Anda di halaman 1dari 9

doi:10.

1093/heapol/czh052 Health Policy and Planning 19(6),


HEALTH POLICY AND PLANNING; 19(6): 371–379 © Oxford University Press, 2004; all rights reserved.

Accountability and health systems: toward conceptual clarity


and policy relevance
DERICK W BRINKERHOFF
Research Triangle Institute, Washington, DC, USA

Improved accountability is often called for as an element in improving health system performance. At first
glance, the notion of better accountability seems straightforward, but it contains a high degree of complex-
ity. If accountability is to be more than an empty buzzword, conceptual and analytical clarity is required. This
article elaborates a definition of accountability in terms of answerability and sanctions, and distinguishes
three types of accountability: financial, performance and political/democratic. An analytic framework for
mapping accountability is proposed that identifies linkages among health sector actors and assesses capacity
to demand and supply information and exercise oversight and sanctions. The article describes three account-
ability purposes: reducing abuse, assuring compliance with procedures and standards, and improving
performance/learning. Using an accountability lens can: (1) help to generate a system-wide perspective on

Downloaded from http://heapol.oxfordjournals.org/ by guest on December 5, 2016


health sector reform, (2) identify connections among individual improvement interventions, and (3) reveal
gaps requiring policy attention. These results can enhance system performance, improve service delivery
and contribute to sound policymaking.

Key words: accountability, health systems, performance improvement

Introduction actors vary. For example, legislatures have quite a different


accountability focus from that of health regulatory agencies.
Around the world governments face pressures to provide The former are interested in clear accounting for the use of
health services effectively, efficiently and equitably. Reform taxpayer resources as well as demonstrating responsiveness
and strengthening efforts in industrialized and to their constituencies. The latter are primarily interested in
developing/transitioning countries have adopted similar whether providers meet procedural and quality standards.
approaches to getting health systems to perform better: Health ministries combine a wide variety of accountability
downsizing, privatization, competition in service delivery, concerns. If the ministry’s mandate includes paying
performance measurement and indicators, and citizen providers, there is usually a unit responsible for payment for
participation (see, for example, McPake and Mills 2000). All services, with an accountability focus on financial accounting
these approaches converge in emphasizing accountability as and value for money. The health ministry also has policy
a core element in implementing health reform and improv- responsibility and thus has accountability interests and pres-
ing system performance. sures related to public health outcomes and issues.

The current concern with accountability and health systems Frequently, it is the perception of failed or insufficient
reflects several factors. First is dissatisfaction with health accountability that furnishes the impetus for change. For
system performance in both industrialized and example, among the rationales for health sector decentral-
developing/transitioning countries. Discontent has focused ization reforms is the need to establish stronger account-
on costs, quality assurance, service availability/access, equi- ability linkages among citizens, policymakers and service
table distribution of services, abuses of power, financial providers. Hutchinson et al. (1999, p. 103) note this dynamic
mismanagement and corruption, and lack of responsiveness. in Uganda’s reform; prior to the creation of decentralized
Secondly, accountability has taken on a high degree of health committees, ‘. . . citizens unhappy with the perform-
importance because the size and scope of health care bureau- ance of health workers or priority setting by local politicians
cracies in both the public and private sectors accord health had few mechanisms for redressing their grievances or
system actors significant power to affect people’s lives and improving services’.
well-being. Further, health care constitutes a major
budgetary expenditure in all countries, and proper account- Uganda is just one example of how accountability is front and
ing for the use of these funds is a high priority. centre on the stage of current health system improvements
and policy prescriptions. However, as a guide to the specifics
All health systems contain accountability relationships of of what to do to improve health systems, simply calling for
different types. Health ministries, insurance agencies, public more accountability is less than helpful. On the surface, the
and private providers, legislatures, finance ministries, regu- notions of checks and restraints on power and discretion, of
latory agencies and service facility boards are all connected increased oversight and scrutiny, or of closer connections
to each other in networks of control, oversight, cooperation between service users and providers seem straightforward.
and reporting. However, the accountability interests of these However, for accountability to inform policy and
372 Derick W Brinkerhoff

programmes effectively, further conceptual work needs to be ‘stewardship’ in its contribution to government responsive-
done. Calls for more accountability are often efforts by inter- ness and good governance (see Saltman and Ferroussier-
ested actors to change the focus and purpose of account- Davis 2000; Travis et al. 2002). Further, such dialogue can
ability, rather than simply to do ‘more of the same’ (Romzek build citizen trust by signalling that government actors are
2000, p. 35). Accountability risks becoming another interested in citizens’ views and well-being (see Gilson 2003).
buzzword in a long line of ineffectual quick fixes, or, worse,
a one-size-fits-all bludgeon that encourages excess and over- The availability and application of sanctions for illegal or
regulation. inappropriate actions and behaviour uncovered through
answerability constitute the other defining element of
This article focuses on accountability as it relates to health accountability. The ability of the overseeing actor(s) to
systems and policy in developing/transitioning countries. The impose punishment on the accountable actor(s) for failures
analysis reviews and synthesizes the literature on the topic, and transgressions gives ‘teeth’ to accountability. Answer-
noting areas of convergence and of ongoing debate. The ability without sanctions is generally considered to be weak
article addresses the definition and clarification of account- accountability. Most health policy sanctions are based upon
ability, examining how the term can be more precisely regulatory power, for example in the United States,
defined and made more operationally relevant. It then offers Medicare’s authority to levy fines on hospitals that improp-
an analytic framework for accountability and health service erly code patient discharges. The courts intervene with legal
delivery systems that highlights the following questions. sanctions to enforce accountability between provider and
What are the various purposes and targets for accountability? patient, and patient and payer, but this relates to a different

Downloaded from http://heapol.oxfordjournals.org/ by guest on December 5, 2016


What are the linkages among accountability actors, and what level of accountability from the health system overall.
is their capacity to exercise accountability?
Other examples of regulatory frameworks that are intended
to create incentives and increase accountability include: (1)
Defining accountability
licensing and accreditation of physicians, nurses, other
Despite its popularity, accountability is often ill-defined. For categories of health care providers, and facilities (for
example, Mulgan (2000, p. 555) calls accountability a example, Salmon et al. 2003); (2) health care financing and
‘complex and chameleon-like term’. As Schedler (1999, p. 13) payment schemes that link funding to the amount and quality
notes, ‘accountability represents an underexplored concept of services provided (see Maceira 1998; Gauri 2001); and (3)
whose meaning remains evasive [sic], whose boundaries are quality assurance policies that establish standards and bench-
fuzzy, and whose internal structure is confusing’. General marks, practice guidelines and compliance mechanisms to
definitions of accountability include the obligation of indi- improve quality of care, service utilization and client satis-
viduals or agencies to provide information about, and/or faction (for example, Hermida and Robalino 2002). Account-
justification for, their actions to other actors, along with the ability is achieved through the application of the laws,
imposition of sanctions for failure to comply and/or to engage standards and procedures these frameworks put in place,
in appropriate action. which shape the incentives for various actors to comply.

Legal and regulatory sanctions are at the core of enforcing


Answerability and sanctions
accountability, but sanctions can be thought of more broadly.
The essence of accountability is answerability; being account- They include, for example, professional codes of conduct,
able means having the obligation to answer questions regard- which do not have the status of law. It should be noted that
ing decisions and/or actions (see Schedler 1999). Two types some of the regulatory frameworks noted above include
of accountability questions can be asked. The first type asks normative elements similar to codes of conduct. Licensing
simply to be informed; this can include budget information and accreditation, linked to human resource development,
and/or narrative description of activities or outputs. This type often incorporate professional socialization to the norms and
of question characterizes basic monitoring and implies a one- values related to patient care and commitment to service.
way transmission of information from the accountable Quality assurance emphasizes a set of core values, not simply
actor(s) to the overseeing actor(s). The second type of the achievement of service provision targets at a given level
question moves beyond reporting of facts and figures, and of quality (see Silimperi et al. 2002). These kinds of incen-
asks for explanations and justifications (reasons); that is, it tives are intended to reward good behaviour and action and
inquires not just about what was done but why. Justification deter bad behaviour and action, without necessarily involv-
questions incorporate information transmission, but go ing recourse to regulatory enforcement.
beyond to dialogue between the accountable and the over-
seeing actors. This dialogue can take place in a range of Another category of such incentives relates to the use of
venues, from internal to a particular agency (for example, market mechanisms for performance accountability; these
medical personnel answering to their hierarchical superiors), underlie reforms to separate service provision from payment,
between agencies (for example, facilities reporting to health and to introduce privatization of, and competition among,
insurance funds), to more public arenas (for example, parlia- service providers. Health systems reform in many countries
mentary hearings where health ministers answer to legis- seeks to establish these types of incentives often through
lators, or community meetings where local health officials contracting (see Maceira 1998; England 2000). For example,
answer to residents). The justification aspect of answerability if public health clinics, under a capitated health services
links to the World Health Organization’s notion of contract system, are required to compete for clients on the
Accountability and health systems 373

basis of publicly available information on quality and as well as a variety of other indicators, thus joining answer-
performance, accountability is enforced through the ability ability and sanctions. Armed with this database, the agencies
of clients to switch from low quality/performing clinics to can enforce both financial and performance accountability
high quality/performing ones. The ability of health clinic through the negotiation of contract provisions and fees.
users to hold clinics accountable by exercising their exit
option creates incentives for responsiveness and service
Accountability for what?
quality improvement (see, for example, Paul 1992). Of
course, as discussed further below, information asymmetry Defining accountability more precisely also relates to speci-
poses a classic barrier in that clients may not have sufficient fying accountability for what? Three general categories
information to judge quality and performance, and thus may emerge from answering this question. The first addresses the
not demand the ‘right’ kind of health care (Gauri 2001). This most commonly understood notion of accountability, finan-
can dampen the effectiveness of exit for accountability. cial accountability. The literature in this area deals with
compliance with laws, rules and regulations regarding finan-
A related set of ‘softer’ sanctions concerns public exposure cial control and management. The second type of account-
or negative publicity. This creates incentives to avoid damage ability is for performance. The literature here is arguably the
to the accountable actor’s reputation or status. For example, largest, encompassing public sector management reform,
investigative panels, the media and civil society watchdog performance measurement and evaluation, and service
organizations use these sanctions to hold government delivery improvement.2 The third category focuses on
officials accountable for upholding ethical and human rights political/democratic accountability. Literature here ranges

Downloaded from http://heapol.oxfordjournals.org/ by guest on December 5, 2016


standards. Self-policing among health care providers is from theoretical and philosophical treatises on the relation-
another example of the application of this type of sanction, ship between the state and the citizen, to discussions of
where professional codes of conduct are used as the standard governance, increased citizen participation, equity issues,
(see, for example, Cruess and Cruess 2000). However, in transparency and openness, responsiveness and trust-
many countries, the medical profession is a powerful actor building.
that tends more toward self-protection than self-policing.
The soft sanction of self-policing is insufficient for improved
Financial accountability
accountability in the absence of transparency, informed
health service users and regulatory enforcement (Brugha and Financial accountability concerns tracking and reporting on
Zwi 1998). allocation, disbursement and utilization of financial
resources, using the tools of auditing, budgeting and account-
Sanctions without enforcement significantly diminish ing. The operational basis for financial accountability begins
accountability. Lack of enforcement and/or selective enforce- with internal agency financial systems that follow uniform
ment undermine citizens’ confidence that government accounting rules and standards. Beyond individual agency
agencies are accountable and responsive, and contribute to boundaries, finance ministries, and in some situations
the creation of a culture of impunity that can lead public planning ministries, exercise oversight and control functions
officials to engage in corrupt practices. Enforcement regarding line ministries and other executing agencies. Since
mechanisms are critical, from broad legal and regulatory many executing agencies contract with the private sector or
frameworks to internal facility monitoring systems. As with non-governmental organizations (NGOs), these over-
discussed below, institutional capacity is also important; the sight and control functions extend to cover public procure-
best regulatory frameworks and enforcement mechanisms ment and contracting. For example as noted above, insurance
will remain ineffective if there is not sufficient capacity fund agencies play a key role in financial accountability in
among the institutions with accountability roles (see, for health systems that pay providers for predetermined
example, Standing and Bloom 2003). In health sector reform, packages of basic services. As purchasers of services, these
capacity-building efforts are directed at health ministries, agencies are able to use their clout to exercise sanctions for
insurance funds, and accreditation and licensing boards. At financial accountability through contracting arrangements.
the facility level, hospital and clinic management systems Provider payment systems can be important mechanisms for
improvement can address accountability enforcement; and at enforcing increased financial accountability and cost control
the local level, community empowerment initiatives often among participating private providers (see Bovbjerg and
target capacity to exercise oversight and to provide feedback Marsteller 1998; Maceira 1998).
to service providers (for example, Cornwall et al. 2000).
Legislatures pass the budget law that becomes the basis for
A lively debate regarding enforcement concerns the extent health ministry spending targets, for which they are held
to which service delivery markets can be created such that accountable within the rules governing budget execution.
accountability is automatically enforced when poor quality Accountability sanctions available to legislatures include
providers are eliminated as purchasers select higher quality, reductions in ministry funding, holding hearings on ministry
more entrepreneurial providers.1 To deal with information spending, and/or launching audit investigations. Obviously, a
and expertise asymmetries, insurance fund agencies often critical issue for the viable functioning of financial account-
serve as the agents of individual citizens in negotiating with ability is the institutional capacity of the various public and
providers. Through the terms of contracting arrangements, private entities involved. Health policymakers, for instance,
funding agencies are able to require participating providers need the ability to track and compare drug prices across
to meet service and quality standards, and to report on costs various types of facilities to identify price variation that is not
374 Derick W Brinkerhoff

attributable to local cost factors. They also need the capacity and social decision criteria (Saltman and van Otter 1995;
to detect and sanction malfeasance and corruption, for Bovbjerg and Marsteller 1998). In developing countries,
example, procurement fraud, overbilling, falsified staffing these tensions are exacerbated by a lack of resources and
levels and so on (for example, Di Tella and Savedoff 2001). capacity; even if government provides fiscal subsidies, facili-
At the facility level, for example, hospital managers need to ties and caregivers are frequently maldistributed, poorly
be able to account for the disposition of the funds they equipped, and in rural areas, scarce or nonexistent (see
receive from various sources, and to enforce compliance Bloom 2000).
from their staff.
Political/democratic accountability also relates to building
trust among citizens that government acts in accordance with
Performance accountability
agreed-upon standards of probity, ethics, integrity and
Performance accountability refers to demonstrating and professional responsibility (Gilson 2003). These standards
accounting for performance in light of agreed-upon perform- reflect national values and culture, and bring ethical, moral
ance targets. At the health system level, the focus is on the and on occasion religious issues into the accountability
services, outputs and results of public agencies and equation at both agency and facility levels. For example, in
programmes, not on individual service encounters between some countries, caring for the sick is a religious duty, and in
patients and providers. Health system performance account- response health care providers feel an obligation to deliver
ability is linked to financial accountability in that the finan- services. What this means for political/democratic account-
cial resources to be accounted for are intended to produce ability is that health systems whose providers reflect such

Downloaded from http://heapol.oxfordjournals.org/ by guest on December 5, 2016


goods, services and benefits for citizens, but it is distinct in values can contribute to increased levels of citizen trust, not
that financial accountability’s emphasis is largely on simply in health care providers, but also in the state’s interest
procedural compliance whereas performance accountability in their welfare (see Tendler and Freedheim 1994).
concentrates on results. For example, provider payment
schemes that maximize efficiency, quality of care, equity and
Analyzing accountability and health systems
consumer satisfaction demand strong financial and manage-
ment information systems that can produce both financial Applying the above classification of types of accountability
and performance information. Performance accountability is to health services delivery will develop a clearer picture of
connected to political/democratic accountability in that what accountability issues emerge, and of where gaps,
among the criteria for performance are responsiveness to contradictions and conflicts may lie. These issues can then be
citizens and achievement of service delivery targets that meet assessed in terms of three purposes of accountability.3 The
their needs and demands. As Saltman and von Otter (1995) first purpose is to control the misuse and abuse of public
point out, however, there can be conflicting pressures resources and/or authority.4 This relates directly to financial
between the pursuit of efficient health system performance accountability. The second is to provide assurance that
and democratic principles of equitable service provision, resources are used and authority is exercised according to
which in many countries has politicized the search for appropriate and legal procedures, professional standards and
accountability. societal values. This purpose applies to all three types of
accountability. The third is to support and promote improved
service delivery and management through feedback and
Political/democratic accountability
learning; the focus here is primarily on performance account-
In essence, political/democratic accountability has to do with ability. These three purposes overlap to some extent, but in
ensuring that government delivers on electoral promises, some cases pursuit of one can lead to conflicts with another.
fulfils the public trust, aggregates and represents citizens’ Perhaps the most recognized tension is between account-
interests, and responds to ongoing and emerging societal ability for control, with its focus on uncovering malfeasance
needs and concerns. As a result, effective political/demo- and allocating ‘blame’, and accountability for improvement,
cratic accountability enhances the legitimacy of government which emphasizes discretion, embracing error as a source of
in the eyes of citizens. The political process and elections are learning, and positive incentives.
the main avenues for this type of accountability. In many
countries, both developing and developed, health care issues There are numerous challenges to achieving these account-
often figure prominently in political campaigns. Building ability purposes in the health sector, as noted by a variety of
health facilities or providing affordable drugs can be attract- observers. Among these are the following. First, health
ive options for politicians in generating electoral support. services are characterized by strong asymmetries among
Elected officials and legislatures, then, are key to service providers, users and oversight bodies in terms of
political/democratic accountability, and through their over- information, expertise and access to services. Regarding
sight of ministers and other agency heads they link to the information, central oversight bodies can experience diffi-
health bureaucracy at various levels, depending upon the culties in monitoring provider performance since providers
extent of decentralization. As previously noted, a central often control the necessary information (see, for example,
concern here is the highly political nature of health system Millar and McKevitt 2000). Concerning expertise, for
performance, particularly concerning the issue of equity. An example, service users ‘may be ignorant of treatments and
important government responsibility is to remedy health care medicines that could harm them, and thus need some form
market failures both through regulation and resource allo- of protection’ (Shaw 1999, p. 12). Regarding access,
cation, which involves inherent tensions between economic providers can exercise significant gatekeeper power, for
Accountability and health systems 375

example, determining who receives what care, despite official The inability of health facilities to track and report on
procedures. Health service users, especially the poor, are in budgets, collection of fees, pharmaceutical purchases and
a weak position to confront this power. supply inventories, vehicles and equipment, and so on, limits
possibilities for accountability for control and assurance
Secondly, there are often divergences between public and purposes. It results in waste in the health system and can
private interests and incentives, which can constrain efforts create fertile ground for corruption. Further, weak capacity
to increase accountability (see Bennett et al. 1997). For to exercise oversight of facility and practitioner performance
example, Shaw (1999) notes differences between public and hampers efforts at accountability for the purpose of perform-
private sector providers in terms of the extent to which they ance improvement. This capacity gap is aggravated by the
receive and face incentives to act upon service user feedback. difficulty in isolating the contributions of various health
The difficulties of creating performance incentives for public system actors to achieving performance goals. Many
sector providers insulated from client accountability are well developing/transitioning countries that have moved away
recognized (see, for example, Goetz and Gaventa 2001), as from predominantly public provision of health care toward
are the challenges facing incentives design for the private private sector models have weak regulatory capacity, making
sector (see Bennett et al. 1997; Brugha and Zwi 1998). it difficult to exercise quality assurance (see Standing and
Bloom 2003).
Another divergence of public versus private interests arises
between policymakers focused on assuring some minimum Disparities between the sanctions that exist ‘on paper’ and
level of care available to all and individual service users with capacity to enforce them pose equally serious accountability

Downloaded from http://heapol.oxfordjournals.org/ by guest on December 5, 2016


an interest in receiving the maximum amount of care neces- problems. Facilities that lack the ability to identify who
sary to address their health need. This divergence can influ- works there, where they are at a given time, and what they
ence accountability enhancement in that it creates conflicting are doing cannot take the first steps toward holding staff
demands for accountability. At the system level, account- accountable for performance. Insurance funds that are
ability is targeted at allocative decisions and the institutional unable to develop a database on costs of care that can inform
arrangements to assure resources allocated are used appro- negotiations with private providers cannot use contracts as
priately. At the service provider level, the accountability an effective sanction for either financial or performance
relationship is between patient and provider, and the grounds accountability.
for accountability focus on the quality of service, professional
ethics, and not the cost (see, for example, Emmanuel and Table 1 presents illustrative health system issues associated
Emmanuel 1996; Fuchs 1996). with the three types of accountability: financial, performance
and political/democratic. It identifies the dominant purposes
Thirdly, institutional capacity gaps often constrain or under- of accountability associated with these issues: controlling
mine efforts to increase accountability for all three purposes. abuse, assuring conformity with standards and norms, and

Table 1. Accountability types, purposes and health service delivery

Type of accountability Illustrative health system issues Dominant purposes of accountability

Financial Cost accounting/budgeting for: • Control and assurance are dominant.


– Personnel • Focus is on compliance with prescribed input
– Operations and procedural standards; cost control; resource
– Pharmaceuticals/supplies efficiency measures; elimination of waste, fraud
Definition of basic benefits packages and corruption.
Contract oversight
Performance Allocation of resources needed for effective system • Assurance and improvement/learning are
performance dominant.
Quality of care • Assurance purpose emphasizes adherence to the
Service provider behaviour legal, regulatory, and policy framework; professional
Regulation by professional bodies service delivery procedures, norms, and values;
Contracting out and quality of care standards and audits.
• Improvement/learning purpose focuses on
benchmarking, standard setting, quality
management, operations research, monitoring and
evaluation (M&E).
Political/democratic Service delivery equity/fairness • Control and assurance purposes are emphasized.
Transparency • Control relates to citizen/voter satisfaction, use of
Responsiveness to citizens taxpayer funds, addressing market failure and
Service user trust distribution of services (disadvantaged populations).
Dispute resolution • Assurance focuses on principal-agent dynamics for
oversight; availability and dissemination of relevant
information; adherence to quality standards,
professional norms, and societal values.
376 Derick W Brinkerhoff

supporting improved performance/learning. This creates a governance and institutional structures: for example,
framework for categorizing and taking stock of health system national, district and local health councils; hospital boards;
reforms in terms of accountability. medical review boards and professional certification bodies;
decentralization, and so on (see, for example, Mills 1994;
A focus on accountability can lead to an increased under- Savage et al. 1997; Gershberg 1998; NPPHCN 1998; Salmon
standing of health system operations, clearer identification of et al. 2003). In the health economics and financing literature,
the pressures and incentives facing health system actors, and as noted above, accountability implications can be identified
better reform design and implementation. This systemic in the context of analyses of health care markets, principal-
focus helps to identify factors that influence the success agent issues arising from information asymmetries, public-
potential of interventions intended to achieve one or another private mix, demand-driven services and user fees,
of the three purposes. For example, tackling corruption in the priority-setting, and separation of payment from provision.5
health sector is not likely to be sustainable without some Accountability also figures, sometimes implicitly, sometimes
degree of political/democratic accountability, which creates explicitly, in the quality assurance/quality improvement
and strengthens the incentives for health policymakers to literature.6
respond to citizens’ needs and demands.
Once types and purposes of accountability have been
However, few policy designs and strategies for health sector unpacked, a next step in integrating a focus on accountability
reform and system strengthening use accountability as an into health policy and systems strengthening is to develop a
integral theme. Rather, they focus on one or another aspect clearer picture of accountability relationships and connec-

Downloaded from http://heapol.oxfordjournals.org/ by guest on December 5, 2016


of health system reform, and treat accountability (if tions. This begins with enumerating a list of health system
mentioned at all) as a secondary or corollary dimension. For actors, and then proceeds with mapping the linkages among
example, there is a large literature on community partici- them.
pation in health services reform and delivery, some of which
notes that among the rationales for, and results of,
Mapping accountability linkages
community participation is increased targeting of services on
community needs and more accountability (see, for example, Figure 1 offers an assessment matrix to map accountability
Cornwall et al. 2000). Another topic area where account- linkages and to examine actors’ interactions. The matrix
ability issues are mentioned concerns health system tracks the patterns of answerability and sanctions in terms of

Demand information, impose sanctions

Health care providers


Agencies of restraint

International donors
Local govt officials

Professional assoc
Funding agencies
Health svc users/

Hospital boards

Health councils

Health sector actors


Parliament
patients

Unions
NGOs
MOH

Health svc users/patients


Supply information, respond to sanctions

MOH
Agencies of restraint
Funding agencies
Parliament
Local govt officials
NGOs
Hospital boards
Health councils
Professional associations
Unions
Health care providers
International donors

à ð è
Code:

â ò ê
Capacity to supply information or respond to sanctions: Weak , Medium , Strong
Capacity to demand information or impose sanctions: Weak , Medium , Strong

Figure 1. Health sector actors accountability matrix


Accountability and health systems 377

which actors are in a position to demand information and types of accountability, for example financial versus service
impose sanctions, and which actors are charged with delivery performance.
supplying information and are subject to sanctions. To
adequately capture the complexity of accountability linkages, Building on the matrix/matrices, next steps would include
separate tables for answerability and sanctions would be identification of problems/issues related to answerability and
prepared, which would take into consideration the distinc- sanctions, and of which types of accountability (financial,
tions between these two elements of accountability and the service delivery performance, political/democratic) are
different implications for the design of system improvements. involved. Such analysis would inform appraisal of actors’
For reasons of economy, Figure 1 illustrates both information capacity to fulfil accountability roles, help to pinpoint gaps,
demand/supply and sanctions on a single table. and feed into setting purposes and targets. When undertaken
as a team effort, the mapping exercise could also serve to
The table(s) can indicate situations where there are either support the process dimension of achieving change targets. It
two few or too many accountability linkages. There is no could forge consensus among reform team members, as well
universally ‘correct’ number of accountability linkages. How as point to who else needs to be involved. Strategy implemen-
many linkages are appropriate will, to an important extent, tation will depend upon tapping the shared interests of
be situation-specific, and will depend upon the quality, not various actors to build coalitions, commitment and mutual
simply the number, of connections. Nonetheless, the litera- understanding (see Gilson 1997; Gilson et al. 1999; Brinker-
ture and experience suggest the following: hoff and Crosby 2002). Clarifying actors’ connections, capac-
ities and interests is a key input for developing strategies to

Downloaded from http://heapol.oxfordjournals.org/ by guest on December 5, 2016


strengthen accountability.
• Too few linkages can open the door to corruption, lack of
responsiveness, poor quality services, and evasion of
responsibility on the part of health service providers.
• Too many linkages, particularly if they are distant or atten- Conclusions
uated connections, can limit the effectiveness of account-
Increasing accountability is a key element in a wide variety
ability. When many actors, along with their differing
of policies and reforms, from government-wide anti-corrup-
interests, are involved, health service provision risks not
tion campaigns, to national-level health system reform
being sufficiently accountable to anyone.
programmes, to decentralized health service delivery at the
• Linkages that are predominantly internal to the public
local level, and community-based health funds. One of the
health bureaucracy and that connect upwards within the
main reasons why this range is so broad relates to the inter-
hierarchy orient actors to the priorities and needs of
connections among the various types and purposes of
bureaucratic superiors rather than being accountable to
accountability (see Table 1). Financial accountability quickly
service users, particularly the poor.
leads to performance issues, and these two combined have
implications for political/democratic accountability.
As the code for the table indicates, these supply and demand Accountability to curb abuse underlies accountability for
linkages can be rated as strong, medium or weak. The purposes of adhering to standards and of improving perform-
downward arrows indicate capacity to demand information ance.
or impose sanctions. The horizontal arrows show capacity to
supply information or respond to sanctions. Effective The accountability landscape is filled with a broad array of
accountability systems will exhibit a high number of boxes actors with multiple connections; in some cases these actors
with both downward and horizontal arrows, indicating that are both accountable to one set of actors while simul-
demand for information is adequately met by supply. For taneously exercising accountability with regard to another set
example, systems with a preponderance of downward arrows (see Figure 1). These connections create layered webs of
without corresponding horizontal ones suggest several accountability with varying degrees of autonomy and sources
possible problems: mistargeted accountability demand, inad- of control/oversight. For example, public providers, health
equate response capacity, and/or disagreements over appro- ministries, finance ministries, parliamentary health commit-
priate linkages. tees, insurance fund agencies and hospital boards are often
linked. This leads to intervention strategy issues, such as the
These ratings seek to capture information on the capacity of advantages or disadvantages of strengthening different nodes
the various actors to fulfil their accountability roles, the in the web. For instance, efforts to increase the power and
pattern of accountability relationships, and the relative autonomy of hospital boards to exercise expanded oversight
strength or weakness of the accountability chains that may not be effective if the health minister is not subject to
connect them. For example, health ministries may have a political accountability and can dismiss board members who
legal mandate for budgetary oversight of public health facil- displease him/her with impunity. The configuration of
ities’ expenditure and collection of user fees, but in many accountability actors and their capacities also highlights the
countries their ability to exercise that accountability function difficult issue of the gap between the ideal and the possible.
is substantially limited (Russell et al. 1999). Regulators are As countries move toward market-driven health systems, the
often another set of actors with weak capacity (Standing and critical weaknesses in regulatory capacity, technical over-
Bloom 2003). For a particular country, the tables should be sight, application of sanctions and availability of information
customized by including the specific array of actors in each to service users can often undermine the hoped-for account-
of the categories, and/or by tracing the linkages for different ability improvements.
378 Derick W Brinkerhoff

The analytic framework presented here represents an initial Bovbjerg RR, Marsteller JA. 1998. Health care market competition
effort to consider accountability from a systemic perspective, in six states: implications for the poor. Occasional Paper No. 17.
with the intent to respond to calls for attention to ‘how best Washington, DC: Urban Institute.
Brugha R, Zwi A. 1998. Improving the quality of private sector
to regulate, supervise and monitor both public and private
delivery of public health services: challenges and strategies.
sector providers and how best to encourage them to act in Health Policy and Planning 13: 107–20.
the broader public interest’ (Mills 1998, p. 511). However, the Cohen JC, Montoya JC. 2001. Using technology to fight corruption
practical utility of the proposed framework in identifying, in pharmaceutical purchasing: lessons learned from the Chilean
measuring and improving accountability in health systems experience. Washington, DC: World Bank Institute. At:
remains to be demonstrated. Determination of what value it [http://www.worldbank.org/wbi/healthflagship/oj_chile.pdf],
adds must necessarily await field applications. accessed 13 December 2002.
Cornwall A, Lucas H, Pasteur K (eds). 2000. Accountability through
participation: developing workable partnership models in the
Endnotes health sector. IDS Bulletin 31 (1). Brighton: University of
Sussex, Institute of Development Studies.
1 In the governance literature, this debate is reflected in a
Cruess SR, Cruess RL. 2000. Professionalism: a contract between
concern that market mechanisms transform citizens into consumers. medicine and society. Canadian Medical Association Journal
When service providers are responsive only to citizen-consumers 162: 668–9.
who ‘vote’ with their money, what happens to accountability to those Di Tella R, Savedoff WD (eds). 2001. Diagnosis corruption: fraud in
with limited purchasing power? See Blanchard et al. (1997). Regard- Latin America’s public hospitals. Washington, DC: Inter-
ing the role of markets and the private sector in the health sector, American Development Bank.
the literature is extensive; see, for example, Appleby (1999), Emmanuel EJ, Emmanuel LL. 1996. What is accountability in health

Downloaded from http://heapol.oxfordjournals.org/ by guest on December 5, 2016


Bovbjerg and Marsteller (1998), Enthoven (1999) and Saltman and care? Annals of Internal Medicine 124: 229–39.
van Otter (1995). See Bennett et al. (1997) and Hanson (2003) on England R. 2000. Contracting and performance management in the
private provision of services in the developing world. health sector: a guide for low and middle income countries.
2 These reforms consist of a loosely bundled set of concepts
London: Department for International Development, Health
drawn from the pioneering administrative change efforts in Systems Resource Centre, April.
Australia, New Zealand and the United Kingdom (the New Public Enthoven A. 1999. In pursuit of an improving National Health
Management or NPM), and later from the United States (the Rein- Service. London: Nuffield Trust.
venting Government movement). For an analytic overview of NPM, Ferlie E, Ashburner L, Fitzgerald L, Pettigrew A. 1996. The new
see Ferlie et al. (1996). For expanded discussion of NPM concepts, public management in action. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
see Minogue et al. (1998). On Reinventing Government, see Fuchs VR. 1996. Economics, values, and health care reform.
Osborne and Gaebler (1992) and NPR (1996). Regarding the appli- American Economic Review 86: 1–24.
cation of NPM in developing countries, see, for example, Polidano Gauri V. 2001. Are incentives everything? Payment mechanisms for
(1999). For a discussion of NPM in the health sector in developing health care providers in developing countries. Health and Popu-
countries, see Russell et al. (1999) and Shaw (1999). lation, Nutrition, Fertility, and HIV/AIDS Working Paper No.
3 The following discussion of purposes draws upon Aucoin and
2624. Washington, DC: World Bank.
Heintzman (2000). Gershberg AI. 1998. Decentralization, recentralization and
4 There is a growing literature on corruption in the health
performance accountability: building an operationally useful
sector. See, for example, Cohen and Montoya (2001), Di Tella and framework for analysis. Development Policy Review 16: 405–31.
Savedoff (2001), Lee et al. (n.d.), Martiny (2000) and Vian (2002). Gilson L. 1997. Implementing and evaluating health reform
5 See, for example, the various chapters in Janovsky (1995). See
processes: lessons from the literature. PHR Major Applied
also the list of applied research reports available at [http://www. Research 1, Working Paper No. 1. Washington, DC: U.S.
PHRproject.com]. Agency for International Development, Partnerships for
6 See, for example, Sheldon (1998), Silimperi et al. (2002), and
Health Reform Project.
the materials available at [http://www.qaproject.org]. Gilson L. 2003. Trust and the development of health care as a social
institution. Social Science and Medicine 56: 1453–68.
Gilson L, Doherty J, McIntyre D et al. 1999. The dynamics of policy
References change: health care financing in South Africa, 1994–1999. PHR
Appleby J. 1999. The reforms of the British National Health Service. Major Applied Research Paper 1, Technical Paper No. 1.
In: Powell FD, Wessen AF (eds). Health care systems in tran- Washington, DC: U.S. Agency for International Development,
sition: an international perspective. London: Sage Publications, Partnerships for Health Reform Project.
pp. 305–26. Goetz AM, Gaventa J. 2001. Bringing citizen voice and client focus
Aucoin P, Heintzman R. 2000. The dialectics of accountability for into service delivery. IDS Working Paper No. 138. Brighton:
performance in public management reform. International University of Sussex, Institute for Development Studies.
Review of Administrative Sciences 66: 45–55. Hanson K. 2003. Who profits? Private healthcare—opportunity or
Bennett S, McPake B, Mills A (eds). 1997. Private health providers risk? ID21 Insights, Health No. 3, March. Brighton: University
in developing countries: serving the public interest? London: of Sussex, Institute for Development Studies. At: [http://www.
Zed Books Ltd. id21.org/insights/insights-h03], accessed 24 July 2003.
Blanchard LA, Hinnant CC, Wong W. 1997. Market-based reforms Hermida J, Robalino ME. 2002. Increasing compliance with
in government: towards a social sub-contract? Paper presented maternal and child care quality standards in Ecuador. Inter-
at the 58th National Conference, American Society for Public national Journal for Quality in Health Care 14 (Suppl I): 25–34.
Administration, Philadelphia, July. Hutchinson P, Habte D, Mulusa M. 1999. Health care in Uganda:
Bloom G. 2000. Equity in health in unequal societies: towards health selected issues. Discussion Paper No. 404. Washington, DC:
equity during rapid social change. IDS Working Paper No. 112. World Bank.
Brighton: University of Sussex, Institute for Development Janovsky K (ed). 1995. Health policy and systems development: an
Studies. agenda for research. Geneva: World Health Organization.
Brinkerhoff DW, Crosby BL. 2002. Managing policy reform: Lee B, Poutanen M, Breuning L, Bradbury K (undated). Siphoning
concepts and tools for decision-makers in developing and tran- off: corruption and waste in family planning and reproductive
sitioning countries. Bloomfield, CT: Kumarian Press. health resources in developing countries. Berkeley, CA: Bay
Accountability and health systems 379

Area International Group. At: [http://www.big.berkeley. edu/ Savage GT, Taylor RL, Rotarius TM, Buesseler JA. 1997.
research.workingpapers.corruption.pdf], accessed 24 Novem- Governance of integrated delivery systems/networks: a
ber 2002. stakeholder approach. Health Care Management Review 22:
Maceira D. 1998. Provider payment mechanisms in health care: 7–20.
Incentives, outcomes, and organizational impact in developing Schedler A. 1999. Conceptualizing accountability. In: Schedler A,
countries. PHR Major Applied Research 2, Working Paper No. Diamond L, Plattner MF (eds). The self-restraining state: power
2. Washington, DC: U.S. Agency for International Develop- and accountability in new democracies. Boulder, CO: Lynne
ment, Partnerships for Health Reform Project. Rienner Publishers, pp. 13–29.
Martiny A. 2000. The lack of transparency in the health sector: Shaw RP. 1999. New trends in public sector management in health:
Squandered resources, improper usage, deception – gates to applications in developed and developing countries. Washing-
corruption. Berlin, Germany: Transparency International. ton, DC: World Bank Institute, April.
Working Paper, translation by Carolyn Taylor Brown, At: Sheldon T. 1998. Promoting health care quality: what role perform-
[http://www.transparency.org/working_papers/thematic/health ance indicators? Quality in Health Care 7 (Supplement): S45-
_care.html], accessed 4 November 2002. S50.
McPake B, Mills A. 2000. What can we learn from international Silimperi DR, Franco LM, van Zanten TV, Macauly C. 2002. A
comparisons of health systems and health system reform? framework for institutionalizing quality assurance. Inter-
Bulletin of the World Health Organization 78: 811–20. national Journal for Quality in Health Care 14 (Supplement I):
Millar M, McKevittD. 2000. Accountability and performance 67–73.
measurement: an assessment of the Irish health care system. Standing H, Bloom G. 2003. Where there is no regulator. ID21
International Review of Administrative Sciences 66: 285–96. Insights, Health No. 3, March. Brighton: University of Sussex,
Mills A. 1998. Health policy reforms and their impact on the practice Institute for Development Studies. At: [http://www.id21.org/
of tropical medicine. British Medical Bulletin 54: 503–13. insights/insights-h03], accessed 23 July2003.

Downloaded from http://heapol.oxfordjournals.org/ by guest on December 5, 2016


Mills A. 1994. Decentralization and accountability in the health Tendler J, Freedheim S. 1994. Trust in a rent-seeking world: health
sector from an international perspective: what are the choices? and government transformed in Northeast Brazil. World
Public Administration and Development 14: 281–92. Development 22: 1771–9.
Minogue M, Hulme D, Polidano C. 1998. Beyond the new public Travis P, Egger D, Davies P, Mechbal A. 2002. Towards better
management: changing ideas and practices in governance. Chel- stewardship: concepts and critical issues. WHO/EIP/DP 02.48.
tenham: Edward Elgar Publishing. Geneva: World Health Organization.
Mulgan R. 2000. Accountability: an ever-expanding concept? Public Vian T. 2002. Corruption, accountability and decentralized health
Administration 78: 555–73. systems: Keeping the public’s trust. Paper presented at the
NPPHCN (National Progressive Primary Health Care Network). American Public Health Association, Annual Meeting,
1998. Community involvement in hospitals: key findings and Philadelphia, November.
recommendations. Cape Town, South Africa: NPPHCN. At:
[http://www.hst.org.za/pphc/commun/], accessed 16 October
2001. Acknowledgements
NPR (National Performance Review). 1996. Reaching public goals:
managing government for results. resource guide. Washington, Support for this research, conducted while the author was at Abt
DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, October. Associates, is acknowledged from the U.S. Agency for International
Osborne D, Gaebler T. 1992. Reinventing government: how the entre- Development, through the Partners for Health Reform Project,
preneurial spirit is transforming the public sector. New York: Phase II (PHRplus). The views expressed are solely those of the
Addison-Wesley Publishers. author and should not be attributed to USAID. The author thanks
Paul S. 1992. Accountability in public services: exit, voice and Sara Bennett, Lucy Gilson, Charlotte Leighton, Mark McEuen,
control. World Development 20: 1047–60. Mary Paterson and Nancy Pielemeier for helpful comments.
Polidano C. 1999. The new public management in developing coun-
tries. Public Policy and Management Working Paper No. 13.
Manchester: University of Manchester, Institute for Develop- Biography
ment Policy and Management.
Romzek BS. 2000. Dynamics of public sector accountability in an Derick W Brinkerhoff is RTI Senior Fellow in International Public
era of reform. International Review of Administrative Sciences Management at the Research Triangle Institute. He is a specialist in
66: 21–44. policy analysis and implementation, strategic management and
Russell S, Bennett S, Mills A. 1999. Reforming the health sector: public administration. He has worked extensively on administrative
towards a healthy new public management. Journal of Inter- and health systems reform in developing countries, concentrating on
national Development 11: 767–75. decentralization, corruption, evidence-based policymaking and
Salmon JW, Heavens J, Lombard C, Tavrow P. 2003. The impact of public-private partnerships. Dr Brinkerhoff has published widely,
accreditation on the quality of hospital care: Kwa-Zulu Natal including six books and numerous articles and book chapters. He
Province, Republic of South Africa. Operations Research holds a doctorate in social policy and administration from Harvard
Results Report 2 (17). Washington, DC: U.S. Agency for Inter- University and a masters in public administration from the
national Development, Quality Assurance Project. University of California, Riverside. Prior to joining RTI, he was a
Saltman R, Ferroussier-Davis O. 2000. The concept of stewardship Principal Social Scientist with Abt Associates Inc. for 10 years, and
in health policy. Bulletin of the World Health Organization 78: previously spent a decade on the faculty of the University of
732–9. Maryland at the International Development Management Center.
Saltman R, van Otter C. 1995. Introduction. In: Saltman R, van
Otter C (eds). Implementing planned markets in health care: Correspondence: Derick W Brinkerhoff, Research Triangle Insti-
balancing social and economic responsibility. Buckingham: tute, 1615 M Street NW, Suite 740, Washington DC 20036, USA.
Open University Press, pp. 1–21. Email: dbrinkerhoff@rti.org

Anda mungkin juga menyukai