrupt institutions through influ-
MBO as a tool is important because it repre- ence are fraught with unintended conse-
sents a ‘familiar, abstract, objective, procedu- quences. These stem from the often indirect
ralized, client-sanctioned form of control’ and nature of institutional agency, as actors affect
thus challenges traditional, professional institutions by, for instance, working through
autonomy based on a discourse of ‘business third parties such as the state or professional
focus’ and ‘meritocracy’. Institutional resist- bodies (Orssatto, den Hond & Clegg, 2002;
ance, in this case, emerged from the profes- Russo, 2001), or developing (or delegitimat-
sionals in the firms who recognized MBO as a ing) vocabularies of action and belief which
political tool, rather than a neutral technology. are only effective to the extent that they are
Interestingly, resistance did not involve direct picked up and adopted by others (Angus,
refusal, but rather an indirect subversion of the 1993; Lawrence & Suddaby, 2006).
aims and effects of MBO through the use of Unintended consequences also result from
mentor relationships: the intersection of multiple organizational
fields and sets of institutional arrangements
mentors recognized MBO for the political as
opposed to instrumental practice it was, and trans- (Phillips et al., 2004).
formed it into a means for advocating for their Dirsmith et al.’s (1997) study of resistance
protégés, by enabling them to game the formal to the implementation of MBO in accounting
system, as in partnership proposal orchestration firms illustrates these dynamics. First, the
to display the ‘right numbers’. (Dirsmith et al.,
MBO system that senior management
1997: 21)
attempted to implement in the accounting
This study highlights the need for both firms provides a good example of a complex,
resources and skills in effecting institutional multi-party system in which the sponsors of
resistance. The mentors who helped their the innovation are significantly dependent on
protégés game the MBO system had access a range of other parties if it is to be success-
to the information necessary to know when fully implemented and institutionalized.
and how to manipulate the MBO system, and Such situations invite the possibility of
held senior enough positions in their resistance from others who perceive these
firms that their subversions would likely go new systems as not serving their interests. In
unpunished. this case, resistance came significantly from
186 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

professionals in the firm who saw the intro- These attempts, however, can lead to resist-
duction of MBO as an opportunity to ance on the part of targeted actors, and result
advance their own interests and resist the in framing contests in which each party
aims of the system sponsors. The resistance attempts to convince the state agencies of the
evidenced in this case also hinged on the greater legitimacy of their own claims.
interaction of MBO with an existing institu- A range of institutional resistance strategies
tion – mentoring – in the firms. The institu- is also connected to the webs of organiza-
tionalized positions and practices associated tional fields and institutions within which
with mentoring provided both the motivation institutional agency occurs. These webs
and the means for actors to compromise the provide space for targeted actors to reposi-
newly implemented MBO system: the men- tion themselves when institutional pressures
toring process provided a set of interests to change.
actors that were in conflict with the MBO
system, and became the tool through which Resisting force
professionals gamed the new system. I While institutional agency based on influ-
describe this as an example of institutional ence engenders resistance because of its
resistance, rather than institutional agency, attendant uncertainty and complexity, I argue
because it seems that the accountants who that the use of force as a basis for institu-
were gaming the system were not so much tional agency has its own distinctive effects
attempting to either create or disrupt an on institutional resistance. The nature of
organizational institution, as compromise institutional resistance to force as a basis for
and avoid its effects on themselves and those institutional agency stems from the reaction
who they supported through mentorship that force can tend to engender in its targets.
programs. The use of force treats the targets of power as
More generally, the reliance of institu- ‘objects’ in the sense that the exercise of
tional agency on third parties and its situation power is not dependent on the agency or
within overlapping fields and institutions potential agency of targets (Lawrence et al.,
provides the foundation for a range of strate- 2001; J. Scott, 2001). Unlike influence, the
gies for institutional resistance. The prob- use of force does not shape the will of the
lems of surveillance associated with reliance target, but rather achieves its ends despite
on third parties opens up space for avoidance that will. Such forms of power, I argue, tend
by institutional actors. Influence depends on to lead to greater resistance on the part
the ability of one actor to observe the degree of targets, because they ‘entail a greater loss
of compliance of another (Pfeffer, 1981; of autonomy, pose more serious threats to
Pfeffer & Salancik, 1978), and so working [actors’] identities, and may be perceived
through the state or other third-party to effect as less procedurally just’ (Lawrence
institutional change or maintain a set of & Robinson, 2007). Moreover, unlike
institutional arrangements may necessitate systems of domination, which also treat tar-
developing some complex scheme for sur- gets as objects, the episodic nature of force
veillance. The involvement of third parties means that it is easily associated with spe-
also invites the possibility of co-optation cific agents, at whom the resistance will
where targeted actors are able to influence likely be directed. This is because targets of
the actions of the third-parties and thus force tend to aim their resistance at the per-
undermine institutional agency. Social move- ceived source of the harms that they perceive
ment organizations, for instance, often themselves as suffering (Berkowitz, 1993;
attempt to transform institutional arrange- O’Leary-Kelly, Griffin & Glew, 1996). The
ments by influencing the state, which might resistance that the use of force tends to
in turn enact new legislation or enforce exist- engender may limit its potential as an effec-
ing laws and rules (Benford & Snow, 2000). tive tool for institutional agency, both
POWER, INSTITUTIONS AND ORGANIZATIONS 187

because targeted actors will attempt to that has fallen into relative disregard.
compromise, avoid or defy the aims associ- Although the controlling effects of institu-
ated with its use, and, even when direct tions was the dominant concern in the early
resistance is difficult, they will tend to years of neo-institutional writing (DiMaggio
quickly revert to previous behaviors & Powell, 1983; Meyer & Rowan, 1977),
(Lawrence et al., 2001). attention to control has shifted significantly
toward a focus on the limits of control that
emerge from the existence of competing
logics and overlapping organizational fields
STUDYING POWER AND (Rao, Monin & Durand, 2003; Thornton &
INSTITUTIONS Ocasio, 1999). This shift suggests to me a
certain complacency with respect to institu-
The framework I have described here sug- tional scholars’ understanding of institutional
gests that the institutional politics of an orga- control – it is as if we understand how insti-
nizational field can be conceived of in terms tutions control organizational actors and so
of an interplay of these three concepts. In the have let go of that question to a significant
sections above, I have attempted to provide a degree. The work of scholars such as
set of ideas from the literatures on power Foucault and Winner (and many others) on
which could inform a more political analysis discipline, domination and other forms of
of institutions and organizations, focusing systemic power suggests otherwise; it sug-
particularly on the forms of systemic and gests that the problem of institutional control
episodic power that might underpin institu- is far more complex than current institutional
tional control and institutional agency, and theories can address, and that many of the
on the dynamics of institutional resistance to important details of how institutional control
each of these forms of power. In this last occurs remain to be worked out. A starting
section of the chapter, I explore five research point for such work would be the develop-
issues that emerge from a consideration of ment of empirically grounded analyses of
institutional control, agency and resistance. how discipline and domination support insti-
The first three focus on making power tutions, how specific instances of those forms
explicit in institutional analysis, incorporat- of power work in different contexts, and the
ing resistance, and attending to overlooked overall limits of their effectiveness.
forms of power including domination and Making power more explicit in studies of
force. The last two issues focus on extending institutional agency would, I argue, also
the scope of research on institutional politics provide significant analytical benefits.
to include sets of actors that are currently Specifically, I suggest that attending more
missing. closely to power in institutional agency and
especially bringing in existing literatures on
influence and force could contribute signifi-
1. Making power explicit cantly to the development of generalizable,
context spanning theory. Studies of institu-
The first direction that I suggest emerges tional agency have tended to describe the
from the discussion above is to make power strategies of institutional agents with idio-
a more explicit element in institutional writ- syncratic, study-specific sets of labels (e.g.,
ing and research. I believe this would have Garud et al., 2002; Greenwood et al., 2002;
immediate consequences for the study of Hensmans, 2003; Lawrence, 1999; Maguire
institutional control and agency. For the et al., 2004), which make comparisons of the
study of institutional control, I believe that dynamics and effects of institutional agency
the explicit incorporation of power as a cen- problematic. Incorporating the language of
tral concept could help re-energize an area influence and force could provide a foundation
188 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

for comparing and contrasting institutional understanding of what those socially


agency in a range of settings. constructed mechanisms might involve, with
a distinct focus on ‘social’ systems that rely
on normative and regulative mechanisms to
2. Broadening our conception of maintain compliance. I argue that our analy-
power: attending to domination sis of those socially constructed institutional
mechanisms needs to expand to include the
and force
built environment including mechanical and
The second issue that I suggest could provide technological systems. Such systems,
a significant direction for research on institu- whether built from concrete or silicon, are
tional politics is the broadening of traditional often a critical element in the institutionaliza-
conceptions of power that have been relied tion of social practice. Moreover, I argue that
upon in the study of institutional control and episodes of force are at least as important in
agency. Research to date has focused almost understanding institutional creation and
exclusively on forms of power that work by transformation as the more subtle influence
affecting the process through which actors processes which have dominated research on
perceive and react to the costs and benefits of institutional entrepreneurship.
various courses of action, by framing those Fully incorporating domination and force
costs and benefits, by affecting how those into our research on institutions and organi-
calculations are carried out, or by shifting the zations may require an expansion of both our
impacts of various actions such that, for conceptual frameworks and our research
instance, noncompliance with institutional- methods. Where unwanted physical force has
ized practices carries with it some significant been examined in organization studies, for
cognitive, social or economic costs. Largely instance, it has largely been understood as
missing from this analysis are systems of deviant violence (O’Leary-Kelly et al.,
domination and episodes of force that 1996). While a deviance perspective high-
directly overcome the intentions of actors lights acts of violence in organizations that
rather than trying to affect those intentions. are clearly important and problematic, it also
The lack of attention to domination and overlooks a range of phenomena that are core
force might arguably be connected to a view to understanding force as a foundation for
of institutions as primarily cognitive or dis- institutions (Arendt, 1970; Harries-Jenkins &
cursive phenomena (Lawrence & Phillips, van Doorn, 1976; Hearn, 1994), including
2004; Phillips et al., 2004), which might ‘violent’ tactics such as forced injection of
suggest that social practices held in place by medication or physical restraints in a medical
physical or technological systems are not facility, incarceration and capital punishment
‘real institutions’ (see Phillips and Malhotra, in the penal system, corporal punishment in
Chapter 29 in this volume, for a cogent pres- the school system, and acts of war by nations
entation of this perspective). Such an argu- in conflict. Moreover, attending to domina-
ment, however, overlooks the distinctions tion and force as bases of institutional control
between institutions, the mechanisms which and agency may also be facilitated by several
underpin those institutions, and the streams methodological shifts. Documenting the role
of action which create them. Phillips et al. of these forms of power may depend on shift-
(2004: 638) argue that institutions are best ing away from actors’ own accounts of how
understood as ‘social constructions institutions are supported or were created,
constructed through discourse’ that are asso- since domination and force may be
ciated with ‘self-regulating socially understood by those involved as less socially
constructed mechanisms that enforce their desirable than other forms of power.
application’. Thus far institutional research Understanding the institutional role of domi-
has maintained a relatively restricted nation may also require detailed analyses and
POWER, INSTITUTIONS AND ORGANIZATIONS 189

presentation of the physical and technologi- the ways in which other individuals and
cal environment in ways that would be organizations push back or deflect the
unusual for an institutional study. Rather impacts of those strategies. That an institu-
than rely exclusively on interview tion does not completely control all of the
quotations, for instance, the presentation of actors it touches does not make it less institu-
data might include diagrams of physical lay- tional. Attending to resistance brings in the
outs, representations of information systems, multiplicity of institutions and institutional
and summaries of actuarial categories. logics that operate in any field. Regulative
frameworks often overlap in their jurisdic-
tions and conflict in their prescriptions.
3. Getting real: incorporating Moral orders overlap and contradict one
another, often providing room for actors
institutional resistance
to ‘choose’ the moral communities within
A second issue for future research on power which they will operate. Even taken-
and institutions concerns the role of resist- for-granted beliefs are not usually taken
ance in our theories and descriptions of for granted by everyone, since multiple,
empirical situations. I have argued that resist- competing sources of meaning usually co-
ance is a relatively neglected phenomenon in exist in fields.
institutional studies of organization. Studies Incorporating resistance could, therefore,
of institutional control have tended to focus be part of an important next step in the evo-
on the homogeneity of organizational lution of institutional studies of organization.
responses to institutional pressures, and the One thread in the evolution of institutional
consequent tendency for isomorphism in theory, at least since Meyer and Rowan’s
organizational fields. Studies of institutional (1977) classic statement, has been an
agency have highlighted the success of indi- increasing attention to the complexity of
viduals and organizations in their attempts to institutional phenomena (W. R. Scott, 2001).
transform institutional arrangements. In nei- Taking resistance into account could advance
ther of these traditions has sufficient atten- this process significantly, and promote stud-
tion been paid to those actors who are able ies that incorporate the wide variety of
somehow to compromise, avoid or defy sys- actors’ responses to institutions, as well as the
tems of institutional control or episodes of conditions that make this variety possible –
interested agency. It seems to me that both the competing logics, overlapping fields, and
deficiencies may result from a perceived intermediated institutional pressures which
need on the part of institutional scholars to provide the opportunity for actors to compro-
demonstrate that the institutional phenomena mise, avoid and defy institutional control and
they are examining are ‘real’ – that institu- institutional agency.
tions do control actors’ beliefs and behaviors,
or that agents really are capable of creating
or transforming institutions. Highlighting the 4. Where are the janitors and
limits of institutional control and agency may mechanics in institutional theory?
have been understood as potentially weaken- Attending to the institutional work
ing those arguments.
of maintaining institutions
In contrast, I argue that the time has come
for institutional scholars to adopt a more bal- A third issue for future research involves a
anced approach to their descriptions of insti- set of actors who are largely missing from
tutional phenomena, demonstrating both studies of institutional control. Perhaps the
institutional control and the ability of actors most distinctive and fundamental element of
to escape that control, and documenting an institutional approach to understanding
strategies for institutional agency as well as organizations and organizational life is an
190 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

understanding of behavior and belief as con- unrealistic account of its politics.


ditioned by enduring structures, practices, Descriptions of institutional control without
rules, beliefs and norms. Institutionalized a recognition of the institutional work of
social elements are largely understood as maintaining institutions suggest an overly
robust, enduring phenomena which provide stable and deterministic image of organiza-
the context for action – the background tional fields – systems of institutional control
against which local politics, negotiations, would appear to effect stable patterns of
and choice occur. What is missing from this behavior and belief unless they were chal-
image is a recognition of the work done by lenged either by institutional entrepreneurs
actors in order to maintain institutions as or by competing institutions. Incorporating
such (Lawrence & Suddaby, 2006). Zucker the institutional work of maintaining institu-
(1988) argues that a key issue in understand- tions points to the inherent instability of
ing institutions is that even in highly institu- institutional control mechanisms: systems
tionalized arenas, entropy is a natural of discipline and domination have the ability
tendency that needs to be overcome. W. R. to significantly control the behavior and
Scott (2001: 110) argues that ‘most institu- beliefs of actors, but only to the extent that
tional scholars accord little attention to the they are maintained over time. The second
issue of institutional persistence’. The per- problem of overlooking the institutional
spective taken by these authors suggests that work of maintaining institutions is that it
even though systemic power may underpin excludes from institutional analyses the insti-
institutions, it does not do so without the tutional roles of the non-elite actors who do
ongoing aid of a variety of interested actors. not occupy positions from which they might
This is not to revert to a rational actor model create or challenge institutions, but whose
of institutional control, where elites design work is essential to maintaining institutional
and manage social institutions. Instead, I think order. Lawrence and Suddaby (2006) suggest
it points to the importance of bringing into six categories of institutional work aimed at
institutional analysis the legions of non-elite maintaining institutions: enabling work that
actors whose work, and sometimes purpose, it involves the creating of supportive rules;
is to maintain social and organizational policing so that compliance is ensured; deter-
institutions – the institutional janitors and ring through the establishment of coercive
mechanics who deal with the mess and break- barriers; valorizing and demonizing; creating
downs of institutional mechanisms that occur and sustaining institutional myths; and
as an everyday occurrence. embedding the normative foundations of an
This omission is hinted at by recent work institution into actors’ routine practices.
on competing institutional logics and institu- These practices depend on the active involve-
tions as mediating political factors (Thornton ment of non-elite actors who do much more
& Ocasio, 1999; Bartley & Schneiberg, than simply enact institutional control
2002) that suggests our traditional image of mechanisms – they creatively and reflexively
institutional control may be overly optimistic work to support institutions and the
with respect to its ability to endure without mechanisms that underpin them.
significant work on the part of institutional
actors (Lawrence & Suddaby, 2006; Scott,
2001) – who these actors are and what they 5. Institutional side effects: where
do, however, is currently not examined in the
are the homeless in our studies?
institutional literature. This issue is critical
for understanding the connection between The final issue I suggest as a future research
power and institutions in two ways. First, direction again concerns a second set of actors
an understanding of institutional control that who are missing in traditional studies of insti-
is missing this perspective provides an tutions and organizations. All institutions
POWER, INSTITUTIONS AND ORGANIZATIONS 191

affect the distribution of power, resources benefited from the lessons learned in the
and risk in the organizational fields they HIV/AIDS arena, and from the templates for
structure (Bourdieu, 1993; Clegg, 1989; action and collaboration that the HIV/AIDS
Douglas & Wildavsky, 1983). This is a cen- community forged in their struggles for rapid
tral tenet of this chapter, and is consistent access to new treatments and alternative
with much of the research on institutional experimental designs. Others, however, seem
entrepreneurship and social movements that to have fared less well in this institutional
has informed the study of institutional battle. People living with HIV/AIDS in the
agency. Studies of institutional control have developing world, for instance, continue to
also moved toward recognizing the power suffer without the political resources to effect
effects of competing logics and institutional institutional change that the community
change (Amenta & Halfmann, 2000, 1991; had access to in the North. Moreover,
Bartley & Schneiberg, 2002; Stryker, 2002; research and treatment dollars are a scarce
Thornton & Ocasio, 1999). What none of resource which shifted significantly toward
these studies account for in any detail, how- work on HIV/AIDS potentially incurring sig-
ever, are the ‘side effects’ of institutions – the nificant costs to advancement in other
impacts of institutionalized practices and disease areas.
structures on the myriad actors who are nei- Attending to the ‘homeless’ in institu-
ther party to their creation nor are contem- tional research would require a much
plated in their design. While it is clear, for widened lens in our research designs and
instance, that the institutions that emerge out data collection and analysis strategies, and
of occupational contests (e.g., between could be facilitated by drawing across
medical doctors and midwives) have a direct boundaries on work focused on issues of
impact on the practitioners of those gender, race, age, and class. Research
occupations, there are a host of other actors, designs that would be sensitive to the effects
such as patients and their families, other of institutions on marginalized actors would
medical practitioners, nurses, public health need to ask broader questions than how did
officers, and health policy makers who are particular institutions emerge and how do
also affected but whose interests are less they control specific groups; instead, they
well-attended to institutional research. would need to seek out the consequences of
Similarly, research on the work of HIV/AIDS institutions more broadly in a society,
activists and advocates has documented the following the traces of institutional impact
significant impacts on the power of doctors, outwards, as well as ‘inverting’ the process
pharmaceutical companies and HIV/AIDS by taking on perspectives well outside of the
community groups (Maguire et al., 2004). assumed fields of influence to try to see the
Missing in this analysis, however, is the institutions from the margins. Data collection
impact on HIV+ individuals who were and analysis in such a process would need to
largely left out of this process, such as be flexible enough to capture unexpected
intravenous drug users, as well as its impact sets of findings and follow them through to
on other individuals living with other their natural conclusions, a process that
diseases. This example points to the hetero- might be difficult in tightly designed
geneous nature of institutional side-effects. qualitative or quantitative studies. Attending
Although intravenous drug users were to and understanding the side-effects of
largely sidelined in the institutional contests institutions might demand a long and deep
around HIV/AIDS treatments, they later engagement in a field, not only observing a
gained significant discursive resources in population of organizations, but also
their attempts to construct drug addiction as connecting with the individuals, groups
health, rather than a criminal, issue. and communities affected by those
Similarly, members of other disease groups organizations.
192 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

CONCLUSION useful tool for helping to re-integrate rela-


tively isolated streams of institutional
In this chapter, I explored the intersection of research.
power, institutions and organizations. I have At this point in the history of institutional
argued that this can usefully be done by artic- theory, we are seeing the development of
ulating the contours of institutional politics – increasingly isolated streams of inquiry.
the interplay of institutional control, agency Studies of institutional control have evolved
and resistance in organizational fields. toward more sophisticated, quantitative meth-
Institutional control represents the impact of ods drawing significantly on ecological
institutions on the behaviors and beliefs of analytical techniques. In contrast, paradig-
actors. Institutional agency involves the work matic studies of institutional agency tend to
of actors to create, transform, maintain and be longitudinal, qualitative case studies.
disrupt institutions. Institutional resistance Institutional resistance has tended to be
describes the work of actors to compromise, examined primarily as a side issue, with little
avoid or defy systems of institutional control systematic theoretical attention or method-
and episodes of institutional agency. ological development, at least within the
Together, these describe the forms of power mainstream of institutional theory. Along
in play in organizational fields; their interac- with these differences in focus and method
tion significantly determines the evolution of has come a fragmenting of the community of
institutions, networks and subject positions scholars engaged in institutional work.
that structure the experiences and opportuni- Although this may be a ‘natural’ turn in the
ties of actors. evolution of a scholarly area, it also presents
There are, of course, other ways in which problems in terms of the development of
the dynamics of power in organizational institutional research which might address
fields could be described and analyzed. As I complex social problems that require under-
mentioned in the introduction, a great deal of standings of control and agency, as well as
work has been done connecting institutions resistance. Bringing power into institutional
and power in feminist, critical, post-struc- analyses might provide the potential for a
turalist and post-colonial traditions. Each of more integrated, coherent approach to under-
these approaches provides a distinctive, valu- standing the institutional dynamics of organi-
able language for understanding the interplay zational fields. More specifically, examining
of power and institutions. In this chapter, an organizational field in terms of the three
I have attempted to develop a way of looking dimensions of institutional politics – control,
at this relationship that fits more closely with agency and resistance – could illuminate a
traditional concerns of institutional scholars, richer and more complex set of institutional
but, in so doing, have obviously replicated dynamics than has tended to be the case in
many of the existing boundaries and blinders traditional institutional studies, which focus
of institutional research. The framework on only one of those elements. Giving
developed here, however, need not be limited equal weight to institutional control, agency
to addressing narrowly defined institutional and resistance will help to show both the
concerns. Understanding institutional interplay of these dimensions, and the limits
control, agency and resistance could provide of each.
a useful foundation for examining issues of
inequality, discrimination or oppression in
organizational fields. This limitation
notwithstanding, the framework developed in NOTES
this chapter has potentially important
implications for institutional studies of 1 A relational understanding of power is in part
organization. In particular, it could provide a an attempt to avoid the distraction of a physical
POWER, INSTITUTIONS AND ORGANIZATIONS 193

metaphor for social power, as established by French Administrative Science Quarterly, 38:
and Raven’s (1959) distinction between power 408–437.
(capacity) and influence (the use of that capacity). Baron, J. N., Dobbin, F. R., & Jennings, P. D.
This distinction provides a problematic foundation for 1986. War and peace: The evolution of
discussions of power and institutions, since discus-
modern personnel administration in U.S.
sions of power easily become conflated with
resources or other sources of power, and the forms
industry. American Journal of Sociology, 92:
of power become narrowed to those which occur 350–383.
through influence. Bartley, T., & Schneiberg, M. 2002. Rationality
2 Although the concept of domination has a long and institutional contingency: The varying
and varied history in the social sciences, and has politics of economic regulation in the fire
been used in a wide variety of ways (Arendt, 1958; insurance industry. Sociological Perspectives,
Habermas, 1972; Marx, 1906), I use it here to 45(1): 47–79.
describe a general category of forms of power. While Battilana, J. 2006. Agency and institutions: The
the term has been used in reference to ‘false con- enabling role of individuals’ social position.
sciousness’ (Jermier, 1985; Marx, 1906), ‘manipula-
Organization, 13 (5): 653–676.
tion’ (Clegg, 1975; Lukes, 1974), the overwhelming
use of power, I use it simply to describe forms of
Beckert, J. 1999. Agency, entrepreneurs, and
power that support institutional control through sys- institutional change: The role of strategic
tems that restrict the range of options available to choice and institutionalized practices in
actors (Lawrence et al., 2001). organizations. Organization Studies, 20(5):
3 Data for this example taken from de Armond 777–799.
(2000), and archived coverage from the Seattle Benford, R. D., & Snow, D. A. 2000. Framing
Times (http://seattletimes.nwsource.com/wto) and processes and social movements: An
the Seattle Post-Intelligencer (http://seattlep-i. overview and assessment. Annual Review of
nwsource.com/wto Sociology, 26: 611–638.
Berkowitz, L. (1993). Aggression: Its causes,
consequences, and control. New York:
McGraw-Hill.
REFERENCES Boxenbaum, E. 2006. Lost in translation: The
making of Danish diversity management.
Aldrich, H. E., & Fiol, C. M. 1994. Fools rush in? American Behavioral Scientist, 49(7):
The institutional context of industry creation. 939–948.
Academy of Management Review, 19: Boxenbaum, E., & Battilana, J. 2005.
645–670. Importation as innovation: transposing
Amenta, E., & Halfmann, D. 2000. Wage wars: managerial practices across fields. Strategic
Institutional politics, WPA wages, and the Organization, 3(4): 355–383.
struggle for U.S. social policy. American Bourdieu, P. 1993. Sociology in Question.
Sociological Review, 65(4): 506–528. London: Sage.
Amenta, E., & Zylan, Y. 1991. It happened here: Brass, D. J. 1984. Being in the right place:
Political opportunity, the new institutional- A structural analysis of individual influence in
ism, and the Townsend movement. American an organization. Administrative Science
Sociological Review, 56(2): 250–265. Quarterly, 29, 518–539.
Angus, L. B. 1993. Masculinity and women Braverman, H. 1974. Labor and Monopoly
teachers at Christian Brothers College. Capital. New York: Monthly Review Press.
Organization Studies, 14(2): 235–260. Brown, G., Lawrence, T. B., & Robinson, S. L.
Arendt, H. 1970. On Violence. London: Allen 2005. Territoriality in organizations.
Lane. Academy of Management Review, 30(3):
Bachrach, S. B., & Lawler, E. J. 1980. Power and 577–594.
Politics in Organizations. San Francisco, CA: Buroway, M. 1979. Manufacturing Consent.
Jossey-Bass. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Barbalet, J. M. 1985. Power and resistance. Clegg, S. R. 1975. Power, Rule and Domination.
British Journal of Sociology, 36(4): 531–548. London: Routledge.
Barker, J. R. 1993. Tightening the iron cage: Clegg, S. R. 1989. Frameworks of Power.
Concertive control in self-managing teams. London: Penguin Books.
194 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Clegg, S. R., & Dunkerly, D. 1980. Eisenstadt, S. N. 1980. Cultural orientations,


Organization, Class and Control. London: institutional entrepreneurs, and social
Routledge. change: Comparative analysis of traditional
Clegg, S. R., Courpasson, D., & Phillips, N. civilizations. American Journal of Sociology,
2006. Power and organizations. London: 85: 840–869.
Sage. Emerson, R. M. 1962. Power-dependence
Clemens, E. 1993. Organizational repertoires relations. American Sociological Review,
and institutional change: Women’s groups 27(1): 31–41.
and the transformation of American politics, Fligstein, N. 1997. Social skill and institutional
1890–1920. American Journal of Sociology, theory. American Behavioral Scientist, 40(4):
98: 755–798. 197–405.
Covaleski, M. A., Dirsmith, M. W., Heian, J. B., Foucault, M. 1977. Discipline and Punish: The
& Samuel, S. 1998. The calculated and the Birth of the Prison. New York: Vintage Books.
avowed: Techniques of discipline and strug- Foucault, M. 1984.The Foucault Reader. P.
gle over identity in Big Six public accounting Rabinow (ed.). New York: Pantheon Books.
firms. Administrative Science Quarterly, 43: Fox-Wolfgramm, S. J., Boal, K. B., & Hunt, J. G.
293–327. 1998. Organizational adaptation to institu-
Czarniawska, B., & Joerges, B. 1996. Travel of tional change: A comparative study of first-
ideas. In B. Czarniawska and G. Sevon (eds.), order change in prospector and defender
Translating Organizational Change: 13–48. banks. Administrative Science Quarterly, 43:
Berlin: De Gruyter. 87–126.
De Armond, P. 2000. Black flag over Seattle. French, J. R. P., & Raven, B. 1959. The bases of
Albion Monitor, 72. <www.monitor.net social power. In D. Cartwright & A. Zander
/monitor/seattlewto/index.html>. (eds.), Studies in Social Power: 15–167. Ann
DiMaggio, P. J. 1988. Interest and agency in Arbor: University of Michigan, Institute of
institutional theory. In L.G. Zucker (ed.), Social Research.
Institutional Patterns and Organizations: Garud, R., Jain, S., & Kumaraswamy, A. 2002.
Culture and Environment: 3–22. Cambridge, Institutional entrepreneurship in the spon-
Mass.: Ballinger. sorship of common technological standards:
DiMaggio, P. J., & Powell, W. W. 1983. The iron The case of Sun Microsystems and Java.
cage revisited: Institutional isomorphism and Academy of Management Journal, 45(1):
collective rationality in organizational fields. 196–214.
American Sociological Review, 48: 147–160. Giddens, A. 1976. New Rules of Sociological
Dirsmith, M. W., Heian, J. B., & Covaleski, M. A. Method: A Positive Critique of Interpretative
1997. Structure and agency in an institution- Sociologies. London: Hutchinson.
alized setting: The application and social Giddens, A. 1984. The constitution of society:
transformation of control in the Big Six. Outline of a theory of structuration.
Accounting, Organizations and Society, Cambridge, UK: Polity Press.
22(1): 1–27. Greenwood, R., & Suddaby, R. 2006.
Douglas, M. 1973. Natural Symbols. New York: Institutional entrepreneurship in mature fields:
Pantheon Books. The big five accounting firms. Academy of
Douglas, M. 1986. How Institutions Think. Management Journal, 49(1): 27–48.
New York: Syracuse University Press. Greenwood, R., Suddaby, R. & Hinings, C. R.
Douglas, M., & Wildavsky A. 1983. Risk and 2002. Theorizing change: The role of profes-
Culture: An Essay on the Selection of sional associations in the transformation of
Technological and Environmental Dangers. institutionalized fields. Academy of
Berkeley, CA: University of California Press. Management Journal, 45: 58–80.
Dyck, B., & Schroeder, D. 2005. Management, Hardy, C. 1994. Managing Strategic Action:
theology and moral points of view: Towards Mobilizing Change. London: Sage.
an alternative to the conventional material- Hardy, C., & Clegg, S. R. 1996. Some dare
ist-individualist ideal-type of management. call it power. In S. R. Clegg, C. Hardy, &
Journal of Management Studies, 42(4): W. R. Nord (eds.), Handbook of Organization
705–735. Studies: 622–6410. London: Sage.
POWER, INSTITUTIONS AND ORGANIZATIONS 195

Hargadon, A., & Douglas, Y. 2001. When inno- organization theory. Journal of
vations meet institutions: Edison and the Management, 11(2): 67–80.
design of the electric light. Administrative Jermier, J. M., Knights, D., & Nord, W. 1994.
Science Quarterly, 46: 476–501. Resistance and Power in Organizations.
Harries-Jenkins, G., & van Doorn, J. 1976. The New York: Routledge.
Military and the problem of legitimacy. Knights, D., & Wilmott, H. 1989. From degra-
London: Sage. dation to subjugation in social relations: An
Hearn, J. 1994. The organization(s) of vio- analysis of power and subjectivity at work.
lence: Men, gender relations, organizations, Sociology, 23: 535–538.
and violence(s). Human Relations, 47(6): Kirsch, M. H. 2000. Queer Theory and Social
731–754. Change. London: Routledge.
Hensmans, M. 2003. Social movement Laclau, E., & Mouffe, C. 1985. Hegemony and
organizations: A metaphor for strategic Socialist Strategy: Towards a Radical
actors in institutional fields. Organizational Democratic Politics. London: Verso.
Studies, 24: 355–381. Lawrence, T. B. 1999. Institutional strategy.
Hickson, D. J., Hinings, C. R., Schneck, R. E., & Journal of Management, 25: 161–187.
Pennings, J. M. 1972. A strategic contingen- Lawrence, T. B., & Phillips, N. 2004. From Moby
cies theory of intra-organizational power. Dick to Free Willy: Macro-cultural discourse
Administrative Science Quarterly, 16: and institutional entrepreneurship in emerg-
216–229. ing institutional fields. Organization, 11(5):
Hinings, C. R. & Greenwood, R. 1988. The nor- 689–711.
mative prescription of organizations. In Lawrence, T. B., & Robinson, S. L. 2007.
Zucker, L. (ed.), Institutional Patterns and Ain’t misbehavin: Workplace deviance as
Organizations: Culture and Environment: organizational resistance. Journal of
53–70. Cambridge, MA.: Balinger. Management 33(3): 378–394.
Hoffman, A. J. 1999. Institutional evolution Lawrence, T. B., & Suddaby, R. 2006.
and change: Environmentalism and the U.S. Institutions and institutional work. In S. R.
chemical industry. Academy of Management Clegg, C. Hardy, T. B. Lawrence, & W. R.
Journal, 42: 351–371. Nord (eds.), Handbook of Organization
Holm, P. 1995. The dynamics of institutionaliza- Studies, 2nd edn, 215–254. London: Sage.
tion: Transformation processes in Norwegian Lawrence, T. B., Winn, M., & Jennings, P. D.
fisheries. Administrative Science Quarterly, 2001. The temporal dynamics of institution-
40: 398–422. alization. Academy of Management Review,
Hughes, E. C. 1936. The ecological aspect of 26: 624–644.
institutions. American Sociological Review, Leblebici, H., Salancik, G. R., Copay, A.,
1: 180–189. & King, T. 1991. Institutional change
Jacques, R. 1995. Manufacturing the and the transformation of interorganizational
Employee: Management Knowledge from fields: An organizational history of the U.S.
the 19th to 21st Centuries. London: Sage. radio broadcasting industry. Administrative
Janowitz, M. 1975. Sociological theory and Science Quarterly, 36: 333–363.
social control. American Journal of Lounsbury, M. 2001. Institutional sources
Sociology, 81(1): 82–108. of practice variation: staffing university and
Jenkins, J. C. 1983. Resource mobilization college recycling programs. Administrative
theory and the study of social movements. Science Quarterly, 46: 29–56.
Annual Review of Sociology, 9: 527–553. Lounsbury, M., Ventresca, M. & Hirsch, P. 2003.
Jepperson, R. L. 1991. Institutions, institutional Social movements, field frames and industry
effects, and institutionalism. In W. W. Powell emergence: A cultural political perspective
& P. J. DiMaggio (eds.), The New Institu- on US recycling. Socio-Economic Review,
tionalism in Organizational Analysis: 1: 71–104.
143–163. Chicago: University of Chicago Lukes, S. 1974. Power: A Radical View.
Press. London: MacMillan.
Jermier, J. M. 1985. ‘When the sleeper wakes’: Maguire, S., Hardy, C., & Lawrence, T. B.
A short story extending themes in radical 2004. Institutional entrepreneurship in
196 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

emerging fields: HIV/AIDS treatment advo- Orssatto, R. J., den Hond, F., & Clegg, S. R.
cacy in Canada. Academy of Management 2002. The political ecology of automobile
Journal, 47: 657–679. recycling in Europe. Organization Studies,
Mann, M. 1993. The Sources of Social Power, 23(4): 639–665.
Volume II: The Rise of Classes and Pfeffer, J. 1981. Power in Organizations.
Nation-states, 1760–1914. Cambridge, UK: Marshfield, MA: Pitman.
Cambridge University Press. Pfeffer, J., & Salancik, G. R. 1978. The External
Mann, M. 2003. Incoherent Empire. London: Control of Organizations: A Resource Depen-
Verso Books. dence Perspective. New York: Harper & Row.
Maslyn, J. M., Farmer, S. M., & Fedor, D. B. 1996. Phillips, N. Lawrence, T. B., & Hardy, C. 2004.
Failed upward influence attempts: Predicting Discourse and institutions. Academy of
the nature of subordinate persistence in pur- Management Review, 29: 635–652.
suit of organizational goals. Group & Rao, H., Monin, P., & Durand, R. 2003.
Organization Management, 21(4): 461–480. Institutional change in Toque Ville: Nouvelle
McAdam, D. 1988. Freedom Summer. New cuisine as an identity movement in French
York: Oxford University Press. gastronomy. American Journal of Sociology,
McCarthy, J. D., & Zald, M. N. 1977. Resource 108(4): 795–843.
mobilization and social movements: A partial Robinson, S. L., & Bennett, R. J. 1995. A typol-
theory. American Journal of Sociology, 82 ogy of deviant workplace behaviors: A multi-
(6): 1212–1241. dimensional scaling study. Academy of
Meyer, S. 1981. The Five Dollar Day. Albany, Management Journal, 38(2): 555–572.
NY: State University of New York Press. Russo, M. V. 2001. Institutions, exchange rela-
Meyer, J. W., & Rowan, B. 1977. Institutionalized tions and the emergence of new fields:
organizations: Formal structure as myth and Regulatory policies and independent power
ceremony. American Journal of Sociology, production in America, 1978–1992.
83: 340–363. Administrative Science Quarterly, 46: 57–86.
Mezias, S., & Scarselletta, M. 1994. Resolving Scott, J. 2001. Power. Oxford: Blackwell.
financial reporting problems: An institutional Scott, W. R. 2001. Institutions and Organi-
analysis of the process. Administrative zations, 2nd edn. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.
Science Quarterly, 39,(4): 654–658. Selznick, P. 1949. TVA and the Grass Roots.
Mintzberg, H. 1983. Power in and Around Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.
Organizations. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Sewell, G. 1998. The discipline of teams: The
Prentice-Hall control of team-based industrial work
Mintzberg, H. 1984. Power and organizational through electronic and peer surveillance.
life cycles. Academy of Management Administrative Science Quarterly, 43:
Review, 9: 207–224. 397–428.
Munir, K. A., & Phillips, N. 2005. The birth of the Sewell, G., & Wilkinson, B. 1992. ‘Someone to
‘Kodak Moment’: Institutional entrepreneur- watch over me’: Surveillance, discipline and
ship and the adoption of new technologies. the just-in-time labour process. Sociology,
Organization Studies, 26(11): 1665–1687. 26(2): 271–289.
Noble, D. 1984. Forces of Production: A Social Shaiken, H. 1984. Automation and Labor in the
History of Industrial Automation. New York: Computer Age. New York: Holt, Rinehart &
Knopf. Winston.
Oakes, L., Townley, B., & Cooper, D. J. 1998. Simon, J. 1988. The ideological effects of actu-
Business planning as pedagogy: Language arial practices. Law & Society Review, 22(4):
and control in a changing institutional field. 771–800.
Administrative Science Quarterly, 43: 257–292. Slack, T., & Hinings, C. R. 1994. Institutional
O’Leary-Kelly, A. M. Griffin, R. W., & Glew, D. pressures and isomorphic change: An empir-
J. 1996. Organization-motivated aggression: ical test. Organization Studies, 15(6):
A research framework. Academy of 803–827.
Management Review, 21, 225–253. Snow, D. A., & Benford, R. D. 1988. Ideology,
Oliver, C. 1991. Strategic responses to institu- frame resonance and participant mobili-
tional processes. Academy of Management zation. International Social Movement
Review, 16: 145–179. Research, 1: 197–218.
POWER, INSTITUTIONS AND ORGANIZATIONS 197

Snow, D. A., Rochford, E. B., Worden, S. K., & Tolbert, P. S., & Zucker, L. G. 1983. Institutional
Benford, R. D. 1986. Frame alignment sources of change in organizational struc-
processes, micromobilization, and move- ture: The diffusion of civil service reform,
ment participation. American Sociological 1880–1935. Administrative Science Quarterly,
Review, 51: 464–481. 28: 22–39.
Strang, D., & Soule, S. A. 1998. Diffusion in Townley, B. 1993. Foucault, power/knowledge,
organizations and social movements: From and its relevance for human resource man-
hybrid corn to poison pills. Annual Review of agement. Academy of Management Review,
Sociology, 24: 265–290. 18: 518–545.
Stryker, R. 1994. Rules, resources, and legiti- Townley, B. 1997. The institutional logics of
macy processes: Some implications for social performance appraisal. Organization Studies,
conflict, order, and change. American 18(2): 261–285.
Journal of Sociology, 99(4): 847–910. Townley, B. 2002. The role of competing
Stryker, R. 2000. Legitimacy processes as insti- rationalities in institutional change. Academy
tutional politics: Implications for theory and of Management Journal, 45: 163–179.
research in the sociology of organizations. Townley, B. 1997. The institutional logics of
Research in the Sociology of Organizations, performance appraisal. Organization Studies,
17: 179–223. 18(2): 261–285.
Stryker, R. 2002. A political approach to organ- Townley, B. 2002. The role of competing
izations and institutions. In M. Lounsbury U rationalities in institutional change. Academy
and M. J. Ventresca (eds.) Research in the of Management Journal, 45: 163–179.
Sociology of Organizations, 19: 169–191. Westphal, J. D., Gulati, R., & Shortell, S. M.
Oxford: JAI Press. 1997. Customization or conformity? An
Suddaby, R., & Greenwood, R. 2005. Rhetorical institutional and network perspective on the
strategies of legitimacy. Administrative content and consequences of TQM adop-
Science Quarterly, 50: 35–67. tion. Administrative Science Quarterly, 42:
Thompson, J. D. 1956. Authority and power in 366–394.
‘identical’ organizations. American Journal Winner, L. 1986. The Whale and the Reactor:
of Sociology, 62(3): 290–301. A Search for Limits in an Age of High
Thornton, P. H. 2002. The rise of the corpora- Technology. Chicago: University of Chicago
tion in a craft industry: conflict and conform- Press.
ity in institutional logics. Academy of Zucker, L. G. 1987. Institutional theories of
Management Journal, 45: 81–101. organization. Annual Review of Sociology,
Thornton, P. H., & Ocasio, W. 1999. 13: 443–464.
Institutional logics and the historical Zucker, L. G. 1988. Where do institutional pat-
contingency of power in organizations: terns come from? Organizations as actors in
Executive succession in the higher education social systems. In L. G. Zucker (ed.),
publishing industry, 1958–1990. American Institutional Patterns and Organizations:
Journal of Sociology, 105(3): 801–843. 23–52. Cambridge, MA: Ballinger.
7
Institutional Entrepreneurship
Cynthia Hardy and Steve Maguire

INTRODUCTION considerations of agency, power and interests


into analyses of institutional fields
(e.g., Powell & DiMaggio, 1991; Greenwood
In this chapter, we review the emerging and
& Hinings, 1996; Hirsch & Lounsbury,
rapidly growing body of organizational
1997). Some work suggests that individual
research on institutional entrepreneurship.
institutional entrepreneurs play highly influ-
This term refers to the ‘activities of actors
ential, if not determining, roles in episodes of
who have an interest in particular institu-
creating and transforming institutional
tional arrangements and who leverage
arrangements. Other writers, however, are
resources to create new institutions or to
more cautious of attributing too much agency
transform existing ones’ (Maguire, Hardy &
or causality to specific actors and have,
Lawrence, 2004: 657); while institutional
instead, emphasized the collective,
entrepreneurs are those actors to whom the
incremental and multi-level elements of
responsibility for new or changed institutions
institutional entrepreneurship as a process,
is attributed. These concepts are most closely
including its unintended consequences. Our
associated with DiMaggio’s (1988: 14) work
purpose in this chapter is, then, to explore
in which he argued that ‘new institutions
different perspectives on the nature, role and
arise when organized actors with sufficient
impact of institutional entrepreneurs, as well
resources (institutional entrepreneurs) see in
as processes of institutional entrepreneurship.
them an opportunity to realize interests that
Underpinning much of the recent interest
they value highly’. Institutional entrepre-
in institutional entrepreneurship (e.g.,
neurs can also work to maintain or to disrupt
Dorado, 2005; Battilana, 2006; Leca &
and tear down institutions, although there is
Naccache, 2006; Garud, Hardy & Maguire,
far less research in these areas as compared
2007) is the paradox of embedded agency
to studies of institution building and
(Powell & DiMaggio, 1991; Friedland &
institutional change (Lawrence & Suddaby,
Alford, 1991; Sewell, 1992; Holm, 1995; Seo
2006).
& Creed, 2002), which raises interesting
The recent growth in the literature on insti-
questions for institutional theorists.
tutional entrepreneurship responds to calls
for institutional theorists to bridge the ‘old’ The theoretical puzzle is as follows: if actors are
and ‘new’ institutionalisms by reintroducing embedded in an institutional field … how are they
INSTITUTIONAL ENTREPRENEURSHIP 199

able to envision new practices and then subse- In this chapter, we explore how research
quently get others to adopt them? Dominant has sought to answer these and related ques-
actors in a given field may have the power to force
tions. We start by considering which types of
change but often lack the motivation; while
peripheral players may have the incentive to create actor take on the role of institutional entre-
and champion new practices, but often lack the preneur, reviewing work exploring the attrib-
power to change institutions (Garud, Hardy & utes of individual actors as well as the place
Maguire, 2007: 961). they occupy in the field. The second section
First, it is not clear how actors are able to describes the field conditions that help to ini-
envision and champion new practices if they tiate institutional entrepreneurship – how
are embedded in an institutional field and particular aspects of an institutional field
subject to its regulative, normative and cog- provide a context in which ideas for change
nitive pressures. As Maguire (2007: 674) can emerge and take hold. In the third section
points out, ‘actors who are truly embedded’ we consider the role of interpretive struggles
are not supposed to imagine, desire or realize and, specifically, how contests over meaning
alternative ways of doing things ‘because are associated with processes of institutional
institutionalized arrangements and practices entrepreneurship. In the fourth section, we
structure cognitions, define interests and, in discuss intervention strategies – patterned
the limit, produce actors’ identities’. So, action by institutional entrepreneurs as they
although central, dominant actors may be seek to change a field. Finally, we provide
able to champion institutional change, they some insights on how this body of literature
appear unlikely to come up with novel ideas has developed and the direction it might take
or to pursue change because they are deeply in the future by distinguishing between two
embedded in – and advantaged by – existing different narratives of institutional entrepre-
institutional arrangements. Resource-rich neurship. We find that the majority of the lit-
central players are often unable ‘to see erature has developed around actor-centric
beyond prevailing “recipes” ’; are committed accounts that focus on particular institutional
to existing technologies; are ‘exposed to nor- entrepreneurs, and how and why they are
mative processes’; and have interests able to transform fields. However, a different
‘aligned with current practices’ (Greenwood narrative can also be identified – one that is
& Suddaby, 2006: 29; also see DiMaggio & process-centric and emphasizes the struggle
Powell, 1983; Tushman & Anderson, 1986; that accompanies processes of institutional
Porac & Thomas, 1990). Second, it is also entrepreneurship. It is this narrative that, we
unclear how institutional entrepreneurs get feel, offers more promising avenues for
other embedded field members to take up future research in as much as it helps to
and institutionalize new practices. Those ensure that the efforts of institutional theo-
actors that are most likely to imagine and rists to incorporate agency – in order to move
desire change are often located at the periph- beyond an over-emphasis on the constraining
ery – by being less embedded in and less effects of institutions – do not swing too far
privileged by existing institutional arrange- in the opposite direction.
ments, they have more to gain from change
and more ideas for what it might look like
(e.g., Leblebici, Salancik, Copay & King,
1991). However, they are also likely to lack INSTITUTIONAL ENTREPRENEURS
the power and resources necessary to realize
it (Maguire, 2007). Moreover, even central Who can become an institutional entrepre-
actors in mature fields have to work to ensure neur? Who are the actors who ‘break away
that a wide range of other field members from scripted patterns of behaviour’ (Dorado,
abandon existing practices in favour of the 2005: 388) and strive ‘to develop strategies
new ones that they are championing. and shape institutions’ (Lecca & Naccache,
200 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

2006: 627). At a basic level, researchers have Other work has examined the characteris-
examined different types of actors that initiate tics of institutional entrepreneurs using a dif-
institutional change and act as institutional ferent theoretical perspective – critical
entrepreneurs, including: individuals realism (Mutch, Delbridge & Ventresca,
(Fligstein, 2001b; Kraatz & Moore, 2002; 2006; Leca & Naccache, 2006). For example,
Lawrence & Phillips 2004; Maguire et al., Mutch (2007) uses Archer’s (2003) work to
2004; Dew, 2006); organizations (e.g., study Sir Andrew Barclay Walker, who pio-
Dejean et al., 2004; Demil & Bensedrine, neered the practice of directly managed
2005; Garud et al., 2002; Hensman, 2003; public houses in England. Mutch (2007)
Leblebici et al., 1991), especially in the suggests that Walker was able to act as an
professions (Edelman & Suchman, 1997; institutional entrepreneur because of his
Greenwood et al., 2002; 2005; 2006; reflexivity. Specifically, he was an
Lounsbury, 2002); networks (Dorado, 2005); ‘autonomous reflexive’ – an actor who
associations (Demil & Bensédrine, 2005); reflected in relative isolation from the con-
and social movements (Lounsbury et al., cerns of others, as a result of which he was
2003; Rao 1998; 2002; Rao et al., 2000). more likely to experience conflict with the
Researchers have, however, explored more structures that surrounded him and, there-
complex questions than whether individuals, fore, to seek opportunities for change. Leca
organizations or collectives can act as institu- & Naccache (2006) use critical realism to
tional entrepreneurs; accordingly, we explore the activities of an organization,
examine work that has linked institutional rather than an individual – ARESE, the first
entrepreneurship to properties associated company to act as a social rating agency in
with particular types of actors, as well as to France. These authors show how, despite
specific positions in a given field. being embedded, reflexivity allowed this
organization to contribute to the institutional-
ization of Socially Responsible Investment in
that country.
Properties
Work in the critical realist tradition, while
One approach to understanding who initiates focusing on the institutional entrepreneur,
institutional change focuses explicitly on the also places considerable emphasis on the
properties – special characteristics, qualities institutional context, reminding us that actors
and abilities – which distinguish institutional are products of the institutional fields in
entrepreneurs from others in the field, and which they operate. Although it has been
allow them to envision and promote alterna- argued that many institutional studies tend to
tive arrangements. This work sees the institu- treat the actor, whether individual or organi-
tional entrepreneur as an ‘analytically zational, as unproblematic (see the chapter
distinguished social type who has the capa- by Ezzemal & Willmott in this volume), it is
bility to take a reflective position towards important to remember that actors, interests,
institutionalized practices and can envision goals and strategies are institutionally, cul-
alternative modes of getting things done’ turally and historically shaped (Friedland &
(Beckert, 1999: 786, emphasis in original). Alford, 1991; Clemens & Cook, 1999;
At the level of the individual, the notion Meyer, 2006). Which actors have ‘the right to
of an institutional entrepreneur thus opens have interests, what interests are regarded as
up avenues of research informed by cog- reasonable or appropriate, and what means
nitive psychology and ‘the development can be used to pursue them are all products
of systematic tools for predicting how indi- of socially constructed rules’, meaning that
vidual cognition is translated into actions ‘who has the right to take self-determined
in the institutional environment’ (George, and self interested actions – is expected to
Chattopadhyay, Sitkin & Barden, 2006: 348). vary over time and place’ (Scott, 1995: 140).
INSTITUTIONAL ENTREPRENEURSHIP 201

In order to recognize the mutually constitutive government in Alberta, Canada imposed


nature of actors and fields, research has also business planning practices on government
focused more directly on the actor’s position departments by fiat (Townley, 2002). Sherer
in the field in trying to ascertain who or what and Lee (2002) found, in their study of law
can act as an institutional entrepreneur. firms, that it was the most prestigious ones
that first adopted new personnel practices.
Similarly, it was the largest accounting firms
Positions that (unsuccessfully) promoted the adoption
of multi-divisional form in the Canadian
To focus more attention on how the actor is a accounting field (Greenwood et al., 2002;
product of the field, researchers have investi- Greenwood & Suddaby, 2006). In the field of
gated the way in which fields create a limited French cuisine, change in the form of nou-
number of subject positions (Maguire et al., velle cuisine came from chefs ‘in the centre
2001) or social positions (Battilana, 2006), of the French culinary world who had
from which actors can take action (Bourdieu, received honors from the French state and
1990). Subject position refers to those legiti- had garnered plaudits from the Guide
mated identities that are available in a field Michelin’ (Rao et al., 2003: 804).
(Oakes et al., 1998). Power relations among Such research has shown even central
actors are thus embedded in the field actors may not be as embedded in a single
(Fligstein, 2001b), including the capital or field as strong institutionalist views would
resources available to different actors, as well suggest. In fact, they may have access to
as a sense of the social ‘game’ – what Bourdieu alternative practices in other fields through a
calls ‘habitus’ (see Everett, 2002). These rela- variety of mechanisms. For example, many
tions and resources in turn provide actors with leading French chefs visited Japan and
institutionally defined interests and opportuni- obtained new ideas from a completely differ-
ties (Bourdieu & Wacquant, 1992) and, in ent culinary field to develop nouvelle cuisine
some cases, with the possibility to exert power (Rao et al., 2003). Large Danish organiza-
over the field at a particular point in time tions introduced American practices of diver-
(Bourdieu, 1986). Fields are ‘structured sys- sity management as a result of the influence
tems of social positions within which struggles of employees and consultants who had expe-
or manouvre take place over resources, stakes rience of other fields, including overseas
and access’ (Oakes et al., 1998: 260). In other work and involvement in the feminist move-
words, actors do not ‘have’ power; instead, ment (Boxenbaum & Battilana, 2005).
they occupy (or fail to occupy) subject posi- Research has also shown that the large, elite
tions that allow them to exercise power in – accounting firms which introduced the multi-
and on – a particular field. For example, divisional form into the field of Canadian
Maguire et al. (2004), in their study of the accounting were not as embedded as might
emerging field of HIV/AIDS advocacy in have been thought, given their central loca-
Canada, found that the institutional entrepre- tion in a highly institutionalized mature field.
neurs were actors who occupied subject posi- Greenwood and Suddaby (2006: 40) found
tions that provided them with legitimacy with that these firms bridged a number of organi-
respect to diverse stakeholders; and enabled zational fields, including those of their global
them to bridge stakeholders in ways which clients. This ‘boundary bridging’ exposed
facilitated access to dispersed resources. them to alternative practices; while their
Empirical studies have found that, despite scope and size meant they were too large to
the paradox of embedded agency, institu- be effectively regulated by their profession;
tional change can be initiated by powerful and their reliance on in-house training
actors located in dominant positions in reduced their exposure to normative
mature fields. For example, the provincial influences.
202 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Research has also shown how institutional entrepreneur, is the preferred direction for
change can also be initiated by less domi- future research: the ability of institutional
nant, peripheral actors. For example, despite entrepreneurs to see or create ‘a window of
the fierce defence of traditional distribution opportunity’ needs to be considered in rela-
networks in the American music industry, tion to the way in which the field produces
‘disruptive challengers’ like Napster were their interests, skills and stocks of knowledge
able to undermine ‘status quo incumbents’ (Meyer, 2006: 732), as we explore in the next
and open up space for new practices section.
(Hensman, 2003); fringe players initiated
change in the US broadcasting industry by
introducing new practices that were adopted
by dominant players to become conventions INITIATING FIELD CONDITIONS
in the field (Leblebici et al., 1991: 345);
while activist organizations, such as environ- Another line of enquiry concerned with
mental NGOs, played an important role in resolving the paradox of embedded agency
the institutionalization of recycling practices has tried to identify particular field
(Lounsbury et al., 2003). Compared to dom- conditions that create opportunities for insti-
inant actors, peripheral actors are expected to tutional entrepreneurship. We begin this
have less difficulty developing ideas for section by summarizing two approaches that
change: they are less likely to be connected explore the stimuli that appear to trigger
to other actors and, therefore, less aware of institutional entrepreneurship: uncertainty as
institutional norms and practices; and they well as other problems in a field for which
are more likely to be exposed to alternative new or changed institutions can serve as
ideas by being on the periphery of the field solutions; and tensions and contradictions
(Suddaby & Greenwood, 2006; Maguire, that exist, even in highly institutionalized
2007). They are also likely to be motivated to fields, which provide actors with margins of
bring about change since they are often dis- manoeuvre and opportunities for creativity.
advantaged by prevailing arrangements We conclude with a discussion of how the
(Leblebici et al., 1991). The paradox in this state of a particular field can facilitate institu-
situation is less about how such actors come tional entrepreneurship.
up with ideas for change; rather, it relates to
how these peripheral, marginal actors get
other field members to adopt them, as we Stimuli
discuss in more detail in the section on
intervention strategies below. Some research, especially work that adopts
In summary, individual and various types an economic approach to institution building
of organized, collective actors can act as and views actors as rational, argues that
institutional entrepreneurs. Some research uncertainty in a field prompts institutional
emphasizes institutional entrepreneurs’ change as actors seek to reduce it. Generally
unique abilities and features that, in effect, speaking, uncertainty is ‘the degree to which
make them a privileged ‘species’ of actor – future states of the world cannot be antici-
one ‘increasingly endorsed with specific pated and accurately predicted’ (Pfeffer &
qualities “normal” actors do not possess’ Salancik (1978: 67) and, in economics, refers
(Meyer, 2006: 732). Other research seeks to more precisely to situations where actors
explain who becomes an institutional entre- cannot define rational strategies because they
preneur with reference to the position they cannot calculate probabilities for decision
occupy in a field. It has been argued that the outcomes (Knights, 1921; Beckert, 1999).
latter approach, which seeks to establish an According to this view, institutions, because
institutional grounding of the institutional they structure and make predictable actors’
INSTITUTIONAL ENTREPRENEURSHIP 203

behaviour, are solutions to the problems According to this work, new institutional
faced by cognitively limited actors whose arrangements are promoted by actors seeking
interdependence with other actors creates the to solve problems, such as reducing uncer-
possibility of opportunistic behaviour and tainty, in their institutional field. One would
increased transaction costs (Coase, 1937; therefore expect to see acts of institutional
Williamson, 1985; North, 1990). Working in entrepreneurship correlated with field-level
this tradition, Dew (2006: 16) elaborates the problems or a high degree of field-level
concept of Coasian-style institutional entre- uncertainty. Interestingly, drawing on
preneurship as ‘the activity of initiating, Schumpeter’s notion of an entrepreneur,
creating and leading organizations that spe- Beckert (1999: 783) argues the opposite:
cialize in developing institutional frame- ‘strategic agency that violates existing
works that lower transaction costs’ for other institutional rules can be expected in situa-
actors in the field. He offers the example of a tions characterized by relatively high degrees
grocery executive who pioneered the now of certainty within an institutional field’.
widespread and institutionalized technology This is because actors, if rational, need to be
standards and associated practices for using able to assign probabilities to the possible
bar codes and universal product codes, to consequences of their choices and to work
facilitate exchange relationships. out whether change is going to be profitable
In this way, institutional entrepreneurship or beneficial for them before taking action.
is associated with solving problems that have Consequently, this argument suggests that
been identified in a field. For example, uncertainty follows the ‘creative destruction’
adverse performance of the major accounting of the institutional order that is associated
firms in Canada called into question the effi- with institutional entrepreneurship, rather
ciency of the traditional organizational form than preceding it. The exact nature of the
in the field, prompting some to adopt a new relationship between uncertainty and institu-
multi-divisional form (Greenwood & tional entrepreneurship is, therefore, not
Suddaby, 2006). Similarly, the inflexibility of entirely clear, and further research is
the Association to Advance Collegiate warranted.
Schools of Business (AACSB) model of Another body of work has focused on the
business education in light of increasingly tensions (Dorado, 2005; Zilber, 2002; Rao
diverse student demands and business school et al., 2003; Seo & Creed, 2002; Greenwood
mandates created ‘ambiguity, scarcity in et al., 2006) and contradictions (Sewell,
legitimizing resources … [and] selection 1992; Seo and Creed 2002; Rao et al., 2003)
pressures’ which, in turn, led to moves to which, it is argued, are always present in
expand the field to include European fields – even mature ones – and which pro-
business schools (Durand & McGuire, 2005: vide potential for institutional change. A
184). The rise of socially responsible range of writers have noted that, despite
investing in France created the problem of work that sees institutional fields as totaliz-
how to measure corporate social perform- ing and shared phenomena, they are in fact
ance, as a result of which institutional entre- riven with inconsistencies and conflict
preneurs sought to institutionalize (Friedland & Alford, 1991; Holm, 1995;
standardized measures (Dejean, Gond & Hoffman, 1998; Clemens & Cook, 1999; Seo
Leca, 2004). Once new practices are initially and Creed, 2002). So, although institutional
adopted by some actors, evidence of processes may appear to be stable because
their effectiveness, such as positive market differences among actors are ‘temporarily
feedback, increases their legitimacy among resolved by socially negotiated consensus’,
other actors and encourages their wider this appearance of stability is ‘misleading’
diffusion and adoption (e.g., Lee & (Greenwood et al., 2002: 59). Boundaries are
Pennings, 2002). not static, conflicts among actors arise, and
204 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

structuration does not produce perfect repro- as considerable advantages can be derived
duction (e.g., Holm, 1995). Institutions are for those who succeed in influencing the way
therefore not homogenous or complete inso- in which a field eventually becomes struc-
far as they do not precisely determine behav- tured structured. Also the constraints are
iour: multiple institutions may exist in a fewer compared to mature fields: there are no
given field and conflict with each other; new established patterns to mimic; widely shared
members with different histories and experi- values and norms have yet to develop; and
ences may join a field; and existing members power is more diffuse (Maguire et al., 2004).
may have access to more than one field and Similarly, fields in crisis may also be par-
therefore exposure to a range of practices ticularly conducive to institutional entrepre-
(Clemens & Cook, 1999). Institutional neurship, as a crisis can bring to the surface
change thus results as human praxis is contradictions and tensions in even highly
brought to bear on these tensions and contra- structured, mature fields (Fligstein & Mara-
dictions: as individuals use contradictions to Drita, 1996). These disruptive events
reflect on and critique the limits of present (Hoffman, 1999), shocks (Fligstein, 1991),
institutional arrangements and to inspire triggering events (Rao et al., 2003) or jolts
ideas for new ones; and as they mobilize and (Meyer, 1982) can take multiple forms –
engage other actors in collective action to social upheaval, technological disruptions,
reconstruct the field (Seo & Creed, 2002). regulatory change, or the publication of
books, reports, and media stories (e.g.,
Davis, Diekmann & Tinsley, 1994; Garud,
Jain & Kumaraswamy, 2002; Lounsbury,
States
2002). For instance, Fligstein (2001a) shows
Another body of work interested in identify- how a crisis in the European Union enabled
ing the field conditions that are most the European Commission to act as an insti-
amenable to institutional entrepreneurship has tutional entrepreneur and develop the Single
focused on the particular state of the field – Market Programme. Disruptive events are
whether it is emerging, mature and stable, or capable of ‘ending what has become locked
in crisis (Fligstein, 1997). Certain types of in by institutional inertia’ through the way
field have been associated with greater they create ‘disruptive uncertainty for indi-
likelihood of institutional entrepreneurship. vidual organizations, forcing the initiation of
It has, for example, been argued that unorthodox experiments that diverge from
emerging fields offer considerable scope for established practice’ and ‘throwing entire
institutional entrepreneurship because the industries into the throes of quantum change’
lack of institutionalized practices results in (Hoffman, 1999: 353). Such events may
fluid relationships, conflicting values, and precipitate the entry of new players into an
the absence of clearly identifiable norms – all organizational field, facilitate the ascendance
of which, in turn, may pose problems that of existing actors, or change the intellectual
actors wish to solve; or provide opportunities climate of ideas (Greenwood et al., 2002;
on which they can capitalize (Maguire et al., Greenwood & Suddaby, 2006). In so doing,
2004). Child, Yu and Tsai (2007) show how they both disrupt existing practices and raise
the state took advantage of the emergent awareness of possible new ones, thereby
nature of China’s environmental protection opening up greater opportunity for action.
field to act as an institutional entrepreneur, In sum, certain stimuli – uncertainty, prob-
drawing on developments in other fields lems, tensions and contradictions in a field –
related to international environmental con- can establish favourable initiating conditions
cerns and domestic economic reform. for institutional entrepreneurship by motivat-
Emerging fields may then be particularly ing and furnishing ideas for change.
conducive to institutional entrepreneurship, Additionally, fields in particular states,
INSTITUTIONAL ENTREPRENEURSHIP 205

especially emerging ones and those in crisis, meanings associated with practices, diffusing
are also more likely to present opportunities them intact and unchanged through a field;
for institutional entrepreneurship, although rather, all actors in the field are viewed as
some researchers argue that uncertainty, active interpreters of practices whose
problems, tensions and contradictions are, to meaning is, as a result, negotiated in on-
some degree, features of all fields, even going, complex processes.
mature fields. Much of this work tends to In this regard, ‘individuals’ interpretations
conceptualize the state of the field as a set of can be seen as part of institutional agency –
objective conditions that trigger acts of insti- the social actions that create, reproduce, and
tutional entrepreneurship. Munir (2005), change institutions’ (Zilber, 2002: 236; see
however, argues that the way in which events also Karnoe, 1997). This work focuses atten-
are interpreted and given meaning is part of tion on the symbolic aspects of institutional
institutional entrepreneurship. In other change (see Zilber, Chapter 5 in this volume)
words, for an event to be deemed disruptive – and, specifically, on how actors draw on dif-
creating a situation of uncertainty, contradic- ferent discourses, and find new ways to
tion or tension, causing a crisis, etc. – frame and theorize change. From this per-
requires that actors interpret it as disruptive. spective, institutional entrepreneurship is
The role of interpretation in institutional seen to emerge from novel interpretations
entrepreneurship is discussed in more detail and ensuing struggles over meaning,
in the following section. although it also recognizes that, because
meanings of existing practices are supported
by existing logics, myths and discourses,
they may not be easily displaced. Meaning
INTERPRETIVE STRUGGLES thus takes on multiple roles in an institutional
field. First, it is the outcome for which actors
A growing body of work on institutional struggle. Different actors have stakes in par-
entrepreneurship examines interpretation and ticular meanings and attempt to assert their
explains institutional change with reference preferred ones (Grant & Hardy, 2004).
to complex, ongoing struggles over meaning Second, it is the medium through and within
among numerous actors, the outcomes of which power struggles take place as actors
which are not necessarily predictable or con- try to influence institutional change (Zilber,
trollable. Drawing on social constructionist 2006). In this regard, meanings are a
assumptions (Berger & Luckmann, 1967) to resource (Zilber, 2002) – they are drawn
emphasize translation at the micro-level upon by actors to support their positions and
(Czarniawska & Joerges, 1996; Zilber, 2002) to undermine those of opponents – and, at the
and discourse at the macro-level (Phillips same time, a contextual constraint, since
et al., 2004; also see Phillips & Malhotra, field and societal level logics (Lounsbury
Chapter 29 in this volume), this work builds et al., 2003), myths (Zilber, 2006) and dis-
on the idea that institutions are formed as courses (Phillips et al., 2004) are not infi-
meanings come to be shared and taken for nitely pliable.
granted. In contrast to the diffusion metaphor Drawing on these ideas, a growing body of
that has dominated much of institutional work has started to explore the processes of
theory, and which ‘connotes a transmission discursive struggle through which institu-
of a given entity,’ the translation metaphor tional entrepreneurship succeeds or fails. For
‘connotes an interaction that involves example, Zilber (2002: 251) shows how
negotiation between various parties, and the struggle over the meaning of institutionalized
reshaping of what is finally being transmit- practices at a rape crisis centre – whether they
ted’ (Zilber, 2006: 283). Actors are not were ‘feminist’ or ‘therapeutic’ – affected
viewed simply as carriers of institutional power relations inside the organization
206 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

and, as a result, the services that it provided, intended institutional change, usually
but not in predictable, predetermined or with reference to specific strategies for inter-
clearly managed ways. Similarly, Maguire vening in a field, as we discuss in the next
and Hardy (2006) examine the creation of a section.
new global regulatory institution – the
Stockholm Convention on Persistent Organic
Pollutants – which, consistent with the
discourse of ‘precaution’, bans toxic chemi- INTERVENTION STRATEGIES
cals based on uncertain scientific knowledge
of the risks they pose. The new institution Institutional entrepreneurship requires actors
was the outcome of discursive struggle to dislodge existing practices (in the case of
among actors over the meaning of ‘precau- mature fields), introduce new ones, and then
tion’: some state and non-state actors ensure that these become widely adopted and
promoted the new discourse of precaution; taken for granted by other actors in the field.
while other actors countered with the legacy How do institutional entrepreneurs succeed
regulatory discourse of ‘sound science’. As a in these activities to change institutional
result, actors on both sides were forced to fields? This question occupies a large portion
engage with and reconcile competing dis- of the literature, which focuses on identify-
courses and it was out of this struggle that the ing and explicating the strategic interven-
particular institution emerged. In another tions made by institutional entrepreneurs to
study, Zilber (2007) shows how institutional bring about change. Sometimes this work
entrepreneurship in the high-tech industry in focuses directly on the strategies and
Israel following the 2000 dot.com crash activities in which institutional entrepreneurs
involved the construction of a shared story of engage (e.g., Lawrence, 1999); at other
the crisis that reinforced the established insti- times, it focuses on the skills and abilities
tutional order. Yet, at the same time, actors required to carry out these activities
were also telling separate ‘counter-stories’ (e.g., Fligstein, 1997; Perkmann & Spicer,
that called for changes in the institutional 2007). We synthesize the diverse work in this
order. Stories were both the medium of and a area in terms of three broad themes: the
resource for institutional entrepreneurship mobilization of resources; the construction of
but not in a clear-cut, strategic way; actors rationales for institutional change, including
used stories both to protect vested interests in the discursive processes through which new
the current institutional order, as well as to practices are framed and legitimated; and the
agitate for change – all at the same time. forging of new inter-actor relations to bring
As these examples illustrate, this growing about collective action. In this way, we show
body of work draws attention to meaning as that institutional entrepreneurship involves
a collective achievement and emphasizes the the mobilization and recombination of
complex and contradictory processes through materials, symbols and people in novel and
which it is negotiated and stabilized. This even artful ways.
work highlights not only the potential
‘messiness’ of institutional entrepreneurship
processes as discursive manoeuvre are met Resources
with counter-moves, but also the potential for
outcomes which are not necessarily those Resource mobilization has been central to the
originally intended by the actors involved. notion of institutional entrepreneurship since
It thus stands in contrast to the bulk of work DiMaggio’s (1988: 14) definition highlighted
on institutional entrepreneurship which seeks the necessity of ‘sufficient resources’ to
to explain the effectiveness or success of create or change institutions. Despite this
institutional entrepreneurs in bringing about centrality, research is often vague as to what
INSTITUTIONAL ENTREPRENEURSHIP 207

is meant by ‘resources’ as well as what is recruit allies that do. Several studies draw
done with them. Certainly, a wide range of attention to how institutional change in a
resources have been mentioned in the litera- given field depends upon other extant institu-
ture, including the use of finance, knowledge tions, especially legal and professional ones
or an actor’s position within a social network in which institutions to be changed are nested
(Beckert, 1999); political, financial and (cf. Holm, 1995). In other words, the formal
organizational resources (Greenwood & authority of other actors such as the state and
Suddaby, 2006); material resources professional associations can be harnessed as
(Lawrence & Suddaby, 2006); cultural a resource to support change. For example, in
resources (Creed, Scully & Austin, 2002); his study of the early stages of the emergence
and discursive resources (Hardy & Phillips, of the automobile industry, Rao (2002)
1999; Hensman, 2003; Lawrence & Phillips, demonstrates how one mechanism for gener-
2004; Maguire & Hardy, 2006). In this ating constitutive legitimacy for innovative
section, we focus on material resources,1 products around which new industries
which, research suggests, are mobilized by emerge is the enactment of laws that make
institutional entrepreneurs to be used as a the product legal and specify how it can be
lever against other actors – subsidiary actors, made, sold, used, etc., thus authorizing and
allies, and external constituencies – to nego- codifying understandings of the new artifact
tiate support for the change project in ques- and practices of using it. Similarly, Garud et
tion (DiMaggio, 1988). In some instances, al. (2002) note how the legal system can be
powerful actors may control sufficient drawn upon to create new rules or to enforce
resources to impose change on an institu- old ones, both of which can be used to
tional field by themselves (Dorado, 2005), advance institutionalization projects. Of
but it appears that, most of the time, institu- course, opponents of institutionalization
tional entrepreneurship involves a degree of projects can also seek to enroll higher author-
dependency on other actors and the resources ities, and different authorities may clash. So,
they control to make bargaining and negotiat- while Greenwood et al. (2002) show how
ing inevitable. This view is consistent with professional associations lent their authority
Colomy’s (1998) claim that institutional to the elite accounting firms’ adoption of a
entrepreneurs employ strategies that operate new multidivisional organizational form,
through exchange mechanisms: support for a they also note the ultimately determining role
project is contingent on the perception that played by the state in legislating an end to
tangible and/or intangible benefits are forth- experimentation with this form.
coming to other actors. Some entrepreneurial
strategies are premised on positive induce-
ments offered to prospective allies in Rationales
exchange for their support. Others are
premised on negative inducements in the Institutional entrepreneurship also involves
form of threats to establish a bargaining rela- interventions in the discursive or ideational
tionship in which the coerced party’s ‘best realm as actors construct rationales or rea-
hope is that it will be no worse off than it sons and communicate them to other actors
would have been had the coercive relation- concerning why they should support or, at a
ship never commenced’ (Turner & Killian, minimum, not resist the institutionalization
1987: 298–299; quoted in Colomy, 1998: project in question. Much of this work draws
280). In this way, institutional entrepr- on social constructionist assumptions. A
eneurship involves materially rewarding wide range of terms from a variety of theoret-
supporters and punishing opponents. ical traditions have been used to characterize
If institutional entrepreneurs do not con- these processes, many of them overlapping.
trol rewards and punishments, they can We summarize this work here, highlighting
208 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

how it explores the content, context and out- appeals: existing practices are decried as
come of the communicative acts associated unjust and accused of being inefficient or
with institutional entrepreneurship. ineffective; and institutional entrepreneurs
One body of work examines how the have been shown to deploy an array of argu-
content of the institutional entrepreneur’s ments that include different appeals for dif-
communication creates shared cognitions ferent constituencies in the field (Maguire
(and emotions) that support institutional et al., 2004). As a result, evangelical appeals
change. Perhaps the most common descrip- (Rao, 2002) in support of institutionalization
tion of the content of discursive interventions projects are often combined with ‘rational’ or
associated with institutional entrepreneur- ‘technical’ demonstrations of efficiency and
ship derives from social movement theory. effectiveness. It is important, however, to
This work has examined how institutional keep in mind that so-called rationality is
entrepreneurs provide entrepreneurial nonetheless socially constructed: ‘entrepre-
accounts (Colomy, 1998) or legitimating neurs commonly invoke efficiency and effec-
accounts of their institutionalization projects tiveness strategically and ceremonially to
(Creed et al., 2002), in which they frame the advance their projects; the validity of these
changes in ways to generate collective action claims is rarely demonstrated in an unequiv-
(Benford & Snow, 2000; also see Lounsbury ocal way, however, and rests chiefly on the
et al., 2003; Garud et al., 2002). A ‘collective project’s perceived conformity to institu-
action frame’ is a coherent interpretive tional myths’ (Colomy, 1998: 289). In addi-
structure that accomplishes three tasks: punc- tion, legitimating accounts often take the
tuation, which identifies a problem and form of stories or narratives (Lounsbury &
defines it as important; elaboration, which Glynn, 2001); contain rhetoric deployed
includes a diagnosis of the problem describ- strategically to increase their impact
ing who or what is responsible for it, as well (Greenwood & Suddaby, 2005); and are
as a prognosis describing what is required to typically communicated to audiences
correct it; and motivation, which encourages through the production, distribution and con-
actors to participate in change (Snow et al., sumption of texts (Philips et al., 2004).
1986; Creed et al., 2002). By using particular Another body of work describing the dis-
frames, institutional entrepreneurs can cursive interventions associated with institu-
increase the chances of successful institu- tional entrepreneurship draws attention to the
tional change. Frames may be transposed context in which legitimating accounts are
from the broader culture to a specific field produced. Appreciating that institutional
(Clemens & Cook, 1999; Seo & Creed, change is always situated in some historical
2002), or new ones may be built (Rao, 1998). and cultural context, research has shown how
Similarly, within institutional theory, the institutional entrepreneurs selectively adopt
study of theorization (Strang & Meyer, 1993; and deploy some of the alternative logics
Greenwood et al., 2002) has explored how available to them (Seo & Creed, 2002); and
institutional entrepreneurs specify a problem align their projects to master rules of society
with existing practices and justify new ones (Havemen & Rao, 1997), cultural accounts
as a solution. (Creed et al., 2002), professionalization proj-
In the case of both framing and theoriza- ects (Rao, 1998), or professional standards
tion, institutional entrepreneurs attempt to (Dejean et al., 2004). In order to gain accept-
discredit the status quo and to present the ance for change, actors typically position it in
alternative practices they are championing as terms of existing categories and schema
necessary, valid and appropriate in ways that (Hargadon & Douglas, 2001); and draw upon
resonate with other field members (Rao, available discourses (Hardy & Phillips, 1999;
1998). These legitimating accounts typically Lawrence & Phillips, 2004) to make change
combine normative and interest based meaningful to other actors in particular ways.
INSTITUTIONAL ENTREPRENEURSHIP 209

A third body of work examines institu- among actors, such as collaborations, coali-
tional entrepreneurs’ discursive interventions tions, and alliances.
in terms of the desired outcomes they are Institutional entrepreneurship is, then,
designed to achieve in relation to the targeted associated with various forms of collabora-
audience. The work varies in terms of the tive relations – partnerships, coalitions, etc. –
degree of to which this audience is accorded which require the cooperation of other
a role in the change process. Sometimes, the actors. For this reason it has been suggested
audience is seen as contributing to institu- that institutional entrepreneurs have unique
tional entrepreneurship in a reciprocal political and social skills (Perkmann &
relationship. For example, it has been argued Spicer, 2007), including ‘the ability to induce
that institutional entrepreneurship involves cooperation among others’ (Fligstein, 2001a:
sharing ideas (Boxenbaum & Battilana, 112). As a result, institutional entrepreneurs
2005) and participating in collective sense engage in a range of material and discursive
making (Edelman & Suchman, 1997) with interventions aimed at changing inter-actor
other actors, who thereby become part of the relations and bringing about collective
change process. Most work, however, places action. In so doing, institutional entrepre-
much more emphasis on a unilateral relation- neurs do not work single-handedly; they
ship where the institutional entrepreneur: engage with other members of the field.
persuades other actors (Dew, 2006; Garud Institutional entrepreneurship therefore
et al., 2002); reorganizes their preferences seems to be predominantly a collective
(Fligstein, 2001a); aligns (Demil & process.
Benesdrine, 2005), translates (Maguire et al., We can, then, see a link between interven-
2004) or aggregates (Fligstein, 1997) their tion strategies which mobilize material
interests in relation to the institutionalization resources and rationales and the subsequent
project; and builds consensus among mobilization of actors to participate in
members of the field (Dew, 2006). In this collective action or to adopt new practices –
work, there is greater emphasis on the role actions in which actors might not otherwise
and skills of the institutional entrepreneur in engage, were it not for the interventions of
achieving the desired outcome; and less institutional entrepreneurs. In this way, insti-
concern for the role of other actors. tutional entrepreneurship is tightly connected
to the exercise of power (Fligstein, 2001b).
Because institutional fields are arenas of
ongoing and shifting power relations that are
Relations
only ever contingently stabilized, institu-
Institutional entrepreneurship often involves tional entrepreneurship can be seen as the
establishing new inter-actor relations to realignment of material, discursive and orga-
bring about change, primarily – as much of nizational forces around new relations and
the work discussed above indicates – through practices (Levy & Scully, 2007). It requires
collective action (Dew, 2006; Aldrich & Fiol, ‘the assent or, minimally, the acquiescence
1994; Garud et al., 2002; Lawrence et al., of various groups as well as the capacity
2002; Wijen & Ansari, 2007). Given that to prevail over opposition’ (Colomy, 1998:
institutional entrepreneurship is about alter- 278). The overt leveraging of material
ing deeply embedded norms, values and resources to ensure change even in the
practices, it is not surprising that it depends face of resistance, such as offering
upon more than a single individual or organ- financial incentives, imposing penalities, or
ization. As a result, both the mobilization of invoking formal authority, etc., represents the
material resources and the construction and exercise of the first dimension of power
communication of rationales for change are (Lukes, 1974). Discursive interventions
typically means to develop new relations to create and communicate convincing
210 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

rationales represent the exercise of what international and global levels of analysis,
Lukes (1974) referred to as the third dimen- including national regulations governing
sion of power, which aims to create legiti- industrial wastes (Demil & Bensédrine,
macy for new practices and institutional 2005); the reconstitution of the European
change by managing meaning (Pettigrew, Union (Fligstein, 2001a); and the Stockholm
1979); and to coopt opponents rather than to Convention on Persistent Organic Pollutants
confront them, thereby avoiding overt (Maguire & Hardy, 2006). It has also con-
conflict and resistance (Hardy, 1985). For tributed to the emergence of new industries
example, research has highlighted that insti- (Aldrich & Fiol, 1994), such as socially
tutional entrepreneurs use stories strategi- responsible investment in France (Dejean
cally to ‘help induce cooperation from et al. (2004), whale-watching (Phillips &
people in their group that appeal to their Lawrence, 2004) and forensic accounting in
identity and interests’ (Fligstein, 2001b: 113; Canada (Lawrence, 1999), as well as inde-
also see Colomy, 1998). Similarly, much of pendent power production (Russo 2001),
the work informed by social movement craft brewing (Rao, 2002), the electricity
theory shows how framing is used purpose- industry (Hargadon & Douglas, 2001) and
fully to enroll allies and to build coalitions recycling (Lounsbury, Ventresca & Hirch,
(Rao, 1998; Rao et al., 2000). Less promi- 2003) in the US. New organizational forms,
nent in the literature are discussions of how such as the multidivisional organizational
institutional entrepreneurship involves exer- form in publishing (Thornton, 2002) and
cising the second dimension of power accounting (Greenwood et al., 2002;
(Bachrach & Baratz, 1962; Lukes, 1974) to Greenwood & Suddaby, 2006; Suddaby &
manipulate decision agendas, arenas and par- Greenwood, 2005), have emerged from
ticipants to bring about change (Hardy, successful institutionalization projects.
1994), although agenda setting has received Institutional entrepreneurs have promoted
some mention (see Fligstein, 2001b). In addi- the adoption of new practices, ranging from
tion, perhaps because of a bias towards the introduction of business plans in
studying successful instances of institutional museums (Oakes, Townley & Cooper, 1998);
entrepreneurship or because of the interest in new forms of diversity management
the ‘heroic’ entrepreneur, non-cooperative (Boxenbaum & Battilana, 2005); new
actors are frequently ignored and actors that exchange media in radio broadcasting
resist change do not figure as prominently (Leblebici et al., 1991); and new technologi-
in analyses of intervention strategies as cal standards (Garud et al., 2002). Finally,
one might expect. We expand upon this institutional entrepreneurship has led to new
observation in the next section. identities for individuals (Fligstein, 2001b;
Maguire et al., 2001; Creed et al., 2002: Rao
et al., 2003) and organizations (Rao et al.,
2000; Greenwood et al., 2002; also
INSIGHTS see Chapter 16 on identity theory in this
volume).
Most studies have found institutional entre- Some of these outcomes are more conse-
preneurs to be highly influential in shaping quential for the field than others, resulting in
their institutional fields, contributing to a major upheaval or transformation as power
range of outcomes that include the creation relations among actors are reconfigured, and
of new formal institutions, industries, organi- only after significant contestation and
zational forms, practices and identities. For struggle. Others represent changes that,
example, empirical work shows that institu- while they might be quite marked, do not
tional entrepreneurship has resulted in new entail a significant redistribution of capital
formal regulatory institutions at national, (Bourdieu, 1990) in the field – as a result of
INSTITUTIONAL ENTREPRENEURSHIP 211

the institutionalization of new practices, elaboration requirements may be greater


dominant actors may do things differently insofar as fluid, embryonic practices and
but they remain dominant. In this way, we relationships have to be stabilized but, even
can see evidence of two different narratives so, institutional entrepreneurs act with the
of institutional entrepreneurship in the litera- intention of securing a more dominant
ture – one that is more actor-centric and position as the field emerges and matures
focuses on the deliberate strategies of partic- (Maguire et al., 2004). In other words,
ular institutional entrepreneurs; and another insofar as uncertainty has been reduced,
which is more process-centric and focuses on problems have been solved, or dominance
the struggles associated with institutional has been secured, the functionalist orienta-
entrepreneurship. tion presents the resulting change as an
The majority of the literature constructs, improvement on the existing situation.
explicitly or implicitly, a narrative centred However, the notion of ‘better’ institutional
on the institutional entrepreneur. This narra- arrangements is rarely problematized; and
tive tends to be more functionalist, and to the question of who benefits from – and who
paint a neat picture of relatively rational, is disadvantaged by – institutional entrepre-
linear, win-win problem-solving activity neurship is rarely asked in this narrative.
where the (usually successful) institutional In contrast, process-centric narratives
entrepreneur possesses a degree of reflexivity focus on institutional entrepreneurship as an
or insight (Seo & Creed, 2002; Mutch, 2007) emergent outcome of activities of diverse,
that allows them to identify opportunities for spatially dispersed actors (Lounsbury &
change as a result of some stimuli, such as Crumley, 2007), who face considerable diffi-
uncertainty or a recognized problem in the culty in achieving effective collective action
field (e.g., Beckert, 1999; Lee & Pennings, (Wijen & Ansari, 2007). This narrative
2002; Dew, 2006). Then, using their superior emphasizes diffuse struggles over – and
political and social skills, the actor inter- through – meaning, where gains for one
venes strategically to realize institutional group may imply significant losses for
change through the combination and mobi- others, providing greater scope for examin-
lization of resources, rationales and relations ing conflict as well as failure. Narratives of
in creative ways (Fligstein, 2001a; 2001b). this form tend to be adopted by researchers
Other actors play minor, supporting – and interested in how particular – not necessarily
cooperative – roles if they figure at all, intended – outcomes are negotiated materi-
and conflict is pushed to the background. ally and discursively. The outcomes that
The new or changed institutions typically do follow from institutional entrepreneurship
not imply or reflect a radical reconfiguration are therefore more varied, ranging from: no
of power relations in the field: they are ‘elab- change, perhaps because the struggle is self-
orative’ rather than ‘reconstructive’ projects defeating or because the prevailing
(Colomy, 1998). For example, dominant discourses are too constraining; through to
players may adopt new practices but retain radical change and the transformation of
their dominance and, in fact, may change power relations among actors in the field.
their practices in order to remain dominant Some researchers are sceptical, however, as
(e.g., Greenwood et al., 2002, 2006). In fact, to the degree that power relations are trans-
institutional entrepreneurship activities are formed when non-dominant actors engage in
often described, in this narrative, as being institutional entrepreneurship, arguing that
directed at aligning change with – and often new institutional arrangements emerge from
embedding it in – existing values, logics and some form of ‘hegemonic accommodation’
practices, which results in minimal change in as dominant actors cede only limited ground,
power relations (e.g., Hargadon & Douglas, typically through partnerships with more
2001). In the case of emerging fields, the moderate actors in the coalition pressing for
212 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

change (Levy & Scully, 2007). In addition, actor-centric narratives when it focuses on
the disadvantages and possible negative out- the activities of those occupying central,
comes of institutional entrepreneurship are dominant positions, especially in mature
more likely to be recognized in process-cen- fields, as does research that sees institutional
tric narratives. For example, in exploring a entrepreneurship as a form of problem-
project to de-institutionalize child labour in solving. The work on contradictions and
the world’s largest soccer ball manufacturing tensions – even though socially construction-
cluster in Sialkot, Pakistan, Khan, Munir & ist – can also be actor-centric through the
Willmott (2007) found that ‘success’ in way it attributes the ability to make sense out
eliminating child labour came at a high price, of contradictions to specific actors, as well as
especially for the women stitchers, the the way it sometimes treats the state of the
majority of whom dropped out of the work- field and contradictions themselves as
force, often plunging their families into objective and unproblematic.
abject poverty. Attention is thus paid not only On the other hand, work that treats crises,
to protagonists during episodes of change – disruptive events, or other stimuli as phenom-
the institutional entrepreneurs – but also to ena that are discursively constructed appears
their opponents and other members of the to have more potential to produce process-
field who may engage in some form of centric accounts, especially when examining
counter-framing (e.g., Creed et al., 2002), the unintended and serendipitous way in
produce counter-narratives (Colomy, 1998) which some events get constructed in ways
or make discursive counter-moves (Munir & that prompt change, while other similar ones
Phillips, 2005). As a result, the purported do not (although work that highlights the
benefits of institutional change, as well as unique skill of particular actors in construct-
attributions of causality to only a handful of ing these events as disruptive tends to be more
actors, are more likely to be problematized. actor-centric). The work that explores inter-
We acknowledge that the two narratives pretive struggles and, specifically, how dis-
are not necessarily mutually exclusive: actor- cursive struggle produces or changes the
centric accounts necessarily talk about nature of subject positions in a field, is also
processes in recounting the activities in more likely to result in process-centric narra-
which institutional actors engage; while tives. Similarly, some of the work on discur-
process-centric accounts inevitably single sive intervention strategies, especially when it
out some actors for special attention, if only juxtaposes the competing rationales offered
as a reference point for their narratives. by protagonists and antagonists as they press
We do not, therefore, intend to neatly divide for and resist change or when it deconstructs
the work that we have reviewed into two dis- explanations that naturalize why one rationale
tinct categories. Nonetheless, we can draw comes to be shared among actors, is more
some conclusions about broad patterns in the likely to invoke a process-centric narrative.
literature. For example, work that empha- In comparing the two narratives, we believe
sizes the properties of particular actors which that the greater potential, as far as future
distinguish them as institutional entrepre- research is concerned, lies with the process-
neurs appears more likely to produce centric narrative, for a number of reasons.
actor-centric narratives (although the recent First, the concept of institutional entrepreneur-
interest in critical realism in some senses ship is not a neutral one, and actor-centric
combines both narratives: a concern for accounts are more prone to naturalizing and
reflexivity draws attention to the actor; while celebrating certain actors as ‘exceptional’ in
an emphasis on context attends to process). some way, compared to process-centric ones.
The work exploring how the position of As Levy and Scully (2007: 986) remind us,
actors facilitates their becoming institutional entrepreneurship ‘conjures masculine images
entrepreneurs also tends to produce more of heroic individuals amassing wealth rather
INSTITUTIONAL ENTREPRENEURSHIP 213

than collective action toward more demo- to largely ignore the non-cooperative reac-
cratic, egalitarian goals’. Concepts and termi- tions of other members of the field. Similarly,
nology that conjure images of activism, process-oriented accounts make it
collective action and struggle may be more easier to examine the phenomenon of failed
appropriate; and these are to be found more instances of institutional entrepreneurship,
readily with research that attends explicitly something that is virtually absent from the
and seriously to process. Second, a focus on literature. Finally, another area for future
process and struggle encourages researchers research is on the unintended or negative con-
to explore the conceptual and temporal bound- sequences of institutional entrepreneurship.
aries of institutional entrepreneurship – where We conclude this chapter by acknowledg-
and when does it begin and end? Actor-centric ing there are dangers in the recent
narratives tend to treat this unproblematically, groundswell of interest in institutional
with researchers commonly picking up the entrepreneurship. While it responds to the
story of institutional change after a problem or recognized need for institutional theorists to
opportunity has been identified by the institu- move beyond the constraining effects of
tional entrepreneur, to whom responsibility institutions and to put agency back into
for change is then attributed retrospectively. institutional analyses of organizations, there
But what of the role of other actors, or the spe- is a risk that the pendulum will swing too far
cific historical discursive context in which in the other direction – celebrating heroic
they find themselves, in constructing a given ‘entrepreneurs’ and great ‘leaders’ who bring
situation as a problem? Is this not also part of about change intentionally, strategically and
the process of institutional change? And does creatively – and, in so doing, reify fields,
institutional entrepreneurship necessarily end actors and the process of change itself.
once new practices are initially adopted, Instead, we need research that interrogates
or does it include subsequent forms of ‘insti- critically and in more depth the phenomena
tutional work’ (Lawrence & Suddaby, that interest us, and we believe the way to do
2006) undertaken to ensure their ongoing so is to keep matters of power and process
reproduction? central to the study of institutional change.
Third, whereas the actor-centric narrative
does not preclude issues of power, it tends to
conceptualize it as something that some ACKNOWLEDGMENTS
actors possess, such as material resources
The authors gratefully acknowledge the financial
that can be mobilized or formal authority that
support of the Social Sciences and Humanities
can be exercised. The process-centric narra- Research Council of Canada and the Australian
tive, on the other hand, can more readily Research Council (Discovery funding scheme, project
incorporate post-structuralist notions of number DP 0771639).
power as being inextricably bound up with
knowledge and language, and as capturing all
actors in a field. It thus encourages more fun- NOTE
damental and critical interrogations of social
1 As can be seen from this heterogeneous list, the
reality and lends itself to more reflexivity on
notion of resource mobilization can include material,
the part of researchers. In this way, it offers a symbolic and human/organizational resources.
number of opportunities for future research. However, because of important differences among
One area that would prove particularly fruit- them, particularly how they relate to power,
ful for future research is the study of we address them separately in terms of three
themes – resources, rationales, and relations. Broadly
resistance to institutional entrepreneurship,
speaking, these themes correspond to the three
about which we know relatively little given interlaced dimensions of field structure – material,
the tendency, especially of the large number discursive, and organizational – proposed by Levy
of studies presenting actor-centric accounts, and Scully (2007).
214 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

REFERENCES legitimating accounts and the social con-


struction of identity. Organization Science,
Aldrich, H. & M. Fiol, M. 1994. Fools rush in? 13(5): 475–496.
The institutional context of industry creation. Czarniawska, B. & Joerges, B. 1996. Travel of
Academy of Management Review, 19: ideas. In B. Czarniawska and G. Sevón (eds.),
645–670. Translating Organizational Change: 13–48.
Archer, M. 2003. Structure, Agency and the Berlin: De Gruyter.
Internal Conversation. Cambridge: Cambridge Déjean, F., Gond, J.P. & Leca, B. 2004.
University Press. Measuring the unmeasured: An institutional
Battilana, J. 2006. Agency and institutions: The entrepreneur strategy in an emerging indus-
enabling role of individuals’ social position. try. Human Relations, 57(6): 741–764.
Organization, 13(5): 653–676. Demil, B. & Bensédrine, J. 2005. Processes of
Beckert, J. 1999. Agency, entrepreneurs, and legitimization and pressure toward regula-
institutional change. The roles of strategic tion. International Studies of Management
choice and institutionalized practices in and Organization, 35(2): 56–77.
organizations. Organization Studies, 20(5): Dew, N. 2006. Institutional entrepreneurship:
777–799. A Coasian perspective. International Journal
Berger, P.L. & Luckmann, T. 1967. The Social of Entrepreneurship and Innovation, 7(1):
Construction of Reality: A Treatise on the 13–12.
Sociology of Knowledge. Garden City, NY: DiMaggio, P. 1988. Interest and agency in insti-
Anchor Books. tutional theory. In Institutional Patterns and
Bourdieu, P. 1990. The Logic of Practice Culture, L. Zucker (ed.), Cambridge, MA:
(R. Nice, trans.), Cambridge: Polity. Ballinger Publishing Company: 3–2.
Bourdieu, P. 1986. The forms of capital. In J. G. DiMaggio, P.J. & Powell, W.W. 1983. The iron
Richardson (ed.), Handbook of Theory and cage revisited: Institutional isomorphism and
Research for the Sociology of Education: collective rationality in organizational fields.
241–258. New York: Greenwood Press. American Sociological Review, 48: 147–161.
Bourdieu, P. & Wacquant, L.J.D. 1992. An Dorado, S. 2005. Institutional entrepreneur-
Invitation to Reflexive Sociology. Chicago: ship, partaking, and convening. Organization
University of Chicago Press. Studies, 26(3): 385–314.
Boxenbaum, E. & Battilana, J. November 2005. Durand, R. & McGuire, J. 2005. Legitimating
Importation as innovation: Transposing man- agencies in the face of selection: The case
agerial practices across fields, Strategic of AACSB. Organization Studies, 26(2):
Organization, 3(4): 355–383. 165–196.
Clemens, E.S. & Cook, J.M. 1999. Politics and Edelman, L.B. & Suchman, M.C. 1997. The
institutionalism: Explaining durability and legal environment of organizations. Annual
change. Annual Review of Sociology, 25(1): Review of Sociology, 23: 479–515.
441. Everett, J. 2002. Organizational research and the
Carson, R. 1962. Silent Spring. New York: praxeology of Pierre Bourdieu. Organizational
Houghton Mifflin. Research Methods, 5(1): 56–0.
Child, J. Lu, Y. & Tsai, T. 2007. Terence Tsai insti- Fligstein, N. 1991. The structural transfor-
tutional entrepreneurship in building an mation of American industry: An institutional
environmental protection system for the account of the causes of diversification in the
People’s Republic of China. Organization largest firms, 1919–979. In The New
Studies, 28(07): 1013–1034. Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis,
Coase, R. 1937. The nature of the firm. W.W. Powell and P. DiMaggio (eds.). Chicago
Economica, 16(4): 386–405. and London: University of Chicago Press:
Colomy, P. 1998. Neofunctionalism and neoin- 311–336.
stitutionalism: Human agency and interest in Fligstein, N. 1997. Social skill and institutional
institutional change. Sociological Forum, theory. American Behavioral Scientist, 40:
13(2): 265–300. 397–405.
Creed, W.E.D. Scully, M.A. & Austin, J.A. 2002. Fligstein, N. 2001a. Institutional entrepreneurs
Clothes make the person? The tailoring of and cultural frames: The case of the
INSTITUTIONAL ENTREPRENEURSHIP 215

European Union’s single market program. Hardy, C. & Philips, N. 1999. No joking matter:
European Societies, 3(3):261–287. Discursive struggle in the Canadian refugee
Fligstein, N. 2001b. Social skill and the theory system. Organization Studies, 20(1): 1–4.
of fields. Sociological Theory, 19(2): 105–125. Hargadon, A. & Douglas, Y. 2001. When inno-
Fligstein, N. & Mara-Drita, I. 1996. How to vations meet institutions: Edison and the
make a market: Reflections on the attempt design of the electric light. Administrative
to create a single market in the European Science Quarterly, 46: 476–501.
Union. American Journal of Sociology, Hensman, M. 2003. Social movement organi-
102(1): 1–3. zations: A metaphor for strategic actors in
Friedland, R. & Alford, R.R. 1991. Bringing soci- institutional field. Organization Studies,
ety back in: symbols, practices, and institu- 24(3): 355–81.
tional contradictions. In W.W. Powell and P.J. Hirsch, P.M. & Lounsbury, M. 1997. Ending
DiMaggio (eds.), The New Institutionalism in the family quarrel: Toward a reconciliation
Organizational Analysis. Chicago: University of ‘old’ and ‘new’ institutionalism. The
of Chicago Press: 2320–2323 American Behavioural Scientist, 40(4):
Garud, R. Hardy, C. & Maguire, S. 2007. 406–418.
Institutional entrepreneurship as embedded Hoffman, A.J. 1999. Institutional evolution and
agency: An introduction to the special issue. change: Environmentalism and the U.S.
Organization Studies, 28(7): 957–969. chemical industry. Academy of Management
Garud, R. Jain, S. & Kumaraswamy, A. 2002. Journal, 42: 351–371.
Institutional entrepreneurship in the sponsor- Holm, P. 1995. The dynamics of institutionalisa-
ship of common technological standards: The tion: Transformation processes in Norwegian
case of Sun Microsystems and Java. Academy fisheries. Administrative Science Quarterly,
of Management Journal, 45: 196–114. 40: 398–322.
George, E., Chattopadhyay, P., Sitkin, S.B. & Khan, F., Munir, K. & Willmott, H. 2007. A dark
Barden, J. 2006. Cognitive underpinning of side of institutional entrepreneurship: Soccer
institutional persistence and change: A fram- balls, child labor and postcolonial impover-
ing perspective. Academy of Management ishment. Organization Studies, 28(07):
Review, 31(2): 347–385. 1055–1077.
Grant, D. & Hardy, C. 2004. Struggles with Kraatz, M.S. & Moore, J.H. 2002. Executive
organizational discourse. Organization migration and institutional change. Academy
Studies, 25(1): 5–4. of Management Journal, 45(1): 120–143.
Greenwood, R. & Hinings, G.R. 1996. Under- Lawrence, T. 1999. Institutional strategy.
standing radical organizational change: Journal of Management, 25: 161–188.
Bringing together the old and the new Lawrence, T. & Phillips, N. 2004. From Moby
institutionalism. Academy of Management Dick to Free Willy: Macro-cultural discourse
Review, 21: 1022–1054. and institutional entrepreneurship in emerg-
Greenwood, R. & Suddaby, R. 2006. Institutional ing institutional fields. Organization, 11(5):
Entrepreneurship in mature fields: The big five 689–711.
accounting firms. Academy of Management Lawrence, T., Hardy, C. & Phillips, N. 2002.
Journal, 49(1): 27–28. Institutional effects of interorganizational
Greenwood, R., Suddaby, R. & Hinings, C.R. collaboration: The emergence of proto-
2002. Theorizing change: The role of profes- institutions. Academy of Management
sional associations in the transformations Journal, 45(1): 281–290.
of institutionalized fields. Academy of Lawrence, T. & Suddaby, R. 2006. Institutions
Management Journal, 45(1): 58–60. and institutional work. In S.R. Clegg,
Greenwood, R., Suddaby, R. & Hinings, C.R. C. Hardy, T.B. Lawrence & W.R. Nord (eds.),
2002. The role of professional associations Handbook of Organization Studies, 215–54.
in institutional change. Academy of London: Sage.
Management Journal, 45: 58–60. Leblebic, H., Salancik, G. Copay, A. & King, T.
Hardy, C. 1985. The nature of unobtrusive 1991. Institutional change and the transfor-
power. Journal of Management Studies, mation of interorganizational fields: An
22(4): 384–99. organizational history of the U.S. radio
216 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

broadcasting industry. Administrative Meyer, R.E. 2006. Visiting relatives: Current


Science Quarterly, 36(3): 333–363. developments in the new sociology of
Leca, B. & Naccache, P. 2006. A critical realist knowledge. Organization, 13(5): 725–738.
approach to institutional entrepreneurship. Munir, K.A. 2005. The social construction of
Organization, 13(5): 627–651. events: A study of institutional change in the
Lee, K. & Pennings, J.M. 2002. Mimicry and the photographic field. Organization Studies,
market: Adoption of a new organizational 26(1): 93–112.
form. Academy of Management Journal, Munir, K.A. & Phillips, N. 2005. The birth of the
45(1): 144–162. ‘Kodak moment’: Institutional entrepreneur-
Levy, D. & Scully, M. 2007. The Institutional ship and the adoption of new technologies.
Entrepreneur as Modern Prince: The Organization Studies, 26(11): 1665–1687.
Strategic Face of Power in Contested Fields. Mutch, A. 2007. Reflexivity and the institu-
Organization Studies, 28(07): 971–991. tional entrepreneur: A historical exploration.
Lounsbury, M. 2002. Institutional transforma- Organization Studies, 28(07): 1123–1140.
tion and status mobility: The professionaliza- Mutch, A., Delbridge, R. & Ventresca, M. 2006.
tion of the field of finance. Academy of Situating organizational action: The rela-
Management Journal, 45(1): 255–266. tional sociology of organizations.
Lounsbury, M. & Crumley, L.T. 2007. New prac- Organization, 13(5): 607–625.
tice creation: An institutional perspective on North, D.C. 1990. Institutions, Institutional
innovation. Organization Studies, 28(07): Change and Economic Performance.
993–1012. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Lounsbury, M. & Glynn, M.A. 2001. Cultural Oakes, L.S., Townley, B. & Cooper, D.J. 1998.
entrepreneurship: Stories, legitimacy and Business planning as pedagogy: Language
the acquisition of resources. Strategic and control in a changing institutional field.
Management Journal, 22: 545–564. Administrative Science Quarterly, 43:
Lounsbury, M., Ventresca, M. & Hirsch, P.M. 257–292.
2003. Social movements, field frames and Perkmann, M. & Spicer, A. 2007. Healing the
industry emergence: A cultural–political per- scars of history: Projects, skills and field
spective on US recycling. Social Economic strategies in institutional entrepreneurship.
Review, 1:71–104. Organization Studies, 28(07): 1101–1122.
Lukes, S. 1974. Power: A Radical View. Pfeffer, J. & Salancik, G. 1978. The External
London: Macmillan. Control of Organizations. New York: Harper
Maguire, S. 2007 Institutional entrepreneur- and Row.
ship. In S. Clegg, and J.R Bailey, (eds.), Pettigrew, A.M. 1979. On studying organiza-
International Encyclopedia of Organization tional cultures. Administrative Science
Studies, Volume 2: 674–678. London, UK: Quarterly, 24: 57–81.
Sage. Phillips, N. & Hardy, C. 2002. Understanding
Maguire, S. & Hardy, C. 2006. The emergence Discourse Analysis, Thousand Oaks, CA:
of new global institutions: A discursive per- Sage.
spective. Organization Studies, 27(1): 7–9. Phillips, N., Lawrence, T. & Hardy, C. 2004.
Maguire, S., Hardy, C. & Lawrence, T. 2004. Discourse and institutions. Academy of
Institutional entrepreneurship in emerging Management Review, 29/4: 1–18.
fields: HIV/AIDS treatment advocacy in Powell. W.W. & DiMaggio, P.J. 1991. The New
Canada. Academy of Management Journal, Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis.
47(5): 657–679. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.
Maguire, S., Phillips, N., & Hardy, C. 2001, When Porac, J.F. & Thomas, H. 1990. Taxonomic
‘silence = death’, keep talking: Trust, control mental models in competitor definition.
and the discursive construction of identity in Academy of Management Review, 15:
the Canadian HIV/AIDS treatment domain. 224–240.
Organization Studies, 22(2): 285–312. Rao, H. 1998. Caveat emptor: The construction
Meyer, A.D. 1982. Adapting to environmental of nonprofit consumer watchdog organiza-
jolts. Administrative Science Quarterly, 27(4): tions. American Journal of Sociology, 103:
515–537. 912–961.
INSTITUTIONAL ENTREPRENEURSHIP 217

Rao, H. 2002. Tests tell: Institutional activists, Thornton, P.H. 2002. The rise of the corpora-
constitutive legitimacy and consumer accept- tion in a craft industry: Conflict and con-
ance in the American automobile industry, formity in institutional logics. Academy of
1895–1912. Advances in Strategic Management Journal, 45(1): 81–101.
Management the New Institutionalism Townley, B. 2002. The role of competing
in Strategic Management, 19: 307–335. rationalities in institutional change. Academy
Rao, H., Monin, P. & Durand, R. 2003. of Management Journal, 45(1): 163–179.
Institutional change in Toque Ville: Nouvelle Turner, R. & Killion, L. 1987. Collective
cuisine as an identity movement in French Behaviour, 3rd edn. Englewood Cliffs, NJ:
gastronomy. American Journal of Sociology, Prentice-Hall.
108: 795–843. Tushman, M. & Anderson, P. 1986.
Rao, H., Morrill, C. & Zald, M. 2000. Power plays: Technological discontinuities and organiza-
How social movements and collective action tional environments. Administrative Science
create new organizational forms. Research in Quarterly, 31: 439–465.
Organizational Behavior, 22: 237–281. Wetherell, M. 2001. Debates in discourse
Russo, M.V. 2001. Institutions, exchange rela- research. In M. Wetherell, S. Taylor & S.J.
tions, and the emergence of new fields: Yates (eds.), Discourse Theory and Practice:
Regulatory policies and independent power A Reader: 380–399. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.
production in America, 1978–1992. Wijen, F. and Ansari, S. 2007. Overcoming inac-
Administrative Science Quarterly, 46(1): tion through collective institutional entrepre-
57–86. neurship: Insights from regime theory.
Scott, R. 1995. Institutions and Organizations. Organization Studies, 28(07): 1079–1100.
Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage. Williamson, O. 1985. The Economic Institutions
Seo, M. & Creed, D. 2002. Institutional of Capitalism. New York: Free Press.
contradictions, praxis and institutional Zilber, T.B. 2002. Institutionalization as an inter-
change: A dialectic perspective. Academy play between actions, meanings and actors:
of Management Review, 27: 222–248. The case of a rape crisis center in Israel.
Sewell, W.H. Jr. 1992. A theory of structure: Academy of Management Journal, 45(1):
Duality, agency and transformation. 234–254.
American Journal of Sociology, 98: 1–29. Zilber, T.B. 2006. The work of the symbolic in
Sherer, P.D. & Lee, K. 2002. Institutional institutional processes: Translations of
change in large law firms: A resource rational myths in Israeli hi-tech. Academy
dependency and institutional perspective. Management Journal, 49(2): 281–303.
Academy of Management Journal, 45: Zilber, T.B. 2007. Stories and the discursive
102–119. dynamics of institutional entrepreneurship:
Suddaby, R. & Greenwood, R. 2005. Rhetorical The case of Israeli high-tech after the
strategies of legitimacy. Administrative bubble. Organization Studies, 28(07):
Science Quarterly, 50(1): 35–68. 1035–1054.
8
Circulating Ideas: Imitation,
Translation and Editing
Kerstin Sahlin and Linda Wedlin

Early institutional theoretical development When reading this paragraph 30 years


grew out of the observations that formal after it was published it is striking to note
organizational structures become increas- that not only does this single paragraph
ingly complex as new organizations emerge encapsulate the motives and problems behind
and as existing organizations incorporate the entire theoretical development of organi-
new practices and procedures. Such elabo- zational institutionalism, but it also largely
rated formal organizational structures, Meyer portrays the development of this research tra-
and Rowan (1977) convincingly showed, dition over the three decades. Initially, the
cannot be understood as devices for main focus was on individual organizations
enhanced coordination and control, but and how their formal structures became at
reflect societal institutions, or rational myths. the same time increasingly complex and
These basic notions were summarized in one increasingly similar as they incorporated
paragraph of the seminal paper of 1977: institutional elements from their environ-
ments. Subsequently, the research interest of
The growth of rationalized institutional structures many scholars turned to wondering about
in society makes formal organizations more
common and more elaborate. Such institutions are how such institutional elements came to be
myths which make formal organizations both ‘littered around the social landscape.’ Thus
easier to create and more necessary. After all, the they began to study the ‘supply side’ of
building blocks for organizations come to be lit- myths: how institutional elements came to be
tered around the social landscape; it takes only a produced and diffused. More recently several
little entrepreneurial energy to assemble them into
a structure. And because these building blocks are studies have significantly developed our
considered proper, adequate, rational, and neces- knowledge of how such myths become ‘con-
sary, organizations must incorporate them to avoid sidered proper, adequate, rational, and neces-
illegitimacy. Thus the myths built into rationalized sary’ – thus how it becomes essential that
institutional elements create the necessity, the organizations incorporate them in order to
opportunity, and the impulse to organize ration-
ally, over and above pressures in this direction cre-
avoid being considered ‘illegitimate.’
ated by the need to manage proximate relational In particular, we find such a progress of
networks. (345) research when we follow those studies that
CIRCULATING IDEAS: IMITATION, TRANSLATION AND EDITING 219

have focused especially on the circulating Scandinavian research on circulating ideas,


ideas that become rational myths. This and relates them to main issues and debates
research developed early in Scandinavia (see in organizational institutionalism.
e.g., Brunsson 1989; Brunsson and Olsen We begin by reviewing research focusing
1993; Czarniawska and Sevón 1996a). The mainly on the adopting organization – and on
Scandinavian scholars were early inspired by the processes through which individual
and learned from John Meyer’s studies, organizations adopt ideas. Such research
thoughts and theories, but clearly mixed and reveals how and why ideas are attended to,
translated them together with other research adopted and incorporated in organizations.
traditions that had been influential in Imitation has been shown to be one main
Scandinavia for some time, or those that mechanism through which organizations
were emerging in Europe at the time. The become exposed to and pick up ideas.
Scandinavian studies built on studies of deci- Following on such conclusions, studies have
sion-making under ambiguity as developed paid special attention to who is imitating
by James March and his colleagues, on social whom and how, making use of the concepts
construction and institutionalization as of identity and fields. A number of studies
developed by Berger and Luckmann and have depicted adopting organizations as fash-
related European traditions and on studies in ion followers, emphasizing the social and
science and technology as developed by, temporal aspects of imitation and adoption.
among others, Latour, Callon, and Knorr- As important as understanding the drivers
Cetina. (See Czarniawska, Chapter 32 in this for adopting new ideas is seeing why and
volume, for an elaborated history on how ideas come to be ‘littered around the
Scandinavian institutionalism.) Moreover, social landscape,’ hence a second line of
institutional theories were incorporated into a research has focused on the construction,
tradition that was based primarily on qualita- supply and transfer of ideas. Ideas do
tive studies with a long tradition of case stud- not diffuse in a vacuum but are actively
ies and of close studies of individual transferred and translated in a context of
decision-making processes, organizational other ideas, actors, traditions and institutions.
change processes and reforms. In this way, This brings actors and interests into the
the Scandinavian research primarily came to analysis. A common theme of these
highlight the dynamic aspects of circulating studies is that ideas do not remain unchanged
ideas; how and why ideas become wide- as they flow but are subject to transla-
spread, how they are translated as they flow tion. To imitate, then, is not just to copy, but
and with what organizational consequences. also to change and to innovate. As diffused
Even if the close ties between the ideas are translated throughout their
Scandinavian and American institutional circulation, and as they evolve differently in
scholars have continued to develop, as is evi- different settings, they may not only
dent in the edited volumes with contributions lead to homogenization but also to variation
from Scandinavian and North American and stratification. The concept of editing
scholars (Scott and Christensen 1995; has served to describe and explain
Czarniawska and Sevón 1996a, 2005; Sahlin- how such translation proceeds – thus further
Andersson and Engwall 2002; Djelic and focusing on the dynamics of circulating
Sahlin-Andersson 2006a), ‘Scandinavian ideas.
institutionalism’ (Czarniawska and Sevón Even if many studies of circulating ideas
1996b) has largely developed along its own have paid attention to how ideas flow and
path having only a limited impact on the how they are edited as they circulate, empha-
North American studies. Focusing specifi- sis in earlier research was on the travel routes
cally on this line of research, this chapter and means rather than on the content of the
presents main themes and trajectories of the ideas as such (Meyer 1996: 250). Later, more
220 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

emphasis was placed on the content and form HOW AND WHY DO ORGANIZATIONS
of the ideas that were spread. As already ADOPT IDEAS?
mentioned, ideas change as they flow. Ideas
in the form of models and practices can be Many scholars of organizations noticed in
adapted, modified or reshaped, but ideas can the 1980s and 1990s that organizations were
also take on new forms and meanings as they picking up popular ideas and seeking to
flow within and between contexts. Many incorporate them into their formal structures.
ideas have been found to form the foundation Those ideas that were most clearly observed
of and inspiration for new regulations – to diffuse in such a way were often what
in the form of standards, guidelines, appeared to be fashionable management
assessing criteria and templates. This has ideas. These were techniques and models for
triggered a stream of research addressing better management, often introduced by con-
issues on how soft regulation and governance sultants or other proponents of improved
of the kind just mentioned emerges, and management, some of them specifically
with what results. It has also been accompa- labeled with acronyms that quickly become
nied by an increased interest in the part of management vocabulary. These waves
consequences that widely diffused ideas included total quality management (TQM),
bring. Meyer and Rowan primarily business process reengineering (BPR),
emphasized the ceremonial adoption of management by objectives (MBO), supply
rationalized myths and the decoupling of chain management (SPC), service manage-
such myths from ongoing activities of organ- ment, new public management (NPM),
izations. Subsequent research has pointed to project management, integrated management
a broader scope of consequences. Widely control, intercultural management, knowl-
circulated ideas have proved to result in or edge management and others. In the
contribute to changes in individual early 2000s popular waves of ideas have
organizations’ identities, in field transforma- included various forms of evaluations,
tions and in more general institutional assessments and rankings, certifications and
changes. accreditation procedures and evidence-based
Each of these research themes is discussed guidelines. Together with those models
in the following sections. Two important con- organizations came to incorporate a new –
clusions clearly run through this research tra- and what was seen to be more modern –
dition, and are thus highlighted throughout terminology.
the chapter. First, while one main question Much, but far from all, of the early work in
that initiated the research of organizational this tradition was performed in Scandinavia,
institutionalists was that of homogenization – largely in studies of public sector organiza-
the program has increasingly become aware tional reforms. Many of these were case stud-
of the important consequences, in terms of ies of individual organizational reforms and
variation and stratification, that follow dif- thus the focus was on how individual organi-
fused ideas. Second, while Meyer and Rowan zations picked up, adopted and incorporated
clearly emphasized the decoupling of new ideas or organizational elements. The
ceremonially adopted ideas from organiza- introduction of new management principles
tional practices, research has, over time, was clearly evident in this sector when
clearly shown the consequential effects of references to private sector management
such adopted ideas on formal structures as were becoming increasingly common, but
well as on day-to-day organizational the imported ideas at the time still stood out
practices. Thus circulating ideas are not only as very different from the administrative
ceremonially adopted but have been shown tradition of the public sector. Striking exam-
to result in both organizational and institu- ples were the introduction of the service and
tional change. customer concepts in the public sector
CIRCULATING IDEAS: IMITATION, TRANSLATION AND EDITING 221

(see, e.g., Sahlin-Andersson 1996; Forssell to spread more widely than less effective
and Jansson 1996). The new terminology and ones. This reasoning may lead to a call for
the new techniques were introduced into the more historical studies to satisfy the need to
public sector organizations together with a go back to search for the original source.
widespread questioning of the previous ways Once we start analyzing and comparing
of working. Furthermore, the new techniques ideas, however, it is difficult to distinguish
did not always work as planned and were in any intrinsic success criteria for ideas that
many cases found to be decoupled from the will ‘make it.’ Hence, it is often pointless – if
daily operations (Brunsson 1989, 2006; not downright impossible – to find an origin
Brunsson and Olsen 1993). (Bourdieu 1977). So it appears to be not so
These observations were clearly in line much a case of ideas flowing widely because
with those proposed by both Meyer and they are powerful, but rather of ideas
Rowan and DiMaggio and Powell. Two kinds becoming powerful as they circulate. For
of observations, however, even if they did not example, some ideas seem to become popu-
stand in opposition to the assumptions lar, not primarily because of their properties
and propositions of Meyer and Rowan and but because of who transports and supports
DiMaggio and Powell, called for an extended them and how they are packaged, formulated
framework and additional conceptual tools. and timed (Czarniawska and Joerges 1996;
These reactions were elaborated in the edited Røvik 1998). Ideas become legitimate, popu-
volume Translating Organisational Change lar and even taken for granted as being
(Czarniawska and Sevón 1996a). First, even effective and indispensable as a result of
if instances of decoupling repeatedly having been adopted by certain actors in
occurred, in many instances the introduced the field (Tolbert and Zucker 1983;
language and models did have clear conse- Westphal, Gulati, and Shortell 1997). In this
quences in terms of how the organizations way, managerial fads and fashions evolve,
and practices came to be identified, assessed some ideas becoming popular for a time then
and presented. Diffused ideas could add to or disappearing again or becoming institution-
result in changes to organizational identities alized (Abrahamson 1991, 1996; Collins
and to what appeared as normal, desirable 2000). Again, historical and contextual
and possible – thus circulated ideas appeared studies are called for, but not solely with the
to trigger institutional change (Sahlin- aim of looking for the original source of dif-
Andersson 1996; Forssell and Jansson 1996; fused ideas; close studies of the circulation of
Brunsson and Sahlin-Andersson 2000; ideas do, in fact, show why some turn out to
Blomgren 2003). be so attractive and powerful. Furthermore,
The second, and more detailed set of the observations showed that such circulating
observations, point out that the framework processes need to be understood in social
that had been developed around the concept rather than physical terms. What was spread-
of diffusion appeared too static and mechan- ing were not ready-made and unchangeable
ical in relation to the observations made. The particles or goods, but ideas subject to repeti-
concept of diffusion was easily associated tive translation (see further Czarniawska and
with a physical process, as though what was Sevón 1996a; 2005; Czarniawska and Joerges
spreading was a physical entity originating 1996; Czarniawska, Chapter 32, this volume).
from one source and (while gaining its power The observations were far from new in
to spread from this source) then becoming empirical terms. DiMaggio and Powell did
more diffuse and diffused. This view has led emphasize that models were not imported
researchers and practitioners to seek best whole cloth, and Westney’s work (1987)
practices to identify ‘the original’ source of on the imitation and innovation that formed
an idea. The perspective is an instrumental the modern Japanese society clearly pointed
one – good and powerful ideas are assumed to the way in which imitated models were
222 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

transformed as they were transferred from interests, resources, identities and abilities,
one setting to another, and her analysis was but at the same time the analysis acknowl-
clearly one of institutional change. The imi- edges that these interests, resources,
tated models were not just ceremonially identities and abilities are neither stable nor
adopted, but formed the basis for building the intrinsic to individuals or organizations.
modern Japanese society. Individuals and organizations develop their
In theoretical terms, however, the interests, identities, resources and abilities in
Scandinavian institutionalism, as Czarniawska their social context, and partly from the ideas
and Sevón (1996: 3) call it, formed a concep- they pick up and in relation to those they
tual framework that put these dynamics at the imitate. Thus actorhood as such needs to be
center and thus formed a more constructivist understood as a process of social construc-
foundation than the one developed in the US. tion (Brunsson and Sahlin-Andersson 2000).
In addition, the European studies were more Those individuals and organizations that
micro and qualitative than the mainstream pick up ideas have been depicted not only as
US ones. acting according to a logic of appropriate-
ness but more specifically as fashion follow-
ers. The word ‘fashion’ here points to the
temporal and social logics of processes of
Appropriateness and fashion
adoption. In several early studies fashion was
Meyer and Rowan and DiMaggio and Powell sometimes coupled with fads; both of these
emphasized that the main motive for incorpo- were associated with the idea that certain
rating rationalized myths and for mapping desires and models came in waves.
those organizations that were seen as central Abrahamson (1996) illustrated the bell-
and successful was to gain or maintain legiti- shaped curve of the spread of popular ideas
macy. The Scandinavian scholars combined such as quality circles, stressing the wave-
this insight with more of a micro-perspective, like movement through which ideas flow
as they studied the processes of adoption and among organizations and between contexts.
sought to make sense of how individuals and He suggests that organizations adopt mana-
organizations acted in relation to the intro- gerial practices and models, such as TQM, to
duced models. Organizations and individuals conform to general norms of rationality and
acted, they argued, according to a logic of progress.
appropriateness, as proposed by March Czarniawska and Sevón (2005) portray
(1981). When initiating changes and when fashion as the ‘steering wheel’ of translation
attending to and adopting new ideas, they rea- and the flow of ideas. Fashion guides imita-
soned as follows: ‘Who am I?,’ What situation tion and the attention of actors to specific
is this?’ and ‘What does a person such as I, or ideas, models and practices, and fashion
an organization such as this, do in a situation identifies but also creates what is appropriate
such as this?’ Thus, individuals and organiza- and desirable at a given time and place. This
tions were depicted as clearly embedded in an leads organizations to adopt, but also to
environment that provided them with expec- translate, these ideas, thus changing both
tations, identities and rules for action. what is translated and those who translate.
In an epilogue to the volume edited by Authors of management fashions stress the
Czarniawska and Sevón (1996a), Meyer inherently contradictory nature of fashion
commented upon what distinguished this following: the adoption of fashionable prac-
‘European flavored’ research from the main tices and ideas is driven by both the need for
US tradition. He used the term ‘soft actor’ to differentiation and the need for conformity
clarify how these European writers saw with expectations and the practices of others.
actors as clearly embedded in cultural This dynamic between differentiation and
material. A soft actor, thus, is an actor with imitation provides the dynamic and the driving
CIRCULATING IDEAS: IMITATION, TRANSLATION AND EDITING 223

force for idea diffusion (Røvik 1996). identifications and opens new avenues for
Fashion followers act differently in order to comparison and for creating new identities.
act in the same way. While building on the In this way fashions and trends largely form
recognition of Blumer (1969) that fashion is through processes of imitation.
a competition mechanism, the institutional When one views the circulation of ideas
writers suggest that following fashion is as processes of imitation, and as involving
simultaneously an act of conformism and dynamics of identity formation, it becomes
creativity (Czarniawska and Joerges 1996: clear that some organizations tend to be
34–35) and that following fashion means more prone to imitate – and more receptive
both working within, thus reproducing, to widely circulated ideas – than others.
and altering the existing institutional Moreover, some organizations and ideas are
order. Thus, fashion incorporates both imitated more than others. While DiMaggio
change and tradition (Czarniawska 2005; and Powell associated the mechanism
Røvik 1996). of mimesis to uncertainty, the close studies
The concepts of appropriateness and fash- of individual organizational reforms –
ion both point to the social processes of idea and imitation – suggest identification
circulation. Ideas are circulated as individu- rather than uncertainty to be the main
als are exposed to each other and as they explanatory concept. Brunsson and Sahlin-
compare themselves with and view them- Andersson (2000) saw a common pattern
selves in relation to others. They define in those management ideas that were
which problems require local solutions and triggering organizational reforms in the
shape plans about what to accomplish (this public sector. They suggested, first, that the
fundamental insight has, interestingly organizational elements that were adopted
enough, become packaged as its own by public sector units tended to come in
management concept – the benchmark – packages or strings rather than individually.
with a whole set of management techniques They suggested further that those ideas were
associated with it). Imitation is a basic based on a common identity program –
mechanism, then, through which ideas together they reconstructed adopting units
circulate. to become more clearly identified with
those associated primarily with the adopted
new ideas. This again paved the way for
further imitation and for further identity
Imitation and identification
transformation.
Imitation is a basic social mechanism tying A main motivation for imitation is to
people together (Tarde 1902/1969). Actors become similar to others, and, even more, to
tend to imitate those they want to resemble become similar to the most prestigious, lead-
(Sevón 1996). As certain models, actors or ing organizations (Haveman 1993). Imitation
practices become widely known, they shape may also, however, be motivated by a desire
the wishes, ideals and desires of others and to distinguish oneself from others, to be
thus provide the impetus for further imita- different. As explained by Czarniawska
tion. Thus, perceived identity shapes imita- (2005), building on Tarde (1890/1962), the
tion: one imitates those one relates to and processes of identity formation and of imita-
those with whom one identifies. The process tion both involve a process of alterity
of imitation involves both self-identification construction – the formation of perceptions
and recognition of what one would like to of being different. As important as the ques-
become (Sahlin-Andersson 1996; Sevón tion: ‘Who am I like?’ is the question: ‘How
1996). The opposite is also true, however, in am I different?’ Both these motives are
that imitation shapes identity. Imitation con- grounded in identity. In order to understand
structs new relationships, references, and and explain, then, who is imitating whom
224 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

and why, we should also study who and what striving for coherence or conformity.
organizations identify with. The identity of a Moreover, peripheral actors challenge
subject – a person or an organization – is dominant understandings, which they try to
defined in relation to others; it is derived modify and/or displace. Central actors have a
from its reference to and relationship with tendency to protect and defend the status
others. quo. They may envision bending and
The concept of organizational fields has adapting dominant understandings some-
been used to explore how organizations iden- what, if only to anchor and stabilize them
tify themselves and thus what they seek to further. This dynamic is behind active
imitate. Groups of organizations whose processes of imitation.
activities are defined in similar ways have
been conceived of as shaping organizational
fields. This notion has of course been a Translation and editing
core concept in organizational institutional-
ism. There are many variants of such field Imitation is an active process, and can be dis-
models, building on various theories and tinguished from diffusion insofar as the latter
taking inspiration from a range of disci- is defined as a phenomenon whereby a cer-
plines. Most commonly references are tain model, idea or practice, once created,
made to DiMaggio and Powell (1983). spreads next to a number of passive recipi-
Elsewhere, we have argued for the impor- ents or trend followers. In contrast, imitation
tance of looking beyond this concept to has been conceptualized as a performative
trace the many frameworks and theoretical process (Sevón 1996). This points to the
traditions that the field concept refers to and importance of understanding how ideas are
builds on (Djelic and Sahlin-Andersson translated, shaped and changed through
2006b; Hedmo, Sahlin-Andersson and processes of imitation. The Scandinavian
Wedlin 2005). scholars emphasized the social aspects
When using the field concept to under- of idea circulation and thus found that
stand motivations for and processes of imita- the predominant conceptual framework
tion, we especially build on Bourdieu’s with physical connotations tended to lead
notion of fields. Bourdieu (1977, 1984) researchers’ attention in unwanted directions.
argued that fields were formed and held Czarniawska and Sevón wrote:
together by the common belief in and
Diffusion suggests a physical process, subject to
upholding of the importance of certain activ- laws of physics, and thus the explanation of phe-
ities. In this sense fields form reference sys- nomena denoted by this term provokes a further
tems, shaping the participants’ attention train of physical metaphors, like ‘saturation’ or
structures and identities – what they view as ‘resistance.’ Latour (1986) proposes to replace it
important issues (cf. March and Olsen 1995). with translation calling attention to the richness of
meanings associated with this term, of which only
The field may also be described as a system some are evoked in everyday life .... It is this rich-
of relations – relations that have evolved ness of meaning, evoking associations with both
among the actors who define their activities movement and transformation, embracing both
as being concerned with similar issues. In the linguistic and material objects, that induced Latour
field a structure of central and peripheral and Callon, and the contributors of this volume
after them, to borrow the notion of translation
positions evolves. Dominating organizations from a contemporary French philosopher, Michel
form reference points and models for the Serres. (1996: 6–7)
rest of the organizations in the same field.
Coherent patterns of action and meaning It should be stressed that ‘translation’ here
thus develop, even without any single is not used as a linguistic term, but points
actor or group of actors intentionally both to movement and transformation. With
CIRCULATING IDEAS: IMITATION, TRANSLATION AND EDITING 225

this conceptual framework at hand these At first glance, editing processes might
authors could follow where and how manage- seem to be creative and open-ended.
ment ideas traveled. As management ideas However, the processes of translation were
were circulating they were translated into rather characterized by social control, con-
objects such as books, models and formism and traditionalism – thus following
presentations (see Czarniawska and Joerges rule-like patterns. Thus editing rules restrict
1996; Czarniawska and Sevón 2005) and and direct the translation – or editing – in each
these translations were done in the various phase of circulation. The term ‘rule’ did not
contexts and by the many actors involved in imply that there were written or explicit
circulating ideas. What is being transferred instructions for the telling and retelling of sto-
from one setting to another is not an idea or a ries and ideas; neither did it imply that these
practice as such, but rather accounts and mate- translations followed clear intentions and
rializations of a certain idea or practice. Such established techniques among the editors.
accounts undergo translation as they spread, Although there are no explicit rules to follow,
resulting in local versions of models and ideas edited stories reveal how these translations
in different local contexts (Czarniawska and were formed by the institutional setting in
Joerges 1996). Both those seeking to be imi- which they were performed. Thus they reveal
tated and those imitating translate ideas and rules that have been followed.
practices to fit their own wishes and the As reforms and experiences are accounted
specific circumstances in which they operate. for and narrated, they tend to be framed and
In search of a concept that could even more presented in familiar and commonly
clearly be used to analyze how ideas were accepted terms so that they will make sense
being transferred, transposed and transformed to a reader or listener. Thus, experiences and
as they circulated, one of the authors of this reforms tend to be presented to others in
chapter chose to analyze the translation as an terms of existing templates, examples,
editing process (Sahlin-Andersson 1996). The categories, scientific concepts, theoretical
choice of this concept followed studies of the frameworks and widespread classifications
circulation of the customer concept into public that are familiar. These concepts, references
sector organizations and studies of a fashion at and frameworks form the infrastructure of
the time – that of building research parks. Both editing and they restrict and direct how the
studies showed how models or prototypes that accounts are given. In such a way widespread
were seen as ‘successes’ were formulated and and well-known classifications may sort out
reformulated as they circulated. Similarities what is being told as accounts are delivered
were emphasized while differences that might and transferred (cf. Bowker and Star 1999).
lead to the conclusion that the imitated proto- Concepts, ideologies, examples, interests
type did not fit in the local setting were played and classifications are not the same every-
down. In such processes of translation, new where. Those that dominate one setting, and
meanings were created and ascribed to activi- may be taken for granted in that setting, may
ties and experiences. In each new setting, a his- be unknown or unpopular in another setting.
tory of earlier experiences was reformulated in The infrastructure, and thus the editing rules,
light of the present circumstances and visions. differs between situations and contexts. This
The circulation was a continuous editing specific infrastructure determines the editing
process performed by a number of involved of ideas and experiences. Each context in
editors. Thus, those circulating management which the editing of models and experiences
ideas were co-constructing these same ideas takes place may be regarded as an editing
(Czarniawska and Joerges 1996, 2005; Sahlin- infrastructure. We may thus describe the
Andersson 2001, Sahlin-Andersson and process as one of recontextualizing experi-
Engwall 2002). ences and models. When using the term
226 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

‘editing’ we want to emphasize that this interpreted as accounts of how reforms have
recontextualization may change the formula- proceeded. In the course of the editing,
tion as well as the meaning and content of accidental or coincidental circumstances are
experiences and models. removed, as are aspects that cannot be
Such editing rules may be more specific or explained and accounted for in simple terms.
more general, and by following the routes of The models that attract the interest of others
circulation one can see how different and that are deemed to be worthy of imitation
contexts provide different editing rules. are those whose implementation seems
However, our studies revealed three kinds of possible in another setting. Thus, models that
rules that appear to work more generally as are imitated are those that are presented as
ideas are widely circulating (see Sahlin- plannable, and the editing procedure may
Andersson 1996). A first set of rules involve emphasizing or ascribing intentions,
concerns the context. When models are actors, procedures, and effects to an observed
applied in a setting that is different from that and presented development. As procedures
of the prototype, time- and space-bounded are imitated they are often described as
features tend to be excluded. Specific local models. As experiences in one place are
prerequisites are de-emphasized or omitted. edited into a model they tend to be rational-
In such a way widely circulated ideas tend to ized, scientized and theorized (cf. Strang and
be formulated in general and abstract terms, Meyer 1993).
and ideas and experiences are made available A third set of editing rules concerns for-
for others to imitate or adopt (Greenwood, mulation. As circulating ideas and their
Suddaby and Hinings 2002; Røvik 1998). effects are presented and represented, they
Stripping models of their local context tends acquire labels and may also be dramatized as
to take place in several steps. For instance, it they are told in a certain kind of language.
may start when someone reports on her own These accounts acquire certain formats or,
practice or experience. This person may want stated differently, they are formed into narra-
to shape her presentation in a way that will tives of certain genres (Czarniawska 1997).
make this experience interesting to others, Concepts, categories, prototypical examples,
disregarding aspects that seem unique and counter-examples, references and ideological
too time- or location-specific and emphasiz- frameworks are used to structure, narrate and
ing those that seem to be general and make sense of a certain procedure or to draw
generalizable. Those who mediate ideas, others’ attention to a certain development. In
experiences and models then do further order to attract attention, imitated prototypes
editing, and the cycle repeats when the model are reformulated in more dramatic terms, and
is adopted in a new setting. they are labeled in ways that make them easy
A second set of rules concerns logic. As to talk about and to remember, etc. They are
initiatives and effects are presented, the logic packaged and commodified with labels such
of the story is often reconstructed. as BPR, MBO, SPC, and TQM. In the editing
Developments may acquire a more rational- process various techniques may be packaged
istic flavor. Effects are presented as resulting under a common heading, or they may be
from identifiable activities, and processes are repackaged under a different heading than
often described as following a problem- they had before (cf. Frenkel 2005; Solli,
solving logic. Attention may be paid to a Demediuk and Sims 2005).
certain aspect of a development, while other Through editing, an idea or an account of
aspects are omitted or erased. Plans tend to a practice may be formulated more clearly
circulate more easily than effects (Sahlin- and made more explicit; however, the editing
Andersson 2001; Hwang 2003). As these process may also change not only the form of
plans are circulated, however, they are often the idea or account but also its focus, content,
described as if were they effects – plans are and meaning. Even small reformulations of
CIRCULATING IDEAS: IMITATION, TRANSLATION AND EDITING 227

an idea, which may accrue as the idea is (e.g., Bäckström 1999; Sahlin-Andersson
transferred from one context to another, may 2001). Some techniques, however, seem
fundamentally change its meaning or focus. clearly connected to a certain program, even
Thus, it is only after the fact that one can when such a program is not explicitly
distinguish revolutionary or fundamental announced as the idea is attended to and
shifts from less substantial ‘semantic’-type adopted. Organizational actors may have
changes arising from editing. Furthermore, been attracted by a certain technique or tool,
while some aspects of an idea may remain discovering only later that this technique
stable as the idea circulates, other aspects presupposed certain programmatic ideas.
may be transformed. Though labels often Vrangbæck (1999) analyzed the introduction
remain the same as they diffuse easily of a system of customers’ choice in the
between settings, this does not necessarily Danish healthcare system, calling it a ‘Trojan
mean that the attendant technologies and horse.’ This system was conceived and
meanings remain the same as the idea argued for in technical terms, but when it was
spreads from one context to another implemented it changed the logic of the
(see, e.g., Mazza, Sahlin-Andersson and whole operation. New comparisons, frames
Strandgaard Pedersen 2005 Solli et al. 2005). of reference, assumptions, and overall objec-
When an idea is translated, it may also be tives were invoked by the newly introduced
reframed in terms of its supporting ideology. techniques (see also Blomgren 1999). In this
Such editing is clearly found if we follow the way, circulating and edited ideas can trigger
cluster of management ideas for the public identity change.
sector that have been circulating under the
label ‘New Public Management.’ In analyz-
ing this circulation Power (1997) built on a
useful distinction, taken from Rose and FLOWS, CARRIERS AND
Miller (1992), between, on the one hand, EDITORS OF IDEAS
programmatic or normative elements of a
certain practice and, on the other hand, its Even if the theoretical framework that was
technological or operational elements. While presented in the previous section clearly
the programmatic element refers to the ideas, painted a broad pattern of idea circulation, dis-
aims and objectives of a certain practice, the cussing travels and translations, most empiri-
technological element refers to the concrete cal studies referred to above, primarily
tasks or routines of which this practice focused on those organizations that incorpo-
consists. New Public Management’s program rated institutional elements from their envi-
has been extensively discussed and analyzed ronment, and on how individual ideas or sets
in academic writings. However, when these of ideas were attended to, translated and
ideas were circulating in practice, the pro- edited in the local settings. The strong
gram behind the techniques was not always Scandinavian tradition of case studies of indi-
visible or explicit, but the technical elements, vidual organizations, decision processes and
such as the introduction of new accounting reforms kept many researchers’ attention pri-
systems, documentation instruments, pricing marily on those organizations that adopted
systems or hiring and payment procedures, new ideas. In subsequent studies, though,
were discussed and introduced in terms of interest more clearly turned to understanding
their technical elements. The program was where those ideas came from and how they
either hidden or it changed as ideas entered were produced and circulated – or, to again
into new settings. Studies have suggested connect to Meyer and Rowan, how ideas came
that the link between the programmatic and to be ‘littered around the social landscape.’
technical elements of a circulating idea The metaphor of travel has been used to
may be loose and change over time describe the circulation of ideas to emphasize
228 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

that management ideas do not flow automat- Such imitation will likely lead to the homog-
ically, but follow certain often highly struc- enization of practices and to further empha-
tured and well-worn routes (Czarniawska sis on a single central model that becomes a
and Sevón 1996a). Furthermore, translation prototype to be imitated. Even if the dynam-
of ideas is an active process: there are means ics of this mode resemble those of diffusion,
of transportation that carry the ideas from in which a strong central idea or model drives
one place to another. The travel metaphor is imitation, imitation in the broadcasting mode
helpful in the sense that it directs our atten- is driven by the active participation,
tion to travel routes and means of travel. initiatives, and motives of those doing the
Connections between actors in the field may imitating. Both those imitated and those
explain the likely routes through which ideas imitating are active shapers of the process
travel and the rate and speed of diffusion (Sevón 1996).
(Rogers 1983). The formation of networks March (1999: 199) distinguished between
and other contacts thus enables ideas to flow. this broadcasting mode and a chain mode of
With intensified interactions among carriers, imitation. While broadcasting, by definition,
channels have opened for the transfer of originates in one place and spreads all
ideas. However, as is the case with many around, in chain imitation an idea is imitated,
metaphors in organization theory, this one and then this imitation is in turn imitated, and
should be used with some caution. If taken so on. This is, in fact, the main mode of imi-
too literally, it may give the impression that tation as described by Tarde (1890/1962).
ideas flow via direct interaction. And the The one who is imitating may in fact have no
concept of imitation has sometimes led to a knowledge of the ‘origin’ of the model; thus
similarly limited view; imitation still seems we can sometimes discern only after the fact
to be understood primarily in terms of indi- that the imitation is part of a larger trend or
vidual relationships, in which a single actor development. This process is akin to the one
imitates one or several models. Many studies identified in relation to fashions: fashions
suggest, however, that greater emphasis may have no clear initiator, driver or direc-
should be placed on the complex webs of tion (Czarniawska 2005; Löfgren 2005). The
imitation processes, on how several imitation trend or fashion is created through chains of
and translation processes may be intercon- imitation and the ensuing translations.
nected, and on how one process of imitation Stressing that imitation may originate from
may lead to another. And just as the term ‘cir- not only one source or model, this mode of
culate’ indicates, the processes involve not imitation highlights even further the active
only the transport, flow or movement role of those involved in imitation.
through established channels – like blood cir- The third mode of imitation is one in
culating through the arteries and veins of the which the relationships between those being
body – but also the distribution, spreading, imitated and those imitating are mediated by
transmission or broadcasting of messages to other organizations and actors. Imitation
wider groups. does not always proceed from those imitated
Based on our studies of the proliferation of to those imitating. Many persons and organi-
management education (Hedmo et al. 2005), zations act as carriers and/or mediators
we distinguished between three modes of (Sahlin-Andersson and Engwall 2002). The
imitation. A first mode of imitation is one in usual diffusion perspective, according to
which a central model inspires imitation. which the diffusion of ideas takes place via
This can be called the broadcasting mode more or less automatic processes, and
(March, 1999: 137). In this mode, imitation according to which the main explanation for
is based on a specific model or core set of the success of an idea is its original strength,
ideas, which is picked up by actors in various has likely helped deflect the attention of
settings and incorporated into local practices. scholars from the actual carriers of ideas.
CIRCULATING IDEAS: IMITATION, TRANSLATION AND EDITING 229

Attention has instead been directed towards Max Weber, focused mainly on what they
the local settings where new practices are termed the ‘primary carriers’ of moderniza-
found and where ideas are received. A car- tion: technological production and the
rier’s identity has often been reduced (usu- bureaucratically organized state. However,
ally with the carrier’s cooperation) to an the authors identified a multiplicity of
entity that only reports on what is going on in ‘secondary carriers’ related to these funda-
various places, but is itself neither an activat- ments of modern society that serve as
ing entity nor an actor with influence. For transmitting agencies for the knowledge and
example, researchers, media, expert commit- ideology derived from the primary carriers.
tees, and international organizations are Alvarez (1998: 38) translated the concept in
presumed to report on actions and events order to analyze ‘the diffusion and consump-
occurring elsewhere, but without taking any tion of business knowledge.’ He analyzed
action or pursuing any interests in such these as secondary carriers and emphasized
events (such assumptions are demonstrated that such carriers ‘can attain considerable
and analyzed, but also questioned, by autonomy as agents in themselves’ (Berger
Finnemore 1996; Barnett and Finnemore et al. 1973: 9).
1999; and Sahlin-Andersson 2000). Along a similar line of conceptualizion,
Those who circulate ideas have been but using a different terminology, John
analyzed as carriers. For some, this concept Meyer (1994 1996) has used the term
may have a somewhat passive association: ‘others’ (inspired by G.H. Mead 1934) to
someone or something carrying a package, a capture such carriers with their specific fea-
passenger, or even a disease. The way the tures and activities, thereby distinguishing
concept has been used in studies of the circu- them from ‘actors,’ who are assumed to
lation of ideas, however, has been to convey pursue their own interests and policies and
a mix of passivity and activity, of supporting, are held responsible for their actions. Even
transporting, and transforming. Jepperson though ‘others’ may present themselves as
(1991) used the carrier concept to point to the neutral mediators, they engage in activities
importance of activities to institutional that are crucial for the circulation and trans-
development. Institutions do not just exist lation of ideas. Such ‘other’ organizations not
independently but are enacted in a host of only mediate ideas, they also influence and
supporting and reproducing practices. Even shape the activities that take place under
though such activities reproduce and their auspices, as they ‘discuss, interpret,
transform institutions, in highly institutional- advise, suggest, codify, and sometimes
ized situations and settings these activities pronounce and legislate [and] develop, prom-
are embedded in institutions or they consti- ulgate, and certify some ideas as proper
tute enactments of institutions. Thus, one reforms, and ignore or stigmatize other
should distinguish such activities from ideas’ (Meyer 1996: 244). To analyze how
actions: ‘If one participates conventionally in these ‘others’ translate and mediate ideas,
a highly institutionalized social pattern, one Sahlin-Andersson (1996; 2000) conceptual-
does not take action, that is intervene in a izes them as editors. These editors not only
sequence, make a statement’ (Jepperson report on and transmit ideas and experiences,
1991: 148). Hence, both the reproduction and but also formulate and reformulate and thus
the alteration of institutions involve activity: frame and reshape them in the process.
this ongoing activity is directed and limited Moreover, they teach (Finnemore 1996) –
by institutions while the activity reproduces more or less directly – other organizations
as well as alters institutions (Scott 1995; see how to act in order to be acknowledged as
also Giddens 1979; 1984). legitimate.
In their analysis of modernization, Berger The three modes of imitation – broadcast-
and associates (1973), highly influenced by ing, chain, and mediated – should be
230 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

understood as ideal types: although we will and practices in contemporary society.


find one or more of them when we study Relational models of diffusion underspecify
processes of imitation, they will not always the variety of effects following from direct
appear in their pure, ideal forms. These three interaction and interdependence as channels
ideal types are also used in analytical frame- of diffusion – thus we need to look beyond
works in imitation studies and, depending on network models of diffusion. They stress
which framework a particular study uses, one instead that linkages can be cultural – the
particular mode of imitation may be singled cultural understanding that social entities
out for identification and emphasis. It belong to a common category constructs a tie
appears to us that studies most often describe between them. Such cultural linkages form
the broadcasting or chain modes of imitation; identities and identification that shapes and
the mediated imitation mode, focusing on the directs processes of imitation and change, as
web of imitated and imitating actors and expectations and norms diffuse among actors
‘others’ who create, modify or circulate within the category or group. Diffusion
models and ideas to be imitated, has received within cultural categories is enhanced by
less attention. In practice, these three modes theorization, or the development of abstract
exist together and we have suggested that categories and generalized, complex models
such intertwined modes of imitation can and patterned relationships (Strang and
be analyzed as fields of imitation (Hedmo Meyer 1993). Mediating organizations,
et al. 2005). again, play important roles in such processes.
Sahlin-Andersson and Engwall (2002) Media and professional organizations, for
used the carrier concept when analyzing instance, theorize practices and models for
those who are professing, providing, and change, driving organizational as well as
circulating management ideas. With the institutional change and development (Rao,
expansion of carriers such as consultants, Monin and Durand 2003; Greenwood et al.
business schools and the media the supply of 2002).
management ideas has expanded. Thus,
Sahlin-Andersson and Engwall (2002)
claimed, the intensified circulation and adop-
tion of management ideas among organiza- FROM PROTOTYPES TO TEMPLATES
tions is largely supply driven. Abrahamsson
(1996) also stressed the role of such carrying The focus of research has recently turned
organizations, or ‘others,’ in forming from studies of how and why ideas circulate
fashions, naming them a ‘fashion-setting to studies of what kinds of ideas circulate,
community’ that continuously identifies and on how the nature of ideas changes, both
ideas, fashions a discourse that presents these as ideas circulate and as the institutional set-
ideas as rational and progressive, and tings in which ideas spread change. We can
markets these back to the management describe this change as a shift in focus from
community. This way, the fashion-setting ideas as prototypes to ideas as templates.
community redefines conceptions of what Prototypes are exemplars, models to be
constitutes rational progress in managerial imitated and put into practice. Such proto-
practice and produces waves of managerial types are typically picked up and edited by
fashions (Abrahamsson 1996). those organizations that want to become, or
Still we should be careful to avoid letting be perceived as, successful in accordance
this seemingly actor- and action-focused ter- with the exemplary models. So, for instance,
minology lead us to see only the interactions when a number of municipalities developed
and actors. Strang and Meyer suggest that their civil services, this became known as a
relational models of diffusion are not enough successful model – or a prototype – to be
to explain the wide distribution of models imitated and other municipalities followed
CIRCULATING IDEAS: IMITATION, TRANSLATION AND EDITING 231

suit (Tolbert and Zucker 1983). Models for new century. Classification systems (Bowker
total quality management were associated and Star 1999), standards (Brunsson and
with success and thus were picked up by Jacobsson 2000) and rules (March, Schulz
organizations that wanted to become or and Zhou 2000) have increased in number
appear successful (Westphal et al. 1997) and, and have been developed and applied across
with reference to Silicon Valley, research organizations and around the world (Djelic
parks became associated with successful and Sahlin-Andersson 2006b). Evaluations
regional development and thus developed and audits (Power 1997), accounting systems
among regional planners into a prototype for (Meyer 1994; Olson, Guthrie and Humphery
how to enable development and growth 1998), assessments and accreditation
(e.g. Hall and Marcusen 1985; Saxenian (Hedmo 2004) and comparisons and rank-
1988; Sahlin-Andersson 1996). We have ings (Miller 1996; Wedlin 2006) have all
shown above that these processes of imita- expanded and become widespread.
tion are largely mediated with consultancies, Thus focus has shifted from management
media organizations, international organiza- to regulation, from an intraorganizational to
tions and the like carrying those models from interorganizational focus, and from talk of
one setting to another and at the same time efficiency to talk of transparency. In general
editing them into success models. this shift is clearly following the logic of an
More than models and prototypes for spe- audit society, the early signs of which
cific imitation, however, templates for Michael Power (1997) pointed out. With an
assessing and evaluating practices are also ‘audit explosion’ the logic of the financial
circulating among organizations and between audit has been replicated to new societal
contexts. These templates are frames or tar- arenas and issues, and it is seen as constitut-
gets that actors use to compare or benchmark ing a new system of governance that
their activities, and they prescribe how inculcates ‘new norms and values by which
success should be assessed. Templates serve external regulatory mechanisms transform
as the currency, the medium of abstraction the conduct of organizations and individuals
used to assess, monitor and present practices. in their capacity as “self-actualizing agents” ’
These can be evaluation criteria, rankings, (Shore and Wright 2000). Thus, this
standards, or just widespread notions of what ‘audit society’ is a society where audits
constitutes success that individuals, groups expand into almost all aspects of social life,
and organizations aspire to or compare them- and operations and organizations are
selves with. The formulation and diffusion of increasingly structured in ways that make
templates shape identities and identification them ‘auditable’ (Power 1997; see also
with a category or group of organizations, Strathern 2000).
and guide the search for models and organi- ‘Transparency’ along with ‘governance,’
zations to imitate (Wedlin 2007). ‘flexibility,’ ‘quality,’ and ‘performance’ are
concepts that have spread almost universally.
In parallel with this emerging transparency
Soft regulation and governance regime (Kjaer and Sahlin 2007) are tech-
niques and models for how to respond to
This change in research focus from proto- such monitoring. These techniques are ways
types to templates has primarily been trig- of auditing and making auditable – they have
gered by empirical observations. The most been characterized as transparency technolo-
fashionable and popular organizational ideas gies (Blomgren and Sahlin 2007) or, more
during the 1980s and 1990s largely con- commonly, as soft modes of governing and
cerned and strengthened management and regulating.
leaders. Slightly different ideas have come to Soft regulations are nonhierarchical rules
be most commonly circulating during the that are not legally binding (Mörth 2004;
232 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

2006). Furthermore, such rules are largely state-centered control and the rise of an ‘age
informal and flexible in the sense that they of legalism’ (Schmidt 2004). New regulatory
are open to interpretation and adjustment by modes – such as contractual arrangements,
those being regulated (cf. Kirton and standards, rankings and monitoring frames –
Trebilcock 2004). The domain and applica- are taking over and are increasingly being
bility of soft rules and the conditions for used by states, too (Hood, Scott, James et al.
compliance are being defined together with 1999). New organizations, alliances and
the rules themselves. Authority is not networks emerge everywhere. Particularly
predefined in the relationships between those salient is the almost exponential growth of
regulated and those regulating, but must be international organizations (e.g. Boli and
built into each governing relationship. Thomas 1999). An important task for many
Despite much general talk about deregula- of these organizations is to issue rules, but
tion, empirical observations point to the they may also be involved in elaborating and
increasing scope and breadth of regulatory activating processes to monitor adoption and
and governance activities of all kinds. The implementation of those rules.
intensity of the latter, in fact, is such that it Hence, we find that just as fashionable
would probably be more accurate, Djelic and management ideas circulated more or less
Sahlin-Andersson (2006c) suggest, to talk of worldwide during the previous decades, the
regulatory ‘activism.’ Regulatory activism early 2000s have seen the circulation of
can take the form of a re-regulation of certain various kinds of regulatory and governing
spheres that had already been regulated, but activities (Drori 2006). These bring templates
generally at the national level. This is the for organizing and for evaluating, assessing
case, for example, with education (Morgan and and judging practices and procedures. We can
Engwall 1999), health (Blomgren 2007), labor point to organizational as well as institutional
markets (Jacobsson 2004) and accounting and consequences of the new emerging trends.
financial reporting (Tamm Hallström 2004; Before turning to these, however, we need to
Botzem and Quack 2006). All of those say a few more words on the dynamics of the
spheres are increasingly subject to regulatory circulation of templates.
activities and initiatives with a transnational
scope.
Regulatory activism can also take the form
Circulation of templates
of an expansion into new territories. This is
the case, for example, with environmental The circulation of templates follows some of
and pollution issues (Frank, Hironaka and the same dynamics as the prototypes – the
Schofer 2000; McNichol and Bensedrine management ideas – that featured in the
2003; Power 2003); ethical, social and envi- 1980s and 1990s, and still do. They display
ronmental aspects of corporate activities (e.g., patterns of fads and fashion, they are picked
Cutler, Haufler and Porters 1999; Kirton and up and displayed as organizations seek to
Trebilcock 2004); the life and rights of appear modern and rational, they are
animals (Forbes and Jermier 2002); adminis- supplied and circulated by many carrying
trative procedures (Brunsson and Jacobsson organizations that look for ways of attracting
2000; Beck and Walgenbach 2002) or the resources and attention, and they are per-
structuring of love and intimate relationships ceived as ways for all these many organiza-
(Franck and McEneaney 1999). The present tions to seek more central and dominating
world, indeed, is a ‘golden era of regulation’ positions in their respective fields. Some
(Levi-Faur and Jordana 2005) marked by a consequences of their circulation appear
profound transformation of regulatory familiar, too: they add to the elaboration and
patterns (see also Braithwaite and Drahos increased complexity of organizational
2000). We witness both the decline of structure, structures that are more or less
CIRCULATING IDEAS: IMITATION, TRANSLATION AND EDITING 233

decoupled from the daily operations of those shifting boundaries and organizations in flux.
organizations, and they lead to isomorphism, There is competition for claims to authority
at least as long as we look at the formal and the regulatory arena can be described as
organizational structures. However, recent a regulatory market – where demands and
studies have also pointed to additional offers stimulate and reinforce each other. On
drivers for and consequences of the circula- the regulatory market the way to reach con-
tion of these modern ideas.1 trol or to react to regulations that are not
On a first level, the expansion of soft favorable to one’s position and strategy is
regulations has been shown to be moved essentially to organize and drive a competing
respectively by distrust, the question of regulatory set-up. In a world where regula-
responsibility and the search for control. tion is expanding, the way to seek control is
Power (1997, 2004, 2007) showed that the not by avoiding regulation. Rather, a more
movement towards expanded regulation is promising strategy is to become actively
driven in part by a lack of trust. A diffuse dis- involved in issuing and supporting a
trust generates the need for activities that satisfactory regulatory scheme.
reveal, make transparent, and set rules, with a These drivers partly explain the expansion
view to building more trust. Those activities, of regulations that serve as the templates
however, may in fact not only solve problems related to which organizations and operations
but also reveal and suggest new problems and are being judged and assessed. The shape of
new questions. In the process, rather than such templates, on the other hand, has been
building trust, they could be undermining it explained by institutional forces that perme-
further, leading to still more requests for ate and shape our modern society.
auditing, monitoring and regulation. When characterizing these as institutional
Partly connected to this, we also find a forces, we refer to four meanings of ‘institu-
‘responsibility spiral.’ Governance and regu- tions.’ First, institutions are constitutive of
lation are in part about allocation of respon- actors, interests, relations and meanings; they
sibility. With the multiplication of regulatory push and pull activities in certain directions.
and governance activities, responsibilities This is precisely why we can conceive of
become diffused and dispersed. Furthermore, them as ‘forces’ (cf. Hoffman and Ventresca
the movement towards soft regulation has a 2002). Institutional forces should not be
tendency to reroute responsibility away from treated as external to the actors, as represent-
rule setters and towards rule followers. ing an environment to which actors are
Voluntary rules that are open to translation merely adapting. Second, institutional forces
mean that those who choose to follow the generally become taken for granted as the
rules, and to follow them in certain ways, are ‘natural’ way of being and doing; they
held responsible. This double blurring of become transparent to the actors themselves
responsibilities may drive the need for (cf. Douglas 1986). Third, institutional
regulation and governance still further, and at forces are self-reinforcing (Jepperson 1991).
the local level expanded soft regulation may As these forces shape relations, interests and
foster a culture of defensiveness (see Power bases for activities, the actions taken carry
2004). Organizational representatives then inscribed meanings and drive activities
have to allocate extended resources, not only further along the same path. Fourth, these
to follow rules but also to explain why they institutional forces constitute the ‘rules of
have chosen to follow certain rules in the game,’ providing frameworks for
particular ways or why they should be held judging which behavioral, organizing, dis-
responsible. cursive, and interaction patterns are appropri-
A third mechanism feeding the spiral ate – thus they may be envisioned as the
revolves around the search for control. Our meta-templates of the modern organ-
present world is in motion with unclear and ized world.
234 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

The newly emerging and circulating regu- Organizing is a third institutional force.
latory measures are structured and framed by Organizing, which in the present context is
the rise, expansion and influence of scientific defined as the almost universal reliance on
discourse throughout the world (Drori, formal organizational structure to order
Meyer, Ramirez and Schofer 2003; Drori and social relations, achieve particular goals, or
Meyer 2006). Actors, activities and settings solve particular problems, has resulted in
are largely shaped and authorized in the what may be termed ‘the organized society’
name of science. As already pointed out by (Perrow 1991, 2002), a society in which
Weber (1919/1949), this is accompanied by a formal organizations become the key vehi-
drive for transparency: Science becomes a cles for governance and social order (see also
paradigmatic umbrella, in terms of which Ahrne and Brunsson 2006). As such, organ-
every aspect of the universe can and should izing is also a way to manage risk and uncer-
be interpreted and framed. In line with this tainty (Power, 2007). Again the prevailing
we find that those templates – in the form of ideal of organizing is to order by making
guidelines, standards and assessment criteria tasks, roles, and relations explicit and subject
– that are widely circulated are directly sup- to formal description. This shapes a demand
ported by references to science. The best for classifica-tions, guidelines, rules and
example of this may be the proliferation of scrutinizing measures.
evidence-based models. Such models were A fourth institutional force has been
first circulated in relation to medical treat- termed moral rationalization (Boli 2006),
ment (Hult 2006) but have lately spread to the widespread assessment and celebration of
all areas of modern life. Arguments have, what is good or bad, excellent or insufficient –
for example, been raised for the need for usually based on moral judgments and
evidence-based management (Pfeffer and expressed in ranking lists, prizes, records,
Sutton 2006). credentials and celebrations, published
A second institutional force that underpins naming and shaming and the like and backed
the expansion, circulation and shape of soft up by a rationalized moral order that assumes
regulatory measures is marketization (Djelic basic cognitive and normative judgment
2006). In about a century, market logics have criteria.
moved from reflecting marginal ideas in a Finally, there is the urge towards rein-
few liberal intellectual centers to becoming a vented democracy, heavily emphasizing
structuring force of the world. Western soci- deliberation and thus the need for open
eties, at least, are being marketized to the accounts and open dialogues. Our world is,
extent that markets are not only framed as as Mörth (2006) has convincingly shown,
superior arrangements for the allocation of increasingly permeated by a view of democ-
goods and resources in every sphere of eco- racy that emphasizes dialogue and delibera-
nomic, social or even cultural and moral life, tion and the autonomy of participating
but are also increasingly defined and per- actors. With this institutional development,
ceived as the ‘natural’ way to organize and we find a widespread quest for accounts and
structure human interactions (Djelic 2006). information on which participants in this
Today we find that marketization permeates deliberation can act, and with which partici-
and structures policies, reforms, discourses pants can be invited to take part in dialogues.
and ideologies in many places in the world. Not only does this institutional development
This progress of marketization comes, foster an increase in the quest for information
furthermore, under a highly scientized guise, on business developments as well as on all
particularly reflected in the professionaliza- other aspects of society, but, in order for the
tion of economics. A common argument for deliberation to actually form into a dialogue,
transparency is that markets, in order to there is a quest for critical scrutiny and for
function well, demand it. multiple perspectives on developments.
CIRCULATING IDEAS: IMITATION, TRANSLATION AND EDITING 235

The editing of corporations producing and editing presentations of them-


selves and their performance in light of such
Together the institutional forces described standard criteria for evaluation and descrip-
above foster the proliferation and circulation tion (Corvellec 1997; Pallas 2007). With this
of rules, standards, classification schemes, increased attention to self-presentation
evaluation procedures, rankings and monitor- follow changes in organizational structure.
ing that form an audit society (Power 1997), Studies of corporate branding (Schultz,
audit culture (Strathern 2000), transparency Antorini and Csaba 2005), of corporate
regime (Kjaer and Sahlin 2007) and golden expressiveness (Hatch and Schultz 1997) and
era of regulation (Levi-Faur and Jordana of corporate reputation (Fombrun 1996;
2005). With this changed nature of proliferat- Deephouse 2000; Pollock and Rindova
ing ideas we find that the main logics of 2003), as well as daily reports on the way
organizations appear to change too. The corporations are traded and valued on the
changed organizational logics that follow stock markets worldwide, all seem to reveal
those institutional changes have not attracted the central importance of the way corpora-
as much scholarly attention as has the issue tions are presented and conceptualized. In
of how new ideas emerge and proliferate – fact, many would claim that brands and
how institutional change comes about. presentations are the core of many modern
However, studies from various research corporations. The way in which corporations
traditions point to a few tendencies of organi- are presented and monitored by the media
zational changes that follow the institutional may thus have a direct effect on their
changes that we have portrayed above. We finances, their development and even their
can particularly note how organizations survival (cf., Jonsson 2005). Power (2007)
become increasingly occupied with showed that reputational risk has become a
presenting themselves in ways that clearly central management concern and he demon-
remind us of those ways of ‘the presentation of strated the many ways in which organizations
self’ that were highlighted by Goffman (1959; govern reputation.
see also, e.g., Ramirez 2006; Power 2007). We have suggested the term ‘edited corpo-
Empirical studies of fields such as health ration’ to emphasize this (Engwall and Sahlin
care and management education have 2007). The activities of organizations are
emphasized the importance of monitoring increasingly geared, as described above, to
organizations, such as accreditation bodies the editing of texts picked up by the organi-
and media, in creating and circulating zation from the environment – management
templates within fields (Erlingsdottir and ideas, market information, news of competi-
Lindberg 2005; Hedmo, Sahlin-Andersson tors, and so on – or texts about the company
and Wedlin 2006 Wedlin 2006). These have intended for its stakeholders or for other
provided categories and measures on the uses. Further, the term ‘editing’ suggests the
basis of which activities and organizations are presence of reciprocal processes in which
compared, monitored, and assessed (Hedmo several individuals and units inside and
et al. 2005). It was particularly noted that the outside the corporation interact with one
entrance of these mediating bodies was another. Moreover, such texts are shaped – in
followed not only by more imitation among fact, edited – according to those circulating
organizations but also by an enhanced templates that we discussed above.
emphasis on self-presentation. The rules set The edited corporation, then, is a corpora-
by the monitoring bodies regulate what is tion that is clearly embedded in and dependent
considered to be good and appropriate upon circulated templates; it is a corporation
self-presentation, and they also frame and in which a great many activities are devoted
structure how the audience views the to editing work, and to managing and organ-
self-presentations. Organizations engage in izing for this embeddedness. The edited
236 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

presentation of an organization and its activ- of monitoring and scrutinizing activities


ities is not directed at an external audience of the kind described above opens spaces for
only. The templates also function as mirrors the circulation of prototypical models
of organizational activities, whereby the for how those scrutinized organizations can
edited organization appears in an be improved relative to the template meas-
auto-communicative process in which activi- ures. Thus, with this shift we find a more
ties are presented in external assessments, densely populated institutional and organiza-
rankings, media, audits, etc., which in turn tional landscape. Again studies have most
informs people in the organization about clearly pointed to the emergence of new and
their own situation and operations. increasingly complex institutional structures
As organizations, groups and individuals and procedures. A critical remark that has
categorize, give accounts of their activities, been made about much of organizational
and benchmark themselves in relation to institutionalism can be repeated relative to
templates, forming themselves according to the present studies: what is the limit? Which
the templates, these efforts can drive institu- forces drive in the opposite direction?
tional change. But rather than serving as Obviously there need to be some counter-
direct blueprints or models to be imitated or forces working against intensified circula-
adopted, these templates shape identities and tion, deinstitutionalization and variation, but
identifications of organizations and groups these are only rarely discussed in studies of
that can lead to ‘identity-movements’ that in institutionalization processes. Even if the
turn significantly alter institutional logics or Scandinavian studies reviewed in this chapter
practices (cf. Rao et al. 2003). The result of have sought to address these issues by
such change, however, is not necessarily or looking more closely at the dynamics of insti-
exclusively an increasing homogenization of tutionalization and circulation, many intrigu-
organizational structures or activities. Rather, ing and difficult questions about limits to
studies have noted both compliance and institutionalization, deinstitutionalization and
resistance to isomorphic pressures intro- deregulation remain largely unanswered.
duced by new evaluation and assessment sys-
tems (Townley 2002), and have shown how
templates provided by monitoring activities NOTES
leave substantial room for diverse interpreta-
tions and local identity formation processes, 1 The following section about drivers for
thus mediating isomorphic pressures (Wedlin expanded regulation builds substantially on Djelic
2007). We can thus expect, and have and Sahlin-Andersson (2006b and c).
observed, both similarity and difference to
follow from the circulation and formulation
of templates. This is in line with contempo- REFERENCES
rary writings on institutional change, show-
ing differential responses to new evaluation Abrahamson, E. 1991. ‘Managerial fads and
mechanisms, performance measures and pro- fashion: The diffusion and rejection of inno-
fessional standards that produce both stabil- vations.’ Academy of Management Review,
ity and change in organizational practices 16: 586–612.
Abrahamson, E. 1996. ‘Technical and aesthetic
and routines (Casile and Davis-Blake 2002;
fashion.’ In B. Czarniawska & G. Sevón
Greenwood et al. 2002; Townley 2002). (eds.), Translating Organizational Change.
In this section we have described and Berlin: Walter de Gruyter, pp. 117–138.
discussed a shift from prototypes to Ahrne, G. & Brunsson, N. 2006. ‘Organizing
templates. This, however, should not be the world.’ In M.-L. Djelic and K. Sahlin-
understood as meaning that prototypes are no Andersson, Transnational Governance:
longer circulating. However, the prevalence Institutional Dynamics of Regulation.
CIRCULATING IDEAS: IMITATION, TRANSLATION AND EDITING 237

Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. Boli, J. & Thomas, G.M. (eds). 1999.
74–94. Constructing World Culture. Stanford:
Alvarez, J.L. 1998. ‘The sociological tradition Stanford University Press.
and the spread and institutionalisation of Botzem, S. & Quack, S. 2006. ‘Contested rules
knowledge for action.’ In J. L. Alvarez (ed.), and shifting boundaries: International stan-
The Diffusion and Consumption of Business dard-setting in accounting.’ In M.-L. Djelic
Knowledge. New York: St Martin’s Press, pp. and K. Sahlin-Andersson, Transnational Gov-
13–57. ernance: Institutional Dynamics of
Barnett, M.N. & Finnemore, M. 1999. ‘The pol- Regulation. Cambridge: Cambridge University
itics, power and pathologies of international Press, pp. 266–286.
organizations.’ International Organization, Bourdieu, P. 1977, ‘The production of belief:
53(4): 699–732. Contribution to an Economy of symbolic
Beck, N. & Walgenbach, P. 2002. ‘The institu- goods.’ Media, Culture and Society, 2(3):
tionalisation of the Quality Management 261–293.
Approach in Germany’. In K. Sahlin- Bourdieu, P. 1984. Distinction: A Social Critique
Andersson and L. Engwall, The Expansion of of the Judgement of Taste. Cambridge, MA:
Management Knowledge: Carriers, Flows Harvard University Press.
and Sources. Stanford: Stanford University Bowker, G.C. & Star, S.L. 1999. Sorting Things
Press, pp. 145–174. Out: Classification and its Consequences.
Berger, P.L., Berger, B., & Kellner, H.1973. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
The Homeless Mind: An Approach to Braithwaite, J. & Drahos, P. 2000. Global
Modern Conciousness. New York: Random Business Regulation. Cambridge: Cambridge
House. University Press.
Blomgren, M. 1999. ‘Pengarna eller livet? Brunsson, N. 1989. The Organization of
Sjukvårdande professioner och yrkesgrupper Hypocrisy: Talk, Decisions and Actions in
i mötet med en ny ekonomistyrning’. Organizations. Chichester: Wiley.
Unpublished doctoral thesis, no 78, Brunsson, N. 2006. Mechanisms of Hope.
Department of Business Studies, Uppsala Maintaining the Dream of Rationality in
University. Organizations. Malmö: Copenhagen Business
Blomgren, M. 2003. ‘Ordering a profession: School Press, Liber, Universitetsforlaget.
Swedish nurses encounter new public man- Brunsson, N. & Jacobsson, B. (eds). 2000.
agement reforms.’ Financial Accountability A World of Standards. Oxford: Oxford
and Management, 19(1): 45–71. University Press.
Blomgren, M. 2007. ‘The drive for trans- Brunsson, N. & Olsen, J.P. (eds). 1993. The
parency: organizational field transformations Reforming Organization. London: Routledge.
in Swedish healthcare’. Public Administration, Brunsson, N. & Sahlin-Andersson, K. 2000.
85(1): 67–82. ‘Constructing organizations: The example of
Blomgren, M. & Sahlin, K. 2007. ‘Quests for public sector reform.’ Organization Studies,
transparency: Signs of a new institutional 21(4): 721–746.
era in the health care field?’ In T. Christensen Bäckström, H. 1999. ‘Den krattade manegen.
and P. Laegreid (eds.), Trancending Svensk arbetsorganisations utveckling under
New Public Management. The Transfor- tre decennier.’ Unpublished doctoral thesis,
mation of Public Sector Reform. Aldershot: no 79, Department of Business Studies,
Ashgate. Uppsala University.
Blumer, H.G. 1969. ‘Fashion: From class differ- Casile, M. & Davis-Blake, A. 2002. ‘When
entiation to collective selection.’ Sociological accreditation standards change: Factors
Quarterly, 10: 275–291. affecting differential responsiveness of public
Boli, J. 2006. ‘The rationalization of virtue and and private organizations.’ Academy of
virtuosity in world society.’ In M.-L. Djelic and Management Journal, 45(1): 180–195.
K. Sahlin-Andersson, Transnational Gover- Collins, D. 2000. Management Fads and
nance: Institutional Dynamics of Regulation. Buzzwords. London: Routledge.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. Corvellec, H. 1997. Stories of Achievements:
95–118. Narrative Features of Organizational
238 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Performance. New Brunswick, NJ: Transac- Governance: Institutional Dynamics of


tion Publishers. Regulation. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Cutler, C.A., Haufler, V. & Porters, T. (eds). Press, pp. 1–28.
1999. Private Authority and International Djelic, M.-L. & Sahlin-Andersson, K. 2006c.
Affairs. New York: State University of New “Institutional dynamics in a reordering
York Press. world.” In M.-L. Djelic & K. Sahlin-Andersson,
Czarniawska, B. 1997. Narrating the Organi- Transnational governance: Institutional
sation: Dramas of Institutional Identity. dynamics of regulation. Cambridge:
Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Cambridge University Press, pp. 375–397.
Czarniawska, B. 2005. ‘Fashion in organizing.’ Douglas, M. 1986. How Institutions Think.
In B. Czarniawska & G. Sevón (eds), Global Syracuse, NY: Syracuse University Press.
Ideas: How Ideas, Objects and Practices Drori, G. 2006. ‘Governed by Governance: The
Travel in the Global Economy. Malmö: Liber Institutionalization of Governance as a Prism
and Copenhagen Business School Press, pp. for Organizational Change’. In Drori, G.,
129–146. Meyer, J. W., & Hwang, H. (eds.) Globali-
Czarniawska, B. & Joerges, B. 1996. ‘Travels of zation and Organization: World Society and
Ideas.’ In B. Czarniawska & G. Sevón (eds.), Organizational Change, Oxford University
Translating Organizational Change. Berlin: Press, pp. 91–118.
Walter de Gruyter, pp.13–47. Drori, G., Meyer, J. Ramirez, F. & Schofer, E.
Czarniawska, B. & Sevón, G. (eds.). 1996a. 2003. Science in the Modern World Polity.
Translating Organizational Change. Berlin: Stanford: Stanford University Press.
Walter de Gruyter. Drori, G. & Meyer, J. 2006. ‘Scientization:
Czarniawska, B. & Sevón, G. 1996b. Making a world safe for organizing.’ In M.-L.
‘Introduction.’ In B. Czarniawska & G. Sevón Djelic and K. Sahlin-Andersson, Transnational
(eds.), Translating Organizational Change. Governance: Institutional Dynamics of
Berlin: Walter de Gruyter, pp. 1–12. Regulation. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Czarniawska, B.& Sevón, G. (eds). 2005. Global Press, pp. 31–52.
Ideas: How Ideas, Objects and Practices Engwall, L. & Sahlin, K. 2007. ‘Corporate gov-
Travel in the Global Economy. Malmö: Liber ernance and the media: From agency theory
and Copenhagen Business School Press. to edited corporation.’ In P. Kjaer and T.
Deephouse, D. 2000. ‘Media reputation as a Slatta (eds), The Rise of the Nordic Business
strategic resource. An integration of mass Press. Copenhagen: Copenhagen Business
communication and resource-based theories.’ School Press.
Journal of Management, 26(6): 1091–1112. Erlingsdóttir, G. & Lindberg, K. 2005.
DiMaggio, P. & Powell, W. 1983. ‘The iron cage ‘Isomorphism, isopraxism and isonymism:
revisited: Institutional isomorphism and Complementary or competing processes?’
collective rationality in organizational In B. Czarniawska & G. Sevón (eds), Global
fields.’ American Sociological Review, 48: Ideas: How Ideas, Objects and Practices
147-160. Travel in the Global Economy. Malmö: Liber
Djelic, M.-L. 2006. ‘Marketization: From intel- and Copenhagen Business School Press,
lectual agenda to global policy-making.’ pp. 47–70.
In M.-L. Djelic and K. Sahlin-Andersson, Finnemore, M. 1996. National Interests in
Transnational Governance: Institutional International Society. Ithaca: Cornell
Dynamics of Regulation. Cambridge: University Press.
Cambridge University Press, pp. 53–73. Fombrun, C. 1996. Reputation: Realizing Value
Djelic, M.-L. & Sahlin-Andersson, K. 2006a. from the Corporate Image. Boston, MA:
Transnational Governance: Institutional Harvard Business School Press.
Dynamics of Regulation. Cambridge: Forssell, A. & Jansson, D. 1996. ‘The logic of
Cambridge University Press. organizational transformation: On the con-
Djelic, M.-L. & Sahlin-Andersson, K. 2006b. version of non-business organizations’. In B.
‘Introduction: A world of Governance. The Czarniawska & G. Sevón (eds.), Translating
rise of transnational regulation.’ In M.-L. Organizational Change, Berlin: Walter de
Djelic & K. Sahlin-Andersson, Transnational Gruyter, pp. 93–1 15.
CIRCULATING IDEAS: IMITATION, TRANSLATION AND EDITING 239

Forbes, L. & Jermier, J.M. 2002.’The institution- Czarniawska & G. Sevón (eds.), Global Ideas:
alization of bird protection: Mabel Osgood How Ideas, Objects and Practices Travel
Wright and the early Audobon Movement.’ in the Global Economy. Malmö: Liber
Organization and Environment, 15: and Copenhagen Business School Press,
458–474. pp. 190–212.
Frank, D., Hironaka, A. & Schofer, E. 2000. ‘The Hedmo, T., Sahlin-Andersson, K. & Wedlin, L.
nation state and the natural environment 2006. ‘The emergence of a European
over the twentieth century.’ American regulatory field of management education’.
Sociological Review, 65: 96–116. In M.-L. Djelic and K. Sahlin-
Frank, D. & McEneaney, E.H. 1999. ‘The indi- Andersson, Transnational Governance:
vidualization of society and the liberalization Institutional Dynamics of Regulation.
of State policies on same-sex sexual rela- Cambridge: Cambridge University Press,
tions, 1984–1995.’ Social Forces, 77 pp. 308–328.
(March): 911–944. Hoffman, A. & Ventresca, M. 2002.’
Frenkel, M. 2005. ‘Something new, something Introduction.’ In A. Hoffman and M.
old, something borrowed: The cross-national Ventresca (eds.), Organizations, Policy, and
translation of the ‘family-friendly organiza- the Natural Environment. Stanford: Stanford
tion’ in Israel.’ In B. Czarniawska & G. Sevón University Press, pp. 1–38.
(eds), Global Ideas: How Ideas, Objects and Hood, C., Scott, C., James, O., Jones, G. & Travers,
Practices Travel in the Global Economy. T. 1999. Regulation Inside Government.
Malmö: Liber and Copenhagen Business Oxford: Oxford University Press.
School Press, pp. 147–166. Hult, E. 2006. ‘Profession och transparens’
Giddens, A. 1979. Central Problems in Social [Profession and Transparency: the
Theory: Action, Structure and Contradiction Development of EBM in the Media Arena.
in Social Analysis. Berkeley: University of In C. Levay and C. Waks (eds), Strävan efter
California Press. Transparens: Granskning, Styrning Och
Giddens, A. 1984. The Constitution of Society. Organisering I Sjukvårdens Nätverk [The
Berkeley: University of California Press. Pursuit of Transparency: Auditing, Control
Goffman, E. 1959. The Presentation of Self in and Organisation in Health Care Networks].
Everyday Life. New York: Doubleday. Stockholm: SNS.
Greenwood, R., Suddaby, R. & Hinings, C.R., Hwang, H. 2003. ‘Planning development’.
2002. ‘Theorizing change: The role of pro- Unpublished PhD Dissertation, Stanford
fessional associations in the transformation University.
of institutionalised fields.’ Academy of Jacobsson, K. 2004. ‘Between deliberation and
Management Journal, 45(1): 58–80. discipline: Soft governance in EU employ-
Hall, P. & Marcusen, A. 1985. Silicon ment policy’. In U. Mörth (ed.), Soft Law in
Landscapes. Boston, MA: Allen & Unwin. Governance and Regulation. Cheltenham:
Hatch, M.-J. & Schultz, M. 1997. ‘Relations Edward Elgar, pp. 81–102.
between organizational culture, identity and Jepperson, R.L. 1991. ‘Institutions, institutional
image.’ European Journal of Marketing, effects and institutionalism.’ In W.W. Powell
31(5/6): 356–366. and P. DiMaggio (eds.), The New Institutio-
Haveman, H.A. 1993. ‘Follow the leader: nalism in Organizational Analysis. Chicago:
Mimetic isomorphism and entry into new University of Chicago Press.
markets.’ Administrative Science Quarterly, Jonsson, S. 2005. ‘Naming me and shaming
38: 593–627. you: Inaccuracies in mechanisms for
Hedmo, T. 2004. Rulemaking in the Transna- loss of legitimacy.’ Paper presented at the
tional Space: The Development of European GEMS workshop at Oxford University,
Accreditation of Management Education, August 2005.
Unpublished doctoral thesis 109, Department Kirton, J.J. & Trebilcock, M.J. 2004. Hard
of Business Studies, Uppsala University. Choices, Soft Law. Aldershot: Ashgate.
Hedmo, T., Sahlin-Andersson, K. & Wedlin, L. Kjaer, P. & Sahlin, K. 2007. Media transparency
2005. ‘Fields of imitation: The global expan- as an institutional practice. In P. Kjaer and T.
sion of management education.’ In B. Slatta (eds), The rise of the Nordic business
240 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

press. Copenhagen: Copenhagen Business Translating Organizational Change. Berlin:


School Press, pp. 285–302. Walter de Gruyter, pp. 241–252.
Latour, B. 1986. ‘The powers of association.’ In Meyer, J.W. & Rowan, B. 1977.
J. Law (ed.), Power, Action and Belief. ‘Institutionalized organizations: Formal
London: Routledge and Kegan Paul, pp. structure as myth and ceremony’,
264–280. American Journal of Sociology, no. 2,
Levi-Faur, D. & Jordana, J. 2005. The Rise of pp. 340–363.
Regulatory Capitalis:. The annals of APSA, Miller, P. 1996. ‘Dilemmas of Accountability:
vol. 598. London: Sage. The limits of Accounting.’ In P. Hirst & S.
Löfgren, O. 2005. ‘Cultural alchemy: Kihlnani (eds.), Reinventing Democracy,
Translating the experience economy into Oxford: Blackwell, pp. 57–69.
Scandinavia.’ In B. Czarniawska & G. Sevón Miller, P. & Rose, N. 1990. ‘Governing economic
(eds.), Global Ideas: How Ideas, Objects and life.’ Economy and Society, 19(1): 1–31.
Practices Travel in the Global Economy. Morgan, G. & Engwall, L. (eds). 1999.
Malmö: Liber and Copenhagen Business Regulation and Organizations: International
School Press, pp. 15–29. Perspectives. London: Routledge.
March, J.G., 1981. ‘Decisions in organizations Mörth, U. 2004. Soft Law in Governance and
and theories of choice.’ In A. Van de Ven & Regulation. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
W.F. Joyce (eds.), Perspectives of Organi- Mörth, U. 2006. ‘Soft regulation and global
zational Design and Behavior. New York: Wiley, democracy.’ In M.-L. Djelic and K. Sahlin-
pp. 205–244. Andersson, Transnational Governance:
March, J.G., 1999. ‘A learning perspective on Institutional Dynamics of Regulation.
the network dynamics of institutional inte- Cambridge: Cambridge University Press,
gration’ In M. Egeberg and P. Laegreid (eds.), pp.119–135.
Organizing Political Institutions. Oslo: Olson, O., Guthrie, J. & Humphrey, C. (eds).
Scandinavian University Press, pp. 129–155. 1998. Global Warning: Debating Inter-
March, J.G., Schultz, M. & Zhou, X. 2000. The national Developments in New Public
Dynamics of Rules. Stanford: Stanford Financial Management. Oslo: Cappelen
University Press. Akademisk Forlag.
March, J.G., & Olsen, J.P. 1995. Democratic Pallas, J. 2007. ‘Talking organizations.’
Governance. New York: The Free Press. Dissertation manuscript, Dep. of Business
Mazza, C., Sahlin-Andersson K. & Strandgaard studies, Uppsala University.
Pedersen, J. 2005. ‘European constructions Perrow, C. 1991. ‘A society of organizations.’
of an American model: Developments of Theory and Society, 20 (6): 725–762.
four MBA programs’. Management Perrow, C. 2002. Organizing America: Wealth,
Learning, 36(4): 471–491. Power, and the Origins of Corporate Capi-
McNichol, J. & Bensedrine, J. 2003. talism. New Jersey: University Presses of
‘Multilateral rule-making: Transatlantic strug- California, Columbia and Princeton.
gles around genetically modified food’. In Pfeffer, J. & Sutton, R.I. 2006. Hard Facts,
M.-L. Djelic and S. Quack (eds), Globalization Dangerous Half-truths and Total Non-
and Institutions. Cheltenham, UK: Edward sense: Profiting From Evidence-based
Elgar, pp. 220–244. Management. Boston, MA: Harvard Business
Mead, G.H. 1934. Mind, Self and Society. School Press.
Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Pollock, T.G. & Rindova, V.P. 2003. ‘Media legit-
Meyer, J.W. 1994. ‘Rationalized environments.’ imation effects in the market for initial public
In W. R. Scott & J.W. Meyer (eds), offerings.’ Academy of Management
Institutional Environments and Organi- Journal, 46(5): 631–642.
zations: Structural Complexity and Individ- Power, M. 1997. The Audit Society: Rituals
ualism. London: Sage, pp. 28–54, 228–254. of Verification Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Meyer, J.W. 1996. ‘Otherhood: The Power, M. 2003. ‘Evaluating the audit explo-
promulgation and transmission of ideas in sion.’ Law & Policy, 25(3): 115–202.
the modern organizational environment.’ Power, M. 2004. The Risk Management of
In B. Czarniawska & G. Sevón (eds.), Everything. London: Demos.
CIRCULATING IDEAS: IMITATION, TRANSLATION AND EDITING 241

Power, M. 2007. Organized uncertainty: The Politics of Regulation. Cheltenham:


Designing a world of risk management. Edward Elgar, pp. 273–295.
Oxford: Oxford University Press. Schultz, M., Antorini, Y.M. & Csaba, F. (eds).
Ramirez, F. 2006. ‘The rationalization of univer- 2005. Corporate Branding: Towards the
sities’. In M.-L. Djelic and K. Sahlin- Second Wave of Corporate Branding. Copen-
Andersson, Transnational Governance: hagen: Copenhagen Business School Press.
Institutional Dynamics of Regulation. Scott, R. 1995. Institutions and Organizations.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.
pp. 225–244. Scott, R. & Christensen, S. (eds.). 1995. The
Rao, H., Monin, P. & Durand, R. 2003. Institutional Construction of Organizations:
‘Institutional change in Toque Ville: Nouvelle International and Longitudinal Studies.
cuisine as an identity movement in French Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.
gastronomy’. American Journal of Sociology, Sevón, G. 1996. ‘Organizational imitation in
108(4): 795–843. identity transformation.’ In B. Czarniawska
Rogers, E.M. 1983. Diffusion of Innovations. and G. Sevón (eds.), Translating Organi-
New York: Free Press. zational Change. Berlin, New York: Walter de
Rose, N. & Miller, P. 1992. ‘Political power Gruyter, pp. 49–67.
beyond the state: problematics of govern- Shore, C. & Wright, S. 2000. ‘Coercive
ment.’ The British Journal of Sociology, accountability: The rise of audit culture in
43(2): 173–205. higher education.’ In M. Strathern (ed.),
Røvik, K.-A. 1996. ‘Deinstitutionalization and Audit Cultures: Anthropological Studies in
the logic of fashion.’ In B. Czarniawska and Accountability, Ethics and the Academy.
G. Sevón (eds.), Translating Organizational London: Routledge, pp. 57–89.
Change. Berlin, New York: Walter de Solli, R., Demediuk, P. & Sims, R. 2005. ‘The
Gruyter, pp. 139–171. namesake: On best value and other reform-
Røvik, K.-A. 1998. Moderne Organisasjoner: marks.’ In B. Czarniawska & G. Sevón (eds),
Trender I Organisasjonstenkninger Ved Global Ideas: How Ideas, Objects and
Tusenårsskiftet. Norge: Fagbokforlaget. Practices Travel in the Global Economy.
Sahlin-Andersson, K. 1996. ‘Imitating by editing Malmö: Liber and Copenhagen Business
success: The construction of organizational School Press, pp. 30–46.
fields.’ In B. Czarniawska and G. Sevón (eds.), Strang, D. & Meyer, J.W. 1993. ‘Institutional
Translating Organizational Change. Berlin, conditions for diffusion.’ Theory and Society,
New York: Walter de Gruyter, pp. 69–92. 22, pp. 487–511.
Sahlin-Andersson, K. 2000. ‘Arenas as stan- Strathern, M. 2000. Audit Cultures:
dardizers.’ In N. Brunsson & B. Jacobsson Anthropological Studies in Accountability,
(eds), A World of Standards. Oxford: Oxford Ethics and the Academy. London: Routledge.
University Press, pp. 100–113. Tamm Hallström, K. 2004. Organizing Inter-
Sahlin-Andersson, K. 2001. ‘National, interna- national Standardization. Cheltenham:
tional and transnational constructions of Edward Elgar.
new public management.’ In T. Christensen Tarde, G. 1890/1962. The Laws of Imitation.
and P. Laegreid (eds), New Public Manage- New York: Henry Holt.
ment: The Transformation of Ideas and Tarde, G. 1902/1969. ‘Invention.’ In T.N. Clark
Practice. Ashgate: Aldershot, pp. 43–72. (ed.), Gabriel Tarde on Communication and
Sahlin-Andersson, K. & Engwall, L. 2002, The Social Influence. Chicago: University of
Expansion of Management Knowledge. Chicago Press, pp. 149–164.
Carriers, Flows and Sources. Stanford, CA: Tolbert, P. S. & Zucker, L.G. 1983. ‘Institutional
Stanford University Press. sources of change in the formal structure of
Saxenian, A. 1988. ‘The Cheshire cat’s grin: organizations: The diffusion of civil service
Innovation and regional development in reform.’ Administrative Science Quarterly,
England.’ Technology Review, 91(2): 67–75. 28: 22–39.
Schmidt, P. 2004. ‘Law in the age of Townley, B. 2002. ‘The role of competing ratio-
governance: regulation, networks and nalities in institutional change.’ Academy of
lawyers.’ In J. Jordana and D. Levi-Faur (eds), Management Journal 45(1): 163-179.
242 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Vrangbæck, K. 1999. Marknedsorientering I Classifications, diffusion and mediated


Syghussektoren, Diss. Institute of Political isomorphism in organizational fields.’
Science, University of Copenhagen. European Management Review, 4: 24–39.
Weber, M. 1919/1946. Science as a vocation. Westney, E.D. 1987. Imitation and Innovation:
In H.H. Gerth & C. Wright Mills (eds.), From The Transfer of Western Organizational
Max Weber: Essays in Sociology. New York: Patterns to Meiji Japan. Cambridge, MA:
Oxford University Press. Harvard University Press.
Wedlin, L. 2006. Ranking Business Schools: Westphal, J.D., Gulati, R., & Shortell, S.M.
Forming Fields, Identities and Boundaries in 1997. ‘Customization or conformity? An
International Management Education. institutional and network perspective on
Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. the content and consequences of TQM
Wedlin, L. 2007. ‘The role of rankings in adoption.’ Administrative Science Quarterly,
codifying a business school template: 42: 366–394.
9
Organizational Implications of
Institutional Pluralism
Matthew S. Kraatz and Emily S. Block

Hence, social control, so far from tending to crush character of these organizations when he
out the human individual or to obliterate his self- observed that the American university is
conscious individuality, is, on the contrary, actually
‘so many different things to so many different
constitutive of and inextricably associated with
that individuality; for the individual is what he is, as people that it must, of necessity, be partially
a conscious and individual personality, just in so far at war with itself’ (Kerr, 1963: 8). In the uni-
as he is a member of society. versity, as in many other organizations, it is
(Mead, 1934: 255) the broader, heterogeneous institutional
environment that imposes these multiple
Institutional pluralism is the situation identities, makes these disparate demands,
faced by an organization that operates within and thus generates these persistent and
multiple institutional spheres. If institutions deep-rooted tensions within the organization
are broadly understood as ‘the rules of the itself. Because the pluralistic organization
game’ that direct and circumscribe organiza- is a unit of multiple institutional systems,
tional behavior, then the organization con- its internal functioning reflects the
fronting institutional pluralism plays in two contradictions between the larger systems
or more games at the same time. Such an themselves.
organization is subject to multiple regulatory Prior empirical research has uncovered
regimes, embedded within multiple norma- numerous instances of organizations facing
tive orders, and/or constituted by more than institutional environments which appear to
one cultural logic. It is a participant in multi- exert pluralistic demands. These include
ple discourses and/or a member of more than hospitals (D’Aunno, Succi & Alexander,
one institutional category. It thus possesses 2000; Denis, Lamothe & Langley, 2001),
multiple, institutionally-derived identities neo-natal intensive care units (Heimer,
which are conferred upon it by different seg- 1999), rape crisis centers (Zilber, 2002), drug
ments of its pluralistic environment. treatment centers (D’Aunno, Sutton & Price,
An ideal-typical example of such an organi- 1991), non-profit and public organizations
zation is the American research university. (Brunsson, 1989; Dutton & Dukerich, 1991;
Clark Kerr well-captured the pluralistic Stone & Brush, 1996), universities (Albert &
244 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Whetten, 1985; Cohen & March, 1986), Salancik, 1978) and more strategic variants
public schools (Rowan, 1982), public broad- of institutional theory (Oliver, 1991;
casters (Powell, 1988), arts organizations Suchman, 1995; Zajac & Westphal, 1995)
(Mouritsen & Skaerbaek, 1995; Alexander, seem to present us with. However, it becomes
1996), Taiwanese computer firms (Hung & considerably more challenging to think
Whittington, 1997), multi-national firms about institutional pluralism when we see
(Kostova & Zaheer, 1999) and small busi- institutional effects as constitutive and
nesses (Pickle & Friedlander, 1967). Much ideational; as suffusing the organization
recent research in stakeholder theory, rather than merely impinging upon it.
which has increasingly drawn from neo- Nonetheless, we believe that some critical
institutionalism, also emphasizes that corpo- insights and images begin to emerge when
rations, in general, are properly viewed as we embrace pluralism and cognitive institu-
pluralistic entities (Donaldson & Preston, tionalism conjointly. Specifically, we are
1995; Mitchell, Agle & Wood, 1997). able to see an organization that may have
However, despite this common awareness of multiple institutionally-given identities, an
the existence of institutional pluralism, there organization that may be the structural
has to date been little apparent effort to sys- embodiment or incarnation of multiple
tematically assess its practical and theoretical logics, an organization that may be
implications. What are the characteristic legitimated by multiple mythologies, and an
challenges and opportunities faced by organ- organization wherein very different beliefs
izations that operate in pluralistic environ- and values might be simultaneously taken for
ments? How do organizations typically adapt granted. In short, we see an organization that
to these challenges and opportunities may genuinely be, like Kerr’s university,
(structurally, politically, symbolically, ‘multiple things to multiple people.’
rhetorically)? What broader and more gen- We are interested in understanding how
eral lessons might researchers take away this is possible. We are also interested in
from the methodical and sustained analysis elaborating pluralism’s positive and negative
of organizations that dwell in pluralism’s consequences for the organization, and in
midst? These are the broad questions that we identifying the factors that tip the balance
set out to address in this chapter. between them. Clearly, pluralism creates the
We are especially concerned with potential for fragmentation, incoherence,
understanding the theoretical and practical conflict, goal-ambiguity, and organizational
implications of what might be called cogni- instability (Heimer, 1999; Stryker, 2000). In
tive, or constitutive, pluralism. The hallmark an organization with multiple identities, pur-
of the neo-institutional perspective is its poses, and belief systems, no group is likely
focus on cognitive institutions that constitute to be fully satisfied, and political tensions are
actors, define social realities and thus shape likely to be endemic. Such organizations may
organizational behavior in subtle but power- even resemble the ‘organized anarchies’ or
ful ways (DiMaggio & Powell, 1991; ‘garbage-cans’ that March and colleagues
Friedland & Alford, 1991; Scott, 2001). This vividly described (Cohen & March, 1986;
perspective on institutions may, at first March & Olsen, 1976). However, we think
glance, appear to be incommensurable with that institutional pluralism may create impor-
the very notion of pluralism. It is relatively tant opportunities for organizations as well.
straightforward to envision a pluralistic insti- We will suggest that institutionally-adept
tutional environment if we see institutions as organizations are often able to simultane-
exogenous forces that exert competing ously meet the expectations imposed by var-
coercive or normative demands on the organ- ious institutional spheres in which they
ization. Indeed, this is the very picture that operate. Indeed, we see the ability to at least
resource dependence theory (Pfeffer & placate diverse external constituent groups as
ORGANIZATIONAL IMPLICATIONS OF INSTITUTIONAL PLURALISM 245

a minimum requirement for bare survival in But, we also believe that baseline levels
the face of pluralism. More importantly, we of pluralism are higher than commonly
also think that significant complementarities thought in many other settings. Thus,
often exist between institutionally given we hope that the chapter’s insights will apply
identities, such that the organization’s ability well beyond the contexts from which they
to successfully be one thing actually primarily emanate.
enhances its ability to be others. Thus, The perspective that we develop on organ-
we try to show how the same institutional ization–environment relationships in plural-
pressures that threaten to divide the organiza- istic contexts draws from several key
tion may, at least in some circum- sources. The first of these is James March’s
stances, hold it together instead. We focus institutionalism (e.g. March, 1994, 1999;
much of our attention on the search for these March & Olsen, 1995, 2004). His work con-
circumstances. verges with other neo-institutionalist thought
We organize the chapter around a discus- in seeing institutions as basically constitutive
sion of three important organizational prob- of actors and their actions. Specifically, he
lems that have been the focus of much prior suggests that much organizational decision
organizational research. These are the prob- making results from an obligatory ‘logic of
lems of organizational legitimacy, organiza- appropriateness’ rather than a calculative
tional governance, and organizational ‘logic of consequence.’ Actors following a
change. We will suggest that conventional logic of appropriateness obey institutional
neo-institutional explanations of these three rules and strive, often preconsciously, to ful-
critical organizational phenomena become fill the obligations that are inherent in their
rather problematic when we attempt to apply institutionally given identities.1 But March
them to organizations operating in pluralistic also stresses that actors possess multiple
contexts. More specifically, we will show identities as a direct result of their multiple
that these standard accounts remain neces- institutional memberships. His theory is thus
sary, but are no longer sufficient in and of (at least implicitly) a pluralistic one.
themselves. In a pluralistic environment, Our perspective is similarly influenced by
organizational legitimacy requires symbolic sociological theories of identity that have
conformity with cultural norms and expecta- emerged within the symbolic interactionist
tions, but also something more and different tradition (e.g., McCall & Simmons, 1978;
than this. In a pluralistic environment, orga- Stryker, 1980, 1987; Stryker & Burke, 2000;
nizational governance is influenced by Stryker & Serpe, 1982). These theories offer
cultural logics that operate at the field level, explanations that are strikingly similar to
but is in no sense determined by these logics. March’s, despite their typical focus on per-
In a pluralistic environment, organizational sonal, rather than organizational, identity.
change is also compelled and constrained by They also offer additional concepts that have
field-level institutions. But, these institutions been usefully applied at the organizational
combine with one another to yield variations, level (Pratt and Foreman, 2000). Stryker,
unintended consequences, and myriad oppor- Burke and other identity theorists parallel
tunities for organizational action and contin- March in arguing that actors are multiply
uous change. In developing our arguments, constituted, receiving their various identities
we will draw heavily on examples from from different segments of the pluralistic
American colleges and universities, but we society they inhabit. However, they augment
will also produce examples from numerous March’s perspective by giving explicit atten-
other contexts. We believe that institutional tion to processes of identity verification.
pluralism is a variable feature of organiza- They suggest that actors seek to validate or
tional environments, and one that is particu- affirm their identities through processes of
larly prominent in American higher education. symbolic exchange with different segments
246 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

of their heterogeneous environments. It is their own, and which integrate and transcend
through these processes that the actor’s their various socially-given identities.
various identities are legitimated (and Interestingly, he also argues that constituent
de-legitimated) over time. Sociological iden- demands play a key role in facilitating this
tity theorists also provide a useful frame for quasi-integrative process (despite their inher-
understanding intra-organizational identity ently divisive potentialities). Specifically,
conflicts, and for conceptualizing the Selznick emphasizes that these groups value
processes through which multiple institu- cross-temporal consistency and revealed
tionally-derived identities may be prioritized commitment, in addition to the conformity
or integrated within the organization as a which is more typically emphasized in neo-
whole. Specifically, they invoke Mead (1934) institutional accounts. Constituencies plainly
in drawing a critical distinction between the want the organization to symbolize its com-
notion of identity and that of self. They mitments to their particular beliefs and to ful-
conceptualize the self as the whole entity fill their material needs. But Selznick
which encompasses an actor’s various emphasizes that they want it to be self-
socially-given identities. As we will show, consistent, trustworthy and non-opportunis-
this distinction may be especially useful for tic, as well (i.e. to evince what he called
understanding governance amid pluralism. In ‘organizational integrity’). We will suggest
particular, we will argue that organizational that it is this preference which makes possi-
governance can be usefully thought of as the ble the emergence of the autonomous (and
process through which an ‘organizational distinctively competent) organizational self
self’ selects, prioritizes and/or integrates its which Selznick first theorized.
various institutionally-given identities (and Before we progress to our consideration of
also as the process through which these the specific problems of organizational legit-
identities conjointly construct an organiza- imacy, governance and change, we think that
tional self). it may be useful to further clarify our chap-
Finally, our perspective on the organiza- ter’s purposes and to comment upon its
tional challenges and opportunities created intended relationship to the extant literature.
by pluralism also relies heavily on Philip Most importantly, we wish to emphasize that
Selznick’s institutionalism (Selznick, 1949, our intent is fundamentally generative, rather
1957, 1969, 1992, 1996). Like March and than critical. Though we do identify several
the sociological identity theorists, Selznick apparent limitations of neo-institutional
sees the individual organization’s environ- accounts, we do this with an eye toward
ment as politically and ideologically hetero- promoting future research and theory on the
geneous. His early research on the Tennessee organizational implications of institutional
Valley Authority vividly reveals the destruc- pluralism (rather than to cast aspersions).
tive effects that this heterogeneity can have Second, we wish to stress that our efforts at
inside the organization (Selznick, 1949). theorizing are admittedly partial and largely
However, he also provides important insights derivative. We think that the recognition of
about how organizations can thrive and institutional pluralism points toward a major
prosper in the midst of institutional plural- void in our collective understanding of the
ism, both despite and because of it (Selznick, relationship between organizations and
1957, 1969, 1992). Most critical among institutions. The theory that we put forth here
these insights is his argument that some may constitute little more than a drop in very
organizations can become institutions in large bucket – and not an especially novel one
their own right, as they harness the otherwise at that. Virtually all of the ideas we develop
discordant forces in their pluralistic milieu. herein are appropriated from somewhere
Selznick argues that such organizations are else (although our reapplication of them
able to forge identities which are uniquely may constitute something of a contribution).
ORGANIZATIONAL IMPLICATIONS OF INSTITUTIONAL PLURALISM 247

Finally, we would like to re-emphasize that From a neo-institutional perspective, legiti-


our chapter assumes an avowedly organiza- macy primarily involves symbolic conform-
tion-centric perspective (as its very title ity with cultural prescriptions and
indicates). It is written in the tradition of understandings (Deephouse, 1999; Meyer &
Barnard, Selznick, March and Simon, Rowan, 1977; Ruef & Scott, 1998). The per-
Thompson and others who viewed the indi- spective holds that organizations tend to
vidual organization as a proper end of study adopt various practices and structures in
in its own right. It diverges (at the outset) order to create and maintain this conformity.
from more recent scholarship that takes a Importantly, it sees legitimacy as a source of
core interest in field-level dynamics and action as well as the product of it (Edelman,
overarching institutional systems. Thus, to 1992; Oliver, 1991; Suchman, 1995).
the extent that our chapter does criticize neo- An organization’s institutionally-given
institutionalism, it questions the perspec- identities create behavioral mandates, and its
tive’s value as a means to ends that are actions can be understood as conscious
not necessarily its own. It also proposes or unconscious efforts to fulfill these man-
new ends toward which the theory’s core dates. This notion of legitimacy as taken-
insights might be productively re-applied. for-grantedness parallels March’s logic of
Specifically, our chapter pushes toward the appropriateness.
creation of an ‘institutional organizational- While we believe that this perspective
ism’ which is quite distinct from (but poten- provides a necessary and appropriate starting
tially symbiotic with) the ‘organizational point for understanding organizational legiti-
institutionalism’ which is the primary focus macy, we encounter at least three important
of this volume. We hope that the outlines of problems when we attempt to apply it to
this perspective – and the basic need for organizations in pluralistic contexts. The first
it – will become apparent in the following and least troubling of these is that the plural-
pages. istic organization is compelled to symbolize
its commitment to the norms, values, and
beliefs of multiple social systems. Thus, if
taken-for-granted assumptions are to drive its
INSTITUTIONAL PLURALISM actions, they can only do so after a specific
AND THE PROBLEM OF institutional identity has been invoked
ORGANIZATIONAL LEGITIMACY (Heimer, 1999). The organization must first
be able to answer March’s troublesome ques-
A natural place to begin our discussion of tion of, ‘who are we?’ before the appropriate
institutional pluralism’s theoretical and prac- institutional rules or scripts can be activated.
tical implications is with the problem of Further, if the organization tries to deliber-
organizational legitimacy. Organizational ately pursue legitimacy through strategic
scholars have long viewed legitimacy as a conformity, it can only do so by conform-
critical resource for organizations (Parsons, ing to multiple sets of institutional rules
1956; Pfeffer & Dowling, 1975), and this and successfully embodying multiple cate-
focus has intensified with the rise of the neo- gorical standards. Given these complex-
institutional perspective (DiMaggio & ities, it may sometimes be appropriate
Powell, 1983; Meyer & Rowan, 1977; to think of the legitimacy of the ‘whole’
Tolbert & Zucker, 1983). Suchman (1995: organization as the mere sum of the legiti-
574) has defined legitimacy as a ‘generalized macy of its individual ‘parts.’ In other words,
perception or assumption that the actions of inasmuch as the pluralistic organization
an entity are desirable, proper, or appropri- enjoys social approval and acceptance, this
ate, within some socially constructed system may be the cumulative result of its
of norms, values, beliefs, and definitions.’ successful performance within its disparate
248 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

role identities. Clark Kerr is also reported to actual nature of organizational legitimacy
have quipped that his job as the University of (Heimer, 1999; Stryker, 2000). Taken-
California’s Chancellor was to provide for-granted beliefs and assumptions obvi-
parking for faculty, football for alumni, and ously affect these organizational decisions
sex for undergraduates. While it is doubtful and influence external responses to them.
that this comment reflected Kerr’s true But, taken-for-grantedness is clearly not
thinking about his role or his university, it sufficient as an explanation for these actions
well-reflects an additive, ‘part-focused’ view or the reactions they engender.
of organizational legitimacy. A final problem with the neo-institutional
A second and more difficult problem in account of organizational legitimacy is that
applying the conventional account of organizations are typically expected not only
legitimacy is that pluralistic organizations to symbolize their agreement with prevailing
may not be able to compartmentalize or beliefs and to act in a culturally appropriate
separate their different institutional identities manner, but also to evince cross-temporal
from one another. The organization’s consistency in their words and deeds. While
attempts to comply with the demands of one the organization may indeed be a prisoner of
constituency are likely to be observed by a cultural ‘iron cage’ (DiMaggio & Powell,
others, who may assign very different subjec- 1983), it is also held ‘hostage to [its] own
tive values to the same displayed symbols history’ (Selznick, 1992: 232). In its search
(Glynn, 2000; Golden-Biddle & Rao, 1997; for legitimacy, it thus faces a ‘commitment
Stryker, 2000). In the language of the problem’ in addition to the ‘conformity prob-
symbolic interactionists, organizational lem’ which has been our exclusive focus thus
efforts to verify or validate one identity may far. Early institutional theorists, including
invalidate another one (Pratt & Foreman, Commons (1970) and Selznick (1957) well-
2000; Stryker & Burke, 2000). Further, recognized this problem and argued that dis-
various internal groups with different consti- plays of commitment were critical in
tutive beliefs and disparate notions of ‘appro- building and maintaining institutions
priate’ behavior are likely to come (Stinchcombe, 1997). They similarly empha-
face-to-face in decision situations, sized the de-legitimating effects of actions
particularly strategic ones (Glynn, 2000). For which violate commitments or otherwise
example, hospitals routinely face decisions convey opportunism. This concern with
wherein their institutionally conferred identi- ‘credible commitment’ abides in contempo-
ties as professional actors and market actors rary perspectives which see organizations
are both active. In such situations, the primarily as solutions to collective
organization’s efforts to fulfill its fiduciary action problems (Britton & Nee, 1998;
duties are likely to engender resistance and Ingram & Clay, 2000; Olson, 1965). Neo-
criticism from internal and external institutionalism, in contrast, says very little
constituencies who identify with the organi- about how consistency and revealed commit-
zation as a professional entity and expect it to ment (or lack thereof) might affect organiza-
act primarily within this role. Analogously, tional legitimacy over time. Neo-institutional
financial constituencies also regularly accounts often do an excellent job of situat-
criticize corporations when they embrace ing the organization within its broader
social responsibilities that appear to fall cultural context, but they typically extract it
outside of their narrow role as profit-making from its own unique history of actions and
entities (cf. Friedman, 1970). In situations transactions in so doing.
like these, organizational actions appear to be This omission is perhaps understandable,
co-produced by multiple identities and/or as the commitment problem would appear to
co-evaluated by multiple audiences. Such mostly vanish in situations where the organi-
situations raise important questions about the zation and its constituencies are jointly and
ORGANIZATIONAL IMPLICATIONS OF INSTITUTIONAL PLURALISM 249

wholly nested within a stable and culturally smelled of opportunism and thus reflected
homogenous field which is replete with negatively upon the ‘whole’ social actors
shared understandings and common scripts. who employed it.
However, the problem appears to re-emerge This counterintuitive finding and interpre-
quite dramatically in the presence of institu- tation calls to mind Groucho Marx’s famous
tional pluralism. When an organization is comment that he would never join a club that
situated in a pluralistic context, its internal would have him as a member (presumably
and external constituencies are likely to because of the second-order signal that his
recognize its capacity to abruptly change inclusion would send about the character of
direction and reprioritize its identities and the club as a whole). More seriously, it also
values. They can thus be expected to trust it coheres with a great deal of contemporary
only with hesitation, and to be particularly research on the psychology of legitimacy,
concerned with gauging its predictability and which has consistently shown that legitimacy
reliability. As a result, they may be especially judgments rest primarily upon perceived pro-
likely to employ what we will call ‘second cedural fairness (a second-order criteria)
order’ evaluative criteria in assessing its rather than distributive fairness (a first-order
legitimacy. While they may react positively one) (Tyler, 1990: 2002). It is also consistent
when the organization symbolizes its agree- with a vast body of research in other
ment with their values and accommodates branches of the social sciences which has
their near-term interests (these being ‘first revealed the powerful, emotional and evi-
order’ criteria), they are also prone to look dently pre-conscious responses that displays
for evidence of commitment, trustworthi- of commitment (and opportunism) can
ness, and non-arbitrariness (second order invoke (Frank, 1988; Hauser, 2006; Nesse,
criteria) in the stream of decisions emanating 2001). The upshot is that the organization
from the organization over time.2 seeking legitimacy in a pluralistic context is
Further, and ironically, some first-order likely to face what we will call the politi-
actions may send unintended second-order cian’s dilemma, a conundrum which results
signals, such that constituents come to think from the interplay of the conformity and
less of the organization as a direct result of its commitment problems. Constituents
efforts to please them. Love and Kraatz obviously want the organization (and the
(2007) provide a rather striking example of candidate) to espouse their values and to
this phenomenon. They show that large pursue policies that further their particular
American corporations’ reputations were interests. But, they are also attracted to
badly damaged by their use of the practice of revealed commitment and integrity, and
downsizing during the 1980s and 1990s. The repulsed by obviously opportunistic
irony in this finding is that the reputations and arbitrary acts. In other words, they are
they studied were ascribed by stock analysts inclined to pass judgment not only upon the
(who strongly advocated downsizing and legitimacy of organizational identities, but
publicly praised downsizing firms) and by also upon the legitimacy of (what at least
peer firm executives (most of whom revealed appear to be) organizational selves. They
their approval of the practice by engaging in evaluate the organization not only as a part of
it themselves). Love and Kraatz suggest that some socially constructed system of mean-
downsizing’s negative effect on reputation ings and rules, but also as a social actor
occurred because of the negative signals that (which is what its divided social context
it conveyed regarding the trustworthiness and appears to make it into).3
credibility (i.e. the ‘character’) of these We see at least four basic ways in which
firms. Downsizing was an attractive and organizations may adapt to pluralistic legiti-
highly legitimate ‘part’ from the perspective macy criteria. The most obvious effect of
of analysts and peer executives, but it also inconsistent expectations is to engender
250 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

resistance and conflict in and around the often viewed as being decoupled from the
organization. In other words, many organiza- core of the organization, or as merely
tions adapt to pluralism by trying to elimi- symbolic, rather than substantive in nature
nate pluralism. The organization’s leaders (Lounsbury, 1999; Meyer & Rowan, 1977;
may, for instance, deny the validity of vari- Westphal & Zajac, 1994, 1998). While such
ous external claims that are placed upon it, characterizations are sometimes apt, we
attack the legitimacy of the entities making think there may be a need for caution in
the claims, attempt to co-opt or control these drawing these conclusions in pluralistic
entities, and/or try to escape their jurisdiction organizations. We do not see how one can
or influence altogether (Oliver, 1991; Pfeffer invoke the concept of decoupling without
& Salancik, 1978; Suchman, 1995). They presuming to know the organizational ‘core’
may, in short, attempt to ‘delete’ or marginal- from which a thing is decoupled. It seems
ize some of the institutional identities and likewise problematic to describe something
attendant obligations that constituencies seek as merely symbolic unless we know where
to impose upon their organization (Pratt & true substance resides. As we have already
Foreman, 2000). A similar dynamic may play seen, this is a difficult trick in the pluralistic
out among internal constituencies, irrespec- organization, with its multiple cores, diverse
tive of managerial influence. Groups that identities, varied substances, and complex
identify with the organization for one reason symbolisms. Practices that are highly periph-
and advocate a particular organizational eral and inconsequential to the identity of
ideology may try to banish or permanently one constituency may be all-important to the
suppress other groups and belief systems identity and values of a different one.
(Selznick, 1949). They may, in fact, succeed Intercollegiate athletics in American
in this task, effectively shedding identities higher education seem to provide a
and eliminating some of the pluralistic compelling example along these lines. It is
demands that initially gave rise to the con- quite difficult to grasp the importance (per-
flict. We shall discuss these possibilities in haps even the existence) of ‘big time’
more detail in the subsequent section, as we college sports when we view the university
explore pluralism’s implications for organi- as an organizational device for accomplish-
zational governance. For now, we will only ing its stated goals of knowledge creation
note that while no organization can be all and dissemination. Excellence in quasi-
things to all people, efforts to completely professional athletic endeavors is not men-
eliminate, silence, or marginalize constituen- tioned in the mission statement of any
cies may prove self-defeating in the long run. university that we know of, and athletic
We suspect that the effective management of departments often seem to be formally cut
pluralism may be a critical organizational off from the rest of the university’s structure.
(and managerial) capability. Its relative Nonetheless, athletics are, empirically
scarcity may be one reason why most speaking, a central part of most American
organizations do not survive very long. universities’ identities. For better or worse,
A second approach to adapting to pluralis- the majority of people who identify with
tic legitimacy standards is to ‘compartmen- universities at all, identify with them through
talize’ identities and relate independently to their sports teams. Further, these identifica-
various institutional constituencies (Pratt & tions are often intense ones that have major
Foreman, 2000). The organization may do implications for university policy and
this by sequentially attending to different resource allocations. And, while it may be
institutional claims, and/or by creating sepa- quite easy for many faculty members to
rate units and initiatives that demonstrate its imagine a university without football, it is
commitment to the values and beliefs of likely the single most taken-for-granted part
particular constituencies. Such initiatives are of the organization from the perspective of
ORGANIZATIONAL IMPLICATIONS OF INSTITUTIONAL PLURALISM 251

other influential constituencies. (One some- its mutual dependence upon another. This
times wonders if society at large would even may partially describe the relationship that
permit our universities to exist without it.) In many athletic departments have with the uni-
sum, while college sports may be entirely versities that house them. Some athletics
beside the point from an academic perspec- departments seemingly tolerate academic
tive, we do not think they can be accurately standards without embracing them, and
classified as peripheral or decoupled. Loose many faculties appear to feel similarly with
coupling would seem to be a more suitable respect to sports (i.e. to view them as a nec-
concept to describe the evident reality of the essary evil). The same general sort of rela-
situation, as this concept does not stipulate tionship sometimes seems to exist between
the existence of a single organizational core the research and teaching identities within
(Orton & Weick, 1990; Weick, 1976). business schools. The line separating situa-
The example of intercollegiate athletics is tions of reluctant mutual acceptance from
also useful in demonstrating the limitations those of true cooperation is not an especially
of loose coupling as an adaptation to plural- bright one. We can certainly find specific
ism. Because athletic and academic purposes examples of situations wherein athletics and
are often almost entirely incommensurate academics (or teaching and research) are
with one another, the operative goals pursued mutually facilitative. Some corporations also
by athletic and academic constituencies are seem able to find true complementarities
frequently at odds. Because athletic depart- between their social responsibilities and their
ments are often structurally and financially duties to their shareholders (Hillman
autonomous, they are also prone to make & Keim, 2001). Nevertheless, tensions abide.
decisions that offend academic sensibilities Relationships that are cooperative in their
and interests (e.g. massive investments in effect may remain quite conflictual in their
athletic facilities and multi-million dollar process (and vice versa). Balances that are
coaching salaries). Finally, because academic struck among various objectives, constituen-
and athletic cultures are so vastly different cies, and role identities are often precarious
(and sometimes hostile to one another), fac- (Clark, 1956; Selznick, 1951).
ulty and administrators are often reluctant to This leads us to the final form of organiza-
engage athletic issues directly. This reluc- tional adaptation which pluralistic legitimacy
tance perpetuates and exacerbates existing imperatives may produce. Specifically, it is
rifts (Bowen & Levin, 2003; Shulman & possible that some organizations may be able
Bowen, 2001; Duderstadt, 2000; Zimbalist, to forge durable identities of their own and to
1999). emerge as institutions in their own right. To
A third category of adaptations to plural- the extent that this occurs, many of the orga-
ism aims at reining in such tensions. nizational legitimacy problems mentioned
Specifically, organizations may also try to above may be mitigated, transformed, or
balance disparate demands, play constituen- even eliminated. An organization that
cies against one another, and/or attempt to becomes an institution may assume a ‘social
find more deeply cooperative solutions to the fact’ status, become a valued end in its own
political and cultural tensions which plural- right, and thus become capable of legitimat-
ism creates (Donaldson & Preston, 1995; ing its own actions, within limits (Goodstein,
Oliver, 1991; Pratt & Foreman, 2000). Blair-Loy & Wharton, 2006). It may become
As with loose coupling, these adaptations a self-directing entity which is not only a cul-
may result from strategic managerial action tural product, but also a producer of culture
or emerge more naturally from the interac- (Pedersen & Dobbin, 2006). In the language
tions of constituent groups. A degree of of relational sociology, it may attain ‘entita-
internal balance may evolve, for instance, as tivity’ (Campbell, 1958; Emirbayer, 1997)
one constituency grudgingly acknowledges and become a ‘thing with consequences’ or a
252 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

‘site of causation’ (Abbott, 1996: 873; institutionalization which we will discuss


Emirbayer, 1997: 304; White, 1992). It may below). However, Selznick’s would-be
also obtain the ability to integrate or some- institution appears to gain much in return for
how transcend the individual identities which essentially giving itself up. What must be
compose it, and which are imposed upon it recognized, we believe, is: (a) that it makes
from without (Padgett & Ansell, 1993; multiple binding commitments; and (b) that
Padgett, 2001). these commitments are profoundly symbolic,
Selznick (1957) provides one important as well as material. While no organization
account of how this might occur within the can realistically be all things to all people at
pluralistic organization. As we have noted, he all times, this may be precisely the point.
is keenly aware of the problem of pluralism, Because the Selznickian institution makes
and he sees institutionalization as a dynamic itself the receptacle for the ideals of multiple
and natural response to the ‘anxiety-laden groups and a vehicle for the realization of
problems’ (1957: 39) which pluralism multiple identities and purposes, it acquires
creates. In his view, the end result of institu- (of necessity) the capacity to reprioritize and
tionalization is the emergence of an reinterpret ‘its’ identities, ideals, and
autonomous and unique ‘organizational self’ purposes as circumstances dictate. It also
(1957: 21). This self possesses its own pur- acquires the moral authority (i.e. the legiti-
poses and distinctive competencies, and it is macy) to make reciprocal claims upon con-
valued as an end in its own right, rather than stituent identity groups. It makes these
a mere means for achieving pre-existing or claims on behalf of the organizational whole
externally-given ends. Importantly though, (i.e. self) which is, somewhat miraculously,
Selznick does not see institutionalization as a conjured into existence as a result of the
process that somehow extracts the organiza- binding, constitutional commitments that the
tion from its constraining external context, or organization makes to its various parts. In
as one that negates the local identities and other words, by agreeing unconditionally to
parochial aims of its constituencies. To the be both ‘this and that,’ the organization may
contrary, he paradoxically argues that the somehow become ‘the other,’ as well.
organization’s acceptance of ‘irreversible Because its diverse constituents perceive the
commitments’ is the very cornerstone of institution to be ‘theirs’ in some fundamental
institutionalization. He likewise sees institu- sense, they come to value it as an end in itself
tionalization as a largely bottom-up (or and thus imbue it with purpose and meaning.
outside-in) phenomenon. The Selznickian We think it is important to emphasize the
organizational institution is ‘infused critical role of symbolism in this hypothe-
with value’ by its constituents and it is sized process. If constituencies were sharply
institutionalized only in so much as it and solely focused upon the tangible outputs
becomes the vehicle through which these and near-term objectives of the organization,
groups pursue their aspirations and creating and sustaining cooperation amid
their ideals. While it develops a logic pluralism might well be impossible.
of its own and attains the ability to give However, people’s tolerance of (or even
identity to its members, it accepts identities preference for) symbolic displays of commit-
and logics from them in at least equal ment and conformity may help things hold
measure. together. Symbolism, in short, may be what
Accepting binding commitments and allows an organization to be multiple things
effectively surrendering to one’s constituents to multiple people (Ansell, 1997; Padgett &
would not appear at first glance to be a prob- Ansell, 1993; Zajac & Westphal, 2004). It
able path to autonomy, distinctiveness, and may enable the creation of a ‘coalition of
organizational selfhood (much less identities’ that is more robust and more sus-
adaptability, another presumed benefit of tainable than a mere coalition of interests
ORGANIZATIONAL IMPLICATIONS OF INSTITUTIONAL PLURALISM 253

could realistically be. It is also important to governance takes place outside the bound-
note, again, that ‘mere’ symbolism is not suf- aries of individual organizations (Fligstein,
ficient according to Selznick’s account. 1991; Friedland & Alford, 1991; Scott, Ruef,
While robust symbols can evoke powerful Mendel & Carona, 2000; Thornton &
meanings and provide the institution with Ocasio, 1999). Governance, from a neo-
needed autonomy, its commitments must be institutional perspective, is largely (not
‘embodied’ and acted out if they are to exclusively) a field-level phenomenon.
engender the reciprocal commitment A now vast body of research has shown that
necessary to sustain the institution over time the state, the professions, and other field-
(Stinchcombe, 1997). In other words, level entities profoundly influence the
second-order legitimacy criteria continue control structures, practices, and even basic
to be critical. Obvious disconnects between purposes of individual organizations
rhetoric and subsequent actions are the very (see Scott 2001 for a review). Second, the
antithesis of organizational integrity, and perspective emphasizes that much
can be expected to damage legitimacy governance work (perhaps most of it) is
accordingly.4 actually done by cultural or cognitive mech-
anisms, rather than the coercive, interest-
based, or value-based ones featured in other
institutionalisms (DiMaggio & Powell,
INSTITUTIONAL PLURALISM AND 1991). Shared beliefs and understandings are
THE PROBLEM OF ORGANIZATIONAL thought to effectively determine much of
GOVERNANCE what goes on in organizations from day to
day, and even to deeply influence fundamen-
We are also interested in understanding plu- tal decisions about the organization’s control,
ralism’s implications for organizational gov- identity, and reason for being (Friedland &
ernance. Governance, broadly conceived, has Alford, 1991; Greenwood & Hinings, 1993;
to do with questions of organizational Hinings, Greenwood, Reay & Suddaby,
purpose and control (Hansmann, 1996; 2004; Thornton & Ocasio, 1999).
March & Olsen, 1995; Selznick, 1992; Neo-institutional insights regarding orga-
Williamson, 1996). Studies of governance nizational governance have manifested them-
are thus generally concerned with identifying selves in a variety of ways. One influential
‘who rules’ organizations, with understand- strand of empirical research has demon-
ing the ends toward which they are ruled, and strated that organizational purposes and con-
with analyzing the means (e.g. incentives, trol structures are transformed over time as
structures, informal norms) employed the result of broader, historical shifts in insti-
to achieve those ends. Questions about the tutional logics (Dobbin, 1994; Fligstein,
processes through which control and purpose 1991; Lounsbury, 1999; Scott et al., 2000;
are decided and changed over time are also Thornton and Ocasio, 1999). A second group
integral to the study of organizational of studies has emphasized the essentially
governance. cultural nature of organizational forms.
Given that institutions are, among many This work invites us to see organizational
other things, mechanisms of governance, it is forms as the embodiments or incarnations of
not surprising that institutional theories of all institutional logics, and argues that cultural
types have been widely applied in the effort understandings imprinted in organizational
to explain governance phenomena. The main forms at the time of founding continue to
message of neo-institutionalism as regards constrain organizations throughout their lives
organizational governance appears to be (Dobbin & Dowd, 1997; Haveman & Rao,
twofold. First, and most basically, the theory 1997; Rao, 1998; Rao, Monon & Durand,
draws attention to the fact that a great deal of 2003; Schneiberg & Bartley, 2001). A third
254 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

manifestation is evident in neo-institutional If multiple logics are active in and around


studies of organizations’ legal environments. an organization, then no single belief
This research suggests that laws are often system can automatically perpetuate its
‘endogenous’ to organizational fields, and dominance. If various constituencies hold
raises doubts about coercive or functionalist different notions about the ‘appropriate’
explanations of the law’s effect on organiza- allocation of power, then something else
tions. Rather, it presents legal compliance as besides a simple logic of appropriateness
a ‘special case of institutional isomorphism,’ would seem to ultimately determine who
and suggests that laws typically govern rules the organization. If the organization
organizations through mechanisms that are claims multiple, institutionally defined
primarily cultural and constitutive (Edelman, identities and purposes, it would seem that
1990, 2002; Edelman and Suchman, 1997; its governance must (at least minimally)
Kelly & Dobbin, 1998; Sutton & Dobbin, accommodate and validate these disparate
1996). Finally, the neo-institutional perspec- identities and purposes. In short, it appears
tive on governance is also much evident in a that the recognition of pluralism leads to
growing number of studies which examine the re-emergence of some basic political
how social movements both create and trans- and structural problems that appeared to
form field-level institutions. This research fade from significance with the rise of neo-
suggests that new cultural frames and institutionalism.
governing logics wrought by social We do not think that an organization which
movements are instrumental in creating, is simultaneously embedded in multiple sys-
transforming, and/or extinguishing individ- tems of governance can be adequately under-
ual organizations and organizational stood as a unit of any one of those systems. It
forms (Davis & Thompson, 1994; Davis, is, at the least, a functioning part of each
McAdam, Scott & Zald, 2005; McAdam respective system. It is at most a system quite
& Scott, 2005; Rao, Morill & Zald, 2000; unto itself, as the preceding section showed.
Zald, Morill & Rao, 2005; see also In either case, much governance activity
Schneiberg & Lounsbury, Chapter 27 this clearly goes on within the pluralistic organi-
volume). This view of organizational zation. It is responsible for internally settling
governance represents a major break from issues that are unsettled within the broader
earlier theories that tended to see the organi- environment. Further, because it possesses
zation as an unstable coalition of local inter- multiple objectives and diverse constituen-
ests, with goals and internal power balances cies, its overall purposes are subject
that are primarily determined by shifting to change (perhaps extreme change) over
resource dependencies in the task environ- time. Cognitive mechanisms would also
ment (Cyert & March, 1963; March appear to be insufficient as explanations for
& Simon, 1958; Pfeffer & Salancik, 1978). the control of such an organization. When
The elaboration of field-level governance one set of taken–for-granted beliefs con-
processes represents a major accomplish- fronts an alternative one, ‘legitimacy
ment of neo-institutionalism. Its demonstra- politics’ (Stryker, 2000) are likely to ensue
tion of the importance of cultural and within the organization. Organizational
cognitive governance mechanisms is equally structures and rules seem necessary in order
impressive. Even institutional economists are to contain and channel these processes. This
now inclined to recognize the importance of need seems particularly acute within those
such mechanisms (North, 1990). However, organizations that sit upon cultural and
the reality of institutional pluralism appears societal fault lines, as inter-identity tensions
to render neo-institutionalism incomplete as are likely to be very deep-rooted and
an explanation for organizational governance, recurrent in such settings. The control of
as well as for organizational legitimacy. such organizations is likely to ‘circulate’
ORGANIZATIONAL IMPLICATIONS OF INSTITUTIONAL PLURALISM 255

between identity groups over time as a result mere result of their divergent beliefs, values,
of political processes (Ocasio, 1994; Ocasio and near-term objectives. But, in the ideal
& Kim, 1999). Persons who can credibly circumstance, the substance of intergroup
claim membership within more than one conflict may shift away from narrow
group may enjoy particular advantages in questions about what the organization should
these perennial internal contests for control do or provide, and toward larger (i.e. second-
(Burt, 1992; Lazega, 2001; Padgett & order) questions about what it should be and
Ansell, 1993). aspire to. The focus of conflict may simulta-
Each of the organizational adaptations that neously shift from near-term concerns to
we described in the prior section can be long-term ones. As these shifts occur, the
rightfully seen as approaches to organiza- organization may begin to become an end in
tional governance, in addition to being strate- itself, and thus an institution in its own right
gies for pursuing legitimacy in the face of (Selznick, 1957, 1969, 1992, 1996). Ongoing
pluralism. Attempts to delete institutionally- conflicts between identity groups subse-
given identities, to loosely couple them, quently become intra-institutional rather
or to balance them against one another are all than extra-institutional. That is, they happen
different ways for a pluralistic organization ‘for’ the organization, and within the
to cope with the twin problems of deciding constitutional framework it creates, rather
organizational purpose and control. than against or outside of it.5
The Selznickian institutionalization process We do not know the frequency with which
can be seen in the same light, and this successful institutionalization processes
adaptation merits additional discussion under actually unfold in organizations. There are
the governance rubric. numerous reasons to believe they might be
We think that the single most important rare and difficult. To begin, pluralism itself is
feature of the pluralistic organization may be a major threat to such processes as well as
its inchoate capacity to govern itself – and its their chief enabler. Workable identity coali-
parallel ability to develop a self which tions (i.e. reasonably coherent organizational
becomes the focal point of its selves) likely become more difficult to
governance efforts. More tangibly, the plural- maintain as identities proliferate within an
istic organization has the capacity to organization. Further, powerful identity
constitute itself by choosing its identities and groups have the opportunity and incentive to
commitments from the menu of choices pre- short-circuit institutionalization by using
sented by its would-be constituencies, and by their power to narrow or rationalize organiza-
society at large. This is an opportunity which tional purposes and effectively cut weaker
is clearly not available to the organization identities out of the coalition. Such efforts
that is a mere incarnation of an externally may often be well-intentioned, though
given cultural logic, or which is otherwise ultimately shortsighted. It is also important
imprisoned within the iron cage of a monis- to remember that self-governance is an ongo-
tic and totalizing institutional field. The ing process; one which is only set in motion
pluralistic organization similarly has the when a nascent institution makes constitu-
opportunity to gain autonomy from its tional commitments. If the self-governing
constituencies, to reprioritize its identities as institution is to flourish, it must actually
needed, and to arbitrate between the claims follow-through on these commitments over
of the identity groups that jointly constitute time (i.e. act with integrity). It must also
it. Perhaps most importantly, it may also develop integrative mythologies and ‘robust’
obtain the ability to harness and channel the symbols that manage to satisfy the individual
divergent energies of these constituencies. parts of the organization at the same time
Under all circumstances, these groups can be they draw these parts together into an emer-
expected to coexist somewhat uneasily as the gent whole (Ansell, 1997; Atkinson, 1985;
256 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Bernstein, 1971; Clark, 1970; Padgett & understood unless we also attend to the
Ansell, 1993; Selznick, 1957). The creation broader institutional orders which the organ-
of formal and informal structures is likewise ization must actually bridge. This may be an
integral to any successful institutionalization important insight for stakeholder theorists.
project (Selznick, 1949, 1957). Finally, While these scholars express much optimism
institutionalization also affords a large about the benefits to be realized from collab-
degree of influence to human selves – who orative organizational governance, they have
appear as ‘leaders’ within the process. The said relatively less about the profound
autonomous and self-governing organiza- ideological and political challenges coopera-
tional institution can be a profoundly cooper- tive governance entails. Organizations may
ative, socially integrative, and highly durable be able to integrate their societally-given
entity. It can also undergo a radical subver- identities to a significant extent, but society
sion of purpose, become an instrument of itself remains divided. Neo-institutionalism
elite domination, and/or become insular and helps us understand the nature and
inertial in the face of a changing significance of these divisions (Friedland &
environment. Selznick (1957) holds that Alford, 1991).
institutional leadership (i.e. ‘organizational
statesmanship’) is often required to ensure
the former outcomes and avoid the latter
ones. But, he also suggests that such leader- INSTITUTIONAL PLURALISM
ship is often most notable by its absence. AND THE PROBLEM OF
These challenges notwithstanding, we see ORGANIZATIONAL CHANGE
an important opportunity for institutional
research which gives renewed attention to Our chapter’s final section focuses on the
integrative processes of governance at the problem of organizational change, and par-
organizational level. Whether or not plural- ticularly on understanding change of the rad-
ism ultimately leads to the development of a ical or transformative sort. We believe that
self-directing organizational institution, its institutional pluralism has significant impli-
minimal effect is to make individual organi- cations for this phenomenon and for our the-
zations into important arenas of governance. oretical understanding of it. In order to
Institutional researchers might learn much by understand these implications, it is first
peering more deeply into these arenas. useful to consider some key neo-institutional
However, we do not suggest that they should insights about organizational change.7
lose sight of broader, embedding institutions To begin, the perspective helps us
in so doing. As we have emphasized, the understand the main reasons why change is
individual identities which contend for influ- likely to be problematic for the organization.
ence within the pluralistic organization have Specifically, it suggests that prevailing
societal roots.6 These roots are not severed institutions are apt to constrain change, and
even when an organization becomes an insti- draws special attention to the role that
tution in its own right. Its autonomy and institutionally-given identities play in subtly
self-awareness may make it a more effective perpetuating the organizational status quo
and formidable player within its pluralistic (D’Aunno et al., 2000; DiMaggio & Powell,
institutional context. But, it likely remains a 1991; Greenwood & Hinings, 1993, 1996,
creature of its social environment and it prob- 2006). Second, the theory helps us under-
ably needs to be understood this way. stand how change is likely to unfold within
The ability to tie together disparate institu- an organization. The most typical expected
tional worlds may be a major source of orga- pattern is one of punctuated equilibrium.
nizational distinctiveness and competence. In ordinary times, the organization is likely
But, this governance capability cannot be to engage in incremental changes that basically
ORGANIZATIONAL IMPLICATIONS OF INSTITUTIONAL PLURALISM 257

converge with its core identity and cohere change somewhat less rare and remarkable
with its constitutive logic. However, these than it may appear from a neo-institutional
convergent periods are intermittently punc- perspective. The deep-rooted tensions that
tuated by shorter episodes of divergent are built in to the pluralistic organization
and revolutionary change (Greenwood seem to make its mere ability to hang
& Hinings, 1996; Greenwood & Hinings, together something of a mystery. It appears
2006). These disruptive spates are most more likely to be fraught with excessive
likely to be exogenously precipitated, to change than to be burdened with inescapable
involve significant conflict, and to be spurred inertia. Stability may thus be seen as a sort of
on by marginal or disadvantaged actors (as achievement (and perhaps a tenuous one).
revolutions typically are) (Hirsch, 1986; Second, pluralism problematizes the mean-
Kraatz & Moore, 2002; Leblebici, Salancik, ing of any given organizational change.
King & Copay, 1991). Finally, the perspec- Categorizing a particular organizational
tive also offers important insights about the change as convergent or divergent becomes a
actual nature of radical organizational troublesome task, one which requires sub-
change. Because neo-institutionalism stantial judgment on the part of the research
conceptualizes the organization as a funda- (and perhaps on the part of the change agent
mentally cultural entity, transformation is as well). Because the same change often
thought to occur when one set of constitutive conveys different symbolic meanings to
beliefs ultimately gives way to another one. different constituencies, it may be highly
It is at this point that the organization is truly convergent (legitimate) with respect to one
reconstituted, becoming something radically identity, deeply divergent (illegitimate) with
different than it once was (Greenwood & respect to another, and wholly irrelevant or
Hinings, 1996, 2006). This general account unnoticed by a third. Finally, pluralism
of organizational transformation shares compels us to see particular changes not just
appreciable similarities with other punctu- in relation to multiple external institutions,
ated equilibrium models of change (Gersick, but also in relation to the institution that the
1991; Meyer, Brooks & Goes, 1990; organization itself may have become. This
Tushman & Romanelli, 1985), with configu- means that we need to ask how a given
rational approaches to organization (Meyer, change fits with the organization’s unique
Tsui & Hinings, 1993; Miller & Friesen, history and claimed purpose. Is it at odds
1984), with models of organizational learn- with the commitments that the organization
ing that emphasize the deep tension between has itself embraced and evinced? How will it
exploitation and exploration (March, 1991; affect the balance of power within the orga-
1994, 1999), and with recent research in nization’s coalition of identities? We also
organizational ecology which sees organiza- need to ask how and if the change fits with
tions’ socially-given identities as key sources the organization’s own unique mythology
of inertia (Baron, 2004; Hannan, Baron, Hsu and espoused mission, which have presum-
& Kocak, 2006). ably developed in order to integrate its
We believe that this perspective is quite identities and sustain the coalition among
useful as a starting point for understanding them. The answers to these questions are
organizational transformation. But, we also likely to determine not only the local
think it becomes increasingly unsatisfactory meaning actually assigned to a given
as institutional pluralism grows. Pluralism’s change, but also the organization’s ability to
basic implications for organizational change implement that change and its ultimate
are largely foreshadowed in our earlier consequences, as well.
discussions of governance and legitimacy. The most obvious pattern of organiza-
First, pluralism has the effect of problematiz- tional change that pluralism may produce is
ing organizational stability and of making one of ongoing and largely uncontrolled flux.
258 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

This rather extreme consequence is espe- Change processes like this one suggest that the
cially likely to occur in loosely coupled problem of controlling organizational change
organizations. Under loose coupling, may be of equal importance to the problem
autonomous identity groups can pursue their of initiating it (at least in pluralistic organiza-
respective aims with little interference from tions). March (1981) and Tsoukas and Chia
other groups and little oversight from a cen- (2002) have previously theorized similar
tral authority. This situation would appear to change processes, though their accounts are
promote the type of organizational dynamics less closely linked to institutional arguments.
that March and colleagues had in mind in Pluralism is likely to affect change some-
their discussion of organizational anarchies what differently in an organization that has
(Cohen & March, 1986; March & Olsen, developed a stronger sense of itself and thus
1976). Another important effect of pluralism become institutionalized in the Selznickian
is to create change processes that are rife sense. One possibility for such an organiza-
with unintended consequences (Merton, tion is that its chosen commitments will
1936; Selznick, 1949). Though constituent become anchors, constraining it in basically
groups within the pluralistic organization the same way that an externally imposed
may be able to act autonomously, their identity might. Selznick (1957) himself
actions are apt to reverberate throughout the warns of this potential, noting that the
larger system as a result of unrecognized (or creation of distinctive competencies is often
disregarded) interdependencies. Thus, organ- accompanied by the parallel emergence of
izations may sometimes be transformed distinctive incompetencies. However, this is
almost by accident. Kraatz & Ventresca clearly not Selznick’s dominant message.
(2007) provide one good example of such a To the contrary, he sees institutionalization as
change process in the context of American a process that tends to promote adaptation;
higher education. They study the diffusion of one which not only allows an organization to
enrollment management (EM), a now- change, but which may also allow (or even
controversial set of marketing practices and compel) it to change intelligently. We have
structures designed to increase enrollments, already elaborated the basic explanations for
improve college rankings, and maximize net- this proposition. To review, the Selznickian
tuition revenues. Enrollment management’s institution: (1) possesses multiple institution-
wide adoption has transformed the admis- ally-derived identities, thus escaping the con-
sions function, fundamentally changed the stitutive iron cage that a monistic field may
purpose of financial aid, and helped make impose; (2) is an autonomous ‘organizational
universities considerably more ‘market- self’ which is capable of reprioritizing, rein-
driven,’ among other consequences. terpreting, and mediating between its identi-
However, Kraatz and Ventresca find that this ties according to necessity; (3) has
change was adopted rapidly and widely with constitutional commitments that put limits
little apparent controversy. Admissions on its flexibility and compel it to act respon-
personnel embraced the practice because it sibly with respect to its constituents and
was an effective solution to technical prob- its history; and (4) is valued not only as a
lems, because it allowed them to realize their means through which constituents pursue
job-specific goals, and because it was their individual aims but also as a non-
increasingly deemed ‘appropriate’ by the expendable end in its own right. Together,
emerging logic of the growing EM profes- these characteristics provide the organiza-
sion. Though EM was (and is) highly tional institution with the necessary motiva-
illegitimate with respect to the values and tion and opportunity for change. In the right
beliefs of many other identity groups in and combination, they may also enable it to
around the university, this conflict remained change intelligently, as we shall discuss
latent until after EM was in wide use. further below.
ORGANIZATIONAL IMPLICATIONS OF INSTITUTIONAL PLURALISM 259

Selznick and his contemporaries provided and sometimes merely absurd. But, it is also
numerous examples of organizational trans- sometimes genuinely desirable and emulable.
formations resulting from institutionalization The same basic processes which allow orga-
processes (Clark, 1956; Messinger, 1955; nizational purposes to be subverted and dis-
Selznick, 1949; Zald & Denton, 1963). The placed in some organizational institutions
recurrent theme in these studies was that allow other institutions to intelligently adapt
individual organizations essentially took on to changing environments and thus continue
lives of their own, obtaining remarkable flu- to serve their constituents. An effectively
idity as their constituents infused them with self-governing institution must, after all, be
value and strived to ensure their survival able to determine (and adapt) its basic
amid changing circumstances. More current purposes. Though Selznick viewed institu-
examples of similar processes are common. tionalization and its accompanying changes
Kraatz and Zajac (1996), for instance, found as ‘fundamentally neutral,’ he had much to
that American liberal arts colleges widely say about the factors that might push the
adopted professional degree programs process in a positive or negative direction. In
(which were seemingly antithetical to their the ideal circumstance, the organizational
missions and identities) in the effort to sur- institution is responsive to the demands of its
vive declining enrollments and changing stu- pluralistic environment but also responsible
dent degree preferences. Suspitsyna (2006) to its defining commitments and its history
shows how economics departments in (Selznick, 1957, 2000). When these pressures
Russian universities have transitioned to the effectively counterbalance one another, the
teaching of western economics, which they organization is unlikely to change too much
officially categorized as a false, ‘bourgeois or too little. The diversity which pluralism
science’ during the Soviet era. Perhaps even builds into the system provides the variation
more striking is the Chinese Communist and conflict necessary to avoid competency
Party’s recent push to integrate prominent traps (March, 1991), which result from exces-
capitalists within its ranks (Kahn, 2002). sive homogeneity and a disproportionate
What is noteworthy about all of these change emphasis on convergent, exploitative change.
processes is not only that organizations have At the same time, the organization’s historical
changed in ways that appear antithetical to commitments and sense of self keep it from
their (apparent) core identities, but that they engaging in excessive exploration and thus
have made these changes without renouncing falling victim to the obverse problem of the
those identities (and often in the very name ‘failure trap’ (March, 1991). The relational
of them). We think that the occurrence of structure of the institution may also be instru-
such changes points to the existence of mental in promoting intelligent adaptation, in
deliberative and adaptive organizational that it brings diverse identity groups into dia-
institutions. These organizations appear to logue with each other and ultimately directs
have been capable of escaping the constraints their energies toward a shared (if necessarily
imposed by their institutional identities, and emergent and robust) organizational purpose
even of reinterpreting those identities in (March & Olsen, 1995; Moore & Kraatz,
order to serve their own changing needs and 2007).
purposes. Organizational change processes Institutionalization is likely to follow a
like these are difficult to conceive through less therapeutic path to the extent that these
the lens of either neo-institutionalism or forces are not in balance with one another.
organizational ecology, both of which tend to One way in which this balance may be
portray identities as externally imposed disrupted is through ‘opportunistic’ adapta-
sources of constraint. tion. Selznick (1957) conceptualizes opp-
The organizational ability for self-transfor- ortunistic changes as ‘irresponsible’ ones
mation is sometimes tragic, sometimes ironic, that are undertaken without sufficient
260 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

consideration of organizational commitments but they also allow the marginalized to sub-
and competencies, and without necessary vert it. While neo-institutional perspectives
regard for their longer-term consequences. on change tend to focus on precipitating orga-
Attempts to pander to constituencies and cash nizational revolutions, Selznick’s theory sug-
in on current fads may, for instance, fall in gests that revolution may be both unnecessary
this category. The flipside of opportunism is and ultimately counterproductive. It suggests
what Selznick calls utopianism. This occurs that the organizational vehicle might be taken
when the organization becomes caught in its in many different directions by those who
past and holds to ideals that it can no longer know how it works.
effectively realize. Importantly, Selznick sees
utopianism, as well as opportunism, as a key
threat to his master ideal of organizational
integrity. Within his pragmatist framework, DISCUSSION: SCHOLARLY,
integrity requires the continued existence of PRAGMATIC, AND HUMANISTIC
the entity. It is not a virtue one ascribes to IMPLICATIONS
martyred organizations or doomed idealists.
Of equal importance is the fact that integrity Our purpose in this chapter has been to draw
can only be assessed on a case-by-case basis greater attention to the phenomenon of insti-
(and even then only tentatively). An organiza- tutional pluralism and to lay out some of its
tion’s choices may cause us to reasonably organizational implications. We think that
question its integrity, but it may also have the problem is an important one for organiza-
commitments and reasons for its actions that tional researchers, for would-be organiza-
are not accessible to the analyst. Integrity tional leaders, and for other organizational
(to the extent it exists) is a characteristic constituents and members. We will discuss
of a dynamic organizational self. All selves these complementary implications in turn as
remain unique and somewhat mysterious in we close the chapter.
the final analysis.
We think that it is quite telling that
Selznick, as a sociologist, chose to make
Scholarly implications
leadership the focal point of his most influen-
tial work on the process of institutionaliza- We have already said much about pluralism’s
tion. Clearly, he recognized that the implications for organizational legitimacy,
complexities of institutionalization provide governance and change. Nevertheless, it may
individual persons with a great ability to be useful to review and elaborate some of our
influence organizational change processes, key points with an eye toward promoting
both for better and worse. His work, espe- future research. We will also consider our
cially Leadership in Administration, is largely chapter’s possible implications for a few
concerned with providing practical and moral other areas of study that we have not yet
guidance to these persons. Though Selznick’s explicitly discussed.
advice seems primarily directed at the power-
ful, we believe his perspective may also be of Organizational legitimacy
great use to those trying to create change Meyer and Scott (1983: 202) proposed that
from within or outside the organizational ‘the legitimacy of a given entity is negatively
institution. Its major implication is that the affected by the number of different authori-
organization is a relational entity which can ties sovereign over it and by the diversity or
become whatever its constituents make it into inconsistency of their accounts of how it is to
(within some broad limits imposed by its his- function’ (reprinted in Scott, 2001: 60). Our
tory). Its robust identity and emergent discussion of the legitimacy problems faced
purpose may allow the powerful to co-opt it, by organizations in pluralistic contexts began
ORGANIZATIONAL IMPLICATIONS OF INSTITUTIONAL PLURALISM 261

in a very similar place, but ended up some- ascribing legitimacy. In other words, they are
where quite different. We acknowledged that likely to anthropomorphize organizations
pluralism problematizes legitimacy, but we and look for evidence of integrity and self-
also suggested that organizations may consistency in their actions (Selznick, 1957;
benefit from it and thrive in its midst. We Stinchcombe, 1997). If this is true, the legit-
think that future research might give more imacy-seeking organization needs not only to
attention to the possibility that organizational be multiple things to multiple people, but
legitimacy can be additive or even multi- also something unto itself. It is hostage to its
plicative, rather than zero-sum as Meyer and own history and to the identities and ideals it
Scott seem to propose. We see no obvious has claimed as its own (Selznick, 1996).
reason to predict that an organization cannot While this dual imperative is the source of
fulfill multiple purposes, embody multiple the ‘politician’s dilemma’ we identified, we
values (or logics), and successfully verify also suggested that this dilemma may carry
multiple institutionally-derived identities. the seeds of its own solution. The organiza-
Indeed, we think that organizations that tion that recognizes its commitments and
embody multiple values and are successful at takes responsibility for them may gain
more than one thing (e.g. research and teach- needed autonomy and support from its con-
ing, satisfying shareholders and environmen- stituents, even when its decisions are at odds
tal groups, upholding professional standards with their near-term interests and parochial
and serving clients) may be especially legiti- values. At the same time, the practical neces-
mate for that very reason. The contradictory sity of responding to the changing needs of
standards and expectations which are constituents may liberate the organization
imposed by different constituencies no doubt from the dead weight of its past. We think
put limits on these hypothesized integrative that future research examining organizational
benefits, and thus block any path to organiza- attempts to navigate the politician’s dilemma
tional utopia. But, as we have also suggested, (both successful and unsuccessful ones) may
the organization may attain substantial be revealing.
autonomy from institutional authorities (who
may not be most accurately described as Organizational governance
‘sovereign’ over it) (Oliver, 1991; Selznick, Our discussion of institutional pluralism also
1957). Further, the very fact that different led us to the conclusion that institutional
institutional actors care enough about an governance is an ongoing process which
organization to levy multiple demands upon transpires within the boundaries of individual
it may be the more telling indicator of its organizations (as well as at higher levels). In
actual legitimacy. Consider the counterfac- some cases, the pluralistic organization may
tual situation wherein no demands are merely serve as an arena wherein diverse
imposed and no support or endorsement is identity groups with different values and
offered in return. logics vie for influence and wherein
We also think that future research on orga- recurrent bouts of ‘legitimacy politics’ occur
nizational legitimacy might give more (Ocasio & Kim, 1999; Stryker, 2000). Such
attention to the ‘commitment problem’ that an organization may constitute a sort of
we discussed and to the related idea that ‘garbage-can’ which is filled with institu-
organizations may acquire some capacity to tional refuse (Heimer, 1999). However,
legitimate their own actions as they become we also suggested that a more durable and
institutions themselves (Goodstein, Blair- stable ‘coalition of identities’ may emerge as
Loy & Wharton, 2006). We suggested that identity groups learn to coexist and recognize
constituents attribute entitativity (Campbell, their symbiosis. We further noted that some
1958; Hamilton & Sherman, 1996) to organ- organizations may become effectively
izations and apply second-order criteria in self-governing as they become institutions
262 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

and develop distinctive ‘organizational while avoiding its obverse (‘the tyranny of
selves’ that somehow encompass, integrate, the or’)? Is loose coupling a sufficient solu-
or transcend their externally-given identities tion? Is the creation of quasi-democratic
(Selznick, 1957). structures and processes which grant voice,
We think that the examination of such due process and autonomy to diverse
integrative processes poses a particularly constituencies a viable option? Can organiza-
important opportunity for future research. tions create integrative mythologies and mis-
We find it unfortunate and somewhat ironic sions that effectively bind together diverse
that much contemporary research on gover- constituents and somehow allow for the joint
nance seems to rule them out by assumption. realization of incommensurable values? Can
The dominant focus on governance as (or must) they develop robust and multivocal
control (whether by ownership, incentive, identities that allow them to be multiple
coercion, or cultural hegemony) often things to multiple people (and to change)
appears to blind researchers to the very pos- while appearing to be unified and self-
sibility of cooperation (i.e. of what Mary consistent? If so, what sorts of rhetoric and
Parker Follett called the ‘power with’ rather symbolism are effective at facilitating this
than ‘power over’) (Graham, 1995). quasi-integration? Finally, what role do
Prevailing theories seem particularly people play in holding together the pluralis-
ill-suited to the analysis of organizations tic organization? What kind of a mindset
wherein constituencies cooperate in order to enables a person (particularly a leader) to
achieve wholly distinct purposes effectively function in the presence of so
(e.g. making money and saving lives, scien- much diversity? We would also like to see
tific research and professional education, more research that examines failed attempts
etc.). We think that the organization with at cooperative governance (and which
such diverse purposes might be productively describes them this way, rather than as the
conceptualized as a sort of ‘pluralistic social mere result of power politics or inexorable
dilemma.’ Its constituencies are mutually cultural forces). Selznick (1949) reminds us
dependent as in the archetypical social that organizations are recalcitrant tools and
dilemma (Hardin, 1968). They require coop- shows how cooperation and idealism can
eration from other groups in order to achieve give way to elite domination and goal dis-
their own ends, and each group has some placement. But, he also reminds us that the
ability to block the others’ attempts at goal iron law of oligarchy is not iron and not a law
attainment. But, because the purposes and (Selznick, 1992). He stresses that ideals are
values of each group are wholly distinct called ideals for a reason. The revealed
(and perhaps fundamentally incommensu- impossibility of perfect cooperation is no
rable) the recognition of mutual reason to abandon cooperative aims or to
dependence and potential symbiosis is devalue organizations which achieve them
greatly hindered. Purposes that are only imperfectly and partially.
merely different are likely to be viewed as
oppositional. The close association of Organizational change
group identities with group objectives Our discussion of organizational change
likely exacerbates this problem (Kramer, yielded at least three key insights for future
1991). research. First, we suggested that pluralism
We would like to see more theory and problematizes stability and makes organiza-
research which looks for organizational and tional change less unusual and difficult than
managerial solutions to this basic dilemma of it often appears when viewed through a neo-
governance. How do successful organiza- institutional lens. The same institutional
tions realize what Collins and Porras (1994) forces which might create organizational
optimistically call ‘the genius of the and’ inertia (operating in isolation) can produce
ORGANIZATIONAL IMPLICATIONS OF INSTITUTIONAL PLURALISM 263

dynamic tensions and a potential for near- highly problematic when change recipients
constant change through their conjoint oper- have the power to resist or ignore change
ation (March, 1981). This effect is likely to initiatives (as they most often do in pluralis-
be especially pronounced when an organiza- tic organizations). In contrast, even extreme
tion is loosely coupled, thus allowing various changes may be more readily accepted when
identity groups to pursue their distinct they are framed in a way that allows people
purposes in relative isolation (March & to conserve their own sense of personal and
Olsen, 1976; Weick, 1976). We suggested organizational identity. This principle of
that the unintended consequences of such ‘identity conservation’ may be a useful one
change processes may produce organiza- for change researchers to explore.
tional transformation without revolution
(Kraatz & Ventresca, 2007). We think that Organizational leadership
this implies a need for research which Our chapter has also made numerous
rethinks processes of radical organizational references to leadership (or ‘organizational
change (and perhaps expands the concept statesmanship’). While this concept was a
itself) (Greenwood & Hinings, 2006). notable casualty of the neo-institutional
Second, we showed that pluralism may facil- revolution, we think that institutional plural-
itate organizational processes of institution- ism has the effect of making leadership both
alization and identity formation that actually practically necessary and philosophically
enable and productively guide adaptation. possible. The pluralistic organization does
The organization that becomes valued as a not automatically hold itself together.
non-expendable end in itself may acquire a Naturally occurring social and political
significant (perhaps extreme) degree of flex- processes may facilitate institutionalization
ibility. But, institutionalization and identity and the formation of an organizational-self.
formation may also put appropriate limits on Political structures and integrative mytholo-
adaptation and allow the organization to gies may likewise help sustain this emergent
avoid failure traps that result from excessive self. But, these processes and structures are
and ill-considered changes which take it too not deterministic or final. Persons who find
far from its existing competencies and histor- themselves at the top of (or in the middle of)
ical commitments (Moore & Kraatz, 2007; pluralistic organizations have much work to
Selznick, 1957). These insights may have do in knitting them together (Gardner, 1990;
significant implications for contemporary Selznick, 1957). We are also inclined to
change research, especially in organizational attribute agency to these persons. Because
ecology and neo-institutionalism. These they work at the nexus of multiple identities
literatures emphasize that organizational (and multiple normative orders), they
identities affect change, but they tend to see regularly find themselves in situations where
these identities as externally imposed, fully they have ‘no choice but to choose.’ Their
constitutive and therefore constraining choices (even their default, taken-for-granted
(Hannan et al., 2006; Zuckerman, 1999). choices) may have very significant conse-
Finally, our discussion of change also offered quences for the evolution of their organiza-
some tangible advice for would-be change tions (Emirbayer & Mische, 1998). We
agents. Specifically, it suggested a practical think it is reasonable to treat such persons
need to justify changes with respect to the as ‘sites of causation’ (Abbott, 1996). We
organization’s own claimed ideals, espoused also think it is appropriate to assign
identity, and distinctive history (and with moral praise and blame to them (as all
respect to the ideals and identities of parti- research which invokes the value-laden
cular groups and persons therein). and inescapably moral concept of leader-
Revolutionary rhetoric is likely to produce ship inevitably does) (Burns, 1978; Ciulla,
counter-revolutionary responses. This is 2004). Kraatz (2007) considers institutional
264 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

pluralism’s implications for leadership in Jones, 1995). Stakeholder theorists have


more detail. based their arguments upon moral philoso-
phy, upon practical reasoning, and to a lesser
Organizational identity extent upon empirical research. The implicit
We have also said much about organizational or explicit objective of most work in this area
identity in the preceding pages. Our chapter is to bring an end to shareholder hegemony
may have some implications for the narrower and to promote a more democratic and coop-
literature on this topic, despite our broader erative social order within the modern corpo-
aims (and despite our acknowledged igno- ration. However, research in this area says
rance of that literature’s subtleties) (see relatively less about how stakeholder gover-
Glynn, Chapter 16 in this volume for a more nance might be achieved if and when share-
nuanced discussion). We think that our holders are deposed from their preferred
notion of the organization as a coalition of status. It also often appears somewhat naïve
identities and as a (potentially) integrated as to the political, ideological and cultural
‘self’ may be particularly generative. The challenges involved in creating and sustain-
identity literature has historically conceptu- ing cooperation in any complex, pluralistic
alized organizational identity as that which organization. The stakeholder literature’s
is ‘central, distinctive and enduring’ about arm’s length relationship to social scientific
an organization (Albert & Whetten, 1985). theory and research appears to be a particular
This idea rests rather uneasily alongside liability in this regard. Our chapter has
more sociological conceptualizations which explored many of the challenges facing plu-
see identities as institutionally-derived, ralistic organizations and has identified some
externally-imposed, and categorical in possible solutions to them. We hope that it
nature. According to the latter view, identi- might serve as a resource for future stake-
ties are certainly central and enduring, but holder research and help build bridges
they are in no real sense distinctive or pos- between this perspective and other theories
sessed by the organization. We have provided of organization.
some insights about how an organization
may develop a distinctive and robust identity Neo-institutionalism
of its own by embracing and embodying its Our chapter has no necessary implications
various institutionally-given role identities for the neo-institutional research agenda.
(rather than escaping or eschewing them). That perspective, as we interpret it, has a core
Institutional pluralism is what seems to make commitment to understanding higher-order
this possible. Identity scholars might further institutions and field-level processes of
explore this proposed process and more institutionalization and institutional change.
effectively unpack the abbreviated theoreti- Its central empirical concern has been with
cal account we have developed here. explaining the legitimation and diffusion of
various practices, structures and forms (and
Stakeholder theory more recently changes therein). The ‘whole’
As we have noted, stakeholder theorists also organizations which are our explicit focus
argue that organizations (specifically corpo- here do not even clearly exist when we view
rations) should be seen as pluralistic entities the organizational world through a neo-
with multiple purposes and responsibilities institutional lens. The perspective does not
(Donaldson & Preston, 1995; Jones, Wicks & tend to support the idea that organizations are
Freeman, 2002). They similarly argue that (or can be) autonomous, integrated or self-
corporations will realize practical benefits governing entities (i.e. ends in themselves).
if they respect the legitimate interests of Rather, it leads us to view them more as the
their multiple constituencies and deal fairly means that powerful institutional actors use
with them (Donaldson & Dunfee, 1994; to achieve their purposes, or perhaps as the
ORGANIZATIONAL IMPLICATIONS OF INSTITUTIONAL PLURALISM 265

slates upon which larger cultural institutions Pragmatic and humanistic


(and institutional entrepreneurs) leave their
implications
mark. While much recent work in this tradi-
tion has focused on the same inter-institu- While our chapter’s primary implications are
tional tensions and conflicts that we have for organizational scholarship, we believe
discussed here, it has primarily sought to that our discussion of institutional pluralism
understand these tensions’ implications for may also have some practical and humanistic
fields, rather than for individual organiza- implications. We are obliged to discuss these.
tions (e.g., Hargrave & Van de Ven, 2006; In writing this chapter, we have been much
Lounsbury, 2007; Marquis & Lounsbury, influenced by the philosophy of American
forthcoming; Schneiberg, 2007; Schneiberg pragmatism (Dewey, 1929, 1938; James,
& Soule, 2005; Thornton, Jones & Kury, 1907). This influence is neither superficial
2005). nor incidental. William James, who first pop-
We think that field-level and societal-level ularized this philosophic stance, was also an
institutions are certainly an appropriate focus early proponent of pluralist thought (James,
for sociological research, and we have 1909). Pragmatism pervades the work of
learned much from studies examining them. Selznick, of Mead, and of the sociological
We also agree that demonstrating these insti- identity theorists whose ideas have also
tutions’ effects upon organizations is a com- much influenced us (Mead, 1934; Selznick,
pelling way to document their existence and 1992; Stryker, 1980). Pragmatist themes are
importance. Nonetheless, we think it is also much apparent (though less explicit) in
essential to clearly distinguish the neo- March’s work and elsewhere in the canon of
institutional research endeavor from the American organization theory dating to
program of research that we inherited and Barnard (Ansell, 2002; Thompson, 1956).
have tried to further in this chapter. Scholars Many stakeholder theorists have been
committed to understanding organizations as influenced by this philosophy as well (Wicks
ends in themselves will never discover & Freeman, 1998).
answers to the questions that legitimately One of pragmatism’s central messages is
preoccupy neo-institutionalists. But, we that theories should be judged (at least in
think the obverse is equally true and perhaps part) according to their practical implications
much less well-understood. We hope that our for the people who may ultimately come to
chapter provides some evidence of the great believe them (James, 1907; Peirce, 1878).
potential symbiosis between neo-institution- Pragmatism highlights the continuities
alism and the ‘organization-centric’ theories between thought and action, and between
of organizations that predated it and that con- academic and practical knowledge. It also
tinue to persist alongside it. But, we also emphasizes that the practical consequences
hope that it demonstrates the continued need of academic ideas can be momentous. Taking
for separation, lest our respective purposes pragmatism seriously thus has the effect of
and competencies become attenuated and putting scholars and organizational
confused (and lest further tensions between participants on the same side of the fence (as
the two scholarly camps be needlessly per- fellow humans trying to understand and live
petuated and exacerbated). It is for this in an ambiguous and unfolding world). We
reason that we have proposed the idea of an believe that this both ennobles and humbles
‘institutional organizationalism’ which is dis- the theoretical enterprise. The ennoblement
tinct from the ‘organizational institutional- comes from the recognition that theories can
ism’ that is the primary focus of this volume. and do matter. Organizational scholars have
The means of the latter are the ends of the the opportunity to participate in the ongoing
former (and vice versa). The one’s figure is construction of reality by creating metaphors
the other’s ground. that escape the academia and ‘become true’
266 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

as people use them to make sense of them- In light of this philosophical background,
selves and their ambiguous organizational one way to read our chapter is as an attempt
worlds (James, 1907). The humility has the to put forth some new metaphors (and some
same essential source. Bad metaphors can recovered metaphors) that might put people
have frightening consequences for people in better relation to their organizations and
and institutions. These consequences can be perhaps positively affect those organizations,
particularly strong when scholarly theories as well (if only on the margins). Institutional
are boldly forwarded in scientific guise, or pluralism is itself a metaphor. It is not an
when theorists display a disregard for empir- innocent one. We have willfully used it to
ical evidence and the lessons of history name an apparent reality which could be (and
(Ferraro, Pfeffer & Sutton, 2005; Ghoshal & has been) described much differently (e.g. as
Moran, 1996). Theorists’ preoccupation with fragmentation or the postmodern condition).
abstract analytical truths (or political agen- We find the pluralism metaphor compelling
das) can also have the deeply ironic effect of because it suggests the possibility of symbio-
making practically soluble problems into sis and latent cooperation among distinct
theoretically or ideologically irresolvable identity groups, even in organizations where
ones (Krygier, 2002; Selznick, 1992). conflict and dissensus are very real and per-
Pragmatism thus suggests that we theorize haps much more clearly evident. It is also
cautiously lest we help create the very world appealing because it suggests the possibility
we fear (or the one that we naively think we of an emergent organizational whole that is
want). It also suggests that social science capable of accommodating, encompassing,
should be seen as a humanistic (i.e. moral) and governing its various distinct parts.
enterprise (Selznick, 1992; Zald, 1993). The idea of an organizational self (or a
Scholars are implicated in their theories and human self) obviously points to a similar
share some responsibility for the ends which possibility (Selznick, 1957; Wiley, 1994).
they ultimately render (or fail to render). These notions are equally metaphorical.
Importantly, this philosophical position does We think that these (somewhat) integrative
not imply that organizational scholars should metaphors are scientifically tenable ones,
wake up in the morning thinking about how based on the available data and the academic
to change the world (or fearing that they arguments we have presented above.
inadvertently might). It also does not imply Organizations do seem to hang together
that researchers should take their marching (however imperfectly), and the centripetal
orders from corporations or management forces that integrate them are no less
consultants. Administrative science (like sci- scientific than the centrifugal ones that tend
ence in general) needs autonomy from its to fragment. But, we also think that integra-
constituencies if it is to deliver anything of tive metaphors are of substantial practical
actual value to them (Selznick, 1992; and humanistic value. This tends to tip the
Thompson, 1956). But, autonomy is not to be balance in their favor to the extent one takes
confused with total independence, and the pragmatism seriously. Any person who has
legitimate need for it should not be used as a spent time in a position of organizational
cover for irresponsibility. Pragmatism thus authority likely recognizes the need for some
implies that organizational theory needs to be notion of shared purpose, common good,
responsive to its different constituents, even and/or collective identity, however vague and
if it ultimately keeps its own counsel and robust those notions might be. These integra-
decides its own purposes. Scholars need to be tive and idealistic notions are not only useful
aware of the consequences their metaphors for elites who are looking to consolidate,
may create, even if they develop those legitimize, and perpetuate their own power
metaphors for purposes that are primarily (though history shows they are certainly
(and justifiably) academic (Selznick, 2000). valuable as means to those ends). Rather, we
ORGANIZATIONAL IMPLICATIONS OF INSTITUTIONAL PLURALISM 267

think they are also essential resources for domination, regardless of what we call it.
leaders who are actually trying to do justice, But, these possibilities seem all the more
achieve diverse purposes, act responsibly, likely to the extent that organizational
and realize the common good within their theorists abandon integrative theoretical
organizations (i.e. to achieve something metaphors altogether. At minimum, these
vaguely resembling substantive cooperation) idealistic notions provide a standard against
(Krygier, 2002; Selznick, 1969, 1992, 1996, which the more disturbing empirical realities
2000). of organizational life can be judged. But,
Such ideals may be equally indispensable they may also be necessary if those realities
to lower-level participants who are striving are to change for the better.
to achieve similar ends on a smaller scale,
or trying to reform unjust organizations
from structurally disadvantaged positions
(Badaracco, 2002; Meyerson, 2003). ACKNOWLEDGMENTS
Cynicism about the motives of organizational
leaders (and about the legitimacy of organi- We would like to thank Jerry Davis, Mary Ann Glynn,
zations in general) may be a very useful out- Andrew Hoffman, Candy Jones, Michael Lounsbury,
Christine Oliver, Mike Pratt, Nelson Phillips, Marc
look for the person looking to incite Schneiberg, Andrew Spicer, Patricia Thornton,
disruptive change and organizational reform. Andrew Van De Ven and Ed Zajac for their comments
But, this same skepticism may foreclose real on earlier drafts of this chapter.
opportunities for cooperative change. It may
also ultimately turn inward, leading the
reflective revolutionary to examine his or her
own motives and to question his or her own NOTES
ability to build a more just and respectful
organizational order in the wake of the revo- 1 March (1999: 228) explains the difference
between the logics thusly: ‘In a consequential logic,
lution (Stever, 2000). The yearning for a new a person is “in touch with reality” and asks, What are
and better form of cultural hegemony is not, my alternatives? What are the probable conse-
after all, the sort of ideal that tends to ani- quences of those alternatives? What are the values to
mate and sustain the romantic mind. (‘Meet me of those probable consequences? Then the
the new boss. Same as the old boss.’). Thus, person selects the alternative whose consequences
he or she values the most. In an obligatory logic, a
of all the real barriers to cooperation which person is “in touch with self” and asks, What kind of
clearly exist, we suspect that a lack of belief situation is this? What kind of person am I? What
in the very possibility of the thing itself may does a person such as I do in a situation such as this?’
be the most thoroughly devastating. We do Importantly, March embraces a sociological concep-
tion of identity in this theory. That is, he or she sees
not think that organizational theorists should
identities as institutionally-derived.
let go of this theoretical possibility thought- 2 The first order/second order distinction that we
lessly or carelessly. We also think they create here is owed to Frankfurt’s (1971) famous
should be very cautious about propagating exposition of first-order and second-order human
organizational metaphors that might lead desires. He suggests that desires of the first order
center on particular things or outcomes. Second-
people to take hegemony for granted as
order desires, in contrast, concern the things that
inevitable. This chapter represents, among one ‘wants to want’ (or wants not to want). He sug-
many other things, a modest effort to sustain gests the capacity to develop second-order desires is
belief (however minimal) in the prospects for essential to the humanistic concept of a ‘person.’
cooperative organization, without disregard- The (perhaps non-obvious) parallel to the current
argument about organizational legitimacy is that
ing the huge challenges it involves or the
constituencies do not just want particular things
estimable empirical evidence which has been from an organization – they also want it to want par-
amassed against it. Pluralism may ultimately ticular things and to ‘be’ a particular type of organi-
devolve into fragmentation or give way to zation. This requires that it possess certain types of
268 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

second-order virtues (i.e. desirable traits of ‘charac- Albert, S & Whetten, D.A. 1985. Organi-
ter’). While the idea that organizations might possess zational identity. In L.L. Cummings and B.M.
character traits is perhaps naïve and objectionable Staw (eds.), Research in Organizational
from a social scientific point of view, much evidence Behavior, V7. Greenwich, CT: JAI Press.
suggests that people tend to anthropomorphize
Alexander, V.D. 1996. Museums and Money:
organizations and other collective actors. We discuss
this evidence and consider its implications below.
The Impact of Funding on Exhibitions,
3 While we think that constituencies often look Scholarship, and Management. Bloomington,
for evidence of commitment in addition to symbolic IN: Indiana University Press.
conformity, we are more agnostic about whether they Ansell, C.A. 1997. Symbolic networks: The
are typically able to discern it. It is apparent that many realignment of the French working class,
self-aware organizations attempt to manipulatively 1887–1894. American Journal of Sociology,
‘fake’ integrity and commitment in the same way that 103(2): 359–390.
they cynically fake conformity. Audiences may often Ansell, C.A. 2002. Pragmatism in organiza-
be taken in by such attempts. Our point here is only tions. Working Paper, University of
that there are two distinct things that must (at least)
California, Berkeley.
be faked by the organization seeking legitimacy. It is
also important to note that these two imperatives are
Atkinson, P. 1985. Language, Structure and
often in significant tension with one another. Reproduction: An Introduction to the Socio-
4 We have painted a relatively positive picture of logy of Basil Bernstein. London: Methuen.
organizational institutionalization here. This is consis- Badaracco, J.L. 2002. Leading Quietly. Boston,
tent with our goal of identifying effective organiza- MA: Harvard Business Press.
tional adaptations to pluralism. While Selznick also Barnard, C.I. 1938. The Functions of the Execu-
emphasizes institutionalization’s positive aspects, he tive. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
similarly documents its pathologies and concludes Baron, J.M. 2004. Employing identities in orga-
that the process should be seen as a ‘fundamentally nizational ecology. Industrial and Corporate
neutral’ one. Organizational autonomy is not an
Change, 13(1): 3–32.
unqualified good, and bad things can certainly
happen when an organization becomes valued as an
Bernstein, B. 1971. Class, Codes and Control
end in itself. Some integrative institutions may be Volume 1: Theoretical Studies Towards a
better described as unholy alliances. Sociology of Language. London: Routledge
5 In discussing political coalitions and parties, & Kegan Paul.
Lyndon Johnson is reported to have said that it is Bowen, W.G. & Levin, S.A. 2003. Reclaiming
better to have people ‘inside the tent pissing out, the Game. Princeton University Press
than outside the tent pissing in.’ The Selznickian Britton, M. & Nee, V. 1998. The New
institutionalization process might be thought of as Institutionalism in Sociology. New York:
the social mechanism creating the tent itself. Russell Sage Foundation.
6 Selznick was clearly aware of this fact himself:
Brunsson, N. 1989. The Organization of
‘… although organizational controversy may be
directly motivated by narrow personal and group
Hypocrisy: Talk, Decisions and Actions in
aims, the contending programs usually reflect ideo- Organizations. Chichester, NY: Wiley.
logical differences in the larger arena. In this way, the Burns, J.M. 1978. Leadership. New York:
internal struggle for power becomes a channel Harper Row.
through which external environmental forces make Burt, R. 1992. Structural Holes: The Social
themselves felt’ (1957: 20). Structure of Competition. Cambridge, MA:
7 Much recent research in institutional theory has Harvard University Press
also examined processes of institutional change at Campbell, T. 1958. Common fate, similarity,
the field level (Dacin, Goodstein & Scott, 2002; Scott, and other indices of the status of aggregates
2001, Thornton & Ocasio, 1999). We do not review
of persons as social aggregates. Behavioral
this literature here, given our central concern with
organization-level processes.
Science, 3: 13–25.
Ciulla, J.D. 2004. Ethics: The Heart of Leader-
ship. New York: Praeger.
Clark, B.R. 1956. Organizational adaptation
REFERENCES and precarious values: A case study.
American Sociological Review, 21: 327–336.
Abbott, A. 1996. Things of boundaries. Social Clark, B.R. 1970. Distinctive Colleges: Reed,
Research, 62: 857–882. Antioch and Swarthmore. Chicago: Aldine.
ORGANIZATIONAL IMPLICATIONS OF INSTITUTIONAL PLURALISM 269

Cohen, M.D. & March, J.G. 1986. Leadership OrganIzational Analysis. Chicago, IL:
and Ambiguity. Boston: Harvard Business University of Chicago Press.
School Press. DiMaggio, P.J. 1988. Interest and agency in
Collins, J.C. & Porras, J.L. 1994. Built to Last: institutional theory. In Institutional Patterns
Successful Habits of Visionary Companies. and Organizations: Culture and Environment.
New York: Harper Business. L.G. Zucker (ed.). Cambridge, MA: Bollinger
Commons, J.R. 1970. The Economics of Publishing.
Collective Action. Madison, WI: University of Dobbin, F. 1994. Forging Industrial Policy:
Wisconsin Press (Original work published in The United States, Britain and France in
1950). the Railway Age. New York: Cambridge
Cyert, R. M. & March, J.G. 1963. A Behavioral University Press.
Theory of the Firm. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Dobbin, F. & Dowd, T. 1997. How policy shapes
Prentice-Hall. competition: Early railroad foundings in
Dacin, T.M., Goodstein, J. and Scott, W.R. Massachusetts. Administrative Science
2002. Institutional theory and institutional Quarterly, 42:501–529.
change: Introduction to the special research Donaldson, T. & Preston, L.E. 1995. The stake-
forum. Academy of Management Journal, holder theory of the corporation: concepts,
45(1): 45–57. evidence and implications. Academy of
D’Aunno, T., Succi, M., & Alexander, J.A. 2000. Management Review, 20(1): 85–91.
The role of institutional and market forces in Donaldson, T. & Dunfee, T.W. 1994. Toward a
divergent organizational change. Administ- unified conception of business ethics:
rative Science Quarterly, 45: 679–703. Integrative social contracts theory. Academy
D’Aunno, T., Sutton, R.I. & Price, R.H. 1991. of Management Review, 19(2): 252.
Isomorphism and external support in con- Duderstadt, J.J. 2000. Intercollegiate Athletics
flicting institutional environments: A study of and the American University: A University
drug abuse treatment centers. Academy of President’s Perspective. Ann Arbor, MI:
Management Journal, 34(3): 636–661. University of Michigan Press.
Davis, G.F. & Thompson, T.A. 1994. A social Dutton, J.E. & Dukerich, J.M. 1991. Keeping an
movement perspective on corporate control. eye on the mirror: image and identity in
Administrative Science Quarterly, 39. organizational adaptation. Academy of
Davis, G.F., McAdam, D., Scott, W.R. & Zald, Management Journal, 34(3): 517–554.
M.N. 2005. Social Movements and Organi- Edelman, L.B. 2002. Legality and the endo-
zational Theory. New York: Cambridge geneity of law. In R.A. Kagan, M. Krygier &
University Press. K. Winston (eds.), Legality and Community:
Deephouse, D.L. 1996. Does isomorphism On the Intellectual Legacy of Philip Selznick.
legitimate? Academy of Management IGS Press/Rowman & Littlefield Publishers.
Journal, 39 (4): 1024–1039. Edelman, L.B. 1992. Legal ambiguity and sym-
Denis, J.L., Lamothe, L. & Langley, A. 2001. The bolic structures: Organizational mediation of
dynamics of collective leadership and strate- civil rights law. American Journal of
gic change in pluralistic organizations. Sociology, 97(6):1531–1576.
Academy of Management Journal, 44(4): Edelman, L.B. 1990. Legal environments and
809–837. organizational governance: The expansion of
Dewey, J. 1929. Experience and Nature. New due process in the American workplace.
York: Dover. American Journal of Sociology, 95(6):
Dewey, J. 1938. Logic: The Theory of Inquiry. 1401–1440.
New York: Holt. Edelman, L.B. & Suchman, M.C. 1997. The
DiMaggio, P. & Powell, W.W. 1983. The iron legal environments of organizations. Annual
cage revisited: Institutional isomorphism and Review of Sociology, 23.
collective rationality in organizational fields. Emirbayer, M. 1997. Manifesto for a relational
American Sociological Review, 48: 147–60. sociology. American Journal of Sociology,
DiMaggio, P.J. & Powell, W.W. 1991. 103(2): 281–317.
Introduction. In W.W. Powell, and P. J. Emirbayer, M. & Mische, A. 1998. What is agency?
DiMaggio (eds.), The New Institutionalism in American Journal of Sociology, 103(4).
270 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Ferraro, F., Pfeffer, J. & Sutton, R.I. 2005. Graham, P. 1995. Mary Parker Follett: Prophet
Economics language and assumptions: How of Management. Cambridge, MA: Harvard
theories can be self-fulfilling. Academy of University Press.
Management Review, 30(1): 8–24. Greenwood, R. & Hinings, C.R. 1993.
Fligstein, N. 1991. The structural transforma- Understanding strategic change: The con-
tion of American industry. In W.P. Powell and tribution of archetypes. Academy of
P.J. DiMaggio, The New Institutionalism in Management Journal, 36(5): 1052–1081.
Organizational Analysis. Chicago, IL: Greenwood, R. & Hinings, C.R. 1996.
University of Chicago Press: 311–336. Understanding radical organizational
Frank, R.H. 1988. Passions Within Reason: The change: Bringing together the old and the
Strategic Role of Emotions. New York: Norton. new institutionalism. Academy of
Frankfurt, H.G. 1971. Freedom of the will and Management Journal, 21: 1022–1054.
the concept of a person. Journal of Greenwood, R. & Hinings, C.R. 2006. Radical
Philosophy, 68(1): 5–20. organizational change. In S. Clegg, C, Hardy,
Friedland, R. & Alford, R.R. 1991. Bringing W.W. Nord & T. Lawrence (eds.),
society back in: Symbols, practices, and insti- Handbook of Organization Studies. Sage
tutional contradictions, pp. 232–263. Publications.
In W.W. Powell and P.J. DiMaggio (eds.), The Hamilton, D.L., & Sherman, S.J. 1996.
New Institutionalism in Organizational Analy- Perceiving persons and groups. Psychological
sis. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Review, 103, 336–355.
Friedman, M. 1970. The social responsibility of Hannan, M.T., Baron, J.M., Hsu, G., & Kocak,
business is to increase its profits. New York O. 2006. Organizational identities and the
Times Magazine, September 13. New York: hazard of change. Industrial and Corporate
The New York Times Company. Change, 15(5): 755–784.
Gardner, J. 1990. On Leadership. New York: Hansmann, H. 1996. The Ownership of Enter-
The Free Press. prise. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press.
Gersick, C.J.G. 1991. Revolutionary change Hardin, G. 1968. The tragedy of the commons.
theories: A multilevel exploration of the Science, 162(3859).
punctuated equilibrium paradigm. Academy Hargrave, T. & Van De Ven, A. 2006. A collec-
of Management Review, 16: 10–36. tive action model of institutional innovation.
Ghoshal, S. & Moran, P. 1996. Bad for practice: Academy of Management Review, 31(4):
A critique of the transaction cost theory. 864–888.
Academy of Management Review, 21(1) Hauser, M.D. 2006. Moral Minds: How Nature
13–47. Designed Our Sense of Right and Wrong.
Glynn, M. 2007. Beyond constraint: How insti- New York: Ecco/Harper Collins.
tutions enable identities. In R. Greenwood, Haveman, H.A. & Rao, H. 1997. Structuring a
C. Oliver, R. Suddaby & K. Sahlin-Andersson theory of moral sentiments: Institutional and
(eds.), Handbook of Organizational Institu- organizational co-evolution in the early thrift
tionalism. London: Sage. industry. American Journal of Sociology,
Glynn, M. 2000. When cymbals become sym- 102(6): 1606–1651.
bols: Conflicts over organizational identity Hirsch, P.M. 1986. From ambushes to golden
within a symphony orchestra. Organization parachutes: Corporate takeovers as an
Science, 11(3): 285–298. instance of cultural framing and institutional
Golden-Biddle, K. & Rao, H. 1997. Breaches in integration. American Journal of Sociology,
the boardroom: Organizational identity and 91(4): 800–837.
conflicts of commitment in a mutual non- Hirsch, P. 2007. Been there, done that, moving
profit. Organization Science, 8(6): 593–611. on: Reflections on institutional theory’s con-
Goodstein, J., Blair-Loy, M., & Wharton, A.J. tinuing evolution. In R. Greenwood,
2006. Organization-based legitimacy: Core C. Oliver, R. Suddaby & K. Sahlin-Andersson
ideologies and moral action. In J. Alexander (eds.), Handbook of Organizational Institu-
& I. Reed (eds.), Culture in the World: tionalism. London: Sage.
Morals, Actions, and Institutions. New York: Heimer, C.A. 1999. Competing institutions:
Paradigm Publishers. Law, medicine, and family in neonatal
ORGANIZATIONAL IMPLICATIONS OF INSTITUTIONAL PLURALISM 271

intensive care. Law & Society Review, management in American higher. Working
33(1):17–66. paper.
Hinings, C.R., Greenwood, R., Reay, T., & Kraatz, M.S. 2007. Institutional pluralism and
Suddaby, R. 2004. Dynamics of change in the possibility of leadership. Working paper.
organizational fields. In M.S. Poole and A. Kramer, R.M. 1991. Inter-group relations and
Van de Ven (eds.), Handbook of Organi- organizational dilemmas: The role of catego-
zational Change and Innovation. New York: rization processes. In L. Cummings & B. Staw
Oxford University Press. (eds.), Research in Organizational Behavior.
Hung, S.C., & Whittington, R. 1997. Strategies Greenwich, CT: JAI Press.
and institutions: A pluralistic account of Krygier, M.E. 2002. Philip Selznick, normative
strategies in the Taiwanese computer indus- theory and the rule of law. In R. A. Kagan,
try. Organization Studies, 18(4): 551–576. M. Krygier & K. Winston, (eds.), Legality and
Ingram, P. & Clay, K. 2000. The choice-within- Community: On the Intellectual Legacy of
constraints new institutionalism and implica- Philip Selznick. IGS Press/Rowman &
tions for sociology. Annual Review of Littlefield Publishers.
Sociology, 26: 525–546. Kostova, T. & Zaheer, S. 1999. Organizational
James, W. 1909. A Pluralistic Universe. legitimacy under conditions of complexity:
Indypublish.com. The case of the multinational enterprise.
James, W. 1907. Pragmatism. Cambridge, MA: Academy of Management Review, 24(1):
Harvard University Press (Republished 1979). 64–81.
Jones, T., Wicks, A. & Freeman, R.E. 2002. Lazega, E. 2001. The Collegial Phenomenon:
Stakeholder theory: The state of the art. The Social Mechanisms of Cooperation
In N. Bowie (ed.), The Blackwell Handbook Among Peers in a Corporate Law Partner-
of Strategic Management. Oxford: Blackwell ship. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Publishing. Leblebici, H., Salancik, G., King, T., & Copay, A.
Jones, T.M. 1995. Instrumental stakeholder 1991. Institutional change and the transfor-
theory: A synthesis of ethics and economics. mation of inter-organizational fields: An
Academy of Management Review, 20(2): organizational history of the U.S. Radio
404–437. Broadcasting Industry. Administrative
Kahn, J. 2004. China’s communist party, to Science Quarterly, 36: 333–363.
‘survive,’ opens its doors to capitalism. New Lounsbury, M. 2007. A tale of two cities:
York Times, November 4. Competing logics and practice variation in
Kelly, E. & Dobbin, F. 1998. How affirmative the professionalization of mutual funds.
action became diversity management. Academy of Management Journal, 50:
American Behavioral Scientist, 41(7): 289–307.
960–984. Lounsbury, M. 1999. Institutional sources of
Kerr, C. 1963. The Uses of the University. practice variation: staffing college and uni-
Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. versity recycling programs. Administrative
Kraatz, M.S. & Zajac, E.J. 1996. Exploring the Science Quarterly, 46(1): 29–56.
limits of the new institutionalism: The causes Love, E.G. & Kraatz, M.S. 2007. The reputa-
and consequences of illegitimate organiza- tional consequences of corporate downsiz-
tional change. American Sociological ing: Empirical findings and theoretical
Review, 61(5): 812–836. implications. Working paper.
Kraatz, M.S. 1998. Learning by association? March, J.G. 1999. The Pursuit of Organi-
Inter-organizational networks and adapta- zational Intelligence. Malden, MA: Blackwell
tion to environmental change. Academy of Business.
Management Journal, 41(6): 621–643. March, J.G. 1994. A Primer on Decision–Making.
Kraatz, M., & Moore, J.D. 2002. Executive New York: The Free Press.
migration and institutional change. Academy March, J.G. 1991. Exploration and exploitation
of Management Journal, 45: 120–143. in learning. Organization Science, 2(1): 71–87.
Kraatz, M.S. & Ventresca, M. 2006. Radical March, J.G. 1981. Footnotes to organizational
organizational change in a loosely coupled change. Administrative Science Quarterly,
context: The emergence of enrollment 26(4): 563–577.
272 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

March, J.G. & Olsen, J.P. 2004. The logic of Meyerson, D. 2003. Tempered Radicals: How
appropriateness. ARENA working paper, WP People Use Difference to Inspire Change
04/09. at Work. Boston, MA: Harvard Business
March, J.G. & Olsen, J.P. 1995. Democratic Press.
Governance. New York: The Free Press. Miller, D. & Friesen, P. 1984. A longitudinal
March, J.G. & Olsen, J.P. 1976. Ambiguity and study of the corporate life cycle.
Choice in Organizations, 2nd edn. Management Science, 30: 1161–1183.
Universitetsforlaget, Bergen, Norway. Mitchell, R.K., Agle, B.R. & Wood, D.J. 1997.
March, J.G. & H. Simon. 1958. Organizations. Toward a theory of stakeholder identification
New York: Wiley. and salience: Defining the principle of who
Marquis, C. & Lounsbury, M. Forthcoming. and what really counts. Academy of
Vive la resistance: Consolidation and the Management Review, 22: 853–896.
institutional contingency of professional Moore, J.H. & Kraatz, M.S. 2007. Governance
counter–mobilization in US banking. form and organizational adaptation: Lessons
Academy of Management Journal. from the savings and loan industry in the
McAdam, D. & Scott, W.R. 2005. Organi- 1980s. Working Paper.
zations and movements. In G.F., Davis, D., Mouritsen, J. & Skærbæk, P. 1995. Civilisation,
McAdam, W.R. Scott, & M.N. Zald, (eds.), art and accounting: The Royal Theatre –
Social Movements and Organizational An enterprise straddling three institutions.
Theory. New York: Cambridge University In The Institutional Construction of
Press. Organization: International and Longitudinal
McCall, G.J. & Simmons, J.L. 1978. Identities Studies. Redigeret af S. Christensen og W.R.
and Interactions: An Examination of Human Scott (eds.), pp. 91–112. Sage.
Associations in Everyday Life. New York: Free Nesse, R.M. 2001. Evolution and the Capacity
Press. for Commitment. New York: Russell Sage
Mead, G.H. 1934. Mind, Self, and Society. Press.
Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press. North, D. 1990. Institutions, Institutional
Merton, R.K. 1936. The unanticipated conse- Change and Economic Performance.
quences of purposive social action. American Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Sociological Review, 1(6): 894–904. Ocasio, W. 1994. Political dynamics and the cir-
Messinger, S.L. 1955. Organizational transfor- culation of power: CEO succession in U.S.
mation: A case study of a declining social industrial corporations, 1960–1990.
movement. American Sociological Review, Administrative Science Quarterly, 39.
30: 3–10. Ocasio, W., & Kim, H. 1999. The circulation of
Meyer, J.W. & Rowan, B. 1977. Institutionalized corporate control: Selection of functional
organizations: Formal structure as myth and backgrounds of new CEOs in large U.S. man-
ceremony. American Journal of Sociology, ufacturing firms, 1981–1992. Administrative
83: 340. Science Quarterly, 44(3): 532–562.
Meyer, A.D., Brooks, G.R., & Goes, J.B. 1990. Oliver, C. 1991. Strategic responses to institu-
Environmental jolts and industry revolutions: tional processes. Academy of Management
Organizational responses to discontinuous Review, 16(1): 145–179.
change. Strategic Management Journal, 11: Olson, M. 1965. The Logic of Collective Action:
93–110. Public Goods and the Theory of Groups.
Meyer, A.D., Tsui, A.S. & Hinings, C.R. 1993. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Configurational approaches to organiza- Orton, J.D. & Weick, K.E. 1990. Loosely cou-
tional analysis. Academy of Management pled systems: A re–conceptualization.
Journal, 36: 1175–1195 Academy of Management Review, 15(2):
Meyer, J.W. & Scott, W.R. 1983. Centrality and 203–223.
the legitimacy problems of local govern- Padgett, J.F. 2001. ‘Organizational genesis,
ment. In J.W. Meyer and W.R. Scott, identity and control: The transformation
Organizations and Environments: Ritual and of banking in Renaissance Florence.’
Rationality, 1999–2006. Beverly Hills, CA: In A. Casella and J. Rauch (eds.), Markets
Sage. and Networks. New York: Russell Sage.
ORGANIZATIONAL IMPLICATIONS OF INSTITUTIONAL PLURALISM 273

Padgett, J.F. & Ansell, C.K. 1993. Robust action the institutional determinants of fire insur-
and the rise of the Medici, 1400–1434. ance regulation. American Journal of
American Journal of Sociology, 98: 1259. Sociology, 107(1): 101–146.
Parsons, T. 1956. Suggestions for a sociological Schneiberg, M. & Clemens, E. 2006. The typi-
approach to the theory of organizations. cal roots for the job: Research strategies in
Administrative Science Quarterly, 1(1): institutional analysis. Sociological Theory,
63–88. 24: 3.
Peirce, C.S. 1878 How to make our ideas clear. Schneiberg, M. & Lounsbury, M. 2007. Social
Popular Science Monthly, 12: 286–302. movements and institutional analysis.
Pfeffer, J. & Dowling, J. 1975. Organizational In R. Greenwood, C. Oliver, R. Suddaby &
legitimacy: Social values and organizational K. Sahlin–Andersson (eds.), Handbook of
behavior. Pacific Sociological Review, Organizational Institutionalism. London: Sage.
18(1): 122. Schneiberg, M. & Soule, S. 2005.
Pfeffer, J. & Salancik, G. 1978. The External Institutionalization as a contested multilevel
Control of Organizations. New York: Harper process: The case of rate regulation in
Row. American fire insurance, pp. 122–160.
Pickle, H. & Friedlander, F. 1967. Seven societal In J. Davis, D. McAdam, D. Scott, and
criteria of organizational effectiveness. M. Zald (eds.), Social Movements and Organi-
Personnel Psychology, 20(2): 165. zation Theory. Cambridge University Press.
Powell, W.W. 1988. Institutional effects on Scott, W.R. 2001. Institutions and Organi-
organizational structure and performance. In zations, 2nd edn. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.
L.G. Zucker (ed.), Institutional Patterns and Scott, W.R., Ruef, M., Mendel, P. & Carona, C.
Organizations: Culture and Environment, 2000. Institutional Change and Healthcare
pp.115–36. Cambridge, MA: Ballinger. Organizations: From Professional Dominance
Pratt, M.G. & Foreman, P.O. 2000. Classifying to Managed Care. Chicago: University of
managerial responses to multiple organiza- Chicago Press.
tionali. Academy of Management Review, Selznick, P. 1949. TVA and the Grass Roots.
25(1): 18–42. Berkeley: University of California Press.
Rao, H. 1998. Caveat emptor: The construction Selznick, P. 1951. ‘Institutional vulnerability in
of non-profit watchdog organizations. mass society.’ American Journal of Sociology,
American Journal of Sociology, 103: 56(4): 320–333.
912–961. Selznick, P. 1957. Leadership in Administration.
Rao, H., Morill, C. & Zald, M. 2000. Power New York: Harper & Row.
plays: Social movements, collective action Selznick, P. 1969: Law, Society and Industrial
and new organizational forms. In B. Staw & Justice. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
R. Sutton (eds.), Research in Organizational Selznick, P. 1992. The Moral Commonwealth:
Behavior. Greenwich, CT: JAI Press, Vol. 22. Social Theory and the Promise of Commu-
Rao, H., Monin, P. & Durand, R. 2003. nity. Berkeley: University of California Press.
Institutional change in Toque Ville: Nouvelle Selznick, P. 1996. Institutionalism ‘old’ and
cuisine as an identity movement in French ‘new.’ Administrative Science Quarterly, 41.
gastronomy. American Journal of Sociology, Selznick, P. 2000. On sustaining research agen-
108(4): 795–843. das: Their moral and scientific basis: An
Rowan, B. 1982. Organizational structure and address to the Western Academy of
the institutional environment: The case of Management. Journal of Management
public schools. Administrative Science Inquiry, 9(3): 277–282.
Quarterly, 27: 259–279. Stever, J.A. 2000. The Path to Organizational
Ruef, M. & Scott, W.R. 1998. Multidimensional Skepticism. New York: Chatelaine Press.
model of organizational legitimacy: Hospital Shulman, J.L. & Bowen, W.G. 2001. The Game
survival in changing institutional environ- of Life: College Sports and Educational Values.
ments. Administrative Science Quarterly, New Haven, CT: Princeton University Press.
43(4): 877–904. Stinchcombe, A. L. 1997. On the virtues of the
Schneiberg, M. & Bartley, T. 2001. Regulating old institutionalism. Annual Review of
American industries: Markets, politics, and Sociology, 23: 1–18.
274 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Stone, M.M. & Brush, C.G. 1996. Planning in Tolbert, P.S. & Zucker, L.G. 1983. Institutional
ambiguous contexts: the dilemma of meet- sources of change in the formal structure of
ing needs for commitment and demands for organizations: the diffusion of civil service
legitimacy. Strategic Management Journal, reform, 1880–1935. Administrative Science
17(8): 633–652. Quarterly, 28; 22–39.
Stryker, R. 2000. Legitimacy processes as insti- Tsoukas, H. & Chia, R. 2002. On organizational
tutional politics: Implications for theory and becoming: Rethinking organizational
research in the sociology of organizations. change. Organization Science, 13(5):
Organizational Politics: Research in the 567–582.
Sociology of Organizations, 17: 179–223. Tushman, M.L. & Romanelli, E. 1985.
Stryker, S. 1980. Symbolic Interactionism: Organizational evolution: A metamorphosis
A Social Structural Version. Menlo Park, CA: model of convergence and reorientation. pp.
Benjamin/Cummings. 171–222. In L. Cummings & B. Staw (eds.),
Stryker, S. 1987. Identity theory: Developments Research in Organizational Behavior.
and extensions. In K. Yardley, & T. Honess Greenwich, CT: JAI Press.
(eds.), Self and Identity: Psychosocial Tushman, M.L. & Romanelli, E. 1994.
Perspectives. New York: Wiley. Organizational transformation as punctu-
Stryker, S. & Burke, P.J. 2000. The past, present, ated equilibrium: An empirical test. Academy
and future of an identity theory. Social of Management Journal, 37(5): 1141–1166.
Psychology Quarterly, 63(4): 284–297. Tyler, T.R. 1990. Why People Obey the Law.
Stryker, S. & Serpe, R.T. 1982. Identity salience New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
and psychological centrality: Equivalent, Tyler, T. 2002. Justice and legitimacy in work
overlapping, or complementary concepts? organizations. In R.A. Kagan, M. Krygier and
Social Psychology Quarterly, 57(1): 16–35. K. Winston (eds.), Legality and Community:
Suchman, M. 1995. Managing legitimacy: On the Intellectual Legacy of Philip Selznick.
Strategic and institutional approaches. Lanham, MD: Roman and Littlefield.
Academy of Management Review, 20, Weick, K. 1976. Educational organizations as
571–611. loosely–coupled systems. Administrative
Suspitsyna, T. 2006. Adaptation of Western Science Quarterly, 21: 1–21.
Economics by Russian Universities: Westphal, J.D. & Zajac, E.J. 1994. Substance
Intercultural Travel of an Academic Field. and symbolism in CEOs’ long–term incentive
New York: Routledge. plans. Administrative Science Quarterly, 39:
Sutton, J.R. & Dobbin, F. 1996. The two faces 367–390.
of governance: Responses to legal uncer- Westphal, J.D. & Zajac, E.J. 1998. ‘The sym-
tainty in US firms, 1955 to 1985. American bolic management of stockholders:
Sociological Review, 61(5): 794–811. Corporate governance reforms and share-
Thompson, J.D. 1967. Organizations in Action: holder reactions.’ Administrative Science
Social Science Bases of Administration Quarterly, 43.
Theory. New York: McGraw–Hill. White, H.C. 1992. Identity and Control: A
Thompson, J.D. 1956. On building an adminis- Structural Theory of Social Action. Princeton:
trative science. Administrative Science Princeton University Press.
Quarterly, 1: 102–111. Wicks, A. & Freeman, R.E. 1998. Organization
Thornton, P. & Ocasio, W. 1999. Institutional studies and the new pragmatism: Positivism,
logics and the historical contingency of anti–positivism and the search for ethics.
power in organizations: Executive succession Organization Science, 9(2): 123–140.
in the higher education publishing industry, Wiley, N. 1994. The Semiotic Self. Chicago:
1958–1990. American Journal of Sociology, University of Chicago Press.
105: 801. Williamson, O.E. 1996. Mechanisms of Gover-
Thornton, P.H., Jones, C. & Kury, K. 2005. nance. New York: Oxford University Press.
Institutional logics and institutional change in Zajac, E. & Westphal, J.D. 1995. Accounting for
organizations: Transformation in accounting, the explanations of CEO compensation:
architecture and publishing. Research in the Substance and symbolism. Administrative
Sociology of Organizations, 23: 125–170. Science Quarterly, 40.
ORGANIZATIONAL IMPLICATIONS OF INSTITUTIONAL PLURALISM 275

Zald, M. 1993. Organization studies as a scien- Theory. New York: Cambridge University
tific and humanistic enterprise: toward a Press.
reconceptualization of the foundations Zilber, T. 2002. Institutionalization as an interplay
of the field. Organization Science, 4(4): between actions, meanings and actors: The
513–28. case of a rape crisis center in Israel. Academy
Zald, M.N. & Denton, P. 1963. From evangelism of Management Journal, (45): 234–254.
to general service: The transformation of the Zimbalist, A. 1999. Unpaid professionals:
YMCA. Administrative Science Quarterly, 8: Commercialism and Conflict in Big–Time
214–234. College Sports. New Haven, CT: Princeton
Zald, M.N., Morill, C., & Rao, H. 2005. The University Press.
impact of social movements on organiza- Zuckerman, E.W. 1999. ‘The categorical imper-
tions: Environment and responses. In G.F. ative: Securities analysts and the illegitimacy
Davis, D. McAdam, W.R. Scott, & M.N. Zald discount.’ American Journal of Sociology,
(eds.), Social Movements and Organizational 104(5): 1398–1438.
10
Microfoundations of Institutional
Theory
Walter W. Powell and Jeannette A. Colyvas

INTRODUCTION trend toward increased efforts at earned


income by nonprofit organizations. These
For almost two decades, scholars have applications illustrate the analytical utility of
stressed the need to make the microfounda- our approach. We conclude with a discussion
tions of institutional theory more explicit of research tools generated by this line of
(DiMaggio and Powell, 1991; Zucker, 1991). theorizing that can be used to fashion com-
Curiously, there has been limited progress in pelling, multi-level explanations.
this effort, although Barley, Glynn, and
Sahlin, in Chapters 8, 16 and 20 in this
volume, also remedy this deficit. We think that
much analytical purchase can be gained by WHY A MICRO-LEVEL THEORY OF
developing a micro-level component of insti- INSTITUTIONALIZATION?
tutional analysis. Moreover, there are useful
building blocks from ethnomethodology to The bulk of institutional research has focused
Goffman on interaction rituals to Weick on on the sectoral, field, or global level.
sensemaking and social psychological And properly so, as the transfer of ideas,
research on legitimation that can be drawn practices, and organizational forms spans the
upon to contribute to this effort. boundaries of organizations, industries,
We begin by making a case for the benefits and nations. A core insight of institutional
of examining micro-processes. We then theory is just how taken-for-granted formal
selectively review the terrain, cobbling organization and rationalization has become
together useful, albeit disparate, lines of (Drori, Meyer, and Hwang, 2006). In our
research and theory. The thrust of this chap- view these macro-lines of analysis could also
ter is generative and by no means intended as profit from a micro-motor. Such a motor
a comprehensive survey. From these diverse would involve theories that attend to enac-
sources, we contend, a viable micro-analysis tion, interpretation, translation, and meaning.
of institutionalization can be developed. We Institutions are sustained, altered, and extin-
apply our ideas to several contemporary guished as they are enacted by individuals in
issues, notably the rise of academic entrepre- concrete social situations. We need a richer
neurship in universities in the U.S. and the understanding of how individuals locate
MICROFOUNDATIONS OF INSTITUTIONAL THEORY 277

themselves in social relations and interpret making unleashed actors the drivers of insti-
their context. How do organizational partici- tutional change.
pants maintain or transform the institutional Institutions are reproduced through the
forces that guide daily practice? From an everyday activities of individuals. Members
institutional perspective, how are the of organizations engage in daily practices,
passions and interests implicated in human discover puzzles or anomalies in their work,
behavior? In our view, the development of problematize these questions and develop
micro-level explanations will give more answers to them by theorizing them. In
depth to accounts of macro-level events and turn, participants ascribe meaning to
relationships. these theories and, in so doing, develop and
Institutional forces shape individual inter- reproduce taken-for-granted understandings.
ests and desires, framing the possibilities Institutional transformation is often rather
for action and influencing whether subtle, not particularly abrupt, and apparent
behaviors result in persistence or change. only after a considerable period. Rather than
Macroinstitutional effects, through processes perspectives that either highlight habitual
of classification and categorization, create replication or savvy change agents, we stress
conventions that are the scripts for meaning that most micro-motives are fairly mundane,
making. This process is recursive and self- aimed at interpretation, alignment, and mud-
reinforcing. Institutional logics are instanti- dling through. And, as individuals and
ated in and carried by individuals through groups engage in such actions and resist
their actions, tools, and technologies. Some others’ attempts as well, they may well trans-
actions reinforce existing conventions, while form logics and alter identities.
others reframe or alter them. Ideas can be We contend that institutional analysis needs
picked up in one setting and transposed to more attention to everyday processes than
another, tools can be multi-purpose, and momentous events, to less powerful members
some settings are rife with multiple logics. of organizations as opposed to only leaders or
Such situations afford considerable latitude champions, and to cultural and cognitive
for human agency and interpretation. aspects as well as political ones. Research on
Nonetheless, the individuals that presently external shocks that prompt change and on
populate institutional analysis are portrayed voices that catalyze transformations has been
as either ‘cultural dopes’ (Garfinkel, 1967: valuable in adding insight into how institu-
68–75) or heroic ‘change agents’ (Strang and tions are altered. But a more explicit focus is
Sine, 2002: 503–507). The move to needed on how the local affairs of existing
consider institutional entrepreneurs was members of a field can both sustain and
motivated by a desire to replace the over- prompt shifts in practices and conventions.
socialized individuals who seemed slavishly The ongoing activities of organizations can
devoted to habit and fashion. But the celebra- produce both continuity and change, as such
tion of entrepreneurs has perhaps gone too pursuits vary across time and place.
far, as not all change is led by entrepreneurs, There is presently much interest in under-
and surely heroic actors and cultural dopes standing institutional change, as attention has
are a poor representation of the gamut of shifted from early concerns with persistence
human behavior. Indeed, we recoil somewhat and convergence to growing concern with
at the frequent use of ‘actors’ in social sci- dynamics and contestation. We welcome this
ence writings to characterize both individuals development, but worry that too many analyses
and organizations. As Meyer (Chapter 21 in conflate macro-factors with structural forces
this volume) notes, such language typically and assume these factors only reinforce stabil-
implies purposive, muscular, rather free ity and homogeneity, while associating micro-
actors, unembedded in their surrounding factors with entrepreneurship and agency.
context. Institutional theory gains little by But individuals also play a powerful role in
278 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

maintaining the social order, and organizations theory, but it is important to attend to the dif-
can serve as entrepreneurs. Moreover, macro- ferent directions of the causal arrows in these
trends, such as globalization, can be pro- research traditions.
foundly destabilizing to local orders and There is, of course, an exceedingly broad
individuals. It is a mistake for institutional ana- literature in social psychology. Our goal is
lysts to blindly equate change with the micro- selective, that is, to cull useful work that
level and persistence with the macro. We need complements the arguments that have char-
to develop multi-level explanations that acterized institutional theory and aid in
account for recursive influences. explaining the creation, transformation, and
Some attention has already been paid to impact of institutions. To this end, we draw
micro-translation, or an understanding of how on research that highlights constructivist
macro-categories get inside the heads of indi- processes. To illustrate, consider the verbs
viduals (Jepperson, 1991). Macro-framings typically used in the literatures we highlight.
or values can be ‘pulled down’ to the every- With interactionist arguments, scholars
day level of practice, as varied activities can commonly use the terms saving face or
be pursued under a common interpretation or affirming. In ethnomethodology, negotiate
account, or diverse practices can be pursued and improvise have primacy. With sensemak-
in the search of a common goal (Colyvas and ing, enact is the standard bearer. Research on
Powell, 2006; Colyvas, 2007a). Indeed, many legitimation processes finds associated with,
micro-processes represent local instantiations orient towards, comply with, and accept.
of macro-level trends. We need a parallel Note that we rarely find words like choose,
effort to link key micro-concepts, e.g. iden- plan, or determine (see Weick, Sutcliffe, and
tity, sense making, typifications, frames, and Obstfeld, 2005 for a lovely discussion on this
categories with macro-processes of institu- point). These verbs are more constructivist,
tionalization, and show how these processes constitutive and interpretive than calculative
ratchet upwards. This linkage between levels or purposive. The individuals in these
holds promise to better explain institutional theories behave, but they seldom choose
dynamics. Attention to the mediating role of (see discussion in DiMaggio and Powell,
language, interaction rituals, and categories 1991: 7–11).
will help explain how organizational routines Many of the writings that provided the ini-
and rules develop, stick, and fall into disuse. tial microfoundations for institutional theory
date from 1967 – Erving Goffman’s
Interaction Ritual, Harold Garfinkel’s
BUILDING BLOCKS FOR Studies in Ethnomethodology, and Berger
MICROFOUNDATIONS and Luckman’s The Social Construction of
Reality were all published in that propitious
As a rough approximation, we divide the lit- year. It is notable that we continue to draw on
eratures we discuss below into two main this work that is more than four decades old.
groupings. The first draws on arguments that In their canonical article, Meyer and Rowan
adopt a ‘built-up’ focus, in which micro-level (1977) observed that much ceremonial activ-
rituals and negotiations aggregate over time. ity, and accompanying categorical rules, gen-
These local influences may bubble up and erates conflict and uncertainty in day-to-day
threaten or replace macro-level coherence. activities. They proposed that organizations
The second line of analysis focuses on how resolve these tensions through decoupling
macro-orders are ‘pulled down,’ and become and a logic of confidence. Drawing on
imbricated in local or particular cases, situat- Goffman (1967: 5–45), they invoked his idea
ing macro-effects inside organizations and of ‘maintaining face.’ Crafting a distinction
individuals. Both streams of research are vital between the public face and backstage
to building microfoundations for institutional reality, overlooking or avoiding anomalies,
MICROFOUNDATIONS OF INSTITUTIONAL THEORY 279

minimizing discordant signals, and decou- ‘more to the efficacy than the frequency of its
pling formal procedures and structures from application’ (p. 13). Skill at face-work is a
everyday work are all steps taken to maintain distinguishing feature that differentiates indi-
the assumption that organizations are acting viduals. He was also very cognizant of how
appropriately and that larger rationalized interaction rituals connected to the larger
myths are sustained. This ‘logic of social order. Goffman himself was a highly
confidence’ is crucial to maintaining an skilled card player, and he drew a distinction
illusion of consensus within schools, for between ‘the value of a hand drawn at cards
example. and the capacity of the person who plays it’
DiMaggio and Powell’s (1991) overview (p. 32). Not only are the rules of how cards
of the elements of a theory of practical action are played highly governed, a reputation for
also drew on microfoundations, using an good or bad play is a face that requires main-
ensemble of ideas from Simon (1945), taining. Such micro-encounters at a card
Garfinkel (1967), and Giddens (1984). table represent sequences of coordinated
Responding to readings of their 1983 article understandings from which social interaction
that contended that mimetic and normative is accomplished.
isomorphism entailed ‘mere’ copying and For Goffman, speech, expressive behavior,
replication, DiMaggio and Powell empha- and demeanor embody intentions, but these
sized that practical consciousness involves individual instruments are ‘governed’ by the
energy, effort, and reflection. Drawing on normative order of society. In Asylums,
Simon (1945: 79–109), they recognized that Goffman (1961) discussed how organizations
habitual action does not reflect passivity, but instill tacit acceptance and conformity
is a skilled means of directing attention. through inducements. But in his work on
Garfinkel (1967) contributed the critical face-saving, he emphasized how individuals
insight that everyday reasoning requires indi- use talk, with ritual care, to present an image
viduals to negotiate rules and procedures of self-control and dignity. While standards
flexibly and reflexively to assure themselves and rules ‘are impressed upon individuals
and others around them that their behavior is from without,’ the particular rules an individ-
sensible. Giddens’ (1984: 54) observation ual follows derive ‘from requirements estab-
that sustaining social interaction is the ‘basic lished in the ritual organization of social
security system’ of the self, and that control encounters’ (Goffman, 1967: 45).
of human anxiety is the ‘most generalized
motivational origin of human conduct’ was
also influential. DiMaggio and Powell’s ini- Ethnomethodology
tial outline of a theory of practical action was
brief, but it clearly attempted to build on While Goffman emphasized how facility at
microfoundations. We seek to continue and everyday interactions sustains face, Harold
deepen that discussion, and build on others Garfinkel, one of Talcott Parsons’ favorite stu-
who have made contributions in recent years dents, developed a distinctive line of inquiry
(Jennings and Greenwood, 2003; Lawrence that stressed the skills that emerge out of
and Suddaby, 2006; Weber and Glynn, 2006; everyday encounters, which generate sociabil-
Lounsbury and Crumley, 2007;). ity and reproduce the social order. His eth-
nomethodological approach has provided
tantalizing insights for institutional theory,
most clearly in Zucker’s (1977) work, where
Interaction rituals
she argues that many taken-for-granted under-
Goffman (1967) was keenly aware that indi- standings are ‘built up’ from the ground level
vidual capability at ‘face work’ varied con- by participants in interactions, and in
siderably, but that such variation pertained DiMaggio and Powell’s (1991: 22–27)
280 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

sketch of a theory of practical action. how the penal code was used by public
Ethnomethodology never developed into an defenders with great facility. Lawyers took
expansive subfield, and given both its cult-like into account a welter of ‘facts’ – the ecologi-
approach and the controversies it provoked, cal characteristics of a community, the
perhaps it never had the chance.1 Nevertheless, biographies of criminals and victims, and
Garfinkel’s focus on practical reasoning and past records of criminal activity. They trans-
the role of ‘accounts’ in normalizing and legit- formed a criminal action into a shorthand
imating the social order offers considerable representation that was intelligible to attor-
insight into the implicit and contested assump- neys and judges. Sudnow’s brilliant analysis
tions that make organizational life possible. revealed how delicate teamwork between the
Rather than find social order in cultural norms offices of public defender and public prose-
or social roles, ethnomethodologists examine cutor in the face of a demanding organiza-
the cognitive work that individuals do to assure tional calendar jointly facilitated the
both themselves and those around them that construction of ‘normal crimes,’ a proverbial
their behavior is reasonable. characterization that certain kinds of illegal
There are several compelling reasons to actions were typically committed by particu-
revisit this line of work. Contemporary lar types of people. Once such categoriza-
scholars are largely unaware of just how tions were made, plea bargaining ensued,
much of this research focused on work and based on unstated recipes for reducing
organizations. Meticulous studies of record- original charges to lesser defenses to avoid
keeping procedures in juvenile justice facili- the costs of trial.
ties (Cicourel, 1968), high mortality wards in In ethnomethodological studies, categories
hospitals (Sudnow, 1967), and psychiatric and classifications become interpretive
clinics (Garfinkel and Bittner, 1967) reveal schema that members of organizations draw
how counting, reporting, and legal require- on. Over time, these schemas become a
ments are often highly improvised, as veteran repository of organizational knowledge. As
staff draw on deep, tacit knowledge of how particular schemas become routinized
reports ought to be assembled. Other work through repeated application and use, they
examined case files, folders, and dockets to develop a habitual, taken-for-granted
ascertain the classification schemes used in character. Berger and Luckman (1967)
psychiatry or a public welfare agency, where emphasized that once joint activities are
documents could be treated either as ‘plain habitualized and reciprocally interpreted,
facts’ or the opportunity to construct an patterns both harden and deepen as they are
account that provides grounds for accepting transmitted to others, particularly newcomers.
the testimony of the document against the When schemas become perceived as objec-
testimony of the welfare applicant tive, exteriorized facts, their contingent ori-
(Zimmerman, 1969). gins are obscured. Organizations do have
Bittner’s (1967) studies of policing on skid rich and varied repertoires, however, and
row illuminate how officers performed com- multiple schemas are available. The possibil-
plicated and demanding work with relative ity of mixing or combining practices in alter-
ease, without any real personal or peer recog- native or novel ways to produce different
nition of their skills. Given that the destitute patterns is ever present.
and mentally ill were often the objects of Throughout this rich vein of research, eth-
police work on skid row, perhaps the lack of nomethodologists demonstrate how classifi-
high regard is to be expected. But Bittner cations and categorizations are invoked on
underscored how strongly a powerful sense the fly by skilled actors to keep peace on the
of craftsmanship among the police was ren- streets, in the courts, in hospital wards, and
dered routine, even as it went unacknowl- welfare agencies. Consider the contrast of
edged. Similarly, Sudnow (1965) analyzed this view with the conception of organization
MICROFOUNDATIONS OF INSTITUTIONAL THEORY 281

found in many other lines of organization relation to one another and to the market
theory. Rather than struggling with or coping through their models and artifacts.3 This
with uncertainty, the practical reasoning view approach to ‘making markets’ resonates with
emphasizes how situations are rendered core themes of ethnomethodology in the
comprehensible, and sees such efforts as an view that phenomena only exist in the
ongoing, contingent accomplishment. In ‘doing’ and social relations have to be
contrast, ever since Weber, most students of continuously performed in order to persist.
organizations regard formal structures and For Callon (1998, 2006), a discourse is
procedures as ‘ideally possible, but practi- performative if it contributes to the construc-
cally unattainable’ (Bittner, 1965). Selznick tion of the reality that it describes. Callon
(1949), for example, attributed these limita- (2006) is careful to distinguish the idea
tions to the recalcitrance of the tools of of performativity from Goffman’s imagery of
action; while Weber conceived of the typical the presentation of self and from Merton’s
bureaucracy more as a target or an idealiza- (1948) notion of a self-fulfilling prophecy.
tion. For the ethnomethodologists, however, A self-fulfilling prophecy often has a
bureaucracy is neither a rarified nor lofty pathological form of influence or entails a
goal, but deeply embedded in common-sense misconception of the situation. In contrast,
routines of everyday life. Organization is a performativity is not arbitrary, rather
formula to which all sorts of problems can be there are contests associated with
brought for solution (Bittner, 1965). performance. Success or failure become
This focus on practical reasoning as a clear at the end of struggles, when opposi-
routine accomplishment emphasizes how tion, controversy and cooperation are sorted
people in organizations both make and find a out. The general claim of this line of study is
reasonable world.2 Organizational life entails that such diverse domains as science,
constant doing and achieving. For Goffman technology, accounting, marketing, engineer-
and Garfinkel, social order is created on the ing, and even friendship are all arenas where
ground floor, through situated local prac- activities, relationships, theories, and tools
tices. As practices are reproduced over time are both created and enhanced by their
and across settings, macro-categories emerge performance.
from these interactions and negotiations. The Scottish sociologist Donald
MacKenzie has been highly influential in
developing and studying the idea of ‘the per-
formativity of economics.’ He has, with his
Performativity
students, studied many of the major eco-
Across the Atlantic, a companion line of nomic innovations of the late 20th century,
work known as actor-network theory has viewing economists and their theories and
developed in France, focusing on scientific tools not only as describers and analysts, but
research and practical applications of science as participants and inventors. Mackenzie and
outside the laboratory (Latour, 1987). Millo’s (2003) research on options trading,
The core assumption of these studies is that which ‘with its cognitive complexity and
laboratory life often requires scientists to mature mathematical models has been a cen-
create material conditions in which theory tral driver of the marketized, mathematicized
and reality can be juxtaposed and in so doing risk-evaluation culture’ of modern life, shows
create affordances that make science ‘work’ that the famous Black, Scholes and Merton
(Latour and Woolgar, 1979; Callon, 1986). model did not describe an already existing
Callon (1998) has recently expanded the world. When first introduced, the model’s
actor-network approach to the field of assumptions were unrealistic and prices dif-
economics, and analyzed how market par- fered systematically from it. But with its
ticipants think about economics and act in growing use and prevalence, option prices
282 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

began to exhibit a near-perfect fit to the as accumulated experience, to interpret and


values predicted by the model.4 Clearly, tech- produce organizational life. These strands of
nological and computational improvements social psychology attend less to emergence
played a role in the acceptance of options, as and performance, and more to interpretation,
did the elite status of the authors of the appropriateness, and meaning making.
model, but options pricing came to shape the
way participants thought and talked about
finance, and altered the understanding of Sensemaking
volatility and arbitrage. MacKenzie (2006)
does not consider a financial model to be a Karl Weick’s research program on sensemak-
camera capturing reality, but an engine that ing addresses how people enact order and
allows traders to explore and exploit eco- coordinate action. Individuals convert cir-
nomic phenomena. cumstances into action through the reciprocal
Abstracting from this important case, interpretation of who they are and how they
MacKenzie (2006) argues that performativity understand their environment (Weick, 1995).
entails transformation: an aspect of econom- Identity, the enacted world, and accepted
ics must be used in a way that has effects on mental models are all key to this perspective.
the economic processes in question. The Taken together, sensemaking is the locus of
model or tool, he argues, must make a differ- how ‘meanings materialize that inform and
ence, that is economic processes that incor- constrain identity into action’ (Weick,
porate this element of economic reasoning Sutcliffe, and Obstfeld, 2005: 409).
must differ from processes where it is not Weick and colleagues draw on many
used. MacKenzie takes pains not to portray strands of microsociology to fashion their
modern economists as rational, calculating approach. Garfinkel’s (1967) insight that
agents but as human beings, limited in their rationality is constructed through common-
cognitive capacity and susceptible to social place interactions is emphasized; so is
influence. Nor does he fully embrace a view Goffman’s (1974) use of frames as providing
that businesses in the U.S. and around the a structure to social context. Sensemaking
world have become ‘financialized,’ and analyses share with ethnomethodology a
attend solely to market-value maximization, methodological stance of privileging cases
even though his superb analysis of the legiti- that reveal rather than represent.5 But there
mation of options pricing provides consider- are notable distinctions as well. While the
able evidence for such an argument. Instead, ethnomethodologists highlight the cognitive
his focus on performativity illuminates how work of individuals in creating social order,
human beings can ‘achieve outcomes that go sensemaking attends to the contingent influ-
beyond their individual cognitive grasp’ ences of norms and role structure. For Weick,
(MacKenzie, 2006: 268). By stressing human conceptions of identity and logics of action
cognitive limits and the distributed nature of are relational, constructed not only through
cognition in contemporary organizations, projections of self and others’ perceptions,
this line of research demonstrates how the but also through scripted interactions in rela-
‘social’ and the ‘technological’ come tion to what others are ‘supposed to do.’
together to constitute markets. Individuals are enmeshed in a structure of
We turn now to other micro research pro- relationships, taking cues from both situa-
grams that also focus on how everyday prac- tions and others, and these guideposts
tice in organizations produces meaning – provide substance for them to enact their
whether in the form of accepted routines or environments.
legitimated models. These other approaches, In his analysis of the Mann Gulch fire dis-
we contend, emphasize more that interaction aster in Montana, Weick (1993) demonstrates
often draws on the larger social order, as well how a breakdown in sensemaking explains
MICROFOUNDATIONS OF INSTITUTIONAL THEORY 283

what went wrong in a seemingly routine codes or specifications (March, 1994; Weick,
encounter for a highly trained crew. The dis- 1995). These distinctions are important
integration of the crew’s routines in the face because while information can provide a
of unexpected conditions impeded the fire- remedy for uncertainty, it can also further
fighters’ ability to draw on their stock of ambiguity, as evidenced by the Mann Gulch
experiences to generate a novel means of sur- fire when new information did not fit precon-
vival, or to comply with their leader who did. ceived categories. Weick also draws on
Weick attributes the tragic deaths of these Garfinkel to emphasize that equivocality is
skilled men to three features: a breakdown in present when numerous or disputed interpre-
role structure among members of the team, a tations exist. As with Garfinkel’s jurors, indi-
stalwart adherence to a less critical catego- viduals may justify multiple, incompatible
rization of the fire, and practical challenges accounts, often with the same evidence.
to their identities as firefighters. All of these Weick argues that uncertainty, ambiguity,
features are reflected in the difficulties that and equivocality may occasion different trig-
the firefighters faced to make sense of who gers to, and remedies for, sensemaking.
they were, the situation they encountered, A notable feature of sensemaking studies
and the repertoire of actions they should take. is a focus on situations where apparently
Because the stock of experience of the fire- normal events go badly awry.6 Sensemaking
fighters did not match their anticipated, less emphasizes interpretation and (mis)percep-
critical categorization of the fire when they tion of the environment, especially where
arrived on the scene, the situation was received wisdom is poorly aligned with
rendered meaningless, as ‘less and less of current context. For example, Scott Snook’s
what they saw made sense’ (Weick, 1993: (2000) examination of the 1991 ‘friendly
635). Cues from other firefighters, e.g. stop- fire’ incident when US F-15 fighter pilots
ping for dinner and taking pictures, rein- shot down their own Black Hawk helicopters
forced a spurious categorization of the fire in peacetime over the Persian Gulf, demon-
and impeded the firemen’s ability to activate strates how an organizational failure may
a different course of action. When the leader occur without anything breaking or anyone
of the crew, confronted with looming disas- to blame. Snook attributes this tragedy
ter, lit a fire in the only escape route, lay to a slow, gradual drift away from globally
down in its ashes, and called on his crew to synchronized logics of action, encoded in
drop their tools and join him, the team disin- written rules and procedures, to locally gen-
tegrated. The firefighter’s identities hindered erated task-based routines. Such ‘practical
their ability to comprehend an order to drop drift’ is often manifested locally as adapta-
the very materials that defined who they were tion because individuals organize around
and comprehend the practicality of a solution the immediate demands of work, and thus
that would have saved their lives. Weick’s learn and adjust to their own realities. Similar
analysis demonstrates that even very effec- to Mann Gulch, where the smokejumpers
tively trained and organized teams can ignored cues that the fire was more serious
falter when ‘the sense of what is occurring than categorized, the F-15 fighter pilots
and the means to rebuild that sense were unable to identify that the helicopters
collapse together’ (1993: 633). were not the enemy. In both settings,
From a sensemaking view, many features the individuals attended to cues that fit
of organizational life are uncertain, which their expectations, missing numerous con-
relates to ignorance or the inability to esti- trary signals. Futhermore, like the smoke-
mate future consequences to present actions. jumpers, the fighter pilots relied on each
Organizational life is also wrought with other and their team for coordination, and
ambiguity, which reflects the inability to their responses reinforced their mistaken
attribute clear, mutually exclusive categories, interpretation.
284 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Through an analysis of the complexities of sensemaking and interpretation as the differ-


command in military missions, Snook ence between discovery and invention.
demonstrates how meaning trumped deci- Interpretation, with its focus on identification
sionmaking as context, identity, and the and understanding vis-à-vis a wider reality,
enacted environment constrained interpreta- relates to discovery, which implies that
tion and shaped action. The F-15 pilots had something is evident and needs to be recog-
to identify ‘what was going on’ before taking nized or approximated. Features of the world
any action, and their interpretation was con- are pre-given or ready-made. Sensemaking,
structed through who they were, prior expe- in its focus on process and generation, relates
rience, the pre-flight context, and social to invention, which emphasizes how images
interactions (Snook, 2000: 81). Sadly, their of a wider reality are created, maintained and
inaccurate reading led them to shoot down rendered objective. Much as action precedes
their comrades in broad daylight. sensemaking, sensemaking is a precursor to
Sensemaking provides important insights interpretation.
to the analysis of meaning, particularly the A sensemaking approach directs attention
idea that meaning making is not only about to the importance of language, routines, and
creation but also contingent expression. For communication for analyzing micro-
Weick, the key to identifying such instances processes. While emphasizing that various
rests on the view that sensemaking is inher- institutional materials are commonly ‘pulled
ently retrospective and precedes action down’ by individuals and translated within
because situations are only understood upon organizations, these processes may differ
completion.7 Meaning is shaped through across circumstances. Multiple modes of
attention to what has already occurred, and is meaning making occur at the interface
therefore directed, not attached, to action. of identity and the enacted environment,
This contrast emphasizes the influence of and how such understandings are forged and
what is current to perceptions of the past. enacted occurs through retrospection.
Thus, ‘… anything that affects remembering Sensemaking is thus a key micro-mechanism
will affect the sense that is made of remem- of institutionalization that allows considera-
bering’ (Weick, 1995: 26). Furthermore, tion of both the ‘cognitive complexities’ that
since outcomes and subjective objects are guide organizational behavior and recogni-
implicit in interpretation, sensemaking tion of the varied ways that institutionalized
entails a process that simultaneously enacts practices operate at the micro-level (Jennings
identity and environment. Identity is central and Greenwood, 2003).
because individuals act based on who they
are, not on what choices they have, and this Status expectations
feature is constituted out of the process of
interaction. Mead’s (1934) insight that each Research on expectation states provides
individual is a ‘parliament of selves’ and that a further point of discussion of how
‘social processes precede the individual macro-categories guide micro-interactions
mind’ are critical. The environment is not (Berger, Ridgeway, Fisek, and Norman, 1998;
viewed as a fixed and stable reality, but as a Correll and Ridgeway, 2003; Zelditch, 2001,
co-construction of individuals’ minds and 2004). This line of research views legitimation
their actions. Enactment represents the recip- as a process shaped by interpersonal status
rocal interaction of the material and the hierarchies, in which individuals draw on
cognitive world. Thus, individuals and envi- widely shared cultural beliefs concerning
ronments are mutually constitutive. status and success. These referential beliefs
This feature extends the process of are evoked in situations as both guides
sensemaking beyond interpretation. Weick for interaction and as ready accounts, creating
(1995: 13–14) likens the distinction between strong expectations as to the types of
MICROFOUNDATIONS OF INSTITUTIONAL THEORY 285

individuals who are or should be influential in level. This line of work emphasizes that it is
specific circumstances. In this fashion, broader in the conduct of tasks that social objects and
understandings about who and what is appro- categories drawn from the larger society are
priate guide local circumstances, and these rendered legitimate. This perspective
interactional processes further reinforce cul- complements sensemaking by stressing how
tural beliefs about what characteristics and external social statuses are manifested in
practices are perceived as appropriate. everyday activities.
Research on expectation states and legiti-
mation analyzes the emergence of status
within task groups, observing that power and
prestige are often accorded based on social MICRO-PERSPECTIVES ON
stereotypes regarding gender, race, age, edu- INSTITUTIONAL CHANGE
cation and occupation. In turn, these charac-
terizations shape and legitimate the manner We turn to a discussion of two examples of
in which group members evaluate one recent transformations that have typically
another (Ridgeway and Berger, 1986; been analyzed in terms of broader social and
Ridgeway and Walker, 1995). Thus, assign- political currents. In both settings, exogenous
ments of status draw readily on the macro- forces loom large in current explanations.
stratification system, while the assignments When attention is directed to the organiza-
and rewards that ensue at the group level tion level, most reports celebrate risk-taking
reinforce the larger social order. entrepreneurs. In contrast, our aim is to
Put differently, micro-level consensus is demonstrate how much explanatory power
generated through a process in which values can be garnered by examining the micro-
and beliefs from the larger society are pulled level processes underpinning these changes.
down into local circumstances, creating dif- We underscore how the ‘entrepreneurs’ did
ferential expectations about the performance not even consider that they were taking risks,
of individuals in task groups. These expecta- but instead were responding to unanticipated
tions can become taken-for-granted features situations.
of organizations, and persist even if they are
unjust or unproductive, thus giving them an
‘objective’ quality. Universities and academic
Owen-Smith (2001) analyzed a neuro-
entrepreneurship
science lab and the rankings of a community
of colleagues with respect to experimental In recent decades, U.S. universities and the
and analytic ability and productivity. He profession of academic science have under-
found that assessments of ability and accom- gone a profound transformation in the way
plishment are not neatly correlated. Instead, science is conducted. Where university and
position in the lab’s prestige order was industry were once separate domains, public
heavily shaped by expectations that accrue and private science have become intermin-
with rank and discipline, and whether one gled, notably in the norms and practices
was dependent or autonomous in regards to related to career advancement and in the
funding. In this academic research setting, development and dissemination of knowl-
gender as a status measure was less conse- edge. Patenting and licensing academic
quential than stereotyped expectations based research findings, taking equity in start-ups,
on disciplinary affiliation. and encouraging academic entrepreneurship,
Research on expectation states offers have become core features of how U.S.
another lens through which to view how universities define success.
widely shared societal beliefs become incor- Most studies of this transformation stress
porated and reinforced at the work group either pecuniary interests or national policies
286 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

(Lach and Shankerman, 2003).8 Indeed, aca- long before the Bayh-Dole legislation or
demic institutions made more than $1.385 bil- significant financial returns from university
lion in gross revenues in fiscal year 2004 from patents. By examining archival records of
technology licenses (AUTM, 2005). Before invention disclosures of biological scientists,
1980, there were fewer than 25 university tech- Colyvas identifies how practices took shape
nology transfer offices, and today there are in advance of external policy developments,
well over 200 (AUTM, 2005). Clearly, some how individual scientists pursued disparate
universities are profiting considerably from entrepreneurial actions, and how these
technology licensing, and virtually every actions were facilitated and anchored by
research university now has a technology organizational procedures. In the perform-
transfer office. Government policy has ance of technology transfer, commercializing
strongly encouraged such efforts. The Bayh- science was re-shaped and became
Dole Act in 1980 authorized universities to institutionalized.
take title to patents generated by federally In the 1970s, commercialization efforts
funded research. A Supreme Court decision in emerged from scientists’ labs when routines
the same year, Diamond vs. Chakrabarty, for technology transfer were ambiguous
authorized the patenting of life, providing a and unfamiliar. Unfamiliar projects included
catalyst to the emerging biotechnology indus- the importation of the legal categories of
try. A few universities, namely University of inventor and invention, the problem of
Wisconsin, Stanford, MIT, and UCSF are cred- establishing boundaries between business
ited for shaping the way in which technology and science, and the necessity to establish
transfer became organized (Mowery, Nelson, procedures for distributing royalties. This
Sampat and Ziedonis, 2004). Many organiza- ambiguity created opportunities for
tional accounts point to the founders and con- interpretation by both scientists and adminis-
sultants to university tech transfer programs as trators. Scientists, in the context of their
the key institutional entrepreneurs for the new laboratories, generated multiple accounts
university models (Mowery et al., 2004). One of who was an inventor, what kinds of
of these founders, Niels Reimers, created the science constituted an invention, as well as
Stanford University Office of Technology divergent views of how material benefits
Licensing, a highly successful operation on from commercial involvement could legiti-
which other technology transfer offices have mately be used.
modeled their operations. Reimers went on to For example, within a basic life science
reorganize programs at MIT and UCSF, and department that eventually became a hotbed
consult to many other universities in Europe of academic entrepreneurship in the 1990s,
and Asia. The ‘Stanford Model’ is practically a early efforts in the 1970s were fraught
household term in the technology licensing with uncertainty. Three examples from
community, emphasizing a marketing focus, this department are illustrative. One
service to faculty, and a lauded ‘incentive distinguished scientist, concerned with his
system’ of a 1/3 division of licensing royalties reputation, allowed the university to license
shared equally among the department, school, his basic biological research tool only with
and scientists. hesitation and declined any personal royal-
A careful analysis of archival records and ties, agreeing to participate only after secur-
interviews with participants at Stanford ing agreement to donate his proceeds. ‘I can
University suggests an alternative account in accept a view that it is more reasonable for
which current practices evolved from con- any financial benefits … to go to the univer-
flicting conceptions about commercializing sity, rather than be treated as a windfall profit
science. Colyvas (2007a) analyzes scientists’ to be enjoyed by profit motivated businesses;
engagement with commercializing life I agreed to cooperate … for that reason …’
science inventions at Stanford in the 1970s, (Colyvas, 2007a: 465). Another noted
MICROFOUNDATIONS OF INSTITUTIONAL THEORY 287

scientist, motivated by how industry develop- to benefit everyone equally. In the third
ment of his invention would disseminate his example, the scientist theorized cause and
technology and expand his research program, effect in response to his perception of a crisis
reasoned that royalties should benefit his over industry exploitation, control and
laboratory, the locus of the effort for the justice: ‘I assure you that I will alert my
research. ‘Many ‘inventions’ are really the colleagues throughout the world to guard
work of a group … Although inventors need against what I consider exploitation’
to be identified in the technical sense to sat- (Colyvas, 2007a: 467).
isfy the requirements of the patent process, in The variation in responses reflects a
fact, the most important advances often are profound tension between public and private
made by other members of the group …’ science at the incipient stages of technology
(Colyvas, 2007a: 464). This scientist refused transfer. Attention to micro-processes,
to patent basic biological materials, stating however, demonstrates how much meanings
that patenting was neither necessary nor were generated through practical action as
appropriate for their dissemination, but he local, experiential aspects of the laboratory
believed that strong property rights for and scientists’ identities and emotions inter-
device inventions were important. A third acted to construct an appropriate conception
scientist, angered at companies’ lucrative of academic entrepreneurship. These scien-
exploitation of academic science, demanded tists were neither cultural dopes nor institu-
remuneration to the university: ‘Although tional heroes. As much as they recognized
many of us are not in a position to exploit our the unfamiliarity of their industry ties and
discoveries, we do feel that universities … questioned the legitimacy of their activities,
should benefit from profitable applications of they were also aware of the opportunities and
our findings. I had hoped that an industry so benefits of their actions. Involvement in
recently spawned by university research entrepreneurial science was not simply
would be enlightened in its recognition of repeated and habituated, however. As
who is responsible for its existence …’ practices were executed, they were also
(Colyvas, 2007a: 467) He also threatened altered and justified anew, as the same indi-
corporate partners that he would patent viduals and their peers tried their hand at
‘everything in sight’ in order to beat industry subsequent inventions. The organization of
at their own game. the laboratory and the ethos embedded in it
These examples provide evidence of informed how technology transfer would be
significant variation in how scientists in one performed.
department at the same university practiced The organizational ambiguity attached to
commercialization differently and ascribed definitions of inventor and invention, and
meaning to what they did. In the first exam- procedures associated with commercializing
ple, the scientist utilized an enduring vocab- science such as royalty distribution, provided
ulary from the profession of science, stating multiple opportunities for generating
that his contribution to a discovery was only disparate meanings and practices. These
because he was ‘standing on the shoulders of individual approaches resonated with the fac-
giants’ and could not identify himself as an ulty members because they drew on their
inventor by profiting personally from a familiar identities and ideals as scientists in
patent. He invoked the legitimacy that is meaning-making processes. As the world of
accorded to the scientific enterprise, and the science came into contact with commerce,
expectations that flow from it. In the second the identity associated with a university
example, political and ideological references scientist expanded to include entrepreneur-
provided resources for justifying practices ship. As more high-status elite scientists par-
and generating claims of ‘team effort’ that ticipated in such activities, commercial
the laboratory was communal and organized involvement transitioned from unfamiliar
288 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

and unusual to plausible and appropriate, forms, boilerplate letters of agreement, and
and finally to a core component of a scien- marketing tools were developed and
tific career (Colyvas and Powell, 2007). By revised in order to anchor and support on-
engaging in the unfamiliar and making it going efforts at clarification. As categories
plausible in the context of academia, became settled, roles were more defined
scientists transformed what it meant to be a and practices well rehearsed. Job titles, con-
scientist. Their involvement helped render flict-of-interest guidelines, and organiza-
the older model of ivory tower science quaint tional routines developed to sustain these
and these new entrepreneurial activities activities. Eventually, there was little need
indicative of engagement (Colyvas and for articulation or explicit expositions
Powell, 2007). of the premises and rationales that char-
A parallel feature of the institutionaliza- acterized scientists’ early engagement in
tion of commercial science was the establish- entrepreneurship.
ment of routines and practices that created Language and meaning played an impor-
and normalized activities. Colyvas and tant harmonizing role at the organizational
Powell’s (2006) analysis of 31 years of tech- level as the vocabularies utilized in this set-
nology transfer archives at Stanford ting transformed over time. In the early
University demonstrates the importance of years, commercializing science was pursued
the instantiation and codification of two core as an exception rather than the rule, justified
institutional features – legitimacy and taken- for the ‘benefit and use of the public.’
for-grantedness – into organizational rules As university technology transfer gained
and procedures. They show how the develop- legitimacy and the once sharp boundaries
ment of conventions extended academic between university and industry blurred, a
science further into the industrial realm, and more local, institutional vocabulary
how the integration of universities and took form. Finally, during the later stages
companies into a community of common of institutionalization, the language of
interests became desirable and appropriate. entrepreneurship and academic mission
Once prohibited from consulting to compa- became integrated into a common identity
nies that commercialized their technologies, of public benefit, profession, and practical
academic scientists became emulated for action. The language of science and
their multiple roles as founders, scientific the mission of the university to benefit the
advisory board members, and equity holders. public endured, yet the conventions associ-
Conflict of interest policies and reporting ated with them were redefined as the institu-
requirements occasioned these opportunities, tionalization process unfolded. We see
shaping and reinforcing the appropriate similar processes of unexpected circum-
form that entrepreneurship would take. stances becoming routinized, and made
Social and technical categories provided sensible in our second case, to which we
windows into the core cognitive features of now turn.
taken-for-grantedness. The criteria that dis-
tinguished an ‘inventor’ from a co-author, or
an ‘invention’ from a research publication Earned income and nonprofit
were transformed from points of elaborate
organizations
discussion to well-understood, highly
scripted routines and guidelines. The kinds Commercialization is a much discussed
of responsibilities and expectations that topic in the nonprofit world. More and more
would be imposed on scientists in the nonprofits are pursuing commercial activities
commercialization process also underwent a to secure funds, and turning to earned
similar process of elaboration and subse- income activities to boost their budgets.
quent compression. Invention disclosure The fiscal challenges faced by nonprofits are
MICROFOUNDATIONS OF INSTITUTIONAL THEORY 289

considerable and many external funding art – and museum directors and entrepreneur-
sources now demand and support more entre- ial administrators who are responsible for the
preneurial approaches (Powell, Gammal, and financial viability of the organization.
Simard, 2005). Not only do some funding Debates over the benefits or disadvantages of
sources stipulate earned income efforts, but earned income activities seldom attend to
there are a growing array of courses, pro- evidence drawn from day-to-day operations,
grams, and elite entrepreneurs that prosely- however. When we examine rare, successful
tize about importing entrepreneurship into cases of revenue generation, we see a rather
the nonprofit sector. Moreover, many non- different account in which local action has
profits prefer to deliver goods and services in often emerged as necessity in response to
a fashion that does not create dependency, as unexpected conditions. These practical
they view extensive reliance on donors as a responses triggered new steps that eventually
sign of vulnerability and weakness. There is led to organizational changes, and connected
also a widespread neo-liberal belief that with much ballyhooed larger macro-trends,
market discipline is healthy, and entrepre- but were not prompted by them. In such
neurial activities generate autonomy and cases the ethnomethodological insight that
build capabilities (Dees, 1998). mixing practices prompts surprise and nov-
Most of the literature on earned income elty can be applied to illuminate how new
activities follows two themes. One argument forms are generated.
stresses the need to augment the social non- A notable case of successful nonprofit
profit sector with practices from for-profit entrepreneurship is Minnesota Public Radio
businesses (Letts et al., 1997; Porter and (MPR), one of the nation’s largest and now
Kramer, 1999), with attention focused on the richest public radio stations, known for
individuals and organizations involved in the award-winning documentaries, innovative
transfer and circulation of ideas across sec- programming, and extraordinary success at
tors.9 To these analysts, entrepreneurial ven- revenue generation.10 Between 1986 and
tures have become the ‘hallmark’ of a 2000, MPR’s for-profit ventures generated
successful nonprofit. The second theme is $175 million in earned income for the non-
sung by a chorus of scholars and practition- profit station, including a $90 million contri-
ers who worry that earned income initiatives bution to its endowment (Phills and Chang,
are particularly difficult for nonprofit organi- 2005). The origins of this success reveal how
zations and that responding to both financial strongly organizational behavior is often
and non-financial concerns is inevitably constructed ‘on the fly’, and necessity is the
fraught with tension (Foster and Bradach, mother of entrepreneurship.
2005). These discussions are healthy for In the late 1970s and early 1980s, MPR
theory and practice, as they not only high- developed a satirical show called A Prairie
light the tensions between making a profit Home Companion. They offered the show to
and staying true to one’s mission, but also National Public Radio, but NPR declined,
recognize that basing decisions solely on saying it wasn’t a show that would have
mission can threaten financial survival, while nationwide appeal. It appears that MPR was
putting business concerns ahead of organiza- peeved by National Public Radio’s decision
tional mission can have deleterious long- to decline the show, which fueled the desire
term consequences (Minkoff and Powell, to make the show successful. By the early
2006). 1980s, A Prairie Home Companion had gen-
The rival metaphors of mission and busi- erated a fairly healthy audience, and in 1981
ness often lead to internal strife within non- Garrison Keillor, the show’s popular host,
profit organizations. For example, this offered listeners a free poster of his mythical
tension is manifest in an art museum between sponsor, Powdermilk Biscuits. The fictitious
curators – the traditional guardians of sponsor was part of a regular ongoing gag on
290 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

the show. To everyone’s surprise, more than fascination with assembling ham radio sets
50,000 listeners requested a copy of the and listening to distant stations.
poster. The station faced a $60,000 printing In December 1995, MPR asked a handful
bill. In such circumstances of surprise, sense- of employees to assist Rivertown Trading on
making efforts often spring into action. And a voluntary basis to fulfill backlogged
so MPR continued the tradition of the ficti- holiday orders. MPR employees were told
tious sponsor by turning it into a commercial that Rivertown would make donations to
product. To avert financial disaster, MPR their favorite charities or contribute to a
President William Kling recalled, ‘We holiday party for those who volunteered.
decided to print on the back of a poster an Nine employees pitched in, working two to
offer for other products that you could buy, three hours each, earning $350 each for their
like a Powdermilk Biscuit t-shirt. The idea favorite charities. The expectation at MPR
worked. I think we netted off that poster, was that employees at the radio station and
which was really our first catalog, $15,000 or the catalog company should be from
$20,000’ (William Kling, quoted in Phills common backgrounds. Indeed, Kling, the
and Chang, 2005: 65). ‘It instantly became general counsel and other key staff were
clear that there were things like that you executives at both companies. ‘We didn’t
could do’ (Kling, quoted in Khan, 1995). want to hire people who worked for Lands
To tap the popularity of A Prairie Home End or Williams Sonoma,’ William Kling
Companion, MPR created the Rivertown commented, ‘we wanted people who held the
Trading Company, a mail order catalog busi- values of the nonprofit.’12 This decision also
ness that sold mugs, t-shirts, novelties, and led to a firestorm of protest and controversy.
eventually clothing, jewelry and items Politicians in Minnesota, newspaper
related to Keillor’s radio show. The new reporters, and other public broadcasting offi-
entity grew rapidly and by 1986 was reorgan- cials were highly critical that employees of
ized as a separate for-profit subsidiary of the nonprofit radio station also received com-
MPR to remove any legitimacy and tax pensation for their work with for-profit
issues related to a nonprofit organization Rivertown Trading, and considerably higher
owning a highly profitable business. By wages to boot. Instead of seeing routines and
1994, Rivertown Trading distributed five cat- organizational continuity, critics saw a pat-
alogs, including Wireless, Signals, Seasons, tern of insider dealing, conflict of interest,
Circa and Classica. It also ran the US Golf and public funding for an entrepreneurial
Association’s catalog. Moreover, the product effort, and raised concerns of unfair compen-
selection in its catalogs extended well sation and lack of transparency. It is not
beyond its original focus on gifts associated our task here to assess the merits of
with the Keillor show. these criticisms. We note instead that
The origins of Minnesota Public Radio Kling and colleagues’ response was to stress
also had a similar ‘creation in the wild’ that the interests of the radio station and the
flavor. Back in the 1960s, the president of a catalog company were indistinguishable.
small Benedictine college in Minnesota Kling emphasized that the $4 million in
asked a young college graduate, William annual support given by Rivertown to MPR
Kling, to start a college radio station to honor over two decades exceeded the budgets of
the Benedictine tradition of providing artistic the great majority of public radio stations in
and cultural enrichment to their local the U.S., and the $90 million endowment
communities. Kling viewed this opportunity that the sale of Rivertown produced, secured
in a simple manner: ‘I was doing what MPR’s future: ‘We could have done a lot of
I really liked to do, building something good things with MPR, but suffice to say the
that hadn’t been done before.’11 He likened $175 million contribution made it possible to
building the radio station to his childhood do things we would not have been able to
MICROFOUNDATIONS OF INSTITUTIONAL THEORY 291

otherwise.’ Rather than engage with or The story of MPR is notable for both
respond to critics, or assume the role of accomplishment and controversy. Few other
entrepreneurial champion, Kling focused on nonprofits have been so successful at revenue
the daily activities of a radio broadcaster: generation or as agile in securing a sizeable
more reporters, better signal coverage, more endowment to guarantee a sustainable future.
investigative journalism, and the ability to But rather than linking their efforts to
acquire struggling public radio stations in broader trends at social entrepreneurship,
other parts of the country. MPR’s leadership has responded modestly to
MPR is not the only nonprofit that has critics, emphasizing how earned income
generated earned income through new or activities were initially a response to an
alternative means in recent years. The chap- unexpected emergency. One might say that
ters in Weisbrod (1998) chronicle an array of MPR learned to perform as entrepreneurs,
activities pursued by organizations as diverse rather than ‘strategize’ about this perform-
as the Girl Scouts, zoos and acquaria, and art ance. Moreover, actions that critics inter-
museums. As government support has preted as inherently conflictual and
declined or stagnated, nonprofits have questionable stemmed from an organiza-
increasingly turned to revenue generation. tional practice that executives should oversee
But such efforts are most likely to be suc- the actions of both the station and the com-
cessful – financially, organizationally, and pany in order to ensure values-based continu-
politically – when they flow from existing ity between them. This choice clearly
operations. In the MPR context, success at reflected a managerial desire to routinize the
the catalog business built upon Garrison efforts of both branches of the organization,
Keillor’s performances. While critics opined and to engage in sensemaking around for-
that ‘if Garrison Keillor ever gets laryngitis, profit activities in service of nonprofit goals.
Bill Kling is out of business!’,13 Kling These two cases of university and non-
commented, ‘My fear is that there are too profit entrepreneurship illuminate how activ-
many nonprofits seeking the holy grail … if ities take form through micro-processes of
it doesn’t come naturally to you, you development and institutionalization.
shouldn’t do it.’14 Archival records, interviews, and vestiges of
In response to growing public criticisms organizational routines provide tools that
in the late 1990s over the large sums gener- reveal instances of practical reason and the
ated by the for-profit operation and the hand- attribution of meanings to such efforts. In the
some financial rewards that Kling and same manner as studies address the adoption
colleagues reaped from the sale of the cata- and spread of organizational forms, these
log business, Kling invoked a political justi- examples underscore how practices and their
fication for the activity: that entrepreneurial attendant meanings and identities develop
efforts with Riverside Trading were and crystallize into a form that later becomes
enhanced by the ‘imprimatur from the adopted.
Reagan administration that it is OK to go out The two cases we have used are admittedly
and think that way, indeed we encourage you unusual in several respects. They both
to think this way.’15 Interestingly, however, involve organizations that eventually became
none of the dozens of reports, newspaper highly successful at activities which were
columns, and magazine articles written about initially regarded as novel and unusual, even
the situation in the 1980s or early 1990s questionable. As the new practices and
employed a political mandate as a rationale. identities became institutionalized, the
More than a decade after the fact, the signa- organizations were held up for scrutiny and
ture of the Reagan era was ‘pulled down’ to debate, and then veneration and emulation
retrospectively explain the entrepreneurial (Colyvas and Powell, 2007). One advantage
effort. of studying these hallmark cases is there is a
292 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

rich documentary trail that can be analyzed. through the creation of formal conflict of
Studies of how institutional practices are interest forms and procedures. Today, the
formed should recognize the tradeoffs that number of spin-off companies has become a
are entailed in the choice of cases. metric by which universities are assessed for
Nevertheless, we think that fine-grained their contribution to local economic develop-
attention to enterprising organizations can be ment. With earned income efforts by
instructive, as well as analysis of how nonprofits, donors look less at the programs
activities do or do not spread to other venues they fund and which audiences they reach,
and are interpreted at other sites. and more at the percentage of administrative
costs that are allocated to program develop-
ment. Administrative overhead has become a
key, but rather orthogonal, criteria for assess-
RESEARCH METHODS FOR STUDYING ing the effectiveness of nonprofits. Such
MICROFOUNDATIONS categories and metrics have become not only
tools of evaluation, but the accounts by
In this last section, we discuss various tools which organizational leaders justify their
that researchers can use to study the activities.
emergence and sustainability of institutions. Following the insights of ethnomethodol-
Instead of assuming that institutions ogy, organizational record-keeping can
reproduce themselves, we examine efforts provide a longitudinal conversation about
that lead to institutional creation and mainte- how daily activities are rendered intelligible,
nance, and ways of capturing these affirming that organizational practices are
processes. comprehensible to others. Close examination
Language and vocabulary are a first step. of organizational archives and correspon-
These are the protocols that people use to dence, as well as newer electronic forms such
engage in dialogue and achieve mutual as websites, blogs and e-mail, afford the
understanding and inter-subjective aware- opportunity to witness organizational
ness. The next step is to see what aspects of performance, and see social reproduction at
language become codified into formal the micro-level, as daily accounts culminate
measures of performance and accomplish- into ongoing conversations and larger stories
ment. These constructed definitions become about organizational purposes and goals.
metrics by which people evaluate one One could, for example, listen to older
another. As these ‘accounts’ of performance broadcasts of Prairie Home Companion to
or activity take hold, they become reified, assess how often references were made on
that is received and accepted as normal by the air to the burgeoning catalog business to
their participants and adopted and emulated discern how earned income efforts perme-
by others who were not a part of their initial ated programming.
creation. In this sense, local measures A sensemaking approach directs us to
become ‘natural.’ Once natural, they become follow organizational actions – the efforts of
public, as the measures redefine and individuals as they engage in the routines of
reinterpret history, and evolve into models regular operations. This naturalistic focus on
that others aspire to, and are recognized as work as skill offers insights into how social
guideposts of accomplishment. meanings become attached to routine con-
Consider how start-up companies as uni- duct. Status expectations research alerts us to
versity spin-offs were once objects of contes- how standards of legitimacy in the broader
tation and debate, when the idea of society inform group practice. In contrast to
universities engaging in commercial ventures other approaches, this line of work alerts us
was nascent and questionable (Colyvas, to look for how social categories and expec-
2007a). Eventually, debate was resolved tations in the wider environment are utilized
MICROFOUNDATIONS OF INSTITUTIONAL THEORY 293

at the local level. Recall, for example, how in When Becker was having a difficult interac-
the early stages of academic entrepreneur- tion with a reservation clerk, he calmly said
ship, faculty used both the norms of science to the person, ‘I am an irate,’ and the opera-
and statements about the proper organization tor responded by asking him, ‘how did you
of their labs to communicate and interpret know that word?’ and immediately sped up
their experience with a novel activity. his reservation. The creation, resilience, and
Sensemaking is most salient when sur- transmission of categories offer a particularly
prises happen or events are perceived to be useful window into organizational life as
dissonant with past experience (Weick, they not only reflect daily practice but con-
Sutcliffe, and Obstfeld, 2005). In such nect organizations to the wider society as
instances, individuals reach into their reper- they render the mundane generalizable.
toire of experience to make a situation fit the Categories also contain either latent or
immediate circumstances and allow them to explicit rules for action, as they invoke
resume their actions.16 Weick suggests a scripts that are associated with people or
repertoire of vocabularies that direct attention problems. Studying the formation of cate-
and shape action. ‘Words approximate the ter- gories in organizations is an excellent way to
ritory’ and reflect resources for individuals to connect micro-level processes with the larger
convert ongoing cues into meaning by social order.
‘edit[ing] continuity into discrete categories Metaphors are another topic for examina-
and observations into interpretations …’ tion, as they provide a means of shaping the
(Weick, 1995: 107). Weick identifies both the understanding of a new experience by defin-
content (as words) and resources (as frames) ing one domain in terms of another. Lakoff
that vocabularies take. Individuals often draw and Johnson (1980: 142) suggest that
on the vocabularies of professions and occu- metaphors ‘… sanction actions, justify infer-
pations to understand organizational actions, ences, and help us set goals ….’ In doing so,
and cope with their consequences. At MPR, metaphors offer meaning to daily activity,
for example, the organization consistently often retrospectively by locating the past in
used the language of radio broadcasting to present beliefs, values, and daily tasks. The
explain their commercial success in the cata- ubiquity of metaphors renders them taken-
log business. In this respect, their discourse for-granted – in many respects invisible, yet
was performative, as it enacted and enhanced very salient in terms of generating and
the commercial enterprise. Since sensemak- transmitting meaning.
ing is primarily a retrospective process, indi- As one illustration, Colyvas (2007b)
viduals make sense of traditions by drawing examined the language used to explain
on the language of predecessors and use nar- the recombinant DNA breakthrough, tracing
ratives to account for sequence and experi- the thematic content in newspaper articles
ence. Language and communication are and campus documents regarding break-
central, as they provide filters and constraints throughs in genetic engineering in the
on what can be said, how expressions are cat- 1970s. The vocabulary of the time drew on
egorized, and conclusions retained. the metaphors of factories, hazards, and
Members of organizations expend consid- contamination, which transcended both
erable effort at communication through bacteria and university. She traced the appli-
codes, categories, and metaphors. Categories cation and flow of common language in both
serve as boxes or bins that people, problems, public media and private, university
and tools get assigned to. Bowker and Star correspondence, following the metaphors of
(1999: 38) recount a lovely story from soci- factory and production in formal announce-
ologist Howard Becker who learned that air- ments about the development of rDNA
line reservations staff have a category called an science. The factory image was first intro-
‘irate’ to characterize disgruntled customers. duced in the popular press as a way to
294 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

describe this basic research tool and explain engagement in entrepreneurship offers an
its linkage to curing disease. Concerns over example. Colyvas (2007a) coded practices
biohazards in the popular press, however, and premises separately for each invention
quickly amplified fears of contamination and over the first 12 years of the Stanford tech-
images of ‘Frankenstein genes.’ Eventually, nology licensing program. She identified
the production metaphor triumphed, captur- core areas in technology transfer where insti-
ing a theme of therapeutic and commercial tutions and resources intersected, notably in
promise. The same images quickly trans- the definitions of social and technical
posed into the university setting through categories and in how revenues from inven-
marketing discussions over patenting and tions were disbursed. Through analysis of
licensing the breakthrough. Becoming a ‘fac- correspondence archives, she discerned how
tory’ or ‘contaminating’ the academy became conventions developed and transformed as
exemplars for contesting commercial efforts scientists were introduced to the emerging
at the university. field of biotechnology. Laboratory-level
Viewed more abstractly, metaphor played models of technology transfer that were once
a comparable role of reducing ambiguity and coherent became fragmented. The conver-
mitigating uncertainty in both science and gence and harmonization of entrepreneurial
university settings. The application and nor- logics was characterized by the re-attach-
mative tone of the same imagery, however, ment of practices from some labs to the
differed as factory language extolled science meanings generated by other labs. She found
and technology, but simultaneously dispar- that the modern interpretation of an incentive
aged universities. By analyzing the two-way system for successful entrepreneurship was
flow of metaphors in science and society, the outcome of the process of institutional-
Colyvas highlighted the ways in which ization, rather than an input to it. Thus,
understandings are conveyed, developed, and actions shape meanings as much as meanings
transmitted through metaphor, and how those shapes practices (Mohr, 1998). This recur-
metaphors morph as they are transferred. sive process has a dynamic of variation and
Such work suggests that when metaphors change, much like the mutation of a virus
become generalized in their use, they render that transforms as it spreads or comes into
some features of social life ‘objective,’ contact with others. The meaning behind
but deflect attention to other aspects. patenting a scientific research finding is quite
As a result, metaphors shape perceptions of different today from 30 years ago, and what
situations, problems, and analogues for was once an exception for technological
solving them. One might regard institutional- necessity or currency for a career transition
ization as making metaphor dead. If the out of academia has become a core
surprise of metaphor is in its novel applica- component of an academic identity in the life
tion, then language may be understood sciences.
as a reef of ‘dead’ metaphors – that is, no Tradition and stories offer insight into the
longer unfamiliar, but routine and taken- retrospective aspects of organization (Weick,
for-granted. 1995). Tradition necessarily invokes the vocab-
The ongoing relationship between mean- ularies of predecessors, reinforcing patterns of
ing and action is another key area for inquiry. action that have been reproduced or believed
These core features of social life are not to have existed across generations. A notable
proxies for one another, but distinctive insti- feature of traditions is that they must become
tutional elements to investigate. Attention to symbolic in order to persist or be transmitted.
what individuals or organizations do, sepa- Stories draw on vocabularies of sequence
rately from what they mean by doing it, and experience. Patterns such as beginning,
should be central to the study of micro- middle, end, or situation, transformation,
processes. Our earlier analysis of scientists’ and situation often provide the basis for
MICROFOUNDATIONS OF INSTITUTIONAL THEORY 295

constructing narratives, drawing analogies and Tricia Martin, John Meyer, David Suarez and
causal linkages, integrating what is present to Megan Tompkins for helpful comments on
what is absent, and what is known to what is an earlier draft. Research support for
conjecture. When pressed about the entrepre- Powell provided by the Center for
neurial success of MPR, William Kling turned Social Innovation at the Stanford Graduate
to childhood memories of ham radios and the School of Business, and for Colyvas by
history of outreach of the Benedictine church, the Columbia-Stanford Consortium on
and not to a celebration of business acumen. Biomedical Innovation.
This discussion was offered as an entry
into methods for studying processes of
micro-institutionalization. As a next step, an
analysis could distinguish between meanings NOTES
and practices in cross-case comparisons over
time, particularly in tracing institutional 1 See, for example, the review symposium on
change as the product of micro-level efforts Garfinkel’s Studies in Ethnomethodology in the
at enactment, interpretation, and compliance. January 1968 American Sociological Review, notably
Coleman’s (1968) blistering critique, or Coser’s
(1974) presidential address where he used the bully
pulpit of the annual ASA meetings to argue that eth-
nomethodology was a method in search of a theory.
SUMMARY 2 Garfinkel (1968) describes this accomplishment
aptly: ‘how jurors know what they are doing when
they do the work of jurors.’
We have argued that institutional research 3 We do not take up the fascination of the
can benefit from complementary attention to actor network approach with artifacts and their poli-
the micro-order and the macro-level. We urge tics. Simply stated, studies demonstrate that eco-
more examination of the genesis of organiza- nomic technologies – trading screens, stock tickers,
calculators, etc. do not simply represent the market’s
tional practices and the resulting meanings
ups and downs, but are very much involved in
that are attached to these routines. Such shaping market behavior (Knorr-Cetina and
attention will not only provide a fuller Bruegger, 2002; Buenza and Stark, 2004; Callon and
account of institutionalization processes, but Muniesa, 2005).
will also enable much clearer parsing of 4 In 1970, there was no financial trading in
‘futures,’ but by 2004, financial derivative contracts
endogenous and exogenous influences. Our
totaling $273 trillion were outstanding worldwide.
aim is to trace how efforts on the ground, so 5 Sensemaking’s insight lies in the ways it
to speak, may prompt macro-level changes ‘captures the realities of agency, flow, equivocality,
and responses. A multi-level view will offer transience, reaccomplishment, unfolding, and emer-
more purchase to the question of why institu- gence …, that are often obscured by the language of
variables, nouns, quantities, and structures’ (Weick,
tional practices and structures take the form
Sutcliffe, and Obstfeld, 2005).
they do. Rather than focus only on the diffu- 6 In contrast to ethnomethodology, where
sion or success of a form, we can better Garfinkel’s (1967) clever studies of breaching trans-
explain the nature of what becomes regarded form mundane encounters into unfamiliar controver-
as appropriate or venerable. The results of sies, sensemaking studies tend to analyze how skillful
routines can result in terrible tragedy.
such inquiry will lead to more compelling
7 Charles Perrow often makes a very Weickian
and integrative analyses. remark, ‘how do I know what I think until I say it?’
8 See Sampat, 2006 and Rothaermel, Agung,
and Jiang, 2007 for excellent reviews of the debates
around university technology policies.
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS 9 Pressures on nonprofits to become more ‘busi-
ness-like’ are certainly not new. Indeed, such urging
has been common throughout the sector’s history
We are grateful to Marisa Bueno, Gili Drori, (Hall, 2006). In the early twentieth century, religious
Mary Ann Glynn, Royston Greenwood, charities were criticized by progressive ‘scientific’
296 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

charity providers who urged the rationalization of Wall Street trading room.’ Industrial and
services for the poor (Lubove, 1965; Mohr and Corporate Change, 13: 369–400.
Duquenne, 1997). In the 1970s and 1980s, leading Callon, M. 1986. ‘Some elements of a sociol-
management consultancies persuaded many large
ogy of translation: Domestication of the scal-
nonprofit organizations to develop strategic plans in
lops and the fishermen of St. Brieuc Bay.’
order to ‘enhance’ their operations (DiMaggio and
Powell, 1983; Mintzberg, 1994; McKenna, 2006). Pp. 196–233 in J. Law (ed.), Power, Action
10 The Center for Social Innovation at the and Belief: A New Sociology of Knowledge?
Stanford Graduate School of Business and National London: Routledge & Kegan Paul.
Arts Strategies, a nonprofit consultancy for the arts, Callon, M. (ed.) 1998. The Laws of the
jointly developed the case on Minnesota Public Radio Markets. Oxford: Blackwell.
for classroom use. We have taught this case numer- Callon, M.. 2006. ‘What does it mean to say
ous times in MBA classes and executive education that economics is performative?’ Working
courses. James Phills and Ed Martenson were the pri- paper, Ecole des Mines, Paris.
mary contributors to the case’s development. We
Callon, M. and F. Muniesa. 2005. ‘Peripheral
draw on it for this extended example.
11 Interview with William Kling by Ed Martenson
vision: Economic markets as calculative col-
of National Arts Strategies, 2004. lective devices.’ Organization Studies, 26 (8):
12 Interview with William Kling by Ed Martenson, ibid. 1229–1250.
13 Ron Russell, ‘Public Radio’s Darth Vader Cicourel, A. 1968. The Social Organization of
invades L.A. by gobbling up a sleepy Pasadena col- Juvenile Justice. New York: John Wiley.
lege station.’ New Times Los Angeles, June 29, 2000. Coleman, J.S. 1968. ‘Review symposium of
14 Interview with William Kling by Ed Martenson, Studies in Ethnomethodology.’ American
2004. Sociological Review, 33 (1): 126–130.
15 Interview with William Kling by Ed Martenson,
Colyvas, J.A. 2007a. ‘From divergent meanings
ibid.
16 The guidepoints to sensemaking are found in
to common practices: The early institutional-
‘institutional constraints, organizational premises, ization of technology transfer in the life sci-
plans, expectations, acceptable justifications, and ences at Stanford University.’ Research
traditions inherited from predecessors’ (Weick et al., Policy, 36 (4): 456–476.
2005: 414). Furthermore, these guidepoints do not Colyvas, Jeannette A. 2007b. ‘Factories,
have to be accurate. What matters is that they are Hazards, and Contamination: Metaphors
plausible from the point of view of enacted identities and Recombinant DNA in University and
and context (Weick, 1995: 55–56). Biotechnology.’ Minerva, 45 (2): 143–159.
Colyvas, J.A., and W.W. Powell. 2006. ‘Roads
to institutionalization: The remaking of
boundaries between public and private sci-
REFERENCES ence.’ Research in Organizational Behavior,
27: 305–153.
Association of University Technology Managers Colyvas, J.A., and W.W. Powell. 2007. ‘From
(AUTM) 2005. U.S. Licensing Survey, vulnerable to venerated: The institutionaliza-
http://www.autm.net tion of academic entrepreneurship in the life
Berger, P.L., and T. Luckman. 1967. The Social Con- sciences.’ Research in the Sociology of
struction of Reality. Garden City, NJ: Doubleday. Organizations, M. Ruef and M. Lounsbury,
Berger, J., C. Ridgeway, M.H. Fisek, and (eds.), 25: 223–266.
R. Norman. 1998. ‘The legitimation and dele- Correll, S.J. and C.L. Ridgeway. 2003.
gitimation of power and prestige orders.’ ‘Expectation states theory.’ Pp. 29–51 in John
American Sociological Review, 63 (3): 379–405. Delamater (ed.), The Handbook of Social Psy-
Bittner, E. 1965. ‘The concept of organization.’ chology. New York, NY: Kluwer Academic Press.
Social Research, 32: 239–255. Coser, L.A. 1974. ‘Two methods in search of a
Bittner, E. 1967. ‘The police on skid row: A study substance.’ American Sociological Review,
in peacekeeping.’ American Sociological 40(6): 691–700.
Review, 32 (5): 699–715. Dees, J. Gregory. 1998. ‘Enterprising Nonprofits.’
Bowker, G. and L. Star. 1999. Sorting Things Harvard Business Review, 76, (1): 54–67.
Out. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. DiMaggio, P.J., and W.W. Powell. 1983. ‘The
Buenza, D. and D. Stark. 2004. ‘Tools of the iron cage revisited: Institutional isomorphism
trade: The socio-technology of arbitrage in a and collective rationality in organizational
MICROFOUNDATIONS OF INSTITUTIONAL THEORY 297

fields.’ American Sociological Review, 48(2): Knorr-Cetina, K. and U. Bruegger. 2002.


147–160. ‘Global microstructures: The virtual societies
DiMaggio, P.J., and W.W. Powell. 1991. of financial markets.’ American Journal of
‘Introduction.’ Pp. 1–38 in W.W. Powell and Sociology, 107: 905–951.
P.J. DiMaggio (eds.),The New Institutionalism Lach, S. and M. Schankerman. 2003.
in Organization Analysis. Chicago: University ‘Incentives and invention in universities.’
of Chicago Press. NBER Working Paper No. W9727.
Drori, G.S., J.W. Meyer, and H. Hwang (eds.) Lakoff, G. and M. Johnson. 1980. Metaphors We
2006. Globalization and Organization: Live By. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
World Society and Organizational Change. Letts, C., W. Ryan and A. Grossman.1997.Virtuous
New York: Oxford University Press. Capital: What Foundations Can Learn from
Foster, W. and J. Bradach. 2005. ‘Should non- Venture Capitalists. Harvard Business Review,
profits seek profits?’ Harvard Business Mar-April: 36–44.
Review, 83 (2): 92–100. Lubove, R. 1965. The Professional Altruist.
Garfinkel, H. 1967. Studies in Ethnomethod- Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
ology. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall. Latour, B. 1987. Science in Action. Cambridge,
Garfinkel, H. 1968. ‘The origins of the term MA: Harvard University Press.
‘ethnomethodology.’ Pp. 15–18 in R. Turner Latour, B. & S. Woolgar. 1979. Laboratory Life:
(ed.), Ethnomethodology. Middlesex, England: The Construction of Scientific Facts.
Penguin Books, 1974. Thousand Oaks: CA: Sage.
Garfinkel, H. and E. Bittner. 1967. ‘Good orga- Lawrence, T.B. and R. Suddaby. 2006. ‘Institutions
nizational reasons for bad clinic records.’ and institutional work.’ Pp. 215–54 in
Pp. 186–207 in H. Garfinkel (ed.), Studies in S.R. Clegg et al. (eds.), The Sage Handbook
Ethnomethodology. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: of Organization Studies, London: Sage
Prentice-Hall. Publications.
Giddens, A. 1984. The Constitution of Society. Michael Lounsbury and Ellen T. Crumley 2007.
Berkeley: University of California Press. ‘New Practice Creation: An Institutional
Goffman, E. 1961. Asylums. New York: Anchor Perspective on Innovation.’ Organization
Books. Studies, 28 (7): 993–1012.
Goffman, E. 1967. Interaction Ritual: Essays on MacKenzie, D. 2006. An Engine, Not a Camera:
Face-to-Face Behavior. New York: Pantheon How Financial Models Shape Markets.
Books. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Goffman, E. 1974. Frame Analysis. Cambridge, MacKenzie, D., and Y. Millo. 2003. ‘Constructing
MA: Harvard University Press. a market, performing theory: The historical
Hall, P.D. 2006. ‘A historical overview of philan- sociology of a financial derivatives exchange.’
thropy, voluntary associations, and nonprofit American Journal of Sociology, 109(1): 107–145.
organizations in the United States, March, J.G. 1994. A Primer on Decisionmaking.
1600–2000.’ Pp. 32–65 in W.W. Powell and New York, NY: Free Press.
R. Steinberg (eds.),The Nonprofit Sector, 2nd McKenna, C. 2006. The World’s Newest Profes-
edn. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press. sion. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.
Jennings, P.D. and R. Greenwood. 2003. Mead, G.H. 1934. Mind, Self, and Society.
‘Constructing the iron cage: Institutional Chicago, IL: Chicago University Press.
theory and enactment.’ Pp. 195–207 in Merton, R.K. 1948. ‘The self-fulfilling
R. Westwood and S. Clegg (eds.), Debating prophecy.’ Antioch Review, 8: 193–210.
Organization. Malden, MA: Blackwell. Meyer, J.W., and B. Rowan. 1977.
Jepperson, Ronald L. 1991. ‘Institutions, insti- ‘Institutionalized organizations: Formal struc-
tutional effects, and institutionalization.’ Pp. ture as myth and ceremony.’ American
143–63 in W.W. Powell and P.J. DiMaggio Journal of Sociology, 83(2): 340–363.
(eds.), The New Institutionalism in Minkoff, D. and W.W. Powell. 2006. ‘Nonprofit
Organizational Analysis. Chicago: University mission: Constancy, responsiveness, or
of Chicago Press. deflection?’ Pp. 591–611 in W.W. Powell
Khan, A. 1995. ‘MPR successful raising money: and R. Steinberg (eds.), The Nonprofit
Its for-profit sister is even better.’ St. Paul Sector: A Research Handbook, 2nd edn.
Pioneer Press, February 26, 1995. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
298 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Mintzberg, H. 1994. The Rise and Fall of Snook, S.A. 2000. Friendly Fire. Princeton, NJ:
Strategic Planning. New York: Free Press. Princeton University Press.
Mohr, J. and V. Duquenne. 1997. ‘The duality Strang, D. and W. Sine. 2002. ‘Interorganiza-
of culture and practice: Poverty relief in New tional institutions.’ Pp. 497–519 in J.A.C.
York City, 1888–1977.’ Theory and Society, Baum (ed.), Companion to Organizations.
26 (2/3): 305–356. Malden, MA: Blackwell.
Mohr, J. W. 1998. Measuring meaning struc- Sudnow, D. 1965. ‘Normal crimes: Sociological
tures. Annual Review of Sociology, 24: features of the penal code in a public
345–370. defender’s office.’ Social Problems, 12(3):
Mowery, D., R. Nelson, B. Sampat and 255–276.
A. Ziedonis. 2004. Ivory Tower and Industrial Sudnow, D. 1967. Passing On: The Social
Innovation. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Organization of Dying. Englewood Cliffs, NJ:
Press. Prentice-Hall.
Owen-Smith, J. 2001. ‘Managing laboratory Weber, K. and M.A. Glynn. 2006.
work through skepticism: Processes of evalu- ‘Making sense with institutions: Context,
ation and control.’ American Sociological thought, and action in Karl Weick’s
Review, 66 (3): 427–452. theory.’ Organization Studies, 27(11):
Phills, J. and V. Chang. 2005. ‘The price of 1639–1660.
commercial success.’ Stanford Social Weick, K. 1993. ‘The collapse of sensemaking
Innovation Review, (Spring): 65–72. in organizations: The Mann Gulch disaster.’
Powell, W.W., D. Gammal and C. Simard. Administrative Science Quarterly, 38 (4):
2005. ‘Close encounters: The circulation and 628–652.
reception of managerial practices in the San Weick, K. 1995. Sensemaking in Organizations.
Francisco Bay area nonprofit community.’ Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage Publications.
Pp. 233–58 in B. Czarniawska and G. Sevón Weick, K., K. Sutcliffe, and D. Obstfeld.
(eds.), Global Ideas. Herndon, VA: 2005. ‘Organizing and the process of sense-
Copenhagen Business School Books. making.’ Organization Science 16(4):
Porter, M. and M. Kramer. 1999. ‘Philanthropy’s 409–421.
new agenda: Creating value’. Harvard Weisbrod, B. (ed.) 1998. To Profit or Not: The
Business Review, Nov–Dec: 121–130. Commercial Transformation of the Nonprofit
Ridgeway, C. and J. Berger. 1986. ‘Expectations, Sector. New York: Cambridge University
legitimation, and dominance behavior in task Press.
groups.’ American Sociological Review, 51: Zelditch, M., Jr. 2001. ‘Theories of legitimacy.’
603–617. Pp. 33–53 in J.T. Jost and B. Major (eds.), The
Ridgeway, C. and H.A. Walker. 1995. ‘Status Psychology of Legitimacy. Cambridge, UK:
structures.’ Pp. 281–310 in K.S. Cook et al. Cambridge University Press.
(eds.), Sociological Perspectives in Social Zelditch, M., Jr. 2004. ‘Institutional effects on
Psychology. Boston: Allyn and Bacon. the stability of organizational authority.’
Rothaermel, F.T., S.D. Agung and L. Jiang. Research in the Sociology of Organizations,
2007. ‘University entrepreneurship: A taxon- 22: 25–48.
omy of the literature.’ Industrial and Zimmerman, D.H. 1969. ‘Record-keeping and
Corporate Change, (4): 691–791. the intake process in a public welfare
Sampat, B.N. 2006. ‘Patenting and U.S. aca- agency.’ Pp. 319–54 in S. Wheeler (ed.), On
demic research in the 20th century: The Record: Files and Dossiers in American Life.
world before and after Bayh-Dole.’ Research New York: Russell Sage.
Policy, 35 (6): 772–789. Zucker, L.G. 1977. ‘The role of institutionaliza-
Scott, W.R. ‘Approaching Adulthood: The tion in cultural persistence.’ American
Maturing of Institutional Theory.’ Working Journal of Sociology, 42: 726–743.
Paper. Zucker, L.G. 1991. ‘Postscript: Microfoundations
Selznick, P. 1949. TVA and the Grass Roots. of institutional thought.’ Pp. 103–6 in
Berkeley: University of California Press. W.W. Powell and P.J. DiMaggio (eds.), The
Simon, H. 1945. Administrative Behavior. New Institutionalism in Organizational
Glencoe, IL: The Free Press. Analysis. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
11
Institutions and
Transnationalization
Marie–Laure Djelic and Sigrid Quack

INTRODUCTION globalization, on the other hand, equate this


evolution with anomie, instability and disorder.
At a first level, the notions of ‘institutions’ and The withering of traditional polities and insti-
‘globalization’ could appear to exclude or tutions is often described, from such a critical
oppose each other. The notion of institution stance, as one of the negative externalities of
suggests stability or at least an attempt at stabi- globalization.
lization. An institutionalist perspective starts The objective of this chapter is to over-
from the basic recognition that human activi- come the apparent opposition between the
ties, including activities of an economic nature, two notions of ‘institutions’ and ‘globaliza-
are embedded and framed within larger institu- tion’. We suggest instead another perspec-
tional schemes that are, on the whole, quite tive, where the two notions emerge as
stable (Weber 1978; Polanyi 1944). A core being tightly intertwined. First, we want to
dimension of the institutionalist project has argue that our reading of the phenomenon
been to understand how embeddedness mat- of globalization will be significantly
ters, how institutions constrain and structure enhanced if we bring to bear upon that
action, create regularities and stability, limiting phenomenon an institutionalist perspective.
at the same time the range of options and The globalization of our world is, we
opportunities. In contrast, the process of glob- propose, deeply about institutions. It is about
alization is often associated with the break- the rules of the game in which economic
down of traditional rules of the game and and social activity are embedded and about
institutions, in particular through the weaken- the profound transformation of those rules
ing of national states and their order-creating in a world where order-creating capacities
capacities. The champions of that process wel- are not coinciding anymore with nation-state
come this evolution. They see globalization power. We argue that much of this institution
as a process where ‘markets’ displace and building is of a transnational rather than a
replace ‘institutions’ through time, bringing global nature; it unfolds across blurring
along wealth and development, economic, boundaries between a variety of actors from
social, if not moral progress. The critics of different nation-states without necessarily
300 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

implying convergence and homogenization The label ‘globalization’ is frequently


at the global level. Second, we also want used to refer to the rapid expansion of opera-
to argue that institutions and processes of tions and interactions across and beyond
institutionalization cannot be understood national boundaries. However, we find it
today without taking transnationalization unsatisfactory; ‘globalization’ has become
into account. Most spheres of economic such a catchword that its meaning is highly
and social life, in most corners of the world, blurred. Transnationalization, we propose,
are not only constrained and framed by local is a more suitable and focused concept to
and national sets of institutions but they make sense of the world we live in. We agree
become enmeshed as well in transnational with Hannerz (1996: 6) that ‘the term “transna-
dynamics. tional” offers a more adequate label for phe-
We define institutions as those collective nomena which can be of quite variable scale
frames and systems that provide stability and and distribution, even when they do share the
meaning to social behaviour and social inter- characteristic of not being contained within the
action and take on a rule-like status in social state’. The term ‘transnational’ suggests entan-
thought and action (Meyer and Rowan 1977; glement and blurred boundaries to a degree
Douglas 1986: 46–48). Institutions stabilize that the term ‘global’ could not. In our contem-
and survive through self-activating social porary world, it becomes increasingly difficult
processes of reproduction (Jepperson 1991). to separate what takes place within national
At the same time, we see institutions not only boundaries and what takes place across and
as sets of constraints but also as tools and beyond nations. The neat opposition between
resources enabling action (Clemens and ‘globalization’ and ‘nations’, often just
Cook 1999). In our view, institutions have beneath the surface in a number of debates,
both a structural dimension, including formal does not really make sense whether empiri-
and informal rules and systems and an cally or analytically. Organizations, activities
ideational dimension, including normative and individuals constantly span multiple
and cognitive schemes. The mix of those two levels, rendering obsolete older lines of demar-
dimensions can vary. The reach of institu- cation (Djelic and Sahlin-Andersson 2006). At
tions will also vary and it will be likely, in the same time, the term transnational does not
fact, to co-vary with the scope of social imply, as globalization often does, the disap-
action and interaction. In other words, if pearance of states. It suggests instead that
action and interaction only play out at the states are now only one type of actor among
level of a local tribe, locally defined and others and that they have to profoundly evolve
enforced sets of rules will be both necessary as a consequence (Katzenstein, Keohane and
and sufficient. If action and interaction Krasner 1998).
expand beyond the boundaries of the tribe, The term transnationalization is also a
then there will probably be a need for term better adapted to our times than the term
translocal institutional frames that may ‘internationalization’. Transnationalization
displace, complement or transform local suggests more than the mere projection
ones. While institutional resilience can be of national states and national actors
quite strong, institutions can change and outside their borders. It implies that
what this chapter does is explore some of the many connections go beyond state-
dynamics of institutional change – those to-state and firm-to-firm interactions.
more particularly associated with the process Transnationalization points to the progres-
of transnationalization. sive structuring of spheres of action
We use the term ‘transnationalization’ to and interaction with an emergent identity,
describe a world – our world – where eco- where debates cannot be reduced to
nomic and social organization and coordina- negotiations between national identities.
tion increasingly reach across national borders. Transnationalization means, in other words,
INSTITUTIONS AND TRANSNATIONALIZATION 301

that the world ‘in between’ nation-states is Organizational institutionalism


not an anomic world with no order, power or and its agnostic stance on
institutions apart from those projected by
transnationalization
strong states. In fact, the term suggests that
there is a need to consider transnationaliza- The field of ‘organizational institution-
tion from an institutional perspective – to alism’ encompasses a wide range of
focus on those processes of institutionaliza- conceptual and empirical studies, demon-
tion and de-institutionalization associated strating how organizations are shaped by,
with the transnationalization of economic adapt to and interact with institutionally
and social activity. legitimized rules and templates in their
We explore, in this chapter, the interplay environment. In the tradition of classical
between institutions and transnation- authors (Barnard 1938; Blau 1955;
alization. We start with a review of the litera- Gouldner 1954; Parsons 1956; Selznick
ture and get a sense of how different 1949; Weber 1978), organizations are
perspectives have handled those notions conceived as adaptive social systems embed-
and sometimes their interaction. Then, build- ded in and responsive to wider societal and
ing on recent developments within the institutional influences rather than just as
broad family of institutionalism, we propose mere production systems geared towards effi-
a reading of transnationalization through ciency. In pursuit of the neo-institutionalist
an institutional lens. In other words, we turn introduced by Meyer and Rowan
approach transnationalization as an institution- (1977), DiMaggio and Powell (1983) and
alization process. Finally, here again building Zucker (1977), recent work gives priority to
on recent contributions, we bring the transna- cognitive and cultural over regulative mecha-
tional dimension into the study of institutions. nisms of institutionalization. The compre-
We do this in order to enhance our understand- hensive concept of institutions used in
ing of contemporary processes of institutional- these analyses encompasses any kind of sus-
ization and de-institutionalization and hence tained, reproduced social practice that may
to contribute to debates on institutional be relevant to organizations, including
change. taken-for-granted practices, norms and
values.
Organizational institutionalism has mainly
focused on the study of institutionalization
LITERATURE REVIEW processes in organizations or organizational
fields and has highlighted isomorphic pres-
We take in turn four different theoretical sures, leading to homogenization of organi-
repertoires and explore what they have zational practices and forms. On the whole,
to tell us, if anything, about the inter- organizational institutionalism has taken a
play between ‘institutions’ and ‘transnation- rather agnostic stance on transnationaliza-
alization’. Three of those repertoires tion. Studies of organizational fields are
are inevitable when we talk about often limited to the local or industry level;
institutions and institutionalization – they rarely encompass a national or even
organizational institutionalism, societal transnational dimension. Institutional
institutionalism and World System institu- processes that extend beyond the boundaries
tionalism. We choose to bring in the fourth of organizational or sectoral fields or run
repertoire – the International Relations through vertically layered institutional orders
Literature – because it is important have been largely neglected. This agnostic
for a discussion of transnationalization stance of organizational institutionalism on
even though it brings less to debates on insti- transnationalization becomes increasingly
tutionalization. problematic as the horizons of action and
302 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

meaning of the actors become transnational crystallized. This occurs together with
and global interdependencies increase. the stabilization of a consensus on the
This also applies to the recent revival of value of the behavioural patterns and of
interest in institutional entrepreneurship their associated meanings and understand-
and institutional change. Building on ings among social actors. This consensus
DiMaggio’s (1988) seminal article, various can translate into fragile preliminary struc-
authors have investigated how institutionally tures and rules that can still be revised or
embedded actors engage in shaping and challenged at this semi-institutionalized
changing their institutional frameworks. stage. The third and last stage of institution-
Oliver (1991) identified various strategies alization is one of ‘sedimentation’. It is char-
ranging from passive conformity to proactive acterized by a wider spread of patterned
manipulation by which organizations act in a behaviours and meanings and by the solidifi-
given institutional environment. Greenwood, cation and perpetuation of structures. During
Suddaby and Hinings (2002) investigated the this last stage, institutions can acquire the
role of professional associations in the trans- quality of ‘exteriority’, i.e., they can become
formation of institutional fields. The large taken for granted and develop a reality of
majority of these studies, though, focus once their own.
more on institutional change at the local and From a process perspective, de-institu-
industry level (see, e.g., Dorado 2005; tionalization is another important element of
Fligstein 1997; Greenwood and Suddaby any institutional change. Institution building
2006; Maguire, Hardy and Lawrence 2004). in the transnational sphere may equally
Very few studies have analyzed institution require a fair degree of de-institutionalization
building at the global level (Maguire and of rules at local or national levels. Following
Hardy 2006). Oliver (1991, 1992), political, functional
Organizational institutionalism, though, is and social pressures can lead to de-
of relevance to the theme of this chapter institutionalization. Political pressures arise
because it provides key concepts that, when from intentional interest-guided actions of
further elaborated, can be fruitfully applied individuals who question the legitimacy of
to the study of institutionalization in the existing institutions. Functional pressures
transnational sphere. We suggest that this may lead to de-institutionalization when
applies particularly to process theories of stakeholders challenge the legitimacy of an
institutionalization and deinstitutionaliza- institution because of its growing incompati-
tion, concepts of diffusion, translation and bility with technical and economic require-
editing, and organizational field analysis. ments. Social pressure can lead to
Organizational institutionalism offers a de-institutionalization when differentiation
micro–approach to institutional change that and fragmentation of an organization’s mem-
can be extended to macro-levels of analysis. bers and environment lead to an erosion of
Building on Berger and Luckmann (1967), institutionalized rules through a declining
institutionalization has been defined by normative consensus and cognitively shared
Tolbert and Zucker (1996) as a three-phase systems of meaning. Faced with such pres-
process. The first phase, called habitualiza- sures for institutional erosion, actors may
tion, comprises the development of patterned engage in various maintenance and repair
behaviours through recurrent and regular activities to stabilize institutions (Suchman
interactions to which shared meanings 1995a; Lawrence, Chapter 6 and Lawrence
and understandings become attached. The and Suddaby 2006).
second phase, called objectification, is the In combination, institutionalization and
subsequent process of generalization of these de-institutionalization provide powerful con-
particular meanings and understandings cepts for the analysis of institutional dynam-
beyond the specific context in which they ics. These concepts have been revised and
INSTITUTIONS AND TRANSNATIONALIZATION 303

refined by various authors (Barley and organizational institutionalism has emphasized


Tolbert 1997; Seo and Creed 2002; isomorphism, this does not mean that diffusion
Greenwood and Hinings 1996; Greenwood always leads to increasing similarity. The
et al. 2002; Greenwood and Suddaby 2006; results of diffusion processes are indeed quite
Suchman 1995b). They are now able to variable. Various reasons for this variability
encompass pragmatic legitimacy based on and divergence have been proposed, e.g.,
self-interest, moral legitimacy based on transmission mistakes (Zucker 1977) and
normative approval as well as cognitive socio-cultural differences. Westney (1987)
legitimacy based on comprehensibility and showed that imitation always involves an
taken-for-grantedness (Suchman 1995a). element of innovation. Czarniawska and Sevón
Lawrence et al. (2001) include power, disci- (1996), Sahlin-Andersson (1996) and
pline and dominance as other sources of Sahlin-Andersson and Engwall (2002) analyze
institutionalization that may lead to a variety the way in which transfers of management
of dynamics. The role of social movements practices between different local contexts con-
in de-stabilizing institutional fields and sist of translation and editing activities
transforming extant socio-economic prac- between different cultural and social contexts,
tices has also been identified as important. It and show that these translations may lead to
has been, for example, at the centre of the rather divergent outcomes. In her analysis of
study by Lounsbury et al. (2003) on the rise the transfer of the US model of economic
of a for-profit recycling industry in the organization to Europe, Djelic (1998) high-
United States. Social movements also played lights how geopolitical dependencies, transna-
a key role in the emergence of international tional elite networks and the strength and type
standards like ISO (Walgenbach 2000). of resistance groups have led to different adap-
The common point of these process tations of the model in Germany, France and
approaches is that they allow for contestation Italy. The extension and refinement of diffu-
between various interested actors in the first sion and transfer studies along these lines
two phases of the process and acknowledge promises substantial contributions to questions
the co-existence of different degrees of insti- about the degree to which increasing
tutionalization (Jepperson 1991; Dorado cross-border and global exchanges will give
2005). This makes them attractive concepts rise to homogenization, hybridization or con-
for the analysis of institutional phenomena in tinued variety of transnational institutional
the transnational sphere where struggles rules.
between different parties and a fair degree of Finally, the concept of organizational field
institutions in the making are to be expected. can be elaborated in ways that allow the inte-
So far, however, these processes have been gration of a transnational dimension into insti-
rarely studied in multinational organizations tutional analysis. In the original definition,
or in multi-jurisdictional and multi–layered organizational field refers to ‘organizations
institutional settings (see Suchman 1995b for that in the aggregate constitute a recognized
an exception) which are likely to be area of institutional life’ (DiMaggio and
characterized by parallel bottom-up and Powell 1991: 64f). While this concept usually
top-down processes of institutionalization applied to the isomorphic diffusion
and de-institutionalization. of organizational forms at a local or industry
Another contribution of organizational insti- level, more recently it has been used
tutionalism is that if offers the tools to study to depict institutionalization processes that
cross-border diffusion of practices, templates unfold around regulatory ‘issues’ (Hoffman
and rules as sources of institutionalization 1999) and ‘transnational governance’
and de-institutionalization. Diffusion can (Djelic and Sahlin-Andersson 2006). Several
be based on structural relationships or on cul- authors have called to give more attention
tural media and artifacts. While one stream of to the relative openness of fields (Greenwood
304 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

and Hinings 1996), their nestedness into where each national ensemble – institutions
wider institutional arrangements (Scott 2001) and organizations – functions in relative
and the unfolding of contradictory logics isolation from the others. Such a description
within such fields (Seo and Creed 2002). of social and economic reality may hold as a
Studies on the emergence of new fields kind of ideal type for the past – and even
point to the importance of social move- there with a varying degree of applicability in
ments (Lounsbury et al. 2003; Walgenbach different historical periods. Quack (2006a),
2000). Building on these treatments, Djelic for example, argues that transnational
and Sahlin-Andersson (2006: 18f) suggest influences significantly shaped German
that ‘transnational governance fields’ are capitalism during its formative period. In the
a pertinent unit of analysis to study contemporary period, the notion of relatively
multi-level institutional dynamics that unfold closed business systems becomes even more
through various overlapping network relations obsolete because of the growing transna-
across blurring territorial and jurisdictional tional interconnectedness of economic actors
boundaries and are driven by institutional across the world and the emergence and
forces that constitute a transnational meaning strengthening of various forms of institution-
system. alized rule systems at the transnational level
(Brunsson and Jacobsson 2000; Djelic and
Quack 2003; Djelic and Sahlin-Andersson
Societal institutionalism and 2006; Drori, Meyer and Hwang 2006).
the challenge of opening There have been a number of attempts to
date to adapt the analytical framework of
national systems
societal institutionalism in a way that can
The label ‘societal institutionalism’ refers to help meet the theoretical challenges raised by
what is now a dense set of conceptual and economic internationalization and transna-
empirical studies focusing on the historical tionalization (for an overview, see Deeg and
emergence and contemporary structuring of Jackson 2007). These attempts reflect essen-
national economies. Societal institutionalism tially three main strategies. One path has
has related the structures and strategies of been to call into question the conception of
firms, the relationships between different institutions as fully determining economic
stakeholder groups, the roles of managers, organization and action. The idea, instead, is
the development and distribution of skills to highlight and look for the degrees of free-
between various layers of employees to the dom that economic actors can enjoy within a
distinct social and institutional settings in given institutional framework. The focus,
which firms operate. The institutions receiv- here, is on the existing and potential variety
ing most attention in societal institutionalism of strategies and behavioural patterns within
are the state, the financial, educational and a given society (Sorge 2000), on the multi-
training systems, the labour market regime plicity of institutional repertoires that
and norms and values governing trust and co-exist and linger on in the background of
authority relationships (Maurice and Sorge any apparently dominant institutional frame
2000; Hall and Soskice 2001; Whitley 1999). (Crouch 2005; Morgan and Quack 2005;
The main focus of societal institutionalism Schneiberg 2007), as well as on the tensions
has been the systemic nature of national con- that can arise from the conflicting interests of
figurations of institutions. And a key preoc- different societal groups, leading to contra-
cupation of that literature has been to show dictions within a particular societal system
how those stable systems in turn shape and and potentially to institutional change
define national economic organizations and (Almond and Rubery 2000; Quack, Morgan
their self-reproduction. The picture has gen- and Whitley 2000). In his studies of the
erally been one of multiple closed systems, German biotech sector, Casper has made
INSTITUTIONS AND TRANSNATIONALIZATION 305

explicit this critique of societal institutional- national level. The adaptation of the theory
ism, suggesting that here leads us well beyond the notion of iso-
‘static descriptions of existing institutional lated and self-contained national business
environments must be combined with micro-level system. We need to reconcile the idea of differ-
accounts, tracing how firms, governments, and ent systems with the reality of homogenizing
other actors within the economy experiment with,
pressures – the outcome being in general
and at times re-configure, the institutional tool-kits
at their disposal’ (Casper 2000). one form or another of hybridization or
creolization.
Such micro-level accounts can build upon A third path, still barely explored, would
various theoretical approaches. Where Casper be to look at the transnational arena as an
(2000) turns to micro-economic theories to institutionalised or institutionalising space.
bridge the gap between dynamic interactions at Hollingsworth and Boyer (1997), for exam-
the level of firms, regulators or policy makers ple, argue that social systems of production
and pre-existing institutional frames, we sug- need increasingly to be seen as nested within
gest that sociological approaches that highlight a complex system of regional, national but
the creative dimension of social behaviour also international arrangements. Whitley
building on interactionism or ethno-methodol- (2003) argues that since 1945 the interna-
ogy are other possibilities (Douglas 1986; tional business environment has undergone a
Emirbayer and Mische 1998; Joas 1992). transformation from a particularistic logic to
A second route for adapting societal institu- an increasing formalization and standardiza-
tionalism has been to explore what happens tion of the rules of the economic game.
when actors or organizations become involved So far, however, societal institutionalism has
in multiple institutional environments with dif- contributed little to our understanding of the
ferent and sometimes conflicting rule systems. processes leading to the emergence of new
A particularly interesting laboratory here institutional arrangements in the transna-
appears to be the multinational company and tional sphere. The few budding attempts,
in recent years studies on its nature and devel- recently, at exploring this frontier have built
opment have flourished (Harzing and Sorge in part upon different theoretical repertoires.
2005; Lane 2000; Morgan, Kristensen and Authors like Brunsson and Jacobsson (2000),
Whitley 2001; Morgan, Whitley and Moen Morgan (2001), Djelic and Bensedrine
2005). The internationalization of companies (2001) or Plehwe with Vescovi (2003) look
creates a ‘battle-field’ where different con- at the actors, preconditions and mechanisms
stituencies enter in conflict and negotiate involved in the emergence and transforma-
(Kristensen and Zeitlin 2001; Sharpe 2001). tion of institutions in the ‘transnational social
Transnational transfers of business practices space’ (Morgan 2001). Djelic and Quack
generally lead to hybridization of practices at (2007) argue that the concept of path-
the organizational level but also of managerial dependency needs to be reconsidered in the
‘mental maps’ (Lane 2000; Smith and Elger context of open systems. Their analysis
2000). In time, as Christel Lane (2001) argues points to increasing co-evolutionary interac-
in the case of German pharmaceutical compa- tion between national path transformation
nies, this can trigger a transformation of and transnational path creation.
domestic institutions (see also Lane 2003;
Vitols 2005a, 2005b). Another important arena
for contestion between competing institutional World system institutionalism,
influences are global production networks
globalization – and their limits
(Lane and Probert 2006). When change in
leading transnational companies reaches a crit- The label ‘world-system institutionalism’
ical mass, managers are encouraged or even refers to a now well-established tradition of
required to press for institutional reforms at the cultural institutionalism. In that tradition,
306 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

institutions are ‘wider cultural and symbolic has also contributed to our knowledge about
patterns’, increasingly with a ‘global’ or key carriers of global models and blueprints
transnational scope, that shape and to a large (Boli and Thomas 1999; Finnemore 1996).
extent determine organizations, structures or These studies, however, focus mostly on
actors and script behaviours and interactions how global cultural models and institutional
(Meyer and Rowan 1977; Scott, Meyer et al. blueprints are diffused, potentially shaping
1994; Jepperson 2000a, b). Cultural processes localized discourse and/or structures and
with a transnational scope explain to a signif- activities. We learn less on the construction
icant extent changes in states, organizations and negotiation of global cultural models
or individual behaviours (Meyer, Boli, or institutions. We also lack an understanding
Thomas and Ramirez 1997). of actual processes and mechanisms of
World society is not only a society of diffusion and local reception – where
empowered actors; it is a society permeated transnational institutional blueprints meet
by and permeating actors with powerful cul- with local institutional traditions. Finally,
tural values or institutional frames (Meyer there is room for more work – both empiri-
et al. 1997). These frames are shaped and dif- cally and conceptually – on carriers. There
fused as global models and blueprints along is an extremely rich and diverse pool of
which states (and other actors) are bench- carriers out there that has only recently
marked and possibly transformed (Finnemore started to be studied in and for itself
1993). There is no global state but the alterna- (Boli and Thomas 1999; Greenwood et al.
tive to state power is not anarchy and chaos. 2002; Sahlin-Andersson and Engwall 2002;
Meyer et al. (1997) convincingly argue that Djelic and Quack 2003; Djelic and
the cultural and institutional web characteris- Sahlin-Andersson 2006). Carriers are often
tic of world society can be, at least in part, located at the interface of multiple sources of
a functional equivalent to a centralized, embeddedness. In particular, they often cross
state-like global power. The stateless but and overcome the national/transnational
rational, organized and universalist character border and contribute to back and forth trans-
of world society may in fact add to rather than lation and negotiation (Campbell 2004).
detract from the speed of diffusion and the Studies combining an analysis of the activi-
global pervasiveness of standardized models ties and interests of carriers with an account
and blueprints (Finnemore and Sikkink 1998). of their institutional embeddedness (with
This line of research and its elaborate sometimes multiple and conflicting sources
theory of world society are enlightening. of embeddedness) should help us capture
They bring cultural perspectives and expla- power interplays and processes of interest
nations into the analysis of states, organiza- formation in highly institutionalized settings
tions and their transformation and provide with a transnational scope. They will also
evidence that actorhood is of the ‘soft’ kind – allow us to understand how transnational cul-
that is always itself embedded in cultural tural models or institutions are negotiated,
frames – and in fact empowered by those cul- constructed, diffused and adapted through
tural frames. This line of research shows that time – leading us well beyond the notion of
the real sources of power and authority in our institutional convergence.
societies are cultural and diffuse rather than
structural and centralized. Studies within this
tradition show that states remain important Learning about transnationalization
regulators, but that they are themselves from the international relations
embedded in, shaped and fashioned by a
literature
powerful world society and its associated
institutional and cultural templates (Meyer The international relations literature is an
et al. 1997; Jacobsson 2006). This research interesting tradition to explore when we
INSTITUTIONS AND TRANSNATIONALIZATION 307

think about transnationalization and its Along with the idea of a retreat and
mechanisms. Traditionally, the perspective in transformation of states, there has been
political science and in the international a focus on the widespread expansion of
relations literature has been of a highly state- various forms of private authority (Cutler,
centreed internationalization process (Martin Haufler and Porter 1999; Hall and Biersteker
2005). If anything, the structure of the 2002). There is an interesting parallel
international sphere is given by and through with pre-modern (i.e., pre-nation-states)
negotiations between states and essentially times when private authority spanning local
reflects, at any given point in time, a communities was widespread; the lex merca-
particular balance of power. For some time toria (or merchant law) being a striking
now, though, a number of scholars within example (Berman and Kaufman 1978;
the international relations community Lehmkuhl 2003). The modern concept of pri-
have contributed to an evolution of those vate authority is wide and encompassing,
state-centreed perspectives in interesting referring to a multiplicity of rule-making and
directions. institution-building activities that emerge and
A first line of reaction has been to point to are structured outside states.
the progressive ‘retreat of the state’ in a glob- Some contributions within the inter-
alizing world (Strange 1996). Many contem- national relations literature pointed already
porary regulatory reforms have been in the 1980s to the importance here of
associated with privatization and the partial transnational social networks. Using the con-
dismantling of public services and welfare cept of ‘social networks’ in its descriptive
states (e.g., Vogel 1996; Djelic 2006). In the and first-level sense, Kees van der Pijl and
process, states have in fact not withered the Amsterdam school explored the sociol-
away. Granted they may be changing, poten- ogy and political economy of transnational
tially quite significantly. As used by Majone class formation (Van der Pijl 1984, 1998).
(1996) and others, the concept of ‘regulatory They unearthed in the process important
states’ points to a significant evolution of mechanisms of transnational governance that
states and the way they control and influence reproduced the class power of particular
activities and actors. Regulatory states are groups and associated structures of domi-
not less influential or powerful than more nance – both reaching progressively a
interventionist states but they are increas- transnational scale and scope.
ingly embedded in complex constellations of Haas (1989, 1992) also pointed to the
actors and structures (e.g., Higgott, Underhill importance of social networks as key mecha-
and Bieler 2000; O’Brien, Goetz, Scholte nisms of governance crossing over state
and Williams 2000). As such, their input and boundaries. Haas’ concept of ‘epistemic com-
identity is difficult to disentangle and sepa- munities’ makes reference to communities of
rate from the inputs and identities of other expertise and practice that are increasingly
actors involved. transnational while individuals in those com-
Furthermore, it becomes less and less munities retain some form of local or national
acceptable to treat states as monoliths. influence and authority (Haas 1992). This mix
State institutions are complex patchworks can allow those groups to be powerful mecha-
and this complexity becomes all the more nisms at the interface between transnational
striking that the porosity of state institutions and national institutional spheres. The under-
has increased significantly, albeit differen- standing of ‘social networks’ here is a sophis-
tially. In fact, boundaries may now be tighter ticated one. Epistemic communities are
and more rigid between sectors of state ‘faceless’ and members generally have direct
administration than between particular state interactions only with small subsets of the
agencies and other actors in the same sector community. Those communities are neverthe-
or field. less powerfully connected. More than through
308 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

direct and regular contacts, the ‘glue’ is gener- TRANSNATIONALIZATION AS


ated by common cognitive and value schemes, INSTITUTIONAL RECOMBINATION
often associated with complex socialization
processes and generally translated into A core insight of institutional theory is that the
‘expertise’, shared interests and projects. It is patterning of social life is not produced solely
interesting here to draw a parallel between this by the aggregation of individual and organiza-
concept and the idea of ‘carriers’ as emerging tional behaviours but also by institutions that
in ‘world–system institutionalism’. structure and shape the interests, strategies and
More recent contributions talk about regula- behaviours of social actors. Authors like Ann
tory networks, underscoring the wide variety Swidler (1986) or Mary Douglas (1986), how-
of public and private actors involved in rule ever, draw our attention to the fact that this
making, institution building and monitoring. institutional patterning is not fully determinis-
As Schmidt puts it, ‘though the hangover of tic. Institutions (or culture in the terminology
the traditional focus on the state’s legal com- of Swidler) provide ‘tool kits’ or repertoires
mands has been felt in the study of regulation, from which actors can to some extent choose
both European and American scholars of in order to construct their ‘strategies of action’.
policy networks have advanced perspectives The resulting variety in social behaviours gen-
on regulation rooted more firmly in institu- erates a pool of alternative mental maps and
tional dynamics and political behaviour’ patterns of behaviour, which, under specific
(Schmidt 2004: 276). The idea of regulatory conditions, can come to interact with each
networks points to complex interconnections other and challenge existing institutions.
between a multiplicity of individual and orga-
nizational actors – interconnections that can be
direct or mediated. The idea also suggests
organizational, cognitive and normative frames Where do transnational institutions
or arenas in which those interactions take place come from?
and are structured. Finally, with a focus on reg-
ulatory networks comes a question about their In processes of institutional emergence,
legitimacy and more generally about the legit- decline or change, new configurations are
imacy of private authority. With a broadening rarely created from scratch. Rather, the genesis
set of rule-makers and institution-builders, the of institutions in contemporary societies
way of authorizing rules and institutional unfolds in general in a form that is closer to
frames is likely to broaden as well. Coercive ‘bricolage’ than to ex-nihilo generation
rules that rest on the monopoly of states over (Offe 1995; Hall and Taylor 1996; Campbell
legal authority and physical violence or 1997; March and Olsen 1998). Actors build
on citizens’ habitual obedience come to upon, work around, recombine, reinvent and
represent only one among several forms of reinterpret logics and institutional arrange-
authorization. ments that function elsewhere and with which
Building upon the richness of insights they are familiar. Within the context of
emerging from a confrontation of the differ- nation–states, the creation of new institutions
ent repertoires presented above, we sketch is likely to be strongly influenced by the state,
out below a theoretical frame that allows us in the form of political actors or agencies
to read the contemporary interaction between (Clemens and Cook 1999). But even there, this
institutions and transnationalization. This should not blind us to the impact and signifi-
frame has two main dimensions – first, we cance of other actors.
reinterpret transnationalization as institu- The relevance of the idea of ‘bricolage’
tional recombination and, secondly, we con- (Douglas 1986) becomes only more signifi-
sider the impact of transnationalization on cant when we look at processes of institu-
processes of institutionalization. tional emergence and institution building
INSTITUTIONS AND TRANSNATIONALIZATION 309

at the transnational level. We suggest, in fact, Historical scenarios – transnational


that turning our attention to the transnational organizations or regional
level should go hand in hand with a refocus-
federations
ing away from the idea of institutional
configurations to that of dynamic institutional Historically, a first and obvious scenario
recombination. Moving from institutions to for institution building in the transnational
institutionalization and thinking about the arena has been the formal setting up of a
latter as a set of sequential stages – habituali- transnational organization. This, naturally, is
zation, objectification and sedimentation an old scenario and, with a little bit of a
(Tolbert and Zucker 1996) – suggests that the stretch, the Roman Catholic Church could be
level of embeddedness and robustness of insti- used as an illustration, and a successful one
tutional rules will vary. Thinking about institu- at that. Without going that far back into his-
tionalization as a process also implies to think tory, a number of other examples come to
in parallel about processes of de–institutional- mind. The League of Nations was an impor-
ization (Oliver 1992). It opens the door, as tant ancestor, although with little impact ulti-
well, to the possibility of social intervention mately (Murray 1987; Knock 1995). In the
and hence agency. Institutions are not only years following 1945, the project of structur-
constraining; they are also enabling. ing the transnational space around transna-
Institutions are not static systems; they are tional organizations regained strength after
malleable processes. nearly two decades of strong nationalism and
Institution building in the transnational protectionism. The United Nations and its
sphere involves multiple actors or groups various divisions, the Organization for
of actors with mental and action maps European Economic Cooperation (OEEC,
originating from quite different institutional later to become the OECD), the International
contexts. Very often those originating con- Labour Office (ILO), the International
texts have a societal or national character Monetary Fund (IMF) or the World Bank and
(Morgan 2001). Hence, the process of insti- the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade
tution building at the transnational level (GATT, later to become the World Trade
cannot be conceived in total isolation Organization) all proceeded from the same
and abstraction from national institutional logic.
contexts. Multiple national actors extend These organizations all had a centralized
their national contextual rationalities into core, in charge of setting the rules and build-
the international sphere where they interact, ing institutions at the transnational level. And
confront and negotiate with each other. this centralized core directly reflected the
Those participants may become involved in interests of national member states – as con-
institution building in a newly emerging veyed by public or semi-public types of
transnational sphere (McNichol and actors such as representatives of particular
Bensedrine 2003; Engels 2006). Or they may national governments and polities. In that
be playing a part in reforming, renegotiating context, such transnational organizations
and transforming existing transnational were in fact little more than the tools of par-
institutional arrangements as motivations, ticular nation-states and governments, mir-
power relations and conditions change roring at any point in time the existing
over time (Lehmkuhl 2003; Botzem and geopolitical balance of power. In time, how-
Quack 2006). Through time, repeated ever, the technocratic elite in charge of every-
interactions and the building up of a transna- day monitoring and management could
tional frame, a number of actors may be evolve its own identity that could then not be
emerging that have a transnational – in the fully reduced to any single national logic.
sense of not purely national – identity or These types of transnational organizations
sense of self. have been more or less successful in their
310 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

attempt at setting the rules of the game on a transnational organizations on the other.
transnational scale. The more successful – A supranational construction such as the
the IMF, the World Bank and probably also European Union is indeed characterized by
the GATT or later the WTO – have been the strength of enforcement mechanisms and
those with some control over compliance and thus by its potential clout and impact over
with sufficient means to monitor that the member nations and states. One type of
rules they are building are indeed being enforcement mechanisms are direct controls
implemented. Control could stem from a associated positively with rewards and nega-
degree of dependence of member states on tively with sanctions. Another type of
transnational organizations as well as from enforcement mechanism is the reliance on
the capacity these organizations may have to voluntary compliance, where member states
associate rewards with compliance and sanc- are aware of the overall benefits they draw
tions with non-compliance. from belonging to the supranational con-
A second scenario for institution building struction and, conversely, realize the danger-
in the transnational space follows from the ous consequences of not respecting the terms
temptation to create a supranational market, of a contract they entered of their own will.
or even a supranational state or nation.
With a little bit of a stretch, once again,
and some degree of historical anachronism, Self–regulating communities:
since a number of them were constituted
scenario of the future?
before the emergence of the nation–state,
empires are the materialization of such a There is, we propose, a third scenario for
temptation. In our modern age, the most institution building in the transnational
obvious illustrations of this second scenario space to which we associate the label
are constructions such as the European ‘self-regulating transnational communities’.
Coal and Steel Community (ECSC), the This scenario has become progressively
European Economic Community (EEC) or more widespread in recent years. In this
the European Union (EU). There are signs third scenario, all actors concerned by a par-
that NAFTA may also be travelling that road. ticular type of transnational activity come
Here again, the process of rule setting and together, often in non-structured and rather
institution building stems from a political, unformalized settings, elaborate and agree
top-down kind of initiative. Public or upon collective rules of the game (Cutler
semi-public actors, governments or their rep- et al. 1999; Morgan and Engwall 1999).
resentatives are instrumental in that process In contrast to the first two scenarios, public
even though they may not always be as pre- or semi-public actors might be involved in
dominant as in the first scenario. The scope rule setting but they are not the only ones.
and reach of those centrally engineered con- In fact, private actors might take the initiative
structions goes well beyond, in general, the and be quite instrumental for the elaboration
scope and reach of transnational organiza- of rules and the building of institutions
tions. The new rules and institutions are as well as for monitoring compliance
enforceable, in the sense of their being (McNichol and Bensedrine 2003; Botzem
formally and efficiently associated with and Quack 2006).
enforcement mechanisms that put member Another difference with the two previous
states under strong pressure to comply. In scenarios is that the logic at work is not
fact, the reality and strength of enforcement external control but rather self-discipline
mechanisms, combined with the scope of the or self-regulation. Instead of waiting for
domain controlled, might be the key differen- public actors to impose an institutional frame
tiating features between this type of suprana- and thus orient private action, the actors
tional constructions on the one hand and concerned and in particular nongovernmental
INSTITUTIONS AND TRANSNATIONALIZATION 311

and private actors, take the initiative and structuring of commercial arbitration at the
set their own rules. Within an arena or a field transnational level by actors themselves –
of transnational activity lacking initially and in particular by private actors – has
in structuration, all concerned actors collabo- existed for a long time. One could also
rate in building institutional arrange- argue that international cartels, particularly
ments that will constrain their own actions, during the interwar period or even after
behaviours and interactions. The process is in some industries (Cutler et al. 1999;
one of voluntary and relatively informal Glimstedt 2001; Lilja and Moen 2003), fit
negotiation; the emerging structural arrange- within this type of scenario. While that sce-
ments are relatively amorphous, fluid and nario is not new, it has recently been going
multifocal in nature. through a period of ‘revival’ after long
Self-disciplining transnational communi- decades when national states had all but
ties of that sort tend to rely on two main cat- established a monopoly over the handling of
egories of enforcement mechanisms. One is transnational issues and spaces. Many non-
voluntary compliance; compliance this time governmental organizations have been
not only of national states and governments established that engage in standard setting,
but directly of all actors involved in the accreditation and other forms of soft regula-
process. Compliance is voluntary for the tion. Large multinational firms, particularly
main reason that these actors define the rules in professional services, have become
themselves and inflict upon themselves the rule-setters and rule-developers of their own
institutional constraints that will bound their (Quack 2006b; Morgan 2006). Informal reg-
actions and interactions. A second enforce- ulatory networks such as the International
ment mechanism, socialization, can be iden- Competition Network (Djelic and Kleiner
tified – although probably more as a potential 2006) are increasingly exerting influence on
and an objective than as an already existing national regulators. We propose, in fact, that
and concrete reality. Indeed, socialization there has been an historical evolution
can only emerge as an enforcement mecha- overall, since 1945, in terms of which
nism at a later stage. Rules and institutions scenario has been predominant. The early
have to be constructed and agreed upon (the period, in the years following the war, was
habitualization or pre-institutionalization characterized by the multiplication of
stage identified above), actors have to func- transnational organizations. Then came
tion within that frame for a while (objectifi- supranational constructions, particularly in
cation), before the double process of Western Europe. This naturally, is still
socialization and self-reproduction through going on. At the same time, empirical
socialization can really become operative evidence points for the recent period
(sedimentation). The advantage of socializa- increasingly in the direction of a greater role
tion as an enforcement mechanism is and place for self-disciplining transnational
the decreasing need for direct controls communities (Braithwaite and Drahos 2000;
and thus for both external rewards and sanc- Brunsson and Jacobsson 2000; Djelic
tions. Actors socialized through a particular and Quack 2003; Djelic and Sahlin-
institutional frame or within a particular Andersson 2006).
set of rules become their own watchdogs.
Ultimately, this institutional frame will have
a tendency to become neutral and transparent Transnational recombination: mode
for those actors who function within the
and nature of the process
space it structures.
This third scenario for institution building In each of these three different scenarii,
at a transnational level is not new. As argued transnational institution building can be
by Lehmkuhl (2003), for example, the analyzed as a process of reinterpretation,
312 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

recombination and bricolage from institu- modes we identify and the likelihood that
tional fragments with different contextual they will co-exist and interact in real-life
origins. We suggest that there are three contexts. In fact, while situations of negotia-
different modes in which the rubbing, contes- tion are rarely perfectly balanced, a situation
tation and recombination of different institu- of dominance is on the other hand rarely so
tional fragments can take place at the extreme as to leave no space for at least par-
transnational level. tial negotiation. In the context of what was
A first, obvious, mode we label here ‘dom- described above as ‘Americanization’, for
inant’. In that mode, the building of institu- example, what many empirical studies show
tions at a transnational level simply reflects is the concomitant partial alteration, transla-
one dominant local or national model. Rules tion and negotiation of the ‘dominant’ model
and institutions originating from one particu- when it comes into contact with previously
lar national space thus shape in a rather direct existing and established national institutional
way the transnational space. In a second configurations (Djelic 1998; Zeitlin and
stage, this local turned transnational model is Herrigel 2000; Amdam, Petter, Kvalshaugen
bound to have an impact on a number of and Larsen 2003).
other national institutional configurations, as Common to illustrations of both the
we will argue below. This overall process ‘dominant’ and ‘negotiated’ modes is the fact
generally reflects the objective and/or per- that the actors involved – whoever and what-
ceived strength of the ‘dominant’ nation, ever they are – remain strongly embedded in
which itself depends upon a combination of and shaped by the institutional contexts of
economic, military and geopolitical factors, their home countries. These actors tend in fact
with some degree of ideological propping up. to extend the actions and strategies used in
Undeniably, since 1945, this role of ‘domi- that context and shaped by it to the transna-
nant’ nation has been played by the United tional arena. This, however, is not necessarily
States and this particular mode of recombina- always the case. The involvement of actors in
tion can be referred to as a process of processes of transnational institution building
Americanization (Djelic 1998; Whitley can – particularly if sustained and recurring
2003; Djelic and Quack 2003; Djelic and over longer periods of time – lead to a blurring
Sahlin-Andersson 2006). of identities, particularly national ones
A second mode emerges that we label (Morgan 2001). Once transnational arenas
the ‘negotiated mode’. Institution building in have been structured for a little while, once
the transnational space can come about transnational institutions and rules of the
through the confrontation or ‘rubbing against game shape behaviours and interactions, some
each other’ of multiple locals or nationals, of the actors concerned come to be more
leading to what can be described as a process directly affected by these transnational institu-
of negotiation. This dimension of negotiation tions than by the institutions of the country
is documented in a number of recent they may originate from. New actors may also
empirical contributions (e.g., McNichol and sprout up and the only referent for these new
Bensedrine 2003; Ventresca, Szyliowicz and actors will be the embryonic transnational
Dacin 2003; Botzem and Quack 2006). institutional context in which they were born
At the same time, if we look at them more (e.g., some transnational nongovernmental
closely, empirical situations often illustrate organizations [NGOs], lobbying organizations
in fact the interplay between the ‘negotiated’ created at the European level, see Salk,
and the ‘dominant’ mode. All participants to Nielsen and Marks 2001).
the negotiations are not created equal and Any further process of transnational institu-
some of them may loom significantly larger tion building in that context cannot anymore fit
than the others in the process. This under- under the categories of either the ‘dominant’
scores the ideal typical nature of the different or the ‘negotiated’ mode. What takes place
INSTITUTIONS AND TRANSNATIONALIZATION 313

then is what we label, for lack of a better word, in the previous section, have a high potential
an ‘emergent’ process. Multiple actors with no to challenge and undermine institutional sta-
clear identities and functioning themselves at bility and identical reproduction at the
the interface of multiple rule systems, come in national level. Transnational institutional
collision with each other. If we are to follow frames in the making are likely to challenge,
the metaphorical use of chaos theory in social to confront and to change – even though
sciences, the result in this case is bound to be slowly and incrementally – national institu-
unpredictable (Thietart and Forgues 1995). We tional systems. They can do so through direct
call this result an ‘emergent’ construction. impact – what we call here ‘trickle-down’
The three modes identified here are clearly effects or mechanisms. When transnational
ideal types. There is bound to be, in other organizations or supranational constructions
words, interaction and interplay between (e.g. the WTO, the IMF, NGOs, multina-
them in real life situations. At the same time, tional firms or the European Union) exert
we suggest that there has been a shift over pressure directly at the national level on
time in their relative importance as a mode member governments to redefine national
of transnational institution building or rules of the game, then we have what we call
recombination. This shift parallels to quite a ‘trickle-down’ effects or mechanisms.
degree the evolution, in terms of scenario, The impact can also be more indirect.
that was identified above. In the immediate Through cross-national interactions at sub-
post-World War II years, we have argued, the societal or meso-levels – sectors, industries,
main scenario for transnational institution professions or even from region to region –
building was the setting up of transnational actors are being drawn into social spaces that
organizations. During this period, the domi- extend well beyond their national context of
nant mode – one national model, the origin. In that process, those actors are likely
American one, imposing itself on a transna- to be confronted with and to have to function
tional scale – was all but overwhelming. The within sets of rules that may be quite differ-
dominant mode has not entirely disappeared ent from those of their country of origin.
with the attempts at supranational construc- Subsocietal actors become the vectors and
tion. But such projects, by their very nature, transmission belts through which those new
meant and required some degree of negotia- rules are brought into a given national space.
tion between the several member nations that In certain circumstances, those subsocietal
were shaping them, generally on a world actors may be more than mere messengers.
regional basis. Finally, the move towards the They may become real mediators and con-
third scenario – transnational institution tribute to pushing those new rules up towards
building by self-disciplining transnational the national institutional level, fostering in
communities – coincides quite closely with the process a transformation of the national
the slow assertion of an emergent mode. It business system or of the national business
seems furthermore to fit particularly the case rationality. This path or pattern we associate
of transnational institution building across with ‘trickle-up’ effects or mechanisms.
world regions – in what gets close to being a
‘global’ space.
Trickle-down trajectories
The challenge, naturally, may come from
TRANSNATIONALIZATION AND ITS transnational organizations or supranational
IMPACT ON INSTITUTIONS constructions. Those organizations and con-
structions quite often turn out to be
Ongoing processes of institutional recombi- rule-making bodies and some of them have
nation at the transnational level, as described gained significant and direct influence over
314 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

national polities. This is clearly the case with Once transnational institutions or rules
the European Union. In recent years, the are there or in the making, the question
impact of the European Union has been the moves to the conditions in which they
object of an increasing number of studies may come indeed to trickle down to the
(Leibfried and Pierson 1995; Fligstein and national level, with a potentially significant
Mara-Drita 1996; Sandholtz and Stone impact upon incumbent national institutions.
Sweet 1998; Plehwe 2001). With respect to One important variable appears to be the
the economic realm, other transnational degree of centrality of a particular country,
organizations such as the International through its private and public representatives,
Monetary Fund (IMF), the World Bank, the in the process of construction and stabiliza-
European Bank for Reconstruction and tion of transnational rules. It seems fair to
Development (EBRD) or the World Trade differentiate between at least three main
Organization (WTO) should be mentioned. groups of countries in that respect.
These organizations contribute to the diffu- The first group is a little peculiar; it is a
sion of particular rules of the game, which one-unit sample. The United States plays
are likely to collide with incumbent rules or quite a unique role even though it does not
practices in any given national space. always manage to impose the solution that
Less attention has been paid to the sce- will best serve its interests. An explanation to
nario where challenger rules emerge from a that special place and role lies in the unique
transnational space lacking formal structure position of geopolitical dominance that has
and being, as a consequence, less visible. characterized the US since 1945 (Djelic
What we have said above about self- 1998; Braithwaite and Drahos 2000).
disciplining transnational communities indi- Through its private and public representa-
cates that rule setting and rule making can tives, that country has often been guiding and
also take place in transnational fields or structuring the process of construction and
arenas lacking structuration in relative terms. stabilization of transnational rules in a more
Actors – all kinds of actors, from private or less direct and visible manner, at least
firms to consumers, lobbies, nongovernmen- since 1945. A second group is made up of a
tal organizations (NGOs) or state representa- few core (and rather rich) countries, which
tives – come together to negotiate and agree are proactive and quite involved in trying to
on rules of the game. Examples can be found shape the process. The third group finally is
in the regulation of financial markets the larger one and brings together those
(Morgan 2001; Ventresca et al. 2003), countries with a more passive connection to
accounting standards (Botzem and Quack the process.
2006), international commercial arbitration Empirical evidence seems to show that
(Dezalay and Garth 1996; Lehmkuhl 2003), compliance may be more regular, once the
or competitive conditions (Djelic and Kleiner rules have been agreed upon, within the
2006). Those rules of the game are institu- second group of countries, rich core coun-
tions, to the extent that they structure action tries. In the third group of countries, those
and economic activity. For the most part, that are more passive in the process of
those are cognitive and normative institutions transnational institution building, appropria-
(Meyer and Rowan 1977). The rules that tion seems to be more of an issue. The
emerge or are negotiated in that context are process is likely to be slower with a greater
essentially norms that are enacted, appropri- distance between the world of discourse and
ated and enforced by the actors themselves formal institutions and the world of action
(Brunsson and Jacobsson 2000). The struc- and practice that will remain very much
tural apparatus – formal organization, legis- structured by traditional patterns (Meyer
lation or coercive machinery – comes if at all et al. 1997a; Meyer et al. 1997b). In the case
in support of those norms. of the United States, compliance appears, on
INSTITUTIONS AND TRANSNATIONALIZATION 315

the other hand, quite irregular and changing an obvious path for trickle-down mecha-
(McNichol and Bensedrine 2003; ENS 2001; nisms. This situation naturally creates
Libération 2002). The profound geopolitical conditions where the rules defined at the
imbalance in favour of the US increases the supranational level are likely indeed to have
degrees of freedom of that country regarding a rapid and significant impact at the national
compliance with transnational rules, even level.
when it has played a significant role in the
process of construction and elaboration of
those rules. Trickle-up trajectories
Other variables with an impact on
trickle-down trajectories are the nature of Threats and challenges to national institu-
incumbent rules and the degree of depend- tional systems may also come from below,
ence of a particular country on external from subsocietal or subnational levels.
players. We hypothesize that a country where Such ‘trickle-up’ trajectories can be of two
local rules are weak, either because they lack kinds. First, national actors crossing national
legitimacy, have proven inefficient or a borders may find that the rules of the
hindrance, are altogether absent or still game with which they are familiar come
at a pre-institutionalization stage, creates into collision and sometimes even are in
more space for rules constructed at a transna- contradiction with rules of the game
tional level to trickle down. This can only dominant elsewhere. Those national actors
be reinforced in situations of dependence, could be individuals, groups of individuals,
where a country, for example, sees the firms, associations or networks of firms.
granting of financial assistance it badly This type of scenario will be all the more
needs being conditioned upon compliance to widespread now that the internationalization
a set of transnationally defined rules (Djelic of economic activities and of exchanges in
1998). This is not, after reflection, in general is becoming increasingly dense and
contradiction with our precedent finding. intense.
Weak countries tend to belong to the group The opening up of national economies
we have defined above as ‘passive’. may stimulate a second scenario that is
Weakness and dependence may compensate parallel but goes in the other direction.
in part for passivity, which might lead to Foreign actors move into a given national
more rapid formal compliance than expected. space with rules of the game that are quite
Quite often, however, a significant gap will different from those of local actors. A variant
remain between the world of discourse and of that scenario is when the champions of
formal institutions on the one hand and the challenger rules on the local or national
world of practice on the other (this finds con- scene are themselves locals or nationals who
firmation in earlier work by sociologists of are pushing for new rules of the game in
global society, e.g., Meyer et al. 1997a; Boli order to carve a space for themselves. What
and Thomas 1999; Meyer and Ramirez this is all about is the attempt by new or
2000). The former might indeed be affected emerging actors, whether local outsiders or
through a trickle-down trajectory by transna- foreign entrants or even a combination of
tional challenger rules. The latter will tend to both, to redefine rules of the game in an
stay, at least for a while, embedded in local industry or impose ‘new’ ones in order to
traditions and national institutional legacies. enter the field and the game and to reshape it
A special and quite different case of depend- to their advantage (Djelic and Ainamo 1999;
ence should be added and mentioned here. Lane 2001; Kleiner 2003).
Direct political dependence of national coun- Various empirical studies show how
tries on a supranational construction, such as this encounter between incumbent and chal-
is the case in the European Union context, is lenger rules plays out at subsocietal levels,
316 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

whether at the level of the firm (Lane 2000; advantage in professional fields such as cor-
Tainio, Huolman and Pulkkinen 2001), porate law or management consulting as well
at the level of an industry (Lilja and as in other activities related to banking or
Moen 2003), an organizational field (Kleiner financing. This allows them to be more
2003) or at the level of a profession (Quack forceful and convincing in the promotion of
2006b; Quack 2007; McKenna, Djelic their own sets of rules of the game. Naturally,
and Ainamo 2003). This interplay at the the strength and legitimacy of those out-
subsocietal level is not neutral for national siders and challengers will be more or less
institutions. Rules of the game may change filtered and mitigated by the existence and
at the subsocietal level well before this is embeddedness of local incumbent rules.
institutionalized at the national level. But Local appropriation will likely be more
transformations at the subsocietal level complex and contested in situations where
may also reverberate in time at the national incumbent rules already exist and are deeply
institutional level. The decision by the embedded – when, in other words, local
German government in 2001 to create a institutional rules have already entered the
Kodex-Kommission in charge of ‘mod- phase of sedimentation.
ernising the rules and practices of German Another condition seems important that
capitalism’ is a clear case of such a process is not unrelated to those identified above.
of post hoc ‘regularisation’ (Le Monde, 7 The greater the shock or the more intense
November 2001). The object of this commis- the collision, the more likely it will reverber-
sion was to take stock of changes that had ate at the national level. The collision
already redefined the German economic will be more intense if subsocietal actors –
game and to institutionalize them at the firms, industries, professions or even possi-
national level. This raises questions about bly regions – lack protective buffers or else
the conditions in which contestation and are in a situation of perceived and self-
transformation of incumbent rules of the acknowledged crisis. The lack of protection
game at the subsocietal level are likely can be due to the immaturity of the local
indeed to reflect and impact at the national field. It can be strategically engineered,
level. either by political authorities or by the actors
One such condition seems to be the central themselves, through deregulation for exam-
position and overall leverage of the subsoci- ple or a lowering of trade or other protective
etal actors concerned by or involved in the barriers (Djelic and Ainamo 1999). It will
collision of rules. Changes within core and also be related, naturally, to the strength of
strategic firms or industries are more likely, the push coming from outsiders and challenger
ultimately, to have some impact on national rules. A perceived and self-acknowledged
level institutions. This appears to be particu- situation of crisis will tend to correspond, on
larly true in smaller countries, as shown by the other hand, to a high degree of dissatis-
the cases of Nokia in Finland (Tainio et al. faction with incumbent rules, either because
2001) or of the forest industry in Norway and these rules do not seem to co-evolve
Finland (Lilja and Moen 2003). In smaller with environmental conditions and/or
countries, core firms or industries have pro- because they narrow the opportunities of
portionally more clout, strategic importance local and incumbent actors in a changing
but also leverage, which could explain their world.
more direct impact. We argue that under these conditions – or
Other important conditions are the a subset thereof – transformations in rules of
strength and legitimacy of those outsiders the game that were initially happening at
championing and pushing for challenger a subsocietal level are likely to have an
rules. In that respect, Anglo-Saxon players impact and reverberate, after a while, at the
benefit from something akin to a ‘trademark’ national level.
INSTITUTIONS AND TRANSNATIONALIZATION 317

CONCLUSION a lack of protection of incumbent rules


because of the immaturity of or a crisis in the
In this chapter we have explored the interac- field.
tions between institutions and transnational- Our findings suggest that economic and
ization. An important layer of institutions social behaviours are increasingly shaped by
with transnational scope has emerged since the interactions between national and
World War II and plays an increasing role transnational institutional orders; at the
in the governance of economic relations. same time, actors at both levels are engaged
We need new categories and analytical tools in processes of institutionalization and
to accurately characterize these institutions de-institutionalization that may redefine
and their impact on institutional change at the carriers, forms and modes of this interac-
the societal level. Comparing, contrasting tion. Consequently, institutional theory
and building upon four existing theoretical and research must consider the possibility
approaches, we move towards a theoretical that multiple layers of institutions and
model that accounts for interactions between institutionalization may be relevant for the
institutions and transnationalization. This subject under study, and that change
model consists of two related and comple- processes result from complex and com-
mentary arguments. bined processes of institutionalization, de-
Firstly, transnational institution building institutionalization, and re-institutionalization.
can be defined as a process of institutional For institutional research, this has concep-
recombination that involves elements of tual, methodological and empirical implica-
different national and local institutional tions that we would like to elucidate,
arrangements. We have identified different particularly as they relate to organizational
scenarios and modes of institutional recom- institutionalism, the subject at the heart of
bination at the transnational level out of this handbook.
which self-disciplining transnational com- At the conceptual level, our analysis
munities with emergent modes of institu- suggests that institutional systems should be
tion building seem to have become more conceived as open systems that are linked to
widespread in recent years. Secondly, each other through cross-border interactions
processes of institutional recombination have between various actor groups. The bound-
a high potential to challenge and under- aries of these systems are permeable, and
mine institutional stability at the national the different rule systems are likely to diffuse
level through trickle-down and trickle-up in both directions. Social actors are embed-
effects. Trickle-down processes can directly ded in locally and temporally specific
influence governments to redefine legal institutional rules of the game. At the same
rules of the game at the national level. time, they become increasingly able to
Trickle-up effects may infiltrate societal rule develop horizons of meaning and action
systems from the bottom-up through that reach beyond their local institutional set-
cross-border interactions between economic tings. Problems and conflicts between
actors, social movements and other stake- different institutional logics at the organiza-
holders at the organizational field, industry tional, societal and transnational level should
or sectoral levels. Encounters between chal- therefore be considered as a major source of
lenger and incumbent rules may lead to new institutional change. So far, however, we
forms of institutional recombination at these know relatively little about the specific
levels. They are likely to impact on national dynamics of change within and between
rules systems if there is a central and strong these different institutional layers. More ana-
position of the transformed institutional field lytical concepts that integrate structural fea-
with respect to the overall society, a high tures of these different layers with relational
legitimacy of outside challenger rules and/or and process approaches need to be developed
318 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

in order to discern the interactions between from the rest of the world (see Crouch 2005:
the different layers. This new analytical 158; Scott 2001).
framework must give more attention to inter- Secondly, methodologies should be reori-
actions between cognitive, normative and ented in order to develop appropriate
regulatory mechanisms of institutionaliza- research designs for analyzing the interac-
tion and de-institutionalization and to the tions between national and transnational
specific types of legitimacy that they draw institutions. Global diffusion pattern studies
on. Institutional rules of the game at the and comparative analyses of societal
societal (generally national) level are institutional systems do not cover the interac-
often backed by legal or regulatory instru- tions between different institutional layers
ments relating to the legitimacy of a demo- as such. Both neglect cross-border interac-
cratically elected government, whereas tions and the mutual interdependence
institutionalization at the transnational level and co-evolution of national and transna-
relies more strongly on cognitive and cultural tional institutions that may result from these
processes of imitation, socialization and interactions. The emergence of new analyti-
adaptation. Problems and conflicts between cal models that assess the emergence
different forms of legitimacy that require res- of transnational regulatory or issue fields
olution can therefore be expected. So far, from a process perspective and combine
organizational institutionalism has concen- these with a comparative analysis of the
trated on the organization and organizational institutional orders from which the partici-
field level. In future research, organizations pants in these fields originate, and which in
and organizational fields need to be concep- turn may be affected by the development of
tualized as social orders that are interlinked transnational rule setting, is a promising
to a variable degree with institutional rule development.
systems at a higher aggregation level. This Thirdly, organizational institutionalism
may be the national level, but also the researchers could make more valuable con-
transnational level. tributions by employing the available tools
Institutional research methodologies and for analysis of global and transnational forms
empirical work must better reflect the of organization, ranging from multinational
multi-layered nature of institutional orders enterprises and financial and knowledge
using a three-point strategy. First, the intermediaries to more loosely connected
research design should better consider the communities and networks and their involve-
possibility of a nested hierarchy of institu- ment in processes of institution building and
tional contexts. Currently, the level of analy- institutional change. In this way, the results
sis (i.e., the organization or organizational of organization studies could promote a
field) is often presented as a starting assump- better understanding of the role of organiza-
tion that rarely is justified in the research tions as vehicles of transnationalization (see
paper. It would be useful to have research also Drori et al. 2006) and enrich the interna-
hypotheses explaining why a particular tional relations literature with in-depth
level or interaction between levels was analyses of how processes of dominance,
selected as the object of analysis. Given the negotiation and emergence within interna-
mutual interaction and diffusion between tional organizations impact on the wider
institutional orders, it would be also helpful institutional environment. At the same time,
to have hypotheses explaining the points organizational studies could also help to
of openness and closure to external influ- improve the current understanding of
ences of an institutional layer to other layers processes related to local interpretation and
rather then assuming that the defined level translation of global and transnational insti-
of an institutional system (e.g., the organiza- tutional rules by analyzing them as nested
tional field or national level) is encapsulated layers of an institutional framework.
INSTITUTIONS AND TRANSNATIONALIZATION 319

REFERENCES Cutler, A. C., V. Haufler and T. Porter (eds.)


(1999), Private Authority in International
Amdam, R. Petter, R. Kvalshaugen and E. Affairs. New York: State University of New
Larsen (eds.) (2003), Inside the Business York Press.
Schools. Oslo, Norway: Abstrakt Press. Czarniawska, B. and G. Sevón (eds.) (1996),
Almond, P. and J. Rubery (2000), Deregulation Translating Organizational Change. Berlin
and societal systems, in Maurice and Sorge and New York: Walter de Gruyter.
(eds.), pp. 277–293. Deeg, R. and G. Jackson (2007), Towards a
Barley, S. and P.S. Tolbert (1997), Institutio- more dynamic theory of capitalist variety,
nalization and structuration: Studying the Socio-Economic Review 5(1): 149–179.
links between action and institution, Dezalay, Y. and B. Garth (1996), Dealing in
Organization Studies 18: 93–117. Virtue. Chicago and London: The University
Barnard, C.I. (1938), The Functions of the Exe- of Chicago Press.
cutive. Harvard, MA: Harvard University Press. DiMaggio, P.J. (1988), Interest and agency in
Berger, P. and T. Luckmann (1967), The Social institutional theory, in Zucker (ed.), pp. 3–21.
Construction of Reality. New York: Doubleday. DiMaggio, P.J. and W.W. Powell (1983), The
Berman, H. and C. Kaufman (1978), The law of iron cage revisited: Institutional isomorphism
international commercial transactions, Harvard and collective rationality in organizational
International Law Journal 19(1): 221–277. fields, American Sociological Review,
Blau, P.M. (1955), The Dynamics of Bureau- 619–637.
cracy. Chicago: University of Chicago Press DiMaggio, P.J. and W.W. Powell (1991),
Boli, J. and G.M. Thomas (eds.) (1999), Introduction, in P.J. DiMaggio and W.W.
Constructing World Culture. International Powell (eds.), pp. 1–38.
Nongovernmental Orgnizations Since 1875. Djelic, M.-L. (1998), Exporting the American
Stanford, CA: Standford University Press. Model. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Botzem, S. and S. Quack (2006), Contested Djelic, M.-L. (2006), Marketization: From intel-
rules and shifting boundaries: International lectual agenda to global policy making,
standard–setting in accounting, in Djelic and in Djelic and Sahlin-Andersson (eds.),
Sahlin-Andersson (eds.), pp. 266–286. pp. 53–73.
Braithwaite, J. and P. Drahos (2000), Global Djelic, M.-L. and A. Ainamo (1999), The coevo-
Business Regulation. Cambridge, UK: lution of new organizational forms in the
Cambridge University Press. fashion industry: A historical and compara-
Brunsson, N. and B. Jacobsson (2000), A World tive study of France, Italy and the United
of Standards. Oxford, UK: Oxford University States, Organization Science 10(5):
Press. 622–637.
Campbell, J. (1997), Mechanisms of evolution- Djelic, M.-L. and J. Bensedrine (2001),
ary change in economic governance: Globalization and its limits: The making
Interaction, interpretation and bricolage, in of international regulation, in Morgan,
Magnusson and Ottosson (eds.), pp. 10–32. Kristensen and Whitley (eds.), pp.
Campbell, J. (2004), Institutional Change and 253–280.
Globalization. Princeton: Princeton University Djelic, M.-L. and S. Quack (eds.) (2003),
Press. Globalisation and Institutions: Redefining the
Casper, S. (2000), Institutional adaptiveness, Rules of the Economic Game. London:
technology policy, and the diffusion of Edward Elgar.
new business models: The case of German Djelic, M.-L. and S. Quack (2007), Overcoming
biotechnology, Organization Studies 5: path dependency: path generation in open
887–914. systems’, Theory and Society, DOI
Clemens, E. and J. Cook (1999), Politics and 10.1007/s11186-007-9026-0.
institutionalism: Explaining durability and Djelic, M.-L. and T. Kleiner (2006), The inter-
change, Annual Review of Sociology 25: national competition network: Moving
441–466. towards transnational governance, in
Crouch, C. (2005), Capitalist Diversity and Djelic and Sahlin-Andersson (eds.), pp.
Change. Oxford: Oxford University Press. 287–307.
320 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Djelic, M.-L. and K. Sahlin-Andersson (eds.) Greenwood, R. and R. Suddaby (2006),


(2006), Transnational Governance. Institutional entrepreneurship in mature
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. fields: The big five accounting firms,
Dorado, S. (2005), Institutional entrepren- Academy of Management Journal 49(1):
eurship, partaking, and convening. 27–48.
Organization Studies 26(3): 385–414. Greenwood, R., R. Suddaby and C. R. Hinings
Douglas, M. (1986), How Institutions Think. (2002), Theorizing change: The role of pro-
Syracuse University Press. fessional associations in the transformation
Drori, G., J. Meyer and H. Hwang (eds.) (2006), of institutionalized fields, Academy of
Globalization and Organization. Oxford: Management Journal 45(1): 58–80.
Oxford University Press. Haas, P. (1989), Do regimes matter? Epistemic
ENS (2001), US pulls out of Kyoto Protocol, communities and Mediterranean pollution
Environment News Service, 28 March, control, International Organization 43(3):
Washington DC, http://ens.lycos.com/ens/ 377–403.
mar2001/2001L-03-28-11.html. Haas, P. (1992), Introduction: Epistemic
Emirbayer, M. and A. Mische (1998), What is communities and international policy
agency?, American Journal of Sociology coordination, International Organization
103 (4): 962–1023. 46(1): 1–35.
Engels, A. (2006), Market creation and Hall, P. and D. Soskice (eds.) (2001), Varieties
transnational rule-making: The case of CO2 of Capitalism. Oxford: Oxford University
emissions trading, in Djelic and Sahlin- Press.
Andersson (eds.), pp. 329–48. Hall, P. and R.C.R. Taylor (1996), Political sci-
Finnemore, M. (1993), International organiza- ence and the three new institutionalisms,
tions as teachers of norms, International Political Studies 44: 936–957.
Organization 47: 567–597. Hall, R.B. and T.J. Biersteker (eds.) (2002), The
Finnemore, M. (1996), Norms, culture and Emergence of Private Authority in Global
world politics: Insights from sociology’s insti- Governance. Cambridge: Cambridge
tutionalism, International Organization 50: University Press.
325–347. Hannerz, Ulf (1996), Transnational Connec-
Finnemore, M. and K. Sikkink (1998), tions. London: Routledge.
International norm dynamics and political Harzing, A.W. and A. Sorge (2003), The relative
change, International Organization 52(4): impact of country of origin and universal
887–917. contingencies on internationalization strate-
Fligstein, N. (1997), Social skill and institutional gies and corporate control in multinational
theory, American Behavioural Scientist 40: enterprises: Worldwide and European per-
397–405. spectives, Organization Studies 24(2):
Fligstein, N. and I. Mara-Drita (1996), How to 187–214.
make a market: Reflections on the attempt Higgot, R.A., G.R.D. Underhill and A. Bieler
to create a single market in the European (2000), Non–State Actors and Authority in
Union, American Journal of Sociology the Global System. London: Routledge.
102(1): 1–33. Hoffman, A.J. (1999), Institutional evolution
Glimstedt, H. (2001), Between national and and change: Environmentalism and the U.S.
international governance: Geopolitics, chemical industry, Academy of Management
strategizing actors, and sector coordination Journal 42: 351–371.
in electrical engineering in the interwar era, Hollingsworth, R. and R. Boyer (eds.) (1997),
in Morgan et al. (eds.), pp. 125–152. Contemporary Capitalism. Cambridge, UK:
Gouldner, A.W. (1954), Patterns of Industrial Cambridge University Press.
Bureaucracy. New York, London: The Free Jacobsson, B. (2006), Regulated regulators:
Press. Global trends of state transformation, in
Greenwood, R. and C. R. Hinings, (1996), Djelic and Sahlin-Andersson (eds.), pp.
Understanding radical organizational 205–224.
change: Bringing together the old and the Jepperson, R. (1991), Institutions, institutional
new institutionalism, Academy of effects, and institutionalism, in Powell and
Management Review 21: 1022–1054. DiMaggio (eds.), pp. 143–163.
INSTITUTIONS AND TRANSNATIONALIZATION 321

Jepperson, R. (2000a), The development and and coevolution of public and private insti-
application of sociological neoinstitutional- tutions, in Djelic and Quack (eds.), pp.
ism, Working Paper Series, Florence, Italy: 278–301.
European University Institute. Leibfried, S. and P. Pierson (eds.) (1995),
Jepperson, R. (2000b), Political modernities: European Social Policy. Washington, DC:
Four main variants of the modern polity, Brookings Institution.
Working Paper, Tulsa, Arizona: Tulsa Le Monde (7 November 2001), Le ‘Kodex’,
University. nouvelle bible du capitalisme Rhénan.
Joas, H. (1992), Die Kreativität Des Handelns. Libération (2 October 2002), Cour Pénale
Frankfurt/Main: Suhrkamp Verlag. Internationale: l’Europe céde à Washington.
Katzenstein, P., R.O. Keohane, and S.D. Lilja, K. and E. Moen (2003), Coordinating
Krasner, (eds.) (1998), International organi- transnational competition: Changing
zation at fifty: Exploration and constesta-tion patterns in the European pulp and paper
in the study of world politics, Special Issue of industry, in Djelic and Quack (eds.), pp.
International Organization, 52(4). 137–160.
Kleiner, T. (2003), Building up an asset man- Lounsbury, M., M. Ventresca and P. M. Hirsch
agement industry: Forays of an Anglo-Saxon (2003), Social movements, field frames and
logic into the French business system, in industry emergence: A cultural–political per-
Djelic and Quack (eds.), pp. 57–82. spective on US recycling, Socio–Economic
Knock, T. (1995), To End All Wars. Princeton: Review 1(1), 71–104.
Princeton University Press. Maguire, S. and C. Hardy (2006), The emer-
Kristensen, P.H. and J. Zeitlin (2001), The gence of new global institutions: A discursive
making of a global firm: Local pathways to perspective, Organization Studies 27(1):
multinational enterprise, in Morgan et al. 7–29.
(eds.), pp. 172–195. Maguire, S., C. Hardy and T.B. Lawrence
Lane, C. (2000), Understanding the globaliza- (2004), Institutional entrepreneurship in
tion strategies of German and British multi- emerging fields: HIV/AIDS treatment advo-
national companies: Is a ‘societal effects’ cacy in Canada, Academy of Management
approach still useful?, in Maurice and Sorge Journal 47(5): 657–679.
(eds.) pp. 189–208. Majone, G. (ed.) (1996), Regulating Europe.
Lane, C. (2001), The emergence of German London: Routledge.
transnational companies: A theoretical March, J. and J. Olsen (1998), The institutional
analysis and empirical study of the globaliza- dynamics of international political orders,
tion process, in Morgan et al. (eds.), International Organization 52(4): 943–969.
pp. 69–96. Martin, Lisa L. (ed.) (2005), International
Lane, C. (2003), Changes in corporate gover- Institutions in the New Global Economy.
nance of German corporations: Convergence Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
to the Anglo-American model?, Competition Maurice, M. and A. Sorge (eds.) (2000),
and Change 7(2–3): 79–100. Embedding Organizations. Amsterdam and
Lane, C. and J. Probert (2006), Domestic capa- Philadelphia: Benjamins.
bilities and global production networks in McKenna, C., M.-L. Djelic, and A. Ainamo
the clothing industry: A comparison of (2003), Message and medium: The role of
German and UK firms’ strategies, Socio- consulting firms in globalization and its local
Economic Review 4: 35–67. interpretation, in Djelic and Quack (eds.),
Lawrence, T.B. and R. Suddaby (2006), pp. 83–107.
Institutions and Institutional Work, in McNichol, J. and J. Bensedrine (2003),
Clegg, Hardy, Thomas and North (eds.), Multilateral rulemaking: Transatlantic struggles
pp. 215–254. around genetically modified food, in Djelic
Lawrence, T.B., M.I. Winn and P.D. Jennings and Quack (eds.), pp. 220–44.
(2001), ‘The temporal dynamics of institu- Meyer, J. and F. Ramirez (2000), The world
tionalization’, Academy of Management institutionalization of education, in
Review 26(4): 624–644. Schriewer, J. (ed.), Discourse Formation in
Lehmkuhl, D. (2003), Structuring dispute reso- Comparative Education. Frankfurt: Peter
lution in transnational trade: Competition Lang Publishers.
322 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Meyer, J., J. Boli, G. Thomas and F. Ramirez Parsons, T. (1956) Suggestions for a sociological
(1997a), World society and the nation–state, approach to the theory of organizations,
American Journal of Sociology 103(1), Administrative Science Quarterly 1(1): 63–85.
144–181. Plehwe, Dieter (2001), National trajectories,
Meyer, J., D. Frank, A. Hironaka, E. Schofer and international competition, and transnational
N. Tuma (1997b), The Structuring of a World governance in Europe, in Morgan et al. (eds),
Environmental regime, 1870–1990, pp. 281–305.
International Organization 51(4): 623–651. Plehwe, D. with S. Vescovi (2003), Europe’s
Meyer, J. and B. Rowan (1977), Institutionalized special case: The five corners of business-
organizations: Formal structure as myth and state interactions, in Djelic and Quack (eds.),
ceremony, American Journal of Sociology, pp. 193–219.
83(2): 340–363. Polanyi, Karl (1944), The Great Transformation.
Morgan, G. (2001), Transnational communities Boston, Mass: Beacon Press.
and business systems, Global Networks: A Quack, S., G. Morgan and R. Whitley
Journal of Transnational Affairs 1(2), (eds.) (2000), National Capitalisms, Global
113–130. Competition and Economic Performance.
Morgan, G. (2006) Transnational actors, Amsterdam and Philadelphia: Benjamins.
transnational institutions, transnational Quack, S. (2006a), Die transnationalen
spaces: The role of law firms in the interna- Ursprünge des ‘deutschen Kapitalismus’, in
tionalisation of competition regulation, in Berghahn and Vitols (eds.), pp. 63–85.
M.-L. Djelic and K. Sahlin-Andersson (eds.), Quack, S. (2006b), Who fills the legal ‘black
pp. 139–160. holes’ in transnational governance? Lawyers,
Morgan, G. and L. Engwall (eds.) (1999), law firms and professional associations as
Regulation and organizations, Advances in border-crossing regulatory actors, in
Management and Business Studies 5. Schuppert (ed.), pp. 81–100.
London: Routledge. Quack, S. (2007), Legal Professionals and
Morgan, G., P.H. Kristensen and R. Whitley Transnational Law-Making: A case of
(eds.) (2001), The Multinational Firm. Distributed Agency, Organization 14(5):
Oxford: Oxford University Press. 643–666.
Morgan, G. and S. Quack (2005), Institutional Sahlin-Andersson, K. (1996), Imitating by edit-
legacies and firm dynamics: The growth and ing success: The construction of organization
internationalization of British and German fields, in Czarniawska and Sevón (eds.),
law firms, Organization Studies 26(12), pp. 69–92.
1765–1785. Sahlin-Andersson, K. and L. Engwall (eds.)
Morgan, G., R. Whitley and E. Moen (eds.) (2002), The Expansion of Management Know-
(2005), Changing Capitalisms? Oxford: ledge. Stanford: Stanford University Press.
Oxford University Press. Salk, J., F. Nielsen and G. Marks (2001),
Murray, G. (1987), From the League to UN. Patterns of cooperation among regional
Greenwood Publishing Group. offices in Brussels: Homophily, complemen-
O’Brien, R., A.M. Goetz, J.A. Scholte and M. tarity and national embeddedness, CER-
Williams (2000), Contesting Global Gover- ESSEC Working Paper, Paris, France: ESSEC.
nance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Sandholtz, W. and A. Stone Sweet (eds.)
Press. (1998), European Integration and Supra-
Offe, C. (1995), Designing institutions for East national Governance. Oxford: Oxford
European transition, in Hausner, Jessop and University Press.
Nielsen (eds.), pp. 47–66. Schmidt, P. (2004), Law in the age of gover-
Oliver, C. (1991), Strategic responses to institu- nance, in Jordana and Levi-Faur (eds.),
tional processes, Academy of Management The Politics of Regulation. Cheltenham:
Review 16(1): 145–179. Edward Elgar, pp. 273–295.
Oliver, C. (1992), The antecedents of deinstitu- Scott, R., J. Meyer et al. (1994), Institutional
tionalization, Organization Studies 13(4): Environments and Organizations. Thousand
563–588. Oaks, CA: Sage.
INSTITUTIONS AND TRANSNATIONALIZATION 323

Scott, W.R. (2001), Institutions and Organi- Thietart, R.-A. and B. Forgues (1995), Chaos
zations, 2nd edn. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage. theory and organization, Organization
Selznick, P. (1949), TVA and The Grass Roots: A Science 6(1): 19–31.
Study in the Sociology of Formal Organi- Tolbert, P. and L. Zucker (1996), The institution-
zation. Berkeley, CA: University of California alization of institutional theory, in Clegg
Press. et al. (eds.), pp. 175–190.
Seo, M.-G. and W. E. D. Creed (2002), Van der Pijl, K. (1984), The Making of An
Institutional contradictions, praxis, and insti- Atlantic Ruling Class. London: Verso.
tutional change: A dialectical perspective, Van der Pijl, K. (1998), Transnational Classes
Academy of Management Journal 27(2): and International Relations. London:
222–247. Routledge.
Sharpe, D.R. (2001), Globalization and change: Ventresca, M., D. Szyliowicz and T. Dacin
Organizational continuity and change within (2003), ‘Institutional innovations in gover-
a Japanese multinational in the UK, in nance: Global structuring and the field of
Morgan et al. (eds.), pp. 196–224. public exchange-traded markets, in Djelic
Smith, C. and T. Elger (2000), The societal and Quack (eds.), pp. 245–277.
effects school and transnational transfer: The Vitols, S. (2005a), Globalization and the trans-
case of Japanese investment in Britain, in formation of the German model, Underhill
Maurice and Sorge (eds.), pp. 225–240. (ed.), pp. 398–407.
Schneiberg, M. (2007), What’s on the path? Vitols, S. (2005b), Changes in Germany’s
Path dependence, organizational diversity bank-based financial system: Implications for
and the problem of institutional change in corporate governance, Corporate
the US economy, 1900–50, Socio-Economic Governance 13(3): 386–396.
Review 5(1): 47–80. Vogel, S.K. (1996), Freer Markets, More Rules.
Sorge, A. (2000), The diabolical dialectics of Ithaca: Cornell University Press.
societal effects, in Maurice and Sorge (eds.), Walgenbach, P. (2000), Die Normgerechte
pp. 37–56. Organisation. Stuttgart: Schäffer-Poeschel
Strange, S. (1996), The Retreat of the State. Verlag.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Weber, M. (1978), Economy and Society.
Suchman, M.C. (1995a), Managing legitimacy: Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.
Strategies and institutional approaches, Westney, E. (1987), Imitation and Innova-
Academy of Management Review 20(3): tion. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
571–610. Whitley, R. (1999), Divergent Capitalisms.
Suchman, M.C. (1995b), Localism and Oxford: Oxford University Press.
globalism in institutional analysis: The emer- Whitley, R. (2003), Changing transnational
gence of contractual norms in venture finance, institutions and the management of
in Scott and Christensen (eds.), pp. 39–63. international business: The impact on
Swidler, A. (1986), Culture in action: Symbols national business systems, in Djelic and
and strategies, American Sociological Quack (eds.), pp. 108–133.
Review, 51 (April), 273–286. Zeitlin, J. and G. Herrigel (2000) (eds.),
Tainio, R., M. Huolman, and M. Pulkkinen Americanization and its Limits. Oxford:
(2001), The internationalisation of capital Oxford University Press.
markets: How international institutional Zucker, L.G. (1977), The role of institutionaliza-
investors are restructuring Finnish tion in cultural perspective, American
companies, in Morgan et al. (eds.), pp. Sociological Review 42: 726–743.
153–171.
SECTION III

Applications
12
Traditions as Institutionalized
Practice: Implications for
Deinstitutionalization
M. Tina Dacin and Peter A. Dacin

Institutional theory provides a powerful lens The framework proposed that the dissipation
for explaining individual and collective or rejection of an institutionalized practice
action. Recently, increased efforts towards was a result of a set of political, functional,
understanding how institutions are created and social pressures. The dissipation or rejec-
have led to a systematic development of tion then leads to deinstitutionalization,
ideas on institutional entrepreneurship and which, in turn, leads to erosion and/or extinc-
attention to processes and mechanisms of tion. For Oliver, deinstitutionalization is ‘the
institutional construction. Despite this process by which the legitimacy of an estab-
growing rise of interest in how institutions lished or institutionalized organizational
are created, we still know relatively little practice erodes or discontinues’ (1992: 564).
about the process of deinstitutionalization. A number of studies examine processes of
Many questions remain concerning how decline and erosion, including erosion via
institutions wax and wane or diminish in replacement as in the case of classic French
potency over time and the processes that cuisine (Rao, Monin, & Durand, 2003); strat-
shape the erosion and extinction of institu- egy abandonment in radio formats (Greve,
tionalized practices. 1995), ideological and political obsolescence
While a few studies examine institutional of CEOs with finance backgrounds (Ocasio
decline within the framework or boundaries & Kim, 1999), impact of downsizing in dein-
of studying institutional change (Dacin, stitutionalizing permanent employment prac-
Goodstein, & Scott, 2002), efforts to unpack tices in Japan (Ahmadjian & Robinson,
the strategies and dynamics associated with 2001), and the shedding and shunning of the
extinction are lacking. Scott defines deinsti- conglomerate form (Davis, Diekmann, &
tutionalization as the ‘process by which insti- Tinsley, 1994). An interesting observation
tutions weaken and disappear’ (2001: 182). from these studies, however, is that institu-
Important theorizing on deinstitutionali- tionalized practices are rarely ever com-
zation was put forth by Oliver (1992). pletely extinguished. The practice continues
Oliver’s framework was the first to albeit weaker in scope (extent of diffusion) or
pay explicit attention to the erosion and potency. These studies also suggest that vari-
extinction of institutionalized practices. ous features or elements of institutionalized
328 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

behaviors continue and serve as either a will also allow us to offer several contributions
reminder of prior strategies and/or as raw towards a fuller and richer understanding of
material for the construction of new ones. deinstitutionalization. First, in order to
We take these findings as a starting point for understand the processes that contributed to
our chapter to understand the nature of tradi- the decline of tradition and institutionalized
tions and how traditions erode and become practices of Bonfire, we bring together liter-
extinguished. As we discuss below, we focus ature from work on culture, social move-
on traditions because, while they share ments, and institutions.
commonalities with institutionalized prac- Second, we are able to extend Oliver’s
tice, they also have some unique qualities (1992) framework in important ways
that make them relevant for understanding by highlighting the roles played by custo-
deinstitutionalization. dians (Soares, 1997), collective memory
In order to understand the process by (Hawlbachs, 1950; Zerubavel, 1997), collec-
which traditions erode, we summarize a tive identity and ritual in preserving institu-
recent illustration of a single tradition in an tionalized practices as well as distinguish
organizational setting and its evolution over between core and ancillary institutional
time. We consider traditions to be institution- dimensions and the role they play in the ero-
alized practices or collections of such prac- sion of an institutionalized practice. We fur-
tices and subsequently focus on developing ther suggest that this erosion leaves behind
implications for understanding the process of an institutional ‘remnant’1 which forms the
deinstitutionalization. We do this through an raw material for the emergence of new insti-
application and extension of Oliver’s frame- tutional practices or re-emergence of old
work of deinstitutionalization in the context institutional practices. As long as there exist
of examining the life history of a single tra- remnants, an institutionalized practice is
dition over time. Before presenting our case never extinguished or completely deinstitu-
study, we want to clarify what we mean by tionalized. Finally, we suggest several direc-
traditions and how they erode. Towards the tions for future work in this area with a
end of our chapter, we demonstrate how our particular focus on the strategic management
story reveals important insights for under- of traditions.
standing the erosion and extinction of institu- We begin by summarizing existing views
tionalized practices. on the nature of traditions and relate
The tradition we examine in this chapter is these views to institutionalized practices.
Texas A&M University’s ‘Aggie Bonfire,’ a Following this, we briefly review Oliver’s
tradition that existed for a period of 90 years. (1992) framework for deinstitutionalization
As we later explain, we chose this tradition and then apply this framework in the histori-
because it is a rich tradition that underwent a cally rich case of the Aggie Bonfire, a case
process of deinstitutionalization and fits well that demonstrates the evolution and erosion
within the context of Oliver’s (1992) deinsti- of a single tradition over time. We then illus-
tutionalization framework. The case of the trate how the understanding we gain through
Aggie Bonfire is especially rich in helping us this case study allows us to offer both an
to unpack the nature of organizational tradi- application and extension of Oliver’s (1992)
tions and implications for the study of framework of deinstitutionalization.
change in institutionalized practices. It has
been studied by scholars in management
(Beyer & Nino, 2000) as well as cultural THE NATURE OF TRADITIONS
geography (Smith, 2004) and described in
rich detail by journalist Irwin Tang (2000). Traditions are important across many con-
The insights we gain from our understand- texts. Think of military and religious tradi-
ing of the deinstitutionalization of Bonfire tions or the tradition of Christmas and
TRADITIONS AS INSTITUTIONALIZED PRACTICE 329

Thanksgiving. There are scientific traditions of variation in traditions over time, he also
(see Kuhn, 1962, for example) and oral tradi- regards traditions as having an invariant core
tions as well as industry orthodoxies or tradi- and as being intergenerational. He also sug-
tional ways of doing business. Traditions gests that a practice has to survive at least
have been widely studied in sociology, three generations in order for it to be consid-
anthropology, cultural geography, political ered a tradition. In Shils’s view, as traditions
science and marketing. evolve the accumulation or removal of new
A brief summary of more recent work on elements leave other aspects relatively
traditions can be found in Soares (1997). For unchanged. Take, for example, the tradition
Soares, there exist several themes or views of convocation. Convocation is a tradition
that define much of the work on the nature of with multiple elements, some core and some
traditions. Drawing on ideas by Freud and ancillary. Convocation involves a number of
Marx, traditions are conceived as restraints elements such as having one’s name called
or the constraining hand from the past that out, receiving a diploma as well as the pro-
defines and limits current action. A second cession, granting of an honorary doctorate,
view of tradition is tradition as taken for and various material and symbolic elements
granted or unreflective habit as found in the such as the adornment of a convocation gown
writings of Weber. However, Soares (1997: and the various colors observed in convoca-
10) notes that Weber’s position on tradition tion hoods and caps. Some of these elements
has a tendency to equate tradition and cus- take on greater or lesser meaning (potency)
toms. Soares views the two constructs as and evolve into core elements in a particular
quite distinct in that while customs involve context based on region, profession, or past
unreflective habit, traditions, on the other practice. However, there are also some
hand, possess a collective memory and a set elements widely shared or core across all
of custodians aware of the past. convocations (scope).
A third view is provided by Shils (1981) Elements of a given tradition are passed
who has written the most extensive treatment down to successive generations. The invari-
on the subject of understanding tradition. For ant core of a tradition provides impetus and
Shils, the study of tradition was largely resources for future generations to accept and
ignored by mainstream sociology. Shils’s enact a tradition. The transmitted material
view of traditions is to think of them as a can take the form of a combination of core
source of continuity with the past or as and ancillary elements in the form of ‘rem-
cultural ‘inheritance.’ The notion is quite nants’ – a limited amount of raw material that
broad and could mean anything that is passed can form the basis for reinventing existing
down or inherited to the present. For Shils, traditions or constructing new ones.3 This
traditions incorporate a variety of beliefs, core or essence can take the form of a
objects, memories, imagery, practices and number of elements, including but not lim-
institutions (1981: 12). Shils introduces tra- ited to a name, an identity, location, activity
dition as something that has exemplars or or imagery. A sense of identity with the past
custodians, not so much because of its prior evolves and a sense of community or collec-
existence but possibly also because it has a tive identity with the present emerges (Shils,
‘quality of pastness’ that appeals to current 1981: 14). There are important normative
practitioners (1981: 13). Therefore, in order implications of traditions as they provide not
for traditions to be successfully transmitted only continuity between the past and present
and repeated, it is likely necessary that they but define what is deemed appropriate in the
also need to be authentic or genuine (Sapir, present. An irony of traditions, as studied
1949)2 in order to be accepted or taken for from Shils’s view, is that while traditions
granted as appropriate and legitimate. While place limits or constraints on what can be
Shils (1981) acknowledges the introduction changed or how things change, traditions
330 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

themselves are continuously evolving and given tradition linked by collective memories.
changing. Custodians value their inheritance and ‘feel a
Hobsbawm (1983) provides a fourth view sense of custodianship for the tradition’s
of understanding tradition by regarding them present and future prospects’ (Soares, 1997:
as invented. Hobsbawm builds on the idea of 14). Soares views traditions as ‘a resource
continuity but provides a different rationale warehouse for the living’ (1997: 15) and is
for the construction of traditions in that they the most dynamic approach to understanding
are created by elites that construct them to the nature of traditions. In his view, the past
assert and reify their power. Hobsbawm also provides values and solutions that can be
examines the process of how traditions are mobilized to deal with today’s problems.
‘invented’ as well as how they change.
Innovations and redesign of traditions come
about as a result of a change in practices
fueled by the interests of those in power. TRADITIONS AS INSTITUTIONALIZED
For Hobsbawm, traditions are an invariant, PRACTICES
repetitive set of symbolic activities rooted in
the past: We conceive of traditions as a construct
a set of practices, normally governed by overtly
residing at the intersection of institutional
or tacitly accepted rules and of a ritual or symbolic theory, as well as scholarly work on culture
nature, which seek to inculcate certain values and social movements, in that they draw
and norms of behaviour by repetition, which upon values, the normative implications
automatically implies continuity with the past. and mobilization of such values and value-
(Hobsbawm, 1984: 1)
laden structures, and are oftentimes much
Soares raises an important critique regarding more stable and enduring than customs or
Hobsbawm’s work, in that his defini- conventions. In this chapter, our focus is
tion makes it difficult to distinguish the more on, as Soares put it, ‘living social’ tra-
notion of tradition from ritual. According to ditions and traditions that are organizational
Soares, Hobsbawm’s contribution was to in nature.
allow for a clearer delineation between It is relatively easy from a review of the
traditions and customs in that traditions are more extensive treatments of tradition in the
more stable structures, whereas customs literature (Hobsbawm & Ranger, 1984; Shils,
evolve to fulfill more pragmatic needs 1981) to identify a number of characteristics
(Soares, 1997: 11). that define organizational traditions. They
Soares (1997) builds on this earlier work are infused with value and meaning and are
and provides a valuable extension for oftentimes associated with myths or narra-
understanding the nature of tradition more tives about their creation or continued exis-
broadly. Soares provides the following tence. They are repositories of collective
definition: memories and identities, building social
a living social tradition requires a distinct social
cohesion via symbols and/or ritual as well as
group with a common identity derived from an shared experiences or imagined communities
interpretation of its past, whose collective memo- (Andersen, 1991). They involve resource
ries have some objective expression in the material mobilization and utilization and are pro-
environment, and whose activities are guided by a tected and enhanced by custodians.
spirit of continuity. (1997: 16)
Traditions imply continuity and thus are
Especially relevant for our discussion is quite stable, enduring, and repetitive.
that both Shils (1981) and Soares (1997) Traditions can be broad or narrow in scope
give explicit attention to the role of custodi- (global versus more local or regional tradi-
ans in preserving and enhancing traditions.4 tions) in terms of their diffusion and con-
Custodians are exemplars or practitioners of a sumption, as well as vary in potency over
TRADITIONS AS INSTITUTIONALIZED PRACTICE 331

time and place. Finally, traditions also have a consist of an interconnected pattern of mean-
temporal dimension (Zerubavel, 1997). ings, custodians, collective memories, and
Given this broad range of dimensions, some but not all ritualized activities.
characteristics and components, we believe In this chapter we are interested in expand-
it is useful to think of traditions and consider ing our understanding of how institutional-
their evolution in three important ways. First, ized practices erode and extinguish. We
we regard traditions as institutionalized orga- believe that understanding the evolution of
nizational behaviors or practices. According traditions will further our understanding of
to Oliver (1992), ‘institutionalized organiza- institutional change and deinstitutionaliza-
tional behaviors’ are ‘stable, repetitive and tion. We next examine how traditions
enduring activities’ º ‘infused with value,’ become extinguished.
repetitive and resistant to change.5 However,
we relax the assumption that institutionalized
practices are ‘taken-for-granted’ as this
makes traditions more akin to customs or ENHANCING, ERODING AND
conventions. Given our earlier summary of EXTINGUISHING TRADITIONS:
work on traditions, we concur that traditions THEORETICAL FOUNDATIONS
are much more than unreflective habit and in
fact are created and managed by mindful In this chapter we pay special attention to
custodians. processes associated with change and its
Second, we agree that traditions change outcome on the evolution of traditions as insti-
frequently in that they adapt to suit the tutionalized practices. We contend that adap-
needs of ‘the living’ or the needs of the tation or change in institutionalized practices
present (Hobsbawm, 1984; Shils, 1981; may result in either erosion or enhancement.
Soares, 1997). Consequently, we also relax As we demonstrate in our case study below,
the assumption that institutionalized prac- the tradition of the Aggie Bonfire changed
tices are highly resistant to change. We frequently but those changes served many
address the issue of institutional stability and purposes, including both the erosion and
endurance by distinguishing between core enhancement of its potency over time.
and ancillary elements of traditions. At the One theoretical starting point for examin-
field level, DiMaggio (1988) notes the pres- ing outcomes that result from changes in tra-
ence of core and subsidiary institutions. ditions is deinstitutionalization, or ‘the
Following Shils (1981), we think of tradi- process by which institutions weaken and
tions as collections and/or containers of core disappear’ (Scott, 2001: 1982). Oliver (1992)
and ancillary micro-institutions and cultural applied deinstitutionalization to specific
elements that may include symbols, material activities or practices that appear institution-
objects, myths, custodians, rituals, temporal alized in organizations. Her framework for
qualities as well as collective identities and the deinstitutionalization of institutionalized
memories. practices suggests that dissipation or rejec-
By making the distinction between core tion of institutionalized practices is driven by
and ancillary elements we are able to theo- political, functional, and/or social pressures
rize about core and enduring qualities of tra- that lead to deinstitutionalization (Figure
ditions versus those that are more malleable 12.1). If these pressures lead to a gradual
yet in some ways relatively ancillary. This deterioration in the acceptance and use of an
distinction allows us to consider both erosion institutionalized practice, Oliver terms this
and persistence of institutionalized practices process to be dissipation. The decline in
as well as consider changes in scope and freemasonry or volunteerism would be an
potency of institutionalized practices over example of dissipation of an institutionalized
time. For us, the core elements of traditions practice (Putnam, 2000).
332 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Political
pressure
Entropy

Functional Dissipation Deinstitution- Erosion or


pressure and rejection alizaton discontinuity

Inertia
Social
pressure

Figure 12.1 A deinstitutionalization framework – Oliver (1992)

Both entropy pressures and inertial pres- withdraw the rewards associated with sus-
sures moderate the rate of dissipation. taining an institutionalized organizational
Entropy consists of pressures that accelerate activity, when social and economic
the process of deinstitutionalization while criteria of organizational success begin to
inertia consists of pressures that impede it. conflict significantly with one another,
On the other hand, if the validity of the insti- and/or when the organization experiences an
tutionalized practice is directly challenged increase in its technical specificity or goal
we could have rejection rather than dissipa- clarity.
tion of the practice. As a result of dissipation The third antecedent, social pressures, rep-
or rejection the practice could become dein- resents a condition under which an organiza-
stitutionalized, which then leads to its erosion tion is neither a proactive agent of
or discontinuity. deinstitutionalization nor centrally intent on
With respect to the three antecedents, abandoning or rejecting particular institu-
Oliver (1992) suggests that political pres- tional traditions. According to Oliver (1992),
sures occur as a result of the utility or legiti- social pressures include increasing normative
macy of the practice being called into fragmentation within an organization as a
question. This tends to occur under condi- byproduct of other organizational changes,
tions of mounting performance crises, the disruptions to the organization’s historical
growth in the criticality or representation of continuity, changes in state laws for societal
organizational members whose interest or expectations that prohibit or discourage the
beliefs conflict with the status quo, increased perpetuation of an institutional practice,
pressures on the organization to adopt and/or lower structural changes to the organ-
innovative practices, and/or the reduction in ization or the environment within which the
the dependence on the institutional con- organization resides that disaggregate collec-
stituents that have encouraged or enforced tive norms and values.
continuing procedural conformity with their In addition to the work in the deinstitution-
expectations. alization literature, the literature on traditions
The second antecedent, functional pres- provides additional insights into various
sure, exists when changes to the perceived responses to these pressures that may occur.
utility or technical instrumentality of a For example, as Oliver (1992) notes, institu-
practice occur, or when there is redistribution tional practices can cease to have value or
in organizational power. Oliver (1992) iden- utility for either their custodians or practi-
tifies this antecedent as having an effect tioners, as a result of political, functional or
under a variety of conditions, including when social pressures. When this occurs in the con-
institutional constituents in the environment text of a tradition, Shils (1981) suggests that
TRADITIONS AS INSTITUTIONALIZED PRACTICE 333

custodians and practitioners may react by process of dissipation. In particular, there


loosening their acceptance of or adherence to exist several mechanisms through which dis-
the tradition. sipation can occur. These mechanisms
include assimilation, dilution, disembedding,
Traditions can deteriorate in the sense of losing
their adherents because their possessors cease to competition and erasure.
present them or because those who once received Assimilation involves being absorbed into
and reenacted and extended them now prefer a new tradition. Shils (1981) describes how
other lines of conduct or because new generations Roman religion ceases to exist yet some of
to which they were presented find other traditions
its elements have been synthesized or incor-
of belief or some relatively new beliefs more
acceptable. (1981: 15) porated into modern Christianity (p. 25).
Dilution involves adding or importing new
The literature on traditions suggests that a elements into a given tradition or expansion
second type of response to political, func- of the core elements till it is difficult, com-
tional and social pressures may be one of plex, or involves changes in value for custo-
overcorrection as custodians and practition- dians or practitioners (declining for some
ers attempt to reframe or revise elements that while increasing for others) of the tradition.
have become problematic or inconsistent Cherlin (2004) describes the weakening of
over time (Shils, 1981). Changes in tradi- social norms defining the idea and practice of
tions, however, could also lead to increasing marriage. Recent debates over the definition
complexity, making transmission of the tra- of marriage in North America point to the
dition increasingly difficult and imperfect. potential dilution of the meaning of the prac-
Another type of reaction to changes in regu- tice but also shed light on the changing value
lative, normative, and cognitive dimensions of this practice for various custodians or
of the tradition is one of significant decou- practitioners of the tradition.
pling between the symbol and substance Disembedding involves disconnecting or
and/or performance of traditions. In the con- dismantling core elements from each other
text of strategic responses to institutional insomuch as there is no longer a definable or
pressure, Oliver (1991) describes this ‘interconnected’ pattern of tradition or insti-
response as avoidance. Finally, reactions to tutionalized practice (Jepperson, 1991).
these pressures may also lead to the emer- Competition involves the presence of other
gence of countervailing social movements to traditions that vie for the attention and sup-
mobilize resources and momentum either port of key constituents. These competing
against or for the tradition. An interesting alternatives present conflicting claims and
and more recent example of this would be are referred to by Shils (1981) as ‘alien’ in
efforts mobilizing worldwide support and nature. The potential for institutional colli-
advocacy for the promotion of slow food sions as a result of competing traditions is
(Rao & Giorgi, 2006) or the decline of fois exacerbated when the potency of custodian-
gras (DeSoucey, 2006). The popular press in ship is weak, collective memory is scarce,
Marketing is rife with attention on the rise of and multiple identities prevent solidarity of
‘counter-culture’ movements against tradi- practice. Erasure, while rare, involves
tion. Integrating the tradition’s literature removal or replacement of core elements
into our understanding of the enhancement, such as core rituals or collective memories.
erosion and extinction of institution- Examples would include attempts by media
alized practices allows us to extend Oliver’s or historians to revise history.
(1992) framework to include some additional By integrating several approaches and the-
insight as to the various responses that may ories about institutionalized practices and
occur as a result of political, functional traditions, we are able to extend Oliver’s
and social pressures. We also believe that (1992) framework in several ways. This
insights on traditions help us to unpack the allows us to clarify different responses to the
334 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

various antecedent pressures for deinstitu- A&M, in contrast, had an agricultural and a
tionalization. From a strategic perspective, mechanical engineering focus.
doing this also provides some insights for Traditions play a central role at the
examining how these different responses, in University. In fact, Tang (2000: 7) notes that
turn, affect dissipation or rejection. Our ‘Traditions, and the value of Tradition, dictate
extension also allows us to unpack the notion Texas A&M culture.’6 The University has sev-
of dissipation, thus providing some insight as eral traditions based around remembrance,
to the various underlying mechanisms symbols, team spirit, and building community,
through which dissipation of traditions and Corps of Cadets, and various class councils
other institutionalized practices occur. (http://aggietraditions.tamu.edu/). Some of
Finally, the integration allows us to introduce these traditions are relatively more recent
the notion of an ‘institutional remnant’ that while others have been in existence for over
suggests that, even after a tradition or institu- 100 years. For example, Big Event, a large
tionalized practice appears to have eroded, student service project, was started in 1982
there may be sufficient remnants of the while Muster, a remembrance to those who
original tradition to lead to a new tradition, have passed, began in 1883.
or a re-invention or even re-emergence of From its inception, Texas A&M sought to
the original tradition or institutionalized establish itself as a distinctive institution by
practice. priding itself that it offered its students what
came to be known as the ‘other’ education.
As a result of its military heritage or the need
to establish its distinctiveness from the
TEXAS A&M UNIVERSITY: University of Texas at Austin, A&M prided
A CASE STUDY itself on its ability to provide opportunities
for its students to build character and acquire
Texas A&M University is a public institution leadership skills. One of these opportunities
founded in 1876 in College Station, Texas. In was the Aggie Bonfire, regarded by many as
the early days, the University had an undefined the largest student organized project in the
mission and was ‘all-male and all-military’ United States.
(Jacobs, 2002: 13). It wasn’t until after 1891
that the University President declared military
training as part of its central mission (Jacobs,
2002). The students, known as Aggies, are THE TRADITION OF AGGIE BONFIRE
known for their spirit and camaraderie.
It is currently one of the largest academic The case of the Aggie Bonfire is especially
institutions in the United States with a cur- rich in helping us to unpack the nature of
rent enrollment of over 46,000 students and organizational traditions and implications for
an endowment valued at over 4 billion US the study of change in institutionalized prac-
dollars (www.tamu.edu). As a consequence tices. The evolution of the Bonfire tradition is
of early state politics and fights over funding a story occurring over a period of 90 years
and mandate (Jacobs, 2002; Smith, 2004; from its emergence in 1909 to its significant
Tang, 2000), the University developed a deinstitutionalization in 2002. Our historical
culture that distrusted outsiders. Due to description and analyses are based on an
state politics and football, Texas A&M extensive review of public documents and
has developed a fierce rivalry with the archival news sources7. We synthesized his-
University of Texas at Austin over time. torical data and key insights into an extensive
While the University of Texas at Austin had set of notes, timelines and tables in order to
a broader mandate that included a broad, make sense of and validate the information
arts- and science-based curriculum, Texas collected.
TRADITIONS AS INSTITUTIONALIZED PRACTICE 335

Many university campuses light bonfires members of the Bonfire hierarchy. A fresh-
but the Aggie Bonfire is distinctive because it man entering the university would grab the
was the largest and most complex student- attention of someone more senior in the
run project in the United States (Tang, 2000). Bonfire organization by doing something
It is said that the construction of the Bonfire risky or brazen during the rituals associated
structure involves more than 125,000 hours with Cut or Stack. Once noticed, this student
of student time with about 70,000 individuals would be selected to take on increasing
turning out to observe the final ritual of Burn responsibility in future years.
(Jacobs, 2002). Over the years, three rituals had become
Bonfire can be regarded as a ritualized tra- central to Bonfire – Cut, Stack, and Burn.
dition (Smith, 2004) consisting of myth and Each of these rituals contained its own set of
meaning systems, custodians, central and activities, thus each served as a meta-ritual.
peripheral rituals, as well as collective mem- Cut involved gathering the necessary logs
ories shared among custodians and key con- starting in early October. The ritual known as
stituents. At Texas A&M University, a Stack involved assembling the logs into what
tradition of Bonfire is inextricably linked to will become the Bonfire. Push was part of
football. The Aggie Bonfire grew to be more Stack and occurred for the two weeks prior to
than a mere fire. Of all the traditions at Texas Burn. The push is to finish with students
A&M University, the Bonfire was regarded working round the clock in shifts to ensure
as the most central and important (Tang, the Bonfire is built on time. The ritual of
2000). Bonfire’s purpose was to maintain and Burn occurs on the night preceding the
instill loyalty as well as provide a symbol annual football game with the University of
representative of the rivalry with the Texas.
University of Texas at Austin. Bonfire was As mentioned, within each of the core rit-
regarded as being representative of the uals of Cut, Stack, and Burn, there were sev-
‘Aggie Spirit’ and for the first 50 or so years eral activities or ancillary elements
went largely unquestioned. associated with the tradition. For example,
Bonfire fulfilled numerous needs of the ‘groding’ involved being thrown in mud at
student body. It allowed students to forge the construction site with food and/or feces
friendships, vent aggression, and demon- while others went unshaven or unwashed for
strate courage. In other words, it provided a weeks as a means of demonstrating one’s
good training ground for the other education loyalty or devotion to the tradition and to the
that A&M deemed shaped its unique charac- Aggie spirit (Smith, 2004: 42). On the night
ter. While numbers vary, it is estimated that of Burn, the Aggie Band, Yell Leaders, and
more than 6000–8000 trees are cut each year Red Pots paraded around the Bonfire, in turn.
to build Bonfire (Jacobs, 2002). Thousands The Red Pots, the last to circle Bonfire,
of spectators (students, former students and would carry the torches that would set fire
members of the local community) turn out to to the structure. The fire, helped along by
watch the fire burn. There was no written 700 gallons of diesel fuel soaked into the
construction plan or blueprint nor was there logs was visible for quite a distance.
any professional supervision. There was, In the remainder of this case study, we
however, an elaborate, hierarchical organiza- break down our examination of the evolution
tion that guided the practice of the Bonfire of the Aggie Bonfire over four distinct peri-
tradition each year. This structure was largely ods. By doing so, we are able to track the
patriarchal (consisting of men in leadership evolution of this tradition on a variety of
roles) and intergenerational. At the top of the important dimensions and relate our insights
Bonfire hierarchy were a group of senior directly to Oliver’s (1992) framework for
students known as Red Pots. These Red deinstitutionalization. We pay particular
Pots would pass along knowledge to other attention to the essence, custodians, rituals,
336 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

myths/stories, symbols and physical artifacts, appeal for burning material expanded to
as well as changes in place and temporality. involve the state and the railroad companies
We also provide insight into the changing who helped to bring in wood and boxes from
nature of the organization in which the tradi- all over the state.
tion was embedded by summarizing the char- In 1933, following a complaint from a
acter of the organization, its key constituents, farmer that students had dismantled and car-
key success factors, and strategic arenas. ried off his log barn, an order was issued in
With respect to Oliver’s framework, we will 1936 that ‘no one would be allowed to collect
demonstrate how these dimensions relate to Bonfire materials or place them on Bonfire
the antecedent pressures, entropy and inertia other than authorized personnel’ and that the
that comprise the framework. building of Bonfire would be under the direc-
tion of the Commandant. It was also in this
year that A&M received permission to
Period 1: the tradition emerges remove dead trees from a nearby field in
which an airport had been built. For the next
(1909–1942)
six years Bonfire continued to take on many
According to several sources (Dethloff, forms under the direction of the
1976; Jacobs, 2002; and especially Tang, Commandant, but it remained primarily a
2000) the Aggie Bonfire began in 1909 as a ‘trash pile.’
prank to arouse interest and excitement in an In these early years, the Bonfire tradition
upcoming Texas A&M – University of Texas was tightly coupled with the university’s
at Austin football game. The tradition arose goals and identity. In these early years, the
out of humble beginnings. The first Bonfire University’s focus of attention was largely
comprised a pile of scrap wood and trash directed inward towards the preservation of
boxes gathered from all over campus, and its distinctive character and goals. Bonfire
deposited in a central gathering place. At epitomized this distinctiveness and grew in
this time, A&M was a military college, so the importance within the University. The tradi-
parade ground served as a symbolic center- tions at Texas A&M, and the tradition of
piece for events. Bonfire in particular, produced important
The participants were primarily students outcomes. Bonfire provided an important
and events around Bonfire were primarily a vehicle for the early custodians, the Corps of
pep rally. In these early years, the bonfire Cadets, to establish their power and legiti-
was relatively small in nature (about 10–12 macy on the campus and in the community.
feet high) and bore resemblance to a pile of As keepers of the tradition, the Corps could
trash. In 1915, the Aggies beat UT-Austin in be regarded as the key custodians of this
a legendary game and a bonfire of trash and important tradition. These custodians worked
dry good boxes was spontaneously con- to promote and preserve the role of traditions
structed and burned after the game but this at the University. As noted by Jacobs’s recent
time in the streets of Bryan, a nearby town. history of the Corps at Texas A&M:
The intensity of the fire exploded the pave- The Cadets began to bond and, in turn, to foster
ment beneath the bonfire, but the community traditions – some born out of boredom and bulls
felt that it was really nothing and could easily sessions, but most derived from respect, loyalty,
be remedied. This was the first time the com- and values that came with a conservative, military
lifestyle. (Jacobs, 2002: 14)
munity had any involvement in Bonfire. This
was also the only time Bonfire was built after The power of the Corps of Cadets at the
the game and not held on the A&M campus. University is critical in understanding the
For the next 25 or so Bonfires, students evolution of Bonfire as well as other tradi-
and community members were asked to tions that define the campus and serve to dis-
supply boards and boxes. By the 1930s this tinguish it from other organizations. In fact,
TRADITIONS AS INSTITUTIONALIZED PRACTICE 337

as recently as 1993 and according to the Blue by 1946. Local filling stations donated hun-
Ribbon Committee on the Corps, they had a dreds of gallons of oil to saturate the logs and
prominent and central role on the University assist in their lighting. As the Commandant
campus: was now securely in charge, flow charts
The Corps of Cadets remains a vital and relevant and instructions as to who was in charge and
part of the overall University community today, the chain of command became the norm.
both as the ‘keeper’ of many of the University’s To prevent early lighting or vandalism
cherished traditions and as a repository and cham- by University of Texas students the
pion of values that make Aggies and Texas A&M
Commandant ordered eighteen 24-hour
truly unique. (Adams, 2001: 264)
guards posted, organized in several rings
During this period, except for minor inci- with orders that no one be allowed into the
dents, Bonfire faced few if any pressures. In innermost rings without clearance. By 1954
fact, the community was willing to accept the the Bonfire reached 73 feet tall.
minor incidents and contributed by helping In 1955 the first Bonfire-associated death
in the gathering of items for Bonfire. During occurred when a Cadet at a guard post
this period, the activities around Bonfire con- pushed another student out of the way of an
tinued to evolve, the core elements began to oncoming truck, was hit himself and later
take shape and the ancillary elements were died of his injuries. By this time, the number
focused on establishing the core elements. of individuals involved in Bonfire was quite
The reactions to the various incidents all large and the military traditions around
served to further entrench the Corps and its Bonfire were evolving, including the posting
Commandant as the custodians of Bonfire of guards as well as the first ‘war hero’ who
with the community and, by the end of the ‘died in action.’
period, the State, reinforcing and legitimiz- Soggy ground in 1956, as a result of
ing this role. In essence, any pressures steady rain, saw the Bonfire stack collapse
including entropy were quickly countered after the center pole started leaning. But with
through the Commandant’s garnering more military precision Bonfire was rebuilt with
control over Bonfire and thus establishing a students hauling logs by hand for as much as
point of responsibility so that it was no half a mile since trucks could not get through
longer just a ‘prank’ by students, but became the mud.
a legitimized organized practice that had As the entrenchment of the tradition grew,
become institutionalized. it was not unusual to allow Cadets to be
While recent ideas on institutional entre- excused from a day of class in order to work
preneurship have tended to focus on the pres- on Bonfire. By 1958, time being taken away
ence of purposeful action in constructing from academic work due to Bonfire was
institutions we observe that they can also becoming an issue. To counter this issue, in
emerge from humble beginnings or out of 1958 the university decreed that Bonfire had
serendipity. to be built in three days (instead of the usual
ten days) and students worked all day and
night non-stop, having food brought to them
Period 2: entrenchment (1942–1963) at the work site. Over time this three-day
time limit was relaxed to the point where it
By 1942 it was clear that Bonfire had under- became two months in recent years.
gone a distinct transformation to a very To summarize, this was a critical period
military-like activity which began a long his- in Bonfire’s evolution. Given the all-
tory of building bigger and better Bonfires. male nature of the University during this
The addition of a center pole (a log stuck into period, Bonfire took on ‘additional meaning
the ground supporting other logs stacked as symbol and proof of Aggie masculinity’
against it) allowed the height to reach 50 feet (Smith, 2004). During this period, the Corps
338 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

also entrenched themselves as the keepers of feature of the University. In other words, the
this tradition and the Bonfire was a symbolic tradition was now being used as part of the
triumph of the University’s core values and University’s identity. The community
source of distinctiveness. Traditions at A&M increased its participation, but only at the
and their primary custodians, the Corps of periphery, and the Bonfire (i.e., the identity
Cadets, provided enormous strategic benefits of the University) became sacred ground for
for the University. The ‘spirit of Aggieland’ the Corps to defend as they would do in
was its ‘longtime intangible’ (Jacobs, 2002: battle. Through the protection of sacred
14). As this spirit grew the University was ground, the core elements for Bonfire began
able to make unique claims about the experi- to become more and more entrenched. As the
ences it offered to its student community, identity of the University began to also
while at the same time benefiting enor- include Bonfire in its definitions, the ele-
mously from the cohesion and collective ments associated with Bonfire were also
identity its traditions conveyed for other becoming part of the University’s identity.
powerful constituents such as the Former As in the previous period, there were very
Students and local community. few pressures brought against Bonfire, but
Throughout this period, the Corps of Cadets when any arose, such as safety concerns, the
were the central custodians of the Bonfire and custodians of Bonfire took it on themselves
through this and other traditions the Corps to take care of the issues. When issues arose
worked hard to find ways to preserve and about how Bonfire might be affecting aca-
enhance their power and position on campus. demic standards, the reaction by the
They did so by making claims that they pro- University was not to question the utility of
vided much-needed links to the past as well as Bonfire, but simply to shorten the timeframe
the provision of character and leadership during which Bonfire was to be built. While
development. While the Corps saw declining there might have been a very slight emergent
numbers during World War II, they saw a concern about the quality of academics in
return to dominance on the campus by the this period, the reaction offered by the
1950s. The Corps and the University began to University suggests that traditions were still
gain increasing notoriety for their prowess in very important, as the solution (shortening
building bigger Bonfires. In fact, by the mid- the build by a week) probably did nothing to
1960s, Bonfire was regarded as a key distinc- enhance academics, but it was a way to
tive feature of the University (Smith, 2004). acknowledge the concern about missing
The University endorsed these traditions and classes by allowing students the time to
student recruiting films and campus orienta- attend classes. This provided further legiti-
tion films often gave prominence to traditions, macy to Bonfire as it demonstrated that the
especially to Bonfire. University, although not the custodian of
Even in the midst of safety concerns raised Bonfire, wanted it to continue to exist and
by the Assistant to the Commandant, the while the ancillary elements had to change to
1960 Bonfire stood over 100 feet tall. In accommodate the change in timeframe, these
1963, the death of John F. Kennedy resulted changes only reinforced the importance of
in the first cancelled Bonfire.8 the core elements. This is also seen when the
Continuing from the first period, it was students hauled the logs by hand – that is, the
clear that this period was the one in which ancillary rituals changed but they were
the Corps were firmly entrenched as the cus- changed so that the core rituals of the Cut,
todians of Bonfire. Integrating Bonfire with Stack and Burn could be maintained.
military myths and traditions only served to As all this was happening, it was clear that
reinforce this and the University continued to the myths and rituals of Bonfire were becom-
legitimize the tradition to the point where ing more and more entrenched, not only with
they proudly displayed this as a distinguishing the Bonfire tradition, but also at the level of
TRADITIONS AS INSTITUTIONALIZED PRACTICE 339

the University’s identity. If there was any first year in which all Aggies were involved.
question whatsoever in the previous period, Non-military Aggies were organized by a
it was now absolutely clear in this period non-military student. Female students were
that Bonfire had become an institutionalized also encouraged to help by serving in the
practice. Interestingly, while Bonfire started first-aid tent. In 1970, a professor raised a
out as closely coupled to football games, proposal to Student Senate to abolish Bonfire
during this period one could see a decou- on environmental grounds. The battle
pling from football games and a stronger between pro-Bonfire and anti-Bonfire groups
coupling of the traditions and the University; continued for several years. Through this
in essence, it was becoming a stand-alone time, it was clear that the majority of students
tradition that really did not need the football favored Bonfire and thanks to a media blitz
game but did become part of the University’s related to the environment and supported by
identity.9 the administration, the students eventually
won out as the call for abolishment eventu-
ally was overwhelmed. In 1973, women were
banned from working on Bonfire and in 1974
Period 3: changes, challenges and
the height was limited to 74 feet.
inertia (1963–1999)
In 1976, women were back working on
The 1960s brought a lot of changes to the Bonfire, some serving on guard duty along-
University. Mandatory participation in the side the males. The first female coordinator
Corps of Cadets was eliminated in 1965. of Bonfire appeared in 1979. Her role was to
Around that time, women and minorities be in charge of the women making lunches
were also permitted to enroll in the for the men working on Bonfire as well as
University. The size of the student body and those working at the Bonfire concession
faculty also increased dramatically. While stands. Although some female Cadets
the Corps of Cadets continued to be the cus- attended tree-cutting classes that year, they
todians of the traditions, many students were not issued necessary credentials to take
enrolled in the University were now able to part in the cutting. After a female filed a dis-
participate in the traditions while others crimination lawsuit, an open debate occurred
rejected the importance and practices associ- and policy was changed. The most vehement
ated with traditions. opponents to allowing women to participate
In 1967, the center pole was extended to were the senior male Cadets involved in the
105 feet and cranes were brought in to help organization of Bonfire. Following the policy
with the stacking. 1968 saw one civilian change, women were allowed to participate
allowed to serve in a leadership role in the in the Cut but they were set up in a separate
Bonfire organization but the civilian had to area and were under constant supervision.
wear a red helmet to distinguish him from In 1981, faced with a shortage of volun-
the other Cadets. In addition, there were teers (only Cadets could be forced to work on
some organizational structure changes that Bonfire), a female member of ‘Off-Campus
saw a ‘Head Stack’ assume the top position, Aggies’ and former Cadet was put in charge
and eight juniors were assigned to do most of of recruiting civilian women to work on
the planning and logistical work. The move Bonfire, including the Cut (this brought
to shared custodianship was an important about much derision from senior Corps
concession by the Corps as enrollment in members). Also in this year, the second
the Corps program was no longer mandatory, Bonfire death occurred when a student was
and interest and support for Bonfire was thrown from sitting on the fender of a tractor
becoming increasingly divided. and was crushed by the tractor, leading to a
In 1969, the largest Bonfire ever (109 feet change in policy regarding riding on tractors
tall) was built (Jacobs, 2002) and it was the and flatbed trucks.
340 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

By 1983 Bonfire decreased to only 54 feet critics as they could not be against the idea of
tall. 1998 again saw some male–female replant (Tang, 2002).
problems as a female was dragged from There were very few major safety inci-
being too near the stack to outside the dents that happened during the remaining
perimeter. Although there was no policy years of this period. The most notable was
against females working the stack, the the leaning of the stack in 1994, again
Cadets enforced their own policy. Although a because of excessive rain. There was another
lawsuit ensued and the Cadets pleaded guilty, death when students were thrown from the
the judge did not find them guilty and took back of a flatbed truck that lost control at
the offenses off their records. There were highway speed and there were still sexist and
more male–female incidents in 1987 with a racial incidents related to Bonfire organizers
lively exchange on the issue in the school and workers.
newspaper, The Battalion (Tang, 2000: 142). It was clear that, towards the end of this
In 1988, after a visit from the President’s period, there were many political, functional
Office’s Sexual Harassment Committee, and social pressures being brought to bear on
women were let on the stack. There were also Bonfire, including a shift in both the custodi-
several other issues that began to emerge. In ans and key constituents. The first major
1987 police started patrolling the stack on the change had to do with the declining presence
eve of Bonfire for alcohol and issued many of the Corps on campus. Enrollment in the
citations and arrested six individuals. In 1988 Corps was no longer compulsory and women
the number of citations increased and there and minorities were given access to the
were nine arrests. University, resulting in the composition of
In 1988, an anti-Bonfire organization, the student body becoming increasingly
‘Aggies Against Bonfire’ was founded diverse. There was an increased focus on
by a student and at the same time Faculty academics and the introduction of new schol-
Senate formed a committee to explore arly traditions such as a focus on graduate
alternatives to Bonfire. The debate between education (Jacobs, 2002: 21). Changes in
those who pushed for alternatives and curriculum and the University’s desire to
those who wanted to keep the tradition become one of the nation’s premier universi-
centered around alcohol use and, over ties brought important changes to it. The
several years, the debate continued as well University launched an initiative called
as media campaigns to reduce the association Vision 2020 with its goal to become one of
of alcohol and Bonfire. Environmental the top 10 public universities by the year
issues also continued to be a focus and law- 2020. The traditions were no longer effective
suits were brought against Bonfire on this in binding together the student body and, to a
ground. large extent, were consumed more by a
In response to criticism, ‘replant’ was ini- minority on campus and widely consumed by
tiated in 1991. Replant saw hundreds of another key constituent and emerging custo-
Aggies planting 10,000 seedlings on land dian, the Association of Former Students or
that was previously cleared. Others partici- alumni of the University.
pating in this initiative included the Texas Thus, important changes in the University’s
Environmental Action Coalition and the internal and external environment led to polit-
A&M Forestry Club. The Environmental ical and social pressures that eventually
Issues Chair stated that the replant, not changed the character, composition and
Bonfire, has ‘come to represent our burning structure of Bonfire. However, critics of
desire to beat the hell out of TU.’ These Bonfire and Aggie traditions were always
responses were an important way of diverting actively managed by the custodians of the
attention away from a focus on Bonfire while University. For example, a strategy to manage
at the same time serving to co-opt Bonfire critics included an elaborate replant program
TRADITIONS AS INSTITUTIONALIZED PRACTICE 341

to overcome increasing challenges from quality of student life, sacredness of tradi-


environmentalists. The challenges and con- tions such as Bonfire, etc.) as a basis for eval-
tests around the legitimacy of Bonfire and uating the success of the institution.
its value and appropriateness as a tradition Consequently, the perceived utility of institu-
began to surface on a more visible and global tionalized practices such as Bonfire was
scale, as opposed to the more limited slowly being subsumed by the perceived util-
challenges that previously occurred both in ity of other practices more closely associated
terms of visibility and frequency. These with achieving the goal of becoming a world-
included the increasing size and diversifica- class research institution.
tion of the student body, as well as changing There were also social pressures that were
goals and aspirations of the University more acting on the deinstitutionalization of
generally. Bonfire. The new goals of the institution as a
To summarize, during this period we can result of vision 2020 represented a disruption
clearly identify aspects of Bonfire that fit to the institution’s historical continuity. As a
onto its various antecedents and constructs in result of these proposed institutional changes
our extended framework of deinstitutional- there was increasing fragmentation within
ization. In terms of political pressures, we the institution. One way in which this frag-
see a reduction in the dependence on the mentation manifested itself was through the
institutional constituents that have encour- splitting of identities among stakeholders and
aged or enforced continuing procedural con- the conflicts that took place within the many
formity with their expectations. Over the layers of these nested identities (Ashforth &
years, the University started to depend more Johnson, 2001).
on different stakeholders. Initially, the focus From the simple analysis above, it is clear
was on the students and former students. that several of the antecedent pressures for
While there was a continuous focus on the the deinstitutionalization of Bonfire were
student body, the intensity of this focus already in play during this period previous to
began to diminish relative to the focus on the the time of the collapse. In addition to these
academic and research goals of the antecedent pressures, we find several entropy
University. Vision 2020 and other initiatives pressures that were also pushing for the dein-
clearly demonstrated the shift towards stitutionalization of Bonfire. These included
becoming a more research-intensive, world- groups opposed to Bonfire on the basis of the
class institution. Furthermore, there was a environmental damage associated with the
growth in the criticality of organizational cutting of the trees used in Bonfire, as well as
stakeholders whose beliefs may not have institutional concerns about safety associated
been consistent with the status quo as a result with the size and height of Bonfire.
of the shift from a local focus on students to Also affecting the deinstitutionalization of
more global focus on institutional impact. As Bonfire were inertial pressures associated
result of the buildup in these pressures, the with the long-standing institutional culture
legitimacy of institutionalized practices such that embodied a resistance to change and the
as Bonfire was being called into question. central role of traditions in maintaining the
With respect to functional pressures, culture.
Vision 2020 and its goal to make Texas A&M While all of these pressures were mount-
University a world-class research institution ing, it became more and more clear as to
brought about a change in the criteria for suc- what role the custodians of Bonfire had in
cess. The benefits of the new criteria, now counteracting the political, functional and
primarily dependent on outside constituents, social pressures as well as the entropy pres-
were neither fully understood nor widely sures. Through their reactions, the custodians
shared by the student constituency, who pre- were able to manage the entropy pressures
viously relied on more social criteria (i.e., and tip the balance in favor of the status quo.
342 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

When the Corps was the sole custodian of be a way to honor those who died (Tedesco,
Bonfire, these rituals and their associated 2000) while others noted that they would be
activities were carried out like a military willing to accept small changes as concessions
operation. As the nature of participants as long they could keep Bonfire.
evolved from the Corps of Cadets to incorpo- Some news stories pointed to the mysti-
rate of a greater number on non-Corps partic- cism of the accident and the students as
ipants, Bonfire took on a more casual and ‘fallen heroes’ who gave their lives for the
laissez-faire atmosphere. In fact, towards the tradition (Tang, 2000). The discourse turned
end of this period, while Bonfire continued to from tragedy to celebrating and memorializing
be an embodiment of the Aggie Spirit, the the dead.
processes and decision-making were more In the days following the Bonfire, the
like a party. This dilution of a core element of University distanced itself from the event by
Bonfire contributed to its eventual dissipa- claiming that Bonfire was a student-run
tion. Furthermore, the challenge faced by the event. However, under enormous pressures
University during this period was to find the University launched its own internal
ways to simultaneously continue the momen- investigation. Until this catastrophe the
tum towards strengthening its academic pro- University was ‘unable’ to publicly challenge
grams without compromising its traditions or penetrate the myth as well as the bound-
and school spirit (Jacobs, 2002: 200).The aries of the tradition. However, a catastrophe
presence of competing traditions served to invokes the need for action, sense-making
challenge the adherence to the tradition as and reflection.
well as the University’s resolve to consider The collapse was investigated by a Special
them as a defining feature of the University. Commission requested by the University. The
Special Commission on the 1999 Texas A&M
Bonfire concluded that the collapse was a
Period 4: erosion, the fall and function of a combination of physical and
organizational factors. The physical factors
beyond (1999–present)
included structural stress caused by problems
A tradition is in trouble: twelve Aggies are dead,
with log placement and inadequate contain-
the campus is still in mourning, and experts are ment and binding strength. However, the
questioning whether the Bonfire collapse was just Commission squarely put the blame for the
a freak accident. Now A&M officials must decide physical deficiencies upon the organizational
whether keeping an Aggie icon is worth the risks. factors that caused them. Cited as key organi-
(Burka, 2000: 117)
zational problems were the cultural bias, the
In the early morning hours of November absence of a plan, and the lack of proactive
18, 1999, the Bonfire stack collapsed with approaches towards the management of risk
approximately 70 students aboard – 12 Aggies (Special Commission on the 1999 Texas
died and 27 more were injured (Tang, 2000). A&M Bonfire Final Report, 2000).
As students and other members of the The University President at the time, Ray
University and local community struggled to Bowen, made a number of key decisions six
make sense of this event, the Bonfire tragedy weeks after receiving the final Commission
drew national attention. There was a strong report. First, he placed the Bonfire on hold for
call for action – How could this happen? Who two years. This led to several reactions and an
was to blame? Why was there no oversight? outcry from current and former students.
Several narratives began to emerge, ranging
Concerned that a hallowed tradition will turn into
from calling the tradition into question to pro-
a hollow gesture, a group of students is circulating
viding support for the tradition and its contin- a petition urging Texas A&M University administra-
uation. In fact, according to a student injured tors to reconsider the limitations placed on future
in the collapse, continuation of Bonfire would Aggie Bonfires. (Garcia, 2000)
TRADITIONS AS INSTITUTIONALIZED PRACTICE 343

Second, he set up a task force known as with an everlasting memorial flame and
Bonfire 2002 to assess the fate of Bonfire. Bonfire is still listed as a core tradition of the
Bowen claimed that future Bonfire was no University on its website. So, while several
longer the defining activity for the future of core and ancillary elements were removed
the University. the University successfully reinvented the
On March 5, 2001, the Committee for tradition.
Bonfire 2002 posted a document out- The remnants in terms of collective mem-
lining some myths and facts about the future ories drove the re-emergence of the tradition
and past of the Bonfire tradition (source: in a new place. The tradition migrated off
Bonfire 2002 Committee Homepage). The campus and former students became even
Committee proposed key changes that sub- more fervent custodians providing resources,
stantively altered the nature of any future land, and cash to support its re-emergence.
Bonfire held on the Texas A&M campus. Groups such as the ‘Bonfire Coalition’ and
Leadership positions were now to be selected ‘KTBF – Keep the Fire Burning’ emerged to
based on a process outlined by the recom- revive, protect and preserve the tradition. As
mendations of a Student Leadership and recently as 2004, Bonfire burned off-campus
Participation Task Force committee. Future and it was claimed that over 10,000 individ-
Bonfires, while student constructed would uals turned out to watch it burn (Nauman,
now have to be administered by and follow 2004). Thus, the tradition took on a life of its
plans prepared by licensed professional own and was no longer embedded in the con-
engineers. Previously, the Cut and Stack text or place in which it was once created.
phase lasted over two months. Now, the Our analysis of the previous period of
core ritual of Cut was eliminated from all Bonfire through the lens of the extended
future Bonfires with a recommendation that deinstitutionalization framework clearly sug-
logs would now be cut and delivered by a gests that several antecedent and direct pres-
professional firm. sures for dissipation existed prior to the fall.
Further, the construction core ritual of However, these pressures were being strate-
Stack was to be limited to a total of two gically kept in balance by the custodians
weeks. The site would now be fenced in and through various types of reactions that were
monitored by video cameras (Brown, 2000). aimed at preserving and further entrenching
Bonfire participants would now have to the tradition of Bonfire.
undergo training certification in preparation The events of 1999 were horrific, yet they
with any roles associated with planning and did not serve to distract the custodians (those
construction. Interestingly, one of the notions who worked on the stack) from their goal of
the Committee sought to dispel was the myth maintaining the tradition. Their reactions
that Bonfire as a tradition had remained were consistent with previous periods and
invariant over time. The Committee provided they fought hard to counterbalance the grow-
key facts about the extent to which there ing political, functional and social pressures
was variation in ancillary elements such as as well as the pressure for entropy. In
the structure and length of time involved in essence, their actions were aimed at main-
construction. taining the dominance of inertia over entropy
In 2002, Bowen announced that there that they managed over the previous years of
would no longer be a Bonfire burned on Bonfire. However, in this case, it was clear
the Texas A&M campus. In order not to that entropy gained the upper hand. As a
challenge the essence of Bonfire, the result of the crisis, the reactions of the
University proposed a new tradition, a University were able to overcome the
Bonfire Memorial and went to great lengths entropy. The University reacted in a number
to promote and develop this project of re- of ways. They disembedded and dismantled
invention. The fallen would now be honored the core elements of the tradition by no
344 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

longer allowing for Cut (the logs being and temporality. Table 12.1 also provides
delivered), and the Bonfire was now to be insights into the changing nature of the
supervised and monitored, eliminating organization in which the tradition was
opportunities for ‘groding’ and other forms embedded by summarizing the character of
of hazing. The University recommended a the organization, its key constituents, key
further dilution of custodianship in that they success factors, and strategic arenas.
would now run and largely control the tradi-
tion. In sum, the University’s decisions sig-
nificantly altered the value of the ‘inherited
resource’ for the custodians of the tradition FROM EROSION OF TRADITION
while not directly challenging the myth of TO UNDERSTANDING
Bonfire. Bonfire was now to be over- DEINSTITUTIONALIZATION
engineered, costly, over-monitored and unin-
teresting. It was now diluted to the point that As Shils notes, ‘there is a great need in the
it ceased to have value for its custodians. world for a better understanding of the
In 2002, when Bowen announced that nature of tradition and for a better apprecia-
Bonfire would no longer be held on campus, tion of its value’ (1981: vii). We examine the
he erased the core element of place for the potential contributions of the findings of our
rituals of Stack and Burn and this directly case study for the study of traditions and illu-
affected dissipation and erosion of the tradi- minate a number of insights for understand-
tion. The crisis allowed the University to ing deinstitutionalization. We do this through
penetrate the boundaries of the tradition. mapping case insights onto our extended
Bonfire was no longer needed to tell the new framework based on Oliver’s (1992) frame-
narrative about the University. This raises work for deinstitutionalization and propose
interesting future questions about the role of several extensions of her process model of
place and migration in the process of deinsti- deinstitutionalization.
tutionalization as well as the assimilation of Given Oliver’s framework, we can clearly
an older element into a newly re-invented tra- identify aspects of Bonfire that map onto
dition. Our observations regarding this its various antecedents and constructs. In
period also raise a number of questions terms of political pressures, we see a
regarding the interplay of challenges and reduction in the dependence on the institu-
mechanisms for dissipation. All at once, a tional constituents that have encouraged
number of mechanisms (assimilation, dilu- or enforced continuing procedural conform-
tion, disembedding, competition, and era- ity with their expectations. Over the years,
sure) were simultaneously in play, making it the University started to depend more on
increasingly difficult for the custodians to different stakeholders. Initially, the focus
counter forces for entropy impacting dissipa- was on the students and former students.
tion. Thus, the custodians could not deal with While there was a continuous focus
everything at once – if challenges or threats on the student body, the intensity of this
to core elements are sequenced or separated focus began to diminish relative to the
over time, then custodians have time to for- focus on the academic and research goals
mulate strategies to combat entropy. of the University. Vision 2020 and other
We summarize our discussion above in initiatives clearly demonstrated the shift
Table 12.1. towards becoming a more research-intensive,
Table 12.1 charts the evolution of Bonfire world-class institution. Furthermore, there
over the four periods described above and was a growth in the criticality of organiza-
provides a summary of changes over time. It tional stakeholders, whose beliefs may not
tracks the essence, custodians, rituals and have been consistent with the status quo
physical artifacts, as well as changes in place as a result of the shift from a local focus on
TRADITIONS AS INSTITUTIONALIZED PRACTICE 345

Table 12.1 The evolution of bonfire: 1909–present


Dimension 1909–42 1942–65 1965–99 Post-Fall
University focus Total Institution Inward Inward/Outward Outward
More academic Mainstream
Vision 2020
Culture and Military Focus Stronger military Sub-cultures present Old Culture is liability
core beliefs ‘Hazing’ common focus promoted Multiple identities New culture focused
differences exist on academics and
Emphasis on the Focus on academics becoming a top
‘Other’ and research public university
Education
Organization – Tightly coupled Tradition is the Last 20 years saw Tradition is: Questioned,
Tradition Link values Institution shift to somewhat unwanted
decoupling yet tightly coupled
Physical Trash and wood Logs (donated) Logs (fresh cut) Two year hold on campus
composition Stolen materials Tepee style design Layered cake design Flame on campus
Disorganized pile 45-100 ft 110 ft Off-campus:
design 20 ft Logs (fresh cut)
Layered cake design
Custodians Cadets Corps Shared custodianship: University
Commandant Cadets plus non- Former students
cadets Non-cadets
Cadets
Rituals Play Cut, Stack, Burn Cut, Stack, Burn Memorial service
Cut, Stack, Burn (Offsite)
Place On campus On campus On campus Off campus
Re-invented on campus
Time Before ‘big game’ Before ‘big game’ Before ‘big game’ Cancelled on campus
Once burned after Off-campus: Before
‘big game’
Arenas and State Politics Football rivalry Public funding Survival
contests Funding Enrollments Relative status
Key success Football Football Increasing enrollment World-class ranking
factors Traditions
Audience and State, Local Students, Local National, Public Global
constituents

students to a more global focus on institu- evaluating the success of the institution.
tional impact. As a result of the buildup in Consequently, the perceived utility of institu-
these pressures, the legitimacy of institution- tionalized practices such as Bonfire was
alized practices such as Bonfire was being slowly being subsumed by the perceived util-
called into question. ity of other practices more closely associated
With respect to functional pressures, with achieving the goal of becoming a world-
Vision 2020 and its goal to make Texas A&M class research institution.
University a world-class research institution There were also social pressures that
brought about a change in the criteria for were acting on the deinstitutionalization of
success. The benefits of the new criteria, now Bonfire. The new goals of the institution as a
primarily dependent on outside constituents, result of Vision 2020 represented a disruption
were neither fully understood nor widely to the continuity of the institution’s historical
shared by the student constituency who identity. As a result of these proposed institu-
previously relied on more social criteria tional changes and refocus on academic
(i.e., quality of student life, sacredness of excellence as a research institution, there
traditions such as Bonfire, etc.) as a basis for was increasing fragmentation among the
346 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

institution’s stakeholders. This fragmentation practices are invented in the beginning so


manifested itself through the splitting of that the reliance on any one of these practices
identities among stakeholders and the con- is minimal. Another strategy is one in which
flicts that took place within the many layers the institutionalized practice is disembedded
of institutional identity from either ancillary institutions that exist or
From the analysis above, several of the from other interconnected elements of the
antecedent pressures for the deinstitutional- organization. Buffering or decoupling refers
ization of Bonfire were already in play at the to the distancing of the organization and the
time of the collapse in addition to the pres- institutionalized practice either cognitively
ence of several pressures for entropy pushing or in its narratives by telling a different
for the deinstitutionalization of Bonfire. story about the meaning of the institutional-
These included groups opposed to Bonfire on ized practice. Distancing could also occur in
the basis of the environmental concerns as the sense of abdicating responsibility for the
well as institutional concerns about safety tradition.
associated with the size and height of Beyond our initial extensions to the dein-
Bonfire. stitutionalization framework based on our
Also affecting the deinstitutionalization of integration of several literature streams, our
Bonfire were pressures to maintain status analysis of the Texas A&M Aggie Bonfire
quo associated with a culture that resisted case suggests further important extensions.
change and nurtured the central role of tradi- First, the analysis leads us to believe that it is
tions in maintaining the culture. important to extend the framework to explic-
Our observations about Bonfire also help itly recognize the role of custodians of insti-
us to illustrate how the elements we intro- tutionalized practices. In our examples based
duced into the extended deinstitutionaliza- on Bonfire, we demonstrate that custodians
tion framework provide additional insight of institutionalized practices can serve as a
and allow us to capture other important critical counterforce to entropy. In essence,
dynamics that appear to be involved in custodians balance the pressures for entropy
deinstitutionalization. It was our belief, and sustain institutionalized practices. The
based on our integration of several streams of Corps of Cadets or ‘Keepers of the Spirit’
research, that whether deinstitutionalization (Adams, 2001) did much to take a tradition
represents dissipation or outright rejection is borne out of humble beginnings and make it
a function of whether the core or ancillary the center-piece of the traditions at the
elements of an institution are affected by sev- University. As the tradition faced detractors,
eral mechanisms. In this chapter, we have the Corps sought to protect the tradition and
described those mechanisms and used the guard against potential dissipation. They did
case of Bonfire to consider the multiple this by limiting access to and knowledge
mechanisms by which dissipation occurs. about the construction of Bonfire. The infor-
Focusing on the mechanism of competition mal hierarchy of Bonfire kept participation in
has allowed us to better understand the the core rituals small and elite while partici-
nature of institutional collisions as compet- pation in the performance aspects of the tra-
ing traditions lead to greater pressures to dition was much broader. The custodians also
demonstrate legitimacy as well as functional countered forces for entropy by providing
utility. innovative solutions to critics (such as the
These mechanisms or strategies include, response of ‘replant’ to environmental criti-
among others, dilution, disembedding, and cisms) versus going on strike as they did in
buffering or decoupling. By dilution, we Period 2 as well as calling on former custodi-
mean that the organization ensures there ans and other key constituents for support as
are new institutionalized practices added needed (former students, parents, members
into the mix or that multiple institutionalized of the University Administration).
TRADITIONS AS INSTITUTIONALIZED PRACTICE 347

Second, through our analysis of Bonfire, of institutional remnants. Mohr (2006) refers
we suggest that the framework should explic- to these ‘bits’ of institutions as institutional
itly recognize the role of crises which allow litter. Remnants can be useful for construct-
for permeability in the boundary and provide ing new traditions, re-inventing old traditions
for windows of opportunity to extinguish lia- (Hobsbawm & Ranger, 1984; Shils, 1981) or
bilities and overcome inertial tendencies. for the re-emergence of institutionalized
Until the fall of the stack in 1999, changes to practices experiencing dormancy (Mohr,
the core elements of Bonfire were always 2006; Tucker, 2006; Zerubavel, 1995).
resisted; critics were managed and when the Remnants can take the form of stories, phys-
numbers and power of the Corps began to ical objects, rituals, temporal connections or
decline in the third period, concessions were linkages to place as well as take the form of
made to share custodianship so as to keep the sentiments and memories. We propose that to
core rituals, collective memories and other the extent remnants of institutionalized prac-
core elements intact. tices remain in place, they are also able to
Third, from our Bonfire analysis, we also prevent extinction. Therefore, it is rare for us
believe that whether deinstitutionalization to observe the complete extinction or eradi-
represents dissipation or outright rejection is cation of deep-rooted traditions or institu-
a function of whether the core or ancillary tionalized practices.
elements of an institution are affected by sev- Finally, in this chapter, we demonstrate
eral strategies that directly impact dissipa- that traditions do not always arise as a result
tion. From our analysis we observe that core of institutionalization projects or purposeful
elements of a tradition also evolve over time action. Rather, they can emerge from humble
but, once in place, they tend to be more or beginnings or arise out of serendipity.
less stable and enduring than peripheral or However, we also demonstrate that the
ancillary elements. Consequently, this sug- processes of re-invention, re-incarnation or
gests that there are both ancillary and core re-emergence may potentially require the
elements that may experience dissipation as a focused attention of custodians or institu-
result of political, functional and social pres- tional entrepreneurs (current and/or future).
sures. While our case study does not allow us In summary, the key extensions to Oliver’s
to establish the relative effectiveness and out- (1992) framework introduced in this chapter
come of bringing political, functional and include the clarification of various reactions
social pressures to bear on the core and ancil- to the political, functional and social pres-
lary elements, it may be that the core are sures, the unpacking of dissipation, the mod-
more resistant to these pressures, requiring erating roles of custodians and crises on
crises as a way of breaking down the resist- entropy and inertia respectively, and the
ance, and that pressures on specific ancillary notion of institutional remnants. The
elements may lead to the erosion of those extended framework for deinstitutionaliza-
specific elements but may not erode, and tion appears in Figure 12.2.
in fact may serve to strengthen, the core
elements.
Fourth, the case of Bonfire clearly illus-
trates that a tradition or institutionalized DIRECTIONS FOR FUTURE RESEARCH
practice can be re-invented or reconstructed,
just as Bonfire migrated off-campus. So, it Oliver’s (1992) framework for deinstitution-
was re-invented in its original location in the alization brought clarification to an impor-
form of a memorial flame and re-incarnated tant concept that has entered the everyday
in a new location. parlance of the institutional theorist through
By unveiling and focusing on the process numerous journal articles, book chapters
of re-invention we highlight the importance and everyday discussions. However, as
348 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Entropy
Political Custodians
pressure

Dissipation or
Reactions rejection
Functional Correction
Assimilation Deinstitution- Erosion or
pressure Decoupling Competition alizaton extinction
Mobilization Dilution
Disembedding
Erasure Institutional remnants
Social Construction of New
Institution
pressure
Crisis Re-invention
Re-emergence
Inertia

Figure 12.2 An extended deinstitutionalization framework

we note, institutionalized practices are com- there are other mechanisms worthy of
monly slow to become extinguished. inquiry. Two mechanisms that might be
Elements of these practices also often con- investigated further in future research include
tinue in residual forms that serve as displacement and migration. Displacement
reminders of prior strategies and/or as raw occurs when exogenous forces such as
material for the construction of new ones. changes in technology or the emergence of
Through our integration of various theoreti- new knowledge or circumstances result in the
cal approaches, we believe our extended tradition being discarded or rejected (Shils,
framework explicates important aspects that 1981: 258). Migration, according to Shils
help us further understand the deinstitution- (1981), occurs when a tradition is transported
alization process in the context of a long- to a new context where it may have a new or
standing tradition. different meaning or become completely
We also believe that our extended frame- irrelevant. An example of this would be wine
work provides a basis for continuing the tasting in a culture where it is forbidden to
important discourse about deinstitutionaliza- consume alcohol. In this case, the adherence
tion that has emerged since Oliver’s seminal to the tradition and associated rituals of wine
work on the topic almost fifteen years ago. tasting would be largely determined by the
Continuation of this discourse is important receptivity of the recipients. DiMaggio
because many aspects of the deinstitutional- (1988) also discusses institutional migration
ization process have yet to be understood. and local modifications that result from vari-
Following, we present several areas for ation in interests and power.
research that emerge out of the work pre- In addition to investigating mechanisms
sented in this chapter. We encourage that promote dissipation, it would also
researchers to pursue any of these future be worthwhile to consider various mecha-
directions. nisms that serve to prevent dissipation and
One promising area for future research eventual deinstitutionalization. This would
would be to examine other key mechanisms provide further insights into the strategic
leading to dissipation. In this chapter we management of institutionalized practices.
focus on some of the key mechanisms In this chapter we only highlighted a
(assimilation, competition, dilution, disem- few such mechanisms that became apparent
bedding, and erasure) but it is likely that to us through our case study of Bonfire
TRADITIONS AS INSTITUTIONALIZED PRACTICE 349

but we encourage researchers to introduce constructing as well as eradicating institu-


other mechanisms of this type to the tionalized practices. In our case, the tradition
literature. of Bonfire took place in an intergenerational
Our analysis of Bonfire led us to identify a organization. By placing the Bonfire on hold
distinction between core and ancillary ele- for two years the University essentially pre-
ments (for example, rituals) of a tradition. vented the core elements of the tradition
While this distinction provided important from being experienced or shared by
insights related to the erosion of institution- Freshmen who entered the year of the Fall.
alized practices such as traditions, we believe Thus, these newcomers did not have shared
that further investigation into a related area experiences with which to create ‘communi-
for future research is one that focuses on the tas’ (Turner, 1969) or new collective memo-
dimensionality of institutions and the extent ries, yet the institutional remnants of Bonfire
to which erosion of one or more core ele- led to its re-emergence as an off-campus
ments results in variable intensity of erosion event. Future research could examine
in terms of both scope and potency. Issues to whether patterns of enhancement and erasure
examine when pursuing this research include are similar in other contexts. For example,
whether there are thresholds at which decline intergenerational organizations such as the
is more rapid or slow, and whether there are military or the field of consulting might also
specific patterns or configurations of core attempt to construct or eradicate institutional
and ancillary elements that once combined practices.
increase or decrease the propensity of With respect to core and ancillary ele-
decline. At a field level, DiMaggio distin- ments associated with a tradition, a fruitful
guishes between core and subsidiary institu- area for future research would be to investi-
tions and states ‘under many conditions, the gate the relative role of these elements in the
interests of these legitimated, partially deinstitutionalization process. We speculated
autonomous, subsidiary institutions diverge that core and ancillary elements differ in
from those of the governors of the core insti- their relative resistance to erosion but,
tutional form’ (1988: 16). Adopting this because we present only a single case study,
to our work, the issue becomes one of under- we could not further investigate this insight.
standing how taking over or controlling One way of pursuing this phenomenon
ancillary elements but not the core elements would be to consider whether there is a
allows one to launch delegitimating attacks hierarchy of core and ancillary elements.
on the core or demand changes in the For example, with respect to core elements,
core. We suggest that much more work needs one could examine whether there is a
to be done to fully understand the nature, hierarchy or ordering of core elements or
dynamics, and interaction of core and ancil- whether the core elements are themselves
lary elements. interconnected in some meaningful way such
The notion of an ‘institutional remnant’ that interactions among these elements serve
is an important one in the extended frame- to produce interactions, and crowd out or dis-
work. We argue that extinction is an ultimate place one another. Following this line of
yet relatively rare event in deinstitutionaliza- thought, interesting questions include:
tion and that the remnants of traditions whether one can remove one core element
often become instrumental in the construc- but still have the institutionalized practice
tion of new institutional practices or the survive; or the extent to which core elements
re-invention or re-emergence of what may would have to be removed to erode the
have been considered an eroded or extinct institution.
institutional practice. In this light, an area for Finally, while our focus in the current
future research would be to examine the chapter is on institutionalized practices, it
role of collective memories more fully in would also be important to understand how
350 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

institutions change. Institutional theorists 3 The remnants transmitted across generations


note the permanence or stability of institu- may be large enough so that no significant change in
the tradition is perceived by its adherents.
tions but it could be that our belief about
4 While we draw upon and further develop the
invariance is merely an illusion that is idea of custodians from Soares (1997), DeJordy and
socially constructed. In other words, do we Jones (2006) have recently used the term ‘institu-
make sense of institutional effects by fitting tional guardians’ in their work on the changing
them into the expectations of what we ‘want’ meaning of marriage.
5 In several passages, Shils (1981) uses the terms
to experience, or do we consider them invari-
traditions and institutions synonymously.
ant because once in place, both violations 6 The web page of the University provides great
and sanctions are rare, unobservable, or detail about the nature of Texas A&M University
inconsequential? These are questions that traditions.
need to be addressed by scholars interested in 7 In particular, we draw upon the rich and
thoughtful historical case study of Bonfire by
furthering their understanding of processes
journalist Irwin Tang, 2000.
of institutional emergence, change, and 8 In 1966, as an acknowledgement to the war in
extinction. Vietnam, thousands of gallons of Napalm were
poured on Bonfire to assist in its lighting.
9 Texas A&M had declining football performance
ACKNOWLEDGMENT for much of Period 2 and the early part of Period 3.

We acknowledge the support of the Social


Sciences and Humanities Research Council REFERENCES
of Canada. Special thanks to N. Anand, Terry
Beckman, Robert David, Jim Denford, Rudy Adams, J.A. 2001. Keepers of the Spirit: The
Durand, Renate Meyer, Willie Ocasio and Corps of Cadets at Texas A&M University,
Hayagreeva Rao for their helpful comments 1876–2001. College Station: Texas A&M
and encouragement in the developmental University Press.
Ahmadjian, C.L. and Robinson, P. 2001. Safety
stages of this work. Thanks also to workshop
in numbers: Downsizing and the deinstitu-
participants at the 3rd annual Davis
tionalization of permanent employment in
Conference for Qualitative Research, as well Japan. Administrative Science Quarterly,
as seminar participants at Bocconi, HEC, 46(4), 622–654.
Erasmus, Insead, Northwestern, London Andersen, B. 1991. Imagined Communities.
Business School, McGill, Queen’s and York New York: Verso.
Universities. Ashforth, B.E. and Johnson, S.A. 2001. Which
hat to wear? The relative salience of multiple
Figure 12.1 reprinted from C. Oliver, 1992 identities in organizational contexts. In M.
‘The antecedents of deinstitutionalization’, Hogg and D. Terry (eds.), Social Identity
Organization Studies, 13, 563–588, with Processes in Organizational Contexts. Hove,
UK: Psychology Press.
permission from the author and Sage.
Beyer, J. M. and Nino, D. 2000. Culture as a
source, expression, and reinforcer of emo-
tions in organizations. In R.L. Payne and C.L.
NOTES Cooper (eds.), Emotions at Work: Theory,
Research, and Applications in Management.
1 A remnant is a ‘small remaining quantity’ and/or New York: John Wiley.
a ‘surviving trace/vestige’ of something that once
Brown, K. 2000. Bonfire suspended until 2002.
existed (Oxford University Dictionary).
The Bryan-College Station Eagle.Online
2 Sapir (1949) makes a distinction between culture
that is genuine versus spurious. Spurious culture is Archive.
often devoid of meaning and is externally con- Dacin, M. 1997. Isomorphism in context: The
structed and controlled. On the other hand, genuine power and prescription of institutional
culture is internally generated, harmonious and norms. Academy of Management Journal,
authentic. 40(1), 46–81.
TRADITIONS AS INSTITUTIONALIZED PRACTICE 351

Davis, G.F., Diekman, K. & Tinsley, C. 1994. The Oliver, C. 1992. The antecedents of deinstitu-
decline and fall of the conglomerate firm in tionalization. Organization Studies, 13,
the 1980s: The deinstitutionalization of an 563–588.
organizational form. American Sociological Putnam, R.D. 2000. Bowling Alone: The
Review, 59(4), 547–570. Collapse and Revival of American Commu-
DeJordy, R. & Jones, C. 2006. The resiliency and nity. New York: Simon and Schuster.
evolution of Institutional Theory: Process, Sapir, E. 1949. Culture, genuine and spurious.
content, & boundary conditions. Presented In D. Mandelbaum (ed.), Selected Writings of
at the University of Alberta conference on Edward Sapir on Language, Culture and
The Future of Institutional Theory, Edmonton. Personality. Berkeley: University of California
Dethloff, H.C. 1976. A centennial history of Press (orig. publication 1924). American
Texas A&M University, 1876–1976. College Journal of Sociology.)
Station: Texas A&M University Press. Schneiberg, M. 2005. What’s on the path?
DiMaggio, P.J. 1988. Interest and agency in Organizational form and the problem of
institutional theory. In L.G. Zucker, (ed.), instititutional change in the US economy,
Institutional Patterns and Organizations, 1900–1950. Working paper, Reed College.
3–22. Cambridge, MA: Ballinger. Scott, R.W. 2001. Institutions and Organizations,
Garcia, R. 2000. Texas A&M students begin 2nd edn. Thousand Oaks: Sage Publications.
petition to alter Bonfire’s future. The Shils, E.C. 1981. Tradition. Chicago: The
Battalion, 10(11). University of Chicago Press.
Greve, H.R. 1995. Jumping ship: The diffusion Smith, J.M. 2004. The Texas Aggie Bonfire:
of strategy abandonment. Administrative Place, ritual, symbolism, and identity.
Science Quarterly, 40(September), 444–473. Working paper, Texas A & M University.
Hawlbachs, M. 1950. The Collective Memory, Soares, J.A. 1997. A reformulation of the con-
trans. F.J. Ditter, Jr. and V. Yazdi. New York: cept of tradition. International Journal of
Harper Sociology and Social Policy, 17(6), 6–21.
Hobsbawm, E. and Ranger, T. (eds.) 1984. Special Commission on the 1999 Texas A&M
The invention of tradition. Cambridge: Bonfire Final Report, 2000, Texas A&M
Cambridge University Press. University.
Jacobs, H. 2002. The Pride of Aggieland. Tang, I.A. 2000. The Texas Aggie Bonfire:
New York: NY: Silver Lining Books. Tradition and tragedy at Texas A&M. Austin:
Jepperson, R. L. 1991. Institutions, institutional It Works Press.
effects, and institutionalism. Pp. 143-63 in Tedesco, J. 2000 Aggies continue to back
W. W. Powell and P. J. DiMaggio (Eds.), The Bonfire. KENS 5 and San Antonio Express
New Institutionalism in Organizational Analy- News <http://www.mySA.com>.
sis, Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Thompson, J.D., & McEwen, W.J. (1958).
Kuhn, T.S. 1962. The Structure of Scientific Organizational goals and environment: Goal-
Revolutions. Chicago: University of Chicago setting as an interaction process. American
Press. Sociological Review, 23(1), 23–31.
Nauman, B. 2004. Bonfire burns despite rain, Tucker, S. 2006. Cyclical institutions: The case
muck at site. The Bryan-College Station of midwifery care in Ontario, 1800–2005.
Eagle.Online Archive. Working paper. Queen’s U.
Ocasio, W. and Kim, H. 1999. The Circulation Turner, V. 1969. The Ritual Process: Structure
of Corporate Control: Selection of Functional and Anti-Structure. Aldine Transaction.
Backgrounds of New CEOs in Large Zerubavel, Y. 1995. Recovered Roots: Collective
U.S. Manufacturing Firms, 1981–1992. Memory and the Making of Israeli National
Administrative Science Quarterly, 44(3), Tradition. Chicago: University of Chicago
532–563. Press.
13
New Forms as Settlements
Hayagreeva Rao and Martin Kenney

INTRODUCTION (DiMaggio, 1988: 18). In this perspective,


institutional projects can arise from organ-
A challenge facing neo-institutionalism is to ized politics or social movements, and in the
detail how pre-existing institutional condi- case of the former they resemble the latter to
tions and alternative institutional projects the extent that resources and interests are not
influence the creation of new organizational fixed and the rules governing interaction are
forms. We build on the idea that varying contested (Fligstein, 2001). A few studies
degrees of contention underlie the construc- have shown when and how new organiza-
tion of new forms, and suggest that a settle- tional forms and industries are spawned by
ment or truce has to occur among contending social movements and entail varying degrees
parties for the new organizational form to of contention (Davis and McAdam, 2000;
gain a foothold. We develop a model of how Rao, Morill and Zald, 2000; McAdam and
asymmetries of power among the contestants Scott, 2005).
and incompatibility among their proposals Recently, organizational ecologists have
shape the nature of the settlement, and its suggested that an organizational form is a
durability. We discuss when asymmetries of taken-for-granted category with default con-
power among contestants are high or low, ditions that define membership such that vio-
and when ideological compatibility among lation of these conditions is penalized by
the proposals is high or low, and present a audiences (Hannan, Pólos, and Carroll,
matrix of possible settlements. We illustrate 2007). Thus, an organizational form is an
the framework by drawing on examples and externally enforced identity composed of
discuss implications for institutional theory diagnostic elements and the expected (and
and organizational ecology. thus, rewarded) values on these elements
The institutional perspective proposes that (Pólos, Hannan, and Carroll, 2002). These
new organizational forms arise when actors diagnostic elements cohere to form a code of
with sufficient resources see in them an conduct which is enforced by consumers,
opportunity to realize interests that they critics and other audiences.
value highly, but first they must legitimate So a challenge is to reconcile the political
the theory and values underpinning the form process by which organizational forms are
NEW FORMS AS SETTLEMENTS 353

constructed with their existence as socially of a code. We illustrate our classificatory


coded identities. Put another way, how endeavor with four distinct cases that illumi-
does conflict and contestation culminate nate the four alternative settlements repre-
in a code? Therein, lies the motivation for sented by our framework.
our chapter. We propose that forms have to
be first constituted as settlements – that is
agreements have to be negotiated among par-
ties before new forms can be institutionalized NEW FORMS AS SETTLEMENTS
as codes. A settlement is a set of understand-
ings and expectations about a form that are Stinchcombe (1968: 194) asserts that the entre-
shared among internal and external audi- preneurial creation of new forms ‘is pre-
ences. Settlements become codes only when eminently a political phenomenon’ because
these understandings and expectations support has to be mobilized for the goals,
become default conditions of membership, authority structure, technology, and clients
and are enforced by external and internal embodied in the new form. In some cases,
audiences. resource spaces unoccupied by other forms
We visualize a process wherein coalitions may exist, or, at least, have the potential to be
of institutional entrepreneurs champion created, but the existence of such unfilled
proposals, that is intended projects that resource spaces does not mean that the
concretize the strategic intent, vision, and resources are ‘free floating’ and thus easily
goals of the promoters. When different available to potential entrepreneurs. Rather,
coalitions promote competing proposals, the entrepreneurs have to assemble resources,
construction of a settlement becomes a legitimate the new form, and integrate it with
political process in which asymmetries in the prevalent institutional order. In other
the power of the various coalitions become cases, resource spaces for a new form may
critical. In particular, the size of the coalition, not exist, and entrepreneurs have to construct
its ability to mobilize additional resources, these spaces by defining opportunity, identi-
and its power to frame become decisive. fying distinctive resources, and prying them
We develop a model of how asymmetries away from existing uses. Since entrepreneurs
of power among the contestants and incom- are trying to convince others to go along with
patibility among their proposals shape their view, the formation of new industries
the nature of the settlement, and argue and forms resembles social movements
that settlements become institutionalized (Fligstein, 2001).
into codes of conduct with varying levels of Social movement theorists propose that
durability and enforceability. We discuss institutional entrepreneurs can mobilize
when asymmetries of power among contest- legitimacy, finances, and personnel through
ants are high or low, and when ideological the use of frames (McAdam, McCarthy, and
compatibility among the proposals is high Zald, 1996). Frames define the grievances
or low, and present a matrix of possible and interests of aggrieved constituencies,
settlements. diagnose causes, assign blame, provide solu-
We suggest that settlements have diffe- tions, and enable collective attribution
rent levels of durability and enforceability processes to operate (Snow and Benford,
as these two parameters vary. New forms 1992: 150). Thus, frames are theories that jus-
do not move from conflict to settlement to tify an organizational form – an incarnation
code in two distinct leaps – instead, the of goals, authority, technology, and clients,
process is more incremental and gradual. as indispensable, valid, and appropriate. In
In this sense, conflict and code are two ‘much the same way that pictures are framed,
ends of a continuum with the settlement as questions and actions are framed, and the con-
an intervening precondition for the emergence text in which they are viewed and discussed
354 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

determines what gets done º Setting the independent businessperson and intrepid
context is a critical strategy for exercising entrepreneurs clash with the ideology of
power and influence’ (Pfeffer, 1992: 202). In governmental non-interference in the mar-
our case the framers are constructing a vision ketplace. In yet another of our cases, the
of the future. contradictory French cultural values devolv-
Institutional entrepreneurs create frames by ing around tradition and progress provide
selecting items from a pre-existing cul- the fuel for contestation in the world of
tural menu (Meyer and Rowan, 1977: 345; gastronomy. Rather than a clash of tectonic
DiMaggio and Powell, 1983). Swidler (1986: plates, we have long-running skirmishes
277) suggests that a culture is not a ‘unified where the frames presented suffer from
system that pushes action in a consistent inconsistencies and difficulties. Which frame
direction. Rather it is more of a “tool kit” and its organizational embodiment should
or a repertoire from which actors select be chosen to define and organize an activity
differing pieces for constructing lines of is a political question. Friedland and Alford
action.’ Douglas (1986) points out that (1991: 240–242), capturing the swirling
bricolage is an important method by which nature of this creative process, propose
entrepreneurs construct new cognitive models that the creation of new organizational
and formal structures. Thus, entrepreneurs forms unfolds at three levels of analysis,
can recombine elements from existing with ‘individuals competing and negotia-
repertoires through imitation, or consciously ting, organizations in conflict and coordina-
revise existing models on the basis of tion, and institutions in contradiction and
their training in other organizations. An under- interdependency º’ We conceive of these
current of these studies is that there are a levels of analysis as ‘nested,’ where organiza-
number of alternative institutional projects tion and institution specify higher levels of
that are proposed in a given situation and constraint and opportunity for individual
projects win out by a political process action.
and constitute an institutional settlement When multiple frames and forms vie
(DiMaggio, 1991). with each other, why one form is chosen and
why other roads are not pursued hinges on
larger constellations of power and social
structure (Brint and Karabel, 1991: 346). In
MULTIPLE FRAMES AND CONFLICT: cases where the criteria for a good technical
THE INSTITUTIONAL VIEW solution are contested, political and institu-
tional processes shape not only what organi-
Politics becomes obtrusive when an unfilled zations can do, but which organizational
resource space ‘calls forth and permits a form can exist (Powell, 1991: 186–187).
range of definitions of the situation’ (Zald Thus, the scope of the form, that is the goals,
and McCarthy, 1980: 6), and when rival authority structure, technology and clients
coalitions of issue entrepreneurs champion embodied in the form, are outcomes of
incompatible frames. Even as entrepreneurs contending attempts at control and compet-
may draw on a generalized Western cultural ing quests to impose a preferred definition
account (Meyer, Boli, and Thomas, 1987) of the identity of the constituencies that
and justify their actions on the basis of the benefit from the form. Struggles to produce
widely-accepted myths of progress and jus- new meanings and new social structures
tice, there is a wide scope for conflict over are, therefore, motors of social change in
the practical implications of the Western cul- societies and these tussles unfold in an orga-
tural account in the construction of new nizational field where the state and the pro-
organizational forms. In one of our four fessions play an important role (DiMaggio
cases, fundamental ‘American’ values of the and Powell, 1983).
NEW FORMS AS SETTLEMENTS 355

Organizational forms as codes: and nouvelle cuisine weakened as high-status


chefs in one category borrowed techniques
the ecological view
from the rival category, and that attendant
As noted earlier, organizational ecologists penalties from critics also diminished as
define an organizational form as an exter- borrowing became rampant.
nally enforced identity composed of diagnos-
tic elements and the expected (and thus
rewarded) values on these elements (Pólos, The architecture of settlements
Hannan, and Carroll, 2002; Hannan, Pólos,
and Carroll, 2007). Two features of this defi- Thus, if institutional researchers place
nition are noteworthy. First, by requiring importance on conflict as antecedent to the
organizational forms to be collective identi- construction of organizational forms, and
ties in the eyes of audience members, it lets organizational ecologists stress consensus
the organizational form be defined in society which takes on a code-like character as the
independently of any specific instance of it. precondition for organizational forms, how
Second, audience members examine only can these seemingly opposed viewpoints of
diagnostic elements, and ignore cultural ele- institutionalists and ecologists be reconciled?
ments that are common across organizational We take a first step and suggest that institu-
forms and so do not identify them as distinct tionalists and organizational ecologists focus
categories. Hence the existence of common on different sub-processes in the creation of
organizational elements such as shared insti- organizational forms: the early sub-process
tutions does not disprove form distinctive- of conflict is followed by the second sub-
ness, it just means that distinctiveness has to process, namely, the construction of settle-
be found elsewhere. ments, and then the final phase of
The ecological view of organizational codification.
forms as identities that need to conform to In short, we propose that organizational
social codes not only emphasizes distinctive- forms first have to be constructed as settle-
ness but also highlights consistency. Some ments, and then institutionalized as codes.
studies contend that organizations which New organizational forms do not move from
seek to straddle multiple categories suffer conflict to settlement to code in two giant
from inconsistent identities and code con- leaps – instead, the process is gradual and
flicts. Carroll and Swaminathan (2000) incremental. One also ought not to think of
showed that since craft brewers were deemed institutionalization as an on-off mechanism;
to be authentic when they were small and instead, it makes more sense to think of new
used traditional artisanal techniques, contract forms as being institutionalized, and existing
breweries that sourced beer from others but forms also being de-institutionalized (Oliver,
sought to portray themselves as craft beers 1992). So institutionalization advances and
could not mobilize support from consumers, recedes, and increases and decreases over
and so had lower founding rates than micro- time. Conflict triggers the de-institutionaliza-
brewers and brewpubs. Zuckerman and Kim tion of existing forms and is precursor to insti-
(2003) demonstrated that films classified as tutionalization of new organizational forms.
major films fared well in the mainstream The institutionalization of organizational
market but floundered in the art-house forms is not an all-or-nothing proposition;
market, and Zuckerman, Kim, Ukanwa, and instead, organizational forms, like other social
von Rittman (2003) showed that movie patterns, can be more or less institutionalized
actors who focused on a single genre were (Tolbert and Zucker, 1996; Zucker, 1988).
more likely to get work in the same genre. Our starting point is Nelson and Winter’s
However, Rao, Monin and Durand (2005) (1982: 109–111) proposal that intra-
found that the boundaries between classical organizational routines become operative
356 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

only when there is a comprehensive truce or the monitoring defensive alertness of parties
settlement, or when there is a cessation of keen on preserving the status quo. As a result,
conflict among members of an organization. just like intra-organizational routines, organi-
Following Rao (1998), we contend that zational forms are ‘confined to extremely
boundaries of a new organizational form narrow channels by the dikes of vested inter-
become established and the new form est. Adaptations that appear “obvious” and
becomes integrated into a community of “easy” to an external observer may be fore-
organizations only when there is a truce closed because they involve a perceived threat
among the constituents of the organizational to the º political equilibrium’ (Nelson and
field about which frame is used to organize Winter, 1982: 111). These dikes are the con-
activities. Like settlements among nations, struction, conscious and, sometimes, uncon-
settlements among rival institutional entre- scious of the beneficiaries of the settlement.
preneurs can also be unequal, with some able The proposals championed by contestants
to capture a privileged position for their can be thought of as Simonian sub-assem-
frame, which allows them a larger share of blies that vary in terms of their ideological
any benefits derived from the settlement. compatibility. The relationships among con-
Settlements increase the capacity for col- testants may be asymmetric if one or a few
lective action by reducing comprehensiveness; of them has greater power due to their size,
often some points of view are ignored or sup- their ability to mobilize resources from
pressed. The terms of a settlement among rival constituencies and allies, and framing skills.
institutional entrepreneurs can never be com- Below, we outline the matrix of possibilities
pletely explicit, thus the maintenance of settle- and concomitant examples in Table 13.1.
ments depends upon the disincentives for Table 13.1 suggests that when all the par-
actors for engaging in provocative actions and ties interested in solving a problem champion

Table 13. 1: Settlement Types and Codification


Ideological Compatibility of Proposals

Low High

Quadrant One Quadrant Two


“Something for Everyone” “Patchwork of Different Flavors”
Low Example: Small Business Example: French cuisine
Investment Corporations Prognosis: Evolving, uneven
Prognosis: Brittle, low codification
likelihood of evolving

Asymmetry
of Power

Quadrant Three Quadrant Four


“Imposition by Dominant “Integration”
Actor” Example: California thrifts
Example: Consumer Prognosis: Extremely durable,
High watchdog groups
Prognosis: Durable as long as high likelihood of codification
dominant form backers retain
power, medium likelihood of
codification
NEW FORMS AS SETTLEMENTS 357

incompatible proposals and none of them is what was a patchwork in Cell 2 can transit
powerful enough, the resulting settlement is a into Cell 4 and vice-versa. Our goal is not to
negotiated outcome that is fragile and likely propose an irreversible stage model, but
to be breached (Cell 1). Indeed, one can even instead to think of settlement activity and, by
think of the settlement being de-institutional- implication, codification as advancing and
ized. A compelling example was the creation receding processes rather than binary, on-off
of small business industry corporations mechanisms.
(SBICs) in America. By contrast, when the The remainder of the chapter is devoted to
parties champion compatible proposals and giving an illustration of each of the four cells,
none of them is decisively powerful, then the and then discussing the framework. Below,
resulting settlement may be characterized as we outline how the construction of the SBIC
the pooling of these sub-assemblies (Cell 2). form was an example of a fragile settlement
The resulting patchwork of a settlement is that eventually dissolved because of the lack
also fragile because parties may be jostling to of power the contestants had over each other
appropriate benefits at the expense of other and the incompatibility of the goals that were
parties. Here again, settlements can be de- coalesced into the SBIC form.
institutionalized. We draw on Rao, Monin
and Durand (2003, 2005) to chronicle how
classical and nouvelle cuisine, which were QUADRANT 1: SOMETHING FOR
initially opposed to each other became com- EVERYONE: THE CASE OF SBICS
patible, and given that no one coalition was
dominant, chefs began to blend classical and The undeniable pain experienced by small
nouvelle cuisine. In Cell 3, the settlement is businesses during the Great Depression in
the outcome of imposition because there is conjunction with serious concerns about
asymmetric distribution of power, and one of the changing nature of the U.S. political
the parties can impose their proposal on the economy made the problem of how to pro-
others. We lean on Rao (1998) to analyze vide capital to small business into an impor-
how Consumers Union sought to promote the tant political issue. In the firmament of
model of non-profit watchdogs as radical American ideological heroes the ‘small
critics that evaluated products and the work- businessperson’ evokes images of Jefferson,
ing conditions that they were made under, Tocqueville, and Horatio Alger. Helping
and how it was hammered into place by small business was an ideal ideological
Consumer’s Research and its supporters, weapon for Democrats supporting govern-
who promoted the idea of a watchdog as an ment intervention in the economy. They
impartial critic rather than as a radical advo- could propose legislation to support small
cate. Finally, in Cell 4, integration is the business, thereby posing dilemmas for con-
likely outcome since the proposals are com- servative Republicans opposed to govern-
patible, and even if one party has decisive ment economic intervention.
power, there is little cause for ideological dis- Federal support for small business is not a
agreement. We draw on Haveman and Rao simple case of an interest group appealing to
(1997) and Haveman, Rao and Parachuri politicians for relief, because small busi-
(2007) to discuss how alternative proposals nesses were not organized into a coherent
about how to organize thrifts were blended social group with a distinct identity, and
into a hybrid form – the Dayton/Guarantee therefore were never directly represented
stock plan during pre-Depression America (Kilgore, 1938; Ziegler, 1961). Conservative
due to the influence of the Progressive Republicans reflexively opposed govern-
movement. mental assistance to small business.
It is important to note that these cells are Ideologically, they were strong supporters
not absorbing states. In principle, settlements of ‘free enterprise,’ so they were constantly
can move across quadrants; so, for instance, exposed to the uncomfortable political
358 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

question of opposing an icon of free enter- who believed that the small businesses
prise: small business. worthy of support were those capable of
The four key actors in the discussion growing to be large corporations. The prob-
about providing financial assistance to small lem was a shortage of venture capital (Liles,
business were: two industry groups, commer- 1977). Given this shortage, they reluctantly
cial bankers and investment bankers, and favored government programs to subsidize
two socio-political groups that we term investors, but they fervently believed that
the populists and the Schumpeterians. From these investments would be profitable.
the political settlement between these They envisioned small technology-based
four groups would come a nominally firms forming the seeds for industries
single organizational form, the SBIC, that in capable of creating the jobs of the future. For
actuality consisted of three related but them, the new Horatio Alger would be the
different manifestations. Each actor under- technically trained entrepreneur. The investor
stood the problem differently, even to the would be a specialized funder of new firms,
point of defining the small businesses worthy the venture capitalist.
of financial support differently and therefore During and immediately after World War
the favored mechanism for delivering sup- Two, a number of plans for providing finan-
port differed. An additional actor, the inde- cial support to small business were floated.
pendent venture capital firm, emerged There was also private sector experimenta-
immediately after World War Two, was out- tion in providing capital to small business. In
side the initial settlement, but was a factor in 1946, the first venture capital firm, American
the settlement’s eventual collapse. Research and Development (ARD) was
Each group had different interests and goals formed in Boston as a closed-end investment
to further, and championed different propos- fund and raised capital through a public
als. The commercial banks wanted to prevent stock offering (Hsu and Kenney, 2005).
the government or government-funded entities Simultaneously, three venture capital firms
from competing with them to provide short- funded by wealthy New York families were
term loans to businesses. They also coveted formed. Also, some banks established units
the right to own equity in industrial corpora- to provide loans to small businesses, though
tions and undertake the investment banking they quickly retreated. The four small ven-
functions that they had lost with the passage of ture capital firms continued to operate, and
the New Deal Glass-Steagall Act. The invest- received much publicity, but had little overall
ment bankers wanted to ensure that businesses impact on small business or new firm
raised capital through them and to loosen SEC formation.
regulations on stock market listing. Their The Republicans gained control of both
main goal was to prevent the government from Congress and the White House in 1953 and
providing capital in such a way as to circum- abolished the Depression Era Reconstruction
vent the need to list on public markets. The Finance Corporation (RFC), which had been
populists were strongly represented in a favorite of Democratic legislators, and had
Congress, though, as a group, they were not a mandate to fund small firms, among its
monolithic. Their goals were conceptually many other duties (Bean, 1996; Ziegler,
clear, i.e. provide government support for 1961). To secure sufficient support for the
small business, while their policy prescrip- RFC closure and protect themselves from
tions were diverse and disconnected. They the political attack, the Small Business
could act forcefully: For example, in the Administration (SBA) was created. To
1930s they mandated that the Reconstruction counter populist criticism of the SBA’s per-
Finance Corporation provide loans to small formance, the Administration commissioned
business, which it did grudgingly. studies by the Hoover Commission in 1955
The Schumpeterians consisted of elite and by the Council of Economic Advisors in
East Coast businesspersons and educators 1957, both of which found no significant
NEW FORMS AS SETTLEMENTS 359

capital shortages for small business. Despite three organizational forms and financial sup-
these study results, the populists were able to port for an already existing form. There was
frame an issue to the public, i.e. a lack of fund- a bank-based SBIC, an SBIC that raised cap-
ing for small business requiring a solution. ital on public markets and operated as a
The populists in Congress continued to closed-end fund, a privately owned SBIC that
pressure the Administration. In 1957 the received low-interest federal matching loans,
House Small Business Committee requested and existing industrial development corpora-
that the Federal Reserve, which was tions could receive federal monies. The legis-
sympathetic to their position, conduct a study lation was an amalgam of proposals with
of the credit needs of small business. In April little direction and ambiguous goals. Was it
1958, the Federal Reserve Board study sug- meant to provide loans to existing firms or
gested that funds were needed for financing support startups? Would it be a venture capi-
new firms and the expansion of existing tal program as the Schumpeterians hoped or
firms. This is a subtle shift, whereas the a more general support program? There were
populists wanted loans for small businesses, no guidelines, restrictions on the investment
the report supported the Schumpeterians. fields, or the requirements in terms of the
The political situation also changed. The skills, capabilities, or rectitude of the license
economy was sinking into recession, and applicants. In effect, any group of investors
with midterm elections approaching the with $150,000 or more was able to borrow
Republican majority was concerned, so the low-cost, guaranteed Federal funds.
Administration decided to support legisla- Though sanctioned by Congress, the
tion. A final settlement to the long debate SBICs had to construct legitimacy. With the
was at hand. vague enabling legislation, the organizational
forms would be defined in practice. As cre-
ations of Congress, only four months after
Something for everyone
the SBIC Act was signed into law an indus-
Six Senate bills were introduced to assist try association, the National Association of
small businesses in obtaining financing. The SBICs (NASBIC) was formed. Fortunately,
ABA, which had opposed the formation of there was a bull stock market from 1959
the SBA, favored using existing state and through early 1962, and investors were
local development corporations as the fund- receptive to the initial public stock offerings
ing vehicles for small businesses. The of the public SBICs. In July 1960, The
commercial banks wanted a waiver from New York Times described the situation
the Glass-Steagall Act so that they could aptly: ‘Wall Street, seldom swift to bestow its
invest in firms. The Investment Bankers affections, has found a new darling – the
Association did not take an official position, small business investment company (Kraus,
but Edward T. McCormick, President of the 1960: 1). There was a wave of new SBICs
American Stock Exchange, testified that he attracted by the promise of easy capital
supported publicly-listed, closed-end invest- gains. Legitimacy appeared to be guaranteed.
ment trusts to provide venture capital. The The positive appraisal of the SBICs’ quest
four existing venture capital firms did not for legitimacy changed in 1962, as a stock
testify, but the Schumpeterians, as repre- market downturn surprised the public SBICs.
sented by the Committee for Economic Unfortunately, as closed-end funds, investor
Development, supported the bill (Anglund, disenchantment led to their valuations being
2000: 64). On August 21, 1958 the Small so depressed that they attracted corporate
Business Investment Act was ratified. raiders. The result was that they were either
None of the contestants had a decisive acquired and liquidated or their managers
edge over the others in terms of size, ability turned in their SBIC licenses. The bank-
to mobilize or to frame. So all the protago- affiliated SBICs, though professionally run,
nists received their wishes. The Act authorized also were troubled. Many banks owning the
360 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

SBICs were disappointed because their bank small business. In a 1967 report they con-
connections did not provide many good cluded that the SBIC Program was replete
investment opportunties. The SBICs were with incompetence and even criminality and
difficult to administer because the skills suggested measures that, were they enacted,
necessary for finding and making a good would have ended the Program.
loan differed sharply from finding and devel- The malfeasance, the resultant increased
oping a good investment (Hayes and Woods, federal regulatory oversight, criticism by
1963: 19). Many of the bank SBICs became venture capitalists outside the Program, and
inactive. continuing experimentation with other orga-
The private SBICs were most numerous. nizational forms for venture capital investing
And yet, they were plagued by inadequate threatened to destabilize the settlement.
capital, inexperienced management, and a NASBIC was aware of the schism emerging
lack of connections necessary for a high- between its members who were loan-oriented
quality deal flow. They invested in a wide and those that were venture capitalists. The
number of areas including real estate, distri- growing importance of the external venture
bution, wholesale grocery operations, and capitalists prompted NASBIC to open dis-
many others. By 1963 it was apparent that cussions regarding representing them in
the Program had attracted unscrupulous indi- Washington. This initiative met with little
viduals. Investigations found that ‘nine out of success, as the venture capitalists decided to
ten SBICs had violated agency regulations create their own organization. The fragile
and dozens of companies had committed settlement was now ready to collapse.
criminal acts,’ thereby threatening the pro- In the early 1970s, even while the SBIC
gram’s legitimacy (Bean, 2000). In 1964, the Program continued to operate, a new organi-
SBA instituted a 90-day hiatus on issuing zational form, the private limited partnership,
new licenses as it decided to reorient the pro- which was first used for a venture capital
gram to stress ‘venture capital investing as organization in 1958, became the dominant
opposed to real estate and secured lending’ organizational form for the external venture
(SBIC Evaluation Service 1964: 1). capitalists. In April 1973 the National
In 1966, Congress gave the SBA enforce- Venture Capital Association (NVCA) was
ment authority to investigate conflicts of launched. In their membership solicitation
interest; to fix legal responsibility on the offi- letter they stated that members must be ven-
cers, directors, and agents of unlawfully ture capitalists ‘investing private capital in
operated SBICs; and to levy stiff penalties young companies on a professional basis
and fines. The effort to end fraud made the (SBIC/Venture Capital (1973: 3).’ The criti-
SBIC Program increasingly bureaucratic and cal proviso was that members must invest
constraining. The proliferating regulations private capital. The bank and publicly-owned
and reporting requirements prompted the SBICs not using Federal monies could join,
most successful SBIC operators, the ones while the private SBICs were unwelcome.
practicing venture capital, to consider leav- The venture capitalists operating SBICs
ing the Program (SBIC Evaluation Service, abandoned their SBICs, formed limited part-
1966: 5). nerships, left NASBIC, and joined the newly
In 1964, the Small Business and Venture formed NVCA. The formation of the NVCA
Capital Associates (SBVCA) was formed marked the end of the settlement achieved by
with a board of directors representing the the 1958 SBIC Act. The banks were the sole
Schumpeterian elite of the East Coast finan- remaining significant venture capitalists for
cial and private venture capital world. The whom the SBIC Program was significant
SBVCA operated a center affiliated with the because they continued to be blocked by
Committee for Economic Development to the Glass-Steagall Act from freely investing
study the role of venture capital in funding in firms.
NEW FORMS AS SETTLEMENTS 361

The NVCA proved to be a stable settle- French Revolution, chefs who once worked
ment, as it was organized to represent private in the houses of private patrons offered their
venture capitalists organized into the limited services to the public by establishing restau-
partnership, which was the result of a bout of rants in Paris and its environs (Ferguson,
organizational mimesis and soon jelled into 1998). Chefs and culinary journalists sought
the dominant organizational form for venture to systematize the principles of cooking in
capital investing. The SBIC Program and restaurants, and the most influential was
NASBIC continued representing the remain- Antonin Caréme (1784–1833). Stressing del-
ing private SBICs and the bank SBICs, both icacy, order, and economy, Caréme brought
of which were no longer significant players symmetry to the service of meals, and intro-
in the venture capital market, and the public duced a new awareness of freshness and san-
SBICs disappeared completely. itation into the French kitchen. Caréme’s
ideas quickly diffused throughout the
kitchens of French restaurants (Ferguson,
QUADRANT 2: A PATCHWORK: 1998) and were strengthened by a new breed
DIFFERENT FLAVORS; FRENCH of chefs such as George Auguste Escoffier
GASTRONOMY (1847–1935) and his circle of collaborators.
In his Guide Culinaire (1903) that remains a
Below, we outline how French gastronomy central text in the training of professional
featured two opposing categories – classical cooks even to the present day, Escoffier con-
and nouvelle cuisine, each of which had an ceived of classical cuisine as codified gram-
identifiable code of conduct and elements. mar of culinary practice: a product can be
Subsequently, we elaborate how the borrow- cooked in different ways, served with differ-
ing of techniques and ingredients breached ent sauces and accompanied with different
the boundaries of both categories, and cre- fillings. Escoffier’s guide was issued in sev-
ated a patchwork. In doing so, we heavily eral editions, and remained as the dominant
lean on Rao, Monin, and Durand (2003, orthodoxy until it was undermined by the
2005). The parties to the initial conflict and nouvelle cuisine movement.
subsequent settlement were chefs belonging In 1970 a group of young French chefs, led
to the society of French chefs (Maitres by Paul Bocuse, Michel Guérard, the
Cuisiniers de France). Ratings agencies such Troisgros brothers, and Alain Chapel,
as the Guide Michelin and Gault Millau also invented a free-form style of cooking.
played a part, as did crusading journalists. Culinary journalists such as Christain Gault
The setting was the haute cuisine restaurants and Henri Millau christened their style as
serving affluent customers. Since the differ- nouvelle cuisine, codified it, and postulated
ences between classical and nouvelle cuisine the Ten Commandments of nouvelle cuisine,
existed more in the press than the kitchen, and launched a culinary guide called Gault-
both proposals were compatible. Moreover, Millau. Gault, Millau and other culinary
neither classical nor nouvelle had a decisive journalists were theorists who depicted nou-
political edge, so the outcome was a patch- velle cuisine as a challenge to the codifica-
work of many flavors. tion of Escoffier and as an anti-school
The origins of classical cuisine are trace- valuing experimentation, autonomy, and
able to the French Revolution of 1789, which innovation. Chefs at the vanguard of the nou-
undermined the institutional logic of the velle cuisine movement, such as Bocuse,
ancien regime cuisine and the associated Troisgros, and Chapel, aimed for simplicity
identity of the chef. In the ancien regime, and transparency of presentation. Nouvelle
meals were public spectacles organized cuisine wanted the chefs to have a role in cre-
according to hierarchy, and the chef was the ating and inventing dishes rather than simply
property of a patron or noble. But, after the understanding the intentions of Escoffier.
362 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

In classical cuisine, the culinary rhet- dishes on the menu as signature dishes –
oric reveals the emphasis on conservatism which telegraphed their identity, and had to
and preservation. Often, dishes have the be served regularly to ordinary customers.
names of places, noblemen, or mythological Signature dishes enabled external actors such
characters associated with dishes. Neirinck as the Guide Michelin to classify chefs into a
and Poulain (1988) studied Caréme’s texts category, but that did not mean that all chefs
and found that nearly 213 dishes had names assigned to a category equally conformed to
associated with noblemen. Moreover, cook- the norms, rules, and dictates of the category.
ing consisted of the application of two Some chefs faithfully adhered to the
specific rules and associated techniques: norms of the category by using the cooking
conformation to the rules formulated by techniques and ingredients associated with
Caréme and Escoffier, and sublimation of the the category. Consider a chef whose signa-
ingredients such that the raw material is visu- tures are all in one category and who does
ally transformed. Fischler (1993: 238) sum- not blend cooking techniques and, instead,
marized it as follows: ‘The art of the cook only uses techniques affiliated with his or her
consisted in accommodating, in transform- chosen category. Jean-Paul Lacombe, of
ing, in metamorphosing the raw material, to Léon de Lyon, a two-star restaurant in Lyon,
put it from Nature to Culture.’ exemplifies the canons of classical cuisine
By contrast, the culinary rhetoric of nou- with three signature dishes such as crayfish
velle cuisine emphasized innovation, and the mousse (mousse de brochet), panned tripe
appellations dished referred to poetry and (Gras double sauté ), and chicken cooked
imagination rather than place names or the with red wine, ‘the ancient way’ (Coq au vin
names of nobles (Weiss, 2001: 233–234). rouge à l’ancienne), offered in 1981. These
Nouvelle cuisine relied on the rules of signature dishes pay homage to the middle-
transgression and acclimatization (Fischler, class kitchens of Lyon during the 19th cen-
1993). Transgression consisted of using tury and refer to classical cuisine ingredients:
unconventional techniques; dishes mixing crayfish and tripe. However, all of them use
meat and fish, salads mixing vegetables and classical cuisine techniques of cooking: pan-
foie gras, or pot au feu featuring fish. ning, mousse, and stewing meat in wine. The
Acclimatization was the import of exotic chef, Jean-Paul Lacombe, defines himself as
foreign cuisine techniques and ingredients, an embodiment of classical cuisine enshrined
notably from Japan and the former colonies in the history of Lyon: ‘I love Lyon, I like the
of France (Beaugé, 1999). The ingredients of region and its products; my cuisine is deeply
nouvelle cuisine were fruits, vegetables, inspired by this native area: it is a cuisine
potatoes, aromatic herbs, exotic ingredients, bourgeois, a cuisine that smells good º. My
sea fish. In summary, ‘the object of the culi- strength? a traditional cuisine based on typi-
nary arts is no more the metamorphosis of cal products from Lyon.’
the food product, but the revelation of its Some chefs signal a hybrid identity – two
essential truth’ (Fischler, 1993: 238). of their signature dishes can belong to classi-
cal (or nouvelle) genre, and the remaining
dish falls in the nouvelle (or classical) genre.
A patchwork of different flavors
In all cases, the signature dishes adhere to the
Classical cuisine and nouvelle cuisine were rules of the genre, and so patrons can have a
not rigid orthodoxies but theories which choice of classical and nouvelle cuisine
could be appropriated by chefs (Ferguson, dishes faithfully executed according to the
1998). Indeed, culinary journalists such as conventions of the genre. An example is La
Henri Gault and Christian Millau depicted Poularde (‘The Fat Chicken’) located in
Escoffier and classical cuisine as rigid, and Montrond-les-Bains, the oldest two-star
portrayed nouvelle as an oppositional cate- restaurant in France. In 1990, Gilles Etéocle
gory. All chefs had to nominate three of their offered the following dishes: cooled off
NEW FORMS AS SETTLEMENTS 363

marinated salmon with sesame (saumon et caramel de Macvin), snails cooked in


mariné tiédi aux graines de sesame), a pure butter served in a liquorice court bouillon
nouvelle cuisine dish based on account of the (embeurrée d’escargots dans une nage à la
spices and techniques used. This dish fea- réglisse), and boned out fat chicken cooked
tures a natural river fish and a spice not avail- in white wine and garnished with morels
able in France, sesame, which was not (poularde en gigot de vin jaune et morilles).
traditionally used as a seasoning in marinated The first dish is a nouvelle cuisine dish,
preparation before. Sesame was mainly used while the others belong to the classical cui-
as an imported product in bakery and pastry, sine genre. However, all borrow ingredients
for dessert preparation, not in fish prepara- and cooking techniques from each genre. The
tion. So the rules of transgression and first dish combines a highly classical cooking
acclimatization apply. Etéocle also has two technique: poaching (simply using boiling
classical cuisine dishes such as chicken fric- water) and a very classical ingredient: foie
assee with truffle (fricassée de poulette truf- gras, with a Macvin caramel, or sugared
fée) and big game (gibier). The two pure dessert with a liqueur based on a local marc.
classical cuisine dishes use classical cuisine The combination of salt and sugar is a nou-
ingredients: truffles, big game, and rely on velle cuisine characteristic. The second dish
the classical cooking technique – fricassee. mixes earth and sea, a typical feature of nou-
But chefs can have all of their signature velle cuisine, in complete disrespect to tradi-
dishes in the classical or all nouvelle cate- tion and the natural order of classical cuisine,
gories, and yet borrow elements from a rival through an ingredient: (snails) and an appel-
cuisine, and blend them with their claimed lation – swimming. Finally, the third dish is
cuisine. An exemplar is Bernard Collon of pretty classical, but the carving technique,
‘Auberge de Letraz’ located on the border of ‘gigot’ (not adequately translated as ‘boned
the Annecy Lake. Collon was awarded one out’) is usually adequate for mutton (a leg of
star in 1975, but downgraded in 1996. Collon mutton) and is not properly used for chicken
defines himself as a classical cuisine chef, under the classical cuisine orthodoxy. Jean-
who uses fresh ingredients of nouvelle cui- Paul Jeunet stated: ‘My role is to bring some-
sine. He characterized his identity as follows: thing, to transcend the product through the
‘I do not like the caricatured classification techniques. I am a technician, first and above
between classical and nouvelle cuisine. I cat- all ’ (italics ours).
egorize myself in the “Classics,” but º I use As these descriptions indicate, French
fresh products º you modernize.’ In 1981, chefs did not neatly fall into classical
for example, two of Collon’s signature dishes and nouvelle cuisine camps, but instead
breached the boundaries of classical cuisine: straddled them. Moreover, those whose cui-
duck aiguillettes with quince (aiguillettes de sine was dominantly classical or nouvelle
canard aux coings), and escalope of salmon also experimented by borrowing techniques
trout with sorrel (escalope de truite and ingredients from the rival cuisine.
saumonée à l’oseille). Both dishes combine Rao, Monin and Durand (2003) formally
classical cuisine ingredients (salmon trout modeled the creation of a patchwork by
and duck) with nouvelle cuisine ingredients analyzing the extent to which chefs belong-
(quince and sorrel ) and nouvelle cuisine ing to classical and nouvelle cuisine bor-
rules of cooking (aiguillettes and escalope). rowed materials from each other. They
Finally, chefs can follow a hybrid argued that when boundaries are strong due
approach and still borrow techniques from a to external sanctions, most actors don’t
rival cuisine. Consider Jean-Paul Jeunet, the borrow, and the sprinkling that do borrow do
chef of the Restaurant de Paris in the Jura so most of the time. As a result, the mean
province, who in 1992 chose the following as number of elements (µ) borrowed from the
his signature dishes: lightly poached foie rival category for each actor is likely to be
gras and a Macvin reduction (foie gras poché low but the variance (σ2) in the number of
364 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

elements borrowed is high. Conversely, when improve the protection of consumers through
boundaries are eroding, the mean number of the establishment of a new mechanism of con-
elements (µ) borrowed by an actor from the trol – the Consumer Watchdog Organization
rival category increases, but the variance (σ2) (CWO). Chase, an accountant by profession,
in the number of elements borrowed had written two polemics entitled The
declines. What increases µ and decreases σ2? Challenge of Waste (1922) and The Tragedy of
They argued that geographically high-status Waste (1925) to warn consumers against prod-
actors have more latitude to be original, and ucts that were superfluous and detrimental.
can borrow techniques from a rival category, Schlink had worked for the National Bureau of
and serve as influential role models for other Standards and the National Standards
chefs. Their study of French haute cuisine Association; together with Chase, in 1927, he
showed that borrowing by high-status actors published Your Money’s Worth, in which man-
increased the mean number of elements (µ) ufacturers were blamed for creating wasteful
borrowed by an actor from the rival category, variety and advertisers were accused of deceit-
but reduced the variance (σ2) in the number ful claims.
of elements. Thus, boundaries between a cat- Building on his experience with a con-
egory weakened when members of a cate- sumer’s club established in a church in White
gory borrowed from the rival category, and Plains, New York, Schlink created Consumer
the sources of erosion were from within Research (CR), whose Bulletin would ‘inves-
and without. They also showed that those tigate, test, and report reliably hundreds of
who borrowed when the categorical differ- commodities’ (Silber, 1983: 18). The goal of
ences were strong received penalties in the CR – a non profit organization that distanced
form of a downgrade by external evaluators. itself from any political party – was to pro-
The penalties diminished as the fraction of tect consumers by pushing manufacturers to
chefs who borrow increased and borrowing reduce wasteful variety and keep fair prices
became prevalent in the social system. Thus, through standardization. Scientific analysis,
chefs redrew boundaries through borrowing and not emotions, had to guide consumption.
which created a patchwork, and, in turn, CR shielded itself from the opposition of
critics based their assessment on the manufacturers and advertisers by building on
patchwork. the ideas of ‘service’ to the customer and
truth in advertising – concepts that firms
were implementing to professionalize their
trade and as a competitive weapon – and by
QUADRANT 3: IMPOSITION: THE emphasizing standardization and testing. CR
CASE OF CONSUMER WATCHDOGS grew quickly: in 1927, it had 656 sub-
scribers, but by 1933, there were 42,000 sub-
The saga of non-profit consumer watchdogs scribers. In 1935 the readership of the
provides a telling example of how a settle- Consumers Research Bulletin reached a
ment was imposed due to powerful external circulation of 55,000. CR’s growth was
actors. So in this case it is not the actors also fostered by the Depression, which
making a settlement, but rather an imposition forced consumers to pay more attention to
of a settlement by external audiences. The price/quality ratios, and by a wave of books
parties were rival entrepreneurs championing that ran exposés of manufacturing and
different visions of a non-profit consumer advertising practices.
watchdog, other media, and Congress. We As CR grew, new activists joined, while
rely heavily on Rao (1998) to provide this some older activists – among them Chase – left
case study. the organization because of disagreements
In the 1930s two issue entrepreneurs, Stuart with Schlink. These disagreements stemmed
Chase and Frederick Schlink, attempted to from different perspectives on the scope of
NEW FORMS AS SETTLEMENTS 365

CR – Chase and other members wanted to industries. Professional journals such as


deal with social questions concerning wages Science and the Journal of Home Economics
and working conditions, while Schlink and declined space to CU because CU’s claims
his supporters believed that these concerns could not be scientifically substantiated. In
could not be scientifically tested and there- 1937, a new watchdog organization began to
fore were outside the boundaries of CR’s publish Consumer Bureau Reports, which
responsibilities towards consumers. In 1935, provided favorable ratings in return for free
Arthur Kallett, an ex-colleague of Schlink at samples from manufacturers. Both the simi-
the American Standards Association and then larity of the name of the bulletin and its
member of the board of CR, founded a new format could confuse the readers and weaken
organization called Consumer Union (CU), CU’s reputation.
which aimed at protecting both consumers Further, CU was directly smeared as a
and workers. The founders of CU defined the Communist newspaper by the Hearst news-
consumer as a worker who was concerned papers, due to a series of CU exposés of
not only about wasteful variety and deceitful Hearst’s Good Housekeeping Institute (so
advertising, but also about wages and much so, that the Federal Trade Commission
income. Living standards could be improved launched an investigation against the insti-
through standardization, product testing, and tute). A few years later, in 1938, a House
control of labor conditions. Labor concerns committee on subversive activities, chaired
also influenced purchasing choices; for by Congressman Dies, sought to investigate
example, CU urged members to boycott anti- whether CU was engaged in un-American
union manufacturers. Labor legislation that activities harmful to the national interest.
created a favorable environment for labor J. B. Matthews, an associate of Schlink at
unions – for example, the Norris-La Guardia CR, served as counsel for the Select
Act in 1932 and the Wagner Act in 1935 – Committee on Un-American Activities and
stimulated CU’s growth: by the end of 1936 suggested that Kallett’s writings and the fact
it had 20,700 members, and by 1937 it had that a CU ex-employee, Susan Jenkins, had
close to 40,000 members. admitted to being an employee of a
Communist newspaper (the Daily Worker)
were proof that the organization was a
Communist front. The Hearst newspapers
Imposition by external actors
printed Matthews’s accusations in full.
CR and CU provided two different models Although there was no systematic investi-
for a consumer watchdog organization. gation of the charges leveled at CU, the Dies
While the concepts of rational decision Committee’s allegations became a matter of
making, standardization, and scientific test- concern to the founders and supporters. This
ing that were initially promoted by CR spate of attacks from multiple actors led
spread to governmental agencies and profes- CU’s founders to disengage from their radi-
sional societies, small, newly founded con- cal agenda. Slowly, CU began to disengage
sumer groups were modeled after CU. These from radical advocacy; thus, reports on labor
endorsements stimulated CU’s founders to conditions were no longer included in CU’s
increase circulation of the organization’s bul- bulletin, which more conservatively focused
letin, Consumers Union Reports. However, on product testing and ratings. In parallel,
CU’s radical agenda encountered resistance CU developed a relationship with scientific
from diverse institutional actors: in 1939 the societies in Boston and sought to inject sci-
postmaster general of New York banned the ence into its testing approach, and by 1944,
bulletin and sixty-two newspapers, including its circulation began to increase. CU had won
the New York Times, refused to sell advertis- the battle with CR but lost the battle for
ing space to CU because of its attacks on ideology. So much so that when Ralph Nader
366 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

wrote his critique of the auto industry, mutual plan’s rigid rules by replacing install-
he first approached CU, only to be rebuffed ment shares with optional-payment and paid-
as unscientific, and later went on to estab- up shares, allowing early payment of loans,
lish a new kind of non-profit consumer and eliminating fees for membership, late
watchdog – one that looked at the legal rights payment, and early withdrawal. The guaran-
of consumers. tee-stock plan introduced non-withdrawable
stock, which was paid in at founding and
which was used to insure other members
against losses. This joint-stock plan linked
QUADRANT 4: INTEGRATION: THRIFTS owners to savers and borrowers in an internal
IN PRE-DEPRESSION CALIFORNIA market for risk and return; it contrasted
sharply with the mutual and Dayton plans,
Early thrifts were incarnations of beliefs which were both cooperatives whose mem-
and values concerning saving and home bers were all owners. The four hybrid plans
ownership and took on value far beyond the were recombinations of two or all three basic
technical requirements of the financial- plans. For example, the Dayton/guarantee-
intermediation task at hand and became insti- stock hybrid combined features of the
tutionalized systems of moral authority. We guarantee-stock and Dayton plans: this joint-
rely on Haveman and Rao (1997) and stock plan created an internal market for risk
Haveman, Rao and Parachuri (2006) to and return, separated borrowers and savers,
describe how thrifts based on the model of and allowed great flexibility for both.
cooperation among friends and enforced The California thrift industry grew rapidly
saving were replaced by thrifts based on from its origins. In 1890, the first year
bureaucratized cooperation among strangers detailed data are available, 116 thrifts oper-
and voluntary saving. ated. In 1894, 146 thrifts operated with
There were three basic thrift forms or 34,000 members and 9,000 mortgage loans
‘plans,’ as contemporary observers called outstanding; by 1928, the number of thrifts
them. Each plan represented a proposal had risen to 216, with 114,000 members and
about how to organize thrift. In order of 92,000 mortgage loans outstanding. While
appearance, these were the mutual plan the industry grew more dramatically in scale
(which had three variants – terminating, rather than in sheer numbers, the distribution
serial, and permanent), the Dayton plan, and of organizational forms shifted dramatically.
the guarantee-stock plan. In addition to these Until 1900, the industry was composed
three basic plans, four ‘hybrid’ plans almost solely of mutual-plan thrifts, although
emerged, which combined the features of there were rare instances of the Dayton,
two or three basic plans: mutual/guarantee- guarantee-stock, and mutual/guarantee-stock
stock, mutual/Dayton, mutual/Dayton/guar- plans. After 1900, the number of mutuals fell
antee-stock, and Dayton/guarantee-stock. and the number of Dayton and mutual/guar-
These hybrid plans represented attempts to antee-stock thrifts rose. Then, after 1906, the
integrate the ‘mutual’ plan with its other number of Dayton/ guarantee-stock thrifts
extreme – guaranteed stock plan. rose dramatically. In 1890, the mutual plan
In the mutual plan, all members were on constituted over 90 percent of all thrifts oper-
equal footing: all were part owners, saved ating. By 1919, that number fell to 48 percent,
and repaid home loans on the same schedule, and by 1928, to 13 percent. By contrast, the
and shared in the association’s profits. Dayton/guarantee-stock plan rose from
Mutual-plan thrifts had rigid schedules for 1 percent of the industry in 1906 to 20 percent
dues and loan payments; they enforced these in 1919, and to 72 percent in 1928.
schedules with fines for late payment and How did the Dayton/guarantee-stock plan
early exit. The Dayton plan relaxed the suddenly replace the serial mutual plan as the
NEW FORMS AS SETTLEMENTS 367

dominant form? When the population in political power, and enacted regulations gave
California was transformed, by immigration legal standing to three elements of the
and internal migration, into a society of Dayton/guarantee-stock form of thrift –
strangers, these social bonds frayed. guarantee stock, optional-payment shares,
Immigration and internal migration together and paid-up shares.
accounted for 65 percent of California’s pop- By 1913, the specific features of the
ulation increase between 1890 and 1900, and Dayton/guarantee stock form were author-
87 percent of the population increase ized but this by itself was inadequate. The
between 1900 and 1910. Social ties could no meaning of thrift not only needed to be
longer enforce the ethic of forced saving and reconstituted, it also needed to be integrated
a system of collective borrowing from into the prevailing cultural order. This consti-
friends. Thus, demographic change made the tutive legitimation project required the cre-
mutual form of thrift ineffective. ation and spread of intermediary institutions,
None of the other forms of thrift in exis- both theorists like the news media, which
tence at the turn of the century could replace constructed functional accounts of the gen-
the mutual form, because all violated, in eral Progressivist model of rational and effi-
some way, the original ideals of thrift cient bureaucracy, and naturalizing analogies
(Haveman and Rao, 1997: 1640–1641), and like the city-manager form of municipal gov-
all contravened the prevailing political cul- ernment, which made bureaucracy a ‘natural’
ture. Two forms in particular merit mention, part of the social fabric. It was only the rise
as they were combined to create the hybrid of Progressive newspapers and the diffusion
Dayton/guarantee-stock form (Haveman, of the city-manager form of municipal gov-
Rao, and Parachuri, 2006). The pure Dayton ernment that made the Dayton/Guarantee
form was not viable when it first appeared in Stock plan natural and possible.
1899 because it eliminated structured effort, As Progressive newspapers proliferated
reduced mutuality, and had an identity that across the various counties of California, and
was similar to banks; the pure guarantee- as Progressive ideas embodied in the city
stock form was unacceptable when it first manager form of government became
appeared in 1898 because it eliminated mutu- entrenched in different parts of California,
ality. Moreover, neither form ever achieved thrift executives began to redefine thrift as
sufficient numbers to confer great legitimacy efficiency and the separation of powers
(Hannan and Freeman, 1987; Hannan, Pólos, between managers and owners as the best
and Carroll 2007). At the dawn of the twenti- way to organize enterprises. The Progressive
eth century, then, there was a problem in the zeitgeist which treated even the governance
thrift industry, but no acceptable solution. As of a city as analogous to a joint-stock
a result, the industry languished and the corporation tipped the balance in favor
number of thrifts fell from a peak of 157 in of the Dayton/Guarantee stock plan.
1898 to a low of 85 in 1918. Integration ensued through conversion of
existing thrifts and the birth of new enter-
prises. The Dayton/Guarantee stock plan
Integration: The Progressives gained recruits through defections of existing
thrifts based on other plans, but mainly
It was the Progressive movement with its through the creation of new thrifts. Existing
emphasis on rationality and bureaucracy plans saw the shifting winds of cultural
that drove the integration of Dayton and change and tacked their sails to adjust to the
Guaranteed stock plans. Progressivism arose in new winds. The Progressive zeitgeist was the
response to the political machines dominating banner under which the new entrepreneurs
municipal government, and sought to impose mobilized themselves. Since there was inte-
rationality and order. Progressives won gration, the settlement was long-lasting – it
368 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

lasted until thrifts were besieged by competi- asymmetry of power among parties is
tion from commercial banks due to deregula- high and proposals are incompatible, the
tion in the Reagan era. settlements that ensue, as in Quadrant 3,
are imposed by an external force. Such
settlements last only as long as the external
party retains its influence. If the external
DISCUSSION
party loses its grip, weaker parties gain the
leeway to defect. If the external party consoli-
Our conception of new forms as settlements dates its power, the settlement can become
strengthens the connection between neo- durable, until the accumulation of unresolved
institutional theory and organizational ecol- issues results in a conflict after a long period
ogy. Neo-institutionalists postulate that of time. When one party is powerful, but
organizational forms are created through an the proposals are compatible, then the settle-
inherently political process. Organizational ment that ensues can be long-lasting and
ecologists assert that organizational forms enforceable.
are socially coded identities. So the question Our chapter focused more on the constitu-
is how conflict and contestation culminate in tion of forms as settlements, and assumed
a code. Our suggestion is that forms have to that durability and enforceability were an
be first constituted as settlements – that is outcome of the nature of the settlement.
agreements have to be negotiated among par- Future research needs to specify the condi-
ties before new forms can be institutionalized tions under which settlements gain institu-
as codes. A settlement is a set of understand- tional strength and sanctions, and become
ings and expectations about a form that are codes of conduct that influence the fates
shared among internal and external audi- of individual organizations. Studies of settle-
ences. Settlements become codes only when ment collapse would be particularly valuable,
these understandings and expectations as they could provide insight into the
become default conditions of membership, boundary conditions of how organizations
and are enforced by external and internal are products of their environments, and envi-
audiences. ronments are outcomes of organizational
Our four examples underscore how new intervention.
forms have to be constituted as settlements
if they are to become durable and enforced
as social codes. When there is low asymme-
try in the power of the various parties and ACKNOWLEDGMENT
their proposals are ideologically incom-
patible, then brittle settlements ensue as We are thankful to Christine Oliver and
in Quadrant 1, and are short-lived and subject Heather Haveman for exceptionally helpful
to schisms. Here the possibility of codifica- comments and suggestions.
tion of a single organizational form is
low. However, when asymmetry of power
among parties is low, and the proposals
REFERENCES
are ideologically compatible (despite rhetor-
ical exaggeration of differences), the settle-
Anglund, Sandra M. 2000. Small Business
ments that ensue as in Quadrant 2 are durable Policy and the American Creed. New York:
but constitute a patchwork. As a result, Praeger.
the settlement is evolving, and codification Bean, Jonathan J. 1996. Beyond the Broker
is uneven, with some parts being highly State: Federal Policies Toward Small Business,
institutionalized and other parts being as 1936–1961. Chapel Hill: University of North
yet underdetermined. In sharp contrast, when Carolina Press.
NEW FORMS AS SETTLEMENTS 369

Beaugé, Bénédict. 1999. Aventures de la and institutional contradictions.’ Pp.


Cuisine Française, Cinquante Ans D’histoire 232–266 in Walter W. Powell and Paul J.
du Goût. Paris: Nil Editions. DiMaggio (eds.), The New Institutionalism in
Brint, Steven and Jerome Karabell. 1991. Organizational Analysis. Chicago: University
‘Institutional origins and transformations: of Chicago Press.
The case of American Community Colleges’, Fligstein, Neil. 2001. An Architecture of Mar-
Pp. 337–360 in W.W. Powell and Paul kets. New York; Oxford University Press.
DiMaggio (eds.), The New Institutionalism in Hannan, Michael T. and John Freeman. 1989.
Organizational Analysis. Chicago: University Organizational Ecology. Cambridge, MA:
of Chicago Press. Belknap Press.
Carroll, Glenn and Anand Swaminathan. 2000. Hannan, Michael T. Laszlo Pólos, and Glenn R.
‘Why the microbrewery movement? Caroll. 2007. The Logics of Organizational
Organizational dynamics of resource parti- Theory: Social Codes and Ecologies.
tioning in the American brewing industry Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
after Prohibition.’ American Journal of Haveman, Heather and Hayagreeva Rao. 1997.
Sociology, 106: 715–762. ‘Structuring a theory of moral sentiments:
Chase, Stuart. 1922. The Challenge of Waste. Institutional and organizational coevolution
New York: New York League for Industrial in the early thrift industry.’ American Journal
Democracy. of Sociology, 102: 1606–1651.
Chase, Stuart. 1925. The Tragedy of Waste. Haveman, Heather A., Hayagreeva Rao, and
New York: The Macmillan Co. Srikanth Paruchuri. 2007. ‘The winds of
Davis, Gerald F. and Douglas McAdam. 2000. change: The Progressive movement and the
‘Corporations, classes, and social bureaucratization of thrift.’ American
movements.’ In Barry Staw and Robert I. Sociological Review, forthcoming.
Sutton (eds.), Research in Organizational Hayes, Samuel L. and Donald H. Woods. 1963.
Behavior 22: 195–238. Oxford: Elsevier Are the SBICs doing their job?’ Harvard
Science. Business Review (March–April): 6–15,
DiMaggio, Paul. 1988. ‘Interest and agency in 178–196.
institutional theory.’ Pp. 3–21 in L.G. Zucker Hsu, David M. and Martin Kenney. 2005.
(ed.), Institutional Patterns and Organiza- ‘Organizing venture capital: The rise and
tions: Culture and Environment. Cambridge, demise of American Research & Development
MA: Ballinger. Corporation, 1946–1973.’ Industrial and
DiMaggio, Paul. 1991. ‘Constructing an organi- Corporate Change, 14: 579–616.
zational field as a professional project: U.S. Kilgore, Bernard. 1938. ‘Small business tackles
art museums 1920–1940.’ Pp. 267–292 in its problems before White House meeting
W.W. Powell and Paul DiMaggio (eds.), The today.’ Wall Street Journal (February 3): 3.
New Institutionalism in Organizational Analy- Kraus, Albert L. 1960. ‘Tax break brings invest-
sis. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. ing vogue.’ The New York Times (July 24),
DiMaggio, Paul J. and Walter W. Powell. 1983. pp. 1, 13.
‘The iron cage revisited: Institutional isomor- Liles, Patrick. 1977. Sustaining the Venture
phism and collective rationality in organiza- Capital Firm. Cambridge, Management
tional fields.’ American Sociological Review, Analysis Center.
48: 147–160. McAdam, Dough, John D McCarthy, and Mayer
Douglas, Mary. 1986. How Institutions Think. N Zald. 1996. Comparative Perspectives on
Syracuse, NY: Syracuse University Press. Social Movements: Political Opportunities,
Ferguson, Patricia. 1998. ‘A cultural field in the Mobilizing Structures, and Cultural Framings.
making: Gastronomy in 19th century Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.
France.’ American Journal of Sociology, 104: McAdam, Doug, and W. Richard Scott. 2005.
597–641. ‘Organizations and movements.’ Pp. 4–40 in
Fischler, Claude. 1990. L’Homnivore. Paris: Gerald F Davis, Doug McAdam, W. Richard
Odile Jacob. Scott, and Mayer N. Zald (eds.), Social Move-
Friedland, Roger and Robert R. Alford. 1991 ments and Organization Theory. New York:
‘Bringing society back in: Symbols, practices, Cambridge University Press.
370 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Meyer, John and Brian Rowan. 1977. SBIC Evaluation Service. 1966. ‘News from
‘Insitutional organizations: Formal structures Washington.’ SBIC Evaluation Service
as myth and ceremony.’ American Journal of (October), pp. 4–5.
Sociology, 83: 340–363. SBIC Evaluation Service. 1964. ‘News of the
Meyer, J.W., J. Boli, and G. Thomas. 1987. month.’ SBIC Evaluation Service (June), p.1.
‘Ontology and rationalization in the Western Silber, Norman Isaac. 1983. Test and Protest:
cultural account.’ Pp. 12–37 in George M. The Influence of Consumers Union. New
Thomas, John W., Meyer and C. Ramirez York: Holmes and Meier.
(eds.), Institutional Structure: Constituting Snow, David A. and Robert D. Benford. 1992.
State, Society, and the Individual. Newbury ‘Master frames and cycles of protest.’ Pp.
Park, CA: Sage. 133–155 in Aldon Morris and Carol Mueller
Neirinck, Edmond and Jean-Pierre Poulain. 1988 (eds.), Frontiers in Social Movement Theory.
(2nd edn 1997). Histoire de la cuisine et des New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
cuisiniers: Techniques culinaires et pratiques Stinchcombe, Arthur L. 1965. ‘Social structure
de la table. Paris: Editions Jacques Lanore. and organizations.’ Pp. 142–193 in James G
Nelson, Richard R. and Sidney G. Winter. 1982. March (ed.), Handbook of Organizations.
An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change. Chicago: Rand McNally.
Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press. Swidler, Ann. 1986. ‘Culture in action: Symbols
Oliver, Christine. 1992. ‘The antecedents of and strategies.’ American Sociological
deinstutionalization.’ Organization Studies, Review, 51: 273–286.
13: 563–588. Tolbert, Pamela S., and Lynne G. Zucker. 1996.
Pfeffer, J.M. 1992. Managing with Power. ‘The institutionalization of institutional
Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. theory.’ In S. Clegg, C. Hardy, and W. Nord
Pólos, Laszlo, Michael Hannan and Glenn (eds.), Handbook of Organization Studies:
Carroll. 2002. ‘Foundations of a theory of 175–190. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.
social forms.’ Industrial and Corporate Weiss, Allen. 2001. ‘Tractatus logico-
Change, 11: 85–115. gastronomicus.’ Pp. 229–241 in Lawrence
Powell, Walter W. (1991) ‘Expanding the scope Schehr and Allen S. Weiss (eds.), French
of organizational analysis.’ Pp. 183–2 in Food: On the Table, on the Page, and in
Walter W. Powell and Paul J. DiMaggio (eds.), French Culture. London: Routledge.
The New Institutionalism in Organizational Zald Mayer and and John D. McCarthy. 1980.
Analysis. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. ‘Social movement industries: Competition
Rao, Hayagreeva. 1998. ‘Caveat emptor: The and cooperation among movement organi-
construction of nonprofit consumer watch- zations.’ Research in Social Movements,
dog organizations.’ American Journal of Conflict and Change, Vol. 3, pp. 1–20.
Sociology, 103, 4: 912–961. Ziegler, Harmon. 1961. The Politics of Small Busi-
Rao, Hayagreeva, Calvin Morrill, and Mayer N ness. Washington, DC: Public Affairs Press.
Zald. 2000. ‘Power plays: How social move- Zucker, Lynne G. 1988. ‘Where do institutional
ments and collective action create new orga- patterns come from? Organizations as actors
nizational forms.’ Research in Organizational in social systems.’ In Lynne G. Zucker (ed.),
Behavior, 22: 239–282. Institutional Patterns and Organizations:
Rao, Hayagreeva, Phillipe Monin, and Rodolphe Culture and Environment: 23–49.
Durand. 2003.’Institutional change in Toque Cambridge, MA: Ballinger.
Ville: Nouvelle cuisine as an identity move- Zuckerman, Ezra W. Tai-Young Kim, Kalinda
ment in French gastronomy.’ American Ukanwa, and James Von Ritter. 2003
Journal of Sociology, 108, 4: 795–843. ‘Robust identities or non-entities: Type-
Rao, Hayagreeva, Phillipe Monin, and Rodolphe casting in the feature film labor market.’
Durand. 2005 ‘Border crossing: Bricolage American Journal of Sociology, 108:
and the erosion of categorical boundaries in 1018–1075.
French gastronomy.’ American Sociological Zuckerman, Ezra W and Tai-Young Kim 2003.
Review, 70, 6: 968–991. ‘The critical trade-off: Identity assignment
SBIC/Venture Capital. 1973. ‘New venture and box office success in the feature film
capital trade association launched.’ industry.’ Industrial and Corporate Change,
SBIC/Venture Capital (May), p. 3. 12: 27–67.
14
Social Movements and Failed
Institutionalization: Corporate
(Non)Response to the AIDS
Epidemic
Gerald F. Davis and Peter J.J. Anderson

A consequence of globalization is that the individual states to respond effectively. They


nation-state becomes too big to solve the require a collective response, from govern-
small problems and too small to solve the big ments and from transnational actors such as
ones, as Daniel Bell has remarked. The same corporations. Yet demands to address broad
might be said of the contemporary multina- social problems challenge conceptions of
tional corporation (MNC). As MNCs have what a corporation is for, and to whom it
grown in size and influence in recent decades, owes a responsibility. How are we to under-
they have faced growing demands to assume stand corporate responses to demands for
greater responsibility for solving social prob- greater responsibility in addressing global
lems large and small. Corporations are problems?
expected to provide safe products for their In this chapter, we argue that organizational
consumers, decent working conditions for institutionalism and social movement theory
their employees, and to police the ethical offer complementary insights to address what
standards of their suppliers and even the we might call ‘collective corporate social
countries where they operate. More recently, responsibility.’ Collective corporate social
MNCs have been asked to address global responsibility (CCSR) is the concept that
problems that would have previously organizations in a sector or field are perceived
been seen as the responsibility of govern- to owe an obligation to certain constituencies.
ments, such as the HIV/AIDS pandemic and These obligations can vary across fields and
the looming crisis of climate change. over time. For example, businesses head-
Such problems outstrip the capacities of quartered in Minneapolis are expected to
372 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

provide generous support to local non-profits, American businesses were offered a rela-
while businesses in Phoenix face no such tively low-cost vehicle sanctioned by the
expectation (Marquis, Glynn and Davis, United Nations to participate in the fight
2007). Pharmaceutical companies are expected against AIDS. In January 2001, Secretary
to provide access to their products for those General Kofi Annan urged American busi-
who cannot afford them, while packaged food nesses to join the Global Business Coalition
companies are not. And thanks to the anti- on HIV/AIDS (GBC), headed by former
sweatshop movement, brand-name sneaker American UN ambassador and investment
companies are now expected to vouch for the banker Richard Holbrooke. Annan framed
labor practices of offshore suppliers who were his appeal to align with prevalent American
previously regarded as outside the realm of conceptions of the corporation, highlighting
their responsibility (Davis, Whitman and Zald, the benefits to shareholders and other con-
2007). CCSR attaches to organizations by stituencies. Yet roughly 95% of the largest
virtue of their membership in a field. Efforts to American businesses declined, and those that
expand the definition of what organizations in did join were a somewhat idiosyncratic
a particular field are responsible for – by social group. Why did some join, and most decline?
movements and others – can thus be regarded Our findings suggest that institutionaliza-
as institutionalization projects: they attempt to tion projects are analogous to efforts to build
change the definition of what field members a social movement (cf. Schneiberg and
are and where their responsibilities lie. As Lounsbury, this volume). Successful institu-
institutionalists point out, organizations adopt tional entrepreneurs induce a critical mass to
practices and structures in large part because adopt their definitions of appropriateness –
these are regarded as appropriate and legiti- what kind of engine should an automobile
mate within their organizational field have (Rao, 2002), what activities should an
(DiMaggio and Powell, 1983). Thus, attempts accounting firm do (Greenwood and
to induce corporations to take on expanded Suddaby, 2006), what are a company’s obli-
responsibilities, by social movements and gations to the local non-profit community
others, entail expanding field-level definitions (Marquis et al., 2007), or to gay and lesbian
of the appropriate. employees (Scully and Creed, 2005), or to
We focus on a particular episode that we citizens in need in other countries.
regard as a failed institutionalization project: Fomenting a social movement follows a
the effort to engage American multinationals similar dynamic, as institutional entrepre-
in the collective global battle against the neurs (such as Kofi Annan) seek to change
HIV/AIDS pandemic. This is a particularly a critical mass of actors’ conception of their
illuminating case for several reasons. The obligations – in this case, what a multina-
AIDS pandemic is the largest public health tional company can and should do
crisis in contemporary history, and the conse- about HIV/AIDS. Some actors are prone to
quences of inaction range from the highly joining a movement based on interests –
personal to problems of national security and pharmaceutical companies, for instance,
economic development. Unlike emergent have a clear stake in efforts to address
crises such as climate change, the scope of HIV/AIDS, and firms with substantial for-
the problem is manifest, and the death toll eign sales receive a benefit in learning from
already numbers in the millions, particularly their peers. Others have already adopted a
in sub-Saharan Africa. Many of the nations conception of their obligations consistent
facing the gravest problems are among the with the movement, making them easier to
poorest in the world, some nominally gov- recruit; in this case, those companies that had
erned by ‘failed states.’ If ever there were a benefits packages for domestic partners of
problem requiring coordinated outside help gay and lesbian employees were far more
from the corporate sector, this was it. likely to join than those that did not. But to
SOCIAL MOVEMENTS AND FAILED INSTITUTIONALIZATION 373

achieve a critical mass, institutional and including mobile phones, computers, and the
movement entrepreneurs often need effective World Wide Web. The globalization of trade
recruitment networks. And while there was and finance has been accompanied by the
clear evidence of network-based recruitment growth of transnational movements and cor-
in this instance, it was not sufficient to spread porations that are dispersed across national
beyond the ‘early adopters.’ Within five years boundaries. And, thanks to ICTs, both move-
of Annan’s plea, only about two dozen mem- ments and organizations are often character-
bers of the Fortune 500 had joined the GBC. ized by nimble and relatively ad hoc alliances
That is, joining the global fight against assembled for particular performances.
HIV/AIDS had not become institutionalized Multinational quasi-firms can be assembled
as part of the standard package of what for specific projects – a movie, a skyscraper,
MNCs do. a line of mobile phones – and broken up
We next provide some background on the when the project concludes. Similarly,
parallels between organizational institution- protest actions, such as those against the
alism and social movement theory, and WTO, typically comprise temporary
recent efforts to integrate them. We then alliances among separate sponsors. Social
describe the context of the corporate move- movements have become as global as corpo-
ment against HIV/AIDS, and derive some rations: six million protesters marched on the
hypotheses about which companies are prone same day in February 2003 behind the
to joining. We analyze data on a sample banner ‘The World Says No to War’ in
of the several hundred largest US firms for dozens of cities on six continents in anticipa-
this decade, and conclude with some impli- tion of the American invasion of Iraq, with
cations of our findings for organizational streaming video feeds of the action available
institutionalism. around the world via the Web. Finally, organ-
izations are often both the objects of social
movements – e.g., Nike (for its contractors’
labor practices), Nestlé (for its sales of infant
THEORETICAL BACKGROUND formula in impoverished countries lacking
clean water), Shell (for its operations in
In recent years there has been a notable con- repressive states); the sites of social move-
vergence in the agendas of those that study ments (such as efforts to gain equal employ-
organizations – particularly institutional the- ment rights), and participants in social
orists – and those that study social move- movements (Davis, McAdam, Scott, and
ments. There are several reasons for this Zald, 2005). Corporations participate in
convergence (Davis and Zald, 2005). First, social movements both covertly (e.g., as fun-
since both domains are concerned with the ders for ‘social movement organizations’
sources of organized action, they are charac- intended to advocate for the firm’s agenda)
terized by similar processes and mecha- and overtly (e.g., through alliances, board
nisms: founding, structuring, recruiting, affiliations, and sponsorships).
incentives, leadership, and culture are all The imagery of networks and contagion
central concerns of both. While social move- are common to research on both institutions
ments often come to be represented by and social movements (Strang and Soule,
formal organizations, organizations have 1998). Networks provide a bridge between
come to be less formal, more permeable, individual and collective action: actors adopt
transient, and network-like (Davis and innovations, in part because those they are
McAdam, 2000). Second, both movements connected to have done so, and potential
and organizations have been transformed by activists ‘adopt’ movement membership
globalization and the advent of information largely via network ties. The nature of rele-
and communication technologies (ICTs), vant ties is quite variable. Networks created
374 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

by shared directors provide an infrastructure behind a cadre of top executives with a par-
for the spread of governance practices among ticular kind of orientation. Edelman (1992)
corporations (e.g., Davis and Greve, 1997), described a similar dynamic in the context of
organizational structures such as the multi- employment relations: in the wake of the
divisional form (e.g., Palmer, Jennings, and Civil Rights Acts of the 1960s, employers
Zhou, 1993), and even choices about which experimented with alternative structures to
stock market to list on (Rao, Davis, and signify compliance with government require-
Ward, 2000). Organizations are also linked ments for equal employment opportunity.
by professional networks, such as those cre- Those that proved sufficient to ward off
ated by human resource managers and their legal challenge subsequently spread widely
professional associations (Dobbin, Sutton, through mimicry. Again, a concomitant of
Meyer, and Scott, 1993). At a more informal the spread of equal employment offices was
level, organizations can be connected by net- the spread of equal employment officers –
works of social activists; for instance, professionals with a particular background
gay/lesbian/bisexual/transgender (GLBT) and training, sensitized to particular issues.
employee groups shared best practices and An implication of this discussion is that
tactics among their peers to advocate for networks are both a cause and a consequence
domestic partner health benefits at employers of contagion. Actors draw on existing net-
across America (Scully and Creed, 2005). works (through shared directors, common
Geographic proximity can create connec- membership in professional or industry asso-
tions among organizations that are conse- ciations, geographic proximity, and so on) to
quential for corporate practice (e.g., Marquis, make judgments about the appropriateness of
2003). And organizations can also be con- innovations, such as poison pills or GLBT
nected through more abstract ties, such as partner benefits. But episodes of contagion
social proximity (e.g., operating in the same can also end up creating networks of firms
industry). Any of these connections can pro- that regard each other as models or peers.
vide a substrate for contagion or cohesion for American antitrust law created opportunities
the purposes of collective action. for CEOs from a finance background; these
Institutional theorists have drawn on CEOs, in turn, promoted corporate strategies
contagion imagery to unpack episodes of diversification. They acted, in effect, as
of widespread organizational change. The agents of a particular worldview, implanted
prevalence of a practice or structure is typi- within organizations and oriented to the
cally taken as evidence for its legitimacy, and actions of their peers. Similarly, employment
thus a prod to further adoption. For example, laws created opportunities for human
Tolbert and Zucker examined the spread of resource managers. Once in place, these
municipal reform among American cities, managers became oriented toward peer
finding that later adopters evidently drew on groups (‘benchmarks’), and act as advocates
the prevalence of the reform as a sign of its for new innovations in human resource man-
appropriateness. Fligstein (1990) described agement, such as maternity leave (Kelly and
how field-level changes in the rules of the Dobbin, 1999). It is as if, by hiring these pro-
game – antitrust regulations limiting certain fessionals, the organization had grown a new
types of horizontal and vertical mergers – sense organ that attuned it to particular types
prompted firms to experiment with alterna- of practice and structure.
tive strategies to achieve growth and stability, Social movements can have a parallel
enacted by CEOs with particular types of effect on corporate change. Zald, Morrill,
functional background and training. Those and Rao (2005) describe the various
strategies that proved successful then spread processes by which social movements can
widely through mimicry, first within their penetrate organizations. At the simplest level,
industry and later more broadly, leaving employees bring with them their social
SOCIAL MOVEMENTS AND FAILED INSTITUTIONALIZATION 375

identities and priorities. Feminist executives collective fight against HIV/AIDS. The
may be advocates for women-friendly corpo- several hundred largest US corporations can
rate policies. Minority executives may be considered an organizational field, a group
shape hiring and promotion policies in ways of mutually-regarding actors that look to
consistent with an agenda of equality. each other for evidence of appropriate action
Scully and Creed (2005) document how net- (Fligstein, 1990). They are connected more
works of gay and lesbian activists formed or less densely at multiple levels by director
within and across companies to advocate for networks, professional networks, and activist
gay-friendly corporate policies. Informal net- networks, among others. The extent that this
works allowed activists in different companies well-connected group adopts or fails to adopt
to compare notes on which tactics worked a practice is an apt indicator of its institution-
and which did not. Moreover, the groups alization. In this case, the practice in question
could use each other’s experiences to docu- is membership in a UN-sanctioned business
ment the prevalence of particular practices organization aimed at halting the spread of
and thus advocate for them more effectively. HIV/AIDS. Prevalence of adoption of this
One of the most visible of these was the rel- innovation stalled at about 5 percent, which
atively widespread adoption of domestic we take as a sign of failed institutionaliza-
partner benefits among large US corpora- tion. We first describe the context of the
tions (Briscoe and Safford, 2007). Notably, AIDS epidemic and then consider the factors
these networks among employee groups that militate for or against joining the fight.
were not neutral conduits for the spread of
information or norms among organizations –
they were channels for activism. And the
prevalence of a practice (such as domestic CONTEXT: CALL AND
partner benefits) was not simply a bench- (NON) RESPONSE
mark, but a tool for advocacy. Activists could
influence how information about best prac- In remarks made on the eve of World AIDS
tices was brought into the organization and Day in 2004, UNAIDS Executive Director
used to guide the organization’s own policies Peter Piot characterized his news about
(Briscoe and Safford, 2007). HIV/AIDS as both ‘sobering’ and ‘ominous.’
Thus, both institutional theory and social He explained that the number of people
movement theory draw on common images living with HIV globally had grown to nearly
and mechanisms for organizational change 40 million and that in 2004 alone, approxi-
(Davis et al., 2005). In this case, organizations mately 5 million people became infected
are connected at multiple levels by networks with HIV and 3 million people died from
among directors that serve on each others’ AIDS-related causes. He indicated that the
boards, executives bound by common training, virus is perilously close to becoming a
professionals connected through professional ‘raging epidemic’ in China, India and Russia
associations, and activists organized via social and that its spread in these places bears
movements that cross organizational bound- alarming similarities to the situation in Africa
aries. Any of these can potentially provide a two decades ago, where it took five years for
channel for recruitment to a social movement. HIV prevalence rates to move from 0.5 percent
But the process is not simply one of the dis- to 1 percent but only seven more years for
semination of neutral information: recruitment such rates to jump from 1 percent to
requires active engagement and advocacy. 20 percent. A 2004 report issued by the
We examine the implications of this World Economic Forum (WEF) echoed
discussion of networks and change in the Piot’s warning while adding warnings about
context of a failed institutionalization proj- the economic consequences of the epidemic:
ect: the effort to recruit corporations to a ‘The AIDS epidemic is first and foremost a
376 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

human tragedy, but its magnitude also America’s business leaders to use their finan-
derives profound social and structural cial strength and influence to take increased
changes, leading to predictions of equally and decisive global action to address
profound economic damage º If effective HIV/AIDS:
action is not taken to combat the spread of I come to you, the leaders of American business,
this epidemic, HIV/AIDS could result in representatives of one of the greatest forces in the
[total] economic collapse’ (World Economic world, but one which has yet to be fully utilized in
Forum, 2004: 3). Eberstadt (2002) suggested the campaign against AIDS/HIV. It is high time we
tapped your strengths to the full º Business is
the following projections: a mild HIV epi- used to acting decisively and quickly. The same
demic would more than halve Russia and cannot be said of the community of sovereign
China’s per person output growth between states. We need your help – right now º Together,
2000 and 2025, while an intermediate epi- I believe we can succeed – if only because the costs
demic would mean the predicted level of of failure are simply too appalling to contemplate.
(Annan, 2001)
output in Russia would be lower in 2025 than
2000, and in China barely higher. In India, a Annan asserted that multinational corpora-
mild epidemic would reduce output growth tions are indispensable in the global fight
by about two-fifths and an intermediate out- against HIV/AIDS. They have the resources
break would reduce growth to zero. and skills that many failed states lack. As
Despite the alarming costs that have such, Annan’s remarks were designed to
already been incurred in sub-Saharan Africa remind the leaders of the American corporate
and those that could likely occur in three of sector that if they can flex their financial
the world’s largest countries, the American might around the world, they need to be pre-
corporate sector’s reaction has been modest, pared to similarly take decisive action in
to put it mildly. A 2004 WEF Executive times of crises. He framed his call to action
Opinion Survey found that 50 percent of in business-friendly terms, emphasizing the
American business executives believe that benefits to reputation, customer loyalty, and
HIV/AIDS will have some impact on their shareholder value. Moreover, he endorsed
business, yet only 7 percent of the executives the Global Business Coalition on HIV/AIDS
surveyed indicated that their company has a (GBC) as the preferred vehicle for collective
written HIV/AIDS-specific policy and a action. Joining the GBC took only $25,000
mere 6 percent expressed confidence that (‘Less than a benefit table at the opera,’ as
their company’s current response to GBC’s CEO Richard Holbrooke quipped),
HIV/AIDS was sufficient (Taylor, DeYoung, and it provided tangible benefits and a visible
and Boldrini, 2004). Executives acknowl- way to signal commitment to the fight
edge that HIV/AIDS is a significant global against HIV/AIDS.
problem while simultaneously judging it not A number of international business
so pressing as to require immediate steps. coalitions have been formed for the purpose
Analysts at the WEF’s Global Health of creating a forum for collective action
Initiative suggest that this inactivity of the on HIV/AIDS. The first was created in
American corporate sector reflects the fact Thailand in 1993. The Thailand Business
that firms lack appropriate information or Council on AIDS (TBCA) was founded by
incentives, and that they are unable to assess two expatriate businessmen who noted that
the risks they face as well as the potential many companies in and around Bangkok
costs and benefits from successful action were quite concerned about HIV/AIDS but
(World Economic Forum, 2004). that none knew where to go for assistance in
In an effort to prod American business the development and implementation of an
executives into action, UN Secretary-General HIV/AIDS policy. The founders put up their
Kofi Annan appeared before the US Chamber own seed money to start the TBCA, with
of Commerce in January 2001 and implored a mission of channeling the creativity
SOCIAL MOVEMENTS AND FAILED INSTITUTIONALIZATION 377

and dynamism of business executives to for- former US Ambassador to the United


mulate solutions to resource, technical Nations, to take over as the President
and strategic planning problems in mounting and CEO of the GBC and turn it into the pri-
effective HIV/AIDS prevention and living mary vehicle for mobilizing the global busi-
with AIDS programs (Thailand Business ness community. At that time, the Global
Council on AIDS, 2000). The TBCA Business Council was renamed the Global
was established as a membership organiza- Business Coalition on HIV/AIDS to reflect
tion where each member firm pays a the new effort to become a more inclusive
membership fee commensurate with the organization with a more extensive corporate
size of that firm and their level of commit- membership base. Under the leadership of
ment to TBCA and AIDS prevention in gen- Holbrooke, the GBC’s membership grew
eral. Within two years, the TBCA from 17 in 2002 to more than 170 companies
membership had grown to 85 companies, in 2005.
among them many large multinational firms The GBC describes itself as the preemi-
such as 3M, American International Group, nent organization leading the business fight
Bristol Myers Squibb, Colgate Palmolive, against HIV/AIDS and defines its role as
General Motors, Kodak and Shell. working with global leaders in government,
Membership now stands at approximately business and civil society, to promote greater
120 firms. partnerships in the global response to
Following the successful model of the HIV/AIDS and identify new, innovative
TBCA, the Global Business Council on opportunities for the business sector to join
HIV & AIDS (GBC) was established in 1997 the growing global movement against
as a small peer-to-peer international advo- HIV/AIDS (Global Business Coalition on
cacy group with the purpose of promoting an HIV/AIDS, 2004). The Coalition charges the
enlarged and enhanced business response to same annual membership fee of $25,000 to
HIV/AIDS. The four founding members – each member and the only expectation is that
Glaxo Wellcome (UK), Industrias Villares members will participate in ways that best
(Brazil), MTV International (US) and Tata suit them. The primary involvement of most
Power (India) – formed the Council based on member companies is through industry-
a shared belief that the corporate sector was related or issue-related project working
not doing a fraction of what it could do to groups (e.g., the Biotechnology Working
address HIV/AIDS despite the fact that it is a Group and the AIDS Orphans and Vulnerable
critical issue for every company precisely Children Working Group); provision of
because it has no boundaries: it penetrates advice on relevant international issues of
borders and threatens the world’s emerging importance to business; and sharing of best
economies (Global Business Coalition on practices, particularly regarding company-
HIV/AIDS, 2004). Levi-Strauss, Bristol wide HIV/AIDS policies. In addition, those
Myers Squibb and Merck had all joined the member companies specifically interested in
Council by 2000, but for the first four years developing an internal corporate HIV/AIDS
of its existence, the number of members policy utilize the GBC’s exclusive Business
remained low and the Council remained AIDS Methodology™ (BAM). BAM is a
more of a peer group than a full-fledged business-management model created for
organization. The importance of the Council the design and implementation of a cus-
changed significantly during a 2001 United tomized company response to HIV/AIDS.
Nations Session on HIV/AIDS. During the Through an intensive process with GBC
session, the UN Security Council called on experts, BAM results in a strategic, goal-
the private sector to increase its engagement oriented action plan, tailormade to an individ-
of the epidemic. As part of that mandate, the ual company’s characteristics and core compe-
Security Council asked Richard Holbrooke, tencies. The variety of activities and services
378 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

notwithstanding, it is important to note that (or avoiding) movements and on social


some GBC members are involved only to the infrastructure, such as networks among
extent that they pay the annual membership potential joiners.
fee, thereby adding their company’s reputa- Institutionalists, as we have seen, view
tion to the Coalition’s work (Global Business joining a movement as akin to the diffusion
Coalition on HIV/AIDS, 2004). of an innovation. Like social movement
researchers, they see networks as a potential
substrate for contagion, as organizations
facing uncertainty follow the example set by
HYPOTHESES their alters (DiMaggio and Powell, 1991).
Institutionalists also point to a central place
We analyze the factors distinguishing those for identity– that answering the question:
American firms that joined the Global ‘What should I do in this situation?’ often fol-
Business Coalition on HIV/AIDS from lows from determining ‘Who am I, and what
those that did not to understand the does someone like me do?’ (DiMaggio and
institutional process behind corporate Powell, 1991). In the hypotheses that follow,
(non)response to the pandemic. We are par- we draw on each of these factors – incentives,
ticularly interested in understanding the networks, and identity –to draw out implica-
social mechanisms – the ‘cogs and wheels’ – tions of social movements and institutionalism
that underlie corporate responses to the AIDS for which firms are likely to join the GBC.
epidemic (Hedstrom and Swedberg, 1998). Organizations that are larger and have better
In doing so, we draw on institutional and performance face greater incentives to join the
social movement theories broadly for a suite fight against HIV/AIDS. First, large organiza-
of possible mechanisms. tions are more visible to the public and there-
Organizational institutionalism and social fore more likely to be the target of demands or
movement theory provide complementary appeals (like that of Kofi Annan before the US
ways of analyzing why firms would join the Chamber of Commerce) that emphasize their
GBC. For social movement researchers, responsibility to take action. Prior research
movements and social movement organiza- suggests that large organizations are more
tions such as the GBC are seen as special likely to be the target of social movement
cases of collective action. Any form of col- efforts than small organizations (Davis et al.,
lective action faces free rider problems – the 2005). Moreover, large firms find it relatively
benefits of successful collective action are less costly to allocate resources to GBC mem-
shared widely, while the costs are borne by bership fees and to develop and implement
the individuals that join in the effort. These HIV/AIDS policies. Second, theory on social
tendencies toward inaction are even more movements suggest that slack resources enable
pronounced among organizations than more prospective collective action – in short,
among individuals: organizations are short- the rich can take the offense, while the poor
term focused, prone to inertia, and respond to must typically respond defensively (Tilly,
problems that have already occurred rather 1978: ch. 3). In this context, superior organiza-
than to ‘predictable surprises’ that may tional performance can create potential slack
happen in the future (Cyert and March, 1963; resources for experimentation and innovation
Bazerman and Watkins, 2004). The progno- that are unavailable to those with poor
sis for corporate executives taking action performance. Thus:
on problems whose consequences will be Hypothesis 1: The larger a firm and the
felt on someone else’s watch – such as the better its performance, the more likely it is to
AIDS pandemic– is grim. Thus, movement join the GBC.
researchers focus on a combination of indi- Firms with more global operations also
vidual and selective incentives for joining have greater incentives to engage against
SOCIAL MOVEMENTS AND FAILED INSTITUTIONALIZATION 379

the HIV/AIDS epidemic. Domestic firms GBC appears congruent with resource depend-
face rather limited exposure to the epidemic, ence theory’s prediction that firms will take
as the prevalence of HIV in the US is rela- action to safeguard their key exchange
tively low by world standards. Companies relationships (Pfeffer & Salancik, 1978).
are expected to have increased exposure In addition, institutionalists point to the
to HIV/AIDS, to the extent that they sell importance of responding to external evalua-
their products and services on a global scale. tors, such as activists and governments in
As such, firms that have high levels of for- stricken countries, with symbolic displays of
eign sales are predicted to possess a more good faith (Meyer and Rowan, 1977).
acute understanding of the damage the Although such displays may be de-coupled
disease has wrought on both their employee from the organization’s actual operations, they
and customer bases, and thus greater serve an important institutional function in
incentives to join in efforts to address it. establishing the firms’ social fitness – and
To that end, levels of foreign sales should potentially warding off more intrusive
serve as a predictor for whether firms join interventions.
the GBC. Hypothesis 3: Pharmaceutical firms will
Hypothesis 2: The greater a firm’s sales be more likely to join the GBC than firms in
outside the US, the more likely it is to join other industries.
the GBC. Not all such organizational changes are
Certain key industries, such as the pharma- purely symbolic, of course. Organizations
ceutical industry, have critical business inter- may establish offices or policies as displays
ests that draw them into the global effort to of good faith, yet they may subsequently
address HIV/AIDS. American pharmaceutical find that the symbol becomes a reality.
companies are among the leading producers of A firm’s internal policies can create
drugs that reduce the amount of virus in a employee constituencies that make the firm
HIV-positive patient’s blood and help to delay more attentive and responsive to certain
the progress of disease. Yet American pharma- social circumstances. The research by Sutton
ceutical companies have come under fire for et al. (1994) and Sutton and Dobbin (1996)
what AIDS activists and AIDS sufferers shows that the establishment of personnel,
(particularly the millions of African AIDS vic- benefits and Equal Employment Opportunity
tims living in dire poverty) decry as impossibly offices created constituencies within firms
expensive drugs. The drug companies contend that actively promoted practices advocated
that it is simply not feasible for them to reduce by their professional networks. A specific
drug prices because doing so would severely example is offered by Kelly and Dobbin
undermine the research and development (1999), who found that firms with benefits
efforts being undertaken to produce new offices were more likely subsequently to
and potentially more effective drugs. Despite create formal maternity leave policies. That
international patent laws that prohibit such is, the establishment of human resource
action, African countries have sought less offices – whatever the initial intention –
expensive generic drugs manufactured prima- connected firms into professional networks
rily in India. As a result of the continued battle that conditioned their responses to subse-
that pharmaceutical firms have found them- quent innovations.
selves in, it is expected that they would make In a similar vein, HR policies related to
every effort to have a seat at the table of a pow- domestic partner benefits may both result
erful advocacy group such as the GBC. It is from and strengthen supportive constituen-
conceivable to imagine that, without the pres- cies for taking corporate action against
ence of pharmaceutical firms, the GBC might HIV/AIDS within the organization. Briscoe
support policies such as the global regulation and Safford (2007) document that domestic
of drug prices. Therefore, membership in the partner benefits were a major target of
380 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

activism by GLBT employee groups in DATA AND METHOD


corporate America during the second half of
the 1990s and the first half of the 2000s. We chose as our sampling frame the 2003
Thus, 93 percent of firms with formal GLBT Fortune 500, that is, the largest 500 firms in
employee groups adopted domestic partner the US by revenues. We excluded commer-
benefits during this time, compared to 41 cial banks and firms that were not publicly
percent of firms without such groups. We traded because certain measures (revenues,
anticipate that firms in the vanguard of HR market capitalization, board membership)
policies recognizing same-sex partnerships are either not comparable or not available for
are likely to attract employees who are more these firms. Our final sample consisted of
attentive to the global HIV/AIDS epidemic 413 firms.
and more likely to press for a proactive Our dependent variable was membership
corporate response. in the Global Business Coalition by 2004.
Hypothesis 4: Firms with more progressive Although there are a number of ways one
HR policies for gay employees will be more might operationalize corporate responses to
likely to join the GBC. AIDS, membership in the GBC has several
Viewing a firm’s GBC membership as akin advantages as an indicator: it is unambigu-
to the adoption of a particular corporate prac- ous, non-trivial, and has the sanction of the
tice suggests an analogy with other forms of United Nations. As of mid-2004, the GBC
institutional diffusion. Davis and Greve had 150 members, of which 76 were US-
(1997), for instance, found that when a com- based firms and 23 were included in the
pany’s directors served on the boards of other Fortune 500.
firms that had already adopted a poison pill, Our independent measures came from sev-
these directors were able to evaluate and even eral sources. Our measure of size (number of
promote adoption. Thus, as more of one’s employees) and performance (the market-to-
contacts adopt, adoption may come to be book ratio, that is, [market capitalization at
seen as normatively appropriate. Such conta- fiscal year end]/[book value of shareholders’
gion processes are also characteristic of equity]) came from Compact Disclosure.
social activism: McAdam (1986) found that Foreign sales, calculated as the ratio of non-
college students were more likely to partici- US sales to total sales for 2002 (or for the
pate in high-risk activism– specifically, most recent available year), came from the
joining the 1964 Freedom Summer project – geographic segment file of Compustat. Firms
when they had friends that were also were classified as pharmaceutical companies
participating. McAdam found that a strong if their primary three-digit SIC code was 283.
ideological identification with the civil rights For progressive HR policies, we drew on the
movement could encourage action, but that Human Rights Campaign’s WorkNet data-
the major factor distinguishing those that base (2004). Specifically, we used an indica-
joined Freedom Summer and those that sat it tor variable equaling one if the firm made
out was having a friend that had joined. domestic partner benefits available to gay
Similarly, we expect that firms which share a and lesbian employees and zero otherwise,
director with an existing member of the GBC according to HRC’s WorkNet. (Domestic
will be more prone to this particular form of partner benefits are health insurance and
corporate activism: directors can spread the other benefits equivalent to those available to
‘innovation’ of GBC membership from board married heterosexual employees.)
to board. We constructed our board interlock
Hypothesis 5: Firms will be more likely to measure using board data for all firms traded
join the GBC to the extent that they share on Nasdaq and the New York Stock
directors with other firms that are members Exchange in 2000. This sample included
of the GBC. 47,349 directors serving on the boards of
SOCIAL MOVEMENTS AND FAILED INSTITUTIONALIZATION 381

5,627 corporate boards. Board membership and some firms share directors with up
data were carefully cleaned to identify over- to seven other members (e.g., Xerox). We
laps in which the same individual served on also see that domestic partner benefits are
two or more boards. All firms in this more prevalent among large firms than one
expanded group were coded for membership might have anticipated. Correlations among
in the GBC. Because several hundred non- the independent variables are generally
US firms are traded on these two markets, we modest, with the notable exception of the
included their data when calculating ties to correlation between domestic partner bene-
GBC members. Our measure is a count of the fits and ties to GBC members, which is cor-
number of other NYSE- or Nasdaq-traded related at 0.25.
firms with which a focal firm shared a direc- Table 14.2 shows the results of the logistic
tor that were members of the GBC. Note that regression analysis. The results offer little sup-
while only 23 Fortune 500 firms were mem- port for Hypothesis 1, as there was no signifi-
bers of the GBC, more than one-third of our cant relation between size (measured as
Fortune 500 sample shared at least one employees or, alternatively, as annual sales)
director with a GBC member (either US or or performance (market/book) and firms’
foreign). propensity to join the GBC. In contrast, we
We analyzed the data using logistic regres- find a significant positive relation between
sion, with the dependent variable being foreign sales and GBC membership, consistent
membership in the GBC, as of 2004. Ideally, with Hypothesis 2. On average, GBC member
we would include a time-series model of firms derived 37 percent of their sales from
membership, but because it is still a rela- outside the US, compared with an average
tively rare event, we would lack sufficient of less than 20 percent for non-members.
statistical power to draw any inferences. Pharmaceutical companies were far more
likely to join the GBC than other firms,
consistent with Hypothesis 3: the coefficient
implies that pharmaceutical companies are
RESULTS 6.7 times as likely to be members of the GBC
as firms in other industries. As predicted
Descriptive statistics are reported in by Hypothesis 4, firms with domestic partner
Table 14.1. The means show that member- benefits were almost five times as likely
ship in the GBC is somewhat rare, in spite of to be members of the GBC as firms without
the fact that the GBC is perhaps the world’s such policies. Interestingly, similar effects
most influential business coalition address- were also observed when we used a more
ing the AIDS epidemic. Yet board-level ties diffuse measure of ‘diversity-friendliness’ in
to GBC members are relatively widespread: HR policies, using the KLD Database’s
more than one-third of the firms in our Diversity Strengths measure instead of HRC’s
sample share a director with a GBC member, WorkNet data on companies with domestic

Table 14.1 Descriptive statistics and correlation matrix for Fortune 500 firms
Variable Mean 1 2 3 4 5 6
1. GBC membership 0.05
2. Employees 17.37 −0.01
3. Market-to-book value 2.84 0.15 −0.03
4. Foreign sales % 19.92 0.18 0.02 0.19
5. Board interlock with existing GBC member 0.68 0.28 0.02 0.11 0.12
6. Pharmaceutical company 0.02 0.28 −0.01 0.21 0.12 0.09
7. Domestic partner health benefits 0.45 0.20 −0.04 0.09 0.06 0.25 0.16
382 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Table 14.2 Logistic regression: factors US-based mid-level manager’s championing


distinguishing Fortune 500 firms that joined of the program.
the global business coalition on HIV/AIDS Second, we found a strong and consistent
Variable Coeff. z
relation between being a member of the GBC
Employees 0.00 −0.02
and board-level ties to other GBC members.
Market-to-book value 0.04 0.47
Foreign sales % 0.04* 2.81 Figure 14.1 shows this graphically (including
Board interlock with existing ties to non-US firms traded on Nasdaq
GBC member 0.50* 3.66 and NYSE that are GBC members). Our
Pharmaceutical company 1.91* 2.20 finding parallels McAdam’s (1986) study of
Domestic partner health benefits 1.58* 2.36
Freedom Summer: while moral commit-
Constant −5.92 −7.28
ments may shape responsiveness to calls for
* p < .05 (two-tailed).
activism, social connections to other activists
may have a more direct effect. We also note a
somewhat surprising connection: every
partner benefits. And lastly, we found that ties Fortune 500 firm with an African-American
to other firms that were GBC members had a CEO (American Express, Fannie Mae,
strong effect. Specifically, each board interlock Merrill Lynch, and Time Warner) was a
with a GBC member increased a firm’s likeli- member of the GBC in 2004, as were almost
hood of being a member by 64 percent. all the firms whose board these CEOs served
Two of our findings stood out as somewhat on. (Fannie Mae’s Franklin Raines served on
surprising from the perspective of the tradi- the boards of Pepsico, Pfizer, and Time
tional literature on corporate social responsi- Warner; Time Warner’s Richard Parsons
bility (e.g., Margolis and Walsh, 2001). First, served on the boards of Citigroup and Estee
firms with progressive HR policies on diver- Lauder; in contrast, GM, whose board Merill
sity, both generally and specific to gay and Lynch’s Stanley O’Neal served on, was not a
lesbian employees, were significantly more member, nor was IBM, where AmEx’s
likely to be involved in the GBC. There are Kenneth Chenault served). Moreover, GM
at least two possible interpretations of this subsequently joined the GBC, while Fannie
finding: such firms may have a culture more Mae left the GBC after the departure of its
attuned to issues of social responsibility, and African-American CEO. This intriguing
thus find activism around the AIDS epidemic observation suggests a source of social
to be a natural response, or they may have responsiveness unexpected in the traditional
internal constituencies that argue in favor of literature.
external responsiveness. Edelman (1992) and
Kelly and Dobbin (1999) find that firms cre-
ating HR offices in response to the Civil
Rights Acts of the mid-1960s – sometimes as DISCUSSION
a cynical effort to ward off potential litiga-
tion – end up building internal constituencies We framed our discussion of American cor-
for progressive HR policies, and later find porations joining the global fight against
themselves being in the forefront of adopting HIV/AIDS as an instance of failed institu-
policies such as paid maternity leave. By the tionalization. Speaking to an audience of
same token, it is possible that firms with pro- America’s top business leaders, UNAIDS
gressive diversity policies developed internal Executive Director Peter Piot (2004)
constituencies attuned to the AIDS epidemic. declared, ‘[You] have a special role. [You]
Indeed, an interview we conducted with the are the only [ones] whose leadership can
officer in charge of one multinational firm’s move the world – not just with funding – but
award-winning AIDS program in Africa with the influence it takes to keep AIDS high
revealed that the program originated in one on the international agenda.’ He then posed
SOCIAL MOVEMENTS AND FAILED INSTITUTIONALIZATION 383

Company has
PLACER DOME INC “Progressive Gay/Lesbian
VIACOM INC
Employment Practices”
LAFARGE CORP
TOTAL FINA ELF SA ABBOTT LABORATORIES
AMERICAN EXPRESS CO

DAIMLERCHRYSLER AG
UNILEVER PLC
COCA COLA CO
MERCK & CO INC
BRISTOL MYERS SQUIBB CO
BPAMOCO PLC
SBC COMMUNICATIONS INC
HEWLETT PACKARD CO

EXXON MOBIL CORP


CHEVRON CORP
FEDEX CORP DIAGEOPLC
PHILIP MORRIS COS INC
MICROSOFT CORP PEPSICO INC
RIO TINTO PLC
TIME WARNER INC NEW

FANNIE MAE CITIGROUP INC NIKE INC GLAXO WELLCOME PLC


ESTEE LAUDER COS INC
PFIZER INC
MERRILL LYNCH & CO INC

JOHNSON& JOHNSON

Figure 14.1 Board ties among GBC members

to them the question that forms the founda- the fight against HIV/AIDS. Moreover,
tion of this research effort, ‘We are clearly at membership was cheap, and thus set a rela-
a crossroads in the global fight, which path tively low threshold for ‘corporate activism.’
will [you] take?’ (Piot, 2004: 7–8). Piot’s Yet the results suggest that incentives were
comments underscore the critical question not the deciding factor: bigger firms, and
that US business leaders find themselves those with better performance, were no
facing: is it worth the investment of their more prone to join the GBC than small firms
companies to engage in the global fight with poor performance. Evidently the cost
against HIV/AIDS? (Nattrass, Neilson, Bery, of membership was not a significant hurdle
Mistry, and Sievers, 2004). In the event, the for firms of this size. Pharmaceutical firms
large majority answered: No. were far more likely than others to join,
Our results indicate what factors distin- but this result is potentially ambiguous.
guished the handful of firms that did join the Pharmaceutical firms have economic incen-
GBC from those that did not. Membership tives to claim a place at the table when
in the Global Business Coalition on it comes to AIDS policies, and they also
HIV/AIDS serves as a valuable measure of have reasons to signal their good faith to
action, as the GBC has emerged over the past outside evaluators by joining in efforts to
few years as the world’s most influential combat the disease (cf. Meyer and Rowan,
business coalition addressing the epidemic, 1977). But they have less cynical reasons
offering member corporations a wide range to join as well, based on their identity as
of ways to become involved and connecting health providers. With only archival data,
them to many, if not all, of the leading it is impossible for us to disentangle these
corporate and public sector actors active in alternative interpretations.
384 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Similarly, firms with greater foreign sales organizations with partner benefits more
were more prone to join the GBC than receptive to the call to join. By virtue of taking
domestically-oriented companies. Again, this a progressive step regarding gay-friendly HR
may be because such firms had greater selec- policies, a firm is likely to attract employees
tive incentives to join (because membership who are generally more attentive to certain
gave them access to tools for constructing their social causes, specifically AIDS-related issues,
own policies for overseas facilities), or because who might then act as internal advocates for
such firms were more aware from first-hand the GBC.
experience of the impact of the epidemic. In contrast, we find that network ties
More intriguing are our results on net- through boards of directors were a relatively
work factors associated with membership. potent source of recruitment – with some
Research on social movements and on orga- qualifications. This parallels the board-based
nizational institutionalism both highlight the contagion process of other practices and
central place of social networks in processes structures that came to be widespread (e.g.,
of change. Organizations look to their peers the poison pill and the creation of investor
and competitors to determine what is appro- relations offices, both of which came to be
priate in a given context, and to answer the standard practice among corporations). But
question ‘What does someone like me do in in this case, adoption stalled at only about
this situation?’ (DiMaggio and Powell, 5 percent, as GBC membership failed to
1991). Social movement participants can act become institutionalized. An unexpected
as evangelists, recruiting their friends and finding may help explain this. We discovered
colleagues to participation. In this case, Kofi that every Fortune 500 firm with an African-
Annan and others were seeking to build a American CEO (of which there were four at
social movement among corporations, to the time of our analysis, of whom only one
change the definition of what a corporation’s remains) was a member of the GBC, and
obligations are with respect to the global almost every board that these CEOs served
fight against the AIDS epidemic. on was a member of the GBC. It seems clear
We examined two types of networks that that the actions of some firms – such as
might serve as a basis for legitimation and Fannie Mae, whose business consists prima-
recruitment to the GBC. First, organizations rily in securitizing American home mort-
that have adopted domestic partner benefits gages – did not result from a direct pecuniary
often share a connection through employee interest in stemming the AIDS pandemic,
activist networks. About 45 percent of the large particularly given that they do essentially no
US corporations in our sample offered such business in the hardest-hit nations. Rather,
benefits, and prior work suggests that such their responsiveness to the call to action evi-
firms are connected by informal interorganiza- dently resulted from other motivations. This
tional networks of employees; indeed, such is not trivial: four black CEOs collectively
networks were in part the basis of advocacy for served on the boards of over one-third of the
these benefits (Briscoe and Safford, 2007; GBC’s American members, and almost half
Scully and Creed, 2005). But while firms with the GBC’s US members shared directors
such benefits were more likely to join the with the firms these four ran.
GBC than those without, we saw little evi- This finding indicates an alternative fram-
dence of contagion, as only a relatively tiny ing of the question that we began with.
proportion of firms with domestic partner ben- Rather than asking: ‘Why did US corpora-
efits joined the GBC. This suggests that the tions join the global fight against AIDS?’, we
inter-organizational network facilitating might instead ask ‘Why did most US corpo-
human resource policies was not activated rations fail to join the fight?’ The early
for recruitment to the GBC. Rather, the find- adopters were largely distinguished by a
ings indicate that firm-level features made small number of factors: either they had
SOCIAL MOVEMENTS AND FAILED INSTITUTIONALIZATION 385

direct business interests in the fight against equally interesting to examine whether there
AIDS (pharmaceutical companies, multina- is a substantive difference in the HIV/AIDS
tionals doing substantial business in Africa) programs of those Fortune 500 firms who
or they had board ties to the four large firms joined the GBC early, as compared to those
run by African-American CEOs at the time who joined later. The primary impediment in
(American Express, Fannie Mae, Merrill conducting such an analysis at this point is
Lynch, Time Warner). Although speculative, that there is little uniformity in the way that
this suggests that recruitment based on net- companies report their HIV/AIDS programs.
works (rather than incentives) spread only as Future research would do well to explore this
far as the reach of these four firms. Had the in more detail.
directors of these first-degree contacts acted
as evangelists, recruiting the other firms
whose boards they served on in turn, it is
possible that GBC membership would have CONCLUSION
reached a critical mass of prevalence suffi-
cient to legitimate it as part of the standard We argued at the outset that organizational
package of what US corporations do. institutionalism and social movement theory
In short, it would have become institutional- offered complementary insights into explain-
ized, an appropriate response to corporate ing failed institutionalization. Organizational
America’s collective corporate social respon- insititutionalists seek to understand how
sibility toward world health. Instead, we practices and structures come to be accepted
found that most corporations abstained, and even taken for granted: why do all
either due to inertia, a lack of incentives, or large American corporations have someone
the (accurate) perception that most of the with a title ‘Chief Executive Officer;’ almost
damage would be felt on someone else’s all have investor relations offices and
watch. Chief Financial Officers; and a large majority
We recognize that there are limitations in have poison pills and golden parachutes?
our approach that prevented us from captur- This question can be extended to issues of
ing a company’s full involvement in the fight social responsibility: why do so many com-
against HIV/AIDS. For data analysis conven- panies headquartered in Minneapolis support
ience, we used a gross dependent variable, local non-profit arts organizations, while
namely ‘GBC member’ or ‘not a GBC those in Columbus, Ohio support child
member’ to assess Fortune 500 firms’ welfare, and those in Orange County,
involvement. Ideally, we would like to know California provide little support to any
more about the specific details of each non-profits (Marquis et al., 2007)? The
Fortune 500 firms’ HIV/AIDS programs and answer turns on field-level processes of defi-
policies. Cursory analysis of the GBC mem- nition and re-definition, where the preva-
bers’ respective HIV/AIDS programs seems lence of a practice serves as an indicator of
to indicate quite a variance in regards to how legitimacy and a spur to further adoption.
different companies are engaged in fighting Successful institutionalization projects are
the global epidemic. One potential way to those in which a practice becomes suffi-
analyze the differences in GBC members’ ciently widespread that it becomes accept-
HIV/AIDS programs would be to conduct able and even obvious. Social movement
research along the lines of Westphal, Gulati theory focuses on similar dynamics to
and Shortell’s (1997) analysis of firms’ adop- explain the prevalence of activism and social
tion of TQM practices. Their work demon- change. In the corporate sector, for instance,
strated that early and later adopters of TQM activists sought to make domestic partner
differed in how they employed TQM prac- benefits for GLBT employees acceptable and
tices within their companies. It might be even obligatory.
386 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

No such process occurred for responses REFERENCES


to the AIDS epidemic. Given a low-cost
opportunity to engage in collective action Annan, K. 2001. Unparalleled Nightmare of
aimed at addressing the worst public health AIDS. Address to the United States Chamber
crisis in recent history through the GBC, of Commerce. Washington, D.C.
the vast majority of American corporations 具www.un.org/News/Press/docs/2001/sgsm78
took a pass. Perhaps their incentives were 27.doc.htm典.
too weak – yet most surveyed executives Bazerman, M. & Watkins, M. 2004. Predictable
Surprises: The Disasters You Should Have
themselves regard their own corporate
Seen Coming and How to Prevent Them.
policies as inadequate to address HIV/AIDS.
Cambridge, MA: Harvard Business School
Moreover, many of the firms that did join Publishing.
the effort did little or no business in sub- Briscoe, F. & Safford, S. 2007. The Nixon
Saharan Africa, where the greatest need is in China effect: Activism, imitation and
felt. Pharmaceutical and oil companies the institutionalization of contentious
have clear incentives to join the conversa- practices. Administrative Science Quarterly.
tion based on their business interests, but (Forthcoming).
why mortgage companies and financial Cyert, R. M. & March, J. G. 1963. A Behavioral
services firms? Theory of the Firm. Cambridge, MA:
Our results indicate that collective action Blackwell Publishers.
Davis, G. F., and Gréve, H.R. 1997. Corporate
failed to reach critical mass and thus to
elite networks and governance changes in
achieve a taken-for-granted status. Some cor-
the 1980s. American Journal of Sociology,
porations joined because of their immediate 103: 1–37.
economic interest. Others evidently joined Davis, G. F. and McAdam, D. 2000.
because they employed individuals with a Corporations, classes, and social movements
rooting interest in the cause, or were after managerialism. In Barry Staw and
recruited through ties to such activists. But in Robert I. Sutton (eds.), Research in Organi-
the end, the numbers were not sufficient to zational Behavior, 22: 193–236. Oxford, UK:
reach a tipping point in which joining the Elsevier Science.
coalition was the sanctioned means of Davis, G. F., McAdam, D., Scott, W. R., and
addressing the HIV/AIDS crisis. Prior Zald, M. N. (eds.). 2005. Social Movements
and Organization Theory. New York:
research on corporate change indicates that
Cambridge University Press.
practices that were initially highly controver-
Davis, G. F., Whitman, M. N., and Zald, M. N.
sial can come to be legitimated and wide- 2007. The responsibility paradox: Forthcoming,
spread through the observed prevalence of Stanford Social Innovation Review.
the practice (e.g., Davis and Greve, 1997). Davis, G. F., and Zald, M. N. 2005. Social change,
Ironically, our examination suggests that social theory, and the convergence of
failure to achieve some level of prevalence movements and organizations. In G. F. Davis,
can undermine the spread of practices that D. McAdam, W. R. Scott, and M. N. Zald
should be utterly uncontroversial, and even (eds.), Social Movements and Organization
mandatory. Theory, 335–350. New York: Cambridge
University Press.
DiMaggio, P. J. and Powell, W. W. 1983. The
iron cage revisited: Institutional isomorphism
and collective rationality in organizational
ACKNOWLEDGMENT fields. American Sociological Review, 48:
147–160.
We would like to thank the Center for Advancing DiMaggio, P. J., and Powell, W. W. 1991.
Research and Solutions for Society (CARSS) at the Introduction to the new institutionalism.
University of Michigan for their support of this In Walter W. Powell and Paul DiMaggio (eds.),
project. The New Institutionalism in Organizational
SOCIAL MOVEMENTS AND FAILED INSTITUTIONALIZATION 387

Analysis, 1–38. Chicago: University of myth and ceremony. American Journal of


Chicago Press. Sociology, 83: 41–62.
Dobbin, F., Sutton, J. R., Meyer, J. W., and Scott, Nattrass, N., Neilson, T., Bery, P., Mistry, N.
W. R. 1993. Equal opportunity law and the and Sievers, S. E. 2004. Opportunities for
construction of internal labor markets. Business in the Fight Against HIV/AIDS.
American Journal of Sociology, 99: 396–427. Discussion paper initiated by Columbia
Eberstadt, N. 2002. The future of AIDS. Foreign University, The Global Business Coalition
Affairs, 81: November/December 2002. on HIV/AIDS and the University of
Edelman, L. B. 1992. Legal ambiguity and sym- Capetown.
bolic structures: Organizational mediation of Palmer, D. A., Jennings, P. D., and Zhou, X.
civil rights law. American Journal of 1993. Late adoption of the multidivi-
Sociology, 97: 1531–1576. sional form by large U.S. corporations:
Fligstein, N. 1990. The Transformation of Institutional, political, and economic
Corporate Control. Cambridge, MA: Harvard accounts. Administrative Science Quarterly,
University Press. 38: 100–131.
Global Business Coalition on HIV/AIDS. 2004. Pfeffer, J. and Salancik, G. R. 1978. The Exter-
具www.businessfightsaids.org/site/pp.asp?c=n nal Control of Organizations. Stanford,
mK0LaP6E&b=202240典. Accessed December California: Stanford University Press.
28, 2004. Piot, P. 2004. AIDS and the Way Forward:
Greenwood, R. and Suddaby, R. 2006. A World AIDS Day Address. Address
Institutional entrepreneurship in mature to the Woodrow Wilson International Center
fields: The Big Five accounting firms. for Scholars. Washington, DC 具www.unaids.
Academy of Management Journal, 49 (1): org/html/pub/media/speeches02/sp_piot_wil
27–48. soncenter_30nov04_en_pdf.htm典. Accessed
Hedstrom, P. and Swedberg, R. 1998. Social January 5, 2005.
Mechanisms: An Analytic Approach to Social Rao, H. 2002. Tests tell: Constitutive legitimacy
Theory. New York: Cambridge University and consumer acceptance in the American
Press automobile industry, 1985–1912. In Paul
Human Rights Campaign. 2004. WorkNet. Ingram and Brian Silverman (eds.), The New
Washington, DC. Human Rights Campaign Institutionalism in Strategic Management,
Foundation. 具www.hrc.org/Template.cfm? 307–339. JAI Press.
Section=About_HRC_WorkNet典. Rao, H., Davis, G. F., and Ward, A. 2000.
Kelly, E. and Dobbin, F. 1999. Civil rights law at Embeddedness, social identity and mobility:
work: Sex discrimination and the rise of Why firms leave the NASDAQ and join the
maternity leave policies. American Journal of New York stock exchange. Administrative
Sociology, 105: 455–492. Science Quarterly, 45: 268–292.
Margolis, J. and Walsh, J. 2001. People and prof- Scully, M. A. and Creed, W. E. D. 2005.
its? The Search for a Link Between a Company’s Subverting our stories of subversion. In
Social & Financial Performance. Mahwah, NJ: G. F. Davis, D. McAdam, W. R. Scott, and
Lawrence Erlbaum and Associates. M. N. Zald (eds.), Social Movements and
Marquis, C., Glynn, M. A., and Davis, G. F. Organization Theory, 310–332. New York:
2007. Community isomorphism and corpo- Cambridge University Press.
rate social action. Academy of Management Strang, D. and Soule, S. A. 1998. Diffusion in
Review, 32: 925–945. organizations and social movements: From
Marquis, C. 2003. The pressure of the past: hybrid corn to poison pills. Annual Review of
Network imprinting in intercorporate Sociology, 24: 265–290.
communities. Administrative Science Sutton, J. R. and Dobbin, F. 1996. The
Quarterly, 48: 655–689. two faces of governance: Responses to
McAdam, D. 1986. Recruitment to high-risk legal uncertainty in U.S. firms, 1955 to
activism: The case of Freedom Summer. 1985. American Sociological Review, 61:
American Journal of Sociology, 92: 64–90. 794–811.
Meyer, J. W. and Rowan, B. 1977. Institution- Sutton, J. R., Dobbin, F., Meyer, J. W. and Scott,
alized organizations: Formal structure as W. R. 1994. The legalization of the workplace.
388 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

American Journal of Sociology, 99: An institutional and network perspective on


944–971. the content and consequences of TQM
Taylor, K., DeYoung, P., & Boldrini, F. 2004. adoption. Administrative Science Quarterly,
Business and HIV/AIDS: A Global Snapshot. 42: 366–395.
Geneva: World Economic Forum. World Economic Forum. 2004. Business and
Thailand Business Council on AIDS (TBCA). HIV/AIDS: Who Me? Geneva, Switzerland:
2000. The Business Response to AIDS World Economic Forum Global Health
in Thailand. 具http://abconaids.org/ABC/ Initiative.
asp/ DispDoc.asp?DocID=294典. Accessed Zald, M. N., Morrill, C., and Rao, H. 2005.
January 6. 2005. The impact of social movements on
Tilly, C. 1978. From Mobilization to Revolution. organizations: Environment and responses.
New York: Random House. In G. F. Davis, D. McAdam, W. R. Scott, and
Walsh, J. 2005. Taking stock of stakeholder M. N. Zald (eds.), Social Movements and
management. Academy of Management Organization Theory, 253–279. New York:
Review, 30: 420–438. Cambridge University Press.
Westphal, J. D., Gulati, R., and Shortell, S. M.
1997. Customization or conformity?
15
Institutions and Corporate
Governance
Peer C. Fiss

From its inception, the institutional field of research only in the late 1970s. Since
tradition of studying organizations has then, traditional scholarship on corporate gov-
been informed by themes of control and ernance has been largely dominated by a legal-
coordination – themes that fall within the economic view of the firm as a nexus of
domain of corporate governance, broadly contracts (e.g. Jensen and Meckling, 1976;
defined as being concerned with the implicit Fama and Jensen, 1983; Hart, 1995). This
and explicit relationships between the corpo- approach has placed the principal-agency
ration and its constituents, as well as the rela- problems at the center of most researchers’
tionships between these constituent groups concerns, and the result has been a rather
(Bradley, Schipani, Sundaram, and Walsh, narrow conception of corporate governance as
1999). With its insights into the nature of concerning primarily the relationship between
authority and control structures, institutional shareholders and managers (e.g. Rubach and
theory is uniquely positioned to provide Sebora, 1998; Shleifer and Vishny, 1997: 737).
important contributions to scholarship on The main thrust of this body of research has
corporate governance. However, the reverse accordingly been to investigate the optimal
is also true: because of its concerns with the contracts between shareholders and managers
control of the corporation, corporate gover- (Fama and Jensen, 1983; Eisenhardt, 1989),
nance presents a particularly attractive field and has resulted in a large body of research that
for institutional theory and an opportunity to addresses a variety of incentive mechanisms to
clarify and refine it. control the behavior of managers, focusing
While questions about corporate control go mostly on compensation, the composition of
back to the emergence of the publicly owned the board of directors, and the market for cor-
corporations as a form of organization (Berle porate control as the three primary control
and Means, 1932), the literature on corporate issues (see e.g. Blair, 1995; Shleifer and
governance presents a somewhat more recent Vishny 1997; Walsh and Seward, 1990;
phenomenon, establishing itself as a distinct Zingales, 1998 for reviews of this literature).
390 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Although the contractarian view clearly to the study of corporate governance, and to
emerged as the dominant paradigm of corpo- examine a number of fruitful areas for further
rate governance research since the 1980s, inquiry, such as the study of contrasting
some recent research has begun to move away national governance systems, governance
from this focus on the effectiveness of individ- in emerging economies, and the effect of
ual mechanisms and has started to take a more globalization.
holistic view of the corporate governance
system as a configuration of interdependent
elements (e.g. Beatty and Zajac, 1994; Davis
and Useem, 2002). Such a view also empha- AN INSTITUTIONAL APPROACH TO
sizes that corporate governance systems them- CORPORATE GOVERNANCE
selves are embedded in larger institutional and
legal frameworks, and that effective practices To accomplish the task of outlining an insti-
are highly contingent on the institutional tutional approach to corporate governance,
environment in which corporations and their a few clarifications are in order. The first
stakeholders are embedded (e.g. Davis and of these concerns the role of power in
Useem, 2002). Emerging from the foundational institutional accounts. Earlier forms of insti-
work of Coase (1937), the new institutional tutional theory have been criticized for their
economics of North (1990, 2005) and relative inattention to themes of power and
Williamson (1981, 1988) have offered frame- domination (e.g. Perrow, 1985; Clegg, 1989).
works regarding the role of institutions in cor- Since power relations lie at the heart of cor-
porate governance that are rooted in a porate governance, such criticism is of
boundedly rational actor model of the corpora- importance and needs to be addressed. In
tion. For example, North (1990) argues that a response to it, I will follow prior work that
national system of corporate governance may has viewed institutions as inherently about
be seen as an institutional matrix that provides the role of power (Stinchcombe, 1968: 107),
both the roles to the players and the goals to be and institutionalization as a process that is
pursued by the corporation. Similarly, innately political, reflecting the relative
Williamson (2000) acknowledges the embed- power and interests of coalitions of actors
dedness of corporate governance arrangements (DiMaggio, 1988). Such an approach places
in larger, society-wide systems of institutions. issues of power and control squarely at
Given several comprehensive and insightful the center of its attention, considering
reviews of the contractarian approach to corpo- governance systems as reflecting underlying
rate governance (see e.g. Eggertsson, 1990; cultural narratives or moral orders that
Furubotn and Richter, 1997; Menard and define how social relations should be
Shirley, 2005; but also Fligstein and Choo, constructed and whose interests have
2005; Fligstein, 2001; Davis, 2005), in this priority (Wuthnow, 1987). These moral
chapter I will focus relatively more on the con- orders thus form the foundation of gover-
tributions of sociological institutionalism to nance systems and are expressed in the
the study of corporate governance. In doing so, ways in which power and influence work.
I will examine corporate governance using a The view presented here furthermore
socially informed view of actors and corpora- necessarily implies that we need to pay
tions as deeply enmeshed in systems of norms attention to both sides of the power relation-
and relations that are both culturally and socio- ship, including both obedience to power
politically constructed. My goal in this chapter and resistance to it (e.g. Clegg, 1989). It
is thus to present an alternative account of how thus points to the potential of institutional
corporate governance may be studied using the theory to offer a critique of existing power
tools of sociological institutionalism, to survey arrangements (Lawrence and Suddaby,
how institutional theory has so far contributed 2005). In this sense, I will focus both on the
INSTITUTIONS AND CORPORATE GOVERNANCE 391

enactment and acceptance of institutions as ideologies to be ‘all ideas which are espoused
well as on forms of resistance to institutions, by or for those who seek authority in economic
particularly in relation to the actual enact- enterprises, and which seek to explain and jus-
ment of institutional orders in governance tify that authority’ (1956: 2). By emphasizing
(cf. Davis, 2005). the symbolic nature and cultural embedded-
Second, an institutional view of corporate ness of corporate governance models, the view
governance needs to start with a clear under- advanced here likewise builds on recent work
standing of the nature of governance arrange- on the role of institutional logics, defined as
ments. As noted earlier, the standard view of ‘the axial principles of organization and action
corporate governance rooted in the economic based on cultural discourses and material prac-
and legal traditions places the defense of the tices prevalent in different institutional or soci-
shareholders’ interests at its center (Shleifer etal sectors’ (Thornton, 2004: 2). The logics
and Vishny, 1997; Tirole, 2001). Its associated that underlie corporate governance models
scholarship considers governance arrange- thus refer to and emerge from the wider cul-
ments as emerging from the distribution of tural belief and rule systems that structure cog-
property rights and based on two fundamental nition and guide decision-making (Wuthnow,
assumptions. The first holds that shareholders – 1987; Lounsbury, 2007). As such, governance
as the ‘residual risk bearers’ of the corpora- models are similar to conceptions of control
tion – are the only stakeholder group that is (Fligstein, 1990; 2001) in that they refer to
not compensated by contract. Within financial local orders that provide actors with cognitive
economics, this view of shareholders alone frames to interpret the actions of others as well
bearing the risk of corporate failure is so as their own.
widely spread as to be taken as self-evident The view of corporate governance models
(O’Sullivan, 2000). The second assumption is presented here is much more dynamic and
that holding managers accountable only to culturally constructed than that employed in
shareholders will result in the most efficient the contractual tradition. It also differs from
aggregate social welfare outcome. It follows the contractual approach by highlighting
from this assumption that the best governance issues of power and contestation, and partic-
system for all stakeholders is to exclude all ularly resistance to governance models.
constituents except shareholders from the Rather than being rigid structures, gover-
governance of the corporation (Hansmann and nance models are symbolic orders that
Kraakman, 2001: 441). require constant tending to be maintained.
In contrast, an institutional approach to cor- Such an approach thus also speaks to a
porate governance suggests that corporate gov- common theme in the institutional literature,
ernance arrangements always reflect political namely questions of why and how institu-
processes (Cyert and March, 1963; Davis and tional change comes about where existing
Thompson, 1994) and as such do not naturally institutional arrangements become replaced
arise out of an order of property rights. Instead, with alternative orders.
I believe that governance models are better There are several reasons why governance
understood as containing implicit and explic- models and their underlying normative claims
itly normative theories or logics about the are more fragile and vulnerable to alternative
distribution of power and the ‘natural’ order theories than usually assumed. First, as is true
of interests in the corporation. In other words, for all systems of institutional order, the mean-
governance models are articulated systems ing embodied by governance models is inher-
of meaning that embody the moral order as ently unstable, as the very symbols that are
they explain and justify the proper allocation their building blocks tend to be open to differ-
of power and resources. This view of gover- ent interpretations that may empower different
nance models goes back to the work of actors. Sewell (1992) refers to one aspect
Reinhard Bendix, who understood managerial of this as the ‘transposability of schemas,’
392 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

suggesting that culturally learned rules and Likewise, many of the current claims about the
assumptions ‘can be applied to a wide and not superiority of the shareholder-oriented model
fully predictable range of cases outside the of the corporation point to the performance
context in which they are initially learned’ gaps between the presumably superior model
(1992: 17). This is particularly true when gov- and more traditional, stakeholder-oriented
ernance models and practices are applied models (e.g. Hansmann and Kraakman, 2001;
across institutional contexts. Similarly, exist- Bradley et al., 1999).
ing institutional settlements are built on the The view of governance models presented
remains of previously contending alternatives, here also speaks to another central concern in
many of which remain available as differing institutional theory, namely the relationship
models of organizing. As a result, the hege- between taken-for-grantedness and purpo-
mony of governance models is intrinsically sive agency (Colyvas and Powell, 2006).
unstable and constantly threatened, either by Building on the work of Comaroff and
the memories of prior social orders Comaroff (1991), it suggests a continuum of
(Schneiberg, 2006), by alternative versions of governance practices that ranges from the
what could be (Comaroff and Comaroff, salient and openly contested to the taken-for-
1991), or by contradictions within the current granted and therefore uncontested assump-
orders (Clemens, 1997). tions about the governance of corporations.
Furthermore, existing models have to be Taken-for-grantedness refers to those aspects
passed on, either through reproduction and of the corporate governance world that ‘... go
socialization or through conversion of new without saying, because, being axiomatic,
members. However, transmission is problem- they come without saying’ (Comaroff and
atic, because many socialization processes Comaroff, 1991: 23). However, due to the
remain far from complete (Zucker, 1977). As mutability of meaning systems and inherent
a result, social systems in general, and sys- contradictions, even highly legitimated gov-
tems of normative claims in particular, tend to ernance models may become subject to chal-
suffer from ‘social entropy’ (Zucker, 1988), lenges, and it may thus be better to
with a gradual erosion of the accepted beliefs conceptualize the cultural field in which they
and assumptions on which the models them- operate as a ‘fluid, often contested, and only
selves are based, opening the door for chal- partially integrated mosaic of narratives,
lengers such as the shareholder-oriented images, and signifying practices’ (Comaroff
model that replaced the traditional managerial & Comaroff, 1991: 29). In this field, actors
model of governance (e.g. Fligstein, 1990; will frequently aim to stake a claim for
Lazonick and O’Sullivan, 2001; Dore, 2000). new and differing governance against
Finally, governance models are vulnerable to contenders, resulting in continuing contest
technical and economic changes that result in and struggle. Such a view of governance has
discrepancies between actual experience and been advanced by some authors in the
explanation offered by the normative narrative accounting literature. For example, Covaleski,
embodied in them (e.g. Goodrick, Meindl, and Dirsmith, and Michelman (1993) argue that
Flood, 1997). Such techno-economic changes control-systems such as case-mix accounting
may open up performance gaps (Abrahamson, present unfinished processes infused with
1996), thereby creating opportunities for chal- power and are open to manipulation by vari-
lengers to step in and offer alternative explana- ous organizational actors, thus echoing the
tions and ways of organizing. In this regard, idea expressed by Thompson (1990) that the
Barley and Kunda (1992) have shown that the symbolic order is fragile and can never be
ebb and flow of managerial ideologies is taken for granted; its maintenance is as
related to broad cycles of economic expansion problematic as its change, making the ‘ideo-
and contraction, leading to alternating waves logical work of repair and renovation’ a never-
of rational and normative rhetorics of control. ending project (Scott, 1985: 23).
INSTITUTIONS AND CORPORATE GOVERNANCE 393

The view I have advanced here does not ‘an adroit substitute for the overt use of power,
imply that governance regimes cannot take on the very deployment of which might actually
a relatively stable nature. Clearly, the symbolic signal weakness’(Covaleski et al., 1993: 76;
orders that underlie corporate governance also Pfeffer, 1981). At the same time, agents
regimes can become reinforced by formalized that are the target of such monitoring and con-
arrangements such as legal regulations and trol attempts frequently try to influence the
political sanctions. But while such legal under- implementation of practices such as incentive
pinnings can have a stabilizing effect, what plans or financial reporting. This highlights
emerges eventually is a continuum of gover- issues of spread, implementation, and manipu-
nance regimes, ranging from settled periods of lation of governance practices, i.e. changing
relative stability to unsettled periods of chal- either the reach or meaning of the practice
lenge and change, with cultural narratives within and for the organization (Davis, 2005).
about power and authority either sustaining In other words, practice diffusion and imple-
existing orders or providing the tools for con- mentation frequently present the grounds on
structing new ones (Swidler, 1986). which battles between various interest groups
So far, I have argued for an institutional are fought, and thus deserve special attention.
approach to corporate governance that takes
into account the normative nature of culturally
constructed governance models and highlights
the role of conflict and resistance in corporate THE DIFFUSION OF GOVERNANCE
governance. Yet, such governance models are PRACTICES
not merely higher-order systems of meaning.
Rather, much of the action of institutions lies The diffusion of corporate governance prac-
in their everyday enactment and the ways in tices presents perhaps the most developed
which abstract meaning systems become tan- field of applying institutional theory to cor-
gible in everyday experience. As suggested by porate governance. Much of this research has
Scott (1985) and Fine & Sandstrom (1993), to focused on the antecedents of successful dif-
understand the working of institutions it is fusion, focusing specifically on the compati-
essential to tie them closely to action and bility of the diffusing practice and the
everyday practice, and specific governance adopting organization. An institutional view
practices in particular. of governance practices as implicit theories
A focus on practices is attractive to the study raises the question of fit between practice
of corporate governance because the normative and those theories held by adopters, as prac-
claims that inform governance models are not tices do not diffuse into an institutional
always readily transformed into corresponding vacuum, but rather into a pre-existing moral
practices. The overt exercise of power reflect- universe or ‘cultural field’ (Comaroff and
ing self-interest is frequently avoided for fear Comaroff, 1991). One of the first works to
it would mobilize opposition. As a result, pow- take this approach was Hirsch’s (1986) study
erful actors often move to replace overt power of the rhetoric of corporate takeovers, which
with more formalized and structural control argued that an early misfit between the
practice (Covaleski et al., 1993). Accordingly, understandings surrounding takeovers and
the appropriate focus may frequently be not the dominant views held by the business
only overt espousal and diffusion of gover- community inhibited the spread of this
nance ideologies, but also the practices practice. However, a normative framing of
through which such ideologies are enacted. the practice in line with the values of
Particularly formalized, highly institutional- American business culture eventually facili-
ized practices such as financial incentive plans tated the diffusion and legitimation of
or monitoring arrangement present effective takeovers. Similarly, Davis and Greve (1997)
tools for influencing social situations and are found that the spread of poison pills and
394 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

golden parachutes – two anti-takeover Ahmadjian and Robinson (2001), in studying


defenses that became popular during the the spread of downsizing among Japanese
wave of hostile takeovers of the 1980s – fol- firms, point to the importance of a ‘safety-in-
lowed differing pathways that depended on numbers’ effect, where growing prominence
the normative claims embedded in these of a practice facilitated its spread as individual
practices. Poison pills diffused quickly and firms were less likely to be noticed or criti-
widely through shared directorships as their cized. Similarly, Venkatraman, Loh, and Koh
legitimacy was based on the defense of the (1994) examine the spread of joint ventures
corporation against outside raiders; a claim and the multidivisional form, finding that iso-
that could be readily rationalized by outside morphic pressures to adopt were more preva-
directors. In contrast, the diffusion of golden lent for joint ventures since this practice did
parachutes proceeded much more slowly not require a drastic rearrangement of the
through regional elite networks, which is organizational structure. Palmer, Jennings,
commensurate with a practice that was sur- and Zhou (1993) also point to the importance
rounded by greater controversy as it of mimetic pressures in the spread of the mul-
appeared to clearly privilege executives over tidivisional form, where prevalence of this
other constituents. Examining the spread of a governance arrangement increased the likeli-
shareholder value orientation among German hood of its adoption by other corporations.
firms, Fiss and Zajac (2004) and Sanders and Suggesting a somewhat modified version
Tuschke (2007) find evidence that gover- of mimetic pressures, Davis’ (1991) study
nance practices compatible with the mental emphasizes the importance of ties to prior
models and educational background of top adopters in the spread of poison pills as an
executives are also more likely to be imple- anti-takeover defense among the largest U.S.
mented. Similarly, Palmer and Barber (2001) corporations during the 1980s, with mimicry
show the importance of elite education for operating mainly through direct ties rather
determining diversifying acquisition activity, than the observation of competitors.
while Espeland and Hirsch (1990) point to Other studies have argued that more atten-
the important role that accounting played in tion needs to be paid to the coercive power of
providing the conceptual underpinnings that other organizations and legislative bodies in
facilitated and legitimated the U.S. conglom- promoting diffusion (e.g. Barron, Dobbin, and
erate mergers of the 1960s. By offering a Jennings, 1986; Scott, 1987). In an important
framework for making sense of the firm as a contribution, Davis and Thompson (1994) sug-
portfolio of income streams, the rhetoric gest that efficiency-oriented governance
of accounting accelerated the spread of a approaches based on agency theory are fre-
variety of practices, culminating in the emer- quently inadequate for explaining the politics
gence of the hostile takeover and the market of corporate control, and particularly the emer-
for corporate control. These studies highlight gence of shareholder activism. Drawing on the
the role of theorization in the diffusion literature on resource mobilization, Davis and
process (Strang and Meyer, 1993), where Thompson develop a social movements per-
diffusing practices are framed such as to spective that highlights the importance of gov-
make them more compatible with existing ernance actors’ interests, social infrastructure,
cognitive and social requirements, an insight and mobilization in determining the likelihood
that has also been applied to the diffusion for successful collective action within a given
and institutionalization of corporate gover- political opportunity structure. Similarly draw-
nance codes in the international arena ing on a social movements perspective, Rao
(Enrione, Mazza, and Zerboni, 2006). and Sivakumar (1999) argue that powerful
Other authors have pointed to the role of investor rights activists compelled organiza-
mimetic isomorphism in influencing choices tions to adopt boundary-spanning structures
of governance mechanisms. For example, that signaled the primacy of shareholder rights.
INSTITUTIONS AND CORPORATE GOVERNANCE 395

The insights of these studies support a ‘forced- research tends to treat diffusing practices
selection’ perspective (Abrahamson, 1991) as homogeneous entities that do not vary
where powerful organizations impose adoption by context and remain stable over time.
of practices – be they technically efficient or However, such homogenizing assumptions
not – over the resistance of other actors. These seem questionable. If diffusing practices come
insights are also reflected in Oliver’s (1991) with explicit and implicit theories attached,
argument that features of the organization’s then adoption should go along with a consid-
context, such as the multiplicity of its stake- erable amount of interpretive work that aims
holders and the organization’s dependence on to integrate these theories into pre-existing
them, are likely to predict adoption or non- organizational frameworks and world views.
adoption of practices. For example, Palmer, As Strang and Soule argue, such interpretive
Friedland, Jennings, and Powers (1987) and work ‘selects and transforms the diffusing
Palmer, Jennings, and Zhou (1993) point to the practice,’ and while some practices may be
importance of powerful owners in determining more appropriate for interpretive work than
organizational structures, while Palmer et al. others, ‘none come out of this process unmod-
(1995) show that the spread of predatory ified’ (Strang and Soule, 1998: 277).
takeovers was consistent with an embedded- Such considerations point our attention to
ness approach that highlights the role of a the study of variation in practices, an issue that
firm’s position in networks as well as the posi- has emerged as a central concern of institu-
tions of its managers and directors in the firm’s tional theory (e.g. Lounsbury, 2007; Lawrence
ownership structure and the social network of and Suddaby, 2005). A number of studies have
the business elite. In a similar vein, Fiss and begun to examine how practices are modified,
Zajac (2004) argue that the spread of a share- translated, and reinvented to fit local needs
holder value orientation among German firms (e.g. Boxenbaum and Battilana, 2005;
importantly reflected the power and interests Czarniawska and Joerges, 1996; Djelic, 1998;
of various ownership groups, thus also high- Fiss and Zajac, 2006; Lounsbury, 2001; Morris
lighting the role of coercive influence in the and Lancaster, 2005; Sahlin-Andersson and
diffusion of governance practices. The insights Engwall, 2002). A common theme emerging
of these studies thus point to a model of the from these studies is that while there are fre-
diffusion process that sees the probability and quently unifying elements that inform diffus-
speed of a diffusing practice as a function of ing practices, their actual enactment tends to
the number, interest, and relative power of take a variety of forms. An important reason
agents within a given environment (Marquette, for such variation lies in the fact that the inter-
1981; Fligstein, 1985), thus including both nal dynamics of organizations may frequently
organizations and outside stakeholders into the result in differential responses to external insti-
diffusion model where both the actors involved tutional pressures (Greenwood and Hinings,
and their interests tend to be institutionally 1996). For example, Zbaracki (1998) suggests
constructed (Aguilera and Jackson, 2003) that implementation of Total Quality
Management (TQM) practices resulted in con-
siderable variation as managers appropriated
the rhetoric of quality management, with TQM
VARIATION IN GOVERNANCE becoming increasingly ambiguous and open to
PRACTICES appropriation. Likewise, Lounsbury’s (2001)
study of staffing practices in college recycling
While institutional theory has contributed programs indicates that practice variation dif-
considerably to our understanding of how and fered depending on both connections to exter-
why governance practices diffuse, less atten- nal social movement organizations and internal
tion has been paid to the diffusing features such as size, ownership nature,
practices themselves. Much of the prior and social comparison processes relating to
396 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

similar organizations. What emerges is imple- controlled and monitored, most of agency
mentation as not only a technical but also a theory concerns itself with refining the incen-
political and cultural process where new prac- tive and monitoring mechanisms to achieve
tices become appropriated into ongoing optimum efficiency, focusing particularly on
exchanges and conflicts. Such a view, where individual performance outcomes. As was true
practices are adapted to fit local needs, has also for Taylor’s scientific management, agency
been suggested by more macro-level studies of theory thus likewise views the executive as
the international diffusion of the arm’s length inefficient and in need of being ‘enmeshed
contracting standard (Eden, Dacin, and Wan, within a routinely-applicable calculative appa-
2001) and corporate governance codes ratus’ (Miller and O’Leary, 1987: 253). The
(Aguilera and Cuervo-Cazurra, 2004). As implications of this process of constructing
these studies indicate, a focus on variation is the nature of the governable person are con-
central for a fine-grained understanding of cor- siderable, as indicated by arguments about the
porate governance practices and moves negative effect of agency theory on ethical
beyond the acceptance of surface conformity behavior (Ghoshal, 2005) as well as recent
to explore the various forms of meaning and work on the transformation of financial mar-
transformation associated with specific kets in accordance with theoretical models
practices (e.g. Lounsbury, 2001; Zilber, 2006). about their nature (MacKenzie, 2006;
MacKenzie and Millo, 2003).
While the institutional view of governance
GOVERNANCE AND RESISTANCE advanced here differs considerably from that
advanced by agency theory, these agentic
The issue of resistance to governance models models nevertheless highlight the fact that gov-
and practices has formed an important yet ernance has to be accomplished since it will
somewhat unrecognized undercurrent in the frequently be resisted by those whose compli-
literature on corporate governance. The con- ance is to be achieved. In line with
cept of corporate governance itself implies the Granovetter’s (1985) caution against overso-
existence of both governable entities and even cialized models of actors, these considerations
more importantly governable persons (Miller point our attention again to the ways in which
and O’Leary, 1987). An important part of cor- institutional processes are frequently far from
porate governance thus relates to the construc- complete, leaving room for contestation and
tion of managers and employees as not only manipulation, the necessary counterparts to
corporate constituents with rights and respon- the exercise of power (Clegg, 1989). The
sibilities but also entities to be managed with knowledgeable and experienced practitioners
efficiency. The roots of this development can that inhabit many organizations will frequently
be traced back to Taylor’s Principles of attempt to resist the introduction of formal
Scientific Management (1913), which cen- control practices by manipulating the applica-
tered around the efficiency of the individual tion of such new practices, transforming them
worker and insisted that ‘each worker be into means for advancing their respective inter-
singled out, to be rewarded or punished on the ests (Dirsmith, Heian, and Covaleski, 1997).
basis of his or her individual performance’ Acknowledging the impossibility of perfect
(Miller and O’Leary, 1987: 253). This theme control, one stream of literature has focused on
finds its counterpart in contemporary agency the role of decoupling as a response to institu-
theory, which likewise constructs the manager tional pressures. In its classic formulation, the
as primarily self-interested, with goals that concept of decoupling referred to a situation
conflict with those of the principal and greater where ‘structure is disconnected from technical
risk averseness (Jensen and Meckling, 1976; (work) activity, and activity is disconnected
Eisenhardt, 1989). Accordingly, after con- from its effects’ (Meyer and Rowan, 1978: 79).
structing the manager as an agent to be At the same time, it is this very decoupling that
INSTITUTIONS AND CORPORATE GOVERNANCE 397

maintains the legitimacy of the organization. GAAP based financial statements and the
Meyer and Rowan suggest that close supervi- mobilization of cost-benefit rhetoric to defend
sion may frequently be counterproductive, non-implementation. Similarly, Fiss and Zajac
since it would reveal a lack of trust in the (2006) show that a lack of implementation is
supervised organizations and would expose the frequently accompanied by rhetoric aimed at
controlling agencies to uncertainties arising at assuring constituents of compliance with
the technical core of these organizations, external demands.
uncertainties that neither the organizations nor However, resistance to institutional
their supervising agencies have the capacity to demands need not only take the form of
control. In order to prevent these uncertainties incomplete implementation, surface compli-
from leaking into the larger governance system ance, and impression management. Rather
and making it ungovernable, controlling agen- than taking the governance environment as
cies thus frequently rely on formal structure as exogenous, corporations can frequently act
an indicator of legitimacy; surface compliance to actively influence this environment to
may suffice where deep control is impractical, make it more suitable to their needs. As sug-
or indeed impossible. gested by Carruthers, ‘organizations are not
Expanding the classic notion of decoupling, only granted legitimacy; sometimes they go
a number of recent studies have connected it to out and get it’ (1995: 324). An example of
work on impression management in develop- this active construction of the institutional
ing a symbolic management perspective that environment is given by Mezias (1990), who
emphasizes how organizations, by purposive shows how large corporations in the U.S.
action, may maintain or increase their legiti- acted to influence their financial reporting
macy. In contrast to the work of Meyer and requirements. Similarly, Bealing, Dirsmith,
Rowan, legitimacy here is not achieved and Fogarty (1996) point to second-order
through a logic of confidence and cooperation, effects of institutionalization in governance
but rather by calculating, manipulative, or affairs, where, particularly in a fragmented
even deceptive actions that aim to show com- socio-political environment, organizations do
pliance towards external observers while con- not simply adopt institutionalized structures.
cealing nonconformity (Elsbach and Sutton, Instead these organizations actively partici-
1992; Oliver, 1991). Such a perspective has pate in building up a framework for social
been successfully applied to study a lack of control relevant to their own constituents
implementation relating to corporate gover- (such as the accounting profession for the
nance practices. For example, Westphal and US Securities and Exchange Commission),
Zajac (1994) find that symbolic adoption of thereby establishing the legitimacy of the
long term incentive plans for management is interrelationship of the organization with its
frequently decoupled from actual implementa- constituents. A symbolic perspective on cor-
tion of such plans. This is particularly true in porate governance thus points our attention to
firms where powerful CEOs have the resources the various ways in which corporations aim to
to resist board efforts to change their incentive elude institutional demands by hiding non-
structure. Likewise, Carpenter and Feroz compliance or aiming to affect the very defini-
(1992; 2001) examine the adoption of gener- tion of what constitutes acceptable conduct.
ally accepted accounting principles among
U.S. state governments and find that imple-
mentation of such accounting standards was
primarily driven by the desire to exhibit insti- OWNERS, MANAGERS, EMPLOYEES,
tutionalized practices to the public and credit AND OTHERS
markets. At the same time, the authors point to
resistance to institutional pressures, such as the The world of corporate governance is inhab-
state of Delaware’s shallow implementation of ited by a variety of groups with varying
398 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

identities and interests; yet much of the in the 1990s and show that the diffusion of this
literature has focused on two of these groups, normative model happened along ownership
namely managers and owners, and has lines where power to adopt a different gover-
furthermore tended to focus on them in the nance model could be exercised. Several other
context of the publicly traded corporation. authors have employed a social movements
The literature in finance tends to assume perspective to examine the origins and effects
that owners are fairly homogeneous in their of shareholder activism (Davis and
interests, focusing primarily on the maximiza- Thompson, 1994; Proffitt and Spicer, 2006).
tion of shareholder value (e.g. Bagwell, While these studies present important devel-
1991; for an overview of the literature on opments in building an institutional theory of
ownership, see Kang and Sørensen, 1999). ownership, much remains to be done to further
A more institutionally oriented approach our understanding here.
points to the idea that both actors and Another important line of inquiry has
their interests are not merely given but focused on understanding who the top
instead constructed through their embedded- managers are, particularly how they are
ness in larger social systems (Aguilera selected, what their educational and functional
and Jackson, 2003). In such a view, owners background is, and what social circles they
are characterized by various interests and inhabit. Such considerations are relevant as the
identities that translate into differences background and social embeddedness of top
in governance orientations and models executives is likely to be reflected in the views
(Fligstein, 1990; Fiss and Zajac, 2004). they hold regarding the nature of the corpora-
Accordingly, owners tend to be much less tion and in whose interest it should be gov-
homogeneous in their interests than com- erned (Hirsch, 1986; Espeland and Hirsch,
monly assumed within the contractual view of 1990; Fligstein, 1990, 2001). A considerable
the firm. Furthermore, owners may differ in amount of work has focused on the formation
their attitudes towards shareholder value max- and influence of the business elite in the
imization, not only across different ownership United States (e.g. Useem 1979, 1980;
groups such as banks, family owners, and Domhoff, 1967). This literature has examined
other corporations, but their interests may both differences and commonalities in values,
differ even within such groups (e.g. Fiss and interests, and identities between managers and
Zajac, 2004). Similarly, Aguilera and Jackson shareholders, with particular interest in
(2003) have advanced an actor-centered insti- whether there exists a ruling class with
tutional approach to corporate governance that common perceived interests. For example,
emphasizes how the interests of the main cor- Useem and Karabel’s (1986) study of the rela-
porate governance actors are both constructed tionship between educational and social back-
and represented. grounds and careers of U.S. managers found
In addition, research drawing on institu- that career mobility was enhanced by presti-
tional arguments has shown the role of owners gious educational degrees, pointing to the
in the spread of governance models. In this importance of social capital for reaching the
regard, Ahmadjian and Robbins (2005) point upper strata of management. Likewise, mem-
to the importance of ownership in studying the bership in the exclusive social clubs of the
spread of practices associated with U.S. share- elite forms an important source of social
holder value capitalism to Japan. Their find- cohesion (Useem, 1980) and affects the spread
ings indicate that foreign investors were of practices among corporations (e.g. Palmer
associated with an increased restructuring of et al., 1995).
Japanese firms that were less central in the Finally, an extensive stream of research
Japanese political economy. Similarly, Fiss has examined the importance of executives in
and Zajac (2004) study the spread of a share- their role of establishing connections bet-
holder value orientation among German firms ween firms through interlocking directorates.
INSTITUTIONS AND CORPORATE GOVERNANCE 399

This literature has examined the effect of board works councils as well as union influence, a
interlocks regarding a variety of issues ranging number of authors have drawn on institutional
from the exercise of corporate control (e.g. arguments (e.g. Aguilera and Jackson, 2003;
Mariolis, 1975; Mintz and Schwartz, 1981) to Gospel and Pendelton, 2004; Streeck and
corporate political action (Mizruchi, 1989, Thelen, 2003). In addition, some authors
1992) to social cohesion (e.g. Useem, 1984; have employed institutional theory to examine
for an overview of these literatures, see e.g. how control of employees is exercised.
Mizruchi, 1996). For example, Barker (1993) shows how
Other researchers have employed institu- value-based normative rules embedded in self-
tional theory to examine the selection of top managing teams make for more effective
executives. Fligstein (1987, 1990) shows how control of workers than more traditional,
a financial conception of control emerging in bureaucratic authority structures, while Oakes,
the postwar United States and the large-scale Townley and Cooper (1998) examine the ped-
merger movement of the 1960s resulted in agogical role of business plans as language that
increasing numbers of CEOs with a back- redirects work and changes the identity of
ground in finance, and firms with such CEOs managers and employees. However, given the
were in turn more likely to be the targets of current dominance of the shareholder-centered
takeover attempts (Fligstein & Markowitz, system, the role of employees is likely to
1993; Davis & Stout, 1992). Finance CEOs remain peripheral at least in the Anglo-Saxon
were also more likely to adopt the new share- governance context, even though themes of
holder value conception of control emerging in hegemony versus resistance to the shareholder-
the 1980s (Fligstein, 2001; Fiss and Zajac, centered governance model the part of
2004). Ocasio (1999) has shown the role of employees would warrant more attention.
both cognitive and political factors in the Finally, some research in the institutional
formal and informal rules governing CEO suc- theory tradition has expanded the focus to
cession, particularly the choice of insider consider the role of outside constituencies
versus outsider successors. Similarly, in corporate governance. Several studies in
Thornton and Ocasio (1999) and Thornton this regard have focused on the role of finan-
(2004) demonstrate how the institutional cial analysts, who occupy a central role as
logics guiding executive succession in the boundary-spanning and evaluating audiences
higher education publishing industry shifted for corporations. For example, Fogarty and
from an editorial to a market logic. Regarding Rogers (2005) examine the creation of
board composition, Luoma and Goodstein analyst reports and find that this process
(1999) have pointed to the importance of insti- largely follows the logic of confidence
tutional influences on the selection of corpo- described by Meyer and Rowan (1977),
rate directors. These studies indicate that the where strong expectations but little control
selection of top management is importantly characterize the production of reports, a
shaped by institutional forces emerging out of process that is furthermore strongly depend-
organizational and societal processes. ent on information controlled by managers.
While owners and managers have received Furthermore, Zuckerman examined the role
greater attention, major constituent group – of analysts as product critics and has shown
employees – has been less often examined that a mismatch between the cognitive cate-
from an institutional perspective. In this gories used by securities analysts to affect
regard, an institutional approach is not differ- stock prices and de-diversification activity
ent from the corporate governance literature (Zuckerman, 1999, 2000). These considera-
more generally (cf. Blair and Roe, 1999) and tions also point to the role of other actors
the Anglo-Saxon corporate governance litera- affecting the governance of corporations,
ture in particular. Within the literatures on such as suppliers, debtors, professional
labor representation, mechanisms such as associations, the courts, and of course
400 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

government regulators (Fligstein and notion that the economic systems of


Choo, 2005). Some of these have been advanced nations are marked by a variable
examined using a comparative perspective degree of cohesion and complemen-
on corporate governance, to which I now tarity among their respective subsystems.
turn. Beginning with a focus on the diversity of
modern economies, these authors argue that
variation emerges because corporations and
other social actors ‘develop distinctive strate-
THE COMPARATIVE STUDY OF gies and structures to capitalize on the insti-
GOVERNANCE SYSTEMS tutions available for market or non-market
coordination in the economy’ (Hall and
The institutional approach to corporate gov- Soskice, 2001: 48). For example, compara-
ernance suggests that national corporate tive research on Japanese business models
governance systems are importantly affected has suggested that the keiretsu structure
by cultural differences (Tricker, 1984, 1990). of corporate governance presents a
This points to the need to comparatively competitive advantage for large Japanese
evaluate the diversity of governance arrange- firms, since this structure leads to higher
ments. Such research on comparative rates of innovation, resulting in a competitive
corporate governance has for a long time advantage (Gerlach, 1992). While these
been primarily the domain of taxonomists, arguments are similar to those advanced
leading to a large body of mostly descriptive by a competitive logic of differentiation,
research on differences in national corporate they differ in their emphasis of a systemic
governance systems (see e.g. Boyd, Carroll, perspective that points to institutional com-
and Howard, 1996; Bradley et al., 1999; plementarities. Building on the work of
Guillén, 2000 for reviews; see Roe 2003 Aoki (1994), the VoC approach thus views
for a political perspective). The main national governance systems as part of a
assumption of this field of research has been system of interconnected institutions that
that each country’s system of corporate reinforce each other, creating stability but
governance developed in response to its par- also resistance to change. In this respect,
ticular historical, cultural, and technological the VoC approach identifies two ideal types
influences. However, recently a number of of economies: liberal market economies
scholars have aimed to develop these (such as the United States, Canada, the UK,
arguments into more coherent frameworks and Australia) that primarily rely on
that allow for a better understanding of the markets to coordinate their financial and
mechanisms that underlie national gover- industrial relations systems, and coordinated
nance systems, as well as a systematic com- market economies (such as Germany, Japan,
parison of national differences in governance the Netherlands, or the Scandinavian
arrangements. Two frameworks that have countries) that employ a variety of non-
particularly garnered attention in recent years market institutions to coordinate these
are the Varieties of Capitalism (VoC) spheres (Hall and Soskice, 2001). Empirical
approach (e.g. Hall and Soskice, 2001; support for these arguments comes from a
Thelen, 2004), and the business systems per- variety of case studies on European
spective (e.g. Whitley, 1999; Morgan, economies as well as comparative works
Whitley, and Moen, 2005). Their arguments (e.g. Thelen 2001, 2004; Wood, 2001).
are relevant to the embeddedness approach Several recent works have applied the VoC
suggested by institutional theory and deserve framework to the study of corporate gover-
special attention here. nance systems (e.g. Casper, 2001; Vitols
Building on a configurational approach, a 2001; Vitols, Casper, Soskice, and Woolcock,
central theme in the VoC approach is the 1997; Ziegler, 2000), suggesting that this
INSTITUTIONS AND CORPORATE GOVERNANCE 401

approach can offer a framework for under- notion of an institutional logic to examine
standing the connections between corporate changes in the German model of corporate
governance systems and the larger political governance. Similarly combining a business
economy. systems approach with other institutional
A related approach to the study of arguments, Djelic and Quack (2003) and
economies and governance is advanced by Djelic and Sahlin-Andersson (2006) show
Whitley (1992a, 1992b, 1999) and others, how national institutional systems are
who aim to explain the institutional structur- increasingly nested within transnational,
ing of business systems. By business sys- higher-order institutional frames. Such
tems, these authors generally refer to the insights are highly relevant for the study of
‘distinctive patterns of economic organiza- corporate governance, and particularly
tion that vary in their degree and mode of regarding the potential for convergence
authoritative coordination of economic activ- in governance systems (Tempel and
ities, and in the organization of, and inter- Walgenbach, 2007). Both the VoC perspec-
connections between, owners, managers, tive and the business systems approach
experts, and other employees’(Whitley, tend to be focused around ideas of comple-
1999: 33). Accordingly, the nature of the mentarity and consistency. However, rather
relationships between these actors is of cen- than exploring how such systems provide
tral importance when contrasting business coherence to corporate governance, an
systems. For example, business systems may institutional approach also emphasizes the
be characterized by inter-firm relations based importance of conflict and inconsistency.
on arms-length contracting or repeated, Such considerations shift the focus to
cooperative connections (e.g. Dore, 1986). the importation of practices from one
Likewise, the providers of capital may institutional context into another, highlight-
view their investments as resources to be ing issues of enactment and integration, and
supervised directly or they may delegate thus questioning the coherence view of
this task to trusted agents (e.g. Whitley, national systems of corporate governance.
1999). From the combination of these forms Consistent with a focus on practices, it would
of relationships emerges a variety of possible also be useful to shift the level of analysis
types of economic organization and gover- further down to the firm level to examine
nance. However, interactions between vari- diversity even within ‘national’ systems.
ous forms of relationships limit the Such systems are frequently less than coher-
feasibility of business systems, and Whitley ent but instead are marked by considerable
(1999) identifies six that range from the frag- tensions between different governance
mented via the state-organized to the highly models and institutional logics, a process that
coordinated. will likely lead to considerable change
Work building on a business systems per- (O’Sullivan, 2000). However, this change
spective offers an intriguing framework for does not necessarily mean greater conver-
those who aim to study corporate governance gence in governance system, but rather
through an institutional lens, particularly increasing variety.
because its theoretical apparatus is not lim-
ited to the study of advanced economies.
The business systems approach provides a
systematic foundation for examining corpo- EMERGING DIRECTIONS FOR
rate governance practices, particularly when FUTURE RESEARCH
merged with insights from other theoretical
traditions (Tempel and Walgenbach, 2007). As a field for applying institutional theory,
For example, Lane (2005) draws on a busi- corporate governance is likely to continue
ness systems approach informed by the expanding, and the institutional approach is
402 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

well poised to provide a coherent framework national level of corporate governance


for the study of governance systems (Hollingsworth, Schmitter, and Streeck,
and practices across various levels of analy- 1994; Casper, 2000).
sis. As I have argued here, a culturally and Future research should also draw further
politically informed institutional approach attention to the ways in which governance
offers a counter weight to the currently dom- models hide power relations as they become
inating contractarian framework for under- increasingly taken for granted and take on the
standing governance arrangements. This is mantle of neutrality and inevitability. An
not to say that both approaches cannot important role in this regard lies with events
inform each other – in fact, some of the most that lift this mantle and provide a glance into
intriguing insights into governance arrange- the political nature of resource distributions,
ments are likely to come from approaches such as the current wave of corporate scandals
drawing on several theories and disciplines that has swept the United States. Governance
(Fiss, 2006). In the remaining, I want to scandals in particular provide opportunities
sketch out some of the more promising when the seams come apart, allowing for
avenues for further research, applying an regimes to be criticized and changed. As such,
institutional approach to the corporate the study of such scandals, the ways in
governance arena. which they are managed by corporations and
In line with my above arguments regarding regulators, as well as how they are framed and
the role of power and the normative nature of used for mobilization by various interest
governance models, we need to expand our groups, such as activist investors, are of partic-
understanding of how governance models as ular interest to institutional theory and provide
shared cognitive understandings are propa- fertile ground for future research. Such an
gated, find support, and become rooted approach might eventually offer a more sys-
across differing institutional contexts. This tematic framework of the conditions that lead
research project would need to pay attention to relatively strongly institutionalized versus
both to the ways in which governance models less strongly institutionalized models of cor-
spread across national and international porate governance.
arenas and to the processes by which indige- The study of emerging and transition
nous governance models become uprooted economies presents another promising
and contested. Prior research in the contrac- area for understanding both change and per-
tarian literature has pointed towards conver- sistence of corporate governance systems
gence in international governance systems and practices (e.g. Allen, 2005; Millar,
due to the effects of globalization and the Eldomiaty, Choi, and Hilton, 2005). How are
power of financial markets (e.g. Coffee, corporate governance models and practices
1999; Bradley et al., 1999; Hansmann and propagated in such environments and do they
Kraakman, 2001). In contrast, emerging take hold or do they remain externally
institutional work has questioned the likeli- imposed orders that meet with resistance
hood of convergence, pointing instead to from established interest groups? What is the
persistence in national systems alongside role of symbolic and surface compliance in
convergence processes (e.g. Aguilera and this regard? Who are the actors that lead
Jackson, 2003; Fiss and Zajac, 2004; reform efforts and what strategies do they
Guillén, 2001; Jackson and Moerke, 2005). pursue? These are but some of the questions
As argued by Tempel and Walgenbach that require answers once we expand the
(2006), further research should look to move focus of inquiry beyond the currently domi-
beyond the convergence–divergence debate nating Anglo-Saxon governance environ-
and should begin to disaggregate the ment, in combination with Germany, Japan,
processes occurring at various levels of aggre- and France, as the economies that have
gation, such as company, sector/industry, and received the most attention from researchers.
INSTITUTIONS AND CORPORATE GOVERNANCE 403

Understanding the variety of governance underlying dimensions along which institu-


arrangements and the role of employees, tional contexts vary. Furthermore, there is an
banks, family owners, company networks opportunity for institutional theory to bring
and the state in Asian, South American, or all the corporate constituents back into the
Eastern European countries requires a holis- focus of governance research. Rather than
tic approach to corporate governance, and the focusing merely on executives and directors,
institutional perspective is well positioned to such work could take seriously how gover-
contribute such an approach nance is constructed at the intersection of
Regarding the emerging themes of transla- various influence spheres, including those of
tion and adaptation in institutional theory, inside and outside constituents and the
we still know rather little about the process attempts of corporate actors to actively
by which the re-organization of a model is manage such constituent groups. Such an
accomplished, pointing to the need for a emphasis on the active construction and
deeper understanding of how governance propagation of governance accounts would
practices combine and recombine. For enable institutional approaches to bring both
example, in what ways are governance sys- relevant and critically-reflective insight to
tems holistic and interconnected or modular in the current and future corporate governance
nature, and which features of these systems debates.
may be safely removed or added without
disturbing overall operation of the governance
system? Do hybridization and loose coupling
present viable trajectories (e.g. Deeg, 2005; ACKNOWLEDGMENT
Lane, 2005)? To analyze such issues, it may
be useful to examine other fields that have The author acknowledges the helpful com-
studied processes of syncretism and recombi- ments of Norman Macintosh, Sigrid Quack,
nation, such as anthropology (e.g. Stewart, Paul Adler, Christina Ahmadjian, Roy
1999). By drawing on insights developed Suddaby and the other editors of the
there, we may be able to gain a much deeper Handbook of Organizational Institutionalism,
understanding of the cultural embeddedness and seminar participants at the University of
of corporate governance practices. Southern California and the Center for
Finally, while researchers working within Advanced Study in the Behavioral Sciences.
the institutional tradition have made some
forays into the role of constituents and their
identities, these still present fruitful fields for
further inquiry. For the most part, institu- REFERENCES
tional theory has not focused directly on the
role of ownership and control (cf. Fligstein Abrahamson, Eric. 1991. ‘Managerial fads and
and Freeland, 1995). In this regard, family fashions: The diffusion and rof innovations.’
owners present a particularly interesting Academy of Management Review, 16:
case, as such owners are a group where con- 586–612.
flicts over economic versus social logics of Abrahamson, Eric. 1996. ‘Management fash-
investment are particularly likely to be ion.’ Academy of Management Review, 21:
254–285.
prevalent. Likewise, while some research
Aguilera, Ruth V., and Alvaro Cuervo-Cazurra.
has focused on the relationship between 2004. ‘Codes of good governance world-
ownership and national institutional context, wide: What is the trigger?’ Organization
there is still a need for more cross-national Studies, 25: 417–446.
studies of strategy and corporate governance, Aguilera, Ruth V., and Gregory Jackson. 2003.
and particularly studies that would go ‘The cross-national diversity of corporate
beyond national differences to examine the governance: Dimensions and determinants.’
404 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Academy of Management Review, 28: Berle, Adolf Augustus, and Gardiner Coit
447–465. Means. 1932. The Modern Corporation and
Ahmadjian, Christina L., and Gregory Robbins. Private Property. New York: Macmillan.
2005. ‘A clash of capitalisms: Foreign Blair, Margaret. 1995. Ownership and Control:
shareholders and restructuring in 1990s Rethinking Corporate Governance for the
Japan.’ American Sociological Review, 70: Twenty-First Century. Washington, DC:
451–471. Brookings Institute.
Ahmadjian, Christina L. and Patricia Robinson Blair, Margaret, and Mark J. Roe. 1999.
(2001). ‘Safety in numbers: Downsizing and Employees and Corporate Governance.
the deinstitutionalization of permanent Washington, DC: Brookings Institution
employment in Japan.’ Administrative Boxenbaum, Eva, and Julie Battilana. 2005.
Science Quarterly, 46(4): 622–654. ‘Importation as innovation: Transposing
Allen, Franklin. 2005. ‘Corporate governance managerial practices across fields.’ Strategic
in emerging economies.’ Oxford Review of Organization, 3: 355–383.
Economic Policy, 21: 164–177. Boyd, Brian K., W. Otto Carroll, and Marla
Aoki, Masahiko. 1994. ‘The Japanese Firm as a Howard. 1996. ‘International governance
System of Attributes: A Survey and Research research: A review and agenda for future
Agenda.’ Pp. 11–40 in M. Aoki and R. Dore research.’ Advances in International
(eds.), The Japanese Firm: Sources of Comparative Management, 11: 191–215.
Competitive Strength. Oxford: Clarendon Bradley, Michael, Cindy A. Schipani, Anant K.
Press. Sundaram, and James P. Walsh. 1999.
Bagwell, L. S. 1991. ‘Shareholder heterogene- ‘The purposes and accountability of the
ity: Evidence and implications.’ American corporation in contemporary society:
Economic Review, 81: 218–221. Corporate governance at a crossroads.’
Barker, James R. 1993. ‘Tightening the iron Law and Contemporary Problems,
cage: Concertive control in self-managing 62: 9–86.
teams.’ Administrative Science Quarterly, 38: Carpenter, Vivian L., and Ehsan H. Feroz. 1992.
408–437. ‘GAAP as a Symbol of Legitimacy: New York
Barley, S. R., and G. Kunda. 1992. ‘Design and state’s decision to adopt generally accepted
devotion: Surges of rational and normative accounting principles.’ Accounting,
ideologies of control in managerial dis- Organizations and Society, 17: 613–643.
course.’ Administrative Science Quarterly, Carpenter, Vivian L., and Ehsan H. Feroz.
37: 363–399. 2001. ‘Institutional theory and accounting
Baron, J., Frank Dobbin, and P. D. Jennings. rule choice: An analysis of four US state
‘War and peace: The evolution of governments’ decisions to adopt gener-
modern personnel administration in U.S. ally accepted accounting principles.’
industry.’ American Journal of Sociology, 92: Accounting, Organizations and Society,
350–383. 26: 565–569.
Bealing, William E., Mark W. Dirsmith, and Carruthers, Bruce G. 1995. ‘Accounting, ambi-
Timothy Fogarty. 1996. ‘Early regulatory guity, and the new institutionalism.’
actions by the SEC: An institutional theory Accounting, Organizations and Society, 20:
perspective on the dramaturgy of political 313–328.
exchanges.’ Accounting, Organizations and Casper, Steven. 2000. ‘Institutional adaptiveness,
Society, 21: 317–338. technology policy, and the diffusion of
Beatty, R. P., and E. J. Zajac. 1994. ‘Managerial new business models: The case of German
incentives, monitoring, and risk bearing: biotechnology.’ Organization Studies, 21:
A study of executive compensation, owner- 887–914.
ship, and board structure in initial public Casper, Steven. 2001. ‘The legal framework
offerings.’ Administrative Science Quarterly, for corporate governance: The influence
39: 313–335. of contract law on company strategies
Bendix, Reinhard. 1956. Work and Authority in in Germany and the United States.’
Industry: Ideologies of Management in the Pp. 387–416 in P. Hall and D. Soskice (eds.),
Course of Industrialization. New York: Wiley. Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional
INSTITUTIONS AND CORPORATE GOVERNANCE 405

Foundations of Competitive Advantage. corporate control.’ Pp. 232–258 in Andrew


Oxford: Oxford University Press. Pettigrew, Howard Thomas, and Richard
Clegg, Stuart R. 1989. ‘Radical revisions: Whittington (eds.). Handbook of Strategy
Power, discipline and organizations.’ and Management. London: Sage.
Organization Studies, 10: 97–115. Davis, Gerald F., and Tracy A. Thompson. 1994.
Clemens, Elizabeth. 1997. The People’s Lobby: ‘A social movement perspective on corpo-
Organizational Innovation and the Rise of rate control.’ Administrative Science
Interest Group Politics in the United States, Quarterly, 39: 141–173.
1890–1925. Chicago: University of Chicago Deeg, Richard. 2005. ‘Path dependency, insti-
Press. tutional complementarity, and change in
Coase, R. 1937. Institutional Economics: Its Place national business systems.’ Pp. 21–52 in
in Political Economy. New York: Macmillan. G. Morgan, R. Whitley, and E. Moen (eds.),
Colyvas, Jeannette A., and Walter W. Powell. Changing Capitalism? Internationalization,
2006. “Roads to institutionalization.” Institutional Change, and Systems of
Research in organizational behavior, edited Economic Organization Oxford: Oxford
by Barry Staw, Vol. 27, pp. 305–353. University Press.
Greenwich, CT: JAI Press. Jackson, Gregory, and Andreas Moerke. 2005.
Comaroff J., and Comaroff, J. L. 1991. Of Rev- ‘Continuity and change in corporate gover-
elation and Revolution: Christianity, Colonial- nance: comparing Germany and Japan.’
ism, and Consciousness in South Africa. Corporate Governance: An International
Chicago: University of Chicago Press Review, 13: 351–361.
Covaleski, Mark A., Mark W. Dirsmith, and DiMaggio, P. J. 1988. Interest and agency in
Jeffrey E. Michelman. 1993. ‘An institutional institutional theory. Pp. 3–22 in L. G. Zucker
theory perspective on the drg framework, (ed.), Institutional Patterns and Organi-
case-mix accounting systems and health-care zations. Cambridge, MA: Ballinger.
organizations.’ Accounting, Organizations Dirsmith, Mark W., James B. Heian, and Mark
and Society, 18: 65–80. A. Covaleski. 1997. ‘Structure and agency in
Cyert, Richard M., and James G. March. 1963. an institutionalized setting: The application
A Behavioral Theory of the Firm. Englewood and social transformation of control in the
Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall. Big Six. Accounting, Organizations and
Czarniawska, B., and B. Joerges. 1996. ‘Travels Society, 22: 1–27.
of ideas.’ In B. Czarniawska and G. Sevón Djelic, Marie-Laure. 1998. Exporting the
(eds.), Translating Organizational Change, American Model: The Post-War Transformation
13–48. Berlin: de Gruyter. of European Business. Oxford: Oxford
Davis, Gerald F. 1991. ‘Agents without princi- University Press.
ples? The spread of the poison pill through Djelic, Marie-Laure, and Sigrid Quack. 2003.
the intercorporate network.’ Administrative Globalization and Institutions: Redefining
Science Quarterly, 36: 31. the Rules of the Economic Game.
Davis, Gerald F. 2005. ‘New directions in corpo- Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
rate governance.’ Annual Review of Djelic, Marie-Laure, and Kerstin Sahlin-
Sociology, 31: 143–162. Andersson (eds.). 2006. Transnational
Davis, Gerald F., and Henrich R. Greve. 1997. Governance: Institutional Dynamics of
‘Corporate elite networks and governance Regulation. Cambridge: Cambridge
changes in the 1980s.’ American Journal of University Press.
Sociology, 103: 1–37. Domhoff, G. William. 1967. Who Rules
Davis, Gerald F., and Suzanne K. Stout. 1992. America? Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-
‘Organization theory and the market for cor- Hall.
porate control: A dynamic analysis of the Dore, Ronald P. 1986. Flexible Rigidities.
characteristics of large takeover targets, Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.
1980–1990.’ Administrative Science Dore, Ronald P. 2000. Stock Market Capitalism:
Quarterly, 37: 605–633. Welfare Capitalism: Japan and Germany
Davis, Gerald F., and Michael Useem. 2002. Versus the Anglo-Saxons. Oxford: Oxford
‘Top management, company directors, and University Press.
406 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Eden, L., M. T. Dacin, and W. P. Wan. 2001. presidents in large corporations.’ American
‘Standards across borders: Crossborder diffu- Sociological Review, 52: 44–58.
sion of the arm’s length standard in North Fligstein, Neil. 1990. The Transformation of
America.’ Accounting, Organizations & Corporate Control. Cambridge, MA: Harvard
Society, 26: 1–23. University Press.
Eggertsson, Thrainn. 1990. Economic Behavior Fligstein, Neil. 2001. The Architecture of
and Institutions. Cambridge: Cambridge Markets: An Economic Sociology of Twenty-
University Press. First Century Capitalist Societies. Princeton:
Eisenhardt, Kathleen M. 1989. ‘Agency theory: Princeton University Press.
An assessment and review.’ Academy of Fligstein, Neil, and Jennifer Choo. 2005. ‘Law
Management Review, 14 (1): 57–74. and corporate governance.’ Annual Review of
Elsbach, Kimberly D., and Robert I. Sutton. Law and Social Science, 1: 61–84.
1992. ‘Acquiring organizational legitimacy Fligstein, Neil, and Robert Freeland. 1995.
through illegitimate actions: A marriage of ‘Theoretical and comparative perspectives on
institutional and impression management corporate organization.’ Annual Review of
theories.’ Academy of Management Journal, Sociology, 21: 21–43.
35: 40. Fligstein, Neil, and Linda Markowitz. 1993.
Enrione, A., Carmelo Mazza, and Fernando ‘Financial reorganization of american corpo-
Zerboni. 2006. ‘Institutionalizing codes of rations in the 1980s.’ Pp. 185–206 in
governance.’ The American Behavioral William J. Wilson (ed.), Sociology and the
Scientist, 49: 961–973. Public Agenda. Newbury Park, CA: Sage.
Espeland, Wendy N., and Paul M. Hirsch. 1990. Fogerty, Timothy J., and Rodney K. Rogers.
‘Ownership changes, accounting practice 2005. ‘Financial analysts’ reports: An
and the redefinition of the corporation.’ extended institutional theory evaluation.’
Accounting, Organizations and Society, Accounting, Organizations and Society,
15: 77–96. 30: 331–356.
Fama, Eugence F. and M. C. Jensen. 1983. Furubotn, Eirik G. and Rudolf Richter. 1997.
‘Separation of ownership and control.’ Journal Institutions and Economic Theory: The Con-
of Law and Economics, 26(2): 301–325. tribution of the New Institutional Economics.
Fine, Gary A., and Ken Sandstrom. 1993. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
‘Ideology in Action: A pragmatic approach to Gerlach, Michael. 1992. Alliance Capitalism.
a contested concept.’ Sociological Theory, Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.
11: 21–37. Ghoshal, Sumantra. 2005. ‘Bad management
Fiss, Peer C. 2006. ‘Social influence effects and theories are destroying good management
managerial compensation evidence from practice.’ Academy of Management
Germany.’ Strategic Management Journal, Learning & Education, 4: 75–91.
27: 1013–1031. Goodrick, E., J.R. Meindl, and A.B. Flood.
Fiss, Peer C., and Edward J. Zajac. 2004. 1997. ‘Business as usual: The adoption of
‘The diffusion of ideas over contested managerial ideology by U.S. hospitals.’
terrain: The (non)adoption of a share- Research in the Sociology of Health Care, 14:
holder value orientation among German 27–50.
firms.’ Administrative Science Quarterly, Gospel, Howard, and Andrew Pendelton (eds.).
49: 501–534. 2004. Corporate Governance and Labour
Fiss, Peer C., and Edward J. Zajac. 2006. ‘The Management: An International Comparison.
symbolic management of strategic change: Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Sensegiving via framing and decoupling.’ Greenwood, Royston, & C. Robert Hinings.
Academy of Management Journal, 49: 1996. ‘Understanding radical organiza-
1173–1193. tional change: Bringing together
Fligstein, Neil. 1985. ‘The spread of the multi- the old and the new institutionalism.’
divisional form.’ American Sociological Academy of Management Review, 21:
Review, 50: 377–391. 1022–1054.
Fligstein, Neil. 1987. ‘The intraorganiza- Gregory Jackson and Andreas Moerke. 2005.
tional power struggle: The rise of finance ‘Continuity and Change in Corporate
INSTITUTIONS AND CORPORATE GOVERNANCE 407

Governance: Comparing Germany and ideology for corporate governance.’


Japan.’ Corporate Governance: An Economy and Society, 29: 13–35.
International Review, 13 (3): 351–361. Lane, Christel. 2005. ‘Institutional transforma-
Guillén, Mauro F. 2000. ‘Corporate governance tion and system change: Changes in
and globalization: Is there convergence corporate governance of German corpora-
across countries?’ Advances in International tions. Pp. 79–109 in G. Morgan, R. Whitley,
Comparative Management, 13: 175–204. and E. Moen (eds.), Changing Capitalism?
Guillén, Mauro F. 2001. The limits of conver- Internationalization, Institutional Change,
gence. Globalization and organizational and Systems of Economic Organization.
change in Argentina, South Korea and Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Spain. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Lounsbury, Michael. 2001. ‘Institutional
Press. sources of practice variation: Staffing college
Hall, Peter A., and David Soskice (eds.). 2001. and university recycling programs.’
Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Administrative Science Quarterly, 46: 29–56.
Foundations of Competitive Advantage. Lounsbury, Michael. 2007. ‘A tale of two cities:
Oxford: Oxford University Press. Competing logics and practice variation in
Hansmann, Henry, and Reinier Kraakman. the professionalization of mutual funds.’
2001. ‘The end of history for corporate law’. Academy of Management Journal, 50:
Georgetown Law Journal, 89: 439–468. 289–307.
Hart, Oliver. 1995. ‘Corporate Governance: Luoma, Patrice, and Jerry Goodstein. 1999.
Some Theory and Implications.’ The ‘Stakeholders and corporate boards:
Economic Journal, 105(430): 678–689. Institutional influences on board composi-
Hirsch, Paul M. 1986. ‘From ambushes to tion and structure.’ Academy of
golden parachutes: Corporate takeovers as Management Journal, 42: 553–563.
an instance of cultural framing and institu- MacKenzie, Donald. 2006. An Engine, not a
tional integration.’ American Journal of Camera: How Financial Models Shape
Sociology, 91: 800–837. Markets. Cambridge: MIT Press.
Hollingsworth, J. Rogers, and Philippe C MacKenzie, Donald and Yuval, Millo. 2003.
Schmitter, Wolfgang Streeck. 1994. Governing Constructing a market, performing theory:
Capitalist Economies: Performance and Con- The historical sociology of a financial deriva-
trol of Economic Sectors. Oxford: Oxford tives exchange. American Journal of
University Press. Sociology, 109 (1): 107–45.
Jensen, Michael C., and William H. Meckling. Mariolis, P. 1975. ‘Interlocking directorates and
1976. ‘Theory of the firm: Managerial control of corporations: The theory of bank
behavior, agency costs and ownership struc- control.’ Social Science Quarterly,
ture.’ Journal of Financial Economics, 56: 425–439.
3: 305–60. Marquette, Jesse. 1981. ‘A logistic diffusion
John Coffee (1999). ‘The Future as History: The model of political mobilization.’ Political
Prospects for Global Convergence in Behavior, 3 (1): 7–30.
Corporate Governance and Its Implications.’ Menard, Claude and Mary M. Shirley (eds.).
Northwestern University Law Review; 2005. Handbook of New Institutional
Vol. 93 (3): 641–707. Economics. Dordrecht: Springer.
Kang, D. L., and A. B. Sørensen. 1999. Meyer, John W., and Brian Rowan. 1977.
‘Ownership organization and firm perform- ‘Institutionalized organizations: Formal struc-
ance.’ Annual Review of Sociology, 25: ture as myth and ceremony.’ American
121–144. Journal of Sociology, 83:340–363.
Lawrence, Thomas B., and Roy Suddaby. 2005. Meyer, John W. and Brian Rowan. 1978.
‘Institutions and institutional work.’ ‘The structure of educational organizations.’
Pp. 215–254 in S. Clegg, C. Hardy, Pp. 78–109 in John W. Meyer, W. Richard
T. Lawrence, and W. Nord (eds.), Handbook of Scott, Brian Rowan and Terrence E.
Organization Studies, 2nd edn. London: Sage. Deal (eds.), Organizational Environments:
Lazonick, William, and Mary O’Sullivan. 2000. Ritual and Rationality. Beverly Hills, CA:
‘Maximizing shareholder value: A new Sage.
408 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Mezias, Stephen J. 1990. ‘An institu- Ocasio, William. 1999. ‘Institutionalized action
tional model of organizational practice: and corporate governance: The reliance on
Financial reporting at the Fortune 200.’ rules of CEO succession.’ Administrative
Administrative Science Quarterly, 35: Science Quarterly, 44: 384–416.
431–457. Oliver, Christine. 1991. ‘Strategic responses to
Millar, Carla C.J.M., and Tarek I. Eldomiaty, institutional processes.’ Academy of
Chong Ju Choi, Brian Hilton. 2005. Management Review, 16: 35.
‘Corporate governance and institutional Palmer, D. A., and B. Barber. 2001.
transparency in emerging markets.’ Journal ‘Challengers, elites, and owning families:
of Business Ethics, 59: 163–174. A social class theory of corporate acquisi-
Miller, Peter, and Ted O’Leary. 1987. ‘Accounting tions in the 1960s.’ Administrative Science
and the construction of the governable Quarterly, 46: 87–120.
person.’ Accounting, Organizations and Palmer, D. A., B. Barber, X. Zhou, and Y. Soysal.
Society, 12: 235–265. 1995. ‘The friendly and predatory
Mintz, B., and M. Schwartz. 1981. ‘Interlocking acquisitions of large U.S. corpora-
directorates and interest group formation.’ tions in the 1960s: The other contested
American Sociological Review, 46: 851-869. terrain.’ American Sociological Review,
Mizruchi, Mark S. 1989. ‘Similarity of political 60: 469–499.
behavior among large America Ocasio Palmer, D. A., P. D. Jennings and X. Zhou.
Corporations.’ American Journal of 1993. ‘Late adoption of the multidivisional
Sociology, 95: 401–424. form by large U.S. corporations: Institu-
Mizruchi, Mark S. 1992. The Structure of tional, political and economic accounts.’
Corporate Political Action: Interfirm Relations Administrative Science Quarterly, 38:
and their Consequences. Cambridge, MA: 100–131.
Harvard University Press. Palmer, D. A., R. Friedland, P. Devereaux
Mizruchi, Mark S. 1996. ‘What do inter- Jennings, and M. E. Powers. 1987. ‘The
locks do? An analysis, critique, and economics and politics of structure: The
assessment of research on interlocking direc- multidivisional form and the large U.S.
torates.’ Annual Review of Sociology, corporation.’ Administrative Science
22: 271–298. Quarterly, 32: 25–48.
Morgan, Glenn, Richard Whitley, and Eli Moen Perrow, Charles. 1985. ‘Review essay:
(eds.). 2005. Changing capitalisms? Overboard with myth and symbols.’ American
Internationalization, Institutional Change, Journal of Sociology, 91: 151–155.
and Systems of Economic Organization. Pfeffer, Jeffrey. 1981. Power in Organizations.
Oxford: Oxford University Press. Marshfield, MA: Pitman.
Morris, Timothy, and Zoë Lancaster. Proffitt, W. Trexler, and Andrew Spicer. 2006.
2005. ‘Translating Management Ideas.’ ‘Shaping the shareholder activism
Organization Studies, 27: 207–233. agenda: Institutional investors and global
North, Douglas C. 1990. Institutions, Institutio- social issues.’ Strategic Organization, 4:
nal Change and Economic Performance. 165–190.
Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University. Rao, H. and K. Sivaumar. 1999. ‘Institutional
North, Douglas C. 2005. Understanding the sources of boundary-spanning structures:
Process of Economic Change. Princeton: The establishment of investor relations
Princeton University Press. departments in the Fortune 500 industrials.’
O’Sullivan, Mary A. 2000. Contests for Corporate Organization Science, 10: 27–42.
Control: Corporate Governance and Roe, Mark J. 2003. Political Determinants of
Economic Performance in the United States Corporate Governance. Oxford: Oxford
and Germany. Oxford: Oxford University Press. University Press.
Oakes, Leslie S., Barbara Townley, and David J. Rubach, Michael J., and Terrence C. Sebora.
Cooper. 1998. ‘Business planning as peda- 1998. ‘Comparative corporate governance:
gogy: Language and control in an changing Competitive implication of an emerging con-
institutional field.’ Administrative Science vergence.’ Journal of World Business, 33:
Quarterly, 43: 257–292. 167–184.
INSTITUTIONS AND CORPORATE GOVERNANCE 409

Sahlin-Andersson, Kerstin, and L. Engwall. New Institutionalism and the business-


2002. The Expansion of Management systems approach can learn from each
Knowledge. Stanford, CA: Stanford Business other.’ Journal of Management Studies, 44:
Books. 1–24.
Sanders, W. G., and A. C. Tuschke. 2007. ‘The Thelen, Kathleen. 2001. ‘Varieties of labor pol-
adoption of institutionally contested organi- itics in developed democracies.’ Pp. 71–103
zational practices: The emergence of stock in P. Hall and D. Soskice (eds.), Varieties of
option pay in Germany.’ Academy of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of
Management Journal, 50: 33–56. Competitive Advantage. Oxford: Oxford
Schneiberg, Marc. 2006. ‘What’s on the University Press.
Path? Path dependence, organizational Thelen, Kathleen. 2004. How Institutions
diversity and the problem of institutional Evolve: The Political Economy of Skills in
change in the US economy, 1900–1950.’ Germany, Britain, Japan and the
Socio-Economic Review, Advance Access United States. Cambridge: Cambridge
published on March 10, 2006, DOI University Press.
0.1093/ser/mwl006. Thornton, Patricia. 2004. Markets from
Scott, J. C. 1985. Weapons of the Weak: Culture: Institutional Logics and Organiza-
Everyday Forms of Peasant Resistance. tional Decisions in Higher Education Publish-
New Haven and London: Yale University ing. Stanford, CA: Stanford University
Press. Press.
Sewell, William H. 1992. ‘A theory of structure: Thornton, Patricia, and William Ocasio.
Duality, agency, and transformation.’ Institutional logics and the historical contin-
American Journal of Sociology, 98: 1–29. gency of power in organizations: Executive
Shleifer, Andrei, and Robert W. Vishny. 1997. succession in the higher education publish-
‘A survey of corporate governance.’ ing industry, 1958–1990. American Journal
The Journal of Finance, 52(2): 737–783. of Sociology, 105: 801–843.
Stewart, Charles. 1999. ‘Syncretism and its Tirole, Jean. 2001. ‘Corporate governance.’
synonyms: Reflections on cultural mixture.’ Econometrica, 69: 1–35.
Diacritics, 29: 40–62. Tricker, Robert I. 1984. Corporate Governance.
Stinchcombe, Arthur L. 1968. Constructing Aldershot: Gower Publishing.
Social Theories. Chicago: University of Tricker, Robert I. 1990. ‘Corporate governance:
Chicago Press. A ripple on the cultural reflection.’
Strang, David, and John W. Meyer. 1993. Pp. 187–213 in S. Clegg and S. G. Redding
‘Institutional conditions for diffusion.’ Theory (eds.), Capitalism in Contrasting Cultures.
and Society, 22: 487–512. Berlin: De Gruyter.
Strang, David, and Sarah A. Soule. 1998. Useem, Michael, 1979. ‘The social organization
‘Diffusion in organizations and social of the American business elite and participa-
movements: From hybrid corn to poison tion of corporate directors in the governance
pills.’ Annual Review of Sociology, 24: of American instructions.’ American
265–290. Sociological Review, 44: 553–572.
Streeck, Wolfgang, and Kathleen Thelen (eds.). Useem, Michael. 1980. ‘Corporations and the
2005. Beyond Continuity: Institutional corporate elite.’ Annual Review of Sociology,
Change in Advanced Political Economies. 6: 41–77.
Oxford: Oxford University Press. Useem, Michael. 1984. The Inner Circle. New
Swidler, Anne. 1986. ‘Culture in action: York: Oxford University Press.
Symbols and strategies.’ American Useem, Michael, and Jerome Karabel. 1986.
Sociological Review, 51: 273–286. ‘Pathways to top corporate management.’
Taylor, Frederick W. 1913. The Principles of American Sociological Review, 51: 184–200.
Scientific Management. New York: Harper Venkatraman, N., Lawrence Loh, and Jeongsuk
and Brothers. Koh. 1994. ‘The adoption of corporate gov-
Tempel, Anne, and Peter Walgenbach. 2007. ernance mechanisms: A test of competing
‘Global standardization of organizational diffusion-models.’ Management Science,
forms and management practices? What 40: 496–507.
410 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Vitols, Sigurt. 2001. ‘Varieties of corporate Wood, Stewart. 2001. ‘Business, government,
governance: Comparing Germany and the and patterns of labor market policy in Britain
U.K.’ Pp. 337–60 in P. Hall and D. Soskice and the Federal Republic of Germany.’
(eds.), Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutio- Pp. 247–274 in P. Hall and D. Soskice
nal Foundations of Competitive Advantage. (eds.), Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutio-
Oxford: Oxford University Press. nal Foundations of Comparative Advantage.
Vitols, Sigurt, Steven Casper, David Soskice, Oxford: Oxford University Press.
and Stephen Woolcock. 1997. Corporate Wuthnow R. 1987. Meaning and Moral
Governance in Large British and German Order. Berkeley, CA: University of California
Companies: Comparative Institutional Press
Advantage or Competing for Best Practice. Zbaracki, M. 1998. ‘The rhetoric and reality of
London: Anglo German Foundation. total quality management.’ Administrative
Walsh, James P., and James K. Seward. 1990. Science Quarterly, 43: 602–636.
‘On the efficiency of internal and external Ziegler, J. N. 2000. ‘Corporate governance and
corporate control mechanisms.’ Academy of the politics of property rights in Germany.’
Management Review, 15: 421–458. Politics & Society, 28: 195–221.
Westphal, James D., and Edward J. Zajac. Zilber, T. 2006. The work of the symbolic in
1994. ‘Substance and symbolism in CEO’s institutional processes: Translations of
long-term incentive plans.’ Administrative rational myths in Israeli high tech. Academy
Science Quarterly, 39: 367–390. of Management Journal, 49: 281–303.
Whitley, Richard. 1992a. Business Systems in Zingales, Luigi. 1998. ‘Corporate governance’
East Asia: Firms, Markets, and Societies. in P. Newman (ed.), The New Palgrave
London: Sage. Dictionary of Economics and the Law.
Whitley, Richard 1992b. European Business New York, NY: Macmillan.
Systems: Firms and Markets in their National Zucker, Lynne G. 1977. ‘The role of institution-
Contexts. London: Sage. alization in cultural persistence.’ American
Whitley, Richard. 1999. Divergent Capitalisms: Sociological Review, 42: 726–743.
The Social Structuring and Change of Business Zucker, Lynne G. 1988. Institutional Patterns
Systems. Oxford: Oxford University Press. and Organizations: Culture and Environ-
Williamson, Oliver. 1981. ‘The modern corpora- ment. Cambridge, MA: Ballinger.
tion: Origins, evolution, attributes.’ Journal of Zuckerman, Ezra. 1999. ‘The categorical imper-
Economic Literature, 19: 1537–1568. ative: Securities analysts and the illegitimacy
Williamson, Oliver. 1988. ‘Corporate finance discount.’ American Journal of Sociology,
and corporate governance.’ Journal of 104: 1398–438.
Finance, 43: 567–591. Zuckerman, Ezra. 2000. ‘Focusing the corpo-
Williamson, Oliver. 2000. ‘The new institutional rate product: Securities analysts and de-
economics: Taking stock, looking ahead.’ diversification.’ Administrative Science
Journal of Economic Literature, 38: 595–613. Quarterly, 45: 591–619.
SECTION IV

Interfaces
16
Beyond Constraint: How
Institutions Enable Identities
Mary Ann Glynn

INTRODUCTION and governs organizational performance.


Finally, implications for future research are
In this chapter, I take a perspective on insti- offered.
tutional theory that moves beyond constraint. Identity is a construct that has long been
I look at how institutions enable organiza- central to institutional theorizing. A half-cen-
tional identity construction by supplying a tury ago, Selznick (1957) postulated that
set of possible legitimate identity elements institutionalization – the infusion of value in
with which to construct, give meaning to, and organizations – ‘produces a distinct identity
legitimize identities and identity symbols. for the organization’ (p. 40) and, moreover,
Institutionalism offers a process model of that ‘maintaining this distinctive identity is
transformational mechanisms that explicates integral to institutional survival’ (p. 63).
how macro-level, interorganizational influ- Institutional approaches that focus on the
ences situate and shape organizational identi- cognitive-normative context of organizations
ties. It can account for the regularity or (DiMaggio & Powell, 1991; Zucker, 1983)
patterning of identity markers (or symbols) have emphasized the importance of social
across organizations within an organizational identities (Scott, 1995: 44) as well as their
field. As well, it offers a dynamic frame- vitality. And yet, in spite of this acknowl-
work on organizational identity construction edged relationship, the link between institu-
which explains how organizations may tional theorizing and organizational identity
adapt their identities so as to align with sanc- remains relatively unexplored. The gap is
tioned norms and practices so as to secure surprising, for the two theories have much in
legitimacy. I explore how institutionalism common. Both institutionalism and identity
expands the current theorization of identity have meaning at their core; as well, both
by deepening our understanding of the theories offer accounts of the creation and
essence of identity, offering a reconcepu- role of meaning in the constitution and
talization of organizational identity as a practices of organizations. How then can two
form of institutional bricolage, and by ex- theories so similar in their focus be so
planing how the logic of identity motivates different in their trajectories?
414 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

In the current literature, there is little inte- In this chapter, I initiate an exploration of
gration of the two perspectives; worse, they the linkage between institutions and organi-
are often depicted as almost antithetical. For zational identity. Because the limiting effects
instance, institutional theory appears to priv- of institutional isomorphism are well recog-
ilege sameness and isomorphism, while orga- nized, I seek to move beyond this model of
nizational identity theory advantages constraint to explore an alternative model of
distinctiveness and polymorphism; and, how institutions enable organizational iden-
while institutional theory focuses on the tity. Essentially, I propose that institutional-
inter-organizational level of organizational ism enables organizational identity formation
fields or industries, identity theory tends to by supplying a set of possible legitimate
be grounded in the organizational level identity elements with which to construct,
(Pedersen & Dobbin, 2006). give meaning to, and legitimize firm identi-
And yet, in spite of these obvious differ- ties and symbolization.
ences, there are subtle points of connection Even though institutional structures and
that offer opportune sites where institutional- environments tend to sanction some kinds of
ism can broaden theories of organizational meanings and elements over others, they are
identity. For instance, institutionalism offers nonetheless complex and multi-textured in
a process model of transformational mecha- meaning, thereby making some variation in
nisms that explicate how macro-level, inter- identities possible. Swidler (2001) illustrates
organizational influences situate and shape the wealth of meanings that are attached to, and
organizational identities. Moreover, through legitimated in, a single institution: marriage.
transformational processes of isomorphic Weber and Glynn (2006) extend this reasoning
conformity and mimesis, institutionalism to the employment contract, arguing that sense-
offers an account for the regularity or pat- making occurs with institutions, not in spite of
terning of identity markers (or symbols) them. And Pedersen and Dobbin (1997: 432)
across organizations within an organizational apply this argument to their discussion of insti-
field. And, institutionalism offers a dynamic tutions and organizational culture; similarly,
framework on organizational identity they see institutions as having a dual role in the
construction which explains how organiza- construction of organizational cultures, one that
tions may adapt their identities so as to align is both constraining and enabling:
with sanctioned norms and practices in order … modern collective actors seek formal isomor-
to secure legitimacy. phism with other actors to classify themselves and
Institutionalism can move the study of informal distinctiveness to enumerate themselves.
identity beyond the organizational level of Enumeration … as integral to this process as was
classification … the naming of the bright planet
analysis to locate identity in broader frames
Venus to distinguish it from the star Polaris and of
of meaning that arise from industry, cultural Halley’s Comet to distinguish it from planets. …
and societal institutions. And, although iso- the method called for naming or numbering par-
morphic pressures can constrain the choices ticular isomorphic units to the end of identifying
of elements that organizations use to con- and differentiating them for study … Enumeration
established the empirical cases from which gener-
struct their identities, institutional forces also
alizations could be drawn. (434).
enable the process of identity construction
itself. The institutional environment supplies Pedersen and Dobbin (2006) offer an inte-
possible and legitimated meanings and sym- gration of the competing and contradictory
bols that constitute the ‘raw materials’ which forces that are implicated by institutionalism
organizations appropriate to construct their and identity construction. In their view, con-
identities. By grafting these institutional formity occurs at the more macro-level of
elements onto their identities, organizations social classification, resulting in broad simi-
attempt to garner legitimacy which enables larities and regularities in patterns of organiza-
resource flows favorable to their enterprises. tional identities that, in the aggregate,
BEYOND CONSTRAINT: HOW INSTITUTIONS ENABLE IDENTITIES 415

constitute a classification system for identi- domains of scholarship, inquiry into organi-
ties. This is apparent, for instance, in organiza- zational identity was launched with vigor
tional naming patterns over time (within when Albert and Whetten published their
historical periods) and in dominant industry influential Research in Organizational
naming practices; First Federal Bank is pre- Behavior article in 1985. Their theorization
ferred to (and legitimated) rather than Tony’s of identity has been quite impactful, receiv-
Bank (Glynn & Abzug, 2002; Glynn & ing nearly 500 citations as of this writing.
Marquis, 2005). And yet, institutions are not My search on widely used databases (e.g.,
perfectly replicated in organizational adoption ABI Inform; Google Scholar) did not yield
and practices; variations arise from the slip- any articles on organizational identity in
page that occurs as institutions adapt to local major management or organizational
conditions or are interpreted in particular con- journals prior to this 1985 publication.
texts to reflect specific organizational mean- The first article of significance to manage-
ings. Within the banking category, for ment researchers appeared five years later in
instance, not only is First Federal Bank legiti- the Academy of Management Journal:
mate, but also Bank of America, Citizens Dutton and Dukerich’s (1990) influential
Bank and Sun Trust Bank. Thus, variations (and award-winning) case study of the NY
arise even from a more standardized set of Port Authority (also with about 500 citations,
constitutive rules that define identities. Thus, as of this writing).
as Pedersen and Dobbin (2006) might predict, Research on organizational identity has
there are broad boundaries that circumscribe demonstrated its significance for a number of
the appropriate elements of identities within key organizational symbols, processes, and
social categories (such as banking organiza- behaviors. Organizational symbols and
tions), but enumeration processes within cate- structures have been shown to reflect organi-
gories that serve to distinguish one bank from zational identity globally (e.g., Glynn &
another. Thus, organizations construct stylized Abzug, 2002) and stakeholder interests more
identities from distinctive institutions in their specifically (e.g., Pratt & Foreman, 2000;
business, social and cultural environments. Scott & Lane, 2000; Brickson, 2005), to
In this chapter, I explore how institutions compartmentalize different or antithetical
enable organizational identities. I start by aspects of identity, by functional or
reviewing the relevant literature to discover professional differentiation (e.g., Glynn,
how organizational identity has been concep- 2000; Golden-Biddle & Rao, 1997; Pratt
tualized and opportunities where institution- & Rafaeli, 1997; Pratt, Rockmann &
alism might inform current theorization. Kaufmann, 2006) or hierarchy (Corley &
Next, I elaborate some specific ways in Gioia, 2004), to motivate the choice of
which institutions enable identities; these organizational aspiration and emulation
include a deepening of our understanding of (e.g., LaBianca et al., 2001), and to be con-
essential elements of identity, a reconceptu- structed as a storied account of organiza-
alization of organizational identity as a form tional history and biography through
of institutional bricolage, and a consideration language and rhetoric (e.g, Czarniawska &
of how institutional logics encourage identity Wolff, 1998; Fiol, 2001, 2002). As well,
performance in organizations. researchers have also focused on individuals’
identification with the organization, which is
at least partly construed by their perceptions
THEORIZATIONS OF of the organizational identity, particularly in
ORGANIZATIONAL IDENTITY terms of its distinctiveness and prestige
(e.g., Mael & Ashforth, 1992; Bhattacharya,
Although the construct of identity has had a Rao & Glynn, 1995; Brickson, 2005;
long intellectual history in several different Bartel, 2001).
416 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Through these twenty years of research, simply identity (checking to see that
the original definition of organizational iden- the latter focused on the level of the
tity articulated by Albert and Whetten (1985) organization). This yielded a total of 32
persists, reverberating through other studies articles, of which roughly one-quarter are
and models. Albert and Whetten described empirical.
organizational identity as consisting of three As I read (and re-read) these articles, two
claims: ‘the criterion of claimed central distinctive approaches to identity clearly
character … the criterion of claimed distinc- emerged. One of these follows directly from
tiveness … [and] the criterion of claimed the Albert and Whetten (1985) definition:
temporal continuity’ (Albert & Whetten, identity as ‘essentialist’ and attribute-based,
1985: 265). The dominant approach models i.e., reflecting some underlying or ‘true’
organizational identity as a claim-making organizational character. A second approach
process that centers on three core attributes: tends to focus on how identity functions as a
the central, distinctive and enduring charac- strategic resource, being deployed to com-
ter of the organization (Glynn, 2000). petitive advantage and functioning as a guide
Researchers have focused as much on the to firm decision-making and strategic choice.
particular attributes themselves as the I categorized the articles on organizational
processes that underlie them. Moreover, identity using these two dominant
while the attribute-based perspective has approaches: identity as attribute-based and
commanded the focus of researchers, it does identity as strategic orientation. And, because
not have consensual affirmation (e.g., Corley I was interested in linking organizational
et al., 2006). Although the model itself is identity to institutional theory, I added a third
rarely contested, its three core attributes are, category: an institutional approach to organi-
particularly in terms of their degree of cen- zational identity. I categorized articles as
trality, distinctiveness and durability over having an institutional approach when they
time (e.g., Gioia, Schultz & Corley, 2000). invoked any institutional elements or expla-
And yet, reflecting on these two decades of nations (explicitly or implicitly) in account-
identity research, post-Albert and Whetten ing for organizational identity, such as
(1985), Corley and colleagues (2006) find ideological fault lines that hybridize identity,
some convergence around the nature of these status groupings and emulation/mimesis, or
attributes. In addition, they note the persist- roles for the professions and elites in identity
ence and dominance of the Albert and dynamics (e.g., a family-oriented firm, a reli-
Whetten (1985) formulation of organiza- gious organization).
tional identity in the literature. More generally, in categorizing work on
To get a more nuanced understanding of organizational identity as institutional in
current models of organizational identity, and approach, I looked for any indications of what
to examine what, if any, linkages to institu- Cerulo (1997: 387) describes as a sociologi-
tionalism are evident, I reviewed the relevant cal approach. This centers on the social con-
management and organizational literature struction of identity such that: ‘every
from 1985 on. I searched for articles whose collective becomes a social artifact – an entity
primary focus was organizational identity molded, refabricated, and mobilized in accord
using several electronic data bases (e.g., ABI with reigning cultural scripts and centers of
inform, ProQuest, Google scholar, Business power.’ Cerulo (1997) and others (e.g.,
Source Complete), as well as my own read- Czarniawski & Wolff, 1998) have categorized
ing of the literature. I began with work pub- this perspective as anti-essentialist, in that it
lished in 1985 and continued through 2006, places less emphasis on the unique character
identifying relevant publications using key- or attributes of organizations and more on
word searches on ‘organization identity’ and organizations’ constructions of their position
its variants, e.g., organizational identity or in the social order or institutional field.
BEYOND CONSTRAINT: HOW INSTITUTIONS ENABLE IDENTITIES 417

The results of my literature review, with Finally, there was some evidence of an insti-
lists of the relevant articles, publication dates tutional perspective on organizational iden-
and their primary approaches, are presented tity, but it was clearly in the minority; only
in Table 16.1. Of the 32 published articles I seven articles (22 percent) explicitly adopted
located on organizational identity, three- an institutional perspective while another
quarters (24 articles or 75 percent) use an five (16 percent) seemed to use institutional
attribute-based perspective. One-third of the ideas implicitly (indicated by # in the Table).
identity articles (11 articles or 34 percent) Thus, it seems that organizational identity
took a strategic perspective on identity; of researchers have emphasized an attribute-
these, nearly two-thirds (7 articles or 64 based construal of identity in terms of its
percent) also used an essentialist approach. core ‘essence,’ i.e., the central, distinctive

Table 16.1 Organizational identity approaches in the management literature, 1985–2006


Publication Attribute-
Author(s) Date outlet a based Strategic Institutional
Albert & Whetten 1985 ROB X
Fiol 1991 JM X X
Dutton & Dukerich 1991 AMJ X X
Dutton, Dukerich & Harquail 1994 ASQ X
Reger 1994 AMJ X
Sarason 1995 AMJ X X
Gustafson & Reger 1995 AMJ X X
Elsbach & Kramer 1996 ASQ X #
Gioia & Thomas 1996 ASQ X X
Golden-Biddle & Rao 1997 OS X
Pratt & Rafaeli 1997 AMJ X
Czarniawska & Wolff 1998 IS X
Fox-Wolfgramm, Boal & Hunt 1998 ASQ X X
Albert, Ashforth & Dutton 2000 AMR X
Pratt & Foreman 2000 AMR X #
Rao, Davis & Ward 2000 ASQ X
Scott & Lane 2000 AMR X
Gioia, Schultz & Corley 2000 AMR X
Glynn 2000 OS X X
Glynn & Abzug 2002 AMJ X
Fiol 2001 JM X #
LaBianca et al. 2001 OS X #
Lounsbury & Glynn 2001 SMJ X X
Fiol 2002 OS X
Hatch & Schultz 2002 HR X
Whetten & Mackey 2002 Business & Society X X
Corley 2004 HR X
Corley & Gioia 2004 ASQ X X
Brickson 2005 ASQ X
Hsu & Hannan 2005 OSb
Ravasi & Schultz 2006 AMJ X
Martins 2006 OS X X #
TOTALS (counts of X’s) 32 24 (75%) 11 (34%) 7 (22%)
Notes: aASQ = Administrative Science Quarterly; AMJ = Academy of Management Journal; AMR = Academy of
Management Review; HR = Human Relations; IS = International Studies of Management & Organization; JM = Journal of
Management; OS = Organization Science; ROB = Research in Organizational Behavior.
b
Population Ecology Framework.
Legend: X denotes an explicit theoretical focus; # denotes an implied theoretical focus
418 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

and enduring elements that Albert and crafting identity (e.g., Lounsbury & Glynn,
Whetten (1985) proposed. This dominant 2001).
approach seems to be consistent with what The relatively less attention given to insti-
psychologists label a ‘personal’ identity, one tutional theory in the organizational identity
that tends to be more individualistic, unique, literature is ironic, because these two perspec-
and idiosyncratic rather than a ‘social’ iden- tives are intertwined. Several institutionalists
tity that classifies identities using socially recognize this connection. For instance,
constructed systems of meaning. The empha- Pedersen and Dobbin (2006: 897) observe:
sis on the more individualistic aspects of ‘Formation of identity through uniqueness
organizational identity seems to have and construction of legitimacy through uni-
emerged in spite of explicit theorizing about formity are two sides of the same coin.’ Scott
the relevance of social identity theory to (1995: 22) remarks that ‘identity theory’ (at
organizations (e.g., Ashforth & Mael, 1989). the individual level) emerged as a corrective
With regard to the strategic approach, to an over-socialized view, modeling an
researchers have theorized organizational active and reflective self that creates, sus-
identity as an ‘imitable strategic resource’ that tains, and changes social structures; he writes
lends competitive advantage (Fiol, 1991). ‘Identities are viewed as “shared social mean-
Scholars have shown empirically that organi- ings that persons attribute to themselves in a
zational identity functions as a filter for inter- role” … (they) are socially produced by actors
preting and responding to strategic issues and who locate themselves in social categories
environmental changes (e.g., Dutton & and interact with others in terms of these cat-
Dukerich, 1991; Elsbach & Kramer, 1996; egories’; ‘self-meanings’ that are acquired in
Gioia & Thomas, 1996; Gusftafson & Reger, specific situations, and symbolically defined
1995; Fox-Wolfgramm, Boal & Hunt, 1998), and reflexively managed. In the next section,
shapes organizational units and professional I try to rebuild this connection by offering
groups’ claims to strategic resources (Glynn, ideas on how institutional theory might
2000), affects strategic response to institu- inform research on organizational identity.
tional (regulatory) change (e.g., Fox-
Wolfgramm et al., 1998), and is the result of
strategic change, such as mergers (e.g.,
Corley & Gioia, 2005). The strategic INSTITUTIONS AND IDENTITY IN
approach seems to have found a basis in the ORGANIZATIONS
notion of identity ‘claim’: Ashforth and Mael
(1996) explicitly state that ‘claim’ relates It seems that the central question of iden-
organizational identity to strategy, and Porac, tity – Who are we as an organization? – has
Wade and Pollock’s (1999) definition of iden- been answered in the existing literature
tity construction as ‘an explicit claim that an primarily in terms of an individuated and
organization is of a particular type.’ distinctive constellation of attributes
Only infrequently has organizational iden- (see Table 16.1). The focus is on naming the
tity been theorized explicitly in terms of the central, distinctive and enduring attributes
institutional dynamics and environment that define the ‘essence’ of the organization.
which embed organizations. This work tends Organizational identity thus becomes a claim
to paint institutional forces in terms of broad of uniqueness and a point of strategic differ-
strokes (e.g., Glynn, 2000; Czarniawska & entiation from other organizational actors in a
Wolff, 1999) that emphasize isomorphic field or market. Cerulo (1987), in her review
pressures towards conformity and constraint of the literature on the sociology of identity,
(Fox-Wolfgramm et al., 1998; Glynn & cogently describes the essentialist approach:
Abzug, 2002). Less evident are the more ‘natural’ or ‘essential’ characteristics [are those]
enabling aspects of institutionalism in qualities emerging from physiological traits,
BEYOND CONSTRAINT: HOW INSTITUTIONS ENABLE IDENTITIES 419

psychological predispositions, regional features, or resistance to the institutional change; they


the properties of structural locations. A collective’s proposed that ‘Organizations whose identity
members were believed to internalize these
and image are inconsistent with institutional
qualities, suggesting a unified, singular social
experience, a single canvas against which social pressures for change will resist change
actors constructed a sense of self (Cerulo, 1997: attempts’ (Proposition 1) and, in turn, that
386–387). ‘Evidence of organizational success will be
used to reinforce and justify an organiza-
An institutional answer to the identity tion’s identity’ (Proposition 2).
question (posed above) would not be in terms In their studies of organizational names,
of an organization’s essence but, rather, in Glynn, with Abzug (1998, 2002) and with
terms of an organization’s membership in a Marquis (2004; 2006), showed how key
social category. Identity, according to institu- markers of organizational identity (organiza-
tionalists, is a set of claims to a social tional names) are embedded within institu-
category, such as an industry grouping, a tional fields. Additionally, they showed that
status ranking or an interest set. And so, an identity isomorphism legitimates – names
organization might be identified as a Top 20 that closely resemble the institutionalized
school, a Fortune 500 firm, or a hospital (and template tend to be more comprehensible
not a bank), for instance. Thus, institutional- (Glynn & Abzug, 1998, 2002) – but that
ists focus on claimed similarity (to other external changes in institutional environ-
category members) as the basis of identity ments can change legitimacy dynamics and,
and institutional alignment with the prevail- in turn, affect organizational survival (Glynn
ing constitutive rules that are used to define & Marquis, 2004). In an extension, Glynn
identity. and Marquis (2006) show that isomorphism
A number of organizational identity may not have universal appeal; rather, that
researchers offer some telling glimpses into individuals have differing preferences for
how institutions – and processes of institu- conformity and differ in the extent to which
tionalization – might surface more fully in they see institutionally isomorphic names as
the dynamics of identity construction, legitimate.
change, and performance. For instance, Structural accounts of organizational
Czarniawska and Wolff (1998) contrast the identity direct attention to the relational,
essentialist (psychologically-grounded) positional and embedded influences that can
approach with more sociological or stem from institutional environments. Here,
structuralist approaches. These authors identity is conceptualized as an actor’s posi-
conducted case studies of two universities tion or role within an established set of
and concluded that identities (and their categories that define an industry, social net-
successes or failures) are shaped in work or labor market, rather than a set of
institutional fields. Their work supports the essential attributes. For instance, Zuckerman,
central tenet of institutional theory, that Kim, Ukana, and von Rittmann (2003) define
isomorphism legitimates but allows for identities in terms of a movie actor’s abilities
limited cases of organizational deviance or skills to signal their membership in one
from institutionalized and legitimated particular film genre (a simple or ‘focused’
templates. identity) or several genres (a complex or
Fox-Wolfgramm et al. (1998) conducted a ‘robust’ identity). Rao, Monin, and Durand
longitudinal case study of two banks, exam- (2003) studied how identity movements,
ining the organizational response to regula- which they define as arising ‘in opposition to
tory change in banking. They found that the dominant cultural codes, [and] consist of
organizational identity, which was linked to a “we-feeling” sustained through interactions
strategic posture (Defender or Prospector), among movement participants’ (p. 796),
affected an organization’s compliance or drove changes in French cuisine over time by
420 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

generating identity-discrepant cues that led of institutional bricolage, where an identity is


chefs to abandon the old institutional logics cobbled together from existing elements or
and role identities and embrace the new. bits of meaning, symbols or values:
Thus, from the few studies that do attend Organizations appropriate bits of institu-
to how institutions surface in organizational tional understandings but combine (and
identity, we can see that they shift the focus recombine) them in institutionally
and dynamics of theorizing identity. Viewing sanctioned ways so as to introduce varia-
organizational identity through an institu- tions. Organizations combine similar institu-
tional lens directs attention to the social tionally-based identity elements in different
meanings and structures that embed organi- configurations so as to make their identities
zational identities and induce conformity. distinct from each other within organiza-
This perspective offers a counterpoint to the tional fields but similar enough within a field
prevailing theories of identity that tend to so as to make their membership claims (to
characterize it in terms of essential central, the field) legitimate. Thus, organizational
distinctive, and enduring attributes (e.g., identities function in ways that are similar
Albert & Whetten, 1985). A focus on to those of individuals in that they seek
institutional isomorphism is particularly ‘optimal distinctiveness’ (Brewer, 1993)
salient for non-instrumental or symbolic within institutionally-bounded social
aspects of organizations (Oliver, 1991), espe- categories.
cially identity (Glynn & Abzug, 1998, 2002; Third, institutions enable not only organi-
Glynn & Marquis, 2004). And, because it zational claims of identity but also their
complements the essentialist and strategic enactment or implementation. The institu-
approaches to organizational identity, it tional elements that organizations appropri-
offers the promise of a more comprehensive ate to construct their identities embed not
approach to organizational identity. only meanings but also performance scripts,
For the remainder of this chapter, I focus i.e., normative guidelines on organizational
on three distinct ways in which institutions appropriateness that inform action and insti-
can enable organizational identity. First, in tutional logics that rationalize action. Thus
theorizing identity, institutionalism supplies action can be as much a part of identity
a complementary explanation to essentialism dynamics as meaning, symbolism and strate-
that is not entirely organization-centric. gizing; this is an important way in which
Rather, institutional suggests that it is the institutions can extend current theorizations
social embeddedness of the individual of identity, which tend to focus more on
identity elements that accounts for why these meaning and change rather than the action or
elements matter, when they matter, how they performance imperatives of identity. I dis-
might develop, evolve and change over time, cuss each of these three aspects whereby
and how they complement (or conflict with) institutions enable identity.
each other. Thus, institutional theory can
deepen dominant theories of organizational
identity by illuminating the processes by Institutionalizing the essence of
which organizations construct the essence of
identity
their identity, i.e., their central, distinctive,
and enduring character (Albert & Whetten, Building from the identity framework that
1985). has dominated the literature (Albert &
Second, institutions (and associated Whetten, 1985), I examine how institutional
institutional meanings and symbols) provide theory might be useful in deepening the indi-
the raw material from which organizational vidual elements of organizational identity.
identities are constructed. And so, organiza- Albert and Whetten (1985) treat organiza-
tional identity construction becomes a form tional identity as a trinity, composed of three
BEYOND CONSTRAINT: HOW INSTITUTIONS ENABLE IDENTITIES 421

key criteria, that ‘of central character, becomes a social artifact – an entity molded, refab-
distinctiveness, and temporal continuity’ ricated, and mobilized in accord with reigning cul-
tural scripts and centers of power. (387)
with ‘each necessary, and as a set sufficient’
as an adequate statement of identity (p. 265). In a study of identity claim-making
I consider each of these three elements during the musicians’ strike at the Atlanta
in turn. Symphony Orchestra, Glynn (2000) showed
how the core of organizational identity was
Identity as central contested by the two major professional
The first of the three identity elements, that groups in the orchestra: musicians and
of claimed central character, describes the administrators. Each advanced claims to a
very ‘essence’ of an identity and is used by particular identity, each attached to identity a
leaders ‘as a guide for what they should do different core ideology, i.e., aestheticism (in
and how other institutions should relate to musical performance) versus economics (in
them’ (Albert & Whetten, 1985: 267, fiscal responsibility). The study highlights
emphases added). Thus, even the essential- how identity can be a source of mobilization,
ism of centrality, it seems, implies an inter- rather than just a product of it; this differs
organizational (and perhaps institutional) from the dominant view which tends to
environment which enrobes the organization. model the organization’s central character as
A more explicit statement on central emerging from its founding, historical trajec-
character is made by Brickson (2005) in her tory and a shared or collective view of the
model of identity orientation. She describes organization. Hybridization of identity, in
this as a particular posture towards individu- complex organizations like a symphony,
alism, relationalism or collectivism; she con- shows how a single organization may have a
tends that this attribute will always be one of multiplicity of claims on its central character.
the characteristics defined as central, distinc- In many ways, then, even the core charac-
tive and continuous as an identity element. ter of organizational identities implies insti-
Note how this typology of identity orienta- tutional space and a set of social categories
tions, with its ‘isms,’ has ideological roots that offer meaningful ways of describing
that position the actor (the self or the organizations (e.g., as a church or a business,
organization) both in a social environment as Albert and Whetten suggest). These
and in relation to others. categories (or their typifications) are defined
Even the core element of centrality seems by a set of symbolic boundaries that function
to hinge the organizational identity to the in the construction of valued identities
inter-organizational or institutional environ- (Lamont, 1992). Moreover, boundary
ment. Albert and Whetten (1985) suggest that strength, i.e., only those boundaries firmly
identity locates organizations in social or grounded in widely shared meaning,
institutional space. Their fundamental notion prove sufficiently strong to generate hierar-
of identity as an organizational claim hints at chy and confer value to collective identities
a collective’s basic struggle to self-name, (Lamont, 1992).
self-characterize and assert social preroga- Thus, institutionally-based categories can
tive and raise questions about the viability of describe cultural repertoires of meaning that
‘essentialism’ in identity construction organizations can appropriate to address the
(Cerulo, 1997); Cerulo (1997) writes of an question of ‘who we are.’ The response
anti-essentialist perspective, which implies simultaneously characterizes their central
institutionalism: character but also classifies them as a
member of one organizational field and not
Recent treatments of collective identity question
the essentialism of collective attributes and of others; category partitions (or boundaries)
images. Anti-essentialist inquiries promote the distinguish them from other organizations
social construction of identity … every collective or social communities. Even as a claimed
422 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

central character may reflect core organiza- that is claimed is relative to a particular cate-
tional values or strengths (e.g., integrity, fair gory of organizations (e.g., Top 20 Business
trade, technology leader, customer-oriented, Week list). Other scholars have shown how
family friendly, etc.), it nonetheless identities have a reciprocal relationship with
implicates a set of institutional categories the external image of the organization
and boundaries from which this character (e.g., Dutton, Dukerich & Harquail, 1994;
draws meaning. In many ways, then, this Gioia, Schultz & Corley, 2000; Gioia &
seems to have been an under-specified Corley, 2002), with identities shifting so as to
aspect of organizational identity that institu- enhance their reputation with important
tionalism might help to explain. stakeholders. Working at a different level of
analysis, organizational ecologists also attest
Identity as distinctive to how identities are ‘conferred by an audi-
Identity distinctiveness and prestige surface ence’ (Hsu & Hannan, 2005: 478) in an effort
in several studies conducted at the individual to garner stakeholder acceptability.
level of analysis that examine organizational Implicit in identity distinctiveness is not
members’ perceptions of, and identification only the enhancement of the reputation or
with, their organizations. Mael and Ashforth image of the organization, but also cues that
(1992) studied the antecedents of alumni’s enable external audiences to perceive the
identification with their organization, a organization as legitimate and appropriate; if
religious college, and found that it was organizations are perceived to conform to
positively influenced by their perceptions of desirable identity categories, then stakehold-
organizational distinctiveness and prestige. ers tend to sanction that organization and
They concluded: resource flows are beneficial. The process of
In general, symbolic management can be directed
identity distinctiveness is the flip side of
towards increasing the salience of the institution isomorphism (or conformity to institutional
as an institution, complete with a unique and com- forces), as Pedersen and Dobbin (1997: 432)
pelling mission and a reputation for fulfilling that have pointed out in their description of
mission. (Mael & Ashforth, 1992: 14, emphasis in enumeration.
the original)
Institutionalists ground the notion of iden-
Similarly, Bhattacharya, Rao and Glynn tity distinctiveness within processes of
(1995), in a survey of art museum member- isomorphism; distinctiveness (or enumera-
ship, found that fee-paying members’ identi- tion) occurs within identity categories, as
fication is positively related to perceived organizations distinguish themselves from
organizational prestige. Thus, as much as other members of the class. However,
distinction serves to differentiate one organi- distinctiveness does not occur in an institu-
zation from another, it also seems to function tional vacuum; isomorphism not only
as a touchstone for individuals’ identification legitimates but it encourages differentiation
with the organization and its identity; for and the distinctiveness which can follow.
both individuals and organizations, such Further, this institutional explanation of
distinctiveness can enhance perceptions of identity distinctiveness can illuminate the
the self. relationship among the three core identity
Organizational identity researchers have elements, suggesting a possible hierarchy
examined how identities respond to status of distinctiveness embedded within claims of
rankings, particularly those by external third central character.
parties. Elsbach and Kramer (1996) show how
business schools can shift the bases of their Identity as enduring
distinctive character to preserve their prestige Of the three identity elements articulated by
and esteem in response to a drop in the Albert and Whetten (1985), the claimed tem-
Business Week rankings; the distinctiveness poral continuity or durability of identity has
BEYOND CONSTRAINT: HOW INSTITUTIONS ENABLE IDENTITIES 423

perhaps been the most contested by other it does tend to set the limits on the scope and
researchers. Gioia, Schultz and Corley scale of this change. Pedersen and Dobbin
(2000) characterized organizational identity (1997: 436) note that the notion of change
as having ‘adaptive instability,’ changing in and differentiation itself has been institution-
response to others’ images of the organiza- alized and so identity change tends to occur
tion. They argue that identity continuity within narrowly defined categorical bound-
implies flexibility (instability) with regard to aries: ‘Presidents and kings actively distin-
a core central character, as external guished their nation-states from others, but
audiences can destabilize identity, causing they did so in routine ways. The dimensions
the organization to reconsider the framing or of identity were clearly institutionalized.’
constitution of its identity. Subsequent work The preceding section illuminated some of
by two of these authors (Corley & Gioia, the ways in which institutions are implicated
2004) examines identity change processes in current theories of organizational identity
during the strategic change of a corporate and particularly in each of its core identity
spin-off; they find that identity change does elements – central character, distinc-
occur and that the organizational leadership tiveness and temporal continuity. The con-
has to manage that change. struction of the organization’s identity also
Other challenges to the enduring nature of implies the construction of a social actor
identity arise from Biggart’s (1977) study of through a process of categorization (that
the US Postal Service and Fiol’s (2002) study form the basis of claimed central character),
of a high technology company. Both of these enumeration (that forms the basis of distinc-
researchers demonstrate that previously tiveness), and isomorphic alignment that
valued aspects of the organization’s identity legitimates (that forms the basis of continuity
had to be discredited before employees could and change).
buy into a new way of approaching their
business, thus requiring a changing identity.
Similarly, Reger et al. (1994) observed that a Organizational identity as a form of
fundamental organizational change, such as
institutional bricolage
the implementation of a total quality initia-
tive, required a fundamental change in how Although organizations can construct identi-
the organization thought of itself. Rao, ties that reflect their central and distinctive
Monin and Durand (2003) demonstrated how attributes, they typically do so with compo-
identity movements that opposed the old nents available in their institutional environ-
institutional logics were essential to the con- ment, i.e., the industry, organizational field,
struction of new role identities. And Hatch societal culture and/or the nation-state. For
and Schultz (2002) proposed a model of instance, Glynn and Abzug (2002) found that
organizational identity dynamics that organizations changing their names made
specified processes by which organizational choices that aligned them with prevailing
identity emerges from the unending conver- institutional practices and templates; Fred’s
sations that occur between members of an Bank was as unlikely a choice to name an
organizational culture and its many organization’s identity as First Federal Pizza.
stakeholders. In narrating the identity of their new ven-
Researchers have challenged Albert and tures, Lounsbury and Glynn (2001) found
Whetten’s (1985) identity element of tempo- that entrepreneurs employ elements from
ral continuity and have done so by mapping widespread identity stories as ‘raw material’
changes that arise from the organization’s when negotiating their emerging identities.
strategic, industry and institutional environ- More generally, people can be artful in their
ments. However, as much as institutional mobilization of different institutional logics
change may prompt organizational change, to serve their purpose (Westenholz, 2006).
424 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Symbols that ‘mark’ an organization’s core identity elements. Thus, the process of iden-
identity as central (or even unique) ironically tity construction becomes the process of
are often composed of common components institutional bricolage, where organizations
established within organization fields. Glynn incorporate cultural meanings, values, senti-
and Abzug (1998; 2002) demonstrated this in ments and rules into their identity claims.
their studies of the names that organizations Identities can thus be bricolaged or cob-
chose to adopt when they changed their name; bled together from shared cultural elements
they examined the explanatory power of an and symbols and it is in this way that they
institutional view (predicting symbolic iso- can come to resemble each other. Although
morphism) and a strategic view (predicting there may be shared elements, they are
uniqueness). They found robust effects for nonetheless combined in fairly unique and
institutional predictions. distinctive ways. In this manner, then, organ-
Relatedly, in work on organizational cul- izations can accommodate both central and
tures, Martin, Feldman, Hatch and Sitkin distinctive elements by claiming uniqueness
(1983) make a similar point: ‘Organizations but doing so with innovative combinations of
claim uniqueness, but at any point in time, institutionalized elements. Moreover,
organizations claim similar sorts of unique- although identities are constructed from
ness’ (p. 901). These authors observed that shared cultural models, they are negotiated in
‘Building blocks of conscious organizational the organization and in the organizational
culture often come from the environment, with field (Westenholz, Pedersen & Dobbin,
the result that distinctive organizational cul- 2006). Moreover, the very process of brico-
tures can be surprisingly similar to one another lage, whereby different elements are con-
at any point in time’ (p. 901). A similar view is joined, carries implications for the both the
echoed in work describing the uniqueness par- distinctive and enduring aspects of identities.
adox in organizational stories (e.g., Martin, When organizations appropriate institutional
Feldman, Hatch & Sitkin, 1983); organizations elements from different – and especially
may claim a central and unique narrative, but oppositional categories – they can erode the
they tend to be similar (or isomorphic) to other boundaries that compartmentalize these ele-
organizations in the very claim that they make. ments and thus blunt distinctiveness. Rao,
Future research on organizational identity Moniin and Durand (2005) describe such
might advance our understanding on the erosion in the context of nouvelle and classi-
wider models in the institutional field from cal cuisines’ boundaries becoming under-
which organizational identities are con- mined by innovative appropriation. Glynn
structed. It would be of interest to examine and Lounsbury (2005) similarly provide an
whether organizations draw their identity’s account of such blending processes for the
central, distinctive and enduring characters symphony’s repertoire in appropriate pieces
from more local environments (such as from both the traditional musical canon as
industry or geographic clusters), from more well as more contemporary art forms. Thus,
distal or universal environments (such as the process of identity construction comes to
nation-states or global trends), or from some resemble a process of institutional bricolage,
combination of both. Some of these cultural the elements and processes of which invite
models available are what Pedersen and closer scrutiny by future identity researchers.
Dobbin (2006) describe: ‘The appropriate
cultural artifacts of identity formation were
traditions (e.g., language, couture, cuisine) Identity not only as claims, but
and newly created symbols (e.g., flags,
performance
anthems, constitutions).’ As Swidler (1986)
reminds us, culture serves as a kind of Although the focus in the organizational
‘toolkit’ from which organizations can draw identity literature has been on claim-making,
BEYOND CONSTRAINT: HOW INSTITUTIONS ENABLE IDENTITIES 425

institutionalism alerts us to another dimen- am I in? What does a person like me do in a


sion of identity construction: identity-driven situation like this? Thus, passions are disci-
performance and action. Institutionalized plined not by incentives, but by identity.
identities and frames come with expectations Thus, the logic of identity offers a counter-
about how actors should perform an identity point to the logic of consequence that typi-
in specific situations (Eliasoph & cally dominates organizational thought.
Lichterman, 2003). When social identities Identity, then, can function as kind of insti-
and frames are put to use in practical per- tutional logic (Friedland & Alford, 1991) that
formance, their meaning and relevance is governs organizational behavior and choice;
reaffirmed as subjective experience. although it can at times limit choices, it also
Institutions are thus ‘embodied in personal enables and advances action because identi-
experience by means of roles’ (Berger & ties are performed. They function as a kind of
Luckmann, 1966: 74). institutional logic, a set of ‘shared rules and
The identity literature comes closest to this typifications that identify categories of social
view in its articulation of strategic identities, actors and their appropriate activities or rela-
which are viewed as resources leveraged for tionships’ (Barley & Tolbert, 1997: 96).
competitive advantage. Although identities Action is implicated and, in the performance
can certainly guide strategic behavior, they of identity, institutions themselves can be
may do more than that; they can ensure orga- transformed. Thus, institutionalists alert us to
nizational survival. Selznick (1956: 63) a relatively unexplored aspect of organiza-
expresses it directly: ‘Institutional survival, tional identity: its performance.
properly understood, is a matter of maintain-
ing values and distinctive identity.’
Organizational fields are characterized by
institutional logics, which Meyer, Boli and POTENTIAL CONTRIBUTIONS OF
Thomas (1987) define as cultural accounts; INSTITUTIONAL THEORY TO THE
logics endow the actors and actions in the STUDY OF ORGANIZATIONAL
field with meaning and legitimacy. Thornton IDENTITY
and Ocasio (1999: 804) offer a similar defini-
tion, but draw out more explicitly the produc- At first blush, theories of institutions and the-
tion of actions consistent with this logic; they ories of identity seemed to be almost anti-
define logics as ‘the socially constructed, thetical. They operate at different levels of
historical pattern of material practices, analysis and seek different explanations for
assumptions, values, beliefs, and rules by organizational sameness and differentiation.
which individuals produce and reproduce Institutionalists look for similarities among
their material subsistence, organize time and organizations in a field; organizational iden-
space, and provide meaning to their social tity theorists look for similarities among
reality.’ individuals in an organization. More gener-
In his compelling book and video, show- ally, as Pedersen and Dobbin (2006: 900)
casing Don Quixote as a model for leader- observed in their study of institutions and
ship, Jim March focuses on identity. As organizational cultures: ‘institutionalists
March tells it, Quixote balances passion with look for interorganizational convergence,
discipline, which stems from Quixote’s iden- isomorphism, and meaning construction
tity, his precise sense of himself. Not only is through interorganizational paradigm
Quixote aware of the consequences of his construct; organizational culture researchers
actions (which are governed by the logic of look for organizational divergence, polymor-
consequence), but is also very aware of the phism, and identity construction through
demands of his identity, his role in the world. collective sensemaking.’ And yet, they are
He asks himself: Who am I? What situation fundamentally circular in their effects; two
426 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

sides of the same coin, as Pedersen and of these mechanisms: socio-normative and
Dobbin (2006) remind us. cognitive. And, although institutional mecha-
A useful approach to relating these two nisms have been typified as constraints that
perspectives is that of mechanism-based narrow possibilities for identity construction
theorizing; this approach relates variables at and choice, I have argued that institutions
one level of analysis to those at a different enable organizational identities in three basic
level of analysis. It suggests a bridge that ways: by formulating the essential identity
could be built between institutionalists’ elements (centrality, distinctiveness and
emphasis on the inter-organizational environ- durability); by supplying the ‘raw’ cultural
ment and identity’s emphasis on the intra- materials that organizations assemble in a
organizational environment. As Davis and process of institutional bricolage to achieve
Marquis (2005: 335) explain: ‘If regressions ‘optimal distinctiveness’ (Brewer, 1993)
reveal the relationship (wind a watch and it within institutional fields; and by motivating
keeps running), mechanisms pry the back off performance in organizations in a way that is
the watch and show how.’ governed by the institutional logics of
The framework of Hedstrom and identity. In all these processes, I have
Swedberg (1998) maps two mechanisms that acknowledged how institutions can induce
move across levels of analysis and are variations, as well as temper them.
relevant to institutions and identity: situa- More generally, I have tried to show how
tional mechanisms, that explain how vari- identity-making processes are shaped both
ables at a macro-level affect those at more by wider cultural accounts circulating in
micro-levels (e.g., effects of regulatory law broader fields of meaning (industry; nation-
on employment practices; new market pres- state) as well as more specific (and perhaps
sures on industries such as education or historical) accounts of organizational charac-
health care; an organization’s layoffs on ter that reflect the essential aspects of the
employee motivation) and transformational firm. Despite the fact that organizations
mechanisms that explain how micro-level assemble similar institutionalized identity
actions or variables alter macro-level patterns elements, variations are possible because of
at a higher level of analysis (e.g., diffusion of the transposability (Sewell, 1992), mutuabil-
one’s organizational HR practices to the ity (Clemens & Cook, 1999), and recombina-
field; the activism of social movements that tory possibilities of institutional scripts
changes civil law or organizational policies (Powell, 1991).
on environmentalism). And, although I have Institutions serve up the resources for
focused on situational mechanisms where identity-work in organizations by supplying
institutions enable identities, surely transfor- cognitive templates for both the form (gram-
mational mechanisms alter fields by mar) and content (meanings; symbols) of
aggregating or leveraging potent organiza- organizational identities. Further, by
tional-level identities. sanctioning (or legitimating) some particular
Institutional theory implies three basic sets identity representations (or symbols) over
of situational mechanisms that operate on others, an institutional perspective on
organizations: the normative (or value-laden) identity suggests that some identities may be
expectations of institutional fields or more potent than others in particular histori-
industries; cognitive ‘guidance systems’ that cal periods.
supply abstract structures of meaning; and Thus, in demonstrating their social fitness,
regulatory or coercive forces that can limit organizational identities can resonate with
identity choices. (e.g., prescribing the use of audiences and develop cultural power,
terms like ‘Incorporated’ in a name or i.e., ‘the capacity of certain works to linger in
trademarking unique organizational logos). the mind … to enter the canon’ (Griswold,
In this chapter, I have focused on the first two 1987: 1105). Ironically, cultural power stems
BEYOND CONSTRAINT: HOW INSTITUTIONS ENABLE IDENTITIES 427

less from organizational individuation and on exogenous models of change (Barley &
distinctiveness and more from its institu- Tolbert, 1997; Farjoun, 2002). However,
tional situatedness, as Griswold (1987: 1105) when organizational identities are conceptu-
explains: ‘A powerful work … locates itself alized as part of a particular institutional field
within a set of conventions that it strains, or industry, attention is redirected towards
plays with, perhaps inverts, but does not modeling institutions as endogenous, the
totally ignore … intrigues or disturbs its result of organizational appropriation of
recipients without utterly mystifying or frus- shared institutional elements and logic but
trating them.’ In this way, then, institutions with a multiplicity of variations. And finally,
can enable not only identity construction but identity construction can afford a way of
also identity legitimacy and potency. Further, introducing agency into institutional
when identities are potent, they persist. accounts of change. By modeling how organ-
Persistence (over time) may arise not only izations actively craft identities from avail-
because of organizational strategy or inertia, able cultural toolkits (Swidler, 1986),
but because institutional pressures sanction combining (or recombining) identity ele-
certain types of identity symbols and ments to achieve both sameness (with appro-
practices as potent. Identities thus can strike priate cultural scripts) and differentiation
such a resonant chord that they endure (from other organizations), theorists intro-
in their vibration, becoming almost duce aspects of organizational choice, and
indestructible. creative deviation that are institutionally
Issues of identity potency and resonance, informed but not necessarily mandated. Such
derived from institutional alignment, raise a perspective would take the institutionalism
several intriguing questions for future of identity beyond a model of constraint to
researchers to pursue. One question again one that enables and enriches identity
challenges the enduring nature of identity, construction in organizations.
but focuses less on shortening its lifespan
and more on lengthening it: Is there more
continuity in organizational identity than one REFERENCES
might expect? Do cultures (or societies or
nation-states) have a preference for Albert, S. & Whetten, D. 1985. Organizational
remembered identities such that they press identity. In L.L. Cummings & B.M. Staw
(eds.), Research in Organizational Behavior
for persistence, in spite of identity threats?
(Vol. 7, pp. 263–295). Greenwich, CT: JAI Press.
Other questions introduce a more active role Ashforth, B.E. & Mael, F. 1989. Social identity
for the institutional environment and key theory and the organization. Academy of
institutional actors. We can redirect current Management Review, 14: 20–39.
leanings towards explaining identity Ashforth, B.E. & Mael, 1996. Organizational
preferences and sanctioning by organiza- identity and strategy as a context for the
tional members. An institutional approach individual. In Baum, J. & Dutton, J.E. (eds.),
might lead us to a different question: Do Advances in Strategic Management, (Vol.
cultures (or societies or nation-states) 13, pp. 19–64).Greenwich, CT: JAI Press.
sanction certain types of identities at differ- Barley, S. R. Tolbert, P. 1997. Institutionalization
ent points in time? and structuration: studying the links
between action and institution. Organization
Finally, although the focus of this chapter
Studies, 18:93–117.
has been on how institutional theory Bartel, Caroline A. 2001. Social compar-
can inform models of organizational identity, isons in boundary-spanning work: Effects
the reverse is also true: organizational of community outreach on members’
identity theories can inform institutionalism. organizational identity and identification.
For instance, a widespread critique of neo- Administrative Science Quarterly, 46:
institutionalism points to its overemphasis 379–414.
428 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Berger P.L. & Luckmann, T. 1966. The Social fields. American Sociological Review, 48:
Construction of Knowledge: A Treatise in the 147–160.
Sociology of Knowledge. New York: Anchor Dutton, J.E. & Dukerich, J.M. 1991. Keeping
Books, Doubleday. an eye on the mirror: Image and identity
Biggart, N.W. 1977. The creative-destructive in organizational adaptation. Academy
process of organizational change: The case of Management Journal, 34: 517–554.
of the post office. Administrative Science Dutton, J.E., Dukerich, J.M. & Harquail, C.V.
Quarterly, 22: 410–426. 1994. Organizational images and member
Bhattacharya, C.B., Rao, H. & Glynn, M.A. identification. Administrative Science
1995. Understanding the bond of identifica- Quarterly, 239–262.
tion: An investigation of its correlates among Eliasoph, N. & Lichterman, P. 2003. Culture in
art museum members. Journal of Marketing, interaction. American Journal of Sociology,
59: 46–57. 108: 735–794.
Brewer, M. 1993. Social identity, distinctive- Elsbach, K. & Kramer, R. 1996. Members’
ness, and in-group homogeneity. Social responses to organizational identity threats:
Cognition, 11: 150–164. Encountering and countering the Business
Brickson, S.L. 2005. Organizational identity ori- Week Rankings. Administrative Science
entation: Forging a link between organiza- Quarterly, 41: 442–476.
tional identity and organizations’ relations Farjoun, M. 2002. The dialectics of institutional
with stakeholders. Administrative Science development in emerging and turbulent
Quarterly, 50: 576–609. fields. Academy of Management Journal, 45:
Cerulo, K.A. 1997. Identity construction: New 848–874.
Issues, new directions. Annual Review of Fiol, C.M. 1991. Frevisiting an identity-based
Sociology, 23: 385–409. view of sustainable competitive advantage.
Clemens, E.S. & Cook, J.M. 1999. Politics and Journal of Management, 27: 691–699.
Institutionalism: Explaining durability and Fiol, C.M. 2001. Revisiting an identity-based
change. Annual Review of Sociology, 25: view of sustainable competitive advantage.
441–466. Journal of Management, 27: 691–699.
Corley, K. 2004. Defined by our strategy or our Fiol, C.M. 2002. Capitalizing on paradox: The
culture? Hierarchical differences in percep- role of language in transforming organiza-
tions of organizational identity and change. tional identities. Organization Science, 13:
Human Relations, 57: 114–1177. 653–666.
Corley, K.G. & Gioia, D.A. 2004. Identity ambi- Fox-Wolfgramm, S.J., Boal, K.B., & Hunt, J.G.
guity and change in the wake of a corporate 1998. Organizational adaptation to institu-
spin-off. Administrative Science Quarterly, tional change: A comparative study of first-
49: 173–206. order change in prospector and defender
Corley, K., Harquail, C.V., Pratt, M.G., Glynn, banks. Administrative Science Quarterly, 43:
M.A., Fiol, M., & Hatch, M.J. 2006. Guiding 87–126.
organizational identity through aged adoles- Friedland, R. & Alford, R. 1991. Bringing soci-
cence, Journal of Management Inquiry, 15: ety back in: Symbols, practices and institu-
85–99. tional contradictions. In W.W. Powell &
Czarniawska, B. & Wolff, R. 1998. Constructing P.J. Dimaggio (eds.), The New Institutiona-
new identities in established organizational lism in Organizational Analysis. Chicago:
fields. International Studies of Management University of Chicago Press.
& Organization, 28: 32–56. Gioia, D.A. & Thomas, J.B.1996. Identity,
Davis, G.F. & Marquis, C. 2005. Prospects for image, and issue interpretation: Sensemaking
organizational theory in the early 21st cen- during strategic change in academia.
tury: Institutional fields and mechanisms. Administrative Science Quarterly, 41: 370–403.
Organization Science, 16: 332–343. Gioia, D. & Corley, K. 2002. Being good
DiMaggio, P. & Powell, W.W. 1983. The iron versus looking good: business school
cage revisited: Institutional isomorphism rankings and the Circean transformation
and collective rationality in organizational from substance to image. Academy of
BEYOND CONSTRAINT: HOW INSTITUTIONS ENABLE IDENTITIES 429

Management Learning and Education, 1: to Social Theory. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge


107–121. University Press.
Gioia, D., Schultz, M., Corley, K. 2000. Hsu, G. & Hannan, M. 2005. Identities, genres
Organizational identity, image, and adaptive and organizational forms. Organizational
instability. Academy of Management Review, Science, 16: 474–490.
25: 63–81. Labianca, G, Fairbank, J., Thomas, J., Gioia, D.,
Glynn, M.A. 2000. When cymbals become & Umphress, E. 2001. Emulation in
symbols: Conflict over organizational identity academia: Balancing structure and identity.
within a symphony orchestra. Organization Organizationational Science, 12: 312–330.
Science, 11 (3): 285–298. Lamont, M. 1992. Money, Morals and Man-
Glynn, M.A. & Abzug, R.A. 1998. Isomorphism ners. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.
and competitive differentiation in the Lounsbury, M. & Glynn, M.A. 2001 Cultural
organizational name game. In J.A.C. Baum entrepreneurship: stories, legitimacy, and the
(ed.). Advances in Strategic Management, acquisition of resources. Strategic
Vol. 15, pp. 105–128. Greenwich, CT: Management Journal, 22: 545–564.
JAI Press. Lounsbury, M.D. & Glynn, M.A. 2005.
Glynn, M.A. & Abzug, R. 2002 Entrepreneurial stories and legitimacy. In M.
Institutionalizing identity: Symbolic Hitt and D. Ireland (eds.), The Blackwell Ency-
isomorphism and organizational names. clopedia of Management (2nd edn), Vol. III
Academy of Management Journal, 45: Entrepreneurship (pp. 117–120). Blackwell.
267–280. Mael, F., Ashforth, B. 1992. Alumni and their
Glynn, M.A. & Lounsbury, M. 2005. From the alma maters: A partial test of the reformu-
critics’ corner: Logic blending, discursive lated model of organizational identification.
change and authenticity in a cultural produc- Journal of Organizational Behavior, 13:
tion system, Journal of Management 103–123.
Studies, 42: 1031–1055. Martin, J., Feldman, M.S., Hatch, M.J., & Sitkin,
Glynn, M.A. & Marquis, C. 2004. When good S.B. 1983. The uniqueness paradox in orga-
names go bad: Organizational Illegitimacy nizational stories. Administrative Science
and the Dotcom Collapse. In C. Johnson Quarterly, 28: 438–453.
(ed.), Research in the Sociology of Organi- Oliver, C. 1991. Strategic responses to institu-
zations, vol. 22, pp. 147–170. NY: tional processes. Academy of Management
JAI/Elsevier Science. Review, 16: 145–179.
Glynn, M.A. & Marquis, C. 2006. Fred’s Bank: Pedersen, J.S. & Dobbin, F. 1997. The social
How institutional norms and individual pref- invention of collective actors. American
erences legitimate organizational names. Behavioral Scientist. 40: 431–444.
In A. Rafaeli, & M. Pratt (eds.), Artifacts Pedersen, J.S. & Dobbin, F. 2006. In search of
and Organizations, pp. 223–239. Mahwah, identity and legitimation. American
NJ: Erlbaum. Behavioral Scientist, 49: 897–907.
Golden-Biddle, K., & Rao, H. 1997. Breaches in Porac, J., Wade, J., & Pollock, T. 1999. Industry
the boardroom: Organizational identity and categories and the politics of the comparable
conflicts of commitment in a nonprofit firm in CEO compensation. Administrative
organization. Organizational Science, 8: Science Quarterly, 44:112–144.
593–611. Powell, Walter W. 1991. "Expanding the Scope
Griswold, W. 1987. The fabrication of mean- of Institutional Analysis." Pp. 183–203 in
ing: Literary interpretation in the US, Great The New Institutionalism in Organizational
Britain, and the West Indies. AJS, 92: Analysis, edited by W.W. Powell and
1077–1117. P.J. DiMaggio. Chicago and London: The
Hatch, M.J. & Schultz, M. 2002. The dynamics University of Chicago Press.
of organizational identity. Human Relations, Pratt, M.G., & Foreman, P.O. 2000. Classifying
55: 989–1018. managerial responses to multiple organiza-
Hedstrom, Peter and Swedberg Richard. 1998. tional identities. Academy of Management
Social Mechanisms: An Analytical Approach Review, 25: 18–42.
430 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Pratt, M.G., & Rafaeli, A. 1997. Organizational Sewell, W. 1992. A theory of structure: Duality,
dress as a symbol of multilayered social iden- agency and transformation. American
tities. Academy of Management Journal, Journal of Sociology, 98: 1–30.
40(4): 862–898. Swidler, A. 1986. Culture in action: Symbols
Pratt, M., Rockmann, K., Kaufmann, J. 2006. and strategies. American Sociological
Constructing professional identity: The role Review, 51: 273–86.
of work and identity learning cycles in the Swidler, A. 2001. Talk of Love: How Culture
customization of identity among medical Matters. Chicago: University of Chicago
professionals. Academy of Management Press.
Journal, 49: 235–262. Thornton, P.H. & Oscasio, W.1999. Institutional
Rao, H., Davis, G.F. & Ward, A. 2000. logics and the historical contingency of
Embeddedness, social identity and mobility: power in organizations: Executive succession
Why firms leave the NASDAQ and join the in the higher education publishing industry.
New York stock exchange. Administrative American Journal of Sociology, 105:
Science Quarterly, 45: 268–292. 801–844.
Rao, H., Monin, P., & Durand, R. 2003. Weber, K. & Glynn, M.A. 2006. Making sense
Institutional change in Toque Ville: Nouvelle with Institutions: The role of context in Karl
cuisine as an identity movement in French Weick’s sensemaking perspective.
gastronomy. American Journal of Sociology, Organization Studies, Special Issue in
108: 795–843. Honour of Karl Weick, 27: 1639–1660.
Ravasi, D. & Schultz, M. 2006. Responding to Westenholz, A. 2006. Identity work and mean-
organizational identity threats: Exploring the ing arena. American Behavioral Scientist, 49:
role of organizational culture. Academy of 1015–1029.
Management Journal, 49: 433–458. Westenholz, A., Pedersen, J.S. & Dobbin, F.
Reger, R.K., Gustafson, L.T., Demaric, S.M., 2006. Institutions in the making: Identity,
Mullane, J.V. 1994. Reframing the organiza- power, and the emergence of new organiza-
tion: Why implementing total quality is tional forms. American Behavioral Scientist,
easier said than done. The Academy of 49: 889–896.
Management Review, 19: 565–584. Zucker, L.G. 1983. Organizations as institu-
Scott, W.R. 1995. Institutions and Organiza- tions. S.B. Bacharach (ed.), Research in the
tions. Sage Publications, Thousand Oaks, CA. Sociology of Organizations. Greenwich, CT:
Scott, S.G. & Lane, V.R. 2000. A stakeholder JAI Press, 1–42.
approach to organizational identity. Zuckerman, E.W., Kim, T., Ukanwa, K., von
Academy of Management Review, 25: Rittman, J. 2003. Robust identities or non-
43–62. entities? Typecasting in the feature film labor
Selznick, P. 1957. Leadership in Administration. market. American Journal of Sociology, 108:
Berkeley: University of California Press. 1018–1074.
17
Institutionalism and the
Professions
Kevin T. Leicht and Mary L. Fennell

The study of the professions, as they are undergoing changes in the markets, organiza-
defined in the developed world, has been tional forms, and technologies that provide
deeply intertwined with institutional theory fertile ground for the use and extension of
and topics central to institutional theory institutional theory. The institutional norms
(legitimation, symbolism, isomorphism, of several key professional sectors are
decoupling, power, agency, and organiza- changing drastically as well as the assump-
tional fields). The professions represent the tions about market structures and the nature
quintessential triumph of Durkheimian occu- of technological changes currently at the
pational communities over and above the forefront.
mass-society-based anonymity of impersonal For the purposes of this chapter, we define
markets and the grinding rigidity of bureau- professional work as occupational
cracies. But, as we’ll see, the classic incumbents: (a) whose work is defined by the
autonomous, peer-oriented professional application of theoretical and scientific
practice is under pressure from institutional knowledge to tasks tied to core societal
constituents interested in lower costs, more values (health, justice, financial status, etc.),
accountability, and ethical transparency at (b) where the terms and conditions of work
the same historical moment that technologi- traditionally command considerable auton-
cal changes put pressure on traditional, omy and freedom from oversight, except by
institutionalized methods for delivering peer representatives of the professional
professional services. The combination of occupation, and (c) where claims to
new places, new people, new technologies, exclusive or nearly exclusive control over a
and new clients has pushed professionals in task domain are linked to the application of
new and uncharted directions. the knowledge imparted to professionals as
In this chapter, we examine recent devel- part of their training (Leicht and Fennell
opments in the study of professional work 2001: 25–30). This definition encompasses
through the lens of institutional theory. the traditional classic professions (physi-
The delivery of professional services is cians, lawyers, and university professors) but
432 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

also includes other abstract workers and 1977; Starr 1982), and management account-
symbolic analysts such as accountants, ing (Johnson and Kaplan 1987). More recent
pharmacists, engineers, and scientists. historical work on the professions has exam-
In the next two sections we look briefly at ined the export of western professional ideals
the more traditional literature on the profes- on economic and legal systems to Latin
sions, and then move on toward contemporary America (Garth and Dezalay 2002),
institutional theory and the ways in which it emphasizing the impact of local political
has addressed the professions and the organi- struggles on the success or failure of such
zational structures where professional work is export attempts.
done. Finally, we develop an updated version Early sociological efforts to consider both
of an institutional analysis of the professions, professional work and the structures within
focusing on change within professions them- which that work takes place are best exempli-
selves, change in the relative importance of fied by models developed by Scott (1992)
institutional and technical environments, and and his colleagues. Scott discussed three
demands for greater transparency and models for embedding professionals in
accountability following well-known ethical organizations. Autonomous organizational
scandals that resulted in significant harm to forms represent the ideal-typical practice set-
clients and employees. Our analyses through- ting where professionals retain authority to
out will draw heavily (though not exclusively) control and evaluate themselves as a group.
from research on the health and medical pro- Heteronomous organizational forms subject
fessions, where the impact of institutional professionals to more line-authority control,
change has been substantial. as exemplified by healthcare managers in
today’s managed care organizations.
Conjoint organizational forms produce sepa-
rate domains of power controlled by profes-
PRIOR LITERATURE ON sionals and administrators who recognize the
THE PROFESSIONS AND shared benefits of their division-of-labor and
PROFESSIONAL PRACTICE collaboration.
The different dimensions of professional
Sociological theory on the professions work that are subject to change have been
moved away from trait theories (theories that discussed by Friedson (1986) and Hafferty
defined professions based on a series of fixed and Light (1995). Changes in the actual
characteristics such as credentials, codes of content, or technical core, of professional
ethics, and knowledge mastery) in the late work refer to specific decisions made and
1960s and 1970s. The prevailing movement procedures used during task performances.
was toward models of professional organiza- In medicine the proliferation of practice
tions and knowledge claims (Leicht and protocols and research on medical effective-
Fennell 2001). These new models of profes- ness represent examples of attempts to limit
sions and professional practice moved control over the content of professional
beyond the conception of professional organ- work. Changes in the terms of work refer to
ization as a rational, goal-oriented system characteristics of the professional work
designed around core tasks carried out and contract (pay, hours worked, and reimburse-
controlled by professionals themselves ment arrangements). The replacement of
toward organizational and institutional fee-for-service delivery with salaried work
claims regarding professionals and their conducted according to fixed schedules
activities. Other classic studies of ‘profes- would be an example of changes in the terms
sionalism’ as a historical process have of work. Finally, changes in the conditions
emphasized the political and social power of of work refer to changes in the organiza-
professional groups in medicine (Larson tional structures, staffing arrangements, and
INSTITUTIONALISM AND THE PROFESSIONS 433

resources made available for professional builds on the concepts of agency theory to
practice. The rising expectation that discuss ways that competing professions
academic scientists will produce patentable make countervailing claims to dominance
discoveries and large research grants to pay over specific task domains. Friedson’s work
for their laboratory infrastructure would be (2001) follows in this tradition by claiming
an example of this change. Changes can that professions represent a ‘third logic’ for
occur in any of these domains independently, the institutionalized organization of service
but changes in the terms and conditions of delivery as a Durkheimian alternative to
work often have implications for the content markets and bureaucracies.
of work that is performed.
Others have focused on systems of profes-
sions and knowledge claims among
professional groups (cf. Abbott 1988, 1991). CONTEMPORARY INSTITUTIONAL
These researchers move away from studying THEORY AND THE PROFESSIONS
single professions in isolation toward studies
of professional groups who claim to control Institutional theory suggests that the regula-
the same (or very similar) task domains. tion of organizational behavior occurs
More important for our purposes, these through and is a consequence of taken-
researchers also focus on the entire system of for-granted beliefs, schemas, and values that
professional claims within specific societies originate in larger institutional contexts (cf.
and cultures. Systems of knowledge claims Powell and DiMaggio 1991; Scott 1987;
are studied when boundary and domain Meyer and Rowan 1977; Greenwood and
disputes develop among competing profes- Hinings 1996; Friedland and Alford 1991).
sional groups. These competitions determine In most institutional accounts these beliefs,
each group’s relative prerogatives and pres- schemas, and values are not primarily
tige. Relatively prestigious occupations (e.g. responses to market pressures and efficiency
medical practice prior to the 1980s) rarely dynamics. Instead, these arrangements repre-
have their task domains challenged by sent active responses to dominant sets of
competing groups. But this perspective norms, values and beliefs of key organiza-
points out that there are far more cases where tional actors (elite business managers,
professional task domains are contested (see partners in professional practices, key regula-
our discussion below of the relationship tors, and powerful clients). Specific ways of
between pharmaceutical companies, organizing become archetypes that represent
scientists, and new technologies or our dis- coherent patterns of organizing in response
cussion of conflicts of interest between man- to underlying values and beliefs
agerial consulting and accounting practice). (cf. Greenwood and Hinings 1993).
Through watching these competitions in new Mechanisms for enforcing institutional
organizational and institutional arrange- configurations are the key to the establish-
ments, researchers can study how task ment and maintenance of a strong correspon-
domains are controlled and how challenges dence between institutionalized values and
to the conventional organization of profes- beliefs and methods of organizing. In institu-
sional practice occur. tional theory these forces usually are
Light’s (1993, 1995) theory of counter- classified under the headings of normative,
vailing powers is another variant of the focus coercive and mimetic pressures. Normative
on systems of professions, a conception that pressures result from the socialization of
is echoed by Friedson (2001). The dynamics institutional actors into a set of beliefs that
of change in the status of professions is define specific organizational arrangements
linked to a profession’s location in a field of as the ‘best and customary’ way of organiz-
institutional and cultural actors. This theory ing specific activities. Professional schools
434 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

and professional associations are classic and archetypes (such as discount brokerage
examples of groups that exert normative houses, mail-order pharmaceuticals, internet
pressure through their socialization (and con- social-networking sites). Organizations
tinued re-socialization) of occupational and/or the professionals within newly devel-
incumbents. Coercive pressures result from oping organizational fields can themselves
the actions of regulatory oversight agencies have significant influence on defining the
and major resource providers. These stake- institutional logics that will become
holders have the ability to enforce their will imprinted upon that sector. Suchman’s work
on organizational actors by conferring or on the legal community in Northern
withdrawing legitimacy and resources. California’s Silicon Valley provides an
Certifications, inspections, and claims to excellent example of how local law firms
speak for broader unorganized constituencies developed and ‘set’ legal patterns for linking
(in addition to the sheer ability to pay large venture capitalists with startup firms in the
fees, secure bank loans, and take legal high tech sector (2003; Suchman et al.
action) make coercive pressures in well-insti- 2001). Greenwood and Suddaby’s (2006)
tutionalized organizational domains credible. study of new forms of multidisciplinary prac-
Mimetic pressure is a consequence of the tice firms in Canadian professional business
establishment of taken-for-granted methods services provides another cogent example of
of organizing. Once specific organizational institutional change – entrepreneurship –
practices dominate a specific field, resorting initiated from the center of a mature organi-
to those practices as the best solution to a zational field.
problem is simply a matter of borrowing In the second conception, strategic
from what others do. responses to institutional processes, there are
More recently neo-institutional theorists a wide variety of responses to institutional
have been interested in examining change pressure, and simply following the norms
processes (cf. DiMaggio and Powell 1991; (acquiescence) is only one of those. In
Greenwood and Hinings 1993; Oliver 1991). Oliver’s conception, organizational leaders
There are two broad strands of institutional can engage in compromise, avoidance, defi-
research and theory that attempt to under- ance, and manipulation of the institutional
stand change: (1) a tradition focusing on environment. These responses may vary
variations in embeddedness in specific insti- depending on how embedded the organiza-
tutional contexts that promote specific orga- tion is in the institutional environment in the
nizational archetypes (cf. Greenwood and first place and the overall availability of alter-
Hinings 1993, 1996), and (2) a somewhat native templates and logics for organizing.
less prominent tradition that talks about In the next section we provide an exten-
strategic responses to institutional processes sion of earlier institutional theory treatments
(cf. Oliver 1991). In the first conception, of the professions, by focusing on change
embeddedness in an institutional context from several directions, including both inter-
makes gradual change less likely and radical nal and external changes. Specifically, we
(or revolutionary) change more likely. assert that the professions have undergone
Embeddedness also reflects the structure of changes in their institutional environment
the institutional context – the extent that con- that reflect the following:
texts are permeable and the extent that insti-
(a) changes from inside the professions as practition-
tutional monitoring practices are tightly or ers become more diversified demographically
loosely coupled. Not all organizations oper- and in terms of their professional interests and
ate in highly institutionalized environments specialization. Not only are the classic profes-
(e.g., restaurants, big-box retailers), and sions now populated by an unprecedented
some environments are vulnerable to new ethnic, racial and gender diversity of practition-
practitioners with different organizing logics ers, but continued professional specialization and
INSTITUTIONALISM AND THE PROFESSIONS 435

rising earnings inequality threaten to undermine professionals (see Leicht and Lyman 2006).1
what little professional solidarity remains. The US trends on both fronts have been grad-
(b) changes in the relative salience of institutional ual, but the overall change has been dramatic.
and technical environments in altering the logics Women have gone from representing fewer
of professional service delivery (cf. Scott, Ruef,
than two in every ten professional jobholders
Mendel and Caronna, 2000; and D’Aunno, 2003).
Historically there have always been tensions
to almost 50 percent, and much of this
between concern for the overall institutional and increase has happened since 1980. The repre-
professional service ethos of professional activity sentation of non-whites in the professions
and the technical environment (markets, technol- has increased as well, but from a lower base-
ogy, and innovation) where professional practice line and with a much more gradual rise. The
takes place. We argue that many professions in representation of non-whites among profes-
the past 25 years have seen shifts toward the sionals currently hovers around 12 percent.
rising salience of the technical environment (mar- By any standard, the slow but steady
kets and technologies) in relation to traditional demographic diversification of the profes-
institutional concerns of professional practice sions is a reality that is here to stay. These
delivery. We argue that one of the environmental
trends in demographic diversification are
precursors of this shift was the Keynesian crisis in
macroeconomics in the mid-1970s and the result-
most apparent among the professions closely
ing questions this raised about a future post- associated with business services; accounting
industrial society dominated by technical, and law. Women constitute a near majority of
professionalized experts. The other contemporary accounting practitioners (both CPAs and
change is in the technological interface used by non-CPAs), and women’s representation
professionals as they attempt to keep abreast of among US lawyers has dramatically
new developments in information and nanotech- increased as well. Women now constitute a
nology. These developments, and the organiza- majority of students in US law schools and
tional responses to them, are especially apparent a substantial percentage of students in US
in the healthcare professions where new tech- accounting and business schools (although
nologies raise questions about old organizational
Hammond (2002) shows that accounting has
forms used to deliver healthcare services.
(c) demands for greater transparency and accounta-
not become more racially diverse). Perhaps
bility in light of well-publicized scandals affecting not coincidentally, accounting and law are
service delivery. These scandals are a product of precisely the professional groups where the
the new institutional environment for profes- reorganization of working arrangements and
sional service delivery that highlight the fault- the creation of the one-stop business service
lines between traditional conceptions of firm (similar to the multidisciplinary practice
professional practice and new avenues for exploit- firm examined by Greenwood and Suddaby)
ing information gaps and the speed of transac- is most evident. This is a significant (but
tions between geographically dispersed clients. certainly not the only) component of the
increasingly fragmented institutional
environment professionals face.

CHANGES WITHIN PROFESSIONAL


GROUPS – DEMOGRAPHIC AND Growing earnings inequality among
INTEREST DIVERSITY professionals

Growing demographic diversity There has always been (for the last 30 years
among professionals at least) considerable diversity in the earn-
ings of professionals and the earnings gaps
One of the more obvious trends of the past 30 among professionals have been wider than
years is in the growing representation of earnings gaps in the rest of the working
women and minorities (non-whites) among population. Assessing the growth in earnings
436 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

inequality among professionals is an underrepresented groups (see also Epstein


important (but far from the only) component 1993, 2004).
of assessing claims that the interests of pro-
fessionals are diversifying.
More interesting from the standpoint of
potential professional interests is that, since CHANGES IN THE RELATIVE SALIENCE
1970, inequality has been rising more OF INSTITUTIONAL AND TECHNICAL
drastically among professionals than among ENVIRONMENTS IN PROFESSIONAL
the general population (Leicht and Lyman SERVICE DELIVERY
2006). If professional practice (in part) repre-
sents the creation of common occupational Cost and quality pressures from
communities with strongly identified
clients
common interests, it is a bit difficult to see
how drastically rising earnings inequality The costs of many professional services (for
could do anything but strain those normative example, medical care and college tuition)
institutional ties. have risen at several times the inflation rate
At minimum, these trends indicate a con- since the early 1980s. This increase in fees,
siderable shift in the material and social basis and the growing affluence of some of the
for the production of common occupational more visible segments of most professional
communities in the professions. This groups (e.g. partners in large urban law
common community is a key component of firms, financial analysts for corporate banks,
promoting and maintaining dominant organ- and college presidents), has occurred at the
izing archetypes that stress autonomy, same time as median income and earnings (in
equality, and a common set of ethics in the real dollar terms) have stagnated, leaving the
delivery of professional services. Whatever average middle-class consumer of profes-
else professional occupations represent, they sional services at the mercy of the market.
are no longer elite occupations full of people Health insurers, in particular, have been
from homogeneous social and economic unable to control the sharp increase in med-
backgrounds. ical costs as new and expensive technologies
Demographic and material diversity is come on-line that promise more effective
compounded further by the growth of treatment for an ever wider variety of
specialty groups within most professional diseases. Scientific instruments necessary to
occupations. The role of the general, establish a university research laboratory in
omnibus practitioner whose professional any of the physical or biological sciences
status and prestige rested on their ability to now routinely cost $500,000 to $1 million or
apply professional knowledge to a wide vari- more and much of this equipment needs to be
ety of conditions is yielding to increasingly replaced every few years, some of it for
specialized practice settings, where clients safety reasons.
come to have specific and narrow sets of The rise in college tuition has been accom-
needs addressed. The combination of demo- panied by the rising expenses associated with
graphic diversification, rising income professional and graduate education. In the
inequality, and extreme specialization have US, young professionals now leave univer-
led some researchers (e.g. Barbara Reskin) to sity-based training hundreds of thousands of
detect a growing gendered and racialized dollars in debt, and the need to pay off these
division of professional labor as glamorous, debts often distorts and/or limits the special-
high-visibility specialties become the prerog- izations and areas of professional practice
ative of whites and men and less glamorous they choose to pursue.
generalist/public service specialties become Complicating this entire process further is
the domain of women and traditionally the institutionalized price signaling that
INSTITUTIONALISM AND THE PROFESSIONS 437

occurs in the most professional practice set- ethics on the one hand, versus a technical
tings. In this environment, price is often a environment stressing market efficiency,
proxy for quality and clients and others are at technological change, and organizational
a severe disadvantage when it comes to eval- innovation on the other (see Malhotra,
uating the quality of professional services Morris and Hinings 2006). In the last
they receive. Since the lowest price isn’t 25 years, the rise of neo-liberal political and
always the best or expected quality, and the economic ideologies has threatened the
client has no way of evaluating the opportu- expert claims of professional groups and the
nity costs of selecting different service logic of professional organization as an alter-
providers, those that set prices have relatively native to and protector of client and public
free rein to charge what they will for profes- welfare. This historic change was triggered
sional services. by the crisis of Keynesian economics in the
On top of this, there has been considerable mid-1970s and the implications this crisis
growth in inequalities among clients and presented for a post-industrial future
traditional purchasers of professional serv- dominated by technical and administrative
ices. Colleges and universities increasingly expertise (cf. Bell 1976). This change is
rely on affluent parents with deep pockets to reflected in the Western European context by
subsidize financial aid programs for students the rise of new public management ideas in
who can’t pay full tuition. Private founda- professional civil service bureaucracies.
tions and corporations increasingly partner The contemporary situation of the profes-
with science laboratories at universities sions can be contrasted with the early- to
to lavishly fund research and support mid-1960s predictions regarding the spread
researchers. Healthcare delivery increasingly of professional expertise and reliance on lib-
is geared toward clients with health insur- eral-technocratic professionals in the new
ance plans who can afford to pay exorbitant post-industrial developed world (see, for
fees for new medical technologies, fees that example, Bell 1976; Frank et al. 1995; Frank
take into account the inability of most 1997). In this world of the future, professions
patients to afford treatment. These plans (in and knowledge-based work roles develop in
the US) are paid for by employers who see response to the demands of post-industrial
their health insurance premiums rise at capitalism. The process of filling these jobs
double-digit percentage rates every year. and the larger societal adjustments that come
Law firms increasingly find their most afflu- with the demand for highly educated workers
ent, corporate clients shopping around for the (educational expansion, credentialing, longer
cheapest (and most expedient) legal advice, stretches of time in school, and mass higher
cutting off steady, long-term income streams education) create a professional elite that
and placing a premium on ‘rainmaking’ (the applies their specialized knowledge to an
solicitation of high-priced legal work by ever-broader range of problems.
partners in law firms). The growing ideology of the efficacy of
professional expertise dovetailed nicely with
1950s and 1960s conceptions of Keynesian
The salience of markets as economics and the Great Society programs
a key component of the of the Johnson administration. Through the
use of demand management and other techni-
technical environment
cal macroeconomic tools, Keynesian
The traditionally-defined professions have economics turned decisions about the appro-
always walked a tightrope between the insti- priate levels of inflation, unemployment, and
tutional logic of professional practice cen- poverty into technical decisions of
tered on professional–client relationships, technocrats and professionals whose actions
autonomy, collegiality, and professional would guide the US Federal Government
438 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

toward full employment, low inflation, and task domains and exercise discretion over the
prosperity for all (see Stein 1983). performance of complex tasks for the benefit
This view of a post-industrial world where of clients and the larger society. Many of
knowledge experts would manage the econ- these challenges are clarified if we take the
omy in the name of full employment, low colloquialisms of the new neo-liberal
inflation and general prosperity, was chal- consensus and contrast those with traditional
lenged by two developments: (1) the crisis in conceptions of professional practice and the
Keynesian economics that resulted from the concept of expert labor:
stagflation and economic stagnation of the
1970s; and (2) the subsequent inability of 1. Consumers know best. Any attempt to interfere
skill-based models to explain rising income with, regulate, or affect consumer choice costs
and earnings inequality among professionals consumers money. This means that any interfer-
and between professionals and non-profes- ence with service provision (such as licensing
sional groups. These developments led to a procedures, legally defined monopolies over task
broad-based questioning of the relationship domains, competency tests, and other devices for
restricting professional service provision)
between technological expertise and general
extracts costs that are rarely if ever justified.
social welfare while also leading to serious Consumers of services eventually will reward
questioning of the ability and desirability of competent, scrupulous providers and punish
attempting to manage the economy. incompetent, unscrupulous ones. All that is nec-
The sets of policy tools advocated by mon- essary is to let the market do its work with the
etarist, new classical and (eventually) dollars of the consuming public voting for best
supply-side economics differed considerably practices.
from those who advocated expert-based 2. Markets will determine what is right. The market
Keynesian macroeconomics. These policies becomes the locus of human perfection (see
included: Giddens 1994). No expert can make, guide or
direct choices in the ways that markets will. No
(1) Deregulation of heavily regulated industries; authority can make the wise choices that markets
(2) Promotion of greater economic competition by can make. Let markets do their job and stay out
lowering trade barriers; of it.
(3) Repeal of special subsidies and tax loopholes for 3. No credentialing or licensing. These are simply
specific industries; attempts to collect monopoly rents. Consumers
(4) Across-the-board tax cuts especially targeted will naturally be led to choices that are best for
toward taxes on corporations and higher mar- them, and credentialing and licensing are just an
ginal income tax rates. attempt to extract windfall profits at the expense
(5) Cuts in government domestic spending in an of consumers.
attempt to remove disincentives to work, invest, 4. No codes of ethics. Markets will naturally reward
and save. those who behave in the best interests of those
who purchase professional services. Information
about ethical and unethical practices can be
Regardless of their distributional conse-
sorted out in the wash and those practitioners
quences, the subsequent success of these who do what clients want them to do and who
polices at restoring economic growth led to act in their best interests will win out in the end.
the vindication and promotion of market- 5. Competition will lower fees and salaries. Service
based solutions to other vexing problems, delivery from a variety of professional groups, in
including the calls for accountability and a variety of settings, with a wide range of organi-
lower costs in the provision of professional zational arrangements, will keep fees and salaries
services. low and service delivery of the best quality.
The present challenge of neo-liberalism as
an economic and political ideology has pro- In European contexts, the 1970s and 1980s
found implications for the professions as and the accompanying economic recessions
coherent occupational entities that control and deindustrialization led to a widespread
INSTITUTIONALISM AND THE PROFESSIONS 439

questioning of the salience of European


models of capitalism (cf. Esping-Anderson PROFESSIONS AND THEIR INTERFACE
1989; Rifkin 2004; Ironside and Seifert WITH TECHNOLOGY – THE NEW
2003; Fourcade 2006). Because professional TECHNOLOGICAL IMPERATIVE IN
practice (and especially the delivery of health HEALTH/MEDICAL CARE
care and education) have much more exten-
sive ties to the public sector in most During the 1980s and 1990s, when a number
European countries, the main response to this of interesting statements and refinements of
general crisis in confidence (for professional institutional theory were appearing,
groups) was the rise of New Public DiMaggio and Powell’s important paper
Management (NPM). While New Public (1983) launched a number of studies, often
Management is a label applied to a diverse focused on classifying organizations by the
set of reforms, ideas, and ideologies characteristics of their technical and institu-
(cf. Manning 2000; Savoie 1995), the general tional environments. This work helped
thrust of NPM initiatives is to subject the remind the field of the importance of both
provision of public service by professionals types of environmental pressures, as well as
to market forces through disaggrega- leading various scholars to consider histori-
tion, competition, and incentivization cal changes in organizations as well as in
(see Dunleavy, Margetts Bastow and Tinkler their institutional and technical environ-
2005). ments. Thus, early conceptualizations of
The specific manifestations of marketiza- technical and institutional environments by
tion and New Public Management vary from Scott and colleagues (1983, 1995, 2000) pro-
place to place and affect a wide array of pro- vided a matrix for classifying organizations
fessional groups. Attempts to implement by the characteristics of their environments,
New Public Management concepts in the UK and by differentiating between powerful
national health service, in particular, have constraints presented by one or the other
been controversial (see Ironside and Seifert environmental type.
2003). As with the case of attempts to bring Scott’s empirical focus was often health-
market incentives to professional practice in care organizations, as this particular industry
the United States, there are very few exam- provides a history of both well-developed
ples of the successful implementation of institutional and market pressures. It is also a
New Public Management concepts in field in which the prominence of the medical
European professional health services (see profession (as well as increasing attempts by
especially Bottery 1996; Scott et al. 1997; other professional groups within healthcare
Dunleavey et al. 2005; Christiansen and to define their own arena of control) has
Laegreid 1999; Lynn 1998; Reschentheler provided a most fertile field for examinations
and Thompson 1996; Kaboolian 1998). The of larger societal and institutional changes in
criticisms of New Public Management in healthcare organizations and the profession-
these contexts revolve around the disarticula- als linked to healthcare delivery (Light 1991;
tion between public service and revenue Hafferty & Light 1995; Leicht and Fennell
maximization, and the inability to ‘get prices 2001).
right’ in the provision of services and inter- Scott’s conceptualization was followed by
mediate goods that are government- the work of Alexander and D’Aunno (1990),
supported natural monopolies. These who tracked the transformation of the
changes in the economic side of the technical institutional environment of health care
environment for professionals have been organizations from post WWII to the late
equaled or exceeded by changes in the 1980s. They suggested the norms of the
technologies used to deliver professional medical/health industry were changing in
services, as we discuss below. important ways, so that the pressures of the
440 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

technical environments of healthcare organi- an extremely rich vein of organizational


zations in the 1990s (both the growing relationships, new organizational forms, and
costliness of the technological imperative in technological pressures affecting healthcare
health care, as well as increasing pressures to professionals, university research laborato-
control costs through the mechanisms of ries, for-profit R&D laboratoriess, and mar-
manage care) were gaining in strength. keting organizations. The intertwined
Concomitantly, the traditional institutional markets and institutional forces linking these
norms surrounding the autonomy of medical diverse actors are ripe for an institutional
professionals and physician control over theory analysis.
decision-making were losing steam in the Burns’ overview of current technological
face of managed care. More recently, Scott innovations in medical/healthcare treatment
and colleagues (2000) have examined in provides at least three examples of how the
detail the healthcare organizations, material- ‘new technological imperative’ is driving
resource environments, and institutional healthcare professionals and organizations
environments in one large metropolitan toward vastly different configurations in both
region of the US – the San Francisco Bay the healthcare value chain and eventually in
Area, from 1945 to 1995. This study also the patient treatment arena: (1) the prolifera-
took pains to examine environmental tion of merger and acquisition (M&A) and
pressures as they transformed over this strategic alliance (SA) development across
period, and did so by considering three multiple parts of the value chain, particularly
environmental levels of analysis: local, in the pharmaceuticals sector, and between
regional and national environments. biotechnology and pharmaceutical compa-
Most of the research on healthcare organi- nies; (2) changes in the methods used to
zations has focused primarily on the communicate with and persuade key stake-
providers of healthcare services (hospitals, holders and customers (particularly
physicians, nursing homes, etc.), or the physicians); and (3) the globalization
payers for healthcare services (employers, of manufacturing, marketing and distribution
insurance companies, the federal govern- of drugs.
ment). Sometimes, regulatory programs and
their designers have been examined
(Williamson 1985; Singh, Tucker and House
Strategic alliances and mergers
1986; Streeck and Schmitter 1985). Until
recently, however, there have been few analy- The pharmaceuticals sector is a particularly
ses of that portion of the industry that has appropriate example of a growing sector
become increasingly more important to the within health care where the characteris-
material/resource/technical environment: the tics of new technologies and products have
producers of new healthcare technology. led to an increase is interorganizational con-
Burns has investigated supply chain relation- nections. All five technology producers in
ships in the healthcare industry (2005), health care (pharmaceuticals, biotechnology,
focusing on trading relationships between genomics-proteomics, medical device, and
healthcare providers and their upstream sup- information technology) share several very
pliers. Most recently Burns has provided a important characteristics: they are all
detailed overview of the pharmaceutical, increasingly interdependent, research-inten-
biotechnology, genomics-proteomics, med- sive, and technologically complex. They
ical device, and information technology differ, however, on a number of dimensions
sectors within the healthcare value chain related to time (development cycles, age of
(2005), as well as the business models and firms, age of the sector, expected product
corporate strategies of firms within these impact as short- or long-term), and
sectors. In doing so, Burns has tapped into space (local vs. global dominance).
INSTITUTIONALISM AND THE PROFESSIONS 441

Pharmaceuticals as a sector are particularly of either an SA or a merger. From the view-


held captive to very high-risk product devel- point of big pharma, connection to innovative
opment models (two out of every hundred discoveries in biotech can be handled either
new drug projects make it to market), and internally (make your own, or more cost-
very long time lines for the ‘bench to bed’ effectively, buy your own biotech company),
program (an average of twelve years; or externally, through alliances with smaller
Northrup 2005). Investment costs are high biotech companies. In either case, it is gener-
for the intellectual capital part of this process ally recognized in the pharmaceutical sector
(discovery through scientific review) that most firms cannot handle all aspects of
and marketing, but quite low for ingredient the product cycle, in both small and large
costs and processing charges. In fact, the molecule development. Further, alliances are
returns for successful products are then also increasingly common between pharma
priced to cover the costs of the many failed firms and genomics-proteomics companies
projects. in order to manage licensing agreements and
Northrup (2005) describes the interplay intellectual property issues. Such alliances
between traditional pharmaceutical firms are commonly based on either a specific
(the older actors in new drug/biologics/bio- therapeutic area, or for data mining activities
products innovation) and more recently (large-scale screening of libraries on a
developed biotechnology firms (most created specific gene sequence), or technology
since the completion of the Human Genome transfer (Sammut, 2005).
Project). Pharmaceutical firms have histori-
cally focused on chemistry-based, small
molecule products (often referred to as new Changes in communication with
chemical entities, NCEs), whereas biotech
market targets
firms typically focus at first on proteins, pep-
tides, or monoclonal antibodies, all of which The traditional method of communicating
are bigger than most NCEs, and require some with targeted markets for new pharmaceuti-
route of administration into the body other cals has always been the one-on-one selling
than taking a pill. Biotech firms tend to of the new product to physicians, either in
evolve from university-based discoveries that MD offices, over lunch, or at the conference
become licensed to a new (and often small) cocktail party/dinner. In their quest for more
biotech company, headed by the academic PI effective and most cost-efficient methods of
(see Stuart and Ding 2006). Financing comes marketing, pharmaceutical firms have been
from venture capitalists during the long drug innovating with the use of information tech-
development stage, perhaps finally involving nology. Although ‘detail reps’ are still a
an initial public offering (IPO) when the commonly-used mechanism, firms such as
biotech firm goes public. Many successful Lilly have been experimenting with the use
new product cycles later, the small biotech of a ‘sales productivity process’ (Northrup
firm may reach the stage of a fully integrated 2005), which employs more frequent elec-
pharmaceutical company (FIPCO). More tronic/phone/video communication with
likely, however, is the scenario in which the physicians who have been pre-identified as
biotech firm links with other specialty firms the right target for the new drug (right spe-
to handle preclinical development/testing, cialty, use of data on past prescribing behav-
such as a contract research organization ior, preferred communication channels, etc.).
(CRO), a contract manufacturing organiza- E-detailing combines multiple channels of
tion (CMO) and a contract sales company to communication with repeated contacts to get
handle marketing (CSO). Another route is for information out on the new product, without
all three later stages to be cycled through a taking time from the physician’s busy office
big pharmaceutical firm, after the development schedule for the traditional one-on-one.
442 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

The use of patient-oriented sales of pre- efforts to build this industry have been seen
scription drugs through media advertisement in Germany, Canada, China, Korea, Taiwan
has increased in volume and advertising and Singapore. In addition, large US pharma-
sophistication. Advertisements stress the per- ceutical firms have expanded both their mar-
sonal benefits to the individual patient with keting reach and their manufacturing
cancer, acid reflux, insomnia, etc. with a networks into South America, Asia, and
dreamy backdrop, colorful costumes, or Central/Eastern Europe (Pfeffer 2005). Out-
shots of happy middle-aged active sourcing globally, once regulatory issues are
people, followed by rapid ‘fine print’ managed, allow big firms to enjoy reduced
instructions to contact your physician and a manufacturing costs and reduced marketing
list of patient conditions which would costs; but the costs involved in startup of
counter-indicate the appropriateness of the infrastructure, regulatory and cultural
new drug. These advertising strategies are no differences are usually beyond the means of
doubt riding on the perception of increasing smaller firms. We have also seen recent
numbers of well-educated, independent efforts to outsource biomedical R&D
consumers who will march into their doctor’s globally by US firms, in order to avoid
offices with demands to ‘let me try this some US regulatory constraints. Singapore
new drug.’ actively supports stem cell research,
Both of these changes in marketing strat- unlike the US, where limits are placed on
egy, away from personal contact with physi- usage of only approved, pre-existing
cians, and toward the use of either new stem-cell families, and embryo research
IT-based marketing, data-based marketing is limited due to bioethical concerns (Pfeffer
strategies, and consumer targeting, are 2005).
examples of how the role of the physician in There is another surprising and somewhat
the new drug market has changed. The insti- troublesome side-effect of globalization and
tutional environment of new healthcare the rising costs of employer-based health
products has shifted toward more compli- insurance plans in the US. Some have noted
cated multi-organizational relationships, just recently an increase in interest in the concept
as the traditional autonomy and dominance of ‘medical tourism’ among smaller,
of the physician in the healthcare sector has self-insured employers (Jonsson 2006).
been replaced by a matrix of corporate Medical tourism (also known as ‘global
actors. The ‘new technological imperative’ health care’) is the practice of sending
is one in which biotech firms, big pharma- employees overseas to receive surgery and
ceutical firms, a range of contract service post-surgical follow-up as part of their health
firms, and advertising strategies have further insurance coverage. Employees are encour-
diminished the physician’s independent aged to travel to India, Jarkarta or Bangkok
decision-making. The comparison to the old for serious surgical interventions, such as hip
imperative of demands from physicians and replacements and heart stents. The costs for
patients fueling the need for access to new overseas surgeries like these can be up to 80
technologies is striking. percent less than the same procedure in the
US, and the overseas surgery includes resort-
style convalescence. This is another example
The globalization of drug of how the technical environment (markets)
of health care has globalized, while the
manufacturing and marketing
traditional, formerly institutionalized,
Although the biotechnology sector is far concepts of US health care as unmatched,
more mature in the US than elsewhere, this and US doctors as a key partner in the
sector is definitely growing in both Europe patient–provider relationship, have receded
and Asia. Major increases in state-supported dramatically.
INSTITUTIONALISM AND THE PROFESSIONS 443

RECENTLY-PUBLICIZED SCANDALS But the case raised other disturbing ques-


AND FURTHER INSTITUTIONAL tions about the role of professional autonomy
CRISES OF ACCOUNTABILITY and the inability (or unwillingness) of other
professionals to police Shipman’s activities.
Some of the antecedents and consequences The cumulative record of suspicious deaths
of the changing institutional environment for was never scrutinized (even though UK
professional groups are well-publicized medical record collection is centralized
scandals in the delivery of professional serv- through the health service). Suspicious col-
ices. Many of these most recent scandals leagues were placated by Shipman’s assur-
involve business services like accounting, ances that he knew what he was doing and
law, and finance (Enron; MCIWORLDCOM; that no scrutiny of the deaths of his patients
Royal Ahold) but there are also scandals was necessary. His colleagues assumed
involving medicine and healthcare Shipman was being honest and open with
(the Harold Shipman scandal in the UK; them when he was being anything but. The
the organ transplantation crisis in the healthcare system did not require post-
University of California hospital system). mortem investigation of patient deaths in a
Each of these scandals points to the promises situation where simple blood tests would
and perils of deregulation, market incentives, have revealed massive drug overdoses. And
and technological change in professional Shipman moved to no fewer than four
practice. locations when outside constituents became
suspicious, but he had no trouble securing
another job and continuing his bizarre and
Harold Shipman, Kaiser grizzly practices. This case reflects a gross
Permanente, the University failure of oversight in a traditional, state-
of California-Irvine and crises supported professional setting that has
of medical confidence changed the nature of medical practice in the
UK and in continental Europe as well (cf.
Between 1976 and 1998, Harold Shipman Weaver 2006).
(a general practitioner in the UK Health The organ transplantation scandal that
Service) murdered at least 236 people all broke in California in May–August, 2006
over central England. Most of Shipman’s vic- (involving Kaiser Permanente and the UC-
tims were elderly women, and almost all of Irvine hospitals) is another example of the
the victims were murdered through drug problems new organizational forms present
overdoses (mostly morphine). Shipman was when they are confronted with new technolo-
convicted of 15 of the murders on gies. In mid-2004, Kaiser sent a letter to all
January 31, 2000 and sentenced to 15 life would-be kidney transplant patients and told
terms. He committed suicide in prison in them that they would no longer pay for
January, 2004. kidney transplants at outside hospitals.
The public inquiry that followed the reve- Instead, patients would have to come to a
lations of Shipman’s behavior, the extent of new transplant facility in San Francisco
his crimes, and the inability of the UK health where doctors affiliated with Kaiser would
service system to detect and respond to the perform the transplant.
problems in its midst have led to a wide- What happened after this is a matter of dis-
spread overhaul of the checks and balances pute. Kaiser went from having no transplant
in the UK healthcare system. Postmortems program to having the longest transplant
are now required in all patient deaths, and waiting list in the nation. In the process, their
deceased patients cannot be cremated until a patients drastically lowered their chances of
proper and independent postmortem has receiving new kidneys, many patients died
been conducted. waiting for organs, and Kaiser failed to fill
444 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

out the necessary paperwork to obtain organs violations of professional ethics that were not
for their patients. According to the Los detected by the traditional system of institu-
Angeles Times, in 2005 Kaiser performed tional oversight. But the response to these
only 54 kidney transplants and at least 108 problems has been a call not for more
patients died waiting for organs. The national market-based accountability but for
statistics for other transplant programs are more regulation of professional activity in
usually the opposite of this – twice as many the name of traditional institutional norms
transplants in proportion to the number of involving patient interests and welfare.
patients who die waiting for organs. This, and the business, financing and
National transplant regulators paid no accounting scandals we discuss below, seems
attention to these troubling trends even to suggest that there are bumps on the road to
though the data were available on the inter- the use of market mechanisms and technical
net. The case was broken when the Los environments to bring discipline to
Angeles Times began an investigative report professional practice.
on transplant programs in California and
uncovered the discrepancies (Los Angeles
Times 2006). Kaiser closed their transplant Enron, MCI-WORLDCOM and
program in May 2006. Roya Ahold: bumps on the
California assemblymen recently called road to professional onmnibus
for more oversight and regulation of trans-
business services
plant programs in light of the Kaiser
Permanente scandal and a related scandal in The accounting and financing scandals that
the University of California-Irvine Hospital rocked the American business community in
system. UCI closed its liver program in 2005 and 2006 (and the European business
November 2005 after the Los Angeles Times community through Royal Ahold, a Dutch
reported that 32 people had died awaiting food market supplier) point to many of the
transplants in 2004 and 2005 while the UC- institutional and technical problems with
Irvine hospital had turned down scores of deregulated financing systems and deregu-
donated organs. Unbeknownst to patients, lated financial markets. For our purposes,
UCI had not had a full-time liver transplant these cases also expose some of the more
surgeon for more than a year when it closed fundamental problems with the interface
the program. St. Vincent Hospital in Los between management consulting, account-
Angeles also halted its liver transplant pro- ing, and law that will likely prevent the con-
gram in September 2005 after acknowledg- solidation of these professional groups into
ing that its doctors had violated national new organizational forms.
transplant standards in 2003. Surgeons In each of these cases (and the case of
transplanted a donated liver into a patient Tyco International), the problems were
who ranked 52nd on the regional waiting list, highly similar, as were the abuses. Top exec-
bypassing dozens of people whose condi- utives of each company were paid through
tions were considered more dire. Staff mem- stock options. These options were supposed
bers subsequently falsified documents to to tie the compensation of top officials to the
cover up the action. Both of these actions financial performance of the company, but
have prompted California assemblymen to instead they provided a built-in incentive to
call for new transplant oversight in California report ever-rising profits to Wall Street
and renewed ability for the state to fine and the larger financial community so
hospitals up to $100,000 for failure to meet that stock prices would rise. None of this
basic national healthcare standards. would be problematic if the profes-
In both the Shipman case and the hospital sional groups (lawyers and accountants)
transplant cases, there were systemic exercised their professional prerogatives to
INSTITUTIONALISM AND THE PROFESSIONS 445

independently monitor the legal and CONCLUSIONS AND IMPLICATIONS


financial behavior of the firms involved.
But, in each case, there were significant The study of professions and professional
conflicts of interest that prevented this from work is intimately tied to institutionalism and
happening. institutional theory, as our chapter illustrates.
The Enron case is a typical example. The questions we raised have direct implica-
Enron purchased consulting and accounting tions for future research programs on institu-
services from Arthur Anderson, at the time tional theory and professional work.
one of the ‘Big Five’ accounting One of the more interesting implications
firms. Enron also retained external legal of the new institutional environment for pro-
counsel that assumed that Arthur Andersen fessional practice is the virtual disappearance
was doing its job of monitoring the finan- of individual clients from our discussion
cial transactions of the company so that the here. Traditional professional practice norms
certified profits of the company were focused on forging links between profession-
legitimate. Both Arthur Anderson and als and clients. But the newly developing net-
Enron’s legal firm received millions of worked linkages we discuss seem to leave
dollars in fees, fees that rose with Enron’s individual clients behind in the name of pur-
reported profits. suing profit and efficiency. Researchers will
When these cases began to unravel, each want to study new organizational alliances,
revealed a tangled web of financial transac- forms and marketing strategies for the provi-
tions that (a) systematically misrepresented sion of healthcare, both in the United
the financial health of the firm, misrepresen- States and elsewhere, documenting the
tations that were certified by accounting evolution and growth of new institutionalized
firms with substantial financial interests in norms and practices. The interface between
the consulting income they were deriving pharmaceutical companies, physicians, hos-
from the firms they were auditing, (b) law pitals, biotechnology terms, advertisers, and
firms that were more than content to look the governments, is spreading in a distinctively
other way as long as legal fees were regularly North American environment where
paid and audits were certified as legitimate, deregulation of health care (even in light of
and (c) CEOs and top managers who made the transplantation scandals in California)
millions from falsified corporate profits and seems to be on an upswing. Researchers
backdated stock options (see Froud et al. interested in the interface between
2004 for an analysis of Enron as both an professional work and institutional theory
example of corporate failure through should also examine more closely the
‘financialization,’ and as a firm embedded increased ability of insurers, big clients, and
within a political web of special interests and others to purchase professional services in a
powerful actors). global outsourced labor market where price
All of these situations have led to funda- competition will become increasingly
mental questioning of Generally Accepted salient. The growing embeddedness of these
Practices in accounting and the ability of networked connections between large institu-
accountants and lawyers to remain tional and corporate actors, to the exclusion
independent from their clients. They have of the best interests of individual clients and
also struck a (for now) fatal blow to consumers of professional services, suggests
the concept of clusters of accounting, that not all forms of embeddedness are
legal, and management consulting desirable.
services (omnibus business services firms) Another area of research will be the
given the likelihood of fundamental con- development of new collaborative alliances
flicts of interest in a deregulated financial between management consultants and
environment. economists as would-be professional groups,
446 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

and the interface between consultants, Delivery: New Insights into Organization
accounting, and legal practice as business Theory. San Francisco: Jossey-Bass, pp. 53–85.
services (see Gross and Keiser 2006). Bell, Daniel. 1976. The Coming of Post-
Management consultants and economists are Industrial Society. New York: Basic Books.
competing over the task domain to reorgan- Bottery, Mike. 1996. “The challenge to profes-
ize professional practice in the name of effi- sionals from new public management:
Implications for the teaching profession.”
ciency and cost effectiveness. Since
Oxford Review of Education, 22:179–197.
management and economic consulting is the Burns, Lawton R., 2002. The health care value
least regulated of these occupational groups, chain: Producers, purchases, and providers.
students of the professions will need to San Francisco, CA: Jossey-Bass.
examine the evolving institutional and tech- Burns, Lawton R. (ed.) 2005. The Business of
nical environment that consultants, account- Healthcare Innovation. Cambridge University
ants, and lawyers face in the wake of the Press.
well-publicized scandals discussed here Christiansen, T. and P. Laegreid. 1999. “New
(see also Fourcade 2006). public management: design, resistance, or
These research problems, among others, transformation? A study of how modern
suggest that the interface between the profes- reforms are received in a civil service
system.” Public Productivity and Manage-
sions and institutional theory will continue to
ment Review, 23:169–193.
attract substantial interest. The ability of
Dunleavy, Patrick, H. Margetts, S. Bastow and
institutional theory to provide insight into J. Tinkler. 2005. “New public management is
both the dark ethical scandals of the early dead – Long live digital-era governance.”
21st century and the growing embeddedness Journal of Public Administration Research
of well-networked corporate actors at the and Theory, 16: 467–494.
expense of clients attests to the flexibility Epstein, Cynthia F. 1993. Women in Law, 2nd
and strength of research on the professions edn. Chicago: University of Illinois Press.
framed by institutional theory. Epstein, C.F. 2004. “Border crossings: The con-
straints of time norms in transgressions of
gender and professional roles.” In C.F.
Epstein and Arne Kalleberg (eds.), Fighting
NOTE for Time: Shifting Boundaries of Work and
Social Life. New York: Russell Sage.
1 Data are from the Current Population Survey, Esping-Anderson, Gosta. 1989. Three Worlds
1970–2004, US Bureau of the Census, and reflect
of Welfare Capitalism. Oxford: Polity.
changes among physicians, lawyers, accountants,
natural scientists, social scientists, and professors of
Fourcade, Marion. 2006. “The Construction of
natural and social science. a Global Profession: The Transnationalization
of Economics.” American Journal of
Sociology, 112:145–194.
Frank, David John. 1997. “Science, nature, and
REFERENCES the globalization of the environment,
1870–1990.” Social Forces, 76: 409–435.
Abbott, A.D. 1988. The System of Professions: Frank, David John, J.W. Meyer and David
An Essay on the Division of Expert Labor. Miyahara. 1995. “The individualist polity and
Chicago: University of Chicago Press. the prevalence of professionalized psychol-
Abbott, A.D. 1991. “The future of professions: ogy: A cross-national study.” American
Occupation and expertise in the age of Sociological Review, 60: 360–377.
organization.” Research in the Sociology of Friedland, Roger and Robert Alford. 1991.
Organizations, 8: 17–42. “Bringing Society Back In: Symbols, Practices
Alexander, Jeffrey A., and Thomas D'Aunno. and Institutional Contradictions,” in Walter
1990. “Transformations of Institutional W. Powell and Paul DiMaggio (eds.), The
Environments: Perspectives on the New Institutionalism in Organizational
Corporatization of U.S. Health Care.” Analysis, pp. 232–263. Chicago, IL:
In S. Mick (ed.) Innovations in Health Care University of Chicago Press.
INSTITUTIONALISM AND THE PROFESSIONS 447

Friedson, Eliot. 1986. Professional Powers: of the management vs. administration


A Study of the Institutionalization of Formal debate.” Public Administration Review, 58:
Knowledge. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago 189–193.
Press. Larsen, Magali Sarfatti. 1977. The Rise of
Freidson, Eliot. 2001. Professionalism, the Third Professionalism. Berkeley, CA: University of
Logic: On the Practice of Professional Know- California Press.
ledge. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Leicht, Kevin T. and Mary L. Fennell.
Froud, Julie, Sukhdev Johal, Viken Papazian, 2001. Professional Work. Oxford: Blackwell
and Karel Williams. 2004. “The Temptation Publishers.
of Houston: A Case Study of Financialization.” Leicht, Kevin T. and Elizabeth C.W. Lyman.
Critical Perspectives on Accounting, 15: 2006. “Markets, institutions, and the crisis
885–909. of professional practice.” Research in the
Garth, Bryant G. and Yves Dezalay. 2002. The Sociology or Organizations, 17–44.
Internationalization of Palace Wars: Lawyers, Light, Donald W. 1991. “The restructuring
Economists, and the Contest to Transform of American health care.” Pp. 53–65 in
Latin American States. Chicago, IL: University T. Litman and L. Robins (eds.), Health
of Chicago Press. Politics and Policy, 2nd edn. New York:
Giddens, Anthony. 1994. Beyond Left and Wiley.
Right: The Future of Radical Politics. Light, D.W. 1993. “Coountervailing power:
Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. The changing character of the medical pro-
Greenwood. R. and C.R. Hinings. 1993. fession in the United States.” Pp. 69–79 in
“Understanding strategic change: The con- F.W. Hafferty and J.B. McKinlay (eds.), The
tribution of archetypes.” Academy of Changing Medical Profession: An Interna-
Management Journal, 36: 1052–1081. tional Perspective. New York: Oxford
Greenwood, R. and C.R. Hinings. 1996. University Press.
“Inderstanding radical organizational Light, D.W. 1995. “Countervailing powers:
change: Bringing together the old and new A framework for professions in transition.”
institutionalism.” Academy of Management Pp. 25–41 in T. Johnson, G. Larkin, and
Review, 21:1022–1054. M. Saks (eds.), Health Professions and
Gross. Claudia and Alfred Kieser. 2006. “Are the State in Europe. New York: Routledge.
consultants moving toward globalization?” Los Angeles Times. 2006. “Kaiser put kidney
Research in the Sociology of Organizations, patients at risk.” May 3rd <www.latimes.
24: 69–100. com>.
Hafferty, F.W. and D.W. Light. 1995. Lynn, L.E. 1998. “The new public manage-
“Professional dynamics and the changing ment: How to transform a theme into a
nature of medical work.” Journal of Health legacy.” Public Administration Review, 58:
and Social Behavior, 36: 132–153. 231–237.
Hammond, Teresa A. 2002. A White Collar Malhotra, N., T. Morris and C.R. Hinings. 2006.
Profession: African American Certified Public “Variation in organizational form among
Accountants Since 1921. Chapel Hill, NC: professional service organizations.” Research
University of North Carolina Press. in the Sociology of Organizations, 24:
Ironside, Michael and Roger Seifert. 2003. 171–202.
Facing Up to Thatcherism. Oxford: Oxford Manning, Nick. (2000) The New Public
University Press. Management and its Legacy. World Bank
Johnson, Thomas and Robert S. Kaplan. 1987. Discussion Note. <www1.worldbank.org/
Relevance Lost: The Rise and Fall of publicsector/civilservice/debate1.htm>.
Management Accounting. Cambridge: Meyer, J.W. and B. Rowan. 1977.
Harvard Business School Press. “Institutionalized organizations: formal
Jonsson, Patrik. 2006. “Union blocks foreign structure as myth and ceremony.” American
healthcare plan.” Christian Science Monitor, Journal of Sociology, 83: 340–363.
Sept. 29th, 2006, www.csmonitor.com/ Northrup, J. 2005. “The pharmaceutical
2006/0929/p02s01-usec.html. sector.” Pp 27–102 in L.R. Burns (ed.),
Kaboolian, Linda. 1998. “The New Public The Business of Healthcare Innovation.
Management: Challenging the boundaries Cambridge University Press.
448 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Oliver, C. 1991. “Strategic responses to institu- Scott, W.R. 1995. Institutions and Organi-
tional processes.” Academy of Management zations. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.
Review, 16: 145–179. Scott, W.R., M. Ruef, P.J. Mendel and
Pfeffer, Cary G. 2005. “The biotechnology C.A. Caronna. 2000. Institutional Change
sector: Therapeutics.” Pp.103–189 in Burns, and Healthcare Organizations. Chicago, IL:
above. The University of Chicago Press.
Powell, W.W. and P. DiMaggio (eds.). 1991. Singh, Jitendra V., David J. Tucker, and Robert J.
The New Institutionalism in Organizational House. 1986. “Organizational legitimacy
Analysis. Chicago: University of Chicago and the liability of newness.” Administrative
Press. Science Quarterly, 31: 171–193.
Reschenthaler, G.B. and F. Thompson. 1996. Starr, Paul.1982. The Social Transformation of
“The information revolution and the new American Medicine. New York: Basic Books.
public management.” Journal of Public Stein, Jeremy. 1983. Monetarist, Keynesian
Administration and Theory, 6: 125–143. and New Classical Economics. Oxford:
Rifkin, Jeremy. 2004. The European Dream. Blackwell.
New York: Penguin. Streeck, Wolfgang and Philippe C. Schmitter,
Sammut, S.M. 2005. “Biotechnology business ed. 1985. Private Interest Government:
and revenue models: the dynamic of Beyond Market and State. Beverly Hills, CA:
technological evolution and capital market Sage.
integretity.” Pp 190–222 in Burns, above. Stuart, Toby E. and W.W. Ding. 2006. “When
Savoie, Donald. 1995. “What’s wrong with the do scientists become entrepreneurs? The
new public management?” Canadian Public social structural antecedents of commercial
Administration, 38: 112–121. activity in the academic life sciences.”
Scott, Graham, I. Ball and T. Dale. 1997. “New American Journal of Sociology, 112:
Zealand’s public sector management reform: 97–144.
Implications for the United States.” Journal Suchman, Mark C. Daniel Steward and Clifford
of Policy Analysis and Management, 16: Westfall. 2001. “The Legal Environment of
357–381. Entrepreneurship: Observations on the
Scott, W.R., and J.W. Meyer. 1983. “The organ- Legitimation of Venture Finance in Silicon
ization of societal sectors.” Pp. 129–53 in Valley.” In C. Shoonhaven and E. Romanelli
John W. Meyer and W. Richard Scott (eds.), (eds.), The Entrepreneurship Dynamic. Palo
Organizational Environments: Ritual and Alto, CA: Stanford University Press.
Rationality. Beverly Hills, CA: Sage. Weaver, Matt. 2006. “Coroners reform plan
Scott, W. Richard. 1987. “The adolescence of criticized.” Guardian, June 12th, 2006.
institutional theory.” Administrative Science <www.guardian.co.uk>.
Quarterly, 32: 493–511. Williamson, Oliver E. 1985. The Economic
Scott, W. Richard. 1992. Organizations: Institutions of Capitalism. New York: Free
Rational, Natural and Open Systems. Press.
Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.
18
Institutionalism and
Globalization Studies
Gili S. Drori

Predating any discussions of globalization, from their global context, and thus political
institutional presuppositions regarding units, once defined as nation-states, they are
embeddedness and diffusion were applied on subject to the global cultural process, such as
the world level in what was then called the discourses of developmentalism or actor-
comparative studies. As early as the 1970s, hood. Derived from this logic are several
when comparative studies were caught in an other institutional emphases, for example on
impasse between dependency and modern- the diffuse state of authority of the global
ization theories, a group of Stanford system, on the role of institutional mecha-
University scholars challenged the prevailing nisms in the cross-national diffusion of
realist comparative traditions and made ideas and practices, and on the rationalizing
initial empirical studies that set the founda- and standardizing impact of international
tion for almost four decades of prolific insti- organizations, the professions, and the uni-
tutional and comparative research. Today, in versalized models they carry. These issues
the era of hyperglobalization and countless serve as the axes for world society theory’s
commentaries on globalization, institu- voluminous research tradition, offering
tional theory of globalization – commonly abstract yet richly empirical work.
referred to as world society theory – has From its initial steps (Meyer, Boli-Bennet
carved a substantial niche in globalization and Chase-Dunn, 1975; Meyer and Hannan,
studies. 1979) through its mature statements (Meyer,
The main theme of the institutionalist Boli and Thomas, 1987; Meyer et al., 1997;
tradition in globalization studies is that the Boli and Thomas, 1997), world society
world is the environment and that nation- theory formulated a new and institutionalist
states, as well as multinational corporations globalization theory while also adding to the
and international organizations, are the richness of institutional thinking. In discus-
organizations embedded in it. The related sions of globalization, world society theory
themes – of interconnectedness, universal- challenged the then-reigning perspectives in
ism, and embedding – invoke Donne's comparative sociology – dependency and
imagery: with the phrase ‘no nation-state is modernization theories – by adding institu-
an island’ (Meyer, Boli, Thomas and tionalist and cultural tones to the highly
Ramirez, 1997): nation-states are embedded instrumentalist discourse of the times and
in world society, rather than disconnected highlighting the constitution of the global as
450 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

an additional ‘level’ to the international and DEBATING GLOBALIZATION


transnational. In its way, it also disputed
the common vision of nation-states as Globalization is a new concept for social
autonomous and calculating rational actors research: the term globalization has flour-
by drawing attention to the consolidating ished as a social science phrase only since
supralevel of globalization and to the the mid-1990s (Guillén, 2001), in spite of the
diffusion of ideas and practices from this long history of comparative work in sociol-
common core. To institutional thinking, ogy and the other social sciences. Yet it is the
world society theory added macro-level theoretical roots in such prior comparative
discussions situating even nation-states studies that are shaping the current scholarly
within a broader environment, elaborated the debates regarding globalization. And so the
phenome-nological tradition within institu- worldviews of dependency and moderniza-
tional thinking, and enhanced the empirical tion theorists, who fiercely debated the
grounding of institutional work with highly nature of world affairs and international
quantitative research. processes during most of the twentieth
The goals of this chapter are to describe century, are now ‘reawakened’ into global-
the tenets of world society theory and to ization debates between world system and
place these institutional insights in the con- neoliberal theoreticians, respectively. In this
text of current debates about globalization, section I describe the debates between these
its definition, and its trajectory. Following a two theories of globalization and argue that
review of the emergence of globalization in spite of their fierce debate they share basic
studies and the breakthrough of world soci- assumptions and that it is these assumptions
ety theory in this field, I lay out the tenets that have been later challenged so effectively
of this theory, define its central concepts, by institutional theory.
and describe its empirical corpus. This These two theoretical traditions differ on
review – empirical and conceptual – almost every idea (Table 18.1). First, they
emphasizes world society theory in particu- differ in their perception of the global
lar, while situating this tradition within the system. Looking at the trends of global
context of other comparative institutional expansion, neoliberal theorists see a
work and of other globalization studies in global system of production and trade. They
the broad field of International Relations. see overall development for the better, even if
To clarify this distinction, two terms are advancement is not yet for all, and they con-
used to refer to the institutionalist compar- sider ‘growth through integration’ to be both
ative traditions: world society theory a development strategy and a description of
refers to the post-1980s studies, mostly globalization to date. World system theorists,
by John W. Meyer and his colleagues on the other hand, see a global capitalist
who mark the phenomenological side of system, with expanding inequalities between
institutional thinking, while the term com- classes of nations and regions. Second, while
parative institutionalism refers to pre- both these realist theories define globaliza-
1980s studies by this Stanford University tion as a period of global capitalist expan-
group (before the self-recognition of this sion, they diverge in their assessments of the
work as a theoretical tradition) and to the nature of capitalism and the trajectory of its
studies by other institutionalists whose expansion. Whereas modernization theorists
comparative work highlights operations view global capitalist expansion as progress
and networks more than the role of culture. based on criteria of efficiency, achievement,
To conclude I open a discussion of the and justice, world system theorists view
trajectory of this line of thought and global capitalist expansion as a compulsion of
research work. profit-seeking forces that results in expanding
INSTITUTIONALISM AND GLOBALIZATION STUDIES 451

Table 18.1 Defining globalization: comparing theoretical issues


Realist perspectives Institutional
Modernization World system perspective
Nature of the global system Web of interdependencies Global capitalist system World society
Nature of international Exchange sponsorship Exploitation Embededdness
relationships Domination Networks
Manipulation
Nature of social actors, Aggregate of individuals Subunit of the global capitalist Highly relevant players,
such as states and INGOs Rational actors structural system yet they are constituted,
Rational yet often passive scripted, or modeled
component units
Research questions International coordination International manipulation tools Density of the world
efforts Concealed interests and power society, hence
Processes and terms of differentials behind trade structuration
negotiated order packs and international Nature of world society
arrangements themes, or models
Capitalist histories Nature of global diffusion
Nature of
institutionalized units

divides between rich nations and peoples and In these divergent views, today’s neoliber-
poor nations and people. Third, they differ in als and world system theorists, although
their understanding of the motivation and commenting on the recent idea of globali-
interest that are driving the global system. zation, continue on old theoretical paths in
Whereas modernization theorists view glob- comparative studies. And so today’s neolib-
alization as powered by rational, cost-benefit eral writers such as Wolf (2004) and
calculation of the parties involved, founded Diamond (1993) continue on the path set by
in the natural human desire for bettering the writings of Inkeles (1969), Rostow
living conditions, world system theorists (1971), Huntington (1968), and Parsons
view it as a process of marginalization of the (1964). On the side of critical thought,
world’s underclass through the global divi- Sassen (1998), Chase-Dunn (1998), Sklair
sion of labor, production, and consumption. (2002), and Mittelman (1996) continue on
Last, they differ in their definition of the the path set in the writings of Frank (1969),
actors involved in the global system. Cardoso (1972), Wallerstein (1979, 2000)
Whereas modernization theorists see a and draw from the yet older roots of Lenin’s
system of transaction relations among work on imperialism, which itself builds on
competing yet cooperating nation-states and Marx’s and Engels’s work on capitalism.
international organizations, world system By the 1970s, these two theories reached a
theorists see a system of exploitative and theoretical impasse: although the neoliberal
manipulative dominance by elites (in both modernization theory and the Marxist world
the global core and the periphery) and multi- system theory shared a structural and global
national corporations. And although it may perspective on social processes, the debates
seem as if the two theoretical camps delin- between them were stagnating. They repeat-
eate the ‘pro and con’ stands on globaliza- edly bickered over the nature of global
tion, there are surely many critics of processes (progress or accumulation), the
globalization from both theoretical stands – motivation for global change (benevolent
most pointedly Joseph Stiglitz (2003) and or malicious), and the projections for
Saskia Sassen (1998), who, among others, future prospects (closing gaps versus
chose Globalization and its Discontents as widening divides). The main concept for
the witty title of their respective books. both these traditions was and still is a realist
452 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

perspective: in their understanding of the collective purpose’ (Meyer et al., 1987: 24),
world system, they highlight a mechanistic is fundamental to describing the influence of
image of the relations among global players culture on behavior and structure. This insti-
and assume that the players are rational and tutionalist emphasis on rationalization
bounded social actors. And any failure of this turns the discourse of rationality on its
global mechanistic system – such as war, head: it regards action and its formal justifi-
economic depression, or trade dependence – cations (in policy and other statements),
was explained in terms of its function. Armed which are often taken by realists to be
with contradictory empirical findings, the prima facie evidence of deliberated and
debates reached no resolution or even a rationally calculated intention, as scripts of
common ground for conversation since the purposive and instrumentalized intention that
presuppositions were so very different. The carry symbolic, ritualized, and ceremonial
root of the empirical and theoretical impasse importance.
was that both theories are functionalist and In this way, the institutionalist (later, the
thus share an ontological belief in the ration- world society theory) critique of the various
ality of the system. As a result, the contention realist comparative perspectives (later,
between modernization and world system globalization studies) is direct. And on all its
theories centered on the questions ‘Whose points of critique and departure, compara-
rationality?’ and ‘Who does this rationality tive institutional work invokes widely
serve?’ rather than questions about the accepted institutional principles. First,
rationality of actors. emerging from institutional insights about
the constituted nature of collective units,
comparative institutionalists challenged the
realist view of the units of the international
ENTER NEOINSTITUTIONALISM system (such as nation-states) as bounded
and rational and that societies are aggregates
On issues common to comparative studies – of individual interests, capacities, and
from war (Hironaka, 2005) to the role of the actions. This realist view, they claim, over-
state (Meyer, 2000) to economic develop- looks the prescribed nature of such collective
ment (Schofer, Ramirez, and Meyer, 2000) – ‘actors’ that is influenced by the available
the point of departure of institutional thought and legitimate models offered in and by its
is on the dual matters of culture and rational- global environment. It also ignores the
ization. First, institutionalists highlighted the porous boundaries of each such unit.
failure of realist theories to recognize the Looking at these limitations of the realist
power of culture and norms in motivating view, institutionalists understand actors to be
social change. As late as 1987, Thomas, constituted, even if reified, entities and study
Meyer, Ramirez and Boli (1987: 7) were still actorhood and agency as a Western cultural
lamenting the view of culture as the residual model (for example, Frank and Meyer,
factor in international processes and advocat- 2002).
ing the reclaiming of culture by macrosociol- Second, drawing on the notion of institu-
ogy. For institutionalists, ‘culture involves tional isomorphism (DiMaggio and Powell,
far more than general values and knowledge 1983; Zucker, 1987), institutionalists
that influence tastes and decisions; it defines challenge the realist expectation that intrinsic
the ontological value of actors and action’ needs and unique histories result in distinc-
(Meyer et al., 1987: 22; emphasis in original tive trajectories and features. Rather, they
text). Second, rationalization, which is demonstrate that nation-states worldwide
defined as ‘the structuring of everyday life share many dominant features – from the
within standardized impersonal rules that form of governmental structures and the
constitute social organization as a means to definition of citizenship to the content of
INSTITUTIONALISM AND GLOBALIZATION STUDIES 453

schoolbooks or legal documents – and argue something of a moot issue in international


that the source of such similarity and con- and comparative studies: all theoretical
vergence toward it is the enveloping world perspectives addressed the international
society (for example, Jang, 2000). ‘Common system and considered societies and states
definitions and theories of social organiza- within the context of that wider environment.
tion generate structural similarities in highly Yet world society theory pushed this point
disparate societies’ (Meyer et al., 1987: 19). further by analyzing the global itself: the
Here, no "island" or "islanders" (to repeat the global was not only the context for the prac-
Donne metaphor) are spared the isomorphic tices of nation-states and other organizations,
global pressures that also infuse the local and but it was also an analytic unit in itself. In
problematize its authenticity. this way, world society scholars came to
Third, based on institutional understand- redefine globalization.
ings of loose coupling (Weick, 1976; March
and Olsen, 1976), they challenge functional-
ists to explain the recurring disconnection REDEFINING GLOBALIZATION
between policy and action (for example,
Drori, Meyer, Ramirez and Schofer, 2003), In comparative institutional terms, globaliza-
which are otherwise explained by functional- tion is a dual process: global institutionali-
ists as failures. And fourth, whereas function- zation of world society and diffusion of
alists explain such failures as problems of world societal models to social units embed-
effective coordination of social relations (due ded in the global environment (Drori et al.,
to either incompetence or capitalist manipu- 2003; Drori, Meyer and Hwang, 2006).
lation), institutionalists draw on the notion of Globalization is therefore ‘not only adapta-
ceremonial and ritualized conformity (Meyer tion and change of national institutions [to
and Rowan, 1977) to demonstrate the power global conditions and pressures]. It is also
of legitimacy and other symbolic resources about institution building in the transnational
(for example, Drori and Meyer, 2006). arena – a space traditionally and typically
Overall, insti-tutionalists challenged the pictured and described as anomic and
common realist assumptions – whether func- adversarial’ (Djelic and Quack, 2003: 3).
tionalist and liberal or critical and neo- Figures 18.1 and 18.2 describe these two
Marxist – on their definition of the social complementary dimensions of globalization.
actor, expectation of diversity and diver- Figure 18.1 shows the diffusion of practices
gence, expectation of competence, and confi- and themes to embedded units, most obvi-
dence in the power of material rewards. They ously nation-states, and Figure 18.2 shows
also added a constructivist dimension to the the consolidation of global fields (in ways
study of the international system and later the that go beyond aggregation of trends in sub-
study of globalization. units), thus highlighting globally shared
This critique of realist approaches by com- practices and beliefs. Together, the two fig-
parative institutionalism matured over time, ures show that similar issues – such as envi-
drawing on elaborations in institutional ronmentalism, health, or rights – are
theory and on the consolidation of globaliza- institutionalized cross-nationally (as national
tion as a formal field of study. I later discuss ministries) and globally (as international
some points of connection between compar- organizations). Similar tales of this duality of
ative institutionalists in various academic globalization are empirically exemplified by
disciplines that have grown during this others: for example, universalized myths
process of coevolution. On the face of it, the of the social role of science as a mechanism
institutional point about the embeddedness of development and a progressive force
of units in their wider environment – what is have become anchored in a global web of
often called the open system model – was international science organizations since the
454 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

1.2
1
0.8
0.6
0.4
0.2
0
1870
1876
1882
1888
1894
1900
1906
1912
1918
1924
1930
1936
1942
1948
1954
1960
1966
1972
1978
1984
1990
1996
2002
Children Health Welfare Women Environment Science

Figure 18.1 Globalization as cross-national diffusion


Ratio of viable states that established a ministry, by field, 1870–2003

nineteenth century, while particular science- diffusion of models to various states and
related activities, from policy making to the organizations worldwide.
regulation of intellectual property rights, are The definition of globalization as a cross-
diffused cross-nationally as a result of these national diffusion process, often referred to
expectations and of the power of these inter- as internationalization, is now common,
national organizations to promote them even among realist researchers. The contri-
(Drori et al., 2003). In this way, globalization bution of world society theory is in the addi-
is a co-constitutive dual process: there are tion of the global level, highlighting the
reinforcing relations between the cross- consolidation of an overarching (universal or
national and the global. On one part, legiti- global) system that extends in meaning and
macy for global themes is bolstered when a form beyond the international sphere. This
practice comes to be institutionalized cross- emerging global system layers the transna-
nationally, while on the other part the global tional (effacing national boundaries) and
field serving as an important source for the global (considerably universal) in the

300

250

200

150

100

50

0
1850

1859

1868

1877

1886

1895

1904

1913

1922

1931

1940

1949

1958

1967

1976

1985

1994

Science Development Human Rights Governance Health

Figure 18.2 Globalization as the constitution of the global


Number of international organizations, by field, 1850–2000
Notee: The numbers of international organizations in development and human rights were divided by 10
to fit the scale of this graph.
INSTITUTIONALISM AND GLOBALIZATION STUDIES 455

obvious international flows or exchanges of (Djelic and Quack, 2003: 7), stalactite-like,
everything from capital and labor to with rare episodes of dramatic shift, balancing
commodities and diplomatic relations. In between the lingering effects of civilizational
addition, now that more attention is given to inertia, on the one hand, and the pressures
the global or supranational sphere, again of an ever-changing physical and social
even by realists (for example, Slaughter, world.
2004), the contribution of world society On all these dimensions – main sphere of
theory is in reorienting the discussion toward globalization, central players in globalization,
the rationalized, ritualized, and systemic and timing of globalization – world society
nature of action and behavior in the emerging theory’s perspective on globalization is a
social arena. This definition of globalization dramatic break from realist theories (see
as a dual process is therefore a clear depar- Table 18.1). Looking at globalization, they
ture from realist definitions of globalization: see a world society with an organizational
globalization is more than worldwide and ‘backbone’ (polity), in which states, organiza-
intensifying transactions and interdependen- tions, and social groups are embedded, even if
cies (for example, Keohane and Nye, 2000; in various degrees. The pivotal axis of global-
Foreign Policy, 2005, 2006); rather, global- ization is cultural, and it has dramatic impact
ization includes an additional conceptual on global change over and above economic
shift toward the universal and is thus a cul- and political effects. In the absence of an
tural process in addition to being an eco- authoritative global state or another central-
nomic and political process. In this way, the ized arrangement (Meyer, 2000: 230), the
era of globalization reflects not only a system hangs together through associational
remarkable intensification of global relations and diffuse authority. The main
exchanges and flows and a dramatic thicken- players are nation-states, international organ-
ing of international and transnational webs of izations (of various sorts), and the professions
relations, but also a change in the organizing (and the rationalized models they carry).
logic from the particularistic (national, Change is driven by world society and by the
ethnic) to the universal (human, standard- empowered ‘local’: world society offers
ized, formal). This special consideration models (scripts or prescriptions) that serve as
given to the global is more than a method- referents to embedded units; heavily infused
ological point about a higher level of analy- with the principles of progress and justice,
sis. Drawing on the idea coined by Peter enactment of such models results in extensive
Berger (1968), the consolidating global isomorphism throughout the world system.
dimension of globalization acts as a ‘sacred With this approach to globalization, world
canopy,’ or a commonly accepted world cul- society theory offers an alternative image of
ture (Drori, 2005; Boli, 2001, 2006). global social change. The realist perspective
Globalization is highly dynamic. It dialec- describes social or policy change as driven
tically contains both institutional change and by the mobilization of grassroots social
institution building: a process of ‘building groups, energized by particular grievances or
and stabilization’ (Djelic and Quack, needs and by the availability of resources
2003: 6), a world of rules and order infused (Figure 18.3A; also see, Meyer et al., 1997:
with reinvention and reordering (Djelic and 150–151, for other graphic displays of these
Sahlin-Andersson, 2006: 375–376), or a spi- competing models). Local social groups then
raling process of institutionalization and pressure the relevant decision-making organ-
globalization (Drori et al., 2003). In this way, izations (state, international nongovernmen-
it reconciles in the same complex and expan- tal organization, or possibly a multinational
sive process both seemingly contradictory corporation), which codifies the demanded
institutional notions of embeddedness and change in rules and later enforces compli-
constant change (or reinvention). Such world ance to the new rules. Change is therefore
change is ‘incremental and consequential’ linear: change is an outcome of pressures
456 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

from demands for efficiency and progress or WORLD SOCIETY: BETWEEN POLITY
for capitalist accumulation, and turning AND CULTURE
points in the linear process reflect change in
the human technologies. This causal chain Rise of the global
operates locally (Putnam, 2001) and interna-
tionally (Keck and Sikkink, 1998). Borrowing the notion of an ‘imagined com-
On the other hand, institutionalists munity’ from Anderson’s (1991) work on
describe both social change and local need as nationalism, institutionalists highlight the
prescribed by world society (Figure 18.3B). consolidation of a global imagined commu-
World society constructs and empowers local nity. Along with the recognition of a global
activity, frequently in decoupled form. As a economy, an international political system, a
result, the state is being ‘squeezed’ by both a global ecology, and world health dependen-
global society and a highly constructed but cies comes an awareness of a global society.
nevertheless active local society (see, Meyer, This awareness of the global is evident in the
1999). Any connection between need or con- increasing availability of world-level infor-
ditions, on the one hand, and action or policy, mation: Hwang (2006) demonstrates that
on the other hand, is epiphenomenal and thus information about the category of the
loosely coupled: not only are needs and ‘world’ (rather than ‘nation’ or ‘region’) is
conditions socially constructed according to increasingly available about many social
legitimate models or scripts, but the scripts issues across the board, with only a few
also assign rationality and agency to the var- exceptions regarding information that is still
ious actors. The outcome of global pressures considered highly parochial and under com-
toward rationalization and agency is a com- petition (namely, military might, employ-
plex, loosely arranged, decentralized, and yet ment, and politics). ‘The emergence of
highly active world society. world-level data indicates the construction of

A. Realist perspective

Conditions: System features: Organization, for


- Resources - Complexity coordination:
- Exchange - Competition - Globally
- Actors - Cross-nationally

B. Institutional perspective

Rationalization

Organization, as
Global rationalization,
imagined formalization and
community expression of agency
- Globally
- Cross-Nationally

Actorhood

Figure 18.3 Images of global organization trends: comparing realist and institutional perspective
INSTITUTIONALISM AND GLOBALIZATION STUDIES 457

problems and issues at the global level’ international system with an image of the
(Hwang, 2006: 82). This statistical aggrega- world as both a transnational and a global
tion to the world level, which also helps to sphere. This universalized vision of society
clarify global social problems (Ritzer, has had an important impact on world organ-
2004a), expresses a vision of the world as the ization and has reshaped world cultural
relevant social unit. tenets: the current world polity is a reflection
The economy is the social category that is of world cultural trends as much as it is a
the ‘big winner’ in terms of aggregation to codification of such norms into formal struc-
the global level. Indeed, the world economy tures of action and policy making.
is the first issue on everyone’s mind when
considering globalization, and most informa-
tion compiled at the global level concerns World polity
global trade, production, and finances.
Nevertheless, in this consolidating world This self-conscious and explicit awareness of
society, many other social issues are now the world as the social horizon has worked to
considered global features. Among them, the energize international and global organizing.
dominant issues are those where systemic Today’s world polity, defined as the
interdependence, now worldwide, can be backbone of globalization (Drori et al., 2003:
argued; ecology, health, and human rights are 44), has four main features: it is (a)
among the dominant issues, acquiring greater expansive, (b) heterogeneous, in both organi-
legitimacy as global and transnational social zational forms and substantive issues,
problems. Even beyond these ecosystemic (c) dynamic, and (d) loosely organized and
spheres, issues from social responsibility to highly decentralized.
citizenship that were once confined to the First, the world polity is rapidly expand-
boundary of the nation or the state are now ing, in numbers and in spread. Multinational
extended worldwide and enjoy heightened corporations (MNCs; Chandler and Mazlich,
attention in policy making and social action. 2005; Jones, 2005) and international organi-
The common thread of these themes is their zations, both governmental (Diehl, 1997) and
universal appeal: their description is nongovernmental (Boli and Thomas, 1997,
composed of the language of interdepend- 1999), are increasing in numbers. For
ency and universality. example, ‘since 1850, 25,000 private, not-
The drama of this reorientation toward the for-profit organizations with an international
world as the social horizon is highlighted in focus have debuted on the world stage’ (Boli
reviews of this continuous historical change, and Thomas, 1997: 174) and some 65,000
at least since the nineteenth century (for MNCs existed as of the year 2000, almost
example, Frank, Hironaka, Meyer, Schofer doubling in numbers during the last decade
and Tuma, 1999; Schofer and Meyer, 2005; of the twentieth century (Roach, 2005). This
Inoue and Drori, 2006). Although the history expansion in formal organization has also
of modernity and of the world is intertwined been experienced at the national and
with the history of the nation-state and subnational level (Drori, Meyer and Hwang,
although nationalism has dominated ideolo- 2006: 2–6). And, although most organiza-
gies since the middle of the nineteenth cen- tion is concentrated in the Western and devel-
tury, the nation-state itself is an institutional oped world (Beckfield, 2003; Roberts,
form and nation-statehood is an organizing 2005), it is under the canopy of global
myth of the current world polity (Meyer, extension and universal purpose, thus signal-
1999). At the turn of the twenty-first century, ing the expansion of the relevant social
the vision of porous boundaries and network unit to the global over and above increases
connections is now applied to the nation- in global production and global political
state, replacing the vision of the world as an integration.
458 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Second, the rapid expansion of world such as labor and religion (Boli and Thomas,
polity pulls into it more and more social 1997: 184). Today, the substantive scope of
actors, resulting in a highly heterogeneous global organization covers many issues, from
network of organizations. To begin with, it standardization (Loya and Boli, 1999) and the
brings more types of organizations into its environment (Frank, 1999; Frank et al., 1999)
web. In addition to nation-states (which are to education (Ramirez and Ventresca, 1992;
the obvious actors in an international system), Schofer and Meyer, 2005) and law (Boyle and
world society today also includes interna- Meyer, 1998), to name a mere few.
tional governmental organizations (Diehl, Third, world polity is dynamic and ever-
1997) and international nongovernmental changing, in scope and in content. Rates of
organizations (Boli and Thomas 1997, 1999). organizing accelerated exponentially at three
As a result, the much debated concern with obvious historic turning points: the late nine-
the demise of the nation-state in the age of teenth century (when Enlightenment Age
globalization (Meyer, 1999; Arrighi, 2000) ideals merged with nationalism to form the
yielded the nation-state that is one organiza- basis for twentieth-century processes), 1945
tional form in a global heterogeneous net- (the end of World War II), and 1990 (the
work of organizations. Private corporations collapse of the Soviet bloc). Any slowdown
(Chandler and Mazlich, 2005; Jones, 2005), in the rate of founding of international non-
professional groups or experts (Sahlin- governmental organizations was confined to
Andersson and Engwal, 2002; Jang, 2006; the periods of the two world wars (Boli and
Moon and Wotipka, 2006), and civil-society Thomas, 1997: 175–176) and quickly
movements (Hafner-Burton and Tsutsui, resumed, with fierce persistence, immedi-
2005; Shanahan and Khagram, 2006) are also ately following them. At these historic
added to this already diverse polity. In this turning points there was also a marked
context, the nation-state is less of a rational change in the issues that form the globally
instrument and more of a scripted rationaliz- organized fields: although most global issues
ing account. sprang out of the nineteenth-century Western
Heterogeneity is also evident in substantive agenda, many additional issues were raised
terms. This growing network of international to global consciousness and formed networks
and transnational governmental and non- of global action while others have been stag-
governmental organizations is active on a nating or even receding. For example, while
wide range of issues and in numerous sectors. ecology and natural conservation were
Although the dominant global organizational ‘almost invisible on the world agenda’ in
field is economic, including trade, industry, 1875, by 1990 ‘a plethora of conferences,
and development (Chabbot, 1999), substantial treaties, and intergovernmental and interna-
organizing is also evident in the fields of med- tional nongovernmental organizations dotted
icine and healthcare (Inoue and Drori, 2006) the global stage’ (Frank et al., 1999: 83).
and the sciences (Schofer, 1999). Together, Similarly, ‘in the late nineteenth and early
these three fields alone account for over twentieth centuries, the discussion of
44 percent of the total of international non- population control was largely taboo in the
governmental organizations active in 1988 public domain,’ yet by the late 1960s
(Boli and Thomas, 1997: 183). With the reori- ‘population had become a routine matter of
entation of world society since the late nine- public interest’ (Barrett and Frank, 1999:
teenth century toward universalized and 199–200).
individualistic themes, there has also been a Established issues have also changed their
dramatic structuration of the field of human orientation. For example, global concern
rights (Tsutsui and Wotipka, 2004) and the with health, which has been organized glob-
rights of specific groups (for example, ally since premodern times, has changed
women; Berkovitch, 1999) and a marked stag- from being perceived as a form of charity
nation in organizing around collective themes, work through visions of it as a professional
INSTITUTIONALISM AND GLOBALIZATION STUDIES 459

activity and as a tool for development to now whose numbers overwhelmed even the grow-
being perceived as a basic human right ing numbers of nation-states, intergovern-
(Inoue and Drori, 2006). Similarly, while mental organizations, and transnational
eugenics dominated the global field of popu- firms. This diffuse nature of authority is
lation control until World War II, ‘the reflected in the looseness of conformity
detestable use of eugenics by Nazi Germany mechanisms, combining coercive and ‘soft
turned the global tide against this model’ and law’ strategies to encourage compliance with
reoriented the field to embrace neo- international laws and global norms alike
Malthusian and individual choice frame- (note the three distinct theoretical stands
works (Barrett and Frank, 1999: 207). about such ‘soft’ compliance are propounded
Adding to the fast transition, the changes in in Abbott and Snidal, 2000; Barnett and
global fields have affected the embedded Finnemore, 2004; Djelic and Sahlin-
units. International organizations, in both Andersson, 2006). The "softness" of compli-
general and in specific fields, have influ- ance is dramatized by the fact that the
enced the behavior of nation-states: in overwhelming majority of international
governance (Drori, 2006), human rights organi-zations are transnational or global
(Hafner-Burton and Tsutsui, 2005), science nongovernmental voluntary associations
(Finnemore, 1993), and rules of war (Boli and Thomas, 1999). In this form,
(Finnemore, 1996a). The intervention of which is interpreted as ‘global corporatism’
international organizations as ‘teachers of (Ottaway, 2001) or ‘new global governance’
norms’ (Finnemore, 1996a) or as conveyors (Pattberg, 2005), authority is derived from
of ‘normal’ expectations (McNeely, 1995) the legitimacy of culture models that are car-
has worked to encourage national legislation, ried by global civil society and its network of
initiate local programs, and energize local organizations. In summary, while the scope,
social action groups, even though loose even if not the power, of international organ-
coupling has caused frequent failure of izations grew over the twentieth century, the
implementation. diffuse forms of their authority, coupled with
Last, the world polity is organized in a the universalized language of their princi-
rather loose and decentralized manner, look- ples, only worked to enhance their cultural
ing much like de Tocqueville’s description of authority further.
American associational society in the late Common explanations of this expansive,
eighteenth century (Meyer, Drori and heterogeneous, and loose global organizing
Hwang, 2006). The most dominant feature of cite the pressures of globalization and related
world society is its diffuse authority, or gov- competition. The conception of globalization
ernance, structure: the world polity is state- as intensification of exchange and competi-
less (absent a world state) and thus tion (for example, Keohane and Nye, 2000)
decentralized. While relying on the nation- or as transference (Bertelson, 2000) explains
state as an organizing principle and while the zeal to organize in functional terms.
sanctifying the related myth of sovereignty, Specific to not-for-profit organizing, the
the global system did not evolve to replicate functional imperative is in the centralization
this format to the global level: even the dom- of collective action and its related efficiency.
inant governmental organization, the United Kenneth Abbot and Duncan Snidal (1998: 5)
Nations, has evolved without the shoring of explicate this utility of international
muscular power or decisive action; rather, it organizations: ‘[International organizations]
is carrying its global missions in partnership allow for the centralization of collective
with many nongovernmental, for-profit, activities through a concrete and stable
and benevolent partners. Adding to this state- organizational structure and a supportive
lessness is the fact that the most dramatic administrative apparatus. These increase
expansion is in global civil society or non- the efficiency of collective activities and
governmental and not-for-profit organizations, enhance the organization’s ability to affect
460 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

the understandings, environment, and inter- conceptions and principles promoted by


ests of states.’ So, whether focusing on eco- INGOs’ (Boli and Thomas, 1997: 187).
nomic viability or political coordination and In this global structuration, the various fields
thus whether realist (Keohane and Nye, of international organization set examples
2000), neoconservative (Abbot and Snidal, of duality between structure (form or polity)
1998) or neo-Marxist (Wallerstein, 2000; and culture (content). Global organization
Sklair, 2002), the explanation rests on the not only marks the field of global action,
complexity of the increasingly global social but rather also sketches the boundaries of
system: demands exerted by globalization world culture.
compel formal organizing. Yet these utilitar-
ian perspectives ignore the reality where World culture
rates of organization outpace increases in
common or related social demands (Drori Formally defined as the ‘definitions, princi-
et al., 2006: 9–11). They also overlook the ples, and purposes [that] are cognitively con-
extent of organizing, whereas the drama of structed in similar ways throughout the
organization is experienced not only in polit- world’ (Boli and Thomas, 1997: 173), world
ical and economic spheres but also, if not culture encodes the models and institutions
mainly, in social spheres, such as rights and that are made sacred. With international
education (see Boli and Thomas, 1997, organizations of various types and forms as
1999). Last, utilitarian explanations fail to its formal embodiment or framework, world
take into account the institutional constraints culture took shape: tracing the drama of
imposed by globalization, mainly the global structuration, ‘post-War period has
requirements for greater standardization witnessed rapidly expanding moral mobili-
and rationalization imposed by the self- zation, that is, exponential increases in the
organizing and self-reinforcing system of recognition and rationalization of virtue and
world society (Drori et al., 2006). virtuosity’ (Boli, 2006: 113). This cultural
Institutional explanations of the expansion praxis worked to enhance the vision of global
of the world polity, although naming global- parameters for human society and to further
ization as the root cause, center on three par- encourage organization on a global scale,
ticular features of globalization: (a) the rise which has escalated even more during the era
of the world as the relevant social unit; (b) of hyperglobal-ization since the end of the
rationalization and standardization processes twentieth century.
that are carried by the rising legitimacy of The breadth and complexity of world
science and expertise; and (c) the rising and polity traces the dimensions of world culture,
globalizing culture of actorhood and empow- primarily expanding the issues directly pro-
erment (Meyer et al., 2006; see Figure 18.3B). nounced as global. As mentioned earlier, the
These three features, which are both cultural range of issues that mobilized world action
and structural, combine to imprint various and were highlighted as important and
globally embedded social units with the now valued world over – again, from human
acceptable features of the modern person and rights to environmentalism to inequality –
the modern organization. The world polity expanded rapidly and extend way beyond the
marks the legitimate institutional themes and trends of global consumer culture (Ritzer,
anchors them in formal structures. Most 2004b). Yet, in spite of this variety in specific
importantly, it shapes the structures and issues, the primary cultural themes remain
behavior of embedded societies: ‘The impe- guided by progress and justice (Drori, 2005).
tus for [local or national] action came from These twin pillars of Western, now global,
the transnational level. As states entered the culture (Meyer et al., 1987) mark the sancti-
process, they responded not only to their own fied themes of the still evolving global nor-
or societal interests but also to the global mative consensus.
INSTITUTIONALISM AND GLOBALIZATION STUDIES 461

Although culture is an illusive concept, the the urgency of social problems. These two
recognition of the global moral order comes cultural features – rationalization and actor-
in celebrations (announcements and titles) hood – imprint organizations, behaviors, and
and certifications (awards and licenses), practices, resulting in a hyperactive world
which vary by degrees of formality and society, increasingly proactive through
rationalization (Boli, 2006). For example, organizations and guided by world culture.
using the practice of UN dedications as a Several issues that are essential to global-
‘metric’ for the scope of world norms (Drori, ization studies are highlighted in the institu-
2005), it is obvious that some issues are more tionalist study of world culture. First, in
valued than others. Specifically, issues linked discussion of world culture, globalization
with the principal themes of progress and debates about trends and trajectories (com-
justice are privileged as global norms: among monly between the dichotomy of conver-
the 127 issues highlighted by UN dedica- gence and divergence) take the form of
tions, 100 (or 79 percent) directly address questioning global moral unity. Although the
issues of development and rights (Drori, global reaches of world culture expand
2005: 182–183); issues relating to security, rapidly, along with the rapid expansion of
sovereignty, and culture are relatively other dimensions of globalization, there are
marginalized. Also, observing the rates of still obvious expressions of national culture,
structuration of fields similarly exempli- cultural regionalization, and ‘glocalization’
fies the obvious dominance of the themes (see, for example, Helacioglu, 2000;
of progress and justice: as shown in Robertson, 1994). By fracturing global
Figure 18.2, the sizes of the global organiza- cultural work, local culture serves as a prism
tional fields of development and human for the influence of international organiza-
rights dwarf all others. tions (see, for example, Wiktorowicz, 2002),
The specific substantive issues exalted as it is also constituted by their influence and
worldwide are infused with two general work (see, for example, Drori et al., 2003,
logics: rationalization and actorhood (Meyer regarding the effects of global scientization
et al., 2006). Rationalization, or the system- trends on the constitution of rights).
atization and standardization of social life Second, in discussions of cultural colo-
(Jepperson, 2002: 257) with scientization as nialism, world society is described as rooted
its pronounced axis (Drori and Meyer, 2006), in European Enlightenment and nationalism,
establishes organizational sites and nodes. It and thus its development is described as
calls for coordination, supervision, planning, intertwined with modernity (Meyer et al.,
and study, all of which build on the mythol- 1987). Institutionalists describe the long his-
ogy of universality, thus undercutting tory as stretching over almost two centuries,
mythologies of national or local culture and before intensifying dramatically after World
further enhancing the spirit of a world soci- War II (Meyer, 2000; Djelic and Quack,
ety. Intertwined with the notion of an ordered 2003: 4), and thus distinguishing this
world is the notion of the world as manage- cultural change from the longer historic trail
able, expressed in the theme of actorhood, or of capitalism (Wallerstein, 1979). Currently,
the sense of empowered agency attributed to globalization is laden with characteristically
social actors (individuals and organizations modernist themes from the nation-state
alike; Meyer and Jepperson, 2000). The and scientization to the individual, and in
decentralized or stateless nature of the particular, of course, the themes of progress
modern world polity reflects and supports and justice.
this sense of agency: the empowerment of Third, in discussions of the tension
individuals, associations, and firms is between form and content and between cul-
enabled by the sense of openness in the polit- tural norms and the actors that propagate
ical realm, in the unbounded market, and in them, this institutional emphasis on world
462 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

culture stabilizes the study of international EMPIRICAL TRADITION


organizations and of globalization by them. It
suggests that ‘movements that anchor them- World society theory, much like the social
selves in the moral order are especially likely issues it comments on, is a distinctly global
to flourish’ (Boli, 2006: 116) and thus perspective. Meyer’s work is clearly influ-
explains the rise of particular fields of global enced by the early European sociology of
organization within the cultural trends of Émile Durkheim and Max Weber, yet it is
modern world society and the cultural (and also heavily infused with American empirical
ideological) themes of this era. In this sense, tradition. As a result, world society theory
international organizations are made up of has always emphasized the role of meaning
actors, including themselves (McNeely, and culture as explanatory factors in social
1998), while also serving as carriers of these processes while demonstrating trends and
themes and diffusing them to other embedded causes in quantitative empirical research
units. Similarly, individuals are constituted by with sophisticated statistical tools.
the professions that celebrate agency: individ- Schofer and McEneaney (2003) and
ualism takes root where psychology (Frank, Schneiberg and Clemens (2006) offer superb
Myere and Miyahara, 1995) or where human summaries of world society research agenda
resource management (Luo, 2006) flourish. and research tools. In accordance with the
In this way, comparative institutionalism, in dual definition of globalization as simultane-
also marking the phenomenological pole of ously a process of the consolidation of the
organizational institutionalism, has departed global and of cross-nation diffusion, institu-
from ‘old’ institutionalism in its focus on cul- tionalist research strategies for studying
ture and on rationalization. If by institutional- globalization apply a two-pronged approach.
ism people are embedded in habit and custom And each of the specific directions of
and thus consideration is given to the tension research is associated with a series of
between free-will and determinism, current research questions, studying the related insti-
discussions, especially in world society stud- tutional conditions and mechanisms.
ies, regard people as rationalized actors, and Table 18.2 summarizes the mounting empiri-
thus consideration is given to the tension cal research of this tradition.
between structure and agency. As is evident in Table 18.2, the body of
The emphasis on the culture of rationaliza- empirical research from a comparative and
tion and actorhood is more than a semantic institutional point of view is rather prolific.
move: this dialectic change in discourse Institutional assumptions and their related
reflects the break with path-dependent theo- propositions have been applied to various
ries (ecological determinism of some) and a issues and fields (from science and rights to
focus on traditional social science (rather than environmentalism and management, to name
strategic and managerial) perspectives. It also just a few) and across sectors (from the
means a straightforward focus on culture public to the private, from the for-profit to
as a fundamental social factor, as strongly civil society). They have also been applied to
expressed in world society-type explanations the study of both institutionalization (at both
(for example, Drori, Jang and Meyer, 2006). the global and the national levels) and diffu-
This highly cultural perspective, even in its sion (across embedded units, most often
most phenomenological works, is neverthe- nation-states). Empirical research in this tra-
less anchored in a highly empirical research dition has relied on a variety of methods:
tradition. As a result, the institutionalist study while most studies rely on statistical methods
of world culture and world polity is grounded (frequently, regression models or event his-
in formidable empirical descriptions of these tory analyses; see Schofer and McEneaney,
otherwise illusive sociological terms and 2003, for a detailed review of strategies),
complex global processes. more and more studies add a component of
INSTITUTIONALISM AND GLOBALIZATION STUDIES 463

Table 18.2 Institutional research of globalization: review of research agenda, tools,


and examples
Globalization Research agenda Examples
As consolidation of Characteristics of world 1. Formalization, standardization, and scientization
the global society 2. Network rather than hierarchical structure
1. Rationalization 1, 2. Frank et al. (1999) on nature and environmentalism, Jang
2. Diffuse authority; (2006) on transparent governance, Boli and Thomas (1997,
statelessness 1999) on global civil society
3. Actorhood, individualism 3. Frank et al. (1995) and Frank and Meyer (2002) on person-
hood, Luo (2006) on personnel training
4. Rise of the global 4. Hwang (2006) on references to the global, Drori (2006) on
expressions of global cultural appreciation
Institutionalization 1-A. Numbers and founding dates of international organizations,
process; expansion by field, over time. Drori (2006) on governance, Chabbott (1999)
on development, Tsutsui and Wotipka (2004) on human rights
1. Normative 1-B. Number and confirmation dates of international
consolidation over time conventions and agreements, by field, over time. Frank (1999)
on environmental treaties, Wotipka and Ramirez (forthcoming)
2. Historical change of on ratification of women’s rights convention, Berkovitch (1999)
dominant models on world conferences on women, Barrett and Frank (1999) on
population control conferences
3. Embeddedness 1-C. Number of references to themes, in literature, by issue, over
intensifying over time time. Drori (2006) on governance, Moon and Wotipka (2006)
on management education
1-D. Number of founding dates of practices in embedded units,
by field, over time. On national practices: Hwang (2006)
on strategic planning, Mendel (2006) on standardization
On practices in other units: Luo (2006) on corporate training
2-A. Consolidation: Drori (2006) on governance
2-B. Change in dominant themes: Schofer (1999) on science,
Berkovitch (1999) on women, Barrett and Frank (1999) on
population policies, Inoue and Drori (2006) on health
3. Boli, Loya, and Loftin (1999) on membership in INGOs
Origins 1-A. Historical turning points, most obviously World War II
1. World events (Barrett and Frank, 1999)
2. Relations with other 1-B. Period-specific effects: Jang (1999) on science
themes or models 2. Schofer and Meyer (2005) on higher education
As worldwide Features of diffusion: 1-A. Adoption across nation-states: Boli (1987) on constitutional
diffusion 1. Adoption across types rights, Finnemore (1993) and Jang (2000) on science
of globally embedded units 1-B. Adoption across other types of embedded units: Luo (2006)
2. Decreased variation on human resource management in corporations
among globally 2-A. Isomorphism across nation-states: Ramirez and Ventresca
embedded units (1992) on education
2-B. Isomorphism across other embedded units: Luo (2006)
on corporate training
Causes: 1. Schofer et al. (2000) on science and economic
1. Absence of effect development, Finnemore (1993) and Jang (2000)
from local needs or on science, Drori (2006) on governance
conditions 2-A. Effects of national membership in international
2. World society organizations: Drori, Jang and Meyer (2006) on
influence: governance, Jang (2000) on science ministry
A. Effects of formation, Schofer and Hironaka (2005) on
embeddedness in world environmental protection
polity 2-B. Effects of missions by IO experts: Finnemore (1993) on
B. Effects of particular UNESCO and national science policy bodies, Strang and
international organizations Chang (1993) on ILO and welfare expenditure, McNeely (1995)
on UNESCO and education policies
Continued
464 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Table 18.2 Institutional research of globalization: review of research agenda, tools,


and examples – cont’d
Globalization Research agenda Examples
C. Imputing effects of 2-C. Finnemore (1993) on science policy
experts and expertise 2-D. Frank (1999) on environmental treaties
D. Endorsement by Wotipka and Ramirez (forthcoming) on ratification of women’s
embedded units rights convention
E. Location in world society 2-E. Strang (1990) on colonial ties, Drori, Jang and Meyer (2006)
on essential and peripheral differences
Outcomes: 1. Drori et al. (2003) on science, Hafner-Burton and
1. Loose coupling between Tsutsui (2005) on human rights
policy and practice 2. Drori et al. (2003) on science and democratization, Drori
and Meyer (2006) on scientization and organization
2. Unintended consequences

content analysis (for example, Drori, 2006; and Thomas, 1997, 1999), conferences
Hwang, 2006). This research tradition has (Berkovitz, 1999), and treaties (Frank, 1999)
been true to its aspiration as commentary to cross-national density of ministries (Jang,
about historical change by compiling rich 2000; Kim, Jang, and, Hwang, 2002), treaty
longitudinal data and relying on change and ratification (Wotipka and Ramirez, 2008),
causation methods. And while the studies and numerous other local practices. Although
cited in Table 18.2 refer strictly to compara- world society scholars have built an impres-
tive research (it relies on a wide range of sive set of cross-national data across a variety
cases for the study of diffusion), numerous of social issues, these studied are still lim-
institutional studies document the process of ited. Most important, although the availabil-
diffusion into particular countries (for exam- ity of historical indicators for globalization
ple, various chapters in Sahlin-Andersson on its dual levels is sure to improve with our
and Engwall, 2002) or on particular organi- growing interest in global studies, the compi-
zational sites (for example, various chapters lation of data poses a problem of reification.
in Djelic and Sahlin-Andersson, 2006). Specifically, cross-national analyses con-
This impressive empirical corpus is not tribute to the reification of nation-states:
without weakness, in regards to both data and while we debate the role and future of
conceptual issues. The obvious weakness nation-states in an increasingly global and
emerges from the availability of data: data transnational world, we rely on national data
about the global system as the unit of analy- to describe diffusion processes. Here, world
sis are available only once we conceive of society scholars share research challenges
this unit as relevant and thus are available with many other institutional scholars, across
only for the recent period and only for an disciplinary lines: Sharing the desire to
incomplete list of social issues (Hwang, remain faithful to constructivist and pheno-
2006). Similarly, data on nation-states are menological assumptions, while at the same
available only since the nation-state was con- time wishing to ground its theory in conven-
ceived as the ‘imagined community,’ and thus tional empirical tradition of social science
longitudinal empirical studies of cross- research.
national patterns have been possible only
since the nineteenth century. Seeing this
challenge, world society researchers have JUNCTURES, OR BEYOND SOCIOLOGY
come up with a range of original longitudinal
indicators for global social change: from Complicated further by the newness of the
global measures of international organiza- term globalization, the debates surrounding
tions and their discourses (for example, Boli globalization are complex ‘since there are no
INSTITUTIONALISM AND GLOBALIZATION STUDIES 465

definite or fixed lines of contestation’ (Held conservative IR scholars who recognize the
and McGrew, 2000: 1). Guillén (2001), magnitude of this phenomenon fail to
in reviewing mainly sociological literature, address the axiomatic institutional claim that
revealed the complex nature of current the social construction of knowledge is
debates by outlining the cross-cutting intertwined with the social construction of
answers to the main questions in these reality (see Barnett and Finnemore, 2004: 29,
debates. In this sea of literature on globaliza- for a review). This unease with the highly
tion, institutional comparative work has constructivist tone of world society work is
engaged many of the established issues. clearly expressed in the substantial literature
Many scholars – from communitarians in IR studies of the role of international
(Etzioni, 2004) to IR institutionalists organizations in producing the obvious simi-
(Ruggie, 1998; Wendt, 1999) – employ the larity across nations: such work (Finnemore,
terms world society and world polity. 1996a; Barnett and Finnemore, 1999;
Similarly, many scholars analyze world Khagram, Riker, and Sikkink, 2001) explic-
norms: of humanitarian aid (Finnemore, itly distances itself from world society
1996a), national security (Katzenstein, arguments (Finnemore, 1996b).
1996), and sovereignty (Krasner, 1999). These debates expose the gulf between
Further, commonalities extend to several world society theory and other theories in
other bodies of literature, along different globalization studies. IR attempts to ‘bring
conceptual and substantive shared themes: society back in’ by considering regimes
the role of the professions (Dezalay and (Krasner, 1983) and epistemic communities
Garth, 1996), even if the world society (Haas, 1992), which, although they shared
approach is less instrumentalist; the consoli- the challenge to the state-centric view with
dation of world order, among conservatives world society theory, still could not accept
(Slaughter, 2004), cosmopolitanists (Held, the highly constructivist and cultural empha-
1995, 2003; Beck, 2006), or communitarians sis of institutionalism. Therefore, current IR
(Etzioni, 2004), even if the world society studies of network relations among various
approach is less deterministic; and the influ- global actors (for example, Ottaway, 2001;
ence of inherent ordering logics, as in Pattberg, 2005) still reject the rationalized
Foucault’s work on governmentality, even if and ritualized nature of such partnerships
the world society approach attributes and fail to see this new mode of global gov-
less influence to the power and interests of ernance as itself a period-specific mythology
government. of management (Drori, 2006).
Still, in general, even these common uses
of such concepts as liberal embeddedness are
challenged by the constructivist view. In
other words, although the obvious presence INSTITUTIONALIST FOCUS ON THE
of globalization led many researchers to con- GLOBAL: A SUMMARY
sider the consolidation of international
regimes that govern world affairs (for exam- Institutional theory developed contempora-
ple, Ruggie, 1982; Krasner, 1983; neously with the consolidation of globaliza-
Moravcsik, 2000), most IR scholars regard tion as a field of inquiry and commentary.
international regimes as governed by the Today, some thirty years after the
power of a few players and as arenas for institutional breakthrough and twenty years
international cooperation (Moravcsik, 2003), into the ‘era of globalization,’ it is clear that
rather than conceiving of them as constituted institutional thought influenced globalization
authorities. Even in recognizing the discussions. Even more, it is clear that
importance of knowledge and expertise to comparative and global studies have con-
the authority of international organizations, tributed to the advancement of institutional
466 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

thinking. In current scholarship, the follow- Sixth, the isomorphism and decoupling
ing institutional propositions have been argument: Ceremonial commitment to the
applied to interpret globalization processes. globally institutionalized models, structura-
First, the institutionalization argument: Over tion based on symbolic gesturing, and
time, cultural themes institutionalize at the gratuitous compliance with universalized
global level – evident in the expansion of standards result in loosely connected struc-
policies and practices and in the consolida- tures, action, and formal discourses. Surely
tion of particular models or scripts – to create not all particularistic factors dissolve in the
the global environment in which societies, face of external influences; rather, various
organizations, and individuals are embedded. studies show that national (for example,
Second, the diffusion argument: Once polity type), organizational (for example, size),
globally institutionalized, a model diffuses to and sector-specific (for example, economic
the various units in the relevant field. Global impact) features influence the diffusion of
diffusion brings the script (in its various practices. This influence creates a varied
forms as a practice, a structure, and an idea) landscape of conditions that often maps onto
to be enacted by entities embedded in this variations in embeddedness and is captured
environment. Global diffusion is supported in the notion of ‘glocalization.’
by the ideas of universality of knowledge and Seventh, the cost of isomorphism argu-
the features of society. ment: Global isomorphism bears unique,
Third, the embeddedness argument: possibly costly or negative effects on stated
Nesting in, connections with, and openness goals of performance, thus explaining much
toward globalized and rationalized institu- of the failure in the implementation of poli-
tional models and their carriers result in cies in developing countries and the embrac-
‘contagion.’ Therefore, relations of various ing of management ideologies into corporate
forms and degrees of intensity affect the practices.
propensity to adopt a model and enact its Eighth and last, the unintended conse-
script. In explaining ‘higher-order’ effects quences argument: Global isomorphism
on globally embedded social units, some results in social changes that were unintended
describe the pressure of world society as the and unplanned in the formal performance
work of social movement (Bartley, 2003), goals. The unintended outcomes diffused and
while others explain this pressure as highly institutionalized worldwide in addition to, yet
diffuse and indirect (Meyer, 2000). in a loose connection with, the diffusion of
Fourth, the argument regarding the role of formal scripts of planned goals of perform-
carriers: Particular international and transna- ance. Drawing on Merton’s (1936) canonized
tional players serve as carriers of the institu- work on the ‘unanticipated consequences of
tionalized global models, using various purposive social action,’ the institutional
strategies of influence and socialization that explanation of systemic failure hinges on
result in isomorphism. the primacy of institutional considerations in
Fifth, the institutional change argument: action and thus on inherent structural condi-
In the face of institutionalization (of models tions, rather than on the bias of intensions or
and their carriers), social actors change to the inefficiency of communications.
conform with or adapt to the new legitimate Together, these canonized arguments
script. This change is an integral part of focus on the process of institutionalization,
the process of institutionalization, further on its antecedents (or causes), on its features,
reinforcing a sense of a field. And although and on its consequences. The different
change has not been without conflict over emphases of the arguments describe histori-
meanings and over the form that practices to cal processes and today’s conditions and
convey the meanings take, globalization has identify causal mechanisms, as well as com-
resulted in dramatic isomorphism and con- menting on the trajectories and impacts of
siderable convergence (Meyer et al., 1975). institutional forms.
INSTITUTIONALISM AND GLOBALIZATION STUDIES 467

In contrast, realist perspectives fail to REFERENCES


explain many of the trends often considered
as ‘globalization.’ In their insistence on Abbott, Kenneth W., and Duncan Snidal. 1998.
seeking power and interests, they are unable ‘Why states act through formal international
to explain the rise of many global social organizations.’ Journal of Conflict Resolution,
movements – from human rights (Hafner- 42(1): 3–32.
Burton and Tsutsui, 2005) and gay and Abbott, Kenneth W., and Duncan Snidal. 2000.
lesbian legislation (Frank and McEneaney, ‘Hard and soft law in international gover-
1999) to science (Drori et al., 2003) – and the nance.’ International Organization, 5(3):
421–456.
persistently loosely coupled nature of such
Anderson, Benedict. 1991. Imagined Commu-
movements. The justifications for the expan-
nities: Reflections on the Origin and Spread
sions are themselves rationalized scripts, and of Nationalism, 2nd edn. London and New
whereas the explanatory factors are mainly York: Verso.
related to emebeddedness in world society. Arrighi, Giovanni. 2000. ‘Globalization, state
With its strongest statement by Meyer sovereignty, and the ‘endless’ accumulation
et al. (1997) and with explication of organi- of capital.’ Pp. 125–148 in Don Kalb et al.
zation (Meyer et al., 2006) and science and (eds.), The Ends of Globalization: Bringing
expertise (Drori et al., 2003), world society Society Back In. New York: Rowman &
theory has articulated explanations for cross- Littlefield.
national diffusion, global structuration, and Barnett, Michael N., and Martha Finnemore.
1999. ‘The Politics, power, and pathologies
the cultural and historical trends that drive
of international organizations.’ International
them. Staying on its current course from
Organization, 53(4): 699–732.
empirical longitudinal studies, this tradition Barnett, Michael, and Martha Finnemore.
will continue to decipher the form and 2004. Rules for the World: International
change of world society. Seeing organiza- Organizations in Global Politics. Ithaca, NY:
tional fields as dimensions of world society, Cornell University Press.
it will continue on the path of studying the Barrett, Deborah, and David J. Frank. 1999.
model in both form and in content, as well as ‘Population control for national develop-
its historical trajectory in both dimensions ment: From world discourse to national
and its antecedents and consequences. And policies.’ Pp. 198–221 in J. Boli and
although current studies focus on particular G. M. Thomas, Constructing World Culture:
International Nongovernmental Organiza-
global fields (such as environmentalism,
tions Since 1875. Stanford, CA: Stanford
health, governance), more can be studied
University Press.
about world society from the new research Bartley, Tim. 2003. ‘Certifying forests and fac-
across these global fields. The research tories: States, social movements, and the rise
moves from a mapping stage (of content and of private regulation in the apparel and
structure and their historical change) to forest products fields.’ Politics & Society,
assessing the principles that are possibly 31(3): 433–464.
imprinted in the various fields, regardless of Beck, Ulrich. 2006. Cosmopolitan Vision.
their focus on specific issues. This work can Cambridge, UK: Polity Press.
also extend world society explanations to Beckfield, Jason. 2003. ‘Inequality in the world
new global phenomena. Such rising organi- polity: The structure of international organi-
zational fashions, or fads, can be outlined by zation,’ American Sociological Review, 68:
401–420.
their various institutional manifestations:
Berger, Peter. 1968. The Sacred Canopy:
from policy to behavior to structure. Last, Elements of a Sociological Theory of Religion.
surely the extent of rationalization, as chang- New York: Doubleday.
ing organizational form and function, is Berkovitch, Nitza. 1999. From Motherhood to
still a virgin part of the study of the cultural Citizenship: Women’s Rights and Interna-
foundations, or causes, for organizational tional Organizations. Baltimore, MD: Johns
change. Hopkins University Press.
468 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Bertelson, Jens. 2000. ‘Three concepts of Transnational Legal Order. Chicago: Chicago
globalization,’ International Sociology, 15(2): University Press.
180–196. Diamond, L. 1993. ‘The globalization of
Boli, John. 2001. ‘Globalization and world democracy.’ Pp. 31–69 in R. Slater,
culture.’ Pp. 6261-6266 in International B. M. Schutz, and S. R. Dorr (eds.), Global
Encyclopedia of the Social and Behavioral Transformation and the Third World.
Sciences. New York: Elsevier Science. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner.
Boli, John. 2006. ‘The rationalization of Diehl, P. F. (ed.) 1997. The Politics of Global
virtue and virtuosity in world society.’ Governance: International Organizations in
Pp. 95-118 in Marie-Laure Djelic, and an Interdependent World. Boulder, CO: Lynn
Kerstin Sahlin-Andersson (eds.), Trans- Rienner.
national Governance: Institutional Dynamics DiMaggio, P., and W. W. Powell. 1983. ‘The iron
of Regulation. Cambridge: Cambridge cage revisited: Institutional isomorphism and
University Press. collective rationality in organizational fields.’
Boli, John, Thomas A. Loya, and Teresa Loftin. American Sociological Review, 48 (2): 147–160.
1999. ‘National participation in world-polity Djelic, Marie-Laure, and Sigrid Quack. 2003.
organization.’ Pp. 50–77 in J. Boli and ‘Introduction’ and ‘Theoretical building
G. M. Thomas, Constructing World Culture: blocks for a research agenda linking global-
International Nongovernmental Organiza- ization and institutions.’ Pp. 1–14 and 15–34
tions Since 1875. Stanford, CA: Stanford in M.-L. Djelic and S. Quack (eds.),
University Press. Globalization and Institutions: Redefining
Boli, John, and George M. Thomas. 1997. the Rules of the Economic Game. New York:
‘World culture in the world polity: A century Edward Elgar Publishing.
of international non-governmental organi- Djelic, Marie-Laure, and Kerstin Sahlin-
zation.’ American Sociological Review, 62: Andersson. 2006. ‘A World of governance:
171–190. The rise of transnational regulation’ and
Boli, John, and George M. Thomas. 1999. ‘Institutional dynamics in a re-ordering
Constructing World Culture: International world.’ Pp. 1–28 and 375-397 in M.-L. Djelic
Nongovernmental Organizations Since 1875. and K. Sahlin-Andersson (eds.), Transnational
Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. Governance: Institutional Dynamics of Regu-
Boyle, Elizabeth Heger, and John W. Meyer. lation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
1998 ‘Modern law as a secularized and Drori, Gili S. 2005. ‘United Nations’ dedica-
global model: Implications for the sociology tions: A world culture in the making?’
of law.’ Soziale Welt, 49: 275–294. International Sociology, 20(2): 177–201.
Cardoso, Fernando Henrique. 1972. Drori, Gili S. 2006. ‘Governed by governance:
‘Dependency and development in Latin The institutionalization of governance as
America.’ New Left Review, 74: 83–95. a prism for organizational change.’
Chabbott, Colette. 1999. ‘Development Pp. 91–118 in G. S. Drori, J. W. Meyer, and
INGOs.’ Pp. 222–248 in J. Boli and G. M. H. Hwang (eds.), Globalization and Organi-
Thomas (eds.), Constructing World Culture: zation: World Society and Organizational
International Nongovernmental Organiza- Change. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
tions Since 1875. Stanford, CA: Stanford Drori, Gili S., Yong Suk Jang, and John W.
University Press. Meyer. 2006. ‘Sources of rationalized gover-
Chandler, A. D., Jr., and B. Mazlich (eds.). nance: Cross-national longitudinal analyses,
2005. Leviathans: Multinational Corporations 1985–2002.’ Administrative Science Quarterly,
and the New Global Economy. Cambridge: 51(2): 205–229.
Cambridge University Press. Drori, Gili S., and John W. Meyer. 2006.
Chase-Dunn, Christopher K. 1998. Global For- ‘Scientization: Making a world safe for
mation: Structures of the World Economy. organizing.’ Pp. 32–52 in M.-L. Djelic and
Lanham, MD: Rowan and Littlefield. K. Sahlin-Andersson (eds.), Transnational
Dezalay, Yves and Bryant G. Garth. 1996. Governance: Institutional Dynamics of
Dealing in Virtue: International Commercial Regulation. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Arbitration and the Construction of Press.
INSTITUTIONALISM AND GLOBALIZATION STUDIES 469

Drori, Gili S., John W. Meyer, and Hokyu Frank, David John, John W. Meyer, and
Hwang. 2006. ‘Introduction.’ Pp. 1–22 in David Miyahara. 1995. ‘The Individualist
G. S. Drori, J. W. Meyer, and H. Hwang polity and the centrality of professionalized
(eds.), Globalization and Organization: psychology: A cross-national study.’ American
World Society and Organizational Change. Sociological Review, 60: 360–77.
Oxford University Press. Guillén, Mauro F. 2001. ‘Is globalization civiliz-
Drori, Gili S., John W. Meyer, Francisco O. ing, destructive or feeble? A critique of five
Ramirez, and Evan Schofer. 2003. Science in key debates in the social science literature.’
the Modern World Polity: Institutionalization Annual Review of Sociology, 27: 235–260.
and Globalization. Stanford, CA: Stanford Haas, Peter. 1992. ‘Introduction: Epistemic
University Press. communities and international policy coordi-
Etzioni, Amitai. 2004. From Empire to Commu- nation.’ International Organization, 46(1):
nity: A New Approach to International 1–35.
Relations’. New York: Palgrave Macmillan. Hafner-Burton, Emilie M., and Kiyoteru Tsutsui.
Finnemore, Martha. 1993. ‘International 2005. ‘Human rights practices in a globaliz-
organizations as teachers of norms: The ing world: The paradox of empty promises.’
United Nations educational, scientific, and American Journal of Sociology, 110(5):
cultural organization and science policy.’ 1373–1411.
International Organization, 47(4): 567–597. Helacioglu, Banu. 2000. ‘Globalization in the
Finnemore, Martha. 1996a. National Interests neighborhood: From the nation-state to
in International Society. Ithaca, NY: Cornell Bilkent Center.’ International Sociology,
University Press. 15(2): 326–342.
Finnemore, Martha. 1996b. ‘Norms, culture, Held, David. 1995. Democracy and World
and world politics: Insights from sociology’s Order: From the Modern State to Cosmo-
institutionalism.’ International Organization, politan Governance. Cambridge: Cambridge
50: 325–347. University Press.
Foreign Policy. 2005. ‘Measuring globalization.’ Held, David. 2003. Cosmopolitanism: A Defence.
Foreign Policy, 148: 652–666. Cambridge: Polity Press.
Foreign Policy. 2006. ‘The globalization index.’ Held, David and Anthony McGrew (eds.).
Foreign Policy, 149: 74–81. 2000. The Global Transformations Reader:
Frank, Andre Gunder. 1969. Capitalism and An Introduction to the Globalization Debate.
Underdevelopment in Latin America. New Cambridge: Polity Press.
York: Monthly Review Press. Hironaka, Ann. 2005. Neverending Wars:
Frank, David John. 1999. ‘The social bases of Weak States, the International Community,
environmental treaty ratification, 1900– and the Perpetuation of Civil War.
1990.’ Sociological Inquiry, 69: 523–50. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Frank, David J., Ann Hironaka, John W. Meyer, Huntington, Samuel. 1968. Political Order in
Evan Schofer, and Nancy Brandon Tuma. Changing Societies. New Haven, CT: Yale
1999. ‘The rationalization and organization University Press.
of nature in world culture.’ Pp. 81–99 in Hwang, Hokyu. 2006. ‘Planning development:
J. Boli and G. M. Thomas, Constructing Globalization and the shifting locus on plan-
World Culture: International Nongovern- ning.’ Pp. 69–90 in G. S. Drori, J. W. Meyer,
mental Organizations Since 1875. Stanford, and H. Hwang (eds.), Globalization and
CA: Stanford University Press. Organization: World Society and Organiza-
Frank, David J., and Elizabeth McEneaney. tional Change. Oxford: Oxford University
1999. ‘The individualization of society and Press.
the liberalization of state policies on same- Inkeles, Alex. 1969. ‘Making men modern: On
sex sexual relations, 1984–1995.’ Social the causes and consequences of individual
Forces, 77: 911–944. change in six developing countries.’
Frank, David J., and John W. Meyer. 2002. ‘The American Journal of Sociology, 75(2):
contemporary identity explosion: Individ- 208–225.
ualizing society in the post-war period.’ Inoue, Keiko, and Gili S. Drori. 2006. ‘The
Sociological Theory, 20(1): 86–105. global institutionalization of health as a
470 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

social concern: Organizational and discursive Loya, T., and J. Boli. 1999. ‘Standardization in
trends.’ International Sociology, 21(2): the world polity: Technical rationality over
199–219. power.’ Pp. 169–197 in J. Boli and G. M.
Jang, Yong Suk. 2000. ‘The worldwide found- Thomas (eds.), Constructing World Culture:
ing of ministries of science and technology, International Nongovernmental Organiza-
1950–1990.’ Sociological Perspectives, 43: tions Since 1875. Stanford, CA: Stanford
247–270. University Press.
Jang, Yong Suk. 2006. ‘Transparent accounting Luo, Xiaowei. 2006. ‘The spread of a ‘human
as a world societal rule.’ Pp. 167–195 in resources’ culture: Institutional individualism
G. S. Drori, J. W. Meyer, and H. Hwang and the rise of personal development train-
(eds.), Globalization and Organization: ing.’ Pp. 225–240 in G. S. Drori, J. W. Meyer,
World Society and Organizational Change. and H. Hwang (eds.), Globalization and
Oxford: Oxford University Press. Organization: World Society and Organiza-
Jepperson, Ronald J. 2002. ‘Political moderni- tional Change. Oxford: Oxford University
ties: Disentangling two underlying dimen- Press.
sions of institutional differentiation.’ March, James G., and Johan P. Olsen. 1976.
Sociological Theory, 20: 61–85. Ambiguity and Choice in Organizations.
Jones, G. 2005. Multinationals and Global Bergen, Norway: Universitetsforlaget.
Capitalism: From the Nineteenth to the McNeely, Connie. 1995. Constructing the
Twenty First Century. Oxford University Press. Nation-State: International Organizations
Katzenstein, Peter (ed.). 1996. The Culture of and Prescriptive Action. Westport, CT:
National Security: Norms and Identity in World Greenwood Press.
Politics. New York: Columbia University Press. McNeely, Connie. 1998. Public Rights, Public
Keck, Margaret, and Kathryn Sikkink. 1998. Rules: Constituting Citizens in the World Polity
Activists Without Borders: Advocacy Net- and National Policy. New York: Garland.
works in International Politics. Ithaca, NY: Mendel, Peter. 2006. ‘The making and expan-
Cornell University Press. sion of international management standards:
Keohane, Robert O., and Joseph S. Nye Jr. The global diffusion of ISO 9000 quality
2000. ‘Globalization: what’s new? what’s management certificates.’ Pp. 137–166 in
not? (And so what?)’ Foreign Policy, G. S. Drori, J. W. Meyer, and H. Hwang
118:104–119. (eds.), Globalization and Organization:
Khagram, Sanjeev, James Riker, and Kathryn World Society and Organizational Change.
Sikkink (eds.). 2001. Restructuring World Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Politics: Transnational Social Movements, Merton, Robert K. 1936. ‘The unanticipated
Networks, and Norms. Minneapolis: consequences of purposive action.’
University of Minnesota Press. American Sociological Review, 1(6):
Kim, Young S., Yong Suk Jang, and Hokyu 894–904.
Hwang. 2002. ‘Structural expansion and the Meyer, John. 1999. ‘The changing cultural con-
cost of global isomorphism: A cross-national tent of the nation-state: A world society per-
study of modern ministerial structures, spective.’ Pp. 123–143 in G. Steinmetz (ed.),
1950–1990.’ International Sociology, 17(4): State and Culture: New Approaches to the
481–503. State after the Cultural Turn. Ithaca, NY:
Krasner, Stephen D. 1983. ‘Structural causes Cornell University Press.
and regime consequences: Regimes as inter- Meyer, John W. 2000. ‘Sources and effects in
vening variables.’ Pp. 1–22 in S. D. Krasner national states and societies.’ International
(ed.), International Regimes. Ithaca, NY: Sociology, 15(2): 233–248.
Cornell University Press. Meyer, John W., John Boli-Bennet, and
Krasner, Stephen D. 1999. Sovereignty: Christopher Chase-Dunn. 1975. ‘Convergence
Organized Hypocrisy. Princeton, NJ: and divergence in development.’ Annual
Princeton University Press. Review of Sociology, 1: 223–246.
Krücken, Georg and Gili S. Drori (eds.) 2008. Meyer, John W., John Boli, and George M.
World Society: The Writings of John W. Thomas. 1987. ‘Ontology and rationalization
Meyer. Oxford University Press. in the western cultural account.’ Pp. 12–40
INSTITUTIONALISM AND GLOBALIZATION STUDIES 471

in G. M. Thomas, J. W. Meyer, F. O. Ramirez, transnational business.’ Global Governance,


and J. Boli, Institutional Structure: 7(3): 265–292.
Constituting State, Society, and the Individ- Parsons, Talcott. 1964. ‘Evolutionary universals
ual. Newbury Park, CA: Sage. in society.’ American Sociological Review,
Meyer, John W., John Boli, George Thomas, 29(3): 339–357.
and Francisco O. Ramirez. 1997. ‘World soci- Pattberg, Philipp. 2005. ‘The institutionaliza-
ety and the nation-state.’ American Journal tion of private governance: How business
of Sociology, 103(1): 273–298. and nonprofit organizations agree on
Meyer, John W., Gili S. Drori, and Hokyu transnational rules.’ Governance, 18(4):
Hwang. 2006. ‘World society and the orga- 589–610.
nizational actor.’ Pp. 25–49 in G. S. Drori, Putnam, Robert D. 2001. Bowling Alone:
J. W. Meyer, and H. Hwang (eds.), The Collapse and Revival of American
Globalization and Organization: World Soci- Community, paperback edn. New York:
ety and Organizational Change. Oxford: Simon & Schuster.
Oxford University Press. Ramirez, Francisco O., and Marc Ventresca.
Meyer, John W., and Michael T. Hannan. 1979. 1992. ‘Building the institution of mass
‘National development in a changing world schooling: Isomorphism in the modern
system: An overview.’ Pp. 3–16 in Meyer and world.’ Pp. 47–59 in B. Fuller and
Hannan (eds.), National Development and R. Rubinson (eds.), The Political Construction
the World System. Chicago: University of of Education: The State, School Expansion,
Chicago Press. and Economic Change. New York: Praeger.
Meyer, John W., and Ronald L. Jepperson. Ritzer, George (ed.) 2004a. The Handbook of
2000. ‘The ‘actors’ of modern society: The Social Problems: A Comparative International
cultural construction of social agency.’ Perspective. Newbury Park, CA: Sage.
Sociological Theory, 18: 100–120. Ritzer, George. 2004b. The Globalization of
Meyer, John W. and Brian Rowan. 1977. Nothing. Thousand Oaks, CA: Pine Forge
‘Institutionalized organizations: Formal struc- Press.
ture as myth and ceremony.’ American Roach, Brian. 2005. ‘A primer on multinational
Journal of Sociology, 83: 340–363. corporations.’ Pp. 19–44 in A. D. Chandler,
Mittleman, James (ed.). 1996. Globalization: Jr., and B. Mazlich (eds.), Leviathans:
Critical Reflections. Boulder, CO: Lynne Multinational Corporations and the New
Rienner. Global Economy. Cambridge, UK:
Moon, Hyeyoung, and Christine Min Wotipka. Cambridge University Press.
2006. ‘The worldwide diffusion of business Roberts, W. T. 2005. ‘The uneven globalization
education, 1881–1999: Historical trajectory of civil society organizations and the conse-
and mechanisms of expansion.’ Pp. 121–136 quences for cross-national disparities in
in G. S. Drori, J. W. Meyer, and H. Hwang human development.’ International Journal
(eds.), Globalization and Organization: of Sociology and Social Policy, 25(1/2):
World Society and Organizational Change. 118–144.
Oxford: Oxford University Press. Robertson, R. 1994. ‘Globalization and glocali-
Moravcsik, Andrew. 2000. ‘The origins of inter- zation.’ Journal of International Communi-
national human rights regimes: Democratic cation, 1: 33–52.
delegation in postwar Europe.’ International Rostow, W. W. 1971. The Stages of Economic
Organization, 54(2): 217–252. Growth: A Non-Communist Manifesto,
Moravcsik, Andrew. 2003. ‘Liberal international 2nd edn. New York: Cambridge University
relations theory: A scientific assessment.’ Press.
Pp. 159–204 in C. Elman and M. F. Elman Ruggie, John. 1982. ‘International regimes,
(eds.), Progress in International Relations transactions, and change: Embedded liberal-
Theory: Appraising the Field. Cambridge, MA: ism in the postwar economic order.’
MIT Press. International Organization, 36: 379–415.
Ottaway, Marina. 2001. ‘Corporatism goes Ruggie, John G. 1998. Constructing the World
global: International organizations, non- Polity: Essays on International Institutio-
governmental organization networks, and nalization. London: Routledge.
472 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Sahlin-Andersson, Kerstin, and Lars Engwall Strang, David. 1990. ‘From dependency to sov-
(eds.). 2002. The Expansion of Manage- ereignty: An event history analysis of decolo-
ment Knowledge: Carriers, Flows and nization, 1870–1987.’ American Sociological
Sources. Stanford, CA: Stanford Business Review, 55: 846–860.
Books. Strang, David, and Patricia Chang. 1993.
Sassen, Saskia. 1998. Globalization and its ‘The International Labor Organization
Discontents: Essays on the New Mobility of and the welfare state: Institutional
People and Money. New York: The New Press. effects on national welfare spending,
Schneiberg, Marc, and Elisabeth S. Clemens. 1960–1980.’ International Organization, 47:
2006. ‘The typical tools for the job: Research 235–262.
strategies in institutional analysis.’ Thomas, George, John W. Meyer, Francisco
Sociological Theory, 24(3): 195–227. O. Ramirez, and John Boli. 1987.
Schofer, Evan. 1999. ‘Science associations in Institutional Structure: Constituting State,
the international sphere, 1875–1990: The Society, and the Individual. Newbury Park,
rationalization of science and the scientiza- CA: Sage.
tion of society.’ Pp. 229–266 in J. Boli and Tsutsui, Kiyoteru and Christine Min Wotipka.
G. M. Thomas (eds.), Constructing World 2004. ‘Global civil society and the interna-
Culture: International Nongovernmental tional human rights movement: Citizen
Organizations Since 1875. Stanford, CA: participation in human rights international
Stanford University Press. nongovernmental organizations.’ Social
Schofer, Evan, and Elizabeth H. McEneaney. Forces, 83 (2): 587–620.
2003. ‘Methodological strategies and tools Wallerstein, Immanuel. 1979. The Capitalist
for the study of globalization.’ Pp. 43–74 in World Economy: Essays. Cambridge:
G. S. Drori, J. W. Meyer, F.O. Ramirez, and Cambridge University Press.
E. Schofer, Science in the Modern World Wallerstein, Immanuel. 2000. ‘Globalization
Polity: Institutionalization and Globali- or age of transition? A long-term view
zation. Stanford, CA: Stanford University of the trajectory of the world-system.’
Press. International Sociology, 15(2): 249–265.
Schofer, Evan, and John W. Meyer. 2005. ‘The Weick, Karl E. 1976. ‘Educational organizations
world-wide expansion of higher education in as loosely coupled systems.’ Administrative
the twentieth century.’ American Science Quarterly, 21: 1–19.
Sociological Review, 70: 898–920. Wiktorowicz, Quintan. 2002. ‘The politi-
Schofer, Evan, Francisco O. Ramirez, and John cal limits to nongovernmental organizations
W. Meyer. 2000. ‘The effects of science in Jordan.’ World Development, 30(1):
on national economic development, 77–93.
1970–1990.’ American Sociological Review, Wendt, Alexander. 1999. Social Theory of
65: 877–898. International Politics. Cambridge: Cambridge
Shanahan, Suzanne and Sanjeev Khagram. University Press.
2000. ‘Dynamics of corporate responsibility.’ Wolf, Martin. 2004. Why Globalization Works?
Pp. 196–224 in G. S. Drori, J. W. Meyer, New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
and H. Hwang (eds.), Globalization and Wotipka, Christine Min, and Francisco O.
Organization: World Society and Ramirez. 2008. ‘World society and human
Organizational Change. Oxford: Oxford rights: An event history analysis of the
University Press. Convention on the Elimination of All
Stiglitz, Joseph E. 2003. Globalization and its Forms of Discrimination Against Women
Discontents. New York: WW. Norton & Co. (CEDAW).’ Pp. 303–343 in B. A. Simmons,
Sklair, Leslie. 2002. Globalization: Capitalism F. Dobbin, and G. Garrett (eds.), The Global
and its Alternatives. Oxford: Oxford Diffusion of Markets and Democracy.
University Press. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Slaughter, Anne-Marie. 2004. ‘Sovereignty and Zucker, Lynn G. 1987. ‘Institutional theories of
power in a networked world order.’ Stanford organization.’ Annual Review of Sociology,
Journal of International Law, 40: 283–327. 13: 443–464.
19
Organizational Institutionalism
and Sociology: A Reflection
C.R. Hinings and Pamela S. Tolbert

In 1991, DiMaggio and Powell observed: origins of contemporary institutional work


Institutional theory presents a paradox. on organizations within this context. We also
Institutional analysis is as old as Emile Durkheim’s consider how more recent organizational
exhortation to study ‘social facts as things’, yet analyses in the tradition of institutional
sufficiently novel to be preceded by new in much theory have been driven by and reflect this
of the contemporary literature. (1991: 1)
basic tension.
We argue that this paradox is, at least in It is not surprising that current institution-
part, the result of a long-standing tension in alism embodies core theoretical issues within
sociology between more materialist, interest- sociology: The roots of this approach to
driven explanations of behavior and organizational analysis are firmly planted in
ideational, normative explanations, a tension the discipline. Tracing the intellectual
that has often driven oscillating waves of genealogy of institutionalism, Scott’s list of
sociological theorizing. It underlies many contributing scholars (2001) includes
classical debates (e.g., between Spencer and Spencer, Sumner, Cooley, Hughes, Marx,
Durkheim, Weber and Marx, and even Durkheim, Weber, Parsons, Mead, Schutz,
Parsons and Mills), and the waves of theory Berger, and Luckmann – a veritable pantheon
associated with it have produced a variety of of sociological theorists! Thus, it is almost
‘neo-isms’, including neo-Marxist as well as inevitable that the issues addressed by
neo-institutionalist theories. This distinction institutionalists are, in many ways, those of
in explanatory approaches is linked to a more central concern to general sociology.
general theoretical problematic for sociolo- Sociology focuses on understanding the
gists: how to provide a single, coherent nature of both the material arrangements and
account of both stable, persisting patterns of the normative systems that characterize
social behavior, and the breakdown and elim- collectivities, and the influence of these on
ination of what were once deeply-entrenched action; this is the same agenda that defines
patterns. In this chapter, we examine the his- and drives institutional analyses of organiza-
tory of these distinctive explanatory tions. Given the relationship between the
approaches in sociology, and locate the field of sociology as a whole and institutional
474 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

studies of organizations, and the claim that for institutional theory, the first includes
most eminent, historical sociologists are the work of Herbert Spencer. Although
forerunners of institutional theory, the time is Spencer’s work is rarely referenced (and
ripe to revisit the origins and evolution of probably read even more rarely) by modern
institutional theory and to ask the question of day sociologists,1 he was generally consid-
how far the work of those forebears is truly ered to be the preeminent sociologist of
represented in contemporary scholarship. his time (Turner and Beeghley 1981).
And this will inevitably lead to the questions, To describe his work as ambitious is to
in what ways has institutionalism added to seriously understate the case; Spencer’s over-
the earlier theoretical insights – and in what arching goal was to discover the fundamental
ways may the earlier insights have been lost set of principles that defined the functioning
in more contemporary studies? of physical, biological and social worlds.
Although the scope of this aim is amusingly
quaint from a contemporary standpoint, it’s
worth noting that one of his ‘laws of the
THE FORERUNNERS cosmos,’ that increasing size in any social
unit is accompanied by increasing differenti-
The starting point for this discussion has to ation, anticipated a staple finding from much
be Dick Scott’s (2001) Institutions and later empirical studies of organizations
Organizations as it provides a comprehen- (Blau, Heydebrand, and Stauffer, 1966; Hall,
sive overview of the institutionalist approach Clark, Giordano et al., 1967; Pugh, Hickson,
to organization theory. While Scott identifies Hinings, and Turner, 1969).
seminal links between this approach and a In describing the nature of society,
wide range of theorists, we focus more nar- Spencer argued that social systems are made
rowly on a particular set of the progenitors he up of a series of subsystems, and that each
discusses, ones we see as contributing most subsystem and its institutionalized structures
directly to the contemporary formulation of serve distinctive functions for society as a
an institutional approach and to the ongoing whole. As Scott (2001: 9) points out, ideas
debates within it. Therefore, we will begin by about ‘the functional division of social life
examining the work of four major theorists into spheres or arenas – kinship, stratifica-
as paired sets, Spencer and Durkheim, first, tion, politics, economics, religion, and so
and then Marx and Weber. In our view, the on,’ have been central to much
point–counterpoint relations between these sociological theorizing. As we discuss in
theorists offer useful insights into unresolved more depth below, this conception of
theoretical problems that are embedded in ‘institutions’ – as core, distinguishing,
much of the development of current institu- societal-level patterns (structures) that char-
tional theory. Within this context, we will acterize one area of social life, and that are
consider the four pieces that DiMaggio and fundamentally interlocked with each other –
Powell (1991) label as the initial formula- is much broader than the conception often
tions of institutional theory, namely, Meyer implied in more contemporary work
and Rowan (1977), DiMaggio and Powell (although, unfortunately, the latter is no more
(1983), Zucker (1977) and Scott and Meyer likely to define the concept of institution
(1983). explicitly and clearly than Spencer or other
early theorists).
Importantly, as an adherent of utilitarian
Spencer and Durkheim philosophy, Spencer also made the case that
these structures arose naturally through a
Among the four streams of early sociological process of competition and exchange among
theorists that Scott considers as foundational individuals who, in the rational pursuit of
ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM AND SOCIOLOGY: A REFLECTION 475

their own self-interests, entered into Durkheim’s fundamental view of social


contracts that facilitated such pursuit. Thus, behavior expressed here not only runs
society was conceived as the nexus of nego- directly counter to Spencer’s emphasis on
tiated contracts. Although Spencer did not individuals’ conscious calculation of how
address the issue directly, implicit in his best to pursue independent interests, but
utilitarian and evolutionary arguments is the anticipates arguments later offered by Berger
notion that when institutionalized arrange- and Luckmann (1967) concerning the limited
ments fail to permit the achievement of ability of individuals to shape social arrange-
agents’ objectives, they are likely to be ments (which they termed ‘exteriority’), and
subject to re-evaluation and purposeful the coercive power of these arrangements
change. over behavior. It is similarly consistent
Writing in the shadows of the French with Bourdieu’s (1977) concept of habitus.
Revolution, Durkheim was also deeply con- The primacy that Durkheim assigned to
cerned with the question of what forces held non-calculative sources of behavior was
societies together. Ultimately, he reached highlighted by a pointed rebuttal to Spencer,
very different conclusions than Spencer, in which he observed that entering into
although two distinct responses to this ques- contractual relations necessarily requires a
tion are evident in his work (Collins, 1994: pre-existing level of trust among society’s
188); the later response is most clearly members. Durkheim concluded that such
opposed to Spencer’s arguments. The earlier trust was produced through collective con-
response, focusing on the division of labor sciousness, the normative commitment and
in society, particularly in industrialized soci- sense of belonging to a social group (Collins
eties, is somewhat more compatible with a and Makowsky, 2005: 95–96).2
materialist, agency-driven view. In this
instance, Durkheim argued that solidarity
reflects recognition of interdependencies
Marx and Weber
among members of society created by
specialization. Later work, focusing on what As in the comparison of Spencer and
Durkheim referred to as ‘social facts,’ and Durkheim, arguments about the validity and
reflecting his increasing rejection of usefulness of assumptions about the impor-
Spencer’s utilitarian view of society, gives tance of conscious choice and self-interested
much more weight to purely ideational, motivations in explaining social behavior
normative forces that serve as constraints on serve as a key point of distinction between
individuals’ behavior. the sociological theorizing of Karl Marx and
In Rules of the Sociological Method, his Max Weber. Marx was, of course, a material-
treatise on the distinctive domain of sociol- ist in philosophy and at the heart of his analy-
ogy, Durkheim argues, sis were notions of conflict, power,
When I fulfill my obligations as brother, husband, oppression, exploitation and alienation
or citizen, when I execute my contracts, I perform between classes. In contrast to Spencer’s and
duties which are defined, externally to myself and Durkheim’s preoccupation with explaining
my acts, in law and in custom. Even if they con- the persistence of social order, Marx focused
form to my own sentiments and I feel their reality
subjectively, such reality is still objective, for I did on forces that led to major transformations in
not create them; I merely inherited them through societies.
my education … The systems of signs I use to Marx’s core argument, that such transfor-
express my thought, the system of currency mations were inherent in class relations, was
I employ to pay my debts, the instruments of predicated on the assumption that individuals
credit I utilize in my commercial relations, the
practices followed in my profession, etc., func- who shared a common role in the economy –
tion independently of my own use of them. a class – would ultimately and inevitably rec-
(1964: 1–2) ognize their shared interests and pursue those
476 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

interests through collective action. Since all in conjunction with the increasing degrada-
economies were constituted by, on one hand, tion of work, were considered key forces in
a class that profited from control of the enabling members of the labor class to recog-
primary means of production and, on the nize their true, shared material interests and
other hand, classes that lacked control of key to collectively act upon these.
productive resources and thus were subject to Thus, the key institutions in Marx’s analy-
the exploitation of the first, class conflict was sis are social classes and their relations, and
inevitable. As technologies and other factors his analysis suggests that these institutions
changed in ways that provided an exploited will be stable as long as the dominant class
class with opportunities to overthrow the is able to sustain acceptance of general
existing system of relations, Marx argued, ideologies that support them. When condi-
their collective action would result in the dis- tions changed sufficiently, though, accept-
solution of the system and the creation of a ance of dominant ideologies was expected
new set of social relations that was consistent to break down under the weight of revealed
with the interests of the rising class. interests, and the institutions to be subject
Thus, although Marx clearly rejected to challenge and collapse. The previous
Spencer’s belief in the benignity and effi- system of class relations would then be
ciency of market allocation processes, the replaced by new institutions (new classes,
two did share the general conception with new relations of dominance and subor-
of social actors as driven by self-awareness dination) that, presumably, were supported
of material interests. by new ideologies.3
However, while Marx’s analysis was pred- Much of Weber’s analyses can be seen as a
icated on the assumption that social action response to Marx’s emphasis on material
primarily reflected rational efforts to maxi- interests, and particularly on class relations,
mize material, class-based interests, he did as the driving force in social action. Along
recognize that individuals sometimes failed with Spencer, Marx and Durkheim, Weber
to realize their true class interests – i.e., that was concerned with large-scale social
they were subject to false consciousness. changes that he saw taking place, changes
This concept entails an implicit acknowl- that were reshaping the whole nature of
edgement of the role of cultural forces, belief society. Although some have argued that his
systems and ideologies, in shaping action as analyses directly opposed those of Marx, by
well. True to materialist logic, though, Marx prioritizing ideas and cultural forces as deter-
located the origins of such forces in the eco- minants of social action (Parsons, 1937),
nomic interests and material capabilities of most contemporary theorists view his aims
the dominant class (Collins, 1994). Thus, more in terms of tempering, rather than
widely-held social beliefs and ideologies rejecting Marx’s arguments (Turner and
were deemed to be shaped largely by the Beeghley, 1981; Collins, 1994; Swedberg,
dominant class, which had the resources to 1998): his approach to explaining social
influence the production and widespread phenomena emphasizes the interaction
dissemination of ideas that were consonant between material conditions and interests, on
with their interests (and of course, influence one hand, and subjective interpretations and
over state agencies to suppress production meanings on the other (Weber, 1949). Thus,
and dissemination of ideas that lacked such neither material nor ideational forces are
consonance). Moreover, he assumed that privileged in his explanations of social
changes in material conditions would phenomena; rather these forces must be
provide the basis for changes in epiphenom- understood as independent though inter-
ena, such as false consciousness. In capitalist twined phenomena.
systems, increased opportunities for inter- It is, however, his work on cultural influ-
action among members of the working class, ences and belief systems that is most clearly
ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM AND SOCIOLOGY: A REFLECTION 477

reflected in at least early formulations of tradition of phenomenology, as articulated by


institutional analyses of organizations. As Schutz (1967) and Berger and Luckmann
Scott (2001: 13) puts it: (1967). As suggested in our discussion
above, such phenomenological explanations
‘more contemporary analysts of institutions lay
claim to Weber as the guiding genius than to any
of social behavior have close parallels to
other early theorist. Although Weber did not those of Durkheim. For Durkheim, though,
explicitly employ the concept of institution, his institutions – the forces that produced ‘social
work is permeated with a concern for understand- facts’ or enduring patterns of behavior char-
ing the ways in which cultural rules, ranging in acterizing collectivities – were primarily nor-
nature from customary mores to legally defined
constitutions or rule systems, define social struc-
mative, operating through the social
tures and govern social behavior.’ solidarity that bound individuals together in a
society (Durkheim, 1947). For phenomenol-
In particular, Weber’s analysis of the nature ogists, on the other hand, institutions were
of rational-legal authority and its critical role defined more in cognitive terms, as shared
in the operation of contemporary organiza- meanings and understandings that arose from
tions provided a key point of departure for the social interaction and shaped behavior
foundational work in institutional studies largely by constraining individuals’ cogni-
offered by Zucker (1977) and Meyer and tions and perceived choices of action. A phe-
Rowan (1977). Arguing that different forms nomenological approach to institutions can
of organizations (e.g., patrimonial adminis- also be distinguished from Durkheim’s by
tration, charismatic communes, bureaucracy) the concern of phenomenologists with expli-
rest fundamentally on different beliefs about cating the micro-interactional processes in
the ‘true’ or ‘proper’ nature of social rela- which institutions originate.
tions, Weber sought to delineate key features
of rational-legal authority, a belief system
underpinning the bureaucratic form.
Rational-legal authority entails acceptance of THE INITIAL FORMULATIONS
social relations as rightly governed by formal OF INSTITUTIONAL ANALYSES
laws and regulations which, in turn, are pre- OF ORGANIZATIONS
sumed to be based on rational calculations of
the most effective means to attain given ends. In terms of contemporary institutional analy-
In this context, obedience is given to persons ses, Powell and DiMaggio (1991) have four
based on the formal offices they hold, in part articles that they call ‘The Initial
because their attainment of office is under- Formulations,’ namely, Meyer and Rowan
stood to indicate possession of skills and abil- (1977), Zucker (1977), DiMaggio and
ities that make them able to execute the tasks Powell (1983) and Scott and Meyer (1983).
of the office. Weber contrasted this form with These expositions show continuity with
traditional authority, in which social arrange- the forerunners, but also a distinct break. The
ments are accepted as preordained, whether continuity involves theoretical notions of the
by a deity or natural law, and charismatic bases of social action; the break involves a
authority, in which accepted social arrange- specific focus on organizations.
ments reflect the dictates of an individual To appreciate, in part, the ‘neo-’ label that
who is viewed as possessing supernatural or is often attached to this tradition, it is useful
magical powers and abilities (Weber, 1947). to recall the dominant lines of sociological
This conception of rational-legal authority theorizing and research on organizations
as a cultural foundation for modern organiza- up to the mid-1970s.4 In the U.S., research on
tions was linked, particularly in Meyer and organizations as a distinct subfield of study
Rowan’s and Zucker’s initial analyses of by sociologists had its roots in efforts
organizational institutions, to work in the by Robert Merton and his students
478 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

(e.g., Merton, 1947a; Gouldner, 1954; Blau, and Rowan drew on Weber’s analysis of
1955) to empirically examine key tenets of rational-legal authority in modern
functionalist theory. Based on the notion that economies, and wove this together with
organizations could be viewed as societies in Berger and Luckmann’s (1967) ideas about
miniature, organizational research was seen as institutionalization, processes leading to the
permitting the kind of comparative study kind of socially-constructed reality depicted
needed to provide systematic validation for in the earlier quote from Durkheim. They
functionalist arguments (and thus represented argued that in modern societies, rules about
a very appealing alternative to conducting how organizations ‘ought’ to operate and the
costly and difficult cross-national studies). kinds of structures they ‘should’ have arisen
The logic of functionalist reasoning from a variety of sources. Among these,
encouraged examining and explaining organi- Meyer and Rowan discuss the effects of com-
zational structures in terms of benefits (par- plex relational networks (interconnections
ticularly in terms of efficient functioning) to among organizations that facilitate the spread
organizations. Thus, by the mid-1970s, the of ideas and understandings), the collective
most prominent line of sociological research organization of the environment (the rise of
on organizations, which had come to be powerful states that can pass and enforce
dubbed as ‘contingency theory,’ reflected a mandates that affect organizations), and the
confluence of this theoretical agenda and the leadership of local organizations (non-gov-
more pragmatic concerns of a tradition ernment organizations that have power
known as administrative theory (Gulick and and/or legitimacy to promote prescribed
Urwick, 1937; Follett, 1942). Studies in this organizational arrangements). Organizations
tradition typically investigated the way in experience pressure to conform to these rules
which various contingencies, such as size and in order to maintain their own legitimacy;
technology, affected the relative efficiency thus, formal structure, Meyer and Rowan
and profitability of variations in structure, suggest, can be viewed as the result of
such as complexity, formalization, centraliza- conformity to such rules or ‘myths.’
tion; that is, organizations were generally This emphasis on ideational and normative
assumed to adopt structural arrangements on sources of structure offered a very sharp con-
the basis of calculations that were aimed at trast to the then-dominant approach to
enhancing efficiency and effectiveness, and explaining organizational structure. Note
that took into account various contingencies here that, in contrast to earlier sociological
facing the organization (e.g., Woodward, analyses that provided the underpinning for
1958; Hage and Aiken, 1967; Pugh et al., their arguments, their concept of ‘institution’
1969; Klatzky, 1970; Blau and Schoenherr, entailed much more circumscribed social
1971; Pennings, 1973). As Meyer and Rowan phenomena – particular social rules and
summarize the literature at this point in time: definitions of the appropriate formal struc-
One of the central problems in organization theory ture of organizations.5
is to describe the conditions that give rise to
rationalized formal structure. In conventional
theories, rational formal structure is assumed to be
the most effective way to coordinate and control Zucker
the complex relationship networks involved in
modern technical or work activities. (1977: 342) Published in the same year, Zucker’s analysis
(1977) provided an elaboration of the phe-
nomenological arguments contained in
Meyer and Rowan, along with empirical
Meyer and Rowan
evidence for these from an experimental
In advancing an alternative view of the study. In contrast to the largely macro-level
sources of organizational structure, Meyer focus of the other foundational work, Zucker
ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM AND SOCIOLOGY: A REFLECTION 479

addressed the microfoundations of institu- dominant lines of organizational research at


tions in some detail and, as she herself says, the time. By the early 1980s, however, con-
such an approach ‘focuses upon institutional- cerns about a perceived overemphasis on
ization as a process rather than as a state; normative imagery in this work and an
upon the cognitive processes involved in the implicit lack of agency had begun to build
creation and transmission of institutions’ (Perrow, 1985; Oliver, 1991, 1992; Abbott,
(Zucker, 1977: 104; see also her post-script 1992; Hirsch and Lounsbury, 1997).
to the re-printing of this study in Powell and These issues were addressed, to some extent,
DiMaggio, 1991). Her experiments demon- in the other two foundational pieces,
strated that when subjects were directed to published in 1983 by DiMaggio and Powell,
think of themselves as being in an organiza- and by Scott and Meyer.
tional setting (rather than simply engaged in DiMaggio and Powell (1983) also start
informal interaction with other participants) from a Weberian view of rationalism as the
they were much more willing to accept the major force in industrializing and moderniz-
judgments of others; moreover, in organiza- ing societies, and echo Weber’s idea of such
tional settings, such judgments were rationalism becoming an ‘iron cage.’
more readily transmitted from one set of However, their purpose is to use this as a
subjects to a new set – across generations of springboard for suggesting that the processes
participants. of rationalization and bureaucratization that
Consistent with Weber’s arguments about drove Weber’s analysis are now standard in
rational-legal authority, then, her research modern society. Like Meyer and Rowan and
indicated that individuals are inclined to view Zucker, they argue that the creation of insti-
the behavior of representatives of organiza- tutional templates serves to drive processes
tions as being relatively objective (presum- of isomorphism, thus resulting in a high level
ably, as reflecting rational decision criteria of structural homogeneity among organiza-
rather than individual, idiosyncratic choices), tions. Their specification of different sources
and that this increases their propensity to of isomorphism – mimetic, normative and
transmit these behaviors to others as rules, coercive – elaborated and clarified distinc-
‘correct’ ways of doing things. Her work tions pointed to in Meyer and Rowan’s work.
thus provided a crucial link between phe- Perhaps more importantly, their notion of
nomenologists’ arguments about the impact organizational field helped to draw attention
of institutions on individual cognitions and to the array of interacting organizations that
behavior and Weberian arguments about the give rise to, shape and re-shape institutional-
nature of authority and normative order in ized definitions. They define a field as (1983:
modern societies. This, in turn, provided a 148), ‘those organizations that, in the
key base for research by later institutionalists aggregate, constitute a recognized area of
on the diffusion of particular structures and institutional life: key suppliers, resource and
practices across sets of organizations product consumers, regulatory agencies and
(Tolbert and Zucker, 1983; Palmer, Jennings other organizations that produce the services
and Zhou, 1993; Zhou, 1993; Skinner and or products.’
Staiger, 2005). The notion of field serves to highlight the
variety of actors that may engage in efforts to
affect institutional definitions, and implicitly
DiMaggio and Powell suggests a role for active agency, at least
during early phases of field structuration,
In part, the positive reception that greeted while still recognizing the constraining
Meyer and Rowan’s and Zucker’s papers effects of such definitions. They posit,
reflected recognition of the absence of ‘(O)rganizational actors making rational
more normative views of behavior found in decisions construct around themselves an
480 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

environment that constrains their ability to depends on the context in which an organiza-
change further in later years’ (1983: 148). tion operates.
This conceptualization foreshadows Both of the analyses by DiMaggio and
DiMaggio’s (1988) later work elaborating on Powell and Scott and Meyer thus partially
the role of institutional entrepreneurs in address the core question that Tolbert and
change processes. It also reflects research by Zucker (1996) later articulated as a key prob-
Tolbert and Zucker (1983), who examined lematic for the further development of an
how the political conflict and struggles institutional approach, reconciling what they
among elites and immigrants that contributed refer to as rational actor models of behavior
to the early formulation and adoption of civil with institutional models. They note:
service reform laws became an increasingly We suggest that these two general models should
irrelevant factor in predicting adoption of the be treated not as oppositional but rather as
reform over time. Thus, DiMaggio and representing two ends of a continuum of decision-
Powell’s analysis provides one avenue for making processes and behaviors. Thus, a key
problem for theory and research is to specify
integrating the agentic, interest-driven the conditions under which behavior is more likely
images of social behavior offered by Spencer to resemble one end of this continuum or the
and Marx, with the more constrained, other. In short, what is needed are theories of
normative conceptions of Durkheim. Like when rationality is likely to be more or less
Weber’s work, their arguments recognize bounded. (176)
the validity and necessity of both approaches Although recent organizational analyses
for adequate sociological explanations. cast in the institutional tradition have
made some progress in addressing this
issue, a fully satisfactory resolution
Scott and Meyer still awaits. There are other issues that
remain to be addressed as well, as discussed
Scott and Meyer (1983) elaborate a similar below.
notion to that of field, namely, societal sector.
They use this term in two ways. The first
usage denotes the set of organizations that
provide similar products and services and ISSUES FOR INSTITUTIONAL THEORY
serve the same function, along with resource-
providing and regulatory organizations; this Comparison of the work of the classic
is clearly akin to DiMaggio and Powell’s theoretical forerunners and the initial formu-
notion of a field. In a second use, though, lations of institutional theory suggests at
sector is used to refer to the kinds of per- least three issues that merit much more atten-
formance criteria that are typically used in tion by contemporary institutional theory.
evaluating different sets of organizations. In These are:
particular, they distinguish between technical
sectors, in which performance evaluation is 1. Integrating conceptions of interest-driven behav-
largely identified with market outcomes, and ior (and hence, problems of power and conflict)
with those of bounded rationality and norma-
institutional sectors, in which performance
tively-guided behavior;
evaluation is closely linked to conformity 2. Setting organizational institutionalism in wider
with institutional rules and regulations and historical and social contexts in order to
only indirectly tied to market outcomes. This understand more profound processes of social
latter concept of sector represents a different change;
way of integrating both agentic and norma- 3. Taking an interpretive approach seriously.
tive approaches to explaining organizations’
behavior, suggesting that the relevance of These issues are not, of course, orthogo-
more agentic or normative explanations nal; there is clearly overlap among them.
ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM AND SOCIOLOGY: A REFLECTION 481

Incorporating issues of power retreat from society, so it is possible to argue


that organizational institutionalism has been
and conflict
in a theoretical retreat from issues of inter-
For both Weber and Marx, the idea of an ests, power, conflict, domination and
institution was inseparable from issues of exploitation. In part, this reflects both an
power and interest. For both, understanding unstated functionalist logic in an institution-
the emergence, functioning and change in alist approach (Kirkpatrick and Ackroyd,
institutions entailed understanding the ability 2005), and a general lack of concern with
of particular groups in society to ensure that these issues in North American organiza-
their interests were served by given arrange- tional theory and sociology in general
ments. For both, processes of legitimization (Hinings and Greenwood, 2002). With few
were seen as key to sustaining institutions. exceptions, there has been a little recognition
And for both, analyses of patterns of power, of class or collective interests and power in
domination, and conflict required in-depth institutional analyses. Although DiMaggio
understanding of the social and historical (1988) addresses the issues of interests and
context in which they occurred. power, his analysis reflects more of a concern
Weber argued that the dominance of for connecting institutional arguments with
bureaucracy as an institution in societies the notion of individual agency (more in line
characterized by rational-legal authority with Spencer’s concerns) than for under-
reflected its substantial advantages over standing how particular groups attempt to
alternative forms of organization (1947: dominate others. Greenwood and Hinings
337): ‘It is superior to any other form in pre- (1996) do have a notion of particular occupa-
cision, in stability, in the stringency of its dis- tional and functional groups having different
cipline, and in its reliability … superior both material interests and vying for the power to
in intensive efficiency and in the scope of its impose their institutional arrangements on
operations, and is formally capable of appli- others. Lawrence et al (2001) propose that
cation to all kinds of administrative tasks.’ influence, force, discipline and domination
He also clearly recognized the dark side of are all mechanisms of institutional change
this advantage, however, noting that an that are based on how power is used.
entrenched bureaucracy can serve any inter- However, in these approaches the empha-
ests, and that those whose interests are served sis is on the ways in which power is utilized
are likely to become increasingly remote to allow institutional change to occur. That is,
from the mass of the population. Weber’s it is primarily conceptualized as a factor or
imagery of members of bureaucratic organi- condition that allows change at either the
zations as cogs in a machine acknowledges field or organizational level. And in spite of
that the institution can be a source of alien- the language that Lawrence et al. (2001) use,
ation, not only in the psychological sense but their concern is not with the ability of partic-
in the more Marxian sense: individuals are ular groups to frame institutional arrange-
separated from the products of their labor, ments in such a way that their interests are
and thus may enact behaviors that run furthered. What is needed is not only a more
directly counter to their material interests. elaborate exploration of the role of institu-
Marx’s notion of false consciousness cap- tional forms, organizations and processes as
tures the same sort of phenomenon. Although frameworks and mechanisms in serving
contemporary institutional theory would some interests rather than others and, poten-
seem a natural point of departure for examin- tially, bolstering the power of some social
ing such behavior, work in this tradition has and occupational groups rather than others,
given surprisingly little attention to it. but also an examination of the conditions
As Friedland and Alford argued that the under which disadvantaged groups will
social sciences have been in a theoretical simply accept or recognize and challenge
482 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

existing institutions. Interestingly, Selznick Thus, overall, sociological forerunners


(1949) dealt with some of these issues in his point organizational institutionalists in quite
work on Tennessee Valley Authority (TVA), different directions than have been taken so
but this aspect has not been taken up. far. The central issues that require explo-
One interesting development that could ration include the way in which institutional
form the basis for such an approach is the arrangements serve as instruments of domi-
idea of institutional logics (see Thornton and nation by particular groups and particular
Ocasio, Chapter 3 this volume). Marx sets of interests rather than others, and better
emphasized the basis of ideologies in inter- specification of the conditions under which
ests and the consequent way in which such they are likely to be subject to challenge by
ideologies control social relations. Thornton competing interests. An important part of the
and Ocasio (1999: 804) defined institutional Marxist, Weberian and critical theory argu-
logics as ‘the socially constructed, historical ments about institutions is the way in which
patterns of material practices, assumptions, forms move across institutional arenas pre-
values, beliefs, and rules by which individu- cisely because of the way in which they sup-
als produce and reproduce their material sub- port particular interests and allow elites to
sistence, organize time and space, and maintain power (cf. Prichard and Willmott,
provide meaning to their social reality.’ And 1997). As Hinings and Greenwood argued
as they point out in this volume, there is an (2002), organizational theorists have to be
inescapably material aspect to institutional more concerned with the implications of
logics. However, the nature of logics as organizational forms and processes for
ideologies and the ways in which they are power and control, something that should
related to interests has not been fully resonate strongly for organizational institu-
explored. tionalists because institutions are the durable,
There is, of course, a stream of sociologi- change-resistant social structures of society
cal and management theory that takes institu- (Scott, 2001: 49). As Giddens (1984: 24)
tional frameworks as embodiments of power, puts it, ‘Institutions by definition are the
control and domination, namely, critical more enduring features of social life ….
theory (Habermas, 1970, 1971, 1974; giving “solidity” (to social systems) across
Alvesson and Willmott, 1992; Alvesson and time and space.’
Deetz, 1996). However, this stream of
theorizing has had little or no impact on
organizational institutionalism. More recent Understanding the relation
efforts to join research on social movements between institutions and
with institutional analyses also partially
social change
addresses this issue, but the problem
with much of this work is that it implicitly As noted, the use of the concept of ‘institu-
takes for granted the ability of actors to tion’ by contemporary organizational
rationally assess the impact of existing researchers has generally involved a much
arrangements on their own interests, and more specific and narrower referent than that
challenge those that fail to serve these of classic sociological theory. Arising as an
interests (e.g., Schneiberg and Bartley, 2001; alternative approach to explaining formal
Ingram and Rao, 2004; Rojas, 2006). organizational structure, the earliest exposi-
Hence, they often rest on a more Spencerian tions of institutionalism associated this
view of social action, and fail to effectively concept with very specific elements of struc-
address the insights of Durkheim and more ture among a set of organizations: e.g., affir-
recent phenomenologists concerning the mative action offices, civil service rules,
power of normative orders in constraining radio programming formats, ‘poison pill’
action. policies, and so forth. One result of this
ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM AND SOCIOLOGY: A REFLECTION 483

approach was the deflection of efforts to con- rich heritage of sociological theorizing from
ceptualize formal structure in terms of which it draws (cf. Hinings, 1988; Hinings
broadly defined dimensions, such as com- and Greenwood, 2002).
plexity, formalization, and centralization, Most of the theorists that Scott labels fore-
efforts that dominated much of organiza- runners were concerned with the broad
tional sociology from the 1950s through the sweep of institutions – how society was
1970s. Indeed, the lack of success by sociol- constituted through its institutional frame-
ogists in coming up with agreed-upon con- work, and how that framework was chang-
ceptualizations and operationalizations of ing. Their analyses dealt with creation and
such broad dimensions (e.g., Kimberly, change in dominant institutions, and under-
1976) may have contributed to researchers’ standing both the historical causes and con-
receptivity to an institutional approach. sequences of such change for both society
Another, and perhaps more consequential and individuals. These issues particularly
outcome, however, has been a neglect of the resonate in the work of Marx, Durkheim and
sorts of broad patterns of social relations and Weber. Conceptually, a strong distinguishing
social change that were traditionally associ- feature of the work of Weber and Marx, espe-
ated with analyses of institutions (for notable cially, was an emphasis on understanding
exceptions, see the work of John Meyer and institutions and institutional change within
his colleagues). That is, there has been a broad historical contexts. They recognized
distinct shift from efforts to understand ‘big that they lived in times of large-scale social
institutions’ to those that are focused on change and upheaval, and struggled to under-
(relatively) ‘little institutions.’ stand them. For them, all analysis was
The redefinition of the concept of institu- historically located in a particular socio-
tion to denote specific elements of structure economic milieu. While all three were highly
may have been driven in part by empiricist analytical (e.g., the use of ideal types, the
concerns. The broad conception of institution labor theory of value, the nature of anomie),
in sociological theory did not lend itself such constructs were only possible because
easily to operationalization or efforts to of both sweeping and detailed scholarship of
verify theoretical claims, as witnessed by the historical trajectories and embedded
the still-ongoing debates over how to define nature of institutions.
and measure ‘class’ (e.g., Erickson and It is not that contemporary institutionalists
Goldthorpe, 1992; Wright, 1997; Weeden are oblivious to the historical settings that
and Grusky, 2005). The redefinition may also frame the diffusion of specific practices (e.g.,
reflect that fact that many (most?) of the cur- see Tolbert and Zucker, 1983; Sine, Haveman,
rent proponents of institutionalism work in and Tolbert, 2005; Haveman, Rao, and
business schools, a context that is apt to Paruchuri, 2006), but that concern with
encourage a stronger focus on explaining the explaining organizational behavior, per se,
behavior of organizations per se and dis- has often led to a lack of concern with under-
courage a broader focus on general societal standing and explaining overarching shifts in
issues and processes of social change society – the increased formalism in all kinds
(Stern and Barley, 1996). One might argue, of organizations (though see Drori, Jang, and
as this volume as a whole does, that institu- Meyer, 2006), the rise of international gover-
tional theory has told us a great deal about nance organizations in the wake of globaliza-
organizational behavior. Indeed, the exis- tion, such as the International Monetary
tence of a ‘Handbook of Organizational Fund, the World Bank, and International
Institutionalism’ is testament to this. Labour Organization, that are not subject to
However, as a consequence of the narrow- the authority of any given nation state, the
ness of its conception of institutions, institu- increasing levels of stratification in many
tional theory has offered little in return to the societies resulting, in part, from changing
484 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

organizational employment policies, and so underpinned Durkheim’s analysis – how nor-


forth – and the implications of such shifts for mative orders arise, are maintained and
individuals and social order. change. That is, institutionalism needs to
Work focusing on the field level of analy- explore in more detail the conditions under
sis, which Scott (2006: 16) defines as ‘a set which individuals are likely to raise and
of interdependent populations of organiza- accept challenges to existing institutional
tions participating in the same cultural and orders, or to reject such challenges. This
social sub-system,’ provides a potential pur- problem also, clearly, relates to Marx’s
chase on this issue. This level has indeed notion of false consciousness, and the ques-
become important in the last 10–15 years in tion of how Klasse an sich may become
institutional theory, and is intermediate Klasse feur sich.
between organizations and wider social As noted, institutionalists have addressed
systems and forces. However, organizational these concerns to some extent, particularly
institutionalists need to do more work that by drawing on work by phenomenologists,
locates fields in a societal (and perhaps such as Schutz, Berger and Luckmann,
international) context. This is particularly and by more recent scholars, such as
important if organizational theorists and Bourdieu and Giddens. Giddens’ notion of
sociologists of organizations believe, with the ‘duality of structure,’ suggesting that
Weber, that organizations are the key institu- while structures constrain social action they
tional forms of society. We need to address are also created and modified by knowledge-
questions concerning the ways in which able actors, has served as an important
organizations both shape and are shaped by springboard for much discussion of the
the larger historical contexts in which they processes of institutional change (1976,
are located. 1979). For the most part, however, analyses
There are, of course, some exemplars that that have drawn on the ideas of these schol-
deal with understanding the relation between ars have remained theoretical (see Sewell,
organizational and societal change, in partic- 1992 for a particularly cogent theoretical
ular, Zucker (1983), Fligstein (1990), Dobbin synthesis). The great majority of empirical
(1994) and in a different way, Orru, Biggart, studies conducted under the banner of insti-
and Hamilton (1991). It’s also worth noting tutionalism have involved large-scale, quan-
that Friedland and Alford’s cri de coeur con- titative studies examining the adoption or,
cerning the retreat from society is not appli- less frequently, the abandonment of particu-
cable in Europe, where the development of lar organizational practices or arrangements.
institutional theory has been strongly located While these studies are often premised on
in differences between nation states and vari- theoretical assumptions about cognitive and
eties of capitalism (Whitley, 1992; Morgan, interactive processes that underpin these
2001; Djelic and Sahlin Andersson, 2006). institutional processes (DiMaggio, 1997;
Much of organizational institutionalism, Oliver, 1991; Tolbert and Zucker, 1996;
though, needs to find its way back to these Barley and Tolbert, 1997; Greenwood,
issues of historical and societal significance. Suddaby, and Hinings, 2002), the
assumptions themselves have seldom been
subject to empirical verification by
Taking an interpretive approach researchers.6
One approach to this entails more inten-
seriously
sive use of data gathered through observa-
The final set of problems that we see as need- tional, interview and analysis of historical
ing more attention by organizational institu- documents derived from first-hand partici-
tionalists involves gaining a better pants involved in change or potential change
understanding of the kinds of issues that processes. This is in line with Silverman’s
ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM AND SOCIOLOGY: A REFLECTION 485

(1970) older agenda for organizational soci- definitions of reality are constituted (Berger and
ology, centering on a critique of reified and Luckmann, 1966). Despite this connection
between institutions and language, most institu-
abstracted empiricism and arguing for its
tional theory has been dominated by realist inves-
replacement with an action frame of refer- tigations in which the examination of
ence. Silverman was particularly concerned organizational practices has been disconnected
with shifting attention to what organizational from the discursive practices that constitute them
actors actually do through the process of (Phillips et al., 2004: 636).
interpretation to construct meanings. In One of the few examples of an empirical
terms of method, this approach promotes the study using a discourse analytic approach to
use of case studies, focuses on actual behav- study institutional phenomena is represented
iors, privileges discourse and emphasizes in Zbaracki’s (1998) thoughtful and provoca-
metaphor. In a similar vein, Barley and tive analysis of the adoption and implemen-
Tolbert have sought to lay out a research tation of total quality management practices
agenda, specifically within the framework of by organizations.
institutional theory, which addresses issues The essential point about an interpretative
of action and institutional change, and which approach is that it takes the actor, subjectivity,
emphasizes the identification and analysis of meanings, and reflexivity seriously. In so
scripts centered on behavior as a key ele- doing it opens up the black box of institution-
ment. Drawing on Giddens’ concepts of alization both in stability and change. And it
structuration, they make a plea for ‘a system- does it from a theoretical and methodological
atic exploration of the relative important of standpoint that is less than prevalent in orga-
behavioral and interpretive phenomena in nizational institutionalism. While we have
the institutional process, and on the basis of many provocative suggestions as to factors
such exploration, the fashioning of a set of that enable actors to question and alter extant
methods that are sensitive to and systematic institutions (see Sewell, 1992), we have little
about documenting both cultural and struc- empirical knowledge of the conditions under
tural dynamics’ (Barley and Tolbert, 1997: which those factors are most likely to come
113). One example of empirical work in this into play. Thus, many questions remain
vein is Barley’s (1986) classic study of the answered, including those such as: What is
adoption of new technology by radiology required for a general reorientation of shared
departments, which analyzes changes pro- cognitions (e.g., under what conditions might
duced in scripts, routines, and processes of a widespread rejection of tenure systems in
structuration (see Scott’s 2001 of this study). academia occur)? What causes breakdowns in
An alternative approach involves linking institutionalization processes, once these are
discourse theory and concepts of framing set in motion (e.g., why did some developed
with institutional theory (Phillips, Lawrence, countries resist signing the Kyoto protocols
and Hardy, 2004; Chreim, 2006). As with the after many of their allies and partners had
attempt to use structuration theory, the con- done so)? And why do institutions that clearly
cern here is with the processes of institution- disadvantage some groups continue to be
alization and actors as active agents accepted by members of those groups (e.g.,
interpreting and establishing meanings in why did some freed slaves in the antebellum
those processes. Phillips et al. (2004) develop U.S. become slaveholders themselves)?
a discursive model of institutionalization that
highlights the relationships among texts, dis-
course, institutions, and action. They argue
CONCLUDING COMMENTS
that language is fundamental to institution-
alization: institutionalization occurs as actors
interact and come to accept shared definitions of We have attempted to revisit the origins of
reality, and it is through linguistic processes that institutional theory and thereby ask questions
486 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

concerning in what ways the earlier insights Salancik, Copay, and King, 1991; Sewell,
may have been lost in more contemporary 1992; Barley and Tolbert, 1997). But we
studies. have little insight into how individuals trans-
Contemporary institutional theory reflects late resource problems into a critical
the core understandings and assumptions that consciousness, or into what determines
provided touchstones for classic sociological whether such constraints will lead merely to
theorizing, as well as the analytic dilemmas minor adaptations or to complete rejection of
that characterize the combined works of its institutional patterns. Gaining a better
forerunners. By tracing its linkages to the understanding of such issues would, we
ideas and arguments of the preeminent social speculate, ultimately provide the foundation
theorists indicated by Scott, we have for a better understanding of the sorts of
intended to help explain both the attraction of broad changes in societies and social orders
this approach to organizational analysis for that motivated the sociological analyses that
many researchers, as well as the difficult and serve as the forerunners of contemporary
ongoing debates that have sometimes fueled institutionalism, and could also help
a general sense of uneasiness about its future. illuminate the way in which existing rela-
We have argued that, in particular, current tions of power are likely to be subject to chal-
institutionalism is characterized by a core lenge. Drawing a link between specific
tension that can be traced to the roots of soci- micro-level interactional processes and
ology, understanding social action as a prod- particular instances of broad social change is
uct of interest-motivated, conscious choices a treacherous business, one that has some
by actors or as a product of normatively- resemblance to exploring the butterfly effect
constrained, habitualized responses. In line (Bradbury, 1953), but a general understand-
with the observations of Tolbert and Zucker ing of micro-level phenomena would, we
(1996) and others, we do not see these as believe, allow a fuller understanding of how
antithetical models, but rather as poles on a individual processes and societal level
continuum: Under different conditions, outcomes may be generally linked.
actors’ decisions and behaviors are likely to In addition, a central motif of the social
be closer to one or the other end of the spec- theorizing that institutional theory draws
trum. In our view, the key problematic facing upon was of the processes of social change.
sociologists (and anyone who seeks to extend While it is necessary to conceptualize institu-
an institutionalist perspective) is specifying tionalization as a state, there has been too
what these conditions are, and explaining the much emphasis on this rather than on institu-
connection between particular conditions tionalization as a process, understanding how
and individuals’ receptivity to cognitive those processes occur over time, and
reorientation and norm-breaking action. what the central drivers of institutional
As argued above, we believe that part of change are. These kinds of questions were at
this effort will require more empirical the heart of the theorizing of Durkheim,
analyses that use interpretive frameworks to Marx and Weber (and are also exempli-
explore institutional phenomena. That is, we fied in the work of Meyer and his col-
need a much more thorough understanding of leagues. They are much less evident in the
institutions as manifested in individual work of contemporary organizational
perceptions and decisions if we are to fully institutionalists.
grasp the duality of structures (using We believe that following up on these
Giddens’ term). It is commonly argued, for themes in our research agendas would
example, that resource constraints that hinder allow modern institutionalism to make
the enactment of institutionally-based behav- a significant contribution to the
iors are often a critical factor in bringing rich sociological heritage on which it has
about institutional change (e.g., Leblebici, drawn.
ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM AND SOCIOLOGY: A REFLECTION 487

NOTES Andreski, Stanislav. 1973. Social Sciences as


Sorcery. New York: St. Martin’s Press.
1 This lack of attention is summed up by Parsons’ Barley, Stephen R. and Pamela S. Tolbert. 1997.
plaintive query, posed in the opening of The “Institutionalization and structuration:
Structure of Social Action, less than 40 years after Studying the links between action and
Spencer’s death (1937: 1): ‘Who now reads institution.” Organization Studies, 18: 93–118.
Spencer?’ Recent theorists (e.g., Andreski, 1973; Berger, Peter L. and Thomas Luckmann. 1967.
Turner and Beeghley, 1981) suggest that the general The Social Construction of Reality: A Treatise
neglect of useful theoretical insights provided by
on the Sociology of Knowledge. Garden City,
Spencer stems from antipathy toward his embrace of
now-discounted ideas, such as Social Darwinism.
NJ: Doubleday.
2 Interestingly, some empirical evidence of Blau, Peter M. 1955. Dynamics of Bureaucracy.
Durkheim’s notion of collective consciousness can be Chicago: University of Chicago.
adduced from recent work by psychologists on the Blau, Peter M., Wolf Heydebrand, and Robert
formation and behavior of in-groups (Tajfel and E. Stauffer. 1966. “The structure of small
Turner, 1979). In a provocative analysis, Zucker bureaucracies.” American Sociological
(1986) offers a reversal of Durkheim’s arguments, Review, 31, 179–91.
noting that institutions can contribute to the forma- Blau, Peter M. and Richard Schoenherr. 1971.
tion of trust and solidarity.
The Structure of Organizations. New York:
3 very similar argument is advanced by Merton
Basic Books.
(1947b), who focuses on the relative balance of func-
tions and dysfunctions associated with existing struc- Boulding, Kenneth. 1953. The Organizational
tures as a source of social change. Merton does not Revolution. New York: Harper.
invoke notions of objectively-defined classes, how- Bourdieu, Pierre. 1977. Outline of a Theory of
ever, and though he recognizes that it is important to Practice. Cambridge: Cambridge University
consider for whom (or for which groups) a given Press.
structure is functional or dysfunctional, how to factor Bradbury, Ray. 1953. “A sound of thunder.”
that consideration into assessments of the likelihood Pp. 203–215 in Golden Apples of the Sun.
of change is left unanswered. New York: Doubleday and Co.
4 For a slightly more expanded account of the ori-
Chreim, Samia. 2006. Managerial Frames and
gins of an institutional approach in organizational
analyses, see Tolbert and Zucker, 1996.
institutional discourses of change: employee
5 A slightly different, but also relatively narrow appropriation and resistance. Organization
notion of institution is found in Selznick’s work on Studies, 27: 1261–1288.
leadership (1957: 16–17). One of the functions of a Clemens, Elizabeth S. and J.M. Cook. 1999.
leader, Selznick argues, is to infuse an organization “Politics and institutionalism: Explaining
with social value that goes beyond the achievement durability and change.” Annual Review of
of its technical goals; this contributes to its Sociology, 25: 441–466.
adaptability and long-term survival. Thus, Selznick’s Collins, Randall. 1994. Four Sociological Tradi-
use here identifies ‘institution’ with a type of
tions. London: Oxford University Press.
organization.
6 Some relevant empirical work that relates to
Collins, Randall and Michael Makowsky. 2005.
this has been provided over the last 20 years by psy- The Discovery of Society. Boston: McGraw-Hill.
chologists in research on processes of cognition for- DiMaggio, Paul J. 1988. “Interest and agency
mation and change, but the use of such research by in institutional theory.” Pp. 3–21 in L.G. Zucker
sociologists or others drawing on institutional theory, (ed.), Institutional Patterns and Organiza-
even as evidential support for underlying assump- tions: Culture and Environment. Cambridge,
tions, is very rare (see DiMaggio, 1997; Clemens and MA: Ballinger Press.
Cooke, 1999). DiMaggio, Paul J. and Walter W. Powell.
1991. Introduction. In W.W. Powell and
P.J. DiMaggio (eds.), The New Institutionalism
in Organizational Analysis. Chicago: University
REFERENCES of Chicago Press.
DiMaggio, Paul J. 1997. “Culture and cognition.”
Abbott, A. 1992. “An old institutionalist reads Annual Review of Sociology, 23: 263–287.
the new institutionalism.” Contemporary DiMaggio, P. and W.W. Powell. 1983. “The iron
Sociology: 754–756. cage revisited: Institutional isomorphism and
488 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

collective rationality in organizational fields.” Institution of Public Administration,


American Sociological Review, 48:147–160. Columbia University.
Djelic, Marie-Laure and Kirsten Sahlin Habermas, Jurgen. 1970. Toward a Rational
Andersson (eds.). 2006. Transnational gover- Society. Boston, MA: Beacon Press.
nance: institutional dynamics of regulation. Habermas, Jurgen. 1975. Legitimation Crisis.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Boston: Beacon Press.
Dobbin, Frank R. 1994. Forging Industrial Habermas, Jurgen. 1984. The Theory of
Policy: The United States, Britain and France Communicative Action. Boston, MA: Beacon
in the Railway Age. New York: Cambridge Press.
University Press. Hage, Jerald and Michael Aiken. 1967. “The
Drori, Gill S., Yong Suk Jang, and John W. relationship of centralization to other struc-
Meyer. 2006. “Sources of rationalized gover- tural properties.” Administrative Science
nance: Cross-national longitudinal analyses, Quarterly, 12: 72–91.
1985–2002.” Administrative Science Hall, Richard H., John P. Clark, Peggy Giordano,
Quarterly, 51: 205–229. Paul Johnson, and Martha Van Roekel. 1967.
Drucker, 1946 “Organizational size, complexity and formal-
Durkheim, Emile. 1947. The Division of Labor ization.” American Sociological Review, 32,
in Society. Glencoe, IL: Free Press. 903–12.
Durkheim, Emile. 1964. The Rules of Haveman, Heather A., Hayagreeva Rao, and S.
Sociological Method. Glencoe, Ill: Free Press. Paruchuri. 2007. The winds of change: The
Erickson, Robert and John H. Goldthorpe. progressive movement and the bureaucrati-
1992. The Constant Flux: A Study of Class zation of thrift.” American Sociological
Mobility in Industrial Societies. Oxford: Review, 72: 117–142.
Clarendon. Hinings, C.R. and Royston Greenwood. 2002.
Fligstein, Neil. 1990. The Transformation of Disconnects and consequences in organiza-
Corporate Control. Cambridge MA: Harvard tion theory? Administrative Science
University Press. Quarterly, 47: 411–422.
Follett, Mary Parker. 1942. Dynamic Administ- Hinings, C.R. 1988. “Defending organization
ration. New York: Harper. theory: A British view from North America.”
Giddens, Anthony. 1976. New Rules of Socio- Organization Studies, 9: 2–7.
logical Method: A Positive Critique of Inter- Hirsh, Paul M. and Michael Lounsbury.
pretive Sociologies. London: Hutchinson. 1997. “Ending the family quarrel: Toward a
Giddens, Anthony. 1979. Central Problems in reconciliation of ‘old’ and ‘new’ institutional-
Social Theory: Action, Structure and Contra- ism.” American Behavioral Scientist, 40:
diction in Social Analysis. Berkeley: University 406–418.
of California Press. Ingram, Paul and Hargaraveo Rao. 2004.
Giddens, Anthony. 1984. The Constitution of “Store wars: The enactment and repeal of
Society. Berkeley, CA: University of California anti-chain-store legislation in America.”
Press. American Journal of Sociology, 110:
Gouldner, Alvin. 1954. Patterns of Industrial 446–487.
Bureaucracy. New York: Free Press. Kimberly, John R. 1976. “Organizational size
Greenwood, Royston and C.R. (Bob) Hinings. and structuralist perspective: A review, cri-
1996. Understanding radical organizational tique and proposal.” Administrative Science
change: bringing together the old and new Quarterly, 21: 571–597.
institutionalism. Academy of Management Kirkpatrick, Ian and Stephen Ackroyd. 2003.
Review, 21: 1022–1054. Archetype theory and the changing profes-
Greenwood, Royston, Roy Suddaby and sional organisation: a critique and alterna-
C.R. (Bob) Hinings. 2002. Theorizing change: tive. Organization. 10 (4): 731–750.
the role of professional aqssociations in Klatzky, Sheila. 1970. “The relationship of
the transformation of institutionalized fields. organizational size to complexity and coordi-
Academy of Management Journal, 45: nation.” Administrative Science Quarterly,
58–80. 15: 428–38.
Gulick, Luther and L. Urwick. 1937. Papers on Leblebici, Husseyin, Gerald R. Salancik, Anne
the Science of Administration. New York: Copay and Tom King. 1991. “Institutional
ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM AND SOCIOLOGY: A REFLECTION 489

change and the transformation of interorga- Prichard, C. and Willmott, H. 1997. Just how
nizational fields: An organizational history managed is the McUniversity? Organization
of the U.S. radio broadcasting industry.” Studies, 18: 287–317.
Administrative Science Quarterly, 36: 333–363. Pugh, Derek S., David J. Hickson, C.R. Hinings,
Merton, Robert K. 1949a. “Bureaucratic struc- and C. Turner. 1969. “The context of organ-
ture and personality.” Pp. 151–160 in Social ization structures.” Administrative Science
Theory and Social Structure. Glencoe, IL: Quarterly, 14: 91–114.
Free Press. Richard Whitley.1992. Business systems in East
Merton, Robert K. 1949b. “Manifest and latent Asia: firms, markets and societies. London:
functions.” Pp. 21–82 in Social Theory and Sage Publications.
Social Structure. Glencoe, IL: Free Press. Rojas, F. 2006. “Social movement tactics, orga-
Meyer, John and Brian, Rowan. 1977. nizational change and the spread of African-
“Institutionalized organizations: Formal American studies.” Social Forces, 84:
structure as myth and ceremony.” American 2147–2166.
Journal of Sociology, 83: 340–363. Schneiberg, Mark and Timothy Bartley. 2001.
Morgan, Glenn. 2001. The development of “Regulating American industries: Markets,
transnational standards and regulations and politics and the institutional determinants of
their impacts on firms. In G. Morgan, fire insurance regulation.” American Journal
R. Whitley and P.H. Kristensen (eds.), The of Sociology, 107: 101–146.
Multinational Firm: Organizing Across Schutz, Alfred. 1967. The Phenomology of
Institutional and National Divides. Oxford: the Social World (trans. G. Walsh and
Oxford University Press. F. Lehnert). Evanston, IL: Northwestern
Oliver, Christine. 1991. “Strategic responses University Press.
to institutional processes.” Academy of Scott, W.R. 2001. Institutions and Organiza-
Management Review, 16: 145–179. tions. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage Publications.
Oliver, Christine. 1992. “The antecedents of Scott, W.R. 2006. Ad astra per aspera:
deinstitutionalization.” Organization Studies, a journey from the periphery. Organization
13: 563–588. Studies, 27: 877–890.
Orru, M., N. Biggart and G. Hamilton. 1991. Scott, W.R. and Meyer, J. 1983. The organiza-
Organizational institutionalism in East Asia. tion of societal sectors. In John W. Meyer
In W.W. Powell and P.J. DiMaggio (eds.). and W.R. Scott (eds.) Organizational
The New Institutionalism in Organizational Environments: Ritual and Rationality. Beverly
Analysis. Chicago: University of Chicago Hills, CA: Sage Publications.
Press. Selznick, Philip. 1949. TVA and the grass
Palmer, Donald, P. Devereaux Jennings and roots. Berkeley, CA: University of California
Xueguang Zhou. 1993. “Later adoption of Press.
the multi-divisional form by large U.S. corpo- Selznick, Philip. 1957. Leadership and Adminis-
rations: Institutional, political and economic tration. New York: Harper and Rowe.
accounts.” Administrative Science Quarterly, Sewell, William H. 1992. “A theory of struc-
38: 100–131. ture: Duality, agency, and transformation.”
Parsons, Talcott. 1937. The Structure of Social American Journal of Sociology, 98: 1–29.
Action. New York: McGraw-Hill. Silverman, David. 1970. The theory of organi-
Pennings, Johannes. 1973. “Measures of orga- zations: a sociological framework. London:
nizational structure: A methodological Heinemann.
note.” American Journal of Sociology, 79: Sine, Wesley D., Heather A. Haveman, and
686–704. Pamela S. Tolbert. 2005. “Risky business?
Perrow, Charles. 1985. “Review essay: Entrepreneurship in the new independent
Overboard with myth and symbols.” power sector.” Administrative Science
American Journal of Sociology, 91: Quarterly, 50: 200–232.
151–155. Skinner, Jonathan S. and Douglas Staiger.
Phillips, Nelson, Thomas Lawrence and Cynthia 2005. “Technology adoption from hybrid
Hardy. 2004. Discourse and institutions. corn to beta blockers.” National Bureau of
Academy of Management Review, 29: Economic Research Working Paper #11251.
635–652. NBER: Cambridge, MA.
490 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Stern, Robert N. and Stephen R. Barley. 1996. Weber, Max. 1949. The Methodology of
“Organizations and social systems: Organiza- the Social Sciences (trans. E.A. Shils and
tion theory’s neglected mandate.” Administ- H.A. Finch). New York: Free Press.
rative Science Quarterly, 41: 141–162. Weeden, Kim A. and David B. Grusky. 2005.
Swedberg, Richard. 1998. Max Weber and the “A case for a new class map.” American
Idea of Economic Sociology. Princeton, NJ: Journal of Sociology, 111: 141–212.
Princeton University Press. Woodward, Joan. 1958. Management and
Tajfel, H. and J.C. Turner. 1979. “An integrative Technology. London: Her Majesty’s
theory of intergroup conflict.” Pp. 33–48 Stationery Office.
in S. Worchel and W.G. Austin (eds.), The Wright, Erik O. 1997. Class Counts:
Social Psychology of Intergroup Relations. Comparative Studies in Class Analysis.
Monterey: Brooks/Cole. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Thornton, Patricia and William Ocasio. 1999. Zbaracki, Mark J. 1998. “The rhetoric and
Institutional logics and the historical contin- reality of total quality management.”
gency of power in organizations: executive Administrative Science Quarterly, 43:
succession in the higher education publish- 602–636.
ing industry, 1958–1999. American Journal Zhou, Xueguang. 1993. “Occupational
of Sociology, 105: 801–843. power, state capacities, and the diffusion
Tolbert, Pamela S. and Lynne G. Zucker. 1983. of licensing in the American states,
“Institutional sources of change in the 1890–1950.” American Sociological Review,
formal structure of organizations: The diffu- 58: 536–552.
sion of civil service reform, 1880–1930.” Zucker, Lynne G. 1977. “The role of institution-
Administrative Science Quarterly, 28: 22–39. alization in cultural persistence.” American
Tolbert, Pamela S. and Lynne G. Zucker. 1996. Sociological Review, 42: 726–743.
“The institutionalization of institutional Zucker, Lynne G. 1983. “Organizations as
theory.” Pp. 175–190 in S.R. Clegg, C. Hardy Institutions.” Research in the Sociology of
and W.R Nord (eds.), Handbook of Organiza- Organizations, vol. 2: 1–48. Greenwich, CT:
tional Studies. London: Sage. JAI Press.
Turner, Jonathan H. and Leonard Beeghley. Zucker, Lynne G. 1986. “Production of
1981. The Emergence of Sociological trust: Institutional sources of economic
Theory. Homewood, IL: Dorsey Press. structures, 1840–1920.” In B.M. Staw and
Weber, Max. 1947. The Theory of Social and L.L. Cummings (eds.), Research in Organiza-
Economic Organization (trans. T. Parsons). tional Behavior vol. 8: 53–111. Greewich,
New York: Free Press. CT: JAI.
20
Coalface Institutionalism
Stephen R. Barley

Famous personages and also periods in the history


human agency of any kind was largely
… may be reassessed, some being demoted and irrelevant, if not illusory. This left the neo-
others raised up or even rediscovered … Some are institutionalists to reinforce the sociological
found worthless, stale; others provide stimulating line in organization studies. In what are
ideas and even technology which can be built on widely acknowledged as seminal papers that
… their ideas and work are more ‘relevant’ – not
merely more useful or suggestive – than that of
staked out neo-institutionalism’s stance,
many contemporaries … No matter that the Zucker (1977), Meyer and Rowan (1977), and
ancestors might be turning uncomfortably in their DiMaggio and Powell (1983) argued that
graves if they knew how their lives and works were organizations not only act, but that they often
reinterpreted and selectively used. (Strauss, do so for cultural, interpretative, and symbolic
1982: 179)
reasons and that these actions matter for an
organization’s fate. For ethnographers of work
and organizations, many of whom still worked
INSTITUTIONALISM, SOCIAL in the spirit of industrial sociology, the neo-
CONSTRUCTION AND institutionalists seemed like kin. Here, finally,
ETHNOMETHODOLOGY were bona fide organizational theorists who
dared to stake their macro-theories on a
Neo-institutionalism appeared in the late micro-sociology.1
1970s with the goal of challenging rational The institutionalists’ micro-sociologies of
theories of organizing that had ruled organiza- choice were phenomenological construc-
tion studies since the 1960s (Zucker 1977, tivism and ethnomethodology. Zucker made
Meyer and Rowan 1977, DiMaggio and the most use of both (Zucker 1977, 1987;
Powell 1983). It also arrived just in time to Tolbert and Zucker 1996). She combined
counterbalance newly emerging transaction Berger and Luckmann’s (1967) concepts of
cost and ecological theories of organizational typification, reification, and objectivation
form (Williamson 1975, Hannan and Freeman with Garfinkel’s (1967) notion of accounts to
1977). Whereas transaction cost theory argue that institutions are best treated as
breathed new life into rational views of organ- taken-for-granted understandings: 2
izing by building on the calculus of a make or Institutionalized acts then, must be perceived as
buy decision, the ecologists professed that both objective and exterior. Acts are objective
492 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

when they are potentially repeatable by other had little to say about organizations.3
actors without changing the common understand- They certainly spoke of institutions, but their
ing of the act, while acts are exterior when the
subjective understanding of acts is reconstructed
institutions were of a different order than
as intersubjective … so that the acts are seen as those that preoccupied institutionalists.
part of the external world (see Berger and Ethnomethodologists have usually focused
Luckmann, 1967 on ‘reification’ and ‘objectiva- on taken-for-granted understandings that are
tion’) … When acts have ready-made accounts widely shared by members of a culture or
they are institutionalized; that is both
objective and exterior. (Zucker 1977: 728, italics in
subculture: for example, how to do gender
original) (Garfinkel 1967), how to do power
(Grimshaw 1981), how to do being a doctor
Although less expansively, Meyer and (Emerson 1970) or how to take turns in a
Rowan (1977) made nearly identical use of conversation (Sachs et al. 1974). In fact, for
the same micro-sociologies. Crediting ethnomethodologists, interpretive procedures
Berger and Luckmann (1977: 341), they were the ultimate institutions. By interpretive
wrote: ‘Institutionalized rules are classifica- procedures ethnomethodologists meant deep,
tions built into society as reciprocated typifi- taken-for-granted rules necessary for engag-
cations or interpretations.’ Later, citing Scott ing in everyday interaction in precisely the
and Lyman (1968: 349), they connected same way that grammars are the deep rules
institutions to the ethnomethodologi- for everyday speech (Cicourel 1970, 1972,
cal notion of accounts: ‘The incorporation of 1981). Among the interpretive procedures
institutionalized elements provides an that interested ethnomethodologists were: a
account of its activities that protects the reciprocity of perspectives (the assumption
organization from having its context that others see the same world
questioned.’ I see), indexicality (the assumption that to
Published six years later, DiMaggio and make sense of what is being said or done
Powell’s (1983) canonical article contained I need to take the immediate context into
no mention of either constructivism or eth- account) and a retrospective-prospective
nomethodology, except for passing reference sense of occurrence (the assumption that
to a paper by Aaron Cicourel (1970). But in others will eventually do or say something
the introduction to their influential book, The that will clarify what they have done or said
New Institutionalism in Organizational so far). Clearly, these taken-for-granteds are
Analysis, DiMaggio and Powell (1991: of a different order than civil service reform
19–22) highlighted both micro-sociologies. (Tolbert and Zucker 1983), internal labor
They concluded: ‘Ethnomethodology and markets (Dobbin et al. 1993), or changing
phenomenology together provide the new forms of corporate control (Fligstein 1993).
institutionalism with a micro-sociology of The latter are components of social or politi-
considerable power’ (1991: 21). Since these cal systems that operate at much higher level
original manifestos, however, institutional- of analysis than the phenomena typically of
ists have devoted little attention to eth- concern to ethnomethodologists.
nomethodology, to social construction, or for Furthermore, ethnomethodology is prima-
that matter, to micro-sociology of any kind. rily a cognitive rather than a behavioral
As institutionalism spread, its micro-social or political sociology (Cicourel 1974).
concerns disappeared into the background. In ethnomethodology, as in institutional
In retrospect, the disappearance is unsur- theory, sense-making trumps vested action.
prising. Ethnomethodology was from the Ethnomethdology’s cognitive perspective, as
start an odd choice for linking organizations well as Berger and Luckmann’s notions of
to situated action and cognition. With a few reification, objectivation, and sedimentation,
notable exceptions (Bittner 1965; Silverman make it easier to view institutions as stable
1971; Cicourel 1967), ethnomethodologists constraints rather than as shifting resources.
COALFACE INSTITUTIONALISM 493

In fact, as Heritage notes (1993), eth- society as a ‘body of institutions’ (Athens


nomethodologists have written more about 2005: 305). Hughes, in turn, equated sociol-
the replication of social order than about its ogy with the study of institutions. ‘Sociology
change. Paul DiMaggio (1988: 10) acknowl- is that one of the social sciences,’ he wrote,
edged a similar proclivity in institutional ‘Which is especially and peculiarly, by intent
theory two decades ago: and not by accident, a science of social insti-
tutions’ (1942: 15). Zucker (1977: 726)
If the focus of institutional theory on norms, taken-
for-granted assumptions, and cognitive and coor-
recognized Hughes’ relevance for the neo-
dinative limitations represent substantive reasons institutionalists’ agenda and opened her
for the neglect (relative to other theoretical tradi- influential paper by citing one of Hughes’
tions) of interests, part of this neglect is implicit not quip-like definitions: ‘The only idea
in the logic of institutional arguments but in the common to all usages of the term ‘institu-
rhetoric that institutional theorists have used to
advance them. The ‘iron cage’ is one such phrase,
tion’ is that of some sort of establishment of
with its implicit portrayal of humans as powerless relative permanence of a distinctly social
…. Similar are assertions that institutionalized sort’ (Hughes 1936: 180). But, she subse-
organizations ‘take on a life of their own’ … quently made little use the Chicagoans.
Presumably if an organization ‘takes on a life of its Meyer and Rowan (1977) made even less:
own’ one need not attend to individual or group
motives to understand behavior … The most wide-
their paper contains no mention of Hughes
spread rhetorical, as opposed to analytic, dis- and only passing references to Dalton (1950)
missals of agency … occur in the chronic use of and Goffman (1967), who studied with
passive constructions and, where nouns are used Hughes at Chicago. DiMaggio and Powell
as the subjects of active verbs, in the selection of (1983) referenced no Chicago School sociol-
subjects so broad of reference as to be substan-
tively empty … [T]he locutions … [that institution-
ogists at all.
alists use] systematically de-emphasize human Substantial acknowledgement of Hughes’
agency. Institutional myths ‘are highly institutional- contribution to the study of institutions
ized,’ and some structural elements are …’soci- awaited the publication of Richard Scott’s
etally legitimated.’ Another approach … would be (1995) Institutions and Organizations. Early
to ask, ‘Who has institutionalized the myths (and
why)?’ and ‘Who has the power to “legitimate” a
in his treatise, Scott (1995: 8) credited
structural element?’ Hughes with being an early institutionalist,
noted that Hughes was particularly interested
Ironically, institutionalism might have in the relationship between individuals and
avoided these issues and others to which they institutions and credited the Chicagoans for
have subsequently been forced to attend had carrying institutionalism ‘forward in an unin-
they looked to a different micro-sociology terrupted fashion’ in occupational
for inspiration: Chicago School sociology sociology (1995: 9). Scott scolded organiza-
as practiced by Everett C. Hughes and his tional sociologists for not having done the
students.4 same, but then said nothing more about the
Chicagoans’ contributions. In fact, later in
the book, when mapping levels of analysis to
bodies of theory and research on institutions
Scott (1995: 59), presented ethnomethodol-
INTERACTIONISM: THE ROAD ogy as the only institutional sociology that
NOT TAKEN operates at the level of the organization and
below.
Chicago School sociologists, especially Scott may have skipped the Chicago sociol-
Hughes, saw their agenda as the study of ogists, not only because they studied occupa-
institutions and institutionalized behavior.5 tions, but also because he classified them as
George Herbert Mead, whose work strongly symbolic interactionists who saw meaning
influenced Chicago sociology, had defined as ‘internalized and subjective’ rather than as
494 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

objective and exterior (1995: 42).6 If by sym- using existing rules and social resources to con-
bolic interactionists Scott had Herbert Blumer struct a social identity with some consistency
across varying situations … A cognitive conception
(1962) and his students in mind, then his of institutions stresses the central role played by
charge of subjectivism is warranted. As Athens the socially mediated construction of a common
(2005: 307–208) points out, Blumer down- framework of meaning. (Scott 1995: 45)
played Mead’s notion of institutionalized
(exterior) meaning (what Mead called, Hughes and his students spent half a cen-
‘common maxims’), because he apparently tury developing and refining an understand-
believed that the notion of an institution was ing of how actors negotiate understandings,
less relevant for ‘modern, mass societies’ than rules, roles, and meaning, albeit from a
it had been in traditional societies.7 However, decidedly sociological and institutional
the charge of subjectivism cannot be so easily perspective.
leveled against Hughes, Anselm Strauss I suspect, however, that institutionalists
(Strauss, Schatzman, Bucher et al. 1964; overlooked the Chicagoans for the same
Strauss 1968, 1978a), Howard Becker (1952, reason that other sociologists have done so:
1953, 1963, 1982) and others who collabo- Hughes and his students are widely thought to
rated or studied with Hughes. Hughes and have developed no theory. The perception of
Blumer were both students of Robert Park the Chicagoans as theory-less arises, in part,
and Ernest Burgess (1921), both were influ- because Hughes and his students eschewed
enced by Mead (1934) and were later col- top-down theory in favor of amassing data to
leagues on the faculty at Chicago, but generate what Glaser and Strauss (1967)
Hughes’ work differed significantly from would eventually call ‘grounded theory.’ Fine
Blumer’s precisely because institutions were (1991: 165) makes precisely this point when
front and center in Hughes’ image of soci- discussing how interactionists have dealt with
ety.8 Hughes wrote about real estate boards, institutional constraints. ‘Any approach to
professional associations, medical schools, social order,’ Fine wrote, ‘Must recognize that
and hospitals among other settings. Perhaps although actors themselves affect how they
most importantly, he studied the processes define their world, others – corporate, collec-
by which occupations become professions: tive, imaginary, or metaphoric – considerably
Processes which, for Hughes, entailed the influence their choices. Our ethnographies,
construction of precisely the sort of institu- grounded in institutional realities and individ-
tions that neo-institutionalists study. ual recognitions of these realities, demonstrate
Perhaps it is because the institutionalists this, but our theory lags behind.’ In other
overlooked the Chicagoans that they have words, institutions served Hughes and his stu-
generally turned to social psychology when dents as an ever-present backdrop for their
they need to link meaning to social structure field studies. The concept of institutions is
and explain how institutional rules are inter- tightly woven into their writings. However,
preted and negotiated (rather than imposed or they had little need for an explicit theory of
coerced): institutions because they did not have institu-
tionalism’s agenda of developing an alterna-
By contrast [to institutionalists], social psycholo-
gists are more likely to emphasize the interactive tive to rationalism.9
and negotiated nature of those choices. Nevertheless, to say that Chicago School
Constitutive rules need not simply be externally sociologists built no explicit theory is not to
imposed on actors. Weick (1979), for example, say that they had no perspective at all. As
emphasizes that understandings and scripts
Rock (1979: 83) noted, the theoretical loose-
emerge out of actions as well as guide them and
that collective symbols are as likely to be used to ness that scholars find troubling about the
justify past behaviors as to guide current ones. Chicagoans was less a matter of muddled
These newer versions of role and identity theory minds than a practiced guard against prema-
emphasize that individuals play an active part, ture generalization. Hughes and his students
COALFACE INSTITUTIONALISM 495

aimed their investigations at bounded ‘social but other than Hughes, few said directly what
worlds’ (Shibutani 1955; Strauss 1978b). they meant by the term. The same is true of
Their guiding notion was that valid theoreti- the entire constellation of concepts (career,
cal concepts could only emerge by compar- role, identity, etc.) with which the interac-
ing the particulars of a variety of settings tionists routinely worked (Barley 1989).
(Glaser and Strauss 1967). If a construct was Scholars must, therefore, infer what the
to be relevant for a range of cases, its reach Chicagoans had in mind by examining the
had to be demonstrated empirically. As a context in which the terms appear. In general,
consequence, the picture of how the Hughes and his students used ‘institution’ in
Chicagoans understood institutions is scat- three ways. The first was to denote types or
tered across forty years of research. classes of organizations: hospitals, schools,
In recent years, scholars have begun to labor unions, firms, and so on. The second
acknowledge the relevance of interactionist was closer to how Mead (1934) and Merton
sociology for institutionalism (Basu, (1957) employed the term: broad sectors or
Dirsmith, and Gupta 1999; Fligstein 2001; domains of society such as the family, sci-
Lounsbury and Kaghan 2001; Hallett and ence, religion and economy. The third usage,
Ventresca 2006).10 My goal is go further and which is more frequent and more interesting,
explain in detail how Hughes and his students is harder to specify, although it underwrites
understood institutions and institutionaliza- the other two. To grasp this more diffuse
tion. As we shall see, their ideas are not only notion of institution, it is useful to turn to
consistent with neo-institutionalism, but their passages drawn from a number of texts.
perspective offers a micro-sociology that Hughes begins ‘The Study of Institutions’
treats institutions as constraints while empha- by inventorying, in his down-home, discur-
sizing the role that human agency and vested sive way, concrete examples of institutions of
interests play in creating, maintaining and different ‘orders.’
changing institutions. I begin by documenting A large portion of the people in our society live
how the Chicagoans defined institutions and together in families º Likewise, people go to work
then explicate Anselm Strauss’s notions of in factories; they study, teach and play in schools
negotiated orders and social worlds, concepts º If they are residents of Latin American villages,
they will engage once a year in a great fiesta: if
that capture, respectively, the institutionalists’
they live in the rural Middle West, they might pos-
image of institutions as social processes and sibly be annually mobilized by a county fair. In all
structures. The discussion subsequently turns these instances people are mobilized to take their
to two issues that currently concern institu- places – important or minor, casual or regular, vol-
tionalists and about which the interactionists untary or involuntary – in a collective enterprise
carried on in a somewhat established and
had much to say: legitimation and the nature expected way. The things I have named – and
of institutional complexes. My agenda is to many others as well – have been called institutions.
suggest how researchers might proceed if Some of the other things, which have been called
they assume, as did the Chicagoans, that by the same name, are of quite different orders. It
action always occurs within the constraints of is not my purpose to explore the limits of a con-
cept. (Hughes 1942: 307, italics added)
an institutional matrix that humans wittingly
or unwittingly create, maintain, and alter. Hughes then goes on to say that students
of institutions should concern themselves
with two phenomena: action and social
forms, the first of which occurs ‘within’ the
INSTITUTION IN THE CHICAGO latter. Given this, he cautions that trying to
TRADITION decide whether something is or is not an
institution is a waste of time:
‘Institution’ and its various semantic deriva- I rest the case by saying that I conceive of the study
tives peppered the writings of the Chicagoans, of institutions to be part of the study of society in
496 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

action. The center of the field lies where the action to ‘common maxims,’ Hughes pointed to
takes place within forms which are somewhat conventions.
firmly established. The student of institutions will,
however, be interested also in seeing how social Since a common feature of definitions of institu-
forms become established, how they bend and tions is that they are clusters of conventions, the
yield under pressure, how they give place to new, obvious things to put into a list are those phenom-
and what functions they perform. He will, if his ena that are beyond dispute conventional, the
interest is in the structure and functioning of soci- things that have a place in the more established
ety, be only incidentally concerned to answer cate- public statements of how we do things (strongly
gorically the question whether the newspaper, the tinged with the notion that these are the right way
beer parlor, the Republican Party or property is an to do things). But if we close our lists there, we
institution at a given moment. (Hughes 1942: 307, miss the main and more fascinating part of the
italics added) sociologist’s work, which is to understand how
social values and collective arrangements are made
and unmade: how things arise and how they
These passages contain four ideas key to change. To make progress with our job, we need
the interactionists’ concept of an institution. to give full and comparative attention to the not-
First, institutions were ‘social forms,’ a term yets, the didn’t quite-make-its, the not quite
drawn directly from Simmel (1964).11 For respectable, the unremarked and the openly ‘anti’
Simmel, as for Hughes, a social form was a goings-on in our society. (1962/71: 52, italics
added)
pattern both of and for social action. It was
exterior to those who participated in it and This passage points to three additional
independent of the particulars of their behav- attributes of Hughes’ notion of an institution.
ior. Form is a structural concept in the sense First, like the ethnomethodologists, Hughes
that genre, script, role, template, and gram- viewed institutions as taken-for-granted cul-
mar are structures. For Simmel, forms were tural understandings and practices. But,
the building blocks of society. Thus, it is fair unlike the ethnomethodologists, he implied
to say that like Berger and Luckmann, that taken-for-granteds could be articulated
Hughes saw institutions as constructions that as ‘how we do things’ and that they had
had become objectified and exteriorized, moral force. In other words, institutions carry
although perhaps less reified. some notion of ‘ought.’ As a result, Hughes
Second, when Hughes spoke of institu- attributed behavioral status to institutions
tions of different ‘orders,’ he implied that without denying that they also had a
institutions vary in their scope or range of cognitive element. For interactionists the
application. Some institutions cover the social, cognitive and behavioral were insepa-
actions of large portions of society (a form of rable. Second, Hughes claimed that conven-
family or notions of property), while others tions ‘cluster,’ they occur in complexes. That
are relatively local (a fiesta or a county fair). institutions co-occur or intersect to form a
Third, institutions are ‘collective enter- social fabric is an important and recurring
prises,’ in the sense that they are jointly pro- image in interactionist sociology. Finally, as
duced through ongoing action and did most Chicagoans, Hughes thought it
interaction. Finally, institutionalized actions important to study institutions in process. For
and interactions are to some degree scripted; the interactionists, institutions were not
people ‘take their places’ in the sense that fixed: They morphed as people created,
they play roles in a ‘somewhat established or attempted to change, and sometimes elimi-
expected way.’ Without such consistency, nated them.
institutions could not exist. By combining these various attributes, we
In a paper written twenty years later, can synthesize an approximate definition
Hughes (1962/71) was more explicit about of what Hughes meant by an institution.
what constituted a social form. Much like Institutions are social forms or templates
Mead, who claimed that behavior was insti- composed of clusters of conventions
tutionalized when people behaved according that script behavior to varying degrees in
COALFACE INSTITUTIONALISM 497

given contexts. Institutions are socially States developed the state mental hospital. We are
constructed and are subsequently maintained all familiar with this form of hospital … Today they
are widely regarded as medieval, cruel, or totally
or changed by people who act and interact
unsuitable for the treatment of the mentally ill. Yet
with each other. For the Chicagoans, then, they were once regarded as suitable … [they]
an institution was an abstract and flexible siphoned off many of the poor, the indigent, and
heuristic applicable at a variety of levels of the unassimilated immigrants, and effectively hid
analysis. Thus, for example, Goffman (1983) them from public view and concern. They relieved
the cities and states of special welfare and protec-
could, in a single paper, employ the term to
tion problems and saved whole families from the
talk about the social meaning of acquain- threat of downward mobility. All this they did with
tanceship as well as the form of a service a minimum of cost … We would say that this insti-
encounter (practices that address customers’ tutional form was appropriate simply because at
expectations that they be treated equitably, that time it reflected the needs, ideas, and charac-
ter of American life. Sociologically, it fit. Today it no
equally and with courtesy):
longer fits. Now we are developing new institu-
Take for example (in our own society) acquain- tional forms and practices appropriate to the
tanceship, or, better still, ‘knowership.’ This is a needs, ideas, and character of American life
critical institution from the perspective of how we today – and not necessarily appropriate to the
deal with individuals in our immediate, or in our needs of the mentally ill. (Schatzman and Strauss
telephonic, presence, a key factor in the organiza- 1966: 12, italics added)
tion of social contacts. What is involved is the right
and obligation mutually to accept and openly to This passage points to two additional
acknowledge individual identification on all initial attributes of institutions, as Chicagoans
occasions of incidentally produced proximity (p.13) understood them. First, institutions are his-
… I have suggested in schematic terms elements
of the structure of service transactions that can be
torically situated and sociologists would do
taken as institutionalized and official, such that well to approach them with a long view.
ordinarily when they are seen to apply in a Second, institutions are tied to ideologies
particular service setting, those present feel that championed by specific segments of society
nothing marked or unacceptable or out of the that lend the institution legitimacy. As ide-
ordinary has occurred by way of substance or cer-
emony (1983: 15)
ologies change, legitimacy will change and,
hence, so will the institution.
Although Goffman’s renderings resembled In short, the Chicagoan’s image of institu-
an ethnomethodologist’s take on institutions tions encompasses much of neo-institutional-
(see especially Goffman, 1981), other ism’s more cognitive view. Like
Chicagoans spoke of institutions at levels of institutionalists, the Chicagoans argued that
analysis that have preoccupied the neo-insti- institutions were typifications – taken-
tutionalists. Consider, for example, Strauss for-granted ways of acting, doing, seeing and
and Schatzman’s comments on forms of psy- thinking. As Fine put it:
chiatric hospitals:
Learning to act appropriately requires understand-
Socio-cultural changes in American life account ing the ‘type’ of situation faced and knowing what
both for much of what is claimed that the mentally behaviors fit … Further, [situations] are
ill need and for the kinds of institutions and prac- perceived as being controlled by and constitutive
tices being fashioned for them. Institutions, like of organizations, groups, institutions, and societies
people, have historical and social loci …. For exam- … Our reading of situations involves creating
ple, Americans may be developing certain forms of typifications of macro-structures that serve as the
institutional practice, not so much because they basis for addressing future interactions. (1991:
are designed for better psychiatric treatment but 165)
because they … meet the requirements of some
special public … Design for psychiatric treatment Like institutionalists, Hughes and his stu-
may be a rationalization of ideological sentiment dents also understood that perceptions of
º for behind mental institutions are social and
legitimacy were crucial to the emergence and
philosophical trends, which give rise to ideas about
appropriate institutional forms. … During the maintenance of institutions and that legitima-
latter half of the nineteenth century, the United tion was integrally tied to ideologies whose
498 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

rhetorics offered justificatory accounts. idea that organizational structures direct


Finally, although ‘social form’ connotes a work intentionally and rationally:
broader concept of social structure than There is need for an explanation of [the rise of
that which most institutionalists employ, it formal organizations] that is partially free
easily encompasses the institutionalists’ from the assumption that, in practice, formal
concern with types of organizations and structures actually coordinate and control work.
Such an explanation should account for the
organizational structures. Indeed, interac-
elaboration of purposes, positions, policies, and
tionists routinely used ‘institution’ to procedural rules that characterizes formal
refer to organizational forms (Schatzman organizations, but must do so without suppos-
and Strauss 1966; Strauss et al. 1964; Bucher ing that these structural features are imple-
and Stelling 1977; McCallion and Maines mented in routine work activity (1977: 343, italics
added)
2002).
At the same time, the Chicagoans’ view of Meyer and Rowan’s agenda was to under-
institutions differed from the institutional- cut the assumption that plans and structures
ists’ in theoretically and empirically impor- cause action, a myth that Bittner (1965) and
tant ways. First, they saw institutions as Silverman (1971) had already debunked
processes. Institutions not only constrained from an ethnomethodological stance.
human action, human action, in turn, created, However, to say that action is not rationally
maintained, and changed institutions. Said linked to structures, purposes, positions, and
differently, institutions were both a product policies, is not equivalent to saying there is
of and resources for interaction and negotia- no relationship at all.
tion in everyday life. Second, institutions Early on, DiMaggio warned that dismiss-
occurred in clusters and these clusters ing agency was neo-institutionalism’s
defined the context for action in the social Achilles’ heel. Noting that the ‘role of inter-
worlds they covered. Institutions were, there- est and agency in institutional theory remains
fore, integral to the segmentation of society. somewhat obscure,’ DiMaggio (1988: 3–5)
To see how these ideas might benefit contem- took institutionalists to task for emphasizing
porary institutionalists requires turning from ‘factors that make actors unlikely to recog-
Hughes to Anselm Strauss’s work on nize or to act on their interests’ and ‘circum-
negotiated order (Strauss 1978a) and social stances that cause actors who do recognize
worlds (Strauss 1978b, 1982, 1984).12 The and try to act on their interests to be unable
former amounts to an action-oriented take on to do so effectively.’ He went on to call atten-
institutions and institutionalization, while the tion to what he called the paradox of institu-
latter provides a way of conceptualizing, tionalization:
investigating, and analyzing institutional
Institutionalization as an outcome places organiza-
clusters. tional structures and practices beyond the reach of
interest and politics. By contrast, institutionaliza-
tion as a process is profoundly political and reflects
the relative power of organized interests and the
NEGOTIATED ORDERS actors who mobilize around them. (DiMaggio,
1988: 13)

Despite Berger and Luckmann’s interest in DiMaggio argued that most institutional
human agency and Garfinkel’s preoccupation research had emphasized outcomes over
with practice, the institutionalists who process. In response, he called for studies of
invoked them paid little attention to agency institutional entrepreneurs: Men and women
and practice. Sometimes, this seemed pur- who intentionally or unintentionally create
poseful. For instance, Meyer and Rowan institutions as a way of achieving their
(1977) apparently separated structure from own interests or the interests of groups they
action as part of a gambit for challenging the represent.
COALFACE INSTITUTIONALISM 499

Taking DiMaggio’s call seriously, a institutions lay at the core of symbolic inter-
number of institutionalists have recently actionism’s view of society:
begun to investigate how individuals, organi- concerns with organization on one hand and with
zations or professions wittingly or unwit- acting units on the other hand set the essential dif-
tingly created institutions by pursuing ference between conventional views of human
lines of action (Fligstein 2001; Seo and society and the view of it implied in symbolic inter-
action … The difference is along two major lines.
Creed 2002; Venkatesh and Shin 2005; First, from the standpoint of symbolic interaction
Greenwood and Suddaby 2006; Battilana the organization of a human society is the frame-
2006; Leca 2006). Young scholars have also work inside of which social action takes place and
paid more attention than earlier institutional- is not the determinant of that action. Second, such
ists to how people cast meaning (Lawrence organization and changes in it are the product of
the activity of acting units and not of ‘forces’
and Phillips 2004; Munir and Phillips 2005; which leave such acting units out of account …
Grodal 2007). Nevertheless, because the idea Social organization enters into action only and to
of an entrepreneur encourages studies of the extent to which it shapes situations in which
‘foundings,’ tales of entrepreneurial agency people act, and the extent to which it supplies
usually end once an institution has been fixed sets of symbols which people use in interpret-
ing their situations.’ (1962: 189–90)
established. Although the actions of entrepre-
neurs are surely a crucial part of the story of Structural duality was also implicit in how
institutionalization, focusing on entrepre- interactionists understood the core constructs
neurs skirts the idea that agency and action around which they organized their research:
are also important for maintaining and roles, rules, careers, status, identity, and so
modifying institutions.13 on. For Hughes and his students, these Janus-
Some scholars, realizing that agency is faced concepts oriented attention simultane-
implicated at all phases of an institution’s ously in two directions (Barley 1989). On
lifespan, have attempted to reformulate insti- one hand, they pointed to patterned forms of
tutionalization in light of Giddens’ (1984) action and participation characteristic of life
concept of structuration (Barley and Tolbert in some social domain. In the case of a role,
1997; Lounsbury and Kaghan 2001; Sandfort for instance, the relevant patterns were the
2003; Battilana 2006).14 Structuration theory recurrent behaviors and types of interactions
portrays institutions simultaneously as con- that were more or less common to and
straints on and products of social action. expected of all who fill a role. To be a police-
Giddens (1984) called this reciprocal causal- man entails wearing a specific kind of uni-
ity the ‘duality of structure.’ Furthermore, form, carrying a gun, stopping speeding
structuration implies that researchers can motorists, handing out parking tickets, keep-
only document how individual and collective ing a watchful eye on public events, making
action creates, preserves or changes institu- court appearances, persuading loiterers to
tions by taking a longitudinal view. Having move along, directing traffic, issuing orders
made these points, however, Giddens says to people from various walks of life, and
little about how to identify much less study having those orders obeyed, however grudg-
structure’s duality. The need to forge empiri- ingly (see Van Maanen 1973, 1975).
cal tools led Barley (1986) to blend structura- Similarly, having a career also denotes a
tion theory with Strauss’s more pragmatic structured and recognized form of participa-
notion of negotiated order and to study tion in a social world: A stream of identifi-
‘structuring’ by observing how scripted inter- able positions, offices, statuses and situations
actions evolved over time.15 that serve as landmarks for gauging a
The notion of structuring was long latent person’s movement through an organization,
in interactionist scholarship. For instance, occupation, family, avocation, or subculture
Blumer (1962: 189–90) argued that a (Hughes 1937: 403; Becker 1963: 24; Braude
reciprocal relationship between actions and 1975: 141; Faulkner 1974: 132; Goffman
500 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

1961: 127). In Hughes’ terminology, this overlooked body of work (at least in organi-
constitutes the ‘objective’ (Berger and zation studies) on negotiated order. Strauss
Luckman would say, ‘objectivated’) aspect believed that unraveling the link between
of a role or a career: Its institutional or public action and structure was one of sociology’s
face which requires some kind of overt primary tasks. Foreshadowing Giddens by
behavior. over a decade, he and Schatzman wrote:
On the other hand, for Chicagoans, role ‘Institutions impose limitations upon prac-
and career also pointed to the incumbent’s tices and ideas, but in turn are modified by
subjective experience. By subjective experi- them. The precise ways in which these are
ence interactionists meant the meanings that related is an important aspect of sociological
individuals attribute to their role or career. inquiry’ (Schatzman and Strauss 1966: 13).
The subjective side of a role entails accounts Strauss’s interest in negotiated order began
or definitions of both self and others that with a field study of a psychiatric hospital in
enable individuals to orient to situations.16 the late 1950s where he and his colleagues
In the case of policing, for instance, Van encountered competing ideologies of illness
Maanen (1978) described how interpretations and treatment (Strauss et al. 1963, 1964).
of self and others are crucial to how police Proponents of these ideologies espoused dif-
classify and, then, behave toward people they ferent visions of a psychiatric hospital’s
encounter on patrol. A ‘subjective career’ mission and how such hospitals should be
similarly encompasses its incumbent’s sense organized and administered. At roughly the
of becoming, which enables her to develop a same time, Rue Bucher (Bucher and
narrative of and align herself with the events Schatzman 1962; Bucher and Stelling 1977)
of her biography. Subjective careers are the documented analogous ideological disputes
tales people tell to themselves and others that raging in pathology: some pathologists saw
lend coherence to the strands of their life. their field as a science, while others believed
More importantly for present purposes, such it should be treated as a medical specialty.
interpretations and enactments lay founda- In their jurisdictional battles, these two
tions for change in role behaviors and career camps formed alliances with different groups
trajectories that eventually modify a role’s or of physicians, championed different systems
a career’s institutional face. of education, formed different professional
Unlike Linton (1936) and Parsons (1951), associations, and politicked for different
the Chicagoans did not conceive of roles as roles in the medical community. Strauss and
predefined sets of rights and duties that could his collaborators explicated and refined the
be donned and doffed. Instead they sub- idea of negotiated order throughout the
scribed to Mead’s (1934) notion that roles 1960s (Bucher and Strauss 1961; Bucher and
emerge in an ongoing process of negotiation, Schatzman 1962; Schatzman and Bucher
a ‘conversation of gestures,’ during which 1964; Glaser and Strauss 1965, 1968;
individuals develop a repertoire of behaviors Schatzman and Strauss 1966; Bucher and
and attitudes tailored to specific interactional Stelling 1969). Their effort culminated
partners. For interactionists, ‘role making’ with the publication of Strauss’s (1978a)
was as important as ‘role taking.’ Role Negotiations.
making (among other dynamics) allowed for Strauss insisted that all social orders are
variations that might eventually reformulate negotiated: That is, all social systems are the
a role’s institutional face (McCall and sediments of a history of voting, decree, con-
Simmons 1978; Turner 1962, 1968, 1976, flict, agreement, compromise, bargaining,
1978) persuasion, coercion, and other forms of
Strauss further developed the interaction- interaction by which humans seek to achieve
ists’ imagery of a reciprocal relationship their interests and legitimate their perspec-
between structure and action in his much tives. Strauss wrote that the negotiated order
COALFACE INSTITUTIONALISM 501

of an organization, such as a hospital or firm, kinds of training to professionals; changing their


was ‘the sum total of the organization’s rules attitudes toward professional partners, toward
their own work and toward themselves; altering
and policies, along with whatever agree-
their ideologies; opening up new types of careers;
ments, understandings, pacts, contracts, and and so on. Negotiated agreements and actions
other working arrangements currently were very much a part of that consequential fer-
[obtain]. These include agreements at every ment. Said another way, the negotiations were
level of organization, of every clique and integral to the subsequent changes in the state of
the mental health professions and their associated
coalition, and include covert as well as overt
institutions. (Strauss, 1978a: 122)
agreements’ (1978a: 6). An important corol-
lary is that negotiated orders are temporally In fact, in some cases, top-down and grass-
bound. Over time every negotiated order is roots forms of action may work in concert.
‘reviewed, reevaluated, revised, revoked or Strauss proposed a three-level ‘paradigm’
renewed’ (1978a: 5). Strauss noted, however, (or model) for studying negotiated order
that because structural conditions influence (Strauss 1978a: 98–99). The paradigm’s pur-
who can negotiate with whom, when, and pose was to ensure that researchers would
about what, negotiated orders ought not be not forget to tie situated action to macro-
viewed as products of unconstrained agency social contexts. At the lowest level – the level
(1978a: 5). The arrival of new participants, a of ongoing action – were negotiations whose
shift in a law, or the development of attributes might vary systematically by the
new technologies could exogenously trigger type of actors involved, by their strategies
revisions of a current order. and tactics, and by other characteristics of
Strauss argued that negotiated orders not people’s actions and interactions.
only have scope or range, they are also usu- Negotiations might yield many types of out-
ally nested in the sense that concentric circles comes including organizations, conventions,
are nested. The negotiated order of an practices, rules, understandings or working
accounting firm, for example, operates agreements. Second, Strauss claimed that all
within the negotiated order of accounting as negotiations occurred within a negotiation
a profession. The former cannot ignore the context, a set of local conditions that shaped
latter and still remain an accounting firm in the actions and interactions that comprised
good standing. Some aspects of a negotiated the negotiations. For Strauss, the analytically
order are, therefore, likely to be local, while relevant aspects of negotiation contexts
others have wider scope. Those with the included the number of actors involved,
widest scope may be created from the top whom they represented, their relative balance
down by people with either the authority to of power, whether negotiations occurred
direct others or a mandate to act on their once or were ongoing, whether sessions
behalf, as would be the case, respectively, occurred sequentially or simultaneously on
with the imposition of a regal decree or an multiple fronts, whether the negotiations
agreement forged through collective bargain- were visible or hidden, the number and com-
ing. Alternately, negotiated orders with a plexity of the issues involved, and the legiti-
wide scope may bubble up from below, as macy of those issues (Strauss 1978a: 100).
Strauss described for institutions of mental Finally, Strauss claimed that negotiation
health: contexts were, in turn, situated within a
In what sense can it be said that [the negotiations structural context, a system of more encom-
he observed in the hospital he studied] … had a passing institutions. The larger institutions
determinable impact on the larger social setting that were relevant for a set of negotiations
[national or professional]? Obviously, no single would vary considerably across negotiation
negotiation or even one hospital had much
impact. Yet the many such ‘experiments’ taking
contexts. For instance, the institutions
place simultaneously or over a very few years must that constrain the negotiations of a corporate
have had considerable impact – in giving new executive would differ from those that
502 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

constrain how and for what high school prin- In sum, taken as a whole, it is fair to say
cipals negotiate. On this point Strauss that negotiated order theory is more accessi-
(1978a: 98) wrote, ‘The structural context for ble, but less well-developed, than structura-
covert negotiations engaged in by a corrupt tion theory. Compared to Giddens’
judge includes features of the American judi- encyclopedic coverage of sociological
ciary system and of marketplaces, while the thought, Strauss’s work on negotiations was
structural context of the negotiations that far less sweeping, but his language was
occur in a mental hospital includes the prop- decidedly less obscure.17 Yet, negotiated
erties of American medical care, the subspe- order theory trumps structuration theory in at
cialty of psychiatry, specialization among the least one important regard: it emphasizes the
caring professions, and the division of labor importance of observing situated behaviors
in mental hospitals.’ in specific social and temporal contexts to
Curiously, Giddens and others have determine how institutions shape actions and
depicted structuration using three-layered how actions, in turn, form, sustain and
models analogous to Strauss’s paradigm of change institutions. Thus, unlike structura-
negotiated order (see Giddens 1984: 12; tion theory, negotiated order theory tells
Barley 1986: 82; Barley and Tolbert researchers what to look for. The notion of a
1997: 97; Yates and Orlikowski 1992: 307). social world suggests where to look.
Negotiations, that occur in the here and now,
belong to what Giddens’ (1984: 11), Barley
and Tobert (1997: 97) and Orlikowski
(2000: 410) respectively called ‘systems of SOCIAL WORLDS: ARENAS,
interaction,’ ‘the realm of action,’ and the NETWORKS, MATRICES, WEBS
realm of ‘ongoing situated human action.’ AND FIELDS
Strauss’s notion of a structural context paral-
lels what Giddens (1984: 31) called the Although Chicagoans had used the term
‘structure of the institutional order’ or what ‘social world’ for decades, aside from
Barley and Tolbert (1997) called the ‘realm Shibutani (1955, 1962) few did so analyti-
of institutions.’ Negotiation contexts mediate cally before Strauss (1978b, 1982, 1984) and
between negotiations and structural contexts, Becker (1978, 1982). In his first paper on
as do scripts in Barley’s (1986) model of social worlds, Strauss (1978b: 119–121)
structuring or modalities in Giddens’ model wrote: ‘Since the early days of Chicago-style
of structuration (1984: 29). In fact, Barley interactionism, the term “social worlds” has
argued that scripts were exteriorized social been used sporadically, sometime descrip-
forms that comprise part of the negotiation tively, rarely conceptually … We have not
context. Finally, in Strauss’s paradigm, as in developed a general view of social worlds as
all structuration models, influence moves up a widespread, significant phenomenon, nor
and down levels. As Maines put it in his have we developed a program for studying
exegesis of negotiated order theory: them systematically.’ By developing the con-
cept more systematically, Strauss hoped to
Strauss emphasizes that the lines of influence push interactionists to acknowledge that
can go both ways, in which the consequences of
negotiations can be measured (eventually) in structural phenomena were as important as
changes in structural contexts, and in which struc- interpretive phenomena in shaping the insti-
tural contexts condition how people will act …. tutional order.18 ‘Though the idea of social
Negotiation contexts are created insofar as certain worlds may refer centrally to universes of
elements of [the structural context] are incorpo- discourse,’ he cautioned his fellow
rated into or become relevant to negotiations, but
negotiations may work their way back through interactionists, ‘we should be careful not to
negotiation contexts ‘up’ to structural contexts. confine ourselves to looking merely at forms
(1982: 270) of communication, symbolization … but also
COALFACE INSTITUTIONALISM 503

examine palpable matters like activities, contractors (Barley and Kunda 2004), or the
memberships, sites, technologies and orga- playing of games like Dungeons and
nizations typical of social worlds.’ Dragons and Little League Baseball (Fine
(1978b: 121). In subsequent papers, Strauss 1983, 1987).
(1982, 1984) elaborated: Second, Strauss emphasized that social
Social worlds refer to a set of common or joint
worlds cleave around sites (places where
activities or concerns, bound together by a net- activities routinely occur and where key
work of communication …. One can point to such actors are found), technologies (tools, tech-
social worlds as those of opera, ballet, baseball, niques and procedures for carrying out key
surfing, art, stamp collecting, mountain climbing, activities) and most importantly, divisions of
homosexuality, and medicine, although the con-
cept also is probably useful in conceptualizing and
labor.19 For example, the thespian world
studying industries and the sciences. These social requires theaters where plays can be per-
worlds vary considerably in size, types, number formed and audiences can be seated, work-
and varieties of central activities, organizational shops for making props, dressing rooms for
complexity, technological sophistication, ideologi- actors to prepare their bodies, box offices for
cal elaboration, geographical dispersion, and so on
… One of the most important features of social selling tickets, print shops for printing pro-
worlds is their inevitable differentiation into sub- grams, and so on. The thespian world also
worlds … The conceptual imagery here is of must have lighting, sound systems, curtains,
groups emerging within social worlds, evolving, wrenches and pulleys, printing presses, car-
developing, splintering, disintegrating or pulling penter’s tools, etc. Most importantly, to pull
themselves together, or parts falling away and per-
haps coalescing with segments of other groups to off plays there must be actors, directors,
form new groups, often in opposition to older producers, stage hands, lighting engineers,
ones – in short, of subworlds intersecting, in pow- printers, patrons, advertisers, janitors, ticket
erful contact with other subworlds both within the agents, critics, electricians, manufacturers of
parent social world and with those ‘inside’ other cosmetics, costume designers, and seam-
social worlds (1982: 172).
stresses among others.
To begin unpacking this fluid notion of These structural features (sites, technolo-
social worlds, notice first that Strauss (as gies and divisions of labor) are usually the
well as Becker 1978) used the plural rather nuclei around which ‘subworlds’ form.
than the singular form of the noun. Plurality Subworlds control and are responsible for
is crucial. Rather than see social worlds as providing materials and services that are cru-
distinct units, interactionists viewed social cial for accomplishing the world’s overarch-
worlds as fuzzy sets composed of elements, ing activity. Because of differentiation,
which Strauss called subworlds. Subworlds representatives of subworlds are linked via
are themselves social worlds that are con- webs of patterned interaction, communica-
nected though their joint involvement in a tion and transaction that allow them to pull
primary activity. It is this joint involvement off the world’s primary activity. The exis-
that warrants speaking of the elements as a tence of social worlds, therefore, implies the
set. Illustrative activities that serve as the existence of social networks, which are use-
basis for social worlds include the production fully understood as a social world’s essential
of a form of art, such as a painting or play structure. However, social worlds cannot be
(Becker 1978, 1982), the manufacturing of reduced to networks. Doing so would focus
computers (Kling and Gerson 1978a, 1978b; attention tightly on structures and flows to
Kling and Sacchi 1982), the production of the exclusion of culture and action.
books (Coser, Kadushin, and Powell 1982; Accordingly, and third, Strauss held that
Powell 1985), the making of musical scores interpretive and political phenomena are
(Faulkner 1987), the manufacturing of wafer integral to the organization of social worlds.
fabrication equipment (Bechky 2003a, Ideologies, perspectives, theories, agendas,
2003b), the hiring and placing of technical points of view, interests, and languages
504 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

differentiate the participants who are bound Strauss claimed that segmentation and inter-
together by networks and their joint contribu- section were central processes of the
tion to a central activity. Interpretive differ- structuring in social worlds. The former is
ences – which are rooted in the social world’s equivalent to the organizational theorist’s
division of labor – engender conflicts, ten- notion of differentiation; the latter fuses
sions, alliances, movements, and disputes. the organizational theorist’s concept of
Thus, the interplay between networks and integration with the idea of overlapping
notions is central to any analysis of social jurisdictions. Ultimately the imagery of
worlds. The idea that social worlds have segmentation and intersection invokes a
interpretive and political as well as structural shifting institutional landscape. Examined
topographies is what links the analysis of over time, analysts should see social worlds
negotiated order to the study of social and subworlds form around new technolo-
worlds. As Strauss et al. (1964) showed for gies or ideas, split, fuse, challenge each
psychiatric hospitals, differences in perspec- other’s bids for expertise, forge alliances,
tives and interests motivate negotiations that and so on.
configure and reconfigure institutions. Writing before the spread of microcomput-
Political and interpretive phenomena are ers, Kling and Gerson (1978a) claimed that
essential for understanding the dynamics of the world of computing cleaved along four
social worlds because they manufacture and axes. The first axis was type of computing:
sustain the legitimacy of a social world’s specifically, scientific, commercial, indus-
institutions and practices: trial, and academic computing. The second
One can initially imagine something of the nature axis was the kind of technology or equipment
of legitimation problems which arise in that kind of used. The third was type of application: for
social matrix. Questions of ‘authenticity’ of per- example, financial, medical or government
formance and product, of genuineness and purity, applications. Interestingly, the fourth dimen-
real and fake, but questions also of propriety and
sion was where actors positioned themselves
impropriety, even morality and immorality, and
legality and illegality arise in kaleidoscopic, rapid relative to IBM. Since the 1970s, the land-
and intricate fashion – not merely in areas like ‘the scape of the world of computing has changed.
arts’ with their perennial legitimacy arguments and Personal computers have replaced main-
dilemmas, but in presumably less problematic, frames and minicomputers in most, but not
seemingly less ideologically-ridden areas like med-
all, computing subworlds. COBOL and
icine, the sciences, industry and business. Imagery
for what occurs in these rapidly changing social FORTRAN have died, and other languages
worlds and subworlds should be the very opposite have taken their place. New areas of appli-
of what is called up by the term ‘stable’ society … cation have arisen, including gaming and
legitimacy in these worlds pertains to issues like animation. Applications that were once
what, how, when, where, and who can legiti-
separated are now integrated: for instance,
mately or properly do certain things, with certain
means and materials, at appropriate places and financial and human resources databases
times, and in certain acceptable ways … under- (by SAP, Oracle, etc.) or word processing and
standing of the legitimation process associated presentation software (Microsoft(R) Office).
with social worlds will require a close look at the Perhaps most telling, positioning relative to
arenas in which such issues are fought out. IBM is arguably far less important today than
(Strauss, 1982: 172–73)
positioning relative to Microsoft.
Struggles for legitimacy in social worlds Finally, for Strauss and other interaction-
were, for Strauss, the engine of action and a ists, social worlds constituted a unique unit
source of intrigue. In other words, legitimacy of analysis. Accomplishing a primary acti-
was always the product of negotiations. vity usually involves actors from a variety of
Fourth, Strauss emphasized that social industries, social sectors, subcultures, occu-
worlds are always in process; the only ques- pations, firms, interest groups, organizations,
tion is the rate at which the process unfolds. and so on. Social worlds, therefore, enroll
COALFACE INSTITUTIONALISM 505

participants who cut across the units of variety of collectives (occupations, associa-
analysis that have traditionally preoccupied tions, subcultures, organizations, etc.), while
organizational theorists and other social sci- the institutionalists, being organizational the-
entists. For this reason, researchers who set orists, have written as if fields comprise pri-
their sights solely on organizations, indus- marily organizations. While accurate, this
tries or occupations, are unlikely to find difference is less important than it might first
social worlds. Seeing social worlds requires appear to be. Although Strauss was not an
greater focal length. organizational theorist and was apparently as
By now it should be clear that the interac- unaware of what the neo-institutionalists
tionists’ notion of social worlds bears an were doing as they were of him, he would
uncanny resemblance to what institutional- have applauded their agenda. In his first
ists have called organizational fields. Indeed, paper on social worlds, Strauss explicitly
it is not unreasonable to argue that the inter- noted that research on social worlds of
actionists and institutionalists arrived at organizations was sorely lacking:
roughly the same analytic destination at more
Organizations are commonly viewed as relatively
or less the same time unbeknownst to each closed in their boundaries, and there are few good
other. Consider, for example, DiMaggio and analyses of interorganizational relations. The social
Powell’s (1983) definition of an organization world perspective tells us that some organizations
field in light of the foregoing discussion: are relatively embedded within a social world,
while others stand at intersections, indeed may
By organizational field, we mean those organiza- have been intentionally constructed that way. The
tions that, in the aggregate, constitute a recog- understanding of organizational evolution,
nized area of institutional life: key suppliers, change, and functions requires an examination of
resource and product consumers, regulatory agen- relations embedded in the same or intersecting
cies, and other organizations that produce similar worlds … Organizational theory which ignores
services or products. The virtue of this unit of these considerations is likely to sell us very short.
analysis is that it directs our attention not simply to (Strauss 1978b: 125)
competing firms … or to networks of organiza-
tions that actually interact … but to the totality of Second, the notion of a social world draws
relevant actors. In doing this, the field idea com- attention to interpretive phenomena that join
prehends the importance of both connectedness as well as delineate and divide actors
and structural equivalence. The structure of an involved in the pursuit of a primary activity.
organizational field cannot be determined a priori
but must be defined on the basis of empirical
In contrast, field has a stronger overtone of
investigation. (1983: 148) structure, especially that of network struc-
ture. Accordingly, students of social worlds
DiMaggio and Powell tell us that an orga- are more likely to view legitimation as a
nizational field ‘constitute[s] a recognized problem of constructing, contesting and
area of institutional life,’ which echoes defending interpretations rather than a
Strauss’s notion of a ‘primary activity.’ Also problem of acquiring status or standing in the
like Strauss, DiMaggio and Powell note that eyes of others. Students of social worlds,
fields have divisions of labor that bind a therefore, have paid more attention to
field’s actors into a network of relations. struggles for legitimacy than have institution-
Finally, DiMaggio and Powell portray field alists, who more commonly study sources of
as a unique unit of analysis in precisely the legitimacy.
same sense that Strauss saw a social world as Finally, in social world analysis the vari-
a crosscutting unit. ous strands of an institutional order – rheto-
Nevertheless, there seem to be three ric, political action, organizations, laws,
important differences between the con- ideologies, and so on – implicate each other.
cepts of social world and organizational Thus, rather than treat institutions as well-
field. First, Strauss and other interactionists bounded practices, interactionists typically
portrayed social worlds as populated by a speak of institutions as forming the ‘web,’
506 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

‘matrix’, or ‘fabric’ of a social world. These Strauss (1982) argued that actors use five
differences point to two topics about which strategies for building for what Hughes
interactionists still have much to offer institu- (1962/1971: 287–292) would have called a
tionalists: the social construction of mandate and license: (1) discovering, claim-
legitimacy, especially in the course of ongo- ing and promoting the worth of their agenda,
ing action, and the study of institutional belief or stance, (2) developing theories that
complexes. bolster their interests or perspectives with a
veneer of rational, moral and even scientific
respectability, (3) distancing themselves
from rivals and alternate ideas, (4) setting
WHAT INSTITUTIONALISTS CAN standards of practice or belief that can be
LEARN FROM INTERACTIONISTS employed in evaluative accounts, and
(5) establishing the boundaries of their juris-
diction. As actors struggle over legitimacy,
Doing legitimacy
they employ a wide range of resources rang-
No concept is more central to institutional ing from court rulings, prophecies, scientific
theory than legitimacy. Yet, as Suchman theories, and high status allies to books, edi-
(1995: 571) noted, ‘Despite its centrality … torials, films, and even the occasional payoff.
the literature on organizational legitimacy Institutionalists have spent much of the
provides surprisingly fragile conceptual last decade rediscovering the role that inter-
moorings. Many researchers employ the pretations and negotiations play in the social
term … but few define it.’20 Furthermore, construction of legitimacy. Some have drawn
even though institutionalists continually inspiration from contemporary social move-
remind us that legitimation is a process, until ment theory, which emphasizes the impor-
recently they have written more about tance of competing frames or ways of
sources of legitimacy, about whom or what making sense out of situations, conditions,
bestows it, than about how it is bestowed. and events (Rao 1998; Creed, Scully, and
Sources of legitimacy commonly mentioned Austin 2002; Rao, Monin, and Durand 2003).
in the literature include public opinion, the Others have turned to rhetorical, narrative,
educational system, laws, courts, and, of late, and discourse analysis (Hoffman 1999;
higher-status others. Edelman, Fuller, and Mara-Drita 2001;
Although, the Chicagoans understood well Greenwood, Suddaby, and Hinings 2002;
that socialization, reputation, power, position Suddaby and Greenwood 2005; Lawrence
and authority meant that some actors had and Philips 2004; Munir and Phillips 2005;
greater (and perhaps final) say over what is Greenwood and Suddaby 2006; Colyvas
legitimate, they trained their eyes less on and Powell 2006). Regardless of their
sources and more on struggles for legitimacy. starting point, however, all have explored
Histories of how a modus operandi, a law, a how individuals, occupations, organizations,
practice, or even an organizational form or coalitions deploy language, symbols,
acquired legitimacy are ultimately tales of assumptions, theories, or frames to develop
how people deploy ideas, ideologies, frames, and promote their agendas or views of the
and arguments in negotiations, persuasions, world. In these papers, interests, politics, and
and political contests that unfold over time, contestation are always front and center,
often across multiple places and arenas. From regardless of whether the institution under
this perspective meaning and action are both construction be a new organizational form
crucial for constructing legitimacy. Legitimacy (Lawrence and Philips 2004; Suddaby
hinges not only on the substance of ideas and and Greenwood 2005; Greenwood and
claims, but also on where, when, how, and Suddaby 2006), a redefinition of an institu-
why people wield ideas and lodge claims. tion’s mission and boundaries (Colyvas and
COALFACE INSTITUTIONALISM 507

Powell 2006), the passage of a law (Creed technicians (EMT’s) vied over who should
et al. 2002), the reinterpretation of a law deliver emergency medical services in local
(Edelman et al. 2001), the emergence of an communities.
occupation (Lounsbury and Kaghan 2001), By 1970, volunteer rescue squads pro-
or the promotion of a set practices that define vided emergency transportation in most
the role of a product in everyday life (Munir American communities. Towns and cities
and Phillips 2005). across the country had formed volunteer
Nevertheless, despite the common empha- squads during the 1950s and 1960s in
sis on interpretation, the new institutional response to a social movement and subse-
scholarship on legitimation differs from the quent legislation designed to reduce highway
interactionists’ work in important ways. fatalities. Growing pressure to medicalize
First, the institutionalists almost always emergency services culminated, in 1973,
employ textual rather than observational with the Emergency Medical Services Act,
data. Second, because the texts are drawn which required that all responders have
from archives, they afford longitudinal formal training in emergency medicine.
analysis. Consequently, recent interpretive Although the Act took no stance on whether
scholarship on institutions covers longer volunteers or ‘professionals’ should deliver
periods of time than even the most dedicated such services, by the 1990s private firms
fieldworker could hope to cover. Taking the employing professional, fulltime EMTs had
long view allows institutionalists the neces- begun to compete with volunteer squads.
sary resolve for identifying what Hughes Jurisdictional dramas over the proper deliv-
might have called the stages and turning ery of emergency medicine were being
points in an institution’s career. In fact, for played out on a daily basis on the streets of
institutions with broad range, analysis of villages, towns, and cities. Although advo-
texts may be the only way to study the pro- cates of voluntary and professional services
tracted twists and turns of legitimation over recorded their perspectives in documents
the long duré. amenable to textual analysis, no documents
Yet, precisely because textual analysis recorded the type of behavior that Nelsen
opens up the panorama of history, it has dif- observed while riding with paid and
ficulty focusing on how struggles for legiti- voluntary squads in two upstate New York
macy played themselves out in daily life. To communities.
be sure, texts offer clues to how people inter- Nelsen and Barley (1997) recount, among
preted a phenomenon at some point in time, other tactics, how paid EMTs pushed volun-
and they can point to the perspectives of dif- teers aside on arriving at the scene of an acci-
ferent factions. Texts often have relatively dent, how they belittled volunteers’ skills
little to say, however, about how people before patients, doctors, and nurses, and how
arrived at those interpretations or what the they rewrote paperwork to expunge evidence
members of various factions did to each that volunteers had ever been involved in
other. Furthermore, texts are almost always responding to an accident. In these and other
silent on what led to the creation of the doc- ways, paid EMTs actively fostered the per-
ument in the first place. To answer questions ception that they were more competent than
about legitimation in action, one must exam- volunteers and that they were more deserving
ine behavior in situ and in real time. This is of a mandate to provide emergency medical
where the Chicagoans excelled. For an services to the community. Without behav-
appreciation of how interactionist studies ioral data, researchers examining the juris-
could enrich our understanding of the situ- dictional dispute would have difficulty
ated dynamics of legitimation, consider discovering that the battle to legitimate
Nelsen and Barley’s (1997) account of professional emergency medical service
how paid and volunteer emergency medical (EMS) was waged with more than ideology
508 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

and rhetoric. Worse, because hospital records become an ontological assumption, organiza-
often did not mention the volunteers who had tion studies would be left with a thin view of
been on the scene, researchers might con- institutional reality.
clude that no volunteers had been active. Chicago sociologists took a thicker view.
In short, grounded studies of action and They typically portrayed institutions as com-
interaction are crucial for developing ade- plexes of related practices, conventions and
quate accounts of the social construction of understandings. Social worlds are always
legitimacy, if for no other reason than that more than the sum of distinct institutions.
they inoculate us against assuming that Consider, for example, what makes a school.
struggles for legitimacy are largely battles of Surely a school needs teachers and students,
rhetoric. As institutional analysis takes its yet teachers and students are found in other
interpretive turn, it is well worth remem- settings, including the boot camps run by the
bering that writing, reading and rhetoric are U.S. Army and Al Qaeda. Tests and books
important for negotiating legitimacy, but are also necessary for schools as we know
words break no bones. them. Yet, libraries have books and employ-
ment offices give tests, neither of which we
would confuse as a school. Even teachers,
students, books and tests are not sufficient
Institutional complexes
for making a school; one needs a host of
An inventory of neo-institutional organiza- other actors, laws, practices, and so on. All
tional studies will reveal that researchers institutional orders are similarly complex in
have often treated institutions as well- this regard.21
bounded entities and their construction as a To acknowledge precisely this sort of mul-
matter of diffusion. For instance, institution- tiplexity, interactionists routinely described
alists have studied the spread of formal social worlds as ‘webs,’ ‘matrices,’ or ‘clus-
evaluation and performance systems in ters’ of institutions (Kling and Sacchi 1982;
municipal governments (Tolbert and Strauss 1978: 172; Hughes 1962/1971: 52).
Zucker 1983), personnel offices (Dobbin and The image of a ‘web’ or a ‘matrix’ draws
Sutton 1998), maternal leave policies (Kelley attention to two key aspects of social worlds
and Dobbin 1999) and poison pills (Davis or organizational fields. First, institutions
1991). Even the interpretive studies of legiti- cluster in the sense that what distinguishes
macy discussed above treat institutions as one social world from another is an inte-
discrete phenomena. For instance, Suddaby grated and unique set of institutionalized
and Greenwood (2005) focused on the rise forms, practices, and conventions. The idea
of multidisciplinary accounting firms. is analogous to cliquing in social network
Lounsbury and Kaghan (2001) examined the analysis: members of a social world share
spread of recycling programs across universi- more institutions with fellow members than
ties. Lawrence and Philips (2004) explored they do with members of other worlds.
how a particular set of whale watching prac- In other words, the density of shared institu-
tices emerged in Victoria, Canada. Studying tions should be higher within than across
well-specified forms and practices makes social worlds. Second, institutions form webs
pragmatic, epistemological sense: A clear (or they cluster) in the sense that one institu-
focus on an identifiable phenomenon allows tion is likely to implicate others. Analysts
researchers to target specific institutional should, therefore, beware of treating institu-
processes. Focusing on discrete phenomena tions as discrete phenomena for any purpose
also makes for a more manageable story, other than analytic convenience. In reality, a
especially within the constrained space of a change in one institutional parameter is
journal article. However, should the image of likely to occasion, and perhaps even require,
institutions as well-bounded phenomena change in others.
COALFACE INSTITUTIONALISM 509

Interactionists routinely pointed to the escalated during the 1980s when Microsoft
complexity of institutional connectedness. and other firms realized that they could sig-
For instance, in an important paper that tied nificantly reduce employment costs by firing
occupational commitment to an occupation’s employees and hiring them back as inde-
institutional order, Geer (1968) noted that pendent contractors. Because the practice
teachers lacked the kind of occupational spread quickly, the Internal Revenue Service
commitment evinced by doctors, scientists (IRS) soon entered the picture and brought
and lawyers. Geer argued the institutions of suit against Microsoft for tax evasion.
teaching were responsible. Unlike a func- Although the suit did not slow the use of con-
tionalist, who might urge teachers to pursue tractors, it did reshape the way contractors
the traits of a profession (Etzioni 1969), or a were employed. On the advice of corporate
Marxist, who might advocate the politics of lawyers, firms began to acquire contractors
monopoly (Larson 1979), Geer recognized through staffing agencies rather than cut
that changing the commitment of teachers deals directly with individuals. Agencies pro-
would require altering the larger web of insti- tected the firms from the IRS, because they
tutions in which teaching was suspended: served as the contractor’s employer of
Several of the mechanisms of commitment in
record. As a result, foundings of staffing
other occupations which we have discussed sug- agencies devoted to high tech contracting
gest changes that might be brought about in the burgeoned in the 1990s. At this point, we
teaching profession if lifelong commitment on the have an institutional story of the construction
part of more teachers is desired. But, as we have and diffusion of two institutions, a type of
seen, commitment is a process so closely fitted to
occupational structure that changes in it would
employment (contracting) and an organiza-
necessarily involve structural change in teaching as tional form (the high tech staffing agency),
a profession, which would, in turn, affect the each of which, in turn, reflects a larger insti-
organization of the school system in ways that tutional development, the rise of finance
might prove disruptive to other desirable goals. capitalism.22 There are, however, more
(Geer 1968: 233)
strands to the institutional web that envelops
In other words, to change teachers’ com- and defines the social world of contracting.
mitment to the occupation would require To reinforce the perception that contrac-
changing institutionalized relationships tors were not employees, employers began to
between schools, communities, families, institute an array of practices for differentiat-
local governments, and school boards. ing contractors from permanent employees.
Because the Chicagoans were primarily These practices spread through mimesis and
ethnographers, their thick descriptions though the intervention of consultants,
tended to capture the web of institutions that accountants, and lawyers who advised firms
enveloped the social worlds they studied. But on how to protect themselves from the IRS.
the Chicagoans did not usually call attention As a result firms began to force contractors to
to how these various institutions were con- wear distinct badges, to assign them to less
nected. Consequently, tracing the web of desirable space than employees enjoyed, to
institutions that is laced throughout out a prohibit contractors from attending meetings
Chicago-style ethnography usually requires in which topics unrelated to their project
readers to do their own analysis. were discussed, to prohibit contractors from
Nevertheless, in most ethnographies the attending company sponsored social func-
material for recovering the web lies near tions and so on. In short, a series of institu-
enough to hand. tionalized work practices spread throughout
Consider, for example, Barley and Kunda’s and across industries that hired contractors.
(2004) recent ethnography of the con- As more and more contractors were forced
tract labor market for skilled technical profes- to go through staffing agencies, contractors
sionals. Contracting in high technology also devised practices that spread by word of
510 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

mouth and that were promoted by maga- perspective forged at the University of
zines, books, and websites designed to help Chicago by Everett C. Hughes, Anselm
contractors better manage their careers. For Strauss, and their students, is potentially more
example, contractors discovered that to min- compatible with the institutionalists’ agenda.
imize downtime (time between contracts) The Chicagoans were themselves institution-
and to maximize earnings, they usually alists, and unlike most ethnomethodologists
needed to change agencies to acquire their and constructionists, they were concerned
next contract. To dissuade contractors from with institutions at the same levels of analysis
switching, agencies began to offer health that have intrigued the neo-institutionalists.
care and 401k’s.23 But, because most agen- In fact, as I have attempted to show, using a
cies also hesitated to find contractors new different language, the Chicagoans antici-
jobs before the current contract ended, few pated and developed many of the stances and
contractors remained with an agency long perspectives that neo-institutionalists have had
enough to secure health care or pension to reinvent as they struggled to incorporate
funds. Thus, large numbers of contractors social action into their analyses. My agenda in
saved little or nothing for retirement and revisiting the Chicago School has been to
relied on their fully employed spouse for point to how interactionism might help neo-
heath insurance. institutionalists resolve important puzzles
As in the case of contracting, institutional- concerning action, legitimation and the
ization – whether defined as the construction social construction of institutional fields.
of meaning or the acceptance and diffusion The Chicagoans held that sociology’s job
of practices – yields a web of conventions, is to study social organization in action,
procedures, laws, and organizations that which they conceived of as the link between
jointly shape an arena of social life into a institutions and the person. Institutions and
social world or organizational field. The actors meet in the throws of everyday life. In
emergence of webs of institutions and the this sense, as the British might say, everyday
interplay between a web’s various strands life is institutional theory’s coalface; it is
remains a fertile and largely unexplored where the rubber of theory hits the road of
opportunity for research that could enrich reality. For over 30 years, the coalface has
institutional theory. Although interactionism lain largely idle while institutionalists have
points institutionalism in this direction, no sought their fortunes in the cities of macro-
interactionist has yet explicitly attempted to social theory. As a result, there is plenty of
develop concepts for analyzing webs of insti- coal left to mine. What we need are more
tutions. A particularly fruitful line of inquiry miners.
would be to examine the various reasons for
why one institution tends to beget, alter,
amplify, or specify other institutions.
NOTES

1 Since this chapter focuses entirely on neo-insti-


CONCLUSION tutionalism in organizational theory, I often drop the
prefix, ‘neo,’ to make the text less clumsy.
2 As phenomenologists, Berger and Luckmann
I began this chapter by arguing that neo-insti- had top pedigrees. Both studied at the New
tutionalism is unique in organization studies, School of Social Research under the tutelage
because it represents the only macro-sociol- of Alfred Schultz, who was mentored by (but
not formally a student of) Edmund Husserl
ogy of organizations rooted in micro-social
(www.soci.canterbury.ac.nz/resources/biograph/schul
concepts. Although the early institutionalists tz.shtml). Garfinkel (1967: 36) also drew heavily on
turned to ethnomethodology and construc- Schultz’s thought, but was not a phenomenologist by
tionism for their micro-social grounding, the training or intent. Garfinkel was a student of Talcott
COALFACE INSTITUTIONALISM 511

Parsons at Harvard. He rejected Parsons’ structural- 8 Furthermore, as Becker (1999: 7) revealed,


functionalism, claiming, among other things, that ‘Hughes and Blumer … had very low opinions of one
internalized social norms and values could not be another. Blumer thought Hughes had a second-rate
responsible for social structure. Garfinkel and other mind, and Hughes was openly contemptuous of
ethnomethodologists vigorously rejected logical pos- Blumer’s inability or unwillingness to do research.’
itivism, yet remained decidedly realist in their hard- 9 Blumer, however, did have this agenda (see
nosed empiricism. Athens 2005).
3 In contrast, ethnomethodologists have had 10 Although the work of Hughes and his stu-
much to say about work and work practices dents is often categorized as ‘symbolic interaction-
(Emerson 1970; Suchman 1987; Cicourel 1987, ism,’ I avoid that term because it is more properly
1990; Lynch 1985; Garfinkel 1986; Button 1993; applied to Blumer’s (1962) work. In this chapter I will
Heath and Luff 1992, 1996). use ‘interactionist’ and ‘interactionism,’ since Hughes
4 This assumes, of course, that the early institu- and his students certainly did examine social relations
tionalists were actually interested in micro-social in everyday life.
dynamics. Aside from Zucker, this was probably not 11 See Rock (1979) and Lewis and Smith (1980)
the case. Hallett and Ventresca (2006: 215) have sug- for extended discussions of Simmel’s importance to
gested that Meyer and Rowan turned to micro-soci- the Chicagoans’ concept of social structure.
ology primarily for its vocabulary of motive: ‘Given 12 Although Strauss received his Ph.D at Chicago
the new institutionalist focus on macro environ- in 1945, Strauss did not align himself with Hughes
ments,’ they wrote, ‘We can turn Meyer and Rowan’s until after he joined the faculty in 1952 (Strauss,
legacy on its head to say that organizational sociol- 1968: 265).
ogy has been “decoupled” from its foundations 13 The term entrepreneur also raises ontological
in social interaction: Passing references to micro- problems. Entrepreneurs are people who usually
sociology are a form of “myth and ceremony” that have some idea of what they are doing. As speakers
create academic “legitimacy” ’. of English commonly use the term, it is difficult to
5 Chicago School sociology covers at least two imagine how an entrepreneur could accidentally
generations of scholars. The first included Robert found a business. Yet, as Berger and Luckmann make
Park, Ernest Burgess, Albion Small, and W. I. Thomas, clear, institutions sometimes (maybe, most of the
who were most active in the first three decades of the time) emerge with anyone intending them.
20th century. The second included Everett Hughes, 14 Although DiMaggio (1988) and DiMaggio and
Anselm Strauss and Herbert Blumer who wrote Powell (1983, 1991) also used the term structuration,
mostly from the 1930s through the 1960s. When I they did so primarily to speak of how people create
speak of the Chicago School in this chapter, unless institutions. Thus, their use of the term is closer to
otherwise noted, I am referring to the second group. Berger and Luckmann’s idea of sedimentation.
6 Ironically, Hughes and his colleagues paid more 15 Barley (1986) spoke of structuring rather than
attention to organizations than did the eth- structuration to emphasize agency. Gerunds have the
nomethodologists. Boys in White (Becker, Geer, utility of nouns while maintaining connotations of
Hughes, and Strauss 1961) and Psychiatric Ideologies action. Barley used the concept of scripts to track
and Institutions (Strauss et al. 1964) were ethnogra- structuring over time. Although scripts surely have a
phies of a medical school and a psychiatric hospital cognitive component, Barley emphasized the actions
respectively. Strauss conducted a famous set of stud- and interactions that instantiated scripts because the
ies on how nurses, doctors and patients construct latter could be observed. Besides, if people don’t do
and manage awareness of dying on cancer wards things because of their thoughts, thoughts cannot be
(Glazer and Strauss 1965). Dalton (1950) wrote real in their consequences, at least for people who
about everyday life among managers in a firm. Roy are not having the thought. With the exception of
studied union organizing (1964, 1965). Van Maanen Johnson, Smith and Coding. (2000) most commenta-
studied police organizations (1973, 1975). Fine tors assume Barley (1986; Barley and Tolbert 1997)
(1996) has written about restaurants and Kunda saw scripts as cognitive rather than behavioral phe-
(1992) about high tech firms. In fact, the hallmark nomena. Orlikowski and her colleagues (1992, 1996,
of these studies is the weaving together of work 2000; Orlikowski and Yates 1994) have pushed
and organization. By contrast, when ethnomethodol- behavioral studies of structuration further than any
ogists studied life in organizations their focus other scholar with their research on the structuring
was almost exclusively on how people do their of technology and technical practice.
work (Lynch 1985, Garfinkel 1986, Suchman 16 It is worth noting that when interactionists
1987). speak of accounts, interpretations, definitions of the
7 Athens, who was Blumer’s student at Berkeley, situation, and so on, they are surely referring to cog-
claims that Blumer mistook the higher rate of change nitions, but they almost always assume that these
of institutions in contemporary society for their cognitions are instantiated in behavior. Accounts
increasing irrelevance. occur in speech; speech is a behavior and, hence,
512 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

a way of doing something. Importantly, speech can was no one institutionalized practice, convention or
be heard and recorded by observers, but thoughts understanding that allowed Agnes to pass as female.
and cognitions can not. The interactionists were, Neither dress, nor stance, nor gait, nor even attitude
above all else, empiricists. was adequate for Agnes being seen as a woman.
17 Like most interactionists, Strauss shied away Rather Agnes had to display and was adept at dis-
from Latinate nouns and wrote in a discursive, collo- playing these and many other gendered traits and
quial style. Could this help explain why organiza- behaviors in a highly integrated fashion. In other
tional theorists have paid so little attention to the words, the institution of gender is a multifaceted
interactionists? How can sociologists be erudite, concept, no one strand of which is sufficient for
when they are so breezy to read? As Mark Knophler defining a person as male or female, however neces-
put it, ‘sociologists invent words that mean industrial sary that facet may be.
disease.’ 22 Finance capitalism matters because contract-
18 Ironically, sociologists from other traditions, ing is about turning the fixed cost of labor into a vari-
including many institutionalists, require precisely the able cost. Wall Street not only encourages firms to
opposite advice: interpretive phenomena are as maximize variable costs, but also rewards them for
important as structural phenomena. doing so. Shifting to contractors boosts a firm’s stock
19 One might argue that with the rise of life on price, at least temporarily, because contractors are
the screen (Turkle 1995) tangible sites for action are not included in the denominators of productivity
no longer necessary for social worlds to form. Be this ratios. Thus, shifting from employees to contractors
as it may, it is quite interesting to note that even vir- not only makes a firm appear more flexible but more
tual worlds like Second Life and Warcraft are marked productive than it is.
by virtual places, virtual divisions of labor and virtual 23 A 401k is a pension plan that allows individu-
technologies. In fact sometimes the divisions of labor als to shelter money from each paycheck for retire-
are real, as in the case of Warcraft where real people ment free of taxation until the individual has retired,
spend time creating virtual characters and accumu- begins to withdraw the funds and is presumably sub-
lating virtual money which they sell to real people for ject to a lower tax rate.
real dollars so the buyers can participate in a virtual
division of labor.
20 Suchman went on to define legitimacy as ‘a
generalized perception or assumption that the
actions of an entity are desirable, proper, or appropri- REFERENCES
ate within some socially constructed system of
norms, values, beliefs, and definitions … Legitimacy
is a perception or assumption in that it represents a Athens, Lonnie. 2005. ‘Mead’s lost conception
reaction of observers to the organization as they see of society.’ Symbolic Interaction, 28: 305–325.
it; thus, legitimacy is possessed objectively, yet cre- Barley, Stephen R. 1986. ‘Technology as an
ated subjectively. An organization may diverge dra- occasion for structuring: evidence from obser-
matically from societal norms yet retain legitimacy vations of CT scanners and the social order of
because the divergence goes unnoticed. Legitimacy radiology departments.’ Administrative
is socially constructed in that it reflects a congruence Science Quarterly, 31: 78–108.
between the behaviors of the legitimated entity and
Barley, Stephen R. 1989. ‘Careers, identities,
the shared (or assumedly shared) beliefs of some
social group; thus, legitimacy is dependent on a col-
and institutions: The legacy of the Chicago
lective audience, yet independent of particular School of sociology.’ Pp. 41–66 in Michael B.
observers. An organization may deviate from individ- Arthur, Douglas T. Hall, and Barbara S.
uals’ values yet retain legitimacy because the devia- Lawrence (eds.), Handbook of Career Theory.
tion draws no public disapproval. In short, when one New York: Cambridge University Press.
says that a certain pattern of behavior possesses Barley, Stephen R. and Gideon Kunda. 2004.
legitimacy, one asserts that some group of observers, Gurus, Hired Guns and Warm Bodies:
as a whole, accepts or supports what those observers Itinerant Experts in a Knowledge Economy.
perceive to be the behavioral pattern, as a whole, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
despite reservations that any single observer might
Barley, Stephen R. and Pamela S. Tolbert. 1997.
have about any single behavior, and despite reserva-
tions that any or all observers might have, were they
‘Institutionalization and structuration:
to observe more’ [1995: 574]. Studying the links between action and insti-
21 Garfinkel (1967) played off this complexity in tution.’ Organization Studies, 18: 93–117.
his analysis Agnes, a young transsexual soon to Basu, Onker N., Mark W. Dirsmith, and Parveen
undergo a sex change. As Garfinkel noted, there P. Gupta. 1999. ‘The coupling of the
COALFACE INSTITUTIONALISM 513

symbolic and the technical in an institutional- Bucher, Rue and Joan Stelling. 1977. Becoming
ized context: The negotiated order of Professional. Beverly Hills, CA: Sage
the GAO’s audit reporting process.’ American Publications.
Sociological Review, 64(4): 506–526. Bucher, Rue and Anselm L. Strauss. 1961.
Battilana, Julie. 2006. ‘Agency and institutions: ‘Professions in process.’ American Journal of
The enabling role of individuals’ social posi- Sociology, 66: 325–334.
tion.’ Organization, 13: 653–676. Button, Graham. 1993. Technology in Working
Bechky, Beth A. 2003a. ‘Object lessons: Order: Studies of Work, Interaction and
Workplace artifacts and occupational juris- Technology. London: Routledge.
diction.’ American Journal of Sociology, 109: Cicourel, Aaron V. 1967. The Social Organization
720–752. of Juvenile Justice. New York: Wiley.
Bechky, Beth A. 2003b. ‘Sharing meaning Cicourel, Aaron V. 1970. "The Acquisition of
across occupational communities.’ Social Structure: Toward a Developmental
Organization Science, 14: 312–330. Sociology of Language and Meaning."
Becker, Howard S. 1952. ‘The career of the Pp. 136–68 in Understanding Everyday Life:
Chicago public schoolteacher.’ American Toward the Reconstruction of Sociological
Journal of Sociology, 57: 470–477. Knowledge, Ed. Jack D. Douglas. Chicago:
Becker, Howard S. 1953. ‘Some contingencies Aldine.
of the professional dance musician’s career.’ Cicourel, Aaron V. 1972. "Basic and Normative
Human Organization, 12: 22–26. Rules in the Negotiation of Status and Role."
Becker, Howard S. 1963. Outsiders: Studies in Pp. 229–58 in Studies in Social Interaction,
the Sociology of Deviance. New York: Free Ed. David Sudnow. New York: Free Press.
Press. Cicourel, Aaron V. 1974. Cognitive Sociology:
Becker, Howard S. 1978. ‘Arts and crafts.’ Language and Meaning in Social Interaction.
American Journal of Sociology, 83: 862–889. New York: Free Press.
Becker, Howard S. 1982. Art Worlds. Berkeley: Cicourel, Aaron V. 1981. "The Role of
University of California Press. Cognitive-Linguistic Concepts in
Becker, Howard S. 1999. ‘The Chicago School, Understanding Everyday Social Interactions."
so-called.’ Qualitative Sociology, 22(1): 3–12. Annual Review of Sociology, 7: 87–106.
Becker, Howard S., Blanche Geer, Everett C. Cicourel, Aaron V. 1987. "The Interpenetration
Hughes, and Anselm L. Strauss. 1961. Boys in of Communicative Contexts: Examples From
White. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press. Medical Encounters." Social Psychology
Berger, Peter L. and Thomas Luckmann. 1967. Quarterly, 50: 217–226.
The Social Construction of Reality. New York: Cicourel, Aaron V. 1990. "The Integration of
Doubleday. Distributed Knowledge in Collaborative
Bittner, Egon. 1965. ‘The concept of organiza- Medical Diagnosis." Pp. 221–242 in
tion.’ Social Research, 32: 239–255. Intellectual Teamwork: Foundations of
Blumer, Herbert. 1962. ‘ Society as symbolic Cooperative Work, Eds. Jolene Galegher,
interaction.’ Pp. 179–193 in Arnold M. Rose Robert E. Kraut, and Carmen Egido.
(ed.), Human Behavior and Social Process: Hillsdale, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates.
An Interactionist Approach. Boston: Houghton Colyvas, Jeannette A. and Walter W. Powell.
Mifflin. 2006. ‘Roads to institutionalization: The
Braude, Lee. 1975. Work and Workers: A remaking of boundaries between public and
Sociological Analysis. New York: Praeger private science.’ Research in Organizational
Publishers. Behavior, 27: 305–353.
Bucher, Rue and Leonard Schatzman. 1962. Coser, Lewis A., Charles Kadushin, and Walter
‘The logic of the state mental hospital.’ W. Powell. 1982. Books: The Culture
Social Problems, 9(4): 337–349. and Commerce of Publishing. New York:
Bucher, Rue and Joan Stelling. 1969. Basic Books.
‘Characteristics of professional organiza- Creed, W. E. D., Maureen A. Scully, and John R.
tions.’ Journal of Health and Social Behavior, Austin. 2002. ‘Clothes make the person?
10(1): 3–15. The tailoring of legitimating accounts and
514 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

the social construction of identity.’ Fine, Gary A. 1983. Shared Fantasy: Role Playing
Organization Science, 13(5): 475–496. Games as Social Worlds. Chicago: University
Dalton, Melville. 1950. Men Who Manage. of Chicago Press.
New York: John Wiley and Sons. Fine, Gary A. 1987. With the Boys: Little League
Davis, Gerald. 1991. ‘Agents without princi- Baseball and Preadolescent Culture. Chicago:
ples: The spread of the poison pill through University of Chicago Press.
the intercorporate network.’ Administrative Fine, Gary A. 1991. ‘On the macrofoundations
Science Quarterly, 36: 583–613. of microsociology: Order, meaning and com-
DiMaggio, Paul J. 1988. ‘Interest and agency in parative context.’ The Sociological Quarterly,
institutional theory.’ Pp. 3–22 in Lynne G. 32(2): 161–177.
Zucker (ed.), Institutional Patterns and Fine, Gary A. 1996. Kitchens: The Culture of
Organizations: Culture and Environment. Restaurant Work. Berkeley, CA: University of
Cambridge, MA: Ballinger. California Press.
DiMaggio, Paul J. and Walter W. Powell. 1983. Fligstein, Neil. 1993. The Transformation of
‘The iron cage revisited: Institutional isomor- Corporate Control. Cambridge, MA: Harvard
phism and collective rationality in organiza- University Press.
tional fields.’ American Sociological Review, Fligstein, Neil. 2001. ‘Social skill and the
48: 147–160. theory of fields.’ Sociological Theory, 19(2):
DiMaggio, Paul J. and Walter W. Powell. 1991. 105–25.
‘Introduction.’ Pp. 1–40 in Walter W. Powell Garfinkel, Harold. 1967. Studies in Ethnome-
and Paul J. DiMaggio (eds.), The New thodology. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice
Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis. Hall.
Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Garfinkel, Harold. 1986. Ethnomethodological
Dobbin, Frank and Frank R. Sutton. 1998. ‘The Studies of Work. London: Routledge and
strength of a weak state: The rights revolu- Kegan Paul.
tion and the rise of human resources man- Geer, Blanche. 1968. ‘Occupational commit-
agement divisions.’ American Journal of ment and the teaching profession.’
Sociology, 104(2): 441–476. Pp. 221–34 in Howard S. Becker, Blanche
Dobbin, Frank, John R. Sutton, John W. Meyer, Geer, David Reisman, and Robert A. Weiss
and W. R. Scott. 1993. ‘Equal opportunity (eds.), Institutions and the Person. Chicago:
law and the construction of internal labor Aldine Publishing Company.
markets.’ American Journal of Sociology, 99: Giddens, Anthony. 1984. The Constitution of
265–316. Society. Berkeley, CA: University of California
Edelman, Lauren B., Sally R. Fuller, and Iona Press.
Mara-Drita. 2001. ‘Diversity rhetoric and the Glaser, Barney G. and Anselm L. Strauss. 1965.
mangerialization of law.’ American Journal Awareness of Dying. Chicago: Aldine.
of Sociology, 106(6): 1589–1641. Glaser, Barney G. and Anselm L. Strauss. 1967.
Emerson, Joan. 1970. ‘Nothing unusual is The Discovery of Grounded Theory: Strategies
happening.’ Pp. 208–22 in Tomatsu for Qualitative Research. Chicago: Aldine.
Shibutani (ed.), Human Nature and Glaser, Barney G. and Anselm L. Strauss. 1968.
Collective Behavior. New Brunswick, NJ: Time for Dying. Chicago: Aldine.
Transaction Books. Goffman, Erving. 1961. ‘The moral career of
Etzioni, Amitai. 1969. The Semi-Professions the mental patient.’ Pp. 125–170 in
and their Organization. New York: Free Press. Asylums. New York: Anchor.
Faulkner, Robert R. 1974. ‘Coming of age in Goffman, Erving. 1967. Interaction Ritual:
organizations: A comparative study of career Essays on Face-to-Face Behavior. Garden
contingencies and adult socialization.’ City, NY: Doubleday.
Sociology of Work and Occupations, 1: Goffman, Erving. 1981. Forms of Talk.
131–173. Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania.
Faulkner, Robert R. 1987. Music on Demand: Goffman, Erving. 1983. ‘The interaction
Composers and Careers in the Hollywood Film order.’ American Sociological Review,
Industry. New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Books. 48:1–17.
COALFACE INSTITUTIONALISM 515

Greenwood, Royston and Roy Suddaby. 2006. Hughes, Everett C. 1937. ‘Institutional office
‘Institutional entrepreneurship in mature and the person.’ American Journal of
fields: The Big Five accounting firms.’ Sociology, 43: 404–413.
Academy of Management Journal, 49(1): Hughes, Everett C. 1942. ‘The study of institu-
27–48. tions.’ Social Forces, 20(3): 307–310.
Greenwood, Royston, Roy Suddaby, and Hughes, Everett C. 1962/1971. ‘Going con-
C. R. Hinings. 2002. ‘Theorizing change: The cerns: The study of American institutions.’
role of professional associations in the trans- Pp. 52–64 in Everett C. Hughes (ed.), The
formation of institutionalized fields.’ Sociological Eye. Chicago: Aldine.
Academy of Management Journal, 45(1): Johnson, Gerry, Stuart Smith, and Brian
58–80. Codling. 2000. ‘Microprocesses of institu-
Grimshaw, Allen D. 1981. ‘Talk and social tional change in the context of privatization.’
control.’ Pp. 200–232 in Morris Rosenberg Academy of Management Review, 35:
and Ralph H. Turner (eds.), Social Psychology: 572–580.
Sociological Perspectives. New York: Kelly, Erin and Frank Dobbin. 1999. ‘Civil rights
Basic. law and work: Sex discrimination and the
Grodal, Stine. 2007. ‘The emergence of an rise of maternity leave policies.’ American
organizational field – labels, meaning Journal of Sociology, 105(2): 455–492.
and emotions in nanotechnology’ Unpub- Kling, Rob and Elihu M. Gerson. 1978a.
lished Dissertation, Stanford University, ‘Patterns of segmentation and intersection in
Stanford, CA. the computing world.’ Symbolic Interaction,
Hallett, Tim and Marc J. Ventresca. 2006. 1: 24–43.
‘Inhabited institutions: Social interactions Kling, Rob and Elihu M. Gerson. 1978b. ‘The
and organizational forms in Gouldner’s social dynamics of technical innovation in
Patterns of Industrial Bureaucracy.’ the computing world.’ Symbolic Interaction,
Theoretical Sociology, 35: 213–236. 1: 132–146.
Hannan, Michael T. and John H. Freeman. Kling, Rob and Walt Sacchi. 1982. ‘The web of
1977. ‘The population ecology of organiza- computing: Computer technology as social
tions.’ American Journal of Sociology, 82: construction.’ Advances in Computers, 21:
929–964. 1–90.
Heath, Christian and Paul Luff. 1992. Kunda, Gideon. 1992. Engineering Culture:
‘Collaboration and control: Crisis manage- Control and Commitment in a High Tech
ment and multimedia technology in Corporation. Philadelphia: Temple University
London Underground line control rooms.’ Press.
Computer Supported Cooperative Work, 1: Larson, Magali S. 1979. ‘Professionalism: Rise
69–94. and fall.’ International Journal of Health
Heath, Christian and Paul Luff. 1996. Services, 9: 607–627.
‘Convergent activities: Line control and pas- Lawrence, Thomas B. and Nelson Phillips.
senger information on the London 2004. ‘From Moby Dick to Free Willy: Macro-
Underground.’ Pp. 96–129 in Yrjo cultural discourse and institutional entrepre-
Engestrom and David Middleton (eds.), neurship in emerging institutional fields.’
Cognition and Communication at Work. Organization, 11(5): 1350–5084.
New York: Cambridge University Press. Leca, Bernard. 2006. ‘A critical realist
Heritage, John. 1993. Garfinkel and approach to institutional entrepreneurship.’
Ethnomethodology. London: Blackwell. Organization, 135(5): 627–651.
Hoffman, Andrew J. 1999. ‘Institutional evolu- Lewis, J. D. and Richard L. Smith. 1980.
tion and change: Environmentalism and the American Sociology and Pragmatism:
U.S. chemical industry.’ The Academy of Mead, Chicago Sociology, and Symbolic
Management Journal, 42(4): 351–371. Interaction. Chicago: University of Chicago
Hughes, Everett C. 1936. ‘The ecological Press.
aspects of institutions.’ American Linton, Ralph. 1936. The Study of Man.
Sociological Review, 1: 180–189. New York: Appleton-Century-Crofts.
516 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Lounsbury, Michael and William N. Kaghan. Administrative Science Quarterly, 39:


2001. ‘Organizations, occupations and the 541–574.
structuration of work.’ Research in the Park, Robert E. and Ernest W. Burgess. 1921.
Sociology of Work, 10: 25–50. Introduction to the Science of Sociology.
Lynch, Michael E. 1985. Art and Artifact in Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Laboratory Science: A Study of Shop Work Parsons, Talcott. 1951. The Social System. New
and Shop Talk in a Research Laboratory. York: Free Press.
London: Routledge and Kegan Paul. Powell, Walter W. 1985. Getting into Print: The
Maines, David R. 1982. ‘ In search of Decision Making Process in Scholarly
mesostructure: Studies in the negotiated Publishing. Chicago: Chicago University Press.
order.’ Urban Life, 11: 267–279. Rao, Hayagreeva. 1998. ‘ Caveat emptor: The
McCall, George J. and George L. Simmons. 1978. construction of nonprofit consumer watch-
Identities and Interactions: An Examination of dog organizations.’ American Journal of
Human Association in Everyday Life. New York: Sociology, 103(4): 912–961.
Free Press. Rao, Hayagreeva, Philippe Monin, and
McCallion, Michael J. and David R. Maines. Rodolphe Durand. 2003. ‘Institutional
2002. ‘Spiritual gatekeepers: Time and the change in Toque Ville: Nouvelle cuisine as an
rite of Christian initiation of adults.’ Symbolic identity movement in French gastronomy.’
Interaction, 25: 289–302. American Journal of Sociology, 108(4):
Mead, George H. 1934. Mind, Self, and Society. 795–843.
Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Rock, Paul. 1979. The Making of Symbolic
Merton, Robert K. 1957. Social Theory and Interactionism. Totowa, NJ: Rowman and
Social Structure. New York: Free Press. Littlefield.
Meyer, John W. and Brian Rowan. 1977. Roy, Donald F. 1964. ‘Unionization in the
‘Institutionalized organizations: Formal struc- South: The organizational campaign in the
ture as myth and ceremony.’ American social and cultural context of the South.’
Journal of Sociology, 83: 340–363. Labor Law Journal, 15(7): 451–468.
Munir, Kamal A. and Nelson Phillips. 2005. Roy, Donald F. 1965. ‘Change and resistance to
‘The birth of the ‘Kodak Moment’: change in the Southern labor movement.’
Institutional entrepreneurship and the adop- Pp. 225–247 in John McKinney and Edgar T.
tion of new technologies.’ Organization Thompson (eds.), The South in Continuity
Studies, 26: 1665–1687. and Change. Durham, NC: Duke University
Nelsen, Bonalyn J. and Stephen R. Barley. 1997. Press.
‘For love or money: Commodification and Sachs, Harvey, Emanuel A. Schegloff, and Gail
the construction of an occupational man- Jefferson. 1974. ‘A simplest systematics for
date.’ Administrative Science Quarterly, 42: the organization of turn-taking for conversa-
619–653. tions.’ Language, 50(4): 696–735.
Orlikowski, Wanda J. 1992. ‘The duality of Sandfort, Jodi R. 2003. ‘Exploring the struc-
technology: Rethinking the concept of tech- turation of technology within human service
nology in organizations.’ Organization organizations.’ Administration and Society,
Science, 3: 398–427. 34(6): 605–631.
Orlikowski, Wanda J. 1996. ‘Improvising orga- Schatzman, Leonard and Rue Bucher. 1964.
nizational transformation over time: A situ- ‘Negotiating a division of labor among pro-
ated change perspective.’ Information fessionals in a state mental hospital.’
Systems Research, 7: 63–92. Psychiatry, 27: 266–277.
Orlikowski, Wanda J. 2000. ‘Using technology Schatzman, Leonard and Anselm L. Strauss.
and constituting structures: A practice lens 1966. ‘A sociology of psychiatry: A perspec-
for studying technology in organizations.’ tive and some organizing foci.’ Social
Organization Science, 11: 404–428. Problems, 14(1): 2–16.
Orlikowski, Wanda J. and Joanne Yates. 1994 Scott, Marvin B. and Stanford M. Lyman. 1968.
‘Genre repertoire: The structuring of com- ‘Accounts.’ American Sociological Review,
municative practices in organizations.’ 33: 46–62.
COALFACE INSTITUTIONALISM 517

Scott, W. Richard. 1995. Institutions and Academy of Management Review, 20(3):


Organizations. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage. 571–610.
Seo, M. G. and W. E. D. Creed. 2002. Suddaby, Roy and Royston Greenwood. 2005.
‘Institutional contradictions, praxis and insti- ‘Rhetorical strategies of legitimacy.’
tutional change: A dialectical perspective.’ Administrative Science Quarterly, 50: 53–67.
Academy of Management Journal, 27(2): Tolbert, Pamela S. and Lynne G. Zucker. 1983.
1–29. ‘Institutional sources of change in the formal
Shibutani, Tomatsu. 1955. ‘Reference groups structure of organizations: The diffusion
as perspectives.’ American Journal of of civil service reform, 1880–1935.’
Sociology, 60: 522–529. Administrative Science Quarterly, 28: 22–39.
Shibutani, Tomatsu. 1962. ‘Reference groups Tolbert, Pamela S. and Lynne G. Zucker. 1996.
and social control.’ Pp. 128–147 in Arnold ‘The institutionalization of institutional
M. Rose (ed.), Human Behavior and Social theory.’ Pp. 175–90 in Stewart R. Clegg,
Processes: An Interactionist Approach. Cynthia Hardy, and Walter W. Nord (eds.),
Boston: Houghton Mifflin Company. Handbook of Organization Studies.
Silverman, David. 1971. The Theory of Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.
Organisations. New York: Basic. Turkle, Sherry. 1995. Life on the Screen:
Simmel, Georg. 1964. The Sociology of Georg Identity in the Age of the Internet. New York:
Simmel. New York: Free Press. Simon and Schuster.
Strauss, Anselm L. 1968. ‘Some neglected Turner, Ralph H. 1962. ‘Role taking: Process
properties of status passage.’ Pp. 235–251 in versus conformity.’ Pp. 20–40 in Arnold M.
Howard S. Becker, Blanche Geer, David Rose (ed.), Human Behavior and Social
Riesman, and Robert S. Weiss (eds.), Processes. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.
Institutions and the Person. Chicago: Aldine Turner, Ralph H. 1968. ‘Role: Sociological
Publishing Company. aspects.’ Pp. 552–557 in David L. Sills (ed.),
Strauss, Anselm L. 1978a. Negotiations: International Encyclopedia of the Social
Varieties, Processes, Context and Social Order. Sciences. New York: Macmillian.
San Francisco: Jossey-Bass. Turner, Ralph H. 1976. ‘The real self: From insti-
Strauss, Anselm L. 1978b. ‘A social world per- tution to impulse.’ American Journal of
spective.’ Studies in Symbolic Interaction, 1: Sociology, 81: 989–1016.
119–128. Turner, Ralph H. 1978. ‘Role and the person.’
Strauss, Anselm L. 1982. ‘Social worlds and American Journal of Sociology, 84: 1–23.
legitimation processes.’ Studies in Symbolic Van Maanen, John. 1973. ‘Observations on the
Interaction, 4: 171–190. making of policemen.’ Human Organization,
Strauss, Anselm L. 1984. ‘Social worlds and 32: 407–418.
their segmentation processes.’ Studies in Van Maanen, John. 1975. ‘Breaking in: A consid-
Symbolic Interaction, 5: 123–139. eration of organizational socialization.’ In
Strauss, Anselm L., Leonard Schatzman, Rue Robert Dubin (ed.), Handbook of Work, Organ-
Bucher, Danuta Ehrlich, and Melvin Sabshin. ization, and Society. Chicago: Rand-McNally.
1963. ‘The hospital and its negotiated order.’ Van Maanen, John. 1978. ‘The asshole.’
In Elliot Freidson (ed.), The Hospital in Pp. 221–238 in Peter K. Manning and John
Modern Society. New York: Free Press. Van Maanen (eds.), Policing: A View from
Strauss, Anselm L., Leonard Schatzman, Rue the Street. Los Angeles: Goodyear Press.
Bucher, Danuta Ehrlich, and Melvin Sabshin. Venkatesh, Murali and Dong H. Shin. 2005.
1964. Psychiatric Ideologies and Institutions. ‘Extending social constructivism with institu-
Glencoe, IL: Free Press. tional theory: A broadband civic networking
Suchman, Lucy A. 1987. Plans and Situated case.’ In Peter V. D. Besselaar, Giorgio d.
Action: The Problem of Human-Machine Michelis, Jenny Preece, and Carla Simore
Communication. Cambridge: Cambridge (eds.), Communities and Technologies 2005:
University Press. Proceedings of the Second Communities
Suchman, Mark C. 1995. ‘Managing legitimacy: and Technologies Conference (Milano, Italy;
Strategic and institutional approaches.’ The New York: Springer.
518 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Weick, Karl E. 1979. The Social Psychology of communication media.’ Academy of


Organizing. Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley. Management Review, 17: 299–326.
Williamson, Oliver E. 1975. Markets and Zucker, Lynne G. 1977. ‘ The role of institution-
Hierarchies: Analysis and Antitrust Implications. alization in cultural persistence.’ American
New York: Free Press. Sociological Review, 42: 726–743.
Yates Joanne and Wanda Orlikowski. 1992. Zucker, Lynne G. 1987. ‘Institutional theories of
‘Genres of organizational communication: organization.’ Annual Review of Sociology,
A structurational approach to studying 13: 443–464.
21
New Sociology of Knowledge:
Historical Legacy and
Contributions to Current Debates
in Institutional Research
Renate E. Meyer

INTRODUCTION sociology of knowledge has become one of


the classics in sociological thinking. In
When laying the foundations for neoinstitu- neoinstitutional theory, it is still among the
tional theory in 1977, both of the subsequent most frequently quoted references and gener-
classic articles (Meyer/Rowan 1977; Zucker ally assumed to be one of the approach’s
1977) pointed to Peter L. Berger and Thomas main theoretical pillars. As with many
Luckmann’s Social Construction of Reality, classics, however, the current citation is often
first published in 1966, as a central theoreti- made in passing and is more frequently a
cal foundation and inspiration for their tribute paid to their overall contribution to
research program. In the equally influential the field than as guidance in concrete theoret-
‘orange book,’ DiMaggio and Powell (1991) ical, conceptual or methodological questions.
underline that Berger and Luckmann’s Four decades after its first publication, the
phenomenological approach, together with actual impact of the sociology of knowledge
Harold Garfinkel’s ethnomethodology seems to be lagging behind its omnipresence
(another American scholar strongly influ- in the bibliographies of institutional
enced by Alfred Schütz; see also Psathas analyses.
2004), provides ‘the new institutionalism The Social Construction of Reality was
with a microsociology of considerable originally published in the United States, but
power.’ Berger and Luckmann’s biographical back-
Today, beyond doubt, Berger and grounds1 and their ambition to reconcile Max
Luckmann’s ‘new’ or social constructionist Weber’s verstehende sociology, Schütz’
520 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

phenomenological analysis of the Lebenswelt otherwise heterogeneous research agenda of


and American pragmatism give their socio- the German sociology of knowledge. In addi-
phenomenologically oriented approach pro- tion, organizational institutionalism’s often
found academic roots on both sides of the quantitative research questions and designs are
Atlantic and make it, as Dirk Tänzler puts it, not easily compatible with a hermeneutic
the ‘heiress and sister of philosophy.’ Despite approach. And last but not least, the language
their prominent position among sociological divide – the German-speaking branches of the
classics, Berger and Luckmann have not sociology of knowledge are unfortunately
given rise to a specific school of thinking nor available mostly in only the German language –
has it been their intention to do so. Apart from prevents the proponents of both approaches
neoinstitutional theory, which was elaborated from entering into a proper dialogue.
mainly in Northern America, in German-speak- In this chapter, I hope to make a contribution
ing interpretive sociology, a particular field of to such a dialogue by bringing together the lit-
study has developed in this tradition especially erature from both currently disparate streams.
after Luckmann’s return. Similar to organiza- The theoretical inspiration that the sociology
tional institutionalism, this field is more a of knowledge has provided is still alive in
research community that shares basic assump- many of organizational institutionalism’s basic
tions and research interests than a formulated assumptions and core concepts that have incor-
and coherent theory: Luckmann and several porated much more of the socio-phenomeno-
other researchers (e.g. Luckmann 2002 or logical legacy than might be apparent at first
2006a; Knoblauch 1995; Knoblauch/ sight. The most prominent example is, of
Luckmann 2004; Keller 2005a) have devoted a course, the overall focus on knowledge and,
considerable part of their oeuvre to analyzing thus, on the cognitive dimensions of institu-
the role of language and communication in the tions that has become one of the ‘trademarks’
construction of reality, a ‘turn’ evidenced by the of neoinstitutional theory, in comparison to
labelling communicative or discursive con- other more normative or regulative strands of
struction of reality. The incorporation of institutional thinking (see Scott 2001). Equally
hermeneutics into the sociology of knowledge important are the understanding of what insti-
(the hermeneutic sociology of knowledge or tutions are and how they operate, the relevance
social scientific hermeneutics as it was previ- of legitimacy, the conceptualization of the
ously called) is primarily tied to the work of process of institutionalization, or the role of
Hans-Georg Soeffner (e.g. 1989, 2004), but has language and symbolism that owe much to this
been taken up by several other scholars in the heritage. In the following sections, I will revive
field (e.g. Schröer 1994; Hitzler/Honer 1997; attention to these roots. However, I am not
Hitzler/Reichertz/Schröer 1999). tracing solely the historic legacy and impact,
Although they have common roots, organi- but argue that by rediscovering and renewing
zational institutionalism and the German the tie with the phenomenological sociology of
branches of the new sociology of knowledge knowledge, institutional theory could gain
pay very little attention to each other, aside much inspiration for theoretical and method-
from cursory cross-references (e.g. Keller ological challenges that have dominated the
2005a; Tänzler, Knoblauch, and Soeffner debate in the last decade and for new directions
2006a). While recent institutional research is in institutional research.
exploring its common ground with a number
of different theoretical approaches (e.g.
Anthony Giddens’ structuration theory, Pierre MEANING, KNOWLEDGE AND THE
Bourdieu’s concepts of habitus and field, or CONCEPTUALIZATION OF INSTITUTIONS
Michel Foucault’s discourse theory), the con-
cern for organizations and organization theory Many critics of the ‘standard version’ of
has been of only minor importance in the organizational institutionalism, especially
NEW SOCIOLOGY OF KNOWLEDGE 521

from Scandinavian institutionalism (e.g. Especially with regard to the interactive con-
Czarniawska/Joerges 1996; Sahlin-Andersson struction of social meaning and knowledge
1996; Brunsson 1998) or from other interpre- (as opposed to the subjective constitution)
tively inspired branches of institutional and the socialization of individuals, Schütz,
thinking (e.g. Zilber 2002, 2006; Meyer at that time already living in the U.S.,
2003) have claimed that institutional theory explicitly drew on the work of American
devotes too much effort to analyzing the tra- pragmatists, mainly of George Herbert
jectories of macro-diffusion patterns while Mead, Charles H. Cooley, William James,
underestimating the meaning the spreading and William I. Thomas.
practices have in the originating as well as Schütz elaborated that individuals work
adopting context and the modifications – with typifications of actions, situations and
translations – they undergo in the course of persons that are generated in interaction and
their ‘travels.’ Several of the Scandinavian communication. They identify typical actors
scholars, for instance Czarniawska and and identities, recognize typical actions and
Joerges (1996) or Forssell and Jansson assign typical meanings. To interpret and
(1996), explicitly draw attention to the work understand the situation they face, individu-
of Schütz, in particular to his notions of typ- als need to draw on the recipe knowledge that
ifications contained in the social stocks of is provided by their Lebenswelten.
knowledge. This ‘social stock of knowledge’ that the
One of the central assumptions derived members of a society share to different
from the Schützian legacy is that action is degrees is built up (‘sedimented’) from the
meaningful and that meaning is constituted experiences of the generations before them
through rules that are sprecific to the social (Schütz/Luckmann 1973). Individuals are
field. To recall, Schütz’s objective was to born into a ‘socio-historical a priori’, as
give Weber’s interpretive sociology, which Luckmann (e.g. 1983; see also Soeffner
identifies the goal of sociology in the under- 1989) calls it, that makes available these
standing of action from the subjective mean- institutionalized typifications, frames of
ing of the actor, a phenomenological interpretation, actor positions, patterns of
grounding (see especially Schütz 1967). In action, etc., and thus delineates the bound-
his appreciative, yet critical interpretation of aries and the ‘horizon’ within which people
Weber’s work, Schütz highlighted that Weber can meaningfully act – and beyond which it
had failed to specify the concept of meaning. is impossible to see or understand: All inter-
In particular, he asked how meaning is con- ests and preferences, all rationalities, choices
stituted by an actor and pointed to the con- and decisions ever imaginable lie within
cept’s inherent temporality. He emphasized these borders; all innovations, crises, shocks
the difference between the meaning assigned or whatever ‘triggers’ of change we assume
by the actors themselves and the meaning have to be interpreted within this horizon to
assigned by an observer, and raised the ques- be taken into consideration and have impact.
tion how understanding is at all possible Building on this hermeneutic and phenome-
given the categorical non-accessibility of nological heritage of Schütz’s work,
another person’s consciousness. The micro- Czarniawska and Joerges postulate that ‘we
sociological approach Schütz proposed by cannot translate what is wholly unrecogniz-
drawing on Husserl’s phenomenology focused able’ (1996: 28).
on how ordinary members of a society con- Accordingly, the phenomenological
stitute the everyday world they live in – the sociology of knowledge is not primarily con-
Lebenswelt – and on the conditions and prin- cerned with questions of epistemology and
ciples according to which intersubjectively methodology, nor with scientific knowledge,
shared meaning is constructed and, thus, how the specialized knowledge of intellectuals, or
mutual understanding is made possible. the history of ideas and ideologies, but with
522 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

the processes and conditions by which a par- (Barley/Tolbert 1997: 96), and is still being
ticular spatially and historically embedded used as the main reference when it comes to
social field defines what counts as knowl- the definition of institutions or the process of
edge and truth – and what does not (Schütz institutionalization (e.g. Zilber 2002; Dobbin
1962; Berger/Luckmann 1989). The central 2004; Dorado 2005; Battilana 2006;
object of the hermeneutic reconstruction is Weber/Glynn 2006). As I will discuss in the
neither to search for a latent macro-structure following sections, it has lost none of its rel-
that unfolds behind the back of the agents nor evance in the decades since its publication:
a singular individual perspective. Instead, it Apart from helping to overcome the concep-
is the social stocks of knowledge that the tual ambiguity and to re-establish a common
acting subjects draw on when constituting understanding of what is meant by institu-
subjective meaning, i.e. the socially tions and institutional processes, a concern
approved typifications available in a concrete increasingly articulated by scholars, various
historical socio-cultural Lebenswelt. Thus, facets of the classic conceptualization can
while departing from the Weberian assertion contribute to unsolved issues and current
that the goal of sociology is to understand debates in organizational institutionalism.
action from the subjective meaning assigned
to it, the perspective is nonetheless not
subjectivist but a structure analytic approach (a) Institutions and the construction
that attempts to reconcile structuralist and
of social actors and identities
interactionist positions (Soeffner/Hitzler
1994; Reichertz 1999; Soeffner 1989, 2004). The reciprocity of the typified, scripted
A focus on the cognition of actors and their action and the type of actor who is expected
stocks of knowledge does not – as is often to perform the script is central to the notion
brought up against the ‘cognitive turn’ in that institutions are constitutive for social
organizational institutionalism – necessarily actors and actorhood and for organizational
entail a de-emphasizing of social structure. institutionalism’s claim against rational
Building on this tradition, Berger and choice models that actors’ preferences and
Luckmann have elaborated how shared typi- interests are tied to and do not precede the
fications become institutions through tradi- institutional order they belong to. Instead of
tion, sedimentation, and legitimation. actors using institutions to foster their indi-
According to them, the reciprocity of typifi- vidual or collective interests, through institu-
cations and the typicality of both habitual- tionalization, not only patterns of scripted
ized actions, in the form of action scripts interactions are created, but also specific
and of social actors who are expected to social categories of actors, whose social
engage in these patterned actions, lie at the identities, worldviews and interests make
heart of all institutions – ‘(p)ut differently, sense only within the sedimented body
any such typification is an institution’ of social knowledge that has given shape
(Berger/Luckmann 1989: 54). This interac- to them (Berger/Luckmann 1989). For
tion-oriented and type-based definition is instance, Meyer/Boli/Thomas (1994: 18;
still central for organizational institutional- see also Meyer/Jepperson 2000 or J. Meyer,
ism. It is mirrored in the early notions of Chapter 34 in this volume) explicitly stress
institutions as ‘frameworks of programs or the close, in fact tautological, link between
rules establishing identities and activity script and actor-type:
scripts for such identities’ (Jepperson 1991:
Both social actors and the patterns of action they
146; see also Meyer/Boli/Thomas 1994) or
engage in are institutionally anchored. The partic-
as ‘shared rules and typifications that iden- ular types of actors perceived by self and
tify categories of social actors and their others and the specific forms their activity takes
appropriate activities or relationships’ reflect institutionalized rules of great generality
NEW SOCIOLOGY OF KNOWLEDGE 523

and scope. It is in this sense that social reality – borrowing Schütz and the sociology of
including both social units and socially patterned knowledge have made from pragmatism:
action – is ‘socially constructed’ (Berger/
Being a social actor means to know what is
Luckmann, 1966). Institutionalized rules, located
in the legal, social scientific, customary, linguistic, expected as appropriate in certain situations.
epistemological, and other ‘cultural’ foundations This, in turn, implies a definition of the
of society, render the relation between actor and situation that is compatible with those of
action more socially tautological than causal. others involved and rests on the ability of the
Actors enact as much as they act: What they do is
actors to take the perspective of the others
inherent in the social definition of the actor itself.’
(significant and generalized others)
The phenomenological heritage is most vis- (see Cooley 1964; Mead 1965; Thomas
ible in John Meyer’s notion of modern social 1967; and Schütz, e.g. 1962). The focus on
actors, but it also surfaces in the more recent the reciprocity of perspectives stresses the
institutional interest in the multiple social necessity of overlapping relevance systems
identities that are a characteristic of the and an intersubjectively shared Lebenswelt,
late-modern actor (see also Giddens 1991) and, thus, of socialization and internaliza-
and are seen to account for hybridization tion. Successful socialization is the basis for
and endogenous institutional change (e.g. the fact-like character of social reality and
Rao/Davis/Ward 2000; Rao/Monin/Durand the degree to which institutions become
2003; Meyer/Hammerschmid 2006; Westen- taken-for-granted ‘background programs’
holz 2006). In pluralistic societies, multiple (Berger/Kellner 1984). By framing world-
social identities go hand in hand with views and perceptions, institutions guide
multiple reference groups (see below), or as behavior prior to any visible sanctions. This
James (1968: 42) notes, an individual has ‘as creates the image of institutions being taken
many different social selves as there are dis- for granted and enacted almost naturally.
tinct groups of persons about whose opinions Internalization mediates between objective
he cares.’ A very similar motif is found in and subjective reality and renders the objec-
Luckmann’s recent work: The increasing func- tive world subjectively meaningful (Berger/
tional differentiation of society and the frag- Luckmann 1989). It is also the moment
mentation of the Lebenswelt more and more where individuals have to actively acquire
require the individual to master fragmented specific segments of the social knowledge
social identities from various specialized insti- and sediment it in a unique way into their
tutionalized domains. As he notes, ‘(l)iving in own subjective knowledge. Without paying
society always requires adaption. However, enough attention to the complex and
in later modernity the social structure favors a two-way relationship between social and
particularly high degree of adaptability, not individual stocks of knowledge, we run
only of a cognitive but also characterological the danger of degrading individuals to
nature’ (Luckmann 2006b: 11). This, he determined ‘cultural dopes,’ or, on the
observes, is happening paradoxically at the macro-level, losing the stratified character of
same point in history that the display of an the knowledge distribution of a society and
autonomous and individualized self has the related symbolic and structural power
become an ‘almost doctrinal obligation for the dimensions out of sight.
modern individual’ (2006b: 8). At least the fundamental institutional
orientations are perceived as fact-like.
Nonetheless, institutions are also supple-
(b) Institutional orders, social mented by various mechanisms of social
control – positive or negative, material or
control and power
immaterial sanctions – to make up for the
In addition, the reciprocity of typifications of incompleteness of all socialization in frag-
action and actors points to the substantial mented societies. Individual deviance does
524 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

not unsettle an established institutional order. historically–empirically unlikely marginal case.


A more collective shift towards increasing Within the ‘constitution analysis’ of institutions,
domination can be bracketed, but not power.
reflexivity and attention to institutionalized
(2002: 113, my translation).
patterns or the necessity to safeguard institu-
tions by actually employing the sanctions For organizational institutionalism,
provided, however, might be a first indicator DiMaggio (1988) noted almost two decades
of a commencing deinstitutionalization by ago that there is no conceptual ignorance of
making the contingency of the institutional- interests and power inherent in the theoreti-
ized patterns apparent (e.g. Berger/Kellner cal scaffolding of the approach. All
1984). Although not elaborating the power institutional order is only a preliminary
and domination dimensions of institutions achievement and the temporary result of
explicitly, Berger and Luckmann emphasize contest. Power is inextricably woven into
that ‘(i)nstitutions and symbolic universes institutional stability and change and institu-
are legitimated by living individuals, who tionalization is a profoundly political
have concrete social locations and concrete process. Although, in the meantime, the chal-
social interests’ (1989: 128) and that the lenge has been echoed by several scholars
‘power in society includes the power to who draw attention to interests, politics and
determine decisive socialization processes power struggles not only within established
and, therefore the power to produce reality’ institutional frames, but particularly in the
(1989: 119; emphasis in original). Strikingly processes leading to the definition of what
similar, when discussing the need to continu- models, frames, criteria of rationality, subject
ously reproduce institutions, DiMaggio positions and interests are appropriate
(1988: 13f.) points out that ‘(a)n important (e.g. Dobbin 1994; Clemens/Cook 1999;
aspect of institutional work is the socializa- Hoffman 1999; Fligstein 2001; Lounsbury/
tion of new participants, which is undertaken Ventresca 2002; Lounsbury 2003), an
most conscientiously by members with the alleged power void has remained among the
greatest stake in the existing institutional most frequently expressed points of criticism
order.’ The social construction of reality is a against institutional theory. I do not
power struggle over the definition of the sit- have the space to enter into a detailed
uation with some interpretations succeeding discussion, but I hope to have shown that by
over others. For Berger and Luckmann, it is, taking seriously the question of what counts
finally, the bigger stick and not the better as knowledge and what doesn’t, as well as
argument that imposes the definition of real- the processes and mechanisms by which this
ity (1989: 109), which, spun further, points is defined in a society (Schütz 1962), institu-
back to the question of domination. In a later tional theory has the potential to address all
work, Luckmann highlights again that faces of power and domination. If they do not
although social interaction requires, at least receive due attention, it is our current
to a certain degree, reciprocity of perspec- research foci that distract us and not short-
tives and of relevance systems, this by no comings of the conceptual framework.
means entails symmetry of relationships but
rather refers to the mutual exchangeability of
perspectives that has to be presupposed even (c) Institutional and organizational
when fighting. He emphasizes that
fields
reciprocity is not based on equality. The definition Apart from the constitution of actors and
of what is an ‘important’ problem is not essen-
attention to power and domination, the con-
tially the concern of ‘democratic rationality.’ The
solutions are not necessarily devised by ‘equi- ceptualization of institutions in the tradition
table’ actors. Institutionalization as rational sym- of the phenomenological sociology of
metric contract can be thought of as a knowledge could also help to come to terms
NEW SOCIOLOGY OF KNOWLEDGE 525

with the ambiguity in the use of the concept rationalizations or legitimations differ across
of ‘field.’ Reciprocity of perspectives time and/or space. They encompass not only
requires that institutionalized practices be those actors who are expected to perform
directed to some reference group (e.g. an institution, but include all those who
Shibutani 1962) or ‘collective audience’ (e.g. expect the institution to be performed,
Suchman 1995) that shares the stock of that is, all actors who share the frame of ref-
knowledge and is entitled to assess the erence. Institutional fields make homogene-
appropriateness and endorse legitimacy, in ity or heterogeneity of meaning and
short, ‘whose presumed perspective is used interpretations without institutionalized
by an actor as the frame of reference in the orders, forms and practices visible (see e.g.
organization of his perceptual field’ the research on translation or editing
(Shibutani 1962: 132; italic in original). processes, Czarniawska/Joerges 1996,
The definition of fields as connoting actors Sahlin–Andersson 1996) as well as the distri-
that partake in common meaning systems bution of knowledge, subject positions and
and share cultural-cognitive or normative power inherent in institutions. Moreover,
frameworks (e.g. Scott 1994: 207f.) is assuming that the borders of institutional
closely related to this understanding. Since fields are floating, the center(s) and periph-
one of the core characteristics of institutions eries of institutional orders could become
is their ability to bridge time and space, in observable (I thank Kerstin Sahlin for this
this sense fields connect actors beyond their point) – not only temporally, spatially/geo-
temporal and spatial co-presence. The graphically or relating to life-spheres, but
second part of Scott’s seminal definition – also in terms of the institutional order’s
‘whose participants interact more frequently strength or exclusiveness to define situations
and fatefully with one another than with (see below), i.e. the extent of taken-for-
actors outside of the field’, however, draws grantedness, or – with regard to the inner
attention to network structures and interac- composition – in terms of the various mani-
tion ties that do require some kind of spatial festations of institutional orders (i.e. central
and temporal co-presence (see e.g. Giddens beliefs/institutions or peripheral beliefs/insti-
1984 and his distinction between social and tutions). Apart from pointing to new research
system integration). directions, this could also contribute
In order to disentangle the multiple to a more systematic approach to our
notions of field that currently inform institu- current research on institutional change.
tional research, I believe it would be helpful Organizational fields focus on the degree to
to distinguish the two aspects analytically. In which a field of actors is characterized by a
current studies, the terms ‘institutional field’ single predominant or by multiple, poten-
and ‘organizational field’ are generally used tially competing institutional orders or
synonymously. I suggest using ‘institutional logics. They draw attention to the hetero-
field’ to demarcate spheres of institutional- geneity of institutionalized patterns and
ized meaning and ‘organizational field’ in interpretation frames in interaction fields. In
order to refer to network ties between con- a similar sense, social movement literature
stituents that directly and indirectly interact identifies ‘multiorganizational fields’ as
with each other. They are both equally complex, structured fields in which individ-
relevant and, in most empirical studies, inter- ual and collective actors in changing systems
twined, but encompass different phenomena: of alliances and conflict try to mobilize con-
Institutional fields focus on shared typifica- sensus for their claims (Klandermans 1992).
tions and mutual expectations and can Similarly, in the neoinstitutional tradition,
provide insights into how institutional orders Hoffman (1999) defines fields as ‘centers of
expand or contract or into how institu- debates in which competing interests negoti-
tional logics, institutionalized practices and ate over issue interpretation.’
526 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

The interactive dimension of this reciprocal


ACTION AND INSTITUTIONAL orientation is encompassed in the project of
ENTREPRENEURS the agents but also in the actual course of the
interaction.
The failure to adequately account for active Schütz distinguishes between two differ-
agents has for a long time been criticized as ent kinds of motives: The ‘in-order-to
one of organizational institutionalism’s motive’ is reflected in the action project and
weakest points, even by the theory’s propo- in the outcome that the agent imagines. The
nents (e.g. DiMaggio 1988; Beckert 1999; primary subjective meaning assigned by an
Mutch/Delbridge/Ventresca 2006). In the fol- individual corresponds to this ‘in-order-to
lowing section, I will draw attention to two motive.’ The ‘because-of motives’ reveal
aspects where organizational institutionalism why agents define the situation and design
could greatly benefit from a re-engagement the action the way they do. Thus, while the
with the Schützian socio-phenomenology: ‘in-order-to motive’ is future-oriented and
the general notion of action on the one only fully comprehensible to the agent alone
hand and the conceptualization of institu- (due to the inaccessibility of consciousness),
tional entrepreneurs and institutional work the ‘because-of motive’ can only be recon-
on the other. structed by analyzing the action context and
Building on Weber as well as the philo- individual’s past, i.e. the socio-historical a
sophical approaches of Henri Bergson and priori of the Lebenswelt and the individual
Edmund Husserl, Schütz (see especially biography. In this reconstruction, the actor
1967) developed the phenomenology in the has no privileged access compared to an
direction of an action theory that centers observer. The distinction between the two
upon the meaningfulness of action in gen- kinds of motives bridges the dichotomy
eral. He takes as a starting point the inten- between oversocialized, determined ‘cultural
tionality of consciousness (i.e. consciousness dopes’ and undersocialized atomistic agents’
is always directed to some object) and the free will: Individuals, in their biograph-
inherent temporality of all constitution of ical uniqueness of different sedimented
meaning. Action differs from passive experi- experiences and different layers of sedimen-
ences (i.e. reflexes) and spontaneous activi- tation that result from the temporality of all
ties (i.e. to perceive a stimulus from the these experiences, are never free from the
environment), insofar as it has a guiding socio-historical a priori of the established
project. For Schütz, action is any meaningful institutionalized order into which they are
experience that is orientated towards a future born, but equally never determined. While
state of affairs (in this sense, not picking the the ‘in-order-to motives’ reflect the freedom
phone up is just as much an action as picking to chose and decide, the ‘because-of motives’
it up). In the action design, the individual show the choices, decisions and interests that
imagines the action to be completed in the are historically and situationally available
future (‘modo futuri exacti’). Schütz points within the agent’s horizon of meaning and
out, that ‘we are conscious of an action only from their actor position.
if we contemplate it as already over and done Drawing more explicitly on Mead and the
with, in short, as an act. This is true even of pragmatists, but also on the socio-phenome-
projects, for we project the intended action as nology of Schütz, Emirbayer and Mische
an act in the future perfect tense’ (Schütz (1998), whose contribution – which they
1967: 64, emphasis in original). Social action, refer to as ‘relational pragmatics’ – received
and, in particular, interaction, does not merely much attention in the recent institutional the-
include this projection, but rather a reciprocal orizing about agency (e.g. Battilana 2006;
orientation towards another agent and is Mutch et al. 2006). They distinguish between
situated in concrete socio-historical contexts. three temporal dimensions of agency – an
NEW SOCIOLOGY OF KNOWLEDGE 527

iterational (informed by the past), a projec- my translation) highlights this intentionality


tive (oriented towards the future) and a prac- and meaningfulness inherent in all action:
tical-evaluative (situationally contextualized) Social reality presupposes intentional activities.
dimension – which, as they argue, dynami- Social worlds are constructed, maintained, trans-
cally interact in each instance of action. They mitted, transformed and, occasionally, destroyed
stress that they do not denote different types of through social action that is meaningful to those
action, but only analytically different who engage in it. Interactions are meaningful
when they lead to results that were intended by
elements, and that, depending on context and them. But they are equally meaningful in another,
actor, one or the other dimension may be often painful sense, when the consequences of the
predominant (Emirbayer/Mische 1998: 972). action differ from those originally intended. Action
According to them, situated actors assume is meaningful, whether the bridges and the mar-
variable temporal ‘agentic orientations’ in riages that were built for eternity, last or don’t.
(2006a: 20f.)
relation to the different action contexts they
face and may switch between these orienta- To insist that all action is intentional and
tions more or less reflexively. In contrast to meaningful entails that all actions – no
these agentic orientations, in the Schützian matter to what degree individuals rely on pre-
conceptualization, the inherent temporality given routines – are projected and comprise
that simultaneously encompasses future, past ‘in-pre-given order-to motives.’ Thus, even
and present is a definitional component of all when enacting highly taken-for-granted insti-
social action and, thus, a constitutive charac- tutionalized scripts, they assign subjective
teristic. In this conceptualization, the specific meaning and project some finished act into
orientation of an agent, no matter in what the future (but see Jepperson 1991). Through
temporal direction, finds expression in the their actions, institutional patterns are main-
agent’s project of action, i.e. their tained or transformed, sometimes as intended
‘in-order-to motives.’ Therefore, projectivity and sometimes institutions erode because
may encompass the creative reconfiguration they cease to make sense. However, this
of structure or may equally entail their mainly intentionality and projectedness does not
routine incorporation into activities. In this mean that all action is strategic in the sense
sense, it is an interesting question, why cele- of rational choice theory or that different
brated modern actorhood is so frequently alternatives are weighed against each other in
linked to future- and change-oriented action a utilitarian way according to individual
projects framed as ‘entrepreneurial,’ while preferences.
projects that reflect past–oriented traditional- Institutions, by definition, denote a certain
ism are not highly appreciated (for a similar durability. However, this emphasis on the sta-
point see Hwang and Powell 2005). bility provided by institutions has to be seen
In the socio-phenomenological tradition, in the context of the ever-present fragility of
meaning is an achievement of an individual’s all order. Berger and Luckmann (1989: 103)
consciousness and consciousness is inten- underscore that ‘(t)he legitimation of the
tional (Schütz 1967). Thereby, it is of little institutional order is also faced with the
relevance whether the future state projected ongoing necessity of keeping chaos at
by the individual is actually realized or bay. All social reality is precarious. All
whether something completely different societies are construction is the face of
occurs. Moreover, the subjective meaning chaos.’ Hence, the existence of order – on the
may change several times as the course of the macro-level of society, the micro-level of
(inter)action unfolds. In addition, the mean- interaction as well as on the individual level
ing assigned retrospectively when the agent of identity construction – cannot be taken for
is reflecting over the finished act is very granted but is an ongoing achievement of the
likely different from the primary meaning agents involved. Its reproduction and trans-
assigned to the project. Luckmann (2006a, formation are equally fragile. The focus on
528 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

the precariousness of order is shared with the the Schützian concept of social action could
negotiated order approach to organizations contribute to such a foundation.
(e.g. Strauss 1978; Maines/Charlton 1985; As they are referring to specific types, the
Fine 1996) – an approach that builds on central questions in this context obviously
pragmatism and symbolic interactionism as are how we identify institutional entrepre-
well as the work of Everett C. Hughes, neurs and institutional work and in what
another forefather of neoinstitutionalism (see respect they differ from other actors and their
e.g. Zucker 1977; Scott 2001), but is mostly actions. One option would be to tie the iden-
neglected in organizational research (for an tification to the outcome, i.e. to institutional
exception see e.g. Hallett/Ventresca 2006; change. However, this would be highly
Walgenbach/Meyer 2008). Strauss stresses problematic for several reasons: First, as
that social order is maintained in continuous Sahlin-Andersson and Engwall (2002) have
processes of negotiating reality. For him highlighted, the relationships between actor,
(1978: ix) ‘rules and roles are always activities, interests and institutional change
breaking down – and when they do not, they are often much more indirect. They conclude
do not miraculously remain intact without that ‘(t)he institutional entrepreneur is only
some effort, including negotiation effort, to one type of actor that is important in the
maintain them.’ processes of institutional change’ (2002:
In organizational institutionalism, the 294). While change may emerge without
insight that not only the primary establish- much effort from those individuals who,
ment or the transformation of institutions often retrospectively, get filtered out as
involves signifying activities, but that also initiators, it might take just as much
the routine reproduction requires continuous resources and work to stabilize an institu-
efforts has led to renewed empirical and the- tional arrangement against opponents as it
oretical interest in ‘institutional entrepre- would to initiate new procedures. However,
neurs’ – actors with sufficient resources who to tie the identification of institutional entre-
see new institutions as an opportunity to real- preneurs and work to the necessity of defeat-
ize interests that they value highly ing resistance or the potential or even the
(DiMaggio 1988: 14; see also Dorado 2005; willingness to do so, would inevitably
Battilana 2006; Greenwood/Suddaby 2006) directly lead into a ‘multiple faces of power’
– and ‘institutional work’ – ‘the purposive debate (Bachrach/Baratz 1962; Lukes 1974;
action of individuals and organizations Clegg 1989) and the argument that any insti-
aimed at creating, maintaining and disrupting tutional explanation has to be especially sen-
institutions’ (Lawrence/Suddaby 2006: 218; sitive to all variations of structural and
see also DiMaggio 1988; Fligstein 2001). symbolic power that is prevalently mani-
From these short definitions, it is evident that fested in the absence of any visible form of
the concepts are not intended to provide gen- resistance.
eral conceptualizations of actors and action, Drawing on the different kinds of motives
but to denote specific types. Hwang and Schütz distinguishes could offer a promising
Powell (2005) identify a discomforting infla- option to embed the institutional entrepre-
tionary growth in the usage of the term neur within a more general conception of
‘entrepreneur’ and a more general trend to action and provide criteria for the identifica-
label all sorts of activities as entrepreneur- tion of the type. I believe that it would be in
ship that they link to essentially modern, yet the spirit of the research building on
under-analyzed, conceptions of empowered DiMaggio (1988) to use the term for agents
individuals. For institutional entrepreneurs to whose action projects and subjective
be an endogenous explanation of change, it is meanings (i.e. their ‘in-order-to motives’) are
necessary to give the concept a firm institu- directed towards the institutional framework
tional grounding. I suggest that drawing on (both future- and change-oriented as well as
NEW SOCIOLOGY OF KNOWLEDGE 529

past- and stability-oriented). I interpret the look at the original conceptualization sup-
‘purposive’ in Lawrence and Suddaby’s defi- ports the skepticism: First, in the new sociol-
nition as leading the same way.2 Whether ogy of knowledge, the three moments of the
they succeed or fail, whether they sponsor dialectical process of reality construction are,
stability or change, is a different question, as as is well known, externalization, objectiva-
is, by the way, the methodological challenge tion (part of which are the sedimentation of
of coming to terms with the temporality of meaning in a social sign system and its insti-
the subjective meaning and the categorical tutionalization) and, finally, internalization.
non-accessibility of consciousness in con- The transmission to a third person who was
crete empirical research designs. To endoge- not involved in the creation – no further
neously account for their specific resources quantitative spread – is required to complete
and to explain how they come to have diver- the process of institutionalization. Secondly,
gent interests and define the situation in a the meaning of a form or practice is stressed
way that they see a window of opportunity on both the level of the individual actors who
requires the incorporation of the related have to make sense of the situations they face
‘because-of motives’, i.e. the socio-historical and the level of society as a whole by linking
Lebenswelt with its institutionalized knowl- institutionalization to some kind of societal
edge and the specific (inter)action context, problem.
into the analysis. The enactment of scripted action is tied to
certain types of actors, i.e. prevalence of a
certain already institutionalized practice is to
be expected among actors belonging to the
THE PROCESS OF same social categorization. Thus, the ques-
INSTITUTIONALIZATION REVISITED tion how far a practice can be expected to
spread in terms of actors who perform it or
Another prominent example of Berger and situations in which it is to be displayed is
Luckmann’s influence on the body of organi- dependent on the typification. Some institu-
zational institutionalism is the notion of insti- tions are frequently performed by many
tutionalization as a process in which, through members of a society (e.g. institutions relat-
repetition, routinization and transmission, ing to meeting and departing, introducing,
ephemeral interactions become objectified etc.); some are enacted by most members
patterns, and meaning, originally constituted but, in general, only infrequently (e.g. insti-
by the individual consciousness, becomes tutions relating to birth or death). Others do
part of the socio-historical a priori. This not imply at all that the practices in question
notion is explicit in the conceptualization of spread quantitatively (such as institutions
advancing institutionalization as sequence of relating to the succession of kings, presidents
the stages of habitualization, objectivation, or the Pope). Prevalence within a social
sedimentation (Zucker 1977; Tolbert/Zucker category does not entail a quantitatively wide
1996; Colyvas/Powell 2006) and implicitly spread of a form or practice if only a few
implicated in studies that regard the broad actors are classified as belonging to this cat-
diffusion or increasing density of some struc- egory, no matter how deeply taken for
ture or practice within a field as an indicator granted and widely shared the institution
for increasing legitimacy – the currently might be. Hence, neither is the absence of a
dominant model for empirically analyzing wide diffusion indicative of the concept’s
institutionalization. Recently, scholars have lack of legitimacy, nor is the spread an indi-
started to question the comprehensiveness of cator for the size of the institutional field.
this model (e.g. Sahlin-Andersson 1996; Moreover, the observation of a practice or
Benford/Snow 2000; Campbell 2004; Meyer form spreading might denote its primary
2004; Lawrence/Suddaby 2006). A closer institutionalization or its translation for other
530 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

types of actors or situations, i.e. the expan- Organizational institutionalism has


sion of the institutional field’s boundaries. devoted much attention to show how prac-
Without understanding the meanings of a tices get institutionalized, maintained or even
concept it is impossible to figure out what we deinstitutionalized. Very little attention has
are actually observing. Presence or absence been dedicated to why they do. From a
of quantitative diffusion of forms of practices European’s perspective, this might be a con-
is too ambiguous to be taken as a measure of sequence of the anxiety of many North
institutionalization. In addition, a wide American scholars to get into the vicinity of
spread in a quantitative sense is not equiva- functionalist explanations (for the relation-
lent to a high degree of institutionalization, ship between Schütz and Parsons see their
as has often been shown with regard to correspondence edited by Grathoff 1978).
management fashions. The sociology of The sociology of knowledge ties the
knowledge, particularly research on existence of institutions or new institutional-
Deutungsmuster (e.g. Oevermann 1973, izations to the social approval of a situation
2001; Meuser/Sackmann 1992), a concept as inherently problematic. In Berger and
that is closely related to Goffman’s frames Luckmann’s words (1989: 69f.), ‘(t)he trans-
(1986), links the strength of social expecta- mission of the meaning of an institution is
tions to the exclusivity with which they based on the social recognition of that insti-
encompass situations (see also Goffman tution as a “permanent” solution of a
1961, on total institutions) and, thus, their “permanent” problem of this collectivity.’
degree of latency (Lüders/Meuser 1997) Institutions are challenged if they cease to be
which may range from reflexive availability seen as solutions or if the situation is no
to the complete taken-for-grantedness that longer regarded as problematic, or, the argu-
characterizes the most powerful typifica- ment turned around, if institutions persist, we
tions. Thus, culturally powerful institutions can assume that they continue to reply to a
are almost naturalized and drawn close to societal problem, which, however, is not nec-
instincts (Douglas 1986; see e.g. Schütze’s essarily the original one (Soeffner in
[1991], interesting analysis of the historical Reichertz 2004), nor does this say anything
transformations of ‘motherly love’). A high about a ‘rationality’ of this solution. Thus,
degree of latency makes it impossible for not merely the spread of institutions, but
individuals to ignore the institutionalized rather the question of which societal problem
expectations, as they are compelling even for the actors defined and attended to is of cen-
those who deliberately try to defect. They, tral concern. Societies only stabilize
too, have to actively make reference, for important forms of action, and, on the macro-
example by feeling the urge to account for level, the societal relevance system can be
their non-compliance (e.g. Elsbach 1994), by inferred from the repertoire of existing
pretending to adhere or by employing decou- institutions (the ‘institutional economy’,
pling strategies (Meyer/Rowan 1977; Oliver Luckmann 2002). This emphasis on the close
1991) or simply by feeling guilty. From this linkage between institution and context
perspective, decoupling and symbolic accounts partly for the heterogeneity of insti-
window-dressing activities, merely rhetorical tutions and for the observation that concepts
adoptions of practices, etc. are not necessar- and their theorizations cannot be trans-
ily antagonistic to institutions (but see ferred ‘wholesale’ from one social sphere to
Tolbert/Zucker 1996). On the contrary, they the next. In Soeffner’s words (2006, my
might point to socially powerful expectations translation),
that can not be neglected. The severity with
(t)hey are all historical plants that owe their
which the disappointment of social appearance to the cultural landscapes and regions
expectations is sanctioned evidences the in which they have grown. Their soil and their
institution’s relevance and centrality. nourishment are the particular problems of
NEW SOCIOLOGY OF KNOWLEDGE 531

concrete societies, times and situations. They are jewellery, clothes or graves, or rituals are
the concrete answers to concrete problematic situ- other forms in which social knowl-
ations, that is, concerning their content and phe-
edge is sedimented. Further, language is the
notype, they are bound to specific socio-historical
contexts and are inexchangeable – unless they be prime instrument for the transmission of
transferred with political and/or ideological power knowledge, thus, for socialization and inter-
and continuous surveillance from one culture to nalization. Moreover, the mobilization of
the other, superseding this culture’s representa- legitimacy is a mainly discursive process.
tions of order or pushing them into the back-
Berger and Luckmann (1989: 64) stress that
ground. (2006: 64)
‘the edifice of legitimation is built upon lan-
Again, there are obvious similarities espe- guage and uses language as its principal
cially to research conducted in the tradition instrumentality.’ In a later publication,
of the Scandinavian institutionalism on trans- Luckmann (2006: 22, my emphasis and
lations and editing processes, but also to translation) asserts that, although it would be
studies on contesting institutional logics (e.g. too narrow to confine knowledge to discur-
Reay/Hinings 2005) or on framing processes sive knowledge and all human praxis to com-
(e.g. Benford/Snow 2000). In addition to this municative interactions, ‘the human social
overlap of research questions, the sociology world is at least mainly constructed in com-
of knowledge provides a rigorous repertoire municative interaction.’ Just like every other
of hermeneutic procedures to be used in form of social action, communicative actions
empirical analyses that follow strict rules of also get habitualized and institutionalized.
interpretation and documentation and war- This requires looking beyond the actual con-
rant a ‘monitored and controlled understand- tent of communication and examining the
ing’ (Soeffner 2004; see also e.g. Soeffner formats in which it is produced – the commu-
1989; Flick/von Kardoff/Steinke 2004; for an nicative genres (Luckmann 2002, 2006a;
English-speaking example in organiza- Knoblauch 1995; Knoblauch/Luckmann
tion research see Lueger/Sandner/Meyer/ 2004). Genres, such as jokes, greetings,
Hammerschmid 2005). This could contribute prayers, job interviews, emails, exams, par-
considerably to enhancing the appreciation liamentary speeches, performance appraisal,
for qualitative research methods in organiza- or gossip are more or less obligatory interac-
tional institutionalism. tion patterns that are available to actors as
part of the social knowledge stocks. The sta-
bilization of communication into genres
serves the same purpose as institutionaliza-
LANGUAGE, DISCOURSE AND tion in general. It ‘frees the individual from
COMMUNICATIVE INSTITUTIONS the burden of “all those decisions” ’
(Berger/Luckmann 1989: 53). Genres give
Language is a main focus in current research, orientation and help in coordinating
both in organizational institutionalism and in and structuring interaction by providing
the phenomenological sociology of knowl- typical expectations with respect to the
edge. Institutionalization, apart from the synchronization of actors and by standardiz-
transmission from one generation to the next, ing the interaction sequences. They are
is bound to social knowledge that is intersub- the ‘communicative institutions’ of a par-
jectively available through its sedimentation ticular society, and, taken together, constitute
in all sorts of symbol systems. Language a society’s ‘communicative economy’
plays a crucial role in several respects: It is (Luckmann 2002).
the most important sign system and In organizational institutionalism, lan-
‘reservoir’ of typifications and institutional guage and symbolism have always had a
knowledge, although by no means the only central role – too central in the eyes of some
one. Artefacts, such as factories or churches, critics (e.g. Perrow 1985). Here, a focus has
532 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

been on the availability of accounts that of knowledge. The replacement of the com-
actors do not have to invent anew when municative construction of reality with a
trying to legitimate their proceeding, but that discursive is meant to underscore this
come ‘ready-made’ with the theorization of emphasis.
the concepts in question (e.g. Meyer/Rowan It is evident that especially the commu-
1977, Strang/Meyer 1993; Elsbach 1994; nicative and discursive strands of the sociol-
Lounsbury/Glynn 2001; Creed/Scully/Austin ogy of knowledge have amazing overlaps
2002; Meyer 2004; Suddaby/Greenwood with the current agenda of organizational
2005). Zucker (1977: 728) points out that institutionalism and could contribute consid-
when acts have ready-made accounts, they erably to future research. In the context of
are institutionalized. Scott and Lyman (1970: organizational studies, communicative
93), who had a strong impact on organiza- genres as social institutions have been ana-
tional institutionalism’s understanding of lyzed, e.g. by Yates and Orlikowski (1992),
accounts, explicate that they introduced the who, building on rhetorical theory and
concept in order to bring together Schütz’s Giddens’ structuration theory, come to a
emphasis on taken-for-granted social recipes strikingly similar definition of a genre as ‘a
‘everyone knows’ and C. W. Mills’ (1940) typified communicative action invoked in
‘vocabularies of motive.’ The repertories of response to a recurrent situation’ (Yates/
such ‘vocabularies of motive’ are distributed Orlikowski 1992: 301). In organizational
within a field according to social position studies, interesting new genres abound (e.g.
and identity, and, thus, are tailored for spe- emails, homepages, sustainability reports,
cific categories of actors to use in typical sit- hearings, accreditation reports). Like all
uations. In the terminology of the institutions, genres attend to fundamental
phenomenological sociology of knowledge, and recurrent communicative problems that
they are ready-made because they are part of are typical for a particular field. Since these
the socio-historical a priori (Luckmann problems and the socially approved way to
2006a). attend to them are own to a specific field, dif-
More recently, a number of institutional- ferent communities use different commu-
ists have suggested drawing on discourse nicative economies (Luckmann 2002) or
analysis (e.g. Phillips/Lawrence/Hardy genre repertoires (Orlikowski/Yates 1994),
2004) or rhetorical analysis (e.g. Suddaby/ and like all institutionalized forms, genres
Greenwood 2005) to strengthen the micro- can not travel from one social context to the
foundation of institutional processes. In next without translation or editing activities.
order to overcome the micro-bias and to Not only are genres closely related to institu-
encompass the ongoing political processes tionalized contexts, but often they are also
related to the production, circulation, trans- constitutive of them, that is, these contexts
formation and manifestation of knowledge at ‘may actually be defined through the use of
the meso- or macro-level, researchers in the such genres’ (Knoblauch/Luckmann 2004:
tradition of the hermeneutic sociology of 306). Changes in the communicative econ-
knowledge (e.g. Keller 2005a, 2005b; omy of a field are, thus, indicative of trans-
Keller/Hirseland/Schneider/Viehöver formations of institutional regimes or logics.
2001, 2005) also direct attention to Many of the analyses of the spread of new
discourses as analytic devices. Keller institutional logics into other fields focus on
(2005a) suggests integrating the work of language and it would be interesting to read
Gusfield (1981), the social movement them in terms of the involved genres, e.g.
research particularly in the tradition of Oakes, Townley, and Cooper’s (1998) analy-
Gamson (e.g. Gamson/Modigliani 1989) sis of how the use of business plan in a public
and, further, Foucault’s discourse theory into organization facilitated the shift from a cul-
the phenomenologically oriented sociology tural to an economic rationality. In addition,
NEW SOCIOLOGY OF KNOWLEDGE 533

it could be interesting to see if the different revisiting its own conceptual background and
types of institutional work (Lawrence/ from a closer engagement with the
Suddaby 2006) or legitimating efforts socio-phenomenological tradition. For exam-
(Suchman 1995) rely on or constitute differ- ple, a closer adherence to the sociology of
ent genres, i.e. if the use of particular genres knowledge could help disentangle diffusion
can be seen as a cue for institutional entre- research and the analyses of institutionaliza-
preneurs at work, or to see how the global tion processes, overcome the power and
diffusion of rationalization according to the agency void, or refocus attention on one of
world polity approach (e.g. Meyer 2005) is organizational institutionalism’s core
displayed in the communicative economies. strengths – stability that is accomplished
amid ever changing situations and constella-
tions of agents after more than a decade of
preoccupation with change and heterogene-
CONCLUSION ity. In addition, we are reminded of other
symbol systems besides language (e.g. arte-
Organizational institutionalism and the facts, design, buildings, architecture, etc.)
various branches of the German-speaking that transport institutional knowledge. For
sociology of knowledge share roots in the example the relevance of ‘locales’ for the
phenomenologically inspired Social evoking of institutional patterns is still
Construction of Reality. My intent in this underemphasized in institutional research.
chapter was to assume an institutional stand- Further, an engagement with the distribution
point and look over the fence to see what of knowledge on the level of the field
could be gained by reopening a dialogue. relates sedimentation to discrimination and
I have shown that neoinstitutional theory’s opens the view on institutionalized knowl-
main concepts still bear a strong socio-phe- edge/power structures and domination.
nomenological imprint, even if this heritage Finally, particularly with regard to a potential
has somewhat become the status of tacit ‘discursive turn,’ the sociology of knowledge
assumptions. I have argued that in terms of with its focus on genres and knowledge
core conceptualizations, such as agency, regimes has a much more ‘indigenously’
meaning, social and individual knowledge, institutionally anchored agenda than institu-
or Lebenswelt, for a phenomenologically tional theory presently seems to have.
inspired approach like organizational institu-
tionalism it is impossible to look back
beyond the work of Alfred Schütz. A firmer
grounding in his tradition could help to over- ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
come the conceptual ambiguity that is cur-
rently being criticized by many of the For helpful discussions and conversations
theory’s proponents. I have outlined that, and insightful comments on earlier drafts of
apart from the historical legacy, many of the this chapter I would like to thank Markus
current research questions overlap with the Höllerer, Peter Leisink, John Meyer, Kerstin
work done in the German-speaking sociol- Sahlin, Roy Suddaby and Marc Ventresca.
ogy of knowledge and have examined poten-
tial contributions the socio-phenomenology
can make to current debates. I have shown
that several of the current challenges do not NOTES
require organizational institutionalism to
‘import’ concepts from other theoretical 1 Peter L. Berger and Thomas Luckmann both
traditions; important impulses and potential have Austrian roots as well as Alfred Schütz, who
new directions could be gained from had to leave Austria in 1938.
534 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

2 Similarly, coming from the social movement Cooley, C.H. 1964. Human Nature and the
research, Snow and Benford (2000: 624) conceptual- Social Order. New York: Schocken.
ize their frame alignment processes as ‘(s)trategic Creed, W.E.D., M. Scully, and J.R. Austin. 2002.
efforts by SMOs to link their interests and interpretive ‘Clothes make the person? The tailoring of
frames with those of prospective constituents and
legitimating accounts and the social con-
actual or prospective resource providers’ and
Klandermans (1988) distinguishes ‘consensus mobi-
struction of identity.’ Organization Science,
lization’ (the ‘deliberate attempt by a social actor to 13: 475–96.
create consensus’) from ‘consensus formation’ Czarniawska, B., and B. Joerges. 1996. ‘Travels
(‘unplanned convergence of meaning’). of ideas’, in B. Czarniawska and G. Sevón,
eds., Translating Organizational Change.
Berlin and New York: deGruyter, pp. 13–48.
DiMaggio, P.J. 1988. ‘Interest and agency in
REFERENCES institutional theory’, in L.G. Zucker, ed.,
Institutional Patterns and Organizations.
Bachrach, P., and M. Baratz. 1962. ‘The two Culture and Environment. Cambridge, MA:
faces of power.’ American Political Science Ballinger, pp. 3–21.
Review, 56: 947–52. DiMaggio, P.J., and W.W. Powell. 1991.
Barley, S.R., and P.S. Tolbert. 1997. ‘Introduction’, in W.W. Powell and
‘Institutionalization and structuration: P.J. DiMaggio, eds., The New Institutionalism
Studying the links between action and insti- in Organizational Analysis. Chicago, London:
tution.’ Organization Studies, 18: 93–117. University of Chicago Press, pp. 1–38.
Battilana, J. 2006. ‘Agency and institutions: Dobbin, F. 1994. ‘Cultural models of organiza-
The enabling role of individuals’ social posi- tion: The social construction of rational
tion.’ Organization, 13: 653–76. organizing principles’, in D. Crane, ed., The
Beckert, J. 1999. ‘Agency, entrepreneurs, and Sociology of Culture. Oxford: Blackwell,
institutional change. The role of strategic pp. 117–41.
choice and institutionalized practices in Dobbin, F. 2004. ‘How institutions create
organizations.’ Organization Studies, 20: ideas: Notions of public and private effi-
777–99. ciency from early French and American rail-
Benford, R.D., and D.A. Snow. 2000. ‘Framing roading.’ L’Année de la Régulation, 8:
processes and social movements.’ Annual 15–50.
Review of Sociology, 26: 611–39. Dorado, S. 2005. ‘Institutional entrepreneur-
Berger, P.L., and T. Luckmann. 1989. The Social ship, partaking, and convening.’ Organization
Construction of Reality. Garden City, NY: Studies, 26: 385–414.
Anchor. Douglas, M. 1986. How Institutions Think.
Berger, P.L., and H. Kellner. 1984. Für Eine Neue Syracuse: Syracuse University. Press.
Soziologie. Frankfurt/Main: Fischer. Elsbach, K.D. 1994. ‘Managing organizational
Brunsson, N. 1998. ‘Homogeneity and hetero- legitimacy in the California cattle industry.’
geneity in organizational forms as result Administrative Science Quarterly, 39: 57–88.
of cropping–up processes’, in N. Brunsson and Emirbayer, M., and A. Mische. 1998. ‘What is
J.P. Olsen, eds., Organizing Organizations. agency?’ American Journal of Sociology,
Bergen–Sandviken: Fagbokvorlag, pp. 259–78. 103, 4: 962–1023.
Campbell, J.L. 2004. Institutional Change and Fine, G.A. 1996. Kitchens: The Culture of
Globalization. Princeton: Princeton Univ. Press. Restaurant Work. University of California
Clegg, S.R. 1989. Frameworks of Power. Press.
Newbury Park, CA: Sage. Flick, U., E. von Kardoff, and I. Steinke, eds.
Clemens, E.S., and J.M. Cook. 1999. ‘Politics 2004. A Companion to Qualitative Research.
and institutionalism: Explaining durability London: Sage.
and change.’ American Review of Sociology, Fligstein, N. 2001. ‘Social skill and the theory of
25: 441–66. fields.’ Sociological Theory, 19: 105–25.
Colyvas, J., and W.W. Powell. 2006. ‘Roads to Forsell, A. and D. Jansson. 1996. ‘The logic of
institutionalization.’ Research in Organizational organizational transformation: On the con-
Behavior, 21: 305–53. version of non–business organizations’, in
NEW SOCIOLOGY OF KNOWLEDGE 535

B. Czarniawska and G. Sevón, eds., and P.J. DiMaggio, (eds). The New Institution-
Translating Organizational Change. Berlin alism in Organizational Analysis. Chicago:
and New York: de Gruyter, pp. 93–115. University of Chicago Press, pp. 143–63.
Gamson, W., and A. Modigliani. 1989. ‘Media Keller, R., A. Hirseland, W. Schneider, and
discourse and public opinion on nuclear W. Viehöver, eds. 2001. Handbuch
power.’ American Journal of Sociology, 1: Sozialwissenschaftliche Diskursanalyse, Bd.
1–37. 1: Theorien und Methoden. Opladen: Leske
Giddens, A. 1984. The Constitution of Society. + Budrich.
Berkeley CA: University of California Press. Keller, R. 2005a. Wissenssoziologische
Giddens, A. 1991. Modernity and Self–Identity. Diskursanalyse. Wiesbaden: VS Verlag.
Self and Society in the Late Modern Age. Keller, R. 2005b, September. ‘Analysing
Stanford: Stanford University Press. Discourse. An Approach From the Sociology
Goffman, E. 1961. Asylums. Essays on the of Knowledge.’ Forum: Qualitative Social
Social Situation of Mental Patients and Other Research, 6, 3: 32. http://www.qualitative-
Inmates. New York: Doubleday. research.net/fqs-texte/3-05/05-3-32-e.htm
Goffman, E. 1986. Frame Analysis. Boston: [September 15, 2005].
Northeastern University Press. Keller, R., A. Hirseland, W. Schneider, and
Grathoff, R. ed. 1978. The Theory of Social W. Viehöver, eds. 2005. Die Diskursive
Action: The Correspondence of Alfred Konstruktion der Wirklichkeit. Konstanz:
Schutz and Talcott Parsons. Bloomington UVK.
and London: Indiana University Press. Klandermans, B. 1988. ‘The formation
Greenwood, R. and R. Suddaby. 2006. and mobilization of consensus,’ in
‘Institutional entrepreneurship in mature fields: B. Klandermans, H. Kriesi and S. Tarrow,
The big five accounting firms.’ Academy of (eds.), From Structure to Action: Comparing
Management Journal, 49: 27–48. Movement Research Across Cultures, CT and
Gusfield, J.R. 1981. The Culture of Public London: JAI Press, pp. 173–97.
Problems. Chicago, London: Univ. of Klandermans, B. 1992. ‘The social construc-
Chicago Press. tion of protest and multiorganizational
Hallett, T., and M.J. Ventresca, Marc J. 2006. fields’, in A.D. Morris and C. McClurg
‘Inhabited institutions: Social interactions Mueller, eds., Frontiers in Social Movement
and organizational form in Gouldner’s Theories. New Haven: Yale University Press,
Patterns of Industrial Bureaucracy.’ Theory & pp. 77–103.
Society, 35: 216–36. Knoblauch, H. 1995. Kommunikationskultur.
Hitzler, R., and A. Honer, eds. 1997. Berlin: de Gruyter.
Sozialwissenschaftliche Hermeneutik. Opla- Knoblauch, H., and T. Luckmann. 2004. ‘Genre
den: Leske + Budrich. analysis’, in U. Flick, E. von Kardoff, and
Hitzler, R., J. Reichertz, and N. Schröer, eds. I. Steinke, (eds.), A Companion to Qualitative
1999. Hermeneutische Wissenssoziologie. Research. London: Sage, pp. 303–7.
Konstanz: UVK. Lawrence, T.B., and R. Suddaby. 2006. ‘Institutions
Hoffman, A.J. 1999. ‘Institutional evolution and and institutional work’, in S.R. Clegg,
change: Environmentalism and the US chemi- C. Hardy, W.R. Nord, and T. Lawrence, T.,
cal industry.’ Academy of Management eds., The Sage Handbook of Organization
Journal, 42: 351–71. Studies. London: Sage, pp. 215–54.
Hwang H. and W.W. Powell, 2005. Institutions Lounsbury, M. 2003. ‘The problem of order
and Entrepreneurship, in Handbook of revisited’, in R. Westwood and S. Clegg, eds.,
Entrepreneurship Research. Kluwer Publishers, Debating Organizing. Oxford: Blackwell,
pp. 179–210. pp. 210–19.
James, W. 1968. ‘The self’, in C. Gordon Lounsbury, M. and M.A. Glynn. 2001. ‘Cultural
and K. Gergen, eds., The Self in Social Inter- entrepreneurship: stories, legitimacy, and the
action, Vol. I. New York: John Wiley & Sons, acquisition of resources.’ Strategic
pp. 41–50. Management Journal, 22: 545–64.
Jepperson, R. 1991. ‘Institutions, institutional Lounsbury, M. and M.J. Ventresca, eds. 2002.
effects, and institutionalism’, in W.W. Powell Social structure and organizations revisited.
536 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Research in the Sociology of Organizations, construction of social agency.’ Sociological


19. JAI Press/Elsevier. Theory, 18: 100–20.
Luckmann, T. 1983. Life-World and Social Meyer, R.E. 2003. ‘Translating shareholder
Realities. London: Heinemann. value Frame alignment strategies and discur-
Luckmann, T. 2002. Wissen und Gesellschaft. sive opportunity structure’. Paper presented
Konstanz: Universitätsverlag. at 19th EGOS Colloquium, Copenhagen.
Luckmann, T. 2006a ‘Die kommunikative Meyer, R.E. 2004. Globale Managementkonzepte
Konstruktion der Wirklichkeit’, in D. Tänzler, und Lokaler Kontext. Wien: Facultas.
H. Knoblauch, and H.-G. Soeffner, eds., Neue Meyer, R.E., and G. Hammerschmid. 2006.
Perspektiven der Wissenssoziologie. Konstanz: ‘Changing institutional logics and executive
UVK, pp. 15–26. identities.’ American Behavioral Scientist, 49:
Luckmann, T. 2006b. Personal Identity as a 1000–14.
Sociological Category. http://www.hsd.hr/ Mills, C.W. 1940. ‘Situated actions and vocab-
docs/Luckmann-personal_identity.pdf. ularies of motive.’ American Sociological
Lukes, St. 1974. Power: A Radical View. Review, 5: 904–13.
London: Macmillan. Mutch, A., R. Delbridge, and M.J. Ventresca.
Lüders, C., and M. Meuser. 1997. 2006. ‘Situating organizational action: The
‘Deutungsmusteranalyse’, in R. Hitzler and relational sociology of organizations.’
A. Honer, eds., Sozialwissenschaftliche Organization, 13: 607–25.
Hermeneutik. Opladen: Leske+Budrich, Oakes, L.S., B. Townley, B. and D.J. Cooper.
pp. 57–79. 1998. ‘Business planning as pedagogy:
Lueger, M., K. Sandner, R. Meyer, and Language and control in a changing institu-
G. Hammerschmid. 2005. ‘Contextualizing tional field.’ Administrative Science
influence activities. An objective hermeneutical Quarterly, 43: 257–92.
approach.’ Organization Studies, 26: 1145–68. Oevermann, U. 1973. Zur Analyse der Struktur
Maines, D., and J. Charlton. 1985. ‘The von sozialen Deutungsmustern, Fragment,
negotiated order approach to the study of unpublished manuscript, Frankfurt/Main
social organization.’ Studies in Symbolic (www.objektivehermeneutik.de)
Interaction, Supplement 1, pp. 271–308. Oevermann, U. 2001. ‘Die Struktur sozialer
Mead, G.H. 1965. Mind, Self and Society. Deutungsmuster.’ Sozialersinn. Zeitschrift Für
Chicago: University of Chicago Press Hermeneutische Sozialforschung, 1: 35–81.
Meuser, M., and R. Sackmann. 1992. Oliver, C. 1991. ‘Strategic responses to institu-
‘Zur Einführung: Deutungsmusteransatz tional processes.’ Academy of Management
und empirische Wissenssoziologie’, in Review, 16: 145–79.
M. Meuser and R. Sackmann, eds., Analyse Orlikowski, W.J., and J. Yates. 1994. ‘Genre
Sozialer Deutungsmuster. Pfaffenweiler: repertoire: Examining the structuring of
Centaurus, pp. 9–37. communicative practices in organizations.’
Meyer, J.W., J. Boli, and G.M. Thomas. 1994. Administrative Science Quarterly, 39: 541–74.
‘Ontology and rationalization in the Western Perrow, C. 1985. ‘Review essay: Overboard
cultural account’, in W. R. Scott and with myth and symbols.’ American Journal
J. W. Meyer, eds., Institutional Environments of Sociology, 91: 151–5.
and Organizations. Thousand Oaks, CA: Phillips, N., T.B. Lawrence, and C. Hardy. 2004.
Sage, pp. 9–27. ‘Discourse and institutions.’ Academy of
Meyer, J.W., and B. Rowan. 1977. Management Review, 29: 635–52.
‘Institutionalized organizations: Formal struc- Powell, W.W., and P. DiMaggio, eds. 1991. The
ture as myth and ceremony.’ American New Institutionalism in Organizational Analy-
Journal of Sociology, 83: 340–63. sis. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Meyer, J.W. 2005. Weltkultur: Wie die Psathas, G.. 2004. ‘Alfred Schutz’s influence on
Westlichen Prinzipien die Welt Durchdringen. American sociologists and sociology.’ Human
Edited by G. Krücken. Frankfurt/Main: Studies, 27: 1–35.
Suhrkamp. Rao, H., G.M. Davis, and Andrew Ward. 2000.
Meyer, J.W., and R. Jepperson. 2000. ‘The ‘Embeddedness and social identity and
‘actors’ of modern society: The cultural mobility: Why organizations leave
NEW SOCIOLOGY OF KNOWLEDGE 537

NASDAQ and join the New York Stock Scott, M.B., and S.M. Lyman. 1968.
Exchange.’ Administrative Science Quarterly, ‘Accounts.’ American Sociological Review,
45: 268–92. 33: 46–62.
Rao, H, P. Monin, and R. Durand. 2003. Scott, M. B., and S.M. Lyman. 1970. ‘Accounts,
‘Institutional change in Toque Ville: Nouvelle deviance, and social order’, in
cuisine as an identity movement in French J. D. Douglas, ed., Deviance and
gastronomy.’ American Journal of Sociology, Respectability: The Social Construction of
108: 795–843. Moral Meanings. New York: Basic Books,
Reay, T., and C.R. (Bob) Hinings. 2005. ‘The pp. 89–119.
recomposition of an organizational field: Scott, W.R. 1994. ‘Conceptualizing organiza-
Health care in Alberta.’ Organization Studies, tional fields’, in H.-U. Derlien, U. Gerhardt
26: 351–84. and F.W. Scharpf, eds., Systemrationalität
Reichertz, J. 1999. ‘Über das Problem der und Partialinteresse. Baden–Baden: Nomos,
Gültigkeit von Qualitativer Sozialforschung’, in pp. 203–21.
R. Hitzler, J. Reichertz, and N. Schröer, eds., Scott, W.R. 2001. Institutions and Organiza-
Hermeneutische Wissenssoziologie, Konstanz: tions. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.
UVK, pp. 319–48. Shibutani, T. 1962. ‘Reference groups
Reichertz, J. 2004, September. ‘Das and social control’, in A.M. Rose, ed.,
Handlungsrepertoire von Gesellschaften Human Behavior and Social Processes: An
erweitern. Hans-Georg Soeffner im Interactionist Approach. London: Routledge
Gespräch mit Jo Reichertz.’ Forum: & Kegan Paul, pp. 128–47.
Qualitative Social Research, 5, 3: 29. Soeffner, H.-G. 1989. Auslegung des Alltags –
<www.qualitative-research.net/fqs-–texte/3- Der Alltag der Auslegung. Frankfurt/Main:
04/04-3-29-d.htm> [September 15, 2005]. Suhrkamp.
Sahlin–Andersson, K. 1996. ‘Imitating by edit- Soeffner, H.-G. 2004. ‘Social scientific
ing success: The construction of organiza- hermeneutics’, in U. Flick, E. von Kardoff,
tional fields’, in B. Czarniawska and and I. Steinke, eds., A Companion to
G. Sevón, eds., Translating Organizational Qualitative Research. London: Sage,
Change. Berlin, New York: de Gruyter, pp. 95–100.
pp. 69–92. Soeffner, H.-G. 2006. ‘Wissenssoziologie und
Sahlin–Andersson, K., and L. Engwall. 2002. sozialwissenschaftliche Hermeneutik sozialer
‘The dynamics of management knowledge Sinnwelten’, in D. Tänzler, H. Knoblauch,
expansion’, in K. Sahlin-Andersson, and and H.-G. Soeffner, eds., Neue Perspektiven
L. Engwall, (eds.), The Expansion of der Wissenssoziologie. Konstanz: UVK,
Management Knowledge. Stanford: Stanford pp. 51–78.
Univ. Press, pp. 277–96. Soeffner, H.-G., and R. Hitzler. 1994.
Schröer, N., ed. 1994. Interpretative ‘Hermeneutik als Haltung und Handlung’,
Sozialforschung. Opladen: Westdeutscher in N. Schröer, ed., Interpretative
Verlag. Sozialforschung. Opladen: Westdeutscher
Schütz, A. 1962. Collected Papers. Volume I: Verlag, pp. 28–54.
The Problem of Social Reality. The Hague: Strang, D., and J.W. Meyer. 1993. ‘Institutional
Nijhoff. conditions for diffusion.’ Theory and Society,
Schütz, A. 1967. The Phenomenology of the 22: 487–511.
Social World. Evanston: Northwestern Strauss, A. 1978. Negotiations: Varieties,
University Press. Processes, Contexts, and Social Order.
Schütz, A., and T. Luckmann. 1973. The San Francisco: Jossey-Bass.
Structures of the Life World. London: Suchman, M.C. 1995. ‘Managing legitimacy:
Heinemann. Strategic and institutional approaches.’
Schütze, Y. 1991. ‘Das Deutungsmuster Academy of Management Review, 20:
‘Mutterliebe’ im historischen Wandel’, in 571–611.
M. Meuser and R. Sackmann, eds., Analyse Suddaby, R., and R. Greenwood. 2005.
Sozialer Deutungsmuster. Pfaffenweiler: ‘Rhetorical strategies of legitimacy.’
Centaurus, pp. 39–48. Administrative Science Quarterly, 50: 35–67.
538 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Tänzler, D., H. Knoblauch, and H.-G. Soeffner. Westenholz, A. 2006. ‘Identity work and
2006a. ‘Neue Perspektiven der Wissensso- meaning arena.’ American Behavioral
ziologie’, in D. Tänzler, H. Knoblauch, and Scientist, 49: 1015–29.
H.-G. Soeffner, eds., Neue Perspektiven der Yates, J., and W.J. Orlikowski. 1992. ‘Genres of
Wissenssoziologie. Konstanz: UVK, pp. 7–14. organizational communication: A structura-
Thomas, W.I. 1967. ‘The definition of the situ- tional approach to studying communication
ation’, in J.G. Manis, and B.N. Meltzer, eds., and media.’ Academy of Management
Symbolic interaction. A Reader in Social Review, 17: 299–326.
Psychology. Boston: Allyn and Bacon, Zilber, T.B. 2002. ‘Institutionalization as an
pp. 315–21. interplay between actions, meanings, and
Tolbert, P.S., and L.G. Zucker. 1996. ‘The insti- actors: The case of a rape crisis centre in
tutionalization of institutional theory’, in Israel.’ Academy of Management Journal,
S.R. Clegg, C. Hardy, and W.R. Nord, (eds.), 45: 234–54.
Handbook of Organization Studies. London: Zilber, T.B. 2006. ‘The work of the symbolic
Sage, pp. 175–90. in institutional processes: Translations
Walgenbach, P. and R.E. Meyer. 2008. of rational myths in Israeli hi–tech.’ Academy
Neoinstitutionalistische Organisationstheorie. of Management Journal, 49: 279–301.
Stuttgart: Kohlhammer. Zucker, L.G. 1977. ‘The role of institutionaliza-
Weber, K., and M.A.Glynn. 2006. ‘Making tion in cultural persistence.’ American
sense with institutions: Context, thought Sociological Review, 42, 5: 726–43.
and action in Carl Weick’s theory.’
Organization Studies, 27: 1639–1660.
22
Systems Theory, Societal
Contexts, and Organizational
Heterogeneity
Raimund Hasse and Georg Krücken

INTRODUCTION the role attributed to organizational agency.


Nevertheless, they both lead to an overem-
From the outset, attention to the embedded- phasis on homogeneity and convergence,
ness of organizations in wider societal con- triggered by world societal forces or by
texts has been a trademark of the new those forces operating within an organiza-
institutionalism in organizational analysis. tional field. As organizational research has
Different strands of neo-institutional analy- increasingly begun to question this overem-
sis converge in continuing this Weberian phasis and to allow for more heterogeneity
approach to the study of organizations by and variety, more and more neo-institu-
focusing on the co-evolution of organiza- tional scholars have looked for conceptual
tions and their societal environments. This remedies against this bias. The concept of
general point of departure is shared by the institutional entrepreneur seems to play
both the macro-sociological and the a crucial role here, as it helps explain why
inter-organizational perspectives on organi- organizations which operate under the same
zations. The former, which has been elabo- circumstances do not always become simi-
rated by John Meyer and his students, lar. By focusing on the micro-level of indi-
assumes that organizations are shaped by vidual actors, however, the basic feature of
the broader social and cultural forces of a the new institutionalism in organizational
global society. The latter, which has analysis, i.e., the analysis of interrelations
become most prominent in the concept of between organizations and their broader
organizational fields, sees organizational societal environments, becomes less pro-
behavior as intimately bound to other organ- nounced. We clearly see both the necessity
izations in their field. Both approaches of allowing for more heterogeneity and vari-
differ with regard to many aspects, most ety in neo-institutional research and the con-
notably the level of abstraction and ceptual problems revolving around analyses
540 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

highlighting the role of institutional entre- To point out precisely this characteristic of his
preneurs. Therefore, we would like to pres- theory, an American collection of some of his
ent a macro-sociological alternative to the articles appeared under the title The
currently debated micro-level approach to Differentiation of Society (1982). In addition,
heterogeneity and variety. and in contrast to Bourdieu and Giddens,
In contemporary European macro-socio- from his early writings up to his later work
logical theories, the argument that modern Luhmann has also been an organizational
society can only be perceived as being com- sociologist (Luhmann 1964, 2000). According
posed of different, at times conflicting to Luhmann, modern society can only be fully
spheres, and not as a homogeneous set of understood when taking into account the
principles is well established. Pierre expansion of formal organizations – in all
Bourdieu has distinguished between different societal systems over time and on a global
societal fields (for example, economy, educa- scale (see Hasse/Krücken 2005b).2
tion, arts, mass media, and politics). Albeit We would like to develop our argument in
these fields may both overlap and be four steps. First, we will reconstruct both the
composed of diverse subfields, they are macro-perspective and the field approach in
characterized by distinct norms, values, and neo-institutionalism. According to our analy-
rationalities. Bourdieu’s fields are conceptu- sis, they both lead to a similar overemphasis
alized as arenas for competition whose ‘rules on homogeneity. Only in this context can the
of the game’ can be modified by powerful search for concepts allowing for heterogene-
actors. It is important to notice, however, that ity and variety be understood. As we will see
success in one field cannot easily be trans- at the end of part 1, the neo-institutional
lated into other fields. In his much cited book figure of the institutional entrepreneur could
Distinction: A Social Critique of the be seen as a result of that search process.
Judgment of Taste (Bourdieu 1984), these Second, we will reconstruct Luhmann’s per-
limits to convertibility become obvious as spective on society with its strong emphasis
Bourdieu delineates cultural barriers to the on differences between societal systems. As
new rich, whose possession of economic we will argue, from this perspective modern
capital does not lead to a similarly developed society can only be reconstructed as a multi-
distinction of taste. Not unlike Bourdieu, dimensional project. This orientation could
Anthony Giddens (1984) has distinguished counterbalance both the bias towards
between different social institutions based on convergence inherent in neo-institutional
their modularities of structuration. Specific analysis and the recent emphasis on institu-
combinations of rules and resources consti- tional entrepreneurs. Third, and in order to
tute political, economic, legal and other fully grasp the interrelatedness of societal
institutional domains on the societal macro- and organizational trajectories in Luhmann’s
level. Though Bourdieu and Giddens could work, we will discuss the basic tenets of his
be of great help in developing a theoretical contributions to organizational sociology.
perspective for organizational institutional- In the fourth part, we will then demonstrate
ism, in which differences, not homogeneity that Luhmann’s macro-perspective can offer
on the societal level are highlighted, we will insights into societal differentiation, which
focus on Niklas Luhmann’s systems theory are also valuable for the concrete analysis of
for this purpose.1 Luhmann has placed a organizations in society. With the help of two
much greater emphasis than the other authors examples we will exemplify the similarities
on the fact that modern society is defined and differences between the macro-
through autonomous, functionally differenti- sociological perspective in the new institu-
ated societal systems (economics, science, tionalism and Luhmann’s systems theory. In
politics, religion etc.), which follow a very the concluding section we will briefly
distinct logic (Luhmann 1995, 1997). discuss the implications of our analysis.
SYSTEMS THEORY, SOCIETAL CONTEXTS, AND ORGANIZATIONAL HETEROGENEITY 541

within nation-states. Against this perspective,


THE NEW INSTITUTIONALISM: Meyer et al. (1997) argue that organizations
HOMOGENIZING FORCES IN SOCIETY are considered to be shaped by their wider
AND ORGANIZATIONAL FIELDS socio-cultural environment.
Though Boli and Thomas (1997) have put
The macro-perspective: global more emphasis on the effects of organiza-
diffusion processes and the tions, they take a similar view. Their main
argument is that organizations of a specific
rationalization of society
type – international ones of the third sector
The macro-sociological strand of the new (i.e., non-governmental and non-profit) –
institutionalism has been elaborated mainly serve as agents of world culture. The norms
by John Meyer over the last thirty years and cognitive schemes of the latter, then, are
(Krücken/Drori 2008). He assumes that supposed to profoundly affect any modern
modern society is not a concrete and hard- state and organizations of all types. The legit-
wired structure composed of actors. It is imacy and power of international organiza-
rather a broader and imagined cultural tions, so the argument goes, stems from their
system, in which the main cultural patterns status as institutions which are driven by uni-
of Western society – like universalism, versal ideals instead of utilitarian interests.3
progress, and equality – are embedded. This As in the case of Meyer et al. (1997), the
cultural system is inherently globalizing. The authors identify a cause/effect-relationship
driving forces of societal development are, between states, organizations, and individu-
therefore, not actors and interests as typically als on the one hand and a broader global cul-
assumed. The causality is not ‘bottom up,’ ture and its organizational representatives on
but rather ‘top down.’ Society as the embod- the other. According to this perspective, the
iment of broader cultural norms constitutes former is the outcome of the latter. In addi-
its actors. With its strong phenomenological tion, even the most influential organizations
and ‘culturalist’ emphasis, the macro-per- are seen as carriers of broader cultural
spective in neo-institutional research is a norms, enacting and enforcing them, but not
strong antidote against all kinds of realist, as independent actors in society.
individualistic and actor-centered social the- This macro-perspective on the relation
ories currently prevailing in American soci- between society and organizations has led to
ology (Jepperson 2002; Krücken 2002). one of the most fascinating contemporary
According to Meyer, the cultural system research programs in sociology, which has
of society constitutes three types of modern been highly influential for the development
actors: nation-states, organizations, and of organizational institutionalism. Over the
individuals. Though organizations are of last thirty years Meyer’s approach has proved
paramount importance in Meyer’s macro- its originality and fruitfulness when address-
sociological institutionalism, from the per- ing the global diffusion of cultural and struc-
spective of organizational research it is tural features of Western society, which
striking that they mainly have the status of a cross-cut different regions and sectors of
dependent variable in this theory context. world society. In this, the spread of formal
The cultural shaping of organizations is organizations, which are the central embodi-
mostly emphasized in Meyer et al. (1997). ment of these features, figures most promi-
Here, the authors criticize dominant interpre- nently (for a most recent and systematic
tations of globalization in which (a) global- account see Drori/Meyer/Hwang 2006).
ization processes are interpreted as an The neo-institutional approach of Meyer and
aggregate effect of state activities, and his students has also proved its innovative
(b) state activities are considered as an out- character by exploring new lines of theoreti-
come of individual and organizational action cal and empirical research. Closer links to
542 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

other research traditions have been looked single organization); and any organization
for, like, for example, social movements was considered to be embedded in a distinct
research (Khagram/Riker/Sikkink 2002; setting of organizations (Greenwood/
Tsutsui 2004). Furthermore, the more recent Hinnings 1996: 1026–7). DiMaggio and
focus on science in the ongoing rationaliza- Powell’s well-known ‘three pillars of
tion of society (Drori/Meyer/Ramirez/ isomorphism’ (Scott 2001) thus can be used
Schofer 2003) and theoretical reflections on to classify the shaping of organizations by
the constitution of individual actorhood in other organizations: Coercion results from
modern society (Meyer/Jepperson 2000; regulatory agencies (predominantly state
Frank/Meyer 2002) have opened up whole organizations); normative isomorphism is
new lines of investigation and made similari- based upon professional associations,
ties to other ways of theorizing visible, consulting firms and educational institutions;
which have hardly been explored yet.4 and mimicry stems from the ongoing
Nevertheless, and this point is central for the observation of peers, competitors and
argument we will develop here, the macro- collaborators.
approach in neo-institutional research does DiMaggio/Powell’s (1983) notion of orga-
not systematically account for heterogeneity nizational fields has expanded the scope of
and differences in society. Despite all theo- organizational analysis profoundly. For the
retical developments and refinements the argument to be developed here it is most cru-
approach has undergone over the last thirty cial to note that the concept of organizational
years, the underlying assumptions on fields and its focus on isomorphism within
homogenizing forces in global society have fields has, implicitly, offered an understand-
remained stable und unchanged. Even critics ing for persistent differences between fields.
who generally sympathize with that approach To the extent to which organizations are
point to the inherent limitations of its shaped by other significant organizations
overemphasis on homogeneity and conver- (such as state organizations, regulatory agen-
gence (for a most comprehensive critique see cies, professional associations, consultants,
Schneiberg/Clemens 2006). competitors and collaborators), they are
exposed to rather specific influences. It thus
may be concluded that organizations differ
The meso-perspective: from inter- according to their field membership which,
for example, results from their embedded-
organizational relations to
ness in national regimes (Orrù/Woolsey/
institutional entrepreneurship
Biggart/Hamilton 1991; Dobbin 1994).
DiMaggio/Powell (1983) have offered a Assumptions regarding the differentiation
starting point, which is different from the of organized contexts also can be found in
macro-perspective discussed above. Their other contributions from the founding phase
contribution does not refer to an all- of the new institutionalism. Scott (1983)
encompassing world culture or to other kinds distinguished between two sectors – techni-
of broader societal contexts. Instead, cal and institutional – and argued that a focal
DiMaggio/Powell considered organizations organization is embedded in either a techni-
as being deeply shaped by those other organ- cal or an institutional environment. This
izations which serve as ‘significant others’ in assumption soon was replaced by the insight
the sense of Berger/Luckmann (1967). that most organizations have to deal with
Conceptually, organizational and inter- both technical and institutional requirements
organizational parameters gained status as (Hasse/Krücken 2005a: 33–4). Additionally,
independent variables, and in this respect the it seemed that such a distinction was too rigid
perspective has been meso-sociological. The to account for differences within these
basic units were organizational fields (not a two sectors. Scott and Meyer (1991) thus
SYSTEMS THEORY, SOCIETAL CONTEXTS, AND ORGANIZATIONAL HETEROGENEITY 543

developed a more differentiated concept of ‘network’) because this shift implies that a
societal sectors. Sectors were conceptualized focal organization appears to be an integral
as functional domains which are composed part of its institutional setting.5
of diverse organizations as well as correspon- Two basic questions emerge from this per-
ding non-organizational features such as spective: (1) What determines whether or not
meaning and belief systems or governance organizations can be successful in actively
structures and other ‘rules of the game.’ In a intervening into their context, and (2) what
similar vein, Scott (1991) has emphasized determines how organizations may use their
characteristic features of organizational potential for active intervention? In order to
fields. Not unlike DiMaggio/Powell (1983), deal with these questions, it should be noted
organizations appear to be deeply influenced that neo-institutionalists ever since have
by ‘their’ field – and to a much lesser extent described the constitution of fields and the
by an all-encompassing world culture. socialization of single organizations as an
To summarize, the field approach is char- open and ongoing process. In this respect,
acterized by the assumption that organiza- references were made to the social construc-
tional fields mediate between a single tivism of Berger and Luckmann (1967)
organization and broader societal contexts. (DiMaggio/Powell 1983; Meyer 1992). The
The implication of such a conceptualization legacy of this theory also has sensitized the
is that global impacts tend to be devaluated potential of organizations to active handling
because such impacts need to be enacted by of institutional constraints. Accordingly, the
field-specific institutions. Such an under- processing of environmental constraints is
standing of organizational fields fits nicely to open for variation, and this deeply affects the
observations of robust differences because reproduction of the institutional context.
isomorphism within fields corresponds with Fligstein (1996), for example, even has
diversity among organizational fields. It thus described organizational fields as political
can be argued that clusters of interacting arenas – arguing that there are striking
organizations can be considered as imbalances of power at work (see also
institutional barriers against homogenizing Greenwood et al. 2002). While some organi-
trends on a global scale. zations may experience their field context as
Based on the organizational fields- being out of control, others may be in a
approach some new institutionalists have position that allows for an institutional engi-
argued from the 1990s onwards that, to a cer- neering of fields.
tain extent, organizations can also actively The idea of organizations being actively
intervene in their contexts. This implies a involved in their context does not just imply
farewell to sharply distinguishing between imbalances of power. It also raises questions
environmental causes and corresponding about how organizations may utilize their
effects on a focal organization. Instead, the potential and to what extent they handle
notion of organizational fields highlights issues of power strategically. These questions
processes of mutual adaptation. As compared have led to a rediscovery of purposive agen-
with the top down-perspective of the macro- cies, being conceptualized as something
sociological approach, organizations are thus which is not covered by institutional factors
considered to be more actively involved in (Beckert 1999). The concept of agency, how-
the overall development of society. ever, is not taken from economic approaches
According to this perspective, organizations such as rational choice or principal/agency-
negotiate with other organizations and they theory. Instead, new institutionalists have
may also try to actively manipulate those incorporated insights from those theories of
organizations and other institutional factors. practice which have been developed in late
Analytically, the crucial shift is from 20th-century European sociology (Bourdieu
‘environment’ to ‘context’ (respectively 1977, 1990; Giddens 1984; Joas 1996).
544 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Agency, then, includes the potential for (Lounsbury 2005: 30). From the latter point
actively making choices and for reflexive of view, this discourse has attracted a great
self-monitoring, but it is not assumed that bulk of attention, because it offers an expla-
decisions and actions are determined by nation for the dynamic character of institu-
fixed preferences (cf. Feldman/Pentland tional contexts (Greenwood/Hinnings 1996).
2003: 95–6; Child 1997). There is also the potential to end quasi-
Institutions, from this perspective, may paradigmatic disputes with old institutional-
constrain or enable to act in accordance with ists, with institutional economics and with
given interests, and they may thus become those social theories which put more empha-
objects of strategic modifications. However, sis on voluntary action and rational decision
it is not just organizations (and, of course, making (Blom-Hansen 1997; Abbell 1995).
not heroic individuals) which can serve as Finally, there are profound non-academic con-
‘institutional entrepreneurs’ (Thornton 1999; siderations which support the emphasis on
Greenwood et al. 2002). Instead, professions, active entrepreneurship, because, as compared
standard setters (Hwang/Powell 2005) and to macro-sociological top down-explanations
social movements (Rao/Monin/Durand the focus on institutional entrepreneurs
2003) can get involved in the engineering of offers better perspectives for decision makers
institutions. As a consequence, institutions and consultants (Sahlin-Andersson/Engvall
can be considered as the outcome of a broad 2002). One may thus expect a high degree of
array of institutional entrepreneurship cultural legitimacy and support for develop-
(DiMaggio 1988) – either because actors are ing such a perspective – and, ironically,
supposed ‘to escape the determining power this is quite in line with basic insights of
of institutions … [or because of] … multiple the macro-sociological approach in neo-
institutional referents that overlap and con- institutionalism (see Hwang/Powell 2005: 182
flict’ (Dorado 2005: 385). This requires for the same argument).
that institutional forces have to be While such pragmatic reasons for bringing
handled actively (Barley/Tolbert 1997; actors back in have been discussed broadly, a
Friedland/Alford 1991). In any case, the more critical reflection of the theoretical
issue of institutional entrepreneurship has led impact of putting interests and entrepreneur-
to a rediscovery of agency (Emirbayer/ ship at center stage has been neglected. In
Mische 1998). It has let researchers deal with order to compensate for this one-sidedness it
the entire range of cognitive, social and needs to be taken into consideration that the
material resources which are needed for suc- outlined trend affects the aspiration to
cessful interventions in the institutional setup explain what otherwise most often is taken
(Rao 1998; Lounsbury 2001), and it has led for granted – i.e., rational action and our
to the identification of contingency factors understanding thereof. In some cases, the
which determine the opportunity structures focus on institutional entrepreneurs has led to
to do so (Seo/Creed 2002).6 a reversal of the traditional neo-institutional
Due to the theoretical significance of perspective because actors’ preferences and
entrepreneurship it comes as no surprise that their choices are assumed to explain institu-
new institutionalists debate the issue contro- tional structures. The advantage of such a
versially. While some ‘stress at the outset perspective seems to be that one can more
that an institutional perspective is more “con- easily focus on issues of variation and
structivist” than “agentic” ’ (Hwang/Powell differentiation – the Achilles heel in both the
2005: 180), others argue that ‘the discourse macro-approach (‘global society’) and the
of institutional entrepreneurship has helped organizational meso-perspective (‘institu-
to usefully redirect neoinstitutional analyses tional isomorphism’) in neo-institutional the-
towards the study of actors and their orizing. The disadvantage, however, is that
role in catalyzing institutional change’ the quest for less situational and for other
SYSTEMS THEORY, SOCIETAL CONTEXTS, AND ORGANIZATIONAL HETEROGENEITY 545

than actor-based causes of persistent differ- unique in combining a grand historical per-
ences tends to be neglected. In particular, this spective with an in-depth analysis of domi-
applies to causes which might be inscribed nant features of contemporary society.7 At its
in the social structure of modern society – core one can find a scheme that outlines the
and which are experienced as external social evolution of human society from the begin-
realities. ning onwards. In this respect, there are some
We assume that the quest for such causes resemblances with Durkheim’s remarks on
is less developed because the institutional simple forms of social life as the starting
context programmatically has been equated point (Durkheim 1933). When it comes to
either with a uniform and homogenizing Luhmann’s reflection on more recent forms
world culture or with homogeneous institu- of societal evolution, one may also identify
tional configurations at the field level. Both similarities with another founding father of
world culture-explanations at the macro- social theory: Max Weber. Not unlike Weber
level and field-concepts of isomorphism at (1958), Luhmann refers to a unique set of cir-
the meso-level did not allow for an explana- cumstances in the Western world which trig-
tion of persistent differences, be they at the gered the take off of modernity.
level of society or within organizational In a broad socio-historical perspective,
fields. In order to emphasize differences and Luhmann has stressed that sophisticated
heterogeneity, for many neo-institutional forms of societal stratification emerged
researchers there appeared to be no alterna- before the advent of modernity, particularly
tive to referring to the micro-level and to in ancient high cultures, as for example in
bring purposive actors and their interests China, Egypt, Greece, and India (Luhmann
and strategies back in. In what follows 1982, 1997). Here, the differentiation is
we will present an alternative explanation strictly vertical, and societal order is struc-
by referring to Luhmann’s systems theory. tured in a clear-cut and hierarchical way.
It is based on a concept of social structure Characteristic features of stratified societies
which is more sensitive to differences – can be illustrated with respect to the tradi-
and which considers such differences to tional caste system in India. First, there are
be deeply inscribed into the macro-structure strict rules which affect every facet of social
of modern society. Our brief account of life. Second, mobility via economic achieve-
the basic tenets is structured around ment or via marriage is restricted. Third,
issues of modern society’s internally hierarchy is legitimized by religion. As a
differentiated character, and the role consequence, status differences and positions
organizations play in that macro-sociological in the societal strata are experienced as des-
approach. tiny, and no legitimate alternative form of
social order is taken into consideration.
Historically, the disappearance of vertical
stratification as the main principle of societal
LUHMANN’S SYSTEMS differentiation was triggered by challenging
THEORY: MODERN SOCIETY, the status of religion as an authority that
DIFFERENTIATION, determines social life in general. This process
AND ORGANIZATIONS began in Europe in the 16th century, when
politics began to claim autonomy from reli-
Modern society as a differentiated gion. At the end of this process, a political
order was to be found, which no longer was
and multidimensional project
subordinated to any other order. Since then,
Luhmann’s theory of social systems is one of politics can be described as a distinct field
the most comprehensive projects in social which follows an inner logic that is independ-
theory of the 20th century. The approach is ent of religious and other authorities.
546 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Likewise, the birth of the modern distinct societal systems with characteristic
sciences is marked by their emancipation rationalities that cannot be subordinated to
from religious beliefs and wider social norms. the logic of other systems. Furthermore, the
In comparison with its ancestors, which were historical appearance of other societal sys-
embedded in guilds and monasteries, science tems has been described. Among them are
defined itself as an enterprise which is based the nuclear family and the ideal of romantic
on the rigorous observation of facts. Since love, which both are no longer primarily
then, social conditions, such as political regu- based upon political or economic or any
lation or religious dogma, may constrain or other external reference. In a similar vein, the
support scientific research, but they do no emergence of an art system, of mass media
longer directly affect the direction of scien- and of sports, has been described as a histor-
tific progress. Luhmann has thus stressed that ical process. The fundamental characteristic
the sciences have matured to an autonomous of any such system is that it is based on a
sphere of modern society, just as politics. distinct logic, which implies that it develops
A similar development could be observed specific criteria for success. As a conse-
with regard to the economy. In this respect, quence, what is politically feasible may not
Luhmann’s contribution is in line with be true according to scientific standards; real
Max Weber (1968), Karl Polanyi (1944), love cannot be affected by economic consid-
Jürgen Habermas (1985/1989), Anthony erations, and arts are not necessarily in line
Giddens (1984), and many others. The with religion.
common ground of these sociologists is to Analytically, Luhmann has argued that
assume that economic relations, which most societal systems, which came into
traditionally used to be embedded in wider being with the turn towards the functional
social bonds, are increasingly characterized differentiation of society, are based on a
by the specific logic and rationality of the binary scheme of information processing
economic field. (i.e., 0 or 1, plus or minus, yes or no). Binary
The economy may serve as the paradig- codes are all-encompassing constructions as
matic case for the emergence and lock-in of they allow everything that happens in society
specific rationalities. It neither can be to be processed by assigning one value or the
derived from wider frames of non-economic other. As everything can be processed
criteria nor can it be reduced to the motives according to the binary coding of informa-
and preferences of individual actors. While tion, societal systems actively scan their
this basic idea was already at the heart of environments for opportunities to apply their
Karl Marx’s analysis, Luhmann expands it to codes. The technical advantage of such a
a more general statement on the horizontal mode of information processing is its reduc-
differentiation of society. That type of socie- tionism: Any information is either ‘0’ or ‘1.’
tal differentiation, which has substituted ver- For example, the application of the binary
tical stratification as the dominant mode of code ‘true’ or ‘false’ is assumed to be at the
differentiation, is called ‘functional differen- core of science. Science can thus be defined
tiation’ as societal systems are considered to as that specific form of information process-
fulfil functions that cannot be substituted by ing which strictly refers to whether or not
other systems.8 The economy as a societal or something is considered as true or false.
functional system regulates the production Binary coding not only allows for the expan-
and distribution of scarce products and serv- sion of the system. It also safeguards against
ices; science generates new knowledge; and the claims of other systems. Monetary pay-
the political system is unique in producing ments, for example, are an important prereq-
collectively binding decisions which affect uisite for science. A direct interference with
the entire society. From this point of view, the code of scientific truth and falsity, how-
both politics and science, for example, are ever, is labelled as a scandalous distortion.
SYSTEMS THEORY, SOCIETAL CONTEXTS, AND ORGANIZATIONAL HETEROGENEITY 547

The same logic is to be found in other sys- are schemes which serve as providers of
tems as well. In the economy, monetary information about what to select and how to
transactions are related to each other. The present what has been selected; in sports
code is ‘payment’ versus ‘non-payment,’ and there are plenty of regulations which limit
the economic system can only be activated to and specify competition. Combining the
the extent to which this code can be applied. selectivity and robustness of binary informa-
In a similar vein, the political system is about tion processing with the openness and
the power to make collectively binding deci- flexibility of programs has provided societal
sions, and the code is ‘power’ vs. ‘lack of systems with a degree of complexity which
power.’ The legal system strictly distin- historically was never experienced before.
guishes between ‘legal’ and ‘illegal,’ regard- The consequence is unprecedented growth:
less of material effects and issues of social Today, there is more science than ever;
norms; mass media are about attracting the politics is more all-encompassing and regu-
attention of the public according to what is lates many facets of society; legal issues can
regarded as newsworthy or not; and sports be related to almost anything, economic
are based on the code ‘winning vs. losing.’ activities have exploded, etc.
To summarize, most systems on the Societal dynamics, however, are not
macro-level of society represent a specific limited to the dynamics of its individual
and highly reductionist binary logic of systems. Any societal system is dependent on
information processing, and concerns rele- the contributions of other systems, and
vant for other systems or overall societal modern society is characterized by an
norms have to be transformed according to extraordinary high degree of mutual depend-
that very logic. ency. The economy, for example, is in perma-
Coded information processing provides nent need of scientific knowledge in order to
societal systems with an identity which be innovative; it is dependent on legal norms,
distinguishes them from each other. This in particular with respect to property rights; it
identity is not open for change. But these needs mass media in order to attract attention
systems are not only based on codes, but also (via advertisement and product placement);
on programs that, by contrast, can and do and it is in need for political decision making
change. Programs provide societal systems and implementation, for example in order to
with information on how the code is to be regulate competition or with respect to anti-
applied. According to Luhmann, the dynamic trust norms. Without such outputs of other
character of societal systems is thus inscribed systems, the economy would be substantially
into the variation of their programs. In order less efficient. Vice versa, the same holds true
to illustrate the dynamics of systems, one for other systems, all of which are dependent
may again refer to science. There is the state on economic and other outputs. Due to the
of the art of a research field, there are high degree of mutual dependency, a crisis in
modifications with respect to theories and any system may negatively affect other
accepted research methods, and there is vari- systems. Societal evolution is thus described
ation of research agendas – all of which indi- as a risky enterprise. As Luhmann has shown
cate how the scientific code is to be applied. in particular in his work on risk and the envi-
Likewise, economic rationality can only be ronment (Luhmann 1989, 1993) as well as in
applied to the extent to which scarcity, his Observations on Modernity (Luhmann
demand and corresponding price signalling 1998), the polycentric and highly interrelated
can be identified; in politics there are character of modern society is both a strength
thematic issues, agendas, and political pro- and a permanent source of vulnerability of
grams; the legal system is based on legal modern society.
norms as inscribed into constitutional law Compared with the macro-sociological
and into court decisions; in mass media there perspective in neo-institutional theory, it is
548 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

obvious that Luhmann’s perspective empha- and it stimulates the further spread of organ-
sizes the multidimensional and internally dif- izations which, again, allow for further
ferentiated character of modern society. The differentiation. This process of mutual self-
basic argument is that neither a hierarchical, enforcement begins with the institutionaliza-
stratified order nor a clearly identifiable tion of guilds and crafts, and it is later related
center remains after the advent of modernity. to religious organizations, scientific associa-
In the polycentric society as described by tions, business enterprises, political parties
Luhmann, no unifying system or common and so forth. The19th century is crucial for
coordinating principle exists. Neither reli- the spread of the organizational form, when
gion nor politics, neither science nor the club membership of very diverse sorts gained
economy determine modern society as a status as an integral part of a modern
whole. From this perspective, societal inte- life style.9
gration or homogenization on the basis of Today, most societal systems are repre-
universal norms and cultural principles sented by specific organizations, and, vice
cannot be achieved. Instead, modern society versa, most organizations are related to a
is shaped by very distinct societal logics and societal system. For organizations, this
their interrelatedness. Before we compare implies copying and reproducing those forms
basic tenets of both macro-approaches with of rationality which are represented by the
the help of two examples, we will focus on codes of the system in which they are embed-
Luhmann’s organizational theory. ded. The business firm, for example, is char-
acterized by subordinating any of its diverse
activities under monetary aspects, i.e., issues
of payments. Likewise, political parties and
Bringing organizations back in
their candidates strive for positions of
In Luhmann’s grand theory of societal evolu- political power; scientific institutions and
tion organizations are of pivotal importance universities aim at the discovery of truths,
as societal macro-structures and organiza- sports clubs aim at being champions, pub-
tions co-evolve. Historically, organizations lishing houses and TV stations try to gain the
emerged in ancient high cultures which were attention of a mass audience, and so forth.
characterized by the prevalence of a hierar- Exceptionally, organizations may alter their
chical and stratified societal order. However, primary orientation. For example, a research
due to shortcomings in the social precondi- institute may transform itself into an
tions of these societies – literacy, money economic organization. Additionally, a few
economy, and technologies of accounting organizations may not be strictly related to
were still not given on a larger scale – the exactly one systemic logic (for example,
diffusion of organizations was rather private hospitals), and there are still organi-
restricted both geographically (close to the zations which cannot be related to any
leaders in the centers) and functionally societal system at all (for example, leisure
(public administration and larger military clubs). Nevertheless, most organizations in
and construction projects). While this con- society strictly accept one societal system
stellation remained rather stable for a long and its binary code as their main frame of
time, the transition from stratified to func- reference.
tionally differentiated societies witnessed the Organization research has found profound
spread of formal organizations. Luhmann has evidence for the fact that organizations tend
described this initial phase of modernity as a to grow. It has also been shown that growth
co-evolutionary process of functional dif- and increasing complexity are parameters
ferentiation and organization building. which stimulate organizational differentia-
According to this interpretation, functional tion. According to Luhmann’s systems
differentiation requires formal organizations, theory, these processes strikingly reflect the
SYSTEMS THEORY, SOCIETAL CONTEXTS, AND ORGANIZATIONAL HETEROGENEITY 549

functional differentiation of society. Many into research issues. Because something sim-
organizations, for example, have established ilar may be said with respect to all other
research departments, some of them have set types of organizations and with respect to
up offices that deal with legal issues, large references to any societal system, heteroge-
organizations often engage in political lobby- neous inter-organizational relations have the
ing, economic criteria have to be considered potential of mediating between different
by organizations of all kinds, and deviance social spheres and rationalities.
from legal norms can seriously threaten any
organization. Organizations thus differentiate
themselves into departments or offices that
concentrate on economic issues, legal norms, ACCOUNTING FOR
research, and so on. A major task for man- HETEROGENEITY: TWO EXAMPLES
agement then is to adjust such diverse ration-
alities to the identity of an organization, In the following section we will briefly dis-
which, as we pointed out before, is defined cuss the implications of Luhmann’s systems
through the specific rationality of the societal theory for the analysis of two general topics,
system in which the organization is embed- which also figure prominently in neo-
ded. To some extent, systems theory would institutional research: the expansion and
thus support the basic idea of the new institu- transformation of the modern welfare state
tionalism that organizations are well advised and recent trends towards academic entrepre-
to copy the prevailing norms of their wider neurship. Both examples show the fruitful-
societal context. In contrast to the new insti- ness of a theoretical perspective, which
tutionalism, however, systems theory would assumes that the sources of societal and
stress that these norms are copied only to the organizational heterogeneity are to be found
extent that they support the realization of at the macro-level of society. Against
ends which constitute the specific identity of the backdrop of the macro-approach in
an organization as a business firm, as a neo-institutional theory, we will argue that
research institute, or as a political party, for the trajectories of the welfare state do not
example. necessarily follow the enactment of broader
From the perspective of Luhmann’s societal norms, but rather the distinct inner
macro-sociological approach, organizations logic and dynamics of the political system of
are not just crucial for the reproduction of the society and its organizations. In our second
differentiation of society into distinct societal example we will focus on an issue which
systems. They may also compensate for the involves different societal systems, hence
sharp differences in the logic of societal triggering inter-organizational collaboration.
systems because organizations of any type Instead of assuming homogenizing forces
are able to interact with each other which lead to the evaporation of institutional
(Hasse/Krücken 2005b: 189–190). While boundaries, from the perspective of sociolog-
economic and scientific rationalities, for ical systems theory distinct logics of
example, cannot be synthesized at the information processing and related identity
macro-level of society, which is character- concepts prevail.
ized by very different societal systems,
economic and scientific organizations quite
frequently set up inter-organizational rela- The expansion and
tions. Depending on their absorptive capa- transformation of the
city, economic organizations can deal with
modern welfare state
research issues, they can collaborate with
academic partners, and they may translate The modern welfare state seems to be a good
and re-translate economic considerations example for pointing out similarities and
550 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

differences between the macro-approach in (Strang/Chang 1993; Meyer 2007). They


neo-institutional theory and sociological sys- have to adhere to broader societal norms of
tems theory. Both converge on highlighting justice and progress and enact related scripts
the relevance of the welfare state for the of social policy in order to be regarded as a
understanding of modern society. But while legitimate actor in society. Global standards
for Meyer the development is driven by the of social policy were codified by the UN
diffusion of general societal norms, Declaration of Human Rights in 1948. Since
Luhmann emphasizes the specific rationality then, international authorities such as the
of the political system as its driving-force. UNESCO, the International Labor
From the macro-perspective both Organization (ILO) and others address wel-
approaches take, welfare state dynamics fare issues to any modern nation-state
cannot be grasped by a comparative perspec- (Marshall 1981). Additionally, welfare state
tive, which emphasizes national differences issues are tackled by scientific experts and
and different types of modern welfare states. social movements, both of which are organ-
From the comparative perspective, which has ized in international associations and net-
been most convincingly elaborated by works. It thus may be concluded that these
Esping-Anderson (1990), specific institu- institutions develop a standardized frame of
tional configurations and power relations on reference, and any state risks its social legiti-
the one hand and varying functional require- macy if it tends to ignore these contextual
ments on the other hand are of central parameters. The driving-forces of the expan-
importance here. As a consequence, many sion of the welfare state are to be found at
parameters have to be taken into account as the level of societal macro-structures,
potential determinants of welfare state i.e., broader societal norms which mainly
dynamics like the degree of industrialization, diffuse through international organizations.
family structures and demographic trends, Different degrees of exposure to the world
economic growth and prosperity, as well as culture and its internationally organized
unionization and the strength of social agents, as well as differences of power
democrats. between those institutions which are not in
From both a neo-institutionalist and a sys- accordance with global cultural scripts, may
tems theory perspective, it is striking that account for differences among nation-states.
comparative welfare state researchers mainly A similar perspective may be applied
refer to national differences and functional when it comes to the transformation of the
requirements. In contrast, both macro- welfare state which has been taking place
approaches focus on causes which can since the 1980s.10 Historical data give
neither be limited to individual nation-states evidence of a rather uniform expansion of
nor to functional requirements of societal welfare state-expenditures until the end of
reproduction. the 1970s (Flora 1986). Since then, however,
Following the neo-institutional approach the development seems to be more contin-
by John W. Meyer and others one rather gent. On the one hand, there are factors
stresses the embeddedness of modern nation- which forcefully support the extrapolation of
states in a global society (McNeely 1995; this trend. On the other hand, serious concern
Meyer et al. 1997). The emphasis is clearly about the sustainability of such a dynamic
on the significance of a global culture and its gained wide attention. As a consequence,
representation by international organizations, substantial changes have been observed – in
and the impact of other welfare states as some cases materializing as sudden quasi-
models or at least as significant others is cen- paradigmatic shifts (Sweden at the end of the
tral (Hasse 2003). From this point of view, 1980s), in others lasting decades (Germany
social policy has become an integral part of from the 1970s until the present time).
the agenda of modern nation-states Sometimes these changes were implemented
SYSTEMS THEORY, SOCIETAL CONTEXTS, AND ORGANIZATIONAL HETEROGENEITY 551

as consensual projects (Finland in the Any of these institutions of the political


1990s); sometimes they were highly contro- system contributes to the expansion of the
versial (the United Kingdom at the beginning welfare-state. Other societal systems are only
of the 1980s). From a neo-institutional point relevant to the political system as an external
of view, however, it does not suffice to resource for its continuous reproduction. It is
observe these transformations at the nation- thus not surprising that systems theory puts
state level. Instead, the historical develop- a strong emphasis on the societal risks of
ment of the welfare-state, as well as more systems dynamics.
recent transformations, have to be seen as a Following Luhmann’s Political Theory in
globally orchestrated process, in which trans- the Welfare State (Luhmann 1990), the
national organizations, world-wide diffusing expansion of the welfare-state appears to be
role models, experts and consultants are of an inevitable consequence of the evolution of
pivotal importance (Hasse 2003). The the political system. The welfare-state pre-
OECD, for example, issued a dramatic report dominantly aims at the inclusion of persons
in 1981 on the limits of welfare-state policies and groups. On the basis of political power
(OECD 1981). Based on critical assessments law and money are used as means of effectu-
like this, substantial re-definitions took ating the welfare-state. Structurally, its
place: Administration as Service (OECD expansion is pushed by the interplay of the
1987) was established as a new ‘Leitbild’; core institutions of the political system and
issues of service delivery were tackled; pri- by referring to other societal systems: First,
vate alternatives to public bureaucracies were dense competition for scarce offices is
favored; and reforms were driven by new assumed to result in political programs, in
best practices such as ‘new public manage- which the societal environment is actively
ment’ or ‘non profits for hire.’ This paradig- scanned for themes and organized interests,
matic change was accompanied by a which might offer opportunities to apply the
replacement of models (from Germany to principle of welfare-state politics. Mass
New Zealand), international organizations media is considered here as an important
(from ILO to IMF), and experts acting on mediator between organized interests on the
global scale (from Keynesian social engi- one hand and political parties and politicians
neers to more practically inclined political on the other hand. Second, administrative
consultants). agencies and their experts actively support
While neo-institutionalism conceptualizes the identification of needs due to their pro-
welfare-state developments as trans-national fessional knowledge and due to micro-
processes, in which global models and political interests. Third, legal claims affect
scripts diffuse through a variety of channels, the relation between the public administra-
systems theory emphasizes the effects of the tion and the public. This fosters the trend
functional differentiation of society. As a towards an expansion of welfare politics, too.
consequence, its political system appears to As a consequence of this unprecedented
be a distinct field which is based on a specific growth, severe problems occur in other parts
logic or rationality, i.e., the application of the of society. In particular, Luhmann has
binary code ‘power/not in power.’ In this, the highlighted negative economic side-effects
political system sharply differs from those of (due to the extensive use of money, but also
other societal systems. In addition, the inter- due to attempts at actively regulating the
nal differentiation of the political system has economy), the risk of overloading the law
to be taken into account. Internally, the system (due to the extensive use of law
system is composed of (a) political decision resulting in shortcomings of application and
makers (governments and office holders), implementation), and the expansion of state
(b) administration and service deliverers, and bureaucracies and professionals (as service
(c) the public (as both voters and clients). deliverers and as experts).
552 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

It should be noted that the starting point of the political system with information about
Luhmann’s analysis of the welfare-state is how to apply its basic principles. Programs
quite similar to the neo-institutional perspec- may vary profoundly across time and space,
tive. Instead of highlighting national varia- and organizations, both within the political
tions, both approaches emphasize structural system and in its relevant environment (like
features of modern society, which affect very media organizations, business firms, and
different nation-states. However, two very courts) do not simply enact broader societal
basic differences may be identified. scripts. Instead, they play a very active
First, Luhmann refers to very general and contingent role in the variation of pro-
characteristics of the political system, its grams, for example those concerning the
internal logic and core institutions as driving welfare state.
forces of welfare-state developments, which
are to be found in very different nation-
states. Neo-institutionalism, instead, empha-
Academic entrepreneurship
sizes trans-national, ‘external’ causes as
triggering these developments. Though Academic entrepreneurship is embedded in a
national differences are not of prime theoret- more general reappraisal of the role entrepre-
ical concern for both approaches, they could neurial activities should play in society.
be explained through either specific national Entrepreneurship has increasingly been seen
configurations of political institutions and as being beneficial with respect to broader
their relevant societal environment (systems socio-economic impacts; in particular, start-
theory) or linkages of nation-states to trans- up companies which contribute to the trans-
national discourses and organizations (neo- fer of new knowledge are highly appreciated
institutionalism). (Thornton 1999). Universities figure most
Second, the trend towards the transforma- prominently in this broader discourse on
tion of the welfare-state, which has occurred entrepreneurship. All over the world, their
in very different countries and which has new economic responsibilities have become
been briefly discussed above, has to be con- visible. Economic parameters such as
ceptualized very differently. While neo- start-up founding rates or the commodifica-
institutionalists focus on the role agents of tion of new knowledge via patenting and
diffusion such as trans-national organiza- licensing have become new evaluation
tions, experts and consultants play, from the criteria, and universities have begun to
point of view of systems theory one has to actively get involved in these activities
stress that the discourses and concepts of (OECD 2003). Though direct links between
these agents do not diffuse easily. Instead, academic researchers and industry have a
they have to be translated into the political long history in many fields, carried out in
system, and this happens according to the addition to the main tasks of the individual
logic and rationality of that very system, and researcher, it has now become an
not according to broader societal norms and institutional mission of the university as
scripts. Therefore, the focus is rather on an organization. Based on the assumption
internal factors triggering change. Following that a direct contribution to economic
the distinction between codes and programs, development has become a third academic
one should assume that aspects related to the mission of universities, on a par with the
former are a source of structural stability. traditional missions of teaching and research,
Societal differentiation, competitive features academic entrepreneurship seems to be
of the political system, and the interplay of at the core of a new, globally diffusing
its core institutions are not considered as model for universities (see, for example,
objects of change. However, there is a perma- Etzkowitz/Healey/Webster 1998; Krücken/
nent variation of programs as they provide Meier/Müller 2007).
SYSTEMS THEORY, SOCIETAL CONTEXTS, AND ORGANIZATIONAL HETEROGENEITY 553

While the new institutionalism emphasizes Likewise, systems theory emphasizes that
the match between academic entrepreneur- the political dynamics fostering academic
ship on the one hand and wider social norms entrepreneurship have to be analyzed like
and expectations on the other, systems theory those of any other political field. These
puts more emphasis on aspects of societal dif- dynamics are related to power issues and are
ferentiation and the distinct logics of societal characterized by the pursuit of a specific
systems. The former perspective is well estab- rationality, which differentiates the political
lished in the context of this handbook. Here system from other parts of society. In addi-
one should mention neo-institutional research tion, one would not expect that innovation
on entrepreneurship (Hwang/Powell 2005), politics and policies are breaking away from
on inter-organizational networks among acade- the traditional means of effectuating the
mia and industry (Powell/White/Koput/ welfare-state, i.e., law and money. Actively
Owen-Smith 2005), and on universities and contributing to academic entrepreneurship
their embeddedness in wider social norms is thus a supplement of political programs,
and expectations (Meyer/Schofer 2007). which inform the political system and its
Therefore, we will only focus on how aca- organizations about where, when and how to
demic entrepreneurship might be conceived apply the binary code of politics. Systems
from the point of view of systems theory. theory would stress that politics and policies
From that point of view one would assume fostering academic entrepreneurship are
that distinct systems – in particular econom- exclusively determined by political consider-
ics, politics, and science – with distinct ations. It assumes that negative side-effects
logics are involved, which cannot be with respect to science and the economy only
transcended. affect political decision making to the extent
First, systems theory considers business that they make a political difference. For
firms as a specific kind of organization, example, the political promotion of start-ups
which is to be characterized by the fact that may have adverse economic implications.
normative expectations are directed towards Financial subsidies by the state may nega-
economic efficiency. Here, efficiency is a tively affect the development of a venture
means to achieve legitimacy, and any busi- capital market, and state-funded start-ups
ness firm which does not meet economic cri- find it harder to attain an economic reputa-
teria in the longer run had to be evaluated as tion, which is important in order to attract
a problematic case. This does not deny that funding from venture capitalists. In a similar
the initial economic difficulties of an aca- vein one may expect long-term negative
demic start-up can be accepted for some effects on science if short-term socio-
time, or that start-ups may aim at new mar- economic effects, which can be labelled as
kets or at attracting new investors instead of the outcome of political decision making and
achieving short-term profits. However, sys- thus be converted into political power,
tems theory assumes that start-up companies become the dominant goal of science politics
get into serious problems if they are evalu- and policies.
ated as hybrid organizations which serve Finally, the same perspective can be
rather general and diffuse societal needs and applied to research organizations, which are
expectations, instead of aiming at economic assumed to process information along the
success in the longer run. Start-ups from aca- binary code ‘true’ vs. ‘false.’ Issues of
demia may thus be characterized by a spe- academic entrepreneurship are framed with
cific economic program (i.e., the marketing regard to the code and programs of the
of new knowledge which is genuinely risky), science system, while material effects of
but they can be considered as being rather start-ups and positive socio-economic
conventionally related to the binary coding of impacts are considered to be less important.
economic activities through money. This implies two things: First, at the level of
554 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

the individual researcher one should assume Though such collaborations are important as
that the specific incentive structure of that they mediate between different systems and
very system makes him or her more prone to make their specific rationalities visible, they
conducting activities which can be mapped need to be conceptualized primarily as
by conventional indicators of successful opportunity structures that can be exploited
scientific action such as peer-reviewed publi- by any of its participants. While new
cations. Publications have no direct equiva- institutionalists might expect processes of
lent in other parts of society. On the other mutual adjustment and isomorphic tenden-
hand, broader societal norms and the criteria cies, which may alter organizations
of other systems – like the general and, in profoundly, systems theorists would rather
particular, political emphasis on entrepre- assume that the impact of such collaborations
neurial activities – have to pass this bottle- will lead to new avenues for exploring the
neck in order to become relevant among dominant rationalities of the organizations
scientists. Second, also at the organizational involved.
level one has to take a rather skeptical view
of the repercussions of the current trend
towards academic entrepreneurship. Most
studies on technology transfer offices at CONCLUSION
universities suggest only very moderate
effects on entrepreneurial activities, and fol- Sociological systems theory in the way it has
lowing Meyer/Rowan (1977) transfer offices been developed by Niklas Luhmann can play
could be seen as a prime example of the a crucial role in coming to terms with the het-
loose coupling between formal and activity erogeneity and variety at the macro-level of
structures of university organizations society. In this, it is a relevant antidote to the
(Krücken 2003). According to systems traditional neo-institutional emphasis on
analysis, however, referring to ‘loose cou- homogenizing forces. Instead of recurring to
pling’ does not suffice as it does not explain the role of purposive actors as in the concept
why most university organizations do not of institutional entrepreneurs, sociological
fully embrace academic entrepreneurship. systems theory stresses the conceptual links
Following that type of analysis, one would between organizational analysis and wider
rather assume that the degree of coupling is societal fields and their developments, and so
closely related to the identity of an organiza- refers to the very starting point of organiza-
tion, which itself is a function of the specific tional institutionalism. With the help of two
societal system in which it is embedded. examples we tried to exemplify the fruitful-
To summarize, from the point of view of ness of that approach. One could see, first,
systems analysis academic entrepreneurship that the neo-institutional emphasis on
has to be considered as creating an opportu- broader societal norms and their diffusion in
nity for societal systems and their organiza- the development of the welfare-state has to
tions. Within different systems, academic be complemented by a perspective, in which
entrepreneurship might lead to variations at the distinct logic of one societal system, i.e.,
the level of their programs. The hypothesis, politics, and the role of political organiza-
however, is that variations at the level of tions, is highlighted. With our second exam-
programs can hardly affect the identity of any ple we enlarged the perspective by focusing
of the systems involved. For system theorists, on how one issue, academic entrepreneur-
the mutual adjustment of societal systems ship, is perceived and processed according to
through dense inter-organizational collabora- the distinct logics of different societal sys-
tion between scientific, political and tems and their organizations. This, again,
economic organizations cannot be equated complements the traditional neo-institutional
with the evaporation of systemic boundaries. emphasis on homogenizing forces in society.
SYSTEMS THEORY, SOCIETAL CONTEXTS, AND ORGANIZATIONAL HETEROGENEITY 555

According to our analysis, though both Foucauldian and neo-institutional thinking relate to
approaches can hardly be integrated at a each other.
meta-theoretical level, they can be used as 5 John Child made a similar point in order to argue
guidelines for re-establishing a macro-per- in favor of his strategic choice-analysis: ‘The concept
spective on the interconnectedness of socie- of an organizational environment as a social network
… raises doubts about how externalized it really is
tal and organizational developments. While from its constituent organizations’ (Child 1997: 57).
neo-institutional theory is particularly good In order to emphasize this, Child rigorously identifies
at analyzing diffusion processes, which tran- ‘inner structuration’ (related to organizational
scend sectoral boundaries of society and parameters) and ‘outer structuration’ (related to the
shape all units of analysis, systems theory organizational context) as objects of strategic choice
(Child 1997: 70–1).
instead focuses on differences between soci- 6 To some extent, the contemporary emphasis on
etal systems and their organizations, which agency and institutional entrepreneurship seems to
cannot be transcended. At the interface of be a ‘forward to the past.’ There are striking resem-
these very different paradigms a fascinating blances to theoretical discussions many decades ago
agenda for future research on the societal when old institutionalists such as Philip Selznick
(1949) and Arthur Stinchcombe (1965) were
embeddedness of organizations might highlighting issues of power and conflict
evolve. As we tried to show, accounting for (Greenwood/Hinnings 1996: 103–4). In doing so,
heterogeneity does not necessarily lead to a they joined a broad coalition of researchers which crit-
reappraisal of individual agency. By referring icized the prevailing Parsonian approach as being far
to sociological systems theory, organiza- too static and sterile. Among these critics was S.N.
Eisenstadt (1964, 1965), who considered elites and
tional institutionalism might do better as we leadership roles as carriers of institutional entrepre-
can combine the more recent emphasis on neurship. Not unlike many contemporary researchers
heterogeneity with the traditional strength of of entrepreneurship, Eisenstadt also argued that ref-
organizational institutionalism which lies in erence to other institutions and the ability to mobilize
its focus on the co-evolution of organizations support were preconditions for institutional change.
7 We deliberately leave out the epistemological
and their societal environments.
underpinnings of Luhmann’s work, which are based
on more recent discussions in general systems theory,
neuroscience, and logics. For an attempt to link these
highly sophisticated arguments, which lead to a
NOTES theory of social systems’ self-reference (Luhmann
1995) and self-observation (Luhmann 1998), to orga-
1 But see Hasse/Krücken (2005a: 85–94) for a nizational theory (see Seidl/Becker 2005).
closer look at Bourdieu and Giddens from a neo-insti- 8 There is a certain tension in Luhmann’s work
tutional point of view. between the early emphasis on societal functions as
2 It should be noted that Luhmann has also devel- the driving-force of differentiation processes and the
oped a specific micro-foundation of organizational later emphasis on processes of internal self-reproduc-
theory, which offers further perspectives for a com- tion. While the early period is marked by the influ-
parison with the new institutionalism (see Hasse ence of Talcott Parsons, the later one is linked to the
2005). ‘autopoietic turn’ in general systems theory, i.e., the
3 See Meyer/Jepperson (2000) for further details assumption that the elements of a system are linked
on status differences between individual and organi- to other elements of the same system, but not to
zational actors with respect to non-utilitarian ends. external references. As we will focus on the distinct
4 Here we think in particular of the work of Michel logics of individual societal systems, through which
Foucault. Though from very different angles and they constitute themselves in difference to other soci-
despite Foucault’s rejection of the idea of a coherent etal systems, the functional aspects of Luhmann’s
narrative of society, with regard to the role of science work are only to be seen against that backdrop.
and, in particular, to the constitution of individual 9 It should be noted that close linkages between
actorhood, both approaches display some remark- organization building on the one hand and the
able similarities (Krücken 2002: 248–53). As Foucault development of specific forms of rationality have
has become one of the intellectual points of refer- been observed by other social scientists as well.
ence for broader organizational theorizing, especially Michel Foucault, for example, has emphasized the
in the European context, also the field of organiza- significance of the ‘birth of the clinic’ (Foucault 1973)
tional research might benefit from exploring how for the development of the modern medical system;
556 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Richard Whitley (1984) convincingly has shown that Berger, P.L./Luckmann, T., 1967: The Social
the transformation of more or less sporadic ‘amateur Construction of Reality. New York, NY:
sciences’ into the modern science system was based Doubleday.
on the re-organization of universities which special-
Blom-Hansen, J., 1997: ‘A ‘new institutional’
ized with respect to academic disciplines and corre-
perspective on policy networks’, in: Public
sponding scientific associations; the modern political
system has been considered to be based on the for- Administration, 75: 669–93.
mation of competitive political parties and the incor- Boli, J./Thomas, G.M., 1997: ‘World culture in
poration of various interest groups (Evans 1999); and the world polity: A century of international
according to Max Weber (1968) modern capitalism non-governmental organization’, in: American
revolutionized the economy on the basis of the insti- Sociological Review, 62: 171–90.
tutionalization of the business firm which is different Bourdieu, P., 1977: Outline of a Theory of
from a traditional economy based on households. For Practice. New York, NY: Cambridge University
a more general account on the importance of the Press.
19th century for the spread of formal organizations
Bourdieu, P., 1984: Distinction: A Social
in society see also Türk (1995).
10 As both neo-institutionalism and systems
Critique of the Judgment of Taste. New York,
theory focus on the long-term development of the NY: Cambridge University Press.
welfare state, they rather emphasize its expansion. Bourdieu, P., 1990: The Logic of Practice.
The more recent experiences mentioned below, how- Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.
ever, could be seen as strong indicators for the Child, J., 1997: ‘Strategic choice in the analysis
‘retreat of the state’ (Strange 1996) and the expan- of action, structure, organizations and envi-
sion of economic rationality in society. From the per- ronment: retrospect and prospect’, in:
spective of neo-institutionalism and systems theory Organization Studies, 18: 43–76.
one could argue that these experiences could only be
DiMaggio, P.J., 1988: ‘Interest and agency in
fully understood against the backdrop of a more
macro-historical and macro-sociological account. In
institutional theory’, in: Zucker, L.G. (ed.),
addition, current discourses and practices could be Institutional Patterns and Organizations:
analyzed without altering the main conceptual tools Culture and Environment. Cambridge, MA:
and premises of both approaches. From a neo-insti- Ballinger: 3–21.
tutional point of view, Lee/Strang (2006) analyze DiMaggio, P.J./Powell, W.W., 1983: ‘The iron
public-sector downsizing in 26 OECD countries as a cage revisited: Institutional isomorphism and
global diffusion process. In a similar vein, one could collective rationality in organizational fields’,
argue from the point of view of Luhmann’s systems in: American Sociological Review, 48:
theory that we can currently witness variation in
147–60.
political programs, while the code of the political
Dobbin, F.R., 1994: ‘Cultural models of organi-
system, in which the dominant rationality of the
system is to be found, remains unchanged. zation: The social construction of rational
organizing principles’, in: Crane, D. (ed.),
The Sociology of Culture. Oxford: Blackwell:
117–42.
REFERENCES Dorado, S., 2005: ‘Institutional entrepreneur-
ship, partaking, and convening’, in:
Abbell, P., 1995: ‘The new institutionalism and Organization Studies, 26: 385–414.
rational choice theory’, in: Scott, Drori, G./Meyer, J.W./Ramirez, F.O./Schofer, E.,
W.R./Christensen, S. (eds.), The Institutional 2003: Science in the Modern World Polity.
Construction of Organizations. Thousand Palo Alto, CA: Stanford University Press.
Oaks, CA: Sage: 3–14. Drori, G./Meyer, J.W./Hwang, H. (eds.), 2006:
Barley, S.R./Tolbert, P.S., 1997: ‘Institutionaliza- Globalization and Organization. Oxford:
tion and structuration: Studying the links Oxford University Press.
between action and institution’, in: Durkheim, E., 1933: The Division of Labor in
Organization Studies, 18/1: 93–117. Society. Glencoe, IL: Free Press.
Beckert, J., 1999: ‘Agency, entrepreneurs, Eisenstadt, S.N., 1964: ‘Social change, differen-
and institutional change: The role of strategic tiation, and evolution’, in: American
choice and institutionalized practices in organ- Sociological Review, 29: 235–47.
izations’, in: Organization Studies, 20: Eisenstadt, S.N., 1965: Essays on Comparative
777–99. Institutions. New York, NY: John Wiley.
SYSTEMS THEORY, SOCIETAL CONTEXTS, AND ORGANIZATIONAL HETEROGENEITY 557

Emirbayer, M./Mische, A., 1998: ‘What is D./Becker, K.H. (eds.), Niklas Luhmann
agency?’, in: American Journal of Sociology, and Organization Studies. Copenhagen,
103/104: 962–1023. Copenhagen Business School Press:
Esping-Andersen, G., 1990: The Three Worlds of 248–61.
Welfare Capitalism. Cambridge: Polity Press. Hasse, R./Krücken, G., 2005a: Neo-Institutio-
Etzkowitz, H./Healey, P./Webster, A. (eds.), nalismus. 2nd edn. Bielefeld: transcript.
1998: Capitalizing Knowledge. New York, Hasse, R./Krücken, G., 2005b: ‘Der Stellenwert
NY: State University of New York Press. von Organisationen in Theorien der
Evans, G. (ed.), 1999: The End of Class Politics? Weltgesellschaft. Eine kritische Weiterent-
Class Voting in Comparative Context. Oxford: wicklung systemtheoretischer und neo-
Oxford University Press. institutionalistischer Forschungsperspektiven’,
Feldman, M.S./Pentland, B.T., 2003: in: Zeitschrift für Soziologie, Sonder Band
‘Reconceptualizing organizational routines as Weltgesellschaft: 186–204.
a source of flexibility and change’, in: Hwang, H./Powell, W.W., 2005: ‘Institutions
Administrative Science Quarterly, 48: 94–118. and entrepreneurship’, in: The Handbook of
Fligstein, N., 1996: ‘Markets as politics: A political Entrepreneurship Research. Dordrecht/
and cultural approach to market institutions’, Boston/London, Kluwer: 179–210.
in: American Sociological Review, 61: 656–73. Jepperson, R.L., 2002: ‘The development and
Flora, P., 1986: Growth to Limits: The Western application of sociological neo-institutional-
European Welfare States Since World War II. ism’, in: Berger, J./Zelditch, M., Jr. (eds.), New
Berlin: De Gruyter. Directions in Contemporary Sociological Theory.
Foucault, M., 1973: The Birth of the Clinic. Lanham, MD: Rowman & Littlefield: 229–66.
London: Tavistock Publications. Joas, H. 1996: The Creativity of Action.
Frank, D./Meyer, J., 2002: ‘The profusion of Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.
individual roles in the postwar period’, in: Khagram, S./Riker, J.V./Sikkink, K. (eds.), 2002:
Sociological Theory, 20: 86–105. Restructuring World Politics. Transnational
Friedland, R./Alford, R.R., 1991: ‘Bringing society Movements, Networks, and Norms. Min-
back in: Symbols, Practices, and institutional neapolis, MN: University of Minnesota Press.
contradictions’, in: Powell, W.W./DiMaggio, Krücken, G., 2002: ‘Amerikanischer Neo-
P.J. (eds.), The New Institutionalism in Institutionalismus – europäische Perspektiven’,
Organizational Analysis. Chicago, IL: University in: Sociologia Internationalis, 40: 227–59.
of Chicago Press: 232–62. Krücken, G., 2003: ‘Mission impossible?
Giddens, A., 1984, The Constitution of Society. Institutional barriers to the diffusion of
Berkeley, CA: University of California Press. the ‘Third Academic Mission’ at German uni-
Greenwood, R./Hinnings, C.R., 1996: ‘Under- versities’, in: International Journal of
standing radical organizational change: Technology Management, 25: 18–33.
Bringing together the old and the new insti- Krücken, G./Drori, G. (eds.), 2008: World
tutionalism’, in: Academy of Management Society. The Writings of John Meyer. Oxford:
Review, 21: 1022–54. Oxford University Press (forthcoming).
Greenwood, R/Suddaby, R/Hinnings, C.R., Krücken, G./Meier, F./Müller, A., 2007:
2002: “Theorizing change:The role of pro- ‘Steps towards the ‘Entrepreneurial
fessional associations in the transformation University’: Lessons from the German case’,
of institutional fields”, in: Academy of in: Cooke, L.W. (ed.), Frontiers in Higher
Management Journal, 45: 58–80. Education. New York, NY: Nova Science
Habermas, J., 1985/1989: A Theory of (forthcoming).
Communicative Action. 2 Vols. Boston, MA: Lee, C.K./Strang, D., 2006: ‘The international dif-
Beacon Press. fusion of public-sector downsizing: Network
Hasse, R., 2003: Wohlfahrtspolitik und emulation and theory-driven learning’, in:
Globalisierung. Zur Diffusion der World Polity International Organization, 60: 883–910.
durch Organisationswandel und Wettbewerb- Lounsbury, M., 2001: ‘Institutional sources of
orientierung. Opladen: Leske und Budrich. practice variation: Staffing college and uni-
Hasse, R., 2005: ‘Luhmann’s systems theory versity recycling programs’, in:
and the new institutionalism’, in: Seidl, Administrative Science Quarterly, 46: 29–56.
558 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Lounsbury, M., 2005: ‘Towards a practice per- Meyer, J.W./Schofer, E., 2007: ‘The university in
spective on institutional entrepreneurship: Europe and the world: Twentieth century
Mutual fund money management change expansion’, in: Krücken, G./Kosmützky,
and the performativity-theorization link’. A./Torka, M. (eds.), Towards a Multiversity?
Manuscript, November 2005. Universities Between Global Trends and
Luhmann, N., 1964: Funktionen und Folgen National Traditions. Bielefeld, transcript: 45–62.
Formaler Organisation. Berlin: Duncker & OECD, 1981: The Welfare State in Crisis. Paris:
Humblot. OECD.
Luhmann, N., 1982: The Differentiation of OECD, 1987: Administration as Service. Paris:
Society. New York, NY: Columbia University OECD.
Press. OECD, 2003: Turning Science into Business.
Luhmann, N., 1989: Ecological Communication. Patenting and Licensing at Public Research
Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press. Organizations. Paris: OECD.
Luhmann, N., 1990: Political theory in the Welfare Orrù, M./Woolsey Biggart, N./Hamilton, G.G.,
State. Berlin/New York, NY: de Gruyter. 1991: ‘Organizational isomorphism in East
Luhmann, N., 1993: Risk: A Sociological Theory. Asia’, in: Powell, W.W./DiMaggio, P.J. (eds.),
Berlin/New York, NY: de Gruyter. The New Institutionalism in Organizational
Luhmann, N., 1995: Social Systems. Palo Alto, Analysis. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago
CA: Stanford University Press. Press: 361–89.
Luhmann, N., 1997: Die Gesellschaft der Polanyi, K., 1944: The Great Transformation.
Gesellschaft. Frankfurt a.M.: Suhrkamp. Boston, MA: Beacon Press.
Luhmann, N., 1998: Observations on Modernity. Powell, W.W./White, D.R./Koput, K.W./Owen-
Palo Alto, CA: Stanford University Press. Smith, J., 2005: ‘Network dynamics and field
Luhmann, N., 2000: Organisation und evolution’, in: American Journal of Sociology,
Entscheidung. Wiesbaden: VS Verlag für 110: 1132–205.
Sozialwissenschaften. Rao, H., 1998: ‘Caveat emptor: The construc-
Marshall, T.H., 1981: The Right to Welfare, and tion of nonprofit consumer watchdog organ-
other Essays. London: Heineman. izations’, in: American Journal of Sociology,
McNeely, C., 1995: Constructing the Nation 103: 912–61.
State: International Organization and Rao, H./Monin, P./Durand, R., 2003:
Prescriptive Action. Westport, CT: Greenwood ‘Institutional change in Toque Ville: Nouvelle
Press. cuisine as an identity movement in French
Meyer, J.W., 1992: ‘From constructionism gastronomy’, in: American Journal of
to neo-institutionalism: Reflections on Sociology, 108: 795–843.
Berger and Luckmann’, in: Perspectives, 15: Sahlin-Andersson, K./Engvall, L. (eds.), 2002:
11–12. The Expansion of Management Knowledge:
Meyer, J.W., 2008: World society, the welfare Carriers, Flows, and Sources. Palo Alto, CA:
state and the life course: An institutional per- Stanford University Press.
spective, in: Krücken, G./Drori, G. (eds.), Schneiberg, M./Clemens, E., 2006: ‘The typical
World society: The Writings of John Meyer tools for the job: Research strategies in insti-
(working title). Oxford: Oxford University tutional analysis’, in: Sociological Theory, 3:
Press (forthcoming). 195–227.
Meyer, J.W./Boli, J./Thomas, G.M./Ramirez, F.O., Scott, W. Richard. 1983: ‘Introduction: From
1997: ‘World society and the nation state’, in: technology to environment’, in: Meyer,
American Journal of Sociology, 103: 144–81. J.W./Scott, W.R., Organizational Environments:
Meyer, J.W./Jepperson, R., 2000: ‘The ‘actors’ Ritual and Rationality. Newbury Park, CA:
of modern society: The cultural construction Sage: 13–17.
of social agency’, in: Sociological Theory, 18: Scott, R.W., 1991: ‘The organization of envi-
100–20. ronments: Network, cultural, and historical
Meyer, J.W./Rowan, B., 1977: ‘Institutionalized elements’, in: Meyer, J.W./Scott, R.W. (eds.),
organizations: Formal structures as myth and Organizational Environments: Ritual and
ceremony’, in: American Journal of Sociology, Rationality, updated edn. Newbury Park, CA:
83: 340–63. Sage: 155–75.
SYSTEMS THEORY, SOCIETAL CONTEXTS, AND ORGANIZATIONAL HETEROGENEITY 559

Scott, W.R., 2001: Institutions and Organizations. welfare state: Institutional effects on
2nd edn. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage. national welfare spending’, in: International
Scott, W.R./Meyer, J.W., 1991: ‘The organiza- Organization, 47: 235–62.
tion of societal sectors’, in: Meyer, J.W./Scott, Strange, S., 1996: The Retreat of the State: The
R.W. (eds.), Organizational Environments: Diffusion of Power in the World Economy.
Ritual and Rationality, updated edn. Newbury Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Park, CA: Sage: 129–53. Thornton, P.H., 1999: ‘The sociology of entre-
Seidl, D./Becker, K.H. (eds.), 2005: Niklas Luhmann preneurship’, in: Annual Revue of Sociology,
and Organization Studies. Copenhagen: 25: 19–46.
Copenhagen Business School Press. Tsutsui, K., 2004: ‘Global civil society and ethnic
Selznick, P., 1949: TVA and The Grass Roots. social movements in the contemporary
Berkeley, CA: University of California Press. world’, in: Sociological Forum, 19: 63–87.
Seo, M.G./Creed, D.W.E., 2002: ‘Institutional Türk, K., 1995: Die Organisation der Welt.
contradictions, praxis, and institutional Opladen: Westdeutscher Verlag.
change: A dialectical perspective’, in: Academy Weber, M., 1958: The Protestant Ethic and The
of Management Review, 27: 222–48. Spirit of Capitalism. New York: Charles
Stinchcombe, A.L., 1965: ‘Social structure and Scribner’s Sons.
organizations’, in: March, J.G. (ed.): Weber, M., 1968: Economy and Society: An
Handbook of Organizations. Chicago, IL: Outline of Interpretive Sociology. New York,
Rand McNally: 142–93. NY: Bedminster Press.
Strang, D./Chang, P.M.Y., 1993: ‘The Whitley, R.W., 1984: The Intellectual and Social
International Labor Organization and the Organization of the Sciences. Oxford: Clarendon.
23
Charting Progress at the Nexus
of Institutional Theory and
Economics
Peter W. Roberts

INTRODUCTION other hand, the strong form of institutional


theory views these actors as more reflex-
The aim of this volume is to chart the ively conforming to the various institu-
progress being made refining institutional tional influences and constraints that
theory (Powell & DiMaggio, 1991) and its emanate from the fields in which organiza-
contributions to organizational studies. This tions are embedded.
progress includes developments at the core This chapter is rooted in the premise that
of institutional theory, as well as those at the there is some potential for a more seamless
intersections with other organizational integration of the two perspectives. In what
perspectives and theories. The specific aim follows, I briefly summarize the main tenets
of this chapter is to reflect on the progress of organizational economics and institutional
made – and still to be made – toward inte- theory, drawing primarily from the organiz-
grating insights from institutional theory ing framework offered by Roberts and
with those from organizational economics. Greenwood (1997). This framework suggests
There is no doubt that the very different ori- two broad ways that the institutional and eco-
gins and orientations of these two approaches nomic perspectives might be bridged: by
make their integration a challenging examining how purposeful and otherwise
endeavor. In the words of Granovetter rational organizational actors react to the
(1985), economists tend to offer under- post-conscious (i.e., sociopolitical) and pre-
socialized accounts of organizational pheno- conscious (i.e., cognitive) institutional influ-
mena, whereas institutional theorists tend ences that they face when navigating
toward over-socialized explanations. More organizational fields. This allows us to point
specifically, economic theories emanate to some productive integrative research
from assumptions of organizational actors located along the first bridge. On the other
as rational calculating entities. On the hand, we find less published work that
CHARTING PROGRESS AT THE NEXUS OF INSTITUTIONAL THEORY AND ECONOMICS 561

integrates Scott’s (1995) cognitive pillar with decision-making process by influencing


economic perspectives on organizations. what is or is not perceived by decision
I then offer several reasons for the more scant makers. These influences correspond to
progress along this second bridge before Scott’s (1995) cognitive pillar, which focuses
concluding with several thoughts about the on the frameworks of meaning by which
prognosis for further integrative research. actors interpret and make sense of their
world. Unlike the bounded rationality
emphasized by transaction cost theorists, the
cognitive influences emphasized by institu-
TWO COMPETING APPROACHES tional theorists relate to ‘the internalized
symbolic representations of the world’
Organizational economics and institutional (Scott, 1995: 40). On the other hand, Scott’s
theory offer seemingly contradictory (1995) normative pillar highlights the sets of
accounts of organizational phenomena. expectations within particular organizational
‘Economic approaches to the study of organ- contexts of what constitutes appropriate and
ization, transaction cost analysis included, thus legitimate behavior. Tangible forces in
generally focus on efficiency’ (Williamson, an organization’s environment directly or
1981: 549) and aspire to ‘provide an answer indirectly tilt choices away from technical
to the most fundamental question in organi- considerations and toward the pursuit of
zational research: why do organizations legitimacy. In this respect, Meyer and Rowan
exist?’ (Hesterley, Liebeskind, & Zenger, (1977: 343), objecting to the common por-
1990: 404) The field originally examined the trayal of organizational designs as the prod-
comparative efficiency of hierarchies, fran- uct of the technical demands placed on an
chises, multidivisionals, conglomerates, organization, argue that ‘elements of formal
holding companies (Williamson, 1975), structure are manifestations of powerful
clans (Ouchi, 1980), and market-hierarchy institutional rules which function as highly
hybrids (Williamson, 1991). More recently, rationalized myths that are binding on partic-
economic logic has been employed to ular organizations.’
explain a broader array of organizational and Admittedly, organizational economists
strategic phenomena, including joint ven- have alluded to the significance of institu-
tures (Yiu & Makino, 2002) and franchising tions. At a general level, institutional
arrangements (Shane & Foo, 1999). In all economists contend that the orthodox micro-
cases, the basic rationale for any given orga- economics paradigm is enhanced if the
nizational action or outcome is rooted in its choices made by ‘economic man’ are under-
efficiency compared to the set of available stood as occurring within the context of insti-
alternatives, including markets. tutions which act as constraints upon the
Historically, institutional theorists have choices made. Williamson (1992: 41) is
been more interested in explaining unifor- explicit about the role of the institutional
mity than heterogeneity (Dimaggio & environment, suggesting that ‘the institutions
Powell, 1983). This naturally leads them to of governance … are embedded in the insti-
focus on the organizational field or even tutional environment.’ However, the institu-
society at large as the primary unit of analy- tional environment that he envisions consists
sis. Organizations operate in environments only of the ‘set of fundamental political,
where much is taken for granted. The taken- social and legal ground rules that establishes
for-granted elements, which are either the basis for production, exchange and
infused with excess value (Selznick, 1957) distribution’ (Williamson, 1993: 11). The
or constructed in the process of social inter- institutional environment envisioned by
action (Berger & Luckmann, 1966), serve as institutional theorists includes its more
powerful schema or frames, shaping the sociological elements, such as patterns of
562 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

social relations (Burns & Wholey, 1993) and arrangements can persist over long time peri-
embeddedness interpretations (Meyer & ods. Beliefs that strong-form efficiency is not
Rowan, 1977). These perspectives – Scott’s paramount, that organizational outcomes are
(1995) second and third pillars of institu- influenced by actors’ perceptions of available
tional thinking – have not figured promi- alternatives, and that these outcomes might
nently in the work of organizational be technically dysfunctional seem to open
economists. Yet, it is to these features that the door for potential contributions from
writers such as Granovetter (1985), Robins institutional theory to economic perspectives
(1987) and Hesterley et al. (1990) point when on organizations.
they assert the need to more fully consider At the same time, institutional theory long
the institutional aspects of organizations. focused on ‘how non-choice behaviors can
This said, there have been movements in occur and persist, through the exercise of
the two theoretical camps toward recogniz- habit, convention, convenience, or social
ing potential contributions from one another. obligation.’ (Oliver, 1991: 151) In its
David and Han (2004: 54) recently con- strongest form, the institutional approach
cluded that transaction costs theory ‘can be rejects the premise that organizational phe-
refined by specifying “scope conditions” … nomena are the products of rational choice
given the mixed support transaction cost eco- based on technical considerations. Rather,
nomics is currently garnering, it is critical to emphasis is placed either on the taken-
understand the conditions under which the for-granted nature of the decisions made or
theory works well and under which it does on the pressures to secure legitimacy that
not.’ Along these lines, organizational econo- operate on organizations, or both. Since the
mists have challenged themselves to account mid-1990s, however, institutional theorists
for the many influences and constraints that have charged themselves with the task of
operate upon the calculating agents that they injecting an appropriate amount of agency
are modeling. Williamson (1987: 176) noted into their accounts of organizational behav-
that if pushed, ‘few economists would insist ior. DiMaggio and Powell (1983) and Tolbert
on an unrelieved efficiency theory of economic and Zucker (1984) recognized early on that
organization.’ Rather, organizational econom- institutional forces are not always primary,
ics should be based on what may be referred to noting the tendency for the early adoption of
as weak-form, rather than strong-form selec- novel organizational practices to be driven by
tion. In a relative sense, it is the more technical as opposed to legitimacy consider-
(but not the most) efficient organizations ations. Echoing Granovetter’s (1985)
that tend to fare well and therefore concerns about over-socialized theory,
survive. There is no reason to insist that sur- Powell (1991: 194) suggested that ‘much of
vivors are always the most efficient in any the imagery of institutional theory portrays
absolute sense. In his critique of transaction organizations too passively and depicts envi-
cost theory, Robins (1987: 74, emphasis ronments as overly constraining.’
added) similarly stressed that optimal From these brief overviews, it seems clear
exchange efficiency need not always result: that some promise for more effective integra-
‘the degree to which any individual organiza- tion is found in the common belief that there
tion will be pushed to find and adopt are (social) structural constraints on the
internal cost economies will reflect both the otherwise purposeful behavior of organiza-
level of competitive pressure to which it is tional actors (Ingram & Clay, 2000). If one
subjected and the available strategic alterna- begins with organizational economics, the
tives.’ Along similar lines, Winter (1991) task is to integrate the many institutional
noted that competitive pressures operate on constraints on rationality into the accepted
whole organizations and that sub-optimal choice paradigms. If one begins with institu-
and even dysfunctional intra-organizational tional theory, the task is to find a way to
CHARTING PROGRESS AT THE NEXUS OF INSTITUTIONAL THEORY AND ECONOMICS 563

inject some economic rationality into the researchers access to different dependent and
otherwise overly passive predictions that (in this case) independent variables.
emanate from institutional theory. However, the prospect of a more complete
and synthetic integration of the institutional
and economic perspectives requires that the
theories themselves interact in order to
PROGRESS TOWARDS INTEGRATION deliver a more nuanced account of important
organizational phenomena. But, as we saw in
Fulfilling this promise, we have been seeing a recent exchange between Zuckerman
a range of organizational research that may (2004b) and Zajac and Westphal (2004a), it
be cast (explicitly or implicitly) as an inte- is quite a bit more challenging to achieve a
gration of institutional and economic satisfactory synthesis when theories and
approaches. The most straightforward way explanations are intended to be integrative
for competing theoretical perspectives to rather than simply additive. All of these
come together is in empirical investigations authors see the prospect for sociological
that include sets of variables representing theory to improve upon prevailing economic
each. One example of this is found in Baker, accounts of financial markets. Zuckerman’s
Faulkner, and Fisher’s (1998) analysis of the (2004a) analysis in the same volume argues
expected duration of ties between advertising that incoherent stocks – as indicated by their
firms and the companies that hire them. The positions in the network of coverage by
authors develop a set of hypotheses grounded investment analysts – face interpretation
in competitive, power-based and institutional problems which lead to greater volumes of
explanations of tie duration. After running trading and greater pricing volatility in
their analysis, they are able to conclude that response to new information relevant to those
all three forces influence client–agency ties stocks. Zajac and Westphal (2004b) invoke
and that their importance clearly varies. institutional theory in general and decou-
From there, they are able to discuss how the pling in particular to explain the pattern of
latter two theoretical perspectives help to stock market reactions to announced stock
elaborate a basic economic view of markets repurchase plans, emphasizing those plans
as straightforward competitive spaces. that were never actually implemented.
Similar types of analyses are found at the Notwithstanding the common interest in
intersection of institutional and transaction some theoretical integration, the above-
cost theories. Shane and Foo (1999) add a set mentioned commentaries invoke questions
of institutional variables to models predicting about the need for a faithful representation of
survival rates of new franchisors and con- each base theory (Zuckerman, 2004b) and
clude that survival is better explained by about how far certain basic economic
adding the institutional variables. D’Aunno, assumptions can and should be stretched in
Succi, and Alexander (2000) argue and then order to achieve theoretical synthesis (Zajac
find that market (economic) and institutional & Westphal, 2004a). And note that this
forces combine to influence radical changes particular debate was waged between an
in rural hospitals. Yiu and Makino (2002) economic sociologist and two organizational
conduct a similar analysis of the use of joint theorists. It would seem that it is easier to
ventures and find that both transaction cost conclude that institutional variables add to
and institutional theory variables return the explanatory power of economic models
significant coefficients in their models. than it is to determine how institutional
These types of empirical efforts are indica- theory might alter the way economists should
tive of the type of integration suggested by build their models.
Gibbons (2005) when he notes that exposure Before discussing the many challenges
to different theoretical perspectives allows that impede a more satisfying theoretical
564 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

integration of these two perspectives on organizational performance by actively


organizations, it is important to emphasize managing aspects of their institutional envi-
that some progress is being made. In propos- ronments. Invoking Suchman (1995), they
ing a nexus between institutional theory and are beginning to articulate how managers
organizational economics, Roberts and might gain, maintain and repair different
Greenwood (1997) proposed that these vari- types of legitimacy, which is itself a critical
ous institutionalisms be grouped into two organizational resource, especially in indus-
broad categories of influence: pre-conscious try settings wherein the dominant selection
and post-conscious. In this respect, forces are not efficiency based.
they follow Jepperson (1991: 147), who These theoretical integrations actually fit
stressed that ‘one may take for granted some nicely with an economic conception of
pattern because one does not perceive it, rational, albeit constrained organizational
or think about it [i.e., pre-conscious]; actors. When there are forces in the external
alternatively, one may subject the pattern to environment that make it costly or impossi-
substantial scrutiny, but still take it for ble to act efficiently, or if there are forces
granted … as an external objective constraint that favor objectives other than efficiency,
[i.e., post-conscious].’ Similarly, Aldrich then it makes sense that the constrained eco-
and Fiol (1994) suggested that the nomic actors will make different choices.
institutional environment delivers two Failure to recognize these forces would pro-
distinct types of legitimacy: cognitive (i.e., duce accounts of organizational behavior that
pre-conscious) and sociopolitical legitimacy are under-specified. The problem is that
(i.e., post-conscious). institutional theory also claims that institu-
A review of the organizational research tional forces take hold in predicting behav-
published in the last fifteen years reveals an iors when actors are not expected to behave
important stream that integrates insights purposefully or rationally. This said, we have
from institutional theory into strategic not seen many similar explanations of
approaches that, while not explicitly eco- managerial choice in the context of pre-
nomic, draw heavily from economics. conscious institutional influences and
Consider Oliver’s (1997) article that inte- constraints.
grates institutional theory and the resource-
based view of the firm. This begins to think
about organizational heterogeneity as being
driven in part by the institutional forces that PROSPECTS FOR FURTHER
(differentially) condition resource accumula- INTEGRATION
tion processes. Deephouse (1999) similarly
introduces institutional factors into strategy The integration of organizational economics
research. Because legitimacy is something and institutional theory should be viewed
that should augment organizational perform- among the broader set of efforts aimed at
ance, managers must weigh the costs and integrating economics and sociology. In the
benefits of being different against the gains last fifteen years, sociologists have published
associated with conforming to institutional- a few articles in leading economics journals
ized industry practices. Also in this line of exploring the nexus of sociology and
research is Krishnan, Joshi, and Krishnan’s economics. While offering some hope for the
(2004) attempt to integrate institutional theory future, Baron and Hannan (1994: 1140)
and the resource-based view in an explana- observed that ‘economists looking for sociol-
tion of the pattern of merger activity. All of ogists for insights regarding norms and insti-
these articles elaborate the above-mentioned tutions report considerable disappointment’
post-conscious institutional influences by and that these same economists have a diffi-
showing how managers might augment cult time setting aside their long-standing
CHARTING PROGRESS AT THE NEXUS OF INSTITUTIONAL THEORY AND ECONOMICS 565

preference for efficiency-driven accounts of comprehensive review of institutional eco-


these norms and institutions. Podolny (2003) nomics, Hodgson (1998) made reference to
urged economists to make greater use of just a handful of sociologists (including
visual imagery in their theorizing and illus- Wayne Baker, James Coleman, Anthony
trates his point by showing how network Giddens, Mark Granovetter and Harrison
sociologists have developed a more refined White), all noteworthy contributors to socio-
and realistic account of social capital than logical theory, but none considered central to
that currently being developed by econo- the development of the sociological variant
mists. Granovetter (2005) elaborated this of institutional theory.
point by describing how social networks A second reason might relate to the differ-
affect economic outcomes by influencing the ent approaches to (especially empirical)
flow and quality of information, the efficacy research between network, ecological and
of rewards and punishments, and the economic sociologists and their institutional
development of trust among exchange part- counterparts. The sociological variants repre-
ners. Both of these latter authors illustrate sented in the above articles tend to pursue
their main points with reference to several deductive theorizing to set up quantitative
specific empirical projects that are situated at analyses of the predictions that result. On the
the nexus of economics and network other hand, institutional theorists, especially
sociology. those working on Scott’s (1995) cognitive
A review of these (admittedly few) articles pillar, tend to pursue more inductive qualita-
reveals several things. That they were pub- tive research agendas. For example, consider
lished at all indicates that there is at least a Zilber’s (2006) analyzes the discourse sur-
latent interest within the economics profes- rounding the high technology sector in Israel
sion in how different sociological approaches to explore ‘institutionalization as transla-
might inform or elaborate economic analysis tion.’ In a similar vein, Suddaby and
(Baron & Hannan, 1994). However, that they Greenwood (2005) analyze the ‘discursive
are all commentary articles suggests that struggle’ that ensued between proponents
many of the potential impacts have not yet and opponents of a new organizational form
been explored or realized. Moreover, note that sprang from an attempt to merge an
that none of the sociologists invited to accounting firm with a law firm. That these
address the economics profession about pos- qualitative approaches are not widely
sible contributions from sociology are insti- accepted in the economics profession
tutional theorists, but rather ecological, (Hirsch, Michaels, & Friedman, 1987)
network, or economic sociologists. This might speak to the under-representation
latter observation may be due to several rea- of certain strands of institutional theory in
sons. First, as suggested earlier, economic these calls for greater appreciation of the
approaches to organizations are subsumed sociological contributions to economic
under the broader heading of institutional research. In this respect, note the conclusion
economics (Roberts & Greenwood, 1997). that Hodgson (1998) reached about the
As a result, the economics profession already demise of the ‘old institutionalism’ within
has a subfield that studies institutional influ- economics:
ences on economic behavior. Although the old institutionalism was partially disabled by a
potential contributions from the sociological combined result of the profound shifts in social
variant of institutional theory are broader science in the 1910–1940 period and of the rise of
than those currently found within institu- a mathematical style of neoclassical economics …
With their use of formal techniques, mathematical
tional economics, the placement of the latter
economists caught the imagination of both theo-
camp within economics might hinder the rists and policy makers. In comparison, institution-
field’s ability to perceive them. As (possible) alism was regarded as technically less rigorous, and
evidence of this, note that in a recent thereby inferior. (1998: 167)
566 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

This suggests that the lack of (potential) appreciate qualitative analysis’), this leaves
appreciation for the more cognitive institu- the prospect of important organizational
tional approaches is rooted in some antago- issues being under-theorized. Even worse, it
nism toward the type of research that these may cause scholars working from the
latter scholars tend to pursue. different perspectives to offer fundamentally
The third possible reason for the relative different explanations for what may be
neglect of institutional theory is more subtle. exactly the same phenomena. Consider the
If one stops to consider the purported case when a researcher observes that the
contributions of ecological, network, and eco- probability that an organizational actor ‘does x’
nomic sociology to mainstream economic increases with the number of prior actors
approaches, one might conclude that institu- who have ‘done x’ in the past. To an institu-
tional sociology can have an important indi- tional theorist, this seems like evidence of
rect influence. Within organizational ecology, cognitive legitimacy. The local prevalence
legitimacy has emerged as an important com- of a given practice causes it to become
plement to competitive effects as a driver of institutionalized and therefore taken for
organizational vital rates and therefore indus- granted.
trial evolution. This is clearly evident in the Now consider the more recent explanation
now standard density-dependence predictions of ‘informational cascades’ (Bikhchandani,
(Carroll & Hannan, 1999). Whereas organiza- Hirshleifer, & Welsh, 1992). According to
tional sociologists have staged heated debates these economists, cascades are observed
about exactly how legitimacy should be when, based on the observations of choices
framed and measured (Baum & Powell, 1995; made by others, an actor makes the same
Hannan & Carroll, 1995), one sees a potential choice regardless of her own private informa-
contribution of institutional theory to tion. On the surface, it seems like economists
economics channeled through the latter’s are embracing the density-driven legitimacy
potential synthesis with organizational ecol- processes channeled through organizational
ogy (Geroski, 2001). Similar conclusions ecologists from institutional theory.
may be made about the contributions of insti- However, in these models of informational
tutional theory through network and cascades, there are no such legitimation
economic sociology. The former group tends processes. Rather, this actor is actually
to channel important institutional concepts behaving rationally and what the economists
such as norms (Portes, 1998), while the over- are observing is called a ‘rational herd’
lap between economic sociology and institu- (Banerjee, 1992): Even when all actors col-
tional theory is well documented (Fligstein, lectively have overwhelming information in
2001). That institutional theory informs these favor of the ‘correct’ course of action, each
other sociological perspectives, which are in actor may still take the ‘wrong’ action. We
turn being called upon to refine economic see within economics the recognition of
approaches, indicates potential for an indirect something that is clearly a density-dependent
integration of institutional theory and process. We also see the potential for the two
economic approaches to organizations. groups of scholars to collaborate on a more
All comments about potential notwithstand- meaningful and nuanced account of this
ing, it would be safe to say that economists observation. In the end, however, economists
have not yet embraced the main tenets of tweak the basic rational actor model and
institutional theory as they develop their refuse to recognize the cognitive institutional
accounts of market and organizational influences that might be operating.
phenomena. Be it due to a categorical over- The resulting stalemate reflects back to the
sight (i.e., ‘we already study institutions’) or basic tension inherent in any integration of
a lack of appreciation of the typical institu- economics and institutional theory. The latter
tional mode of analysis (i.e., ‘we do not group seeks to elaborate the externalized
CHARTING PROGRESS AT THE NEXUS OF INSTITUTIONAL THEORY AND ECONOMICS 567

social constraints that impinge on the agency evaluation and abandonment decisions on the
of actors (i.e., cognitive legitimacy), while part of the analysts, they are able to offer a
the former seeks to develop more nuanced more nuanced account of when otherwise
accounts of the inherent rationality of those rational actors are made passive in the face of
actors (i.e., rational herds).1 The problem is institutional pressures, and when their
that both accounts cannot be simultaneously accumulating knowledge and information
correct. If actors are reflexively adopting the allows them to adjust their behaviors more
more prevalent ‘x’ because it has become purposefully.3
taken for granted then they are not forming
and updating assessments based on the
balance of private and public information.
One way to make progress on this front is by WHERE IS THIS HEADING?
conducting detailed examinations of the
decision-making processes that are actually If one casts the integration issue as a simple
adopted by the focal actors. The problem debate between whether organizational
here is that we are taken back to the above- actors are rational or are passively shaped by
mentioned ambivalence among economists prevailing institutional forces, then there is
toward the outcomes of such qualitative or little hope for progress toward integration.
interpretive empirical exercises.2 There is The good news here is that – as suggested in
simply no shared appreciation of the more several places in this chapter – several schol-
qualitative research approaches that would ars are moving past the simplest of polemics
help determine whether and how legitimation by modeling organizational actors as being
might be shaping the decision-making inside purposeful within institutional constraints.
the information cascades. Oliver (1991), Deephouse (1999) and
Scholars working toward an improved Suchman (1995) are developing accounts
understanding of the organizational phenom- of how managers seek to accrue legitimacy
ena should not strive to lay down overlapping by actively managing post-conscious
and inconsistent accounts of the same things. institutional constraints, while Rao et al.
Rather, they should strive to develop more (2001), Zuckerman (2004a) and Zajac and
synthetic and more reasonable accounts of Westphal (2004b) are incorporating different
these phenomena. One way to make progress institutional elements into prevailing
is to follow the advice of Zuckerman (2004a, economics accounts of how stock markets
2004b) and take seriously the idea that actors actually operate.
seek to, and in many cases do, behave ration- This said, further progress along these
ally and then call on sociological explana- lines may not be as smooth as some would
tions to explain behavior that sits beyond the like. Problems in developing a more produc-
bounds of that rationality. In this respect, tive synthesis will inevitably arise from
note what happens when organizational underlying tensions between the ‘culture of
researchers adopt the more synthetic economics,’ the ‘culture of institutional
approach. Rao, Greve, and Davis (2001) con- theory’ and the ‘culture of the integrative
ducted an analysis of information cascades in domains.’ What is ultimately required is an
the context of stock analysts’ decisions to agnostic blending of the irrational and the
cover certain firms. While they find evidence rational elements of organizational issues.
of mimetic behavior in the context of cover- However, whereas economists are becoming
age decisions, they are careful to understand more open to the prospects of constraints
the extent to which their results imply that operating on rationality (witness the rise
‘actors are cognitive dopes rather than of behavioral economics), they are less
cognitive misers’ (2001: 502). In the end, by interested in approaches that begin with
examining the full range of adoption, the notion that the majority of observed
568 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

organizational behavior sits outside the to conduct and interpret empirical research
purview of rational calculus. We require an that speaks to the emerging integrative
agnostic blending of a respect for social insights and explanations. Here, economists’
structural constraints on action with the preferences for deductive theorizing leading
notion that organizational actors strive to be, to archival studies that validate predictions
and indeed can be quite purposeful at times. will come up against institutional theorists’
In this respect, institutional theorists are too preferences for qualitative research that cap-
often skeptical of research that adopts the tures the salient nuances of prevailing institu-
latter orientation. All told, fundamental ten- tional environments. Without recourse to
sions between the core disciplines may retard common methodologies, the groups run the
the development of a productive synthesis risk of speaking and theorizing in more
within either mainstream economics or soci- similar terms while observing and drawing
ology journals. inferences from the organizational world in
This leaves journals devoted to organiza- incompatible ways. We have seen this in the
tions and strategy as outlets for integrative institutional theorists’ discomfort with an
research. However – and especially in exclusive reliance on measuring cognitive
respect of work that addresses the pre- legitimacy with counts of the number of
conscious institutional influences – we organizations adopting a given organization
require research that embraces both goal- form or practice (Baum & Powell, 1995;
directed action and genuinely emergent Hannan & Carroll, 1995). These concerns
organizational outcomes. Whereas organiza- were countered by claims that more nuanced
tional research is amenable to finding some approaches do not lend themselves to the
balance between rational and (seemingly) generalizability that more positivist scholars
irrational bases of action, it has a bias toward seek (Hannan & Carroll, 1995). It is also
studying problems faced by managers and a evident in similar concerns about using
concomitant tendency to speak to how indi- period dummy variables to account for vary-
vidual actors might ‘effectively manage’ ing institutional influences. While the justifi-
their institutional constraints. This bias may cation for the expected period effects may be
push integration attempts away from strong and drawn from the kind of contextual
effectively addressing the pre-conscious knowledge favored by institutional theorists,
influences that emanate from the taken- the context-specific interpretation of these
for-granted elements in the institutional period effects also tends to limit generaliz-
environment. Note in this respect that organi- ability while suppressing the richness inher-
zational ecologists once had a hard time con- ent in the underlying data.
vincing managerial audiences (and therefore If one of the latent impediments to a more
journals) that most organizational change satisfying integration of institutional and
occurs through selection and not purposeful economic theorizing relates to different pre-
adaptation. They therefore published much ferred modes of empirical analysis, then
of their early research in sociology journals. there may be some hope for further advances.
Institutional theorists who are working We are beginning to see developments on the
Scott’s (1995) cognitive pillar might have a empirical front by ecological, network and
similarly hard time getting these same audi- economic sociologists who are conducting
ences to accept the premise that managers empirical work in a manner that is quite
‘tend to do x because they really don’t know acceptable to those trained in economics. By
any better.’ capturing institutional ideas in network
Consider also that as the more economic- models and methods, or institutional con-
oriented, institutional and organizational structs with variables that are amenable to
scholars begin to find common theoretical large-scale archival analysis (without
ground, they will increasingly face pressures recourse to idiosyncratically explained, or
CHARTING PROGRESS AT THE NEXUS OF INSTITUTIONAL THEORY AND ECONOMICS 569

history-specific period effects) these scholars simple fact that boundedly rational organiza-
are at least challenging economists to think tional actors do behave purposefully, and
differently about the organizational and they do act and make choices within institu-
market phenomena that they are wont to tional contexts, where much is taken for
study. This said, the concern among institu- granted and where external pressures
tional theorists is that even these approaches do render certain otherwise efficiency-
are not sufficiently nuanced to capture the enhancing options unattractive. The real
relevant details of prevailing institutional question is not whether these statements are
environments. What we need are large-scale true, but rather how these actors go about
archival techniques that also allow reconciling the different inducements and
researchers to capture and model the nuance constraints to generate the outcomes that
and detail of institutionally-relevant data. In organizational scholars are then called upon
this respect, recent developments in text and to observe and explain. It would be sad (even
discourse analysis may offer potential for a ironic) if we were unable to tap the colle-
more effective empirical synthesis. Mohr ctive rationality of these two scholarly
(1998) summarized the many techniques communities because of our failure to
available to those trying to discern and inter- examine those things that we
pret patterns from text-based data or from inefficiently take for granted, or because
verbal protocols. These approaches aim to be we fail to appreciate and overcome the
faithful to the richness of the sources from powerful external forces that constrain
which meaning structures are derived and to the operation of our respective scholarly
offer interpretations of the observed struc- communities.
tures that are themselves generalizable. As
such, they offer one means to bridge the
qualitative-archival divide that currently sep-
arates institutional and economic researchers. ACKNOWLEDGMENTS
An excellent example of this kind of work is
Hsu’s (2006) analysis of evaluative schemas The author would like to thank Royston
in the U.S. film industry. By analyzing text Greenwood and Christine Oliver for guid-
extracted from a large number of movie ance and feedback that led to improvements
reviews published over many years, she is in this chapter.
able to offer insights about how variance in
the structure of these reviews (predictably)
influences observed market behaviors.
Assuming that more empirically-oriented
NOTES
scholars are prepared to spend the time and
1 Moreover, the prospective mediating group –
effort that is required to assemble such the organizational ecologists – would be content
detailed datasets, and assuming that they are with the empirical generalizability of evolution and
willing to maintain a proper balance between change as a density-driven process.
preserving the nuance found in the 2 Blinder (Blinder, Canetti, Lebow and Rodd,
1998) is one economist who sought to gain some
underlying institutional data while seeking
empirical traction in this manner. Growing frustrated
theories, and explanations that are by a growing number of competing and theoretical
generalizable to other contexts, these explanations for price stickiness, he set out to survey
techniques offer the promise of more integra- those who actually set prices in order to determine
tive empirical research to complement any what they actually consider when setting prices.
3 In a similar manner, Ahmadjian and Robinson
emerging synthetic theories.
(2001) propose that rational and institutional influ-
In closing, let me stress that the integration ences can operate on different aspects of the same
of economics and institutional theory must phenomenon. In an analysis of organizational downsiz-
progress at a healthy pace. This is due to the ing, they show that economic factors account for
570 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

whether downsizing occurs but that institutional theory Carroll, G. R., & Hannan, M. T. 1999. The
is required to account for the pace at which it occurs. Demography of Corporations and Industries.
Princeton: Princeton University Press.
D’Aunno, T., Succi, M., & Alexander, J. A.
2000. The role of institutional and market
REFERENCES forces in divergent organizational change.
Administrative Science Quarterly, 45:
Ahmadjian, C. L., & Robinson, P. 2001. Safety 679–703.
in numbers: Downsizing and the deinstitu- David, R. J., & Han, S.-K. 2004. A systematic
tionalization of permanent employment in assessment of the empirical support for
Japan. Administrative Science Quarterly, 46: transaction cost economics. Strategic
622–54. Management Journal, 25: 39–58.
Aldrich, H. E., & Fiol, C. M. 1994. Fools rush in? Deephouse, D. L. 1999. To be different or to be
The institutional context of industrial cre- the same? It’s a question (and theory) of
ation. Academy of Management Review, 19: strategic balance. Strategic Management
645–70. Journal, 20: 147–66.
Baker, W. E., Faulkner, R. R., & Fisher, G. A. Dimaggio, P. J., & Powell, W. W. 1983. The iron
1998. Hazards of the market: The continuity cage revisited: Institutional isomorphism and
and dissolution of interorganizational market collective rationality in organizational fields.
relationships. American Sociological Review, American Journal of Sociology, 48:
63: 147–77. 147–60.
Banerjee, A. V. 1992. A simple model of herd Fligstein, N. 2001. The Architecture of Markets:
behavior. Quarterly Journal of Economics, An Economic Sociology of Twenty-First-
107: 797–817. Century. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Baron, J. N., & Hannan, M. T. 1994. The impact Geroski, P. A. 2001. Exploring the niche over-
of economics on contemporary sociology. laps between organizational ecology and
Journal of Economic Literature, 32: industrial economics. Industrial and
1111–46. Corporate Change, 10: 507–40.
Baum, J. A. C., & Powell, W. W. 1995. Gibbons, R. 2005. What is economic sociology
Cultivating an institutional ecology of organ- and should any economists care? Journal of
izations: Comment on Hannan, Carroll, Economic Perspectives, 19.
Dundon and Torres. American Journal of Granovetter, M. 1985. Economic action and
Sociology, 60: 529–38. social structure: The problem of embedded-
Berger, P. L., & Luckmann, T. 1966. The Social ness. American Journal of Sociology, 91:
Construction of Reality. New York: Anchor 481–510.
Books. Granovetter, M. 2005. The impact of social
Bikhchandani, S., Hirshleifer, D., & Welsh, I. structure on economic outcomes. Journal of
1992. A theory of fads, fashion, custom, and Economic Perspectives, 19: 33–50.
cultural change as informational cascades. Hannan, M. T., & Carroll, G. R. 1995. Theory
Journal of Political Economy, 100: building and cheap talk about legitimation:
992–1026. Reply to Baum and Powell. American
Blinder, A. S., Canetti, E. R. D., Lebow, D. E., & Sociological Review, 60: 539–44.
Rodd, J. B. 1998. Asking About Prices: A Hesterley, W. S., Liebeskind, J., & Zenger, T. R.
New Approach to Understanding Price 1990. Organizational economics: An
Stickiness. New York: Russell Sage Foundation impending revolution in organization theory.
Publications. Academy of Management Review, 15:
Burns, L. R., & Wholey, D. R. 1993. Adoption 402–20.
and abandonment of matrix management Hirsch, P. M., Michaels, S., & Friedman, R.
programs: Effects of organizational charac- 1987. ‘Dirty hands’ versus ‘clean models’: Is
teristics and interorganizational networks. sociology in danger of being seduced by
Academy of Management Journal, 36: economics? Theory and Society, 16:
106–38. 317–36.
CHARTING PROGRESS AT THE NEXUS OF INSTITUTIONAL THEORY AND ECONOMICS 571

Hodgson, G. M. 1998. The approach of institu- Rao, H., Greve, H. R., & Davis, G. F. 2001. Fool’s
tional economics. Journal of Economic gold: Social proof in the initiation and aban-
Literature, 36: 166–92. donment of coverage by Wall Street analysts.
Hsu, G. 2006. Evaluative schemas and the Administrative Science Quarterly, 46:
attention of critics in the US film industry. 502–26.
Industrial and Corporate Change, 15: Roberts, P. W., & Greenwood, R. 1997.
467–96. Integrating transaction cost and institutional
Ingram, P., & Clay, K. 2000. The choice-within- theories: Toward a constrained-efficiency
constraints new institutionalism and implica- framework. Academy of Management
tions for sociology. Annual Review of Review, 22: 346–73.
Sociology, 26: 525–46. Robins, J. A. 1987. Organizational economics:
Jepperson, R. L. 1991. Institutions, institutional Notes on the use of transaction cost theory
effects and institutionalism. In W. W. Powell, & in the study of organizations. Administrative
P. J. DiMaggio (Eds.), The New Institutionalism Science Quarterly, 32: 68–86.
in Organizational Analysis: 143–63. Chicago: Scott, W. R. 1995. Institutions and Organizations.
University of Chicago Press. Thousand Oaks: Sage Publications.
Krishnan, R. A., Joshi, S., & Krishnan, H. 2004. Selznick, P. 1957. Leadership in Administration:
The influence of mergers on firms’ product- A Sociological Interpretation. Berkley:
mix strategies. Strategic Management University of California Press.
Journal, 25: 587–611. Shane, S., & Foo, M.-D. 1999. New firm sur-
Meyer, J. W., & Rowan, B. 1977. vival: Institutional explanations for new fran-
Institutionalized organizations: Formal struc- chisor mortality. Management Science, 45:
ture as myth and ceremony. American 142–59.
Journal of Sociology, 83: 340–63. Suchman, M. C. 1995. Managing legitimacy:
Mohr, J. W. 1998. Measuring meaning struc- Strategic and institutional approaches.
tures. Annual Review of Sociology, 24: Academy of Management Review, 20:
345–70. 571–610.
Oliver, C. 1991. Strategic responses to institu- Suddaby, R., & Greenwood, R. 2005. Rhetorical
tional processes. Academy of Management strategies of legitimacy. Administrative
Review, 16: 145–79. Science Quarterly, 50: 35–67.
Oliver, C. 1997. Sustainable competitive advan- Tolbert, P. S., & Zucker, L. G. 1984. Institutional
tage: Combining institutional and resource- sources of change in the formal structure of
based views. Strategic Management Journal, organizations: The diffusion of civil service
18: 697–713. reform, 1880–1935. Administrative Science
Ouchi, W. G. 1980. Markets, bureaucracies, Quarterly, 28: 22–39.
and clans. Administrative Science Quarterly, Williamson, O. E. 1975. Markets and Hierarchies:
25: 129–41. Analysis and Antitrust Implications. New York:
Podolny, J. M. 2003. A picture is worth a thou- The Free Press.
sand symbols: A sociologist’s view of the Williamson, O. E. 1981. The economics of
economic pursuit of truth. The American organization: The transaction cost approach.
Economic Review, 93: 169–74. American Journal of Sociology, 87:
Portes, A. 1998. Social capital: Its origins and 548–77.
applications in modern sociology. Annual Williamson, O. E. 1987. Economics and sociol-
Review of Sociology, 24: 1–24. ogy: Promoting a dialogue. In G. Farkas, & P.
Powell, W. W. 1991. Expanding the scope of England (Eds.), Industries, Firms and Jobs:
institutional analysis. In W. W. Powell, & P. J. 159–85.
DiMaggio (Eds.), The New Institutionalism in Williamson, O. E. 1991. Comparative economic
Organizational Analysis: 183–203. Chicago: organization: The analysis of discrete struc-
University of Chicago Press. tural alternatives. Administrative Science
Powell, W. W., & DiMaggio, P. J. 1991. The Quarterly, 36: 219–44.
New Institutionalism in Organizational Analy- Williamson, O. E. 1992. Markets, hierarchies,
sis. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. and the modern corporation: An unfolding
572 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

perspective. Journal of Economic Behavior Zajac, E. J., & Westphal, J. D. 2004b. The social
and Organization, 17: 335–52. construction of market value: Institutional-
Williamson, O. E. 1993. Transaction cost eco- ization and learning perspectives on stock
nomics and organization theory. Industrial market reactions. American Sociological
and Corporate Change, 2: 107–156. Review, 69: 433–57.
Winter, S. G. 1991. On Coase, competence Zilber, T. B. 2006. The work of the symbolic
and the corporation. In O. E. Williamson, & in institutional processes: Translations
S. G. Winter (Eds.), The Nature of the Firm: of rational myths in Israeli high tech.
179–95. New York: Oxford University Press. Academy of Management Journal, 49:
Yiu, D., & Makino, S. 2002. The choice 281–303.
between joint venture and wholly owned Zuckerman, E. W. 2004a. Structural incoher-
subsidiary: An institutional perspective. ence and stock market activity. American
Organization Science, 13: 667–83. Sociological Review, 69: 405–32.
Zajac, E. J., & Westphal, J. D. 2004a. Should Zuckerman, E. W. 2004b. Towards the social
sociological theories venture into ‘economic reconstruction of an interdisciplinary turf
territory?’ Yes! American Sociological war. American Sociological Review, 69:
Review, 69: 465–71. 458–64.
24
Ecologists and Institutionalists:
Friends or Foes?
Heather A. Haveman and Robert J. David

In this chapter, we consider the web of rela- Our title poses a question about the nature
tions between institutional and ecological of the relationship between ecology and
analysis of organizations. These research tra- institutionalism. Depending on whom you
ditions are very similar in some ways, ask, you will get divergent answers to this
notably that foundational articles for both question. Some will say that ecologists
were published in the same year (Meyer and and institutionalists are happy bedfellows
Rowan, 1977; Hannan and Freeman, 1977). because they ask similar questions about the
Yet, in other ways, they are remarkably dif- nature and functioning of organizations and
ferent, as evidenced by vociferous debates they provide similar answers (e.g., Fligstein
between ecologists and institutionalists (e.g., and Dauter, 2007). Both sets of scholars
Carroll and Hannan, 1989a vs. Zucker, 1989 attend to many of the same concepts, notably
vs. Carroll and Hannan, 1989b; Hannan, legitimacy and organizational form, and seek
Carroll, Dundon, and Torres, 1995 vs. Baum to explain change and stability in organiza-
and Powell, 1995 vs. Hannan and Carroll, tional systems. Moreover, both sets of schol-
1995). Given their concurrent origins and the ars tend to conduct longitudinal analysis of
combination of similarity and difference in original data on collections of organizations –
their lived histories, it is not surprising that populations in the case of ecologists and
these two research traditions have been fields in the case of institutionalists. Such
sometimes contrasted and other times com- basic similarities are not surprising, as both
bined. In this chapter, we will review how ecology and institutionalism emerged as
and when ecological theory has been used in corrections to the rationalist approach preva-
contrast to or in combination with institu- lent in the 1960s and early 1970s, which
tional explanations, and suggest how they focused on the design and management of
might be fruitfully combined in future efficient organizations, and both directed
research. attention towards the external environment
574 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

and away from internal organizational func- who, when surrounded by ecologists, feels
tioning. like a stout-hearted institutionalist, and when
But when faced with the same question, surrounded by institutionalists, feels like a
other scholars will wonder whether ecologi- died-in-the-wool ecologist. Robert is an
cal analysis is inconsistent with institutional- organizational theorist who has delved into
ism (e.g., Zucker, 1989; Baum and Powell, both traditions, yet never feels quite like a
1995). Perhaps the most obvious divide ‘pure’ ecologist or a ‘pure’ institutionalist.
stems from the fact that ecologists investigate We are thus members of both communities,
highly abstract models of population evolu- in varying proportions, depending on time of
tion and organizational outcomes, while day, question at hand, and surroundings. But
institutionalists seek nuanced explanations at heart, we are members of a broader com-
that are sensitive to the specifics of time and munity – organizational sociologists. As
place. This yields, by necessity, a difference such, our goal is to understand formal organ-
in relationships between theory and data: izations, the building blocks of all modern
research in organizational ecology is driven societies and the most powerful actors in
by a desire to test and extend formal models those societies (Coleman, 1974; Perrow,
with general applicability, while research in 1991). We are happy to achieve this objective
the institutional tradition is driven by a desire with any implements that we can use skill-
to explain particular empirical phenomena. fully – including, but not limited to, institu-
This divergence in research activity stems tional and ecological tools.
from a profound difference in theoretical
perspective: organizational ecology focuses
on demography (numbers of organizations
and their vital rates), while institutional WHAT IS ORGANIZATIONAL
analysis focuses on culture (norms, values, ECOLOGY ANYWAY?
and expectations) and its manifestations
(rules, regulations, conceptions, frames, and Organizational ecologists wonder ‘why
schemas). are there so many kinds of organizations?’
To discover our own take on the vexing and seek to understand the distribution of
question of whether ecologists and institu- organizations across different environments
tionalists are friends or foes, you must read (Hannan and Freeman, 1977: 936). To this
on. To convince you that our answer is end, ecologists have adapted and applied the-
correct, we proceed in stages. We first define ories and formal models of population biol-
the nature and scope of ecological analysis. ogy and human demography to explain the
After briefly reviewing the institutional evolution of organizational systems – that is,
perspective, we reflect in detail on how, and to explain rates of organizational founding,
how well, ecology and institutionalism get failure, growth, performance, and change.
along intellectually. Our assessment of Ecologists begin with the core assumption
convergence and divergence encompasses that understanding organizational diversity
research questions, assumptions, predictions, requires ‘population thinking’ (Hannan and
and methods; we pay particular attention to Freeman, 1989: 15). Populations are aggre-
those hard-to-define, harder-to-defend, yet gates of organizations that share a common
critical issues that are related to taste and dependence on material and cultural environ-
style. After answering the question posed in ments. Empirically, populations have been
our title, we conclude by suggesting how identified as sets of organizations that pro-
scholars in both traditions can benefit from a duce similar goods or services, use similar
closer relationship. resources, and have similar identities.
Some disclosure is in order before we Organizational diversity increases when new
begin. Heather is an organizational theorist populations emerge and expand in size;
ECOLOGISTS AND INSTITUTIONALISTS: FRIENDS OR FOES? 575

it declines when existing populations Ecologists have extended and refined the
decrease in size and become extinct. basic density-dependence model. One
In the paragraphs below, we briefly review approach involves assessing the effect of
the main assumptions underlying ecological density across subpopulations defined along
analysis and the main lines of research.1 Our such key dimensions of organizational form
commentary involves four areas: density as goals, size, technology, and location. For
dependence, resource partitioning, structural example, a study of competitive interactions
inertia, and organizational identity. We (those that harm one or both parties) and
discuss each in turn. mutualistic interactions (those that benefit
one or both parties) between commercial
(for-profit) and mutual (non-profit) tele-
Density dependence phone companies in Iowa disaggregated pop-
ulation density according to technology and
The basic model of organizations’ vital rates location relative to the focal organization
is density dependence, which proposes that (Barnett and Carroll, 1987). This analysis
organizational founding and failure depend revealed that the non-local density of both
on population density, meaning the number commercial and mutual telephone companies
of organizations in a population. When den- raised failure rates, as did the local density of
sity is low, increasing density enhances the commercial companies. These results indi-
legitimacy, or taken-for-grantedness, of the cate purely competitive interactions. Only
population; thus, at low levels of density, the local density of mutual companies con-
increases in density cause founding rates to tributed to mutualistic interactions. Density
rise and failure rates to fall. At higher levels has been disaggregated by subpopulation
of density, however, more organizations vie in studies of organizations as varied as
for resources, so competition becomes more breweries (Carroll and Swaminathan, 1992),
intense. At the same time, increasing health-care organizations (Wholey, Christianson,
numbers of organizations provide only incre- and Sanchez, 1992), and credit unions
mental legitimacy benefits. Thus, as density (Barron, West, and Hannan, 1994), demon-
increases, competition begins to overwhelm strating the broad applicability of this
legitimation as the primary mechanism approach.
driving vital rates. At high levels of density, Another way to disaggregate density is to
therefore, further increases in density cause allow for the fact that organizations in a pop-
founding rates to fall and failure rates to rise. ulation often differ in degree rather than
Over the full range of density – from very kind. To reflect this, some ecologists have
low to very high – this logic predicts followed McPherson (1983) and assessed
non-monotonic effects on vital rates, specifi- similarities (and differences) between popu-
cally an inverted-U-shaped relationship lation members by how much their domains
between density and founding rates, and a overlap (or not) along some dimension. One
U-shaped relationship between density and such study showed that Manhattan hotels
failure rates. The earliest empirical investiga- experienced more intense competition from
tions of the density-dependence model were hotels that overlapped in terms of size, geo-
Hannan and Freeman’s (1987, 1988) studies graphic location, and price (Baum and
of labour unions in the United States. They Mezias, 1992). Going even further, a study of
found that unions’ founding and failure rates day-care centres in Toronto showed that
followed the predicted non-monotonic pat- competition and mutualism varied with
terns. Many studies of other organizational overlap in the ages of children enrolled: a
populations have yielded similar effects high degree of overlap between a focal day-
(e.g., Carroll and Hannan, 1989a; Hannan care centre and other centres raised failure
and Carroll, 1992). rates, while a high degree of non-overlap
576 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

lowered failure rates (Baum and Singh, (Carroll and Swaminathan, 1992, 2000),
1994). wineries (Swaminathan, 1995), and automo-
bile manufacturers (Dobrev, Kim and
Hannan, 2001).
Resource partitioning
A related stream of research focuses on com- Inertia
petition and mutualism between organiza-
tions that serve a wide range of clients with a Organizational ecology proceeds from the
diverse array of products (‘generalists’) and assumption that the core features of organi-
organizations that focus on a more limited zations change slowly, if at all, because of
clientele, offering them a narrower set of strong inertial pressures (Hannan and
products (‘specialists’). The basic argument Freeman, 1984). Eight constraints on adapta-
is that when there are economies of scale and tion are proposed, four internal and four
a resource distribution with a single rich external (Hannan and Freeman, 1984). The
centre and poor peripheral regions, the internal constraints are investment in plant,
resource ‘space’ (the combination of inputs equipment, and specialized personnel; limits
and demand for output) becomes partitioned, on the internal information received by deci-
with generalists occupying the centre and sion-makers; vested interests; and organiza-
specialists the periphery (Carroll, 1985; tional history, which justifies past action and
Carroll, Dobrev and Swaminathan, 2003). prevents consideration of alternatives. The
This happens because generalists compete external pressures for stability are legal and
with one another to control the resource-rich economic barriers to entry and exit; con-
centre by offering generic products with straints on the external information gathered
broad appeal. Specialists, meanwhile, avoid by decision-makers; legitimacy considera-
competing with generalists in the market tions; and the problem of collective rational-
centre, instead exploiting peripheral regions ity and the general equilibrium. All of these
by serving small groups of clients with idio- pressures favour organizations that perform
syncratic tastes. Because economies of scale reliably and can account rationally for their
favour large organizations, the generalist actions, which in turn requires that organiza-
subpopulation concentrates; a smaller number tional structures be highly reproducible – that
of larger generalists competes for the market is, unchanging (Hannan and Freeman, 1984).
centre. As this happens, generalists focus If inert organizations are favoured over
more tightly on the market centre and aban- changeable ones, inert organizations will be
don more of the periphery to specialists. The less likely to fail.
upshot of this partitioning of the resource The structural inertia thesis does not imply
space between a core occupied by generalists that organizations never change; rather, it
and a periphery occupied by specialists is implies that when organizations do change,
that increasingly intense competition resources are diverted from operating to reor-
between generalists leads to not only higher ganizing, reducing effectiveness and increas-
failure rates for generalists, but also lower ing the likelihood of failing. Ecologists
failure rates and higher founding rates for distinguish between two consequences of
specialists. Like the density-dependence change: process effects, which stem from the
model and its offshoots, the resource- inevitable frictions generated by undertaking
partitioning model has been tested on a wide change and which are inherently deleterious,
array of organizations, including newspapers and content effects, which derive from the
(Carroll, 1985; Boone, Carroll and van altered fit between changed organizations
Witteloostuijn, 2002), auditors (Boone, and their environments, and which may be
Broecheler and Carroll, 2000), breweries good if fit to the environment is improved, or
ECOLOGISTS AND INSTITUTIONALISTS: FRIENDS OR FOES? 577

bad if fit is worsened (Barnett and Carroll, of organizations, including newspaper


1995). Notwithstanding the grim prognosis publishers (Carroll and Delacroix, 1982;
for organizational change, some of the more Freeman, Carroll and Hannan, 1983;
optimistic ecologists have investigated the Amburgey et al., 1993), labour unions
possibility that in some circumstances, (Freeman et al., 1983), and semiconductor
organizations can adapt and change can be manufacturers (Freeman et al., 1983). But
beneficial, such as when organizations these studies confounded the effects of age
diversify after large-scale shifts in external with those of size (Barron et al., 1994;
conditions (Haveman, 1992), or when organ- Hannan, 1998). Findings that failure rates
izations’ constituencies support the content decline with age may be spurious because
of change and are willing to supply resources there is a positive correlation between size
to effect change (Minkoff, 1999). Others and age, and a negative effect of size on fail-
have shown that ties to state and community ure. This was clear in an analysis of New
institutions, which provide resources and York credit unions: age on its own had a neg-
legitimacy, can buffer organizations from the ative effect on failure, but after including size
deleterious effects of change (Baum and in the analysis, the effect of age became pos-
Oliver, 1991). Despite these important limi- itive, while the effect of size was negative
tations on the inertia hypothesis, empirical (Barron et al., 1994). Similarly, size damp-
analysis generally shows that change harms ened failure rates for all but the largest life
organizations (Barnett and Carroll, 1995; insurance companies in New York, while
Carroll and Hannan, 2000: 357–380). age increased failure rates (Ranger-Moore,
Change may be harmful, but organizations 1997). The current consensus is that failure
do often change. Change exhibits momen- rates generally decline with size and increase
tum: the more organizations have changed in with age (Hannan, 1998). However, the effect
the past, the more they are likely to change in of age, after controlling for size, may be non-
the future because they have learned how to linear – increasing in the first few years after
change (Amburgey and Miner, 1992; founding, as fledgling organizations use up
Amburgey, Kelly and Barnett, 1993; Greve, their initial stores of resources, then decreas-
1998). Change is often driven by prior per- ing, as organizations learn how to operate
formance, assessed relative to goals, and by efficiently and develop solid reputations
changes made by rivals, which in the aggre- (Levinthal, 1991).
gate alter an organizational population’s
demography (Greve, 1998). If the forces that
drive change (notably performance) also Organizational form as identity
drive failure, analyses of change and failure
must account for endogeneity. Doing so The newest strand of ecological theory
reveals that even though change causes per- involves analyzing organizational forms as
formance to decline and the chance of failure identities or social codes, which are ‘recog-
to rise, there is a big difference between nizable patterns that take on rule-like stand-
well- and poorly-performing organizations. ing and get enforced by social agents’ (Pólos,
Poorly-performing organizations may benefit Hannan and Carroll, 2002: 89; see also
from change, but well-performing ones are Hannan, Pólos and Carroll, 2007). Such
usually harmed (Greve, 1999). socially-coded identities comprise both rules
Because older and larger organizations are of conduct and signals to internal and exter-
expected to be more inert and thus less likely nal observers. Rules of conduct provide
to fail, empirical research has often focused guidelines for members of a population by
on the effects of age and size on organiza- delimiting what they should and should not
tional failure. Failure rates have been found be and do, while signals generate a cognitive
to decline with age in studies of many kinds understanding about the population because
578 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

they define what observers understand the With regard to inertia, research on young
members of an organizational population are high-technology firms in California showed
and what they do. that the content effects of change are most
Thinking about organizational form as hazardous when they involve shifts in iden-
identity has benefited the other strands of tity (Hannan, Baron, Hsu and Koçak, 2006).
ecological analysis. Consider resource parti- Growth in market capitalization slowed and
tioning first. An analysis of the identities and failure rates rose following changes in
competitive tactics of U.S. breweries showed human-resource blueprints – a core aspect of
how and why established firms (mass-pro- these firms’ identities. In contrast, outside
ducer breweries) that are under siege by CEO succession depressed growth in market
insurgents (microbreweries and brewpubs) capitalization but did not affect failure rates.
have a limited ability to adopt the beneficial This study redirects attention from the inter-
features of their new rivals (Carroll and nal consequences of change – disruption of
Swaminathan, 2000). Quite simply, it is diffi- routines and structures – to the external con-
cult for organizations with established identi- sequences, in particular, to what happens
ties to present themselves as entirely when organizations violate the expectations
different kinds of organizations, even when of external observers (here, investors). Thus,
their identities are based on intangibles such it paves the way for empirically assessing the
as perceived authenticity. In a similar vein, a content effect of change, to complement pre-
study of American feature films showed that vious studies of the process effects of change
there is a fundamental tradeoff between (e.g., Amburgey et al., 1993; Greve, 1999).
appealing to a broad customer base (being a
generalist) and targeting a more focused base
(being a specialist): films pitched in multiple
Summary
genres attracted larger audiences but
were less appealing than films pitched in a The great strength of the ecological tradition
single genre, because audiences found is its high level of paradigmatic consensus
multi-genre films difficult to make sense of (Pfeffer, 1993). Ecologists agree on what
(Hsu, 2006). outcomes to study (founding, failure, growth,
For the density-dependence model, analy- performance, and change), what explanatory
ses of identities among disk-array producers factors to consider (the number of organiza-
showed that, contrary to what happens when tions of various (sub)forms, as well as their
classic density-dependent competition and sizes, ages, locations, technologies, net-
legitimation operate, increases in the density works, and identities), and what analytical
of disk-array producers did not legitimate the strategies to employ (primarily quantitative
disk-array-producer form (McKendrick and analysis of original data sets covering entire
Carroll, 2001; McKendrick, Jaffee, Carroll populations of organizations over extended
and Khessina, 2003). Most disk-array periods of time). Among theories of organi-
producers had heterogeneous origins and zations, ecology displays the highest degree
continued to derive their primary identities of logical rigour. Indeed, ecology has bene-
from other fields. These heterogeneous fited from several logical tests: of resource
origins and persistently derivative identities partitioning (Péli and Nooteboom, 1999),
made it impossible for the disk-array- inertia (Péli, Bruggeman, Masuch and
producer form to cement its own distinctive Ó Nualláin, 1994; Hannan, Pólos and Carroll,
identity. Following this logic, only increases 2003), and density dependence (Kamps and
in the density of firms with focused identi- Péli, 1995). These tests have revealed incon-
ties, not increases in total density, should sistencies and incoherencies in natural-
result in the establishment of a distinct language statements of ecological theory and
organizational form. so paved the way for theoretical refinements.
ECOLOGISTS AND INSTITUTIONALISTS: FRIENDS OR FOES? 579

In sum, because organizational ecologists scope of organizational institutionalism (for


have always built on and refined each other’s a more detailed review, see Greenwood
work, they have accumulated much knowl- [Introduction, this volume] or Scott
edge about organizational dynamics. [1995/2001]). Like ecological analysis, insti-
But the strength of the ecological research tutional analysis of organizations can be
programme reveals a weakness: precisely broken down by subject area. Three of the
because it is such a ‘normal-science’ most important are legitimation and institu-
activity, some find it too narrow to interest tionalization, isomorphism and diffusion,
anyone except ecologists themselves (e.g., and strategic action. We discuss each in turn.
Hedström, 1992). As van Witteloostuijn
(2000: v) put it, organizational ecology has a
‘relatively small influence outside the inner Legitimation and
circle of its own parish’. Narrowness may
institutionalization
overtake this paradigm because much work
clarifies and refines the basic theory without Legitimacy is the central concept in institu-
extending it in truly novel directions; as a con- tional analysis. Organizations are legitimate
sequence, ecologists’ work rarely intersects when they are comprehensible and taken for
with – or draws the interest of – scholars in granted as the natural way to achieve some
other research traditions. The marginalization collective goal (Berger and Luckmann,
of organizational ecology is revealed in analy- 1967), when they are justified and explained
ses of submissions to the Organization and on the basis of prevailing values, role
Management Theory Division of the models, and cultural accounts (Meyer and
Academy of Management Annual Meetings of Rowan, 1977; Douglas, 1986), when they are
2004 and 2005 (Thompson, 2004; Davis, sanctioned or mandated by authorized actors
2005). According to author-assigned key- (DiMaggio and Powell, 1983), and when
words, which could indicate either theory or those involved cannot even conceive of alter-
phenomenon, a relatively small number of natives (Zucker, 1983). Legitimacy can rest
papers labelled as ‘ecological’ were submit- on any of three foundations: regulative,
ted, far fewer than the number of papers which includes the laws and administrative
labelled as ‘institutional’. Perhaps more guidelines that constitute the basic rules gov-
important, organizational ecology occupied a erning relationships within and between
relatively peripheral position in the network of organizations; normative, meaning ‘expert’
references to other perspectives and phenom- sources of information and value judgments
ena, as it was used in combination with few about the nature of organizations; and cogni-
other perspectives and it was used to tive, meaning shared perceptions of organ-
explain relatively few phenomena. This ized social activity (Scott, 1995 [2001]).
situation is unfortunate, given ecology’s Highly legitimate forms of organization are
many theoretical advances and empirical highly institutionalized – perceived as objec-
successes. tive and exterior facets of social life (Berger
and Luckmann, 1967). The greater the legiti-
macy attributed to an organizational form,
the less any member of that form will require
HOW DO WE UNDERSTAND active justification and the more it will be
INSTITUTIONAL ANALYSIS? taken for granted and accepted by observers.
Legitimacy improves access to resources and
Before comparing institutional analysis of acceptance from customers, and thus con-
organizations to ecology, we want to make tributes to organizations’ ability to persist
sure we’re all ‘on the same page’, so we offer (Meyer and Rowan, 1977). Empirical
our own brief assessment of the nature and research has supported these ideas for many
580 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

kinds of organizations, including hospitals (Haveman and Rao, 1997; Haveman, Rao
(Ruef and Scott, 1998), biotechnology start- and Paruchuri, 2007).
ups (Stuart, Hoang and Hybels, 1999), day-
care centres (Baum and Oliver, 1991), and
banks (Deephouse, 1996). Isomorphism
The flip side of institutionalization is dein-
stitutionalization: erosion of activities or Institutionalists wonder why organizations
practices (Oliver, 1992). And the flip side of are so similar (DiMaggio and Powell, 1983).
legitimation is delegitimation: reduced Accordingly, one of the most important ideas
acceptance of activities or practices. Some in institutional analysis is that of isomor-
scholars see the continuance of structures, phism (literally, ‘same shape’). As communi-
rules, and routines as inherently problematic, ties of organizations evolve, a variety of
and see deinstitutionalization as an inevitable forces (interorganizational power relations,
process (e.g., Covaleski and Dirsmith, 1988; the state and professions, and competition)
Zucker, 1988) Deinstitutionalization can be promote isomorphism within sets of organi-
precipitated by political, functional, or social zations that either play similar roles or are
forces (Oliver, 1992). Some forces for tied directly to each other. There is a logical
deinstitutionalization are internal to the focal connection between isomorphism and legiti-
organization, including increasing workforce macy. The more prevalent an organizational
diversity, declining performance, and execu- structure, practice, or tactic, the more legiti-
tive succession. For instance, poor per- mate it is. Therefore, one indicator of legiti-
formance triggered the abandonment of macy is the spread of organizational features,
permanent-employment guarantees and which increases isomorphism within fields
increased downsizing by Japan firms; more- (Tolbert and Zucker, 1983). Moreover, the
over, the rate of abandonment increased with three bases of legitimacy map neatly onto the
the number of firms downsizing (Ahmadjian three processes driving isomorphism: cogni-
and Robinson, 2001). Other forces for dein- tive legitimacy onto mimetic processes, reg-
stitutionalization are external, such as tech- ulative legitimacy onto coercive processes,
nological innovation, shifts in the polity or and normative legitimacy onto normative
general culture, economic booms or busts, processes (Scott, 2001).
and changes in regulation. For example, the Interest in isomorphism has produced
decline of large conglomerates in the 1980s many, many studies of the diffusion of
was precipitated by shifts in attitudes and formal structures and practices across organi-
beliefs about the nature of the firm (Davis, zational fields, encompassing all three
Diekmann, and Tinsley, 1994). The idea of engines of diffusion. Coercive pressures
the firm as a bounded social entity, analogous accelerate diffusion; for instance, structures
to a sovereign body which could not be mandated by the state diffuse more rapidly
dismembered, lost legitimacy in the face of than structures encouraged but not mandated
evidence that conglomerates were inefficient; (Tolbert and Zucker, 1983). Although state
as a result, many were taken over and broken regulations appear to be simple coercive
up. Similarly, several forms of savings- forces, reality is often more complex, as
and-loan associations, each embodying many state regulations allow discretion in
a different set of opinions, beliefs, and judg- their interpretation and application (Dobbin
ments, were extinguished by a combination and Sutton, 1998). For example, in response
of technical pressures (changes in human to legal mandates against employment
demography and employment patterns) discrimination, firms experimented with
and institutional pressures (changes in several ways to demonstrate compliance –
attitudes towards bureaucracies precipi- creating both new rules and new units
tated by the Progressive movement) (Edelman, 1992) – until court rulings showed
ECOLOGISTS AND INSTITUTIONALISTS: FRIENDS OR FOES? 581

one way – formal, merit-based rules govern- management (TQM) programmes as TQM
ing hiring and promotion – to be suffi- adoption increased (Westphal, Gulati and
cient, after which the sanctioned approach Shortell, 1997).
diffused widely (Dobbin, Sutton, Meyer and
Scott, 1993).
Normative pressures often trump coercive Strategic action
pressures, because state regulations often
allow discretion in their interpretation and Organizations do not simply react to environ-
application (Edelman, 1992; Dobbin et al., mental demands; instead, they are often
1993). Take, for instance, the diffusion of proactive and control their environments.
human-resources practices among U.S. Recognizing this, institutionalists place con-
firms. Human-resources managers and formity on a continuum of responses that
labour lawyers used the ambiguity inherent includes compromise, avoidance, defiance,
in employment law to promote particular and manipulation (Oliver, 1991). Indeed,
solutions – those that would solidify their organizations can avail themselves of many
power – and discourage others (Dobbin and different tactics for gaining legitimacy (con-
Sutton, 1996; Sutton and Dobbin, 1998). form to, select, or manipulate the environ-
Thinking more broadly, the civil-rights ment), maintaining legitimacy (police
mandates of the 1960s created a normative internal activity, eschew obvious appeals for
environment that led employers to adopt legitimacy, and stockpile goodwill), and
several human-resources procedures, even in repairing legitimacy (offer normalizing
the absence of formal legal sanctions accounts, restructure, and (our favourite!)
(Edelman, 1990). don’t panic) (Suchman, 1995). These ideas
Mimetic pressures are ubiquitous but pave the way for investigating when con-
subtle. In the early stages of diffusion, formity will or will not occur, and assessing
adopters of new structures and practices tend the effectiveness of various strategic
to be those facing technical problems of con- responses.
trol and co-ordination they hope will be Empirical work on strategic action often
solved by these innovations; later, however, investigates how rhetoric is used to legiti-
as the innovations become widespread, con- mate change. For example, tracing the evolu-
nections between technical rationality and tion of corporate takeovers from 1950
adoption are attenuated and the causal engine through 1985 revealed that rhetoric created
shifts from technical rationality to blind imi- powerful new patterns of meaning, which in
tation, as innovations become taken for turn affected the status attributed to buyers
granted as the ‘right’ way to do things and target firms alike (Hirsch, 1986). As the
(Tolbert and Zucker, 1983; Baron, Dobbin practice of hostile takeovers diffused, the
and Jennings, 1986). There is widespread language used to describe them became more
evidence of mimetic diffusion: corporations positive and more complex (borrowing from
were more likely to adopt the multidivisional more genres; evaluating bidders and targets).
form when others in their industry had Moreover, takeovers came to be framed as
done so (Fligstein, 1985), savings and loans violent when the bidder was outside the cor-
were more likely to expand into new service porate establishment, but dispassionately and
areas when large and profitable firms benignly when the bidder was an insider. In
were active there (Haveman, 1993), acquir- the same vein, a study of attempts to repair
ing firms were more likely to select invest- legitimacy after a public-relations crisis in
ment banks used by large and profitable the cattle-ranching industry demonstrated the
others (Haunschild and Miner, 1997), and efficacy of verbal accounts (Elsbach, 1994).
hospitals were more likely to adopt standard- Similarly, a study of accounting firms
ized (as opposed to customized) total quality showed that the profession was ‘framed’ as
582 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

being under threat and that change was thus marginalized and have little power – like
natural, almost inevitable; thus, rhetoric por- women in the late nineteenth and early twen-
trayed the broadening of accounting firms’ tieth centuries – can develop new kinds of
professional scope as a solution to evolving organizations; these ventures are most likely
client needs and heightened competition to succeed when they embody familiar struc-
(Greenwood, Suddaby and Hinings, 2002). tures and practices (Clemens, 1997).
Strategic actors in accounting deployed
many rhetorical strategies to legitimate mul-
tidisciplinary partnerships: appealing to Summary
myths of progressive rationality, suppressing
contradictions, and emphasizing consistency The strength of the institutionalist perspective
with professional values (Suddaby and is its sweeping reach. Consider the core con-
Greenwood, 2005). Finally, institutional cepts, institution and institutionalization.
entrepreneurs in the HIV/AIDS-treatment Scholars working in this tradition have
field framed new practices of consultation claimed that institutionalization is both an out-
and information exchange among commu- come, which suggests attention to stability,
nity organizations and pharmaceutical com- and a process, which suggests attention to
panies in ways that integrated the interests of change. They have identified the carriers of
many different stakeholders and that were institutions at multiple levels of analysis: the
consistent with existing routines (Maguire, routines, rules, scripts, and schemas that guide
Hardy and Lawrence, 2004). the perceptions and actions of individuals and
Strategic action is especially obvious small groups; local regional or demographic-
when people are trying to create new kinds of group identities and regimes; meso-level
organizations. Such institutional entrepre- organizations, occupations, and fields; and
neurship requires the skillful use of resources society-wide norms and codified patterns of
to overcome skepticism and persuade others meaning and interpretation. They have identi-
to believe entrepreneurs’ representations of fied a wide array of mechanisms through
reality and thus to support their new ventures which institutionalization occurs: habituation,
(DiMaggio, 1988; Fligstein, 1997). For blind or limitedly-rational imitation, norma-
example, art historians and their patrons tive conformity, accreditation, social obliga-
co-operated in the nineteenth century to tion, and coercion. In building theory, they
develop art museums as a distinct cultural have drawn not only on sociology, but also on
form by creating a framework that distin- cognitive psychology, philosophy, and lin-
guished vulgar art from high art and by guistics. Finally, they have employed a wide
establishing non-profit enterprises to show- array of methodologies, ranging from ethno-
case and conserve their cultural capital graphies and qualitative historical studies to
(DiMaggio, 1991). Product-testing organiza- laboratory experiments to statistical analyses
tions and consumer leagues promoted con- of survey and archival data. As a result of its
sumer watchdog associations by tapping into breadth and flexibility, institutionalist analysis
the growing customer-service and truth-in- has recently dominated submissions to the
advertising movements; these institutional Organization and Management Theory
entrepreneurs also linked their activities to Division of the Academy of Management
home-economics professors, who already Annual Meetings (Thompson, 2004; Davis,
enjoyed the legitimacy accorded to academia 2005). Institutional analysis was also central
(Rao, 1998). Such actions conferred norma- in the network of references to other perspec-
tive appropriateness to the new consumer- tives or to specific phenomena, indicating that
watchdog form and shielded it from institutionalism was used to explain a wide
opposition, thus allowing it to stabilize and range of phenomena and was used in combi-
persist. Even individuals and groups that are nation with many other perspectives.
ECOLOGISTS AND INSTITUTIONALISTS: FRIENDS OR FOES? 583

But the strength provided by this broad differences, then – finally! – answering the
reach also generates a critical weakness. If question posed in our title.
institution and institutionalization mean
everything and explain everything – change
and stability; routines, values, and norms; Points of similarity
intra-organizational, organizational, and
interorganizational structures and behav- Ecological and institutional approaches have
iours; cognitive, regulative, and normative as their most basic commonality their ori-
processes – then they mean nothing and gins: both developed as corrections to ratio-
explain nothing. The institutional ‘tent’ nalist and adaptationist theories that were in
houses a loose collection of propositions, of use in the 1960s and early 1970s, which
varying degrees of formality, some seem- assumed that those in charge of organizations
ingly incompatible and others only tenuously could survey the environment and determine
connected. For example, it is unclear when what the organization should do, and that
coercive, mimetic, or normative forces organizations could easily change their
predominate, and to what extent these are strategies and structures, and thus improve
conceptually or empirically distinct phenom- their performance. Both organizational
ena (Mizruchi and Fein, 1999). Given these ecology and institutionalism broke with the
fundamental uncertainties, debates in assumption that organizations could be
the institutionalist tradition tend to be unpro- adapted to external conditions in a techni-
ductive feuds about intellectual origins cally rational way. In the case of ecology,
and definitions, rather than substantive inertial forces prevent timely adaptation;
arguments about logic or evidence in the institutional perspective, conforming
(e.g., Scott, 1995 [2001] vs. Hirsch, 1997). to institutional rules can prevent efficient
Institutionalists have not built systematically operation.
on one another’s work to the same Another deep commonality – albeit one
extent that ecologists have, and the institu- that is often mistaken for a basic difference –
tional perspective has not accumulated is a concern for the variety (or lack thereof)
empirical successes at the same rate as of organizations. As we noted above, ecolo-
ecology has. This lack of accumulation of gists ask ‘why are there so many kinds of
knowledge happened because institutional- organizations?’ (Hannan and Freeman, 1977:
ists eschewed ‘theories of the mid range’ – 936), while institutionalists wonder why
logically interconnected sets of propositions, organizations are so similar (DiMaggio and
derived from assumptions about essential Powell, 1983: 148). The apparent contrast in
facts (axioms) and causal mechanisms these questions is illusory, however, because
(unobservables), that yield empirically they point to the ends of a single continuum,
testable hypotheses and deal with delim- which runs from a setting in which each
ited aspects of social phenomena (Merton, organization is unique to one in which all
1968: 39–72). organizations are identical. To explain one
end of the continuum, one must explain the
other. The real questions are how much orga-
nizational variety there is and what factors
COMPARING ECOLOGICAL AND contribute to more or less variety.
INSTITUTIONAL ANALYSIS These core similarities have led researchers
within the two traditions to focus on similar
We begin by laying out the things that make constructs and to study similar phenomena:
ecology and institutionalism similar. We then legitimacy, organizational form, the emer-
discuss the things that make them different. gence and spread of new organizational
We conclude by weighing similarities and forms and features, organizational change
584 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

(or persistence), and organizational survival institutionalism. The most basic discord
or failure. Consider legitimacy: ecologists stems from their theoretical agendas.
and institutionalists alike believe that legiti- Ecologists value parsimony and generality,
macy is necessary for the emergence of new while institutionalists prefer richness and
organizational forms, and the proliferation contextual specificity. Therefore, ecologists
and persistence of existing organizational strive to identify broad regularities across
forms. For ecologists, legitimacy is cognitive populations. Institutionalists, in contrast,
in nature and accrues to an organizational attempt to offer highly contextualized and
form as it increases in numbers and thus nuanced depictions of organizations or fields.
becomes accepted as the natural way to effect This conflict is difficult to reconcile because
collective action (Hannan and Freeman, it reflects a difference of taste in theorizing,
1987, 1988). Institutionalists also recognize but it could be settled by careful empirical
the cognitive aspect of legitimacy, but attend analysis. The issue boils down to whether or
to its regulative and normative dimensions as not relationships between explanatory and
well (Scott, 2001). Both traditions also outcome variables vary over time and across
emphasize organizational survival as a central contexts – clearly empirical questions. For
outcome of interest; this stands in contrast to instance, does density dependence operate
other areas of organizational scholarship, over a population’s entire history or just
such as strategic management, that focus on within particular periods defined by larger
profitability or market share. For ecologists, forces, such as technology, social mores, and
organizational survival is determined by tan- the state (e.g., Dobbin and Dowd, 2000)?
gible resource flows, whereas for institution- Does the similarity (or difference) between a
alists it is rooted in the subjective assessments focal population and related populations
of constituents. This overlapping interest in a affect density-dependent processes (e.g.,
core set of constructs and phenomenon, Ruef, 2000; Dobrev, 2001)? And does the
despite differences in the ways they have nature of the organizations under study or
been conceived and measured, forms the their context determine how inert they are
basis for considerable conceptual, method- and whether change harms or helps them
ological, and empirical common ground. (e.g., Dobrev, Kim and Carroll, 2003)?
Indeed, methodological similarity is obvi- Ecologists’ concern for parsimony and
ous, as both sets of scholars employ original generality has led them to follow a tight
data on collections of organizations – popula- normal-science trajectory, while institution-
tions in the case of ecologists and fields in the alists’ concern for richness and contextual
case of institutionalists. This empirical strategy specificity has yielded a more emergent and
stands in stark contrast to much other sociolog- diffuse research agenda. To put it more for-
ical research, where reliance on publicly-avail- mally, ecology is a collection of overlapping
able data, especially survey data, is the norm. theories of the mid-range, each of which
Both research traditions also emphasize longi- builds on a small set of assumptions and
tudinal analysis. This contrasts with the causal mechanisms to derive empirically
approach taken in other research traditions, testable predictions about a delimited set of
such as transaction-cost economics and organizational outcomes. Institutionalism,
resource-dependence theory, both of which in contrast, is not really a single mid-
tend to rely on cross-sectional data. range theory, or even a collection of such the-
ories – despite the prevalence of the label
‘institutional theory’. Instead, institutional-
Points of difference ism is a perspective – a congeries of ideas
and empirical tests of those ideas that
Despite these basic commonalities, there are demonstrate the power of rules and regula-
important differences between ecology and tions; frames and schemas; and norms,
ECOLOGISTS AND INSTITUTIONALISTS: FRIENDS OR FOES? 585

values, and expectations in explaining orga- use contextually sensitive measures of the
nizational genesis and functioning. three bases of legitimacy, none of which can
Institutionalists and ecologists also differ be reduced to simple counts: links between
remarkably in their ontological stance – their the focal organizations or fields and powerful
understanding of the essential nature of the supporting organizations or fields, such as
empirical world. Basically, ecologists are the state or professions; coverage of the focal
empirical realists who believe that the mate- organizations or fields in the news media,
rial world is primary and consciousness is either positive or negative; and laws and reg-
secondary; thus, the material world, includ- ulations supporting or undermining various
ing organizations and their environments, forms of organization.
exists outside of and independent of our The last core difference between ecology
observations. In stark contrast, institutional- and institutionalism is that while both tradi-
ists are social constructionists (subjective tions feature quantitative analyses of longitu-
idealists) who believe that all phenomena are dinal data on collections of organizations,
mental constructions created through social institutionalism encompasses a greater vari-
interaction; thus, the material world is sub- ety of methods, including case studies of
jective and interior, rather than objective and single organizations (e.g., Ritti and Silver,
exterior. To put the difference in plainer 1986), qualitative historical analyses of fields
terms, ecologists believe that organizational (e.g., DiMaggio, 1991; Rao, 1998), and labo-
environments are ‘real’ phenomena, while ratory experiments of organizational mem-
institutionalists hold that they are created by bers (e.g., Zucker, 1977; Elsbach, 1994).
the shared perceptions and interactions of Ironically, the tradition most interested in
individuals, groups, and organizations.2 organizational diversity – ecology – displays
Differences in goals and philosophy lead little diversity in its theoretical and method-
naturally to differences in constructs, predic- ological approaches, while the tradition inter-
tions, and methods. As noted above, even ested in isomorphism – institutionalism –
though the construct of legitimacy figures displays a great deal level of diversity.
prominently in both traditions, ecologists
have focused exclusively on its cognitive
dimension, while institutionalists have vari- The bottom line: answer the
ously studied its regulative, normative, and
question already!
cognitive components. There are two related
issues here: what does legitimacy mean, and After surveying the nature of organizational
how should it be measured? According to ecology and institutional analysis of organi-
organizational ecologists, legitimacy is the zations, and considering their points of simi-
degree to which an organizational form is larity and difference, we conclude that
taken for granted. To capture legitimacy, ecologists and institutionalists have in the
researchers simply count the number of past been both friends and foes, but that they
organizations in the focal population. have good reason to be far friendlier in the
Institutionalists recoil from this simple future. Both sets of scholars reject the
approach (Zucker, 1989; Baum and Powell, assumption, pervasive in the late 1960s and
1995). They protest that legitimacy encom- early 1970s and still popular today, that
passes cognitive, normative, and regulative organizations are pliant tools that can easily
dimensions, which may or may not correlate be made to fit technical exigencies. Both sets
with one another (Scott, 2001). To institu- of scholars are centrally concerned with
tionalists, a count of organizations of a given explaining organizational variety, even
form says little about the subjective evalua- though they use different terms – ecologists
tions constituents make about that form. talk about heterogeneity, institutionalists
Institutionalists therefore argue that we must about homogeneity. Moreover, both sets of
586 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

scholars seek to explain organizational adap- We are also hopeful because we see an
tation, or lack thereof, to shifting circum- increasing number of well-executed studies
stances, even though they use different that combine ecological and institutional
terms – ecologists discuss inertia, institution- arguments to gain richer insights. For exam-
alists persistence. In addition, both sets of ple, in a study of child-care centres, Baum
scholars emphasize the role of legitimacy, and Oliver (1991) tested the structural-inertia
although they disagree about its basis – hypothesis of organizational ecology by
purely cognitive for ecologists; cognitive, taking into consideration sociopolitical legit-
regulative, and normative for institutionalists. imacy as understood by institutionalists.
Moreover, both traditions generally focus on They found that linkages to powerful state
collections of organizations, rather than indi- actors mitigated the high failure rates of
vidual organizations or subunits, although young and small organizations. Haveman
they use different labels – ecologists talk of (1993) combined ideas about density
populations and communities while institu- dependence in organizations’ vital rates with
tionalists discuss fields and sectors. Finally, the mimetic isomorphism hypothesis to pre-
both sets of scholars take a dynamic, rather dict diversification into new markets in the
than comparative-static, approach to savings-and-loan industry; she found that
organizational phenomena and use original increases in the number of successful organ-
longitudinal, rather than derivative cross- izations in a market drew in new entrants
sectional data. until competitive effects swamped legitimat-
We may be wide-eyed optimists, but we ing ones, at which point new entries began to
see differences between ecology and institu- decline. Dacin (1997) found that both sheer
tionalism eroding. Consider the basic unit of density and sociopolitical factors like rising
analysis for ecologists and institutionalists nationalism could be used in concert to
alike, organizational form. Ecologists origi- explain founding rates of Finnish news-
nally conceived of distinct forms of organiza- papers. Similarly, Wade, Swaminathan and
tions as having a unitary standing with Saxon (1998) showed how both density
respect to the environment, and identified and particularistic institutional conditions –
them empirically through observable social non-uniform state-government regulation –
discontinuities and conventional cognitive affected the geographic distribution of
maps (Hannan and Freeman, 1977). In other breweries’ foundings and failures. Most
words, for ecologists, the difference between recently, David and Strang (2006) combined
forms could be deduced from observation of insights from ecology’s resource-partitioning
their inputs and outputs. In contrast, institu- model with notions of mimetic behaviour
tionalists typically classified organizations from institutional analysis; they showed how
according to their distinctive logics – the among management-consulting firms, gener-
socially-constructed sets of beliefs and alists and specialists exploited different types
values upon which they are based. To iden- of demand and reacted differently to shifts in
tify a form, researchers would need to under- collective understandings regarding popular
stand the cultural elements upon which the management practices.
form was built (e.g., DiMaggio, 1991; Rao,
1998). This distinction between resource
flows and cultural underpinnings is disap-
pearing, as ecologists have recently come to PRESCRIPTIONS FOR FUTURE
conceive of organizational forms as identities RESEARCH
or social codes (Pólos, Hannan and Carroll,
2002; Hannan, Pólos and Carroll, 2007), Our final task is to offer suggestions for
which is much closer to the conception of readers about how to engender a more pro-
form used by institutionalists. ductive exchange of ideas between the two
ECOLOGISTS AND INSTITUTIONALISTS: FRIENDS OR FOES? 587

research traditions. In particular, we suggest normative, and cognitive (Scott, 2001) or


how scholars in each tradition can learn from pragmatic, moral, and cognitive (Suchman,
the other to improve their research. 1995) – and the fact that ecologists have been
expansive in their use of this term – talking not
just about taken-for-grantedness but also
How to live peaceably and prosper about conformity to recognized principles or
accepted rules and standards (Aldrich and
Can institutionalists and ecologists stop snip- Fiol, 1994), and normative (value) judgments
ing and develop productive intellectual by observers (Pólos et al., 2002; Hannan et al.,
exchanges? Although there is a substantial 2007). This bewildering list must be win-
middle ground between ecology and institu- nowed down. What kinds of legitimacy result
tionalism, important philosophical, theoreti- from which sources, and what effect does each
cal, and empirical differences (and the have? Do different kinds of legitimacy work in
occasional dust-up over them) have pre- tandem or opposition? Which kinds are most
vented much fruitful interaction. Indeed, potent, when, and for which outcomes? Not
clashes between ecologists and institutional- until these questions about legitimacy are
ists have been intense precisely because answered, along with similar questions about
there are such great overlaps between the other constructs central to both ecology and
phenomena they study and close similarities institutionalism, can the research traditions
in the constructs they use to explain these fruitfully co-exist.
phenomena. If ecologists and institutionalists
were studying very different things using
very different ideas, the divergence in their How can institutionalists learn
theoretical tastes – that is, basic preferences and benefit from the experiences
for parsimony versus richness – would not
of ecologists?
vex them so much.
Given this, how can accord be achieved? Our first prescription is for institutionalists to
The answer is simple: ecologists and institu- develop a set of related theories of the mid-
tionalists must reach a level of consensus con- range (that is, to focus on delimited and sub-
cerning the many constructs they share, and stantively important topics), in order to
agreement concerning the logical and empiri- accumulate knowledge (that is, to reject
cal relationships between them. Fuzzy con- some ideas and affirm others). We are not
struct definitions open doors for fruitless alone in thinking this way. Institutionalists
debates: ‘he-said-vs.-she-said’ situations have already produced solidly cumulative
develop in which both parties talk past and knowledge about U.S. employers’ responses
caricature each other, rather than talking to to employee-rights legislation in the U.S.
and hearing each other. While some theoreti- (Edelman, 1990, 1992; Dobbin et al., 1993;
cal tension between the perspectives is Dobbin and Sutton, 1996; Sutton and
healthy, we are hopeful that we can escape a Dobbin, 1998; Guthrie and Roth, 1999; Kelly
situation in which ecologists seem like they and Dobbin, 1999). This knowledge informs
are from Mars and institutionalists from subsequent research on the effectiveness of
Venus. An excellent place to start would be organizational structures and practices in
legitimacy. As explained above, ecologists decreasing sex and race segregation (Reskin
and institutionalists define this construct dif- and McBrier, 2000; Kalev, Kelly, and
ferently. The situation is exacerbated by the Dobbin, 2006). Notwithstanding this valu-
fact that institutionalists do not agree among able example, much more could be done.
themselves how to categorize the various One excellent candidate for more focused
aspects of legitimacy – sociopolitical and con- and paradigmatic theorizing is institutional
stitutive (Haveman et al., 2007), regulative, entrepreneurship – currently a ‘hot’ topic, as
588 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

evidenced by our finding of 115 citations to about how to live peaceably and prosper,
DiMaggio’s (1991) pioneering paper on the above.) Second, we must formulate more
topic, and 12 articles published in 2005 and coherent and more clearly falsifiable hypothe-
2006 using this term in the title, abstract, or ses about relationships between constructs,
keywords.3 Work on institutional entrepreneur- and disdain loose propositions. In other words,
ship presents a much needed theoretical and we should act (just a little bit!) more like ecol-
empirical ‘boost’ to the generally woeful state ogists: in exchange for greater generality and
of entrepreneurship research more generally, cumulative knowledge, sacrifice theoretical
which has long been dominated by rationalist ambiguity and some small degree of contex-
ideas, functionalist logic, and cross-sectional tual specificity. Doing so will have the benefit
research designs. This means that institution- of allowing some institutionalist predictions to
alists have a great opportunity to make an be disconfirmed by empirical analysis, while
intellectual contribution. How does institu- others are confirmed, perhaps in contingent
tional change create entrepreneurial opportu- formulations. Following this prescription will
nity (e.g., Sine and David, 2003)? How do also allow us to take stock of the vast institu-
entrepreneurs seize this opportunity to found tionalist output and outline scope conditions –
new organizations (e.g., Sine, Haveman and explicit statements of the circumstances under
Tolbert, 2005)? How do entrepreneurs modify which predictions do and do not hold, and the
or create institutions to advance their interests types of phenomena that are more and less
(e.g., Lawrence, 1999; Garud, Jain and amenable to institutional analysis.
Kumaraswamy, 2002)? Institutionalism is
uniquely placed to address such questions in a
focused, cumulative manner that can expand How can ecologists learn from the
our knowledge about an important social and
experience of institutionalists?
economic phenomenon.
A second candidate for focused theorizing We offer two related prescriptions that will
is the diffusion of new organizational features. refresh ecological research and return it to
This should be an easy pill to swallow, as we the centre of organizational theory. First and
have two first-rate models on which to build. most fundamentally, we should develop
DiMaggio and Powell’s (1983) article about richer conceptions of organizational con-
institutional isomorphism explains both what texts, ones that are more sensitive to time and
kinds of forces drive the diffusion of organiza- place. In other words, we should take a page
tional features to create isomorphism within out of the institutionalist handbook, and sac-
institutional fields (mimetic, coercive, norma- rifice some parsimony and generality to
tive) and the mechanisms by which diffusion acquire conceptual richness. Theoretically,
operates (cohesion and structural equiva- this means returning to our roots in human
lence). Strang and Tuma’s (1993) article pro- ecology, as pioneered by Park and Burgess
vides a detailed, integrated model of diffusion (1921), and refined by Hawley (1950).
processes, one that bridges the gap between Empirically, it means expanding our set of
natural-language theory and hypothesis test- explanatory variables. Most ecological
ing. It should not be difficult to turn the growth analysis has used the characteristics of the
industry that is institutionalist studies of diffu- focal organization and the focal population to
sion into a true knowledge-building project. explain organizations’ vital rates. Little
Even if you accept our suggestions, it will ‘pure’ ecological work has considered
be difficult to make institutionalist research characteristics of the world outside the focal
more paradigmatic and cumulative. First, we population, including the state, social and
need to reach agreement on the meaning of political movements, socially-constructed
central constructs and stop using the vapid technological systems, and belief systems.
umbrella term ‘institution.’ (See also our ideas Those more macroscopic explanations have
ECOLOGISTS AND INSTITUTIONALISTS: FRIENDS OR FOES? 589

been the domain of institutional analysis. inherit legitimacy from other pre-existing
Indeed, in some ways ecological analysis, as entities can be answered by observation in the
it has been practiced to date, can be seen as field and by qualitative analysis (e.g., textual
nested within institutional analysis. By this, analysis) of organizational archives; these
we mean that processes that have been the methods can shed new light on the content of
object of ecological analysis, such as density organizing. Finally, experimental methods
dependence, resource partitioning, structural like vignette studies can allow us to control,
inertia, and identity valuation, seem to oper- in a rigorous way, alternative explanations for
ate within contexts that are assumed to be several observed relationships, such as den-
invariant in time and space (Dobbin and sity dependence in founding and failure rates.
Dowd, 2000). Expanding the reach of eco- The second use to make of a greater variety of
logical analysis to include forces exogenous empirical methods – direct observation in the
to the population will connect ecology to field, laboratory experiments, historical/nar-
many other research traditions: sociology of rative analysis, textual analysis – is to expand
culture, political sociology, sociology of law, our set of core research questions by gather-
and sociology of work. There is precedent ing new kinds of data on forces exogenous to
here, as ecologists have long noted the organizational populations (see our first pre-
importance of political environments on pop- scription for ecologists).
ulation evolution (e.g., Carroll, Delacroix
and Goodstein, 1988).
Second, ecology would benefit from
greater methodological pluralism. Statistical FINAL WORDS
analyses of longitudinal archival data on
entire populations of organizations, aug- In closing, we wish to step back and take the
mented by computer simulations and logical perspective of nearby outsiders: strategy
analyses, have demonstrated the veracity of researchers, economists, cognitive and social
core ecological ideas. We are now in a posi- psychologists, and applied mathematicians.
tion to expand our horizons in two ways. To them, institutionalism and ecology look
First, we could cement our knowledge of remarkably similar. All of these fields are
core causal mechanisms by gathering new highly rationalist. When scholars steeped in
kinds of data. For example, questions about these traditions examine organizations, their
organizational identities can be answered by focus is generally on understanding and
gathering data on the opinions of observers, improving organizational performance. If
both internal and external, through surveys institutionalism and ecology arose as an anti-
and interviews. This is something that dote to rationalism within organizational
innovative ecological research is beginning theory, then they might very well be seen as
to do (e.g., Carroll and Swaminathan, 2000). allies within the broader context of organiza-
Questions about inertia can be given new tional studies. Both institutionalists and ecolo-
life through direct observations of change gists care deeply about theory, methodological
efforts in theoretically important cases – rigour, and building an understanding of
organizations that are either exemplary of organizations that goes beyond a narrow focus
their form, outliers, or hybrids. Field meth- on optimizing performance. It is often those
ods like participant observation can also help groups that are most similar to each other –
us develop more nuanced understandings of French and English Canadians, Flemish and
how the members of new organizations Walloon Belgians, Protestant and Catholic
develop structures, routines, and norms, thus Irish – that fight most intensely, even when
clarifying the process of organizing. more important battles lie elsewhere. The
Questions about how new organizations, intellectual world of organizational studies
especially those using novel forms, borrow or would benefit from a true peace – not a form
590 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

of mutually assured destruction – between on merger activity. Strategic Management


ecologists and institutionalists. Journal, 13: 335–48.
Barnett, William P., and Glenn R. Carroll. 1987.
Competition and mutualism among early
telephone companies. Administrative Science
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS Quarterly, 32: 400–21.
Barnett, William P., and Glenn R. Carroll.
We thank Christine Oliver for her insightful 1995. Modelling internal organizational
comments and Royston Greenwood for shar- change. Annual Review of Sociology, 21:
ing his draft chapter tracing the evolution of 217–36.
the institutional analysis of organizations. Baron, James N., Frank R. Dobbin, and
P. Devereaux Jennings. 1986. War and
peace: The evolution of modern personnel
administration in U.S. industry. American
NOTES Journal of Sociology, 92: 350–83.
Barron, David N., Elizabeth West, and Michael
1 For more detailed reviews, see Carroll and T. Hannan. 1994. A time to grow and a time
Hannan (2000) and Baum and Shipilov (2006). Note to die: Growth and mortality of credit unions
that our analysis does not cover the study of internal in New York City, 1914–1990. American
organizational demography and demographic
Journal of Sociology, 100: 381–421.
change. Both reviews delve into this more micro-
scopic line of work.
Baum, Joel A.C., and Stephen J. Mezias. 1992.
2 Organizational theory is not alone in being Localized competition and organizational
divided into material realists and social construction- failure. Administrative Science Quarterly, 37:
ists/idealists. Physics, for example, has long been 580–604.
fraught by similar disagreements. Recall Einstein’s Baum, Joel A.C., and Christine Oliver. 1991.
famous quip, when he rejected the idea from quan- Institutional linkages and organizational
tum mechanics that reality was indeterminate and mortality. Administrative Science Quarterly,
subjective: ‘God does not play dice with the uni- 36: 187–218.
verse’. To put it crudely, the ontology of classical
Baum, Joel A.C., and Walter W. Powell. 1995.
physics is material realism, while that of quantum
Cultivating an institutional ecology of organ-
mechanics is subjective idealism.
3 These statistics come from searches conducted izations: Comment on Hannan, Carroll,
on the Web of Science, February 2007. Dundon, and Torres. American Sociological
Review, 60: 529–38.
Baum, Joel A.C., and Andrew V. Shipilov. 2006.
Ecological approaches to organizations.
REFERENCES Forthcoming in S. Clegg, C. Hardy, and
W. Nord, eds., Handbook of Organization
Ahmadjian, Christina L., and Patricia Robinson. Studies, 2nd edn. London: Sage.
2001. Safety in numbers: Downsizing and Baum, Joel A.C., and Jitendra V. Singh. 1994.
the deinstitutionalization of permanent Organizational niches and the dynamics of
employment in Japan. Administrative organizational mortality. American Journal of
Science Quarterly, 46: 622–54. Sociology, 100: 346–80.
Aldrich, Howard E, and Marlene Fiol. 1994. Berger, Peter L., and Thomas Luckmann. 1967.
Fools rush in? The institutional context of The Social Construction of Reality. Garden City,
industry creation. Academy of Management NJ: Doubleday.
Review, 19: 645–70. Boone, Christophe A.J.J., Vera Broecheler, and
Amburgey, Terry L., Dawn Kelly, and William P. Glenn R. Carroll. 2000. Custom service:
Barnett. 1993. Resetting the clock: The Application and tests of resource partitioning
dynamics of organizational change and failure. among Dutch auditing firms from 1880 to
Administrative Science Quarterly, 38: 51–73. 1982. Organization Studies, 21: 355–81.
Amburgey, Terry L., and Anne S. Miner. 1992. Boone, Christophe A.J.J., Glenn R. Carroll, and
Strategic momentum: The effects of repeti- Arjen van Witteloostuijn. 2002. Resource
tive, positional, and contextual momentum distributions and market partitioning: Dutch
ECOLOGISTS AND INSTITUTIONALISTS: FRIENDS OR FOES? 591

daily newspapers, 1968 to 1994. American Covaleski, Mark A., and Mark W. Dirsmith.
Sociological Review, 67: 408–31. 1988. An institutional perspective on the rise,
Carroll, Glenn R. 1985. Concentration and social transformation, and fall of a university
specialization: Dynamics of niche width in budget category. Administrative Science
populations of organizations. American Quarterly, 33: 562–87.
Journal of Sociology, 90: 1262–83. Dacin, M. Tina. 1997. Isomorphism in context:
Carroll, Glenn R., and Jacques Delacroix. 1982. The power and prescription of institutional
Organizational mortality in the newspaper norms. Academy of Management Journal,
industries of Argentina and Ireland: An eco- 40: 46–81.
logical approach. Administrative Science David, Robert J., and David Strang. 2006.
Quarterly, 27: 169–98. When fashion is fleeting: Transitory collective
Carroll, Glenn R., Jacques Delacroix, and Jerry beliefs and the dynamics of TQM consulting.
Goodstein. 1988. The political environments Academy of Management Journal, 49:
of organizations: An ecological view. In Barry 215–33.
Staw and Larry Cummings, eds., Research in Davis, Gerald F. 2005. The prevalence of ‘theory’
Organizational Behavior, 10: 359–92. among OMT submissions. Presentation made
Greenwich, CT: JAI Press. at Academy of Management Annual
Carroll, Glenn R., Stanislav D. Dobrev, and Meetings, Honolulu, HI.
Anand Swaminathan. 2003. Organizational Davis, Gerald F., Kristina A. Diekmann, and
processes of resource partitioning. In B. Staw Catherine H. Tinsley. 1994. The decline and
and R. Kramer, eds., Research in Organizational fall of the conglomerate firm in the 1980s:
Behavior, 26: 1–40. The deinstitutionalization of an organiza-
Carroll, Glenn R., and Michael T. Hannan. tional form. American Sociological Review,
1989a. Density dependence in the evolution 59: 547–70.
of populations of newspaper organizations. Deephouse, David L. 1996. Does isomorphism
American Sociological Review, 52: 524–41. legitimate? Academy of Management
Carroll, Glenn R., and Michael T. Hannan. Journal, 39: 1024–39.
1989b. On using institutional theory in DiMaggio, Paul J. 1988. Interest and agency in
studying organizational populations. Reply institutional theory. In Lynne G. Zucker, ed.,
to Zucker. American Sociological Review, 52: Institutional Patterns and Organizations:
545–48. Culture and Environment: 3–21. Cambridge,
Carroll, Glenn R., and Michael T. Hannan. MA: Ballinger.
2000. The Demography of Corporations and DiMaggio, Paul J. 1991. Constructing an organi-
Industries. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University zational field as a professional project: U.S.
Press. art museums, 1920–1940. In Walter W.
Carroll, Glenn R., and Anand Swaminathan. Powell and Paul J. DiMaggio, eds., The New
1992. The organizational ecology of strate- Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis:
gic groups in the American brewing industry 267–92. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
from 1975 to 1990. Industrial and Corporate DiMaggio, Paul J., and Walter W. Powell. 1983.
Change, 1: 65–97. The iron cage revisited: Institutional isomor-
Carroll, Glenn R., and Anand Swaminathan. phism and collective rationality in organiza-
2000. Why the microbrewery movement? tional fields. American Sociological Review,
Organizational dynamics of resource parti- 48: 147–60.
tioning in the American brewing industry Dobbin, Frank R., and Timothy Dowd. 2000.
after Prohibition. American Journal of The market that anti-trust built: Public policy,
Sociology, 106: 715–62. private coercion, and railroad acquisitions,
Clemens, Elisabeth S. 1997. The People’s 1825–1922. American Sociological Review,
Lobby: Organizational Innovation and The 65: 635–57.
Rise of Interest Group Politics in the United Dobbin, Frank R., and John R. Sutton. 1996. The
States, 1890–925. Chicago: University of strength of a weak state: The employment
Chicago Press. rights revolution and the rise of human
Coleman, James S. 1974. Power and THE STRUC- resources management divisions. American
TURE OF SOCIETY. New York: W.W. Norton. Journal of Sociology, 104: 441–76.
592 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Dobbin, Frank R., John R. Sutton, John W. Microsystems and Java. Academy of
Meyer, and W. Richard Scott. 1993. Equal Management Journal, 45: 196–214.
opportunity law and the construction of Greenwood, Royston, Roy Suddaby, and C.R.
internal labor markets. American Journal of Hinings. 2002. Theorizing change: The role
Sociology, 99: 396–427. of professional associations in the transfor-
Dobrev, Stanislav D. 2001. Revisiting organiza- mation of institutionalized fields. Academy
tional legitimation: Cognitive diffusion and of Management Journal, 45: 58–80.
sociopolitical factors in the evolution of Greve, Henrich R. 1998. Performance, aspira-
Bulgarian newspaper enterprises, tions, and risky organizational change.
1846–1992. Organization Studies, 22: Administrative Science Quarterly, 43: 58–86.
419–44. Greve, Henrich R. 1999. The effect of change
Dobrev, Stanislav D., Tai-Young Kim, and on performance: Inertia and regression to
Michael T. Hannan. 2001. Dynamics of niche the mean. Administrative Science Quarterly,
width and resource partitioning. American 44: 590–614.
Journal of Sociology, 106: 1299–337. Guthrie, Douglas, and Louise Marie Roth.
Dobrev, Stanislav D., Tai-Young Kim, and Glenn 1999. The state, courts, and maternity leave
R. Carroll. 2003. Shifting gears, shifting policies in U.S. organizations: Specifying
niches: Organizational inertia and change in institutional mechanisms. American
the evolution of the U.S. automobile indus- Sociological Review, 64: 41–63.
try, 1885–1981. Organization Science, 14: Hannan, Michael T. 1998. Rethinking age
264–82. dependence in organizational mortality:
Douglas, Mary. 1986. How Institutions Think. Logical formalizations. American Journal of
Syracuse, NY: Syracuse University Press. Sociology, 104: 126–64.
Edelman, Lauren B. 1990. Legal environments Hannan, Michael T., James N. Baron, Greta
and organizational governance: The expansion Hsu, and Özgecan Koçak. 2006.
of due process in the American workplace. Organizational identities and the hazard of
American Journal of Sociology, 95: 1401–40. change. Industrial and Corporate Change,
Edelman, Lauren B. 1992. Legal ambiguity and 15: 755–84.
symbolic structures: Organizational media- Hannan, Michael T., and Glenn R. Carroll. 1992.
tion of civil rights law. American Journal of Dynamics of Organizational Populations:
Sociology, 97: 1531–576. Density, Legitimation, and Competition.
Elsbach, Kimberly D. 1994. Managing organi- New York: Oxford University Press.
zational legitimacy in the California cattle Hannan, Michael T., and Glenn R. Carroll.
industry: The construction and effectiveness 1995. Theory building and cheap talk about
of verbal accounts. Administrative Science legitimation: Reply to Baum and Powell.
Quarterly, 39: 57–88. American Sociological Review, 60: 539–44.
Fligstein, Neil. 1985. The spread of the multidi- Hannan, Michael T., Glenn R. Carroll, Elizabeth
visional form among large firms, A. Dundon, and John Charles Torres. 1995.
1919–1979. American Sociological Review, Organizational evolution in a multinational
50: 377–91. context: Entries of automobile manufactur-
Fligstein, Neil. 1997. Social skill and institu- ers in Belgium, Britain, France, Germany, and
tional theory. American Behavioral Scientist, Italy. American Sociological Review, 60:
40: 397–405. 509–28.
Fligstein, Neil, and Luke Dauter. 2007. The soci- Hannan, Michael T., and John Freeman. 1977.
ology of markets. Forthcoming in the Annual The population ecology of organizations.
Review of Sociology, 33. American Journal of Sociology, 82: 929–64.
Freeman, John, Glenn R. Carroll, and Michael T. Hannan, Michael T., and John Freeman. 1984.
Hannan. 1983. The liability of newness: Age Structural inertia and organizational change.
dependence in organizational death rates. American Sociological Review, 49: 149–64.
American Sociological Review, 48: 692–710. Hannan, Michael T., and John Freeman. 1987.
Garud, Raghu, Sanjay Jain, and Arun The ecology of organizational founding:
Kumaraswamy. 2002. Institutional entrepre- American labor unions, 1836–1985.
neurship in the sponsorship of common American Journal of Sociology, 92:
technical standards: The case of Sun 910–43.
ECOLOGISTS AND INSTITUTIONALISTS: FRIENDS OR FOES? 593

Hannan, Michael T., and John Freeman. 1988. spanning genres in feature film marketing.
The ecology of organizational mortality: Administrative Science Quarterly, 51:
American labor unions, 1836–1985. 420–50.
American Journal of Sociology, 94: 25–42. Kalev, Alexandra, Frank Dobbin, and Erin Kelly.
Hannan, Michael T., László Pólos, and Glenn R. 2006. Best practices or best guesses?
Carroll. 2003. The fog of change: Opacity Diversity management and the remediation
and asperity in organizations. Administrative of inequality. American Sociological Review,
Science Quarterly, 48: 399–432. 71: 589–617.
Hannan, Michael T., László Pólos, and Glenn R. Kamps, Jaap, and Gábor Péli. 1995. Qualitative
Carroll. 2007. Logics of Organizational reasoning beyond the physics domain: The
Theory: Audiences, Codes, and Ecologies. density dependence theory of organizational
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. ecology. In Bert Bradeweg, ed., Proceedings
Haunschild, Pamela R, and Anne S. Miner. of the 9th International Workshop on
1997. Modes of interorganizational imita- Qualitative Reasoning: 114–22. Amsterdam:
tion: The effects of outcome salience and University of Amsterdam.
uncertainty. Administrative Science Kelly, Erin, and Frank Dobbin. 1999. Civil rights
Quarterly, 42: 472–500. law at work: Sex discrimination and the rise
Haveman, Heather A. 1992. Between a rock of maternity leave policies. American Journal
and a hard place: Organizational change of Sociology, 105: 455–92.
and performance under conditions of Lawrence, Thomas B. 1999. Institutional strat-
fundamental environmental transformation. egy. Journal of Management, 25: 161–88.
Administrative Science Quarterly, 37: 48–75. Levinthal, Daniel A. 1991. Random walks and
Haveman, Heather A. 1993. Follow the leader: organizational mortality. Administrative
Mimetic isomorphism and entry into new Science Quarterly, 36: 397–420.
markets. Administrative Science Quarterly, Maguire, Steve, Cynthia Hardy, and Thomas B.
38: 593–627. Lawrence. 2004. Institutional entrepreneur-
Haveman, Heather A., and Hayagreeva Rao. ship in emerging fields: HIV/AIDS treatment
1997. Structuring a theory of moral senti- advocacy in Canada. Academy of
ments: institutional and organizational Management Journal, 47: 657–79.
coevolution in the early thrift industry. McKendrick, David G., and Glenn R. Carroll.
American Journal of Sociology, 102: 2001. On the genesis of organizational
1606–51. forms: Evidence from the market for disk
Haveman, Heather A., Hayagreeva Rao, and arrays. Organization Science, 12: 661–82.
Srikanth Paruchuri. 2007. The winds of McKendrick, David G., Jonathan Jaffee,
change: The Progressive movement and the Glenn R. Carroll, and Olga M. Khessina.
bureaucratization of thrift. American 2003. In the bud? Analysis of disk array
Sociological Review, 72: 117–42. producers as a (possibly) emergent organi-
Hawley, Amos H. 1950. Human Ecology: zational form. Administrative Science
A Theory of Human Structure. New York: Quarterly, 48: 60–93.
The Ronald Press Co. McPherson, J. Miller. 1983. An ecology of affil-
Hedström, Peter. 1992. Is organizational ecol- iation. American Sociological Review, 48:
ogy at an impasse? Contemporary Sociology, 519–32.
21: 751–53. Merton, Robert K. 1968. Social Theory and
Hirsch, Paul M. 1986. From ambushes to Social Structure, enlarged edn. New York:
golden parachutes: Corporate takeovers as Free Press.
an instance of cultural framing and institu- Meyer, John W., and Brian Rowan. 1977.
tional integration. American Journal of Institutionalized organizations: Formal struc-
Sociology, 91: 800–37. ture as myth and ceremony. American
Hirsch, Paul M. 1997. Sociology without social Journal of Sociology, 83: 340–63.
structure: Neoinstitutionalist theory meets Minkoff, Debra C. 1999. Bending with the
brave new world. American Journal of wind: Strategic change and adaptation by
Sociology, 102: 1702–23. women’s and racial minority organizations.
Hsu, Greta. 2006. Jacks of all trades and American Journal of Sociology, 104:
masters of none: Audiences’ reactions to 1666–703.
594 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Mizruchi, Mark S., and Lisa C. Fein. 1999. The Ruef, Martin. 2000. The emergence of organi-
social construction of organizational knowl- zational forms: A community ecology
edge: A study of the uses of coercive, approach. American Journal of Sociology,
mimetic, and normative isomorphism. 106: 658–714.
Administrative Science Quarterly, 44: Ruef, Martin, and W. Richard Scott. 1998.
653–83. A multidimensional model of organizational
Oliver, Christine. 1991. Strategic responses to legitimacy: Hospital survival in changing
institutional processes. Academy of institutional environments. Administrative
Management Review, 16: 145–79. Science Quarterly, 43: 877–904.
Oliver, Christine. 1992. The antecedents of Scott, W. Richard. 1995 [2001]. Institutions
deinstitutionalization. Organization Studies, and Organizations, 2nd edn. Thousand
13: 563–88. Oaks, CA: Sage.
Park, Robert E., and Ernest W. Burgess. 1921. Sine, Wesley D., and Robert J. David. 2003.
An Introduction to the Science of Sociology. Environmental jolts, institutional change,
Chicago: University of Chicago Press. and the creation of entrepreneurial opportu-
Péli, Gábor, Jeroen Bruggeman, Michael nity in the U.S. electric power industry.
Masuch, and Breanndán Ó Nualláin. 1994. Research Policy, 32: 185–207.
A logical approach to formalizing organiza- Sine, Wesley D., Heather A. Haveman, and
tional ecology. American Sociological Pamela S. Tolbert. 2005. Risky business?
Review, 59: 571–93. Entrepreneurship in the new independent
Péli, Gábor, and Bart Nooteboom. 1999. power sector. Administrative Science
Market partitioning and the geometry of the Quarterly, 50: 200–32.
resource space. American Journal of Strang, David, and Nancy Brandon Tuma.
Sociology, 104: 1132–53. 1998. Spatial and temporal heterogeneity
Perrow, Charles. 1991. A society of organiza- in diffusion. American Journal of Sociology,
tions. Theory and Society, 20: 725–62. 99: 614–639.
Pfeffer, Jeffrey. 1993. Barriers to the advance- Stuart, Toby E., Ha Hoang, and Ralph C.
ment of organizational science: Paradigm Hybels. 1999. Interorganizational endorse-
development as dependent variable. ments and the performance of entrepren-
Academy of Management Review, 18: eurial ventures. Administrative Science
599–620. Quarterly, 44: 315–49.
Pólos, László, Michael T. Hannan, and Glenn R. Suchman, Mark C. 1995. Managing legitimacy:
Carroll. 2002. Foundations of a theory of Strategic and institutional approaches. Acad-
social forms. Industrial and Corporate emy of Management Review, 20: 571–610.
Change, 11: 85–115. Suddaby, Roy, and Royston Greenwood. 2005.
Ranger-Moore, James. 1997. Bigger may be Rhetorical strategies of legitimacy. Adminis-
better, but is older wiser? Organizational age trative Science Quarterly, 50: 35–57.
and size in the New York life insurance Sutton, John R., and Frank Dobbin. 1998. The
industry. American Sociological Review, 62: two faces of governance: Responses to legal
903–20. uncertainty in U.S. firms, 1955 to 1985.
Rao, Hayagreeva. 1998. Caveat emptor: The American Sociological Review, 61: 794–811.
construction of nonprofit consumer watch- Swaminathan, Anand. 1995. The proliferation
dog organizations. American Journal of of specialist organizations in the American
Sociology, 103: 912–61. wine industry, 1941–1990. Administrative
Reskin, Barbara F., and Debra Branch McBrier. Science Quarterly, 40: 653–80.
2000. Why not ascription? Organizations’ Thompson, Tracy, editor. 2004. OMT
employment of male and female managers. Newsletter, Fall 2004. Briarcliff Manor, NY:
American Sociological Review, 65: 210–233. Academy of Management.
Ritti, R. Richard, and Jonathon H. Silver. 1986. Tolbert, Pamela S., and Lynne G. Zucker. 1983.
Early processes of institutionalization: The Institutional sources of change in the formal
dramaturgy of exchange in interorganiza- structure of organizations: The diffusion of
tional relations. Administrative Science civil service reform, 1880–1935. Administra-
Quarterly, 31: 25–32. tive Science Quarterly, 28: 22–39.
ECOLOGISTS AND INSTITUTIONALISTS: FRIENDS OR FOES? 595

van Witteloostuijn, Arjen. 2000. Organizational organizations. American Sociological


ecology has a bright future. Organization Review, 57: 829–42.
Studies, 21: 5–14. Zucker, Lynne G. 1977. The role of institution-
Wade, James B., Anand Swaminathan, and alization in cultural persistence. American
Michael Scott Saxon. 1998. Normative and Sociological Review, 42: 726–43.
resource flow consequences of local regula- Zucker, Lynne G. 1983. Organizations as insti-
tions in the American brewing industry, tutions. In S. Bacharach, ed., Research in the
1845–1918. Administrative Science Sociology of Organizations, 2: 1–47.
Quarterly, 43: 905–35. Greenwich, CT: JAI Press.
Westphal, James D., Ranjay Gulati, Zucker, Lynne G. 1988. Where do institutional
and Stephen M. Shortell. 1997. Customi- patterns come from? Organizations as actors in
zation and conformity: An institutional social systems. In Lynne G. Zucker, ed.,
and network perspective on the content Institutional Patterns and Organizations:
and consequences of TQM adoption. Culture and Environment: 23–49. Cambridge,
Administrative Science Quarterly, 42: MA: Ballinger.
366–94. Zucker, Lynne G. 1989. Combining institutional
Wholey, Douglas R., Jon B. Christianson, and theory and population ecology: No legitimacy,
Susan M. Sanchez. 1992. Organizational size no history. Comment on Carroll and Hannan.
and failure among health maintenance American Sociological Review, 52: 542–45.
25
Networks and Institutions
Jason Owen-Smith and Walter W. Powell

INTRODUCTION sustains, and transforms social worlds.


The cognitive categories, conventions,
Research on institutions and networks has rules, expectations, and logics that give insti-
proceeded on largely separate trajectories tutions their force also condition the forma-
over the past few decades. The former is tion of relationships and thus the network
more associated with work in organizational structures that function as the skeletons of
and political sociology, and the latter serves fields. But networks are more than just the
as the wellspring of research in economic scaffolds and circulatory systems of organi-
sociology. To be sure, a number of loose link- zational fields. They are also the source of
ages exist between the subfields. For exam- ‘horizontal’ distinctions among categories of
ple, many institutional studies presume that individuals, organizations, and actions, as
professional or inter-organizational networks well as ‘vertical’ status differentials. While
serve as conduits for the diffusion of appro- institutions shape structures and condition
priate practices and ideas. Indeed, much their effects, networks generate the cate-
institutional research conflates ‘simple’ dif- gories and hierarchies that help define insti-
fusion with ‘deep’ institutionalization. tutions and contribute to their efficacy. Thus,
Meanwhile, research on networks often con- any effort to understand institutional
siders how categorical or status variations in processes must take networks into account,
network structures shape social comparison and vice versa.
and stratification processes. But these points Our argument draws on core concepts
of intellectual cross-fertilization have from institutional and network theory that are
remained undertheorized.1 utilized across both lines of work. Despite
We think there is much to be gained from their portability, however, they have rarely
a more analytically driven dialogue between been theoretically integrated. Using institu-
these literatures. We argue that networks and tional theory, we highlight the under-
institutions mutually shape one another. Over theorized relational aspects of both fields and
time, this co-evolutionary process creates, logics. Starting in network theory, we
NETWORKS AND INSTITUTIONS 597

emphasize the important institutional fea- This canonical article incorporated net-
tures of embeddedness and social capital. work ideas in several key ways, although
Our goal is to do more than review existing subsequent work has tended to overlook its
points of contact or stimulate joint discus- structural aspects. In part, this neglect may
sion. We aim to provide a roadmap for future be traced to a contrast that Meyer and Rowan
research that will directly address two critical emphasized between organizations where
animating questions. First, how do institu- survival depended on managing the contin-
tional practices and forms emerge from gencies of boundary-spanning relations and
networks? Second, how do institutionalized others that had to respond to ceremonial
categories and conventions shape the demands which were present in their
structure and effects of networks? environments. This continuum suggested that
We begin with a brief excursion through managing relational networks involved mat-
several canonical works in institutional ters of coordination and control, while more
analysis, highlighting the implicit, but institutionalized settings necessitated efforts
nonetheless strong, network underpinnings at symbolic management. But Meyer and
of these theoretical arguments. For symme- Rowan also emphasized that all organiza-
try, we select several well-known empirical tions are embedded in both relational and
studies that directly measure network effects institutionalized contexts. They stressed that
to account for the transmission of institu- the complexity of relational networks gener-
tional practices and structures. Next we ated ‘explosive organizing potential,’ and this
revisit four foundational ideas – organiza- greatly increased both the spread and number
tional field, institutional logic, embedded- of rationalized myths. Central to this process
ness or the non-contractual basis of contract, of transmission and standardization were
and social capital – which contain both trade and professional associations and inter-
network and institutional insights that organizational coalitions.
are, we contend, indissoluble. We then The generative potential of networks as
develop answers to our key questions transmission channels is readily apparent in
about emergence and constraint against this the Meyer and Rowan paper. Similarly,
background. DiMaggio and Powell (1983) argued that the
great rationalizers of the latter half of the
twentieth century were the professions and
the modern state. The growth and elaboration
NETWORKS ARE CARRIERS OF of professional networks spanning organi-
INSTITUTIONAL EFFECTS zations contributed, they argued, to the rapid
spread of various models of organizing.
In their classic paper, Meyer and Rowan Networks were also essential components of
(1977) observed that the formal structures of DiMaggio and Powell’s conception of an
organizations ‘dramatically reflect the myths organizational field, which emphasized both
of their institutional environments.’ They connectedness (Lauman, Galaskiewicz, and
argued that organizations are driven to incor- Marsden, 1978) and structural equivalence
porate practices and procedures defined and (White, Boorman, and Breiger, 1976). The
buttressed by widely prevalent, rationalized institutional development of an organiza-
concepts in the larger society. These prac- tional field hinged on: (1) increased interac-
tices were institutionalized through profes- tion among participants; (2) the development
sional standards and prestige hierarchies, and of well-defined status orders and patterns of
reinforced by public opinion. Consequently, coalition; (3) heightened information shar-
Meyer and Rowan contended that the build- ing; and (4) mutual awareness and respon-
ing blocks of formal organization ‘litter the siveness. The twin imprints of the relational
societal landscape.’ sociologies of Harrison White and Pierre
598 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Bourdieu clearly stamp this account of field health care eroded professional sovereignty,
evolution and institutional formation. opening the door for more market-based cri-
From DiMaggio and Powell’s perspective, teria. The key point, however, is not that a
status orders shaped patterns of information new managerial logic replaced physicians or
exchange, creating a core and periphery bureaucrats, but that health care became a
structure that channeled the flow of news and complex, multi-level field in which both the
personnel within organizational fields. The number and novelty of inter-organizational
policies and structures of the most central connections between hospitals and other
organizations in a field were more likely to types of health care institutions expanded
be emulated by others. While many subse- dramatically. ‘Managers appear to have been
quent researchers picked up on the mimetic the beneficiaries, not the agents’ of deinstitu-
aspects of this phenomenon, the underlying tionalized professional power’ (Scott
structural elements received less attention et al., 2000: 328).
(see discussion in Mizruchi and Fein, 1999). The forces that transformed the health
Nevertheless, this account of field structura- care field were varied and numerous, ranging
tion emphasized how shared meanings and from policy legislation to medical specializa-
typifications, as well as stable role structures, tion to the increasing complexity of service
emerged out of repeated interaction. delivery. These broad changes were typically
In one of the most comprehensive empiri- ushered in by new linkages, formed by
cal studies of institutional transformation, accreditation bodies, shifting organiza-
Scott and colleagues (2000) analyzed the tional control structures, inter-organizational
profound changes that occurred in health alliances and coalitions, as well as new affil-
care delivery in the San Francisco Bay Area iations with purchasers, intermediaries, serv-
between 1945 and 1990. They demonstrate ice providers, and government. These
the effects differing forms of legitimacy have network realignments not only brought with
on hospital survival rates. In the period fol- them participants who changed the bound-
lowing World War II, physicians and their aries of the health care field, but the new
professional code of conduct dominated entrants were also carriers of novel ideas that
health care standards. Federal financing and profoundly altered the meaning of health
the regulation of health care arose in the late care. Scott et al. (2000) captured this
1960s and greatly expanded in the 1970s and change in relationships and meanings aptly
1980s. That growth was accompanied by in their discussion of the shift from the
increasingly salient technical forms of legiti- doctor–patient relationship to one of a health
macy. In recent decades, the health care care provider–consumer transaction. This
industry became more intensely competitive. upsurge in linkages and connections was
For-profit entities entered the field in large critical to accreditation, health care provi-
numbers, and managerial legitimacy increas- sion, and fiscal solvency; but these new rela-
ingly shaped evaluative standards. Scott and tionships also remade the taken-for-granted
colleagues’ rich analysis documented that understandings of the medical field.
earlier professional and regulatory standards Each of these pillars of sociological insti-
were not extinguished by the new managerial tutionalism argues that social networks trans-
and market orientations; rather, each succes- mit ideas and practices in distinctive ways.
sive era displayed more heterogeneus forms Networks also reflect key micro-level inter-
of legitimacy. actions that influence institutional dynamics.
Consequently, as the health care field To illuminate the recursive nature of institu-
evolved, ‘three logics – professional, public, tional and network influences, we turn to
corporate – were all present, active and several notable empirical studies that demon-
contending with one another’ (Scott et al., strate the potent force of social networks.
2000: 316). Federal funding and oversight of Though the orientations of the authors differ
NETWORKS AND INSTITUTIONS 599

and the objects of inquiry vary, we argue that his or her position in the contributions com-
these prominent papers carry a common mes- munity’ (Galaskiewicz and Burt, 1991: 90).
sage that networks are shaped by social com- Galaskiewicz and Burt recognize the
parison processes in which institutionalized strong parallels between their account of the
categories are highly influential. Twin Cities nonprofits community and
DiMaggio and Powell’s (1983) explanation
for how and why organizations, and the
structure of organizational fields, change
NETWORKS ARE STAMPED BY over time. Indeed, they explicitly note that
INSTITUTIONAL CATEGORIES ‘an important component of DiMaggio and
Powell’s argument is the network of contacts
Galaskiewicz and Burt (1991) analyze how among organizations or their agents’
corporate officers evaluated nonprofit organ- (Galaskiewicz and Burt, 1991: 88). Within
izations in the Minneapolis-St. Paul region this philanthropic community, the manner in
and decided whether to make significant which evaluative categories varied across
charitable contributions to them. In the Twin organizations could be predicted by how
Cities, the networks of high-profile corporate corporate contributions offices were strati-
philanthropists and leaders of the nonprofit fied within the status hierarchy of their
community were closely inter-connected. profession.
The authors tested to see whether the spread Palmer, Jennings, and Zhou (1993) ana-
of evaluative standards operated through the lyzed the influence of institutional, political,
mechanisms of cohesion or through struc- and economic factors on the adoption of the
tural equivalence. The frame of reference in multidivisional form (MDF) by large U.S.
the former is the dyad, stemming from a his- corporations in the 1960s. To assess how
tory of past experiences, while the latter is institutional factors influenced the transition
the larger social system. Dyadic influence to an MDF, they measured the professional
processes operate on a one-to-one basis, training and social network connections of
while structural equivalence effects draw on key organizational decision makers, focusing
perceptions of similarity rather than direct specifically on elite business school training
communication. Consequently, structural of corporate chief executive officers and
equivalence processes are driven by what interlocks among corporate boards of direc-
officers presume others in comparable posi- tors. They also assessed economic and polit-
tions are doing. ical considerations, including corporate
In a community that is closely knit and in strategy and performance, as well as the
regular contact, one might expect direct influence of managerial rivalries, both inside
interaction and cohesion to trump structural companies and in external coalitions.
equivalence. Instead, Galaskiewicz and Burt This impressive effort to test rival theoret-
find the opposite. In the Twin Cities, the ical arguments found ample support for both
importance of structural equivalence economic and institutional factors, but little
reflected common norms and standards mag- for an explicitly political view. Both corpo-
nified within a professional community, rate industrial diversity and geographic dis-
demonstrating how the field’s informal strat- persion stimulated the adoption of the
ification orders conditioned individual multidivisional structure. Differentiated
acceptance of these norms. As the authors companies (i.e., firms involved in multiple
put it, when an opinion comes to be shared unrelated lines of activity) and those with
within ego’s profession, ‘ego is expected to facilities spread across the nation encounter
follow rapidly to avoid the embarrassment of problems that a multidivisional structure pur-
being the last to espouse a belief that has ports to solve. Institutional variables also
become a recognized feature of occupying proved to be robust. Most notably for our
600 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

purposes, networks were critical factors in in other regions the practice never took hold.
the transition to a multidivisional form. In the status-bound corporate world of
Corporations in which CEOs had graduate New York City, for example, protecting the
degrees from elite business schools were CEO was seen as a duty of boards, but in
more likely to adopt the MDF than firms with the more rough-and-tumble entrepreneurial
executives who did not hold elite degrees. world of Silicon Valley, parachutes were
Boards of directors with interlock ties to eschewed. The mechanism at work here was
firms that had already adopted an MDF social comparison among local elites, who
structure also influenced adoption. Not sur- looked to their regional reference groups
prisingly, corporate board connections to for a sign of whether their CEO should be
non-MDF firms did not (Palmer et al., 1993: protected against unexpected job loss. This
120). Thus, institutional backgrounds and ‘parochial’ social comparison process
social connections jointly condition corpo- resulted in a slower rate of diffusion than the
rate strategies. more national and cosmopolitan transmis-
Davis and Greve (1997) analyzed the dif- sion of pills through director networks.
fusion of two practices that were adopted by Davis and Greve point out that these local
corporations in the 1980s as a defense and national network channels were also
against hostile takeovers. The ‘poison pill’ characterized by different normative stan-
and the ‘golden parachute’ were embraced by dards. The poison pill was couched in a lan-
companies and their managers to raise the guage of fending off unscrupulous raiders.
costs of an unwanted takeover bid. Both This defense was perceived as appropriate
of these practices were initially controversial and legitimate by board members; and thus
but came to be adopted by the majority championed by them in different corporate
of U.S. corporations. Yet, despite their settings. Contact with directors in similar
similarities, the ‘pill’ spread quickly and industry sectors and in corporations of com-
the ‘parachute’ diffused more slowly. parable status became the venues for diffu-
Interestingly, the channels of social influence sion of a practice that came to be regarded as
varied too. Pills spread through cohesive ties accepted and necessary.
among members of corporate boards of Parachutes were much more difficult to
directors, while parachutes were adopted legitimate. They were perceived by some to
on the basis of geographic proximity. reflect naked managerial self-interest, while
Corporations adopted golden parachutes as others saw them as payoffs for weak man-
other firms in their local metropolitan area agers. Questions about the appropriateness of
did so. parachutes were answered locally, by look-
This intriguing analysis revealed a puzzle: ing to the behavior of central individuals and
the same individuals – members of corporate companies in the regional economy. In short,
boards – decided to adopt both practices, but the relevant networks for diffusion and the
the tools spread at different speeds through pace at which they communicated specific
divergent routes. Davis and Greve ask what practices were shaped by the broader institu-
factors accounted for these different patterns tional context in which they were situated.
of diffusion. Social networks provide one Davis and Greve’s analysis affords keen
compelling answer. Pills spread from one insight into how network configurations
corporation to another across the nation are conditioned by institutional forces.
because the corporate director network has a Understanding why the same boards take sig-
national reach. Boards that shared directors nals about adopting pills from distant but
were the conduits through which this mecha- connected rivals, while turning to local com-
nism to deter hostile raiders spread. Golden munity members for signals about the legiti-
parachutes, in contrast, circulated locally. macy of parachutes, requires not only
Their diffusion was rapid in some areas, but attention to networks, but to the meaning of
NETWORKS AND INSTITUTIONS 601

practices, to categorical distinctions and to a community of organizations that engage in


status hierarchies. common activities and are subject to similar
We find numerous shared analytical under- reputational and regulatory pressures
pinnings in these different, notable accounts (DiMaggio and Powell, 1983; Scott et al.,
of institutional influences and network 2000). Through a more politically filtered
effects. Hany scholars identify networks as lens, a field is seen as a space of positions
the channels through which institutional whose characteristics are jointly defined by
effects flow, and see networks of like-minded the configuration of their inter-relationships
individuals as central reference groups that and by the struggles of actors who seek to
promote widely emulated practices. The pres- claim them (Bourdieu and Wacquant, 1992).
ence of these common elements in a handful These two definitions bracket contemporary
of important empirical studies lends credence institutional parlance, where ‘field’ carries
to our claim that networks and institutions three distinct, but only partially decompos-
mutually influence one another. To pursue able connotations. We highlight each sense
this argument, we move from empirical stud- of the term, and then argue that their indissol-
ies to conceptual claims, and offer a brief exe- ubility results from the relational threads that
gesis of four core ideas that are widely used cross-cut them. Networks both structure and
in both network and institutional analyses. integrate fields.
We demonstrate that core concepts in institu- The fields of institutional theory are recog-
tional and network theory are analytically nizable arenas of social action, as such they
richer and more useful when they take each are fields of endeavor. A more dynamic view
other into account. suggests differentiated fields of play where
more or less attractive positions convey
opportunity, and constrict the possibilities of
various social groups. Finally, fields are
FOUNDATIONAL CONCEPTS molded into their characteristic shapes by
rules, conventions and expectations that
define appropriate activities and legitimate
Organizational fields
positions. Thus, this view emphasizes fields
Fields are simultaneously master concepts of force that regulate social action.
and fundamental empirical sites for institu- Relationships are moves in games and fun-
tional analysis. Much recent (and some not damental components of the fields on which
so recent) work has focused on genesis and they are played. As such, concrete network
change in such diverse fields as politics, the structures map past struggles, and shape pos-
arts, law, gastronomy, and the chemical sibilities for the future by differentially chan-
industry (Clemens, 1997; DiMaggio, 1991; neling resources to contestants. Networks
Dezalay and Garth, 1996; Ferguson, 1998; also push and pull players into finite sets of
Hoffman, 2001; Rao, Monin, and Durand, positions. Thus, the positions and affiliations
2003). These rich narrative efforts, as well as participants claim are only partially under
more abstract treatments, rely heavily on their control. The presence and absence
relational language to describe the contours of ties render a confusing struggle clear
and characteristics of fields. Perhaps more to observers and participants alike
importantly, organizational action within by allowing them to classify and order both
fields is understood largely in terms of affili- the players and their moves into categories
ation, competition, and shared membership, (forms, identities, strategies) and hierarchies
all features that emphasize how social rela- (status orders). A fundamental insight of
tions shape institutions (Fourcade, 2007). network theory, often neglected in institu-
Consider two related definitions of tional analyses, is that relationships are both
fields. In one view, an organizational field is pipes that channel resource flows and as
602 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

prisms that help render action sensible ‘defining the relationships among roles in
(Podolny, 2001). terms of what the incumbent of one role
Networks are essential to fields in at least owes to the incumbents of other roles’
two senses: they are both a circulatory (March and Olsen, 1984: 23). In contrast to
system and a mechanism for sensemaking. classic Weberian notions of authority, it is the
Fields are shaped by networks, which condi- linkages among conventional recipes for
tion the formation of relationships and help action that are central, defining characteris-
establish their consequences. But it is only tics of organizations. When spread across
against the backdrops of particular fields that the categorical distinctions provided by orga-
rationalities and strategies of action are sen- nizational roles, logics comprise formal
sible. The relational aspects of fields are the structures.
threads that weave together the term’s dis- Clemens (1993, 1997) extends the idea
parate meanings. of logics by recognizing that the social world
is rife with alternative models for organizing
any particular endeavor. In her view,
organizational repertoires are templates that
Institutional logics
structure concrete relationships within organ-
Logics constitute the rules and conventions izations and convey scripts for behavior that
of a particular organizational field. In broad link forms of organization to cultural
terms, an institutional logic is the constella- expectations (Clemens 1993: 758). In this
tion of beliefs and associated practices (the sense, logics offer a mechanism by which
schemas and scripts) that a field’s partici- institutions direct the formation and
pants hold in common. These packages of mobilization of networks, while providing a
beliefs and practices are organizing princi- means for expectations and regulations to
ples and recipes for action. They have exert force upon the participants in a
instrumental, normative, and cognitive impli- field. The analytic link she makes between
cations (Friedland and Alford, 1991; institutional logic and organizational form
Whitley, 1992; Thornton, 2004). Logics pro- is an important one that deserves further
vide rationales for action. They are most explication.
influential when they are consistent and Institutional logics, then, are inextricably
easily taken-for-granted. But when multiple tied to concrete structures that define the
competing logics are in play in the same set- authority relationships that characterize orga-
ting, they can trigger conflict and/or generate nizational forms. Logics do more, however,
new accounts of activity. than forge collections of roles into formal
Three different approaches to the idea of organization. Friedland and Alford (1991)
logics rely on relational underpinnings, but offered a now widely held view of logics as
their structural features are rarely elaborated. central, distinguishing features of fields.
Consider first the idea, drawn from work in In their view, the content of a field’s
the Carnegie School tradition of organization dominant logic renders networks much more
theory, that organizational action is routine- than mere affiliations. Without institutional
based, rule-governed, and triggered by con- logics, ‘it will be impossible to explain what
ventions that match concrete situations and kinds of social relationships have what kind
actions to the needs of particular positions of effect on the behavior of organizations and
(Cohen, March, and Olsen, 1972; March and individuals’ (Friedland and Alford, 1991: 225).
Olsen, 1984). These logics of appropriate- Logics make networks meaningful features
ness do more than simply set the grounds for of social and economic worlds precisely by
concrete action in particular situations. When disciplining (though not determining) the
strung together across roles, they represent formation and implications of relationships.
the authority structure of an organization by The presence or absence of connections and
NETWORKS AND INSTITUTIONS 603

the resources that flow through them, as well multiple institutional arrangements and
as the meanings that participants and logics, only some of which are instrumental.
observers attribute to relationships, depend Relationships matter precisely because their
upon prevailing logics. The same relation- meanings are variable and depend on the ori-
ship or affiliation may exist under the aus- entations of participants to the various logics
pices of multiple institutional logics, which and contexts that render them sensible.
provides leverage to elaborate the ways in Return, for a moment, to Macaulay’s (1963:
which relationships carry the social into 61) discussion of contract and consider the
instrumental exchanges. oft-cited example of a businessman who
notes: ‘You don’t read legalistic contract
Embeddedness: the non-contractual clauses to each other if you ever want to do
basis of contract business again. One doesn’t run to the lawyers
Classic research in organizational studies if he wants to stay in business because one
(Dalton, 1959; Gouldner, 1954) and a foun- must behave decently.’ There is clearly a story
dational work in economic sociology about trust, forbearance, and the shadow of the
(Macaulay, 1963) demonstrated that even future implicit in these statements. Much less
highly purposive economic exchanges are explored, however, is the idea that ‘behaving
enmeshed in and freighted with social expec- decently’ is defined against a particular social
tations. Organizational and economic actions and institutional backdrop.
result from a complex lamination of motiva- The idea that lawyers should be excluded is
tions and meanings that participants draw not because they are personal strangers but
from the various fields in which they partici- because they view the same relationship
pate. Macaulay’s (1963) key finding that through a different institutional lens, which
businessmen often disregard the legal rights helps explain why they find the business-
and responsibilities inherent in contract in man’s approach ‘startling’. As Macaulay
favor of more social means of dealmaking noted, where businessmen see orders that can
and dispute resolution underscored how legitimately be cancelled, lawyers see the
social relations cemented economic transac- same exchanges as contracts whose violation
tions. His study offered a starting point for carries strongly negative consequences.
Granovetter (1985) who, drawing on Economic exchange has a non-contractual
Polanyi’s (1957) insight that market relation- basis, but that bedrock is both relational and
ships are embedded in both economic (con- categorical. The meaning of a relationship
tract) and non-economic (friendship, familial) and the actions appropriate to it depend
institutions, illuminated how concrete social jointly on the parties to the tie and the broader
relationships shape economic activity. institutional and professional milieus to
Granovetter’s (1985: 500) argument that which they belong. Put differently, relation-
social relationships are fundamental to eco- ships are multiply embedded and the social
nomic processes has been highly influential. entanglements that make economic exchange
Nevertheless, we concur, to a degree, with possible are the joint outcome of both net-
critics of the embeddedness perspective works and institutions. We make a similar
(Krippner, 2001; Lie, 1997) who argue that claim about our final concept, social capital,
a purely relational view of market activity which more closely situates individual activi-
loses some of the evocative features of ties in both fields and networks.
Polanyi’s original, more institutional defini-
tion. Social ties are fundamental to eco-
nomic relations, certainly. What we find Social capital
more interesting is the insight that economic
relationships (as well as any other collective Like ‘embeddedness,’ the voluminous
social activity) can be understood in terms of and disparate uses of ‘social capital’ have
604 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

rendered the concept slippery. At a basic actors ... within the structure.’ Note three fea-
level, capital is a resource that can grow with tures of this definition. First, there are multi-
investment and use. Social capital, then, is ple ‘social capitals.’ Second, social capital
capital derived from relationships external to does not equally facilitate all activities.
the individual (Lin, 2001). In other words, Third, the activities for which this capital is
social networks convey an array of resources an efficacious resource are located within
to individuals at differential rates. Viewed the structure that defined it. Put more suc-
instrumentally, that capital can be invested cinctly, social capital is contextual: it derives
with some expectation of returns. The from and only pays dividends in certain
networks that convey social capital can be situations.
either concrete, measurable relationships or Pierre Bourdieu offers a subtly different
more diffuse affiliations based on group definition of the concept. He emphasizes a
membership. broader notion of social structure and a more
The latter sense of membership owes explicit emphasis on resources, distinguish-
much to Durkheim and treats the collective ing social capital from both cultural and
effervescence and shared identification of human forms of capital: ‘The aggregate of
social groups as both a public and a private the actual or potential resources which are
good that can be harvested for personal and linked to possession of a durable network
collective benefit (Putnam, 2000). In of more or less institutionalized relationships
Alejandro Portes’ terms (1998: 52), ‘involve- of mutual acquaintance or recognition’
ment and participation in groups can have (Bourdieu, 1985: 248). This definition is also
positive consequences for the individual and a complicated one, but note that it makes
the community.’ Other scholars take a nar- social capital an outcome of both direct ties
rower view, focusing more explicitly on con- and recognizable membership. Perhaps more
crete relationships of exchange. Burt (2005: importantly, Bourdieu’s emphasis on institu-
4), for instance, notes ‘One’s position in tionalized relationships returns us to the
the structure of ... exchanges can be an asset consideration of fields, a complementary
in its own right. That asset is social capital, concept in his theory of practical action.
in essence, a conception of location effects in Here, capital (of whatever form) is derived
differentiated markets.’ In this formulation, from the arrangements that characterize par-
social capital derives from the structure of ticular fields, and it is within those fields that
the collective, but the returns are to the indi- different varieties of capital can be mobilized
vidual and are based on differential positions to serve disparate ends.
within networks rather than on the interplay We argue that this close look at key con-
of affiliation and identification emphasized cepts from institutional theory and network
in more categorical, membership-based theory demonstrates that the approaches are
treatments. indissoluble. Fields are fairly barren without
Two often-cited general definitions of the interpretive lenses and resource channels
social capital combine both these aspects in a created by networks. Logics render networks
fashion that is instructive for our effort. Both and organizational structures sensible in par-
situate social capital within a particular ticular fields, but many, if not most, activities
context, while treating it as an imperfectly are amenable to multiple logics. Thus, the
fungible resource. Coleman (1990: S98) rec- ability of logics to shape social action
ognizes that social capital is plural: ‘Social depends intimately on the structures in which
capital is defined by its functions. It is not a activities take place and the partners with
single entity, but a variety of different enti- whom they are undertaken. Expanding the
ties, with two elements in common: they reach of all four concepts to more fruitfully
all consist of some aspect of social struc- capture such relationships will be particu-
tures, and they facilitate certain actions of larly important to the growing number of
NETWORKS AND INSTITUTIONS 605

studies that examine the genesis and dynam- institutions, and the concrete relation-
ics of institutions and networks. In the fol- ships that are the basis of networks have a
lowing section, we abstract from our dual character. Like other well-known duali-
foregoing discussion to sketch an analytic ties – between persons and groups (Brieger,
framework that takes up this challenge. 1974), meanings and structures (Mohr,
1998), organizations and environments
(Stinchcombe, 1965) – we take meaningful
social categories to be defined in large part
CONTEXT OR CO-CONSTITUTION? by relationships’ participants from within
and across them (White et al., 1976). At the
We have documented a set of analytic con- same time, the likelihood and implications of
nections between networks and institutions. particular relationships stem from the
Canonical works in neo-institutional theory categories that collaborators occupy and
rely explicitly on network imagery and span. As a result, categories and relationships
mechanisms, while exemplary empirical jointly bound and determine action in social
pieces demonstrate that networks are central systems.
to explanations of institutional phenomena. Understanding how networks and institu-
Similarly, four master concepts – field, logic, tions co-evolve to shape social and economic
embeddedness, and social capital – mix both arrangements requires us to attend to the
relational and categorical claims. We believe myriad ways that relationships and cate-
these interdependencies can be understood in gories influence each other. We argue that
two ways. The first, less radical view, treats one force behind that shaping is organiza-
networks and institutions as mutually tions and individuals who strive to navigate
reinforcing, contextual features of social settings where multiple institutional logics
systems. The second line of argument exam- either co-exist or collide.2 If logics offer tem-
ines how networks and institutions co-consti- plates for action and organizing while ren-
tute one another. Put differently, the first dering existing and potential relationships
view sees institutions as the landscape and meaningful, then settings where multiple
networks as the social relations on that field. logics overlap will be particularly fertile
The second view argues that fields influence ground for institutional entrepreneurship.
which relations are possible, and how Some of those in structural locations that
these relations are forged can alter the engage multiple logics – as in art and com-
landscape in profound ways. We hold the merce, patient care and administrative
second view. efficiency, or altruistic medical donations
Many institutionalists have recognized that and income generation – can use their
networks are important contexts for under- circumstances to forge new opportunities or
standing institutional process (Jepperson, craft multivocal identities. In settings
1991; Davis, Diekmann, and Tinsley, 1994; where numerous logics reflect conflicting or
Dobbin and Dowd, 2000). Contextual effects incompatible demands, ambiguous identities
are key, but more important, we believe, is the and multiple networks offer room to maneu-
idea that networks and institutions are co- ver. Still, the tensions that are generated
constitutive. In other words, networks shape by ambiguity, multiplicity, and contradiction
institutions but institutions sculpt networks can be daunting to individuals and
and direct their growth. Genesis and change, organizations.
not just context, are at stake in the merger of Practical action draws on both relation-
structural and cultural approaches to complex ships and categories, and, in so doing, links
social systems. networks and institutions. Such efforts are
Our argument rests on the idea that most visible in settings characterized by con-
categorical distinctions are at the heart of flicting logics, multiple audiences, and
606 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

ambiguous categories. Participants in spe- These questions do not exhaust the con-
cific fields draw on categories and associated nections between networks and institutions.
logics to make sense of their worlds and Nevertheless, we believe that initial answers
direct their relationships and affiliations. At to these queries will aid in developing a
the same time, relationships and affiliations theory of social and economic life that treats
offer participants disparate types and networks and institutions as flip sides of the
amounts of capital, depending on their insti- same analytic coin.
tutional context. Continuity and change in We begin by revisiting our work on the
categorization systems and network struc- evolution of inter-organizational collabora-
tures alike depend on discernable patterns in tion in human therapeutic and diagnostic
the formation of ties and affiliations. biotechnology. The commercial field of the
How, then, do we explore the generative life sciences provides us with fertile ground
relationship between networks and institu- to answer our first two questions. We first
tions? A thorough-going elaboration of a discuss how the same collaborative activi-
‘network-institutional’ research program is ties, for instance joint R&D efforts, have
beyond the scope of this chapter. We opt very different implications for biotech firms
instead to reconsider some of our own work depending on the organizational form of
on the evolution of the human therapeutic partners. Here categorically different forms
and diagnostic biotechnology industry and of organization bring different logics to the
on the institutional changes that surround the same activities. As a result, the likelihood
commercialization of academic research. In and effects of any particular tie depends on
the former setting, multiple logics of discov- institutional features of the partner.
ery associated with different types of organi- R&D undertaken with pharmaceutical
zational partners encourage biotechnology firms, for instance, differs dramatically
firms to create and maintain diverse network from scientifically comparable research con-
ties in order to innovate and develop novel ducted with academic, university-based
products. These ties span multiple types of collaborators because pharmaceuticals and
organizations to form a field where relation- universities operate in different selection
ships and outcomes alike are stamped by environments under different institutional
the categorical features of partners. In the logics. Moreover, as the field developed
latter setting, logics associated with the biotech firms and partner organizations
commercial use of science are imported into become relational generalists. In addition to
the established field of public science, spark- learning to manage multiple types of activi-
ing both structural and institutional transfor- ties across stages of product development,
mations. We address a set of research biotech firms developed the capacities neces-
questions that emerge from treating skilled, sary to conducting the same kinds of endeav-
but constrained, performances as a mecha- ors with different types of partners. Their
nism linking relationships and categories. efforts to develop and maintain network port-
The key questions we consider are: folios that include diverse activities and part-
ners accounts for the characteristic structure
(1) How do the meaning and consequences of of the industry-wide network.
relationships depend on the character of the We next turn to analyses of innovation in
participants?
two densely populated biotechnology
(2) How do the effects of macro-structures depend
on the types of participants that comprise them?
regions, Boston and the San Francisco Bay
(3) How do locally situated individuals pull down area, to address our second question. These
global categories and draw on external relation- two regional communities are highly produc-
ships in their daily activities? tive, but one (Boston) is anchored in a net-
(4) How does situated action escape its local context to work that grew from public sector origins.
alter global categories and external relationships? The other community (SF Bay) is centered
NETWORKS AND INSTITUTIONS 607

on a network that emerged from starting Bourdieu and Wacquant (1992) in viewing a
points in venture capital (VC) initiatives. The field as a center of debate in which compet-
different institutional anchors in these two ing interests negotiate over resources and the
regional networks result in divergent interpretation of key rules and conventions.
approaches to innovation. Both clusters are Their study focuses on the interaction of
highly successful and network structures are multiple overlapping networks through time
fundamental in both places, but the types of by examining how the formation, dissolu-
success and the ways in which networks tion, and rewiring of network ties from 1988
matter vary with the organizational form and to 1999 shaped the opportunity structure of
associated logics of key participants. the biomedical field. By linking an evolving
We dramatically shift levels of analysis network topology and field evolution, Powell
and go ‘microscopic’ to examine our next et al. demonstrate that social change is not
two questions. We first consider the ways in an invariant process that affects all partici-
which broad logics (of appropriate skepti- pants equally. Rather, field-level transfor-
cism), salient categories (such as academic mations are multi-dimensional phenomena.
discipline) and concrete relationships (of col- Organizations feel the reverberations of
laboration and mentorship) are pulled down change in different ways, depending on their
into the daily life of a scientific laboratory. institutional status and location in the overall
The institutional and relational features of network. But the status orders and structures
academic science shape laboratory life, but of the field change over time.
they do so imperfectly because they also The analytical aim of the 2005 paper was
offer researchers avenues for resistance. to illuminate how patterns of network inter-
Finally, we turn to an analysis of decision action emerged, took root, and transformed
making in a high-profile technology licens- the field, with disparate ramifications for all
ing office to consider how local action can of the varied participants. The empirical set-
escape its immediate context to reshape ting was the field of biotechnology, which
broader categories and relationships. In developed out of university laboratories in
this instance, situated efforts to resolve con- the 1970s, saw the founding of dozens of sci-
tradictory logics at the boundary between ence-based companies in the 1980s, and
academe and the market drive licensing matured in the 1990s with the release of
officers to create complicated deals that can dozens of novel medicines. The field is
entangle participants from different indus- notable for both scientific and commercial
trial and technological categories, thus shift- advances and for a diverse cast of organiza-
ing the character of the field. tions ranging from universities, public
research organizations, venture capital firms,
dedicated biotech firms, and giant multina-
tional pharmaceutical corporations. Because
THE RECURSIVE NATURE OF the sources of scientific leadership were
NETWORKS AND INSTITUTIONS widely dispersed and developed rapidly, and
the relevant skills and resources needed to
In their study of the commercialization of the produce new medicines were broadly distri-
life sciences, Powell and colleagues (2005) buted, the participants in the biomedical field
offer a co-evolutionary analysis of how fields have found inter-organizational collaboration
and networks influence one another. Their essential (Powell, Koput, and Smith-Doerr,
starting point is the view that fields emerge 1996). By analyzing the evolving structure of
when social, technical, or economic changes inter-organizational networks, we demon-
exert pressures on existing relations, and strated how the larger field and its conven-
reconfigure models of action and social tions changed both the meaning of ties and
structures. In this respect, they follow the practice of collaboration.
608 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

In the early years of the industry, from multiple activities. For example, universities
1975 to the late 1980s, most biotech firms and public research organizations specialized
were small companies that relied heavily on in basic science and in early stages of drug
external support. No biotech firm had the development. Venture capital firms special-
necessary skills or resources to bring a new ized in financing. Biotechnology companies,
medicine to market in the early days, thus and especially large multinationals, tended to
they became involved in an elaborate lattice- have a hand in many more activities. More
like network of relationships with universi- recently, public research organizations such
ties, hospitals, and large multinational firms. as universities have greatly broadened their
The large corporations, despite well- range of endeavors in the biomedical field.
established internal capabilities, lacked The most dramatic finding of this research
access to the cutting edge of university sci- was that, over time, all participants in the
ence. Deficient in a knowledge base in the field had to learn to master a wider array of
new field of molecular biology, large firms relationships and move from specialist to
were drawn to the biotech start-ups that had generalist roles. That move makes the need
more capability at basic and translational sci- to navigate multiple potentially competing
ence. This diverse distribution of technologi- logics a key feature of the field.
cal and organizational resources was a key Second, as the field gained coherence and
factor driving early collaborative arrange- the pattern of reliance on networks solidified,
ments in the industry. A number of institu- various institutions emerged to facilitate and
tional factors undergirded this collaborative monitor inter-organizational collaboration.
division of labor. Offices were established on university cam-
The breakneck pace of technical advance puses to promote technology transfer, law
has rendered it difficult for any single organ- firms developed expertise in intellectual
ization to remain scientifically abreast on property issues, and various angel investors
multiple fronts, hence linkages to universities and venture capital firms provided financing,
at the forefront of basic science have been along with management oversight and refer-
necessary. The availability of funding also rals to a host of related businesses. As these
increased rapidly, as biomedicine became a relations thickened and a relational contract-
major force in modern global society. The ing infrastructure grew, the reputation of a
budget of the U.S. National Institutes of participant came to loom large in shaping
Health, a key funder of basic research, nearly identities (Powell, 1996).
doubled in the 1990s during the Clinton There are two aspects of this analysis that
years. Venture capital financing flowed into are highly relevant to our current discussion
biotech somewhat irregularly in the 1990s, of network and field evolution. One, notable
but over the course of the decade grew changes in the nature of the actions pursued
markedly. Biotech financing by venture cap- by the field’s participants accompanied shifts
ital has always been somewhat counter-cycli- in the field’s characteristic practices, logics,
cal. When there was great enthusiasm for the and norms. Two, both the cast of participants
internet and telecommunications start-ups, and the rules of the game changed as new
interest in biotech waned. But when the logics of affiliation emerged and spread. We
bloom fell off the internet rose, financing for briefly summarize these two co-evolving
biomedical ventures went on the upswing. trends, and refer the reader to the more exten-
Two factors stood out in shaping the early sive discussion in the 2005 paper.
structure of the field and the nature of its net- In the late 1980s, the most active partici-
works. One is that the different members of pants in the emerging biotechnology industry
the field had varying abilities and competen- were the dedicated biotech firms, pharma-
cies. Some of the participants were highly ceutical corporations, and key government
specialized, while others had a hand in agencies such as the National Institutes
NETWORKS AND INSTITUTIONS 609

of Health. In these early years, biotech firms Moreover, the primary locus of activity
lacked the capability to bring novel medi- shifted from commercialization to research
cines to market, while large firms trailed in and development and finance.
understanding new developments in molecu- The industry expanded geographically as
lar biology (Gambardella, 1995; Powell and well, moving from its early origins in the Bay
Brantley, 1992; Henderson, Orsenigo, and Area and Boston to San Diego and a handful
Pisano, 1999). Venture capital activity in of other key regions in the United States and
biotech was limited, and most small compa- Europe (Owen-Smith, Riccaboni, Pammolli,
nies supported their research and develop- and Powell 2002). Growth in the number of
ment activities by selling their lead products new firms, new partnerships, and new ideas
to large corporations, which subsequently was greatly enhanced by an increase in finan-
marketed the medicine and pocketed the cial linkages and government research fund-
lion’s share of the revenues (Powell and ing. The combination of the growth of private
Brantley, 1996). equity markets and national funding for
A handful of emerging dedicated biotech R&D replaced the former reliance on large
firms with considerable intellectual property corporations for support.
and strong translational research ability were The older relationship with giant multina-
highly sought after as collaborators. This first tionals for commercialization activity was a
wave of biotechs founded in the 1970s and very restrictive one. A small handful of firms
early 1980s included Genentech, Centocor, had the ability to take a drug to late-stage
Amgen, Genzyme, Biogen and Chiron, and development and a small set of dominant
the most active large corporate partners were multinationals could manufacture and dis-
firms such as Eastman Kodak, Johnson and tribute the drug worldwide. This commer-
Johnson, and Hoffman La Roche. While the cialization arrangement was a downstream
commercial logic of young firms selling their activity, involving the sale of a new medical
lead products to major corporations domi- product. One might consider it the last dance
nated the landscape of the 1980s, a new set of in the product life cycle. In contrast, finance
relationships was quietly emerging. is an upstream activity, which fueled research
The National Institutes of Health began and development, licensing, and subsequent
forging R&D relationships with new entrants commercialization. Consequently, it enrolled
to the industry, and linking university scien- many more participants into the industry net-
tists and start-up firms. As the science under- work. With the addition of more participants,
girding biotechnology expanded by leaps and a wider array of organizational forms joined
bounds, the intellectual property associated the field. Diversely anchored, multi-con-
with the science became more codified and nected networks are much less likely to
legally secure. This, in turn, attracted greater unravel than are networks that are reliant on
interest from venture capital. By the early a few forms of organization.
1990s, biotech firms not only had highly Most notably, multiple logics were now at
prestigious science, evidenced by publica- play. Pharmaceuticals began to recognize
tions in top-tier journals, but they also had that they had to learn skills other than devel-
secure legal rights to their intellectual prop- opment and commercialization in order to
erty in the form of patents. The networks of compete with university researchers and ven-
affiliation began to change, in some respects ture capitalists for access to cutting edge
quite dramatically. By the mid 1990s, ideas. The network structure of the field con-
the most active participants in the field tinued to expand throughout the 1990s, as
continued to be dedicated biotech firms, but both the number of entrants and the number
the large pharmaceutical companies were of ties linking incumbents and new entrants
pushed to the sidelines by the entrance expanded greatly. Indeed, in 1998 more
of venture capital firms and universities. than 1100 new ties were forged. All of the
610 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

participants – from federal funding agencies combinatorial or multivocal took root and
to universities to biotech firms to pharmaceu- began to diffuse to the field’s periphery.
ticals – had begun to engage in a wide array Neither money, market power, nor the
of activities and were no longer specialists. sheer force of novel ideas dominated the
We refer to the ability of participants to par- field. Rather organizations with diverse port-
ticipate effectively in multiple kinds of ties folios of well-connected collaborators
with diverse parties as multivocality, a domi- became the most cohesive, central partici-
nant pattern that emerged whereby highly pants in the field and played the largest
central participants were involved in a role in shaping its evolution. The
diverse array of collaborations with an exten- density of the expanding network and the
sive set of partners of different types (Padgett open scientific trajectory combined to
and Ansell, 1993). enhance the importance of the various partic-
As the cast of participants grew, and as ipants’ reputations. The pattern of cross-cut-
diversity in both organizational form and ting collaboration meant partners on one
activity became more important, new logics project were often rivals on another. As a
of affiliation took hold. In the early years, result, networks were frequently rewired.
there was a powerful influence of accumula- Thus participants had to learn how to exit
tive advantage. Those entrants who had the relationships gracefully, so as not to damage
most visibility attracted the most attention their future collaborative prospects. The co-
and the greatest sponsorship. In short, the evolution of networks and categories in the
rich got richer in the Mertonian sense field created a social structure in which exter-
(Merton, 1968). As the field grew, homophily nal sources of knowledge and resources
became more important, particularly in terms became widely differentiated and a prefer-
of geographic location as firms located near ence for diversity and affiliation with multi-
one another connected. Particular regions of ply connected partners had powerful
the country became known for their biotech mobilizing consequences.
clusters. Through time, a logic of appropri-
ateness developed, in which assumptions
about what a biotechnology firm looked like
became widely accepted. A new canonical INSTITUTIONAL EMBEDDEDNESS
firm excelled in translational science and SHAPES CATEGORIES AND
typically had ties to a research university, a PRODUCTS
venture capital firm or two, and a large cor-
porate partner. A highly successful firm In more recent work we have moved from
would add affiliations with a noted research analyzing the evolution of the macro-network
hospital and perhaps a federal agency, such to more fine-grained study of the two most
as one of the branches of the National active biotechnology clusters, the San
Institutes of Health. But note that each of Francisco Bay Area and the Cambridge/
these affiliations was for a specific type Boston region. The attributes and successes
of relationship, the venture capital tie for of these clusters are widely touted, and their
finance, the university tie for research, the efforts have been broadly emulated world-
link to the hospital for clinical trials, and the wide (Powell, Owen-Smith, and Colyvas,
partnership with a large corporation for com- 2007). But interestingly, despite their similar-
mercialization. ities in scale and reputation, each region
As the field evolved, the diversity of emerged through distinctive patterns of col-
participants began to reshape the range laboration that appear to influence their char-
of activities that the participants undertook. acteristic processes of discovery and types of
As key participants became relational gener- innovation. We explored the relationship
alists, the logic of affiliation that we dub between the forms of affiliation and the types
NETWORKS AND INSTITUTIONS 611

of innovative activity pursued in these regions Dana Farber Cancer Center, and Brigham
(Owen-Smith and Powell, 2006). and Women’s Hospital. The Boston area had
In the conceptual terms used earlier, our many fewer venture capital firms in the
analyses of innovation in Boston and Bay 1970s and 1980s, and VCs arrive in the
Area biotechnology draw on two core ideas. Boston region much later (Powell, Koput,
First, our work demonstrates that the organi- Bowie, and Smith-Doerr, 2002). Neither
zational form of the dominant players in a region housed a large multinational pharma-
network shapes the character of social capital ceutical corporation during the period
in a community. Where universities domi- stretching from 1970s through the 1990s.
nate, a logic of discovery that favors open- Both clusters have structurally cohesive net-
ness and information diffusion prevails and works, but they differ in their mix of organi-
membership alone suffices to increase rates zational types.
of innovation. In contrast, when for-profit We have shown that the Boston network
organizations are key players in the network grew from early origins in the public sector,
and more ‘closed,’ proprietary logics are at and that public science formed the foundation
the fore, a central network position is essen- or anchor for subsequent commercial applica-
tial (Owen-Smith and Powell, 2004). In addi- tion (Owen-Smith and Powell, 2004; Porter,
tion to shifting the ways that organizations Whittington, and Powell, 2005). Because the
extract benefits from their networks, the dif- Boston biotechnology community was linked
ferent logics associated with partners of dis- by shared connections to public research
parate form shape strategies for innovation, organizations early in its evolution, this clus-
the kinds of connections firms forge, and the ter manifested a more open technological tra-
markets they seek to serve. jectory than clusters more heavily reliant on
Recall our description of the different types industrial R&D. By contrast, the Bay Area
of organizations — including VC firms, gov- was much influenced by the prospecting and
ernment agencies, large multinationals, public matchmaking efforts of venture capitalists,
research organizations, and dedicated biotech- the multidisciplinary science of the UCSF
nology firms – that comprise this field. These medical school, and efforts novel technology
diverse organizational forms were linked by transfer at Stanford (Colyvas, 2007). The San
multiple types of affiliations: R&D connec- Francisco Bay Area evolved out of this more
tions for shared research and development, commercial and entrepreneurial orientation.
finance ties reflecting investment, licensing Interestingly, both Boston and the San
relations that transfer the rights to intellectual Francisco Bay Area developed from depend-
property across organizations, and commer- ence upon a non-biotech organizational
cialization partnerships that include product form, and these diverse forms, whether they
development, clinical trials, manufacturing, are public science organizations or highly
and sales and marketing. engaged entrepreneurial financiers, helped
We find two notable differences between catalyze the development of the respective
the Bay Area and Boston regional networks. clusters.
The Bay Area is larger organizationally and Do these different relational components
geographically, with many more biotech and logics influence the nature of research
firms, several major universities, including and the kinds of medical products that
Stanford and the Universities of California emerged from the companies in these two
(UC) at Berkeley and at San Francisco regions? We explored this question in two
(UCSF), and numerous venture capital firms. ways, by examining the nature of patenting
The Boston network, while denser and some- among the participants in the two regions and
what smaller, has many more public research through a paired comparison of two compa-
organizations, including MIT, Harvard rable treatments for multiple sclerosis. In a
University, Massachusetts General Hospital, 2006 study, we found a significant difference
612 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

in the patenting activity of biotech firms in the characteristic Bay Area commerciali-
Boston and the Bay Area, with Bay Area zation strategy. We find that the Boston-
firms producing roughly 3,800 U.S. utility based companies had a stronger focus on
patents over the period 1988–1999, while orphan drugs aimed at patients with rare
Boston area firms generated 1,376. Bay Area diseases. In 1983, the Orphan Drug Act was
firms are much more prolific patentors. created to speed the development of thera-
The highly skewed distribution of patents, pies for rare diseases by offering tax breaks
however, suggests that the difference results and regulatory assistance to organizations
from a small number of exceptionally pro- that would develop medicines for small
ductive Bay Area companies (Owen-Smith market medical needs. Many Boston-based
and Powell, 2006). firms have chosen to focus on orphan drugs,
More interesting, however, are the consid- as one might expect of companies that are
erable differences we observe in the citations enmeshed in networks that are dominated by
Boston and Bay Area firms make in their universities and hospitals. In contrast, Bay
patents. These data suggest that Boston Area biotech firms have pursued medicines
biotechs routinely engage in exploratory for larger markets in which the potential
innovative search, which typically yields a patient populations run into the millions, and
few very high impact patents at the expense for which there is likely to be stiff product
of numerous innovations with lower than competition. This high-risk, high-reward
average future effects (Fleming and strategy shows the imprint of the venture
Sorenson, 2001). In contrast, the dominant capital mindset.
Bay Area patenting strategy appears to be a We did a paired comparison of two drugs:
more directed and incremental, ‘exploitation’ Betaseron, developed by the Bay Area
strategy; exactly as that is what one might firm Cetus, which was eventually acquired
expect of companies supported by investor by Chiron, a Berkeley-based biotech firm;
networks that demand demonstrated progress. and Avonex, developed by Boston-based
Companies that pursue exploitative strategies Biogen in tandem with Berlex Laboratories,
generally develop numerous related improve- an American subsidiary of the German
ments on established components of their pharmaceutical firm Schering-Plough.
research trajectories. Exploratory Boston We compared these similar drugs by
area companies are much more reliant on looking at FDA labeling information
citations to prior art generated by universities and patenting citations to prior art. These
and public research organizations, while are two drugs are biologically and chemically
exploitative Bay Area companies rely heavily comparable. Both are therapies for the same
on citations to their own prior art. Indeed, disease, recurring and remitting multiple
71 percent of the patent citations by Boston sclerosis. Betaseron relies on a set of four
companies are to prior art developed outside patents, three initially assigned to Cetus
of biotech firms. and reassigned to Chiron following the
How might such differences in patenting merger of the two firms, as well as one
be reflected in the kinds of products released process patent, which was reassigned to
by the companies? We used the Food and Berlex Labs. These four patents cite a
Drug Administration (FDA) approval records small group of prior art patents, and in
to identify the 58 new drugs developed by turn, a larger group of second generation
Boston and Bay Area biotech firms. Fifty- citations. In sum, Betaseron rests on a
three of these medicines were approved history of some 55 interlocking patents,
between 1988 and 2004. All of the drugs that almost all of which are based on intellectual
appeared on the market prior to 1988 were property owned by companies.
developed by just two Bay Area firms, Alza Avonex, developed by Biogen, is based on
and Genentech. These early approvals reflect a single compound patent, but it reached
NETWORKS AND INSTITUTIONS 613

more broadly into the prior art, relying on and numerous leading research-oriented
155 separate pieces of intellectual property. hospitals and health institutes. The upshot
Not a single piece of the prior art on which of this institutional mix appears to be a
Avonex depends is owned by Biogen, sug- corporate focus on expansive science and
gesting that Biogen developed its market- new treatments for definable patient
leading therapeutic drug without the benefit populations.
of a thicket of intellectual property rights, In contrast, the biotech community in
and relied instead on a mix of public domain the Bay Area had its earliest origins in the
science and its partners’ intellectual property. partnership of Herbert Boyer, the UC San
Obviously, internal R&D was critical to the Francisco scientist, and Robert Swanson, a
development of both drugs, but Biogen’s prominent venture capitalist, who joined
much heavier reliance on public science together to create Genentech, one of the first
reflected the local network characteristics biotech companies, and long a bellwether of
of Boston. Indeed, among the holders of the industry. UCSF is an unusual institution
prior art patents for Avonex are MIT and the that lacked disciplinary departments in the
Massachusetts General Hospital. full range of research programs. The organi-
Citation network comparisons for similar zational model at UCSF was interdiscipli-
drugs offer an interesting natural experiment nary, with a cross-functional approach to
that holds constant technical, clinical, and medicine and an emphasis on translating
regulatory features of the innovation process. basic science into clinical applications
Even when such factors are quite similar, the (Varmus and Wineberg, 1992). Genentech
patent citation networks underlying these adopted and refined UCSF’s interdisciplinary
two drugs differ in a manner that reflects team model, adding the impatience and
the larger institutional environment of the restlessness of venture capital financiers
regional innovation system. The Bay Area- with their focus on swinging for the fences.
based drug relies more heavily on internal Thus, the company has pursued new medical
R&D and on research efforts of other firms, products for illnesses suffered by millions.
while the Boston-based therapy draws on a This contrast of Boston and the Bay Area,
broad cross-section of prior intellectual the most prolific biotechnology clusters in
property owned by a wide range of different the world, gives considerable insight into the
types of organizations. manner in which the institutional field
Our comparison demonstrates that the shapes the formation of networks. Our
two networks bear a strong institutional foot- examination of two important biotechnology
print. Bay Area firms were faster, more pro- regions demonstrates that logics of action
lific in terms of new product development, shaped by growing network structures
and more likely to pursue novel medicines influences both the habits of mind and the
for large markets. In contrast, Boston firms type of products that companies develop.
were more deliberative in their commercial
strategies and more likely to focus on medi-
cines for identifiable undoserved patient
populations in need of relief from specific SEEING THE FIELD IN
illnesses. We conjecture that the organiza- PERFORMANCE
tional development and innovation processes
were significantly influenced by the sur- Linking relationships and categories through
rounding institutional environments. Boston situated action requires us to understand how
is home to MIT, a powerful basic science individuals draw on and modify seemingly
institution that lacks a medical school, stable, persistent networks and classifications
Harvard, a world-class institution rich in in daily practice. We draw on examples
basic science with a notable medical school, from Owen-Smith’s (2001) ethnographic
614 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

work in a multidisciplinary neuroscience Owen-Smith’s field-work suggests, are dif-


laboratory to explore how scientists use ferentially enabled by scientists’ disciplinary
existing categories and relationships to affiliations. Disciplines have different sta-
make sense of and maneuver within their tuses in the academic field and participants
fields. The particular logics associated with draw on broad expectations of disciplinary
different scientists, technicians, researchers, competence in assessing scientific claims.
and students, and the varieties of capital Discipline is a means to position an
(resources) that can be derived from their individual and his or her claims in a
positions and relationships have primacy in general status hierarchy and a tool for
shaping both identities and opportunities. making sense of their competencies. Bio-
In the H-lab3 – a large, multidisciplinary physicists, for instance, are accorded differ-
academic neuroscience group that conducts ent degrees and types of leeway in skeptical
fundamental research on olfaction in the interactions than chemists or ecologists,
moth Manduca sexta – Owen-Smith found even if their claims do not rest explicitly on
that collective opportunities for skepticism the particular competencies associated with
were shaped by relative positions within the their discipline. In practice, comparable
laboratory as well as expectations based on findings presented by scientists whose
the ascribed skill and disciplinary affiliations disciplines differ can meet with disparate
of participants. In the scientific field, skeptical reactions.
skepticism is a core aspect of the logic by Relationships matter equally as much as
which novel claims are validated. disciplinary categories, however. New find-
In an arena where tacit knowledge made ings are also evaluated in light of the individ-
direct replication problematic and the uals whose research produced them.
multidisciplinary insights needed to pursue Collaboration is a clear example. The vast
the research nevertheless resulted in widely majority of empirical articles in neuroscience
different competencies, public performances have multiple authors. In the life sciences,
of skepticism and resistance became key authorship apportions credit according to a
features of training and knowledge produc- well-understood formula.5 Co-authorship has
tion. Even though public episodes of long been understood as a means for scien-
skepticism were clearly improvisational, tists to invest established stores of profes-
they occurred against the backdrop of well- sional credibility in findings and colleagues
understood (though rarely articulated) (Latour and Woolgar, 1976). But in categori-
norms of appropriateness. Those standards cally and hierarchically differentiated fields,
were structured by the relationships (of men- such investments can be double-edged.
torship, collaboration, and sponsorship), Here, relationships serve as important con-
categories (disciplines, methods, audiences), duits of information and material resources,
and hierarchies (status) that characterize but they are also key prisms for evaluating
scientific fields. The stage for particular new claims under conditions where direct
skeptical performances was thus neither monitoring and replication are implausible or
flat nor neutral. Scientists’ career trajectories impossible.
and the fate of new knowledge claims owed Consider a skeptical performance that
much to the skilled performance and recep- takes discipline, status, and relationships into
tion of skepticism. account simultaneously (Owen-Smith 2001:
Fligstein (2001) identifies social skill 445 fn). In addition to serving as a means to
with the ability to induce cooperation from validate findings developed ‘locally’ in the
others.4 This view of skill is apparent in laboratory, collective skepticism was a means
individual scientist’s abilities to convince by which members of the laboratory deter-
skeptical peers of the quality and validity of mined which ‘external’ claims could be
their findings. Such skilled performances, trusted and whether findings that contradicted
NETWORKS AND INSTITUTIONS 615

their own needed to be taken into account. broader field (e.g. standards of presentation,
In one instance, Owen-Smith observed a long means of apportioning credit via authorship),
discussion of a working paper from outside but relied on a mix of local and global stan-
the H-lab that purported to contradict one of dards of appropriateness.
the group’s primary findings. The paper gen- In instances like this one, local action and
erated heated discussions, including one situated performances bring categories, hier-
interchange between Beth (a technician in the archies, and relationships together in mean-
lab) and Jim, the group’s principal investiga- ingful efforts to navigate a field. Global
tor. They discussed a paper authored by features of the field of neuroscience – a mul-
Blanca, a post-doc in a Scandinavian labora- tidisciplinary endeavor that plays out on a
tory, and Bill, that laboratory’s principal status-differentiated pitch where collabora-
investigator (PI) and a former student in the tions are fundamental to claims-making and
H-Lab. In this interaction the categorical evaluation – are apparent in the local interac-
implications of Blanca’s discipline (she is a tions of skilled scientists. Convincing one
chemist) and of her collaborative relationship another of the validity (or lack thereof) of
with Bill loomed large, as does Bill’s relative particular claims required both careful
status in the field and the legacy of his time in rhetorical effort and the ability to draw the
the H-lab. broader field and its conversations into spe-
cific performances.
Beth: You might also want to ask her about
her method. Before she came here she
worked on really small beetles. That is a
really difficult animal. She is an expert PERFORMANCES CAN CHANGE
with these methods and she has techniques FIELDS
that we do not. Also, she is really good
with chemistry. She has a really strong Observations in the H-lab clarify some of the
background, stronger than anyone here. So ways that categories and relationships get
the answer to your implication that she imported into local performances. We also
hasn’t thought through her controls is that suggest there are (perhaps fewer) instances
she probably has! where situated action can shift the categori-
Jim: There’s no question about the chem- cal and relational features of fields. We offer
istry, but she is working in Bill’s lab and a pair of examples drawn from Owen-
we know that Bill is a little too flamboyant Smith’s field work in a high-profile univer-
with his methods. sity technology licensing office (TLO)
(Owen-Smith, 2005, 2007)6.
This snippet of conversation is part of a Like the H-lab, the TLO is a university-
larger, collective skeptical performance that affiliated workplace situated in a differenti-
drew on categorically based expectations ated, hierarchical field. Where work in the
(e.g. chemists are good at structuring experi- H-laboratory is focused on scientific
mental controls), ascribed levels of individ- attempts to understand the neuroscience of
ual skill (e.g. working with a difficult model olfaction, the TLO’s goal is to identify,
animal results in better technique), and past manage and market potentially valuable
relationships (e.g. evaluations of Bill’s scien- technologies for ‘society’s use and benefit
tific competency based on his time in the while generating unrestricted income for
H-lab), as well as present ones (e.g. Jim’s research and education.’ The TLO is a
insistence that Blanca’s discipline and skill boundary-spanning administrative unit
be interpreted in light of her senior where work is framed as a service to faculty
co-author). Such performances were disci- researchers and industrial partners. The
plined by logics of action native to the office’s staff comprises individuals who
616 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

typically hold bachelor’s (and in some cases and licensing the invention.7 Marketing plans
master’s) degrees in technical fields. typically begin by ‘shopping’ an invention to
Because this office spans the boundary potential licensees. Classifying a technology
between academe and industry, its work can in terms of existing markets and products
be understood in light of multiple logics. In triggers licensing officers’ efforts to search
most instances, licensing associates can draw their ‘mental rolodexes’ for appropriate
on one or more ‘appropriate’ logics as they partners. Prior licensing relationships are
make decisions. Because the office opts not highly salient to that process.
to employ legal counsel, the staff has few Collective licensing discussions in the TLO
normatively ‘correct’ approaches to prob- typically address difficult cases. More
lems encoded in their training. These features straightforward deals are the province of indi-
and the prestige of this office make the TLO vidual staff members. The most common form
a fertile site for local action that can reshape of difficulty arises as a result of the conflicting
broader arrangements. logics under which university technology
The TLO is one of the oldest and most transfer operations function. Recall the TLO’s
accomplished offices of its kind. As a result mission, which combines a focus on income
the office, its staff, and (especially) its direc- generation from licensing and efforts to
tor, occupy prominent positions in the rela- ensure broad public access to technologies
tively new field of university technology that are often developed with federal R&D
transfer. Unlike academic life science, the funds. This mission puts the TLO and other
professional field of university technology offices like it squarely at the intersection of
transfer is still developing. Where skeptical business logics that emphasize revenues and
evaluations in the H-lab draw explicitly on academic logics that emphasize open access
the broader landscape of scientific norms, and the public good. That tension is palpable
similar collective performances in the TLO in discussions about whether federally funded,
are overwhelmingly local and only rarely university-developed technologies should be
reach beyond the university (Owen-Smith, licensed exclusively or non-exclusively. The
2007). The TLO’s highly visible position in former can be particularly lucrative (espe-
the field, combined with its enviable record cially if equity ownership in a start-up com-
of success, results in its being widely emu- pany is a condition of the deal), but comes at
lated. Thus, the outcomes of actions taken in the expense of access. While they sometimes
the confines of the office often get trans- generate extensive revenues, non-exclusive
ferred out into the broader arena where they licenses often forgo a high financial upside to
alter the shape of relationships and help to keep a new technology accessible.
create or modify emerging categories of pro- The technologies with the greatest poten-
fessional action. tial value often have the broadest appeal. As
Much of the daily work of the TLO is a result, university technology managers
informed by routine meetings characterized routinely find themselves adjudicating
by improvisational efforts to make sense of, between more academic and more commer-
evaluate, and respond to scientific findings cial approaches to their deals. In the TLO,
couched as ‘invention disclosures.’ In the this dilemma is commonly solved by writing
TLO, those evaluations take the form of ‘field-of-use’ (FOU) deals that grant
efforts to determine what kind of technologi- exclusive rights to different aspects or uses of
cal innovation is embedded in a scientific a technology to disparate licensees. As the
discovery and what sort of market that inno- TLO’s director noted in an interview (Owen-
vation might reach. Both of these decisions Smith, 2005: 83):
are acts of classification, and once they are
made, TLO staff members (singly and, often, Almost everything we do is field-of-use. The posi-
collectively) develop a plan for marketing tive side of that is that you can get more than one
NETWORKS AND INSTITUTIONS 617

license in different fields. But there is also a nega- therapy is difficult to distinguish. As a result,
tive side. If there is a problem with a patent, or a efforts to partition this technology to allow
relationship, then you have compounded your
for exclusive licensing to a pharmaceutical or
difficulties if you have licensed it to multiple
entities. biotechnology company, and non-exclusive
licensing to manufacturers of laundry deter-
This brief description of a common response gents may be imperfect. Problems that result
to one of the TLO’s primary institutional from trying to forge this separation may have
contradictions implies both the local chal- the unintended effect of creating relation-
lenges and the global effects of widespread ships across industrial categories that other-
reliance on this strategy. First, locally, TLO wise might remain unconnected.
associates who are often ill-prepared to deal Local evaluations of scientific findings in
with highly technical inventions must the H-lab draw broader categorical and rela-
partition early-stage technologies into multi- tional characteristics into situated perform-
ple fields of use that can be separately and ances. In contrast, similar efforts in the TLO
independently licensed. Such efforts at dis- have some potential to alter the relationships
tinction are often imperfect, and raise subse- and categories of the larger field. Clearly,
quent problems. More globally, when efforts in the H-lab could also remake its
FOU licenses convey rights to the same tech- field by, for instance, making fundamentally
nology to licensees in widely disparate novel discoveries about the neuroscience of
industries, one effect is to make the TLO olfaction. We do not wish to argue perform-
(and the university that houses it) a network ances on some stages can only draw upon their
‘short-cut’ between firms that might other- larger contexts while others can alter them.
wise share no (or at least few) connections or Instead, we wish to suggest that a network-
affiliations. institutional theory sensitive to genesis and,
In other words, local decisions in the TLO particularly, change should have some way to
can yield changes in the relationships and cat- account for when and why local action shifts
egories of larger fields by bridging otherwise larger fields. We believe that attending to the
separate licensees. To the extent that existing stability of a field and to the relative
imperfect efforts to define fields of use are positions of actors within them offers some
likely to create later problems, FOU deals useful starting points. It matters, for instance,
may be more likely to deeply entangle differ- that the H-lab is an important but not domi-
ent licensees. Consider the example of nant player on a large and established field
an invention disclosed by a prominent while the TLO is (arguably) one of the
biochemist. The technology – a compound dominant players on a relatively young and
that interrupts the metabolic processes growing field.
of a particular bacterium and kills it – has
multiple uses.
The bacterium in question produces a
sticky plaque that, if found in veins, has been CONCLUSION AND FUTURE
implicated in heart attacks. If the bacterium DIRECTIONS
inhabits a washing machine, however, the
plaque results in smelly clothes. The We argue that understanding the characteris-
compound, then, can be understood as a tics and effects of social and economic
component in laundry detergent or as a phar- systems requires simultaneous attention to
maceutical aimed at the cardiovascular the categorical and relational features of
market. Both are potentially profitable uses fields. Institutions and networks are inter-
but, technically speaking, it is difficult twined in canonical theoretical and empirical
to define separable fields of use because works in sociology and organizational
the mode of action of the detergent and the theory. Perhaps more importantly, master
618 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

concepts in institutional and network and institutions will be particularly apparent


theory – fields, logics, embeddedness, and (and important) in situations where roles and
social capital – are shot through with both identities are ambiguous, logics and institu-
institutional and relational terminology. tions are conflicting or multiple, and net-
Throughout our discussion, we return to the works span diverse audiences.
dual relationship between social relation- We revisited some of our empirical work
ships and social categories that we take to be on biotechnology, scientific collaboration
at the heart of a unified, ‘network-institu- and university technology transfer to exam-
tional’ approach to social and economic life. ine a few specific implications of our
Networks are essential to fields because approach. Our discussion highlights four
they are both the pipes through which issues where we believe further research can
resources circulate and the prisms that forward a network-institutional theory. We
observers use to make sense of action. Fields, summarize those analytic questions and then
though, are associated with particular logics suggest some concrete methodological
of action and it is those logics that make net- implications for future studies of networks
works efficacious by determining which and institutions.
sorts of relationships participants can con- First, we contend that studies of evolution
ceive. More tellingly, the dominant logics in and change in social systems must take
a field define which sorts of connections will into account the recursive nature of networks
have what types of effects for different kinds and institutions. Explaining the contempo-
of partners. In this sense, the relational and rary character of biotechnology requires
structural embeddedness of economic action attention to the field’s history and to the par-
depends not just on networks but also on the ticular tensions that regulatory regimes and
orientations of participants to the fields and market competition create. More impor-
logics that render ties sensible and help tantly, we suggest, such an explanation
determine the shape and effects of structures. requires that we attend to the process by
Social ties and affiliations are not all of a which collaborative relationships and
piece. Similar activities and structures may network structures alike come to have the
have different implications depending on the implications and effects they do because of
institutional character of participants. Even their institutional context. As a result, we
the most purely structural definition of, for argue that studies of social dynamics must
instance, social capital must take institutional integrate network and institutional concepts
context into account. Institutions and net- and constructs.
works jointly determine when various sorts Networks must be understood in the
of capital can be invested, by whom, and context of institutional arrangements and
with what expectations of returns. their institutional embeddedness shapes
We argue that networks and institutions categories and products. Our examination
are co-constitutive. They set the conditions of innovation in the San Francisco Bay
of possibility for each other. At base, we take Area and Boston biotechnology regions
this co-evolutionary relationship to rest on a reinforces the important role network
key duality between relationships (the build- connections play in explaining outcomes.
ing blocks of networks) and categories (the We add to that a recognition that the institu-
building blocks of institutions). The situated tional characteristics of a network alter
and often improvised performances of highly both the character of what participants
bounded, but nonetheless purposive, organi- produce and the process of production. The
zational and individual agents breathes life features and evolution of social systems, as
into this duality, and, over time, provides a well as their substantive outcomes, are
motor for evolution and change. We expect shaped by the joint pressures of networks and
the link between practical action, networks, institutions.
NETWORKS AND INSTITUTIONS 619

Both of these arguments rest on a belief which particular practices and innovations
that participants’ strategies and rationalities diffuse or fail by making rules and practices
are shaped by their network-institutional themselves the unit of analysis.
context. We suggest that macro-organiza- Finally, our sketch of a network-institu-
tional efforts should attend more closely to tional approach to social organization carries
behavior. Whether that attention focuses on methodological implications. We note that
the practical and situated performances of studies at multiple levels of analysis – ranging
individuals or on re-integrating a behavioral from practices, to activities, organizations,
theory of organizations into network and dyads, collectives, structures, and fields – are
institutional analyses depends primarily on necessary. More importantly, temporality and
levels of analysis and topics. We shift focus dynamics are at the center of our analyses.
from the dynamics of industry-wide net- Seeing the interplay of networks and institu-
works to situated action in bounded organi- tions, we contend, requires more than cross-
zational settings to emphasize the links sectional explanations of variation. Instead,
between activities on the ground and broader efforts to track change in the categorical and
categorical and relational constraints. relational features of social worlds over time
We argued that attention should be paid to are needed. Finally, we include a call for
seeing fields in performances. Individuals comparison. Each of the studies we discuss
and organizations act in contexts structured attends either to locally fluid behaviors or to
by relationships, categories, and hierarchies. change over time in a single field. Variations
But such contexts cannot completely deter- in networks and institutions, which can all too
mine action and sources of constraint can easily be treated as ubiquitous and invariant
offer unexpected opportunities to players characteristics of social realms, may be more
whose positions and characteristics offer apparent when we adopt a lens that empha-
them room to maneuver. If, as we contend, sizes comparative dynamics.
networks and institutions are yoked together
by situated action, then studies of local
action must take relevant relationships,
categories, and logics into account. NOTES
We do not wish to suggest, however, that
1 Obviously, there are several notable exceptions,
the flow of influence is uni-directional. For
where more explicit conceptual connections are
networks and institutions to be recursively offered. See Mizruchi, Stearns and Marquis, 2006;
related through action, the endeavors of par- Strang and Meyer, 1994; Zuckerman, 1999;
ticipants must have some possibility of influ- Zuckerman, Kim, Unkawa, and von Rittman, 2003;
encing their larger social environment. More Powell, White, Koput, and Owen-Smith, 2005.
2 In this regard, see the chapters on the
effort should be put to uncovering the situa-
micro-level roots of institutional theory in this
tions and conditions under which local per- volume (Powell & Colyvas, Chapter 10 and Barley,
formances shift the structural and institutional Chapter 20), as well as Barley and Tolbert (1997);
features of fields. Because the macro-social Hallett and Ventresca (2006).
world is obdurate, action in some locales 3 In order to maintain confidentiality we refer to
the H-Lab and its occupants using pseudonyms.
must be more likely to effect change than
4 In this regard, see also Callon (1986) and
efforts in others. More attention should be Latour (1987) whose formulations of actor-network
paid, then, to the relational and categorical theory emphasize the differential abilities of individu-
sources of innovation in fields. Even within als to enroll disparate allies and maintain the
locations that are situated to effect shifts in stability of diverse constellations of relationships. This
their wider contexts, not all actions or partic- sense of skill was also at play in the H-lab where sci-
entists whose ‘golden hands’ routinely yielded partic-
ipants are equally likely to have a broader ularly compelling experimental data were accorded
influence. As a result, we suggest that more greater deference than their less dexterous col-
studies should focus on the conditions under leagues.
620 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

5 The first author is usually a junior scientist and Belief: A New Sociology of Knowledge.
responsible for the bulk of the ‘bench’ work that sup- London: Routledge & Kegan Paul
ports a particular claim. The last author is typically a Clemens, Elisabeth. 1993. ‘Organizational
senior scientist who ‘owns’ the lab in which the work
repertoires and institutional change:
occurred and may have played a significant role in
Women’s groups and the transformation of
designing experiments and framing questions. Other
authors are typically arrayed alphabetically or in a American politics, 1890–1920.’ American
fashion that places the least important participant Journal of Sociology, 98(4): 755–98.
nearest the center of a long list. While they are rarely Clemens, Elisabeth. 1997. The People’s Lobby:
explicitly articulated, such authorship rules represent Organizational Innovation and The Rise of
another characteristic logic that lets participants eval- Interest Group Politics in the United States,
uate claims and scientists by attending to researchers’ 1890–1925.
relative positions in author-lists and to the strength of Cohen, M. D., March, J. G., and Olsen, J. P. 1972.
a finding’s association with high-profile scientists. ‘A garbage can model of organizational
6 All names are pseudonyms.
choice.’ Administrative Science Quarterly,
7 A license is a deal that transfers the right to use
17(1): 1–25.
an invention or material that is protected by some
form of intellectual property from the property’s Coleman, James S. 1988. ‘Social capital in the
owner (in the case a university) to a licensee (most creation of human capital.’ American Journal
often a firm) that hopes to develop it. Licenses can of Sociology Supplement, 94: S95–S120.
convey exclusive rights, non-exclusive rights, or some Colyvas, Jeannette A. 2007. ‘From divergent
limited form of exclusivity. meanings to common practices: The early
institutionalization of technology transfer in
the life sciences at Stanford University.’
Research Policy, 36(5): 456–77.
Dalton, Melville. 1959. Men Who Manage.
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS New York: John Wiley and Sons.
Davis, Gerald F. and Henrich R. Greve. 1997.
We are grateful to Royston Greenwood for ‘Corporate elite networks and governance
comments on an earlier draft. changes in the 1980s.’ American Journal of
Sociology, 103(1): 1–37.
Davis, Gerald F., Kristina Diekmann, and
Catherine H. Tinsley. 1994. ‘The decline and
REFERENCES fall of the conglomerate firm in the 1980s:
The deinstitutionalization of an organiza-
Barley, Stephen R. and Pamela S. Tolbert. tional form.’ American Sociological Review,
1997. ‘Institutionalization and structura- 59(4): 547–70.
tion: Studying the links between action and Dezalay, Yves and Bryant G. Garth. 1996.
institutions.’ Organization Studies, 18: Dealing in Virtue: International Commercial
93–117. Arbitration and the Construction of a
Bourdieu, Pierre. 1985. ‘The social space and Transnational Legal Order. Chicago: University
the genesis of groups.’ Theory and Society, of Chicago Press.
14(6): 723–44. DiMaggio, Paul J. 1991. ‘Constructing an organi-
Bourdieu, Pierre, and Loïc J. D. Wacquant. zational field as a professional project:
1992. An Invitation to Reflexive Sociology. U.S. art museums, 1920–40.’ Pp. 267–92 in
Chicago: University of Chicago Press. W. Powell and P.J. DiMaggio (eds.), The
Breiger, Ron L. 1974. ‘The duality of persons New Institutionalism in Organizational
and groups.’ Social Forces, 53: 181–90. Analysis, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Burt, Ronald S. 2005. Brokerage and Closure: DiMaggio, Paul J. and Walter W. Powell. 1983.
An Introduction to Social Capital. New York: ‘The iron cage revisited: Institutional isomor-
Oxford University Press. phism and collective rationality in organiza-
Callon, Michel. 1986. ‘Some elements of a soci- tional fields.’ American Sociological Review,
ology of translation: domestication of the 48(2): 147–60
scallops and the fishermen of St Brieuc Bay.’ Dobbin, Frank and Timothy J. Dowd. 2000. The
Pp. 196–233 in John Law (ed.), Power, Action market that antitrust built: Public policy,
NETWORKS AND INSTITUTIONS 621

private coercion and railroad acquisition.’ Jepperson, Ronald L. 1991 ‘Institutions,


American Sociological Review, 65: 631–647. institutional effects, and institutionalism.’
Ferguson, Priscilla Parkhurst. 1998. ‘A cultural Pp. 143–63 in W.W. Powell and P.J. DiMaggio
field in the making: gastronomy in 19th cen- (eds.), The New Institutionalism in
tury France.’ American Journal of Sociology, Organizational Analysis. Chicago: University
104(3): 597–641. of Chicago Press.
Fleming, Lee and Olav Sorenson. 2001. Krippner, Greta. 2001. ‘The elusive market:
‘Technology as a complex adaptive system: Embeddedness and the paradigm of economic
Evidence from patent data.’ Research Policy, sociology.’ Theory and Society, 30(6): 775–810.
30(7): 1019–39. Latour, Bruno. 1987. Science in Action: How to
Fligstein, Neil. 2001. ‘Social skill and the theory Follow Science and Engineers Through Society.
of fields.’ Sociological Theory, 19(2): 105–125. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Fourcade, Marion. 2007. ‘Theories of market, Latour, Bruno and Steve Woolgar. 1976.
theories of society.’ American Behavioral Laboratory Life: The Construction of Scientific
Scientist, 50(8): 1015–34. Facts. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Friedland, Roger, and Robert R. Alford. Laumann, Edward O., Joseph Galaskiewicz,
1991. ‘Bringing society back in: Symbols, and Peter V. Marsden. 1978. ‘Community
practices, and institutional contradictions.’ structure as interorganizational linkages.’
Pp. 232–63 in Walter W. Powell and Paul J. Annual Review of Sociology, 4: 455–84.
DiMaggio (eds.), The New Institutionalism in Lie, John. 1997. ‘Sociology of markets.’ Annual
Organizational Analysis. Chicago: University Review of Sociology, 23: 341–60.
of Chicago Press. Lin, Nan. 2001. Social Capital: A Theory of
Galaskiewicz, Joseph and Ronald S. Burt. 1991. Social Structure and Action. New York:
‘Interorganization contagion in corporate Cambridge University Press.
philanthropy.’ Administrative Science Macaulay, Stewart. 1963. ‘Non-contractual
Quarterly, 36(1): 88–105. relations in business.’ American Sociological
Gambardella, Alfonso. 1995. Science and Review, 28(1): 55–67.
Innovation: The U.S. Pharmaceutical Industry March, James G. and Johan P. Olsen. 1984.
During the 1980s. Cambridge, UK: Rediscovering Institutions. New York: The
Cambridge University Press. Free Press.
Gouldner, Alvin. 1954. Patterns of Industrial Merton, Robert K. 1968. ‘The Matthew effect
Bureaucracy. New York: Free Press. in science.’ Science, 159: 56–9.
Granovetter, M. 1985. ‘Economic action and Meyer, John W., and Brian Rowan. 1977.
social structure: The problem of embedded- ‘Institutionalized organizations: Formal struc-
ness.’ American Journal of Sociology, 91(3): ture as myth and ceremony.’ American
481–510. Journal of Sociology, 83(2): 340–63.
Hallett, Timothy and Marc Ventresca. 2006. Mizruchi, Mark S. and L.C. Fein. 1999.
‘Inhabited institutionalism: Social interac- ‘Coercive, normative, and mimetic isomor-
tions and organizational forms in Gouldners’ phism: A study of the social construction of
patterns of industrial bureaucracy.’ Theory sociological knowledge.’ Administrative
and Society, 35(2): 213–36. Science Quarterly, 44(4): 29–56.
Henderson, Rebecca, Luigi Orsenigo, and Gary Mizruchi, Mark S., Linda B. Stearns and
P. Pisano. 1999. ‘The pharmaceutical indus- Christopher Marquis. 2006. The conditional
try and the revolution in molecular biology: nature of embeddedness: A study of borrow-
Interactions among scientific, institutional, ing by large U.S. firms. American
and organizational change.’ In D.C. Mowery Sociological Review, 71(2): 310–33.
and R. R. Nelson (eds.), Sources of Industrial Mohr, John. 1998. ‘Measuring meaning struc-
Leadership: Studies of Seven Industries. tures.’ Annual Review of Sociology, 24:
Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. 345–70.
Hoffman, Andrew J. 2001. From Heresy to Owen-Smith, Jason. 2001. ‘Managing laboratory
Dogma: An Institutional History of Corporate work through skepticism: Processes of evalua-
Environmentalism. Stanford, CA: Stanford tion and control.’ American Sociological
University Press. Review, 66(3): 427–52.
622 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Owen-Smith, Jason. 2005. ‘Dockets, deals, Portes, Alejandro. 1998. ‘Social capital: Its ori-
and sagas: Commensuration and the gins and application in modern sociology.’
rationalization of experience in university Annual Review of Sociology, 24: 1–24.
licensing.’ Social Studies of Science, 35(1): Powell, Walter W. 1996. ‘Inter-organizational
69–97. collaboration in the biotechnology industry.’
Owen-Smith, Jason. 2007. ‘Where does profes- Journal of Institutional and Theoretical
sional knowledge come from? Licensing talk, Economics, 120(1): 197–215.
problem resolution, and rationalization in Powell, Walter W. and Peter Brantley.
university licensing.’ Working paper, 1992.’Competitive cooperation in biotech-
University of Michigan. nology: Learning through networks.’
Owen-Smith, Jason and Walter W. Powell. Pp. 366–294 in R. Eccles and N. Nohria (eds.),
2004. ‘Knowledge networks as channels Networks and Organizations. Boston, MA:
and conduits: The effects of spillovers in Harvard University Press.
the Boston biotechnology community.’ Powell, Walter W. and Peter Brantley. 1996.
Organization Science, 15(1): 5–21. ‘Magic bullets and patent wars: New prod-
Owen-Smith, Jason and Walter W. Powell. uct development and the evolution of the
2006. ‘Accounting for emergence and biotechnology industry,’ pp. 233–60 in
novelty in Boston and Bay area biotechnol- Toshihiro Nishiguchi (ed.), Competitive
ogy.’ In P. Braunerhjelm and M. Feldman Product Development, Oxford: Oxford
(eds.), Cluster Genesis: The Emergence University Press.
of Technology Clusters and their Implications Powell, Walter W., Jason Owen-Smith, and
for Government Policy. Cambridge, UK: Jeannette Colyvas. 2007. ‘Innovation and
Cambridge University Press. emulation: Lessons from American universities
Owen-Smith, Jason, Massimo Riccaboni, Fabio in selling private rights to public knowledge’
Pammolli, and Walter W. Powell. 2002. Minerva, 45(2): 121–42.
‘A comparison of U.S. and European Powell, Walter W., K.W. Koput, J.I. Bowie, and
university–industry relations in the life sci- L. Smith-Doerr. 2002. ‘The spatial clustering
ences.’ Management Science, 48(1): 24–43. of science and capital: Accounting for
Padgett, John F. and Christopher K. Ansell. biotech firm–venture capital relationships.’
1993. ‘Robust action and the rise of the Regional Studies, 36(3): 291–306.
Medici, 1400–1434.’ American Journal of Powell, Walter W., Kenneth Koput, and Laurel
Sociology, 98(6): 1259–319. Smith-Doerr. 1996. Interorganizational col-
Palmer, Donald, P. Devereaux Jennings and laboration and the locus of innovation:
Zueguang Zhou. 1993. ‘Politics and institu- Networks of learning in biotechnology.
tional change: Late adoption of the multidi- Administrative Science Quarterly, 41(1):
visional form by large U.S. corporations.’ 116–45.
Administrative Sciences Quarterly, 38(1): Powell, Walter W., Doug White, Ken Koput,
100–31. and Jason Owen-Smith. 2005. ‘Network
Podolny, Joel M. 2001. ‘Networks as the pipes dynamics and field evolution: The growth of
and prisms of the market.’ American Journal inter-organizational collaboration in the life
of Sociology, 107(1): 33–60. sciences.’ American Journal of Sociology,
Polanyi, Karl. 1957. ‘The economy as an insti- 110(4): 1132–205.
tuted process.’ Pp. 243–70 in K. Polanyi, Putnam, Robert. 2000. Bowling Alone: The
C. Arensberg, and H. Pearson (eds.), Trade Collapse and Revival of American Community.
and Market in the Early Empires: Economies New York: Simon and Schuster.
in History and Theory. Chicago: Free Press. Rao, Hayagreeva, Phillipe Monin, and Rudolphe
Porter, Kelley, Kjersten Bunker Whittington, Durand. 2003. ‘Institutional change in Toque
and Walter W. Powell. 2005. ‘The institu- Ville: Nouvelle cuisine as identity movement
tional embeddedness of high-tech regions: in French gastronomy.’ American Journal of
Relational foundations of the Boston Sociology, 108(4): 795–843.
biotechnology community.’ Pp. 261–96 in Scott, W. Richard, Martin Reuf, Peter J. Mendel,
Stefano Breschi and Franco Malerba (eds.), and Carol Caronna. 2000. Institutional
Clusters, Networks, and Innovation. Oxford: Change and Health Care Organizations.
Oxford University Press. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
NETWORKS AND INSTITUTIONS 623

Strang, David and John W. Meyer. 1994. White, Harrison, Scott Boorman, and Ronald
‘Institutional conditions for diffusion.’ Breiger. 1976. ‘Social structure from multiple
Pp. 100–12 in W.R. Scott and J.W. Meyer networks I: Blockmodels of roles and positions.’
(eds.), Institutional Environments and American Journal of Sociology, 81(4): 730–80.
Organizations: Structural Complexity and Whitley, Richard. (ed.). 1992. ‘Societies, firms
Individualism. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage. and markets: the Social structuring of busi-
Stinchcombe, Arthur C. 1965. ‘Social structure ness systems’. Pp. 5–45 in European Business
and organzation.’ Pp. 142–93 in James G. Systems. London: Sage.
March (ed.), Handbook of Organizations. Zuckerman, Ezra. 1999. ‘The categorical imper-
Chicago: Rand McNally & Co. ative: Securities analysts and the illegitimacy
Thornton, Patricia. 2004. Markets from Culture: discount.’ American Journal of Sociology,
Institutional Logics and Organizational 104(5): 1398–438.
Decisions in Higher Education Publishing. Zuckerman, Ezra W., Tai Y. Kim, Kalinda Unkawa,
Stanford: Stanford University Press. and James Von Rittman. 2003. ‘Robust iden-
Varmus, Harold E. and Robert A. Weinberg. tities or non-entities? Typecasting in the fea-
1992. Genes and the Biology of Cancer. New ture film labor market.’ American Journal of
York: Scientific American Press. Sociology, 108(5): 1018–74.
26
Institutional-Level Learning:
Learning as a Source of
Institutional Change
Pamela Haunschild and David Chandler

INTRODUCTION It is not clear, however, that this


dichotomy of economic (early) versus insti-
Institutional theory tells us that as a new idea tutional (late) actors provides a sufficiently
or business practice diffuses through a popu- comprehensive spectrum of adoption behav-
lation, some firms adopt it early on for effi- iors by firms. Consider the example of Wal-
ciency reasons (they have considered the Mart, which has started to adopt social
merits of the idea and believe it to be benefi- responsibility practices, particularly in rela-
cial to their business), while others resist tion to environmental sustainability1 (includ-
until later in the diffusion curve (they are ing the launch of its ‘Sustainability 360’ plan
either not aware of the idea or do not feel it is in February, 2007),2 and is recognized as
applicable or advantageous to their situa- being relatively progressive in this respect by
tion). When these later adopters do finally a broad section of the media.3 An institu-
succumb, they do so out of social pressures tional theorist might argue that this adoption
to conform and believe that the primary ben- behavior (which is occuring later, in the dif-
efit for adopting is the legitimacy gained by fusion cycle) happened because the idea of
acceding to societal norms (Galaskiewicz, environmental sustainability (going green)
1985; Parsons, 1956; Suchman, 1995). had diffused throughout society to such an
For these later adopting firms, institu- extent, and the firm was facing so much crit-
tional theory tells us that the prospective effi- icism for its failure to adopt previously, that
ciency benefits of the idea in question are it adopted in search of social legitimacy
not a concern – they have either not been (DiMaggio & Powell, 1983; Meyer &
considered, or are believed to be too slight Rowan, 1977). This pattern of behavior, how-
to be of significant value to the firm ever, would be out of character for a firm that
(Westphal, Gulati, & Shortell, 1997; Zajac & focuses so strongly on minimizing operating
Westphal, 2004). costs and passing those cost savings on to
INSTITUTIONAL-LEVEL LEARNING: LEARNING AS A SOURCE OF INSTITUTIONAL CHANGE 625

customers in the form of ‘Always Low This expanded perspective still recognizes
Prices,’4 and that has resisted conforming to the institutional pressures to adopt that Wal-
pressure on several previous occasions.5 Mart faces (like all firms, Wal-Mart is suscep-
An alternative explanation of Wal-Mart’s tible to the increased prevalence of calls for
decision to make a large-scale move into the greater social responsibility and was likely
green area is that it is learning from the expe- disturbed by the criticism it was facing in this
rience of other firms who have already gone respect), but it also provides an additional
green, and is adapting its own behavior explanation of observed behavior that is more
accordingly. Once the diffusion of an idea has consistent with the firm and its corporate
progressed beyond its initial stages, a track strategy. The concept of inferential learning8
record of success and failure of firms that pre- (Miner & Haunschild, 1995), placed in this
viously adopted similar policies is established, context, implies that firms facing strong
and firms pressured to adopt at later stages are institutional pressures are not stuck with
sometimes able to cherry-pick the most appro- adopting unprofitable practices – they have
priate (and potentially profitable) policies that the potential to learn from the successes and
suit their situation and needs, while still con- failures of earlier adopters to maximize the
forming to institutional norms that dictate efficiency benefits they receive from adopt-
some form of response. We suggest that this is ing later in the diffusion curve. Wal-Mart is
a possible driver of the decision to adopt an responding to institutional pressures, but is
idea or business practice by firms later in the doing so in a way that provides anticipated
diffusion curve that is not theoretically inte- economic benefit.
grated within the institutional literature. Thus, This complicated, cause-effect process of
institutional theory would currently say that change concerning firm adoption behavior
Wal-Mart is simply responding to societal blends two large bodies of work in organiza-
pressure and legitimacy threats. Yet Wal-Mart tion theory – institutional theory and
could instead (or also) be learning from the the organizational/interorganizational learn-
experiences of prior adopter firms and adopt- ing theories. On the one hand, institutional
ing these policies later in the diffusion theorists recognize that firms are susceptible
process, at least partially, for anticipated effi- to coercive, normative, and mimetic isomor-
ciency benefits. For example, Wal-Mart’s phic forces (DiMaggio & Powell, 1983;
decision to start selling organic foods might Scott, 2001) and that such social pressures to
have been stimulated by the success of Whole conform are powerful predictors of firm
Foods and other organic retailers. At the same behavior – usually seen as independent of, or
time, however, Wal-Mart is showing consis- even in opposition to, economic benefit. On
tency with the institutional environment the other hand, however, a learning perspec-
(going green) with statements about how the tive provides an explanation of firm behavior
firm wants to ‘democratize organic food, that allows for firms to respond to social
making products affordable for those who are pressures in ways that are economically ben-
reluctant to pay premiums of 20 percent to eficial. We contend that it is only when this
30 percent.’6 The dual institutional/efficiency learning perspective is added to the institu-
rationales inherent in Wal-Mart’s activities are tional perspective that a more complex,
also reflected in statements by one senior level holistic change process that spans the com-
executive who admitted that he was initially plete range of potential firm behavior in the
unenthused about going green, because he face of institutional forces can be appreci-
thought such a move was all about ‘saving the ated. Our understanding of the various
whales and the trees.’7 He became more conflicting interests, motivations, and learn-
enthusiastic when he realized that these prac- ing processes that interact to instigate change
tices could increase Wal-Mart’s efficiency is enhanced by this blend of learning and
through lower costs. institutional theories.
626 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

To some extent, the thesis we present learning as firms adapt to their evolving
in this chapter builds on existing research sociocultural environment can contribute sig-
within institutional theory and concepts nificantly to institutional theory in explaining
already embedded in learning theories, institutional change (Dacin, Goodstein, &
such as the concept of mimetic learning – Scott, 2002). Yet, in spite of these potential
consciously or unconsciously learning from benefits, the intersection of these two theo-
the routines, actions, and outcomes of others ries has received scant attention from schol-
(Miner & Mezias, 1996). Mimetic learning is ars to date. An attempt to identify where
quite similar to the concept of mimetic iso- these two literatures overlap, so that knowl-
morphism (DiMaggio & Powell, 1983) and edge is shared and replication is avoided
both concepts are usually measured as the (wherever possible), constitutes, we hope, a
prevalence of adoption by other firms in a constructive addition to the institutional
given field (e.g., Greve, 1998; Haunschild theory literature.
& Miner, 1997). In other ways, however, we We start with a definition of the process
draw on unique work within the learning the- that constitutes the focus of this chapter, a
ories in areas that institutional theory has yet process we call Institutional-Level Learning.
to explore fully, such as the process of infer- Institutional-level learning occurs when
ential learning (Miner & Haunschild, 1995) institutions9 change due to some learning
and the emergence of unintended conse- experience. Such change might result from
quences from everyday routine actions three possible sources: (1) an institution
(March, 1981). might evolve deliberately over time, adapting
Applied examples of the benefits of inte- to field-level changes in experience affecting
grating these two theories exist all around us. values, beliefs, and attitudes; (2) an institu-
As with the Wal-Mart example outlined tion might be affected by a specific agent
above, it is relatively easy to think of cases of change (an institutional entrepreneur) that
where both theories collectively provide a learned from its own experience or the
more effective explanation of the antecedent experiences of others and initiated change; or
conditions, processes, or outcomes of organi- (3) an institution might undergo unin-
zational action. It is to be expected that these tended change as the result of boundedly
two theories interface across multiple aspects rational action, imperfect imitation, or ordi-
of organizations’ day-to-day activities. After nary routines that led to unintended
all, institutional theory is primarily an outcomes.
attempt to locate the organization within its In terms of the structure of this chapter, we
social and cultural context and analyze the begin by discussing definitions of organiza-
extent to which social institutions (rules, rit- tional learning and identifying how they
uals, routines, beliefs, and so on) shape relate to institutional change. We then provide
organizations as they pursue the legitimacy a brief overview of how institutional theory
necessary to ensure success and survival over has begun to incorporate the concepts of orga-
the long term (DiMaggio & Powell, 1983; nizational agency and address the notion of
Meyer & Rowan, 1977; Suchman, 1995), active change. Shedding further light on the
while learning theories seek to explain the relatively unexplored area of overlap
shaping of organizations through the interac- between the two bodies of work, we then
tion and influence of various social and consider how organizational learning theo-
cultural forces (Huber, 1991; Levitt & ries can inform institutional theory by high-
March, 1988). lighting a number of important mechanisms
It is our contention, therefore, that under- by which institutional evolution and change
standing the processes and consequences occur, but which the institutional literature
of organizational and interorganizational has yet to incorporate. These mechanisms
INSTITUTIONAL-LEVEL LEARNING: LEARNING AS A SOURCE OF INSTITUTIONAL CHANGE 627

include the following: institutional change information distribution; information inter-


resulting from the unintended outcomes of pretation; and organizational memory, defin-
everyday action; interfirm and inter-popula- ing learning in its broadest sense:
tion learning processes that flow along geo-
learning need not be conscious or intentional ....
graphic and network lines; change produced Further, learning does not always increase the
through imperfect mimesis; change produced learner’s effectiveness, or even potential effective-
by field-level underperformance and slow ness. ... Entities can incorrectly learn, and they
adaptation processes; institutional change can correctly learn that which is incorrect. Finally,
resulting from unlearning caused by factors learning need not result in observable changes in
behavior. ... An entity learns if, through its process-
like field-level personnel turnover; efficiency- ing of information, the range of its potential
based change due to inferential learning from behaviors is changed. [Emphasis in original.]
earlier adopters; and institutional change
driven by heterogeneity in regulation, firm Another classic definition of learning
responses to regulation, and competition comes from Levitt and March (1988: 320),
based on novelty or extreme values. who note that organizations are ‘seen as
We believe that these mechanisms provide learning by encoding inferences from history
a research agenda for future work within into routines that guide behavior.’ The impor-
institutional theory that begins to address tant characteristics of these definitions for us
some of the unanswered questions generated are the following: (1) routines are independ-
at the boundary of these two important ent of individual actors and are history-
organization theories. dependent; but (2) they change based on
interpretations of past experience (interpreta-
tions that are not necessarily coherent); and
(3) they change as new experiences accumu-
ORGANIZATIONAL LEARNING late. Such experiences can be the individual
AND INSTITUTIONAL CHANGE actor’s own experience or the experiences of
others that the actor has observed. Thus,
We begin by discussing definitions of organi- learning and change, whether deliberate or
zational learning, its fundamental assump- unintended, are unavoidably intertwined.
tions, and identifying how learning relates to Much of the empirical work on learning is
institutional change. These definitions and focused on examining the impact of these
assumptions form the foundation upon which various types of experiences on organiza-
we analyze the intersection between institu- tional outcomes, generally in the form of
tional and learning theory. improvements. Early work tended to be
The literature on organizational learning is based on a learning curve perspective
large and does not fit well into any single (Lieberman, 1984), predicting and finding
classification scheme. Several good reviews positive returns to gaining experience
of the literature exist (Argote, 1999; (Dutton, Thomas, & Butler, 1984). Much of
Easterby-Smith, 1997; Fiol & Lyles, 1985; this early work was conducted in manufac-
Hedberg, 1981; Huber, 1991; Levitt & turing settings, but recent work has moved to
March, 1988; Shrivastava, 1983); thus, we more complex empirical contexts like strate-
will not attempt to replicate such work here, gic decisions (Beckman & Haunschild, 2002;
except to indicate the definitions of key terms Hayward, 2002). Empirical research in the
that inform our discussion of organizational learning literature has also moved away from
learning in an institutional context. In terms a focus on the amount of experience to a
of specific definitions, Huber (1991: 89) more comprehensive view of different types
breaks his review of organizational learning of experiences; for example, experiences
into four constructs: knowledge acquisition; gained in heterogeneous as opposed to
628 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

homogeneous settings (Miner, Haunschild, both literatures, however, reflect movement


& Schwab, 2003). There is also a growing toward a meeting of the minds in terms of
body of empirical work on the conditions level of analysis as institutional theory begins
that stimulate learning and change. In this to reassess its focus on the organizational
vein, Cyert and March’s (1963) behavioral field and allow for the prospect of individual
theory of the firm provides the foundation for actor agency (change driven from below),
understanding aspiration levels (both indi- while learning theory begins to account for
vidual and social) as a determinant of change change that occurs at the population level
(Greve, 1998). (change driven from above). This (re-)emer-
A further contribution in understanding gence of a more micro-perspective within
the concept of learning on a more macro institutional theory,11 combined with the
level was made by Miner and Haunschild emergence of a more macro-perspective
(1995), who explicitly moved the definition within the learning theories, has resulted in
of learning to the population (or field) level greater overlap between the two areas and,
of analysis. They achieved this by defining thus, increased the potential for compari-
learning at that level as occurring from son.12 For the purposes of this chapter, there-
changes in population level routines that are fore, we intend to focus on those areas of
based either on the experiences of that popu- organizational learning that have something
lation or of another population whose experi- to say to institutional theory, especially insti-
ences can be observed. This higher-level tutional change, at the field (a.k.a. population,
view of learning makes the concept much interorganizational, community, industry)
more accessible to institutional theorists in level of analysis (Anderson, 1999; Haunschild
terms of definition, level of analysis, and & Miner, 1997; Miner & Anderson, 1999).
accounting for how change occurs at the Levitt and March (1988) theorize about
field-level. learning at this macro-level in their discus-
In two important respects in relation to our sions of vicarious learning among organi-
thesis, however, organizational learning zations and ecologies of learning. Miner
departs from the fundamental assumptions and Haunschild (1995: 118) build on this
that have informed much of the more recent work by defining population-level learning
work within institutional theory – level of as a ‘systematic change in the nature and
analysis and change processes. mix of organizational action routines in a
population of organizations, arising from
experience.’
We contend that reconciling this distinc-
Levels of analysis
tion between levels of analyses in learning
Aside from Miner and Haunschild’s (1995) and institutional theories, while attending to
expansion of the learning literature to con- the growing overlap between the two, is
sider population-level learning, much of the important for advancing both theories, in
work within the learning literature has been general, and for advancing our understanding
conducted at the individual (Simon, 1991), of institutional change, in particular. In addi-
group (Hutchins, 1991), and organizational tion to levels of analysis, another difference
(Cyert & March, 1963) levels of analysis (cf. between the two theories lies in their
Miner & Mezias, 1996). Historically, this has approach towards change.
been problematic in terms of any attempt to
integrate the body of learning literature into
contemporary institutional theory, which is
Processes of change
conceptualized almost exclusively at the
level of the organizational field (DiMaggio & In addition to differences in the key assump-
Powell, 1983: 148).10 Recent developments in tions of institutional and learning theories
INSTITUTIONAL-LEVEL LEARNING: LEARNING AS A SOURCE OF INSTITUTIONAL CHANGE 629

concerning levels of analysis, both theories theory that have expanded its scope to incorpo-
have also differed in their understanding of rate the idea of institutional change, in general,
how change occurs. and individual actor agency as the source of
A key part of the argument against the such change, in particular. In introducing this
ability of organizations to adapt to change broader perspective, contemporary institu-
via learning (Cyert & March, 1963) can be tional theory has moved closer to the learning
found in arguments made in support of pop- view of the world and, in the process, estab-
ulation ecology – that firms are inherently lished itself on a firmer theoretical footing.
inertial and find it difficult to adapt substan-
tially to changes in their environment
(Hannan & Freeman, 1984). As firms survive
longer, their competitive advantage/routines INSTITUTIONAL THEORY
become entrenched and outdated, and any AND CHANGE
innovation that occurs is more likely to be
incremental and travel ‘along existing tech- Institutional theory places socially con-
nological trajectories’ (Sorensen & Stuart, structed beliefs, norms, and rules at the
2000: 83). This inertia results in a focus on center of organizational routines and struc-
the refinement of existing processes and, tures (Berger & Luckmann, 1967; Meyer &
thus, contributes to their institutionalization Rowan, 1977; Scott, 2001; Zucker, 1977). As
by making firms less able to instigate radical outlined by DiMaggio and Powell (1983),
leaps in technology or other major changes in agents for the diffusion and dissemination of
firm strategies, structures, or processes. these cultural beliefs, models, and schema
These assumptions of inertia featured promi- include the state and the professions. Such
nently in early statements of neoinstitutional agents act to influence organizations via
theory where change, if it occurred at all, coercive pressures through government regu-
happened in punctuated leaps (DiMaggio & lations, normative pressures through profes-
Powell, 1983; DiMaggio & Powell, 1991: sional associations, and mimetic actions
9–11), rather than incremental adaptation resulting from cultural-cognitive processes,
(Kraatz & Zajac, 1996; Selznick, 1948, such as taken-for-granted meanings and
1957). The distinction in these positions schema. Over time, these pressures result in
speaks largely to the debate between old and practices that diffuse through a population
new institutional theorists (DiMaggio & and converge around an institutional norm
Powell, 1991; Greenwood & Hinings, 1996; (Baron, Dobbin, & Jennings, 1986;
Hirsch & Lounsbury, 1997; Scott, 1987; Greenwood & Hinings, 1996; Strang &
Selznick, 1996; Stinchcombe, 1997) and is Meyer, 1994). Institutional theorists believe
still contested. In contrast, however, learning that the reason for this convergence is that
theories have consistently assumed that actions by firms that conform to institutional
change occurs in an incremental fashion as expectations help these firms maintain suffi-
actors learn from their own experience or the cient legitimacy to prosper and survive
experience of others and adapt accordingly in the long term (Baum & Oliver, 1992;
(Huber, 1991; March, 1991; March & Olsen, Galaskiewicz, 1985; Parsons, 1956; Pfeffer
1976; Miner & Haunschild, 1995). & Salancik, 1978; Suchman, 1995).
We believe that it is important to appreciate Institutional theorists have found that the
these differences in fundamental assumptions longer an organization waits during the diffu-
regarding change (in addition to reconciling sion process before adopting a business idea
differences in terms of levels of analysis) in or practice, the more likely the reason
any attempt to compare institutional and for eventual adoption is a desire for conform-
learning theories. As such, we now turn to a ity and legitimacy by that firm (Tolbert
review of recent developments in institutional & Zucker, 1983; Westphal et al., 1997),
630 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

irrespective of the efficiency benefits (or between competing institutions (1967: 63,
even harm) that adoption might cause (Davis, 85). In particular, they talk of the conflict that
Diekmann, & Tinsley, 1994; Rao, Greve, & occurs between an individual’s ‘primary’ and
Davis, 2001; Zajac & Westphal, 2004). ‘secondary’ internalization of competing,
Although early iterations of neoinstitu- objective institutions – an integral aspect
tional theory stressed the constraining influ- of socialization. Since Berger and
ence of institutions on individual actors Luckmann, many researchers have identified
(DiMaggio & Powell, 1983; Meyer & and empirically documented various
Rowan, 1977; Zucker, 1977), however, more instances of institutional change (Dacin
recent developments in the field allow for et al., 2002). For example, researchers
a greater interplay between constraints and have investigated change in areas of work-
proactive, strategic actions by actors who place routines and practices (Baron et al.,
instigate change. During this process, two 1986; Mezias, 1990), forms and struc-
areas of thought have evolved within institu- tures (D’Aunno, Succi, & Alexander, 2000;
tional theory around the notion of change: Davis et al., 1994; Greenwood & Hinings,
The first concerns the general concept that 1993; Greenwood & Suddaby, 2006; Kraatz
institutions can change, while the second & Zajac, 1996), industry standards
concerns the sources of that change and con- (Ahmadjian & Robinson, 2001; Leblebici,
ditions under which it occurs. In the follow- Salancik, Copay, & King, 1991), and institu-
ing sections, we briefly review this work. tional logics (Hirsch, 1986; Thornton &
This review is central to our task because Ocasio, 1999).
learning theory’s main contribution to insti- Consistent with this idea of change,
tutional theory is as an additional (and unex- Friedland and Alford (1991: 232) contend
plored) source of both endogenous and that it is the potential conflict among compet-
exogenous change. We, therefore, first dis- ing institutions that produces the ‘multiple
cuss how institutional theory views change in logics’ from which individuals and organiza-
general, and then discuss the various exoge- tions select (see also Scott, 1991). And,
nous and endogenous sources of change. closely combined with the notion that institu-
We finish by noting how learning theories tions change as a result of competition, is the
significantly expand our understanding in implicit idea that institutional environments
both these respects. change when one institution replaces another
(Greenwood & Suddaby, 2006; Hirsch, 1986;
Thornton & Ocasio, 1999). Once the concept
of institutional change is accepted, then the
Institutional change
idea of deinstitutionalization – that in order
The process of institutionalization is a cycle – to be replaced, an existing institution has to
institutions emerge, diffuse, change, die, and diminish in influence – is not far behind
are replaced by new institutions (Hinings, (Abrahamson & Fairchild, 1999; Barley
Greenwood, Reay, & Suddaby, 2004; Scott, & Kunda, 1992; Burns & Wholey, 1993;
2001: Ch. 8). This idea was evident in the Davis et al., 1994; Leblebici et al., 1991;
foundations on which contemporary institu- Oliver, 1992).
tional theory was built, but it was seemingly The combined effects of this evolving area
ignored in early theoretical statements of research is to overcome early interpreta-
(DiMaggio & Powell, 1983; Meyer & tions of neoinstitutional theory that spoke to
Rowan, 1977). Berger and Luckmann (1967), the permanence of institutions once formed
for example, discuss the notion of the (Scott, 2001: 109–110), as well as to high-
‘change of institutions’ (1967: 88) and light the necessity for institutions to be
‘deinstitutionalization’ (1967: 81) as well as consistently reinforced if they are to be
consider at length the potential for conflict preserved – what Berger and Luckmann
INSTITUTIONAL-LEVEL LEARNING: LEARNING AS A SOURCE OF INSTITUTIONAL CHANGE 631

(1967: 54) term ‘reciprocal typification.’ Exogenous sources of change


It is these preserved and reinforced ‘taken- There are three exogenous conditions that
for-granted routines’ that Berger and have been discussed broadly within the
Luckmann (1967: 57) assert form such a cen- literature as necessary (in part or combina-
tral role in establishing and maintaining tion) for change to occur: the influence of
social order. institutional and technical forces in the envi-
Although there is consensus within the ronment; a state of incomplete institutional-
institutional literature today that change ization (the absence of a dominant logic) and
occurs due to competition among institu- other contextual factors; and an exogenous
tions (Dacin et al., 2002), there is less agree- shock that significantly alters the firm’s
ment on whether such change is adaptive environment.
due to the flexibility of organizations/institu- (a) Institutional/technical forces In institu-
tions (Kraatz & Zajac, 1996; Selznick, 1948; tional theory, researchers have identified
Selznick, 1957) or, instead, punctuated due both institutional and technical forces as
to the inertia generated as a result of institu- sources of change, but different forces have
tional isomorphism (DiMaggio & Powell, predominated in various iterations at differ-
1983; DiMaggio & Powell, 1991: 9-11; ent times. Neoinstitutionalism presents a
Greenwood & Hinings, 1996). In addition, view of the organization that is active and
there is disagreement about whether the conscious, but also represents a rejection of
driving force behind change emerges from the rational- and efficiency-based theories
forces at the environmental (exogenous) that grew in prominence within organization
or at the individual actor (endogenous) level theory during the 1960s and early 1970s
(Mezias, 1990). As noted above, the distinc- (Kraatz & Zajac, 1996). DiMaggio and
tion in these positions concerning the Powell (1991: 3) state starkly that neoinstitu-
sources of institutional change speaks tional theory represents an attempt ‘to
largely to the debate between old and replace rational theories of technical contin-
new institutional theorists (DiMaggio & gency or strategic choice with alternative
Powell, 1991; Greenwood & Hinings, 1996; models that are more consistent with the
Hirsch & Lounsbury, 1997; Scott, 1987; organizational reality that researchers have
Selznick, 1996; Stinchcombe, 1997) observed.’ As such, early iterations of neoin-
and remains a point of contention within stitutional theory perceived institutional
the field. forces as acting at the level of the field, con-
straining organizational behavior. Firms were
deemed to adopt specific business practices,
Sources of institutional change especially those acting later in the diffusion
of an innovation, in search of institutional
While it is universally accepted that environ- and societal legitimation, rather than any
ments, to varying degrees, influence organi- technical benefits the specific practice might
zations (Meyer & Scott, 1983; Scott & generate for the firm (DiMaggio & Powell,
Meyer, 1994; Thompson, 1967), it is less 1983; Meyer & Rowan, 1977), which were
clear to what extent individual actors (i.e., either not considered or deemed to be
organizations) are able to influence the insignificant (Westphal et al., 1997; Zajac &
institutional makeup of the environments in Westphal, 2004).
which they operate. This debate between Since the early iterations of neoinstitu-
exogenous and endogenous sources of insti- tional theory, however, many key researchers
tutional change is one that has featured have emerged to correct this stark contrast
strongly within the neoinstitutional literature between the influence of institutional and
since its origin (Meyer & Rowan, 1977; technical environments (Meyer, Scott, &
Zucker, 1977). Deal, 1983: 61–64; Powell, 1991: 183–186;
632 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Scott, 1983: 159–160; Scott, 1991: 2004; Leblebici et al., 1991) and bring
167–169). A shift in thinking that presented change to fields. The necessary conditions
the two states as extremes on a spectrum under which such change is expected to
along which different environments contain occur include high levels of existing legiti-
different mixes of the two was the first step macy (Zimmerman & Zeitz, 2002), estab-
on this journey (Scott, 1991). Kraatz and lished authority (DiMaggio, 1988), and
Zajac (1996: 832) then went further, showing social capital (Maguire et al., 2004).
that organizations are able to adapt their Common sense tells us, however, that the
structures to technical pressures in the envi- more marginal the actor, the lower their level
ronment and benefit from change, even to the of legitimacy, formal authority, and social
extent that such change challenges taken-for- capital is likely to be, which would imply a
granted institutions within the organizational relative ineffectiveness as an agent of
field. More recently, researchers have begun change. This apparent contradiction has been
to question more directly the artificial identified by another stream of research that
dichotomy of economic and institutional notes the key conditions necessary for the
actors (Fiss & Kennedy, 2006; Lounsbury, emergence of institutional change and entre-
2007), suggesting that institutional theory preneurial action by actors firmly embedded
has yet to develop a comprehensive under- within mature organizational fields.
standing of the complex motivations that Although a number of studies in the late
drive firm adoption behavior. 1980s and early 1990s identified that central
(b) Incomplete institutionalization and other actors can act as instigators of institutional
contextual factors Institutional theorists change (Baron et al., 1986; Davis, 1991;
have also framed the environmental hetero- Fligstein, 1985; Palmer, Jennings, & Zhou,
geneity that results from incomplete 1993), however, it is only recently that this
institutionalization in terms of competing, issue has been revisited and built upon
complementary, and conflicting logics that (Greenwood & Suddaby, 2006; Rao, Monin,
create a second condition under which & Durand, 2005). This confusion regarding
change can occur. D’Aunno, Succi, and the characteristics of those actors most likely
Alexander (2000: 680), for example, demon- to instigate change requires further empirical
strate that, in specific circumstances, diver- clarification if we are to have a better under-
gent organizational change follows ‘varying standing of whether it is more central or
market and institutional changes’ within more peripheral actors who are more likely
fragmented organizational fields. to act as ‘institutional entrepreneurs’
In spite of this work, however, a tension in (DiMaggio, 1988: 14). Perhaps one possible
the literature remains regarding other general solution is to distinguish between an entre-
conditions that can facilitate change. While it preneur, who is more likely to be a periph-
is accepted within institutional theory that eral player, and entrepreneurial action,
change driven by institutional entrepreneurs which can be performed by anyone (given
is likely to occur in emerging (Maguire, the appropriate conditions), including more
Hardy, & Lawrence, 2004) and fragmented established and central actors?13
(D’Aunno et al., 2000; Seo & Creed, 2002) (c) Environmental shocks Finally, a third
fields, hierarchical fields, where dominant source of potential change in an organiza-
actors have vested interests in maintaining tional field comes from dramatic shifts in
the status quo, are cited as less likely to expe- environmental conditions. If environments
rience such change. On this point, however, are dynamic, the possibility of radical change
the literature offers contradictory evidence. increases (Meyer & Scott, 1983; Scott &
One stream of empirical studies suggests that Meyer, 1994). ‘Environmental jolts’
marginal actors are more likely to act as (Greenwood, Suddaby, & Hinings, 2002;
institutional entrepreneurs (Ingram & Rao, Meyer, 1982) come in many forms (such as
INSTITUTIONAL-LEVEL LEARNING: LEARNING AS A SOURCE OF INSTITUTIONAL CHANGE 633

shifts in technology, regulatory change, or creation of new institutions and reform exist-
sudden resource scarcity) and stimulate the ing institutions in ways that they deem to be
opportunity for change by opening the door appropriate and aligned with their interests.
for new entrants (Thornton, 2002; Thornton These agents have the resources and, hence,
& Ocasio, 1999), accepted norms (Hirsch, the power to shape the character of institu-
1986), organizational forms (Davis et al., tions and enact institutional change (Dacin
1994; Greenwood & Suddaby, 2006), and et al., 2002: 47).14 Scott (2001: 74–77)
population-wide shifts in operating practices discusses the concept of agency in terms of a
(Baum & Oliver, 1992). firm’s ability to influence the institutional
In the process of identifying the various logics that constitute its environment.
exogenous sources of potential change out- Following DiMaggio’s (1988) lead, this
lined in this section, however, institutional proactive perspective diffused throughout
theorists also broadened their search to institutional theory as institutions were seen
include endogenous factors – first discussing as providers of the framework within which
strategic (Oliver, 1991) and then adaptive actors are able to define and pursue their
(Kraatz & Zajac, 1996) elements of change interests (Leblebici et al., 1991; Oliver,
that emerge at the level of the individual actor. 1991). Powell (1991), in particular, sought
to identify variation in firm responses to
Endogenous sources of change institutional forces, as well as the organiza-
Building on the exogenous sources of change tional heterogeneity and institutional change
outlined above, institutional theory has also that such varied responses generate.
begun to recognize the importance of indi- Oliver (1991: 151) made a crucial contri-
vidual actors (organizations) as sources of bution to this debate, noting five specific
institutional change. DiMaggio (1988: 12), strategic responses that are employed by
Powell (1991: 194–200), DiMaggio and organizations in response to institutional
Powell (1991: 22–27), and Leblebici et al. pressures. Each response varies in the degree
(1991: 335–338) all noted that limiting of ‘active agency’ employed by the firm:
explanations of change within institutional acquiescing, compromising, avoiding, defy-
theory to exogenous sources alone limits the ing, and manipulating. Several researchers
theory merely to explaining the diffusion and have since utilized this framework to look at
reproduction of institutional practices. the implementation of these various strate-
Endogenous explanations of interest, agency, gies within fields (Covaleski & Dirsmith,
and institutional entrepreneurship, however, 1988; Elsbach & Sutton, 1992; Westphal &
help constitute institutionalism as a more Zajac, 1994), thus expanding our knowledge
complete theory of organizations, releasing of agency within different empirical contexts
the ‘full power of the institutional perspec- (Davis et al., 1994; Leblebici et al., 1991;
tive’ (Powell, 1991: 183). Such ideas have Zucker, 1991).
since become central to the contemporary Many of these researchers, however, were
institutional literature. focused on endogenous sources of institu-
(a) Interest, agency, and institutional entrepre- tional change that are internal to the firm. As
neurship DiMaggio (1988: 14) first intro- noted earlier, our primary focus in this chap-
duced the term ‘institutional entrepreneur’ as ter is on change at the level of the field.
part of his call for institutional theory to While such change may occur as a result of
include a more complete explanation of indi- endogenous change by a subset of population
vidual interests and agency. Institutional members, it may also occur as a result of
entrepreneurs are agents who deploy the endogenous processes at the level of the
resources at their disposal to create, alter, and field. There is some (though not a lot) of
empower institutions. Such actors serve as work that examines the role of endogenous
agents of legitimacy who support the field-level processes instigating field-level
634 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

change (Hinings et al., 2004). Fligstein (Friedland & Alford, 1991; Scott, 1991) from
(1990), for example, notes the rise of the which individual actors select (Greenwood &
finance conception of control with the spread Suddaby, 2006; Hirsch, 1986; Suddaby &
of financially trained professionals among Greenwood, 2005; Thornton & Ocasio,
organizations. These professionals brought a 1999).15 Contemporary institutional theorists
set of values and beliefs to their work that, as believe, therefore, that firms are not always
they diffused within the population of large passive recipients of institutional forces, but
industrial firms in the U.S., transformed the have the strategic potential both to select
view of control from the notion of the firm as from, and also to influence and change, the
a single entity, to one of the firm as a bundle institutional logics that are prevalent in their
of assets to be bought and sold. Others have environment when it is in their best interests
also noted the importance of professionals, to do so (Oliver, 1991).
marginal players, and reform agents as This development, theoretically, brings us
sources of endogenous change in institu- full circle within institutional theory. By rec-
tional fields (Greenwood & Suddaby, 2006; ognizing that, under the right circumstances,
Strang & Sine, 2002). Empirically, Brint and actors have strategic alternatives that allow
Karabel (1991) and Miner, Haunschild and them to break the bonds of their institutional
Schwab (2003) identify specific, endogenous constraints, the paradox of embedded agency
field-level processes that induce change, dissolves (Seo & Creed, 2002); moreover, the
including the presence of an industry struc- sociological foundations of the theory again
ture that rewards winner take all models become apparent. Yet, institutional theory still
and imperfect inter-firm copying of routines has far to go in terms of a complete theoreti-
(Miner et al., 2003). cal understanding of the endogenous mecha-
(b) The paradox of embedded agency An nisms of change. There are many more
analysis of endogenous sources of change, sources of change than agency or other delib-
however, brings into focus a central debate erate processes of institutional entrepreneur-
within institutional theory concerning the ship. We contend that the learning theories
paradox of embedded agency (DiMaggio & are a fruitful place for institutional theorists to
Powell, 1991; Greenwood & Suddaby, 2006; discover such sources and processes.
Leblebici et al., 1991; Seo & Creed, 2002).
Institutional theorists who advocate the
notion of agency as a source of institutional
change face an inherent paradox – if institu- INSTITUTIONAL LEVEL
tions and institutional logics form the social LEARNING: A NEW SOURCE
environment, which, in turn, shapes our per- OF CHANGE
ceived reality (Berger & Luckmann, 1967)
that is structured at the level of the organiza- Below we review six key areas of inquiry
tional field (Giddens, 1984), then how do within learning theory – areas that, we
entrepreneurs perceive the need to instigate believe, have received little attention within
change and put their plan into action? institutional theory, yet have strong implica-
This contradiction has come to be known tions for helping to understand and explain
within institutional theory as the paradox of the nature of institutional change. Our key
embedded agency, or, what Berger and argument is that agency and other deliberate
Luckmann (1967: 13) refer to as ‘somewhat processes of institutional entrepreneurship
like trying to push a bus in which one is are not the only sources of change in institu-
riding.’ Although perplexing if thought tional fields and that there is a vast and rele-
through to the extreme, this paradox is par- vant body of research in organizational
tially neutralized by adopting the perspective learning that can provide institutional theo-
of multiple, coexisting institutional logics rists with a much broader perspective on
INSTITUTIONAL-LEVEL LEARNING: LEARNING AS A SOURCE OF INSTITUTIONAL CHANGE 635

change. For example, the role of unplanned Within this overarching framework at the
change resulting from the enactment of pro- intersection of the learning and institutional
saic routines, local and boundedly rational literatures, therefore, we offer the following
action, and ad hoc decision-making six areas in which advances made within the
processes (March, 1981) can all result in learning literature can provide insight or
shifts in institutions and institutional fields. value to the field of institutional theory.
Very little attention has been given within the
institutional literature, however, to processes
of change resulting from these types of unin- The role of unintended
tended consequences. In the following sec-
consequences
tions, we will discuss how these components
of learning theories can inform our under- As indicated above, a relatively under-
standing of institutional change. explored area of organization theory that is
Organization theorists have long recog- relevant to institutional change is the notion
nized the importance of environmental influ- of the unintended consequences of deliberate
ence on organizational structure and actions action. March (1981) notes how organiza-
(Meyer & Scott, 1983; Scott & Meyer, 1994). tional action – even prosaic, everyday
It is also recognized that environments are actions, routines, and processes that relate an
dynamic and unpredictable (Pfeffer & organization to its environment – have the
Salancik, 1978; Thompson, 1967). The ability potential to produce unintended conse-
of actors to respond to their environments – quences in organizations and organizational
with action that both shape and are shaped by populations. Within neoinstitutional theory,
dominant institutions – is also gaining sup- the institution has traditionally been the final
port within institutional theorists.16 Given the arbiter of organizational action. The idea that
dynamic and unpredictable nature of envi- institutional change might result from the
ronments, however, it would be strange if unplanned and unpredictable outcomes of
actors were always able to retain control over deliberate action is not addressed in any
their actions as well as the subsequent conse- depth in institutional theory. Nonetheless, we
quences of those actions. On the contrary, see such action/consequence disjunctions
firms that act in response to a complex envi- every day.
ronment are often unable to react with uni- March (1981), for example, notes how
fied goals, abilities, and intentions, let alone rational organizations with normal mobility
control the outcomes of their actions (March, among managers will be more concerned
1981: 573). The consequences of these reac- with the measurement of performance than
tions, in other words, cannot always be actual performance. This is especially true of
planned. In his path-breaking work in this long-term performance. He further observes
area, March (1981) presents the notion that how this preference can lead to actions
the stable and deliberate processes devoted to refining and managing perform-
of firm action can lead to unintended ance measurement systems, rather than a
change. This idea is well established in the focus on the underlying actual performance.
learning literature, but has received little At the field-level, this might lead to something
attention in the institutional literature; like the emergence of an approach to execu-
although the work on actors’ interests tive compensation that is measurement-ori-
and agency (DiMaggio, 1988) and the ented, yet divorced from actual performance.
more recent scholarship on change in And, in fact, we see things like this in stock
general (Dacin et al., 2002) provide both a option plans where the originally granted
solid foundation for such a discussion and strike price (the price at which executives are
indicate a positive shift of thinking in this able to buy the option) gets reset after the
direction. price has declined. The frequency with which
636 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

this was done in the late 1990s suggests the (e.g., concern over performance measure-
practice was institutionalized and had become ment at the expense of actual performance)
a widely accepted business norm – albeit one have the potential to produce change in insti-
that is now facing deinstitutionalization.17 tutions (e.g., the acceptance of stock option
As a second example of the unintended repricing as a ‘normal’ business activity).
consequences of everyday action, Denrell
(2003) notes that ordinary inter-firm learning
processes will lead to an under-sampling of The role of learning processes
failure (as failed organizations and failed
and field-level change
individuals are excluded from the sample),
which then leads to the widespread accept- A consideration of organizational learning
ance of practices that are not actually related theory leads to additional potential mecha-
to performance. For example, there seems nisms by which endogenous change may
to be a widespread acceptance of the occur in organizational fields. Organizations
idea that strong organizational cultures are frequently show evidence of having learned
superior to weaker ones. Yet, this idea (which various routines, practices, and structures
has taken on a rule-like status in thought and from each other (Argote, Beckman, & Epple,
practice) is likely the result of an under-sam- 1990; Rogers, 1995). Some of this learning
pling of failure, since the performance of occurs at the inter-firm level and some occurs
firms with strong cultures is likely to be at the inter-population level, where industries
higher than the performance of those with or other collective bodies learn from the
weaker cultures, even though strong culture experiences of similar others (Miner &
firms are also more likely to fail during peri- Haunschild, 1995). When such learning
ods of market change as their culture falls out occurs, it reshapes the distribution of routines
of step with changes in the environment. in the population of firms and, thus, reshapes
the institutional context within which firms
The consequences of unintended operate. The processes through which this
consequences for institutional theory inter-firm and inter-population learning occurs
What are the implications of these types of include social connections, geographic prox-
unintended consequences for institutional imity, and other mechanisms of social com-
theory? One implication is that institutions parison, such as size similarity (Rogers, 1995;
will not automatically reproduce themselves. Strang & Soule, 1998). While reviewing all
Institutional theory has fruitfully explored these mechanisms is beyond the scope of this
the idea of institutional reproduction chapter, they are all conceptually related to the
(Hinings et al., 2004; Scott, 2001). Yet, if we boundary between institutional and learning
allow for the prosaic role of unintended con- theories, and all provide potential explana-
sequences occurring in institutional fields, tions for institutional-level learning.
change will develop as a matter of course and There is much evidence, for example, that
institutions will not automatically reproduce. firms will learn from the experiences of
Another implication of unintended conse- others to whom they are connected through
quences is that it is not just agency that pro- various networks – including interlocking
duces change in organizational fields. That directorships, common social club member-
is, the deliberate actions and interests of indi- ships, and Business Roundtable connections
viduals and organizations are not the only (Beckman & Haunschild, 2002; Davis &
driver of change in institutional norms, rules, Greve, 1997; Haunschild, 1993; Henisz &
or other practices. The unintended outcomes Delios, 2002; Palmer et al., 1993; Westphal
of everyday routines also generate change. & Zajac, 1994). This implies that institutional
The examples outlined above show how change (especially endogenous change) can
the unintended consequences of action occur along these interorganizational
INSTITUTIONAL-LEVEL LEARNING: LEARNING AS A SOURCE OF INSTITUTIONAL CHANGE 637

pathways with the extent of change depend- Suppose that an organization is able to deci-
ent on the level of interconnectedness among pher the core processes that deserve to be
the organizations in a particular field. imitated in the Toyota production system; its
Learning also tends to flow along geo- attempts to imitate these systems will still be
graphic lines such that organizations in close affected by its own local context, the other
proximity tend to learn more from each other practices existing in its portfolio, the
than organizations that are more geographi- responses of competitors to the imitation of
cally distant (Burns & Wholey, 1993; Davis these practices, as well as a number of other
& Greve, 1997; Marquis, 2003). This means dynamic variables. These complications are
that institutional change is also more likely to all a potential source of imperfect imitation –
occur in geographic clusters by starting in where the practice is changed (for better
co-located firms and then spreading to more or worse, consciously or unconsciously) to
distant ones (Greve, 2002). fit the local context, competitor responses,
and so on. Organizational learning studies
The consequences of learning processes have noted such issues and the factors
for institutional theory that make them more or less likely
The implication of these learning processes (e.g., Miner & Raghavan, 1999). Learning
for institutional theory is that institutional studies also observe that such imperfections
mechanisms and the spread of institutional- increase the chances of divergent or hetero-
ized practices may be affected significantly geneous outcomes (in other words, they are a
by specific contextual factors for which insti- source of inconsistent change in the institu-
tutional theory has failed to fully account – tional environment) in the sense that there is
factors such as geographic co-location, net- now a greater variety of routines in the
work ties, and learning/information flows population.18
between organizations and populations of
organizations.
In early versions of neoinstitutional theory The role of search: exploration
where the idea of mimetic isomorphism was
versus exploitation
a central tenet (e.g., DiMaggio & Powell,
1983), the assumption was that such imita- The role of search in learning theory is cen-
tion processes are relatively straightforward, tral to an understanding of population-level
with one firm copying the practices of shifts in routines, practices, and structures.
another. Yet, learning theories have discussed One key distinction in learning theory that
the problematic aspects of imitating others in differentiates search from other firm strate-
some detail (Levinthal, 2000; Miner & gies is contained within the roles of explo-
Raghavan, 1999). Imagine, for example, the ration and exploitation (March, 1991; Miner,
problems inherent in an attempt to imitate 1994). Exploration involves search directed
a Toyota production system (Levinthal, toward new knowledge and competencies,
2000). It is not clear which of the many while exploitation involves search directed
underlying routines, practices, and structures toward the better utilization of existing com-
employed by Toyota are good targets for imi- petencies. It has been noted that organiza-
tation. Is the uniform dress of management tions will generally tend toward the
important? What about the just-in-time exploitation of existing competencies
supply of materials? (March, 1991; Starbuck, 1983), in part
While institutional theory has advanced because exploitation generates clear feed-
our knowledge of the isomorphic processes back and tends to yield positive, short-term
that act as forces for field-wide convergence results (Levinthal & March, 1993). At the
over time, there is also the issue of imperfect field-level, this means that exploration will
imitation (which results in divergent change). tend to produce more dramatic and varied
638 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

change, while exploitation will tend to pro- died, some switched to a different structure
duce more incremental and localized change through the process of divestiture of under-
(March, 1991). Thus, any factors that lead a performing assets, but some firms continued
field toward a preponderance of exploration to underperform until a new wave of de-
are also likely to be associated with field- conglomeration activities occurred at a later
level change in institutions. For example, period. Thus, the institutionalization of an
emerging fields such as the treatment of organizational form resulted in underperfor-
HIV/AIDS patients in Canada (Maguire mance, which then triggered learning
et al., 2004) and government incentives for processes, which led to institutional change – a
new entrants in the green technology sector shift from conglomeration to de-conglomera-
(Sine, Haveman, & Tolbert, 2005) can be con- tion as an accepted form of doing business
sidered fields where exploration-driven (Davis et al., 1994).
search processes led to field-level fragmenta- Another factor that seems to lead to a pre-
tion that encouraged change (D’Aunno et al., ponderance of exploration (riskier change
2000). Other work has identified conditions resulting in greater leaps of innovation) is
in well-established, more coherent fields like slow adaptation (Denrell & March, 2001).
the accountancy profession, and represents Slow adaptation benefits an organization
examples of invested actors exploring because it encourages the incorporation of
beyond established institutions in an attempt new and divergent ideas (March, 1991). Fast
to instigate change in an established organi- learning, on the other hand, tends to drive out
zational form (Greenwood & Suddaby, alternatives, narrowing the body of knowl-
2006). edge within the organization, which limits
Yet, if we look at the learning literature, the available options and encourages more
there are additional factors likely to affect conservative exploitation in the system. The
institutional change, including problemistic implication is that systems of fast adaptation
search and slow adaptation. We know from will tend to exhibit more exploitative behav-
the learning literature that performance that ior, even in situations where the long-run
does not meet aspirations triggers search and implications of exploration are positive.
learning (Cyert & March, 1963; Greve, Fads, for example, which tend to be adopted
1998). We also know, however, that these quickly, are less likely to be altered in sub-
search processes for new knowledge and rou- stantial ways by the firms adopting them.
tines are more likely to result in riskier A slowly adopted field-level change,
approaches that, in turn, can pose greater however, such as the finance conception
danger to firms (March, 1991). This means of control (Fligstein, 1990), is a practice
that, at the field-level, a preponderance of that might engender more exploratory
underperforming organizations will likely processes and, consequently, result in greater
lead to an increased acceptance of risk and change during the adaptation process. This
changes that produce greater variance in out- argument presents an alternative explanation
comes. For example, the institutional forces to institutional persistence, but one that is
that lead to a preponderance of conglomerate related to timing (overly fast versus
firms adopting the M-form structure are well beneficially slow adaptation), rather than
documented in research by Fligstein (1985; taken-for-granted assumptions and
1991) and Palmer, Jennings and Zhou isomorphic processes. The important impli-
(1993). Yet, the use of such strategy/structure cation for this argument is that institutional
combinations comes with corresponding change is more likely to occur with slow,
issues and, in general, firms that adopt insti- rather than fast, field-level adaptation. Future
tutional structures can end up underperform- research could explore profitably these
ing in comparison to those that did not differential processes as a function of
(Davis et al., 1994). Some of these firms adaptation rate.
INSTITUTIONAL-LEVEL LEARNING: LEARNING AS A SOURCE OF INSTITUTIONAL CHANGE 639

The consequences of exploration/ The role of forgetting


exploitation for institutional theory (unlearning, disadoption and
It is well-established within institutional deinstitutionalization)
theory that new ideas and business practices
diffuse among firms within organizational As noted by DiMaggio (1988), we know rel-
fields at different times, for different reasons atively little about incomplete institutional-
(Baum & Rowley, 2002; Scott, 2001) and at ization, and even less about why
different rates (Argote, 1999; Tolbert & institutionalized forms and practices fall into
Zucker, 1983). Some practices diffuse disuse. Organizational learning theory, on the
quickly, whereas others do so more slowly. In other hand, has addressed the issue of
addition, some firms are early adopters, ‘unlearning,’ as well as the disadoption or
while some are later adopters. Institutional ‘negative diffusion’ (Rao et al., 2001: 509) of
theory has explored this latter distinction organizational forms and routines. This
(early versus late), but has yet to discuss the literature can contribute to institutional
implications of fast versus slow adoption/ theory in its quest to provide insight into
adaptation. institutional change, in general, and deinsti-
In addition, institutional theory has largely tutionalization, in particular (Oliver, 1992).
limited its focus to adoption in response to In the learning curve tradition, there are
coercive, normative, or mimetic isomorphic studies showing that organizations forget.
forces (DiMaggio & Powell, 1983). The Various factors have been proposed to
adoption of a new practice due to the under- explain forgetting or the depreciation of
performance or failure (Strang & Sine, 2002: knowledge, including asset shortages and
507) of the existing dominant institutional personnel turnover (Argote, 1999; Argote
practice (i.e., adoption due to efficiency rea- et al., 1990). In addition, there appear to be
soning) has generally only been considered more permanent and transitory types of
as a factor driving early adoption (c.f. Fiss & memory in organizations, and the results of
Kennedy, 2006; Lounsbury, 2007). Later empirical studies tend to find that transitory
adopters are considered to adopt not as a memory is more subject to being forgotten
result of underperformance, but rather as a (Argote, 1999). It may also be the case that
response to uncertainty and a desire for con- more technologically sophisticated organiza-
formity as well as the social legitimacy that tions have less forgetting than less sophisti-
comes with adopting highly institutionalized cated organizations, in part because the
practices (DiMaggio & Powell, 1983). Firms knowledge embedded in technology is more
at this stage often adopt reluctantly and with- stable than knowledge embedded in routines,
out customization because the practice has interactions, or other forms of human inter-
become taken-for-granted (Rao et al., 2001; actions and, thus, more resistant to change.
Westphal et al., 1997). In doing so, later This suggests that institutional fields in
adopting firms typically pay little heed to the technologically sophisticated areas (e.g., aero-
potential advantages or disadvantages of the space) may have less forgetting and, thus,
practice in relation to its best interests (Davis will exhibit more institutional stability than
et al., 1994; Zajac & Westphal, 2004). Thus, fields in less technologically sophisticated
considering the predictions of learning theo- areas (e.g., restaurants). Another implication
ries with respect to adoption behavior, the from the learning literature is that field-level
concepts of exploration and exploitation can turnover of personnel is a source of forgetting
provide a fuller picture of the various firm and, therefore, change in institutions. Ingram
actions at various points in the adoption/ and Simons (2002), for example, found no
adaptation process and, thus, afford a more evidence of depreciation over time in the prof-
complete picture of institutional change in itability of kibbutz agriculture, which Argote
various societal sectors. (1999) suggests may be due to the fairly stable
640 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

membership that is typical of these organiza- The roles of selective and


tions. The kibbutz is also relatively stable and inferential learning
institutionalized as an organizational form. In
contrast, consider the substantial amount of In opposition to established theory within the
change that has occurred in hospitals and institutional literature (Rao et al., 2001;
healthcare over the past half century, as well Westphal et al., 1997), the learning literature
as the field-level turnover of personnel that tells us that sometimes later adoption may
has accompanied this change (Scott, Ruef, not be due to conformity pressures, but may
Mendel, & Caronna, 2000). instead be caused by learning processes that
Another area of learning that might have occur at the field-level. These processes are
relevance for institutional theory is the work selective and inferential, rather than mimetic.
on cycles of adoption and abandonment of Sine, Haveman, and Tolbert (2005), for
practices (Abrahamson & Fairchild, 1999; example, discuss learning by firms that
Barley & Kunda, 1992; Burns & Wholey, observed the earliest market entrants into
1993; Davis et al., 1994; Rao et al., 2001; the unproven green technology sector (them-
Strang & Macy, 2001). Strang and Macy selves prompted by government incentives),
(2001) note that faddish cycles of adoption before deciding themselves to enter. By
and abandonment can occur in fields and that entering this sector later in the diffusion
the dynamics of fads are sustained, in part, curve, these firms were able to infer potential
because modestly successful firms tend to efficiency benefits for themselves, based on
copy the practices of very successful firms the combined experiences of earlier entrants.
that are more likely to have satisficed in their Such performance-based imitation is not
search for success (Abrahamson & Fairchild, done during a period of uncertainty (uncer-
1999; Strang & Macy, 2001). This view of tainty is reduced by the experiences of prior
the role played by satisficing in promoting firms), is not the implementation of a prac-
fads and by constraining the institutionaliza- tice that is taken-for-granted within the
tion of practices provides a deeper under- industry (the sector is not yet sufficiently
standing of the factors driving the established for this to occur), but is a deci-
institutionalization process than currently sion made, at least partially, for economic
suggested by institutional theory. and rational reasons. All of these criteria
resist easily categorizing the adopting firm as
The consequences of forgetting for responding to mimetic institutional forces
institutional theory but, instead, seem to fit into a learning model
Work on organizational forgetting can con- that is based on the experiences of others.19
tribute to institutional theory in expanding There is also research that discusses how
the mechanisms that drive deinstitutionaliz- entire fields learn from the experiences of
ing forces. Currently, deinstitutionalization is other fields. For example, Cho, Kim and
seen as occurring due to the actions of out- Rhee (1998) discuss how Korean firms
siders or institutional entrepreneurs. Instead, achieved success in semiconductors, despite
the characteristics of the technologies their late entry into this market, precisely
involved in the field (whether these technolo- because they learned from the experiences of
gies are producing good or modest returns), the United States and Japanese semiconduc-
the roles played by unlearning (disadoption tor industries. Similarly, the Microelectron-
and/or forgetting) due to personnel turnover ics and Computer Consortium (MCC), the
and other factors, and the concept of satisfic- first major electronics research consortium in
ing can all play a role in instigating the the U.S., is recognized as successful, in part,
diminishment of established institutions, as because of its observation and imitation of
well as the rise of new institutions to replace similar consortia in Japan (Aldrich & Sasaki,
them and renew the dominant order. 1995; Miner & Haunschild, 1995).
INSTITUTIONAL-LEVEL LEARNING: LEARNING AS A SOURCE OF INSTITUTIONAL CHANGE 641

As noted earlier, social ties and geographic structures and activities over time (Baron
proximity are two factors likely to affect et al., 1986; Greenwood & Hinings, 1996;
endogenous institutional change. These fac- Strang & Meyer, 1994). In one of the key for-
tors may also affect exogenous change when mulations of the theory, DiMaggio and
fields learn from the experience of other Powell (1983) discuss the very strong institu-
fields. Miner and Haunschild (1995), tional (as opposed to competitive) mecha-
for example, examined how the existence of nisms by which this convergence occurs:
strong inter-firm ties between small biotech coercive, mimetic, and normative isomor-
firms and large pharmaceutical firms in the phism. It is increasingly accepted within
U.S. facilitated the learning and integration institutional theory, however, that different
by the pharmaceuticals of the successful strategic responses by firms to the same insti-
organizational routines and technologies tutional stimuli can result in greater, rather
of the biotechs. Consequently, this is another than less, field-level heterogeneity (Oliver,
example of field-level change that was 1991; Powell, 1991).
facilitated by learning processes among Thus, it becomes important to distinguish
socially connected firms. The consideration under what conditions firms converge in the
of this type of change is of noteworthy value face of institutional pressures and when the
to institutional theory in its quest to explain opposite result occurs. The organizational
such instances of change. learning literature has begun to specify
some of these conditions, in part because
The consequences of selective and learning theories are at least somewhat
inferential learning for institutional theory concerned with sources of variance in rou-
The potential benefits of selective and infer- tines, processes, and structures (Miner &
ential learning for institutional theory were Haunschild, 1995), whereas the preponder-
first highlighted by Miner and Haunschild ance of work within institutional theory has
(1995: 126). As illustrated above, these two focused more on sources of institutional
processes describe the means by which firms retention and replication. Learning theories
(or fields) either copy routines they believe have specified three key field-level condi-
have been successful elsewhere (selective tions/processes that will tend to divergence
copying) or use the experiences of other (and, thus, institutional change) rather than
organizations or fields as a natural experi- convergence: imperfect copying; regulatory
ment, drawing conclusions and adapting the pressures; and field-level competition.
processes to suit their specific circumstances
(inferential learning). If institutional theo- Imperfect copying
rists are able to build a body of research that The first key field-level process is mimetic
successfully integrates and uses these con- learning, in which the learning involves not
cepts, they will be filling a significant gap in simple copying but, instead, imperfect copy-
the institutional literature, which to date has ing or, at times, even doing something
no explanation for late adoption based on an entirely different. We noted earlier how
efficiency rationale. imperfect copying is a process by which
field-level change can occur. In addition to
imperfect copying, however, there is also
The role of heterogeneity work on other experience-based responses
that might occur, including what has been
versus homogeneity
called non-mimetic learning. For example,
According to an institutional perspective of research shows that some conditions
organizations, firms facing similar institu- produce action that, while informed by the
tional environments experience isomorphic experiences of others, results in outcomes
forces that tend toward convergence in their that are unique to the focal firm (Greve &
642 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Taylor, 2000). When imitation results in these occurs in instances where there is ben-
action that differs in this way, the result efit to an actor in promoting novelty – in
is likely to be field-level heterogeneity other words, where it pays to be different.
(Greve, 2005; Miner et al., 2003) and, there- Many arts-based organizations operate
fore, a possible source of new institutions within such industries. Such an extreme
and institutional change. incentive-based industry will encourage
established firms to innovate and also
Regulatory pressures encourage new entrants to the field, which
The second key field-level change process generates both field-level heterogeneity and
specified in the learning literature is the change. The second condition is likely to
result of regulatory pressures, which were occur when maximum performance is dis-
initially theorized by DiMaggio and Powell proportionately rewarded – in other words, in
(1983) to lead to convergence. More recently, a winner-takes-all environment. Such envi-
however, such pressures have been shown ronments encourage high-risk strategies that
also to produce divergence when firms tend to result in greater variance rather than
respond differentially (D’Aunno et al., higher average performance (March, 1991),
2000). Examples in the learning literature which has a diversifying impact on the indus-
note the changes that can result from differ- try as a whole.
ential learning in response to regulation –
either learning from the experiences of other The consequences of heterogeneity/
firms (Sine et al., 2005), or learning from the homogeneity for institutional theory
experience of one’s own firm (Haunschild & The implications of this body of work within
Rhee, 2004). In addition, whole industries the learning theories for institutional theory
can learn from the regulatory responses of are significant, especially for those
other industries. An example of this occurred researchers who have begun to consider how
when the medical industry learned from the variations in actor responses to the same
airline industry in relation to regulatory pro- institutional environments can produce
cedures surrounding accidents, subsequently greater heterogeneous, rather than homoge-
installing similar regulation within hospitals neous, outcomes (Oliver, 1991). Integrating
(Miner et al., 2003). Thus, learning from these three key field-level learning processes
another population in response to regulation (imperfect copying, regulatory pressures, and
can also lead to change in the institutional competition) will add significant depth to
environment. discussions in this area of work that are only
just beginning within institutional theory.
Competition
The third key field-level condition occurs in
industries that are highly competitive. In con-
trast to DiMaggio and Powell’s (1983: CONCLUSION
149–150) argument that competitive forces
are one of two types of isomorphic tenden- We have argued that both institutional and
cies among firms and industries, learning learning theorists have considered the impor-
theorists have argued that, under specific tant issue of change in organizational fields,
conditions, competition can generate hetero- although largely in isolation from each other.
geneous outcomes (Miner et al., 2003). The purpose of this chapter has been to try
Miner, Haunschild and Schwab (2003) and open up a beneficial avenue of commu-
identify two conditions under which such nication between the two theories, believing
competitive heterogeneity might occur – that understanding the processes and conse-
competition based on novelty and competi- quences of organizational and interorganiza-
tion based on extreme values. The first of tional learning can contribute significantly to
INSTITUTIONAL-LEVEL LEARNING: LEARNING AS A SOURCE OF INSTITUTIONAL CHANGE 643

institutional theory in its quest to explain theory contained within this chapter has deep-
institutional change. Our goal has been to ened our understanding of what is possible
identify where these two literatures overlap, and begun to hint at a research agenda for
so that knowledge is shared and replication is future work within institutional theory that
avoided (wherever possible), in a way that addresses some of the unanswered questions
constitutes, we hope, a constructive addition generated at the boundary of these two impor-
to the institutional literature. tant organization theories.
To this end, we have identified areas where
we feel learning processes and mechanisms
can work in conjunction with our existing
knowledge of institutions to inform our ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
understanding of field-level change. These
processes and mechanisms include the idea Much of this chapter was drafted during the
that ordinary organizational processes can first author’s residency at the Rockefeller
lead to unintended outcomes, which can then Foundation’s Bellagio Center during May
lead to the disruption of existing institutions. 2006. We thank Roy Suddaby, Matt Kraatz,
The processes also include the effect of and an anonymous reviewer for their very
network ties, geographic location, and infor- helpful comments and suggestions for
mation flows as sources of institutional improvements in our arguments.
reproduction (and non-reproduction).
Furthermore, these mechanisms investigate
the idea that processes of exploration engen-
der dramatic institutional change and that NOTES
such processes are more likely to occur under
slow adaptation and underperformance in 1 Is Wal-Mart going green? CEO vows to be
relation to specific institutional norms, rules, ‘good steward for the environment’ in announcing
goals,’ MSNBC.com, October 25, 2005, <www.msn
and models. They also include the idea that bc.msn.com/id/9815727/>.
forgetting may erode institutions, a situation 2 Kris Hudson, ‘Wal-Mart Wants Suppliers,
that is more likely in conditions such as high Workers to Join Green Effort,’ Wall Street Journal,
personnel turnover. Finally, these processes February 2, 2007, pA14.
and mechanisms explore the idea that selec- 3 Jonathan Birchall, ‘Sun rises over Wal-Mart’s
power policy,’ Financial Times, January 22, 2007, p.8;
tive and inferential learning processes, both Melanie Warner, ‘Wal-Mart Eyes Organic Foods,’
within and across fields, produce institu- New York Times, May 12, 2006, <www.common
tional change, as well as the view that hetero- dreams.org/headlines06/0512-07.htm>.
geneity produced by imperfect copying, 4 <www.walmart.com/>.
5 For examples, see: ‘Wal-Mart: The High Cost of
regulatory pressures, and competition based
Low Price,’ <www.walmartmovie.com/>; and ‘Wal-
on novelty or extreme values can lead to Mart Watch,’ <walmartwatch.com/>.
institutional change. 6 Melanie Warner, ‘Wal-Mart Eyes Organic Foods,’
This is an exciting time for institutional New York Times, May 12, 2006, www.common
theory. The relatively recent focus on change dreams.org/headlines06/0512-07.htm>.
7 Ann Zimmerman, ‘Wal-Mart Sees Profit in
opens up huge possibilities for understanding
Green—Some Recycling Initiatives Are Helping
how institutions adapt and what the conse- Retailer’s Bottom Line,’ Wall Street Journal, August
quences of such adaptation might be. We 21, 2006, p. B3.
believe that the learning theories can supply 8 We outline this concept in greater detail later
at least some of the answers that institutional on in this chapter.
9 We do not take a stand here concerning the
theorist seek. Yet, in spite of the potential ben-
debate within institutional theory between compet-
efits, the intersection of these two theories has ing conceptualizations of institutions at the organiza-
received scant attention from scholars to date. tional (Selznick, 1957) or field (DiMaggio & Powell,
We hope that the consideration of learning 1983) levels. Instead, we perceive of an institution in
644 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

its broadest and most inclusive sense, utilizing learning: Technology choice in the American
Jepperson’s (1991: 145) definition where ‘Institution cement industry. In J. Baum (ed.), Advances
represents a social order or pattern that has attained in Strategic Management. JAI Press Inc.
a certain state or property; institutionalization Argote, L., Beckman, S. L., & Epple, D. 1990.
denotes the process of such attainment.’
The persistence and transfer of learning in
10 For a discussion of the multiple definitions of
an organization’s environment that have emerged
industrial settings. Management Science,
from the assumption of a field level of conceptualiza- 36(2): 140–54.
tion within the institutional literature over time, Argote, L. 1999. Organizational learning:
see Scott (1983: 161–162) and Scott (1991: Creating, retaining & transferring knowl-
172–174). edge. Boston, MA: Kluwer.
11 See the section titled ‘Institutional Theory and Barley, S. R. & Kunda, G. 1992. Design and
Change’ later in this chapter. devotion: Surges of rational and normative
12 There are also learning theories at lower levels ideologies of control in managerial dis-
of analyses, however, that can be used to illuminate course. Administrative Science Quarterly,
institutional processes and we will incorporate these
37(3): 363–99.
theories as appropriate.
13 See the discussion below for an indication of
Baron, J. N., Dobbin, F., & Jennings, P. D. 1986.
the role played by institutional entrepreneurs within War and peace: The evolution of modern
institutional theory as instigators of change. personnel administration in U.S. industry.
14 For a comprehensive review see Leca, American Journal of Sociology, 92: 350–83.
Battilana, & Boxenbaum (2006). Baum, J. A. C. & Oliver, C. 1992. Institutional
15 Institutional logics are described as societal- embeddedness and the dynamics of organi-
level ‘beliefs, norms, routine practices’ (Scott, 2001: zational populations. American Sociological
134). Review, 57(4): 540–59.
16 See the section titled ‘Institutional Theory and
Baum, J. A. C. & Rowley, T. J. 2002. Companion
Change’ earlier in this chapter.
to Organizations: An Introduction: Blackwell.
17 James Surowiecki, ‘The Dating Game,’ The
New Yorker, November 6, 2006, <www.new Beckman, C. M. & Haunschild, P. R. 2002.
yorker.com/archive/2006/11/06/061106ta_talk_suro Network learning: The effects of partners’
wiecki>. heterogeneity of experience on corporate
18 The role of divergent versus convergent forces acquisitions. Administrative Science
for change is discussed in greater detail later in this Quarterly, 47(1): 92.
section. Berger, P. L. & Luckmann, T. 1967. The Social
19 Our initial example of Wal-Mart learning Construction of Reality: A Treatise in the
from examples provided by earlier adopters of
Sociology of Knowledge. Garden City, NY:
environmentally-friendly policies is also of this nature.
Anchor Books.
Brint, S. & Karabel, J. 1991. Institutional origins
and transformations: The case of American
community colleges. In W. W. Powell &
REFERENCES P. J. DiMaggio (eds.), The New Institutionalism
in Organizational Analysis. Chicago, IL: The
Abrahamson, E. & Fairchild, G. 1999. University of Chicago Press.
Management fashion: lifecycles, triggers, Burns, L. R. & Wholey, D. R. 1993. Adoption and
and collective learning processes. abandonment of matrix management pro-
Administrative Science Quarterly, 44(4): grams: Effects of organizational characteristics
708–40. and interorganizational networks. Academy of
Ahmadjian, C. L. & Robinson, P. 2001. Safety in Management Journal, 36(1): 106.
numbers: Downsizing and the deinstitution- Cho, D. S., Kim, D. J., & Rhee, D. K. 1998.
alization of permanent employment in Latecomer strategies: Evidence from the
Japan. Administrative Science Quarterly, semiconductor industry in Japan and Korea.
46(4): 622–54. Organization Science, 9(4): 489.
Aldrich, H. E. & Sasaki, T. 1995. R&D consortia Covaleski, M. A. & Dirsmith, M. W. 1988. An
in the United States and Japan. Research institutional perspective on the rise, social
Policy, 24(2): 301–16. transformation, and fall of a university
Anderson, P. 1999. Collective interpretation budget category. Administrative Science
and collective action in population-level Quarterly, 33(4): 562–87.
INSTITUTIONAL-LEVEL LEARNING: LEARNING AS A SOURCE OF INSTITUTIONAL CHANGE 645

Cyert, R. M. & March, J. G. 1963. A Behavioral Elsbach, K. D. & Sutton, R. I. 1992. Acquiring
Theory of the Firm: A Summary of Basic organizational legitimacy through illegiti-
Concepts in the Behavioral Theory of the mate actions: A marriage of institutional and
Firm, Chapter 7, 161–176. Englewood Cliffs, impression management theories. Academy
NJ: Prentice-Hall. of Management Journal, 35(4): 699–738.
D’Aunno, T., Succi, M., & Alexander, J. A. Fiol, C. M. & Lyles, M. A. 1985. Organizational
2000. The role of institutional and market learning. The Academy of Management
forces in divergent organizational change. Review, 10(4): 803–13.
Administrative Science Quarterly, 45(4): Fiss, P. C. & Kennedy, M. T. 2006. Cognition
679–703. and conformity: The micro-linkages of insti-
Dacin, M. T., Goodstein, J., & Scott, W. R. tutional theory, the present and future status
2002. Special research forum on institutional of institutional theory. University of Alberta.
theory and institutional change. Academy of Fligstein, N. 1985. The spread of the multidivi-
Management Journal, 45: 1(1). sional form among large firms, 1919–1979.
Davis, G. F. 1991. Agents without principles? American Sociological Review, 50(3):
The spread of the poison pill through the 377–91.
intercorporate network. Administrative Fligstein, N. 1990. The Transformation of
Science Quarterly, 36(4): 583–613. Corporate Control. Cambridge, MA: Harvard
Davis, G. F., Diekmann, K. A., & Tinsley, C. H. University Press.
1994. The decline and fall of the conglomer- Fligstein, N. 1991. The structural transforma-
ate firm in the 1980s: The deinstitutionaliza- tion of American industry: An institutional
tion of an organizational form. American account of the causes of diversification in the
Sociological Review, 59(4): 547–70. largest firms, 1919–1979. In W. W. Powell &
Davis, G. F. & Greve, H. R. 1997. Corporate elite P. J. DiMaggio (eds.), The New Institutionalism
networks and governance changes in 1980s. in Organizational Analysis. Chicago, IL: The
American Journal of Sociology, 103(1): 1–37. University of Chicago Press.
Denrell, J. & March, J. G. 2001. Adaptation as Friedland, R. & Alford, R. R. 1991. Bringing
information restriction: The hot stove effect. Society Back in: Symbols, Practices, and
Organization Science, 12(5): 523. Institutional Contradictions. In W. W. Powell &
Denrell, J. 2003. Vicarious learning, undersam- P. J. DiMaggio (eds.), The New Institutionalism
pling of failure, and the myths of manage- in Organizational Analysis. Chicago, IL: The
ment. Organization Science, 14(3): 227–43. University of Chicago Press.
DiMaggio, P. J. & Powell, W. W. 1983. The iron Galaskiewicz, J. 1985. Interorganizational
cage revisited: Institutional isomorphism and Relations: Annual Review of Sociology, 11:
collective rationality in organizational fields. 281–304.
American Sociological Review, 48(2): Giddens, A. 1984. The Constitution of Society:
147–60. Outline of the Theory of Structuration.
DiMaggio, P. J. 1988. Interest and agency in Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.
institutional theory. In L. G. Zucker (ed.), Greenwood, R. & Hinings, C. R. 1993.
Institutional Patterns and Organizations: Understanding strategic change: The contri-
Culture and Environment. Cambridge, MA: bution of archetypes. Academy of
Ballinger Publishing Company. Management Journal, 36(5): 1052.
DiMaggio, P. J. & Powell, W. W. 1991. Greenwood, R. & Hinings, C. R. 1996.
Introduction. In W. W. Powell & P. J. DiMaggio Understanding radical organizational
(eds.), The New Institutionalism in change: Bringing together the old and
Organizational Analysis. Chicago, IL: The the new institutionalism. Academy of
University of Chicago Press. Management Review, 21(4): 1022–54.
Dutton, J. M., Thomas, A., & Butler, J. E. 1984. Greenwood, R., Suddaby, R., & Hinings, C. R.
The history of progress functions as a mana- 2002. Theorizing change: The role of profes-
gerial technology. Business History Review, sional associations in the transformation of
58(2): 204. institutional fields. Academy of Management
Easterby-Smith, M. 1997. Disciplines of organi- Journal, 45(1): 58–80.
zational learning: contributions and cri- Greenwood, R. & Suddaby, R. 2006.
tiques. Human Relations, 50(9): 1085–113. Institutional entrepreneurship in mature
646 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

fields: The Big Five accounting firms. instance of cultural framing and institutional
Academy of Management Journal, 49(1): integration. The American Journal of
27–48. Sociology, 91(No. 4): 800–37.
Greve, H. R. 1998. Managerial cognition and Hirsch, P. M. & Lounsbury, M. 1997. Ending the
the mimetic adoption of market positions: family quarrel: Toward a reconciliation of
What you see is what you do. Strategic ‘old’ and ‘new’ institutionalisms. American
Management Journal, 19(10): 967–88. Behavioral Scientist, 40(4): 406–18.
Greve, H. R. & Taylor, A. 2000. Innovations as cat- Huber, G. P. 1991. Organizational learning: The
alysts for organizational change: Shifts in orga- contributing processes and the literatures.
nizational cognition and search. Administrative Organization Science, 2(1): 88.
Science Quarterly, 45(1): 54–80. Hutchins, E. 1991. Organizing work by adapta-
Greve, H. R. 2002. An ecological theory of spa- tion. Organization Science, 2(1): 14–39.
tial evolution: Local density dependence in Ingram, P. & Simons, T. 2002. The transfer of
Tokyo banking, 1894–1936. Social Forces, experience in groups of organizations:
80(3): 847–79. Implications for performance and
Greve, H. R. 2005. Interorganizational learning competition. Management Science, 48(12):
and heterogeneous social structure. 1517–33.
Organization Studies, 26(7): 1025–47. Ingram, P. & Rao, H. 2004. Store wars: The
Hannan, M. T. & Freeman, J. 1984. Structural enactment and repeal of anti-chain-store
inertia and organizational change. American legislation in America. American Journal of
Sociological Review, 49(2): 149–64. Sociology, 110(2): 446–87.
Haunschild, P. R. 1993. Interorganizational imi- Jepperson, R. L. 1991. Institutions, Institutional
tation: The impact of interlocks on corporate Effects, and Institutionalism. In W. W. Powell &
acquisition activity. Administrative Science P. J. DiMaggio (eds.), The New Institutionalism
Quarterly, 38(4): 564–92. in Organizational Analysis. Chicago, IL: The
Haunschild, P. R. & Miner, A. S. 1997. Modes of University of Chicago Press.
interorganizational imitation: The effects of out- Kraatz, M. S. & Zajac, E. J. 1996. Exploring the
come salience and uncertainty. Administrative limits of the new institutionalism: The causes
Science Quarterly, 42(3): 472–500. and consequences of illegitimate organiza-
Haunschild, P. R. & Rhee, M. 2004. The role of tional change. American Sociological
volition in organizational learning: The case Review, 61(5): 812–36.
of automotive product recalls. Management Leblebici, H., Salancik, G. R., Copay, A., & King, T.
Science, 50(11): 1545–60. 1991. Institutional change and the transfor-
Hayward, M. L. A. 2002. When do firms learn mation of interorganizational fields: An
from their acquisition experience? Evidence organizational history of the U.S. radio
from 1990–1995. Strategic Management broadcasting industry. Administrative
Journal, 23(1): 21. Science Quarterly, 36(3): 333–63.
Hedberg, B. L. T. 1981. How organizations Leca, B., Battilana, J., & Boxenbaum, E.
learn and unlearn. In P. C. Nystrom & W. H. 2006. Taking stock on institutional entrepre-
Starbuck (eds.), Handbook of Organizational neurship: What do we know? Where do we
Design, Vol. 1. New York, NY: Oxford go?, Forthcoming: CLAREE Université de
University Press. Lille.
Henisz, W. & Delios, A. 2002. Organizational Levinthal, D. A. & March, J. G. 1993. The
survival in uncertain times. Unpublished myopia of learning. Strategic Management
working paper, University of Pennsylvania Journal, 14(8): 95–112.
Wharton School, Philadelphia. Levinthal, D. A. 2000. Organizational Capabilities
Hinings, C. R. B., Greenwood, R., Reay, T., & in Complex Worlds, Nature & Dynamics of
Suddaby, R. 2004. Dynamics of change Organizational Capabilities: 363: The Several
in organizational fields. In M. S. Poole Contributors 2000.
& A. H. Van de Ven (eds.), Handbook of Levitt, B. & March, J. G. 1988. Organizational
Organizational Change and Innovation, learning. Annual Review of Sociology, 14:
304–24. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press. 319–40.
Hirsch, P. M. 1986. From ambushes to golden Lieberman, M. B. 1984. The learning curve and
parachutes: Corporate takeovers as an pricing in the chemical processing industries.
INSTITUTIONAL-LEVEL LEARNING: LEARNING AS A SOURCE OF INSTITUTIONAL CHANGE 647

RAND Journal of Economics, 15(2): L. Cummings (eds.), Research in Organizational


213–28. Behavior, 17: 115–66.
Lounsbury, M. 2007. A tale of two cities: Miner, A. S. & Mezias, S. J. 1996. Ugly duckling
Competing logics and practice variation in no more: Pasts and futures of organizational
the professionalizing of mutual funds. learning research. Organization Science,
Academy of Management Journal, 50(2): 7(1): 88–99.
289–307. Miner, A. S. & Anderson, P. 1999. Industry and
Maguire, S., Hardy, C., & Lawrence, T. B. 2004. population-level learning: Organizational,
Institutional entrepreneurship in emerging interorganizational, and collective learning
fields: HIV/AIDS treatment advocacy in processes. In J. Baum (ed.), Advances in
Canada. Academy of Management Journal, Strategic Management. JAI Press Inc.
47(5): 657–79. Miner, A. S. & Raghavan, S. V. 1999. The
March, J. G. & Olsen, J. P. 1976. Ambiguity and hidden engine of selection: Interorganiza-
Choice in Organizations. Oslo: Norway: tional imitation. In J. R. Baum & B. McKelvey
Scandinavian University Press. (eds.), Variations in Organization Science: In
March, J. G. 1981. Footnotes to organizational Honor of Donald T. Campbell. Thousand
change. Administrative Science Quarterly, Oaks, CA: Sage Publications Inc.
26(4): 563. Miner, A. S., Haunschild, P. R., & Schwab, A.
March, J. G. 1991. Exploration and exploitation 2003. Experience and convergence:
in organizational learning. Organization Curiosities and speculation. Industrial &
Science, 2(1): 71. Corporate Change, 12(4): 789–813.
Marquis, C. 2003. The pressure of the past: Oliver, C. 1991. Strategic responses to institu-
Network imprinting in intercorporate com- tional processes. Academy of Management
munities. Administrative Science Quarterly, Review, 16(1): 145.
48(4): 655–89. Oliver, C. 1992. The antecedents of deinstitution-
Meyer, A. D. 1982. Adapting to environmental alization. Organization Studies, 13(4): 563.
jolts. Administrative Science Quarterly, 27(4): Palmer, D. A., Jennings, P. D., & Zhou, X. 1993.
515–37. Late adoption of the multidivisional form by
Meyer, J. W. & Rowan, B. 1977. Institutional- large U.S. corporations: Institutional, politi-
ized organizations: Formal structure as myth cal, and economic accounts. Administrative
and ceremony. The American Journal of Science Quarterly, 38(1): 100–31.
Sociology, 83(2): 340–63. Parsons, T. 1956. Suggestions for a sociological
Meyer, J. W. & Scott, W. R. (eds.). 1983. approach to the theory of organizations – I.
Organizational Environments: Ritual and Administrative Science Quarterly, 1(1): 63.
Rationality. Beverly Hills, CA: Sage Pfeffer, J. & Salancik, G. R. 1978. The External
Publications, Inc. Control of Organizations: A Resource
Meyer, J. W., Scott, W. R., & Deal, T. E. 1983. Dependence Perspective. New York: Harper
Institutional and technical sources of organi- and Row.
zational structure: Explaining the structure of Powell, W. W. 1991. Expanding the scope of
educational organizations. In J. W. Meyer & institutional analysis. In W. W. Powell &
W. R. Scottr (eds.), Organizational Environ- P. J. DiMaggio (eds.), The New Institutionalism
ments: Ritual and Rationality. Beverly Hills, in Organizational Analysis. Chicago, IL: The
CA: Sage Publications, Inc. University of Chicago Press.
Mezias, S. J. 1990. An institutional model of Rao, H., Greve, H. R., & Davis, G. F. 2001. Fool’s
organizational practice: financial reporting at gold: Social proof in the initiation and aban-
the Fortune 200. Administrative Science donment of coverage by Wall Street analysts.
Quarterly, 35(3): 431–57. Administrative Science Quarterly, 46(3): 502.
Miner, A. S. 1994. Seeking adaptive advantage: Rao, H., Monin, P., & Durand, R. 2005. Border
Evolutionary theory and managerial action. crossing: Bricolage and the erosion of cate-
In J. R. Baum & J. V. Singh (eds.), gorical boundaries in French gastronomy.
Evolutionary Dynamics of Organizations. American Sociological Review, 70(6):
Oxford: Oxford University Press. 968–91.
Miner, A. S. & Haunschild, P. R. 1995. Rogers, E. M. 1995. Diffusion of Innovations
Population level learning. In B. M. Staw & (5th edn.). Free Press.
648 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Scott, W. R. 1983. The organization of environ- Starbuck, W. H. 1983. Organizations as action


ments: Network, cultural, and historical generators. American Sociological Review,
elements. In J. W. Meyer & W. R. Scott 48(1): 91–102.
(eds.), Organizational Environments: Ritual Stinchcombe, A. L. 1997. On the virtues of the
and Rationality. Beverly Hills, CA: Sage old institutionalism. Annual Review of
Publications, Inc. Sociology, 23(1): 1.
Scott, W. R. 1987. The adolescence of institu- Strang, D. & Meyer, J. W. 1994. Institutional
tional theory. Administrative Science conditions for diffusion. In W. R. Scott &
Quarterly, 32(4): 493. J. W. Meyer (eds.), Institutional Environments
Scott, W. R. 1991. Unpacking institutional and Organizations. Thousand Oaks, CA:
arguments. In W. W. Powell & P. J. DiMaggio Sage Publications, Inc.
(eds.), The New Institutionalism in Organiza- Strang, D. & Soule, S. A. 1998. Diffusion in
tional Analysis. Chicago, IL: The University of organizations and social movements: From
Chicago Press. hybrid corn to poison pills. Annual Review of
Scott, W. R. 2001. Institutions and Organiza- Sociology, 24(1): 265.
tions (2nd edn.). Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage. Strang, D. & Macy, M. W. 2001. In search of
Scott, W. R. & Meyer, J. W. (eds.). 1994. excellence: Fads, success stories, and adap-
Institutional Environments and Organizations: tive emulation. American Journal of
Structural Complexity and Individualism. Sociology, 107(1): 147–82.
Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage Publications, Inc. Strang, D. & Sine, W. D. 2002.
Scott, W. R., Ruef, M., Mendel, P. J., & Interorganizational institutions. In J. A. C.
Caronna, C. A. 2000. Institutional Change Baum (ed.), The Blackwell Companion to
and Healthcare Organizations: From Organizations.
Professional Dominance to Managed Care. Suchman, M. C. 1995. Managing legitimacy:
Chicago, IL: The University of Chicago Press. Strategic and institutional approaches.
Selznick, P. 1948. Foundations of the theory of Academy of Management Review, 20(3):
organization. American Sociological Review, 571–610.
13(1): 25–35. Suddaby, R. & Greenwood, R. 2005. Rhetorical
Selznick, P. 1957. Leadership in Administration. strategies of legitimacy. Administrative
Harper & Row. Science Quarterly, 50(1): 35–67.
Selznick, P. 1996. Institutionalism ‘old’ and Thompson, J. D. 1967. Organizations in Action:
‘new’. Administrative Science Quarterly, Social Science Bases of Administrative
41(2): 270–77. Action. New York, NY: McGraw-Hill.
Seo, M.-G. & Creed, W. E. D. 2002. Institutional Thornton, P. H. & Ocasio, W. 1999. Institutional
contradictions, praxis, and institutional logics and the historical contingency of
change: A dialectical perspective. Academy power in organizations: Executive succession
of Management Review, 27(2): 222–47. in the higher education publishing industry,
Shrivastava, P. 1983. A typology of organiza- 1958–1990. American Journal of Sociology,
tional learning systems. Journal of 105(3): 801–44.
Management Studies, 20(1): 7. Thornton, P. H. 2002. The rise of the corpora-
Simon, H. A. 1991. Bounded rationality and tion in a craft industry: Conflict and con-
organizational learning. Organization formity in institutional logics. Academy of
Science, 2(1): 125–34. Management Journal, 45(1): 81–101.
Sine, W. D., Haveman, H. A., & Tolbert, P. S. Tolbert, P. S. & Zucker, L. G. 1983. Institutional
2005. Risky business? Entrepreneurship sources of change in the formal structure of
in the new independent-power sector. organizations: The diffusion of civil service
Administrative Science Quarterly, 50(2): reform, 1880–1935. Administrative Science
200–32. Quarterly, 28(1): 22.
Sorensen, J. B. & Stuart, T. E. 2000. Aging, Westphal, J. D. & Zajac, E. J. 1994. Substance
obsolescence, and organizational innova- and symbolism in CEOs’ long-term incentive
tion. Administrative Science Quarterly, 45(1): plans. Administrative Science Quarterly,
81–112. 39(3): 367–90.
INSTITUTIONAL-LEVEL LEARNING: LEARNING AS A SOURCE OF INSTITUTIONAL CHANGE 649

Westphal, J. D., Gulati, R., & Shortell, S. M. Zimmerman, M. A. & Zeitz, G. J. 2002. Beyond
1997. Customization or conformity? An survival: Achieving new venture growth by
institutional and network perspective on the building legitimacy. Academy of Manage-
content and consequences of TQM adop- ment Review, 27(3): 414–31.
tion. Administrative Science Quarterly, 42(2): Zucker, L. G. 1977. The role of institutionaliza-
366–94. tion in cultural persistence. American
Zajac, E. J. & Westphal, J. D. 2004. Sociological Review, 42(5): 726–43.
The social construction of market Zucker, L. G. 1991. The role of institutionaliza-
value: Institutionalization and learning pers- tion in cultural persistence. In W. W. Powell
pectives on stock market reactions. & P. J. DiMaggio (eds.), The New Institution-
American Sociological Review, 69(3): alism in Organizational Analysis. Chicago, IL:
433–57. The University of Chicago Press.
27
Social Movements and
Institutional Analysis
Marc Schneiberg and Michael Lounsbury

Calls for reintroducing agency, politics and attention to actors and what they do, produc-
contestation into institutional analysis are now ing studies of ‘institutional entrepreneurs’
legion, spanning nearly two decades since (Beckert 1999; Hwang & Powell 2005;
DiMaggio’s (1988) classic piece, and gaining McGuire Hardy & Lawrence 2004; Hardy &
new urgency as scholars struggle to explain McGuire, Chapter 7 this volume) and institu-
institutional emergence and change. tional work (Lawrence and Suddaby 2006).
Institutionalists face persistent difficulties in Within this milieu, scholars have also sought
these tasks. Working from arguments about to overcome ‘excessive institutional determin-
isomorphism, diffusion, or path dependence, ism’ by turning to social movement theory and
they often invoke ad hoc explanations like the study of collective mobilization.
exogenous shocks in order to reconcile change Spanning sociology and political science,
and path creation with theories that stress the social movement theory has produced a
contextual sources of stability, continuity and wealth of concepts and research on change,
conformity (Greenwood & Hinings 1996; including studies of students organizing to
Clemens & Cook 1999; Campbell 2004; register black voters in the 1960s (McAdam
Streeck & Thelen 2005; Schneiberg 2005; 1988), the mobilization of farmers, workers
Guillén 2006). To address these difficulties, and women to make claims on the state
institutionalists have begun to revise both their (Clemens 1997), shareholder activism to
conceptions of fields and their views of action. contest managerial control over corporations
From a structural standpoint, some scholars (Davis & Thompson 1994), the growth of
increasingly view fields as comprising multi- identity movements pursuing peace, gay/les-
ple logics, or by indeterminacy, ambiguities or bian rights and environmentalism (e.g.,
contradictions, opening theoretical spaces for Laraña, Johnston, & Gusfield 1994), and the
action (Scott, Ruef, Mendel & Caronna 2000; rise of transnational pressure groups (Keck &
Stryker 1994, 2000; Seo & Creed 2002; Sikkink 1998). What these studies share is an
Schneiberg 2002, 2007; Lounsbury 2007; interest in contestation and collective mobi-
Marquis & Lounsbury 2007). Focusing more lization processes – how groups coalesce to
on agency, other scholars have brought new make claims for or against certain practices
SOCIAL MOVEMENTS AND INSTITUTIONAL ANALYSIS 651

or actors in order to create or resist new insti- of the same processes as critical for change,
tutional arrangements or transform existing including framing, theorization, transposi-
ones (McCarthy & Zald 1977). They also tion, and the recombination of logics. Yet
share an interest in tracing how contestation where institutional entrepreneurship research
and collective action rest on the capacity of often attributes substantial casual efficacy to
groups to mobilize resources and recruit mem- individuals, studies linking movements and
bers, their ability to engage in cultural entrepre- institutionalism are more deeply rooted in
neurship or frame issues to increase acceptance structural perspectives. They thus place
of their claims, and the political opportunity greater emphasis on politics and collective
structures that constrain or enable mobilization mobilization as motors of change, and more
(McAdam, McCarthy, & Zald 1996). This systematically address the relations between
chapter focuses on how engaging collective activity, collective organization and existing
mobilization and social movement theory has institutional contexts.
inspired new work in institutional analysis. Our central claim is that analyzing move-
The integration of movements into institu- ments within neo-institutional theory is
tional analysis has begun to revise existing essential for understanding when and how:
imageries of institutional processes, actors, (1) paths or fields become constituted around
and the structure of fields, generating new multiple, competing logics; and (2) multiple
leverage for explaining change and path logics, contradictions and ambiguities fuel
creation. Regarding processes, it adds con- field-level change and new path creation. In
testation, collective action, framing and making this claim, we accept, rather than dis-
self-conscious mobilization to conceptual miss, contextual arguments about durability,
repertoires of legitimation, diffusion, path dependence, and stability that give insti-
isomorphism and self-reproducing taken- tutionalism its analytical edge in explaining
for-granted practices (Jepperson 1991; continuity, differences or ‘higher order’
Colyvas & Powell 2006). Regarding actors, it effects on organizations (Schneiberg &
counter-poses challengers and champions of Clemens 2006). Institutions often exhibit
alternatives to standard accounts of states, increasing returns and positive feedbacks
professions and other incumbents as key (Pierson 2000). Actors empowered by exist-
players. Regarding structure, it moves away ing institutions use their advantages to elabo-
from images of an isomorphic institutional rate institutions in ways that preserve their
world of diffusion, path dependence and con- power and preclude alternatives. Diffusion,
formity toward conceptions of fields as sites adoption and the resulting communities of
of contestation, organized around multiple practice create isomorphic pressures that
and competing logics and forms (Kraatz & make conformity a condition for legitimacy,
Block, Chapter 9 this volume). fueling further diffusion. Institutionalized
As will be clear, work that integrates theories of order render alternatives unthink-
movements into neo-institutionalism paral- able, irrational or inefficient. And the preva-
lels work on institutional entrepreneurship in lence of taken-for-granted understandings
key respects (Hardy & McGuire, Chapter 7 means that even opposition occurs in those
this volume). Both emphasize agency, delib- terms, deepening the paths it contests.
erate or strategic action, and self-conscious In short, rather than simply assert an
mobilization around alternatives. Both wres- agentic, actor-centered institutionalism, we
tle with problems or paradoxes of how actors begin with the structural insight that limits on
embedded within institutions can change alternatives and pressures for continuity
those systems, how institutions limit or sup- or convergence often exercise considerable
port change, and how actors draw on the force. Reflexive action, the capacity to articu-
elements or contradictions of existing institu- late alternatives, the salience of multiple
tions to forge new ones. Both identify some logics, or their translation into change, cannot
652 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

be assumed. To the contrary, these are often structure and institutional mediation (e.g.,
fragile achievements which ultimately rest Amenta, Caruthers, & Zylan 1992; McAdam
on the emergence and efficacy of social 1999; Davis & Thompson 1994), prompting
movements. new insights about opportunity structures, a
Using existing and ongoing research, this reinvigoration of multi-level approaches, and
chapter outlines analytical strategies for new strategies for analyzing movements,
addressing the rise and effects of movements existing institutions and change. Taking a
on institutional fields. We pay particular decidedly cultural cast, these strategies
attention to how those strategies revise exist- reformulate arguments about political oppor-
ing institutional accounts of change and path tunity structures as institutional opportunity
creation. In parts I and II, we consider move- structures, highlighting how movements
ments as agents and infrastructures of and change are endogenously shaped by
change, outlining two emerging approaches institutions.
to what movements do and how they affect Based on these discussions, we turn in part
fields. One treats movements as forces IV to suggest new directions for research on
against institutions; that is, as forces operat- how movements and institutional dynamics
ing outside established channels to assert combine to produce change. One key direc-
new visions and disrupt or directly contest tion is methodological: to develop clearer,
existing arrangements, evoking legitimacy more direct measures of movements and to
crises, sense-making and other institutional exploit the analytical leverage of multivariate
processes within fields. This approach approaches. This will help assess and sys-
revises two canons in institutional theory – tematize claims from qualitative and histori-
the two-stage model of institutionalization cal work about movement effects and the
and histories of change as punctuated equi- relations between movements, institutional
librium. It also provides insights into how contexts and outcomes.
fields become constituted around multiple A second direction is to analyze move-
logics. ments as a political condition for diffusion
A second approach considers the rise and and other institutional processes. Insofar as
impact of movements within fields, examin- alternatives are contested or suppressed by
ing movements as institutional forces or vested interests, their diffusion will depend
infrastructures for institutional processes on collective action and the mobilization of
including theorization, recombination and power by champions of new practices and
diffusion. This approach reveals how diffu- forms. In cases like these, movements can
sion, translation and adoption are contested, moderate institutional processes, supporting
political processes that often depend on col- diffusion or translation in three ways:
lective action. It also sheds light on how by serving as field-wide or cross-field mech-
movements emerge from and exploit contra- anisms for mobilizing power, by working
dictions or multiple logics within fields to as political forces within organizations
mobilize support, forge new paths or produce to increase their receptivity to alternatives,
change. or by working between organizations to
In part III, we turn from movements as increase innovators’ influence as exemplars.
agents of change to analyses of how contexts Taking this approach to how movements
shape contestation and collective action. operate in fields can help explain the diffu-
Institutionalists have recognized that existing sion of alternatives and more diverse sets of
institutions constrain and enable mobiliza- outcomes related to practice variation.
tion, create openings for challengers, and Finally, we consider the origins of move-
shape their capacities to produce change. ments and institutions, taking an historical
This has led neo-institutionalists to the move- approach and considering the relationship
ments literature on political opportunity between institutions and movements as an
SOCIAL MOVEMENTS AND INSTITUTIONAL ANALYSIS 653

ongoing process in which combinations or model of institutionalization, the emergence


sequences of movements cumulatively pro- of new paths or fields is a ‘bottom up’ phe-
duce change. Movements might figure in the nomenon: (1) organizations or states adopt
production of unintended and incremental structures or policies in response to local
trajectories of change. That is, even when problems, politics or characteristics, which
they are defeated or their time has passed, then spark (2) processes of mimesis, theo-
movements may leave legacies, elements of rization and diffusion, eventually crystalliz-
institutional orders and bits and pieces of ing a broader community of practice around
paths not taken, producing diffuse but impor- a core set of principles or models (Tolbert &
tant effects, and creating possibilities for sub- Zucker 1983; Baron, Dobbin, & Jennings
sequent movements, institution-building and 1986; Galaskeiewz & Wasserman 1989;
transformation (Schneiberg 2007). Focusing Strang & Chang 1993). As solutions diffuse,
on these possibilities sheds further light on they become taken-for-granted as an
how movements and their effects are endoge- accepted norm, serving as baselines to which
nously produced, helping researchers avoid organizations must subsequently conform as
the trap of invoking movements, like exoge- a condition for legitimacy. In punctuated
nous shocks, as a deus ex machina. equilibrium models, change occurs as a
sequence of shock, disruption, deinstitution-
alization, and reinstitutionalization (Edelman
1990, 2006; Fligstein 1990, 2001; Sutton
MOVEMENTS AGAINST et al. 1994; Sutton & Dobbin 1996). Shocks
INSTITUTIONS: CHALLENGER/ like new laws or court rulings subvert exist-
DOMINANCE APPROACHES ing routines, vested interests and established
understandings, evoking uncertainty, sense-
One way to integrate movements into institu- making and a succession of players and
tional research preserves the analytical dis- models as new groups emerge to define the
tinction between movements, contestation and situation and establish their solutions as new
deliberate mobilization, on the one hand, and bases of order.
institutional processes like the reproduction of Both models shed light on key institutional
taken-for-granted practices, on the other, processes: (1) mutual monitoring, mimesis
taking movements as an ‘extra-institutional’ and the diffusion or transposition of practices
force for change or new path creation. This across organizations; (2) theorization, codifi-
approach hardly exhausts the possible rela- cation or the endorsement of best practices
tions between movements and institutions. by professional associations; and (3) inter-
But it captures the potentially wide class of ventions by states to ratify, redraw or reject
cases where movements arise outside of or field boundaries and emerging solutions
on the peripheries of established fields, (e.g., Strang & Meyer 1993). Yet both tend to
acting as outsider-challengers to assert new neglect the origins of new ideas and practices
visions of order, disrupt existing systems, or as well as the sources of disruption, leaving
secure policies or representation from estab- key players and processes unanalyzed.
lished authorities. Thinking in these terms However, in many canonical cases featuring
also extends the institutional framework to isomorphism, the instigating shocks or moti-
highlight key processes left exogenous by vations for adoption were the direct and
existing accounts of emergence and change, deliberate results of social movements –
opening up the black-box of ‘pre-institutional’ municipal reformers and progressives fight-
dynamics, and adding new imageries and ing corruption in city government, civil
mechanisms to our conceptual repertoire. rights activists demanding state intervention
Consider two canonical formulations in to end discrimination, and agrarian populists
neo-institutional analysis. In the two-stage contesting corporate consolidation.
654 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Schneiberg and Soule’s (2005) study of professions endorsed regulation, promul-


rate regulation in insurance develops one gated model laws, and built field-wide
model of the role of movements in the insti- administrative organs. Taken together, these
tutionalization process, filling in gaps in the institutional processes shifted the balance of
canonical accounts. It conceptualizes institu- power within states, crystallizing insurance
tions as political settlements. And it analyzes around economic models and regulatory
path creation as a contested process solutions that settled political struggles over
grounded in sequences of mobilization, dis- industry governance (see also Schneiberg
ruption and conventional institutional 1999, 2002; Schneiberg & Bartley 2001).
dynamics, tracing how mobilization outside Rao, Clemens and Hoffman also go
established channels catalyzes path creation beyond canonical accounts by foregrounding
and change. Specifically, their study shows movements, understanding paths as political
how rate regulation by American states in the settlements, or analyzing path creation as
early twentieth century was provoked neither sequences of movements, mobilization and
by exogenous shocks, nor by scattered and institutional processes. Rao (1998) shows
unconnected politics or problem-solving how the consumer watchdog agencies and
behavior. Rather, it was sparked by anti-cor- product rating schemes that are now taken-
porate movements, including the Grange and for-granted in the US emerged from con-
Farmers Alliance who worked to contest cor- sumer mobilization and contestation over
porate consolidation and assert alternative whether scientific testing and the power of
forms of economic order. This mobilization informed consumers should be blended with
was a response to the rise of ‘trusts’ and the role of labor, unionization and concerns
‘combines’ in various sectors. Grangers and about production conditions. At first, con-
other groups directly opposed ‘corporate sumer groups fought for two different
liberal’ models of order based on for-profit logics of market reform, one that blended
corporations, national markets and unregu- consumer advocacy with unionism and one
lated industry. Instead, they pursued ‘pro- that focused more narrowly on the consumer.
ducer republican’ logics that envisioned But broader political dynamics eliminated
American capitalism as a regionally decen- the more comprehensive radical change
tralized and cooperatively organized frame from the path, segregating ‘consumer’
economy of independent producers, farmers and ‘worker,’ and ensuring the dominance of
and self-governing towns. Moreover, a consumer-only impartial testing logic
in targeting insurance, Grangers and other (see Carruthers & Babb 1996 for a similar
groups secured anti-compact laws to analysis of monetary systems).
break up the ‘insurance trust,’ organized con- Clemens (1993, 1997) more directly
sumer-owned mutual firms, and otherwise addresses how change flows from combina-
disrupted insurance markets, fueling legiti- tions of movements and institutional
macy crises, public hearings, and new processes, tracing how interest group politics
interventions within key states. became a core feature of the American polity
These disruptions and interventions, in through successive waves of mobilization
turn, sparked politics and conventional insti- and transposition by three outsider/chal-
tutional processes within the insurance field. lenger groups. Acting collectively to contest
They evoked inter-state diffusion in which parties and patronage, first unions, then
key players monitored other states, theorized farmers, and then women’s groups built on
rate regulation as a solution to the ‘insurance previous efforts to disrupt existing arrange-
problem,’ recombined elements to forge ments (strikes, boycotts, protests) by trans-
those solutions and adopted laws passed by posing fraternals, cooperatives, clubs and
other states. They also evoked supra-state or other kinds of apolitical associations into
field-wide process in which courts and the mainstream politics. These sequences of
SOCIAL MOVEMENTS AND INSTITUTIONAL ANALYSIS 655

actions fundamentally altered the terms of involved a clear cut victory of one logic of
political representation and influence, consumerism over other.
creating access and clout for previously dis- Second, these studies suggest an image of
enfranchised groups and institutionalizing the process of institutionalization as a
lobbying, legislative monitoring, and other sequence or interaction between contestation
now taken-for-granted modes of American and mobilization around alternatives, on the
politics. one hand, and more conventional institutional
Hoffman’s (1999) study of environmental- dynamics, on the other. In insurance, chal-
ism likewise finds that movements and insti- lengers mobilized outside the system to contest
tutional dynamics play pivotal roles in field the ‘insurance combine’ and forcibly impose
creation and change. Here, conflicts over alternative forms and anti-trust policies on the
competing institutions and successive rounds industry. Regulators and reformers within the
of environmental mobilization, scandal and field responded, in turn, by theorizing, endors-
legislative activity provoked new forms of ing and diffusing regulatory policies which
discourse, theorization, and new patterns of recombined multiple forms into new packages.
interactions among firms, non-profits and Multiple dynamics likewise figured in the case
governments. These dynamics, in turn, of American state building, where farmers,
helped produce an increasingly structured unions and women’s groups progressively
environmental field. institutionalized modern interest group politics
As a group, these studies substantially in the US via successive waves of mobiliza-
revise canonical accounts of path creation tion, contestation and translation
and change. First, they support a view of Third, these studies provide a more varied
institutions as settlements of political strug- understanding of how movements fuel path
gles over the character of fields fueled by the creation and change by mobilizing outside
mobilization of challengers around compet- established channels to contest extant sys-
ing projects and logics (Davis & Thompson tems. At a minimum, by introducing multiple
1994; Fligstein 1996, 2001; McAdam & logics and promoting awareness of problems,
Scott 2005; Armstrong 2005). Emphasizing challenger movements subvert the taken-
contestation and collective action, this view for-grantedness of existing arrangements,
departs from ‘cooler’ imageries of paths as fueling legitimacy crises and institutional
based mainly in diffusion, taken-for-granted politics (Stryker 2000), and providing insid-
practices, theorization and normative ers with cultural resources for criticism,
endorsement by professions or states. Thus, reflexive action or ‘mindful deviation’
insurance rate regulation represented a polit- (Garud & Karnoe 2001). Thus, as anti-
ical solution of struggles between insurers, corporate forces, consumers and women’s
who pursued economic logics of corpora- groups took action and asserted new logics,
tions, markets and unregulated industry they not only evoked media attention and
associations, and challenger groups, who public debate, creating openings for chal-
sought anti-trust laws, regulation and mutual lengers and reformers to delegitimate domi-
alternatives to promote decentralized and co- nant institutional systems. They also supplied
operatively organized economies. Conflicts experts, reformers and other groups with
over these visions yielded structural innova- models and cultural resources for criticizing
tions, but were not resolved until field and revising extant paths such as by combining
members crafted packages that combined or layering them with new forms and elements.
regulation with private association, and Moreover, challenger movements are often
mutuals with for-profit corporations. The carriers of new organizational forms, and can
consumer advocacy field likewise reflected a work around or outside established channels
settlement of struggles and mobilization to build parallel, alternative systems of
around competing logics, albeit one which organizations (Rao, Morrill & Zald 2000;
656 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Carroll & Swaminathan 2000; Schneiberg Simple in its essentials, a conception that
2002; Schneiberg, King & Smith 2008). emphasizes sequences of outsider movements,
These efforts may not be disruptive in intent. mobilization and institutional processes has
Yet promoting alternative forms can foster supported increasingly sophisticated analyses
new competitive dynamics and populate of path creation and change. As we show in
fields with instances of new logics. By trans- part III, a ‘movements against institutions’
lating apolitical forms of association into conception lends itself readily to multi-level
state, agrarians, unions and women’s groups analyses of fields, and to consideration of how
altered both the terms of competition in existing institutions or political opportunity
American politics and prevailing conceptions structures shape challengers’ capacities to
of appropriate political action. By promul- mobilize and effect change. Yet this concep-
gating mutual insurance, Grangers and other tion does not exhaust the ways that move-
groups both instantiated cooperativism and ments figure as agents of path creation and
transformed the terms of economic competi- change.
tion in a key sector, forcing insurance corpo-
rations to engage in new forms of rivalry
based on prevention, re-reengineering and
loss reduction. And by introducing the sci- MOVEMENTS WITHIN INSTITUTIONS:
ence-based, not-for-profit product testing COLLECTIVE MOBILIZATION AS
agency, the consumer movement transformed INSTITUTIONAL PROCESS
the terms of trade throughout the economy.
Furthermore, challenger movements can Groups seeking change often mobilize col-
mobilize masses, networks and political sup- lectively outside established institutions to
port to pressure states and other power cen- assert new logics and disrupt taken-for-
ters for new agencies, laws and policies that granted arrangements. Yet institutionalists
ban or mandate practices. As scholars have have recognized movements also arise within
shown, the uncertainties or prohibitions asso- institutions or fields, mobilizing insiders as
ciated with new laws, agencies, and man- well as outsiders, using established networks
dates can profoundly destabilize existing and resources to diffuse alternative practices,
systems, fueling sustained institutional and drawing effectively on existing institu-
dynamics (Fligstein 1990; Edelman 1992; tional elements and models to craft new sys-
Dobbin & Dowd 1997; Hoffman 1999). tems (see Fligstein 1996, 2001). Indeed,
Finally, outsider groups like ACT UP and while movements can drive change by
Earth First! can and do use protests, boycotts directly opposing existing schemes, generat-
and direct actions to dramatize problems and ing legitimacy crises or otherwise disrupting
directly disrupt daily operations and routines institutions, they sometimes promote path
(Elsbach & Sutton 1992; Hoffman 1999). In creation and change incrementally by engag-
all of these ways, movements can fuel path ing in institutional processes (or becoming
creation and change as political-cultural institutional forces). That is, movements can
forces for contestation, confrontation and emerge and operate within established chan-
disruption. Instantiating new logics, they can nels and power structures, drawing on exist-
evoke controversy and debate within fields, ing institutions and taken-for-granted
conflicts and policy responses within organi- understandings to theorize, articulate and
zations, inter-organizational diffusion and combine new projects or practices with pre-
field-wide association, while supplying vailing models and arrangements. In so
insiders and reformers with templates, politi- doing, movements may themselves become
cal support and cultural resources for theo- vehicles or established channels for diffu-
rization, transposition, recombination and sion, theorization, recombination and other
the assembly of new institutions. institutional processes within fields.
SOCIAL MOVEMENTS AND INSTITUTIONAL ANALYSIS 657

This broader conception of movements established channels, working independently


risks a loss of analytical specificity and a of and against the waste industry to organize
diminished focus on contesting power struc- thousands of local non-profit, drop-off
tures, especially where movements become recycling centers. Such efforts were part of
synonymous with collective or quasi-collec- a broader project to restructure capitalism.
tive action geared toward any type of change They were articulated within a holistic
(Scully & Segal 2002; Scully & Creed 2005). frame that theorized recycling as a way to
Yet analyzing movements as intra-institu- rebuild community, create local closed-loop
tional forces productively blurs distinctions production and consumption, and reduce
between ‘extra-institutional’ and ‘institu- community dependence on conglomerates
tional,’ ‘mobilization’ and ‘self-reproducing’ and capitalist commodity systems. Yet the
process, or ‘contentious’ versus ‘conven- commitment of industry and state agencies to
tional’ politics. It has led to new insights a resource recovery logic which emphasized
about parallels between institutional phe- landfill, waste-to-energy programs and
nomena and collective action processes stud- large-scale incineration left the recycling
ied by movement scholars (Campbell 2005; movement isolated and its centers without
Strang & Jung 2005; Davis & Zald 2005; outlets for materials.
Wade, Swaminathan & Saxon 1998). It has In fact, a viable infrastructure for recycling
led to new understandings of the relations did not emerge until activists, working
between movements and institutions, includ- through the National Recycling Coalition,
ing how institutional reproduction and diffu- entered mainstream policy negotiations,
sion depend on mobilization, political forged ties with solid waste handlers, and
resources and contestation (Thelen 2004; retheorized recycling as a for-profit service
Hargrave & Van de Ven 2006). It supports that built on curbside programs and comple-
research that goes beyond analyzing move- mented landfills and incineration. Coupled
ments as ‘extra-institutional’ producers of with grass-roots mobilization against new
multiple logics to consider also how move- incinerators, and negotiations with state
ments and contestation are products of – and agencies to buy recycled materials, theoriz-
mobilize – contradictions and multiple ing recyclables as commodities transformed
models within fields (Strkyer 2000; Seo & cultural beliefs and discourse about waste in
Creed 2002; Morrill 2006). And it has let the industry, creating institutional conditions
institutionalists interested in movements sup- for diffusing recycling practices (see also
plement images of change as disruption, con- Strang & Meyer 1993; Strang & Soule 1998;
flict and settlement with analyses of how King, Cornwall, & Dahlin 2005).
movements also work in an incremental and In addition, environmental movements
embedded fashion, producing trajectories also served as institutional forces by operat-
of path creation or change as reconfiguration, ing inside organizations (see Zald & Berger
recombination or layering (Clemens & 1978 for an early statement on movements
Cook 1999; Streeck & Thelen 2005; within organizations). The Student
Schneiberg 2007). Environmental Action Coalition promoted
Lounsbury and colleagues’ studies of recycling within universities by codifying
recycling address how movements can arguments, building inter-collegiate net-
enter into and operate within fields as institu- works and disseminating standardized argu-
tional forces, emphasizing their role as ments and facts about similar programs
agents of theorization, classification, and elsewhere. And the College and University
the diffusion of codified arguments or Recycling Coordinators provided universi-
frames (Lounsbury 2001, 2005: Lounsbury, ties and colleges with standards and classifi-
Ventresca, & Hirsch 2003). Initially, cation schemes for measuring the progress,
eco-activists pursued recycling outside costs and benefits of programs, which helped
658 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

deepen discourse and theorization of recy- early efforts supported the mobilization
cling as a rational economic activity. Thus, as of two competing critical masses of ADR
Greenwood, Suddaby and Hinings (2002) activists – one around a ‘community media-
document for professional associations, tion’ model, the other around the ‘multi-door
social movements can create cultural and courthouse.’
theoretical foundations for new activities, Both groups devoted considerable energy
forms and fields (see also Moore 1996, and into theorizing and disseminating their
Frickel & Gross 2005 for examples of move- approach, holding conferences, publishing
ments among scientific professionals). They manifestos in prominent law journals and
can operate within existing power structures seeking support from foundation or other
as agents of theorization, classification and established centers. Both also worked hard to
diffusion, and can themselves become infra- articulate and recombine their models with
structures for those processes within fields. prevailing models and institutions, including
Indeed, as recycling became institutional- the ‘Great Society’ vision of federally
ized, the movement itself blurred into profes- funded community social programs and the
sional associationalism. Activists became increasingly ascendant new federalism.
recycling employees; employees used the Moreover, once advocates could articulate
National Recycling Coalition to form a pro- ADR with the divorce revolution and
fessional association; and the association no-fault divorce as a non-adversarial solution
forged new identities, statuses and proce- to custody and interpersonal problems, they
dures for recycling managers within the gained a lever for professionalizing media-
new field. tion and diffusing its practices. They used
Research by Morrill, Creed, Scully, conferences, new organizations, instructional
and Moore on the institutionalization of videos, newsletters, and the like to further
alternative dispute resolution, domestic codify and disseminate ADR, effectively lay-
partner benefits, and public science, ering ADR into the legal system as an
likewise document how movements operate increasingly taken-for-granted complement
as forces within mainstream institutions, to conventional legal arrangements.
de-emphasizing confrontational tactics in Creed, Scully and colleagues’ studies of
favor of their role as agents or vehicles gay rights/GLBT activists shed additional
for recombination, assembly, translation light on how movements working within
and diffusion. In Morrill’s (2006) study existing institutions can help establish new
of alternative dispute resolution (ADR), practices by exploiting contradiction and
mobilization for alternatives and contestation multiple logics, importing or redeploying
themselves rested fundamentally on the logics across settings, and articulating or
presence and recombination of multiple recombining new elements with prevailing
logics of practice in the socio-legal field. models, myths or concerns (Creed & Scully
In this case, institutional processes of 2000; Creed, Scull, & Austin 2002; Scully &
bricolage, hybridization and innovation Segal 2002; Scully & Creed 2005; see also
preceded broader mobilization. Lawyers, Raeburn 2004). Decisive here were activists’
social workers, community activists use of contradiction and recombination to
and judges working at the interstices or disturb taken-for-granted assumptions, high-
overlaps between fields during the light injustice, and legitimate claims for
1960s drew in an ad hoc fashion on ther- reform. For example, activists strategically
apeutic techniques, community mediation, deployed identity in face-to-face encounters
and other forms of non-adversarial nego- with co-workers and supervisors. They used
tiating to help process minor disputes casual mentions of partners’ gendered names
in small claims, family and other courts. when sharing experiences of mundane activ-
As the ‘litigation crisis’ deepened, these ities and enacted non-stereotypical behavior
SOCIAL MOVEMENTS AND INSTITUTIONAL ANALYSIS 659

to challenge stigma. They also employed nar- by anti-war and environmental groups
ratives of discrimination or inequality to for their connections to the military and
highlight hypocrisies, evoking understand- chemical industry, but they also began to
ings that everyday routines produce injustice, criticize themselves and their peers for these
and activating listeners’ identities as non- connections.
prejudiced persons. At first, activists tried to link science and
In addition, activists used their knowledge politics and mobilize for change within estab-
and status as insiders and loyal corporate cit- lished science associations. But mixing parti-
izens to couch reforms like domestic partner sanship and ‘pure science’ produced public
benefits as good business practice or expres- discord within the scientific community and
sions of firms’ espoused commitments to directly challenged its legitimacy as an impar-
diversity. Furthermore, like those fighting for tial, objective producer of facts. This led sci-
the federal Employment Non-Discrimination entist-activists to create a hybrid form – the
Act, activists within firms imported higher public science organization – that resolved
order logics or frames, articulating domestic this tension by recombining science and
partner benefits and other gay-friendly poli- politics in novel ways. Through dedicated
cies with broader civil rights frames, values organizations like the Union for Concerned
of fairness and equality, corporate social Scientists and Scientists’ Institute for Public
responsibility, and concerns with competi- Information, scientists could provide nuclear
tiveness in an increasingly diverse world. In safety information, challenge non-scientists’
a sense, GLBT movements worked for uses of science, and address the public inter-
change by simultaneously coming out and est without risking their credibility as scien-
fitting in; that is, by carefully articulating and tists by acting in openly partisan ways.
combining difference, assertions of GLBT Moreover, hybrid organizations separate
identity and new practices with ‘normal’ from professional and political associations
everyday life, insider identities as dutiful cor- provided activists with a vehicle for public
porate citizens, and ongoing organizational science that directed attention away from
concerns. Here too, diffusion of new prac- the inner workings of the scientific commu-
tices like domestic partner benefits was a nity, letting scientists mobilize politically
political process, resting on mobilization, without calling their legitimacy as scientists
contestation, framing and the recombination into question or sparking conflict within
of prevailing models and cultural elements in professional communities.
and across firms. All of these studies highlight rich opportu-
As Moore shows, the institutionalization of nities for exploring the role of movements
public science organizations in American pol- within existing institutions and organiza-
itics also rested critically on multiple logics, tions. In general, social life is rife with col-
mobilization by insiders, and the role of lective mobilization, and whether these
movements as bricoleur-agents of recombina- efforts are made by challengers working as
tion and redeployment (Moore 1996; Moore outsiders to redefine existing arrangements,
& Hala 2002). During the 1960s and 1970s, insiders seeking change from within, or elites
university scientists faced increasingly severe striving to keep existing structures intact
contradictions between the logic of public (Fligstein 1990, 1996), a focus on move-
service or social utility, on the one hand, ments expands our understanding of institu-
and the logics of objectivity, non-partisanship tional dynamics. Moreover, mobilization can
and detachment as scientists, on the other. In occur at the level of the field as with anti-cor-
fact, extant ways of joining science and poli- porate forces or ecological activists promot-
tics – serving the public interest by serving ing communitarian alternatives to corporate
the state – had become distinct liabilities. capitalism and with scientists forging new
University scientists not only faced attacks associations to link expertise to politics.
660 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Or it can occur within and between organiza- begun to theorize how multiple logics within
tions as recycling advocates pressed for fields can motivate contestation and collec-
more substantive forms of recycling or as gay tive action (Stryker 2000; Seo & Creed 2002;
and lesbian groups pushed for recognition Morrill 2006), they have also considered how
and benefits. A focus on movements, existing institutional contexts shape mobi-
therefore, sheds new light on path creation lization and movements’ capacities for pro-
and change, particularly when it attends to ducing change. Indeed, addressing relations
the multi-level character of the institutional between movements, institutional contexts
context. and outcomes lays the foundation for more
To be sure, the distinction between move- sophisticated analyses of power and agency.
ments operating outside and inside fields It lets scholars go beyond simple power elite
raises questions for future work about their or interest group arguments about agency
different enabling conditions, trajectories or and change to consider how extant institu-
effects. Insiders will more likely pursue dif- tions block access, provide challengers with
ferent tactics and forms of contestation than levers and openings, and otherwise condition
outsider groups. They will likely mobilize actors’ ability to translate numbers, resources
collectively in different ways, frame or organization into change. Moreover, in
problems and solutions differently, and dif- exploring relations between movements,
ferentially negotiate or exploit structures, contexts and outcomes, institutionalists have
networks and institutional frames provided made good use of research on political oppor-
by established fields. And they may be tunity structure (McAdam 1999; Tarrow 1998;
more likely to err on the conservative side. McAdam, Tarrow, & Tilly 2002) and related
Conversely, outsiders pursuing disruptive arguments about institutional mediation
activities face legitimacy dilemmas that may (Amenta, Carruthers, & Zylan 1992; Amenta
pressure them to mobilize as insiders, articu- & Zylan 1991) and institutional contingency
late their projects with existing institutional (Thornton & Occasio 1999; Bartley &
logics, or form separate, decoupled organiza- Schneiberg 2002; Schneiberg & Clemens
tions for disruptive and conventional action 2006; Lounsbury 2007), supporting a deepen-
(Elsbach & Sutton 1992; Lipsky 1968). And, ing integration of movements research and
as we suggest in part IV, we can also prof- neo-institutional analysts.
itably consider how outsider and insider Work at this interface has identified vari-
movements occur in waves or sequences, ous features, institutional and political fields
producing historical trajectories of change. that condition movement dynamics or suc-
Fortunately, future work on both kinds of cess. These include the legacies of prior
movements can exploit existing research on policies, the receptivity of institutional
how institutional contexts shape mobilization authorities toward challengers’ claims, the
and movement efficacy. concentration of resources within a field, and
the prevalence of certain cultural models.
Work on contexts has also shown how the
multi-level character of fields provides open-
INSTITUTIONAL FIELDS AS CONTEXTS ings for challengers, and how movements
FOR MOVEMENTS evoke counter-movements within fields.
Davis and colleagues’ studies of shareholder
While the work just described provides rich movements nicely document how success may
depictions of movements as agents of institu- hinge on the institutional context (Davis &
tional creation and change, analysts of ‘out- Thompson 1994; Davis & Greve 1997; Davis
sider’ and ‘insider’ movements have also paid & McAdam 2000; Vogus & Davis 2005).
careful attention to the institutional context During the 1980s, shareholder activists
of social movements. They have not only mobilized to promote new conceptions of the
SOCIAL MOVEMENTS AND INSTITUTIONAL ANALYSIS 661

corporation, transform the markets for corpo- culture shapes mobilization and change.
rate control, and break the hold of vested Some of the studies discussed above high-
managerial interests over large US firms. To light how institutionalized models or logics
this end, shareholder groups formed new represent cultural resources for mobilization,
organizations, launched takeover actions framing and change. So does research by
against individual firms, used existing gover- Lounsbury and Hironaka, Schofer and Frank.
nance machinery to oust entrenched man- Shifts in the recycling field from a radical,
agers, and sought legislative and regulatory holistic logic to a technocratic logic facili-
changes, relying on their considerable mate- tated the creation of recycling advocacy
rial resources and connections. Yet activists’ groups in urban regions in response to con-
ability to translate resources into change was test waste management through incineration
institutionally and organizationally medi- (Lounsbury 2005). More broadly, the diffu-
ated. The concentration of assets held by sion of environmentalism as a global blue-
institutional investors provided shareholder print for the nation state has enhanced the
activists with critical leverage in firm-level capacity of domestic environmental activists
conflicts with management over the control to organize and slow environmental degrada-
of corporations. The SEC’s review of proxy, tion (Frank, Hironaka & Schofer 2000;
rules weakened managers’ ability to control Hironaka & Schofer 2002; Schofer &
votes and signaled a favorable regulatory Hironaka 2005). As these studies suggest,
stance toward shareholders and corporate formal mechanisms (e.g., environmental
reform. State governments that were heavily impact assessments) and the prevalence of
dependent on franchise fees for incorporation global environmentalism as a valued cultural
were reluctant to alienate shareholder groups model have legitimated environmental move-
by passing anti-takeover statutes that would ments, fueling organization, while creating
deprive shareholders of a key weapon. And rhetorical and procedural opportunities for
prosperity made it harder for vested interests activists to point out failures and pursue legal
to use fears of economic ruin to mobilize actions.
political support for anti-takeover legislation. Research on movements and institutional
Soule and her colleagues likewise trace contexts has also documented how the
how the ability of the women’s movement to multi-level or federated character of institu-
secure equal rights amendments from tions sometimes creates opportunities for
American states rested on political and insti- movements. The multi-level nature of fields
tutional opportunity structures (Soule & is central to institutionalist imageries
Olzak 2004; Soule & King 2006). of context (Scott 2001; Schneiberg &
Mobilization for equal rights amendments Clemens 2006), and bears directly on move-
was more likely to result in ratification ments’ capacities to produce change.
in states with a high level of electoral As Davis and colleagues’ analyses of share-
competitiveness, extensive histories of prior holder activism show, challengers sometimes
civil rights legislation, and favorable have to mobilize simultaneously at multiple
(Democratic) allies in power. It was also levels within fields to assert new models and
more effective in public opinion climates effect change (Davis & Thompson 1994;
characterized by the prevalence of new con- Davis et al. 1994; Davis & Greve 1997;
ceptions of women’s roles in private and Vogus & Davis 2005). Shareholder
public spheres. groups were mainly interested in promoting
Findings that public opinion climates new conceptions of the corporation and
enhance prospects for movements are partic- contesting entrenched management at the
ularly noteworthy here, as they move beyond firm (‘lower order’) level. But they quickly
traditional realist formulations about politi- found that they had to take the fight to the
cal opportunity structure to consider how state and federal level. Influencing these
662 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

‘higher order’ units were essential for chal- programs while schools without movements
lengers’ ability to make change, since state tended to adopt a more minimalist approach
and federal laws set the terms for mobiliza- that was staffed by part-time custodial
tion and access at the firm-level, defining staff (Lounsbury 2001). Moreover, ecologi-
rules for proxy systems, takeovers and cal activists were better able to gain
whether shareholders could act collectively. footholds for securing programs at larger
By blocking anti-takeover legislation, secur- college and universities with more resources,
ing new proxy rules, and so on, shareholder selective colleges with histories of
activism at state and federal levels created activism, and universities with environmen-
critical opportunities for mobilization against tal majors that could serve as local allies
and within corporations. or institutional conduits for field-level
The fractured and multi-level structure of pressures.
institutions also enabled anti-corporate Finally, researchers attending to context
groups to get insurance rate regulation on the have also found that outcomes are shaped by
states’ agenda in the early twentieth century whether or not initial movements catalyze
(Schneiberg & Soule 2005; Schneiberg & counter-movements within fields. Vogus and
Bartley 2001; Schneiberg 1999). Challengers Davis’ (2005) study of anti-takeover legisla-
seeking decentralized, producer republican tion takes one step in this direction by ana-
models of economic development were lyzing how managerial and local elites
largely closed out of policy making and counter-organized in response to shareholder
had little leverage for their regulatory ambi- activism to obtain legislation that protected
tions in New York, Connecticut and other corporate managers from raiders and hostile
centers of the ‘insurance combine.’ But the takeovers. Soule and colleagues’ analyses go
more peripheral, agrarian states proved more one step further. In analyzing states’ adoption
open to populist pressures, enabling agrarian of the Equal Rights Amendment, they simul-
and independent producers to assert statist taneously include variables for the presence
regulatory measures in the insurance field, or strength of women’s movement groups
disrupt markets, and organize mutuals. (NOW and AAUW) and anti-ERA organiza-
Insurers tried to close off access entirely by tions (Soule & Olzak 2004; Soule & King
suing in state and federal courts to void 2005). Similarly, in modeling the passage of
states’ rights to regulate insurance prices. anti-hate crime laws, they include counts of
Yet, that strategy backfired when advocates pro-gay community organizations and
of regulation found an unexpected ally in community centers, on the one hand, and
the US Supreme Court, which opened the measures of conservative group lobbying
door for further intervention in states by and the presence of a Family Policy
ruling that insurance was ‘affected with a Council, on the other (Soule 2004). Ingram
public interest’ and thus subject to the states’ and Rao (2004) also think in terms of move-
authority. ments and counter-movements, but elaborate
Indeed, the multi-level character of fields a different research strategy, analyzing the
creates possibilities for movements to couple passage and then the repeal of legislation
field-level and intra-organizational mobiliza- banning chain stores as indicies of populist
tion, with the characteristics of organizations mobilization and chain store counter-
serving as opportunity structures that shape mobilization over the rise of new market
the capacities of movements within organiza- forms. In this way also, the capacities of
tions to produce change. For example, uni- movements to promote change or new path
versities and colleges that had previously creation rests not just on size, resources or
experienced recycling activism on campus movement strength, but also on the structure
hired full-time ecologically-committed coor- and dynamics of the political and institu-
dinators and created full-blown recycling tional context.
SOCIAL MOVEMENTS AND INSTITUTIONAL ANALYSIS 663

SOCIAL MOVEMENTS AND There are substantial methodological chal-


NEO-INSTITUTIONAL THEORY: lenges involved in documenting movement
FUTURE DIRECTIONS effects on path creation and institutional
change, challenges that literally multiply as
We conclude our review by discussing new researchers address the moderating influence
frontiers for analyzing combinations of insti- of existing institutional contexts. At a mini-
tutional process and social movements as mum, documenting movement effects
sources of path creation and change. Future depends on credibly measuring the develop-
work, we suggest, can and should attend more ment, strength and activities of challenger
carefully to key methodological issues of movements. Existing research linking move-
measurement and modeling. It can also fruit- ments, organizations and institutions has
fully consider how movements produce made real progress here, using the presence
change as political forces or conditions for dif- of movement organization or chapters,
fusion, while simultaneously addressing how counts of movement organizations, and the
movements are endogenously produced and number of movement members to document
always institutionally conditioned. Such an movement emergence and strength (e.g.,
approach captures the substantial benefits of Lounsbury 2001; Schneiberg 2002; Soule &
introducing contestation and collective action King 2006). It also suggests that future work
into institutional analysis. But it does so while can more directly tap such effects by measur-
avoiding the traps of either invoking move- ing protests and other movement activity, or
ments as extra-institutional forces or simply by using newspaper coverage, public hear-
using movements to assert agency and aban- ings or other measures of controversy to
don institutional context entirely. Such an assess whether movements have been able
approach, in other words, engages, rather than to force issues or new conceptions onto the
avoids, the paradoxes of embeddedness and public agenda or call existing arrangements
analytical impasses involved in explaining into question.
path creation and change (Seo & Creed 2002; Documenting movement effects also rests
Schneiberg 2007). We begin with a discussion critically on using movement research and
of methodological issues, and then emphasize multivariate approaches to isolate and disen-
two major substantive categories for future tangle the effects of movement strength or
research – the outcomes of movements and the activity, mobilizing structures, framing, and
origins of institutions and movements. institutional or political opportunity struc-
tures (for exemplars, see Vogus & Davis
2005 and Soule & King 2006). Absent multi-
Measuring and modeling variate designs or careful comparative analy-
movements sis, inferences about movement effects on
change remain vulnerable to counterclaims
Much of the work on movements from a neo- about spurious relations.
institutional perspective has relied on quali- Furthermore, designing research that
tative and historical methods, playing to attends explicitly to multiple factors is partic-
those methods’ strengths in theory construc- ularly important for addressing how existing
tion and producing a rich body of theory and institutions and opportunity structures
thick descriptions. Supplementing qualitative enhance or undermine movements’ capaci-
work with multivariate quantitative research ties for influence, disruption and new path
can not only help systematize theory con- creation. Research on institutions or political
struction in important ways, it can also help opportunity structures sometimes analyzes
clarify causal relations, isolate effects, and those factors additively. But whether made
strengthen inferences about movement emer- by movement scholars or neo-institutional-
gence and outcomes. ists, arguments about political opportunity
664 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

and institutional mediation are fundamen- state power, and can hinder, halt or even
tally arguments about interaction effects reverse the diffusion of new forms.
(Thornton & Occasio 1999; Bartley & Under these conditions, diffusion is a con-
Schneiberg 2002; Schneiberg & Clemens tested process, and the success of the initial
2006). They are arguments that political movement for alternatives depends on
or institutional configurations amplify or whether or not challengers can muster politi-
blunt the effects of movement numbers, cal support to place and keep alternatives on
resources or activities on policies, paths and the agenda (Soule & King 2005; King,
change. And they can be implemented empir- Cornwall & Dahlin 2005). Under these con-
ically in relatively straightforward ways ditions, the diffusion of novel practices
(Amenta & Zylan 1991; Amenta et al. 1992; depends on challengers’ abilities to mobilize
Schneiberg 2002; Soule & Olzak 2004; sufficient power (resources, numbers, organ-
Soule 2004). ization) to secure authorizing legislation,
defend alternatives politically, and so on. For
example, the diffusion of mutuals and coop-
Mobilization outcomes: eratives in the US economy was most exten-
movements, politics and sive where anti-corporate forces could secure
decisive political victories against corpora-
(heterogeneous) diffusion
tions, including anti-trust laws and populist
A second, more substantive direction for railroad regulation (Schneiberg 2002, 2007).
future research revisits the relationship Under these conditions, movements matter
between collective mobilization and diffu- not just as a conduit, theorizer or assembler
sion, and considers how movements operate of frames and new forms, but also, and more
as political forces in promoting the spread of critically, as an accumulator of political
alternatives. Thinking in these terms keeps power and thus an essential political condi-
politics and power at the forefront of a recon- tion for diffusion.
stituted institutional analysis, while high- Considering movements as political condi-
lighting how diffusion is often a contested tions for diffusion revises conventional views
political process (Schneiberg & Soule 2005; of the relationship between movements,
Fiss & Zajac 2005; Hirsch & Lounsbury institutions and outcomes. Arguments about
1997). Researchers have demonstrated that political opportunity structure trace how
social movements can shape the composition existing institutional structures condition the
of fields and fuel path creation by promoting effects of movements and mobilization on
new kinds of forms such as craft breweries policies and change. Here, politics and
(Carroll & Swaminathan 2000), nouvelle power are institutionally contingent (Amenta
cuisine (Rao, Monin & Durand 2003), et al. 1992; Thornton & Occasio 1999;
mutual, cooperative and state enterprises Thornton 2002; Bartley & Schneiberg 2002).
(Schneiberg 2002, 2007), and community- As institutional systems become more open to
based, non-profit recycling centers challengers or provide them with elite allies,
(Lounsbury, Ventresca, & Hirsch 2003; see movements’ abilities to translate conventional
also Clemens 1997; Rao, Morrill & Zald resources into desired outcomes will increase.
2000). Yet, as also noted, mobilization can Favorable institutional contexts amplify the
spark counter-mobilization by powerful effect of movement numbers, organizations or
vested interests threatened by novel prac- resources on change outcomes.
tices, pitting industrial brewers against craft Conceptualizing movements as political
producers, managers and unions against forces for diffusion inverts this logic, sug-
shareholders, or corporations against cooper- gesting that institutional dynamics of diffu-
atives and state enterprises. Such counter- sion are politically contingent. Whether or
attacks are typically political, often involve not actors can adopt, borrow or translate
SOCIAL MOVEMENTS AND INSTITUTIONAL ANALYSIS 665

novel forms depends on the capacities of or subsets of organizations susceptible to


challenger movements to amass political alternatives that are endorsed or adopted by
resources, defend novel forms against peers. Here, movements operating as politi-
counter-attacks, and create favorable politi- cal forces within organizations can fuel
cal contexts for the spread of alternatives a differential flow of novel practices across
(Schneiberg, King & Smith 2008). Here, organizations.
institutional effects depend on movement Furthermore, as movements become more
power. Generally speaking, the likelihood powerful, they can fuel variation in the con-
of an organization adopting a new practice tent of practices that diffuse within fields.
increases as professional communities In the recycling case, activist groups on
endorse the practice and the number of prior campuses pushed colleges and universities to
adopters increase. Professional endorsement go beyond minimal approaches to recycling
and increased prevalence of practices staffed by part-time custodial staff to
increases their legitimacy. But, where novel adopt programs with full-time ecologically-
forms are subject to contestation, diffusion committed coordinators (Lounsbury 2001).
will require the mobilization of numbers, Similarly, in the insurance case, increasing
resources or organization to defend and pro- the political strength of anti-corporate forces
tect these alternatives. Absent such mobiliza- drove some states beyond limited anti-
tion, endorsement or prior adoption will have discrimination forms of price regulation to
little or no effect on subsequent adoption. full rate control measures that gave regula-
Yet, as champions of alternatives mobilize tors authority to order comprehensive changes
and shift the balance of power, endorsement in rates (Schneiberg & Bartley 2001).
and prior adoptions will have increasingly Fortunately, well-developed tools are
powerful effects on subsequent adoption, available for analyzing movements as politi-
translation or other institutional processes. cal conditions for diffusion, provided meas-
Overall, our knowledge of how move- ures of movement strength or presence are
ments create favorable political contexts for available. To analyze how movements create
the diffusion and translation of alternatives is possibilities for diffusion by shifting the bal-
relatively undeveloped. However, future ance of power at the field-level, models of
research can draw on both a multi-level per- adoption can employ interaction effects to
spective and existing strategies for modeling examine whether the political strength of
diffusion. In principle, movements can movements at the field-level moderates the
support diffusion as a political force at either effects on organizational adoption of prior
the field-level or within organizations. adoption by peers or endorsement by expert-
Movements can raise the overall receptivity professionals. To analyze these dynamics at
of organizations to new practices by amass- the organizational level, a similar strategy
ing numbers and resources to contest field- could be used, provided measures are
wide authorities, report success stories in available of the presence, strength or efficacy
media, enhance the visibility of new prac- of movements within organizations.
tices, or demonstrate the possibility of dis- Researchers could again use interaction
ruption and change. As movements mobilize effects to see if the strength of movements in
effectively at this level, they create political organizations increases the effects of preva-
space for alternatives and multiple logics lence or endorsement on the likelihood of
across entire fields, increasing the risk of those organizations adopting novel practices.
adoption of novel practices in the aggregate. Alternatively, one can use heterogeneous
Alternatively, movements can shift the diffusion models (Strang & Soule 1998)
balance of power and enhance receptivity by to see whether increasing movement
mobilizing ‘locally’ within individual organ- strength within organizations renders them
izations and making particular organizations more susceptible to the influence of peers
666 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

or professions. As Soule’s (2006) study of over time, via sequences or successive stages
university divestment shows, student protests of translation, layering, theorization and
on campuses against investing in South assembly that elaborate and innovate on pre-
Africa did not directly promote divestment. vious, partial accomplishments (Streeck &
But by increasing awareness among adminis- Thelen 2005). And central to field and path
trators of university and surrounding com- creation is some sort of collective mobiliza-
munities, demonstrations were a nagging tion or movement, not just a single burst of
reminder that rendered colleges and universi- organization, but also waves or cycles of
ties more vulnerable to legitimacy pressures, mobilization and organizational formation.
making them more likely to divest as their The parallels between institutionalist
peers jumped on the bandwagon. imageries of path creation as waves of layer-
Finally, future research can use existing ing, on the one hand, and movement research
analytical strategies, including competing on cycles of mobilization and protest, on the
hazards models, to analyze how growing other, suggest that linking the two can pro-
movement strength might promote the diffu- vide new insights for future research on path
sion of increasingly varied, comprehensive creation and change, while adding new his-
or radical alternatives (Lounsbury 2001; torical dimensions to neo-institutional schol-
Schneiberg & Bartley 2001). In this way, too, arship. Movement scholars have done
institutionalists can address how movements important work in highlighting the sequenc-
as political forces shape not just the overall ing of social movements and cycles of protest
flow of practices across fields, but also the (e.g., Tarrow 1998), tracing, among other
differential flow of alternatives and practice things, how contentious politics that involve
variants within them. tactics such as protest are transformed into
more conventional forms of political action
such as lobbying (Meyer & Tarrow 1998;
The origins of institutions: history, Kriesi, Koopmans, Duyvendak & Giugni
1995). Minkoff (e.g., 1993, 1997) adds orga-
sequence and layering
nizational dimensions to the analysis of
An important and neglected question in neo- sequences, showing how the proliferation of
institutionalism is where institutions such as radical organizations created legitimacy and
fields, practices or paths come from and how favorable political opportunities for subse-
they are forged or elaborated over time. As quent organization by advocacy and practi-
sociologists have emphasized, there is never tioner groups, institutionalizing civil rights
a clean slate. Rather, new fields and arenas of more deeply within American politics.
social life are typically constructed from the For their part, institutionalists have just
rubble, or flotsam and jetsam, of previous begun to think in these terms. But prelimi-
institutions or paths not taken (Stark 1996; nary efforts to analyze path and field creation
Schneiberg 2007) or from variations pro- as waves of mobilization, structuration and
duced within extant fields (Lounsbury & layering have established a new direction for
Crumley 2007). After all, as Meyer and future research. Lounsbury, Ventresca and
Rowan (1977: 345) observe in their classic Hirsch (2003) took one step in this direction,
piece, ‘the building blocks for organizations showing how efforts by early and more radi-
come to be littered around the social land- cal ‘outsider’ environmental movements in
scape; it takes only a little entrepreneurial the 1960s and 1970s to restructure capitalism
energy to assemble them into a structure.’ via not-for-profit, community-based recy-
Moreover, new systems are often not created cling centers unintentionally laid foundations
in one fell swoop through one wave of diffu- for subsequent mobilization by insider
sion or comprehensive settlements. Rather, groups in the 1980s to create a for-profit
paths may emerge through multiple waves, recycling industry. Most non-profit recycling
SOCIAL MOVEMENTS AND INSTITUTIONAL ANALYSIS 667

centers proved economically non-viable, but that exposed corruption and promulgated
they nonetheless trained a generation of reform principles. They also advocated city-
Americans in the habits of saving, cleaning, manager forms of municipal government that
and sorting their trash, a critical cultural exemplified those principles, providing tan-
infrastructure for the creation of markets gible analogies for reformers within the thrift
based on curb-side pick up. industry. Both institutions promoted the con-
Schneiberg (2007; Schneiberg, King & stitutive legitimacy of bureaucracy, prompt-
Smith 2008) takes this avenue of research a ing saving and loans associations to adopt
step further in analyzing the development of organizational forms more consistent with
mutual, cooperative and publicly owned ‘modernist’ moral sentiments.
enterprise in the US economy. For the most Nor are these processes confined to eco-
part, populists and the radical anti-corporate nomic industries or organizational dynamics.
movements of the late nineteenth and early As Armstrong (2002, 2005) illustrates, the
twentieth centuries faced decisive defeats in legacy of initial movements may also include
their efforts to forge alternatives to corporate the establishment of new identities, cultural
capitalism. But even though they collapsed, tools such as frames and logics, and ‘creative
these movements nevertheless left behind contexts’ that enable subsequent groups to
organizational, cultural and institutional continue struggles, mobilize and realize
legacies – bit and pieces of the paths they had new gains in their efforts. The rise of the
pursued, including theories of order, regula- New Left in the 1960s enabled the creation
tory fragments, local movement chapters, and of new kinds of lesbian/gay organizational
alternative systems of enterprise in key indus- identities in San Francisco in the early 1970s.
tries. These legacies of Populistera mobiliza- The development of gay identity politics, in
tion, in turn, served as legitimating structures, turn, proved crucial in structuring subsequent
platforms and infrastructures for subsequent lesbian/gay organizations as well as enabling
collective mobilization in the same or related changes within mainstream organizations
industries, first during the Progressive era, such as the establishment of domestic partner
and then in the early New Deal. Indeed, suc- benefits (Creed & Scully 2000; Scully &
cessive waves of reformers and anti-corporate Creed 2005). While this work traces the
forces built or transposed theories, moral sequencing and layering from ‘outsider’ to
sentiments and cooperative forms out from ‘insider’ movements, it would be interesting
insurance and other early sites of alternative to also understand how ‘insider’ movements
enterprise into the dairy and grain industries, facilitate ‘outsider’ mobilizations.
the electrical utility industry and banking, Overall, the approach to movements and
elaborating what amounts to a secondary path institutions that we advocate celebrates the
of industrial order in the US economy. heterogeneity of actors, multiple logics and
Haveman, Rao and Paruchuri’s (2007) practice variation. A focus on such multiplic-
study of Progressivism and savings and loans ity revises the isomorphic imagery of the
associations likewise highlights the distal canonical two-stage diffusion and punctuated
and often unintended effects of movements equilibrium models (e.g., Tolbert & Zucker
on organizational fields. Progressive activists 1983). Such a perspective concentrates less
quite deliberately and directly sought to on the contagion of unitary practices or a sin-
reform a variety of economic institutions, gular rationality, but rather on multiple forms
from the railroads to savings and loan associ- of rationality that inform the decision making
ations. Yet they also fostered Progressive of actors in fields (Bourdieu 1984), and pro-
models of rationality, bureaucratization and vide foundations for ongoing struggle and
expert management within the thrift industry contestation. This conceptualization of insti-
indirectly, via two intermediary institutions. tutionalization and fields as multiple, frag-
Activists formed Progressive newspapers mented and contested (Schneiberg & Soule
668 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

2005; Washington & Ventresca 2004; Beckert, J. 1999. Agency, entrepreneurs, and
Lounsbury 2007) is a crucial ontological institutional change. The role of strategic
starting point for a new wave and generation choice and institutionalized practices in
of institutional scholars. And when combined organizations. Organization Studies, 20:
with a renewed attention to movements, it 777–799.
Bourdieu, P. 1984. Distinction: a social critique
directs analytical attention to how historical
of the judgment of taste. Cambridge:
legacies of prior social action become Harvard University Press.
embedded in existing fields, providing bases Campbell, John. 2004. Institutional Change
for sequences of mobilization, and the con- and Globalization. Princeton: Princeton
struction of new paths from the elements or University Press.
ruins of old or forgotten orders. The early Campbell, John. 2005. Where do we stand?
work in this direction has proven fruitful and Common mechanisms in organizations and
promises to propel institutional analysis for social movements research. Pp. 41–68 in G.F.
many years to come. Davis, D. McAdam, W.R. Scott & M.N. Zald
(eds.), 2005. Social Movements and
Organization Theory. Cambridge, UK:
Cambridge University Press.
REFERENCES Carroll, G.R. & Swaminathan, A. 2000. Why the
microbrewery movement? Organizational
Amenta, E., Carruthers, B. & Zylan, Y. et al. dynamics of resource partitioning in the U.S.
1992. ‘A hero for the aged? The Townsend brewing industry. American Journal of
Movement, the Political Mediation Model, Sociology, 106: 715–762.
and the U.S. old-age policy, 1934–1950.’ Carruthers, B.G. & Babb, S. 1996. The color of
American Journal of Sociology, 98: 308–39. money and the nature of value: Greenbacks
Amenta, E. & Zylan, Y. 1991. ‘It happened and gold in postbellum America. American
here: Political opportunity, the new institu- Journal of Sociology, 101: 1556–1591.
tionalism and the Townsend Movement.’ Clemens, E.S. 1993. Organizational repertoires
American Sociological Review, 56: 250–65. and institutional change: Womens’ groups
Armstrong, E.A. 2002. Crisis, collective creativ- and the transformation of U.S. politics,
ity, and the generation of new organizational 1890–1920. American Journal of Sociology,
forms: The transformation of lesbian/gay 98: 755–798.
organizations in San Francisco. Research in Clemens, E.S. 1997. The People’s Lobby:
the Sociology of Organizations, 19: Organizational Innovation and The Rise of
369–406. Interest Group Politics in the United States,
Armstrong, E.A. 2005. From struggle to settle- 1890–1925. Chicago: University of Chicago
ment: The crystallization of a field of les- Press.
bian/gay organizations in San Francisco, Clemens, E.S. and Cook, J. 1999. Politics and
1969–1973. In G.F. Davis, D. McAdam, W.R. institutionalism: Explaining durability and
Scott & M.N. Zald (eds.), Social Movements change. Annual Review of Sociology, 25:
and Organization Theory (pp. 161–188). 441–466.
Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Colyvas, Jeannette & Powell, W. 2006. Roads
Press. to institutionalization. Research in
Baron, J.P., Dobbin, F. & Jennings, P.D. 1986. Organizational Behavior, 27: 305–53.
War and peace: The evolution of modern Creed, W.E.D. & Scully, M. 2000. Songs of our-
personnel administration in U.S. industry. selves: Employees’ deployment of social
American Journal of Sociology, 92: identity in workplace encounters. Journal of
250–283. Management Inquiry, 9: 391–412.
Bartley, T. & Schneiberg, M. 2002. Rationality Creed, W.E.D., Scully, M.A. & Austin, J.R. 2002.
and institutional contingency: the varying Clothes make the person: The tailoring
politics of economic regulation in the fire of legitimating accounts and the social
insurance industry. Sociological Perspectives, construction of identity. Organization
45(1): 47–79. Science, 13: 475–496.
SOCIAL MOVEMENTS AND INSTITUTIONAL ANALYSIS 669

Davis, Gerald F. & McAdam, Doug. 2000. century capitalism. Princeton: Princeton
Corporations, classes, and social movements University Press.
after managerialism. Research in Organi- Frank, D.B., Hironaka, A. and Schofer, E. 2000.
zational Behaviour, 22: 195–238. Environmentalism as a Global Institution.
Davis, G.F., & Thompson, T. 1994. A social American Sociological Review, 65: 122–127.
movement perspective on corporate control. Frickel, Scott and Gross, Neil. 2005. A general
Administrative Science Quarterly, 39: theory of scientific/intellectual movements.
141–173. American Sociological Review, 70: 204–232.
Davis, G.F. & Zald, M.N. 2005. Social change, Galaskiewicz, J. & Wasserman, S. 1989.
social theory, and the convergence of move- Mimetic processes within an interorganiza-
ments and organizations. In G.F. Davis, tional field: An empirical test. Administrative
D. McAdam, W.R. Scott & M.N. Zald Science Quarterly, 34: 454–479.
(eds.), Social Movements and Organization Garud, R. & Karnoe, P. (eds.) 2001. Path
Theory (pp. 335–350). Cambridge: Cambridge Dependence and Creation. Mahwah, NJ:
University Press. Lawrence Erlbaum.
DiMaggio, Paul J. 1988. Interest and agency in Giugni, M., McAdam, D. & Tilly, C. 1999. How
institutional theory. In Lynne Zucker (ed.), Movements Matter. Minneapolis, MN:
Institutional Patterns and Organizations, University of Minnesota Press.
3–22. Cambridge, MA: Ballinger. Greenwood, R. & Hinings, C.R. 1996.
Dobbin, F. & Dowd, T. 1997. How policy shapes Understanding radical organizational change:
competition: Early Railroad foundings in Bringing together the old and the new institu-
Massachusetts. Administrative Science tionalism. Academy of Management Review,
Quarterly, 42: 501–529. 21: 1022–1054.
Edelman, L.B. 1990. Legal environments and Greenwood, Royston, Suddaby, Roy & Hinings,
organizational governance: The expansion of C.R. 2002. Theorizing change: The role of
due process in the American workplace. professional associations in the transforma-
American Journal of Sociology, 95: 1401–1440. tion of institutional fields. Academy of
Edelman, L.B. 1992. Legal ambiguity and sym- Management Journal, 45: 58–80.
bolic structures: Organizational mediation of Guillén, Mauro F. 2006. The Taylorized Beauty
civil rights law. American Journal of of the Mechanical: Scientific Management
Sociology, 97: 1531–1576. and The Rise of Modernist Architecture.
Edelman, L.B. 2006. Constructed legalities: The Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
endogeneity of law. In W. Powell and Hargrave, T.J. & Van de Ven, A.H. 2006. A col-
D. Jones (eds.), How Institutions Change. lective action model of institutional innova-
Chicago: University of Chicago Press. tion. Academy of Management Review, 31:
Elsbach, K. & Sutton, R. 1992. Acquiring orga- 864–88.
nizational legitimacy through illegitimate Haveman, H. Rao Hayagreeva, & Paruchuri,
actions: A marriage of institutional and Srikanth. 2007. The winds of change: The
impression management theories. Academy Progressive movement and the bureaucrati-
of Management Journal, 4: 699–738. zation of thrift. American Sociological
Fiss, P.C. & Zajac, E.J. 2004. The diffusion of Review, 72: 117–42.
ideas over contested terrain: The (non)adop- Hironaka, A. & Schofer, E. 2002. Decoupling in
tion of a shareholder value orientation the environmental arena: The case of
among German firms. Administrative environmental impact assessments. In
Science Quarterly, 49: 501–534. A. Hoffman and M. Ventresca (eds.),
Fligstein, Neil 1990. The Transformation of Organizations, Policy and the Natural Envi-
Corporate Control. Cambridge, MA: Harvard ronment. Stanford: Stanford University Press.
University Press. Hirsch, P. & Lounsbury, M. 1997. Ending the
Fligstein, N. 1996. A political-cultural approach family quarrel: Towards a reconciliation of
to market institutions. American Sociological ‘old’ and ‘new’ institutionalisms. American
Review, 61: 656–673. Behavioral Scientist, 40: 406–418.
Fligstein, N. 2001. The architecture of markets: Hoffman, A. 1999. Institutional evolution and
An economic sociology of twenty first change: Environmentalism and the US
670 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

chemical industry. Academy of Management Academy of Management Journal, 50:


Journal, 42: 351–71. 289–307.
Hwang, H & W. Powell, 2005. ‘Institutions and Lounsbury, M. and Crumley, E.T. 2007. New
Entrepreneurship,’ in Sharon Alvarez, practice creation: An institutional approach
Rashesh Agrawal and Olav Sorenson, to innovation. Organization Studies, 28:
Handboo of Entrepreneurial Research. 993–1012.
New York: Springer: 179–210. Lounsbury, M., Ventresca, M.J. & Hirsch, P.M.
Ingram, P. & Rao, H. 2004. Store wars. American 2003. Social movements, field frames and
Journal of Sociology, 110: 446–487. industry emergence: A cultural-political per-
Jepperson, R. 1991. Institutions, institutional spective of U.S. recycling. Socio-Economic
effects, and institutionalism. In W.W. Powell & Review, 1: 71–104.
P.J. DiMaggio (eds.),The New Institutionalism Maguire, S., Hardy, C., & Lawrence, T. B. 2004.
in Organizational Analysis. Chicago: University Institutional entrepreneurship in emerging
of Chicago Press: 143–163. fields: HIV/AIDS treatment advocacy in
Keck, M.E. & Sikkink, K. 1998. Activists Beyond Canada. Academy of Management Journal,
Borders. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. 47(5): 657–679.
King, Brayden G., Cornwall, Marie, & Dahlin, Marquis, C. & Lounsbury, M. 2007. Vive la
Eric C. 2005. Winning woman suffrage one résistance: Consolidation and the institu-
step at a time: Social movements and the tional contingency of professional counter-
logic of the legislative process. Social Forces, mobilization in US banking. Academy of
83: 1211–1234. Management Journal, 50: 799–820.
Kriesi, H., Koopmans, R., Duyvendak, J.W. & McAdam, D. 1988. Freedom Summer. Oxford:
Giugni, M.G. 1995. The Politics of New Oxford University Press.
Social Movements in Western Europe: A McAdam, D. 1999. Political Process and
Comparative Analysis. Minneapolis, MN: the Development of Black Insurgency,
University of Minnesota Press. 1930–1970 (rev. edn). Chicago: University of
Laraña, E., Johnston, H. & Gusfield, J.R. (eds.), Chicago Press.
1994. New Social Movements: From McAdam, D., McCarthy, J.D. & Zald, M.D.
Ideology to Identity. Philadelphia: Temple 1996. Comparative Perspectives on Social
University Press. Movements. NY: Cambridge University Press.
Lipsky, M. 1968. Protest as a political resource. McAdam, D. & Scott, W.R. 2005. Organizations
American Political Science Review, 62: and movements. In G.F. Davis, D. McAdam,
1144–1157. W.R. Scott & M.N. Zald (eds.), Social Move-
Lawrence, T.B. & Suddaby, R. 2006. Institutions ments and Organization Theory (pp. 4–40).
and Institutional Work. In S. Clegg, C. Hardy, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.
T.B. Lawrence & W. Nord (eds.), The Sage McAdam, D., Tarrow, S. & Tilly, C. 2002. The
Handbook of Organization Studies (2nd Dynamics of Contention. Cambridge, UK:
edn), pp. 215–254. London: Sage. Cambridge University Press.
Lounsbury, M. 2001. Institutional sources of McCarthy, J.D. & Zald, M.N. 1977. Resource
practice variation: Staffing college and uni- mobilization and social movements: A partial
versity recycling programs. Administrative theory. American Journal of Sociology, 82:
Science Quarterly, 46: 29–56. 1212–1241.
Lounsbury, M. 2005. Institutional variation Meyer, D.S. & Tarrow, S. (eds.), 1998. The
in the evolution of social movements: Social Movement Society. Lanham, MD:
Competing logics and the spread of Rowman & Littlefield.
recycling advocacy groups. In G.F. Davis, Meyer, J. & Rowan, B. 1977. Institutional
D. McAdam, W.R. Scott & M.N. Zald (eds.), organizations: Formal structure as myth and
Social Movements and Organization Theory ceremony. American Journal of Sociology,
(pp. 73–95). Cambridge, UK: Cambridge 83(2): 340–363.
University Press. Minkoff, D.C. 1993. The organization of sur-
Lounsbury, M. 2007. A tale of two cities: vival: Women’s and racial-ethnic voluntarist
Competing logics and practice variation in and activist organizations, 1955–1985.
the professionalizing of mutual funds. Social Forces, 71: 887–908.
SOCIAL MOVEMENTS AND INSTITUTIONAL ANALYSIS 671

Minkoff, D.C. 1997. The sequencing of social American property insurance. Sociological
movements. American Sociological Review, Forum, 1: 93–137.
62: 779–799. Schneiberg, M. 2007. What’s on the path?
Moore, Kelly. 1996. Organizing integrity: Path dependence, organizational diversity
American science and the creation of and the problem of institutional change in
public interest organizations, 1955–1975. the US economy, 1900–1950. Socio-
American Journal of Sociology, 101: Economic Review, 5: 47–80.
1592–1627. Schneiberg, M. & Bartley, T. 2001. Regulating
Moore, K. & Hala, N. 2002. Organizing iden- American industries: Markets, politics, and the
tity: The creation of Science for the People. institutional determinants of fire insurance
Research in the Sociology of Organizations, regulation. American Journal of Sociology,
19: 311–343. 107: 101–146.
Morrill, Calvin. 2006. Institutional change and Schneiberg, M. & Soule, S.A. 2005.
interstitial emergence: The growth of alter- Institutionalization as a contested, multilevel
native dispute resolution in American law, process: The case of rate regulation in
1965–1995. In W. Powell and D. Jones American fire insurance. In G.F. Davis, D.
(eds.), How Institutions Change. Chicago: McAdam, W.R. Scott & M.N. Zald (eds.),
University of Chicago Press. Social Movements and Organization Theory
Pierson, Paul. 2000. Increasing returns, path (pp. 122–160). Cambridge, UK: Cambridge
dependence, and the study of politics. University Press.
American Political Science Review, 94: Schneiberg, M. & Clemens, E.S. 2006. The typ-
251–267. ical tools for the job: Research strategies in
Raeburn, Nicole. 2004. Inside Out: The Struggle institutional analysis. Sociological Theory,
for Lesbian, Gay and Bisexual Rights in the 3: 195–227.
Workplace. Minneapolis, MN: University of Schneiberg, M., King, M., & Smith, T. 2008.
Minnesota Press. Social movements and organizational form:
Rao, Hayagreeva. 1998. Caveat emptor: The Cooperative alternatives to corporations in
construction of nonprofit consumer watch- the American insurance, dairy and grain
dog organizations. American Journal of industries. American Sociological Review:
Sociology, 103: 912–961. Forthcoming.
Rao, Hayagreeva, Monin, P. & Durand, Schofer, E. & A. Hironaka. 2005. The effects of
Rodolphe. 2003. Institutional change in world society on environmental protection
Touque Ville: Nouvelle cuisine as an identity outcomes. Social Forces, 84: 25–47.
movement in French gastronomy. American Scott, W.R. 2001. Institutions and Organiza-
Journal of Sociology, 4: 795–843. tions (2nd edn). Newbury Park, CA: Sage.
Rao, Hayagreeva, Morril, Calvin & Zald Mayer Scott, W.R., Ruef, M., Mendel, P. & Caronna, C.
N. 2000. Power plays: Social movements, 2000. Institutional Change and Organizations:
collective action and new organizational Transformation of a Healthcare Field.
forms. Research in Organizational Behavior, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
22: 237–282. Scully, M. & Segal, A. 2002. Passion with an
Schneiberg, M. 1999. Political and institutional umbrella: Grassroots activists in the work-
conditions for governance by association: place. Research in the Sociology of
Private order and price controls in American Organizations, 19: 127–170.
fire insurance. Politics and Society, 27: Scully, M. & Creed,W.E.D. 2005. Subverting
67–103. our Stories of Subversion. In G.F. Davis, D.
Schneiberg, M. 2002. Organizational hetero- McAdam, W.R. Scott & M.N. Zald (eds.),
geneity and the production of new forms: Social movements and organization theory
Politics, social movements and mutual (pp. 310–332). Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge
companies in American fire insurance, University Press.
1900–1930. Research in the Sociology of Seo, M. & Creed, W.E.D. 2002. Institutional
Organizations, 19: 39–89. contradictions, praxis, and institutional
Schneiberg, M. 2005. Combining new institu- change: A dialectical perspective. Academy
tionalisms: Explaining institutional change in of Management Review, 27: 222–247.
672 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Soule, S. 2004. ‘Going to the chapel? Same-sex Sutton J.R., Dobbin, F., Meyer, J., Scott, W.R.
marriage bans in the United States, 1994. The legalization of the workplace.
1973–2000.’ Social Problems, 4: 453–77. American Journal of Sociology, 99:
Soule, S. 2006. Divestment by colleges and uni- 944–971.
versities in the United States: Institutional Sutton, John R. & Dobbin, Frank. 1996.
pressures toward isomorphism. In W. Powell Responses to legal uncertainty in U.S. firms,
and D. Jones (eds.), How Institutions Change. 1955 to 1985. American Sociological
Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Review, 61: 794–811.
Soule, S. & Olzak, S. 2004. When do move- Tarrow, S. 1998. Power in Movement: Social
ments matter? The politics of contingency Movements and Contentious Politics (2nd
and the Equal Rights Amendment. American edn). New York: Cambridge University Press.
Sociological Review, 69: 473–97. Thelen. K. 2004. How Institutions Evolve: The
Soule, S. and King, B. 2006. The stage of the Political Economy of Skills in Germany,
policy process and the Equal Rights Britain, The United States and Japan. New
Amendment, 1972–1982. American Journal York, Cambridge University Press.
of Sociology, 6: 1871–1909. Thornton, P.H. 2002. The rise of the corpora-
Strang, D. & Chang, M.Y. 1993. The tion in a craft industry: Conflict and con-
International Labor Organization and the formity in institutional logics. Academy of
welfare state: Institutional effects on Management Journal, 45: 81–101.
national welfare spending, 1960–1980. Thornton, P.H. & Ocasio, W. 1999. Institutional
International Organization, 47: 235–262. logics and the historical contingency of
Strang, David & Meyer, John W. 1993. power in organizations: Executive succession
Institutional conditions for diffusion. Theory in the higher education publishing industry,
and Society, 22: 487–512. 1958–1990. American Journal of Sociology,
Strang, D. & Jung, D. 2005. Organizational 105: 801–843.
change as an orchestrated social movement: Tolbert, P.S., & Zucker, L.G. 1983. Institutional
Recruitment to a corporate quality initiative. sources of change in the formal structure of
In G.F. Davis, D. McAdam, W.R. Scott & M.N. organizations: The diffusion of civil service
Zald (eds.), Social Movements and Organiza- reform, 1880–1935. Administrative Science
tion Theory (pp. 280–309). Cambridge, UK: Quarterly, 28: 22–39.
Cambridge University Press. Vogus, T.J. & Davis, G.F. 2005. Elite mobilizations
Strang, D. & Soule, S.A. 1998. Diffusion in for antitakeover legislation, 1982–1990. In
organizations and social movements: From G.F. Davis, D. McAdam, W.R. Scott & M.N.
hybrid corn to poison pills. Annual Review of Zald (eds.), Social Movements and Organiza-
Sociology, 24: 265–290. tion Theory (pp. 96–121). Cambridge, UK:
Stark, D. 1996. Recombinant property in East Cambridge University Press.
European capitalism. American Journal of Wade, James B., Swaminathan, A. & Saxon, M.S.
Sociology, 101(4): 993–1027. 1998. Normative and resource flow conse-
Streeck, Wolfgang & Thelen, Kathleen. 2005. quences of local regulations in the American
Beyond Continuity: Institutional Change in brewing industry, 1845–1918. Administrative
Advanced Political Economies. Oxford: Science Quarterly, 43: 905–935.
Oxford University Press. Washington, M., & Ventresca. M.J. 2004. How
Stryker, R. 1994. Rules, resources, and legiti- organizations change: The role of institu-
macy processes: Some implications for social tional support mechanisms in the incorpora-
conflict, order, and change. American tion of higher education visibility strategies,
Journal of Sociology, 99: 847–910. 1874–1995. Organization Science, 15:
Stryker, R. 2000. Legitimacy processes as insti- 82–96.
tutional politics: Implications for theory and Zald, M.N. & Berger, M.A. 1978. Social move-
research in the sociology of organizations. ments in organizations: Coup d’etat, insur-
Research in the Sociology of Organiza- gency, and mass movements. American Journal
tions,17: 179–223. of Sociology, 83: 823–861.
28
Examining ‘Institutionalization’:
A Critical Theoretic Perspective*
David J. Cooper, Mahmoud Ezzamel and Hugh Willmott

INTRODUCTION theory has taken on board and accommo-


dated critiques which, alternatively, have
Various forms of critical theory have been called for a rebalancing of the emphasis
suggested to illuminate social practices. given to the conditioning constraints of
Versions of such theories has been promoted ‘structure’ or the innovative capabilities of
for the analysis of management, organiza- ‘agency’ (Reed, 1997). This chapter steps
tions and work (e.g. Burrell, 1988; Burrell, back from this process of critique and incor-
1994; Alvesson and Willmott, 2004) and this poration to provide a ‘critical theoretic’ illu-
chapter considers how such analyses, with mination of institutional theory to facilitate
their emphasis on power, domination and reflection on its distinctiveness and limits.
emancipation, can be used to examine a cen- We begin by noting how, in their different
tral focus of institutional theory, namely ways, varieties of institutional theory and crit-
institutionalization. Limitations and anom- ical theory share an attentiveness to institu-
alies in institutional theory have stimulated tionalization, conceived as processes that
its development from ‘old’, through ‘new’, to order and constrain but also enable forms of
‘neo’ variants of analysis1 (DiMaggio and interaction and organization. In institutional
Powell, 1991). At each stage, institutional theory, dominant ‘logics’ that are irreducible

*An earlier version of this paper was presented to the Organization Theory Research Group at the Tanaka
Business School, Imperial College, London. We would like to thank participants at this meeting for their help-
ful and supportive discussion of the paper and especially the comments received from Marc Ventresca and
André Spicer. We are especially indebted to Nelson Phillips and Jaco Lok for their invaluable suggestions for
focusing and clarifying central arguments of the paper. Albert James assisted with the references. David Cooper
and Mahmoud Ezzamel thank the Social Sciences and Humanities Research Council for financial support, and
David Cooper thanks the Certified General Accountants of Alberta for their financial support.
674 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

to rational choices or a to a series of environ- commitments and consequences. The differ-


mental contingencies, are held to account for ences are both theoretical and practical. As
why, for example, within a population of Lounsbury (2003: 16) notes, differences of
organizations there is an homogeneity of orientation to ‘the problem of order as well
form and practice. For critical theorists, as conflicting social imageries of the rela-
processes of institutionalization account for tionship between culture and power lead
how patterns of domination and oppression – institutional and critical analysts of organiza-
for example, racism or sexism but also more tions to ask different kinds of questions’.
subtle, normalized forms of subjugation such This observation helps to account for why, in
as bullying and pressurizing at work – the voluminous literature of institutional
become naturalized in workplaces and else- theory, there are so few references to key crit-
where yet, in principle, are open to transfor- ical thinkers, such as Marx, Habermas and
mation. What they share, nonetheless, is a Foucault.4 Advocates of institutional theory
rejection of analysis founded upon method- position and develop their work in rela-
ological individualism (e.g. rational choice tion to rational choice theory, contingency
theory)2 that ignores how ‘choices’ are theory and resource dependency theory.
embedded in, and organized through, Consideration of the possible relevance of
processes that are infused with value. So, for critical theory concepts of ‘totality’, ‘contra-
example, in principle, institutional theory diction’ and ‘praxis’ (Benson, 1977) is highly
problematizes analyses that do not appreciate unusual (e.g. Seo and Creed, 2002).
how the very idea of ‘choice’, for example, Tellingly, what is perhaps the most pene-
articulates a particular, institutionalized way trating critique of institutional theory
of making sense of the world. Critical analy- (Hasselbladh and Kallinikos, 2000) has been
ses extend and radicalize this understanding ignored in the plethora of institutional papers
as institutionalization is examined as a means that have appeared since its publication.5
of domination and oppression. We will argue that institutional theory is
We conceive of the differences – of embedded in a distinctive tradition of social
emphasis and bearing – between institutional scientific enquiry that is preoccupied with the
and critical theories in terms of their con- possibility of developing more objective
trasting value-orientations.3 Crucially, we knowledge of what it conceives the social
reject any suggestion that institution theory is world to be (that is, a product of processes of
value-free whereas critical theory is value- institutionalization). A concern to enhance
laden or normative. Instead, both are norma- prediction – for example, by researching how
tive, although in different ways. In broad strategic responses ‘are predictable largely in
terms, institutional theory is conservative terms of the nature of institutional pressures’
insofar as it inclines to naturalize the status (Oliver, 1991: 174) in order to secure
quo and shies away from (critical) theories improved control of the social world – pro-
that, in contrast, problematize the status quo vides a taken for granted, but rarely interro-
as oppressive. A key difference is that the gated, impetus for institutional theory. Other
normativity of institutional theory is possible traditions of social science –
occluded by its pretensions to positivist hermeneutic or critical (see Bernstein, 1976) –
objectivity whereas the normativity of criti- are rarely contemplated or debated. In con-
cal theory is comparatively explicit. trast, critical theoretic analysis conceives of
A guiding thread running through the social scientific knowledge production in
chapter is the (institutional) idea that critical relation to its capacity to de-naturalize the
theory and institutional theory are embedded present, and thereby to open up questions
in differing ‘general views of life and of whether the conditions and consequences
the Universe’ that articulate different projects of present circumstances are oppressive or
which are inherently political in their emancipatory (and to whom).
EXAMINING ‘INSTITUTIONALIZATION’: A CRITICAL THEORETIC PERSPECTIVE 675

From these introductory remarks, it can be more specifically, to reflect critically upon
appreciated that it is a challenging task to the role and relevance of notions of ‘power’
relate institutional theory to critical theory. and ‘agency’ invoked by neo-institutionalists
Critical theory (and indeed institutional to address its alleged anomalies and
theory) covers a vast and expanding terrain limitations. We have two reasons for our
of intellectual endeavour (see Appendix) and selection of Michel Foucault. The first is that
consideration of its connection(s) with insti- during the past decade and more his thinking
tutional theory can be approached from has been exceptionally influential in social
numerous angles. A review might, for exam- science as well as critical theory.7 The second
ple, consider how key elements in institu- is that his writings on power and subjectifica-
tional theory relate to, deviate from, or run in tion are suggestive of an alternative under-
parallel to a more narrowly (e.g. confined to standing in which oppressive dimensions and
Critical Theory, Marxism, and so on), or to a effects are the focus of analysis.
more expansive (e.g. extending to poststruc- Subjectification is conceived by Foucault
turalist theory) notion of critical theory. as the ‘different modes by which ... human
Alternatively, a review of their relationship beings are made into subjects’ (Foucault,
might concentrate on those contributions to 1983: 208). Foucault’s focus upon subjectifi-
institutional theory that have selectively cation has an (unexplored) resonance with
deployed elements of critical theory to refine processes of institutionalization, not least
or augment their analysis; and such a review because, as Hasselbladh and Kallinkos
could be extended to discuss how other ele- (2000: 701) put it, ‘institutionalization is sus-
ments of critical theory may be incorporated tained and given meaning and direction
in the development of institutional theory. through its capacity to constitute distinctive
If, however, the value-orientations of insti- forms of actorhood’. A condition of institu-
tutional theory and critical theory are tionalization, in other words, is subjects’
believed to diverge significantly, as we identification with the forms and practices
have suggested, then it is an unrewarding that it reproduces. For example, in modern
challenge to imagine how either theory societies, the institution of actorhood – that is
can be subsumed within the other without the attribution of agency to subjects – is pre-
diluting or compromising their distinctive dominantly constituted and institutionalized
intent and associated contributions to in ways that Weber (1978) has characterized
knowledge.6 Our favoured approach, there- as ‘instrumental’. Actors’ identifications with
fore, develops an appreciation of, and respect the institutions of work, family, religion, etc.
for, their differences; and it explores how become progressively less traditional, affec-
a variant of critical theory may be engaged tive or value-rational. Crucially, this does not
to shed some new light upon the particularity mean that we are any less habituated to, or
and limits of institutional theory but without any less institutionalized or subjectified as
the restrictive and subjugating requirement agents within zweckrational modes of
of having to limit an assessment or demon- action.8 Indeed, the commonsense appeal of
stration of its relevance and value as a rational choice explanations of action is,
source of remedies for problems preoccupy- from an institutionalist perspective, indica-
ing institutional theorists. tive of the dominance of what, in a
Accordingly, in this chapter, in-depth Foucauldian analysis, might be identified as
attention is given to one key contribution to a particular mode of subjectification. This
critical theory – the work of Michel Foucault. mode is disciplined by a specific conception
We mobilize his thinking to give some indi- of competent agency that privileges and nat-
cation of what it could mean to think criti- uralizes the exercise of conscious, sovereign
cally about the value-orientation and calculation to achieve desired ends with
contribution of institutional theory; and, appropriate means (see also Friedland and
676 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Alford, 1991). This chapter explores these legitimation for institutional theorists. Our
issues in more detail. specific focus is on questions of how
The next section provides a discussion of ‘agency’ and ‘power’ are addressed and
how a particular understanding of institutions incorporated within institutional theory.
has become naturalized in institutional
theory and introduces our focus on issues of
power and agency. This is followed by a brief Conceptualizing institutionalization
overview of critical theory before we attend
directly to Foucault’s contribution to concep- In his landmark text on institutional theory,
tualizing power, knowledge, and subjectifi- Scott (1995/2001) identifies Parsons’ defini-
cation. Applying Foucault’s ideas, we then tion of institutionalization as a synthesis
consider some recent efforts to revise institu- of the arguments of earlier major theorists
tional theory. A further section discusses a (e.g. Veblen, Commons, Durkheim, Weber):
number of issues arising from our explo- ‘A system of action is said to be institution-
ration of the relationship between institu- alized to the extent that actors in an ongoing
tional theory and critical theory before we relation oriented their action to a common set
draw together our main arguments. of normative standards and value patterns’
(Scott, 1995/2001: 15, emphasis in original).
For Parsons, compliance to institutional
norms ‘is a need disposition in the actor’s
INSTITUTIONAL THEORY AND personality structure’ (1951: 37, cited by
INSTITUTIONALIZATION Scott, 1995/2001: 12), where compliance is
motivated by the moral authority that institu-
Before ... institutionalisms themselves become tional norms exert over the individual. Actors
institutionalized – reified as distinct ‘theoretical feel compelled to comply because refusal or
strategies’, codified in textbooks, and taken as failure to do so results in feelings of anomie
given by practitioners – we had better take stock. and, at the extreme, mortification.
(Jepperson, 1991: 143–144)
Critics of this (functionalist) conception of
Jepperson cautions against a forgetfulness of institutionalization have argued persuasively
the particularity of institutional theory – in that it attributes ‘needs’ to actors which are
the sense that it is a construction based upon seemingly either unconditioned by processes
specific, institutionalized assumptions. of institutionalization or unequivocally well
Within this particularity, there is consider- disposed to them. A widely canvassed remedy
able diversity and debate (DiMaggio and for this limitation is to emphasize the role of
Powell, 1991) and recurrent attempts to rec- interests, instrumental action and/or rational
oncile internal differences (e.g. Hirsch and choice (Alexander, 1983; Silverman, 1970).
Lounsbury, 1997). Institutional theory’s par- In this remedy we encounter an example of a
ticularity has been frequently surveyed and flip-flopping between (functional) structural-
typified (e.g. Scott; 1991; DiMaggio and ist and action-theoretic accounts of social
Powell, 1991) but, for the most part, has not action. The dynamic of the flip-flop depends
been critically addressed. In this section, we upon each pole being simultaneously recog-
examine this particularity through a series of nized and denied as one or other side of
reflections upon institutional theory’s ‘take’ the dualisims privileged, and subsequently
on institutionalization. We consider the con- found to be unbalanced by advocates of the
tributions of a number of leading proponents alternative pole. So, for example, Parsons’
of institutional theory and pay particular systems-theoretic conceptualization of insti-
attention to Berger and Luckmann’s discus- tutionalization is censured for assuming a
sion of institutionalization as this has pro- model of human action in which compliance
vided a key source of inspiration and with moral authority is governed by the
EXAMINING ‘INSTITUTIONALIZATION’: A CRITICAL THEORETIC PERSPECTIVE 677

‘need’ to internalize its order(s) rather than, the process of institutionalization, paying
say, a calculation by agents that involves the particular attention to how ‘agency’ and
strategic development of, or identification ‘power’ are formulated in their thinking:
with, particular norms and values.
Externalization – the production, in social interac-
It is notable that mention of agency is tion, of symbolic structures whose meaning comes
largely excluded from Meyer and Rowan’s to be shared by participants [in particular social
(1977/1991) classic paper where their rejection worlds, e.g. the world of institutional theory];
of methodological individualism is clearly sig- Objectification – the process by which this produc-
tion ‘comes to confront him as a facticity outside of
nalled in the definition of institutionalization:
himself’ as something ‘out there’, as a reality expe-
Institutionalized rules are classifications built into rienced in common with others [e.g. the ‘institu-
society as reciprocated typifications or interpreta- tionalisms’ to which Jepperson (1991: 144) refers].
tions (Berger and Luckmann, 1966: 54). Such rules And only then comes Internalization – the process
may be simply taken for granted or maybe sup- by which the objectivated world is ‘retrojected into
ported by public opinion or the force of law ... consciousness in the course of socialization. (Scott,
Institutionalization involves the process by which 1995/2001: 40, emphases omitted and added,
social processes, obligations, or actualities come to citing Berger and Luckmann, 1966: 60–61)
take on rule-like status in social thought and
action. (Meyer and Rowan, 1977/1991: 42) The emphasis on ‘facticity’, ‘out there’, ‘out-
Writing from the structuralist pole of the side of himself’ serves to counteract Parsons’
dualism (see above), Meyer and Rowan omit functionalist accent on the moment of inter-
reference to actors’ orientations and also nalization. On the other hand, Berger and
exclude consideration of power in respect of Luckmann account for institutionalization in
the conditions of institutionalization as well terms of ‘the important psychological gain’
as its consequences, possibly because they (echoes of Parsons) that institutionalization
equate the conceptualization of power with a delivers as it narrows choices and ‘thereby
notion of one individual or group possessing opens up a foreground for deliberation and
the power to secure their interests despite the innovation’ (1966: 71). There is little or no
resistance of others. consideration of how, for example, the very
The development of neo-institutional sense of agency emerges through processes
theory has involved a rehabilitation of a of institutionalization; or how, in Foucault’s
notion of agency (and power and interests) so terms, human beings become subjectified as
as to account for processes of change that, in they/we are made into subjects through par-
part at least, are attributed to the interven- ticipation in such processes. Relatedly, there
tions of powerful agents (e.g. institutional is no appreciation of the ambivalence of the
entrepreneurs and social movements, see ‘gain’ secured by habitualization (see
especially DiMaggio, 1988). In order to fur- Willmott, 1986). As a consequence, when
ther develop and deepen our reflections on considering the ‘controlling character’
institutionalization, we turn to Berger and (Berger and Luckmann, 1966: 72) of institu-
Luckmann’s The Social Construction of tionalization, Berger and Luckmann under-
Reality which has provided the theoretical stand it as something that is ‘inherent’, and
underpinning and legitimacy for much insti- not mediated by relations of power.
tutional theory (Gulrajani and Lok, 2005). In conceiving of institutionalization as
occurring ‘whenever there is a reciprocal
typification of habitualized actions by types
of actors’ (1966: 72), Berger and Luckmann
Institutionalization in ‘The social assume an unforced reciprocity in processes
of habitualization which is based upon the
construction of reality’
‘psychological gain’ enjoyed by all parties:
We begin by considering Scott’s reading of ‘the most important gain is that each will be
Berger and Luckmann’s three moments in able to predict the other’s actions’ (1966: 74).
678 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Institutionalization is thus represented as have endeavoured to rehabilitate agency (and


universal and politically neutral. It is con- power) to counteract the determining force
ceived as universal in the sense that it has no attributed to institutional pressures by new
historical specificity: all forms of institution- institutionalists. Doubting that change can be
alization are deemed to be equivalent. adequately explained by functionalist fine-
And it is politically neutral, if not amorally tuning or endogenous shocks, neo-institu-
conservative, in the sense that the (political) tionalists have flip-flopped in the direction of
conditions and consequences of institutional- other catalysts – such as (powerful) institu-
ization are excluded from its characteriza- tional entrepreneurs or members of a social
tion. As Berger (1988: 223) has commented, movement – as agents of change.
those who read radicalism into his construc-
tionism laboured under a ‘profound misun-
derstanding’. Berger and Luckmann’s Agency and institutionalization
understanding of social constructionism can
be applied as readily to slave plantations, for Inspired by DiMaggio’s (1988) critique of
example, as it can to movements for the new institutional theory, neo-institutionalist
abolition of slavery without, in either case, analysis is propelled by a taken-for-granted,
making reference to the oppressive or eman- and thus unexamined, assumption that
cipatory character of such institutions. There ‘agency’ must play some (important) part in
is barely a gesture9 towards the possible processes of de/institutionalization and, more
involvement of more or less powerful actors specifically, is a source of diversity or cre-
in establishing and imposing typifications ativity that is productive of innovation and
that, over time, become habitualized and change. A recurrent shortcoming of such
reciprocated or, at least, complied with. Nor, appeals to agency concerns their tendency to
building on critical theorizing, is there overlook how ‘agency’ does not exist exter-
acknowledgment of the powerful, normaliz- nally to, but is itself a powerful product of,
ing effects that all forms of institutionaliza- processes of institutionalization. This is evi-
tion – whether imposed or embraced – exert. dent when ‘agency’ (and ‘interests’ and
The reliance upon Berger and Luckmann ‘power’) are invoked by neo-institutionalists
for theoretical inspiration and legitimation to account for processes of institutionaliza-
combined with, at best, a loose coupling of tion and de-institutionalization without suffi-
power and processes of institutionalization in cient attention being paid to the frameworks
their thinking, helps to account for why that render their reality plausible and/or sup-
‘power’, let alone domination or oppression, port their adoption as explanatory variables.
is so weakly theorized in new institutional Even if, as DiMaggio contends, ‘interest
theory (see Perrow, 1985) and appears as and group conflict’ is important for explain-
an ‘add-on’ in neo-institutional analysis. ing ‘the processes by which institutions
As DiMaggio (1988: 3) comments, in some- emerge, are reproduced, and erode’, it should
thing of an understatement, the presence and not be conceived as external to institutional-
significance of agency and power in institu- ization. Unless a basic premise of institu-
tional theory is ‘somewhat obscure’. tional theory is to be abandoned or at least
They are obscured as a consequence of new severely compromised, then ‘interests’ must
institutional theory’s consensualist, conser- be conceived as identified, whether by agents
vative assumptions that are endorsed, if or their observers, through processes that
not inspired, by Berger and Luckmann’s are institutionalized. The very claim that
conceptualization of institutionalization. ‘behaviour is driven by, and understandable
Consensualist analysis encounters a problem in terms of, the interests of human actors’,
when it comes to accounting for change, for example, is not self-evident but, rather,
at which point neo-institutional theorists an articulation of a particular institution that
EXAMINING ‘INSTITUTIONALIZATION’: A CRITICAL THEORETIC PERSPECTIVE 679

asserts and legitimizes the credibility of such <http:// plato,stanford.edu/entries/critical-


claims. To put it another way, the claim is an theory>).11 The de-naturalizing intent of
articulation of (hegemonic) power that oper- critical theories is generally motivated by
ates to define the world in a distinctive way a value-oriented conviction that the principal
(Friedland and Alford, 1991),10 to naturalize import of knowledge resides in problematiz-
and legitimate that which is institutionalized. ing conventional wisdoms and de-legitimizing
established institutions so as to foster and
facilitate emancipatory change (e.g. the
contribution of feminist knowledge to
CRITICAL THEORY AND identifying and challenging patriarchal
NATURALIZATION OF THE PRESENT practices).
Consider, for example, how reference is
Calling a theory ‘critical’ is, of course, a routinely or implicitly made to the ‘real
provocation as it implies that other theories world’ without any acknowledgement of how
are ‘uncritical’. Yet all theory develops in the ‘reality’ of this world is apprehended or,
relation to some other theory against which, better, constituted, from a particular, histori-
more or less overtly, it defines itself and takes cally and culturally located, point of view. In
critical issue. We noted earlier how variants business textbooks and journal articles as
of institutional theory have established their well as in the classroom, the ‘real world’
claims by being critical of forms of which is evoked is frequently, and more or
un-institutional (e.g. rational choice and con- less explicitly, the one presumed by a point
tingency) theory. To draw an authoritative or of view attributed to senior management – a
stable distinction between theories that are view that tends to take for granted the neces-
‘critical’ and others that are ‘uncritical’ is sity of the status quo, the legitimacy of exec-
untenable, not least because the sense and utives and academics privileged place
significance of their meanings shifts over within it and the heroism of all engaged in
time (the Appendix examines this issue in reproducing the system. This ignores a criti-
relation to critical theory; the other contribu- cal understanding of the present world as
tions to this volume speak to the variety of divisive and destructive, where the relentless
meanings of institutional theory). expansion of capitalism is made possible, in
The signifier ‘critical theory’ is not part, by its routine legitimation in social
restricted here to the Critical Theory of the science and business school education12
Frankfurt School such as Adorno, Marcuse, (in which institutional theory plays its part).
and Habermas (Held, 1980) but, rather, is And yet, some residual, albeit barely
invoked to signal forms of thinking that acknowledged, awareness of the selectivity,
provide a radical challenge to, as contrasted limitations and self-serving rationalization
with, an incremental refinement of, estab- involved in bodies of knowledge, such as
lished conventions of thought and practice, those constructed in business schools, is
with respect to their anticipated emancipa- to be expected. Those engaged in reproduc-
tory impetus or potential. Thus, a chief ing and consuming bodies of knowledge
target of critical theory is patterns of activity that naturalize the present ‘rarely experience
which, in different ways, naturalize the pres- their oppressive character’, yet they ‘can
ent – from Marx’s critique of political econ- feel that burdensome weight if they dare
omy to Derridean deconstructionism. What step outside the presuppositions of under-
critical theories share is a (value-based) con- standing and the sanctioned forms of
cern to develop thinking with a practical inference and presentation of “evidence” ’
intent that may be broadly characterized as (Barnett, 1997: 17). Taking this ‘step
‘aimed at decreasing domination and increas- outside’ is the invitation extended by
ing freedom’ (Stanford Encyclopaedia our exploration of institutional theory from
680 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

an alternative, critical theoretic standpoint. side of modernity. We focus largely on his


Our intent is to develop a picture of institu- writing on power and subjectification, an
tional theory less as an appealing and pros- emphasis that Foucault (1983) himself retro-
perous research programme, and more as an spectively identifies as central. In contrast to
exemplar of Kuhnian ‘normal science’ that institutional theory, which points (ironically)
has contentedly settled down in the suburbia to the mythical quality of rationality without
of social theory (cf. Pollner, 1991). In subjecting it to critique, ‘Foucault questions
Kuhnian terms, we identify institutional the rationality of post-Enlightenment society
theory as a ‘puzzle-solving’ activity within a by focusing on the ways in which many of
given (i.e., institutionalized) framework the enlightened practices of modernity pro-
where any appetite for interrogating the gressively delimit rather than increase
underlying tenets of the framework tends to the freedom of individuals and, thereby, per-
be marginalized or suppressed (Kuhn, 1970: petuate social relations of inequality and
especially p. 35). It is precisely this appetite oppression’ (McNay, 1994: 2). McNay’s
that critical thinking stimulates and feeds as observation on Foucault’s scepticism about
it problematizes what it understands to have ‘post-Enlightenment society’ and his atten-
become naturalized, excluded or glossed. As tiveness to the ‘freedom of individuals’ as
we indicated earlier, our attentiveness to crit- well as ‘relations of inequality and oppres-
ical thinking is highly selective, being sion’ is indicative of a difference between his
restricted to a Foucauldian reading and cri- position and that of many other critical theo-
tique of institutional theory. Accordingly, we rists (e.g. Frankfurt School); it also signals
elaborate our understanding of Foucault’s what distinguishes his thinking on the signif-
critical thinking in the following section icance of institutionalization. We consider
before applying it to examine a number of each of these in turn.
key contributions to institutional theory. Many advocates of critical analysis (as
well as positivists) assume the possibility of
establishing foundational knowledge, either
by applying scientific methodology (e.g.
FOUCAULT, POWER/KNOWLEDGE Bhaskar) or through counterfactual argumen-
AND CRITICAL THEORY tation (e.g. Habermas).14 And, of course, this
gets Foucauldians into trouble, as well as
others who lean in a non-foundationalist15
My role – and that is too emphatic a word – is to
show people that they are much freer than they direction, such as liberals like Rorty, with
feel, that people accept as truth, as evidence, those wedded to some particularism which
some themes which have been built up at a certain they privilege as universalism – whether this
moment during history, and that this so-called evi- is spiritual or secular, or whether it is leftist
dence can be criticized and destroyed. To change or rightist, in inspiration. Non-foundational-
something in the minds of people – that’s the role
of an intellectual. (Foucault, 1988: 10) ists regard the kinds of truth claims asserted
by foundationalists not only as elusive but,
The directness of this quote suggests that when taken seriously, as potentially very
many critics of Foucault – who assert that his dangerous. Notably, they are seen to harbour
approach is totalizing in its denial of subjec- a misplaced assuredness about truths which,
tivity or that he is relativist or nihilist – are at best, prop up the repressive/cynical toler-
difficult to sustain. This is not to deny that his ance of liberal pluralism and, at worst,
writings are multifaceted and susceptible to engender dogmatism and court the dangers
diverse readings.13 Amongst the themes that of totalitarianism. The rejoinder to the
recur in his writings are those on the nature assessment that, lacking any normative basis
of rationality, the relationship between truth for critique, non-foundationalism harbours
and power and an examination of the dark relativism and nihilism is that, ultimately, the
EXAMINING ‘INSTITUTIONALIZATION’: A CRITICAL THEORETIC PERSPECTIVE 681

authority of foundationalist critique relies idea of rationality is identified as a normative


upon self-referentiality with regard to (partic- imperative with which modern organizations
ular) assumptions and assertions about its and their members conform to ‘increase their
authority that can be supported only by refer- legitimacy and survival prospects’ (Meyer
ence to the very assumptions upon which it and Rowan, 1977/1991: 41). However, in
relies. Acknowledging the limitations and institutional theory, this problematizing of
hazards of all forms of thinking, critical rationality is not connected to (ethical) issues
thinking included, is, despite the lack of cer- (e.g. of freedom). Rather, the study of ration-
tainty, considered by anti-foundationalists to ality is linked to questions of the (scientific)
be more defensible and/or to be of greater adequacy of forms of explanation. In Meyer
social value than to claim or assume that there and Rowan’s case, their analysis concludes
is some independent or non-self-referential with three testable hypotheses. Likewise,
basis for producing knowledge. DiMaggio and Powell (1983: 154) assess
Non-foundationalism is a stance that takes ‘the ultimate value’ of their work in terms of
us away from the quest for transcendental or its ‘predictive utility’ and present a series of
normative criteria that aspire to provide the hypotheses for empirical testing. In each
definitive identification of what, for example, case, the theory-laden nature of empirical
is (essentially) oppressive or emancipatory. findings collection/construction is unac-
Turning away from this alluring but treacher- knowledged. A perspective that is latently
ous fantasy, we are obliged to face up to our normative (the value of predictive science) is
reliance upon whatever ‘standards of ration- presented as descriptive or positive.
ality and justice are available to us within the In Foucault’s study of rationality, the focus
specific contexts in which we find ourselves’ is on its ethical significance, not its status as
(Sawicki, 1994: 352). Such standards are not a variable in the development of an empiri-
regarded as hopelessly flawed or useless in cal-analytic science of prediction and con-
relation to some higher ideal. Rather, their trol. His focus is on what, loosely, may be
(limited) value and their (inherent) ‘danger- termed the institutionalization and reproduc-
ousness’ is recognized (Foucault, 1984: 343). tion of ‘inequality and oppression’ (McNay,
As Dreyfus and Rabinow (1986: 118) assess 1994: 2) that takes the form of routine and
Foucault’s stance, it ‘has never been to ambivalent subjectification as well as more
denounce power per se nor to propound truth overt and unequivocal subjection. There is no
but to use his analysis to shed light on the (scientistic) assumption or pretence that
specific dangers that each specific type of some objective measure of ‘inequality and
power/knowledge produces’. What, for oppression’ can be devised and applied.
Foucault is uniquely dangerous about moder- Instead, all truth claims, including those of
nity is that ‘everything becomes a target for institutional theory, are understood to be
normalization’ (Hiley, 1988: 103). Such nor- embedded in, and subject to, evaluation by
malization, we argue, includes the study of relations of power-knowledge; and it is
institutionalization. within the specificity of these relations that
Turning now to the question of Foucault’s their meaning and significance is fashioned.
distinctive position on the nature and signifi- Taking this stance, it would be inconsistent to
cance of rationality and institutionalization, discredit as bogus or incorrect forms of
we first note that, for institutional theorists, power-knowledge that ascribe truth to the
human action is infused by value in the form findings of an empirical-analytical concep-
of ‘social entanglements and commitments’ tion of science preoccupied with hypothesis
(Selznick, 1992: 232), the implication being testing. Instead, Foucault’s approach com-
that rationality is a myth, at least to the extent mends critical reflection upon the particular
that this infusion is unacknowledged (e.g. in (institutionalized) basis upon which seem-
rational choice theory). The (institutionalized) ingly authoritative, universal claims are
682 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

founded; and it advocates close attentiveness power that underpins the assessment
to the (political) effects of believing such that ‘Perhaps no writer of the last half cen-
knowledge to be true. tury has done more to illuminate the nature
of power than Michel Foucault’ (Wolin,
1988: 179).
For Foucault, there are two related kinds
Power: juridical and disciplinary
of normalizing power: ‘disciplinary power’
A significant area in which Foucault has and ‘bio-power’. ‘Bio-power’ is at work in
opened up epistemological space is in the the subjugation of human bodies; and the
study of power where he challenges the nat- control of populations by making clear what
uralization of a view of power that conceives is ‘normal’ and what is not. Normalizing
of it as possessed by unitary, ‘sovereign’ effects are articulated through discursive for-
political (individual or collective) agents mations such as psychiatry, medicine, man-
(Foucault, 1977, 1979a, 1979b, 1980). So agement and social work. ‘Disciplinary
doing, Foucault does not deny, or seek to power’ renders specific individuals or groups
invalidate, the force of what he characterizes of people orderly and regimented through the
as the ‘juridical’ conception of power (see development and use of technologies of
Foucault, 1979a: especially p. 7 and 1994: assessment and surveillance – technologies
especially p. 42 et seq). After all, he makes that became widely disseminated through
no assumption that power has an essence organizations and institutions. Disciplinary
which conventional wisdom fails to mirror; power is conceived to operate ‘through
instead, he problematizes its exclusivity by a multiplicity of organisms, forces, energies,
posing an alternative to the established, materials, desires, thoughts, etc.’ (Foucault,
juridical view.16 That is, additionally, he 1994: 35). Such power, Foucault contends,
invites us to conceive of power as productive ‘must be analysed as something which
of extensive, subjectifying processes of nor- circulates ... It is never localized here or
malization – which he associates with the there, never in anybody’s hands, never
development of modern organizations and appropriated as a commodity or piece of
which he also understands to be ‘embodied wealth. Power is employed and exercised
in the background of everyday practices’ through a netlike organization’ (Foucault,
(Dreyfus, 2004). Foucault’s interest is not 1994: 36). Moreover, disciplinary power
primarily directed at the expression of power is not exclusively negative or zero-sum; it is
in its most central and institutionalized forms productive, not just repressive; it is diffuse
such as state apparatuses or class relations. and relational. It is also subjectifying,
Rather, he is concerned to examine how inasmuch that it constitutes subjects as
power relations of inequality and oppression individuals:
are created and maintained in more subtle power produces; it produces reality; it produces
and diffuse ways through ostensibly humane domains of objects and rituals of truth. The individ-
and freely adopted social practices. These ual and the knowledge that may be gained of him
subtle practices can be deeply institutional- belong to this production. (Foucault, 1984: 204–5,
emphasis added).
ized and taken for granted. In modern organ-
izations, such as factories, offices and state Amongst these ‘domains of objects’ is the
agencies, a juridical form of power exercised sense of agency attributed to, and demon-
from above is seen to depend upon, promote strated by, subjects. This could imply that
and even be displaced by a ‘disciplinary’ Foucault’s concept of subjectification is
form of power that objectifies and institu- equivalent to the more established, sociolog-
tionalizes social reality through processes of ical idea of socialization. But this is to jump
normalization and subjectification. It is this to an unsupportable conclusion, as Dreyfus
shift in the conceptualization and analysis of (2004) observes,
EXAMINING ‘INSTITUTIONALIZATION’: A CRITICAL THEORETIC PERSPECTIVE 683

Socialization into norms is the universal way the system’ or simply refusing to act in a respon-
understanding of being or power governs the sive, disciplined manner. As Foucault (1978:
actions of the members of any society. .... how-
95) puts it, ‘where there is power, there is
ever, norms are progressively brought to bear on
‘all aspects of life’... normalization works directly resistance’. Exercises of power are therefore
through new sorts of invisible, continuous prac- endemically vulnerable to both overt and
tices of control Foucault calls micro-practices ... covert resistance that challenges, and may
disciplinary power works meticulously by ordering ultimately displace, its ‘truth’. The effects of
every detail. So, while for Foucault all forms of
juridical as well as disciplinary power
power are bottom up and the understanding of
power as monarchical misses this important fact, are indeterminate as they are contingent upon
nonetheless bio-power is bottom-up in a new and its dispersed targets – the ‘individual or
dangerously totalizing way, so that understanding collective subjects who are faced with a field
power on the model of the power of the ruler of possibilities in which several ways of
covers up an important change in how our prac-
behaving, several reactions and diverse com-
tices are working.
portments may be realized’ (Ezzamel,
Crucially, knowledge and power do not exist 1994: 221).
independently of each other: We have noted how both ‘old’ and ‘neo’
there is no power relation without the correlative versions of institutional theory incorporate
constitution of a field of knowledge, nor any elements of a juridical, top-down conception
knowledge that does not presuppose or constitute of power as they invoke notions of agency
at the same time power relations ... it is not the
and interests to account for processes of
activity of the subject of knowledge that produces
a corpus of knowledge, useful or resistant to de/institutionalization. There is, however, no
power, but power/knowledge, the processes and equivalent to ‘disciplinary power’ in institu-
struggles that traverse it and of which it is made tional theory. This is not entirely surprising
up, that determines the forms and possible as a focus upon subjectification is far
domains of knowledge. (Foucault, 1977: 27–28)
removed from the normal science value-ori-
Foucault draws us towards analysis that entation of institutional theory which focuses
strives to appreciate the terms, and more upon ‘enduring elements of social life’, such
especially, the effects, of particular dis- as ‘logics’ (Lawrence and Suddaby, 2006:
courses with regard to how they articulate 215) rather than the particularity of their sub-
and sustain a ‘regime of truth’ such that a jectifying effects17 (but see Lok, 2007 and
particular ‘object of discourse’, or social Khan, Munir and Willmott, 2007 for exam-
objectivity, is successfully institutionalized. ples of how Foucauldian thinking may be
Foucault’s attentiveness to power/knowledge introduced into the examination of processes,
explores how it is productive of subjects who e.g. institutional entrepreneurship typically
are normalized through the operation of studied by institutional theorists).
‘micro-practices’ that regulate numerous
aspects of their/our everyday lives.
Technologies of power (that include manage- Power and subjectification
ment practices such as accounting and infor-
mation systems) not only aspire to identify, To recap, what institutional theorists charac-
monitor and control numerous aspects of life, terize as ‘institutionalization’ can alterna-
but, crucially, provide a seductive regime of tively be understood from a more critical,
truth for governing subjects who come to Foucauldian standpoint as ‘normalization’,
comply with its disciplinary logic. where human beings become bound to the
Yet, for Foucault, the effect of power’s identities to which they/we are subjected.
operation is by no means totalizing as it oper- Foucault is distinctly attentive to the discipli-
ates upon recalcitrant material (humans) – as, nary processes through which subjects are
for example, when the ‘objects’ of discipli- constituted as an effect of participation in
nary technologies respond by ‘gaming the social institutions, as contrasted to the
684 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

(juridical) establishment and enactments of (Simons, 1995: 82). For Foucault, institu-
sovereignty by one group over another. tions are not benign; nor are they mere objects
Notably, when discussing how the human of analysis; they are mobile complexes of
sciences have developed alongside juridical and disciplinary power. Disciplinary
power/knowledge technologies invested in mechanisms have power effects as they sort,
disciplinary institutions (the prison, the fac- rank, homogenize, differentiate, individualize,
tory, the school, etc.), Foucault (1979b: 305) and produce the rules that are at once both
links power with the subject, and draws inclusive and exclusive of populations of indi-
attention to specific forms (modalities) of viduals. Foucault is attentive to the productive
power: and insidious effects of power, and to the
resistance that discloses the limits of power.
a certain policy of the body, a certain way of ren- To recap key elements of our argument,
dering the group of men docile and useful. This
policy required the involvement of definite rela-
we have identified institutional theory’s con-
tions of knowledge in relations of power; it called ceptualization of institutionalization as
for a technique of overlapping subjection and preoccupied with explanation rather than
objectification; it brought with it new procedures emancipation, and as methodologically col-
of individualization. ... Knowable man (soul, indi- lectivist and tendentially consensualist with a
viduality, consciousness, conduct, whatever it is
called) is the object-effect of this analytic invest-
tendency to revert to methodological individ-
ment, of this domination-observation. ualism, where change is attributed to wilful
agency that is in possession of some kind of
In everyday activities and routines, normaliz- power. A key difference between Foucault’s
ing power constitutes subjects as agents to approach to the study of power and that of
whom sovereignty is attributed as a ‘natural institutional theorists is the central concern to
entity’, and to which interests are also highlight the operation of unacknowledged
ascribed. Such discourse produces a sense of processes of domination and oppression in
self as a centred, autonomous decision- the guise of normalization and subjectifica-
maker as well as self-affirming beliefs about tion. In Foucauldian analysis, power, con-
the location of power – either as a possession ceived as disciplinary as well as juridical, is
of subjects (agency) or as an enabling/dis- not treated as a ‘bolt on’; and agency/struc-
abling constraint on agency (structure). In his ture dualism is problematized by understand-
later works. Foucault turned his attention ing it as a naturalized product of a particular
more directly to strategies of resistance and power/knowledge complex that frames so
the production of alternative discourses much ‘normal’ social scientific discourse.
whose aim is to challenge dominant dis- With a few exceptions (e.g. Knights, 1992;
courses of power, including technologies of Townley, 1993; Ezzamel and Willmott,
self (Foucault, 1988), at a particular juncture 1998), the important Foucauldian insights
in time and space (see also McWhorter, discussed above have hardly received any
1999). Power is conceptualized as a network attention in the mainstream organization liter-
of relations, rather than as juridical or sover- ature. By way of illustrating the contribution
eign. The effects of its operation are con- that Foucault’s work can offer to organization
ceived as ambivalent and unpredictable but studies we briefly discuss the work of
also potentially ‘dangerous’ as they are Knights and Townley, and refer to less well-
appealing, yet can have unintended, malig- known, critical literature.
nant as well as beneficial consequences. Knights (1992: 515) draws on Foucault’s
These effects include the ambivalent capaci- work to disrupt ‘knowledges that are built on
ties of agency in which subjects become representations deeming to reflect reality’.
absorbed: ‘all subjectifying power endows Examining the study of strategy from a
subjects with some capacities required to Foucauldian standpoint, Knights notes how
be agents, even when it is oppressive’ positivistic studies of strategy objectify
EXAMINING ‘INSTITUTIONALIZATION’: A CRITICAL THEORETIC PERSPECTIVE 685

businesses and their practices, whilst being costing produced ‘governable persons’.
‘oblivious to how their representations actu- Hoskin and Macve (1988) and Carmona et al.
ally constitute the subjectivity of manage- (2002) similarly use historical methods to
ment, as practitioners draw upon these studies show how the inter-connection between
in their exercise of power’ (Knights, 1992: power and knowledge produced modern
523) such that particular features of strategic conceptions of management. Field research
discourse could be self-fulfilling in their as diverse as Knights and Collinson (1987),
effects. Knights (1992: 529) emphasizes the Preston, Cooper and Coombs (1992) and
constitutive power of discourse by arguing Ezzamel, Lilley and Willmott (2004) illus-
that ‘strategic discourse and practice repre- trate the insights derived by examining
sent a set of power-knowledge relations that disciplinary processes of subjectification and
constitutes the subjectivity of managers and the construction of specific conceptions
employees’. of organization and management. Finally,
Townley (1993) draws on Foucault to the empirical studies of Haigh (2006),
present human resource management (HRM) Preston, Cooper, Scarbrough and Chilton
as ‘the construction and production of knowl- (1995) and Kosmala MacLullich (2003)
edge’, and as a way of ‘rendering organiza- indicate how the analysis of normalization
tions and their participants calculable arenas, can be applied to investment, ethical and
offering, through a variety of technologies, audit practices.
the means by which activities and individuals Space limitations do not permit us to
become knowable and governable’ (1993: engage with these illustrations in more detail,
526, original emphasis). She shows how the nor to comment on the extent to which we
disciplinary technologies of HRM govern endorse their readings of Foucault. Rather,
populations of employees, in particular the their work is cited here as examples of how
distribution of individuals into work space, Foucault’s work can be usefully extended to
their spatial enclosure, their partitioning from areas of organization studies as an alternative
each other, their ordering into hierarchical way of seeing, rather than as a replacement
positions, as well as the use of temporal or corrective, to other research approaches.
(timetable) examination, and confessional In the following section, we examine in some
technologies to construct the subjectivity of detail some of the recent attempts made in
employees and to render them calculable, the organizational literature to refine institu-
analyzable and governable. Townley (1995) tional theory and comment on the extent to
extends this analysis to examine the discipli- which such attempts are commensurate with
nary effects of technologies of accounting our reading of Foucault’s work.
and performance measurement. Her work has
been developed by Covaleski, Dirsmith,
Heian and Samuel (1998) in their Foucaudian
examination of HRM practices in accounting THE LIMITS OF REFINING
firms, by Ezzamel and Willmott (1998) in INSTITUTIONAL THEORY
their examination of teamwork in manufac-
turing, and by Grey (1994) in his analysis of We now apply our reflections on institutional
the disciplinary effects of conceiving one’s theory, critical thinking and Foucauldian
work as a ‘career’. analysis – to consider the interventions by
There has also been considerable research advocates of institutional theory who have
using Foucaudian concerns about the disci- pointed to, and proposed ways of overcom-
plinary power of management practices such ing, its limitations. Initially, we elaborate and
as accounting. Notably, Miller and O’Leary support our claim that neo-institutionalist
(1987) conduct an historical analysis to show analysis relies upon deinstitutionalized con-
how scientific management and standard ceptions of agency and related, juridical
686 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

understanding of power. We then examine ‘argue that organizational stability is


some examples of how critical thinking, achieved through the exercise of power, con-
including Foucauldian ideas, has been intro- trol, or the negotiations of interdependencies
duced into institutional analysis. for purposes of achieving a predictable or
stable inflow of vital resources and reducing
environmental uncertainty’ (1991: 149,
Incorporating agency, interest and emphasis added). In this turn to agency,
power? DiMaggio, Oliver, Meyer exemplified in the work of both DiMaggio
and Oliver, power is conceived as a posses-
and Jepperson
sion of agents which, when operationalized,
Amongst the more influential reformers of is seen to render behaviour more predictable
institutional theory are DiMaggio (1988) and and thereby attenuate uncertainy. This orien-
Oliver (1991; 1992). DiMaggio (1988: 3) tation differs markedly from Foucault’s nor-
calls for incorporating ‘the role of interest malizing conception of power as a network
and agency’ as a corrective to an analysis of relations whose outcome is indeterminate.
‘predicated on the assumption, often In commenting upon this turn to the role of
implicit, that persons and organizations hold, ‘agency’ in the exercise of power, we focus
and act on, universal interests in survival and upon two related issues. First, the compati-
in the reduction of uncertainty’. Oliver bility of its methodologically individualistic
(1991) follows this lead as she commends conceptualization of action with the founda-
resource dependency theory in order to pay tional assumptions of institutional theory;
‘attention to the role of organizational self- and, secondly, the focus upon a juridical con-
interests and active agency in organizational ception of power to the exclusion of other
responses to institutional pressures and concepts of power, such as those articulated
expectations’ (1991: 45). The intent of these by Foucault.
interventions is to acknowledge and under- As Friedland and Alford (1991) incisively
stand how ‘institutionalization is a product of point out, DiMaggio’s proposal to correct
the political efforts of actors to accomplish the ‘defocalization of interest and agency’
their ends’ (DiMaggio, 1988: 13), with a (1991: 3) assumes a ‘materialist-idealist
view to extending the capability and reach of dualism’. This dualism is evident, for
institutional theory in relation to its study of example, in the view ‘that actors have objec-
‘strategic responses to the institutional envi- tive interests, which can be understood inde-
ronment’ (Oliver, 1991: 151). pendently of the actors’ understandings’
Revisions to institutional theory that (1991: 244) and to which, presumably, social
attribute change to the agency of actors scientists have privileged knowledge and
depart, as DiMaggio (1988: 11) notes, from access. In such formulations, agency appears
the understanding that institutional and inter- to exist externally to, and to operate in
est-based frameworks are incommensurable some measure outside of, processes of insti-
or ‘antagonistic’ – a position which, for both tutionalization. Thus, DiMaggio asserts that
him and Oliver, is seen to impede ‘the devel- ‘there is much about the processes by which
opment of a more comprehensive theoretical institutions emerge, are reproduced, and
apparatus’ (1988). Such revisions are intro- erode, that cannot be explained without ref-
duced as a remedy for what is regarded as the erence to interest and agency’ (1988: 3). In
restrictive capacity of institutional theory ‘to DiMaggio’s rehabilitation of agency within
develop predictive and persuasive accounts institutional theory, actors are susceptible to
of the origins, reproduction, and erosion of the influence of institutions only when their
institutionalized processes’ (1988, emphasis real interests are adequately catered for, or
added). In a similar vein, Oliver approvingly are recognized by them.18 Oliver (1991) is
quotes resource dependency theorists who less explicit about her conception of agency,
EXAMINING ‘INSTITUTIONALIZATION’: A CRITICAL THEORETIC PERSPECTIVE 687

although in drawing upon resource depend- power, is also evident in more recent work,
ency theory, she relies on a juridical concep- where change is seen as a problem that is
tion of power: she does not conceive of the ‘solved’ by identifying the agents who ‘must’
organization, the environment, or, indeed, the possess power to change things – institutional
perspective that differentiates them, as artic- entrepreneurs or social movements. These
ulations of power in the manner suggested by ‘powerful’ agents are said to establish some-
Foucault. The power attributed to organiza- thing that does not simply reproduce what
tions appears to develop and be exercised already exists (Suddaby and Greenwood,
independently of the institutional framework 2005), but whose ethical or political properties
and processes through which organizational are irrelevant to such analysis. This approach
practices are enacted. These are the taken- exemplifies a mode of knowledge production
for-granted ‘context’ against which power is which aspires to capture, order, and reorder
exercised by actors pursuing their interests. such ‘objects’. Such (power-) knowledge
In short, a basic limitation of both enhances the position of comparative sover-
DiMaggio’s and Oliver’s theoretical posi- eignty of a certain class of actors (e.g. man-
tions is their ‘institution-free conception of agers, technocrats) in identifying ‘better’
interest and power’ (Friedland and Alford, (from their perspective) strategic responses
1991: 244). The materialist-idealist dualism to institutional pressures. A Foucauldian
effectively ‘defocalizes’ (using DiMaggio’s response to this endeavour is not necessarily
terminology), processes of institutionaliza- to deny the potential benefits of prediction
tion with respect to both what the signifier and managerialism, per se, but rather to
‘interests’ (and ‘agency’ and ‘power’) emphasise that belief in the possibility of pre-
is intended to describe (its referent) and to dicting the outcome of power is conditional
what it signifies (see Hirschman, 1986, cited upon the exclusion of a conceptualization of
in Friedland and Alford). Put bluntly, there is power as a network of relations, or problema-
a lurch to methodological individualism tizing the ethical rights of managers.
where institutional entrepreneurs somehow Turning to the work of Meyer and Jepperson
evade or ‘escape the rules, routines, and (2000), they valuably remind us that the mean-
norms of institutional fields’ (Levy and Egan, ing and significance of terms such as agency
2003: 811). and interests is neither self-evident nor intransi-
In pointing to this example of structure- tive. Rather, such terms are articulations of a
agency flip-flopping in neo-institutional cultural system in which ‘the modern actor [is
theory, we stress that DiMaggio’s and constructed] as an authorized agent for various
Oliver’s proposed refinements seek to avoid interests via an ongoing relocation into society
deficiencies attributed to (new) institutional of agency originally located in transcendental
theory, but suggest that their analysis resem- authority’ (2000: 100). Meyer and Jepperson
bles a version of action theory rather than effectively admonish those who appeal to
one that is institutionalist. Their conceptual- agency or interests – for example, in order to
ization of power, self-interest and politics explain processes of institutionalization – when
highlights our earlier observations about the the appeal to agency fails to recognize how any
conservative value-orientation of institu- conception of agency relies on a set of ‘precon-
tional theory. For, despite Oliver’s character- scious understandings’ (DiMaggio, 1988: 3)
ization of interests as ‘political’ (1991: 147), that modern actors come to acquire and broadly
she treats politics as synonymous with bar- share. This critique is subtly articulated when
gaining, where the substance or issues being Meyer and Jepperson deconstruct the taken for
bargained over are regarded as an ethically grantedness of agency and ‘agenticness’ in so
irrelevant feature of institutionalization. much social and organization theory:
Reliance on a juridical view of power, to Most social theory has recognized one way or
the exclusion of bio-power and disciplinary another that core social entities have been more
688 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

elaborately constructed over time. The agentic that agency, for example, is external to,
aspect and its underlying spiritual devolution is less and operates in some measure outside of,
well recognized. Modern individuals, organizations,
processes of institutionalization. But
and nation-states, in becoming legitimated agents
for their underlying interests, incorporate the highly Meyer and Jepperson have virtually nothing
standardizing responsibility to enact imagined to say about power or hegemony, and in
moral and natural principles. The proper, modern this sense their contribution is radically
agentic individual, for instance, manages a life, car- conservative in the tradition of Berger and
rying a responsibility not only to reflect self-interest
Luckmann (1966).
but also the wider rationalized rules conferring
agency ... Modern agentic actors involve them-
selves in all sorts of efforts elaborating their
agentic capabilities. (2000: 107, emphasis added)

From agency to contradiction?


Here we have a strong and timely reassertion Seo and Creed
of the distinctive, central idea of institutional
theory that the key to understanding human Seo and Creed (2002) take up and amplify
behaviour is the manner and process of its Meyer and Rowan’s observation (1977/1991)
institutionalization. They recall that the that gaining legitimacy by conforming to
‘proper, modern, agentic individual’ is a prevailing logics within the institutional field
product of a particular institution that consti- can be damaging for efficiency and social
tutes and legitimizes their/our sense of reproduction, notwithstanding possibilities
agency and associated responsibility for the for a loose coupling between logics and
enactment of ‘imagined moral and natural action. They formulate this insight as contra-
principles’ (2000), including the seeming dictions in a way that builds upon Friedland
naturalness of self-interest and the preoccu- and Alford’s (1991) thesis that contemporary
pation with its preservation and pursuit. Western societies are organized on, and
Given that Meyer and Jepperson question through, diverse and contradictory logics,
the way in which agency has been attended such as those of capitalist enterprise, family
to in institutional theory, it is disappointing values, democratic principles, etc. They
that, despite their observations on modern argue that it is disjunctures within and
actorhood – which they helpfully associate between these logics that prompt agents to
with ‘European efforts’ and particularly with act in ways that produce change.
Foucault’s emphasis on how specific features Seo and Creed’s (2002) work engages
of actorhood are generated by specific insti- directly with critical theory which, as they
tutional structures (2000: 102, note 3) – they note, ‘raises concerns about the possibilities
pay no attention to Foucault’s thinking on of dominance and alienation in the processes
power and knowledge. One way to interpret of institutionalization that are seldom dis-
this silence is to understand their analysis as cussed in the managerialist treatments of
a sophisticated restatement of an established institutional phenomena’ (2002: 241). They
conservative conception of institutional also observe that institutional theory, in con-
theory. What, in neo-institutionalist analysis, trast, ‘treats rules, logics of action, and insti-
appears to escape the operation of institution- tutionalized patterns of behaviour ... as
alization is understood by Meyer and something neutrally embedded within
Jepperson to be a product of ‘deeply held, people’s cognitions and/or as external givens
unexamined logics’ that currently form the of the broader society’ (2002). This assess-
framework ‘within which reasoning takes ment echoes our earlier reflections on
place’ (Horn, 1983: cited by Suddaby and the divergent value-orientations of critical
Greenwood, 2005: 37). and institutional theory, and our comments
Meyer and Jepperson’s (2000) argument on the latter’s consensualist and conservative
is a potent rejoinder to those who contend leanings.
EXAMINING ‘INSTITUTIONALIZATION’: A CRITICAL THEORETIC PERSPECTIVE 689

To explore the operation and significance formation and identification involving


of contradictions for analyzing change, Seo processes characterized by Foucault as
and Creed commend a dialectical version of subjectification.
critical theory (Benson, 1977). But they
simultaneously cling to a neo-institutionalist,
juridical conception of agency and power. Foucault at last? Lawrence, Winn
Processes of institutionalization are under-
and Jennings
stood to involve ‘political struggle involving
various participants who have divergent The distinctive way in which Foucault con-
interests and unequal power’ (2002: 229, nects the exercise of disciplinary power to
emphasis added). A juridical attribution of the process of subjectification is central to
power is assumed that excludes considera- Lawrence et al.’s (2001) examination of ‘the
tion of its hegemonic and net-like operation. set of power relations that support the
Echoing DiMaggio (1988), they contend that process [of institutionalization]’ (2001: 629).
change is instigated by agents when their As they put it, ‘the power of discipline ... pro-
‘ideas and interests are not adequately served vide(s) the basis for agency in the form of
by the existing social arrangements’ (2002: identity’ (2001: 636). Identity is understood
229). Such ideas and interests are presented to precede agency, and is not theorized as
as ‘givens’ that are self-evidently in a relation something that is chosen by (autonomous)
of more or less tension with ‘given’ social agents. Contrasting disciplinary power with
arrangements. There is no consideration of ‘influence’, which is conceived as being con-
how the identification of interests, or of the cerned with ‘shaping a subject’s actions’
‘needs’ that are ‘unmet’ (2002: 229), or the (2001: 636), processes of institutionalization
assessment of existing arrangements is medi- governed by disciplinary power are under-
ated by (contradictory) processes of institu- stood to ‘shap(e) the actual formation of the
tionalization. subject’ (2001: 636) and to be involved in ‘the
Seo and Creed’s contribution to the refine- constitution of their targets’ subjectivity’
ment of institutional theory usefully points (2001: 636). While this is useful, precisely
towards contradictory, rather than simply what is involved in such ‘constitution’
competing, forms of institutionalization. receives no attention beyond a cursory and
Perversely, their use of critical theory to pro- descriptive reference to Foucault’s observa-
vide an explanation of change directly con- tions concerning the role of hierarchical
tradicts what they initially identify as ‘one of observation, normalizing judgement and
the most central assertions in institutional examination in ‘maintaining power relations’
theory – that actors and their interests are (2001: 636) through the shaping of subjects’
institutionally constructed’ (2002: 222–3, formation. Their relevance of these observa-
emphasis added). Seo and Creed’s ‘dialecti- tions for developing an alternative view of the
cal perspective’ aspires to show how contra- nature and significance of institutionalization
dictions in and between institutional is unexplored. Instead, Foucault’s ‘disciplinary
arrangements induce the realization of trans- power’ is taken up to analyze the temporal
formative agency such that agents’ latent dimension of institutionalization processes.
interests are expressed through processes of More specifically, ideas drawn from
institutional change. While this is a com- Foucault’s Discipline and Punish (1977) are
mendable attempt to address the paradox of deployed to populate one cell within a 2 x 2
embedded agency, Seo and Creed fall back typology of power-centred mechanisms of
on essentialist, or at least de-institutional- institutionalization, which is distinguished
ized, notions of ‘need’ and ‘interests’ in their by its generation of comparatively slow and
conception of agency that are somehow stable processes of institutionalization (see
transcendent of their institutional(ized) fig. 2, p. 630 and Propositions 3a and 3b).
690 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Lawrence et al. (2001) claim that modes of employ each of the four types of institutional
power target either ‘subjects’ or ‘objects’ mechanisms’ (2001: 641). In short, it is busi-
when, arguably, it is always subjects that are ness as usual for institutional theory.
targeted and subjectified by discipline, even
when their subjectivity is disregarded (as in
the case of the power-knowledge effects of
actuarial tables or standard costs). From a CONCLUDING REMARKS
Foucauldian perspective, actors rarely have
‘no choice’ (2001: 631), as Lawrence et al. Our reflections on ‘Examining Institutional-
contend. Disciplinary power is not distin- ization’ are premised on the understanding
guished from juridical power by the attribu- that accounts of the world generated by insti-
tion of choice to those who are subjectified tutional theory and critical theory are contin-
by it. It may be the case, as Simon (1988) gent upon the value-orientations in which
contends, that ‘Where power once sought to they are embedded. We have pointed to some
manipulate the choice of rational actors, it limits of institutional theory, not with a view
now seeks to predict behaviour and situate to correcting or enhancing it but, rather, to
subjects according to the risks they pose’ show how it articulates a particular, value-
(1988: 772, cited by Lawrence et al., 2001: oriented form of power/knowledge; and,
637). But, as we argued earlier, this does not relatedly, to suggest that it does not have a
exclude consideration of the ways in which monopoly of truth over the nature and signif-
subjects become knowledgeable about such icance of institutionalization.
changes and seek to resist them. We have argued that institutional theory
Frustratingly, what we encounter in understands institutionalization as a univer-
Lawrence et al.’s application of Foucault’s sal and politically neutral process, albeit one
thinking is an example of how, in the lan- where juridical conceptions of ‘agency’,
guage of institutional theory, rhetoric is ‘power’ and ‘interests’ are increasingly
deployed [by academic entrepreneurs] to invoked to account for the emergence or
accommodate and align some new ideas [in demise of institutions. Even though institu-
this case, Foucauldian ideas] to an estab- tional analysis conceives of organizations as
lished, taken-for-granted mode of compre- value-imbued human constructions, rather
hensibility (see Suchman, 1995; Suddaby and than as impersonal, rational entities, its focus
Greenwood, 2005) that strips Foucauldian is on how institutions constrain and facilitate
critical theory of some of its most provocative organizational forms and practices, and not
and original insights. Their domestication upon how institutions, dominate and oppress
of critical thinking is brought home in the as they subjectify human beings. It is guided
concluding section of their article where it is by a conception of knowledge production in
conjectured that contemporary processes of which there is a (positivist) emphasis upon
rationalization ‘involve a movement away prediction and control, as manifest in a pre-
from institutionalization through influence occupation with the identification and meas-
and force and towards discipline and domina- urement of variables, including the power
tion’ (Lawrence et al., 2001: 641) without attributed to agents, that are deemed to pro-
connecting this development to processes of vide a more complete explanation of how
subjectification.19 Moreover, the implications organizational forms converge and change.
of this shift for researching institutionaliza- Institutional theory, we contend, is institu-
tion are framed not in terms of the effects of a tionalized within a tradition of normal sci-
putative shift to discipline and domination on ence which assumes an incrementalist and
subjects but, rather, in a neo-positivist con- imperialist conception of theory develop-
cern with the question of the ‘resources or ment, inspired by the belief that it should be
abilities ... needed on the part of agents to possible to devise one, single, universally
EXAMINING ‘INSTITUTIONALIZATION’: A CRITICAL THEORETIC PERSPECTIVE 691

valid theory that successfully incorporates it uncritically deploys dominant ‘cultural


and integrates every possible relevant understandings’ to present a benign and
element. totalizing understanding of institutionaliza-
The particular value-orientation that pro- tion in which, for example, the institutional-
pels and legitimizes critical theory, in con- ization of agency is unaddressed. We have
trast, produces knowledge that aims to also noted how recent discussion of institu-
‘denaturalize the present’, and thereby tionalization has centred on the question
prompt and facilitate processes of emancipa- of how the theory might be enhanced by
tion.20 Consistent with this impulse, we have remedying a perceived neglect of inter alia
engaged critical theory to problematize the ‘agency’, ‘power’, ‘interests’, ‘inequality’,
institutionalization of institutional analysis ‘meaning’ (e.g. Beckert, 1999; Whittington,
rather than to revise or replace its distinctive 1992; Zilber, 2002; Lounsbury and
power/knowledge framing of institutional- Ventresca, 2003; Phillips, 2003) where it is
ization. Specifically, we have suggested the assumed that any shortcoming identified in
relevance of Foucault’s discussions of disci- institutional theory can be corrected by
plinary forms of power and processes of sub- applying a restitutive patch in a way that will
jectification for thinking critically about how not transgress or compromise its particular-
to study institutionalization. ity. But these interventions have not reflected
In applying a critical, Foucauldian, read- on how the particularity of institutional
ing to the central tenets and some key texts of theory has permitted or spawned such limita-
institutional theory our position is that there tions. A consistently institutionalist perspec-
is nothing inherently unacceptable about tive, in contrast, could be expected to
defining and accounting for institutionaliza- conceive of ‘agents’, and whatever is attrib-
tion in a particular way or, indeed, in many uted to them (e.g. ‘interests’ and ‘power’)
different ways. Nor is there anything insup- as embedded manifestations of processes
portable in the ambition to develop more of institutionalization, and as existing exter-
robust, normal science explanations of insti- nally to such processes. What Meyer, Boli
tutionalization so long as the contingency of and Thomas (1987: 13, quoted in Scott,
the definition is fully acknowledged and sub- 1995/2001: 42) have observed of ‘most
sequently recalled. Our point is that what is social theory’ would seem to be no less appli-
presented, and what is counted, as ‘plausible’ cable to neo-institutionalist analysis:
or ‘adequate’ is not a reflection of the corre-
Most social theory takes actors (from individuals to
spondence of a particular approach with what states) and their actions as real, a priori, elements
it aspires to refer to or ‘capture’ but, rather, .... [in contrast] we see the ‘existence’ and charac-
its resonance with available, and perhaps teristics of actors as socially constructed and highly
dominant, discourses to which it is heard to problematic, and action as the enactment of broad
institutional scripts rather than a matter of inter-
contribute in an affirming or disruptive
nally generated and autonomous choice, motiva-
manner. To articulate this argument in terms tion and purpose.
more familiar to institutional theorists:
actors employ rhetorical devices to connect ele- Meyer et al.’s (1987) commentary invites
ments of the existing or proposed [meaning] to the development of a more institutionally
broader cultural understandings in order to sup- grounded analysis of agency (and subjectifi-
port or challenge the comprehensibility of a [defi- cation) that has not been taken up by
nition]. (Suddaby and Greenwood, 2005: 41, institutional theorists. Foucault’s thinking
emphasis added)
resonates, as Meyer and Jepperson
We have emphasized how institutional (2000, note 3) note, with the institutionalist
theory advances an important alternative to understanding that actors’ ‘characteristics’
methodologically individualist analysis but are ‘socially constructed and highly
we have also argued that, in this process, problematic’. But there is nothing equivalent,
692 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

in institutional theory, to the Foucauldian of more critical thinking. In one of their more
view that everyday processes of institutional- radically phenomenological moments,21
ization exemplify a disciplinary form of Berger and Luckmann (1966: 82) caution
power that is productive yet also dangerous that ‘great care is required in any statements
in respect of its subjectifying effects. In insti- one makes about the “logic” of institutions’.
tutional theory, disciplinary power is either Why do they urge this vigilance? Because
unrecognized or domesticated (Lawrence ‘the logic [of institutions] does not reside in
et al., 2001). Agency is displaced by a focus the institutions and their external functional-
upon ‘broad institutional scripts’ (new ities, but in the way these are treated in
institutional theory) or it is treated reflection about them’ (1966). What is con-
as the locus of a previously missing variable, ceived, or passes, for the logic of institutions
in the form of power that is believed to is inescapably an articulation of a particular
enhance its explanatory capability. This is (value-oriented) discourse – such as institu-
illustrative of how ‘old’, ‘new’ and ‘neo’ tional or critical theory – not a reflection of
institutional analysis tends to flip-flop the social practices that are represented
between ‘structure’ and ‘agency’. through these discourses. The dimming of
When faced with anomalies within institu- this insight – that ‘reflective consciousness
tional theory, such as the paradox of embed- superimposes the quality of logic on the
ded agency, some institutional theorists have institutional order’ (1966) – results in, or
turned to critical theories – for example, in makes possible, the dominance, if not
order to support efforts to pay greater atten- monopolization, of the representation of
tion to issues of inequality and conflict institutions and institutional theory by a form
(Hirsch and Lounsbury, 1997; Lounsbury of analysis that is positivistic and conserva-
and Ventresca, 2002, 2003). However, the tive in tenor. This dominance is reflected in
belief that elements of critical theory might the absence of engagement with, or selective
be incorporated to develop a less partial appropriation of, critical theory by institu-
account of aspects of institutionalization tional theorists.
labours, in our view, under a misapprehen- In institutional theory, a posture of schol-
sion. Critical theory does not offer an ‘addi- arly inquisitiveness towards whatever illumi-
tive adjustment’ to other theories (Kuhn, nation critical theory might bring has been
1970: 53). Instead, it advances alternative, exceptional. Institutional theorists have
more radical, ways of representing the seemed reluctant to pay critical theory con-
nature, and especially the significance, of centrated attention – perhaps because of an
processes of institutionalization. That institu- intuition that it could throw up some destabi-
tional theorists have largely ignored, or oth- lizing anomalies or ‘inconvenient facts’, and
erwise dismissed critical theory, including thus ignite a process of theoretical reflection
the thinking of Foucault (e.g. Hirsch and and reassessment which would be counter-
Lounsbury, 1997: 412; Lounsbury and productive to the business-as-usual, ‘puzzle-
Ventresca, 2003: 464), does not, for us, imply solving’ modality of much institutional
that an opportunity to refine institutional theorizing (Kuhn, 1970: 35). Institutional
theory has been missed. Rather, it reflects theory is perhaps, as Jepperson (1991) hints,
and affirms our thesis that institutional something of a prisoner of its own, distinc-
theory and critical theory offer alternative, tive institutional(izing) logic(s); and, in this
value-oriented ways of representing the respect, its analyses run the risk of:
social world, including the nature and signif-
becoming ideologies of the institutions they study.
icance of institutionalization.
Foucault has pointed to the double relation
That said, a more fully institutionalist between truth and power, between forms of
understanding of knowledge, including knowledge and power relations ... (Foucault, 1980).
‘agency’, can prompt a shift in the direction When social scientists import the dominant
EXAMINING ‘INSTITUTIONALIZATION’: A CRITICAL THEORETIC PERSPECTIVE 693

institutional logics into their analyses of individuals They each challenge the authority of individ-
and organizations in unexamined ways, they unre- ualist, rational choice forms of analysis. But
flectively elaborate the symbolic order and social
the forced integration or selective appropria-
practices of the institutions they study. These elabo-
rations subsequently become factors in the repro- tion of elements of critical theory to patch up
duction of these institutions. (Friedland and Alford, weaknesses in institutional theory risks
1991: 260) devaluation of their distinctive value-orienta-
tions and associated contributions to knowl-
That there is limited critical reflection within edge. Respecting and preserving these
institutional theory, as Jepperson (1991) and differences serves to enrich our understand-
Friedland and Alford (1991) point out, may ing and, more specifically, impedes any ten-
not be a problem for institutional theory. dency for a particular conception of
To the contrary, we interpret this restriction institutionalization to become totalizing (Lok
as contributing to institutional theory’s and Willmott, 2006). It is when critical
appeal and influence as it suppresses reflection upon the totalizing tendencies of
consideration of the ethics, institutonalized institutional theory is absent that it presents
as a value-orientation, of knowledge produc- an obstacle to the development of other,
tion. For us, the boundedness of critical critical forms of analysis as it paints them
reflection is a problem of institutional as ‘politically charged’ or ‘biased’ in a
theory. If critical reflection were more ener- way that simply normalizes the ‘bias’, or
getically engaged, it would threaten the very value-orientation, of institution theory.
taken-for-grantedness of institutional theory A challenge for advocates of critical analysis
with respect to the ‘theoretical strategies’ is to show why, instead of seizing upon
(Jepperson, 1991: 143) that give it distinc- ‘agency’ or ‘power’ as overlooked variables
tiveness and ensure its future reproduction. for devising better predictions of institution-
Critical theory illuminates how institutional alization, closer acquaintance with critical
theory ignores power; how neo-institutional theory can offer an alternative for anyone
theory incorporates it in an inconsistent way; interested in studying how power and agency
and shows that neither variant is in a position are institutionalized in forms of normaliza-
to appreciate the subjectifying effects of tion and subjectification.
institutionalization.22 By de-naturalizing the
analysis of institutions and processes of
social ordering constructed by institutional
theory, critical theory opens up the possibil- APPENDIX
ity of alternative forms of institutional analy-
sis, including a Foucauldian attentiveness to Critical theory is a capacious and slippery
subjectification. label invoked to characterize diverse forms of
In addressing the question of what value analysis. Just as institutional theory is, on
critical thinking has for students of institu- occasions, identified with one of its leading or
tionalization, our answer has been that it is favoured (e.g. normative, rational choice,
less germane as a resource for supplying sociological, economic or historical)
ideas or fixes for shortcomings detected in variants, critical theory is sometimes directly
institutional theory. Rather, a way of devel- associated with, or even assumed to be identi-
oping some critical distance from which cal to, either Marxism (in its various forms)
to appreciate the particularity and limits or Critical Theory (distinguished by its
of institutional theory. Appreciating the dif- capitals) of the Frankfurt School (e.g.
ferences between institutional theory and Marcuse, Habermas, etc.). All versions of crit-
critical theory avoids strained, contradictory ical theory draw on a range of disciplines –
and confusing efforts to incorporate elements economics and philosophy, as well as
of critical theory into institutional theory. sociology and psychoanalysis, to advance
694 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

critical thinking within a broad framework of processes. Whatever knowledge is, it cannot be
humanistic Marxism (see Alvesson and justified through metaphors which commit us to
thinking that it is an accurate representation of the
Willmott, 1996, especially ch. 3). Refusing
external world. [It is] what Vattimo calls ‘the myth
the restrictiveness of this intellectual terrain, of transparency ‘... it is language and the social
which contemporary Critical Theorists have negotiation of meaning themselves that need
also sought to extend or revise, a growing to be illuminated to display their constructive
number and range of theories are identified properties and processes. (Johnson and Duberley,
2000: 96–7)
as ‘critical’.
So, in the contemporary context, it is
implausible to equate critical theory with A ‘crisis of representation’ has developed as
Critical Theory although an important conti- a consequence of the view that the referent
nuity with the Frankfurt School is its inter- eludes any transparent or stable representa-
disciplinary orientation and emancipatory tion by the signifier because, it is argued, the
intent. A common, recent, thread is a critique latter can articulate only a particular, histori-
of death in a variety of forms, e.g. of realism, cally and culturally embedded and fre-
of narratology, of the author. Our chapter quently contested, signified. Consider the
may also be read as a critique of the death signifier ‘critical theory’. This term (or text)
threat posed to critical theory in organization is deployed to point to a referent (what criti-
studies by the suffocating expansion of cal theory is) but the contested nature of crit-
(uncritical) institutional theory. The range of ical theory makes it impossible to fully
critical theory resonates strongly with critical stabilize what is signified by this signifier. To
work that is emerging within the field of the extent that some degree of stability is
management under the umbrella of Critical accomplished, it is achieved hegemonically
Management Studies. For proceedings of the by effectively excluding or silencing other
CMS conferences held bi-annually since possible signifieds, and not as a consequence
1999, see <www.mngt.waikato.ac.nz/ejrot/ of providing a fully transparent or compre-
cmsconference/default.htm> and <www. hensive characterization of its referent.
mngt.waikato.ac.nz/ejrot/>; see also Adler, Derrida coined the phrase ‘metaphysics of
Forbes and Willmott, 2007. presence’ to characterize the fantasy of trans-
Developments in the fields of philosophy parency (see also Rorty, 1979). This example
(Wittgenstein), linguistics and semiotics also serves to indicate the centrality of power
(Saussure) and literary criticism (de Man) (hegemony) in the reproduction and transfor-
have become highly influential in the con- mation of human realities, including the real-
temporary formation of critical theory in the ities produced by scientists (Kuhn, 1970:
social sciences, especially through the writ- 206). The resolution, or ‘sedimentation’, of
ings of Foucault, Derrida and, increasingly, such contests is understood, by Foucault
Bourdieu, Lacan and Žižek. What these criti- (1980) for example, as an articulation of
cal thinkers challenge and unpack, in differ- power-knowledge, and not as a product of
ent ways, is the capacity of language to consensus or epistemological privilege, as
provide a faithful representation of that implied, for example, by Berger and
which it aspires to reference (Rorty, 1979). Luckmann (1966) and Tolbert and Zucker
This ‘linguistic turn’ does not necessarily (1999). Post-realist thinking has fuelled the
involve a reductionist equation of social development of critical theory across the
reality with language, as some of its lazy social sciences and humanities in ways that
detractors are inclined to claim. Rather, the have considerably extended its scope, diver-
post-realist position is that, sity and influence.
Analyses identified as ‘functionalist’ and
what we take to be knowledge is constructed in ‘positivist’ have been amongst the primary
and through language. Knowledge has no secure intellectual targets of critical theories as
vantage point outside such socio-linguistic these approaches are inclined to assume the
EXAMINING ‘INSTITUTIONALIZATION’: A CRITICAL THEORETIC PERSPECTIVE 695

functional value of the status quo and/or the NOTES


ahistorical status of social facts (see Alvesson
and Willmott, 1996). But, of course, the aspi- 1 There are many versions of institutional theory.
ration to critique the naturalization of the We focus here on the dominant, sociologically
present, whether in social science or every- informed, versions in the Anglo-American literature.
day life, does not exempt elements and ver- As might be expected, there are regional variations,
and institutional theories that are more historical and
sions of critical theory from critical scrutiny. economic in emphasis (e.g. Menard and Shirley,
In such ways, ostensibly ‘critical standards’ 2005).
within a discipline can ‘generate a relatively 2 Methodological individualism ‘amounts to the
closed world’ (Barnett, 1997: 18) as critical claim that social phenomena must be explained by
theory becomes over-protective of its internal showing how they result from individual actions,
which in turn must be explained through reference
sacred cows. It is the limiting, oppressive to the intentional states that motivate the individual
qualities of such closures in all approaches actors.’ (Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy,
(including its own) that, in different ways, <http://plato.stanford.edu/entries/methodological-
critical theories aspire to bring to conscious- individualism> accessed 03/01/07)
ness and open up to scrutiny. 3 The term ‘value-orientation’ is closely associ-
ated with the work of Weber and is a shorthand
Critiques of naturalization of the present
translation of Weltanshaungen, a term which
are not, of course, limited to problematizing Brubaker (1984) regards as virtually ‘untranslatable’!
how language(s) are engaged to bolster and Value-orientations are not judgements but, rather,
refine what is normal. For critical theories are ‘general views of life and the Universe’ that are
assess processes of emancipation to be frus- both theoretical and practical as ‘they endow the
world with meaning and at the same time define
trated, nationally and globally, by socially
paths of action’ (Brubaker, 1984: 62, citing Weber,
unnecessary limitations on radically demo- 1949: 57). Since ‘methodological individualism (see
cratic forms of decision-making and associ- note 2) is also associated with Weber’s position, we
ated self-determination within both public stress that it is possible to agree with philosophical
and private (e.g. workplace) spheres. Variants elements of Weber’s thinking without subscribing to
his methodology.
of critical theory challenge the fetishized,
4 Aside from the question of their compatibility,
and seemingly uncontrollable, order of the lack of inquisitiveness is perhaps attributable to
global capitalism that generates extremely dark mutterings about the leftist leanings of some of
asymmetrical distributions of resources and the original institutional. theorists. In the repressive
life-chances. Critical theory does not pretend intolerance of many business schools, scholars
have taken refuge in an orientation to the study of
to provide value-neutral reports of processes
institutionalization in which critical thought is
of globalization, for example. Rather, reject- domesticated if not fully cleansed. Amongst that
ing the notion of value-free science as a band of highly influential, ‘old’ institutionalists,
myth that sustains the status quo, critical Selznick is known for his youthful association with
theories challenge the relentless pursuit of ‘the Trotskyists, the socialists, the anarchists and
Zionist socialists’ (Lipset, 1996: 4). Jonathan Murphy
growth for being socially divisive and eco-
alerted us to the link between leading institutional
logically unsustainable. Such critical think- theorists and leftist politics.
ing understands that resources – in the form 5 Likewise, critical students of organization have
of knowledge as well as raw materials and rarely engaged with institutional theory. As an indica-
technologies – exist that could bring about a tor of this neglect or indifference, the coverage of
institutional theory by two critical textbooks is either
radical redirection of priorities. Critical
almost non-existent (Thomson and McHugh, 2002)
theory, as conceived here, is engaged in the or largely descriptive (Clegg,1990).
critique of ideas and institutions – patriarchy, 6 That selective appropriations and translations
racism, and science, as well as capitalism – of elements of critical theory into institutional
that are assessed to legitimize resistance to a theory (and vice-versa) have occurred is not at issue
(e.g. Oakes, Townley and Cooper, 1998; Lawrence,
progressive transformation of social relations
Winn, and Jennings, 2001; Seo and Creed, 2002).
as well as to the advancement of ideas and Such hybridization is inherently perilous and poten-
institutions more relevant to facilitating radi- tially confusing, especially where some variant of
cal change than to preserving the status quo. critical theory is shoehorned into the framework
696 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

of institutional theory. In this regard, we agree with to correct other interpretations that stand accused
Lounsbury (2003: 216), though for rather different of producing mere ‘social constructions’ which take
reasons, that ‘analytical approaches of interest to on ‘identities created as much by their users as
critical theorists [are] not easily translatable into the their authors’ (Mizruchi and Fein, 1999: 653).
repertoire of institutional analysis’. In Foucauldian analysis, the author is de-centred
7 Foucault’s work was cited more frequently in in the sense that s/he is not ascribed the
scholarly social scientific journals during 1995–2000 sovereign power to adjudicate the meaning of the
than any other author, and indeed received twice the text. We recognize that this undermines both literal-
number of citations as the second most cited author ism and the sovereignty typically attributed to
(see Posner, 2001). authors and, for this reason, it tends to attract knee-
8 Against this thesis, it might be argued that jerk accusations of ‘relativism’ and ‘nihilism’.
instrumental rationality provides for more assessment However, reducing a text to a single, authoritative
of, and thus reflection upon, the means of attaining reading – as dictated by the author or by anyone
ends as well as the possibility of distancing oneself else – would seem to be an absurd, Sisyphean task
from (responsibility for) calculating their selection. (Camus, 1955).
However, within Weber’s conception of instrumental 14 Bhaskar’s warrant is a (retroductive) mode of
rationality, such forms of reflection and distancing science that is concerned to disclose the causal
are themselves instrumentally rational. mechanisms which generate empirical phenomena,
9 Only as an aside (that is not integrated within whereas Habermas’s warrant is a counterfactual ideal
their notion of institutionalization), do Berger and speech situation that, he argues, is inherent in the
Luckmann make any reference to institutionalization structure of communication, and which provides a
as an articulation of power; and, even then, it is foundation for objective knowledge.
restricted to a discussion of a situation in which 15 By ‘non-foundationalist’ we mean ‘rejecting
forms of institutionalization compete with each other the asymmetric image of basic (immediately justified,
(1966: 126–7). Specifically, they note that the foundational) beliefs that support nonbasic beliefs.
construction of reality which proves victorious in such Non-foundationalists prefer the image of a web of
contests is likely to be advocated ‘by those mutually supporting beliefs, which are mediated
who wielded the bigger weapons rather than those through a particular community.
who had the better arguments’ (1966: 127). 16 This allows for the possibility of productively
But this very brief commentary on how conflicts studying power in a variety of ways. Other critical
between rival forms of institutionalization are approaches, such as Braverman’s (1974) labour
resolved is absent from their (consensualist) concep- process analysis, adopt a sovereign or juridical con-
tion of institutionalization. ception of power and shed insight into the way
10 Along with much else in Friedland and Alford’s workers’ knowledge is appropriated by management
(1991) instructive contribution, this observation has in the pursuit of profit.
not been taken up in institutional theory. Instead 17 Institutional theory does not readily conceive
Friedland and Alford’s has been selectively appropri- of these ‘logics’ as forms of power since power is
ated for its use of ‘logics’ and ‘contradiction’. We are associated with agency, whereas logics are associ-
grateful to Jaco Lock for this insight. ated with legitimacy.
11 The aspiration to critique the naturalization of 18 It is also evident in his assessment of the con-
the present, whether in social science or everyday tribution of institutional theory which is character-
life, does not exempt elements and versions of ized as one that ‘rests in the identification of causal
critical theory from critical scrutiny. Critical thinking mechanisms leading to organizational change and
may also be developed, selectively appropriated stability on the basis of precarious understandings
and translated to bolster and refine what is ‘normal’ that organizational actors share, independent of
(cf Kuhn, 1970) – for example, through an assess- their interests’ (DiMaggio, 1988: 3). For critiques of
ment and effective domestication of elements the use of ‘interests’ in institutional theory, see
that are potentially threatening to established Campbell, 2006; Enrione, Mazza and Zerboni, 2006;
thinking, as is illustrated by the recent flirtation by Fligstein, 2006.
neo-institutonalists with critical discourse analysis 19 In Lawrence et al.’s typology, power as ‘domi-
(Phillips, Lawrence and Hardy, 2004); semiotics and nation’ is reserved, oddly enough, for ‘forms of
actor network theory (Lawrence and Suddaby,2005) power that support institutionalization processes
and rhetoric (Suddaby and Greenwood, 2006). through systems of organized, routine practices that
12 See Baritz (1960) and Brief (2000). do not require agency or choice’ (2001: 637) – a
13 Indeed, from our Foucauldian standpoint, it restriction that eliminates virtually every form or exer-
would be perverse to claim that we provide an ‘accu- cise of non-juridical power. In comparison to ‘influ-
rate interpretation’ either of Foucault’s work or of the ence’, ‘force’ and ‘discipline’, ‘domination’ is
diverse contributions to institutional analysis dis- (conveniently) conceived by Lawrence et al. to be a
cussed in this chapter; or, relatedly, that we aspire marginal and exceptional form of power.
EXAMINING ‘INSTITUTIONALIZATION’: A CRITICAL THEORETIC PERSPECTIVE 697

20 In the spirit of self awareness and reflection, it Benson, K. (1977), ‘Organizations: A dialectical
is appropriate to acknowledge that Foucault’s version view’, Administrative Science Quarterly, 22,
of critical theory leaves open the nature and 1: 1– 21.
processes of emancipation. While this openness is Berger, P. (1988), ‘Epilogue’ in J.D. Hunter and
appealing to us, since it leaves such determinations
S.C. Ainlay (eds.), Making Sense of Modern
to local struggles, contexts and understandings,
other versions of critical theory – for example
Times: Peter Berger and the Vision of Inter-
Marxism and Critical Theory – identify more universal pretive Sociology. London: Routledge and
notions of emancipation. The relevance of differing Kegan Paul.
versions of critical theory for understanding manage- Berger, P. L. and Luckmann, T. (1966), The Social
ment can be found in Alvesson and Willmott (2004), Construction of Reality: A Treatise in the Sociol-
and engaging debates about their relevance for ogy of Knowledge. New York: Doubleday & Co.
studying accounting can be found in Neimark (1994), Bernstein, R. (1976), The Restructuring of
Armstrong (1994) and Hoskin (1994). Social and Political Theory. Philadelphia:
21 The phenomenological tradition, in which University of Pennsylvania Press.
Berger and Luckmann’s thinking is partially located,
Braverman, H (1974), Labor and Monopoly
problematizes, or denaturalizes ‘cultural understand-
ings’, albeit in a universalizing rather than historical,
Capitalism, New York: Monthly Review Press.
power-sensitive, manner. Brief, A. (2000), ‘Still servants of power’,
22 We are indebted to Jaco Loc for this felicitous Journal of Management Inquiry, 9 (4):
summary. 342–351.
Brubaker, R. (1984), The Limits of Rationality:
An Essay on the Social and Moral Thought of
Max Weber. London: George, Allen and
REFERENCES Unwin.
Burrell, G. (1988), ‘Modernism, post mod-
Adler, P., Forbes, L. and Willmott, H.C. (2007), ernism and organizational analysis 2:
‘Critical management studies: Premises, The contribution of Michel Foucault’,
practices, problems, and prospects’, Annals Organization Studies, 9 (2): 221–235.
of the Academy of Management, vol. 1, in Burrell, G. (1994), ‘Modernism, postmodernism
press. and organizational analysis 4: The contribu-
Alexander, J. (1983), Theoretical Logic in tion of Jurgen Habermas. Organization
Sociology: The Modern Reconstruction of Studies, 16 (6).
Political Thought, Vol. 4: Talcott Parsons. Campbell, J.L. (2006), ‘Institutional analysis
Berkeley: University of California Press. and the paradox of corporate social respon-
Alvesson, M. and Willmott, H.C. (eds.) (1992), sibility’, American Behavioural Scientist, 49
Critical Management Studies. London: Sage. (7): 925–938.
Alvesson, M. and Willmott, H.C. (eds.) (1996), Camus, A. (1955), The Myth of Sisyphus and
Making Sense of Management: A Critical Other Essays. New York: Knopf.
Introduction. London: Sage. Carmona, S., Ezzamel, M., and Gutiérrez, F.
Alvesson, M. and Willmott, H.C. (eds.) (2004), (2002), The relationship between accounting
Studying Management Critically. London: and spatial practices in the factory,
Sage. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 27
Armstrong, P. (1994), ‘The influence of Michel (3): 239–274.
Foucault on accounting research’, Critical Clegg, S. (1990), Modern Organizations:
Perspectives on Accounting, 5 (1): 25–55. Organization Theory in the Postmodern
Baritz, L. (1960), The Servants of Power, Age. London: Sage.
Middletown, Conn: Wesleyan University Press. Covaleski, M., Dirsmith, M., Heian, J.B. and
Barnett, R. (1997), Higher Education: A Samuel, S. (1998), ‘The calculated and the
Critical Business. Buckingham: SRHE/Open avowed: Techniques of discipline and strug-
University. gles over identity in Big 6 public accounting
Beckert, J. (1999), ‘Agency, entrepreneurs, and firms’, Administrative Science Quarterly, 43
institutional change: The role of strategic (2): 293–327.
choice and institutionalized practices in DiMaggio, P. (1988), ‘Interest and
organizations’, Organization Studies, 20 (5): agency in institutional theory’, in
777–799. L.G. Zucker (ed.), Institutional Patterns
698 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

and Organizations: Culture and Environment. Foucault, M. (1979b), The History of Sexuality.
Cambridge, MA: Ballinger. London: Allen Lane.
DiMaggio, P.J. (1991), ‘Constructing an organi- Foucault, M. (1980), ‘Power/Knowledge:
zational field as a professional project: U.S. art Selected Interviews and Other Writings by
museums, 1920–1940’, in W.W. Powell and Michel Foucault, ed. C. Gordon. Brighton:
P.J. DiMaggio (eds.), The New Institutionalism Harvester.
in Organizational Analysis, pp. 267–292. Foucault, M. (1983), ‘The subject and power’,
Chicago: University of Chicago Press. in H.L. Dreyfus and P. Rabinow (eds.),
DiMaggio, P. and Powell, W.W. (1983), ‘The Michel Foucault: Beyond Structuralism and
iron cage revisited: Institutional isomorphism Hermenutics. New York: Harvester:
and collective rationality in organizational pp. 208–226.
fields’, American Sociological Review, 48 (2): Foucault, M. (1984), ‘On the genealogy of
147–160. ethics: An overview of work in progress’, in
DiMaggio, P. and Powell, W.W. (1991), P. Rabinow (ed.), The Foucault Reader.
‘Introduction’, in W.W. Powell and P.J. London: Perigrine.
DiMaggio (eds.), The New Institutionalism in Foucault, M. (1988), ‘Truth, power, self:
Organizational Analysis, pp. 1–33. Chicago: An interview with Michel Foucault’, in
University of Chicago Press. L. Martin, H. Gutman, and P.H. Hutton
Dreyfus, H.L. and Rabinow, P. (1986), ‘What is (eds.), Technologies of the Self. Amherst,
maturity? Habermas and Foucault on “What MA: University of Massachusetts Press,
is enlightenment’’’, in D.C. Hoy (ed.), pp. 9–15.
Foucault: A Critical Reader. Oxford: Basil Foucault, M. (1994), ‘Two lectures’, in M. Kelly
Blackwell. (ed.), Critique and Power: Recasting the
Dreyfus, (2004), <http://socrates.berkeley.edu/ Foucault/Habermas Debate. Cambridge,
~hdreyfus/html/paper_being.html>. MA: MIT Press.
Enrione, A., Mazza, C., & Zerboni, F. (2006), Friedland, R. and Alford, R.R. (1991), ‘Bringing
‘Institutionalizing codes of governance’, society back in: Symbols, practices and insti-
American Behavioral Scientist, 49 (7): tutional contradictions’, in W.W. Powell and
961–973. P.J. DiMaggio (eds.), The New Institutionalism
Ezzamel, M. (1994), ‘Organizational change in Organizational Analysis. Chicago:
and accounting: Understanding the budget- University of Chicago Press.
ing system in its organizational context’, Grey, C. (1994), ‘Career as a project of the self
Organization Studies, 15 (2): 213–241. and labour process discipline’, Sociology, 28:
Ezzamel, M., Lilley, S. and Willmott, H.C. 479–497.
(2004), ‘Accounting representation and the Gulrajani, N. and Lok, J. (2005), Theorizing
road to commercial salvation’, Accounting, change and agency in neo-institutionalism:
Organizations and Society, 29 (8): 783–813. A call for re-examining the sociology of
Ezzamel, M. and Willmott, H.C. (1998), social constructivism. Paper presented at the
‘Accounting for teamwork: A critical study of Institutional Theory Workshop April 2005,
group based systems of organizational con- Judge Business School, University of
trol’, Administrative Science Quarterly, 43 Cambridge.
(2): 358–397. Haigh, M. (2006), ‘Social investment:
Fligstein, N. (2006), ‘Sense making and the Subjectivism, sublation and the moral eleva-
emergence of a new form of market gover- tion of success’, Critical Perspectives on
nance: The case of the European defense Accounting, 17 (8): 989–1005.
industry’, American Behavioral Scientist, 49 Hasselbladh, H. and Kallinikos, J. (2000), ‘The
(7): 949–960. project of rationalization: A critique and reap-
Foucault, M. (1977), Discipline and Punish: The praisal of neo-institutionalism in organization
Birth of the Prison. London: Tavistock. studies’, Organization Studies, 21 (4): 697–720.
Foucault (1978), The History of Sexuality: An Held, D. (1980), Introduction to Critical Theory.
Introduction. Harmondsworth: Penguin London: Heinemann.
Foucault, M. (1979a), Power, Truth, Strategy, Hiley, D.R. (1988), Philosophy in Question:
ed. N. Morris and P. Patton. Sydney: Federal Essays on a Pyrrhonian Theme. Chicago:
Publications. University of Chicago Press.
EXAMINING ‘INSTITUTIONALIZATION’: A CRITICAL THEORETIC PERSPECTIVE 699

Hirsch, P.M. and Lounsbury, M. (1997), institutionalization’, Academy of Management


‘Ending the family quarrel: Toward a recon- Review, 26 (4): 624–644.
ciliation of ‘old’ and ‘new’ institutionalisms’, Levy, D.L. and Egan, D. (2003), ‘A neo-
American Behavioral Scientist, 40: 406–18. Gramscian approach to corporate political
Hirschman, A.O (1986), Rival Views of Market strategy: Conflict and accommodation
Society. New York, NY, USA: Viking. in the climate change negotiations’,
Hoskin, K. (1988) ‘Boxing clever: For, against Journal of Management Studies, 40 (4):
and beyond Foucault in the battle for 803–829.
accounting theory’, Critical Perspectives on Lipset, S.M. (1996), ‘Steady work: An academic
Accounting, 5 (1): 57–85. memoir’, Annual Review of Sociology, 22:
Hoskin, K. and Macve, R. (1988), ‘The genesis of 1–27.
accountability: The West Point connections’, Lok, J. (2007), The Logic of Shareholder Value
Accounting, Organizations and Society, 13 as An Identity Project. Unpublished paper,
(1): 37–73. University of Cambridge.
Jepperson, R.L. (1991), The New Institutional- Lok, J., and Willmott, H. (2006), ‘Dialogue:
ism in Organizational Analysis, in Institutional theory, language and discourse
W.W. Powell and P.J. DiMaggio (eds.), analysis, a comment on Phillips, Lawrence
The New Institutionalism in Organizational and Hardy’, Academy of Management
Analysis. Chicago: University of Chicago Review, 31 (2): 477–488.
Press. Lounsbury, M. (2003), ‘The problem of order
Johnson, P. and Duberley, J. (2000), revisited: Towards a more critical institutional
Understanding Management Research. perspective’, in R. Westwood and S. Clegg
London: Sage. (eds.), Debating Organization: Point-
Khan, F., Munir, K. and Willmott, H.C. (2007), Counterpoint in Organization Studies.
‘A dark side of institutional entrepreneur- Oxford: Blackwell.
ship: Soccer balls, child labour and postcolo- Lounsbury, M. and Ventresca, M.J. (2002),
nial impoverishment’, Organization Studies, ‘Social structure and organization revisited’,
28(7): 1055–1077. Research in the Sociology of Organizations,
Kosmala MacLullich, K. (2003), ‘The emperor’s 19. New York: JAI Press.
‘new’ clothes? New audit regimes: insights Lounsbury, M. and Ventresca, M.J. (2003), ‘The
from Foucault’s technologies of the self’, new structuralism in organizational theory’,
Critical Perspectives on Accounting, 14 (8): Organization, 10 (3): 457–480.
791–811. McNay L. (1994), Foucault: A Critical Introduc-
Knights, D. (1992), ‘Changing spaces: The dis- tion. Cambridge: Polity Press.
ruptive impact of a new epistemological McWhorter, L. (1999), Bodies and Pleasures:
location for the study of management’, Foucault and the Politics of Sexual Normaliza-
Academy of Management Review, 17: tion. Bloomington: Indiana University Press.
514–536. Menard, C., and Shirley, M. (eds.) (2005),
Knights, D. and Collinson, D. (1987), Handbook of New Institutional Economics.
‘Disciplining the shopfloor: A comparison of Dordrecht, Netherlands: Springer.
the disciplinary effects of managerial Meyer, J.W., Boli, J., and Thomas, G. (1987),
psychology and financial accounting’, ‘Ontology and rationalization in the Western
Accounting, Organizations and Society, 12 cultural account’, in G. Thomas et al.,
(5): 457–477. Institutional Structure. Beverly Hills, CA:
Kuhn, T.S. (1970), The Structure of Scientific Sage.
Revolutions, 2nd edn. Chicago: University of Meyer, J. W. and Rowan, B., (1977/1991),
Chicago Press. ‘Institutionalized organizations: Formal struc-
Lawrence, T.B. and Suddaby, R. (2006), ture as myth and ceremony’, American
‘Institutions and institutional work’, in Journal of Sociology, 83: 340. Reprinted in
S.R. Clegg, C. Hardy, T.B. Lawrence and W.W. Powell and P. J. DiMaggio (eds.), The
W.R. Nord (eds.), The Handbook of Organi- New Institutionalism in Organizational Analy-
zation Studies, 2nd edn. London: Sage. sis. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Lawrence, T.B., Winn, M.I. and Jennings, Meyer, J.W. and Jepperson, R.L. (2000),
P.D. (2001), ‘The temporal dynamics of ‘The ‘actors’ of modern society: The cultural
700 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

construction of social agency’, Sociological Reed, M. (1997), In praise of duality and dual-
Theory, 18 (1): 100–120. ism: Rethinking agency and structure in
Miller, P. and O’Leary, T. (1987), ‘Accounting organizational analysis. Organization
and the construction of the governable Studies, 18 (1): 21–42.
person’, Accounting, Organizations and Rorty, R. (1979), Philosophy and the Mirror of
Society, 12 (3): 235–265. Nature. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Mizruchi, M.S. and Fein, L.C. (1999), ‘The Sawicki, J. (1994), ‘Foucault and feminism:
social construction of organizational knowl- A critical reappraisal’, in M. Kelly (ed.),
edge: A study of the uses of coercive, Critique and Power: Recasting the
mimetic, and normative isomorphism’, Foucault/Habermas Debate. Cambridge,
Administrative Science Quarterly, 44: MA: MIT Press
653–83. Scott, W.R. (1995/2001), Institutions and
Neimark, M. (1994), ‘Regicide revisited: Organizations. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage
Marx, Foucault and accounting’, Critical Publications.
Perspectives on Accounting, 5 (1): 87–108. Scott, W.R. (1991), ‘The evolution of organiza-
Oakes, L.S., Townley, B., and Cooper, D.J. tion theory’, in G. Miller (ed.), Studies in
(1998), ‘Business planning as pedagogy: Organizational Sociology: Essays in Honour
Language and control in a changing institu- of Charles W. Warriner. Greenwich, CT: JAI,
tional field’, Administrative Science Quarterly 53–68.
(June): 257–292. Selznick, P. (1992), The Moral Commonwealth:
Oliver, C. (1991), ‘Strategic responses to Social Theory and the Promise of Commu-
institutional processes’, Academy of nity. Berkeley: University of California Press.
Management Review, 16 (1): 145–179. Seo, M.–G. and Creed, W.E.D. (2002),
Oliver, C. (1992), ‘The antecedents of deinstitu- ‘Institutional contradictions, praxis, and
tionalization’, Organization Studies, 13: 563- institutional change: A dialectical perspec-
568. tive’, Academy of Management Review,
Parsons, T. (1951), The Social System. Glencoe, 27 (2): 222–247.
IL: Free Press. Silverman, D., (1970), The Theory of Organiza-
Perrow, C. (1985), ‘Overboard with myth and tions: A Sociological Framework. London:
symbols’, American Journal of Sociology, 91: Heinemann.
151–155. Simon, J. (1988), ‘The ideological effects of
Phillips, N.(2003), ‘Discourse or institution? actuarial practices’, Law and Society Review,
Institutional theory and the challenge of crit- 22 (4): 771–800.
ical discourse analysis’ in R. Westwood and Simons, J. (1995), Foucault and the Political.
S.R. Clegg (eds.), Debating Organization: London: Routledge.
Point-Counterpoint in Organization Studies. Suchman, L. (1995), ‘Managing legitimacy:
Oxford: Blackwell. Strategic and institutional approaches’,
Pollner, M. (1991), ‘Left of ethnomethodology: Academy of Management Review, 20 (3):
The rise and decline of radical reflexivity’, 571–610.
American Sociological Review, 56 (3): 370–380. Suddaby, R. and Greenwood, R. (2005),
Posner, R.A. (2001), Public Intellectuals: ‘Rhetorical strategies of legitimacy’,
A Study of Decline. Harvard University Press. Administrative Science Quarterly, 50: 35–67.
Preston, A., Cooper, D.J., and Coombs, Thompson, P. and McHugh, D. (2002), Work
R. (1992), ‘Fabricating budgets: A study of Organization: A Critical Introduction.
the production of management budgeting Houndmills, Basingstoke, Hampshire:
in the national health service’, Accounting, Palgrave.
Organizations and Society, 17 (6): 561–593. Tolbert, P.S. and Zucker, L.G. (1999), ‘The insti-
Preston, A., Cooper, D.J., Scarbrough, D.P. and tutionalization of institutional theory’, in
Chilton, R.C. (1995), Changes in the code of S.R.Clegg and C. Hardy (eds.), Studying
ethics of the U.S. accounting profession, Organization: Theory and Method. London:
1917 and 1988: The continual quest for Sage.
legitimation, Accounting, Organizations and Townley, B. (1993), ‘Foucault, power/knowledge,
Society, 20 (6): 507–546. and its relevance for human resource
EXAMINING ‘INSTITUTIONALIZATION’: A CRITICAL THEORETIC PERSPECTIVE 701

management’, Academy of Management Willmott, H.C. (1986), ‘Unconscious sources of


Review, 18 (3): 518–545. motivation in the theory of the subject: An
Townley, B. (1995), ‘Managing by numbers: exploration and critique of Giddens’,
accounting, personnel management and the Dualistic models of action and personality’,
creation of a mathesis’, Critical Perspectives Journal for the Theory of Social Behaviour,
on Accounting, 6 (6): 555–575. 16 (1): 105–122.
Weber, M. (1949), The Methodology of the Wolin, S. (1988), ‘On the theory and
Social Sciences, trans. and ed. E.A. Shils and practice of power’, in J. Arac (ed.), After
H.A. Finch. New York: Free Press. Foucault: Humanistic Knowledge, Postmodern
Weber, M. (1978), Economy and Society, Challenges. New Brunswick: Rutgers
ed. G. Roth and C. Wittich. Berkeley: University University Press.
of California Press (2 vols). Zilber, T. (2002), ‘Institutionalization as an inter-
Whittington, R. (1992) ‘Putting Giddens into play between actions, meanings, and actors:
action: Social systems and managerial The case of a rape crisis center in Israel’,
agency’, Journal of Management Studies, Academy of Management Journal, 45 (1):
29: 693–712. 234–254.
29
Taking Social Construction
Seriously: Extending the
Discursive Approach in
Institutional Theory
Nelson Phillips and Namrata Malhotra

Institutionalization occurs whenever there is a institutional theory (e.g., Tolbert & Zucker,
reciprocal typification of habitualized actions by 1983) as researchers worked to understand
types of actors. Put differently, any such typifica-
the effects of cognitive institutions on indi-
tion is an institution.
(Berger & Luckmann, 1967) viduals and organizations.
In many ways, it is this cognitive focus
Early work in institutional theory1 focused that provides the distinctiveness of institu-
explicitly on the socially constructed nature tional theory. According to DiMaggio and
of institutions, arguing that they arise out of Powell (1991), new institutional theory is
the meaningful interactions of actors and characterized by ‘a scepticism toward
shape behaviour by conditioning cognition. rational-actor models of organization’ (1991:
Meyer and Rowan (1977: 341), for example, 12) which are replaced by ‘an alternative
argue that ‘[i]nstitutionalization involves the theory of individual action, which stresses
processes by which social processes, obliga- the unreflective, routine, taken-for-granted
tions, or actualities, come to take on a nature of most human behaviour and views
rulelike status in social thought and action’. interests and actors as themselves constituted
In this definition, institutions are cognitive by institutions’ (1991: 14). By moving
structures and institutionalization is the beyond arguments regarding rational action
process whereby institutions are constructed in contexts characterized by various forms of
in social interaction through the production resource dependency, institutional theory
of what Berger and Luckmann (1967: 54) provides explanations of patterns of behav-
call ‘shared typifications’. This view of insti- iour that make little sense from other per-
tutions drove much of the early work in new spectives. Furthermore, and perhaps more
TAKING SOCIAL CONSTRUCTION SERIOUSLY 703

importantly, institutional theory goes well action that we can differentiate between truly
beyond the remit of these theories in examin- institutional forms of isomorphism and the
ing the sources of the interests and identities multitude of other pressures that can lead to
that determine the preferences which frame increasing similarities in form or action but
rational action in the first place. which do so in very different ways. Simply
Yet the emphasis of this early work, and calling something an institution because it
the source of much of the distinctiveness of results in conformity does little to explain how
institutional theory, has been diluted despite it actually does so and even less to explain
the retention of a general interest in what what it actually is. It is only by being very
Douglas (1986: 11) calls the ‘social basis of clear about the nature of institutions, and by
cognition’. Rather than clearly focusing on ensuring that what we study fits that defini-
cognitive institutions and continuing to tion, that we can hope to develop deeper
develop this unique contribution, the concep- understandings of what are legitimately
tualization of an institution has blurred and, institutional processes.
as a result, significant analytical power has Second, this lack of clarity about the
been lost. In fact, from the perspective of nature of institutions leads to a lack of
much of recent institutionalism, institutions attention to explaining the actual process
are seemingly most recognizable by their of institutional production. As Zucker (1991:
effects and a number of mechanisms that 105–106) observes:
produce isomorphism have been lumped Without a solid cognitive, micro-level foundation
together to form the focus of institutional we risk treating institutionalization as a black box
analysis. However, such an all-encompassing at the organizational level, focusing on content at
approach neglects critical theoretical and the exclusion of developing a systematic explana-
tory theory of process, conflating institutionaliza-
philosophical distinctions among the differ-
tion with resource dependency, and neglecting
ent mechanisms that lead to isomorphism. institutional variation and persistence. Although
For example, an organizational form that is important insights can be gained by examining the
widely adopted in order to gain access to a content of institutions, there is an ever present
government grant is seen as equally the result danger of making the neo-institutionalist enter-
prise a taxonomic rather than explanatory theory-
of an institution as an organizational form
building science. Institution theory is always in
that is adopted due to its taken-for-granted- danger of forgetting that labeling a process or
ness in a field. Yet, the first case is simply a structure does not explain it.
rational and conscious decision by managers
to allow their organizations access to By adopting a view of institutions that looks
resources that they value. Clearly not the all too much like the taxonomy that Zucker
sort of taken-for-grantedness originally feared, we have left ourselves with no way to
associated with institutions. explain how they come to be. The fact that
From our perspective here, defining an very different kinds of things are treated as
institution based on its effects is problematic different forms or elements of institutions
for two reasons. First, in failing to clearly leaves us without any common understand-
focus on cognitive institutions, institutional ing of the process of institutional production
theory has conflated what have traditionally and, consequently, the nature of institutions.
been considered institutional processes with In other words, a ‘taxonomic’ approach has
resource dependency and the coercive appli- come to dominate institutional theory while
cation of power. The fact that isomorphism there has been little attention paid to develop-
occurs in an organizational field does not nec- ing an explanation for the process of produc-
essarily mean that taken-for-granted cognitive tion of institutions in the first place.
structures are the cause. It is only by examin- In this chapter, we argue that there is a sig-
ing the actual micro-processes through which nificant opportunity for institutional theory to
organizations become more alike in form and clarify the nature of institutions and to develop
704 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

the sort of ‘solid cognitive, micro-level institutions are socially constructed leads
foundation’ for institutional theory that necessarily to the observation that all institu-
Zucker envisages. More specifically, we build tions are fundamentally cognitive. If we
on one strand of work in institutional theory accept, as Meyer and Rowan (1977) argue,
that has begun to further develop an approach that institutions take on a rulelike status in
to understanding the process of social con- thought, then no matter what the mechanism
struction that underlies institutional produc- of their genesis, they are social facts and are
tion and the ramifications of this for the fundamentally cognitive. Institutional theory
cognitive nature of institutions: the work done therefore becomes a perspective focused on
to date developing a discursive approach to developing a deep understanding of the
institutionalization (e.g., Phillips, Lawrence, genesis, maintenance, change and effects of
& Hardy, 2004). cognitive institutions.
This work has begun to inform our under- Third, building on the previous point,
standing of institutionalization by providing we go on to argue that we need to de-
a theoretical and methodological approach institutionalize the tripartite understanding
explaining the process of social construction of regulative, normative and cultural-
through which institutions are constituted. cognitive institutions and move to a much
As Phillips et al. (2004: 648) argue: clearer separation between mechanisms that
lead to isomorphism and the institutions that
Understanding institutional phenomena requires
a broader, more comprehensive theory that
may or may not be produced by these
encompasses stability and change in institutions, mechanisms. Rather than the current lack
institutional fields, and institutional effects. of clarity, we need a more nuanced theory
Including a much more developed discursive con- that differentiates between mechanisms or
ceptualization of social construction is one impor- pressures for institutionalization and the
tant step toward understanding and exploring
these issues.
actual process of institutionalization itself.
In other words, we need to differentiate
We draw on this existing work and examine between simple isomorphism, which can be
the potential of discourse analysis in the caused by a variety of mechanisms and the
study of institutional processes and, more institutional processes that drive isomor-
generally, the distinctive role of discourse phism by structuring cognition and that have
analysis in conceptualizing social construc- been the core focus of institutional theory.
tion in institutional theory. Finally, we point to the opportunities for
In further developing a discursive perspec- research into the production of institutions
tive, we contribute to discussions of institu- from a discursive point of view. While dis-
tional theory in four ways. First, as we said course analysis is a theoretical framework
above, discourse analysis provides a useful explaining processes of social construction,
way of conceptualizing the process through it is also a method for exploring these
which institutions are socially constructed. If processes that can be applied usefully
institutional theory is going to take social to the study of institutions and institutional-
construction seriously, we need a much more ization. Discourse analysis therefore
developed idea of how the process of social provides well-developed approaches to
construction occurs. Discourse analysis pro- empirically investigating the actual processes
vides the building blocks for a theory of the of production that underlie institutions.
production of institutions and a method for In doing so, discourse analysis can help
researching instances of institutionalization. move institutional theory from its current
Second, we explore some of the ramifica- focus on the effects of institutions in organi-
tions of returning to a strong form of social zational fields to a focus on the micro-level
construction in institutional theory. In partic- processes that lead to the formation of
ular, we argue that accepting the notion that cognitive institutions.
TAKING SOCIAL CONSTRUCTION SERIOUSLY 705

We will present our arguments in Social Construction and New


three steps. We begin by discussing the social Institutional Theory
constructivist roots of new institutional
theory and further explain why we believe As far back as the late nineteenth century,
the tripartite view of institutions that has institutional economists began challenging
developed in institutional theory is problem- economic assumptions about rational indi-
atic. We will then discuss how discourse vidual behaviour. Veblen (1909: 245), for
analysis provides a theoretical and method- example, argued that behaviour is governed
ological frame for understanding the by habit and convention where an individ-
processes of social construction that under- ual’s conduct is directed by his or her habit-
pin institutionalization. We draw on dis- ual relations to other members of his or her
course analysis to provide an alternative group. He defined institutions as ‘settled
perspective on the nature of institutions and habits of thought common to the generality
the micro-institutional processes upon which of man’ (1909: 239). In doing so he foreshad-
they depend. Finally, we conclude with a dis- ows the development of the cognitive view of
cussion of some of the implications of this institutions that came to characterize new
view of institutions for empirical research in institutionalism many years later. This defini-
institutional theory and outline some of the tion is particularly striking as we can already
outstanding issues and problems that remain see a strong cognitive understanding of insti-
unresolved. tutions at such an early stage of development
of institutional thought.
Even Menger ([1871]1981), who stoutly
defended the utility of overarching simplify-
INSTITUTIONS AND THE SOCIAL ing assumptions in economics, acknowl-
NATURE OF COGNITION edged the importance of broader institutional
forces and, in fact, argued that institutions
In the first part of this section, we explore themselves were social phenomena in need
the social constructivist thread running of theoretical explanation (Scott, 2001: 2).
through new and neo-institutionalism. Commons (1924), in emphasizing that a
We revisit the roots of institutional transaction was the appropriate unit of analy-
theory and follow the development of sis alluded to the rules of conduct governing
the cognitive view of institutions in a transaction. By rules of conduct he meant
institutional analysis. Our point in the something very much like a social institution
first part of this section is to show characterized by a degree of adherence to
that various kinds of social construc- collective norms of reasonable behaviour
tionism have played a central role in (Van de Ven, 1993).
institutional theory from its earliest develop- While modern institutional theorists may
ment and that this constructionism points find significant aspects of this work quite
directly to the cognitive nature of institu- sympathetic to their views, organizational
tions. We will then discuss the recent devel- institutionalism was predominantly built on
opment of the tripartite conception of more sociological foundations. The earliest
institutions as regulative, normative and cul- forms of institutionalism in sociology started
tural-cognitive that has come to dominate with a more functionalist flavour than
institutional analysis and argue that there is characterizes institutional theory today, but
an opportunity for institutional theory to with a clear cognitive orientation. Sumner
progress more quickly in understanding (1906), for example, defined an institution
institutions by returning to its roots in social simply as a concept or idea. Scott (2001)
constructivism and refocusing on cognitive summarizes Sumner’s conceptualization of
institutions. institutions as evolving from individual
706 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

activities to folkways, to mores, and to full- cited definition, define an institution as


fledged institutions, although he also recog- ‘a reciprocal typification of habituated
nized that institutions can also be enacted as actions by types of actors’. In other words,
products of rational invention and intention. institutions arise when groups of people come
Similarly, Davis (1949) defined an institution to understand some activity in a certain way
as a set of interwoven folkways, mores, and and that understanding becomes shared
laws built around one or more functions. In across a group. From their perspective, insti-
both cases the cognitive nature of institutions tutions are cognitive constructions and the
is clear although underpinned by a function- process of institutionalization is a process of
alist understanding of social processes. social construction.
But there was also important early work While there were many early discussions
from a less functionalist perspective, clearly of institutions in the literature, systematic
emphasizing the cognitive and socially con- attempts to connect organizations and
structed nature of institutions. Cooley institutions only appeared much later.
([1902] 1956: 313–314), for example, Selznick (1948) was the first major
observed that institutions are developed contributor to the institutional theory of
through interactions and exist ‘as a habit of organizations. Selznick (1957) described
mind and of action, largely unconscious institutionalization as a process that happens
because largely common to all the group .... to an organization over time, reflecting its
the individual is always cause as well as own distinctive history, the people who have
effect of the institution’. Hughes (1936: 180) been in it and the vested interests they have
further emphasized the social production of created, and the way it has adapted to its
institutions when he defined them as an environment. From his perspective, to insti-
‘establishment of relative permanence of tutionalize is to ‘infuse with value beyond the
a distinctly social sort’. Mead (1934) drew technical requirements of the task at hand’
attention to the role of symbolic systems (Selznick, 1957: 16).
arguing that meaning is created in interaction This early approach to institutional analy-
through gestures, particularly vocal gestures ses of organizations was followed by the
in the form of language; an argument that emergence of new institutional approaches to
is particularly interesting to us here as it organizational sociology. Scott (2001: 39)
foreshadows a discursive approach to the points out that attention to cognitive frames
analysis of social construction. Schutz and cultural frameworks rather than to nor-
[1932](1967) similarly examined ways in mative systems was a critical defining feature
which common meanings are constructed of this new form of institutional theory in
through interaction by individuals and sociology. The most significant difference
become taken-for-granted assumptions. between the old and the new institutionalisms
Berger and Luckmann (1967) proposed the lies in the conception of the cognitive bases of
most influential conceptualization of institu- institutionalized behaviour. According to the
tions as cognitive structures. Their approach old institutionalists, organizations became
focused on the creation of shared knowledge institutionalized when they were ‘infused
and belief systems through meaningful with value’ as ends in themselves (Selznick,
interaction. They saw their work as being 1957). Individuals’ preferences were shaped
about developing a sociology of knowledge by values and norms emphasizing normative-
that would explain how objectified social evaluative judgements. New institutionalism
knowledge arose through meaningful and departed from a focus on a moral framing in
subjective interaction. In doing so, they terms of norms and values and drew attention
brought cognitive frameworks for conceptual- to the taken-for-granted scripts, rules, and
izing institutions centre-stage. Berger and classifications as the basis of institutions
Luckmann (1967: 58), in their commonly (DiMaggio & Powell, 1991).
TAKING SOCIAL CONSTRUCTION SERIOUSLY 707

The works of Meyer and Rowan (1977) Zucker (1977) provides a complementary
and Zucker (1977) grounded new institu- characterization of institutions as primarily
tional theory firmly in the sociological cognitive. In her study of the role of institu-
realm and conspicuously in the work of tionalization in cultural persistence, Zucker
Berger and Luckmann (1967). Meyer and argues that ‘internalization, self-reward, or
Rowan (1977) provide a macro-perspective other intervening processes need not be pres-
on institutionalized organizations, arguing ent to ensure cultural persistence because
that formal structures of organizations reflect social knowledge, once institutionalized,
the myths of their institutional environments exists as a fact, as part of objective reality,
instead of the demands of their work activi- and can be transmitted directly on that basis’
ties. They draw on Berger and Luckmann’s (1991: 83). Most importantly, the study
(1967) notion of institutionalized rules as comes closest to developing Berger and
classifications built into society as recipro- Luckmann’s (1967) work in that it deals with
cated typifications or understandings when the process of institutionalization especially
they argue that ‘formal structures are not highlighting the social constructivist nature
only creatures of their relational networks in of the process: ‘[i]t is a process by which
the social organization .... the elements of individual actors transmit what is socially
rationalized formal structure are deeply defined as real and simultaneously at
ingrained in, and reflect, widespread under- any point in that process the meaning of
standings of social reality (Meyer & Rowan, an act can be defined as more or less taken-
1977: 54). for-granted part of this social reality’
In describing institutionalization as a (Zucker, 1977: 85). In other words, institu-
process by which social processes, obliga- tionalized acts are perceived as objective as
tions, or actualities take on a rulelike status they can be repeated by other actors with a
in social thought and action, they implied common understanding of the act. Further,
that the rules become taken-for-granted. institutionalized acts are exterior when
From their conceptualization of institutional- ‘subjective understanding of acts is recon-
ization one could deduce that they perceived structed as intersubjective understanding so
the nature of institutions to be primarily that the acts are seen as part of the external
cognitive. They state, ‘such elements of world’ (1977: 85). Most critically, institu-
formal structure are manifestations of tionalized acts do not require monitoring and
powerful institutional rules which function enforcement.
as highly rationalized myths that are binding Following Meyer and Rowan (1977) and
on particular organizations (Meyer & Zucker (1977), several significant contribu-
Rowan, 1977: 343). In other words, these tions to institutional theory developed a
shared understandings result in certain macro-level perspective on institutionaliza-
organizations having to perform certain tion (e.g., DiMaggio & Powell, 1983; Meyer
activities regardless of their rationale & Scott, 1983). However, there seemed to be
because of the taken-for-granted nature of little attention to clarifying and developing,
those understandings. The fact that we under- theoretically and empirically, an understand-
stand an organization to be of a particular ing of the nature of institutions and the
kind means that a set of taken-for-granted process by which they come to be. Rather the
rules must be followed. But it is not that line of enquiry changed from institutions and
some outside actor is enforcing these rules. how they are constructed to the effects of
Rather it is the fact that they are broadly institutionalization. DiMaggio and Powell
accepted makes them unavoidable. Meyer (1983), for example, addressed the question
and Rowan (1977) therefore provide one of why there is such striking homogeneity of
of the strongest statements in terms of the organizational forms and practices, the phe-
cognitive nature of institutions. nomenon of isomorphism. They elucidated
708 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

three key mechanisms by which institutional The 1980s saw an impressive expansion
effects are diffused through a field of organi- of the realm of institutional theory both
zations resulting in structural isomorphism: theoretically and empirically. However, there
coercive, mimetic and normative. appeared to be continued ambiguity about
Tolbert and Zucker (1983) investigated the the nature of an institution and the processes
diffusion of civil service employment prac- through which it is constituted. The ambigu-
tices across US local governments, arriving ity is particularly striking in Baron and
at a two-stage model of diffusion encompass- Bielby (1986), where the term institution is
ing early adopters and late adopters. Early conceptualized in fundamentally different
adoptions were motivated by functional ways. The study depicts mimetic, coercive
imperatives but as an increasing number and normative mechanisms underpinning the
of organizations adopted the innovation, the spread of modern personnel administration
authors surmised that it became progres- in the US during and after World War II. In
sively institutionalized. They concluded that one sense, it uses the term institution as con-
social legitimacy was a driver for late stituting cultural prescriptions but in another
adopters. usage it describes it as depicting regulatory
Fligstein (1987) also examined diffusion agencies. The first usage resonates closely
of the rise of finance personnel to the posi- with Meyer and Rowan (1977) and Zucker
tion of president in large US corporations (1977) but the description of institutions as a
between 1919 and 1979. He posited a framework of regulatory policies leans more
mimetic explanation of diffusion. An anti- toward the sort of perspective developed
trust legislation pushed firms toward unre- in institutional economics (e.g., North,
lated diversification creating the conditions 1990). This example illustrates that in spite
for the rise in finance officers but as these of significant advances in institutional
actors established themselves in one set of research, a foundational concept – the
firms, their counterparts in other firms were institution – remains unclear. And, to make
able to use that as a basis for gaining power matters worse, these contradictory conceptu-
(Fligstein, 1987). alizations of the nature of institutions
Several studies in the 1980s pursued cross- remained unresolved over the next decade
category comparisons, for example, between and, in fact, became exacerbated.
commercial and not-for-profit organizations To summarize, impressive theoretical and
suggesting that the former were less sensitive empirical advances have been made in institu-
to institutional influences (e.g., Baron & tional theory over the past three decades. At
Bielby, 1986; Eisenhardt, 1988; Fennell & the same time, much of this work has side-
Alexander, 1987; Pfeffer & Davis-Blake, stepped the issue of what an institution actu-
1987; Tolbert, 1985). Further studies made ally is and how it comes to be. Although the
cross-national comparisons analyzing the cognitive nature of institutions is ostensibly
effect of cultural institutional effects (e.g., the foundation of institutional theory, estab-
Carroll, Goodstein, Gyenes, 1988; Hamilton lished clearly in the early works of Meyer and
& Biggart, 1988; Lincoln, Hanada, & Rowan (1977) and Zucker (1977), we see that
McBride, 1986). All of these studies covered very aspect gets muddied through the 1980s
a variety of different agents of diffusion and 1990s. A conspicuous absence of cita-
including government agencies, professional tions to Meyer and Rowan (1977), Zucker
networks, senior executives; a wide array of (1977) and Berger and Luckmann (1967) in
practices including personnel procedures, much of the work reflects this lack of clarity.
boundary-spanning strategies and accounting The process of institutionalization and the
practices; and a diverse range of settings role of social construction in that process –
including municipalities, hospitals, universi- the very basis for understanding that institu-
ties and corporations. tions are fundamentally cognitive – are
TAKING SOCIAL CONSTRUCTION SERIOUSLY 709

often neglected. Partly this has occurred approach associated with John Meyer and his
because of the overwhelming attention in students posits the importance of myths and
macro-level institutional research on institu- ceremony’, it ‘does not ask how these models
tional effects rather than the process itself. arise’ (DiMaggio & Powell, 1983: 157).
But to a great extent Scott’s (1995) three They then go on to suggest that their mecha-
pillars framework for defining institutions nisms may provide some explanations for
has compounded the ambiguity. We expand how and why cognitive institutions arise.
on this in greater detail in the next section. The work of DiMaggio and Powell (1983),
and the irresolvable ambiguity of their
framework, was taken up and developed by
Challenging the Three Pillars Scott (1995, 2001) in his highly influential
book Institutions and Organizations. Scott’s
As we discussed above, several influential book has played a significant role in shaping
contributions to institutional theory soon fol- the broad conception of institution that has
lowed the foundational works of Meyer and come to dominate in institutional theory and
Rowan (1977) and Zucker (1977). In one of has also had an important influence more
the most often cited articles, DiMaggio and broadly across related fields such as interna-
Powell (1983) identified the now ubiquitous tional management. We believe, however,
three mechanisms of institutional isomorphic that this conceptualization may in fact have
change. However, while this framework is been a distraction from actually understand-
very valuable in identifying sources of pres- ing the process of institutional production
sure for organizational isomorphism, the that is essential to completely comprehend
mechanisms they propose shed little light on the nature of institutions as it has had the
the actual process of institutionalization – a effect of taking institutionalization for
prerequisite for understanding institutions – granted.
nor on the nature of institutions. In his book, Scott develops a typology of
Furthermore, there is an underlying ten- what constitutes an institution comprising
sion in their framework. They begin by three component elements or pillars: the regu-
clearly indicating that they are interested in latory, normative and cultural-cognitive pillars.
something other than simple rational actor He draws on DiMaggio and Powell’s (1983)
explanations for isomorphism: typology to describe the mechanisms of con-
trol – coercive, normative and mimetic –
Today, however, structural change in organizations
seems less and less driven by competition or by the underpinning the regulatory, normative and
need for efficiency. Instead, we will contend, cultural-cognitive pillars respectively. The reg-
bureaucratization and other forms of organiza- ulatory pillar emphasizes explicit regulatory
tional change occur as the result of processes that processes involving ‘the capacity to establish
make organizations more similar without necessar-
rules, inspect others’ conformity to them, and
ily making them more efficient. (DiMaggio &
Powell, 1983: 147) as necessary, manipulate sanctions – rewards
and punishments – in an attempt to influence
Yet at the same time, they mix together future behaviour’ (Scott, 2001: 52). He goes on
acting in a taken-for-granted way in the face to explain that ‘[f]orce, fear, and expedience
of the cognitive institutions of Meyer and are central ingredients of the regulatory pillar’
Rowan (1977) and acting purposefully and (Scott, 2001: 53). Powerful actors may impose
rationally in the face of coercion or norma- their will on others, based on the threat of sanc-
tive pressures. Furthermore, they indicate tions or by offering inducements. In summary,
that, in fact, the sorts of cognitive institutions the basis for compliance underlying a regula-
that Meyer and Rowan (1977) are interested tory pillar is expedience, the mechanism is
in may be a result of these other mechanisms. coercive, and the basis of legitimacy is socially
They argue that while the ‘institutional sanctioned.
710 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

The normative pillar emphasizes ‘norma- development of a unified theory of institu-


tive rules that introduce a prescriptive, evalu- tions as it is difficult to see how to bridge the
ative and obligatory dimension into social ontological differences between the underly-
life’ (Scott, 2001: 55). Norms specify how ing perspectives on which the pillars rest.
things should be done and provide legitimate Second, the dynamics arising out of the
ways of pursuing valued ends. The basis of three pillars are very different. The regulative
compliance is social obligation, the mecha- and normative aspects of institutions are
nism is normative and the basis of legitimacy ‘the products of human design, and the out-
is moral. Sometimes regulative and norma- comes of purposive action by instrumentally
tive pillars can be mutually reinforcing, espe- oriented individuals’ (DiMaggio & Powell,
cially when coercive power is legitimated by 1991). Consequently, there is an opportunity
a normative framework that both supports for deviance and contestation as agents
and constrains the exercise of power (Scott, work to resist pressures that they recognize
1987). Scott (1995) points to the normative and which they believe to not be in their
conception of institutions embraced by early interests (Hirsch, 1997). Questions of power
sociologists such as Durkheim, Parsons, and and politics are central to these pillars as
Selznick, who focused on types of institu- actors work purposively and consciously to
tions such as kinship groups, social classes, advance their own interests. Furthermore, the
and religious systems that are usually under- literature that is most useful in understanding
pinned by common beliefs and values. these dynamics lies largely in work on
The cultural-cognitive pillar is what Scott power, resource dependency, and other
(1995) considers central to the thinking of related work.
scholars such as Berger, Meyer, and Zucker. The cognitive aspect of institutions, on the
The basis of compliance underlying the other hand, is very different from the other
cultural-cognitive pillar is taken-for-granted- two pillars (DiMaggio & Powell, 1991;
ness based on shared understandings, the Hirsch, 1997; Hoffman, 1997, 1999). Hirsch
mechanism is mimetic, and the basis of legit- (1997) argues that the basic assumptions and
imacy is something that is comprehensible, mechanisms underpinning the regulative and
recognizable and socially supported (Scott, normative pillars are, in fact, rejected in a
2001). Compliance occurs because other cognitive framework. In the first two pillars
types of behaviour are inconceivable – it stability and compliance is assured through
becomes the ‘way we do things around here’. values and norms that provide individuals
The socially mediated construction of a and corporate actors consciously understood
common framework of meaning is central to legal, social or moral rules and guidelines for
the cultural-cognitive pillar. behaviour (Hirsch, 1997). On the other hand,
Scott’s typology of the three pillars pro- within a cognitive frame conformity is driven
vides a comprehensive all-inclusive frame- unreflectively. As Hirsch puts it, the cogni-
work combining the different perspectives on tive pillar works with ‘no questions asked
institutions emanating from different theoret- and without deviation’ (Hirsch, 1997: 1710).
ical disciplines. While such a typology serves The underlying questions that arise around
that purpose of integrating different perspec- this pillar and the sorts of theoretical per-
tives, conceptualizing institutions as com- spectives useful in answering these questions
prising these three disparate elements raises a are fundamentally different from the other
number of problems. First, the processes by two pillars.
which these three pillars come to be are dif- Third, if an institution is enduring and
ferent. Scott (1995) himself points out that stable then it does not need regulatory sanc-
the three pillars are based on very different tions or other social controls to support it – it
philosophical assumptions about the nature is simply taken-for-granted. In a discussion of
of social reality. This is problematic for the various avenues for institutional reproduction,
TAKING SOCIAL CONSTRUCTION SERIOUSLY 711

Powell (1991) alludes to the exercise of power is functioning. Much of the empirical work in
in ensuring persistence of certain practices but institutional theory has failed to do this leav-
acknowledges that practices can take on a life ing us without any clear indication of what
of their own and not require any active elite actually happened.
support. Zucker (1991: 86) succinctly argues In sum, we are not arguing for a separate
that ‘direct social control through norms or institutional theory of cognitive institutions
sanctions (incentives or negative) is not neces- or claiming that one type of institution is
sary .... applying sanctions to institutionalized better than another. Rather we are posing
acts may have the effect of deinstitutionalizing a question central to the theoretical founda-
them .... the act of sanctioning may indicate tion of neo-institutional theory – what is
that there are other possible, attractive alterna- an institution and how does it come to
tives’. Berger and Luckmann, similarly, con- be? Furthermore, we are highlighting the
trast institutions with other forms of social problems with the three pillars approach
control: in helping address this question.
To say that a segment of human activity has been
We believe we need to delve into the
institutionalized is already to say that this segment process of institutional production at the
of human activity has been subsumed under social macro-organizational level that provides
control. Additional control mechanisms are required insight into how an institution comes to be.
only in so far as the processes of institutionalization And, we will argue in the next section that a
are less than completely successful. (1967: 73)
discursive perspective on institutions and
This is a powerful argument suggesting institutionalization provides a practical foun-
that institutions are best thought of as dation for developing a more effective theory
fundamentally cognitive and that these other of institutions. Using a discursive perspective
two pillars not be combined in a theory of we are able to illuminate the social construc-
institutions. When something has become tivist nature of the process of institutionaliza-
institutionalized no outside sanctions or tion and this leads us to the understanding
controls are required. These other forces can that when compliance comes naturally and
create social order, but they are of a very dif- automatically without the active intervention
ferent sort than cognitive institutions. of sanctions or norms an institution comes to
Furthermore, this raises an interesting the- be. Hence, institutions are fundamentally
oretical question: are the regulative and nor- cognitive. In other words, a discursive
mative pillars, important pressures in the approach is a useful theoretical and method-
process of institutionalization rather than ological approach for understanding micro-
elements of an institution? It would seem processes of institutionalization at the
that most of us, for example, obey traffic macro-organizational level and clarifies the
laws unthinkingly rather than because we cognitive nature of institutions.
are concerned about the potential punish-
ment. Traffic laws have become a cognitive
institution for most of us most of the time.
However, the appearance of a new law often USING DISCOURSE ANALYSIS TO
leads to changes in behaviour because of the UNDERSTAND AND STUDY
potential punishment that is associated with INSTITUTIONS
the new law. But soon it too becomes taken-
for-granted over time. It is important to note In this section, we will explore some of the
that there is no way to differentiate between implications of a discursive perspective for
the two motivations for behaviour except institutional theory. We will begin by
by examining the behaviour itself. We need explaining what discourse analysis is and
to study intentions at an individual level explaining its usefulness as a theoretical and
to understand which sort of mechanism methodological framework for studying
712 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

processes of social construction. We will strong claims about the way in which social
then discuss the existing literature which reality is constructed through the production,
links discourse analysis and institutional transmission, and reception of texts.
theory, focusing in particular on a discursive Discourse analysis is therefore both a method
model of institutionalization drawing on and a methodology in that it makes explicit
Phillips et al. (2004) We will argue that a dis- claims about the nature of the social world
cursive view of institutions leads to a very and provides a set of tools for studying it
different view than the prevailing idea of (Phillips & Hardy, 2002).
three pillars of institutions as argued by Scott It is important to point out that discourses
(2001). Finally, we will discuss some of the can never be found in their entirety.
ramifications for theory and empirical inves- Discourse analysts are therefore limited to
tigation in institutional theory of adopting examining selections of the texts that
this approach. embody a particular discourse. Derived
from linguistics, ‘text’ is used to refer to
various forms of meaningful interaction. In
other words, texts are texts because they can
Discourse Analysis and Social be interpreted. Texts may take a variety of
forms, including written texts, spoken
Construction
words, pictures, symbols, artefacts, etc. At
Discourse analysis, at its most fundamental, the same time, discourse analysts do not
is an attempt to answer the question of where simply focus on individual texts; rather, in
meaning comes from (see Alvesson & analyzing discourse researchers must refer
Karreman, 2000; Grant, Hardy, Oswick, & to bodies of texts since it is the interrela-
Putnam, 2004; Phillips & Hardy, 2002 for tions between texts, changes in texts, new
extended discussions of discourse analysis). textual forms, and new systems of distribut-
Understanding what discourse analysis is ing texts that constitute a discourse over
about begins with an understanding of what time. Similarly, discourse analysis requires
discourse is. Discourse, in general terms, researchers to make reference to the social
refers to an interrelated set of texts and the context in which texts are found and the dis-
associated practices of production, dissemi- courses of which they are a part are pro-
nation, and reception that bring an object into duced. It is this connection between
being. For example, at one point in history discourses and the social reality that they
the concept of endangered species did not yet constitute that makes discourse analysis
exist and by extension there were no ‘endan- a powerful method for studying social
gered species’ as we understand them today. phenomena.
Through a long process, the concept of Texts can thus be considered to be a dis-
endangered species came to be meaningful cursive ‘unit’ and a material manifestation of
and accepted. Furthermore, the concept discourse. Texts are not meaningful individu-
became applied to certain species of animals ally: it is only through their interconnection
and endangered species came into being. with other texts, the different discourses
This process, from a discourse analysis per- upon which they draw, and the nature of their
spective, occurs in and through discourse. production, dissemination and consumption
Discourse analysis, by extension, is the that they are made meaningful. Discourse
study of discourse and the social reality that analysis explores how texts are made mean-
it constitutes. In our case here, the study of ingful through these processes, and also how
the discourses that are implicated in the they contribute to the constitution of social
social production of institutions. But in addi- reality by making meaning.
tion to simply a method of studying social What is important here from a social con-
construction, discourse analysis includes struction point of view is that these processes
TAKING SOCIAL CONSTRUCTION SERIOUSLY 713

do not occur in single texts. No single text is very existence of an institution and the
sufficiently powerful to bring an object into process of institutionalization. It is this
being. Social construction occurs when suffi- aspect that resonates strongly with discourse
cient numbers of texts are produced and analysis. It is important to emphasize that
structured in discourses. These texts draw on discourse analysis is not just a methodologi-
one another and in doing so increasingly give cal approach but also a theoretical approach
the social reality represented in the texts a with underlying theoretical assumptions that
taken-for-granted facticity. Any one text is relate specifically to the social construction
insufficient to result in the construction of of reality (e.g., Chia, 2000; Gergen, 1999;
some new object. It is only when complex Phillips & Hardy, 2002; Grant & Hardy,
bodies of text occur that this process can 2004) making it a potentially powerful and
move forward. useful lens in the context of institutional
theory. Institutions as social constructions,
produced through meaningful interaction, are
central to institutional theory (e.g., Meyer &
Discourse and Institutional Rowan, 1977). From a discursive perspec-
tive, institutions are not just social construc-
Theory
tions but social constructions constituted
There has been growing interest among through discourse (Phillips et al., 2004).
scholars of institutional theory in the discur- In their article Phillips et al. (2004)
sive perspective and its potential to further propose a model linking action and discourse
explicate and expand core aspects of this that begins to explain the process of
influential theoretical stream. There are at institutionalization (see Figure 29.1).
least two triggers that have sparked this inter- Institutionalization does not occur through
est: first, the publication of Phillips, the simple imitation of an action by immedi-
Lawrence and Hardy’s (2004) article arguing ate observers, but through the creation of
for a rapprochement between institutional supporting texts that range from conversa-
theory and its social constructivist roots and, tional descriptions among co-workers and
second, when there has been an important colleagues to more elaborate and widely dis-
shift in institutional theory from the language tributed texts such as manuals, books, and
of conformity and isomorphism to a strong magazine articles. Actions do not become
interest in change and deviation (e.g., institutionalized by themselves but only
Greenwood & Hinings, 1996). when they become understood in a particular
In their article, Phillips et al. (2004) begin way. This is particularly true in the organiza-
by arguing that the processes underlying tional realm where many actions are not
institutionalization are not well understood. directly observable but must rather be
They go on to argue that institutionalization learned about through accounts in various
occurs as actors interact and come to accept texts (think of Total Quality Management
shared definitions of reality, and that it is and its institutionalization as a common
through linguistic processes that definitions organizational practice). Accordingly, the
of reality are constituted (Berger & upward, diagonal arrows illustrate how the
Luckmann, 1967). From their perspective, an actions of individual actors affect the discur-
institution is a reciprocal typification of sive realm through the production of texts,
habitualized action by types of actors and some of which leave meaningful traces that
institutionalization is the ‘social process by become embedded in new or existing
which individuals come to accept a shared discourses. Not all, or even most, actions
definition of social reality’ that enacts an lead to the production of texts. But some
institution (Scott, 1987: 496). Thus, the do and some of these go on to influence the
social construction of reality underpins the discourse in important ways.
714 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Figure 29.1 The relation between action and discourse (adapted from Phillips et al., 2004)

In turn, discourses provide the socially This question becomes crucial especially
constituted, self-regulating mechanisms that in regard to how new institutions are created
enact institutions and shape the actions that and existing ones changed. Discourse is both
lead to the production of more texts. a source of stability and of change (Clegg,
The bodies of texts that accumulate lead to Courpasson, & Phillips, 2006). Embedded in
the production of ‘shared typifications’ and the notion of discourse is the potential
institutions are produced through processes for stabilizing social relations and as well
of social construction. Thus, the discursive as acting as a source of social change.
realm acts as the background against which As much as discursive practices reaffirm
current actions occur – enabling some and re-enact social structure, they also
actions, constraining others (as illustrated provide an arena for contradictions and
by the downward, vertical arrows in conflicts (Clegg et al., 2006: 303). A discur-
Figure 29.1). This then is the discursive sive framework, therefore, provides
explanation of how particular sorts of actions an appropriate theoretical and empirical
become institutionalized. ground to examine processes of institutional
In terms of the second point, the change.
development of a discursive perspective has The issue of institutional change raises
been also encouraged by an increasing another question: Are cognitive based institu-
interest in institutional change. In the past tions and their creation different from coer-
couple of decades institutional theory cive and normatively based institutions? The
has predominantly provided insights into regulative, normative and cognitive pillars of
processes that explain institutional stability institutions have become taken-for-granted
rather than change and the emphasis in institutional theory but the relationship
has been on how institutional pressures between these aspects continues to be
(regulative, normative, cultural-cognitive) ambiguous. Scott (2001: 51) posits ‘one pos-
force organizations to converge on a stan- sible approach would be to view all of these
dard set of practices. Due to an over- facets as contributing, in interdependent and
whelming concern with convergence, there mutually reinforcing ways, to a powerful
has been little attention toward unpacking social framework’ but suggests that distin-
processes of how institutions are socially guishing among these elements may be more
constructed. useful. However, the focus is on effects of
TAKING SOCIAL CONSTRUCTION SERIOUSLY 715

these different types of institutional pillars organizational field or on the impact of an


rather than how they get created. Hoffman institutional change, a discourse perspective
(1997: 36) suggests that the three pillars form refocuses attention on the process of institu-
a continuum ‘from the conscious to the tionalization itself. This is not to say that
unconscious, from the legally enforced to the existing and future studies on the effects of
taken-for-granted’. This raises the question: institutions are any less valuable. Rather it is
Does the process of social construction simply to say that a new area of research
underlie that continuum? In a recent review becomes available looking at the process of
of developments in institutional theory even institutionalization, how it unfolds in differ-
Scott acknowledges that the three pillars are ent circumstances, and the roles of various
found together but it is the cultural-cognitive actors in the process.
pillar that provides the ‘deeper foundations From the perspective of a discursive
of institutional forms ... the infrastructure theory of institutions, the process through
on which not only beliefs, but norms and which institutions come into being is empiri-
rules rest’ (2004: 5). This further raises cally accessible. Researchers can follow the
the question: Is the ambiguity surrounding production of texts looking for the appear-
the relationship between the three types of ance of key concepts and understandings and
institutions due to the lack of an appropriate can therefore trace the production of institu-
theoretical and empirical lens to unpack it? tions as well as the processes through which
institutions change or are de-institutionalized
(Oliver, 1992). The focus on the appearance
of influential texts and the meanings that
Extending the Discourse Perspective these texts create as they accrete over time
provides a clear empirical approach to the
on Institutions
processes of social construction that underlie
So far, we have introduced discourse analysis institutional dynamics. Researchers can also
and explored how it can be used as a frame- trace the impact of the activities of particular
work to explain the social construction of actors by tracing the texts that they produce
institutions. But what are the ramifications and the impacts of these texts.
of this for institutional theory? And what
are the next steps in the development of
the discursive perspective in institutional Reframing the symbolic versus practice
theory? We will turn our attention to these debate
questions now. In particular, we will discuss A discursive theory of institutionalization
three areas with important ramifications also has important ramifications for the sym-
for institutional theory: changing the focus bolic versus practice debate in institutional
of empirical research, reframing the sym- theory. Where some theorists have argued that
bolic versus the practice debate, and bringing institutions arise out of practices (e.g., Barley
society back in. & Tolbert, 1997), others have argued strongly
for a more symbolic foundation for
institutions (e.g., Zilber, 2002). Interestingly,
Changing the focus of empirical the discursive perspective takes us back to the
research early formulations of Berger and Luckmann
First, a discursive perspective on institutions (1967) in focusing on both symbols and
and institutionalization leads to an important practices. Just as Berger and Luckmann pro-
change in the focus of empirical studies in posed that an institution is a practice made
institutional theory. Rather than a focus on meaningful through interaction, so too does
the outcomes of institutional processes in the discursive perspective focus our attention
terms of increasing similarity across an on both the practice and how it is made
716 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

meaningful in discourse. It requires both to needs to be done in this area, we believe


make up an institution. An institution without there is real potential for illuminating the
action makes no more sense than one without complex processes and relationships that sur-
meaning. round institutional logics.
From this perspective then, we are search-
ing for a combination of the development of
patterned practices and the textual work done CONCLUSIONS
to make the practices meaningful. This
process may be more or less intentional with In this chapter, we have argued that discourse
actors working to ensure that their preferred analysis can contribute an important new
meanings prevail but often these activities will perspective to institutional theory. This is
be overshadowed by factors endogenous and unsurprising given that the two streams of
exogenous to the discourse. Unravelling literature arise from a single source – the
this complex process becomes the task of the linguistic turn in social science (Alvesson &
institutional theorist interested in how institu- Karreman, 2000) – and that discourse analy-
tions come to be and why they are the way sis seeks to understand the nature of the
they are. processes of social construction that lie at
the heart of institutionalization. Interestingly,
the interest in social construction that charac-
Bringing society back in terized the earliest forms of new institutional
Finally, taking social construction seriously theory in the work of Meyer and Rowan
in institutional theory leads to important (1977) has reappeared in several recent arti-
questions regarding the relation between dis- cles from different but related perspectives
course at a field level and broader societal highly sympathetic to social construction
discourses. In discourse theory, the question such as Phillips et al. (2004), Suddaby and
of the relation between levels of discourse Greenwood (2005) and Zilber (2006).
(and to some degree the question of whether The increasing interest in a more balanced
‘levels’ is even the right metaphor) remain a perspective on change and stability as well
source of serious contention (e.g., Alvesson as structure and agency has necessarily led
& Karreman, 2000). At the same time, it is to this increasing interest in the micro-
clear that there are broader societal level dis- foundations of institutional processes.
courses that frame the sorts of discourses In adding to the emerging discursive per-
which occur in organizational fields and the spective in neo-institutional theory, we make
discourse approach we are arguing for here three main contributions. First, we explore
provides tools and a frame for considering some of the ramifications of adopting a dis-
and exploring this interaction. cursive perspective on the process of institu-
This question of levels of discourse has tionalization. While the process itself has
obvious parallels to discussions of institu- already been presented in some detail, the
tional logics in institutional theory (e.g., theoretical ramifications of this perspective
Lounsbury, 2002). The interaction between have not been fully explored. Our argument
well-established societal discourse and dis- here is that a discursive perspective high-
course at the level of the organizational field lights the cognitive nature of institutions and
parallels the interaction of societal level exposes the unresolved tensions around the
logics and the logics of fields. It therefore nature of an institution. We argue that they
seems possible that a discourse perspective are fundamentally cognitive and that they do
may shed some light on what is currently a not involve external sanctions. We concur
rather murky theoretical construct and on with Jepperson (1991) that institutions are
how various levels of logics combine and self-reinforcing and external sanctions are
reinforce each other. While much more work not part of institutional mechanisms.
TAKING SOCIAL CONSTRUCTION SERIOUSLY 717

This leads to our second contribution. theory, discourse analysis is also a research
If institutions are fundamentally cognitive, method (e.g., Phillips & Hardy, 2002) with
then the three pillars framework of Scott important ramifications for empirical
(2001), which has become so dominant in research in institutional theory. We believe
institutional analysis, has been more limiting there are three important areas that have par-
than helpful in developing our understanding ticular potential. First, discourse analysis
of the nature of institutions. By combining all provides an approach to exploring the micro-
of the mechanisms which can lead to isomor- dynamics of the production of institutions. In
phism into the definition of an institution, particular, the initial production of a proto-
Scott has produced a framework which has institution and then its subsequent diffusion
something for everyone, but it raises critical throughout an organizational field.
theoretical and philosophical problems. In Second, as we have argued above, there are
mixing such different constructs, institutional two alternate explanations of institutionaliza-
theory is left without any way of developing a tion: a behavioural one (Barley & Tolbert,
unified theory of institutionalization. The fact 1997) and a textual one (Phillips et al., 2004).
that coercive and normative mechanisms are Given the textually mediated context of
externally managed by other actors makes organizational fields, we argue that discursive
them very different from the taken-for-granted- approaches are critical to understanding the
ness of cognitive mechanisms. Where coercive development of institutions but that a sensitiv-
and normative mechanisms result in strategic ity to both behaviour and discourse is required
action and often resistance, cognitive mecha- for a full understanding.
nisms function by conditioning thinking. Finally, discourse analysis has an impor-
Douglas (1986: 10) makes this argument very tant role to play in the ongoing exploration of
clearly when she says that ‘[e]pistemological the interactions between different organiza-
resources may be able to explain what cannot tional fields and between broader societal
be explained by the theory of rational behav- institutions and local fields. The methods
iour’. In other words, theories of rational provided by discourse analysis allow
behaviour explain the responses of actors researchers to begin to explore the intertextu-
to coercive and normative mechanism; cogni- ality that characterizes these processes and
tive mechanisms explain something very dif- untangle some of the complexities of these
ferent and this is the proper domain of cultural systems.
institutional theory. In closing, we hope that the themes we
Third, in reconnecting neo-institutional have explored in this chapter explain some of
theory with social construction we empha- our enthusiasm for the subject. We believe
size the broad interest in culture and lan- that neo-institutional theory is at a crossroads
guage that has played such an important part and risks in some ways trying to be every-
in new and neo-institutional theory. Even a thing to everyone. While a multiplicity of
cursory examination of the literature reveals approaches and views is a sign of robust
a preponderance of empirical studies and health, it can also wear away at the infra-
theoretical discussion focused on taken- structure that provided the impetus for dis-
for-grantedness and the dynamics of the cussion in the first place. In some ways,
underlying cognitive processes. The connec- perhaps we have overshot – in trying to move
tion with discourse analysis provides new away from a theory that was unnecessarily
opportunities for studying institutions and narrow we have developed one that is
institutionalization. impractically broad. We believe that institu-
This leads to the final point of this chapter. tional theory needs to return to its roots in
While much of our discussion has been about social constructionism and the well-spring of
the theoretical and philosophical ramifica- creative thought that this produced. While
tions of discourse analysis for institutional this will necessitate a narrowing of our
718 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

understanding of what an institution is, it Commons, J.R. 1924. The Legal Foundations of
will also provide a renewed ability to under- Capitalism: New York: Macmillan.
stand how they work. Zucker’s call to focus Cooley, C.H. [1902] 1956. Social Organization.
on the micro-processes of institutional pro- Glencoe, IL: Free Press.
duction at the macro-level has been ignored Davis, K. 1949. Human Society. New York:
Macmillan.
for too long!
DiMaggio, P.J., and Powell, W.W. 1983. The
iron cage revisited: Institutional isomorphism
and collective rationality in organizational
fields. American Sociological Review, 48:
NOTES 147–160.
DiMaggio, P., and Powell, W. 1991. The iron
1 We use the term institutional theory in this cage revisited: Institutional isomorphism and
chapter to refer to the stream of literature running collective rationality in organizational fields.
from new institutional theory down through more In W.W. Powell and P.J. DiMaggio (eds.),
recent developments in neo institutional theory. The New Institutionalism in Organizational
When we wish to differentiate between new and
Analysis: 63–82. Chicago: The University of
neo institutionalism we will identify them explicitly.
References to other forms of institutionalism will be
Chicago Press.
made explicitly (e.g., old institutionalism or institu- Douglas, M. 1986. How Institutions Think.
tional economics). Syracuse, NY: Syracuse University Press.
Durkheim, E. 1949. Division of Labor in Society.
Glencoe, IL: Free Press.
Eisenhardt, K.M. 1988. Agency-theory
and institutional theory explanations:
REFERENCES The case of retail sales compensation.
Academy of Management Journal, 31 (3):
Alvesson, M., and Karreman, D. 2000. Taking 488–511.
the linguistic turn in organizational research: Fennell, M.L., and Alexander, J.A. 1987.
challenges, responses, consequences. The Organizational boundary spanning in insti-
Journal of Applied Behavioral Science, 36(2): tutionalized environments. Academy of
136–158. Management Journal, 30 (3): 456–476.
Barley, S.R., and Tolbert, P.S. 1997. Fligstein, N. 1987. The intraorganizational
Institutionalization and structuration: power struggle: The rise of finance presi-
Studying the links between action and insti- dents in large corporations, 1919–1979.
tution. Organization Studies, 18: 93–117. American Sociological Review, 52: 44–58.
Baron, J.N., and Bielby, W.T. 1986. The prolifer- Gergen, K. 1999. An Invitation to Social
ation of job titles in organizations. Construction. London: Sage.
Administrative Science Quarterly, 31(4): Grant, D., and Hardy, C. 2004. Introduction:
561–586. Struggles with organizational discourse,
Berger, B., and Luckmann, T. 1967. The Social Organization Studies, 25(1): 5–13.
Construction of Reality: A Treatise on the Grant, D., Hardy, C., Oswick, C., and Putnam,
Sociology of Knowledge. Garden City, NY: L. 2004. Handbook of organizational dis-
Anchor. course. London: Sage.
Carroll, G.R., Goodstein, J., and Gyenes, J. Greenwood, R., and Hinings C.R. 1996.
1988. Organizations and the state: Effects of Understanding radical organizational
the institutional environment on agricultural change: Bringing together the old and the
cooperatives in Hungary. Administrative new institutionalism. Academy of
Science Quarterly, 33: 233–256. Management Review, 21: 1022–1054.
Chia, R. 2000. Discourse analysis as organiza- Hamilton, G., and Biggart, N.W. 1988. Market,
tion analysis. Organization, 7(3): 513–518. culture and authority: A comparative analysis
Clegg, S.R., Courpasson, D., and Phillips, N. of management and organization in the Far
2006. Power and Organizations. Sage: East. American Journal of Sociology, 94
London. (Supplement): S52–S94.
TAKING SOCIAL CONSTRUCTION SERIOUSLY 719

Hirsch, P. 1997. Sociology without social struc- Phillips, N., Lawrence, T.B., and Hardy, C. 2004.
ture: Neo-institutional theory meets brave Discourse and institutions. Academy of
new world. American Journal of Sociology, Management Review, 29: 635–652.
102: 1702–1723. Powell, W. 1991. Expanding the scope
Hoffman, A. 1997. From heresy to dogma: of institutional analysis. In W.W. Powell
An institutional history of corporate environ- and P.J. DiMaggio (eds.), The New
mentalism. San Francisco: New Lexington Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis:
Press. 183–203. Chicago: The University of
Hoffman, A. 1999. Institutional evolution and Chicago Press.
change: Environmentalism and the U.S. Schutz, A. [1932]1967. The Phenomenology of
chemical industry. Academy of Management the Social World. Trans. George Walsh and
Journal, 42: 351–371. Frederick Lehnart. Evanston, IL: North
Hughes, E.C. 1936. The ecological aspect of Western University Press.
institutions. American Sociological Review, Scott, W.R. 1987. The adolescence of institu-
1: 180–189. tional theory. Administrative Science
Jepperson, R.L. 1991. Institutions, institutional Quarterly, 32: 493–511.
effects, and institutionalism. In W.W. Powell Scott, W.R. 1995. Institutions and Organiza-
and P.J. DiMaggio (eds.), The New Institu- tions. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.
tionalism in Organizational Analysis: 143–163. Scott, W. R. 2001. Institutions and Organiza-
Chicago: The University of Chicago Press. tions. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.
Lincoln, J.R., Hanada, M., and McBride, K. 1986. Scott, W.R. 2004. Reflections on a half-century
Organizational structures in Japanese and of organization sociology. Annual Review of
United States manufacturing. Administrative Sociology, 30: 1–21.
Science Quarterly, 31 (3): 403–421. Selznick, P. 1948. Foundations of the theory of
Lounsbury, M. 2002. Institutional transforma- organization. American Sociological Review,
tion and status mobility: The professionaliza- 13: 25–35.
tion of the field of finance. Academy of Selznick, P. 1957. Leadership in Administration.
Management Journal, 45: 255–266. Evanston, IL: Row, Peterson.
Mead, H. 1934. Mind, Self and Society. Suddaby, R., and Greenwood, R.
Chicago: University of Chicago Press. 2005. Rhetorical strategies of legitimacy,
Menger, C. [1871]1981. Problems of Economics Administrative Science Quarterly, 50: 35–67.
and Sociology. Trans. F.J. Nock. Urbana: Sumner, G. 1906. Folkways. Boston: Ginn & Co.
University of Illinois Press. Tolbert, P.S. 1985. Institutional environments
Meyer, J., and Rowan, B. 1977. Institutio- and resource dependence: Sources
nalized organizations: Formal structure as of administrative structure in institutions of
myth and ceremony. American Journal of higher education. Administrative Science
Sociology, 83: 340–363. Quarterly, 30(1): 1–13.
Meyer, J.W., and Scott, W.R. 1983. Tolbert, P.S., and Zucker, L.G. 1983.
Organizational Environments. Beverley Hills, Institutional sources of change in the formal
CA: Sage Publications. structure of organizations: The diffusion of
North, D.R. 1990. Institutions, Institutional civil service reform, 1880–1935.
Change, and Economic Performance. Administrative Science Quarterly, 30: 22–39.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Van de Ven, A.H. 1993. The institutional theory
Oliver, C. 1992. The antecedents of deinstitu- of John R. Commons: A review and com-
tionalization. Organization Studies, 13: mentary. Academy of Management Review,
563–588. 18: 129–52.
Pfeffer, J., and Davis-Blake, A. 1987. The effect Veblen, T.B. 1909. The limitations of marginal util-
of the proportion of women on salaries: The ity. Journal of Political Economy, 17: 235–245.
case of college administrators. Administrative Zilber, T.B. 2002. Institutionalization as an
Science Quarterly, 32 (1): 1–24. interplay between actions, meanings, and
Phillips, N., and Hardy, C. 2002. Discourse actors: The case of a rape crisis center in
Analysis: Investigating Processes of Social Israel. Academy of Management Journal,
Construction. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage. 45(1): 234–254.
720 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Zilber, T.B. 2006. The work of meaning in insti- Zucker, L. 1991. The role of institutionalization
tutional processes: Translations of rational in cultural persistence. In W.W. Powell and
myths in Israeli Hi-Tech. Academy of P.J. DiMaggio (eds.), The New Institutionalism
Management Journal 49(2): 279–301. in Organizational Analysis: 83–107. Chicago:
Zucker, L. 1977. The role of institutionalization University of Chicago Press.
in cultural persistence. American Sociological
Review, 42: 726–743.
30
Institutional Leadership: Past,
Present, and Future
Marvin Washington, Kimberly B. Boal and John N. Davis

INTRODUCTION in Administration. Many scholars have cred-


ited this work with ushering in discussions
Since the early writings of DiMaggio and of institutions as ‘organizations infused
Powell (1983), Meyer and Rowan (1977) and with value.’ However, not only did Selznick
Zucker (1987), many insights have been describe how organizations become institu-
gained under the broad umbrella of institu- tions, but he also described the characteris-
tional analysis. Constructs such as ‘isomor- tics of leaders of these organizations.
phism,’ ‘de-coupling,’ and ‘coercive Projects have since examined institutional
pressure,’ are now mainstream in much orga- leadership (e.g., Kraatz and Moore, 2002).
nizational theorizing. Recently, there have Institutional leadership, ‘ the promotion and
been new terms coined to describe the grow- protection of values’ (Selznick, 1957: 28)
ing interest in agency in institutional analy- is different from traditional leadership: ‘task
ses. Now, it is not uncommon to see phrases and person-oriented behaviors of leaders
such as ‘institutional strategy’ (Lawrence, as they attempt to provide guidance, support,
1999) and ‘institutional entrepreneurship’ and feedback to subordinates’ (Boal and
(DiMaggio, 1988; Suddaby and Greenwood, Schultz, 2007). It is the concept of institu-
2005), to describe the behavior of individuals tional leadership that we examine in this
and organizations that are attempting to article.
change the institutional landscape in a partic- In this article, we do three things. First, we
ular environment. In this chapter, we con- discuss Selznick’s original ideas about insti-
tinue this line of inquiry, not by going tutional leadership and the role they play in
forward, but by stepping back and highlight- institutionalization processes. We also review
ing the contribution of early work on exam- the trajectory of his work, by examining the
ining agency in institutional analysis. Here, work in the organizations and institutions lit-
we discuss and extend ideas around institu- erature that have built upon Selznick’s ideas.
tional leadership. Second, we extend his work by examining
It has been 50 years since Selznick the three functions of institutional leaders.
published his seminal work Leadership First, they manage the internal consistency of
722 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

the firm (Selzick’s notion of commitment to and technical its operations, the slower the
the values and mission of the organization). institutionalization process. Thus, to institu-
Second, they develop external supporting tionalize an organization is to ‘infuse with
mechanisms to enhance the legitimacy of the value beyond the technical requirements of
organization. Third, institutional leaders, the task at hand’ (1957: 17). This ‘infuse with
overcome external enemies. We conclude by value’ statement is closely connected with an
suggesting a reconciliation between institu- organization’s concern with self-mainte-
tional leadership and the work on traditional nance (the organization’s desire to maintain
(or organizational) leadership. Our core its existence beyond the technical require-
argument is that organizational leadership, or ments of the organization). Note the active
leaders inside of organizations, is(are) nature of the word institutionalize. Selznick
based upon a notion of instrumental agency, is suggesting the process of institutionaliza-
hierarchical and charismatic power, and typ- tion is a process that occurs as leaders
ically uses a future leaning vision. respond to the internal and external forces
Institutional leadership, or leaders of organi- that are placed upon organizations.
zations, is(are) based upon a notion of After describing what Selznick means by
embedded or constrained agency, influence institution, as opposed to organization, he
or negotiated power, and typically uses a returns to his primary objective of describing
backward-leaning vision meaning that the the role of institutional leaders in this
vision is there to remind the organization of process. ‘Most of this essay will be devoted
the core values. to identifying and analyzing the chief func-
tions of institutional leadership’ (1957: 22).
He distinguishes the institutional leader as
separate from the interpersonal leader (what
SELZNICK’S VIEWS OF might be described as the charismatic
INSTITUTIONAL LEADERSHIP or transformational leader). The interper-
sonal leader’s task is ‘to smooth the path of
Most scholars know of Selznick’s work human interaction, ease communication,
Leadership in Administration as providing evoke personal devotion, and allay anxiety’
the famous definition of institutions as organ- (1957: 27). The institutional leader’s task
izations ‘infused with value.’ However, this however is ‘the promotion and protection of
is a secondary concern with his work. values’ (1957: 28).
Selznick’s primary objective in Leadership The first task Selznick describes is the cre-
in Administration is to understand the behav- ation and maintenance of the organization’s
iors and characteristics of those who lead character. Selznick suggests that leading an
institutions and how these behaviors are dif- institution:
ferent than the behaviors of those who lead is far more than the capacity to mobilize personal
organizations. In Selznick’s own words ‘The support; it is more than the maintenance of
argument of this essay is quite simply stated: equilibrium through the routine solution of everyday
The executive becomes a statesman as he problems; it is the function of the leader-statesman –
whether of a nation or a private association – to
makes the transition from administrative
define the ends of group existence, to design an
management to institutional leadership’ enterprise distinctively adapted to these ends, and
(1957: 4). This leads to his discussion of to see that the design becomes a living reality.
institutionalization as a process; organiza- These tasks are not routine; they call for continu-
tions become institutions over time. The ous self-appraisal on the part of the leaders; and
they may require only a few critical decisions over
degree of institutionalization depends upon
a long period of time. (1957: 37)
the potential conflict between the leader’s
goals and group’s goals; the more precise an It is these few critical decisions that create an
organization’s goals and the more specialized organization’s character.
INSTITUTIONAL LEADERSHIP: PAST, PRESENT, AND FUTURE 723

The development of an organization’s char- with leadership of organizations and the lead-
acter is a necessary step in the institutionaliza- ership literature is concerned with leadership
tion process of organizations. ‘The study of inside organizations.
organizational character-formation is, then, a
phase of institutional analysis. Here the
emphasis is on the embodiment of values in an Extensions that do not deal
organizational structure through the elabora-
with leadership
tion of commitments – ways of acting and
responding that can be changed, if at all, only Most of the citations to Selznick’s 1957 book
at the risk of severe internal crises’ (1957: 40). are not about institutional leadership. Though
To expand upon this point further, Selznick our search and analysis was not exhaustive,
draws upon his examples as diverse as the from the articles that we did review, the
Tennessee Valley Authority (Selznick, 1949) typical citation to Selznick’s work is his
and the Bolshevik Party (Selznick, 1952). description of institutions as organizations
Selznick summarizes his arguments about infused with value (Selznick, 1957: 17).
institutional leadership by suggesting that the Another major part of the literature that
function of institutional leadership is inher- builds on Selznick is his work on organiza-
ently political. ‘We have argued that policy tional commitments. Of the work that focuses
and administration are interdependent in the on institutional leadership, the top manage-
special sense that certain areas of organiza- ment team literature refers to Selznick most
tional activity are peculiarly sensitive to often. For example, in their work on cognitive
policy matters. Because these areas exist, and affective conflict, Amason and Sapienza
creative men are needed ... These men are (1997) argue that the greater agreement
called leaders; their profession is politics’ among the top management team, the less
(1957: 61). However, he is not referring to the affective conflict. They draw this support
the political or power sense of the word pol- from Selznick’s argument that ‘a central
itics but politics in the sense of consensus. function of top management is to create
super-ordinate goals that unite action and to
reward cooperative behavior towards those
goals’ (Amason and Sapienza, 1997: 502).
EXTENSIONS OF SELZNICK’S WORK This is similar to the other work on top
management teams that draws from Selznick.
A search of ‘Leadership in Administration’
on Google Scholar generated over 750 cita-
tions. Of those citations, 170 have been in The leadership extensions
Academy of Management Journal, Strategic
Management Journal, Administrative It is the work of Kraatz and Moore that most
Science Quarterly, Organization Studies, exemplifies the extensions of Selznick’s
Human Relations, Organization Science, and work on institutional leadership. Kraatz and
Journal of Management Studies. Ironically, Moore’s (2002) study examines the role of
fewer than 10 of the 750 citations were in leadership migration in the institutional
Leadership Quarterly (more on that later). In changes of liberal arts college education.
this section, we examine how Selznick’s They argued that, except for a few theoretical
ideas on institutional leadership have been statements about the role of leadership in
extended in the current literature. After that, institutional change and the rare empirical
we speculate as to why Selznick’s concept of exception (Hirsch, 1986; Leblebici, Salancik,
institutional leadership hasn’t been more Copay and King, 1991), the role of leader-
prominent in the leadership literature: our ship in institutional change has been neg-
brief answer is that Selznick is concerned lected over the past 40 years. Drawing from
724 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Selznick’s statement that a critical compo- to evaluate the senior managers. These
nent of institutionalization is the selection of assessments created a ‘carrot and stick’
leaders from a homogeneous pool of candi- (2004: 596) approach to managing internal
dates, Kraatz and Moore examine three expectations. Similar to Selznick’s original
mechanisms of how leadership changes lead conclusions, Tengblad concluded that the
to institutional change: (1) knowledge CEOs in his study spent enormous energy in
transfer and interorganizational learning; managing the external expectations of their
(2) introduction of new mental models and organizations. However, this management
assumptions; and (3) attenuation or replace- process did not automatically lead to changes
ment of institutional values (2002: 123). to the organization.
Kraatz and Moore find support for their By bringing institutional leadership back
hypotheses regarding the factors that allow to the forefront of institutional analysis, we
leadership migration to impact organiza- argue that institutional leadership might be
tional change. the reconciliation between the first wave of
While this represents an exemplar in the institutional analysis which were more inter-
extension of Selznick’s work, other scholars ested in a deterministic view of institutional-
have also contributed to a better understand- ized action (DiMaggio and Powell, 1983)
ing of institutional leadership. In a wonderful and the calls for a more agentic view of insti-
study examining the role of CEOs, Tengblad tutions (Hirsch and Lounsbury, 1997).
builds upon Selznick’s conception of the Recently, authors have been calling attention
institutional leader by defining the role of the to a middle ground of institutionalized
CEO as managing internal and external action; institutional work (Lawrence and
expectations. In a replication of work by Suddaby, 2006). By institutional work, the
Sune Carlson (Carlson, 1951), Tengblad concern is on how institutions maintain their
observed 8 CEOs for a total of 159 days. He status and legitimacy in the face of their own
directly followed CEOs around for 26 days institutionalized environment. We argue that
(more than 300 hours) and had the CEOs the institutional leader’s role in maintaining
conduct self-recordings of themselves for the legitimacy of their institutions warrants
133 days. Tengblad focused his study on renewed attention.
understanding how CEOs handled financial
expectations. One of his key findings was the
increasing use of organizational culture as a
management and communication tool. SO WHAT DO INSTITUTIONAL
‘Messages about the desired state of affairs LEADERS DO?
(formulate, for instance, as ‘ten command-
ments,’ ‘cornerstones,’ ‘business mission’ or We argue that institutional leaders do three
‘corporate vision’) were transmitted through things to maintain the legitimacy and sur-
booklets and brochures in most companies. vival of their institution. The first is that they
During the observations the CEOs made manage the internal consistency of the organ-
numerous efforts to spread these messages’ ization. This extends Selznick’s concepts of
(Tengblad, 2004: 592). Tengblad argued that leaders maintaining internal commitment to
the CEOs in his study often resorted to using the organizational values and mission. The
the mission of the organization as a way of second is that institutional leaders develop
communicating the financial expectations. external supporting mechanisms that lead to
The CEOs did not just want to paint a ‘rosy increasing legitimacy of their organization
picture’ but wanted to demonstrate that they (how organizations become institutions).
were doing all they could to improve their The third activity that institutional leaders
financial outlook. Internally, Tengblad found engage in is actions to overcome external
that the CEOs used a variety of assessments enemies.
INSTITUTIONAL LEADERSHIP: PAST, PRESENT, AND FUTURE 725

on an important ceremonial tradition, the


Internal consistency
annual presentation of the Thayer Award
It is clear that institutional leaders play an (James, 1985: 678). ‘Duty, Honor, Country’ –
active role in developing the vision and mis- the cadet motto (Thomason, 1971: 43) – pow-
sion of the organization. However, while erfully defines historical identity and guides
some scholars view the vision setting process behavior for the cadets of the U.S. Military
as a strategic or organizational function Academy and for graduates of the USMA for
(Boal and Schultz, 2007; Nutt and Backoff, the rest of their lives (Boal and Schultz, 2007;
1997), from an institutional perspective, Ellis and Moore, 1974):
vision setting is also inherently political.
Duty, honor, country: Those three hallowed words
Organizational visions give rise to stories, reverently dictate what you want to be, what you
myths, and ceremonies (Meyer and Rowan, can be, what you will be. They are your rallying
1977); they enable the organization to point to build courage when courage seems to fail,
remember the ‘good old days’ or to reinforce to regain faith when there seems to be little cause
some key values of the organization (Bolman for faith, to create hope when hope becomes
forlorn .... The code which those words perpetuate
and Deal, 2003). Selznick describes one task embraces the highest moral law .... Its requirements
of institutional leadership that helps in the are for the things that are right and its restraints are
institutionalization process as ‘the elabora- from the things that are wrong .... The long, gray
tion of socially integrating myths’ (1957: line has never failed us. Were you to do so, a mil-
151). These myths are used to help ‘infuse lion ghosts in olive drab, in brown khaki, in blue
and gray, would rise from their white crosses, thun-
day-to-day behavior with long-run meaning dering those magic words: Duty, honor, country.
and purpose’ (1957: 151). (Duffy and Carpenter (1997: 197–200)
Gregory Berry (2001) notes, ‘Stories are a
fundamental way through which we under- This speech is an example of institutional
stand the world .... By understanding the sto- leadership in two ways. The first is by notic-
ries of organizations, we can claim partial ing what was not said. MacArthur’s speech
understanding of the reasons behind visible was more about character, mission, values of
behavior’ (2001: 59). As such the exchange the organization (hence its institutional char-
of stories, rather than merely routines, allows acter) than it was about tactics. Second, this
participants to develop a new ‘collective speech has been ‘retold’ countless times,
story’ through which they can become a reinforcing the military’s commitment to
social learning system. Stories are thus an these values. For example, each year New
important part of establishing internal con- Cadets at the USMA are issued a personal
sistency. Balancing the past, present, and copy of Bugle Notes (Thomason, 1971). One
future through storytelling is an essential of the coauthors’ personal copy, which he
skill for institutional leaders who hope to received on his first day at the USMA, con-
promote it. It is in the creating, telling, and tains this dedication:
retelling of key stories by institutional lead-
To the men who join the corps in 1971, 169 years
ers that the past, the present, and the future of
after its beginning, this book is dedicated. Bugle
the organization are connected. Notes is the story of the Long Gray Line. Within these
Creating and seizing upon ceremonies are pages can be found the reasons for the greatness
also in important part of maintaining internal and esprit of those who have graduated from West
consistency (Bolman and Deal, 2003). Point. Herein lie the relationships of the corps to the
United States, the Army, and itself. These are the tra-
A great example of this is a speech given by
ditions held sacred by every West Pointer; they are
Douglas McArthur. General Douglas your heritage. Cherish them, and pass them on to
MacArthur’s farewell address to the Corps of those who will follow after you. (1971: 1)
Cadets at West Point, May 12, 1962, illus-
trates how institutional leaders symbolically In the heart of this copy of Bugle Notes
shape behaviors of individuals by capitalizing (Thomason, 1971: 108–118) is printed the
726 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

complete text of MacArthur’s speech, a and eventual return or arrival in victory.


deliberate effort to infuse with value the Shamir and his colleagues (2005), in their
army of the future by connecting it to the analysis of the narrative accounts, found that
army of the past. the theme of struggle was common among
We suggest that institutional leaders take leaders. Through battles and ordeals, leaders
part in building an autobiographical pattern saw themselves transformed, thereby attain-
of historical accounts of their organization to ing the power to assume the task of leader-
produce a coherent picture of an organiza- ship. One of the insights that Bluck and
tion’s identity, their own roles within their Habermas (2000) provide is that one source
organization, and the realities of organiza- of an individual’s motivation is the sense of
tional life, while also preparing the organiza- self that the life story provides. The themes
tion to effectively respond to future and order that structure life events in the cre-
environmental changes. There are a number ation of the life story schema set the rationale
of possible ways in which institutional for behavior across time, and guide future
leaders might organize events into a coherent goals and actions by their linkage with that
pattern producing an overarching institu- life story model.
tional narrative. In their work on the Beyond being an expression of their own
individual-level life story construct, Bluck identity, institutional leaders use their life
and Habermas (2000) suggest thematic stories in an effort to influence their follow-
coherence as an important part of the indi- ers, by framing expectations and impres-
vidual and institutional story creation sions, serving as a role model, showing the
process. legitimacy of their leadership role, and shap-
Thematic coherence is useful in compre- ing collective expectations and meanings
hending periods of organizational transition, (Shamir et al., 2005). By extension, a shared
such as Andrew Grove’s concept of strategic organizational life story provides the inspira-
inflection points (1996, 1997). ‘Strategic tion for collective behavior among members
inflection points are caused by fundamental by connecting it with the past through the
industry dynamics, technologies, and strate- organization’s history. In establishing the
gies that create new opportunities for institu- rationale behind the organization’s life story,
tional leaders to develop new visions, create the schema generates an organizational iden-
new strategies, and move their organizations tity that insures continuity between past and
in new directions as they traverse through future goals and actions. Looking at the
turbulence and uncertainty’ (Boal and development of an effective leader vision,
Hooijberg, 2000: 520). Strategic inflection Strange and Mumford (2005) found that
points may be virtually impossible to detect a vision emerged in a process where leaders
priori, but by maintaining thematic coher- reflected on the fortunes of past goals and
ence, institutional leaders impose their own behaviors in deriving mental models for the
sense on successes and failures in the face of future. The vision formation process causes
extreme uncertainty. leaders to use a descriptive mental model of
One theme that is frequently used by insti- the organization – one that articulates the
tutional leaders to establish meaning for their themes and relationships between actions
followers is the concept of the hero’s journey. and outcomes – and by assessing that model
Coined by Joseph Campbell in his book, The in light of organization members’ experience,
Hero with a Thousand Faces (1972), he to then devise a prescriptive model for situa-
argued that all myths, regardless of the cul- tions yet to be encountered. Storytelling and
ture that produced them, shared the same the coherence demanded by the structure of
basic narrative features and structure. Central the life story schema combine in the ongoing
to his view of myth is the figure of the hero, vision formation process occurring within
his or her journey or struggle in adventure, organizations.
INSTITUTIONAL LEADERSHIP: PAST, PRESENT, AND FUTURE 727

The enduring values, expectations, and External supporting mechanisms


responsibilities that maintaining coherence Another task that institutional leaders perform
produces for the organization – and which are is to develop external supporting mechanisms
manifested in its vision – show the opportunity in order to maintain survival and obtain legiti-
that institutional leadership has in defining an macy for the organization. Organizational
organization’s approach to future circum- survival requires maintaining a balance
stances. Although all individual members are between stability and flexibility (Brown and
‘coauthors’ of an organization’s life story Eisenhardt, 1998). Vision setting and story-
(Czarniawska, 1997: 14), powerful individu- telling are excellent mechanisms to maintain
als, such as institutional leaders, can produce internal consistency and produce stability in
narratives for which the rest of the organization an organization. Without stability a firm
is more of a passive audience. Control over would not be able to accumulate knowledge,
storytelling and the way members interpret an and would be in a constant state of flux, never
organization’s path over time allows control being able to move any distance from its
over the vision formation process, and should original founding because the organization
significantly influence the character and effec- would have no basis to evaluate every new fad.
tiveness of organizational mission. Although Institutional leaders overcome this inertia
many individuals may possess experience rel- problem by serving as cognitive network
evant to the development and evaluation of brokers (Burt, 1992). By interaction with a
past mental models of the organization, insti- wide range of networks, inside and outside the
tutional leaders have a unique position from boundaries of the firm, individuals are encour-
which to influence this critical feedback mech- aged to bring new ideas/schema to old prob-
anism in the vision-formation process. The lems as well as discover new problems to
background and past experiences of the which known or knowable shared schema can
leader is influential in developing descriptive be applied (Kraatz and Moore, 2002).
mental models and the leader’s experience One of the ways that institutional leaders
with those models as they confront the ensure their survival is to maintain their legit-
demands of current organizational situations imacy. In Suchman’s (1995: 574) definition,
influences their current mental models. legitimacy is the ‘generalized perception that
An institutional leader’s own life story, the actions of an entity are desirable, proper,
thus, enters into the vision formation process or appropriate within some socially con-
along with the life story of the organization structed system of norms, values, beliefs
itself and its members. The requirement for and definitions.’ Institutional theory helps
coherence in both organizational and leader us to understand that as companies are
life stories means that an institutional leader embedded in the economic and institutional
imparts much of their own meaning and environment, we can infer the cultural mean-
sense-making onto the organization; actions ings, ideals and norms that have been
and events are interpreted through the lenses socially accepted in a society. These norms
of thematic and causal coherence in the con- can be seen as flexible guidelines that com-
text of the histories of both the organization panies must maintain in order to achieve con-
and the institutional leader. When Jack Welch gruence with society and in the legal
was the head of General Electric he taught environment.
a course on Leadership and Values seven Organizations and their associated prac-
times a year to high-potential middle man- tices are built upon three types of legitimacy
agers. In addition, courses were taught by the (Scott, 2001). A new practice is normatively
vice-chairman and the CFO. In fact, corpo- legitimate when it is consistent with
rate leaders taught 60 percent of the senior- wider societal values. Regulatory legitimacy
level courses, with Welch often standing in is conveyed when existing rules and laws
front of the group (Greiner, 2002). support a new practice. A new practice is
728 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

culturally/cognitively legitimate when it is component of institutional leadership at the


connected to wider belief systems inside of individual level, specifically, the strong
the institutional environment. When an adherence to a set of principles that drive the
organization is endorsed and supported by a actions of the individual. These pieces
segment of society large enough to ensure its (among others) serve to identify and
effectiveness and survival it can be consid- construct the external version of an institu-
ered to be legitimate (Pfeffer and Salancik, tional leader – an individual who utilizes
1978), and as such, the organization only institutional supporting mechanisms, exist-
needs to be supported by a segment of a pop- ing governance mechanisms and cognitive
ulation in order to remain legitimate in the frameworks to alter power arrangements
presence of attacks from external sources. As through explicit institutional strategies.
organizations utilize socially acceptable pro- In a recently published dissertation,
cedures to conduct potentially controversial Patterson (2007) extends the idea of institu-
activities, the organization can manage the tional leader as evangelists in her examina-
impression that it is rational and legitimate tion of D.D. Palmer and his efforts to create
(Scott, 1987). the field of chiropractic medicine. She exam-
Selznick himself recognized the relation- ined how Palmer created Palmer Chiropractic
ship between institutional leaders and the College to gain legitimacy for chiropractic
legitimacy of the institution they are attempt- medicine. Her work shows the link between
ing to lead. To understand the nature of insti- the creation of chiropractic colleges and the
tutional leadership, we must have some growing support and cognitive legitimacy of
notion of the meaning and significance of the chiropractic medicine.
term ‘institution’ itself’ (1987: 4). This leads Drawing from the work in institutional
to the discussion of the differences between theory, we argue that institutional leaders per-
institutions and organizations. Organizations form two tasks to gain external legitimacy for
are ‘a rational instrument engineered to do a their institution. First, institutional leaders
job’ (1987: 5). An institution is ‘a natural develop supporting mechanisms (Washington
product of social needs and pressures – a and Ventresca, 2004) that help to maintain
responsive, adaptive organism’ (1987: 5). their existence and sustain the acceptance and
The pressures of institutions come from two use of the practice. These supporting mecha-
sources: external, or the wider environment, nisms commonly take the form of state or
and internal, or the inner workings of the normative support for particular practices.
organizations. Using examples of the mili- Drawing from Scott’s three pillars of institu-
tary and the Catholic Church, Selznick tionalism, these practices could be the devel-
describes how these pressures produce opment of an association, interest group, or
administrative ideologies useful as commu- lobbying group to impact the normative or
nication and self-defense techniques, the cre- regulative aspects of the environment
ation and the protection of elites, and the The second process recalls the major con-
emergence of contending interest-groups. tribution of Berger and Luckman (1967) in
Selznick argues that the diversity of forces that institutional leaders strive for wide-
has a unifying effect in that they define the spread social acceptance of their organiza-
‘commitments of the organization and give it tion. Stigmatized practices are very difficult
a distinctive identity’ (1957: 16). to institutionalize because they are generally
Rao (2002) also identifies strong individu- contested. This aspect provides boundaries to
als as ‘evangelists’ for a practice, alluding to tease apart how an organization might have
the significant of a singular powerful actor established supporting mechanisms yet never
who drives the legitimation of a practice gain widespread social acceptance (prostitu-
much like a religion or ideology. Rao’s termi- tion, drug use, and same-sex marriage would
nology most aptly signifies an important be examples of such institutions).
INSTITUTIONAL LEADERSHIP: PAST, PRESENT, AND FUTURE 729

An example of this type of institutional (other organizations have stopped perform-


work would be the efforts of Captain Palmer ing the practice). Patterson (2007) identified
E. Pierce. As the first president of the the attacks on chiropractic medicine as
National Collegiate Athletic Association coming from traditional medicine in the form
(NCAA), he worked to eliminate the vio- of basic science laws. These laws were put in
lence in college football which was causing place as a form of regulation against anyone
numerous deaths (Falla, 1981). The violence practicing medicine; all medical practitioners
in football was so bad that many schools regardless of specialty had to pass a set of
abandoned the sport or switched to the less science requirements that the traditional
violent sport of rugby (Smith, 1988). His medicine community knew chiropractors
efforts not only helped to reduce the vio- could not pass.
lence, but also helped to grow the member- Another attack comes from fragmentation
ship of the NCAA. Founded in 1906 with of the population that originally institutional-
only 38 member schools, by 1942 the NCAA ized the practice (Zucker, 1987). Institutions
had 314 schools which included ‘nearly are only legitimate for a given population or
every college or university of importance in segment of society. If the population splits,
the country’ (Stagg, 1946: 81). either politically as organizations within the
population fight over jurisdiction, or socially,
Overcome external enemies the supporting populations create niche popu-
The final task of institutional leadership is lations, then support for that practice may
overcoming external enemies. Institutions wane. We also argue, extending the work of
don’t exist in a vacuum. Friedland and Alford Zucker (1987) and Greve (1995), that an
(1991) suggest that organizational fields oper- organizational practice comes under attack as
ate under diverse belief systems that differ other actors choose to invest in a competing
fundamentally in their content, as well as the practice. Here we contend that there is com-
nature of central assumptions and ordering petition among practices to become institu-
principles that they refer to as institutional tionalized. Thus, if a set of actors decide to
logics. However, Washington, Forman, institutionalize a second practice, this might
Suddaby, and Ventresca (2005) argue that in fact de-institutionalize the first practice.
there could be multiple institutions competing In short, we argue that institutional leaders
for control over the organizational field. These are involved in their own institutions’ work
competing institutions have different sources of maintaining survival. The activities of the
of interest and identities. Much like the insti- institutional leaders range from vision set-
tutional leaders of the NCAA defending their ting, storytelling, network brokering to
institutions against the NAIA, AAU, and defending the practices of their institution.
AIAW (Washington, 2004; Washington, Future research could empirically test these
Forman, Suddaby, and Ventresca, 2005) we ideas by examining the practices of institu-
argue that institutional leaders also have to tional leaders. In the next section we return to
defend against external enemies. one problem that plagued us as we conducted
Where will the attack come from? First, our literature review of institutional leader-
we argue that leaders have to defend against ship; why is there a lack of institutional lead-
the death of their existing practice. Oliver ership ideas in the leadership literature?
(1992: 581) argues that ‘threats to the persist-
ence of an institutionalized practice may be
explained by a decline in .... the functional Reconciling leadership research
necessity of the practice.’ These threats can
with leadership in administration
come from political pressures (changes in
laws, or regulations) technical pressures A surprising result of our review of
(innovative practices) or social practices how Selznick’s work has been cited in
730 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

management research was the relative Design (2004) has no chapter (of thirteen)
absence of Selznick’s work in the traditional primarily on leadership, considers leadership
leadership literature. Of more than 750 cita- primarily as a process, and does not mention
tions to Selznick’s work, fewer than 10 were Selznick in its index. Bolman and Deal’s
from Leadership Quarterly – the preeminent (2003) somewhat less traditional Reframing
journal focused on leadership. This is sur- Organizations has one chapter (of twenty-
prising to us given that all of the articles in one) dealing primarily with leadership, takes
The Leadership Quarterly are about leader- a less traditional integrative perspective on
ship. Yet we found only 10 articles out of leadership, and mentions Selznick only in
more than 250 articles published since the conjunction with a discussion of the symbolic
founding of The Leadership Quarterly that frame of organizational culture.
even cited Selznick and usually he was not Leadership studies have enjoyed a
central to their arguments. renaissance in the past two decades, thanks
Selznick’s work is similarly absent in primarily to the shift to the transforma-
other leadership texts. Stogdill’s classic tional/charismatic perspectives (Hunt, 1999).
Handbook of Leadership (1974: 28) contains Yet a partial result of this renaissance has
only one mention of Selznick, a single sen- been what Hunt and Dodge (2000) called
tence listing Selznick among those who treat ‘leadership déjá vu all over again.’ That is,
address leadership by classifying its func- neglect of historical antecedents in the lead-
tions. Yukl’s (2002) advanced leadership ership literature has caused an overemphasis
textbook, Leadership in Organizations, con- on concepts that exploit the spirit of the
tains no mention of Selznick (1957). Not times. Less charitably, this neglect generates
only is there a relative lack of Selznick in the leadership fads. Similarly, Bedeian and Hunt
academic literature, but there is also a lack of (2006), in a recent effort to tease out essential
Selznick in leadership textbooks. Using an differences between leadership and manage-
admitted convenience sample of two popular ment, went even further, questioning whether
organizational behavior textbooks, we found the long-standing confusion between leader-
the following: Robbins and Judge’s (2007) ship and management in both popular and
Organizational Behavior contains two chap- academic understandings of leadership has
ters (of nineteen) on leadership and classifies led to the need for a complete reconceptual-
both chapters at the group level of analysis. ization of leadership. Selznick’s (1957) work
Robbins and Judge contains no mention of may thus be positioned for another ‘shot’ at
Leadership in Administration. Similarly, a influencing the field of leadership.
‘core concepts’ organizational behavior text- Lowe and Gardner (2000), in their sum-
book, Schermerhorn, Hunt, and Osborn’s mary and evaluation of the first ten years of
(2004) Core Concepts of Organizational The Leadership Quarterly, categorized the
Behavior contains one chapter (of nineteen) articles from that journal’s first decade in to
on leadership, considers leadership as an the following categories: trait theories,
organizational process, and does not mention behavioral theories, contingency theories,
Selznick in its index. multiple-level approaches, neo-charismatic
Perhaps the problem is the traditional aca- approaches, leadership and information pro-
demic classification of leadership as an orga- cessing, other prominent approaches (e.g.,
nizational behavior topic. Considering the romance of leadership, top management
perspective in Selznick (1957), maybe we teams), and new directions (e.g., political
would be better off to consult the treatment of leadership, strategic leadership). Their table
leadership in organization theory textbooks. (2000: 477–479) of leadership paradigms
However, we found similar results in a simi- and theories identified only one article on
lar sample of popular organization theory institutional theory and classified it among
textbooks. Daft’s Organization Theory and ‘other prominent approaches.’
INSTITUTIONAL LEADERSHIP: PAST, PRESENT, AND FUTURE 731

In the early days of The Leadership argued that institutional leaders operated
Quarterly, however, there was a strong within an embedded agency perspective.
‘taste’ for institutional leadership. While actions are not totally determined by
Birnbaum’s (1990) article, published in the the institutional constraints of the organiza-
first volume of The Leadership Quarterly, tion, these missions and values of the institu-
was an excellent analysis of how college and tion do reduce the degrees of freedom of the
university presidents assessed their own leader. An organizational leader however, is
effectiveness. The question goes to the heart less constrained. In much research, it is the
of our argument that institutional leaders risk-taking part of being a leader – stepping
create external supporting mechanisms and outside of the organizational boundaries –
overcome external enemies. He found that that is often the difference between managers
the presidents in his sample used institutional and leaders (Hacker and Washington, 2007).
performance and constituent (key stakehold- The view of constrained agency is connected
ers) satisfaction. For our purposes, this arti- to the tactics of influence and negotiation for
cle represents the type of work that we think the institutional leader. Keeping the institu-
there should be more of. More work on insti- tion on track requires the institutional leader
tutional leaders needs to examine the to develop political skills. This is in sharp
processes by which leaders lead organiza- contrast to the organizational leader that uses
tions, not examine the traits, behaviors, and either their position or their charisma to ‘get
characteristics of leaders. things done.’
We, along with others, argue that the lack One of the sharpest distinctions between
of inclusion of Selznick’s work on institu- institutional leaders and organizational lead-
tional leadership is due to leadership’s focus ers is their use of a vision statement. For
on leadership inside of organizations an institutional leader, the vision is a chance
(Biggart and Hamilton, 1987; Boal and to embed the values and mission of the
Hooijberg, 2000; Dubin, 1979; Hunt, 1999). organization into the everyday reality. For an
‘Theories of leadership have tended to focus organizational leader, the vision is a chance
on the characteristics of leaders, on the to look forward to future challenges and
behaviors leaders exhibit, or on the situa- developments.
tional factors that determine effective In this section we argue that both the leader-
approaches to leadership. Early research on ship literature and the institutional theory liter-
leadership attempted to identify the attributes ature can benefit from a return to Selznick’s
of great leaders, such as Napolean and ideas about institutional leadership. Most
Washington, that set them apart from “lesser” scholars would put Selznick in the ‘old insti-
persons (Biggart and Hamilton, 1987: tutional theory’ category. However, with the
430–431).’ The leadership literature classi- growing calls to incorporate more agency in
fies these types of studies as supervisory the- new-institutional studies (Hirsch and
ories of leadership. ‘Supervisory theories of Lounsbury, 1997) Selznick’s ideas might offer
leadership, (e.g., path-goal, contingency, a theoretical advance of the current institu-
Leadership Menber Exchange) focus on tional theory literature. The old literature on
tasks and person-oriented behavior of leaders institutional theory focused on concepts of
as they attempt to provide guidance, support, isomorphism, legitimacy and diffusion. While
and feedback to subordinates’ (Boal and these are three different ideas, they all share a
Hooijberg, 2000), while institutional leader- common trait in that you can examine issues of
ship is concerned with the leadership of isomorphism, legitimacy, and diffusion without
organizations. looking inside of the organization. All three
Table 30.1 summarizes our arguments ideas lend themselves wonderfully to the ‘now
about the relationship of institutional leader- legitimate’ use of event history analysis where
ship and organizational leadership. We have researchers develop variables that measure
732 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Table 30.1 Summary differences between institutional leadership and


organizational leadership
Differences between the Institutional leadership Organizational leadership
two concepts
Type of agency Muted, constrained Instrumental, rational
‘Here the emphasis is on the ‘Early research on leadership attempted
embodiment of values in an to identify the attributes of great
organizational structure through leaders, such as Napoleon and
the elaboration of commitments – Washington, that set them apart
ways of acting and responding from “lesser” persons’ (Biggart and
that can be changed, if at all, Hamilton, 1987: 430–431)
only at the risk of severe internal
crises’ (Selznick, 1957: 40)
Power Influence, negotiation Hierarchical, charismatic
‘Because these areas exist, creative ‘Supervisory theories of leadership ... focus
men are needed ... these men are on tasks and person-oriented behaviour
called leaders; their profession is of leaders as they attempt to provide
politics’ (Selznick, 1957: 61) guidance ... to subordinates’ (Boal and
Hooijberg, 2000)
The role of vision Reconnect the organization to the Move the organizational forward
original values to new goals and challenges
‘The promotion and protection of
values’ (Selznick, 1957: 28)

institutional concepts and then examine how environment, and they are involved in the
these variables impact the adoption of a partic- politics of organizational decisions and
ular factor that represents legitimacy, diffusion, would represent a key part of the puzzle to
or isomorphism. While there are wonderful understanding institutional phenomena. We
studies that use this approach to studying insti- argue that more work similar to that by
tutionalism, these studies are losing their Kraatz and Moore (2002) should be done.
prominence in institutional analysis. This type of work is also being called for in
Recently, there has been work focusing on the leadership literature.
institutional strategy (Lawrence, 1999), insti-
tutional entrepreneurship (DiMaggio, 1988;
Suddaby and Greenwood, 2005; etc.) and
institutional work (Lawrence and Suddaby, CONCLUSION
2006). These concepts all share an interest
in the more micro-processes of institutionali- While we have focused on institutional lead-
zation. How do institutions compete for pri- ership, we do not think all leaders are institu-
macy in a new field? How do new practices tional leaders. Thus, we have two boundary
become institutionalized? How are institu- conditions of institutional leadership.
tions created, maintained and disrupted? First, not all organizations are institutions.
These are the new questions in institutional In addition to understanding institutional
theory. Answers to these questions can be leadership, Selznick also informs of as to
found by returning to the study of leaders. how we should study institutions.
The argument is not that leaders are fully
The study of institution is in some ways compara-
rational (or even boundedly rational) and ble to the clinical study of personality. It requires a
make strategic decisions. The argument is genetic and developmental approach, an emphasis
that leaders do things, they make sense of the on historical origins and growth stages ... Our
INSTITUTIONAL LEADERSHIP: PAST, PRESENT, AND FUTURE 733

problem is to discover the characteristic ways REFERENCES


in which types of institutions respond to types of
circumstances. The common-sense distinctions
among enterprises according to whether they per- Amason, A.C., & Sapienza, H.J. 1997. The
form economic, political, religious, or military func- effects of top management team size and
tions. (1957: 141–142) interaction norms on cognitive and affective
conflict. Journal of Management, 23 (4):
We think that institutional and organizational 495–516
theorists need to be more precise in describ- Bedeian, A.G., & Hunt, J.G. 2006. Academic
ing the collective they are studying; what is it amnesia and vestigial assumptions of our
forefathers. The Leadership Quarterly, 17:
about a particular collective that leads one to
190–205.
call it an institution as opposed to an organi- Berger, P.L. & Luckman, T. 1967. The Social
zation, group, practice, or association. Construction of Reality. New York: Doubleday.
Second, not all leaders of institutions are Berry, G.R. 2001. Telling stories: Making sense
institutional leaders. Institutional leaders’ of the environmental behavior of chemical
focus is on maintaining homeostasis. As firms. Journal of Management Inquiry, 10:
opposed to institutional leaders, leaders of 58–73.
institutions (as well as leaders of organiza- Biggart, N.W. & Hamilton, G.G. 1987. An
tions, associations, and practices) are charac- institutional theory of leadership. The
terized as administrators or managers, and Journal of Applied Behavioral Science, 23 (4):
their concern is with the technical core of the 429–441.
Birnbaum, R. 1990. How’m I doing? How col-
organization and its functioning.
lege presidents assess their effectiveness.
We have argued that to infuse the organi- Leadership Quarterly, 1 (1): 25–39.
zation with value, institutional leaders Bluck, S., & Habermas, T. (2000). The life story
must do three things. First, they must schema. Motivation and Emotion, 24:
management internal consistency. We sug- 121–147.
gest they do this through the telling of Boal, K.B., & Schultz, P. 2007. Storytelling,
stories and the management of thematic time, and evolution: The role of strategic
coherence. Second, we argue that institu- leadership in complex adaptive systems. The
tional leaders develop external supporting Leadership Quarterly 18: 411–428.
mechanisms that lead to increasing legiti- Boal, Kimberly B., & Hooijberg, Robert J.
macy of their organizations. They do this by Strategic leadership research: Moving
on: Yearly review of leadership:
serving as cognitive network brokers
A Special issue of The Leadership Quarterly,
enabling a wide range of interaction inside 11: 515–550.
and outside the organization. Third, institu- Bolman, L.G., & Deal, T.E. 2003. Reframing
tional leaders must overcome external Organizations: Artistry, Choice, and Leadership.
enemies. To do so, institutional leaders 3rd edn. San Francisco: Jossey-Bass.
must defend against the death of existing Brown, S., & Eisenhardt, K. 1998. Competing
practices, and prevent fragmentation of the on the Edge: Strategy as Structured Chaos.
population that originally institutionalized Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Press.
the practice. Burt, R. 1992. Structural Holes: The Social
Finally, we note that, despite the enormous Structure of Competition. Cambridge, MA:
intellectual contributions to understanding Harvard University Press.
Campbell, J. 1972. The Hero with a Thousand
organizations, institutions, and leadership,
Faces. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University
Selznick has gone relatively unnoticed by Press and the Bollingen Foundation.
those who study leadership. We hope that Carlson, S. 1951. Executive Behaviour.
as researchers start to focus on the leadership Stockholm: Strombergs.
of organizations, rather than leadership in Czarniawska, B. 1997. Narrating the
organizations, this will lead future leadership Organization: Dramas of Institutional
scholars to a rediscovery of his insights. Identity. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
734 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Daft, R.L. 2004. Organization Theory and Hirsch, P. & Lounsbury, M. 1997 Ending
Design. 8th edn. Mason, OH: Thomson the family quarrel: toward a reconciliation
South-Western. of ‘old’ and ‘new’ institutionalisms.
DiMaggio, P.J. 1988. Interest and agency in American Behavioral Scientist, 40: 406–18.
institutional theory, in L.G. Zucker (ed.), Hunt, J.G. 1999. Transformational/charismatic
Institutional Patterns and Organizations: leadership’s transformation of the field: An
Culture and Environment. Cambridge, MA: historical essay. The Leadership Quarterly,
Ballinger, pp. 3–22. 10: 129–144.
DiMaggio, P.J., & Powell, W.W. 1983. The iron Hunt, J.G., & Dodge, G.E. 2000. Leadership
cage revisited: Institutional isomorphism and déjá vu all over again. The Leadership
collective rationality in organizational fields, in Quarterly, 11: 435–458.
W.W. Powell and P.J. DiMaggio (eds.), The new James, D.C. 1985). The Years of Macarthur.
institutionalism in organizational analysis: 63- Vol. III Triumph and Disaster, 1945–1964.
82. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press. Boston, MA: Houghton Mifflin.
Dubin, R. 1979. Metaphors of leadership: An Kraatz, M.S. & Moore, J.H. 2002. Executive
overview, in J.G. Hunt & L.L. Larson (eds.), migration and institutional change.
Crosscurrents in Leadership, pp. 225–238. Academy of Management Journal, 45 (1):
Carbondale, IL: Southern Illinois University 120–143.
Press. Lawrence, T.B. 1999 Institutional strategy.
Duffy, B.K., & Carpenter, R.H. 1997. Douglas Journal of Management, 25: 161–87.
Macarthur: Warrior as Wordsmith. Westport, Lawrence, T.B. & R. Suddaby. 2006. Institutions
CT: Greenwood Press. and Institutional Work, pgs 215–254, in
Ellis, J., & Moore, R. 1974. School for Soldiers: S. Clegg, C. Hardy, W. Nord & T.B. Lawrence
West Point and the Profession of Arms. New (eds.), The Handbook of Organization
York: Oxford University Press. Studies. London: Sage.
Falla, J. 1981. NCAA: The voice of college Leblebici, H., Salancik, G.R., Copay, A., & King,
sports. Mission, KS: National Collegiate T. 1991. Institutional change and the trans-
Athletic Association. formation of the interorganizational fields:
Friedland, R., & Alford, R.R. 1991. Bringing An organizational history of the U.S. radio
society back in: Symbols, practices, and insti- broadcasting industry. Administrative
tutional contradictions, in W.W. Powell and Science Quarterly, 36: 333–363.
P.J. DiMaggio (eds.), The New Institutionalism Lowe, K.B., & Gardner, W.L. 2000. Ten years of
in Organizational Analysis, pp. 232–263. the leadership quarterly: Contributions and
Chicago: University of Chicago. challenges for the future. The Leadership
Greiner, L.E. 2002. Steve Kerr and his years Quarterly, 11: 459–514.
with Jack Welch at GE. Journal of Meyer, J.W. & Rowan, B. 1977. Institutionalized
Management Inquiry, 11: 343–350. organizations: Formal structure as myth and
Greve, H. 1995. Jumping ship: The diffusion ceremony. American Journal of Sociology,
of strategy abandonment. Administrative 83: 340–363.
Science Quarterly, 40: 444–473. Nutt, P.C. & Backoff, R.W. 1997 Crafting a
Grove, A.S. 1996. Only the Paranoid Survive. Vision. Journal of Management Inquiry, 6(4):
New York: Currency Doubleday. 308–328.
Grove, A.S. 1997. Navigating strategic inflec- Oliver, C. 1992. The antecedent of de-institu-
tion points. Business Strategy Review, tionalization. Organization Studies, 13:
8(3): 11–18. 563–588.
Hacker, S., & Washington, M. 2007. Pack Patterson, K. 2007. Creation and Evolution: The
Leadership: Lessons from the Wild Dogs of Processes and Strategies of Institutional
Africa. Milwaukee, WI: Quality Press. Entrepreneurs in Alternative Medicine,
Hirsch, P. 1986. From ambushes to golden 1896–2005. Ph.D. Dissertation in
parachutes: Corporate takeovers as an Management at Texas Tech University.
instance of cultural framing and institutional Pfeffer, J., & Salancik, G. 1978. The External
integration. American Journal of Sociology, Control of Organizations: A Resources Depend-
91: 800–837. ence Perspective. New York: Harper & Row.
INSTITUTIONAL LEADERSHIP: PAST, PRESENT, AND FUTURE 735

Rao, H. 2002. Tests Tell: Constitutive legiti- Strange, J.M., & Mumford, M.D. 2005. The ori-
macy and consumer acceptance of the auto- gins of vision: Effects of reflection, models,
mobile: 1895–1912. New Institutionalism and analysis. The Leadership Quarterly, 16:
in Strategic Management Advances in 121–148,
Strategic Management: A Research Annual, Suchman, M.C. 1995. Managing legitimacy:
19: 307–335. Strategic and institutional approaches.
Robbins, S.P., & Judge, T.A. 2007. Academy of Management Review, 20(3):
Organizational Behavior, 12th edn. Upper 571–610.
Saddle River, NJ: Person Prentice-Hall. Suddaby, R., & Greenwood, R. 2005. ‘Rhetorical
Scott, W.R. 1987. Organizations: Rational, strategies of legitimacy,’ Administrative
Natural and Open Systems. Englewood Science Quarterly, 50: 35–67.
Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall. Tengblad, S. 2004. Expectations of Alignment:
Scott, W.R. 2001 Institutions and Organizations, Examining the link between financial mar-
2nd edn. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage. kets and managerial work. Organization
Selznick, P. 1949. TVA and The Grass Roots. Studies, 25 (4): 583–606
Berkeley: University of California Press. Thomason, T. 1971. Bugle Notes, 63rd edn.
Selznick, P. 1952. The Organizational Weapon. West Point, NY: United States Military
New York: McGraw-Hill. Academy.
Selznick, P. 1957. Leadership in Administration: Washington, M. 2004. Field approaches to insti-
A Sociological Interpretation. New York: tutional change: The evolution of the National
Harper & Row. Collegiate Athletic Association 1906–1995.
Schermerhorn, J.R., Hunt, J.G., & Osborn, R.N. Organization Studies, 25(3): 1–25.
2004. Core Concepts of Organizational Washington, M. & Ventresca, M. J. 2004. How
Behavior. New York: Wiley. organization change: The role of institutional
Shamir, B., Dayan-Horesh, H., & Adler, D. 2005. support mechanisms in the incorporation
Leading by biography: Towards a life-story of higher education visibility strategies
approach to the study of leadership. 1874–1995. Organization Science, 15: 82–97.
Leadership, 1: 13–29. Washington, M., Forman, P.F., Suddaby, R. &
Smith, R.A. 1988. Sports and Freedom: The Ventresca, M.J. 2005. Strategies and strug-
Rise of Big-Time College Athletics. New gles over rules of the game: The governance
York: Oxford University Press. of U.S. intercollegiate athletics 1950–1982,
Stagg, P. 1946. The Development of the in K. Elsbach (ed.), Qualitative Organizational
National Collegiate Athletic Association in Research, 75–112. Greenwich, CT:
Relationship to Intercollegiate Athletics Information Age Publishing.
in the United States. Unpublished Ph.D. Yukl, G. 2002. Leadership in Organizations,
Dissertation, New York University. 5th edn. Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice-Hall.
Stogdill, R.M. 1974. Handbook of Leadership: Zucker, L.G. 1987. Institutional theories of
A Survey of Theory and Research. New York: organization. Annual Review of Sociology,
The Free Press. 13: 443–464.
SECTION V

Reflections
31
Is the New Institutionalism
a Theory?
Donald Palmer, Nicole Biggart and Brian Dick

INTRODUCTION new institutionalism focused their attention


on norms and mandates such as laws and reg-
The new institutionalism (NI) developed ulations, belief systems, cultural pressures
in the 1970s at a time when an increasing and social comparison processes (e.g., Meyer
number of scholars studying organizations and Rowan [1977]/1991; Powell and
began to embrace the notion that much of DiMaggio [1983]/1991). The new institution-
what happened inside organizations had little alism helped to explain why organizations
to do with the objective tasks in which organ- often looked alike, even if they were engaged
izations were engaged and much to do with in quite different activities in varied contexts,
the social relationships in which they were and why managers would adopt administra-
embedded. This focus on the larger social tive practices developed in dissimilar indus-
structure in which organizations are situated tries. It recognized that organizing is not only
was a huge intellectual leap over the manage- about reaching for technical efficiency in get-
rialist engineering approach to organizations ting the job done, but also about presenting
that accompanied the post WWII economy. one’s organization and management as
Dominated by industrial engineers, organiza- ‘informed,’ ‘up-to-date,’ and ‘compliant.’
tional analysts had difficulty conceptualizing In the 1980s W. Richard Scott wrote
social elements of organizing beyond the an assessment of the new institutionalism,
psychological traits of workers and the orga- an approach that was very much in ascen-
nizational structures that conditioned their dance at the time. In ‘The Adolescence of
interactions. While some organizations- Institutional Theory,’ Scott (1987) appraised
environments scholars, such as resource a theoretical teenager, albeit one with a
dependence theorists and population ecolo- distinguished ancestry, to assess the NI’s
gists, focused on the resource environment of contributions thus far and the potential
organizations (e.g., Pfeffer and Salancik for further development and intellectual
[1978]/2003; Hannan and Freeman 1977; gifts. In concluding his assessment, Scott
Aldrich and Pfeffer 1976), proponents of the (1987: 510) wrote that ‘[t]hroughout, I have
740 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

attempted to sound an optimistic note. conceptualizations are more relevant to


Institutional theory is at an early stage of practicing organization studies scholars than
development. Adolescents have their awk- are abstract normative models (cf. Cohen
wardness and their acne, but they also embody 1968). We use the conception of theory
energy and promise. They require encourage- building advanced by Edward Litchfield and
ment as well as criticism if they are to channel James D. Thompson, two influential figures in
their energies in productive directions and the emergence of the field of organization
achieve their promise.’ studies, as our in-use theory building bench-
Some twenty-five years later, institutional mark. We think that most organization
theory is still very much with us. No longer studies scholars have been guided by their
an adolescent, it is reaching adulthood (Scott implicit affinity for this framework. Further,
forthcoming) and has become part of the we think it represents the kind of theory
organization theory community alongside building that some contend holds the most
resource dependency, population ecology, promise. DiMaggio (1995) has recently
the resource-based view of strategy, and a identified three types of theory in use,
few other stalwart conceptualizations that covering law theories, narrative theories, and
help us to understand the dynamics of a enlightenment theories, each of which has
world organized into firms, NGOs, agencies, strengths and weaknesses. Covering law
and industries. Indeed, the new institutional- theories consist of generalizations that
ism is arguably now the dominant paradigm describe the world as we see and measure
in organization studies (Mizruchi and Fein it; that is, they explain what the world is
1999; Gmür 2003). But has its adolescent like. Narrative theories consist of accounts
promise been realized? Although Jennings that explain the way the world works;
and Greenwood (2003: 201) consider the that is, they explain how and why the world
new institutionalism to be ‘a mature theory,’ is like it is. Enlightenment theories are
they contend that it still ‘relies more on complex, defamiliarizing and rich in
richness and relevance than rigor.’ A more paradox aimed at clearing away conventio-
cynical appraisal might be that the new insti- nal notions to make room for artful and
tutionalism represents merely an umbrella exciting insights; that is, they are ‘surprise
for a diverse array of theory and research machines.’ DiMaggio contends that the best
seeking a legitimate pedigree. There are theory building approaches tend to be hybrids,
many ways to assess a theoretical program’s which draw on different types of theories
progress. In this essay we assess the extent to in combinations where the strengths of
which the new institutionalism has become one counterbalance the weaknesses of the
a ‘theory’ as opposed to a more loosely others. Litchfield and Thompson’s suggested
organized perspective or framework. We mode of theorizing represents a hybrid of
adopt this metric, because arguably the most the covering law and narrative approaches.
frequently stated goal of work in our field is We recognize, though, that the Litchfield
to develop theory about organizations rather and Thompson characterization of theory
than simply adding to our knowledge of is open to question. Thus, we conclude our
them. Indeed, in many journals, the absence chapter by examining conceptions of theory
of a theoretical contribution is grounds for a that have been offered in opposition to the
submitted manuscript’s rejection (cf. the dominant view: social mechanism, postmod-
notice to contributors for Administrative ernism, and critical realism. In each case,
Science Quarterly). we inquire into the extent to which the
We use a conception of theory building new institutionalism has come to resemble
‘in use’ by organizational studies scholars as a theory in that particular conception’s
our benchmark against which to evaluate sense and how these alternatives might
the new institutionalism. Concrete in-use enlighten the NI.
IS THE NEW INSTITUTIONALISM A THEORY? 741

LITCHFIELD AND THOMPSON’S Concepts


VISION OF ORGANIZATION THEORY The new institutionalism is characterized by
a growing number of concepts. These con-
The first issue of Administrative Science cepts can be grouped into three categories:
Quarterly contained essays by two of the institutional structures, attributes, and
journal’s founders, Edward Litchfield (1956) processes. We review what we believe are
and James Thompson (1956). In these several key new institutional concepts, with
essays, Litchfield and Thompson laid out a an eye to indicating the extent to which they
common vision of organization theory that are well elaborated and operationalized. We
contained four elements. Organization do not aspire to completeness. There are
theory, first, should be composed of abstract many more new institutional concepts than
concepts that can be operationalized and pos- those we consider in this section of the chap-
tulated relationships that can be empirically ter. Rather we aspire to representativeness,
evaluated. Second, it should be general, tran- with respect to the level of precision with
scending different types of organizations and which the concepts have been elaborated and
contexts. Third, organization theory should operationalized.
be comprehensive, pursuing multiple levels Structures The most fundamental NI struc-
of analysis, drawing on a wide array of the tural concept is the ‘institution,’ which corre-
social sciences, and apprehending the full sponds to a way of organizing human activity
range of behavior in and of organizations. that is stable, resilient, and hence relatively
Finally, it should be cumulative, growing in enduring because it is considered appropriate
explanatory power over time. by relevant actors, in particular powerful
ones. Institutions can have a sense of perma-
nence that makes it almost unimaginable that
they could ever be different or might at one
Concepts and relationships
time not have existed. The taken-for-granted
Litchfield and Thompson complained that nature of institutions is part of their power –
organization theory in their time was charac- they are often not called into question or
terized by a plethora of vague concepts that examined for their efficacy or appropriate-
were ambiguously related to one another and ness (Meyer and Rowan ([1977]/1991: 44–5;
that researchers often documented empirical Scott forthcoming). According to Scott
regularities without providing a theoretical (2001: 47–70), there are three broad classes
framework within which they could be inter- of institutional structures. Regulative struc-
preted. They contended that organization tures are generally formal and explicit,
theory should aspire to develop a coherent set legally sanctioned, and indicated by rules and
of abstract constructs that could be opera- laws, often enforced by the state. Normative
tionalized and postulated relationships that structures are based on the value or moral
could be empirically verified. An examina- expectations associated with roles and, in
tion of Thompson’s ([1967]/2006) classic the contemporary world, are generally
integration of contemporary organization associated with processes of professional
theory suggests that he at least also envi- accreditation and certification. Finally,
sioned organization theory to include not just cultural-cognitive structures are based on the
‘covering laws’ but causal explanations of shared understandings of actors, which are
such relationships. Almost forty years later, generally taken-for-granted and legitimated
Sutton and Staw (1995) presented a strik- by the larger cultural and institutional milieu
ingly similar conception of organization (e.g., what a ‘good’ person should do in a sit-
theory as a logical framework that explained uation, or what a ‘just’ solution is in a dis-
‘why variables or constructs come about or pute). Specific institutional structures, such
why they are connected’ (1995: 375). as ‘conceptions of control,’ ‘myths,’ ‘logics,’
742 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

and ‘recipes’ occupy an ambiguous relation- respect to their relations to other organiza-
ship with respect to these three categories, tions). Fields are also different from
seemingly spanning two or all three cate- ‘networks,’ which are composed of organiza-
gories. For example, a particular conception tions that are not necessarily subject to the
of justice can find expression in cultural same institutional constraints. Early propo-
forms and be codified in law. nents of the new institutionalism distin-
There is a considerable amount of research guished between two types of fields:
that measures the regulative dimension ‘technical’ and ‘institutional’ (Scott and
of institutional structures. For example, Meyer [1983]/1991). While in technical
research on the proliferation of the finance environments rewards are accrued by organ-
conception of control examined the spread of izations for ‘effective and efficient control
the multidivisional form (Fligstein 1990). of their production systems,’ institutional
There is also much work that taps the norma- environments require that organizations
tive dimension of institutional structures. For conform to rules and regulations ‘to receive
example, research on the evolution of the support and legitimacy’ ([1983]/1991: 123).
normative framework that underpins the However, as we note below, it is noteworthy
modern market for corporate control exam- of the new institutionalism’s expanding com-
ined changes in the language used in the prehensiveness that, later on, this distinction
business press to describe hostile takeovers was put into question.
and their principal players (Hirsch 1986). Many proponents of the NI consider the
There is even research that attempts to map field to be a unique and crucial concept of
both the regulative and normative dimen- this approach. DiMaggio has argued that ‘the
sions of institutional structures. For example, organization field has emerged as a critical
research on the proliferation of the share- unit bridging the organizational and the
holder model of governance in Germany societal levels in the study of social and com-
examined the use of language that privileged munity change’ (quoted in Scott 2001: 148).
stock holder interests in corporate annual Davis and Marquis (2005a) contend that it is
reports and tracked the adoption of the level of analysis most likely to give rise to
governance structures and accounting sys- improved understanding of modern organiza-
tems that reflect those interests (Fiss and tions. Thus it is ironic that fields are seldom
Zajac 2004). But work that explores the characterized precisely. To the best of our
cognitive expression of institutions is just knowledge, most NI studies do not go to
beginning. One interesting study in this vein great lengths to establish the boundaries of
examines the emergence of the cognitive the fields they study. More often than not,
construct ‘nanotechnology’ that accompa- fields are defined as coterminous with more
nied the emergence of the industry that we traditional aggregates such as industries
now know by this name (Grodal 2006; also (cf. Thornton and Ocasio 1999) or groups of
see George, Chattopadhyay, Sitkin, and organizations listed in standard annuals such
Barden 2006). as the Fortune 500 (Fligstein 1990).
Another fundamental NI structural con- Attributes The most fundamental NI attribute
cept is the ‘field,’ which corresponds to the is ‘legitimacy,’ which corresponds to the
domain within which a particular institution extent to which a structure or practice resem-
operates. It consists of a group of organiza- bles an institution. The more legitimate a
tions that interact with one another and that structure or practice is considered by actors
are subject to the same regulative, normative, in general and powerful actors more specifi-
and cognitive institutional constraints. Fields cally, the more reasonably the structure or
differ from ‘populations’ and ‘industries,’ practice can be called an institution. The
which are composed of organizations that are extent to which structures and or practices
similar to each other (importantly, with are considered legitimate have been for the
IS THE NEW INSTITUTIONALISM A THEORY? 743

most part only measured indirectly by the A variety of historical and quantita-
extent to which the structure or practice is tive empirical studies have examined
prevalent in a field (cf. Fligstein 1990) or by how strategies and practices become institu-
measuring the extent to which organizations tionalized. For example, researchers have
that adopt the structure or practice receive shown that actors, both collective and individ-
resources from powerful actors (Baum and ual (Battilana 2006; Garud, Jain, and
Oliver 1991, 1992). However, a few scholars Kumaraswamy 2002; Greenwood, Suddaby,
have attempted to measure legitimacy more and Hinings 2002; Macguire, Hardy, and
directly, by assaying explicit endorsements Lawrence 2004), can play the role of ‘institu-
of organizations that conform to institutional tional entrepreneur’ (DiMaggio 1991;
expectations by key gatekeepers such as Fligstein 1997; Greenwood and Suddaby
regulators and media representatives 2006; Leca and Naccache 2006) advocating
(Deephouse 1996). and disseminating a particular structure.
Processes The most fundamental NI process Business schools, for example, have taught
is ‘institutionalization,’ which roughly corre- organizational practices as ‘appropriate’ or
sponds to the mechanisms through which a ‘modern’ and encouraged their adoption.
way of organizing becomes accepted as Individuals have championed structural inno-
appropriate by numerous and/or powerful vations and sometimes have been successful
actors. DiMaggio and Powell ([1983]/1991) (Selznick 1957; Hirsch, 1975; Garud and
have formulated a series of concepts that Kumaraswamy 1995). Actors, however, differ
describe the way institutionalized elements in their capacity to bestow legitimacy on a
proliferate (coercive, normative and mimetic way of organizing. High status actors, in par-
isomorphism). Following Berger and ticular those who enjoy high performance and
Luckman (1966), Tolbert and Zucker maintain affiliations with other high status
([1996]/1999) identify three processes actors (such as top business schools) and
involved in institutionalization. The first powerful actors who occupy positions in
process, ‘habitualization,’ results in the formal hierarchies (such as government offi-
formalization of new structural arrange- cials) or who possess valuable and scarce
ments. ‘Objectification’ refers to the devel- resources (such as Chief Financial Officers),
opment of a social consensus with regard to play particularly important roles in institu-
the value of these new arrangements. And, tionalizing ways of organizing (Rao, Greve,
finally, ‘sedimentation’ (or full institutional- and Davis 2001). More recently, social move-
ization) ‘is characterized both by the ment theorists have also used these ideas to
virtually complete spread of structures across understand the success and failure of those
the group of actors theorized as appropriate seeking to promote or undermine institutions
adopters, and by the perpetuation of (Davis, McAdam, Scott, and Zald 2005).
structures over a lengthy period of time’
([1996]/1999: 178). The related concepts Relationships
of ‘institutional reproduction’ and The new institutionalism is characterized by
‘de-institutionalization’ signify mechanisms two types of relationships: tendencies and
through which institutions are maintained causal relations.
and undermined. Oliver (1992) has elabo- Tendencies Proponents of the NI recognize
rated a series of conditions that she contends two kinds of tendencies. The first type of ten-
undermine institutional regimes. Jepperson dency refers to developments that tend to
(1991: 152) also recognizes the process of unfold over time. For example, proponents of
‘reinstitutionalization,’ which is illustrated the new institutionalism postulate that organ-
by the ‘exit from one institutionalization, and izations tend, over time, to become more
entry into another institutional form, organ- similar to one another. That is, they tend to
ized around different principles.’ become ‘isomorphic’ even when these
744 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

changes do not increase organizational effi- New organizational forms developing out-
ciency. DiMaggio and Powell ([1983]/1991) side of institutionalized norms, for example
have identified three types of isomorphic for-profit higher educational systems, must
pressures. Coercive isomorphism ‘results orient themselves in regard to accepted forms
from both formal and informal pressures and practices. All three processes are impor-
exerted on organizations by other organiza- tant for understanding how institutionalized
tions upon which they are dependent and by components proliferate. A large number of
cultural expectations in the society within empirical studies have charted the emergence
which organizations function’ ([1983]/1991: of institutions over time (see citations in the
67). Regulative structures may demand, section immediately above). However, these
through the force of law for example, that studies have disproportionately focused upon
organizations adopt affirmative action prac- mimetic processes as the mechanism driving
tices. Very different organizations will thus isomorphism (Mizruchi and Fein 1999).
have similar sorts of human resources units Furthermore, while one could imagine the
and practices in response to this outside reg- degree of isomorphism to vary across organi-
ulatory pressure (Sutton, Dobbin, Meyer, and zational fields, proponents of the new institu-
Scott 1994). While changes in organizations tionalism have not identified variables that
resulting from coercive isomorphism gener- regulate the extent to which these tendencies
ally arise from controls placed on organiza- are exhibited.
tions by the state, ‘normative isomorphism’ The second type of tendency designates
typically arises from professionalization, characteristics that are time invariant. For
similarities in formal education and profes- example, the NI postulates that when institu-
sional networks, which results in the stan- tional elements are incorporated into an
dardization of organizational responses. organization, they tend to be ‘loosely cou-
Accounting firms and hospitals in different pled’ with the organization’s technical core
market settings, and with different special- (Meyer and Rowan [1977]/1991; for a cri-
izations, may end up looking much like tique see Tyler 1987). While one could imag-
other accounting firms and hospitals because ine the degree of loose coupling between
that is what is sanctioned by their profes- institutional and technical elements to vary
sional certification bodies (Abbott 1983; as a function of other conditions, proponents
Greenwood et al. 2002; Gendron, Suddaby, of the new institutionalism have rarely exam-
and Lam 2006; Scott, Ruef, Mendel, and ined this potential problematic (cf., however,
Caronna 2000). Finally, ‘mimetic isomor- Orton and Weick 1990). Early studies on
phism’ occurs when organizations face loose coupling focused on the not-for-profit
environmental uncertainty and so mimic one sector, looking at, for example, education
another, conferring on one another a degree organizations (Meyer 1977; Meyer and
of legitimacy, as a solution to this condition. Rowan 1978; Weick 1976; for criticism see
Copying the structure and practices Lutz 1982) and the criminal justice system
of other organizations allows organizations (Hagan, Hewitt, and Alwin 1979).
to be mutually understood, as well as under- Subsequently, the new institutionalism began
stood by outsiders when there is cognitive to look at the for-profit sector. Some
uncertainty. Adopting the symbols, language, researchers have examined what might be
structures and practices of other organiza- considered the ceremonial adoption of legiti-
tions allows new or transforming organiza- mate practices, such as the employment of
tions to identify themselves institutionally new accounting standards (Mezias 1990) or
as a college textbook publisher (Levitt and stock buy-back programs (Westphal and
Nass 1989), museum (DiMaggio 1991) Zajac 2001). Others, though, have examined
or school (Meyer and Rowan 1978; the adoption of substantively significant
Meyer 1977). structures and practices in the for-profit
IS THE NEW INSTITUTIONALISM A THEORY? 745

sector, such as the adoption of the multidivi- testifies to the fact that the more institution-
sional form and diversifying acquisitions alized and thus legitimate an organizational
(Fligstein 1985, 1987; Fligstein and Dauber structure or process is, the more beneficial
1989; Fligstein and Freeland 1992; Palmer, outcomes organizations enjoy by embracing
Barber, Zhou, and Soysal 1995). For a while, them (see, for example, Baum and Oliver
the concept of loose-coupling appeared to 1991; Baum and Oliver 1992; Human and
dwindle in importance. In the process, the Provan 2000; Ruef and Scott 1998; Singh,
concept looked like it would be transformed Tucker, and House 1986; Zucker 1987).
from a largely explanatory framework to a Another important causal relationship
more strategic one, which offers managers pertains to the moderating effects of uncer-
practical insights for managing their environ- tainty on the relationship between
ments, as evinced in research on the relation- institutional conformity, legitimacy, and
ship between entrepreneurial firm linkages organizational outcomes. Proponents of the
and IPO success (Stuart, Hoang, and Hybels new institutionalism believe that the more
1999). However, there has recently been an uncertainty there is about the efficiency char-
outpouring of studies that have examined acteristics of alternative forms of organizing,
loose-coupling as an explanatory concept in the less impact those efficiency characteris-
the for-profit sector (e.g., Brandes, Hadani, tics will have on the choice of organizing
and Goranova 2006; Christmann and Taylor form and the more impact that institutional
2006; Fernandez-Alles, Cuevas-Rodriguez, forces will have on this choice (Powell and
and Valle-Cabera 2006; Fiss and Zajac 2006; DiMaggio [1983]/1991). This postulated
Stevens, Steensma, Harrison, and Cochran relationship is arguably one of the new insti-
2005), indicating that the concept will con- tutionalism’s most novel aspects, one which
tinue to play more than just a strategic role. sets it apart from economic and functionalist
Causal relationships The new institutional- sociological explanations of organizational
ism’s most fundamental causal relationship behavior. It suggests that the adoption of
is that between institutionalization, legiti- institutionalized elements can benefit organi-
macy, and beneficial organizational out- zations, even if it does not increase the effi-
comes (birth, the acquisition of resources, ciency and/or effectiveness of (indeed, even
high performance, and survival). The rela- if they inhibit the efficiency of) the genera-
tionship between institutionalization and tion of products and services, because the
legitimacy is often treated as definitional (see efficiency and/or effectiveness characteris-
Suchman 1995 for a critical discussion). tics of alternative modes of organizing are
Indicative of this, the many grammatical often unknown (and partly because institu-
forms of institution (institutional, institution- tional elements tend to be loosely coupled
alized, institutionalization) are used inter- with an organization’s technical core).
changeably with the various forms of A number of studies presented evidence sug-
legitimacy (legitimate, legitimized, legiti- gestive of the moderating impact of uncer-
mating, etc.). However, one study of tainty (cf. Haunschild and Miner 1997).
commercial banks demonstrated that the
adoption of institutionalized practices Assessment
(the adoption of asset strategies prevalent in This discussion suggests that the new institu-
the industry) leads to increased legitimacy tionalism has come a long way with respect
(Deephouse 1996). The predicted relation- to the articulation of measurable concepts
ship between being institutionalized and (pertaining to structures, attributes, and
legitimate on the one hand and enjoying ben- processes) and the elaboration of empirically
eficial organizational outcomes on the other, verifiable postulated relationships. This con-
though, has been examined in considerable clusion is echoed by Scott (forthcoming) in
depth. And a substantial body of research his stocktaking of the new institutionalism.
746 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

He argues that the new institutionalism has discussion of power in organization studies
moved ‘from looser to tighter conceptualiza- see Hardy and Clegg [1996/1999]). This
tions.’ And he argues that the new institution- raises the question of the extent to which the
alism has moved from elaborating simple to new institutionalism in some cases represents
more complicated relationships; specifically, a new bottle for old wine.
‘from determinant to interactive arguments.’
And he contends that this has happened
partly by moving ‘from assertions to evi- General theory: organizational
dence.’ While we identify specific gaps in
type, time, and space
conceptual development and empirical vali-
dation, we suspect that progress towards fill- Litchfield and Thompson complained that
ing these gaps will be made in the coming organization theory in their time was frag-
decades. mented into separate theories for different
Still, we think that at least one question kinds of organizations: military organiza-
can be raised about this dimension of the new tions, educational organizations, governmen-
institutionalism’s development as a theory. tal organizations, and business organizations.
More than a few of the concepts and relation- They advocated the development of general
ships that the new institutionalism posits are theory, by which they meant theory that was
borrowed from other theories. Indeed, the applicable to multiple types of organizations
concept of ‘legitimacy’ is central to many and presumably in multiple times and places.
other theories, going as far back as Max The new institutionalism began as a
Weber’s ideas on systems of imperative coor- behavior- and context-specific theory. It was
dination (1968: vol. 1) and Parsons’s elabora- developed to explain the ceremonial adop-
tion of what substantively became known as tion of structures and practices by organiza-
structural functionalism (e.g., 1951: 348–59, tions situated in non-market environments,
1956a, 1956b, 1961), and as recently as contexts in which such inefficient structures
modern management theories such as Pfeffer and practices could survive. Thus it
and Salanciks’s ([1978]/2003) resource explained why public schools adopted educa-
dependence perspective. Similarly, the con- tional reforms in which teachers were
cept of ‘uncertainty’ is central to decision required to develop elaborate lesson plans, an
theory (March and Simon [1953]/1993; organizational practice that was both rational
Cohen, March, and Olsen 1972), contin- and legitimate, but these lesson plans bore
gency theory (Thompson [1967]/2006; little relation to what teachers actually did in
Lawrence and Lorsch 1967), and (again) the their classrooms (Meyer 1977; Meyer and
resource dependence perspective. The new Rowan 1978). Proponents of the new institu-
institutionalism also borrows postulated rela- tionalism at this time surrendered analysis of
tionships from other theories. For example, it non-ceremonial forms in market contexts to
is difficult to distinguish between coercive economists. Over the years, proponents of
institutional pressures and resource depend- the new institutionalism have continued to
ence-based power. Similarly, it is difficult to examine adoption of organizational elements
distinguish mimetic isomorphism from inter- that are not tied to an organization’s technical
organizational learning and other diffusion core (e.g., charitable giving) in non-market
processes. The argument that uncertainty contexts (e.g., the corporate philanthropy
increases the salience of institutional field). However, it has also become increas-
processes parallels arguments that uncer- ingly more general in several ways.
tainty enhances the salience of status and Perhaps most important, the NI has
social comparison processes. Finally, there increasingly been employed to analyze
have been attempts to borrow other concepts, the adoption of more pragmatic structures
such as ‘power’ from other theories (for a and practices by for-profit organizations.
IS THE NEW INSTITUTIONALISM A THEORY? 747

The new institutionalism expanded its scope institutionalism by explicitly taking into
by developing arguments that characterized account the temporal dimension. They exam-
markets as fundamentally (albeit, variably) ined how the institutional context in the
uncertain and by characterizing legitimacy as health care sector evolved over time, making
an attribute that can increase a firm’s access different kinds of governance arrangements
to valued resources and thus improve its per- more or less advantageous. Similarly,
formance, in the process transforming the Thornton and Ocasio (1999) demonstrated
concept of efficiency (cf. Fligstein 1990). how the institutional context in the publish-
Two important theoretical pieces summarize ing industry changed over time from a family
the generality of the new institutionalism in logic to a market logic, altering the condi-
this respect. In his stock taking of the then tions that made corporate acquisitions desir-
adolescent neo-institutional approach, Scott able. And Dobbin (1997, 2000) documented
(1987) jettisoned the distinction between how the institutional context in the US
technical (market) contexts and institutional railroad industry changed as the result of
ones and embraced a perspective that viewed alterations in anti-trust policy, shifting the
market and non-market contexts simply as conditions that made railroad foundings and
different institutional spheres. More recently, acquisitions in that industry more or less
Biggart and Delbridge (2004) developed a likely.
classification scheme of different kinds of Finally, there is now a growing body of
market institutions. In their typology markets research that expands the generality of the
are not a single institutional type. Rather new institutionalism along the spatial dimen-
markets have four qualitatively different sion. This work examines different national
institutional expressions, depending on contexts, which can vary with respect to the
whether they emerge in social environments types of sectors that dominate society (state,
where instrumental or value-based substan- market, and mixed) and with respect to the
tive rationality dominates decision making characteristics of those sectors (types of mar-
and where social action is particularistic or kets). Works by Orrù, Biggart, and Hamilton
universalistic (oriented towards individual (1997) and Biggart and Guillén (1999)
characteristics or supra-individual princi- demonstrate how variation in the institutional
ples). Social environments vary along the context of Asian economies has generated
instrumental-substantive rationality dimen- different market structures and performance.
sion and the universalistic-particularistic Guillén and his associates (Guillén 2000;
dimension and result in four logically differ- Guler, Guillén, and Macpherson 2002) have
ent institutional settings: price, communal, shown how variation in the institutional con-
moral, and associative economic orders with text of developing economies has generated
very different hypothesized structures and differential rates of adoption of work process
dynamics. Rather than seeing the market as reform and hostile takeovers.
one historically developed institutional form
for organizing exchange, Biggart and Assessment
Delbridge argue that economic exchange We think that the new institutionalism is now
relations can be institutionalized in quite a truly general framework, in that it can be
different ways. This classification system used to explain both ceremonial and substan-
opens up the possibility of economic theory tive behavior in complex organizations of all
testing, and also for seeking other forms of types (i.e., in both non-market and market
institutional types, for example of health care environments, and in different types of
systems or educational structures. market environments) in virtually all times
Ruef and Scott’s (1998; Scott et al. 2000) and places. This is an impressive achieve-
empirical analysis of health care systems ment. With this said, we discern a tension
further expanded the generality of the new between the forces seeking to make the new
748 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

institutionalism more general (identified First, Litchfield and Thompson argued that
above) and those seeking to preserve its sen- organization theory should draw on the full
sitivity to context. range of social science disciplines. This argu-
A major appeal of the NI is its rejection of ment laid the foundation for the two addi-
the often abstract character of much organi- tional contentions. Second, they thought that
zation theory (Davis and Marquis 2005a). organization theory should operate at three
Early organization theorists aspired to char- levels of analysis – the individual, the
acterizing organizations according to con- organization, and the environment. Third,
structs such as technology, size, and they thought organization theory should
centralization, irrespective of environmental apprehend the many dimensions of the
context. A subsequent wave of organization administrative process – decision making,
theorists aspired to characterize organiza- implementation, and learning.
tions according to their environments, but
they characterized organization environ- Disciplines
ments in categories such as ‘munificence’ Proponents of the new institutionalism, like
and ‘dynamism’ that ignored more fine- the proponents of many other theoretical per-
grained dimensions of context. Many modern spectives in organization studies, have drawn
organization theorists have continued this heavily on sociological theory. Scott (2005)
tendency (Hannan and Freeman 1977; Burt recently located the roots of new institution-
1980). The proponents of the NI have taken alism in the works of classic social theorists
into account the context in which organiza- Marx, Durkheim, and Weber. The notion that
tions are situated to a much greater extent organizations operate on an institutional level
than the advocates of other theoretical has its modern origins in Selznick’s (1948,
approaches; considering not just the material 1949) path-breaking study of the Tennessee
relationships in which organizations are Valley Authority, which showed how the
embedded but the normative and cognitive authority’s environment influenced the goals
environment as well. But characterization of it pursued, shifting them from a progressive
an organization’s normative and cognitive to a more conservative agenda. Parsons’s
environment requires non-positivist modes (1956a, 1956b) explicitly theorized the insti-
of analysis, such as historical and interpreta- tutional level of analysis in his early outline
tive methods, which Ventresca and Mohr call of a theory of organizations. Stinchcombe
the ‘new archival project’ (2002). Such (1965) exploited this basic model when he
modes of analysis tend to produce conclu- detailed how organizations are constructed of
sions that are highly industrially, historically, elements in their surrounding social structure
and spatially specific. Exemplary studies in and that this imprinting is resistant to change.
this vein include Mohr and Duquenne The new institutionalism also has roots in
(1997), DiMaggio and Mullen (2000), the work of Berger and Luckmann’s The
Spicer, McDermott, and Kogut (2000) and Social Construction of Reality (1966),
Kogut and Spicer (2002). Thus, the more which, put crudely, advanced the notion that
context-specific NI’s analyses are, the less there is no reality beyond what we manufac-
generalizable its insights tend to be. ture and agree upon together. This notion had
wide-ranging effects in social thought, but
only in macro-units of analyses among new
Comprehensive theory: disciplines, institutionalism scholars. The notion of insti-
tutions as inter-subjectively meaningful
levels, and substantive areas
social constructions permeated NI studies
Litchfield and Thompson argued that organi- at the levels of the organization, field,
zation theory should aspire to comprehen- and global systems, but few NI scholars
siveness. By this they meant three things. have elaborated the implications of this view
IS THE NEW INSTITUTIONALISM A THEORY? 749

at a micro-level. Institutions are by definition collective meanings that allow social


constructs that are only visible when enacted processes to develop, stabilize, institutional-
by individuals in social settings, including ize, and change in organized settings, for
organizations. However, those interested in example Barley’s (1986) study of the intro-
micro-processes in organizations such as duction of CT scanners into radiology
decision-making and identification processes departments demonstrated the disruption of
(Elsbach and Kramer 1996) have largely established interactional and authority
approached these dynamics from the per- patterns. New machines demanded new prac-
spective of individual psychology. tices and created opportunities for subordi-
In what ways can we think of individuals nates to become experts and reverse roles
enacting institutions? Biggart and Beamish with superiors. With time, new practices and
(2003: 257) argue that conventionalized roles were institutionalized. Similarly,
activities, for example routine ways of Bechky (2003) examined how occupational
making and justifying decisions, are actually categories and boundaries are negotiated
‘institutions writ small.’ Conventions are through material technologies. She found
taken-for-granted and socially efficient ways that engineering prototypes and technical
of enabling actors to coordinate with and drawings used by a semiconductor firm were
evaluate each others’ actions, not only in the imbued with meanings. Artifacts symbolized
moment, but over time as a socially legiti- and structured relations between groups of
mate pattern. According to Palmer and assemblers, technicians, and engineers.
Biggart (2002), because organized ‘action is Although they do not claim to be part of
collective, situations must be interpreted the new institutionalism, there are logical and
iteratively in mutually intelligible ways, theoretical links between these scholars and
therefore developing and utilizing institu- institutional theory. When meanings crystal-
tionalized conventions’ may be a solution to lize in objects and communities of practice
individuals’ uncertainty in ambiguous set- such as radiologists and hardware designers
tings. Institutionalized organizations are in they are in the process of becoming institu-
fact bundles of conventions about decision- tionalized (Biggart and Beamish 2003). To
making rules and other organizational the extent that the new institutionalism wants
routines that have congealed into structural to claim to be a comprehensive theory that
forms. can operate at all units of analysis, it must
Social construction as both a concept and develop a micro-logical orientation that
as a process for study has had far more devel- shows the emergence of meaning, its devel-
opment in other areas of the social sciences, opment into inter-subjectively agreed-upon
including anthropology and communica- classifications, definitions, and values, and
tions. The analysis of micro-social processes the development of structures that emerge
has traditionally been the purview of tradi- from these understandings. Psychology
tions rising out of pragmatism, particularly and economics, by themselves, predicated as
symbolic interactionism, but also the French they are on methodological individualism,
conventions school (also known as the new cannot conceptualize the shared and taken-
economics of conventions), and in the for-granted meanings that are central to new
Science and Technology Studies tradition of institutionalism.
the dynamics of scientific discovery and One can imagine five lines along which a
practice (Latour and Woolgar [1979]/1986; micro-NI might develop. First, a micro-NI
Latour 1987; Pickering 1992). These related could look at traditionally psychological
perspectives have found their way into orga- areas of investigation such as employee
nizational studies recently through the analy- selection, work design, training and leader-
sis of technological artifacts in organized ship to examine how differently institutional-
settings, artifacts that become imbued with ized firms develop conventional solutions
750 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

around these issues. Second, it could theorize Coase (1937) and extended and codified by
the role of individuals as institutional entre- Williamson (1975, 1981). The central idea in
preneurs to develop a truly institutional this line of inquiry is that economic transac-
theory of leadership (cf. Biggart and tions (not producers [the source of supply] or
Hamilton 1987; DiMaggio 1991; Hargadon consumers [the source of demand]) are the
and Douglas 2001). Third, a micro-NI could fundamental unit of analysis in economics.
examine the cultural-cognitive components The institutional structures through which
involved when decision makers attempt to transactions are governed are the fundamen-
‘read’ the institutional environment for tal variables. Put bluntly, institutional struc-
strategic opportunities and threats (George tures persist to the extent to which they are
et al. 2006). This line of research, while efficient means of governing transactions
rooted in the psychology of decision making, under particular conditions (which pertain to
opens the door to incorporating interpretive uncertainty, asset specificity, etc.). Nelson
processes that decode social meanings. and Winter (1982) have developed a more
Fourth, it could pursue a comparative analy- nuanced brand of institutional economics
sis of conventions in different institutional- which emphasizes the path-dependent
ized fields that might suggest ways in which process through which institutional change
organizational actors find solutions to prob- occurs, a path in which new forms emerge
lems of organizing, for example, how archi- from existing ones.
tects in state-directed building programs This work adds an important caveat to ear-
construct building plans in comparison to lier institutional economics: while institu-
those in industrialized arenas of the same era tional structures persist to the extent to which
(Guillén 2006). Finally, a micro-NI could they are efficient, a structure’s efficiency
develop a more active understanding of characteristics are only evaluated with
institutionalization processes (cf. Zucker respect to concrete alternative structures in
[1977]/1991). At present institutional theory the market at the time. Thus, persisting insti-
is relatively static, assuming the processes tutional structures are not optimally efficient,
from which structures emerge (see Barley but only relatively so. As such, it brings eco-
and Tolbert 1997 for a discussion of this nomic institutionalism in closer correspon-
problem). An interactive NI offers the prom- dence with sociological institutionalism.
ise of seeing how institutions emerge out of Perhaps the best example of this line of work
negotiation, conflict, and collaboration. is the simultaneously historical and game
There is also work in economics upon theoretic comparative analyses of economist
which new institutionalists might draw. Avner Greif (1994). Greif examined two
Institutional thinking in economics dates premodern trading societies with different
back to the work of Veblen, Commons, institutional structures, the 11th-century
Mitchell and Coase, who looked at the indi- Maghribi traders living in a Muslim world
vidual to see how socialization and organiza- and the 12th century Genoese traders which
tional arrangements shape the choices he or were part of the Latin world. The Maghribi
she makes (see Hodgson 1998 and society was a collectivist one, with informa-
Rutherford 2001 for more on institutional tion shared and punishments collectively
economics). These new economists differed enforced, and the Genoese society was
from neoclassical economists in not assum- decidedly individualist. Both faced the
ing that actors have fixed preferences, but danger of embezzlement when using over-
argued that their preferences may be socially seas agents but resolved this principal–agent
formed and influenced by the context in problem with different institutional means
which they find themselves – for example in and each society created practices and sanc-
a newly emerging middle class (Veblen tions consonant with their cultures. Greif
[1899]/1979). This strain was developed by goes on to argue that differently efficient
IS THE NEW INSTITUTIONALISM A THEORY? 751

solutions cannot be changed because of the institutional thinking is enjoying something


effects of path dependence. The work of of a renaissance in political science, in part as
Milgrom and Roberts (1992) also approaches a critique of the methodological individual-
issues of interest to the NI. They ask why ism of rational choice. Robert Lieberman’s
organizational forms take the shapes that (2002) reconciliation of ideational and insti-
they do. This is a fundamental theory of the tutional approaches with economically
firm question posed by Coase (1937) and inspired ones was one of the ten most down-
Williamson (1975) but like Greif they find loaded articles in political science between
the answer in the structure of social relation- 2002 and 2004 (APSA 2005: 13). New col-
ships between firms, not assuming that all lections of work are appearing that compete
contracts are arms-length but may be with rational choice approaches (Lecours
alliances or relational contracts. 2005; Mahoney and Rueschemeyer 2003).
The new institutionalism in organization Institutional analysis in political science
studies, though, has not much benefited from never disappeared from European thought
the resurgence of institutional thinking in where historical and ideational approaches
economics. Economic institutionalism regis- have always been important. Many of these
tered an impact within organization studies political science analyses are using new insti-
soon after it experienced its resurgence in tutionalism to account for the possibilities
economics (cf. Walker and Weber 1984). And and difficulties for institutional change in
it has had a substantial impact in the strategy settings such as post-colonial multicultural
area in recent years (cf. Mayer and Salomon Canada and the formation of the European
2006). However, economic institutionalism Union.
is typically presented as a stand-alone The NI approach in organization studies
approach, rather than as a component of the has benefited from the resurgence of institu-
new institutionalism as we have character- tional thinking in political science. Indeed,
ized it here. We suspect that this is because one might say that the regulative pillar of
the long-standing antagonism between eco- institutional theory is to a large extent built
nomics and sociology (the primary founda- upon the theoretical foundation of the institu-
tion of NI) has spilled over into the field of tional wing of political science. Certainly the
organization studies. Indeed, many lament work of several new institutionalists is heav-
the growing influence of economic thinking ily influenced by institutional thinking in
in organization science (Pfeffer 1993, 1995; political science (cf. Campbell 1998;
Hirsch, Michaels, and Friedman 1987; Clemens 1993). And some new institutional-
Hirsch, Friedman, and Koza 1990). However, ist scholars have done more than simply
as economists ‘relax’ assumptions of individ- borrow from institutional scholarship in
ual omniscience and rationality, some bor- political science; they have developed ideas
rowing from NI is likely as well. that suggest the limitations of that scholar-
Proponents of the new institutionalism ship. Perhaps most important, Edelman
have also drawn on work in political science. (1992) has shown how regulative structures
The earliest political scientists focused pri- can be considered endogenous products of
marily on the institutional structure of politi- institutional development in the area of equal
cal life; in particular, the structure of opportunity legislation and policy. With this
governing bodies of the state, political par- said, the new institutionalism’s incorporation
ties, and trade unions. This institutional focus of institutional thinking in political science is
was rejected by what might be called modern far from complete. This is perhaps most evi-
political science, which to a large extent dent in the failure of the new institutionalism
focuses on voter behavior and which recently to develop a unique understanding of power,
has drawn on micro-economics in the form despite the repeated exhortations of leading
of rational choice theory. Recently, though, figures in the field to do so (DiMaggio and
752 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Powell 1991: 30–1; Hirsch 1997; Perrow Subsequently, however, some proponents
1985). We think that new institutionalists of the new institutionalism began to theorize
might make headway in addressing this an even higher level of analysis: the global or
deficiency by drawing on radical analyses world system. These theorists, most notably
of power within political science and John W. Meyer and his associates (Boli,
political sociology that characterize it as a Ramirez, and Meyer 1985; Meyer and
multifaceted phenomenon that includes sym- Jepperson 2000; Ramirez and Boli 1982;
bolic and cognitive elements (cf. Gaventa Ramirez and Meyer 1980) contend that insti-
1982; Lukes 2005). tutionalized forms and practices may develop
and disseminate above the field, sector, and
Levels of analysis nation-state levels. Ideas, imageries, and
Proponents of the new institutionalism have functions may emerge in one setting but
clearly focused primarily on the environmen- migrate globally, being incorporated in regu-
tal level of analysis, viewing the environment lative, normative, and cognitive systems
as the source of rationalized myths that could operating at the world system level. For
be used as building blocks by new organiza- example the notion of what constitutes
tions or as material for change by existing progress may be encapsulated in measures
ones. Soon thereafter, proponents of the new such as the Gross National Product (GNP)
institutionalism advanced a new level of which diffuses through the world polity,
analysis within the broader environment, the which is composed of international bodies
‘field’ (DiMaggio and Powell [1983]/1991). such as the World Bank, the United Nations,
As indicated above, fields group organiza- and the International Monetary Fund. This
tions according to their tendency to establish results in common measurements and poli-
relationships with one another and according cies in very different settings. Ideas such as
to their regulation by a common set of insti- financial transparency and practices such as
tutional constraints. New institutionalists accounting rules, initially alien in non-
also recognize another level of analysis sim- Western societies, are carried across national
ilar to the organizational field but operating boundaries by consulting firms and Western
at a higher level of aggregation: the societal educational institutions that attract interna-
sector. Scott and Meyer ([1983]/1991: 117) tional students who eventually return home
define the societal sector as: ‘(1) a collection with new constructs. Ideas, concepts, and
of organizations operating in the same practices are thus rationalized as ‘normal’
domain, as identified by the similarity and become embedded in organizations
of their services, products or functions, globally (cf. Drori, Jang, and Meyer 2006).
(2) together with those organizations that Proponents of the new institutionalism,
critically influence the performance of the though, have also pursued lower levels of
focal organizations ... The adjective societal analysis. The earliest proponents of the new
emphasizes that organizational sectors in institutionalism implicitly theorized dynam-
modern societies are likely to stretch from ics within organizations when they con-
local to national or even international actors.’ tended that the institutional elements drawn
The concepts of field and societal sector from the environment were not tightly cou-
emerged out of role-set theories in sociology pled with the organization’s technical core.
where individuals are seen in terms of the Subsequently, Fligstein (1996) developed
roles and relationships they have with each what he referred to as a ‘political/cultural’
other, not just as a collection of individuals. theory of the firm, which considers the
Organization fields and sectors are similarly interplay between regulative, normative, and
communities of interconnected firms or other cognitive structures within the organization.
forms of organization such as suppliers or He contended that different coalitions of
regulatory agencies. managers that embrace dissimilar norms and
IS THE NEW INSTITUTIONALISM A THEORY? 753

cognitive models, which are derived from the change. These analyses portrayed change
environment, vie for power within the firm. justified on rationalist or functionalist
The coalitions that rise to power adopt struc- grounds as primarily symbolic in character,
tures and pursue strategies and tactics that geared not to alter the way organizations
are consistent with their cognitive models. conducted their business but rather towards
Fligstein argued that executives with finance winning approval from important con-
backgrounds rose to power in the 1960s and stituents of their environments (Meyer and
1970s, replacing marketing and production Rowan [1977]/1991). Some recent new insti-
executives. Finance executives embraced the tutionalist analyses continue this debunking
finance conception of control, which under- tradition (Drori, Jang, and Meyer 2006). Soon
stood the firm to be a portfolio of invest- after the new institutional lens was ground,
ments. The finance conception of control had though, it was adopted by organization stud-
its origins in agency theory, which was dis- ies scholars as a tool with which they could
seminated by the major US business schools. ply their trade. In the early years of the field
It was consistent with the adoption of the (long before the new institutional framework
multidivisional form and the pursuit of was fashioned), organization studies scholars
diversification via mergers and acquisitions, embraced Litchfield and Thompson’s exhor-
a policy that was also consistent with recent tation to focus attention on the administrative
developments in anti-trust law and federal process, which they characterized as a ‘cycle
government policy. Others have also devel- of action,’ consisting of decision making,
oped new institutional arguments at the level programming, communicating, controlling
of the organization, such as Ocasio’s (1999) and reappraising (Litchfield 1956: 12).
analysis of the institutionalization of norms As the field developed, the conception of the
and rules regulating executive succession in administrative process broadened. Mintzberg
large corporations. (1971) discovered that the administrative
More recently, some proponents of the process consisted of a wide range of activi-
new institutionalism have migrated to the ties that were divorced from decision
individual level of analysis. For example, making, programming, etc. And Pfeffer
Zbaracki (1998) has examined managers’ (1976) identified the institutional level as an
adoption of Total Quality Management important and largely ignored domain of
(TQM), analyzing how managers conceptu- managerial action. When it emerged in the
alize and in the process transform this inno- late 1970s, the new institutionalism became a
vation as they adopt it. Elsbach (1994) has new theoretical resource from which
looked at how the cattle industry responded hypotheses could be drawn for deductive
to a health crisis, examining how managers work and to which new ideas could be added
employ legitimated logics to protect them- via inductive work on virtually every
selves from potentially damaging criticisms. substantive topic of the day. It is now hard to
In both articles, managers are drawing on think of a substantive topic within organiza-
institutional elements in the environment to tion studies where the new institutionalism
conceptualize and solve managerial prob- has not left its mark; from the hiring of
lems. Finally, George et al. (2006) have workers (Dobbin and Sutton 1998), the
attempted to develop the cultural-cognitive choice of accounting systems (Mezias 1990),
pillar of the new institutionalism by engaging the adoption of innovations (Westphal,
with behavioral theories of decision making. Gulati, and Shortell 1997), the implementa-
tion of innovations (Zbaracki 1998), to the
Substantive areas promotion of top managers (Ocasio 1999),
The earliest new institutionalist analyses the pursuit of particular strategies and
were geared towards debunking rational and structures (Fligstein 1990), the adoption of
functionalist accounts of organizational particular growth tactics (Palmer et al. 1995);
754 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

and the understanding of temporal and spa- fundamentally arbitrary. In the hands of con-
tial variation in all of the above (Guler, temporary organization studies scholars,
Guillen, and Macpherson 2002; Schneper these fundamental insights have increasingly
and Guillén 2004). been used to develop theories, analyses, and
even prescriptions about how organizational
Assessment leaders can obtain legitimacy and attendant
This discussion suggests that new institution- benefits for their organization. And in the
alism is now an extremely comprehensive process, a theoretical perspective that views
theory. Proponents of the new institutional- organizational action as fundamentally non-
ism have drawn upon several of the social rational and non-functionalist becomes a tool
sciences for their insights, although they for analyzing behavior in and of organiza-
could range further from their largely socio- tions in such a way that it is seen as even
logical base to incorporate the work of polit- more self-consciously instrumental.
ical scientists, economists and, in particular,
the work of psychologists to a greater extent.
The proponents of the new institutionalism
Cumulative theory
have also plied their trade at multiple levels
of analysis, although they could certainly If a general theory explains organizations in
stray further from the highest levels to exam- multiple settings and a comprehensive theory
ine organizational and even more individual draws on many disciplines to explain a wide
level phenomena. Finally, proponents of the range of organizational phenomena at multi-
new institutionalism have used their theoret- ple levels of analysis, a theory that is cumu-
ical lens to examine a wide range, perhaps lative is one that grows better with additional
the full range of organizational phenomena studies that expand its scope, strengthen its
recognized by contemporary organization powers, and reveal and diminish its limita-
studies scholars. tions. For a theory to grow, researchers must
With this said, we wonder whether some self-consciously tackle the theory as an
of the NI’s most penetrating insights are at object of study, growing and pruning it as
risk of being lost as it expands to incorporate evidence and argument support. From a the-
multiple disciplines, operate at multiple oretical standpoint, it must refine existing
levels of analysis, and address a cornucopia concepts, clarifying and perhaps in the
of substantive topics. We think that such a process bifurcating existing concepts. It must
risk is exacerbated by the fact that organiza- refine existing relationships, identifying
tion studies scholars have increasingly been scope conditions and moderating and
concentrated in graduate schools of manage- mediating mechanisms, and, of course, it
ment and business and that their scholarship must add new concepts and relationships.
is influenced by managerial and business This can be accomplished deductively, by
concerns (Augier, March, and Sullivan 2005; examining logical gaps, limitations, and
Perrow 2000). The unique insight of the inconsistencies in the corpus of ideas that
new institutionalism, an insight that it compose the theory. And it can be accom-
shares with few if any other organization plished inductively, by conducting research
theories, is that organizations and organiza- to examine the adequacy of existing concepts
tional participants are products of the larger and relationships.
social structure; in particular, the cognitive There are signs that proponents of the
elements of that structure. As a result, organ- new institutionalism self-consciously attempt
izations and the people who inhabit them act to build on one another’s work. Perhaps
in ways that are taken for granted as appro- most notably, and discussed above, the con-
priate and even presumed to be rational, cept of institution has become increasingly
despite the fact that these ways of being are more multidimensional. Scott and Meyer
IS THE NEW INSTITUTIONALISM A THEORY? 755

([1983]/1991) distinguished between techni- forward progress. Perhaps no area is defined


cal environments, in which organizations by the spinning of wheels more than the new
compete with one another on the basis of institutionalist work on the diffusion of inno-
their efficiency and effectiveness of opera- vation. Early work in this new institutionalist
tion, and institutional environments, in which domain generated evidence that issues of
organizations vie for legitimacy. Later, Scott efficiency and effectiveness became less
(1987) contended that all environments are important in the adoption of new innovations
institutional, but differ in their institutional as new practices proliferated (Tolbert and
character. Importantly, in Scott’s formula- Zucker 1983). Subsequent work built on this
tion, the market is one type of institutional early research by showing how normative
setting, in which organizations follow the processes (the incorporation of professionals
logic of competition and compete on the who championed innovations) and mimetic
basis of efficiency and effectiveness. More processes (linkage to other organizations
recently, Biggart and Delbridge (2004) elab- already embracing the innovations) stimu-
orated a typology that distinguishes between lated adoption at the late and early stages
different types of market settings on the basis of a new practice’s proliferation (Palmer,
of their institutional structure. Jennings, and Zhou 1993). Additional work
Similarly, the concept of loose-coupling added precision to this research, focusing on
was initially conceived as a baseline assump- how the characteristics of adopters, objects
tion of the new institutionalism, allowing of social comparison, and the innovations
proponents of this perspective to analyze the themselves shaped diffusion (Davis and
adoption of innovation in market contexts. Greve 1997). However, research on the diffu-
For-profit organizations could more easily be sion of innovation typically failed to consider
understood to incorporate institutionalized the operation of coercive processes
elements that increased their legitimacy but (Mizruchi and Fein 1999). Instead, a plethora
not their efficiency if those elements were of studies proliferated that evaluated essen-
integrated in a way that left them loosely- tially the same hypotheses as applied to dif-
coupled with their technical core. However, ferent kinds of organizations and different
Westphal and Zajac (2001) reinvigorated the kinds of innovations.
concept of loose-coupling by characterizing
it as a variable attribute of organizations Assessment
which could be analyzed like other innova- The new institutionalism has exhibited signs
tions. They contended that stock buy-back of growth, as concepts become differentiated
programs became legitimate as agency and refined and relationships become elabo-
theory became widely accepted, because rated, partly as the result of empirical
they promised to reduce the separation of research. To this conclusion, though, we add
ownership and control which generated one caveat. As the NI might predict, organi-
agency costs. They argued, however, that zations studies scholars seeking legitimacy
firms typically announced but did not imple- for their own work often cast their work as
ment such programs so that they could obtain falling under the protective umbrella of theo-
the legitimacy benefits from them without retical perspectives in vogue at the time. We
actually changing corporate policy. They think that too often the new institutionalism
demonstrated that firms adopted such has served as a shade tree under which organ-
loosely-coupled stock buy-back programs to ization studies scholars, some of whom are
the extent that they were linked to other firms only peripherally connected to the new insti-
that had already pursued them. tutionalist project, have found company and
Certainly, though, there are areas where support with little in the way of self-criticism
the new institutionalism appears to be and self-improvement. This was perhaps to
spinning its wheels more than it is making be expected in the theory’s adolescence, as
756 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

scholars promoted new institutionalism as useful in explaining organizational change


superior to alternative theories such as eco- and because current organizational realities
nomic perspectives. However, for theoretical are in flux. Further, they argue that the new
development the NI community is obliged to institutionalism is a particularly fruitful
consider issues of validity, paradigmatic archive from which to draw social mecha-
purity, application, methodologies, and other nisms, because the new institutionalism
matters that reveal the strength and limits of operates at the field level of analysis and
the NI. organizational fields are in flux. This
approach to organization theory differs from
the Litchfield and Thompson approach in
important ways. It eschews general theory
ALTERNATIVE MODELS OF THEORY and cumulative theoretical development. It
also eschews prediction, which is inherent in
Our assessment of the theoretical status of the L&T view. Importantly, Davis and
the new institutionalism uses Litchfield and Marquis contend that organization theorists,
Thompson’s model of theory as they devel- at least macro-organizational behavior theo-
oped it 40 years ago as a benchmark. We rists, have already largely embraced this
adopted this yardstick because we believe the approach. Davis (2005) reports a survey of
most contemporary organization theorists the last 10 years of Administrative Science
develop their ideas with this model of theory Quarterly that reveals that the vast majority
building in mind. However, there are compet- of macro-organizational behavior articles are
ing models of doing organization studies. In ‘problem-driven’; that is, motivated by a
this section we briefly review three alterna- desire to explain events in the world rather
tive conceptions of what constitutes a ‘good’ than by a desire to test a particular theoretical
theory: the social mechanism approach, idea. Furthermore, most of these problem-
postmodernism, and critical realism. driven articles drew on multiple theories to
Furthermore, we assess their suitability for develop possible (sometimes alternative)
developing the new institutionalism as a explanations of these events.
theoretical enterprise. Davis and Marquis (2005a) review a vari-
ety of studies that use the social mechanisms
approach and draw on institutional theory to
implement this approach, one of which is
The social mechanism approach
Davis and Marquis’s (2005b) own study of
Recently Hedström and Swedberg (1998) the causes and consequences of convergence
proposed the articulation of cause and effect in corporate governance form, as evinced in
relationships called social mechanisms that the listing of foreign firms on the New York
occupy a position between pure description Stock Exchange (NYSE) and Nasdaq. Davis
and universal laws. These postulated middle- and Marquis drew on institutional theory to
range relationships do not hold in all contexts identify several social mechanisms that
and cannot be used to predict social develop- might explain these listings. Foreign firms
ments. Rather, they can only be drawn on to might list on the NYSE and Nasdaq after
explain social developments in specific con- they turned American, presumably suggest-
texts after the fact. Davis and Marquis ing the operation of the institutional mecha-
(2005a; see also Davis 2006) are the fore- nism known as mimetic isomorphism. Or
most proponents of the social mechanism firms might turn American after they have
approach in organization studies. They con- been listed on the NYSE and Nasdaq for a
tend that this approach is particularly appro- while, perhaps suggesting the operation of
priate in the contemporary period because coercive mechanisms. Or foreign firms might
social mechanism reasoning is particularly turn American to the extent that they are tied
IS THE NEW INSTITUTIONALISM A THEORY? 757

via interlocking directorates to American mechanism approach would also have to


firms, presumably suggesting the operation embrace the process called ‘reappraisal,’
of normative mechanisms. Or foreign firms which Litchfield and Thompson considered
might remain inert, while new firms are born fundamental to the scientific method.
American, suggesting the operation of Specifically, proponents of the social mecha-
imprinting. According to Davis and Marquis, nisms approach would have to view efforts to
the new institutionalism could not provide validate one as opposed to another possible
researchers with an a priori definitive expla- social mechanism explanation of an organi-
nation of why foreign firms listed on the zational development as an opportunity to
NYSE and Nasdaq. But it could provide a evaluate and thus confirm, reject, or refine
number of possible explanations of why existing social mechanisms arguments.
firms listed on the NYSE and Nasdaq that
could be tested for post hoc plausibility.
Their empirical analysis provided support for
Postmodernism
the imprinting mechanism.
This use of institutional theory as a com- Postmodernism has a variety of expressions
pendium of causal arguments that can be (cf. Weiss 2000; Deetz 2000). One can distin-
drawn upon to explain organizational phe- guish four thrusts of postmodernism in
nomena seems sensible. There are many con- organization studies. A substantive thrust
crete historical developments that have characterizes contemporary organizations
organizational dimensions and that cry out as qualitatively different (i.e., as postmodern)
for adequate explanation. For example, the from previous (modern) organizations.
emergence and proliferation of terrorism, A methodological thrust advocates the use of
especially state-sponsored and religion- deconstruction to reinterpret dominant
inspired terrorism, throughout the world is an understandings of organizations. Perhaps
important phenomenon, perhaps most most importantly, deconstruction provides a
obviously because it is responsible for con- means to read scientific understandings of
siderable political instability and much organizations as value-laden and biased
human suffering. Yet our understanding of accounts that are but one of many possible
terrorism is infantile (Stampnitzky 2006) and interpretations. An epistemological thrust,
terrorism is certainly an organizational referred to as the skeptical postmodernism
phenomenon, requiring complex coordina- by Kilduff and Mehra (1997), calls into
tion. We think an analysis of terrorism that question the enterprise of attempting
draws on organization theory, including the to uncover the truth about organizations,
new institutionalism, could be exceptionally by calling into question the independent
insightful (cf. Perrow 1999). existence of organizational reality and main-
With this said, we think that adopting the taining the existence only of multiple inter-
social mechanism approach to theory build- pretations of a presumed reality. Finally, a
ing to the exclusion of the L&T approach theoretical thrust, characterized as the affir-
would be worrisome. Perhaps most impor- mative postmodernism by Kilduff and Mehra
tant, a single-minded application of the (1997), attempts to develop new, interesting,
social mechanism approach would by defini- and exciting understandings of organiza-
tion bring the creation of new theory to a tions, at the same time holding in reserve
halt. If we only borrowed social mechanisms various degrees of skepticism about the inde-
from existing theory to develop explanations pendent existence of organizational reality. It
of observable phenomena, the store of social is this theoretical thrust that is most relevant
mechanisms available to explain observable to our analysis here.
phenomena would not grow. In order for The types of understandings that the
theory to grow, proponents of the social affirmative postmodernism develops about
758 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

organizations have a number of defining be efficient. Insofar as the adoption of these


characteristics, some of which they share structures and practices facilitated their sur-
with understandings produced by other alter- vival, by bringing adopting organizations
native modes of inquiry, such as feminist legitimacy and resources, they acted as if
theory, critical theory and post-structuralism they were efficient.
(Agger 1991). Postmodern understandings With that said, the proponents of postmod-
tend to explicitly acknowledge the point of ernism tend to eschew the pursuit of theories
view from which they are developed. Further, composed of precise constructs and formal
the points of view from which postmodern relationships that apply across contexts and
understandings are developed tend to be grow cumulatively independent of the phe-
those of constituents who are typically nomena that they are designed to apprehend
ignored (e.g., subordinates, women, minori- (Van Maanen 1995). Thus, to the extent that
ties, etc.). Postmodern understandings tend new institutionalists embrace a postmodern
to be conveyed through a more personal lan- sensibility, they will likely impede the
guage. They tend to be less definitive, invit- development of the new institutionalism as a
ing leeway for audience interpretation. And theory in the Litchfield and Thompson sense.
they may aid in stimulating practical action We do not by any means intend this assertion
on the part of the constituency from whose to imply a critique of the postmodern
point of view they are formulated. There are perspective. We merely wish to note what we
relatively few studies that include all of these believe is the obvious; that the pursuit of the
characteristics, although there are a few postmodern perspective, like the pursuit of
exemplary studies, perhaps most famously the social mechanisms approach, is funda-
Martin’s (1990) analysis of a male top man- mentally incompatible with theory building
ager’s utterances about a pregnant female in the Litchfield and Thompson sense.
employees’ devotion to the firm.
While the new institutionalism does not
exhibit any of the above four specific charac-
Critical realism
teristics, it does tend to exhibit a general
point of view that resonates with postmod- Critical realism (CR) is a largely British
ernism. Postmodernism takes seriously the philosophy developed by Roy Bhaskar
idea that reality (to the extent that we can ([1975]/1997, [1979]/1998, 1986) and others
speak of reality as an independent state) only (e.g., Archer 1995; Collier 1994; Sayer
comes into practical existence insofar as it is [1992]/1997, 2001) that offers a ‘third way’
encoded in representations of social actors. between positivism and postmodernism. In
Thus, postmodernism considers representa- contrast to both approaches, it begins with
tions of reality (and the relationships among the ontological nature of the objects under
them), rather than reality itself (and the rela- study, which then determines their proper
tionship of representations to it), as the cru- epistemology (i.e., how they can be known),
cial objects of study. The earliest proponents rather than the other way around (termed the
of the new institutionalism called into ques- ‘epistemic fallacy’). CR has become increas-
tion the independent existence of the techni- ingly popular among social theorists and
cal realities of organizational structures and practitioners. However, it has only recently
practices. They considered many organiza- begun to make headway into the organization
tional structures and practices to be rational- studies and management literature (e.g.,
ized myths that took on the appearance of Ackroyd and Fleetwood 2000; Ekström
reality and were taken for granted as such. 1992; Reed 2005).
Thus, educational organizations adopted Similar to the social mechanisms
structures and practices prevalent in business approach, CR provides an explanatory
organizations because they were assumed to framework based upon the identification of
IS THE NEW INSTITUTIONALISM A THEORY? 759

the mechanisms that produce the organiza- actors, institutional logics will unfold in the
tional phenomena observed by researchers. domain of [the] actual as institutions.
In contrast to their approach, however, CR Institutions are the results of the ways in
provides a stratified social ontology distin- which actors transpose those institutional
guishing between the levels of the real, the logics through precise scripts, rules, and
actual, and the empirical. Acknowledging norms in specific contexts’ (2006: 632).
that all social phenomena operate in open The identification of these abstract causal
systems, these distinctions allow critical powers, the institutional logics, is carried
realists to explain why a particular mecha- out by organization researchers through
nism that is ‘in play,’ so to speak, may only a process of retroductive logic. Following
be contingently actualized and empirically Sayer (1992), Leca and Naccache (2006:
identified. Hence, the powers of generative 635; also see Bhaskar [1975]/1997) note
mechanisms operate ‘transfactually’ in open that there is a three stage process where
systems and may not be realized due to the researchers observe connections or regulari-
operation of countervailing causes (i.e., other ties that have been actualized in an institu-
mechanisms). That is, their powers ‘may be tion, build hypothetical models that might
possessed unexercised, exercised unrealized, account for the observed phenomena, and
and realized unperceived (or undetected) by then subject the models to empirical scrutiny.
[humans]’ (Bhaskar [1975]/1997: 184). By incorporating CR into the new institution-
Thus, the stratified ontology of CR may give alism they hope that this approach will be
a firmer grounding to Davis and Marquis’s able to ‘bring agency back into the institu-
(2005a: 336) invocation of Coleman’s notion tional framework without denying the crucial
of ‘sometimes-true theories.’ Furthermore, importance of institutional embeddedness
unlike Litchfield and Thompson’s view, and thus move beyond the vague notion of
which focuses on identifying empirical regu- institutional pressures to investigate the
larities, that is regularities that are actualized dialectical interplay between actors’ actions
and empirically observed, CR identifies the and institutional embeddedness’ (Leca and
important theoretical interest to lie at the Naccache 2006: 643; cf. Archer 1995).
level of the real. CR, then, appears to potentially provide
For example, Leca and Naccache (2006) the new institutionalism with an adequate
approach the NI from a critical realist per- response as to what their theory is. That is,
spective, providing a non-conflationist the various concepts, tendencies, and rela-
account of agency and structure in their tionships that make up the new institutional-
analysis of institutional entrepreneurship. ism refer to the generative mechanisms
Corresponding to the three domains identi- (consisting of both ‘things’ and ‘relation-
fied by CR, they place the actor’s experience ships’) of complex organizations that, in
at the domain of the empirical, institutions at open systems, may or may not be actualized
the domain of the actual, and institutional and are contingently empirically identified
logics at the level of the real. At the level of by social scientists. Since social scientists
the empirical, organization researchers are will never be able to construct a completely
interested in interpreting the subjective closed system, theory choice must be
meanings actors give to their activity through decided by explanatory power, rather than
discourse analysis. At the level of the actual, empirical prediction, although this will
institutions can be identified, even if actors certainly remain an important, but not final,
do not recognize them because they have criterion. A general theory is justified
become taken-for granted. Finally, the insti- because complex organizations share similar
tutional logics that underlie and shape insti- powers and liabilities across an array of orga-
tutions lie at the level of the real. ‘Depending nizational domains, from hospitals to corpo-
upon contextual factors and the actions of rations, from schools to the criminal justice
760 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

system; the same mechanisms (e.g., loose- with the emerging critical realist perspective,
coupling or isomorphic pressures) are at which seeks to carve out a middle ground
work. Finally, institutional processes, which between positivism and postmodernism.
have received less examination in the Clearly there is much that can be
new institutionalism than they deserve done to move the new institutionalism further
(Barley and Tolbert 1997), such as in the direction of a theory in all four senses
institutionalization and deinstitutionaliza- of that term. A theoretical understanding of
tion, might be profitably explored through the micro-level has only been weakly
the ‘morphogenetic approach’ devel- developed by the new institutionalism. For
oped by Archer (1995; Willmott 2000; Mutch example, we think that it would useful to
2005). Nevertheless, it seems that critical build upon the sociology of culture
realism may be open to the same problem (DiMaggio 1997), to improve our under-
as the social mechanisms perspective if standing of categories such as conventions
the process of ‘reappraisal’ is not expli- and scripts (Biggart and Beamish 2003),
citly incorporated into its theoretical and to engage with symbolic interactionism,
approach. dramaturgical, ethnomethodological and
other interactionist theories that presume
institutionalized understandings that are
necessary for temporal stability in social
CONCLUSION interaction.
The question in our minds is how much
Is the new institutionalism, after 30 years, further should the new institutionalism go?
fulfilling its promise as a theory in Litchfield As children in the US, we were told that if we
and Thompson’s terms? Our answer is a were to dig deep enough, we would end up in
qualified ‘yes.’ The new institutionalism has China. That is, we would end up not at the
developed a multitude of measurable con- center of things, but rather in different even
cepts and empirically verifiable relationships antagonistic place. We think this just might
to describe and explain organizational phe- be the case with theories. At some point,
nomena. The new institutionalism also attempts to develop a theoretical orientation,
appears to be one of the most general and to make it more elaborate, more general,
comprehensive theories plied by organiza- more comprehensive, and more encompass-
tional scholars today; arguably more general ing of other modes of theorizing threatens to
and comprehensive than a number of theories transform it into something else, its theoreti-
that came before it such as the resource cal competitors. For example, it seems
dependence and population ecology possible that attempts to build up the new
perspectives. And cumulative growth in the institutionalism’s currently underdeveloped
new institutionalism, resulting partly from understanding of individual level phenome-
empirical research, can be detected. Is the non by drawing more on psychology
new institutionalism a theory in other senses and social psychology might result not
of the term as well? Again, our answer is a in the articulation of new ideas but rather the
qualified ‘yes.’ It has been used as a library re-labeling (as new institutional) of old
from which researchers can borrow social ideas. Thus we think that new institutional
mechanisms to explain organizational scholars should remain alert to the
phenomena. And that branch of the new possibility that they are engaging in
institutionalism that seeks to uncover the semantic games and stay focused on the
operation of taken-for-granted cognitive goal of identifying truly new insights
structures resonates with the main tenets of about behavior in and of organizations as
postmodernism. Finally, the general orienta- they deepen and expand the scope of NI
tion of the new institutionalism is compatible theory.
IS THE NEW INSTITUTIONALISM A THEORY? 761

REFERENCES occupational jurisdiction.’ American Journal


of Sociology, 109: 720–52.
Abbott, Andrew. 1983. ‘Sequences of social Berger, Peter and Thomas Luckmann. 1966.
events.’ Historical Methods, 16: 129–47. The Social Construction of Reality. New York:
Ackroyd, Stephen and Steve Fleetwood (eds.) Anchor Books.
2000. Realist Perspectives on Management Bhaskar, Roy. [1975]/1997. A Realist Theory of
and Organizations. London: Routledge. Science, 2nd edn. London: Verso.
Agger, Ben. 1991. ‘Critical theory, poststruc- Bhaskar, Roy. [1979]/1998. The Possibility of
turalism, postmodernism: Their sociological Naturalism: A Philosophical Critique of the
relevance.’ Annual Review of Sociology, 17: Contemporary Human Sciences, 3rd edn.
105–31. London: Routledge.
Aldrich, H. and J. Pfeffer 1976. ‘Environments Bhaskar, Roy. 1986. Scientific Realism and
of organizations.’ Annual Review of Human Emancipation. London: Verso.
Sociology, 2: 79–105. Biggart, Nicole Woolsey and Thomas D.
American Political Science Association (APSA). Beamish. 2003. ‘The economic sociology of
2005. ‘100th APSA Annual Meeting atten- conventions: Habit, custom, practice, and
dees offer evaluations and suggestions.’ routine in market order.’ Annual Review of
Available online at: <http://journals. Sociology, 29: 443–64
cambridge.org/download.php?file=%2FPSC Biggart, Nicole Woolsey and Rick Delbridge.
%2FPSC38_01%2FS1049096505056155a. 2004. ‘Systems of exchange.’ Academy of
pdf&code=abc951fb0025c201799cf8f4155 Management Review, 29: 28–49.
84175>. Biggart, Nicole Woolsey and Mauro F. Guillén.
Archer, Margaret. 1995. Realist Social Theory: 1999. ‘Developing difference: Social organi-
The Morphogenetic Approach. Cambridge: zation and the rise of the auto industries of
Cambridge University Press. South Korea, Taiwan, Spain, and Argentina.’
Augier, Mie, James G. March, and Bilian Ni American Sociological Review, 64: 722–47.
Sullivan. 2005. ‘Notes on the evolution of a Biggart, Nicole Woolsey and Gary G. Hamilton.
research community: Organization studies in 1987. ‘An institutional theory of leadership.’
anglophone North America, 1945–2000.’ The Journal of Applied Behavioral Science,
Organization Science, 16: 85–95. 23: 429–41.
Barley, Stephen R. 1986. ‘Technology as an Boli, John, Francisco O. Ramirez, and John W.
occasion for structuring: Evidence from Meyer. 1985. ‘Explaining the origins and
observations of CT scanners and the expansion of mass education.’ Comparative
social order of radiology departments.’ Education Review, 29: 145–70.
Administrative Science Quarterly, 31: Brandes, Pamela, Michael Hadani, and Maria
78–108. Goranova. 2006. ‘Stock options expensing:
Barley, Stephen R. and Pamela S. Tolbert. 1997. An examination of agency and institutional
‘Institutionalization and structuration: theory.’ Journal of Business Research, 59:
Studying the links between action and insti- 595–60.
tution.’ Organization Studies, 18: 93–117. Burt, Ronald. 1980. ‘Autonomy in a social
Battilana, Julie. 2006. ‘Agency and institutions: typology,’ American Journal Sociology, 85:
The enabling role of individuals’ social posi- 892–925.
tion.’ Organization, 13: 653–76. Campbell, John. L. 1998. ‘Institutional analysis
Baum, Joel A. C. and Christine Oliver. 1991. and the role of ideas in political economy.’
‘Institutional linkages and organizational Theory and Society, 27: 377–409.
mortality.’ Administrative Science Quarterly, Christmann, Petra and Glen Taylor. 2006. ‘Firm
36: 187–218. self-regulation through international certifi-
Baum, Joel A. C. and Christine Oliver. 1992. able standards: Determinants of symbolic
‘Institutional embeddedness and the dynam- versus substantive implimentation.’ Journal
ics of organizational populations.’ American of International Business Studies, 37:
Sociological Review, 57: 540–59. 863–78.
Bechky, Beth A. 2003. ‘Object lessons: Clemens, Elisabeth S. 1993. ‘Organizational
Workplace artifacts as representations of repertoires and institutional change: Women’s
762 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

groups and the transformation of U.S. politics, Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis.


1890–1920. American Journal of Sociology, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 267–92.
98: 755–98. DiMaggio, Paul J. 1995. ‘Comments on ‘What
Coase, Ronald H. 1937. ‘The nature of the theory is not’.’ Administrative Science
firm.’ Economica, 4: 386–405. Quarterly, 40: 391–7.
Cohen, James. 1968. ‘Multiple regression as a DiMaggio, Paul. 1997. ‘Culture and cognition.’
general data-analytic system.’ Psychological Annual Review of Sociology, 23: 263–87.
Bulletin, 70: 426–43. DiMaggio, Paul J. and A. Mullen. 2000.
Cohen, Michael, James G. March and Johan P. ‘Enacting community in progressive America:
Olsen. 1972. ‘A garbage can model of orga- Civic rituals in National Music Week, 1924.’
nizational choice.’ Administrative Science Poetics, 27: 135–62.
Quarterly, 17 (1): 1–25. DiMaggio, Paul J. and Walter W. Powell.
Collier, Andrew. 1994. Critical Realism: An [1983]/1991. ‘The iron cage revisited:
Introduction to Roy Bhaskar’s Philosophy. Institutional isomorphism and collective
London: Verso. rationality in organizational fields.’ Reprinted
Davis, Gerald F. 2005. ‘Firms and environ- in Walter W. Powell and Paul J. DiMaggio
ments.’ In Neil J. Smelser and Richard (eds.), The New Institutionalism in Organiza-
Swedberg (eds.), The Handbook of Economic tional Analysis. Chicago: University of
Sociology. Princeton: Princeton University Chicago Press, 63–82.
Press, 478–502. DiMaggio, Paul J. and Walter W. Powell. 1991.
Davis, Gerald F. 2006. ‘Mechanisms and ‘Introduction.’ In Walter W. Powell and Paul
the theory of organizations.’ Journal of J. DiMaggio (eds.), The New Institutionalism
Management Inquiry, 15: 114–18. in Organizational Analysis. Chicago:
Davis,, Gerald and Henrich Greve. 1997. University of Chicago Press, 1–38.
‘Corporate elite networks and governance Dobbin, Frank. 1997. ‘How policy shapes
changes in the 1980s.’ Administrative competition: Early railroad foundings in
Science Quarterly, 44: 215–39. Massachusetts.’ Administrative Science
Davis, Gerald F. and Christopher Marquis. Quarterly, 42: 501–29.
2005a. ‘Prospects for organization theory in Dobbin, Frank. 2000. ‘The market that
the early twenty-first century: Institutional antitrust built: Public policy, private coercion,
fields and mechanisms.’ Organization and railroad acquisitions.’ American
Science, 16: 332–43. Sociological Review, 65: 631–57.
Davis, Gerald F. and Christopher Marquis. Dobbin, Frank and John Sutton. 1998. ‘The
2005b. ‘The globalization of stock markets strength of a weak state: The employment
and convergence in corporate governance.’ In rights revolution and the rise of human
Richard Swedberg and Victor Nee (eds.), The resource management divisions.’ American
Economic Sociology of Capitalism. Princeton: Journal of Sociology, 104: 441–76.
Princeton University Press, 352–90. Drori, Gili, Yong Suk Jang, and John W. Meyer.
Davis, Gerald F., Doug McAdam, W. Richard 2006. ‘Sources of rationalized governance:
Scott, and Mayer N. Zald (eds.), 2005. Social Cross-national longitudinal analyses, 1985–
Movements and Organization Theory. New 2002.’ Administrative Science Quarterly, 51:
York: Cambridge University Press. 205–29.
Deephouse, David. 1996. ‘Does isomorphism Edelman, Lauren. 1992. ‘Legal ambiguity and
legitimate?’ Academy of Management symbolic structures: Organizational media-
Journal, 39: 1024–1039. tion of civil rights.’ American Journal of
Deetz, Stanley. 2000. ‘Putting the community Sociology, 95: 1401–40.
into organizational science: Exploring Ekström, Mats. 1992. ‘Causal explanation of
the construction of knowledge claims.’ social action: The contribution of Max Weber
Organization Science, 11: 732–738. and of critical realism to a generative view of
DiMaggio, Paul J. 1991. ‘Constructing an orga- causal explanation in social science.’ Acta
nizational field as a professional project: U.S. Sociologica, 35: 107–22.
art museums, 1920–1940.’ In Walter W. Elsbach, Kimberly D. 1994. ‘Managing organi-
Powell and Paul J. DiMaggio (eds.), The New zational legitimacy in the California cattle
IS THE NEW INSTITUTIONALISM A THEORY? 763

industry: The construction and effectiveness standards: The case of Sun Microsystems and
of verbal accounts.’ Administrative Science Java.’ Academy of Management Journal, 45:
Quarterly, 39: 57–88. 196–214.
Elsbach, Kimberly D. and Roderick M. Kramer. Garud, Raghu and Arun Kumaraswamy. 1995.
1996. ‘Members’ responses to organizational ‘Technological and organizational designs
identity threats: Encountering and countering for realizing economies of substitution.’
the business week rankings.’ Administrative Strategic Management Journal, 16: 93–109.
Science Quarterly, 41: 442–76. Gaventa, John. 1982. Power and Powerlessness:
Fernandez-Alles, Mariluz, Gloria Cuevas- Quiescence and Rebellion in an Appalachian
Rodriguez and Ramon Valle-Cabera. 2006. Valley. Urbana: University of Illinois Press.
‘How symbolic remuneration contributes to George, Elizabeth, Prithviraj Chattopadhyay,
the legitimacy of the company: An institu- Sim B. Sitkin, and Jeff Barden. 2006.
tional explanation.’ Human Relations, 59: ‘Cognitive underpinnings of institutional per-
961–92. sistence and change: A framing perspective.’
Fiss, Peer C. and Edward J. Zajac. 2004. ‘The Academy of Management Review, 31:
symbolic management of strategic change: 347–65.
Sensegiving via framing and decoupling.’ Gendron, Yves, Roy Suddaby, and Helen Lam.
Academy of Management Journal, 6: 2006. ‘An examination of the ethical com-
1173–93. mitment of professional accountants to audi-
Fiss, Peer C. and Edward J. Zajac. 2006. ‘The tor independence.’ Journal of Business
diffusion of ideas over contested terrain: The Ethics, 64: 169–93.
(non) adoption of a shareholder value orien- Greenwood, Royston and Roy Suddaby. 2006.
tation among German firms.’ Administrative ‘Institutional entrepreneurship in mature
Science Quarterly, 49: 501–34. fields: The Big Five accounting firms.’
Fligstein, Neil. 1985. ‘The spread of the multi- Academy of Management Journal, 49:
divisional form among large firms, 27–48.
1919–1979.’ American Sociological Review, Greenwood, Royston, Roy Suddaby, and C. R.
50: 377–91. Hinings. 2002. ‘Theorizing change: The role
Fligstein, Neil. 1987. ‘The intraorganizational of professional associations in the transfor-
power struggle: Rise of finance personnel mation of institutionalized fields.’ Academy
to top leadership in large corporations, of Management Journal, 45: 58–80.
1919–1979.’ American Sociological Review, Gmür, Markus. 2003. ‘Co-citation analysis and
52: 44–58. the search for invisible colleges: A method-
Fligstein, Neil. 1990. The Transformation of ological evaluation.’ Scientometrics, 57:
Corporate Control. Cambridge, MA: Harvard 27–57.
University Press. Greif, Avner. 1994. ‘Cultural beliefs and the
Fligstein, Neil. 1996. ‘Markets as politics: A organization of society: A historical and the-
political-cultural approach to market institu- oretical reflection on collectivist and individ-
tions.’ American Sociological Review, 61: ualist societies.’ Journal of Political Economy,
656–73. 102: 912–50.
Fligstein, Neil. 1997. ‘Social skill and institu- Grodal, Stine. 2006. ‘The co-evolution of
tional theory.’ American Behavioral Scientist, labels, resources, and meaning in nanotech-
40: 397–405. nology.’ Working paper, School of
Fligstein, Neil and Kenneth Dauber. 1989. Management Science and Engineering,
‘Structural change in corporate organization.’ Stanford University.
Annual Review of Sociology, 15: 73–96. Guillén, Mauro F. 2000. ‘Organized labor’s
Fligstein, Neil and Robert Freeland. 1992. images of multinational enterprise:
‘Theoretical and comparative perspectives on Divergent foreign investment ideologies in
corporate organization.’ Annual Review of Argentina, South Korea, and Spain.’
Sociology, 21: 21–43. Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 53:
Garud, Raghu, S. Jain and Arun Kumaraswamy. 419–42.
2002. ‘Institutional entrepreneurship in the Guillén, Mauro F. 2006. The Taylorized Beauty
sponsorship of common technological of the Mechanical: Scientific Mangement
764 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

and the Rise of Modernist Architecture. models’: Is sociology in danger of being


Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. seduced by economics?’ Theory and Society,
Guler, Isin, Mauro F. Guillén, and John Muir 16: 317–36.
Macpherson. 2002. ‘Global competition, Hodgson, Geoffrey M. 1998. ‘The approach
institutions, and the diffusion of organiza- of institutional economics.’ Journal of
tional practices: The international spread of Economic Literature, 36: 166–92.
ISO 9000 quality certificates.’ Administrative Human, Sherrie E. and Keith G. Provan. 2000.
Science Quarterly, 47: 207–32. ‘Legitimacy building in the evolution of small-
Hagan, John, John D. Hewitt, and Duane F. firm multilateral networks: A com-
Alwin. 1979. ‘Ceremonial justice: Crime and parative study of success and demise.’
punishment in a loosely coupled system.’ Administrative Science Quarterly, 45: 327–65.
Social Forces, 58: 506–27. Jennings, P. Devereaux and Royston
Hannan, Michael T. and John Freeman. 1977. Greenwood. 2003. ‘Constructing the iron
‘The population ecology of organizations.’ cage: Institutional theory and enactment.’ In
American Journal of Sociology, 82: 929–64. Robert Westwood and Stewart Clegg (eds.),
Hardy, Cynthia and Stewart R. Clegg. Debating Organization: Point-Counterpoint
[1996]/1999. ‘Some dare call it power.’ In in Organization Studies. Malden, MA:
Stewart R. Clegg and Cynthia Hardy (eds.), Blackwell Publishing, 195–207.
Studying Organization: Theory & Method. Jepperson, Ronald L. 1991. ‘Institutions, insti-
London: Sage Publications, 368–87. tutional effects, and institutionalism.’ In
Hargadon, Andrew B. and Douglas Yellowlees. Walter W. Powell and Paul J. DiMaggio
2001. ‘When innovations meet institutions: (eds.), The New Institutionalism in Organiza-
Edison and the design of the electric light.’ tional Analysis. Chicago: University of
Administrative Science Quarterly, 46: Chicago Press, 143–63.
476–501. Kilduff, Martin and Ajay Mehra. 1997.
Haunschild, Pamela and Anne Miner. 1997. ‘Postmodernism and organizational
‘Modes of interorganizational imitation: the research.’ The Academy of Management
effects of outcome salience and uncertainty.’ Review, 22: 453–81.
Administrative Science Quarterly, 42: Kogut, Bruce and Andrew Spicer. 2002.
475–500. ‘Capital market development and mass pri-
Hedström, Peter and Richard Swedberg (eds.), vatizaton are logical contradictions: Lesson
1998. Social Mechanisms: An Analytical from the Czech Republic and Russia,’
Approach to Social Theory. Cambridge: Industrial and Corporate Change, 11: 1–37.
Cambridge University Press. Latour, Bruno. 1987. Science in Action: How to
Hirsch, Paul M. 1975. ‘Organizational effective- Follow Scientists and Engineers Through
ness and the institutional environment.’ Society. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University
Administrative Science Quarterly, 20: 327–44. Press.
Hirsch, Paul M. 1986. ‘From ambushes to Latour, Bruno and Steve Woolgar. [1979]/1986.
golden parachutes: Corporate takeovers as Laboratory Life: The [Social] Construction of
an instance of cultural framing and institu- Scientific Facts, 2nd edn. Princeton, NJ:
tional integration.’ The American Journal of Princeton University Press.
Sociology, 102: 1702–23. Lawrence, P. and J. Lorsch 1967. Organization
Hirsch, Paul M. 1997. ‘Review: Sociology with- and Environment. Cambridge, MA: Harvard
out social structure: Neoinstitutional theory University Press.
meets brave new world.’ The American Leca, Bernard and Philippe Naccache. 2006. ‘A
Journal of Sociology, 102: 1702–23. critical realist approach to institutional entre-
Hirsch, Paul M., Ray Friedman, and Mitchell P. preneurship.’ Organization, 13: 627–51.
Koza. 1990. ‘Collaboration or paradigm Lecours, Andre (ed.), 2005. New Institutional-
shift?: Caveat emptor and the risk of romance ism: Theory and Analysis. Toronto: University
with economic models for strategy and policy of Toronto Press.
research.’ Organization Science, 1: 87–97. Levitt, Barbara and Clifford Nass. 1989. ‘The lid
Hirsch, Paul M., Stuart Michaels, and Ray on the garbage can: Institutional constraints
Friedman. 1987. ‘’Dirty hands’ versus ‘clean on decision making in the technical core of
IS THE NEW INSTITUTIONALISM A THEORY? 765

college-text publishers.’ Administrative Organizations. San Francisco: Jossey-Bass,


Science Quarterly, 34: 190–207. 78–109.
Lieberman, Robert C. 2002. ‘Ideas, institutions Mezias, Stephen J. 1990. ‘An institutional
and political order: Explaining political model of organizational practice: Finan-
change.’ American Political Science Review, cial reporting at the Fortune 200.’
96: 697–712. Administrative Science Quarterly, 35: 431–57.
Litchfield, Edward H. 1956. ‘Notes on a general Milgrom, Paul and John Roberts. 1992.
theory of administration.’ Administrative Economics, Organization and Management.
Science Quarterly, 1: 3–29. Englewoods Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.
Lukes, Stephen. 2005. Power: A Radical View. Mintzberg, H. 1971. ‘Managerial work:
Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan. Analysis from observation.’ Management
Lutz, Frank W. 1982. ‘Tightening up loose cou- Science, 18: B97–B110.
pling in organizations of higher education. Mizruchi, Mark S. and Lisa C. Fein. 1999. ‘The
Administrative Science Quarterly, 27: social construction of organizational knowl-
653–69. edge: A study of the uses of coercive,
Macguire, S., Cynthia Hardy, and T.B. Lawrence. mimetic, and normative isomorphism.’
2004. ‘Institutional entrepreneurship in Administrative Science Quarterly, 44: 653–83.
emerging fields: HIV? AIDS Treatment advo- Mohr, John and V. Duquenne. 1997. ‘The dual-
cacy in Canada.’ Academy of Management ity of culture and practice: Poverty relief in
Journal, 47: 657–79. New York City, 1888–1917.’ Theory and
Mahoney, James and Dietrich Rueschemeyer Society, 26: 305–56.
(eds.). 2003. Comparative Historical Analysis Mutch, Alistair. 2005. ‘Discussion of Willmott:
in the Social Sciences. Cambridge: Cambridge Critical realism, agency and discourse: Moving
University Press. the debate forward.’ Organization, 12: 781–6.
March, James G. and Herbert Simon. Nelson, Richard R. and Sidney G. Winter. 1982.
[1958]/1993. Organizations. Cambridge, An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change.
MA: Blackwell Publishers. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press of Harvard
Martin, Joanne. 1990. ‘Deconstruction organi- University Press.
zational taboos: The suppression of gender Ocasio, William. 1999. ‘Institutional action and
conflict in organizations.’ Organization corporate governance: The reliance on rules
Science, 1: 339–59. of corporate succession.’ Administrative
Mayer, Kyle and J., Salomon, R. 2006. Science Quarterly, 44: 384–416.
‘Capabilities, contractual hazard and gover- Oliver, Christine. 1992. ‘The antecedents of
nance: Integrating resource-based and trans- deinstitutionalization.’ Organization Studies,
action cost perspectives.’ Academy of 13: 563–88.
Management Journal, 49: 942–59. Orrü, Marco, Nicole Woolsey Biggart, and Gary
Meyer, John W. 1977. ‘The effects of education G. Hamilton. 1997. The Economic Organiza-
as an institution.’ The American Journal of tion of East Asian Capitalism. Thousand
Sociology, 83: 55–77. Oaks, CA: Sage Publications.
Meyer, John W. and Ronald L. Jepperson. 2000. Orton, Douglas J. and Karl E. Weick. 1990.
‘The ‘actors’ of modern society: The cultural ‘Loosely coupled systems: A reconceptualiza-
construction of social agency’ Sociological tion.’ Academy of Management Review, 15:
Theory, 18: 100–20. 103–23.
Meyer, John W. and Brian Rowan. [1977]/1991. Palmer, Donald, Brad M. Barber, Xueguang
‘Institutionalized organizations: Formal struc- Zhou, and Yasemin Soysal. 1995. ‘The
ture as myth and ceremony.’ Reprinted in friendly and predatory acquisitions of large
Walter W. Powell and Paul J. DiMaggio U.S. corporations in the 1960s: The other
(eds.), 1991, The New Institutionalism in contested terrain.’ American Sociological
Organizational Analysis. Chicago: University Review, 60: 469–99.
of Chicago Press, 41–62. Palmer, Donald, P. Devereaux Jennings, and
Meyer, John W. and Brian Rowan. 1978. Xueguang Zhou. 1993. ‘Late adoption of the
‘The structure of educational organizations.’ multidivisional form,’ Administrative Science
In M. W. Meyer (ed.). Environments and Quarterly, 37: 100–31.
766 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Palmer, Donald and Nicole Biggart. 2002. Rao, Hayagreeva, Henrich R. Greve, and Gerald
‘Organizational institutions.’ In Joel A. C. F. Davis. 2001. ‘Fool’s gold: Social proof and
Baum (ed.), The Blackwell Companion to the initiation and abandonment of coverage
Organizations. Oxford: Blackwell, 78–109. by Wall Street analysts.’ Administrative
Parsons, Talcott. 1951. The Social System. New Science Quarterly, 46: 502–26.
York: The Free Press. Reed, Michael I. 2005. ‘Reflections on the ‘real-
Parsons, Talcott. 1956a. ‘Suggestions for a ist turn’ in organization and management
sociological approach to the theory of studies.’ Journal of Management Studies,
organizations, I.’ Administrative Science 42: 1621–44.
Quarterly, 1: 63–85. Ruef, Martin and W. Richard Scott. 1998. ‘A
Parsons, Talcott. 1956b. ‘Suggestions for a multidimensional model of organizational
sociological approach to the theory of legitimacy: Hospital survival in changing
organizations, II.’ Administrative Science institutional environments.’ Administrative
Quarterly, 1: 225–39. Science Quarterly, 43: 877–904.
Parsons, Talcott. 1961. Structure and Process in Rutherford, Malcom. 2001. ‘Institutional eco-
Modern Societies. Glencoe, IL: Free Press. nomics: Then and now.’ The Journal of
Perrow, Charles. 1985. ‘Review Essay: Economic Perspectives, 15: 173–94.
Overboard with Myth and Symbols.’ Sayer, Andrew. [1992]/1997. Method in Social
American Journal of Sociology, 91: 151–5. Science: A Realist Approach, 2nd edn.
Perrow, Charles. 1999. ‘Organizing to reduce London: Taylor and Francis Group.
the vulnerabilities of complexity.’ Journal of Sayer, Andrew. 2001. Realism and Social
Contingencies and Crisis Management, 7: Science. London: Sage Publications.
150–5. Schneper, William and Mauro Guillén. 2004.
Perrow, Charles. 2000. ‘An organizational analy- ‘Stakeholder rights and corporate governance:
sis of organizational theory.’ Contemporary A cross-national study of hostile takeovers.’
Sociology, 29: 469–76. Administrative Science Quarterly, 49: 263–95.
Pfeffer, J. 1976. ‘Beyond management and the Scott, W. Richard. 1987. ‘The adolescence of
worker: The institutional function of man- institutional theory.’ Administrative Science
agement.’ Academy of Management Quarterly, 32: 493–511.
Review, 1: 36–46. Scott, W. Richard. 2001. Institutions and
Pfeffer, Jeffrey. 1993. ‘Barriers to the advance Organizations, 2nd edn. Thousand Oaks,
of organizational science: Paradigm develop- CA: Sage Publications.
ment as a dependent variable.’ Academy of Scott, W. Richard. 2005. ‘Institutional theory:
Management Review, 18: 599–620. Contributing to a theoretical research pro-
Pfeffer, Jeffrey. 1995. ‘Mortality, reproducibility, gram.’ In Ken G. Smith and Michael A Hitt
and the persistence of styles of theory.’ (eds.), Great Minds in Management: The
Organization Science, 6: 681–6. Process of Theory Development. New York:
Pfeffer, Jeffrey and Gerald R. Salancik. Oxford University Press, 460–84.
[1978]/2003. The External Control of Scott, W. Richard. Forthcoming. ‘Approaching
Organizations: A Resource Dependence adulthood: The maturing of institutional
Perspective. Stanford, CA: Stanford theory.’ Theory and Society.
University Press. Scott, W. Richard and John W. Meyer.
Pickering, Andrew. 1992. Science as Practice. [1983]/1991. ‘The organization of societal
Chicago: University of Chicago Press. sectors: Propositions and early evidence.’
Ramirez, Fransisco O. and John Boli. 1982. Reprinted in Walter W. Powell and Paul J.
‘Global patterns of educational institutional- DiMaggio (eds.), The New Institutionalism in
ization.’ In Philip Altbach, Robert Arnove, Organizational Analysis. Chicago: University
and Gail Kelly (eds.), Comparative Education. of Chicago Press, 108–40.
New York: Macmillan. Scott, Richard W., Martin Ruef, Peter J. Mendel,
Ramirez, Francisco O. and John W. Meyer. and Carol A. Caronna. 2000. Institutional
1980. ‘Comparative education: The social Change and Healthcare Organizations: From
construction of the modern world system.’ Professional Dominance to Managed Care.
Annual Review of Sociology, 6: 369–97. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
IS THE NEW INSTITUTIONALISM A THEORY? 767

Selznick, Philip. 1948. ‘Foundations of Administrative Theory. London, UK: Trans-


the theory of organization.’ American action Publishers.
Sociological Review, 13: 25–35. Thornton, Patricia H. and William Ocasio.
Selznick, Philip. 1949. TVA and The Grass Roots. 1999. ‘Institutional logics and the historical
Berkeley: University of California Press. contingency of power in organizations:
Selznick, Philip. 1957. Leadership in Adminis- Executive succession in the higher education
tration. New York: Harper & Row. industry, 1958–1990.’ The American Journal
Singh, Jitendra V., David J. Tucker, and Robert of Sociology, 105: 801–43.
House. 1986. ‘Organizational legitimacy and Tolbert, Pamela S. and Lynne G. Zucker. 1983.
the liability of newness.’ Administrative ‘Institutional sources of change in the formal
Science Quarterly, 31: 171–93. structure of organizations: The Diffusion of
Spicer, Andrew and Gerry McDermott and civil service reform, 1880–1935.’
Bruce Kogut. 2000. ‘Entrepreneurship and Administrative Science Quarterly, 28: 22–39.
privatization in Central Europe: The tenuous Tolbert, Pamela S. and Lynne G. Zucker.
balance between creation and destruction.’ [1996]/1999. ‘The institutionalization of
Academy of Management Review, 25: institutional theory.’ In Stewart R. Clegg and
630–49. Cynthia Hardy (eds.), Studying Organiza-
Stampnitzky, Lisa. 2006. ‘Fields, boundary tion: Theory & Method. London: Sage
spaces, and hybrid knowledges: The produc- Publications, 169–84.
tion of terrorism expertise in the contempo- Tyler, William. 1987. ‘‘Loosely coupled’ schools:
rary U.S.’ Paper presented at the American A structuralist critique.’ British Journal of
Sociological Association meeting in Sociology of Education, 8: 313–26.
Montreal, Canada. Van Maanen, John. 1995. ‘Style as theory.’
Stevens, J.M., H.K., Steensma, D.A. Harrison, Organization Science, 6: 133–43.
and P.L. Cochran. 2005. ‘Symbolic or sub- Veblen, Thorstein. [1899]/1979. The Theory of
stantive document? The influence of ethics the Leisure Class. New York: Penguin.
codes on financial executives.’ Strategic Ventresca, Mark and John Mohr. 2002.
Management Journal, 26: 181–95. ‘Archival research methods.’ In Joel Baum
Stinchcombe, Authur L. (ed.). 1965. ‘Social (ed.), The Blackwell Companion to Organiza-
strucutre and organizations.’ In James G. tions. Oxford: Blackwell, 805–28.
March, Handbook of Organizations. Walker, Gordon and David Weber. 1984. ‘A
Chicago: Rand McNally, 142–93. transaction cost approach to make-or-buy
Stuart, Toby E., Ha Hoang, and Ralph C. decisions,’ Administrative Science Quarterly,
Hybels. 1999. ‘Interorganizational endorse- 29: 373–91.
ments and the performance of entrepre- Weber, Max. 1968. Economy and Society. New
neurial ventures.’ Administrative Science York: Bedminster Press.
Quarterly, 44: 315–49. Weick, Karl E. 1976. ‘Educational organizations
Suchman, Mark C. 1995. ‘Managing legiti- as loosely coupled systems.’ Administrative
macy: Strategic and institutional Science Quarterly, 21: 1–19.
approaches.’ Academy of Management Weiss, Richard. 2000. ‘Taking science out of
Review, 20: 571–610. organization science: How would postmod-
Sutton, John R., Frank Dobbin, John W. Meyer, ernism reconstruct the analysis of organiza-
and W. Richard Scott. 1994. ‘The legalization tions?’ Organization Science, 11: 709–31.
of the workplace.’ The American Journal of Westphal, James D., Ranjay Gulati, and Steve
Sociology, 99: 944–71. Shortell. 1997. ‘Customization or conform-
Sutton, Robert I and Barry M. Staw. 1995. ity? An institutional and network perspective
‘What theory is not.’ Administrative Science on the content and consequences of TQM
Quarterly, 40: 371–84. adoption.’ Administrative Science Quarterly,
Thompson, James D. 1956. ‘On building an 42: 366–94.
administrative science.’ Administrative Westphal, James D. and Edward J. Zajac. 2001.
Science Quarterly, 1: 102–11. ‘Decoupling policy from practice: The case of
Thompson, James D. [1967]/2006. Organi- stock repurchase programs.’ Administrative
zations in Action: Social Science Bases of Science Quarterly, 46: 202–28.
768 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Williamson, Oliver. 1975. Markets and Hierar- Administrative Science Quarterly, 43:
chies: Analysis and Antitrust Implications. 602–36.
New York: Free Press. Zucker, Lynne G. [1977]/1991. ‘The role of
Williamson, Oliver. 1981. ‘The economics of institutionalization in cultural persistence.’
organization: The transaction cost Reprinted in Walter W. Powell and Paul J.
approach.’ American Journal of Sociology, DiMaggio (eds.), The New Institutionalism in
87: 548–77. Organizational Analysis. Chicago: University
Willmott, Robert. 2000. ‘The place of culture in of Chicago Press, 83–107.
organization theory: Introducing the morpho- Zucker, Lynne G. 1987. ‘Institutional theories of
genetic approach.’ Organization, 7: 95–128. organizations.’ Annual Review of Sociology,
Zbaracki, Mark J. 1998. ‘The rhetoric and 13: 443–64.
reality of total quality management.’
32
How to Misuse Institutions
and Get Away with It:
Some Reflections on
Institutional Theory(ies)
Barbara Czarniawska

THE ABUNDANCE OF DEFINITIONS rooms, buildings, or plants in which activity of


a particular kind regularly goes on’
The editors of this volume asked me to write (Goffman, 1961: 15, my italics). But Goffman
about the uses and misuses of institutional also spoke of ‘members of an institution’
theory – a quest that provided me with a per- (1961), which is closer to Mary Douglas’s
verse pleasure. In my reading, the most inter- suggestion that institutions are legitimized
esting interpretations of institutional theory social groupings (Douglas, 1986: 41).
result from the misuse of the term ‘institu- None of this, however, is close to what
tion’; in Latin that means a human, inten- Thorsten Veblen (1899) seemed to mean
tional act of creating and enacting some type when speaking of institutions. To begin with,
of collective practice. As noted by March and Veblen used the term ‘institution,’ assuming
Olsen (1989) in their overview of various that it did not require a definition: ‘The insti-
definitions of the word, this meaning is used tution of a leisure class is found in its best
primarily in law and economics. In the every- development at the higher stages of the
day meaning of the word (which enters barbarian culture’ (1899: 1); and ‘In the
almost every scholarly text), however, an sequence of cultural evolution the emergence
institution is a public administration organi- of a leisure class coincides with the begin-
zation. Another meaning, close to it, is the ning of ownership. This is necessarily the
Goffmanian definition: ‘Social establish- case, for these two institutions result from the
ments – institutions in the everyday sense of same set of economic forces’ (1899: 15).
that term – are places such as rooms, suites of Veblen was a cultural evolutionist, and
770 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

believed that people who act collectively barren in no time. As it is, institutional theory
form certain patterns of action that are even- is not a theory at all, but a framework, a
tually taken for granted. If they are contested vocabulary, a way of thinking about social
or broken, it results in normative justifica- life, which may take many paths. It would be
tions, corrections or/and sanctions. Such nor- my recommendation to attempt an institu-
matively justified patterns of action are tional theory account of institutional theory.
institutions. This is probably too large a task for a
Gabriel Tarde would have agreed, but single author or a single text, at least this
added that people also imitate one another; author and this text; the Reflection part of
after all, it was Tarde who launched the this volume consists, in fact, of contributions
notion of diffusion in social sciences. He did toward that purpose. My own input com-
not think, however, that ideas spread like par- prises three pieces that may be added to a
ticles; in his view, particles may spread the larger mosaic: a reflection on the local varia-
way ideas do, as he believed that natural sci- tions of institutional theory, a commentary
ences should borrow metaphors from social on the (mostly missing) connection between
sciences, not the other way around. institutions and technology, and a suggestion
Tarde is often seen as a ‘diffusionary evo- of possible gains from insights concerning
lutionist,’ as he differed from diffusionists institutions in literature theory.
(the early school in anthropology, repre-
sented by Franz Boas, 1904/1974) in noting
the variation inherent in each displacement,
and from evolutionists in pointing out the LOCAL TRANSLATIONS:
role of action, i.e. imitation. Thus he ‘SCANDINAVIAN INSTITUTIONALISM’
spoke of ‘evolution by association’ (Tarde,
1893/1999: 41) à la Stephen Jay Gould, or When the word got around that Steve Barley
‘diffusion by transformation.’ His influence and Pamela Tolbert (1997) had written about
is rarely acknowledged by the contemporary ‘European institutionalism,’ all of us in
institutionalists, however, as they seem to Scandinavia ran to check who and what
prefer his rival, Emile Durkheim. This incli- would be quoted. Much to our surprise, the
nation may change, as ‘Tardomania’ has sup- ‘European institutionalists’ turned out to be
posedly made an appearance, at least in Max Weber and Emile Durkheim and the
France, Italy, Germany, and Denmark contemporary writers were represented by
(Mucchielli, 2000; Latour, 2002). Anthony Giddens. Not for the first time
At this point, some readers may expect a we could observe that ‘local knowledge’
recommendation that the interested commu- seems to be of interest primarily when it
nity of scholars should mobilize, turning reproduces ‘global knowledge’, which is that
institutionalism into a ‘proper theory,’ with which circulates at any given time among
proper definitions of its subject and a set of many localities.
axioms and logically connected statements. Yet all local translators arrive at their own
This, in my view, would be the death of insti- version or versions of the global idea. Guje
tutional theory as we have learned to know Sevón and I coined the term ‘Scandinavian
and appreciate it. Apart from the fact that any institutionalism’ (Czarniawska and Sevón,
social theory would be killed by strict for- 1996) to denote works from Denmark,
malization, the strength of institutional Norway, and Sweden, written under the
theory lies in the tolerance of its propagan- influence of Richard W. Scott, James G.
dists. Here, I think, most thanks should be March, and John W. Meyer.1 What seemed
directed to Walter W. Powell and Paul J. to characterize this group of texts and
DiMaggio (1991). Had they insisted on authors was a common interest in the con-
policing the field, it would have turned struction and deconstruction of institutions
SOME REFLECTIONS ON INSTITUTIONAL THEORY(IES) 771

(institutionalization and deinstitutionaliza- transdisciplinary character of Scandinavian


tion) as the most fruitful way of conceptual- organization theory, with its roots in econom-
izing social order. ics and engineering, but also with
This interest may be seen as being shared strong links to sociology, psychology, and
by all social sciences, so further delimita- anthropology.
tions are needed. The Scandinavian transla- Field studies were rendering unequivocal
tors were mostly organization scholars, so results; it was action rather than decision that
the issue of organizing was of central interest was at the center of organizing (Brunsson,
to them. For many decades, organization 2007). As pointed out by March and Olsen
theory has been developed around the (1989), organizational action heeds the logic
rational theory of choice as applied to deci- of appropriateness, and not, as the theory of
sion making. This theory did a poor job of rational choice would have it, the logic of
explaining the results of studies conducted in consequentiality. Actions are decided on the
the field of organizational practice. To basis of actors’ classifications of the situation
explain why the Scandinavians exhibited in which they find themselves, as well as
such great interest in new institutional theory, their own identity. Logic of consequentiality
a few words on the tradition of organization or of rational choice is used to legitimize the
studies in Scandinavia are in order. actions undertaken, especially when ques-
To begin, Scandinavian organization theo- tioned. The combination of insights of one of
rists had traditionally had a strong interest the classic authors of decision-making theory
in the practice of organizing. Long before and a Norwegian political scientist resulted
Pierre Bourdieu legitimized ‘social practices’ in the theory that fit the data, as the
as the central study object, Scandinavian Scandinavians found them.
researchers studied ‘praxis’ (‘practices’ Why ‘new’ institutionalism? The ‘old’
cannot be used in plural in Scandinavian lan- institutionalism emphasized the central role
guages) of organized work. This interest led of norms and socialization processes, of rule
naturally to a great number of field studies, and role conflict, and revealed that rules
facilitated by easy access, especially to public and identities are taken for granted in a
sector organizations, where the transparency ‘normal attitude.’ Institutions could be thus
rule permitted researchers access to anything defined as collections of stable rules and
that was not classified as confidential. As a roles and corresponding sets of meanings and
result, perhaps, the approach has been interpretations.
strongly process-oriented, as opposed to New institutionalism, as presented by
structure-oriented. Powell and DiMaggio (1991), adopted the
Furthermore, in conscious opposition to centrality of the logic of appropriateness in
the universalizing tendencies, the researchers organizational action, and continued the
were taking the embeddedness of the prac- emphasis on rules and roles, as well as the
tices they studied very seriously indeed. This construction of meaning that occurs in organ-
focus did not make their interests parochial; izations. It also radicalized older approaches
indeed, connectedness was another typical by presenting identities as results of actions
trait of Scandinavian research (Czarniawska rather than their antecedents (see especially
and Sevón, 2003). Most authors are well Meyer, 1986); it dynamized them by focus-
versed in the North American tradition, albeit ing upon the process of rule development
they treat it critically; are familiar with (institutionalization); and it increased their
European developments; and, more recently, complexity by adding nuances to the theory
direct their curiosity to the remaining conti- of conflict.
nents, especially Asia and Australia. This It has been suggested by many critics,
practically demands a great openness to other however, that the issue of change was not
academic disciplines, and results in the properly explained by the new institutionalists.
772 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

It was understandable in light of the fact whereas routines create novelty by faulty
that the main thrust of the institutionalist reproduction.2
approach was to contradict traditional orga- This acknowledged ambiguity of change
nizational theory which, informed by rational was the focus of what we called a
choice theory, was based on the assumption Scandinavian institutionalism. It can be said
that change was an organizational norm. to have originated in the works of Johan
Stability, not change, was the norm, claimed Olsen and Nils Brunsson (see e.g. Olsen,
the institutionalists. 1970, 1989; Brunsson and Olsen, 1993).
Powell’s (1991) defense did not fully Many examples can be found in edited vol-
answer this criticism; he claimed that change umes such as Scott and Christensen, 1995;
must be treated as an exception rather than as Czarniawska and Sevón, 1996, 2003, 2005;
a rule. Although this insistence on stability or special issues of American Behavioral
over change can be seen as part of the Scientist, edited by Christensen, Karnøe,
provocative program of the new institutional- Pedersen, and Dobbin (1997) and
ism, a further glimpse into the roots of the Westenholz, Pedersen, and Dobbin (2006).
‘old’ institutionalism can be revealing. Born mainly in contact with the US new
Institutionalism’s philosophical roots are institutionalists, the Scandinavian institution-
usually be traced back to the Chicago school alism nevertheless reached for additional
of pragmatism, especially to George Herbert sources of inspiration, to be able to address
Mead (Aboulafia, 2001). Two of the authors the issue of change more fully. Change
who inspired Mead’s understanding of the and stability together were seen as an organi-
social world were the European psycholo- zational norm, and the logic of appropriate-
gist, Wilhelm Wundt, and the US psycholo- ness as complementary to the logic of
gist, James Watson, one of the founders of consequentiality.
behaviorism. The only dissension between Describing organizations as a combination
Mead and Watson was over the fact that the of change and stability assumed a paradoxi-
symbolic meaning of communication was cality in organizational life (in tune with
not included in Watson’s behaviorism. Thus Luhmann’s theory of autopoietic systems –
Watson’s approach, according to Mead, see Luhmann, 1986; and Seidl and Becker,
failed to incorporate what was truly human. 2005). The dynamic focus has been main-
They agreed, however, that institutions were tained; the processes that attract the attention
‘natural’ systems, and thus stable (see also of researchers are processes of identity for-
Scott, 1981). mation and deconstruction, rule establish-
Was this conception wrong? Of course ment and rule breaking, institutionalization
not – unless we permit the existence of and deinstitutionalization.
supernatural forces, all we know is natural. The emphasis on the processes of construc-
Culture, like people and everything else, is tion indicates another source of inspiration,
the product of nature. This does not give us which can be traced to the enormous popular-
an explanatory apparatus of any power, how- ity in Scandinavia of the works of
ever. In such light, population ecology would Peter Berger and Thomas Luckmann (1966,
be the only theory that made sense. 1995; Berger, Berger, and Kellner, 1974;
Unfortunately, this type of explanation did Luckmann, 1978), heirs of Alfred Schütz
not allow the Scandinavians to interpret what and his genial combination of European phe-
they were repeatedly witnessing in the field: nomenology and American pragmatism.
that, although ‘planned change’ never fully Considering Mead’s influence on US institu-
succeeds, people do persuade each other to tionalism (especially visible in the work of John
change their opinions, beliefs, and ways of Meyer, Walter Power, and Paul DiMaggio),
acting – and not only by mistake. The results the bridge was not difficult to assemble.
are paradoxical: planned change stabilizes, The constructivist version of institution
SOME REFLECTIONS ON INSTITUTIONAL THEORY(IES) 773

theory permitted the Scandinavians to con- by ‘real changes,’ thus maintaining an


tinue their tradition of organization studies, unnecessarily dualist view of organizations
consisting of fieldwork with the processual and producing an unintended impression that
focus. Their main interest remained the ques- symbolic changes are ‘unreal’ (for a critique
tion of how institutions emerge, change, and of such dualism, see Gagliardi, 2006).
vanish – not merely that they do. They Studies of science and technology, such as
offered a type of research complementing, on those by Latour and Woolgar (1979/1986),
the one hand, largely speculative historical Callon (1986), Callon and Latour (1981), and
research, such as that of Torstein Veblen, Knorr-Cetina (1981, 1994), revealed that
Gabriel Tarde, Thurman Arnold, and Michael objects and facts are socially constructed as
Oakeshott;3 and, on the other hand, the statis- much as symbols are; that all human knowl-
tical studies of the type for which John W. edge is social; and that, as much as it is sen-
Meyer and his collaborators are famous. sible and practical to believe that things exist
Thus Scandinavian research answers the even when nobody looks at them, it can never
need for micro-studies of institutions, as for- be ‘proven’ or ‘demonstrated’ that they exist.
mulated by Renate Meyer (2006). A growing Thus the adjective ‘social’ as in ‘social con-
collection of such studies will soon enable a structivism’ is obviously redundant. The
combination that seems desirable to me: a point is that, in spite of the appearances of
series of field studies documenting in micro- stability and many stabilizing mechanisms,
perspective institutionalization processes that among which is the emergence of institu-
require decades, if not yet centuries. tions, the reality is under constant construc-
What is needed, then, is a review of existing tion. In tune with Tarde’s postulates, but to
local translations of institutionalism. I am cer- the irritation of natural scientists, students of
tain there are others, but just as Renate Meyer science and technology have also demon-
(2006) did not know about the Scandinavian strated that the practice of natural science is
version, I have never heard of them. Revealing much closer to that of social sciences and
and recording them will permit the achieve- humanities than anyone suspected.
ment of two goals: creating a data basis of At the same time, the Society/Nature
micro-studies across places and times, and dichotomy was taken for granted in organiza-
applying institutional theory onto itself. More tion studies as in most social science, causing
of this in the second last section. notorious problems when confronting tech-
nology. Scholars in the Tavistock tradition
(e.g. Rice, 1958; Woodward, 1965) tried to
fill the gap by introducing the notion of
SOME THINGS MISSING? socio-technical systems. Yet conceptual
TECHNOLOGY AND INSTITUTIONS energy was focused on the ‘socio-,’ and the
notion remained firmly dualistic. The con-
Supporters of numerous variations of social cept was revived by some authors during
constructivism engaged in a fight against sci- sociology’s turn to technology throughout the
entistic realism try to demonstrate that 1980s (e.g. Mayntz, 1988; T. E. Burns and
people, not nature, construct culture; objects Dietz, 1991), but primarily within the same
were supposed to be ruled by different laws dichotomizing spirit, even if the ‘socio-’
than meanings are. In such interpretations, part of the term was enriched by notions
organizational life was seen as being rife of technological design and regulation.
with spiritual endeavors, and organizational Contingency theory within organization
change seemed to be a change in symbols theory started from a Tavistock perspective
and metaphors. The result was an unfortunate (Burns and Stalker, 1961), but ended by actu-
debate around the question of whether or not ally excluding physical technology through
those ‘symbolic changes’ were accompanied abstracting the notion of technology into task
774 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

structures of various kinds. And the new By envisioning organizations as action


institutionalism kept the distinction between nets transcending face-to-face interactions
‘institutional environments’ and ‘technical (Czarniawska, 2004), it is easy to see that the
environments’ (Meyer and Scott, 1981), a existence of any such action net requires a
clear echo of the traditional distinction stable lock into large technical systems. The
between administration and industry, but telephone connects to satellite-based global
problematic at a time when administration is telecommunications systems, the toaster to
run by computers, and engineering follows integrated electricity grids fed with nuclear
management fads. A need for dispensing energy, and wrist watches to a technical
with the dichotomy can be seen in the fol- system called World Time. These ubiquitous
lowing quote from Goodman and Sproull technical systems and their countless termi-
(1990), who concluded their overview of the nals are easily overlooked by the layperson
organization technology studies in the 1980s and the organization theorist. Where does
with: water come from? From the tap, of course.
Joerges and I introduced the argument
While there appears to be a movement to focus that, through time, various institutional
primarily on technology as socially constructed, we responsibilities have been partially trans-
feel that some balance is necessary. There are
issues that concern technology as a physical reality.
ferred to machine technologies, and therefore
These have not been well addressed and have partially removed from everyday awareness
implications for doing work on technology and (Joerges and Czarniawska, 1998). As organ-
organizations. ... We feel that a fruitful approach ized actions are externalized in machines,
would be to increase our understanding of both and as these machines grow more and more
the social and the physical aspects of technology ...
The real contribution, however, will be under-
complicated, norms and practices of organiz-
standing the intersection between both forms of ing progressively devolve into society’s
reality. (1990: 260–261) material base; inscribed in machines, institu-
tions are literally ‘black-boxed’ (Whitley,
One such contribution could be found in 1972). As a result, ‘technical norms’ or ‘rules
those approaches to science and technology of technology,’ although they regulate and
research in which nonhuman components order social life, remain absent from the
were conceptualized as social subjects of attention of social scientists. Social scientists
action and as autonomous political actors are interested in social norms; technical
(Callon, 1988; Latour, 1996). Bernward norms have, until recently, remained within
Joerges and I (1998) thought that technolo- the purview of engineers. Two things have
gies were better conceived of as instituti- happened recently, however: A series of
onalized organizing patterns than as catastrophes has reintroduced material tech-
organizational members. Trust in machinery nology as a central concern in organization
is ‘system trust’ (Giddens, 1990), as distinct studies (see e.g. Barry Turner, 1978/1997;
from personal trust. In other words, we Perrow, 1984; Weick, 1988; Vaughan, 1990;
extended to organizations Latour’s (1992) Shrivastava, 1993; Weick and Sutcliffe,
argument that ‘technology is society made 2001); and there is a growing interest among
durable.’ Technology makes organizing organization scholars in science and technol-
durable, thus contributing to the institutional ogy studies (see e.g. Czarniawska and
stability of one of its products – the modern Hernes, 2005), especially in the computer
organization – and through it many others. industry (see e.g. Lanzara and Mörner,
What is more, this process is circular; 2005).
modern organizations, as users of machines In order to get closer to the institutional
for producing machines and other artifacts, norms inscribed in the machines, one must
have the task of inscribing institutional order observe technical things functioning in their
into matter. ‘natural’ – that is, social – contexts. Again,
SOME REFLECTIONS ON INSTITUTIONAL THEORY(IES) 775

computers offer the most obvious examples, saw as being interrelated. We related them to
within and outside of organizations. When other, nontechnical genres of inscription:
we start the new PC we just bought, a smil- norms for human action, machine behavior,
ing face will welcome us and let us know and the natural environment.
what we are supposed to do, via a step- The first subgenre contains norms for
by-step action program. For those of us who human action, defining human rights and
have bought many a PC over the years, it duties vis-à-vis a machine or some other
comes as no surprise to see that the instructor material artifact: ‘Turn bottle cap clockwise.’
in the program is no longer a man and the The second subgenre has norms for machine
learner a woman; the virtual world does its behavior: DIN A4, for example, the stan-
best to follow the rules of political correct- dard-sized page for European copying
ness, with mixed results (Gustavsson and machines; or 220 V, the regulation voltage in
Czarniawska, 2004). Europe. Such norms prescribe the way spe-
Thus even such cases of intentional per- cific technical artifacts are to be constructed
sonal control are instances of institutional and how they are to function. The third sub-
control. The controlling power of technical genre consists of such norms for the natural
norms stems from the fact that a given prac- environment as emission and immission
tice has been incorporated into an artifact and limits for SO2 air pollution or the nitrate
therefore seems impossible to question. content of groundwater.
Technology is one of the ways in which soci- These examples show that technical norms
ety controls itself, socializes its members by are embedded in a complicated mesh of insti-
unobtrusive measures, and thereby con- tutions. All three types of norms are specified
stantly re-constructs itself. by various prescriptions for measuring and
Treating technical norms as social norms testing and are, in general, connected to a
of a particular kind does not imply a deter- multitude of interrelated procedural norms.
minist connection between the content of the In addition, technical norms are always refer-
technical and nontechnical norms they may ring back to nontechnical ones.
or may not promote. A computer in a matri- Organizations establish and maintain tech-
archal society would probably speak with a nical norms in relation to the environmental
female voice, but it would still be recruited technical norms, as well as norms for users
into supporting as well as subverting the and producers like themselves. Furthermore,
dominant institutional order. Rather than technical norms always evoke manifold ref-
unmasking particular power games or posit- erences to nontechnical institutionalized
ing deterministic structural relationships, the rules and cultural symbols (gender equality
idea that institutions are inscribed in technol- for example). As mentioned, the process is
ogy calls for something like an ‘eth- circular. Each machine norm implies a pro-
nomethodology of machines.’ What social ducer and a user norm, and each producer
order does the dialogue with our computers and user norm alludes to a machine norm.
follow, and try to instill in us? Similarly, each type of norm reflects certain
Technical norms are the institutional normative images present in the wider con-
structure of machinery. As such, they are text, and vice versa. These interconnections
inscribed by organizations: Inscriptions are best revealed in cases in which artifacts
made by non-organized agents (graffiti, a are moved outside the institutional context of
handwritten label on a homemade dish) are their production, as documented by the
not legitimate technical norms. Furthermore, anthropologists’ sense of wonder over the
technical norms contain an explicit or possible uses of Coca-Cola® cans in some
implicit reference to some quantitative meas- cultures (Sahlins, 2001).
ure. In our article, Joerges and I enumerated The divisions among the three types of
three subgenres of technical norms that we technical norms are in no way unambiguous.
776 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

In fact, their attribution to one class or the the new institutionalism, in order to live up to
other may be controversial, and in this sense their mission of explaining the social charac-
may remove their taken-for-grantedness. ter of the organizational world, need to
Blurring genres and redefining their bound- reflect on their own metaphors.
aries is an affair of politics (‘Who are those The issue at stake is much more than
computer guys to tell me what to do?’), jokes metaphorical purism. It is possible to trans-
(‘Be nice to your computer, or else!’), and late the physical metaphors of new institu-
experimentation (‘Let’s see if we can use it tionalism into literary categories as well as
this way instead’). In the everyday life of the other way around, each time producing
organizations, all three blend, and the effects some sort of creative displacement.4 In the
of that blending are pragmatically decided; case at hand, however, the replacement of
for some purposes it is important to keep physical metaphors by cultural ones may
them apart, for others, to blend them. finally remove the assumption of stability
Organizational actors may or may not prob- that sneaked into the new institutionalism,
lematize their contents, form, or sheer exis- acknowledge the interplay between inten-
tence, but researchers must. Technology tions and contingencies, and permit self-
ought to become an interesting topic for the reflection.
institutionalists, precisely because technical I return to the notion of institutional iso-
norms tend to operate outside the awareness morphism, as explicated in the original
of their habitual followers. Smoothly and DiMaggio and Powell article from 1983.
reliably prescribed machine operations This notion assumes the homogenization of
become sealed off from representations of an organization field due to coercive pres-
organizational life, and, by the same token, sures, mimetic processes, and normative
the constitutive parts of the action nets repre- pressures. Later comments by Powell (1991),
sented by the concept of ‘organization’ written in reply to various criticisms,
remain invisible, and are not given a voice in addressed the sources of heterogeneity, albeit
organizational accounts. treating it merely as a type of error variance.
The introduction to Powell and DiMaggio
(1991) took a more generous view of the pos-
sibility that homogenization may be accom-
SOMETHING COULD BE ADDED: panied by heterogenization, but it was also
A NARRATIVE INSTITUTIONALISM? more abstract than the specific original word-
ing, thus making it impossible to judge if
My interest in narratology brought another they actually changed their minds or were
field with a developed theory of institutions merely placating their critics.
to my attention: literary theory (see e.g. This problem is not as troublesome once
Zeraffa, 1973; Bruss, 1976, 1982). Thus the the metaphors are exchanged. In genre
idea of arranging an encounter between a theory,5 which is the institutional theory of lit-
narrative approach and the new institutional- erature, the sources of homogeneity and het-
ism (Czarniawska, 1997) was based on the erogeneity are the same. The result may veer
hope that the combination could lead to to one side or another temporarily and locally;
greater metaphorical clarity in both. In what what is more, because no ‘thermostats’ are
follows, I neglect narratology in order to con- fitted, the imbalance can lead to the extinction
centrate on institutional theory, which must of a genre or to its temporary dominance over
not be seen as a proof that it is only institu- others. No predictions of the kind ‘If A then
tionalism that can benefit from the encounter B ... ’can or need be made. But an under-
(for a reverse example, see e.g. Gumbrecht, standing of the dynamics can be attempted,
1992, applying Luhmann’s theory to litera- because the coercive pressures or attempts
ture). However, I believe that proponents of to use power to establish the superiority
SOME REFLECTIONS ON INSTITUTIONAL THEORY(IES) 777

of one genre over another invariably produce construct their identity around it – authorize
counter-narratives and subversive genres. it, as it were. Once again, the reaction of the
Thus one could claim that the Académie readers – or the spectators – may be accept-
Française promoted freedom of expression in ance or rejection.
French art; that the increasing control of All these contradictions may be connected
positivism revealed the strength of with a paradox that seems to be inherent in
symbolist approaches; and that the bureau- institutionalism, at least in its constructivist
cratic orders of central administrations version (Sismondo, 1993 used Berger and
produce bursts of creative avoidance activities. Luckmann, 1966 as an example). On the one
The emergence of institutions is always rife hand, the construction of institutions implies
with paradoxes. and demands a proactive vision of human
Mimetic processes become much more actors busying themselves with plotting,
complex, as well, when interpreted in terms performing, and accounting for what they do,
of fashion (a social phenomenon) rather than and thus producing reality as they know
individual imitation (Czarniawska, 2005). it. On the other hand, the notion of institu-
The concept of fashion, conceived in the way tions suggests accretion, a passive process
Tarde (1890/1962) and Simmel (1904/1973) under no one’s control – something that just
understood it, combines a striving to conform happens.
with a striving to be original. The municipal- For Sismondo, this is a historical accident,
ities espousing yet more reforms and changes a somewhat unreflective combination of two
are afraid of being left alone (‘What if different thought traditions, which is obvi-
everybody else reforms?’) and are proud of ously ‘wrong.’ There is no point in insisting
being avant-garde (‘We were there before that it be corrected, however. For me, it opens
anybody else’). a vast area of possibilities, because and not in
Finally, normative (professional) pressures spite of its lack of coherence. Is not a fuller,
may be the most ambiguous of all. On the richer picture of knowledge and reality being
other hand they were described in DiMaggio created by this emphasis on a combination of
and Powell (1983) as idealistic and at vari- plots and intentions, which produces unin-
ance with social realities; and on the other, as tentional but powerful changes? According
hierarchical, authoritarian, and akin to coer- to this reading, even institutionalism and the
cive pressures. The narrative version of insti- rational model can complement each other.
tutionalism needs no more than corroborate The rational model promotes change and the
this ambiguity. Within professional environ- illusion of controllability, which, according
ments, there is always a simultaneous pres- to Luhmann (1986), is necessary to keep the
sure to adhere to tradition and to rebel system going. The institutional response is
against it, to create new traditions and to that the change happens only within the
follow the conventional way of doing things. frames permitted by the institutional thought
Additionally, genre theory reveals interplay structure; and observations confirm this
between intentionality and field forces that is view, insofar as it concerns planned change.
hardly visible in the ‘institutional isomor- But the changes are many, and truly radical
phism’ version of events. Literary works can ones are, by definition, unpredictable;
be and are consciously constructed, but it although it could be claimed that the proba-
does not mean that the intentions of the read- bility of such radical changes would be
ers will ever approximate the intentions of the smaller if all planned change ceased to exist.
authors or that a text can be intentionally cre- ‘Looking at the system from the outside’ is
ated as an exemplar – a beginning of a new a metaphorical, paradoxical attempt in
genre ordered by fiat. Once a pattern begins Escherian spirit, as Luhmann repeatedly
to emerge, actors try to appropriate it, give stated in his writings. Thus it does not make
it a name, translate it for their own needs, sense, from this imaginary travel to the
778 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

outside, to make ‘predictions’ or to form (1985, 1989), inspired by Arnold (1935)


‘recommendations for action,’ which can and by Meyer and Rowan (1977), who
be used ‘inside.’ ‘It is not the task of an exter- spoke about rationalist decision façades
nal observer to de-paradoxize the system and action-oriented practices, postulated
and describe it in a way that is suitable hypocrisy as a joining mechanism; March
for multi-level logical analysis’ (Luhmann, and Olsen (1989) spoke of ‘healthy
1986: 179). What our imaginary ‘vision hypocrisy.’
from outside’ says is that the system survives, Many new institutionalist works, however,
thanks to its fictions – its illusions of steer away from such solutions and return to
selection, rational choice, and intentionality – Arnold’s dilemma, doing precisely what, in
combined with complexity and with his opinion, made no sense: formulating their
the knowledge of closeness, repetition, and observations about the paradoxical nature of
self-reflection. the system in a language of one of the sub-
Pointing out the ‘iron cage’ of institutions, systems – the one that forbids paradoxicality.
DiMaggio and Powell failed to see what Perhaps this need to formalize and formulate
Luhmann has been emphasizing all along. Of predictions is connected with the trap of
course it is an iron cage, but it ‘functions’ institution-maintenance that lies in wait for
well, as long as people inside believe that every institutionalist. Genres and other insti-
they are free. ‘The autopoiesis does not stop tutions presuppose permanence (an institu-
in [the] face of logical contradictions: it tion is a practice that lasts) and difference (an
jumps, provided that possibilities of further institution must be different and differen-
communication are close enough at hand’ tiable from other institutions). Such a state-
(Luhmann, 1986: 180). It would be unfair to ment is apparently in perfect congruence
claim that the new institutionalists are with the stationary assumptions of the new
unaware of this paradox, but many try to institutionalism.
deparadoxize their theory – an unnecessary
feat, given that a theory describing paradoxes
does not have to be paradoxical itself.
Neither does it have to exclude paradoxes at DON’T GO TOO FAR; TURN AROUND
all costs; in general, it does not have to imi- AND TAKE A LOOK
tate the system it describes. Such an ‘anthro-
pological approach toward social ideas,’ as As long as a genre or an institution is used
Thurman Arnold (1935: 30) called it, is not properly – for classification – this is not a
supposed to lead to ‘a logically formulated problem. ‘Any public tends to classify what it
set of principles’ (1935: 30), which receives and to receive it through a classifica-
some new institutionalists try to develop. tion of everything that it has received before’
Neither should it demand that the system it (Lejeune, 1989: 147). This is what the con-
observes should stop producing such princi- cept of the ‘institutional thought structure’
ples: ‘It is the system under examination (Warren, Rose, and Bergunder, 1974) was all
which can no more help producing principles about.
than a hen can keep from laying eggs’ The possible transgressions are two. One
(Arnold, 1935: 30). is to attempt to construct a complete theory,
Karl E. Weick’s (1979) description of the as Northrop Frye (1957/1990) tried within
world of organizations was similar to genre theory. Lejeune’s (1989: 152) critique
Arnold’s, with the added mechanism of was firm: ‘To elaborate “a theory of genres”
‘loose coupling,’ which permitted different is to try to formulate a synthesis in the absolute
and even contradictory subsystems to coexist by making use of concepts that make
peacefully under the same label and under sense only in the historical field’ (Lejeune,
the same organizational roof. Brunsson 1989: 152). As mentioned, this danger has
SOME REFLECTIONS ON INSTITUTIONAL THEORY(IES) 779

been avoided, at least in DiMaggio and behind the institutionalist ideas? Why should
Powell’s tolerant presentations of a variety of one attempt to formalize a world undergoing
institutional theories. construction?
The other risk is that the phenomenon in There is always the possibility of alternat-
the focus of reflection – the unproblematic ing between the position of an observer and
(because it is institutionalized) use of classi- that of the actor – in this case as observers of
ficatory devices – re-occurs within the reflec- and actors in social science. Thus I end as I
tion itself. One solution to this problem is to began: with a plea for an institutional
place oneself and one’s analysis in the closed account of institutional theory.
system that is being depicted, as the genre
analysts often do. The narrative angle makes
self-reflection easier, in view of the observa-
tion that theoretical narratives are produced NOTES
within the same institutional thought struc-
ture as the narratives of the field. Seeing 1 Roine Johansson limits this development to
one’s theory as a narrative among many (or, Sweden (Johansson, 2002).
2 Paul DiMaggio’s (1988) view of the temporality
in case of institutional theory, a genre among of every institutional order is close to this idea, but is
others) can help to locate it institutionally. more conflict oriented.
Otherwise, the theoreticians are doomed to 3 According to Ernest Gellner, on the occasion
including a blind spot in their theory, which of the 70th anniversary of the foundation of LSE,
covers their own position in it. Oakeshott and Gellner quarreled, Gellner arguing
that 70 years is long enough to speak of the estab-
Lack of self-reflection is not a trait of the lishment of an institution, and Oakeshott arguing
new institutionalism alone. The ‘old’ institu- that it requires at least 200 years (Gellner, 1980). I am
tionalists also took the notion of one institu- on Oakeshott’s side, as the recent changes in Russia
tion for granted: the institution of social have demonstrated; 70 years is not enough to
science research. Even sociologists of knowl- change an institutional order.
4 The very distinction between ‘physical’ and ‘cul-
edge, such as Berger and Luckmann, tural’ metaphors is tenuous. As mentioned, Tarde
assumed that their task was to study everyone saw diffusion as a cultural process, whereas biolo-
else – that sociology itself can be studied gists speak of both diffusion (a movement of a sub-
only by philosophy (Berger and Luckmann, stance from an area of high concentration to an area
1966). One could argue, however, that the of lower concentration) and translation (of messen-
ger RNA in a bacterium E.coli, for example). The term
‘old’ institutionalism was born in harmony ‘translation’, as used in the sociology of translation,
with its institutional environment, in the sense is also nonlinguistic (Steve Brown, 2002).
that its ideas blended well into the main- 5 Genres are sets of rules and conventions gov-
stream of its time. Not so the new institution- erning expectations about the length and composi-
tional structure of communicative acts, but also ways
alism, somewhat in opposition to the present
of conceptualizing reality, forms of seeing and inter-
mainstream in social sciences, and appearing preting particular aspects of the world. I am referring
to try to appease the institutional core by sac- here to dynamic genre theories, such as those devel-
rificing its traditional methods, which were oped by Bakhtin (1979/2000) and Bruss (1982).
close to those of anthropology. The result, 6 ‘Facts, as telescopes and wigs for gentlemen,
were a seventeenth century invention’ (MacIntyre,
however, seems sometimes not so much para-
1988:357).
doxical as confused. Many studies report
straightforward statistical analyses. Surely it
is the task of an institutionalist to explore the REFERENCES
way statistics are built and used, and not to
take them as ‘facts’,6 ‘revealing regularities’? Aboulafia, Mitchell (2001) The Cosmopolitan
Many contributions contain predictions and Self. George Herbert Mead and continental
formalizations. How can this be reconciled philosophy. Chicago: University of Illinois
with the pragmatist-constructivist assumptions Press.
780 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Arnold, Thurman W. (1935) The Symbols of Outset. Frankfurt/Boulder: Campus/West-


Government. New Haven: Yale University view, 206–238.
Press. Callon, Michel (1986) Some elements of a soci-
Bakhtin, Mikhail (1979/2000) The problem ology of translation: Domestication of the
of speech genres. In: Duff, David (ed.) scallops and the fishermen of St Brieuc’s Bay.
Modern Genre Theory. Harlow, UK: Pearson, In: Law, John. (ed.) Power, Action and Belief.
82–97. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul,
Barley, Stephen and Tolbert, Pamela (1997) 196–229.
Institutionalization and structuration: Callon, Michel (1988) Society in the making:
Studying the links between action and insti- The study of technology as a tool for socio-
tution. Organization Studies, 18(1): 93–117. logical analysis. In: Bijker, Wiebe; Hughes,
Berger, Peter and Luckmann, Thomas (1966) Thomas P., and Pinch, Trevor (eds.) The Social
The Social Construction of Reality. New York: Construction of Technological Systems.
Doubleday. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 83–103.
Berger, Peter and Luckmann, Thomas (1995) Callon, Michel and Latour, Bruno (1981)
Modernity, Pluralism and the Crisis of Meaning: Unscrewing the big Leviathan: how actors
The Orientation of Modern Man. Gütersloh: macro-structure reality and how sociologists
Bertelsmann Foundation Publishers. help them to do so. In: Knorr-Cetina, Karen
Berger, Peter; Berger, Brigitta; and Kellner, and Cicourel, Aaron V. (eds.) Advances in
Hanfried (1974) The Homeless Mind. Social Theory and Methodology. London:
London: Penguin. Routledge and Kegan Paul, 277–303.
Boas, Franz (1904/1974) The history of anthro- Christensen, Søren; Karnøe, Peter; Pedersen,
pology. In: A Franz Boas Reader (edited by Jesper Strandgaard; and Dobbin, Frank
George W. Stocking, Jr.). Chicago: University (1997) Actors and institutions: Editors’ intro-
of Chicago Press, 23–41. duction. American Behavioral Scientist, 40
Brown, Steve (2002) Michel Serres: Science, (4): 392–396.
translation and the logic of the parasite. Czarniawska, Barbara (1997) Narrating the
Theory, Culture & Society, 19(3): 1–28. Organization. Dramas of Institutional Iden-
Brunsson, Nils (1985) The Irrational Organiza- tity. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.
tion. London: Wiley. Czarniawska, Barbara (2004) On time, space
Brunsson, Nils (1989) The Organization of and action nets. Organization, 11(6):
Hypocrisy. Talk, Action and Decision in 777–795.
Organizations. London: Wiley. Czarniawska, Barbara (2005) Fashion in organ-
Brunsson, Nils (2007) The Consequences of izing. In: Czarniawska, Barbara, and Sevón,
Decision-Making. Oxford: Oxford University Guje (eds.) Global Ideas. How Ideas, Objects
Press. and Practices Travel in the Global Economy.
Brunsson, Nils and Olsen, Johan (eds.) (1993) Malmö/Copenhagen: Liber/CBS Press,
The Reforming Organization. London: 129–146.
Routledge. Czarniawska, Barbara, and Hernes, Tor (eds.)
Bruss, Elisabeth W. (1976) Autobiographical (2005) Actor-Network Theory and Organiz-
Acts. The Changing Situation of a Literary ing. Malmö/Copenhagen: Liber/CBS Press.
Genre. Baltimore: John Hopkins University Czarniawska, Barbara, and Sevón, Guje (1996)
Press. Introduction. In: Czarniawska, Barbara, and
Bruss, Elisabeth W. (1982) Beautiful Theories. Sevón, Guje (eds.) (1996) Translating Organi-
Baltimore: John Hopkins University Press. zational Change. Berlin: De Gruyter, 1–23.
Burns, Tom, and Stalker, G. M. (1961) The Czarniawska, Barbara, and Sevón, Guje (eds.)
Management of Innovation. London: (1996) Translating Organizational Change.
Tavistock. Berlin: De Gruyter.
Burns, Tom E., and Dietz, Thomas (1991) Czarniawska, Barbara, and Sevón, Guje (2003)
‘Technology, sociotechnical systems, techno- Introduction: Did the Vikings know how to
logical development: An evolutionary per- organize? In: Czarniawska, Barbara, and Sevón,
spective. In: Dierkes, Meinholf and Guje (eds.) Northern Lights: Organization
Hoffmann, Ute (eds.) Technology at the Theory in Scandinavia. Malmö: Liber, 9–13.
SOME REFLECTIONS ON INSTITUTIONAL THEORY(IES) 781

Czarniawska, Barbara, and Sevón, Guje (eds.) notion of fiction. Theory, Culture and
(2005) Global Ideas. How Ideas, Objects Society, 11: 1–22.
and Practices Travel in the Global Lanzara, Giovan Francesco, and Mörner,
Economy. Malmö/Copenhagen: Liber/CBS Michéle (2005) Artifacts rule! How organi-
Press. zing happens in open source hardware proj-
DiMaggio, Paul J. (1988) Interest and agency in ects. In: Czarniawska, Barbara, and Hernes,
institutional theory. In: Zucker, Lynne G. (ed.) Tor (eds.) (2005) Actor-Network Theory and
Institutional patterns and organizations: Organizing. Malmö/Copenhagen: Liber/CBS
Culture and environment. Cambridge, MA: Press, 67–90.
Ballinger, 3–21. Latour, Bruno (1992) Technology is society
DiMaggio, Paul J. and Powell, Walter W. (1983) made durable. In: Law, John (ed.) Sociology
The iron cage revisited: Institutional isomor- of Monsters: Essays on Power, Technology
phism and collective rationality in organiza- and Domination. Routledge: London,
tional fields. American Sociological Review, 103–131.
48: 147–160. Latour, Bruno (1996) Aramis or the love of
Douglas, Mary (1986) How Institutions Think. technology. Cambridge, MA: Harvard
London: Routledge and Kegan Paul. University Press.
Frye, Northrop (1957/1990) The Anatomy of Latour, Bruno (2002) Gabriel Tarde and the
Criticism. London: Penguin. end of the social. In: Joyce, Patrick (ed.) The
Gagliardi, Pasquale (2006) Book Review: Social in Question. London: Routledge,
Artifacts and Organizations: Beyond Mere 117–132.
Symbolism. Administrative Science Quarterly, Latour, Bruno and Woolgar, Steve 1979/1986
51(3): 505–508. Laboratory Life: The Construction of Scientific
Gellner, Ernest (1980) The LSE: A contested Facts. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
academy. The Times Higher Education Lejeune, Philippe (1989) On Autobiography.
Supplement, November 7, 12–13. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press.
Giddens, Anthony (1990) The Consequences of Luckmann, Thomas (ed.) (1978) Phenomenology
Modernity. Cambridge, UK: Polity Press. and Sociology. Harmondsworth, Middlesex:
Goffman, Erving (1961) Asylums. Essays on the Penguin.
Social Situation of Mental Patients and Other Luhmann, Niklas (1986) The autopoiesis of
Inmates. Harmondsworth, Middlesex: Penguin social systems. In: Geyer, Felix and van der
Books. Zeuwen, Johnnes (eds.) Sociocybernetic
Goodman, Paul S.; Sproull, Lee S.; and Associates Paradoxes. Observation, Control and Evolu-
(eds.) (1990) Technology and Organizations. tion of Self-Steering Systems. London: Sage,
San Francisco: Jossey-Bass Publishers. 172–192.
Gumbrecht, Hans-Ulrich (1992) Making Sense MacIntyre, Alasdair (1988) Whose Justice?
of Life and Literature. Stanford, CA: Stanford Which Rationality? Notre Dame, Indiana:
University Press. University of Notre Dame.
Gustavsson, Eva, and Czarniawska, Barbara March, James G., and Olsen, Johan (1989)
(2004) Web Woman: The on-line construc- Rediscovering Institutions. The Organiza-
tion of corporate and gender images. tional Basis of Politics. New York: The Free
Organization, 11(5): 651–670. Press.
Joerges, Bernward, and Czarniawska, Barbara Mayntz, Renate (1988) Zur Entwicklung tech-
(1998) The question of technology, or nischer Infrastruktursysteme. In: Mayntz,
how organizations inscribe the world. Renate; Rosewitz, Berndt; Schimank, Uwe,
Organization Studies, 19(3): 363–385. and Stichweh, Rudolf (eds.) Differenzierung
Johansson, Roine (2002) Nyinstitutionalismen und Verselbständigung: Zur Entwicklung
inom Organisationsanalysen. Lund: Student- gesellschaftlicher Teilsysteme. Frankfurt/New
litteratur. York: Campus, 233–259.
Knorr-Cetina, Karin (1981) The Manufacture of Meyer, John W. (1986) Myths of socialization
Knowledge. Oxford: Pergamon. and of personality. In: Heller, Thomas C.;
Knorr-Cetina, Karin (1994) Primitive classification Sosna, Morton; and Wellbery, David E. (eds.)
and postmodernity: Towards a sociological Reconstructing Individualism: Autonomy,
782 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Individuality and The Self in Western Shrivastava, Paul (1993) Crisis theory/practice:
Thought. Stanford, CA: Stanford University towards sustainable development. Industrial
Press, 208–221. and Environmental Crisis Quarterly, 7(1):
Meyer, John W. and Rowan, Brian (1977) 23–42.
Institutionalized organizations: Formal struc- Simmel, Georg (1904/1973). Fashion. In: Wills,
ture as myth and ceremony. American Gordon, and Midgley, David (eds.) Fashion
Journal of Sociology, 83(2): 340–363. Marketing. London: Allen & Unwin,
Meyer, John, and Scott, W. Richard (1981) 171–191.
Institutional Environments and Organiza- Sismondo, Sergio (1993) Some social construc-
tions: Structural Complexity and Individual- tions. Social Studies of Science, 23:
ism. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage. 515–553.
Meyer, Renate (2006) Visiting relatives: Current Tarde, Gabriel (1890/1962) The Laws of Imita-
developments in the new sociology of tion. New York, NY: Henry Holt.
knowledge. Organization, 13(5): 725–738. Tarde, Gabriel (1893/1999) Monadologie et
Mucchielli, Laurent (2000): ‘Tardomania? Sociologie. Paris: Institut Synthélabo.
Réflexions sur les usages contemporains de Turner, Barry A. (1978/1997) Man Made
Tarde.’ Revue d’histoire des Sciences Disasters. London: Wykenham Publications.
Humaines, 3: 161–184. Vaughan, Diane (1990) Autonomy, interde-
Olsen, Johan P. (1970) Local budgeting, deci- pendence, and social control: NASA and the
sion-making or a ritual act? Scandinavian space shuttle Challenger. Administrative
Political Studies, 5 (3): 85–118. Science Quarterly, 35: 225–257.
Olsen, Johan P. (ed) (1989) Petroleum og Poli- Veblen, Torsten (1899) The Theory of Leisure
tikk. Bergen: Tano. Class. New York: Dover Publications.
Perrow, Charles 1984 Normal Accidents: Living Warren, Roland L.; Rose, Stephen M.; and
with High-Risk-Technologies. New York: Bergunder, Ann F. (1974) The Structure of
Basic Books. Urban Reform. Community Decision
Powell, Walter W. (1991) Expanding the scope Organizations in Stability and Change.
of institutional analysis. In: Powell, Walter W. Lexington, MA: Lexington Books.
and DiMaggio, Paul J. (eds.) The New Institu- Weick, Karl E. (1979) The Social Psychology of
tionalism in Organizational Analysis. Chicago: Organizing. Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley.
The University of Chicago Press, 183–203. Weick, Karl E. (1988) Enacted sensemaking in
Powell, Walter W. and DiMaggio, Paul J. (1991) crisis situations. Journal of Management
(eds.) The New Institutionalism in Organiza- Studies, 25: 305–317.
tional Analysis. Chicago: The University of Weick, Karl E., and Sutcliffe, Kathleen M.
Chicago Press. (2001) Managing the Unexpected. San
Rice, Albert K. (1958) Productivity and Social Francisco: Jossey-Bass.
Organization: The Ahmedabad Experiment. Westenholz, Ann; Pedersen, Jesper
London: Tavistock. Strandgaard; and Dobbin, Frank (2006)
Sahlins, Marshall (2001) ‘Sentimental pessimism’ Introduction: Institutions in the making:
and ethnographic experience or, why culture is Identity, power, and the emergence of new
not a disappearing object. In: Daston, Lorraine organizational forms. American Behavioral
(ed.) Biographies of Scientific Objects. Chicago, Scientist, 49 (7): 889–896.
IL: University of Chicago Press, 178–202. Whitley, Richard (1972) Black boxism and the
Scott, Richard W. (1981) Organizations: sociology of science. Sociological Review
Rational, Natural and Open Systems. Monograph, 18: 61–92.
Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall. Woodward, Joan (1965) Industrial Organiza-
Scott, W. Richard and Christensen, Søren tion: Theory and Practice. Oxford, UK:
(1995) The Institutional Construction of Oxford University Press.
Organization. International and Longitudinal Zeraffa, M. (1973) The novel as literary
Studies. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage. form and as social institution. In: Burns,
Seidl, David, and Becker, Kai (eds.) (2005) Elisabeth and Thomas (eds.) Sociology of
Niklas Luhmann and Organization Studies. Literature and Drama. Harmondsworth,
Malmö/Copenhagen: Liber/CBS Press. Middlesex: Penguin, 35–55.
33
Been There, Done That, Moving On:
Reflections on Institutional
Theory’s Continuing Evolution
Paul Hirsch

In the literature of Sociology, one seldom FROM POLITICS TO CULTURE


finds references today to terms like grand vs
middle range theory, structural-functional- My introduction to the term ‘institution’
ism, and social Darwinism. But, for more came from Parsons’ classic (1956) essay on
than two decades, debates over these terms three levels of analysis in the study of organ-
raged throughout the discipline – until the izations, published in the first issues of
field moved on – having arrived at some con- Administrative Science Quarterly. In this
ceptual agreements and letting the rest drift framework, work gets done at the firm’s1
away. The recent history of Institutional technical level and is coordinated at its
Theory repeats conflicts over many of the managerial level. Laws and regulations are
same issues and themes. I am pleased to say created outside the firms’ boundaries, at the
we have also followed suit in resolving these institutional level, and enforced in the mar-
by having the various sides’ framing of issues kets and external environments in which
converge some, and otherwise, moving on. these organizations operate. Parsons’ concep-
Since this chapter reflects on some of these tion of this process was two-way, with each
paradigm conflicts as I saw them, much of the side mutually influencing the other. Going
essay is historical, written in the past tense. way beyond a closed system conception of
The good news is I am pleased to celebrate organization, his ‘Institutional’ level encom-
the end of an era of tough conflicts over passed a political world in which lobbyists,
defining Institutional Theory, and participate trade associations and others with direct
in its future development. interests met with authorities to negotiate
784 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

over rules that would govern their firms’ action occurred and change was possible.
behavior. In Parsons’ terms: As Stinchcombe (1997: 2) put it: ‘Institutions
were created by purposive people in legis-
Subject to the overall control of an institutionalized
value system in the society and its subsystems, the latures and international unions, and in
central phenomenon of organizations is the mobi- pamphlets of business ideologists.’
lization of power for the attainment of the goals of Of course, the action’s result could well be
the organization. The value system legitimizes the to reinforce existing rules – but this remained
organization’s goal, but it is only through power
a variable, with outcomes often uncertain.
that its achievement can be made effective. (1956:
225, italics in the original) For example, my article, ‘Organiza-
tional Effectiveness and the Institutional
Parsons’ framework, and the subsequent Environment,’ published in ASQ (1975b)
influence of the open systems perspective utilized the concept ‘institutional’ to track
had a large impact on the developing organi- how U.S. patent law and State regulations
zational field. The value (and possibility) of about prescribing brand-name drugs were
analytically deriving an organization’s influenced by the pharmaceutical industry’s
behavior from its external environment was lobbying.2
new (Hirsch, 1975a). As a student of culture as well at the time
Also exciting was the opportunity this pro- (Hirsch, 1972), I found the two concepts –
vided to examine how, in turn, the organiza- culture (on the one hand) and institution (on
tion could work to change a regulation or law the other) did not overlap and were not linked
from being, in James Thompson’s terms in the field. For sociological articles address-
(1967: 24), an unwelcome ‘constraint’ to a ing culture at that time, it was deemed neces-
more manageable ‘contingency’ and, finally, sary to connect the topic addressed to social
a manipulable ‘variable.’ Two notable conse- structural issues (e.g., economic concentra-
quences of so analyzing organizations were tion or audience demograpics), rather than
developing strategies to ‘beat’ the market, focus on (just) its narrative or aesthetic con-
and having a unit of analysis between the tent, imagery or other nonmaterial features.
individual and society that could ‘act.’ The ‘Production of Culture’ school (Peterson
Organizations were seldom conceived as and Berger, 1975; Hirsch and DiMaggio,
such independent units in economics (in 1977) successfully extended the dominant
which firms were ‘typical,’ not distinctive), studies of social structure to cultural issues
or sociology (which conceived organizations and sites; the later ‘cultural turn,’ which
as tools implementing agendas set exter- partly reordered and reversed these priorities
nally). Several of the fault lines that in subfields across social sciences, had not
would later develop between what DiMaggio occurred yet (Peterson and Anand, 2004;
and Powell (1991) framed as ‘old’ and ‘new’ Hirsch and Fiss, 2000).
institutionalism trace to conflicting interpre-
tations which subsequently developed
around such questions as: how open to influ-
ence from below are open systems?; how
much influence (if any) can managers exert REFRAMING THE CONCEPT OF
in constructing their organizations’ environ- INSTITUTION: FROM ACTION TO
ments?; and, is the appropriate unit of ICON – A TRAIN LEAVES THE STATION
analysis for organizational studies the
organization, or the image and category of I visited Stanford in 1975. Dick Scott was
organization it is presumed to fit? on leave and I was honored and pleased
At this time (mid-1970s), the term ‘institu- to be asked to teach the Sociology of
tion’ was not coupled with the term ‘theory.’ Organizations class. It was a wonderful year,
Rather, it implied a place at which political during which John Meyer and Brian Rowan
REFLECTIONS ON INSTITUTIONAL THEORY’S CONTINUING EVOLUTION 785

were finishing what became their classic arti- John Meyer et al.’s volume, Organizational
cle (1977) on ‘Institutionalized Organi- Environments: Ritual and Rationality (1983),
zations: Formal Structure as Myth and Perrow (1985) commended what he
Ceremony.’ It proclaimed an explicit re-entry described as a resulting contingency-like
of a cultural framing to explain organiza- framework, exhibiting a continuum in which
tional actions in the face of environmental the assessment of some (mainly industrial)
demands. The multiple ways in which Meyer organizations was based on production and
and Rowan also showed organizations could efficiency standards, while greater reliance
‘game’ the system to attain legitimacy were on myth and ceremony characterized assess-
as clear and impressive as their point that to ments of (mainly) government agencies and
gain legitimacy organizations needed to non-profit organizations. At this time, both
respond to signals from their environments, conceptions of organizations and measures
or appear to do so. My sense at the time was were included and distinguished in the grow-
their contribution was compatible with, and ing institutional framework.3
added to, the ways in which Thompson Meyer’s innovative approach was
(1967) had suggested organizations could extended and applied in multiple projects
gain from and exert a reciprocal influence on with Scott. The term ‘institutional’ was
their environments. added to what in sociology had more tradi-
In the years which followed, writers on tionally been attributed to culture’s and
institutional theory rightly credited and symbols’ influence on people and organi-
praised Meyer and Rowan’s formulation for zations. Cognitive framing rather than a
being among the first to shift the field’s atten- focus on socialization also displaced more
tion away from the technical sides of measur- conventional references to ‘values’ and
able performance, focusing more on the ‘norms.’ Before long, what we now know as
importance of organizations’ conformity to ‘Institutional Theory’ was launched, with
the appearance and symbols defined as legitimacy as the currency for success, and
legitimate by their external evaluators. its conferral uni-directional (top down). This
Interestingly, these two sides of their formu- latter focus, emphasizing the persistence of
lation both contributed to what later became ‘taken for granted’ rules to conform to,
called ‘old’ and ‘new’ institutionalism. On brought on comparisons with population
one hand, its discussion of the symbolic envi- ecology – for which environments also
ronment’s power to confer legitimacy had a ‘dominate or overpower organizations’
strong influence on DiMaggio and Powell’s (Aldrich, 2006: 41) and similarly ‘treat
(1983) initial presentation of the powerful organizations as a population within an orga-
role of legitimacy in rewarding conformity nizational field’ (Greenwood and Hinings,
through isomorphism; this one-way conferral 1997: 1026). Brint and Karabel (1991: 355)
of status in exchange for conformity was an also noted its contributions to the study of
important step towards their subsequent for- institutional forms and functioning, while
mulation of ‘new institutionalism’ (1991). also criticizing the absence of interest in their
On the other hand, Meyer and Rowan’s enu- origins and transformations.4 Interestingly,
meration of ways organizations (through the theory’s interpretation of decoupling as a
myth and ceremony) can reap rewards by deliberate strategy to avoid following rules
only appearing to be (but not actually) con- also brought on alternative formulations
forming to that environment’s signals is more proposing the same behaviors to instead
consistent with what became ‘old’ institu- be responses to confusion over multiple
tionalism. These were well documented in signals and rule ambiguity (Weick, 1995;
(Marshall) Meyer and Zucker’s (1989) study Martin, 1992).
of Permanently Failing Organizations, for The theoretical ascent of culture, as estab-
example. In his (otherwise critical) review of lishing the appropriate behaviors to follow,
786 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

both challenged and reversed earlier over- as a ‘battle of the coasts.’ After
statements by structuralists, which (para- DiMaggio and Powell (1991) published
phrasing Marx) had framed culture as their famous ideal type dichotomy of the
insignificant ‘superstructure.’ The sides were ‘old’ and ‘new’ institutional schools, it
now reversed.5 In this developing version, became clear from departmental composi-
Institutional Theory effectively ignored the tion and hirings that the more political ver-
‘flipside’ earlier allowed by Meyer and sion of what was now called ‘old’
Rowan (1977), and Meyer, Scott, et al. institutional theory remained rooted in the
(1983) to interact with their environments east, while advocates of the ‘new’ institu-
over determining what rules must be fol- tional school were based primarily
lowed. This understanding of the term ‘insti- at Stanford and on the west coast. The
tutional’ as political in nature, which I (and ‘new’ institutional framework, joined
others) had utilized (and still also see) as the by population ecology (also rooted
analytical level where the process of change on the west coast, mainly Berkeley),
and bargaining over rules occurs, was now discounted the idea that organiza-
reframed more as an untouchable icon, tions can or should adapt to or impact
whose signals are set and rules enforced and their surroundings (Greenwood and
not subject to challenge. Hinings, 1996). Published articles work-
For the discipline of Sociology, this ing from this perspective came dispropor-
revived echoes of a long-standing debate tionately from scholars based in (and
between a focus on stability (‘romancing graduating from) departments on the
the norm’) and proponents of change. west coast. (Ironically, if each coast was
Max Weber, along with noting the power disproportionately tied to one or the
and great efficiency of rule-following other of these poles, departments in the mid-
bureaucracies, had also worried about how west [e.g., at the Big Ten schools] were
the rules they enforce can be socially generally learning from both and not
harmful and in need of change. At the time taking sides.)
of the discipline’s arrival in the U.S., its A pictorial version of this review,
proponents divided between advocates of coupled with the happy observation that the
social Darwinism vs. those seeking to reform two poles are no longer so far apart, appears
poverty and injustice. The dispute between in Table 33.1 of the Appendix.
‘old’ vs ‘new’ institutionalism recalled
earlier competing agendas – to study
deviance vs. dominance, peripheries vs.
centers, exotic vs. normal activities, as well RESOLUTION AND
as middle range vs. functionalist formula- BRIGHT FUTURE
tions, and (statistically) variation on scatter-
plots vs. a greater focus of regression lines. In the midst of this contention, I was hon-
A critique of new institutionalism as more ored to be selected to assess the field, as
‘sociology without villains’ was not much of the Academy of Management OMT
a departure from these earlier intellectual Division’s Distinguished Scholar for 1998.
debates. In this talk (‘Process Detective: A Role
for the Organization Researcher’), I had
a chance to reflect on how the Open Systems
BATTLE OF THE COASTS revolution had turned out so far. I noted the
irony that it expanded the explanatory field to
For the organizational field, this debate also which we turn to explain organizational out-
took on what Howard Aldrich (2007) noted comes, but was failing to provide adequate
REFLECTIONS ON INSTITUTIONAL THEORY’S CONTINUING EVOLUTION 787

explanations for how these unfolded. My We look forward to the reconciliation of


concern was that: the old and new institutional perspectives. ... There
is so much of value and interest in each, we do
we now risk a closed system model of the environ- not see how they can remain empirically
ment. It calls its own shots, does not conform to and intellectually separate for very long. (1997:
models of what makes it change, doesn’t seem to 417)
be dependent organizationally on many input or
output analogues. We placed the environment in Happily (though the article was discour-
control, no questions asked. At this broader aged by an ASQ editor at the time), the field
level, formalisms and scientific management
can be redefined as re-engineering or process con-
has subsequently moved in this direction.
trols; informal relations can be reframed as net- Similarly, I suggested that the research
work studies. We have reconstituted a closed in the three pillars of Scott’s (1995) typology
system at either level. So, it’s probably time for a of institutional perspectives be combined
new theory to come along and put more interac- or collapsed, to encourage more options
tion and enactment back into the theoretical
equation.
for locating ‘additional complementarities
and alliances across them’ (Hirsch, 1997:
An easier solution became apparent when 1721).
Michael Lounsbury and I imagined combin- It is heartening so many of these visions
ing the best of ‘old’ and ‘new’ institutional have been realized. The chapters in this
theories. In fact, it seemed clear these ideal handbook attest to it, and their indifference
types could not go much farther before each to the framings of the ‘old’ vs. ‘new’ debate
needed to incorporate and ‘borrow’ elements can help make it a thing of the past. We
associated with the other. We proposed this now benefit from the larger inventory of
as the resolution for ‘Ending the Family sophisticated concepts and methodological
Quarrel’ (Hirsch and Lounsbury, 1997), tools to conduct our studies. As suggested at
suggesting that more history and politics be the start of the essay, we have been there and
permitted entry into the ‘new’ and more sym- are done with the preliminaries. The prospect
bols and cultural framing be included the of much fascinating research lies ahead. Now,
‘old.’ We concluded these suggestions by to move on and continue the Institutional
stating: journey!

APPENDIX

Table 33.1 In the kingdom of the institutional


Hegemony of New York Principality Princes Find independence (out west) Happy Ending (2007)
● Merton>Parsons ● Meyer ‘Old’ and ‘New’ adjectives dropped
● Selznick ● Powell & DiMaggio from use. e.g., sample
● Perrow ● Scott characters in Handbook:
● Granovetter ● Zucker ● Schneiberg et al. reframe their meaning;

● Palmer ● Ocasio and Thornton

find compatibility logic


Currency: Currency: Currency:
Muckraking Conformity – with persistence and Peace and curiosity
‘Man Bites Dog’ legitimacy reframed “No bites at all”
Variation and scatterplots (isomorphism; regression to mean)
788 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

NOTES Hirsch, P. (1998). Process detectives: a role for the


organization researcher. Distinguished Scholar
1 The terms ‘organization’ and ‘firm’ are being Lecture, AOM Division of Organization and
used here interchangeably. Management Theory (unpublished).
2 If replicated today, one would learn that the Hirsch, P. (1997). Sociology without social
number of lobbyists employed by this still powerful structure: Neoinstitutional theory meets
industry in 2007 was more than double the number brave new world. American Journal of
of U.S. Senators and congressmen (CBS News, Sixty Sociology, 102 (6): 1702–1723.
Minutes 2007). Hirsch, P. (1986). From ambushes to golden
3 Meyer’s influence in reviving culture as an
parachutes: corporate takeovers as an
important part of the sociological landscape in which
instance of cultural framing and institutional
to conduct research also contributed to the explosion
of studies on ‘organizational culture.’ His student, integration. American Journal of Sociology,
Terence Deal co-authored one of the first (and best- 91 (4): 800–837.
selling) texts in this area (Deal and Kennedy, 1982). Hirsch, P. (1975b) Organizational effectiveness
4 Interestingly, DiMaggio and Powell (1991: 12), and the institutional environment. Adminis-
who included Brint and Karabel’s essay in the same trative Science Quarterly, 20 (4): 327–344.
volume, also agreed that this version of institutional Hirsch, P. (1975a). Organizational analysis and
theory ‘usually downplayed conflicts of interest industrial sociology: an instance of cultural
within and between organizations.’ lag. The American Sociologist, 10 (1): 3–12.
5 I have consistently insisted both be included in
Hirsch, P. (1972). Processing fads and fashions:
our studies (cf. Hirsch, 1986). In one Author’s Bio
an organization-set analysis of cultural
(Hirsch, 1997), I wrote that I ‘have straddled the
boundaries dividing culture and social structure for industry system. American Journal of
two decades, usually seeking more balance by taking Sociology, 77 (4): 639–659.
the side of whichever one seems to be getting the Hirsch, P. & Fiss, P. (2000). Doing sociology and
worst of it from the other.’ culture: Richard Peterson’s quest and contri-
bution. Poetics, 28: 97–105.
Hirsch, P. & Lounsbury, M. (1997). Ending the
family quarrel: towards a reconciliation of
REFERENCES ‘old’ and ‘new’ institutionalism. American
Behavioral Scientist, 40 (4): 406–418.
Aldrich, H.E. (1979, 2007). Preface, in Hirsch, P. & DiMaggio, P. (1977). Production
Organizations and Environments. Palo Alto, organizations in the arts. American
TX: Stanford University Press. Behavioral Scientist, 19 (6): pp. 735–752.
Aldrich, H.E. & Ruef, M. (2006). Organizations Martin, J. (1992). Cultures in Organizations.
Evolving, 2nd edn. Thousand Oaks, CA.: Sage. New York: Oxford University Press.
Brint, S. & Karabel, K. (1991). Institutional ori- Meyer, J.W. & Rowan, B. (1977). Institutional-
gins and transformations: The case of ized organizations: formal structures as myth
American community colleges, pp. 337–361, and ceremony. American Journal of
in W. Powell & P. DiMaggio, The New Sociology, 83: 340–363.
Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis. Meyer, J.W. & Scott, R. (1983) Organizational
Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press. Environments. Thousand Oaks, CA.: Sage.
DiMaggio, P. & Powell, W. (1991). Introduction, Meyer, M. & Zucker, L. (1989). Permanently
pp. 1–38, in W. Powell & P. DiMaggio (eds.), Failing Organizations. Thousand Oaks, CA.:
The New Institutionalism in Organizational Sage.
Analysis. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Parsons, T. (1956). Suggestions for a sociologi-
DiMaggio, P.J. & Powell, W.W. (1983). The iron cal approach to the theory of organizations –
cage revisited: institutional isomorphism and II. Administrative Science Quarterly, 1 (2):
collective rationality in organizational fields. 225–239.
American Sociological Review, 48: 147–160. Perrow, C. (1985). Overboard with myth and
Greenwood, R. & Hinings, C.R. (1996). symbols. American Journal of Sociology, 91
Understanding radical organizational (1): 151–155.
change: bringing together the old and Perrow, C. (1988). Complex Organization: A
the new institutionalism. Academy of Critical Essay, 3rd ed. New York: Random
Management Review, 31 (4): 1022–1054. House.
REFLECTIONS ON INSTITUTIONAL THEORY’S CONTINUING EVOLUTION 789

Peterson, R.A. & Anand, N. (2004). The Stinchcombe, A. (1997). On the virtues of the old
production of culture perspective. Annual institutionalism. Annual Review of Sociology.
Review of Sociology, 30: 311–334. Palo Alto, CA.: Annual Reviews, 23: 1–18.
Peterson, R.A. & Berger, D. (1975). Cycles Thompson, J. (1967, 2003). Organizations in
in symbol production: the case of popular Action: Social Science Bases of Administrative
music. American Sociological Review, 40: Theory. New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction
158–173. Books.
Scott, W.R., Institutions and Organizations. Weick, K. (1995). Sensemaking in Organizations.
(1995). Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage. Thousand Oaks, CA.: Sage.
34
Reflections on Institutional
Theories of Organizations
John W. Meyer

Contemporary institutional theorizing in the And within sociological versions, I concen-


field of organizations dates back thirty-odd trate on phenomenological theories. These
years. This particularly describes what are reflect my own interests, are continuing loci
called new or neo-institutionalisms. These of research creativity, and contrast most
terms evoke contrasts with earlier theories of sharply with other lines of social scientific
the embeddedness of organizations in social theorizing about organizations. In practice,
and cultural contexts, now retrospectively ‘organizations’ tends to be both a research
called the ‘old institutionalism’ (Hirsch & field, and a realist ideology about modern
Lounsbury, 1997; Stinchcombe, 1997). They society: phenomenological thinking steps
went through a period of inattention, so that back from that commitment, and is useful in
when institutional thinking came back in analyzing, for example, why so much formal
force after the 1960s, it seemed quite new. organization exists in the modern world
Institutional theories, as they emerged in (Drori, Meyer, & Hwang, 2006).
the 1970s, received much attention in the
field, along with other lines of thought
emphasizing the dependence of modern
organizations on their environments. Perhaps BACKGROUND
surprisingly, they continue to receive atten-
tion, and seem to retain substantial measures Throughout most of the post-Enlightenment
of vigor. One secondary aim, here, is to history of the social sciences, notions that
explain why. human activity is highly embedded in institu-
I primarily review the status and prospects tional contexts were central. Individuals were
of the principal themes of institutional theory. seen as creatures of habit (Camic, 1986),
I concentrate on sociological institutionalism, groups as controlled by customs (famously,
as capturing core ideas in their most dramatic Bagehot’s cake of custom or Spencer’s folk-
form, rather than the limited arguments ways and mores), and societies as organized
emphasized in economics or political science. around culture.
REFLECTIONS ON INSTITUTIONAL THEORIES OF ORGANIZATIONS 791

The nature of the institutions and their con- older institutional theories tended to crum-
trols over activity, in social scientific thinking, ble. Studies of persons no longer attended to
was never clear and consensual. Theories notions of habits (Camic, 1986), and con-
ranged from economic to political to cepts of culture and custom as driving forces
religious. And they variously emphasized receded. If the old institutions remained, they
more cultural forms of control or more remained as dispositional properties of the
organizational ones. Then, as now, anything actors involved – tastes and values of individ-
beyond the behavior of the people under study uals, core values of states and societies.
could be seen as representing a controlling The key concept in the new system was the
institutionalized pattern (a strikingly clear def- notion of the ‘actor’ – variously, individual
initional discussion is in Jepperson, 1991). persons, national states, and the organiza-
Over the long history of social scientific tions created by persons and states. Society
thinking through the mid-twentieth century, was produced by these powerful entities. It
institutional theories grew and improved. was made up exclusively of actors, and even
Sophisticated syntheses like Parsons’ were pro- the rapidly disappearing peasants could be
duced, with many variations on broad evolu- analyzed as individual actors. Social change
tionary schemes and typologies, as high was a product of such actors: thus the contin-
Modernity progressed. But they came into uing use of an individualistic version of
dialectical conflict with another aspect of the Weber’s Protestant Ethic thesis as a proof
same Modernity. As ‘men’ came to believe they text for proper social analysis (e.g., Coleman,
understood the institutional bases of human 1986; Jepperson & Meyer, 2007). And all
activity, they also came to believe they could this had a normative cast – social institutions
rise above, and control, them – no longer sub- that restricted the development and choices
ject to, but playing the parts of, the now-dead of real social actors could be seen as ineffi-
cultural gods. Embeddedness in culture and cient at the least, and perhaps as destructive
history was a property of the superstitious past, of freedom and progress.
over which the Moderns had triumphed. So The new models remain in force, and it is
institutional thinking could survive in anthro- now conventional in social science publica-
pology and about primitive societies (including tions to refer to ‘actors’ rather than people and
earlier Western history), but only tenuously in groups. But over time there have been doubts
the social sciences of Modernity (Meyer, 1988). about models of society and the world as
In short, the old institutionalisms were made up of interested actors, and only of
driven into marginality by the rise of (often actors. Too many studies of individual persons
policy-oriented and scientistic – see Toulmin, showed astounding levels of embedded non-
1990) conceptions of social life as made up actorhood in what were supposed to be politi-
of purposive, bounded, fairly rational, and cal, economic, and cultural choices.
rather free actors. Society was discovered, A whole literature on organization in actual
headed by the sovereign state as its central social life showed the overwhelming impor-
actor, freed by the constitution of Westphalia. tance of uncertainty in organizational
The human person as individual actor was (non)decisions (Cyert & March, 1992) and of
discovered, unleashed by markets, democ- the informal resolutions involved in practice
racy, property rights, and religious freedom. (Dalton, 1959; and many others): formalistic
And rationalized social life, made up of or technicist analyses (e.g. Perrow, 1970; Blau
bureaucracies essentially delegated from the & Shoenherr, 1971) seemed much too limited.
state (as in Weber or Fayol) or associations And notions of rational sovereign nation-state
built up by individual actors (as in Barnard), action as driving development did not stand up
was discovered and celebrated. against the realities of chaotic Third World
In the new schemes, built around notions nation-states, and the surrealities of the First
of society as made up of empowered actors, and Second Worlds’ Cold War.
792 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

So, since the 1970s, in every social science called ‘path dependence.’ So that individuals
field except anthropology (where older institu- or organizations, faced with a new problem,
tionalisms had never receded), ‘new’ institu- use their accustomed older solutions whether
tionalist theorizing appeared, with models or not these ever worked or can reasonably be
again envisioning people and groups as expected to work (see the various essays by
embedded in larger structures and cultures of March and his colleagues, 1988).
one sort or another (See Jepperson 2002 for In the present essay, we leave aside this
a review). There have been as many different line of institutional theory, and concentrate
varieties as in the ‘old’ institutionalisms, but only on lines of argument locating institu-
they all have had one main element in tionalized forces in wider environments than
common. They all have come to terms with the history of the actor itself. These tend to
one or another version of the idea that society fall on a broad continuum ranging from more
is made up of interested, purposive, and often realist theories to more phenomenological
rational actors. ones. After reviewing this range of argu-
If the old institutionalisms had seen people ments, we turn to focus more intensively on
and groups as rather naturally embedded in the phenomenological side of the spectrum,
broad cultural and structural contexts, the new which is of special interest here, the locus of
institutionalisms incorporate a tension in the the most distinctive advances in the field, and
conceptualized actor–environment relation. an important contribution to a field which
This is often seen as a stress between structure tends to merge theory and realist ideology in
(i.e., the environment) and agency or actorhood ways that are often unexciting.
(see e.g., Giddens, 1984; or Sewell, 1992), in
replication of the debates in the old institution-
alism about free will and determinism.
Realist institutionalisms
The new institutionalisms see the social
environment as affecting the behaviors and Some institutionalist lines of thought, arising
practices and ideas of people and groups now particularly in economics and political sci-
conceived as bounded, purposive and sover- ence, retain very strong notions of society as
eign actors. Many different lines of thought made up of bounded, purposive, sovereign,
are involved, varying in their conception of and rational actors. In economics, these
what an actor is, and what properties of might be individuals or organizations, oper-
which environments are relevant. ating in market-like environments. In politi-
cal science, they might be sovereign
national-states operating in an almost anar-
TYPES OF INSTITUTIONAL THEORY chic environment. Institutionalism, in such
schemes, involves the idea that some funda-
Most institutional theories see local actors – mental institutional principle must be in
whether individuals, organizations, or place before systems of such actors can
national states – as affected by institutions effectively operate. The classic core principle
built up in much wider environments. required in economic versions is property
Individuals and organizations are affected by rights (North & Thomas, 1973). In interna-
societal institutions, and national-states by a tional relations theory it is the principle of
world society. In this chapter, we focus on nation-state sovereignty (Krasner, 1999).
these lines of theory. Once the core principle is in place, sys-
But it can be noted that some other lines of tems of actors freed from further institutional
thought treat modern actors as affected by the influences are thought to function stably and
institutionalization built into their own histo- effectively over time. Indeed, further institu-
ries. Older ideas about habit, custom, and cul- tional interventions in the market or interna-
ture are resurrected as theories of what is now tional polity are thought, in extreme versions
REFLECTIONS ON INSTITUTIONAL THEORIES OF ORGANIZATIONS 793

of these traditions, to be counter-productive the institutional context of actorhood, and a


disturbances of rationality. There is a ten- conception of the modern actor as rather more
dency to see the situation as one of punctu- penetrable. The institutions have cultural or
ated equilibrium. Collective history operates discursive dimensions, and also structural or
briefly, creating the crucial change, and then organizational ones. The key term describing
stable equilibria ensue. So there are accounts institutionalized culture, here, is ‘norm,’ espe-
of the unique circumstances producing the cially common in political science (see for
construction of property rights in Western extended examples, Katzenstein, 1996). The
history. And there are discussions of the sim- key notions of institutionalized organization,
ilarly unique circumstances producing the especially utilized in sociology, are ‘relation’
magic of Westphalia, thought to undergird or ‘network’ (Granovetter, 1985).
the rise to world dominance of the Western A norm is a rule with some degree of bind-
nation-state system. ing authority over actors – for instance, in
Extreme realist institutionalism, thus, international relations, the principle that a state
retains very strong assumptions about the should not kill the diplomats representing
capacities of actors, and very limited pictures other states; or the proscription of chemical
of the institutional environment. The envi- weapons in war. In the most realist theories, a
ronment really contains only one narrow norm is created by the actors involved, and has
institutional rule – and in most versions it is binding power over an actor only inasmuch as
a rule created by the actors themselves, that actor continues to support it. In less realist
whose existence and character are seen as versions, norms may have been created by
entirely prior to the institutional regime. forces in the past, and may have binding power
Over time, realist institutionalism has whether or not present actors support them. In
tended to become a good deal less extreme, these latter accounts, norms are internalized by
and more realistic (see e.g., North, 1981). To actors through some sort of socialization
property rights, the economists add a variety of process: thus, in a compromised realism,
other important institutions needed to make the actors are partly creatures of the rules, not only
modern system go (Jepperson & Meyer, 2007). creators of them.
A variety of institutions must reproduce and Similarly, a network relation between
socialize the population, for instance, and a actors is a simple form of organizational
knowledge system is required to encourage institutionalization. Such relations are
technical improvements (Mokyr, 1992). And thought to constrain actors, as well as pro-
perhaps even some cultural supports for entre- vide opportunities for their activities. In the
preneurship are needed (Landes, 1998). most realist versions, actors create their net-
Similarly, realist political scientists add institu- works: in less realist models, the networks
tional elements necessary to make the world are more institutionalized, have prior
political system work: guarantees of agree- histories and external determinants and thus
ments, and trust, for example. In political sci- generate considerable path dependence.
ence realism, as well as in economics,
however, the institutions thought to be required
are also mainly thought to be products of the Sociological institutionalism I:
interested activity of the basic actors involved.
social organizational versions
Moving further away from realist models, we
come to some core ideas of modern sociolog-
Compromises with realism
ical institutionalism (see DiMaggio & Powell,
Moving away from more extreme realist 1983; Powell & DiMaggio, 1991; Scott, 2001;
thinking, much modern social science is built Jepperson, 2002; Hasse & Kruecken, 2005).
up around more complex pictures of Here, actors are substantially empowered and
794 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

controlled by institutional contexts, and these perspective in which the actors of modern
contexts go far beyond a few norms or net- society are seen, not simply as influenced by
work structures. Further, these contexts are by the wider environment, but as constructed in
no means simply constructions built up by the and by it (see Jepperson, 2002 for a review).
contemporary actors themselves, but rather Related ideas in political science are called
are likely to have prior and exogenous histori- ‘constructivism.’ Rationalized organizations
cal origins. as actors are creatures of rationalized envi-
Institutions, in these conceptions, are ronments (Meyer & Rowan, 1977; Meyer &
packages or programs of an expanded sort. Scott, 1983; see also Zucker, 1977). The indi-
‘Regimes’ is a term employed in political sci- vidual as actor is a continually expanding
ence for the idea – organizational packages construction of modernity (Meyer, 1986, fol-
infused with cultural meaning (often from lowing on a long discussion in the literature,
professions as epistemic communities). including Berger, Berger, & Kellner, 1973).
So one can refer to a neo-liberal regime in the The nation-state as actor is a construction of
contemporary world. Or an anti-trust pro- a world polity (Meyer, 1980; Thomas,
gram in earlier America (Fligstein, 1990). Meyer, Ramirez, & Boli, 1987; Meyer, Boli,
Sociologists capture this idea by referring to Thomas, & Ramirez, 1997).
societal sectors, or social fields, or arenas of The concept of ‘actor’ in this scheme is far
action. Institutions, in these senses, are com- removed from that envisioned in realist per-
plex and often coherent mixtures of cultural spectives. The realists imagine that people are
and organizational material. really bounded and purposive and sovereign
Similarly, the institutions involved pene- actors, and that nation-states are too. And so
trate actors in multiple and complex ways, are the organizations deriving from these. The
ranging from more realist formats to more sociological institutionalists, on the other
phenomenological ones. DiMaggio and hand, suppose that actorhood is a role or iden-
Powell (1983) provide a list that is much uti- tity, as in a theatrical world (Frank and Meyer
lized (see Scott 2001, for a related one). On 2002): individual actors, in this usage, have
the realist side, they argue that institutional socially conferred rights and responsibilities,
structures affect actors through what they and socially conferred agency to represent
call ‘coercive’ processes, including nation- these (and other) interests (Meyer &
state legal actions. On the middle ground, Jepperson, 2000). Actorhood, in this usage, is
they envision ‘normative’ controls of envi- scripted by institutional structures; and the
ronments over actors, emphasizing the influ- relation between actor and action is no longer
ence of professionalized standards. And then, a simple causal one – both elements have
moving to a more phenomenological per- institutional scripts behind them, and their
spective, they suppose that environments relation has, causally speaking, strong ele-
create standards that actors adopt ‘mimeti- ments of socially constructed tautology. That
cally,’ reflecting taken-for-granted standards. is, the actor–action relation is a package, and
At this point, actors are not really well- as people and groups enter into particular
bounded entities any more, but may be built forms of actorhood, the appropriate actions
up of cultural and organizational materials come along and are not usefully to be seen as
from their environments. choices and decisions. Institutional theories,
thus, do not depend on particularly elaborate
social psychological assumptions about
Sociological institutionalism II: people or groups: almost any social psycho-
logical model is good enough to explain what
phenomenological versions
institutionalization has made socially obvious.
A key turning point in the rise of the new Thus, when a group of modern people
institutionalism is the development of a gather to assemble or change an organization,
REFLECTIONS ON INSTITUTIONAL THEORIES OF ORGANIZATIONS 795

they do not do so from scratch. Everywhere, extreme cultural dependence of modern organi-
there are models put in place by law, ideol- zational structures. Thus, the institutionalists
ogy, culture, and a variety of organizational emphasize that much modern social rationali-
constraints and opportunities. People are zation has mythic functions encouraging the
likely to install these in the organization they formation of organizations and their compo-
are building with little by way of thought or nents. This sometimes leads to criticisms that
decision: exotic psychological assumptions institutionalism is only about ‘symbols’ rather
are not required. There will be offices and than ‘realities,’ and institutionalist research
departments that were unknown a few occasionally in fact makes this mistake. On the
decades ago (CFO, or Chief Financial Officer; other hand, the realists, ignoring the depend-
HR, or Human Relations Department). Few ence of modern organizational structure on the
will spend time deciding to adopt these insti- rapidly-expanding myths of rationality, have
tutions, and thus perhaps the word ‘mimetic’ no serious explanation for the rise – in every
applies. But it is an imprecise word, in this con- country, every social sector, and almost every
text, because the people adopting the new detailed social activity – of so much modern
structures will often be able to articulate organization itself (Drori et al., 2006).
clearly the legitimating rationales for their Phenomenological ideas are by no means
action, as if these were thought-out purposes. incompatible with more realist ones – in
The purposes come along with the enterprise. most situations, both can be true and often
As an illustration at the individual level, are. Tensions arise because realist models
any good student in a prestigious American tend to be exclusionary and core modern ide-
university ought to be able, almost instanta- ologies, undergirding polity, economy, cul-
neously, to write some paragraphs about ture, and society. They are normative models
‘why I decided to go to college.’ But on as well as cognitive ones, and thus alternative
inspection, it turns out that almost none of lines of thought are seen as in part normative
these students actually decided to go to col- violations. Further, closed-system realist
lege, as they had never contemplated any models are often central to policy advice, and
alternative. Going to college was taken for this function is limited by more open-system
granted. Indeed, any student who had spent institutional theories.
serious time deciding whether or not to go to
college would be very unlikely to have a
record enabling admission to a prestigious The career of sociological
one. Nevertheless, many researchers study-
institutional theory
ing college attendance formulate their task as
analyzing a ‘decision’ – a decision they prob- The phenomenological perspectives of socio-
ably never made, and their subjects probably logical institutionalism have prospered over
never made. A number of methodological the last three decades. Before discussing why
errors follow, and beset the research tradition this is so, we need to note why it should not
involved. Parallel errors characterize much have been so.
research in the field of organizations and
states: decision analyses of matters never in The ideological absorption of
fact decided. Mistakes of this sort routinely institutional ideas
follow from the established realist assump- Modern social science, following on modern
tions that human activity, more or less by ideology, celebrates a social world made up
definition, follows from choices. of strong actors, in the realist sense. Theory
Sociological institutionalism of the phenom- and ideology give great emphasis to notions
enological sort is not only furthest from real- of society as a product of such actors and
ism, but arises in some opposition to it. Realist their purposes. Methods of social research,
theory, it is argued, grossly understates the and public data collection, build data on and
796 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

around these units, and define proper analyses developments, in American organizational
as focused on both their independence and life, around affirmative action pressures and
their purposive action. And normative ideolo- requirements (see Dobbin & Sutton, 1998;
gies infusing both research and public life Edelman, 1992; Dobbin, Sutton, Meyer, &
give much preference to treatments that take Scott, 1993; Edelman, Uggen, & Erlanger,
individual persons (and also nation-states and 1999). After the long wave of legalizing pres-
organizations) as highly interested and agen- sures on organizations, a whole set of
tic actors (Jepperson & Meyer, 2007). schemes are produced – policies, offices, and
More concretely, modern democratic professions – responding to these pressures.
political systems rest, for their legitimacy, on Organizations incorporate packages of these.
doctrines of free individual choice. If the But after a time, it is all naturalized in the pre-
individuals and their choices are construc- ferred models of relatively rational actorhood.
tions of the powers of the system itself, the And by now, any reasonable organizational
legitimacy of democracy tends to disappear. manager would be able to explain why his or
Similarly, if choices of individuals and her organization has affirmative action poli-
organizations in markets are in fact ‘wired’ cies – these policies are obviously the best
consequences of the market system, the legit- way to ensure hiring the most able people.
imacy of the free economy is undercut. The Given that the processes stressed by the
same points can be made about religious and phenomenological versions of institutional
cultural choices in the nominally free society. theory are in many ways constantly undercut
Thus, there are cultural tendencies in the or absorbed by evolving modern organiza-
modern actor-centered society to celebrate tional systems, the question arises as to what
actors in a very realist sense: these tenden- forces keep these lines of theory alive, well,
cies are very strong ideological currents in and in fact prospering. If the social world
the social sciences. Social science influence were moving toward a modern equilibrium,
over policy tends to depend on them we have noted above, institutional theories
(Jepperson & Meyer, 2007). would tend to be absorbed in a socially con-
Consider that much organizational research structed realist ideology. Obviously, equilib-
and theory go on, worldwide, in schools of rium is not what is going on.
business and education and public policy. The rapid social changes distinctive to the
These schools are built on the notion that period since World War II have tended to
organizational leaders are decision-makers, create rapid cultural expansions of the sorts
and their main tasks are to train their students attended to by institutional theories. The
to be such decision-makers. They are in no period, in other words, creates both institu-
position to emphasize that their students are, tional theories and a globalizing social world
or should be, drifting non-decision-making which operates along the lines suggested by
followers of institutionalized currents. Scott those theories.
(2007), for instance, defends realist institu-
tional theory on precisely these grounds. Stateless globalizations
Thus, as new institutional forces are built Recent centuries of development have system-
up in the modern system, the system atically tended to create interdependencies
itself tends to absorb them in expanded theo- transcending the organizational capacities of
ries of actorhood and decision-making. extant political systems to maintain control
Organizational members and research ana- (classically, Wallerstein, 1974). Rapid expan-
lysts tend over time to see the organizational sion and globalization have created sweeping
elements newly adopted under institutional economic, political, social and cultural forms
pressures as if they were functional, rational, of (often conflictful) movement and integra-
and reasonable organizational choices. This tion extending far beyond the boundaries of
process is analyzed with care in studies of the controlling organizational structures. Forces for
REFLECTIONS ON INSTITUTIONAL THEORIES OF ORGANIZATIONS 797

social control and stability, thus, emphasize version of a world polity or society around
both the authority and the responsibilities of notions of lawful nature, inherent rationality,
the existing actors in national and world soci- and the natural rights of humans (or, in gen-
ety. At the world level, meanings have piled up, eral, natural law: Thomas et al., 1987; Meyer
rationalizing and expanding the powers and et al., 1997). These movements take the form
responsibilities of national states. And simi- of broad global wave-like developments, and
larly, individualisms, stressing the rights, a ‘wave theory’ like sociological institution-
powers, and capacities of individuals, have alism is appropriate for the massive changes
expanded enormously, supporting for example involved.
the long-term and dramatic expansion of edu- Thus the character of worldwide social
cation around the world (Boli & Ramirez, change since World War II continually rein-
1987; Meyer, Ramirez & Soysal, 1992). The forces the more phenomenological versions of
whole process is analyzed in Tocqueville’s dis- sociological institutional theory. I briefly note
cussion of social control in stateless America some of these massive social changes, and
(1836/1969), and his emphasis on the resultant their wave-like diffusive character. All the
empowerment and control of the individual, changes involved refer to laws and rationalities
including the rapid expansion of a great deal of and rights built into nature rather than particu-
mobilized and rationalized social organization. lar societies. They are built around rapidly-
The term globalization now tends to refer expanding meaning systems and formally
to (a) economic interdependencies, and structured in decentralized associational for-
(b) very recent time periods. But for our pur- mats rather than around sovereign actorhood.
poses, the time frame is much longer, and the First, there is in place of positive law the
interdependencies involved more political, dramatic expansion of science (Drori, Meyer,
social, cultural, and military than economic. Ramirez, & Schofer, 2003). Science expands
The post World War II period represented a exponentially in terms of numbers of people
dramatic up-turn in the long history. The fail- and amounts of resources involved, and also
ure of social control in an interdependent in terms of the social authority it carries. It
world was dramatic and incontrovertible. expands enormously in terms of content cov-
Two devastating world wars (both between erage, as essentially all aspects of natural and
supra-state forces), a disastrous depression social worlds come under scientific scrutiny.
seen as rooted in nationalist provincialisms, And it expands spatially, finding a strong
the holocaust and sweeping destruction of presence in essentially all the societies of the
social life, and the end of normal war given world. Science, as reality and even more as
nuclear weaponry, all made it obvious that metaphor, provides a cognitive and norma-
new forms of order and control were neces- tive base for all sorts of integrating world
sary. This was all enhanced by the Cold War regulation – making the world more govern-
conflict, and by the destruction of the older able (Foucault, 1991; Rose & Miller, 1992;
stabilizing colonial arrangements. An old Drori & Meyer, 2006).
nominally-anarchic world of conflicting Beyond science, there is the enormous
nation-states was no longer remotely justifi- expansion of rationalizing social science – by
able: war, for instance, lost meaning as a far the most rapidly expanding fields in the
heroic achievement in interstate competition. life of the university in the last half of the
But on the other hand nothing like a world twentieth century (Drori & Moon, 2006;
state was plausible. Frank & Gabler, 2006). Theories, and occa-
In the absence of much possibility for sionally evidence, expand rapidly and take
state-like world organization, with a cultural the center stage in much policy-making
system organized around positive law, the around the world. In a world celebrating the
world has produced an astonishing set of equality of persons and societies, rationalis-
socio-cultural movements building up a tic social theories are seen as applicable
798 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

everywhere: any country can develop, any et al., 2006). The old nation-state, with its
person can be equipped with cultural capital, passive bureaucracies, is reformulated as a
independent of time and place. And any modern organization, filled with agencies that
organization, anywhere, can and should be a are to function as autonomous and account-
rational actor. able organizations (i.e., actors: Brunsson &
Second, in partial replacement for an older Sahlin-Andersson, 2000). Old family firms
Modern celebration of the primordiality of are reconstructed as modern organizations
the national-state, there is the dramatic rise with empowered managerial capabilities,
of a natural law emphasis on human rights. and with work forces full of participatory
The standing of persons as citizens of modern individual actors. Traditional struc-
national states is replaced by a greatly tures housing professionals – hospitals and
expanded set of doctrines of the person as an schools and legal and accounting partner-
entitled and empowered member of the ships – are reformulated as real agentic social
human race in a global society (e.g., Soysal, actors, capable of the highly purposive pur-
1994). More and more categories of humans suit of their own goals (Scott, Ruef, Mendel,
are directly capacitated in this system – & Caronna, 2000).
women, children, old people, handicapped All of the institutionalizations of the new
people, gay and lesbian people, indigenous globalized (or ‘knowledge,’ or ‘post-
people, racial and ethnic minorities, and so modern’) society noted above find a core
on (for examples, see Ramirez, Soysal, & basis in the dramatically expanded educa-
Shanahan, 1998; Berkovitch, 1999; Frank & tional systems of the post-War world (Meyer
McEneaney, 1999; Abu Sharkh, 2002). And et al., 1992, for mass education; Schofer &
the moral and legal principles involved rap- Meyer, 2005, for the university). The univer-
idly take coverage (though commonly not sity, in particular, is the core home of the
practical effect) worldwide (Hathaway, 2002; explosions of scientific analyses of nature,
Tsutsui & Wotipka, 2004; Cole, 2005; and rationalistic analyses of social life that
Hafner-Burton & Tsutsui, 2005). try to tame the modern supra-national envi-
The new human, in this expanding system, ronment. And it is the core home where ordi-
has greatly enhanced rights, and responsibil- nary persons of an older world are
ities. But also greatly expanded attributed transformed into knowledgeable and empow-
capacities for economic, political, social, and ered carriers of ‘human capital’ for the new
cultural action. These capacities support the society (Frank & Meyer, 2007). If classic
extraordinary worldwide expansion in both bureaucratic structures of the Modern society
mass and elite education in the world since rested on populations equipped with mass
World War II (Meyer, Ramirez & Soysal, education (Stinchcombe, 1965), the organi-
1992; Schofer & Meyer, 2005). zations of the Knowledge Society rest on
The expanded model of empowered and university-installed knowledge and empow-
entitled individuals, operating in a tamed and erment (Frank & Meyer, 2007). Worldwide,
scientized natural and social environment, about 20 percent of a cohort of young per-
generates – as in Tocqueville’s America – the sons is enrolled in university-level training
expanded modern picture of the human actor; (Schofer & Meyer, 2005).
and of the host of social organizations this
actor creates. The world is now filled with Actors and others
human persons who assume the posture of The post-War period has, thus, experienced
empowered actor, and have the capacity to dramatic expansion in cultural rationaliza-
create and participate in collective organiza- tion. On the one side there has been the
tions formed as social actors. exponential and global growth of the scien-
So organization and organizations blos- tific and rationalistic analysis of natural
som everywhere (see the studies in Drori and social environments. On the other lies
REFLECTIONS ON INSTITUTIONAL THEORIES OF ORGANIZATIONS 799

a similarly exponential and global growth in occupations, agency with very constrained
the rights and powers attributed to the human interested actorhood has been a great
beings who enter into society. And in the cul- success: everywhere there are consulting
turally-constructed crucible at the center of firms, therapists, advisors, researchers, and
all this, the result is the extraordinary modern other creatures of a higher purity.
growth in social actors. Passive old national Thus actors themselves often step out
state bureaucracies turn into actors filled of their narrow actorhood, and take on
with plans and strategies. And persons every- the higher calling of agency for universal
where shift from traditional (i.e., peasant) truths and the collective good. So we have
identities into modern schooled ones: as an successful national-states offering them-
indicator, persons turned actors are able to selves to their competitors as models of the
opine on all sorts of general questions – and proper conduct of business. And successful
survey research can now be done almost organizations delighted to display their
anywhere (Meyer & Jepperson 2000). virtues, rather than concealing them from
But the question arises, who is doing all the competition. And individual persons
this cultural construction? Who or what sup- entering into public life with disinterested
ports the rationalization of the natural and analyses of what their President should do
social environments? Who props up all the (Jepperson, 2002a).
new human rights and powers? If ‘interested actor’ is one core role in the
The world of actors – entitled and empow- modern system, we need a term for the roles
ered beings with the rights to have goals and of actors that adopt a legitimated posture of
the capacities to be agents in pursuit of those disinterest, and tell more interested actors
goals – is also a world in which the same how to be and what to do. I suggest the old
actors have the legitimated capacity to use Meadian concept of ‘Other’ (Meyer, 1999).
their agency in pursuit of collective goods of The modern world is filled with these others.
all sorts. Indeed, the agency of actors is There are the representatives of the whales
collectively legitimated and dependent. In and other creatures, of the distant ecological
this sense, a properly constructed actor is future, and of the rights of humans in the
always partly an agent for one or another most distant places and cultures (e.g., over
collectivity – in the modern system, often a issues like female genital cutting – see Boyle,
fairly universal one – as well as an agent for 2002). And there are the proponents of social
his or her own needs and goals as actors rationality and critics of corruption anywhere
(Meyer & Jepperson, 2000). Thus modern in the world. Closer to home, there are the
actors are partly above petty interest, and are advisors and therapists, offering consultation
agents for more general and universal goods. to individuals and organizations and
So the most rapidly expanding individual national-states on how to be more virtuous
occupations, worldwide, are the nominally and more effective actors.
disinterested professions: they may partly This whole system offers explanatory
serve particular interests, but they are in opportunities calling for sociological institu-
good part agents for the collective – more tional theories. The modern nominally-realist
accurately for what used to be called God interested actor is at every side surrounded
(Truth, and the like). And the most rapidly by institutions with much cultural character
expanding organizational structures in the and legitimacy – the sciences and professions
world may, similarly, be the non-govern- constructing the rationalized environment of
mental and often non-profit organizations proper ‘action,’ the legal and intellectual con-
that serve as agents for various universal structers of expanded human rights and
goods, often at the global level (Boli & capacities, and the ‘Others’ who create these
Thomas, 1999). And even among the more arrangements and who often directly instruct
mundane profit-making organizations and the expanded actors. And of course, the
800 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

expanded actors themselves, who enhance that national population control policies tend
their value by displaying their virtuous actor- to arise in countries with ties to modern
hood, and whose expanded and virtuous demography, a typical institutional argument.
actorhood is utterly dependent on a host of But they are not surprised to find that
sciences, legal and intellectual supports, and national population control policies tend also
therapists and consultants. In fact, the to arise in countries with great population
modern individual actor tends to incorporate density. Institutional theory is not closely
much of this material in the expanded ‘self.’ tied to broader philosophical concerns, but
And the modern organizational or nation- has rather developed as a set of very general
state actor certainly incorporates enormous sociological explanatory ideas.
amounts of this material – often as profes- To assess the status of sociological institu-
sionalized roles – within its formal structure. tionalism, we review its four most important
explanatory ideas. These ideas make up a
simple causal chain accounting for stability
The core arguments of sociological and change in modern organizational struc-
institutional theory: status and tures. First, expansive modern institutional-
prospects ized models of states and societies are
commonly generated, not only by interested
Sociological institutional theory employs actors, but by what above we called ‘others’ –
general phenomenological perspectives collective participants like professions and
which often have many dimensions and social movements and non-governmental
which can make up a broad vision of social structures. Second, states and other organiza-
life and of methods for studying it. tions tend prominently to reflect institution-
Methodologically, a taste for qualitative and alized models in standardized ways, not
highly interpretive research is sometimes simply the local resources and powers and
involved. Substantively, critical perspectives interests that vary so greatly around the
on the modern liberal society are often world. Third, there is the idea that because
emphasized, sometimes from the conserva- states and other organizations reflect highly
tive right, and on other occasions from the standardized institutionalized models, but
left. Sometimes, society itself is seen as also variable local life in practice, a great
entirely an interpretive construction, with deal of decoupling between more formal
other realities entering in only insofar as they structures and practical adaptation is to be
enter social interpretive systems. expected. Fourth, there is the idea that insti-
As it has developed, sociological institu- tutionalized models are likely to have strong
tional theory is tied to none of these broader diffusive or wave-like effects on the orienta-
philosophical perspectives. Methodologi- tions and behavior of all sorts of participants
cally, it has commonly been pursued with in organizational life, whether or not they are
quite standard (often quantitative) proce- incorporated in formal policies.
dures. Its ties to any normative perspective
on modern society are weak: at the most, it Cultural and institutional forces affect the
carries an ironic distance from a naïve development of institutional models
liberalism. And there is no special tendency As a result of extensive research showing the
to deny the operation of many different impact of institutionalized models on organi-
theories (and variables) in the analysis of the zations of all sorts, argumentation in the field
modern system – sociological institutional- of macro-social research has shifted to the
ism emphasizes causal structures rooted in question about the origins of the models
culture and interpretation, but is not given to involved. For instance, we know that the
denying other lines of causal process. Thus worldwide emphasis on the rights of women
Barrett, Kurzman and Shanahan (2006) note has greatly impacted policy and practice
REFLECTIONS ON INSTITUTIONAL THEORIES OF ORGANIZATIONS 801

everywhere (Bradley & Ramirez, 1996; the assumption of very strong and agentic
Ramirez et al., 1998). So it becomes impor- human actorhood. So attacks along the line
tant to ask what produced the worldwide that powerful and interested actors in the
emphases involved. background drive the creation of institutional
Very extreme realists argue that institutions models have been intensive (e.g,
are produced by the mixture of power and Stinchcombe, 2001; Hirsch, 1997; Hirsch &
interest in the actors of the system – the only Lounsbury, 1997). And to a striking extent,
entities such realists recognize as existing. some institutionalists have taken positions
This makes the institutions involved relatively that are almost apologetic in response (Scott,
minor in importance, since an adequate 2007; DiMaggio, 1988), apparently conced-
analysis can be obtained simply by under- ing that behind the façade of institutional
standing the extant structures of actor power structure inevitably lie real men of power.
and interest. A more moderate realism sees a Sociological institutionalists, of course, do
‘sticky equilibrium’ as involved – institutions not take issue with the argument that many
are created by mixtures of actor power and institutionalized patterns may directly reflect
interest, but may take on something of a life the power and interest of dominant states or
of their own afterwards. A still more moder- other organizations. But, especially under
ate realism supposes that there are some conditions of modern globalization as we
mediators in the power and interest game – discuss above, institutionalists observe dra-
some participants (possibly professionals, matic effects that do not reflect the mechan-
or other honest brokers) who help in the ics of power and interest. In global society,
enterprise. and also in other organizational arenas, many
Beyond this point, realism may be com- other phenomena operate — reflecting the
bined with a more political or sociological dependence of modern expanded actors on
view. Stinchcombe (2001) develops an argu- institutionalized scripts operating in their
ment along these lines, imagining that actors environments. For example:
and perhaps some mediators struggle to work
out general institutional rules that reflect ● Professionalized and scientized forces may gen-
local power and interest circumstances but erate rules coming to terms with modern sci-
also reflect functional requirements of the ences and rationalities, and with modern notions
whole enterprise. In his work, he often thinks of human rights and welfare. Despite powerful
interests working in the opposite direction, for
of institutional arrangements in complicated
instance, environmental policies like the ozone
sectors like the construction industry as layer agreements have taken on considerable
instances. His arguments apply less clearly to force (Meyer, Frank, Hironaka et al., 1997b; Frank,
the worldwide rise of something like gay and Hironaka & Schofer, 2000). Similarly, it is difficult
lesbian rights (Frank & McEneaney, 1999). to see power and interest – and easy to see pro-
Given the great successes of institutional- fessionalized forces – behind the worldwide
ist analyses in showing the great impact of movement to restrict female genital cutting
environmental models on the structures and (Boyle, 2002). Large-scale social movement struc-
programs of organizational actors in the tures and non-governmental organizations are
modern system, realism has been on the obviously involved in the construction of many
defensive. One position to which it has institutional systems. Thus many programs for
organizational rationality, like the International
retreated is the stance that, while moden
Standards Organization, or various bodies stress-
actors copy environmental models, these ing improved accounting arrangements, find their
models themselves must have been put in origins in forces considerably removed from
place by hard-line realist forces of power and simple matters of power and interest (see the
interest. Realism has, as noted above, papers in Sahlin-Andersson & Engwall, 2002;
strongly legitimated and legitimating roots in Djelic & Quack, 2003; Djelic & Sahlin-Andersson,
the modern system, which clearly rests on 2006; Drori et al., 2006 for extended examples).
802 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

● Constructions of institutional models may reflect social audiences are so eagerly responsive
successes and failures in organizational or inter- (Drori et al., 2003).
national stratification systems, without necessar- Similarly, realists tend to see any diffusive
ily reflecting the interests of the powerful bodies influence of the stratification system as indi-
in that system. Because globalization involves cating the power and interest of the elites of
the construction of myths of underlying world
that system. This is implausible. Thus, in
similarity, an extraordinary amount of diffusion
goes on as a matter of fashion (Strang & Meyer,
global society, the world environment move-
1993). So Japanese economic success of the ment clearly reflects the values and orienta-
1980s produced a little wave of Japanified poli- tions of American society. But the American
cies around the world, in no way reflecting the national-state actor clearly resists subscrib-
purposive power or interest of the Japanese ing to this system, as do leading American
national-state. Similarly, there is much imitation corporations. As another example, the world
of elite firms in any industry, whether or not the human rights movement clearly reflects
elite firms encourage, or gain from, this imitation. American values: but the American national-
● When powerful or successful organizations in state actor was reluctant to have a human
fact portray themselves as models for others, it is rights declaration built into the United
often unclear that they are acting in what is ordi-
Nations; and continues to refuse to ratify var-
narily conceived to be their interest. The
American national-state, for instance, likes to
ious human rights treaties. In exactly the
encourage others to do things the ‘right’ way – same way, massive worldwide efforts at all
the American way – as a matter of encouraging sorts of organizational reform and rationali-
virtue in the world. There is no evidence that zation clearly reflect American ideologies of
much of this aid activity particularly benefits the organization: but the American national-state
interests of the American state. aggressively resists participation.
Exactly the same criticisms can be made
In many areas, institutional and realist expla- of realist argument in other organizational
nations of the development of institutional- arenas. Elite universities may be sources of
ized models overlap. And conflicts between much educational rationalist ideology, but
them are often conflicts over the interpreta- are often organizationally primitive (e.g.,
tion of the effects of the same variables. Thus Oxford, Harvard). The same is true of elite
when institutionalists note the impact of pro- firms and agencies.
fessionalized models (e.g., in the accounting All in all, in the modern stateless but glob-
area), the realists talk grimly of the profes- alized world, institutionalist arguments
sions involved as carrying out ‘professional explaining the dramatic rise of cultural
projects’ presumably to enhance their inter- models of expanded actorhood show every
ests and powers (see Abbott, 1988 for exam- prospect of continued success. Only in a
ples often incorporating this sort of more stabilized world society would the
reasoning). The impact of the scientists who process of social construction of actor
discovered the ozone layer problem is, how- motivations catch up, creating the proper
ever, difficult to interpret as a simple appearance of an apparently realist world
Machiavellian scheme to enhance the power society.
of the sciences. And, indeed, the whole ‘pro-
fessions as plots against the body politic’ Institutionalized models affect
scheme runs into the problem that the picture the construction of actors
of the profession as a rational self-interested The most conspicuous success of sociologi-
actor requires the assumption that the general cal institutional theory has been in the
population is naïve and foolish. This is unre- demonstration of powerful effects of institu-
alistic: explaining the expanded authority of tional models on the construction and modi-
the sciences in the modern system requires fication of actors. Thus national-state
an institutional analysis of why so many structures reflect standard world models,
REFLECTIONS ON INSTITUTIONAL THEORIES OF ORGANIZATIONS 803

despite the enormous resource and cultural Meyer, 2005). Coercive pressures were
variability of the world (Meyer et al., 1997). clearly not involved – indeed the centers of
Schools similarly reflect both world and power in world society (e.g., the United
national social forms. And so do firms and States, the World Bank, or the major corpora-
hospitals and organizations in essentially any tions) tended initially to be skeptical about
other sector (Drori et al., 2006). Furthermore, the virtues of ‘overeducation’ for impover-
extant actors of these sorts change over ished countries. Similarly, global standards
time, reflecting changes in institutionalized of women’s rights tended to produce national
models. reactions quite apart from any coercive
Now that effects of this sort are widely forces. And in other areas – like environmen-
and routinely recognized in the field, discus- tal policy, or efforts to build international
sion shifts to questions of mechanisms. quality standards – where realists try to
Institutionalists, convincingly, show that discern coercive pressure, empirical analyses
organizational conformity to standard models tend to be unconvincing.
is widespread and can occur in very routine Contested areas of interpretation, here,
ways through taken-for-granted understand- revolve around the impact of professional
ings. They commonly show the effects of bodies and non-governmental organizations.
processes such as simple linkage between The sorts of normative pressures produced
organizational settings and the wider environ- by these forces can be given something of a
ments carrying the institutions. Thus, at the realist interpretation. The problem is that the
nation-state level, world models are adopted relevant professions and associations are
more quickly in countries with many non- amply represented inside actors, not only
governmental organizational linkages to outside them. That is, modern national and
world society (Meyer et al., 1997). Similarly, organizational actors already incorporate in
professional linkages facilitate the quick their own authority systems formal represen-
adoption of environmental policies (Frank tatives of the wider world cultures dealing
et al., 2000, call the professions ‘receptor with the environment, organizational ration-
sites’ for the local incorporation of wider alization, human rights, and so on. Modern
rationalized models). At the organizational organizations and national-states appear to
level, the adoption of fashionable personnel be eager to construct themselves as actors,
policies is enhanced by having professional- thus incorporating, often wholesale, global
ized personnel officers (Dobbin et al., 1993). standards (for nation-state examples, see
Realists try to see processes of coercive McNeely, 1995; or Boli, 1987).
power as involved in such relationships, and In an expanding and globalizing world
there are situations in which this is clearly society, people and groups everywhere seem
the case. But the rapid social changes we to be eager to be actors – this often takes
have discussed as globalization continue to precedence over other goals, and can produce
generate waves of organizational change that assertions of actor identity far from any actual
cannot easily be conceived as reflecting actor capability. People, in short, may put
straightforward coercive power and control more effort into being actors than into acting.
by environments. Wave-like processes are We can see this readily in the empirical
endemic in the modern system (Czarniawska studies of modern individuals in increasing
& Sevón, 1996), and institutional theories numbers of countries. They produce opinions
gain much credibility from the obvious and judgments, routinely, in matters they
empirical situations involved. know nothing about. A good American,
Thus, with the global rise in conceptions it seems clear, would produce opinions
of the nation-state as a development-oriented about whether the United States should
social actor, university enrollments shot invade a country that does not exist. Good
up in every type of country (Schofer & organizations have policies about things that
804 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

never occur. National states promote world The institutionalist answer is that actor struc-
norms with which they have no capacity to tures, forms, and policies reflect institutional
conform at home. Agentic actorhood is, in prescriptions and models in the wider envi-
the modern system, a central good (Meyer & ronment. Such institutional models make it
Jepperson, 2000; Frank & Meyer, 2002). possible to build great organizations in situa-
Some of the intellectual tensions involved tions where little actual control is likely or
here – between a realistic institutionalism and possible – school systems, for instance; or in
an unrealistic realism – show up in a discus- developing countries, national-states.
sion by Mizruchi and Fein (1999). These This line of argument has had much
researchers, committed to an older realist tra- empirical success in the cross-national study
dition in the study of organizations, seem of national-states. It is common, now, to dis-
puzzled by the extraordinary citation atten- cover that nation-states subscribe to human
tion continuingly given to the classic paper by rights standards – but the subscribers are no
DiMaggio and Powell (1983). So they turn more likely to implement these standards
from their normal work as organizational in practice than are the non-subscribers
researchers to become sociologists of science (Hathaway, 2002; Cole, 2005; Hafner-Burton
(it is often a dangerous business for social sci- & Tsutsui, 2005). The same finding holds for
entists to study their own fields), and to inves- research on child labor rates (Abu Sharkh,
tigate the uses of the classic paper. They are 2002), and for research on the education of
disturbed by the fact that few references pick women (Bradley & Ramirez, 1996).
up on the more realist themes in the paper The line of argument has had dramatic
(coercive isomorphism, which can readily be empirical success in studies of organizations,
subsumed by realists; and normative isomor- too. Brunsson (1985; 1989), develops it as a
phism, which a realist can re-shape into con- contrast between policy talk and practical
formity). And all the research emphasis goes action. He sees a hypocritical inconsistency
to the famous ‘mimetic isomorphism,’ which between the two as a central consequence
lies far from the realist track. The reason for and requirement for the rationalized society.
this is obvious: any line of interpretation that Thus, inconsistency that to realists is a social
can be given a realist spin, in modern social problem is to Brunsson a stabilizing solution.
science, tends to be given that spin. So insti- In other work, the line of argument is
tutionalist arguments tend to survive best if extended to account for the high frequency of
they are furthest from realism. Oddly, organizational reforms, and the lack of con-
Mizruchi himself later ends up employing sequences of much reform (Brunsson &
mimetic isomorphism as an explanatory idea Olsen, 1993). If reform is commonly a
(Mizruchi, Stearns, & Marquis, 2006). process of constructing improved actorhood,
rather than improved action, the often-
The construction of actors is often noted ‘failure of implementation’ is to be
loosely coupled with practical activity expected. Given the enormously exaggerated
Sociological institutional theory, in part, models of the proper actor – individuals and
arose from the observation that organizational organizations alike – characteristic of the
policies and structures are often loosely cou- modern globalized world, any respectable
pled with practical activity (Meyer & Rowan, reform should have excellent prospects for
1977, 1978). Given this commonly recog- disimplementation.
nized reality, the question arose – why are the Despite its obvious uses, the concept of
structures and policies there? The question ‘loose coupling’ has been a considerable
took force from the fact that conventional source of tension in the field. This arises
theories of organizational structure empha- because realist thinking is quite central to
size that, for functional and political reasons, modern ideology as well as to much social
structure is put in place to control activity. theory. And from a realist point of view,
REFLECTIONS ON INSTITUTIONAL THEORIES OF ORGANIZATIONS 805

decoupling between organizational rules and piece of poetry (Bendor, Moe, & Shotts,
policies and programs and roles, on the one 2001). They proved that the illustrative simu-
hand, and local practical action, on the other, lation models (which it seems nobody had in
is deeply problematic. Rules are created by fact taken very seriously) were inconsistent
powerful and interested actors, desiring to with the real arguments of the paper, and
control action. They are put in place in par- made dramatic assertions about this as indi-
ticular organizations because the interests of cating a fundamental failure of the scientific
powerful actors demanded it. They should enterprise involved. (Again, the authors
normally be implemented in practice. Only rested the importance of their paper on asser-
limited realist theory can explain why not. tions about the nature of science itself – often
(a) Perhaps the powerful actors creating rules a warning sign in the social sciences, e.g.,
want to deceive the world around them. But p. 169: ‘We evaluate the verbal theory and
if they are so powerful, why would they need argue that it fails to create an adequate
to do this? And if they do depend on impres- foundation for scientific progress.’)
sions of others, why are these others so easily
deceived? (b) Perhaps particular actors sub- Institutionalized models impact practices
scribe formally to the rules intending to independent of organized actor adoption
deceive the powerful forces behind these In the modern system, institutionalized
rules. But if so, why are the powerful forces forces usually diffuse more as cultural waves
so easily deceived? (c) Perhaps local partici- than through point-to-point diffusion. Thus,
pants simply cheat on the organized actor, standards arise in world discourse, promul-
suboptimally going their own way and vio- gated by professional consensus and associa-
lating the rules. If so, why are organized tional advocacy. The new emphasis might be,
actors so little able to notice? say, on the improved treatment of children
The extreme tension experienced by realist with some specific handicaps. National
theorists over the ‘loose coupling’ notion can states, of course, adopt appropriate policies
be illustrated by the treatment of a renowned with some probability, which might vary
initial essay on the subject. Before the rise of depending on their linkage to the world
new institutional theories, March and his col- organizations and professions involved.
laborators, working from the ‘uncertainty’ But of course organizations internal to that
tradition, produced a precursor. Their essay state are also immersed in responsible agentic
was called ‘A Garbage Can Model of actorhood organized by the global culture. So
Organizational Choice’ (Cohen, March, & independent of national policy, schools and
Olsen, 1972). Instead of working from medical organizations and professional asso-
rational decision models outward to incorpo- ciations and even some business firms would
rate more uncertainty, this essay started from be likely to notice the new models and incor-
the frame of decision-making under almost porate aspects of them. This might depend on
complete uncertainty. The authors illustrated their own linkages to world society.
their points with some quickly forgotten sim- And independent of what policies and
ulation models, but the impact of the paper – programs states and non-state organizations
on a field that had grown a bit deadly – was put in place, modern people too tend to be
simply as a strong fundamental theoretical agentic actors immersed in wider society
image or metaphor. The paper is much cited, (including global society). So all sorts of local
almost entirely for its grounding imagery actors – parents, teachers, medical profes-
rather than its specific analytic points. sionals, neighbors, relatives – have some
Interestingly, thirty years later, several probability of picking up the new world or
researchers committed to the extreme national story lines, independent of the
rational choice version of realism, found it national state policies or of any organized
necessary to mount a massive attack on this actor at all.
806 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Realist theories, with very limited concep- over time are too weakly standardized to tell
tions of the embeddedness of actors in wider (Hafner-Burton & Tsutsui, 2005).
cultural arrangements, tend to have blind Similar studies at the organizational level
spots on such processes. And for this reason, of analysis show similar effects. Practices in
realist theories – and thus much social scien- the treatment of employees, for instance,
tific theory and ideology – have the drift along following world or national
greatest difficulty accounting for large-scale models in good part independent of formal
modern social change, because such change policies (Drori et al., 2006). In the same way,
tends to flow through diffusive waves rather the practices of teachers or doctors reflect
than down through an organized realist shifting customs in good part independent of
ladder of world to state to organization organizational policies (Coburn, 2004).
to individual effects. The global expansion Realist theories have little to say about
of organization (and organization theory) such broader effects. So sweeping social
itself is an excellent example (Drori changes occur, at the edges of social
et al., 2006). scientific notice. Modern society is organized
The social scientific failures in explaining around general and cultural models, as
large-scale change are stunning. The move- much as around hard-wired organi-
ment for racial and ethnic equality, the zational structures. And these models are
women’s movement, the environment move- increasingly worldwide in character (Meyer
ment, the modern movements for organiza- et al., 1997).
tional transparency, the breakdown of
the Communist system, the movement for
gay and lesbian rights – all these worldwide
changes were poorly predicted, and are CONCLUSIONS
poorly explained, by social scientific thinking.
Empirically, research on the diffusive The rapid expansion of a stateless global
impacts of world models on social practice society – in transactions and perceptions
independent of national-state action is con- alike – has produced a great wave of cultural
vincing. The world models impact national materials facilitating expanding organization
policy, certainly: but they impact practice at every level. Scientific and rationalistic pro-
whether or not they impact policy. The world fessionals and associations generate highly
movement to constrain child labor seems to rationalized and universalized pictures of
have very large effects on practice, whether natural and social environments calling for
or not countries subscribe to the appropriate expanded rational actorhood of states, organ-
prohibitions (Abu Sharkh, 2002). World izations, and individuals. Legal and social
movements for women’s rights have dra- scientific professionals generate greatly
matic effects increasing the educational expanded conceptions of the rights and capa-
enrollment of women, independent of any bilities of all human persons, transcending
national policies (Bradley & Ramirez, 1996). national citizenship. Universities and other
Changed world models related to reproduc- educational arrangements expand, world-
tion impact birth rates independent of wide, installing newly rationalized knowl-
national policy (Bongaarts & Watkins, 1996). edge in newly empowered persons.
The world environment movement impacts So models of organized actorhood expand,
practice both through national policy and penetrate every social sector and country. All
around it (Schofer & Hironaka, 2005). It is sorts of older social forms – bureaucracies,
probably also true that the world human family structures, traditional professional
rights movements have impacted local prac- arrangements – are transformed into organi-
tice independent of national policy subscrip- zations. The process is driven by a cultural
tions – the data on human rights practices system that is a putative substitute for
REFLECTIONS ON INSTITUTIONAL THEORIES OF ORGANIZATIONS 807

traditional state-like political arrangements – from such sources. Naturally, successful


realist analyses that root the process in pow- models tend to be derived and edited from
erful interested actors miss out on most of the the most successful organizations – which
important changes. The process spreads realists then call hegemonic – but this does
through the diffusion of models of actorhood, not mean that the interests of those organiza-
not principally via a power and incentive tions play a causal role.
system. The changes transcend practicality, Institutionalists are instructed to investi-
leaving great gaps between policy and prac- gate the realist ‘mechanisms’ by which local
tice essentially everywhere – almost any structures conform to wider models: it is not
organization can be seen as a failure, now. a good idea to take seriously the pretenses
And the changes diffuse at multiple levels – of modern interested actorhood involved.
through central organizations and through Conformity to standard models may not
their professionalized memberships and involve much ‘influence’ or much decision-
populations. making. The relevant network linkages, for
Sociological institutional theory – especially example, may simply involve the most ele-
its phenomenological version – captures the mentary forms of information transmission.
whole post-World War II enterprise very Institutionalists are told to investigate the
well, and for this reason has been successful. assumed true linkages that powerful inter-
In a world less rapidly changing, the pre- ested actors put between policy and practice:
ferred realisms of modern ideology and it is wiser to imagine that developing the pos-
social theory might have constructed realist ture of the proper actor is a main goal of
explanations but change has been too rapid. modern people and groups, transcending
Realist theories and ideologies have not their needs to implement this posture in
caught up with the explosion of human rights actions. In a world in which an enormous
(e.g., gay and lesbian rights), of environmen- premium is placed on actorhood, entering
tal doctrines and policies, of all sorts of into this identity is obviously central.
social rationalization (e.g., a global standards Institutionalists are told that the analysis of
movement), and the transformation of all diffusion waves is unscientific – the only cor-
sorts of unlikely social structures into puta- rect approach is to assume each particle in
tively rational organizations. such a wave is a properly rational and inter-
Much social theory, however, retains its ested actor: following this advice would
theoretical/ideological preference for tradi- mean giving up on really trying to explain the
tional realisms, leaving the great social dramatic social and organizational changes
changes of the modern period poorly of our period. The great changes of our
explored. So this leaves much intellectual period – often poorly recognized by realist
space within which institutional theory can social sciences – occur much more through
develop. In this context, the best strategy for waves of conforming non-decision than
institutional theory is to keep to its last, and through networks of fully formed and
to avoid attending to the clamor arising from autonomous rationalized actors.
realist ideological assumptions.
Thus, institutionalists sometimes are
instructed to seek for the interested actors
behind the new social models under con- REFERENCES
struction, and to assume such actors exist by
definition. This is not a good idea, and it Abbott, A.D. 1988. The System of Professions.
makes more sense to track the relevant pro- Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
fessions and ‘others’ who are central. Most Abu Sharkh, M. 2002. History and Results of
new models of organizational or national Labor Standard Initiatives. Unpublished doc-
structure are developed with heavy influence toral dissertation, Free University of Berlin.
808 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Barrett, D., Kurzman, C., & Shanahan, S. 2006. institutional environment and the classroom.
Coreless Diffusion: Export-Only Policies for Sociology of Education, 77 (3): 211–244.
Population Control. School of Social Work, Cohen, M, March, J, & Olsen, J. 1972.
University of North Carolina, Chapel Hill. A garbage can model of organizational
Bendor, J., Moe, T.M., & Shotts, K.W. 2001. choice. Administrative Science Quarterly,
Recycling the garbage can: An assessment of (17) 1: 1-25.
the research program. American Political Cole, W. 2005. Sovereignty relinquished?
Science Review, 95 (1): 169–190. Explaining commitment to the international
Berger, P.L., Berger, B., & Kellner, H. 1974. The human Rights covenants, 1966–1999.
Homeless Mind: Modernization and Con- American Sociological Review, 70 (3):
sciousness. New York: Vintage Books. 472–495.
Berkovitch, N. 1999. From Motherhood to Citizen- Coleman, J.S. 1986. Social theory, social
ship. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press. research, and a theory of action. American
Blau, P.M., & Schoenherr, R.A. 1971. The Struc- Journal of Sociology, 91: 1309–1335.
ture of Organizations. New York: Basic Books. Cyert, R.M., March, J.G. 1992. A Behavioral
Boli, J., & Ramirez, F. 1987. The political con- Theory of the Firm, 2nd edn. Cambridge,
struction of mass schooling: European ori- MA.: Blackwell Business.
gins and worldwide institutionalization. Czarniawska, B., & Sevón, G. (eds.) 1996.
Sociology of Education, 60: 2-17. Translating Organizational Change. Berlin:
Boli, J. 1987. World-polity sources of expand- de Gruyter.
ing state authority and organization, 1870- Dalton, M. 1959. Men Who Manage. New
1970. In G. Thomas et al., Institutional York: Wiley.
Structure. Beverly Hills: Sage. DiMaggio, P.J. 1988. Interest and agency in
Boli, J., & Thomas, G. 1999. Constructing World institutional theory. In L. Zucker, ed.,
Culture: International Non-Governmental Institutional patterns and organizations.
Organizations Since 1875. Stanford: Stanford Cambridge, MA: Ballinger.
University Press. DiMaggio, P.J., & Powell, W.W. 1983. The iron
Bongaarts, J., & Watkins, S.C. 1996. Social cage revisited: Institutional isomorphism and
interactions and contemporary fertility collective rationality in organizational fields.
transitions. Population and Development American Sociological Review, 48 (2):
Review, 22 (4): 639–682. 147–160.
Boyle, E.H. 2002. Female Genital Cutting: Djelic, M-L., & Quack, S. 2003. Globalization
Cultural Conflict in the Global Community. and Institutions. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press. Djelic, M-L., & Sahlin-Andersson, K. (eds.)
Bradley, K., & Ramirez, F. 1996. World polity 2006. Transnational Governance. Cambridge:
and gender parity: Women’s share of Cambridge University Press.
higher education, 1965–1985. Research in Dobbin, F., & Sutton, J.R. 1998. The strength of
Sociology of Education and Socialization, a weak state: The employment rights revolu-
11: 63–91. tion and the rise of human resources man-
Brunsson, N. 1989. The Organization of agement divisions. American Journal of
Hypocrisy. Chichester: Wiley. Sociology, 104: 441–476.
Brunsson, N. 1985. The Irrational Organization. Dobbin, F., Sutton, J.R., Meyer, J.W., & Scott,
Chichester: Wiley. W.R. 1993. Equal opportunity law and the
Brunsson, N., & Olsen, J.P. 1993. The Reforming construction of internal labor markets.
Organization. London: Routledge. American Journal of Sociology, 99: 396–427.
Brunsson, N., & Sahlin-Andersson, K. 2000. Drori, G.S., & Meyer, J.W. 2006. Scientization:
Constructing organizations: The case of Making a world safe for organizing.
public sector reform. Organizational Studies, In M-L. Djelic & K. Sahlin-Andersson (eds.),
21: 721–746. Transnational Governance: Institutional
Camic, C. 1986. The matter of habit. American Dynamics of Regulation, pp. 31–52.
Journal of Sociology, 91: 1039–1087. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Coburn, C. 2004. Beyond decoupling: Drori, G.S., Meyer, J.W., & Hwang, H. (eds.)
Rethinking the relationship between the 2006. Globalization and Organization: World
REFLECTIONS ON INSTITUTIONAL THEORIES OF ORGANIZATIONS 809

Society and Organizational Change. Oxford: empty promises. American Journal of


Oxford University Press. Sociology, 110 (5): 1373–1411.
Drori, G.S., Meyer, J.W., Ramirez, F.O., & Hasse, R., & Kruecken, G. 2005. Neo-Institution-
Schofer, E. 2003. Science in the Modern alismus. Rev. ed. Bielefeld: transcript Verlag.
World Polity. Stanford: Stanford University Hathaway, O.A. 2002. Do human rights
Press. treaties make a difference? Yale Law Journal,
Drori, G.S., & Moon, H. 2006. The changing 111: 1935–2042.
nature of tertiary education: Cross-national Hirsch, P.M. 1997. Sociology without social
trends in disciplinary enrollment, 1965–1995. structure: Neoinstitutional theory meets
In D.P. Baker & A.W. Wiseman (eds.), The brave new world. American Journal of
Impact of Comparative Education Research on Sociology, 102 (6): 1702–1723.
Institutional Theory. Elsevier Science. Hirsch, P.M., & Lounsbury, M. 1997. Ending the
Edelman, L. 1992. Legal ambiguity and family quarrel: Toward a reconciliation of
symbolic structures: Organizational media- ‘old’ and ‘new’ institutionalism. American
tion of civil rights law. American Journal of Behavioral Scientist, 40 (S): 406–418.
Sociology, 97: 1531–1576. Jepperson, R. 2002. The development and
Edelman, L., Uggen, C., & Erlanger, H.S. 1999. application of sociological neo-institutional-
The endogeneity of legal regulation: ism.’ In J. Berger & M. Zelditch, Jr. (eds.),
Reevance procedures as rational myth. New Directions in Contemporary Sociological
American Journal of Sociology, 105: Theory, p. 229–266. Lanham, MD: Rowman
406–454. and Littlefield.
Fligstein, N. 1990. The Transformation of Jepperson, R. 2002a. Political modernities:
Corporate Control. Cambridge: Harvard Disentangling two underlying dimensions of
University Press. institutional differentiation. Sociological
Foucault, M. 1991, Governmentality. Theory, 20: 61–85.
In G. Burchell, C. Gordon & P. Miller (eds.), Jepperson, R. 1991. Institutions, institutional
The Foucault Effect: Studies in Governmen- effects, and institutionalism. In W.W. Powell
tality, p. 87–104. Chicago: University of & P.J. DiMaggio (eds.), The New Institutional-
Chicago Press. ism in Organizational Analysis, p. 143–163.
Frank, D.J., & Gabler, J. 2006. Reconstructing Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
the University: Worldwide Changes in Jepperson, R., & Meyer, J.W. 2007. Analytical
Academic Emphases Over the 20th Century. individualism and the explanation of
Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. macrosocial change. In V. Nee & R. Swedberg
Frank, D.J., Hironaka, A., & Schofer, E. 2000. (eds.), On Capitalism, pp. 273-304. Stanford:
The nation-state and the natural environ- Stanford University Press.
ment over the twentieth century. American Katzenstein, P.J. 1996. The Culture of National
Sociological Review, 65 (1): 96–116. Security: Norms and Identity in World Politics.
Frank, D.J., & McEneaney, E. 1999. The individ- New York: Columbia University Press.
ualization of society and the liberization of Krasner, S.D. 1999. Sovereignty: Organized
state policies on same-sex sexual relations, Hypocrisy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
1984–1995. Social Forces, 77: 911–944. Landes, D.S. 1998. The Wealth and Poverty of
Frank, D.J., & Meyer, J.W. 2002. The contem- Nations. New York: Norton.
porary identity explosion: Individualizing March, J.G. 1988. Decisions and Organizations.
society in the post-war period. Sociological New York, NY: Blackwell.
Theory, 20 (1): 86–105. McNeely, C.L. 1995. Constructing the Nation-
Giddens, A. 1984. The Constitution of Society. State: International Organization and Pre-
Berkeley: University of California Press. scriptive Action. Westport: Greenwood Press.
Granovetter, M. 1985. Economic action and social Meyer, J.W. 1999. The changing cultural
structure: The problem of embeddedness. content of the nation-state: A world
American Journal of Sociology, 91 (3): society perspective. In G. Steinmetz (ed.),
481–510. State/Culture: State Formation After the
Hafner-Burton, E., & Tsutsui, K. 2005. Human Cultural Turn, p. 123–143. New York:
rights in a globalizing world: The paradox of Cornell University.
810 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL INSTITUTIONALISM

Meyer, J.W. 1988. Society without culture: North, D.C., & Thomas, R.P. 1973. The Rise of
A nineteenth century legacy. In F. Ramirez the Western World. Cambridge: Cambridge
(ed.), Rethinking the Nineteenth Century, University Press.
pp. 193–201. NY: Greenwood. Perrow, C. 1970. Organizational Analysis: A Socio-
Meyer, J.W. 1986. The self and the life course: logical View. Belmont, CA: Brooks/Cole Publ. Co.
Institutionalization and its effects. In Powell, W.W., & DiMaggio, P.J. (eds.) 1991. The
A. Sorensen, F. Weinert & L. Sherrod (eds.), New Institutionalism in Organizational Analy-
Human Development & The Life Course, sis. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
pp. 199–216. Hillsdale, NJ: Erlbaum. Ramirez, F.O., & Boli, J. 1987. The political con-
Meyer, J.W. 1980. The world polity struction of mass schooling: European ori-
and the authority of the nation-state. gins and worldwide institutionalization.
In A. Bergesen (ed.), Studies of the Modern Sociology of Education, 60 (1): 2–17.
World-System, pp. 109–137. New York: Ramirez, F.O., Soysal, Y., & Shanahan, S. 1998.
Academic Press. The changing logic of political citizenship:
Meyer, J.W., Boli, J., Thomas, G., & Ramirez, F. Cross-national acquisition of women’s suf-
1997. World society and the nation-state. frage. American Sociological Review, 62:
American Journal of Sociology, 103 (1): 735–745.
144–181. Rose, N., & Miller, P. 1992. Political power
Meyer, J.W., Frank, D., Hironaka, A., beyond the state: Problematics of government.
Schofer, E., & Tuma, N. 1997b. The structur- British Journal of Sociology, 43 (2): 173–205.
ing of a world environmental regime, Sahlin-Andersson, K., & Engwall, L. (eds.) 2002.
1870–1990. International Organization, The Expansion of Management Knowledge.
51 (4): 623–651. Stanford: Stanford University Press.
Meyer, J.W., & Jepperson, R. 2000. The ‘actors’ Schofer, E., & Hironaka, A. 2005. The effects of
of modern society: The cultural construction world society on environmental protection
of social agency. Sociological Theory, outcomes. Social Forces, 84 (1): 25–47.
18 (1):100–120. Schofer, E., & Meyer, J.W. 2005. The world-
Meyer, J.W., Ramirez, F., & Soysal, Y. 1992. World wide expansion of higher education in the
expansion of mass education, 1870–1970. twentieth century. American Sociological
Sociology of Education, 65 (2): 128–149. Review, 70: 898–920.
Meyer, J.W., & Rowan, B. 1978. The structure Scott, W.R. 2001. Institutions and Organizations,
of educational organizations. In M. Meyer 2nd edn. Thousand Oaks: Sage.
et al., Environments and Organizations, Scott, W.R., 2007. Approaching adulthood:
pp. 78–190. San Francisco: Jossey-Bass. The maturing of institutional theory. Dept.
Meyer, J.W., & Rowan, B. 1977. Institu- of Soc., Stanford University. Theory and
tionalized organizations: Formal structure as Society, forthcoming.
myth and ceremony. American Journal of Scott, W.R., Ruef, M., Mendel, P., & Caronna,
Sociology, 83 (2): 340–363. C. 2000. Institutional Change and Healthcare
Meyer, J.W., & Scott, W.R. 1983. Organizational Organizations: From Professional Dominance
Environments: Ritual and Rationality. Beverly to Managed Care. Chicago: University of
Hills: Sage. Chicago Press.
Mizruchi, M.S., & Fein, L.C. 1999. The social Sewell, W.H., Jr. 1992. A theory of structure:
construction of organizational knowledge: Duality, agency, and transformation.
A study of the uses of coercive, mimetic, and American Journal of Sociology, 98 (1): 1–29.
normative isomorphism. Administrative Soysal, Y. 1994. Limits of Citizenship. Chicago:
Science Quarterly, 44 (4): 653–683. University of Chicago Press.
Mizruchi, M.S., Stearns, L.B., & Marquis, C. 2006. Stinchcombe, A.L. 2001. When Formality
The conditional nature of embeddedness. Works. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
American Sociological Review, 71 (2): 310–333. Stinchcombe, A.L. 1997. On the virtues of the
Mokyr, J. 1992. The Lever of Riches. Oxford: old institutionalism. Annual Review of
Oxford University Press. Sociology, 1997: 1–18.
North, D.C. 1981. Structure and Change in Stinchcombe, A.L. 1965. Social structure and
Economic History. New York: Norton. organizations. In J. March (ed.), Handbook
REFLECTIONS ON INSTITUTIONAL THEORIES OF ORGANIZATIONS 811

of Organizations, 142–193. Chicago: Rand Toulmin, S. 1990. Cosmopolis: The Hidden


McNally. Agenda of Modernity. New York: Free
Strang, D., & Meyer, J.W. 1993. Institutional Press.
conditions for diffusion. Theory and Society, Tsutsui, K., & Min Wotipka, C. 2004. Global
22: 487–511. civil society and the international human
Thomas, G., Meyer, J.W., Ramirez, F.O., & Boli, J. rights movement. Social Forces, 83 (2):
1987. Institutional Structure: Constituting 587–620.
State, Society, and The Individual. Beverly Wallerstein, I. 1974. The Modern World-System,
Hills, CA: Sage. vol. I. New York: Academic Press.
Toqueville, A. de. 1836/1969. Democracy in Zucker, L.G. 1977. The role of institutionaliza-
America, ed. J.P. Maier, trans. G. Lawrence. tion in cultural persistence. American Journal
Garden City, NJ: Anchor Books. of Sociology, 42: 726–743.
Index

(figures in bold, tables in italics)

accreditation 21, 40, 58, 67–68, 174, 220, 231, 235, alterity construction 223
532, 582, 598, 741 American pragmatism. See pragmatism
acquisitions 88, 129, 133, 394 antitrust regulations 9, 374, 547, 655, 664, 708, 747,
actor(s) 753, 794
cognitive 522 Asylums (Goffman) 279
definition 791, 799
economic 34, 304, 317, 564, 632 biotechnology 294, 440–42, 405, 606–9, 611, 613,
foreign 315 617–18
ideal types and 102–3, 109–11, 119, 121–22, bricolage 113, 117, 308, 312, 354, 413, 415, 420,
128–29, 164, 194, 230, 304, 313, 400, 483, 423–24, 426, 658
786–77 bureaucracy 101, 107, 172, 281, 367, 477, 481, 667
imitation by 223–24 business process reengineering (BPR) 220, 226
institutional 27, 118, 158, 163, 186, 190, 212, 261,
264, 427, 433, 632, 743 capitalism 101, 110, 128–29, 304, 316, 398, 400, 437,
institutional change and 158, 205, 245, 632–33 439, 450–51, 461, 484, 509, 512, 556, 654, 657,
models 567, 807 659, 666–67, 679, 695
multiple institutional environments and 305 capitalist market 101, 104
nation-state 794 categorization 112–13
networks and 374 ceremonial conformity 4
other 799–800 Civil Rights Act 374, 382
rational 62, 154, 178, 190, 390, 450, 451, 480, classification 112–13
566–67, 690, 702, 709, 792, 796, 798, 806 collaboration 26, 32, 209, 549, 554, 607–8, 614–15,
rationales of 207–9 618, 750
social 27, 59, 61, 63, 69–70, 106, 112–13, 249, 302, collective corporate social responsibility (CCSR)
308, 317, 419, 423–25, 451, 452–53, 461, 466, 371–72
476, 522–23, 541, 758, 791, 798–99, 803 commercialization 286–88, 606–12
soft 222 consumer advocates 364–66, 654–55
template use by 231 Consumer Research (CR) 364
actor-network theory 93, 281, 619, 696, 781 Consumer Union 365–66
affirmative action 22, 85, 88, 132–33, 744, 796 Consumer Watchdog Organization 364
agency contingency theory 3, 7, 11, 478, 674, 679, 746, 773
characteristics 544 corporation(s)
embedded 17, 103–4, 114–17, 120, 144–42, 198, branding 235
201–2, 634, 689, 692, 731 editing 235–36 (see also idea(s): editing)
institutional change and 633 governance 245–46, 250, 253–56, 261–62, 391–96
institutionalization and 678–79, 691 managers 396
institutional politics and 173 models 392
institutional theory and 686–88 reputation 235
temporal dimensions 526–27 takeovers 394–95
theory 396 critical realism 200, 212, 740, 756, 758, 760
See also agent(s) critical theory
agent(s) Foucault, Michael and (see Foucault, Michael)
institutional entrepreneurs and 633 of the Frankfurt School 679–80, 693–94
legitimacy 69 goals 692
models 396 institutional theory and 482, 692–93 (see also
See also agency institutional theory)
814 INDEX

critical theory (Continued) performativity and 281


logics of action in 102–4, 108, 117, 282–83, 613, scientific 234, 684
615, 618, 688. See also institutional logics social construction and 712–13, 716
and naturalization of present 679–80 theory 26, 109, 167, 485, 520, 532, 716
patterns of activity in 101, 679 dispute resolution 38, 321, 658, 660
value-orientations of 675 Durkheim, Émile 462, 473–78, 480, 482–84, 486, 545,
culture 604, 676, 710, 748, 770
measuring effects of 109
normative 53 ecology. See organizational ecology
world society theory and 462 editing. See idea(s): editing
embedded agency 17, 103–4, 114–17, 120, 144–42,
decision-making 34, 81, 172, 219, 391, 561, 567, 635, 198, 201–2, 634, 689, 692, 731
771, 796, 805 embeddedness
decoupling of actors 115–16
definition 87, 90, 346 contracts and 603
deliberate 4 institutional context and 434, 610–13
field heterogeneity and 86–87 entrepreneurs. See institutional entrepreneur(s)
forms of 86 entrepreneurship 285–88, 291
isomorphism and 78, 91 environmentalism 426, 453, 463, 655, 661
legitimacy and 79, 81–82, 396 equal employment opportunity 69, 132–33, 374, 379
measurement 85 ethnomethodolgy 276–77, 279–82, 292, 295, 491–93,
networks and 88 510, 519, 775
predicting 87–88 European Economic Community (EEC) 310
reasons for 86–87 European Union (EU) 4, 210, 310, 313–15, 751
risks 86 evaluators 63
rule avoidance and 785 event sequencing 116–17, 128–29
sustainability 88 expectation states 284–85
tradition and 333
de-institutionalization Federal Reserve 359
actors in 317 Federal Trade Commission 365
definition 327, 331 field(s)
diffusion and 303 definition 525
institutional change and 302, 630 discourse analysis and 717 (see also discourse
pressures for 332–33, 355 analysis)
process 332, 344–47, 348 heterogeneity 86, 90
social pressure and 302 institutional 19, 24, 131, 156, 161, 198–200, 203,
transnationalization and 301 205, 209–10, 255, 302–3, 416, 419, 424, 426,
democracy 101, 104, 234, 791, 796 510, 524–25, 529–30, 613, 634–36, 639, 660,
deregulation 232, 316, 438, 443, 445 687–88, 742
diffusion isomorphism and 90
coercive 6 membership 542
definition 224 movements and 652, 660–62
field-level populations and 142 multi-level 660–62
globalization and 318, 454, 456, 464, 541–42, 552 neo-institutionalism and 742
governance and 393–95 networks and 618, 742 (see also network(s))
institutional theory and 624 organizational (see organizational field(s))
isomorphism and 78–79, 89, 708 performance and 615–17
legitimacy and, 89 technical 742
legitimation and 58 types 601, 742
mechanisms for 6–7, 708 See also organizational field(s)
mimetic 6, 222–23 Food and Drug Administration (FDA) 612
models 90, 142, 230, 395, 665 form(s)
normative 6 as codes 355
politics and 664–66 creation 355
speed 306 definition 352, 355
taken-for-grantedness and 653 ecological theories of 491
theorization and 162 as identities 355
of world society models 453 institutionalization of 355–56
See also institutionalization multidimensional (MDF) 599–600
discourse analysis networks and 611
action and 714 as settlements 353–57, 368
definition 712–13 social 496
institutional theory and 162, 485, 711–16 Foucault, Michael 176, 465, 532, 555, 675–77, 680–92,
language and 531–33 694, 696–97
levels of 716 founder effect 108–9
INDEX 815

frames 353–57 human resource management (HRM) 374, 462, 463, 685
framing 105, 121, 136 human rights 454, 457–61, 775, 798–99, 801–4, 807
cognitive 136, 785
cultural 160, 167, 183, 254, 306, 706, 785, 787 idea(s)
linguistic 152, 160 carriers 227–30
normative 160, 393 circulation 221, 223, 227, 229–30, 289
Frankfurt School of Critical Theory 679–80, 693–94. editing 225–27
See also critical theory; Habermas, Jürgen flow in networks 228
ideal types 102–3, 109–11, 119, 121–22, 128–29, 164,
genre theory 776–78 194, 230, 304, 313, 400, 483, 786–87
Global Business Coalition (GBC) on HIV/AIDS translation (see translation)
372–73, 376–85, 383 identity
globalization as bricolage 423–24
carriers in 466 centrality of 421
consequences 371 claim 418, 421, 421, 424–25
definition 300, 451, 453–56, 459, 462, 797 collective 111, 183, 266, 328–29, 331, 338, 351,
destabilization by 278, 299 355, 421
diffusion and 318, 454, 456, 464, 541–42, 552 creation 418, 420, 424
embeddedness and 466 definition 416, 419
institutional constraints from 460 distinctive nature of 422
isomorphism and 466 history and 426
limits 305–7 hybridization 421–22
movements and 373 institutionalizing 420–21
neoinstitutionalism and 452–53, 456, 465–66 institutional theory and 425–27
neoliberal theory and 450 isomorphism 419 (see also isomorphism)
organizational change and 803 meanings 420 (see also meaning(s))
outside constituents in 399 mobilization and 421
in pharmaceuticals 442 models 416
rationalization and 456, 456, 460–61, 553 performance and 424–25
realist perspective of 456 persistence 422–23, 427
research on 450, 463–64 social construction of 416
rise of 456–57 sources 128
side-effects 442 status and 422
stateless 796–98 symbols 424
of trade 373 theory 16, 35, 210, 414, 418, 494
world polity and 457–60 traditions 42
world system theory and 449–50, 452–55, 462, verification 245
465, 467 imitation
See also transnationalization broadcasting mode 228, 230–32
golden parachute 16, 133, 385, 394, 600 chain mode 228, 230–32
governance identity and 223
business systems perspective of 400–401 imperfect 626–27
comparative study 400–401 innovation and 303, 581
as control 262 models 231
cultural differences in 400 motivation for 223
cultural logics and 245 networks 84
diffusion 393–96 by others 228, 230–32, 637, 802
players 397–400 indexicality 492
pluralism 253–56 informational cascade 566
resistance to 396–97 information and communication technologies (ICTs) 373
scandals 402 institution(s)
variation 395–96 accretion 777
varieties of capitalism (VoC) approach to 400–401 agency in 135, 192
grounded theory 494 bricolage in (see bricolage)
change in (see institutional change)
Habermas, Jürgen 674, 693, 696 Chicago School and 495–96
Handbook of Leadership (Stogdill) 730 compliance 710
health maintenance organizations (HMOs) 118 creation 4, 26, 95, 105–6, 241, 272, 308–9, 327, 556,
HIV/AIDS 653, 666–68, 704, 744, 777, 782, 801 (see also
corporate assistance with 379, 382 (see also Global bricolage; institutionalization)
Business Coalition (GBC) on HIV/AIDS) cross-category comparisons of 9–10
death toll 372 cross-national comparisons 10, 28
economic consequences of 376 cultural-cognitive elements in 153, 705–11
as pandemic 371 definition 4, 20, 32, 233, 300, 483, 495–97, 703,
prevalence rates 374–75 705, 709–10, 713, 769, 794
816 INDEX

institution(s) (Continued) institutional entrepreneur(s) (Continued)


as discourse 162 professions as 544
erosion 327–28, 332, 347, 348 role in organizations 136, 528
evaluation 508 social movements as 544
historical situation of 497, 666–68 See also institutional entrepreneurship
isomorphism (see isomorphism: institutional) institutional entrepreneurship
leaders (see leadership) academic 552–54
maintenance 189–90 field and 204–5
meaning and 520–25 (see also meaning(s)) inducements 207
movements and 653–56 (see also movements) methodologies 115–16
networks and 605–10, 618 (see also network(s)) neo-institutionalism and 542–45
norms and 106, 793 power and 209
origins resources and 207–8
pluralism 244, 247–53, 258–61, 748–59 stimulus 202–4
politics in 68, 171, 173, 174 See also institutional entrepreneur(s)
power and 170, 172–73 (see also power) institutional environment 5, 27, 58, 79, 81–82, 84, 90,
as processes 498 130, 243–44, 397, 414, 421, 434, 542, 561, 564
regulative structures 32, 131, 741–42, 744, 751 institutional fields. See field(s): institutional
reproduction 26, 277, 636, 643, 657, 710–11, 743 institutionalism
resistance within 189, 192 comparative 1, 28, 450, 453
sanctions and controls in 711 ecological analysis and 573
social change and 482–84, 791 narrative 776–78
taken-for-grantedness 496, 741 (see also realist 792–93
taken-for-grantedness) Scandinavian 34, 92, 219, 222, 521, 531, 770–73
transnational 308–9 sociological 793–800
variety in 135 institutionalization
See also corporation(s); organization(s) agency and 678–79
institutional change codification in 653
actors in 158, 205 (see also actor(s)) definition 5, 11, 413, 676–77, 702
adaptive nature of 631 diffusion and 161 (see also diffusion)
ambiguity in 772 dynamics 159, 161, 233, 653
competition 631 fields and 160 (see also organizational field(s))
diffusion and 629 (see also diffusion) habitualization in 302, 309, 311, 529, 677, 743
dynamics 20, 629, 631, 654–55 identity and (see identity)
editing rules for 225–26 incomplete 631–32, 639
environmental shocks and 632 institutional theory and 676–79
event sequencing and 116 (see also event of law 159
sequencing) legitimation and 52–53, 57–58, 506
fashion and 222 models 89–90, 653, 800–806
heterogeneity and 633, 641 monitoring 653
ideas and (see idea(s)) objectification in 34, 302, 309, 311, 677, 684, 743
institutional theory and 629–34 particularities 155–56
leadership and 723–24 (see also leadership) process 157–59, 529–31, 655, 677–78, 688–89, 702,
learning and 626–42 707–8, 711, 713, 722
mechanisms 626–27, 629, 746 sedimentation in 34, 302, 309, 311, 316, 493, 511,
micro-perspective 285–92 522, 526, 529, 531, 533, 694, 743
models of 27 social construction of reality in 677–78
power effects of 190 taken-for-grantedness and 709 (see also
sources 631–34 taken-for-grantedness)
unintended consequences and 635–36 transnationalization and 300–301, 313–17
institutional context 3–6, 12, 22, 29–30, 102, 182, 434, See also de-institutionalization
544, 618–19, 636 institutional logics 21
institutional economics 390, 544, 565, 708, 718, 750. action and 602
See also organizational economics assumptions of 105
institutional entrepreneur(s) changes 100, 114–19
action 526–29 classification 112–13
as actors in 206–7, 633 culture and 105
characteristics 199–201, 208 definition 21, 100–101, 602
definition 198, 498 embedded agency and 103–4 (see also agency:
field conditions and 202–5, 634 embedded)
frames and 354 (see also frames) fields and 107, 425
institutional change and 18–21, 115, 171, 198 history 102–3, 108–9
inter-actor relationships in 209 institutional analysis and 106, 109–11, 121
legitimacy 136, 158 meta-theory of 103–9, 122
motivation 526–29 misconceptions regarding 119–20
INDEX 817

institutional logics (Continued) isomorphism (Continued)


multiple 244, 254, 277, 604–6, 609, 616, 630, competitive 23
650–52, 655, 657–60, 665, 667 decoupling and 78, 91
origins of 119 definition 132
power structures and 112 diffusion and 79, 89, 651 (see also diffusion)
social actors and 113 dynamics 14
See also logic(s): of action environment and 81, 84
institutional order 119, 154–55, 157, 159, 161, 165, fields and 90, 703
203, 502, 505, 524, 527, 692 global 466
institutional recombination 308, 309, 313, 317 history 84
institutional theory institutional 15–17, 78–80, 84–85, 89–90, 254,
adaptation 403 420, 588
advantages 32 legitimacy and 4, 419, 785 (see also legitimacy)
basic elements 6, 308, 486 mechanisms 6, 83, 704
change and 629–34 mimetic pressures for 80, 83–84, 394, 433–34, 581,
coercive pressures in 434, 708 637, 744, 746
cognitive guidance systems in 426 model 15
contextualization 32–33 normative pressures for 80, 83, 86, 433–34, 581,
corporate governance and 389, 390–93 629, 709, 744, 776, 803
critical theory and 692 (see also critical theory) rationalized myths and 78
definition 130 sources 479
discourse and 713 surface 4
diffusion and 624 ISO 9000 25, 67, 71, 80, 303
economics and 564–67, 569
employees and 399 knowledge
exploration/exploitation and 639 acquisition 627, 727
globalization and (see world society theory) categories 104–5, 206, 280, 431, 465, 521, 547,
heterogeneity and 642 587–88, 638, 674, 680
history and foundations 3–23, 29, 99–100, 706, 708, claims 433, 614
785, 790 critical theory 680–85
institutional entrepreneurship and 539 language and 531 (see also language)
institutionalization and 676–79 management 220
institutional logics in 21 power and 681, 683–85, 687–91, 694
isomorphism and (see isomorphism) sociology of 25, 519–24, 529–33
meaning and 277 (see also meaning(s)) transmission 250, 285, 531
normative expectations in 426, 708
organizational field and (see organizational field(s)) language
organizational identity and 413–14 discourse and 531–33
pressures and 426, 433–34, 708 in institutionalization 162, 288, 292, 485, 520, 744
processual studies of 8–9 knowledge and 531, 694
prospects for 800–806 power of 158, 176, 213, 278
social construction of 2–21 taken-for-grantedness 153, 294
social movement and 137, 373, 375 leadership
rationalization and 276 external enemies and 722, 724, 729, 731, 733
realist 792–93 fads 73
social scientific inquiry in 674 institutional 256, 722–24, 731, 732, 750
taken-for-grantedness 693 (see also taken-for- legitimacy and 724, 727–28
grantedness) management and 722
translation in 403 (see also translation) organizational 132, 262–64, 423, 722, 731, 732
unintended consequences and 636 power and 732
value-orientation in 674–75, 683, 687–88, 690–91, role of 724–33
693, 695 Leadership in Administration (Selznick) 260,
See also structural contingency theory 721–23, 730
Institutions and Organizations (Scott) 51, 474, 493, 709 Leadership Quarterly 723, 730–31
integrity 246, 249, 253, 255, 260–61, 268, 422 learning
intellectual property 441, 454, 609, 611–13, 620 analysis 628
internationalization. See globalization change processes and 629–30
International Labor Office (ILO) 309, 463, 550–51 competition and 642
International Monetary Fund (IMF) 309–10, 313–14, 551 definition 627–28
international relations 301, 306–7, 318, 450, 792–93 field-level change and 636
International Standards Organization, 25, 67, 71, 80, 303 inferential 626–27, 640–41, 643
isomorphism institutional change and 627, 634–42
agentic perspective of 84–85 institutional theory and 636–37
coercive pressure for 80, 83, 86, 434, 580–81, 629, intraorganizational 636
721, 744, 776–77, 803 networks and 636 (see also network(s))
818 INDEX

learning (Continued) loose coupling 81, 90–92, 96, 251, 258, 262, 403, 453,
non-mimetic 641 459, 464, 554, 678, 688, 744–45, 755, 778, 804–5.
regulatory pressures and 642 See also decoupling
search and 637–39 Luhmann’s systems theory 545–49, 553
selective 640–41
theory 16, 627–28, 630, 634, 636–37, 639, 643 macroeconomics 435, 438
lebenswelt 520–23, 526, 529, 533 management
legitimacy evidence-based 234, 240
agents 69 fads 221, 774
antecedents 58 function 723
assessing 57, 62–63, 249 impression 17, 51, 58, 70, 87, 397
categories 18, 50, 52–53, 58, 56, 60, 67–68, 18, 303 leadership and 722
542, 544, 580, 564, 586, 727–28 new public (NPM) 220, 227, 437, 439, 551
characteristics 52, 61–62, 542, 665 by objectives (MBO) 185–86, 220, 226
consequences 58–59 supply chain 220, 226
cues to 422 techniques 220, 439 (see also specific techniques)
decoupling and 396–97 Total Quality (TQM) 58, 220, 231, 395, 423, 430,
definition 50–52, 247 485, 581, 753
and diffusion 89 marketization 234, 439
evolution 49–59, 63 Marx, Karl 193, 249, 329, 451, 453, 460, 473–76,
gain/loss of 51, 414 480–84, 486, 509, 546, 674–75, 679, 693–94, 697,
guidelines 69 748, 786
history 49 Mead, George Herbert 229, 265, 284, 473, 493–96,
interorganizational relationships and 56 500, 521, 526, 706, 772
isomorphism and 4, 422 (see also isomorphism) meaning(s)
leadership and 724, 727–28 definition 152
manipulation 59 institutional fields and 205
market access and 64 institutions and 520–25
measurement 18, 53, 60 shaping of 284, 529
media and 56 social 28, 292, 157, 418, 420, 497, 521, 750
mediators 69 world society theory and 462
mimicry in 542 mergers and alliances 116, 399, 440–41, 445, 564, 612
neo-institutionalism and 247 (see also Merton, Robert 63, 106, 281, 466, 477, 487, 495,
neo-institutionalilsm) 610, 787
pluralism and (see pluralism) Meyer John 2, 2–13, 24, 34–35, 50, 86–87, 90, 100, 153,
rationale for 51 175, 219, 222, 450, 462, 478–80, 539, 541, 550, 597,
rationalized myths in 222 (see also myths: 686–88, 707, 709, 770, 772–73, 784–85, 787, 788
rational) microsociology 282, 511, 519
reputation and 62, 66 (see also status) mimesis 23, 83, 223, 361, 414, 416, 509, 627, 653.
resource flows and 64 See also isomorphism: mimetic pressures for
sociopolitical sources 54–57, 68, 128, 506 modern organizational institutionalism 3–7, 28, 371,
status and 62, 66, 66 (see also reputation) 373, 457
subjects 54 movements
sustainability 62 against institutions 653–56, 663, 665
taken-for-granted aspects of 53 diffusion and 652, 656–57, 664–66
theories of 69 in fields 652
visibility 52–54 intra-institutional 656–60
See also legitimation measuring 663–64
legitimation 52–53, 57–58, 506. See also mobilization in 656–60, 664–66
legitimacy modeling 663–64
lesbian/gay issues 372, 374–75, 380, 382, 383, 650, origins 652
660, 667–68, 798, 801, 806 politics and 664–66
logic(s) social (see social movement)
of action 102–4, 108, 117, 282–83, 613, 615, 618, theorization and 656–57
688. See also institutional logics multidisciplinary practice (MDP) 54, 116, 158, 434–35
aesthetic 114, 128–29 multinational corporation (MNC) 28, 371, 373, 457
alternative 208 myths
competing 107, 114, 117–19, 121, 140, 187, 189, institutional 11, 29, 50, 58, 70, 152–53, 155, 190,
190–91, 602, 608, 651, 655 208, 493
editorial 105, 107, 111–12, 114, 117, 129, 133 rational 3–9, 12, 20, 24–25, 28, 30, 61, 78–81, 152–53,
efficiency 128–29 156, 218–20, 222, 561, 597, 707, 752, 758
evolution 133
institutional (see institutional logics) National Institutes of Health (NIH) 608–9
market 105, 107–8, 111–14, 116–17, 121, 129, 224, nation-states 301, 308–10, 371, 423–24, 427, 449–53,
339, 747 455, 457–59, 461–64, 541, 550, 552, 668, 752,
organizational actions and 111–14 791–94, 796, 803–4
INDEX 819

negotiated order 500–502 organization(s)


neo-institutionalism accountability 443–46
analysis levels 752–53 behavior 5, 433
assessment 745–47, 754–55 categories in 293, 439
causal relationships 745 ceremonies 725, 747
change and 263 (see also organizational change) change (see organizational change)
cultural/cognitive mechanisms 253 character 722
diffusion and 555 (see also diffusion) competition 576
entrepreneurship and 553 cultural shaping 541
field and 742, 752 density dependence 575–76
governance and 253–54 (see also governance) diversity 574–75
history 491, 706, 739 failure 283, 575–78, 586–89
homogenizing forces 554–55 field membership and 542
institutionalization and 352, 741–43 (see also governance 245–46, 250, 253–56, 261–62
institutionalization) health care 99, 107, 439, 575
legitimacy and 616 (see also legitimacy) hypocrisy 8, 778
macro-perspective in 541 idea adoption 220–27, 395
meso-perspective 542–45 identity (see identity)
movements and (see movements) inertia 576–77
networks and 742 institutional contexts of 3, 6
political science and 751 institutionalization of 4, 246
postmodernism and 757–58 institutional theories of 78, 477–80
power and 746 internal consistency 725–27
self-reflection in 779 international 454 (see also globalization)
social construction and 717 isomorphism and (see isomorphism)
social mechanism approach to 756–57 leadership 113, 132, 262–64, 423, 434, 722,
societal sector in 81–82, 103–4, 119, 121, 480, 543, 731, 732
639, 752, 794 learning (see learning)
tendency analysis in 743–45 legitimacy (see legitimacy)
theory 131, 163, 170, 368, 547–50, 555, 605, 651, logics 235 (see also logic(s))
663–68, 677, 687, 693, 711, 716–17 memory 627, 639
network(s) mergers (see mergers and alliances)
decoupling and 88 monitoring 235
directors 375, 384, 399 mutualism 576, 610
embeddedness 618 naming patterns 415
fields and 602 negotiated order of 500
individuals and 613 network contexts of 6
institutional logics and 604 (see also institutional non-profit 9, 357, 364, 372, 385, 541, 575, 655,
logics) 785, 799
institutions and 597–601, 605–10, 618 organizing in 234
social 88, 207, 307, 384, 395, 419, 434, 503, 508, power contests in 9, 111–12 (see also power)
555, 565, 598–99, 600, 604 professional networks and 374
theory 16, 31, 82, 93, 281, 596, 601–2, 604, rational-legal authority in 477–79, 481
618–19, 696 reputation 59
as transmission channels 597–98 resources in 64, 576
new institutionalism (NI). See neo-institutionalism responses to institutional pressures 16
new public management (NPM) 220, 227, 437, scandals in 443–46
439, 551 social facts and 84–85, 113, 131, 251, 462, 475, 477,
non-governmental organizations (NGOs) 202, 312–14, 695, 704
451, 460, 463, 740 social movements and 373 (see also social
non-profit organizations 9, 357, 364, 372, 385, 541, movement)
575, 655, 785, 799 as source of legitimacy 56
North Atlantic Free Trade Association (NAFTA) 310 status 59, 111 (see also status)
nouvelle cuisine 361–64 structural overlap in 116
survival of 58
organization(al) theory symbols in 415
concepts 741–43 technology and 439
contingency theory and 773 (see also contingency theory (see organization(al) theory)
theory) transmission of practices in 10
history 1, 3, 14, 33 vision 725–27, 731, 732
institutionalism and 14, 474, 625 organizational change
isomorphism in 79–90 (see also isomorphism) by bricolage (see bricolage)
leadership and 730 (see also leadership) globalization 803
legitimacy in (see legitimacy) inertia 576
Litchfield/Thompson and 741–56 institutional change and 423
See also neo-institutionalism leadership and 724 (see also leadership)
820 INDEX

organizational change (Continued) positivism 274, 511, 558, 750, 760, 777
organizational ecology and 568, 577 (see also postmodernism and 129, 740 756–58, 760
organizational ecology) power
pluralism and 245, 256–60, 262–63 avoidance 393, 508, 600
processes 259, 576–77 categories 173–74, 177–78, 180, 187, 190, 682–85,
social movements and 137, 756 (see also social 687, 689–90, 692
movement) competition for, 111–12
See also institutional change corporate governance and 390
organizational ecologists 342. 352, 355, 368, 422, 566, decoupling and 87
568–69, 574, 579, 585 definition 174, 188–89, 684–85
organizational ecology 3, 55, 259, 263, 352, 368, 566, dynamics 157
574–80, 583, 586 force and 188–89
organizational economics 560–62, 564. See also institutional theory and 686–88
institutional economics institutions and 170, 172–73, 390, 481–82,
organizational field(s) 523–26
actors and 140 knowledge and 683
agency in 135 leadership and 732
change in 135, 139 meanings and 157
configurations 133–37 obedience to 390
constituents 131, 543 as object of research 187–88
construction 160 in organizational fields 192
definition 130–31, 138, 224, 303, 479, 505, 543, 601 politics and 547
emerging 204 resistance to 390
filtering processes and 136 sources 112
history 131–33, 143 stereotypes and 285
homogenizing forces in 541–45 struggles among organizations 9
identity and 224 subjectification and 683–85
institutional logics 425 (see also institutional logics) pragmatism 265–66, 520, 523, 528, 749, 772
mature 204 prestige
membership 542 legitimacy and 66, 66
social evolution and 548–49 media 56
social movements and 303 occupational 99, 112, 128–29, 285, 422, 433, 597
social world and 505 stereotypes and 285
sociology of knowledge and 524–25 (see also Principles of Scientific Management (Taylor), 396
sociology: of knowledge) professional services and practice
subject position and 201–2 academic scientists and 433
success of 63 change in 434–35
structuration of 6 characteristics 432
variety in 135 client interactions in 436–37
See also field(s) conditions of 432
organizational forms. See form(s) definition 432
organizational homogeneity theory 7 delivery 431
organizational institutionalism 5, 50–52, 301–4, demographics 435–36
531–33 as institutional entrepreneur 544
Organization for Economic Co-Operation and institutional theory and 433–35
Development (OECD) 309, 551–52, 556 knowledge claims and 433
orphan drugs 612 markets and 437–39
models for 432
paradox of embedded agency 115, 198, 201–2, 634, technology and 436–42
663, 689, 692. See also agency: embedded progressivism 107, 367, 667
performativity 281–82 punctuated equilibrium 108, 256–57, 652–53,
pharmaceutical companies 60, 191, 305, 372, 379–82, 667, 793
385, 433–34, 440–41, 445, 582, 606, 609–10, 641
pluralism rationalization
adaptation to 250 cultural 100, 461–62, 463, 798
categories 244, 247–53 definition 452, 461
change and 258 globalization and 456, 456, 460–61, 553
comprehensiveness 748–54 indicators 13
consequences 244–45 legitimation and 58
legitimacy and 249–50, 260–61 market 108, 120
variable effects of 258–59 moral 234
point of provider organizations (PPOs) 118 of society 541–42, 795, 807
poison pill 16, 133, 374, 380, 384–85, 394, 482 taken-for-grantedness of 276
population ecology 11, 22, 35, 79–80, 90, 574, 629, 740, rationalized myths 3–9, 12, 20, 30, 78–81, 53, 220,
760, 772, 785–86. See also organizational ecology 222, 279, 561, 597, 707, 752, 758
INDEX 821

realist theory 450, 452, 455, 792–93, 795, 805–7 social world 502–5, 541–55
reality construction 265, 520, 524, 532–33, 677–78, 696, societal institutionalism 301, 304–5
713. See also institutionalization: social construction society
of reality in; Social Construction of Reality, The ‘audit’ 231, 235
reciprocal typification 34, 631, 677, 702, 706, 713 as body of institutions 493
regulation characteristics 545–54
agencies 5 definition 540
decoupling and 87 differentiation 540, 545–46, 552–53
expansion 233 dynamics 547
global 379, 797 evolution 547–49
governance and 233 homogenizing forces in 541–45
networks 308 as inter-institutional system 104–5
rate 97, 273, 654–55, 662 systems 546 (see also systems theory)
soft 231, 233, 311 sociology
See also deregulation Chicago School of 493–94, 510–13, 772
regulatory activism 232 economic 565, 603
reputation 59–60, 62–63 focus 473–74
resource historical 474
-dependence theory 3, 5, 13, 51, 584 institutionalism in 705–6
mobilization 207–8 interactionist 495–96
partitioning 576 of knowledge 25, 519–24, 529–33
Rules of the Sociological Method (Durkheim) 475 neo-institutional 51
Spencer, Herbert 473–76, 480
Scandinavian institutionalism 34, 92, 219, 222, 521, stakeholder theory 244, 264
531, 770–73. See also institutionalism status
science competition for, 61, 111–12
academic 659 enhancement 63
expansion 797 expectations 284–85
institutionalization 659 honor and 61
neuro- 285, 555, 614–15, 617 legitimacy and 59–61 66
society rationalization and 542 organizational resource flows and 64
sensemaking 30, 139, 276, 278, 282–85, 290–93, segregating nature of 61
295–96, 414, 425, 602, 653 sources 112
service learning 160–61 structural contingency theory 3, 7, 10
settlement(s) 353–55, 356, 357, 368 Studies in Ethnomethodology (Garfinkel) 278, 295
small business industry corporations (SBICs) 357–61 supply chain management 220, 226
social capital 398, 565, 597, 603–5, 611, 618, 632 symbols 415, 424, 531–32
social change 452, 482–84, 486 systems theory 545–49, 553
social construction
actors in 222 (see also actor(s)) taken-for-grantedness 54, 68, 248, 288, 303, 392, 530,
discourse analysis and 162, 712 575, 587, 693, 703, 710, 717, 776
forms and 368 (see also form(s)) technology
of identity 416, 421 information and communication (ICT) 373
institutional theory and 2–21, 704–9 in institutions 774–75
institutions and 163, 188, 222, 491–93, 585, 677–78 norms 774–76
interactional rituals and 279 transfer 287–88, 294, 441, 554, 608, 611, 616, 618
of legitimacy 506, 508 templates
neo-institutional theory and 717 for action 132, 191
of reality 465, 524, 677–78, 713 (see also Social circulation 232–33
Construction of Reality, The) creation 230–36
Social Construction of Reality, The (Berger and cultural-cognitive 133, 306, 419, 426
Luckman) 278, 519, 533, 677, 748 institutional 479, 496
social meaning 28, 292, 157, 418, 420, 497, 521, 750 isomorphism and 233
social movement logics and 605
institutional change and 170, 303 organizational 236, 303, 602
as institutional entrepreneur 544 text 712–13
institutional theory and 137, 375 theory
organizations 87, 137, 186, 373, 378, 395 actor-network 93, 281, 619, 696, 781
social movement theory 19, 24–25, 137, 208, 210, 353, agency 396
370–71, 373, 375, 378, 385, 506, 663, 650–51 contingency 3, 7, 11, 478, 674, 679, 746, 773
social order 5, 234, 279–82, 318, 475, 493–94, 500, covering law 740–41
528, 631, 693, 771 critical (see critical theory)
social psychology 58, 69, 278, 282, 494, 760 discourse 26, 109, 167, 485, 520, 532, 716
social systems 53, 56, 175–76, 178, 188, 247, 301, 305, enlightenment 740
392, 398, 474, 484, 605, 618 genre 776–78
822 INDEX

theory (Continued) tradition (Continued)


grounded 494 at Texas A&M 334–44
identity 16, 35, 210, 414, 418, 494 transmission 219, 294, 329
institutional (see institutional theory) transaction cost theory 28, 491, 562
learning 16, 627–28, 630, 634, 636–37, 639, 643 translation 17, 24, 28, 35, 85, 92–93, 142, 156–57,
narrative 740 161–62, 164, 205, 224–28, 403, 521, 565, 652, 658,
neo-institutionalism 131, 163, 170, 368, 547–50, 770–74 (see also institutionalism: Scandinavian)
555, 605, 651, 663–68, 677, 687, 693, 711, transnational communities 310–11
716–17 transnational cultural models 306
neoliberal 450 transnationalization 300–301, 313–17. See also
network 16, 31, 82, 93, 281, 596, 601–2, 604, globalization
618–19, 696 transnational recombination 311–12
organizational (see organization(al) theory) transnational social networks 307
realist 450, 452, 455, 792–93, 795, 805–7 transparency 91, 231, 234–35, 237, 431–32, 435,
resource-dependence 3, 5, 13, 51, 584 694, 806
social movement 19, 24–25, 137, 208, 210, 353,
370–71, 373, 375, 378, 385, 506, 663, 650–51 UNESCO 463, 550
stakeholder 244, 264 United Nations 62, 309, 372, 377, 380, 459, 752, 802
structural contingency 3, 7, 10 universities 99, 243–45, 250–51, 276, 285–88, 292,
systems 545–49, 553 294, 334, 345, 436–37, 443–44, 548, 552–54,
transaction cost 28, 491, 562 606–10, 612, 615–17, 729, 798, 802, 806
world society 449–50, 452–55, 462, 465, 467 utopianism 260
thrifts 366–68
Total Quality Management (TQM) 58, 220, 231, 395, venture capital 26, 358–61, 553, 607–13
423, 430, 485, 581, 753 venture capitalists 358–61, 434, 441, 609, 611, 613
tradition vocabularies
assimilation and 333 change 160
categories 85, 462–64 institutional 109, 115, 136, 158
change in 330–34 legitimated 153
characteristics 294, 328–30, 349 management 220
competition of 333 of motive 101, 511, 532
creation 330 of structure 153
custodians of 346, 348
dilution and 333, 346 Weber, Max 3, 50, 53, 79, 112, 155, 229, 281, 329,
disembedding and 333 462, 473–81, 486, 519, 521, 526, 545, 695, 746,
displacement 348 748, 770, 786
dissipation 331–32, 332, 348 welfare state 549–54
erasure 333 women’s issues and rights 10
erosion 331–34, 344–47 World Bank 309, 310, 314, 483, 752, 803
in institutional entrepreneurs 158 world culture 460–62
as institutionalized practice 330–31, 434 World Economic Forum (WEF) 375–76
migration 348 world polity characteristics 457–60
reconstruction 347 world society theory 449–50, 452–55, 462, 465, 467
sensemaking and 293 world system institutionalism 301, 305–6, 308
taken for granted nature 329 World Trade Organization 25, 184, 309, 314

Anda mungkin juga menyukai