Anda di halaman 1dari 22

bs_bs_banner

Strategic Entrepreneurship Journal


Strat. Entrepreneurship J., 7: 70–91 (2013)
Published online in Wiley Online Library (wileyonlinelibrary.com). DOI: 10.1002/sej.1147

CAPABILITIES AND STRATEGIC


ENTREPRENEURSHIP IN PUBLIC ORGANIZATIONS
PETER G. KLEIN1, JOSEPH T. MAHONEY2*, ANITA M. MCGAHAN3, and
CHRISTOS N. PITELIS4
1
Division of Applied Social Sciences, and Truman School of Public Affairs,
University of Missouri, Columbia, Missouri, U.S.A.
2
Department of Business Administration, College of Business, University of Illi-
nois at Urbana-Champaign, Champaign, Illinois, U.S.A.
3
Rotman School of Management and Munk School of Global Affairs, University
of Toronto, Canada
4
Centre for International Business and Management, Judge Business School,
University of Cambridge, Cambridge, U.K.

Public organizations are relatively understudied in the strategic entrepreneurship literature. In


this article, we submit that public organizations are usefully analyzed as entities that create and
capture value in both the private and public sectors and that a capabilities lens sheds important
new insights on their behavior. As they try to create and capture value, public organizations can
act entrepreneurially by creating or leveraging bundles of capabilities, which may then shape
subsequent entrepreneurial action. Such processes can involve complex interactions among
public and private actors. For example, public organizations often partner with private firms
to produce existing products, create new products, and establish new markets which, in turn,
generate new capabilities for both public and private actors. Yet such coevolutionary processes
are not guaranteed to create value, and capabilities acquired in the pursuit of public interests
may, over time, enable activities that damage those same interests. We show how a capabilities
approach helps explain the nature and evolution of public organizations and we apply this
approach to a series of cases on the growth and diversification of public organizations, the
private provision of public goods, and related issues. Copyright © 2013 Strategic Management
Society.

INTRODUCTION govern, administer, and transform these resources.1


Governmental capabilities that can create value from
An organization’s capabilities—built on its resource public resources are essential to efficient and effec-
base—are critical to its entrepreneurial behavior and tive government. How unique and inimitable are
performance. Yet, in the field of entrepreneurship, public resources and capabilities? Are they mainly
public and governmental capabilities have not been serving public or private interests? Under what con-
researched comprehensively. Governmental organi- ditions does public entrepreneurship create value?
zations not only control resources such as land, Can efficient stewardship of public capabilities and
buildings, and budgets, but also the capabilities to resources lead to outcomes that are not aligned with
public interests?
Keywords: capabilities; strategic entrepreneurship; public orga- 1
These capabilities relate to infrastructure such as highways
nizations (Small and Verhoef, 2007) and prisons (Hart, Shleifer, and
*Correspondence to: Joseph T. Mahoney, Department of Busi- Vishny, 1997), sensitive information about military activities
ness Administration, College of Business, University of Illinois (Vandenbroucke, 1993), organizational assets such as the cul-
at Urbana-Champaign, 1206 S. Sixth St., Champaign, IL 61820, tures and routines of established agencies (Peters, 2001), and
U.S.A. E-mail: josephm@illinois.edu knowledge systems such as rules of law (Tamanaha, 2005).

Copyright © 2013 Strategic Management Society


Capabilities and Strategic Entrepreneurship in Public Organizations 71

This article explains how capabilities that develop 1971), the durability of capabilities alone may, over
in pursuit of specific public goals may subsequently time, subvert the pursuit of public goals. We begin by
shape opportunities in unanticipated ways. Our per- asking what makes a resource, opportunity, activity,
spective is informed by the idea that value creation or outcome ‘public’ or ‘private.’ We rely on the idea
in the public domain is more difficult to identify than from the field of entrepreneurship that capabilities
in many private situations. A major difference develop as actors seek to deploy resources strategi-
between private and public organizations is in the cally. We briefly consider how these resources and
clarity of organizational goals. Whereas organiza- capabilities attain value.2 Assessing the value of the
tional objectives in the private domain typically services supported by these resources requires evalu-
hinge on enhancing returns on investment for share- ating opportunity costs in nonmonetary terms. We
holders and founders, the objectives of public orga- posit that capabilities may develop in public organi-
nizations are often less clear, qualitative, changeable, zations to deploy resources in valuable ways—with
and ill specified, not only because of the lack of value assessed against objectives that may not be
profit indicators, but also because of interventions by pecuniary.
multiple authorities and interest groups and sharply We then briefly review concepts from strategic
conflicting mandates and values—e.g., obtaining entrepreneurship, neoclassical economics, agency-
environmental conservation and economic develop- theoretic, transaction cost, and evolutionary perspec-
ment or achieving equality and efficiency (Dixit, tives on the management of public capabilities. The
1997; Okun, 1975; Rainey and Bozeman, 2000). purpose is to motivate a new perspective on the link
Research in public administration and political between capabilities and value creation and capture
science has long acknowledged capabilities in in the public domain, including how public goals
shaping goals in the public sector. Allison’s (1971) may change over time.
seminal account of the Cuban missile crisis showed We next illustrate with a simple model, inspired
how military objectives are shaped by available by Arrow (1951), how durable capabilities influence
resources and capabilities which, in turn, affect the the process of resource deployment in the public
costs and risks of strategic options. However, the sector and, thus, have a significant impact on how
strategic entrepreneurship literature has given little public goals evolve over time. The analysis indicates
attention to the boundaries, internal organization, that perverse public outcomes, such as the consump-
growth, and performance of public organizations tion of bureaucratic ‘slack’ and the overprovision or
(Bonardi, Hillman, and Keim, 2005; Hillman, Keim, transformation of existing public goods (which we
and Schuler, 2004, Kivleniece and Quelin, 2012). label ‘public bads’) can arise from hazards in the
Moreover, while research in public administration administration of public resources. We show how
and political science has examined the growth of these processes can occur even without regulatory
public agencies (Horn, 1995; Peters, 2001), the capture by private interests, a prevalent explanation
research in these fields has mainly emphasized the in the agency-theoretic and transaction cost litera-
limitations of classical theories and pointed toward tures (see Dal Bo [2006] for a review of both the
the potential importance of entrepreneurship theory, theory and empirical literatures on regulatory
without leveraging this theory. Similarly, although capture).
transaction cost economics and agency theory have Finally we offer several detailed examples of how
informed research on public entities (Moe, 1995; capabilities in the public domain shape and are
Spiller and Tommasi, 2003; Weingast, 1995), the shaped by entrepreneurial behavior and perfor-
entrepreneurial capabilities approach has rarely mance. The purpose is to explore the implications of
been employed (Kivleniece and Quelin, 2012; the entrepreneurial capabilities perspective on the
McWilliams, Fleet, and Cory, 2002; Oliver and creation and capture of value in the public domain
Holzinger, 2008). and to point toward opportunities for further research
Our analysis examines how public capabilities can
2
enable and constrain subsequent opportunities that The value of some resources utilized by public entities—
buildings, office equipment, and human capital—is tractable
both public and private actors confront. We conceive because of the value they command in private markets and
of a public organization as any sovereign entity with because these resources may be fungible into private use, thus
sovereign authority over a specific constituency. The engendering competition between public and private entities for
the productive services of these resources. Other resources—
analysis suggests that, even without any form of such as a town’s name or identity—either cannot be or are not
‘regulatory capture’ by private interests (Stigler, used privately and may have no market values.

Copyright © 2013 Strategic Management Society Strat. Entrepreneurship J., 7: 70–91 (2013)
DOI: 10.1002/sej
72 P. G. Klein et al.

in this area. In this section, we turn to issues such as activity is returns to shareholders, founders, and
organizational boundaries, growth, and quasi priva- other investors. As a result, most entrepreneurship
tization.3 We conclude by affirming the central theory addresses the challenge of resource and capa-
importance of an entrepreneurial capabilities lens to bility deployment under uncertainty to achieve the
an understanding of public organization. aim of return on invested capital.
Theory that has developed in the field of strategic
entrepreneurship emphasizes facets of efficiency in
CAPABILITIES AND VALUE IN the deployment of resource to achieve these aims.
PUBLIC ORGANIZATIONS The research literature attends to the ways in which
capability development itself depends on the entre-
The strategic entrepreneurship field offers important preneurial process. Capabilities may arise as orga-
insights on how organizations deploy capabilities in nizations develop routines for conducting this
pursuit of value creation and capture. Public entities, assembly and redeployment of resource bundles
like private firms, have been described using the (Eisenhardt and Martin, 2000; Nelson and Winter,
language of entrepreneurship theory (Klein et al., 1982). Thus, entrepreneurship is not a purely cogni-
2010; Short, Moss, and Lumpkin, 2009). Govern- tive act, but is manifest in action (Foss et al., 2008;
ments, government agencies, charitable organiza- Penrose, 1959). To better understand the entrepre-
tions, social enterprises, and other ‘nonmarket’ neurial function, we must examine the capabilities
decision makers are alert to recognize (Kirzner, that entrepreneurs establish, maintain, reshape, and
1997; Shepherd, McMullen, and Jennings, 2007; dissolve to govern the creation and deployment of
Sleptsov and Anand, 2008) and realize (Alvarez and resources.4
Barney, 2007; Luksha, 2008; Miller, 2007) opportu- How can we characterize public-sector resources
nities for creating and capturing value. These deci- and capabilities? Public organizations employ both
sion makers exercise judgment over the mobilization private and public resources and their productivity in
and deployment of resources under uncertainty, seek transforming the services of these resources into
the insights of users, introduce technological and publicly valued outputs is complicated by the fact
organizational innovations, and develop novel strat- that their inputs are difficult to measure and their
egies (Felin and Zenger, 2009; Klein, 2008; Shah outputs are sometimes hard even to conceptualize.
and Tripsas, 2007; Van de Ven, Sapienza, and Public organizations such as government bodies and
Villanueva, 2007). multilateral agencies (e.g., the United Nations and
Yet a central facet of public organizations that has the World Health Organization) produce public
not been examined comprehensively is the creation, outputs, which are not sold on the market and, thus,
stewardship, deployment, and dynamics of capabili- in contrast to private sector outputs, there are no
ties in purported pursuit of public goals. Unlike market prices at which these public outputs can be
much of the extant entrepreneurship literature evaluated (Mises, 1944; Peters, 2001). The produc-
emphasizing Kirzner’s (1973) ‘pure entrepreneur- tivity of public organizations is elusive because the
ship’ concept of alertness to profit opportunities, value of public inputs and outputs is difficult to
which is separated from resource ownership (Foss assess quickly, quantitatively, and objectively (Dixit,
and Klein, 2010), the strategic entrepreneurship field 1997; Wilson, 1989). Insights, tools, and theoretical
highlights the close relationship between underlying relationships established in the fields of strategic
capabilities and value creation and capture (see entrepreneurship and management are relevant to the
Figure 1 for a summary of these differences). Orga- study of public organizations precisely because they
nizations are examined as unique bundles of rela- can help relieve this intractability.
tional, cultural, and institutional capabilities and
entrepreneurship constitutes the assembly and rede- 4
The primary contribution of the current article is in joining
ployment of new resource bundles under uncertainty strategic entrepreneurship, capabilities, and public organiza-
(Dacin, Dacin, and Matear, 2010; Foss and Klein, tion. Indeed, the strategic entrepreneurship literature, in
general, is in progress in joining entrepreneurship and capa-
2012). The dominant view on the objective of this bilities including, for example, in the Strategic Entrepreneur-
ship Journal alone: Agarwal, Audretsch, and Sarkar (2007);
3
While a diversity of organizations purport to act in the public Anderson, Covin, and Slevin (2009); Bingham, Eisenhardt,
interest, the current article focuses on the differences between and Furr (2007); Brinkman and Hoegl (2011); Carmeli and
private and public organizations rather than among the types of Azeroual (2009); Foss et al. (2008); Simsek and Heavey
public organizations. (2011); and Sleptsov and Anand (2008).

Copyright © 2013 Strategic Management Society Strat. Entrepreneurship J., 7: 70–91 (2013)
DOI: 10.1002/sej
Capabilities and Strategic Entrepreneurship in Public Organizations 73

Private organizations Public organizations Public and private


organizations

Recognition and
Decision making within realization of
organizations opportunity; judgment
over resource
deployment

Returns to founders, Improvements in Efficiency and


Common measures of shareholders, and other security, education, effectiveness in resource
entrepreneurial value investors; time to IPO; health, and civic life; and capability
creation time to revenue advances in the provision deployment
generation; return on of utilities and
invested capital transportation services

Developed though
Genesis of capabilities experience and learning;
may be tacit; can lead to
excess capacity

Accumulated and Initially accumulated to Accumulated and


Deployment of deployed to support the support the pursuit of deployed by actors
capabilities pursuit of well-defined qualitative goals, but within the organization
goals for achieving ultimately outlive the seeking to create and
returns on investment goals and may be capture value
deployed elsewhere

Resources and Resources and Productivity is difficult


Measures capabilities are difficult capabilities become to assess
to measure separately visibly evident as
from their value in use bureaucratic structures
emerge; these structures
are more readily
observable than the
achievement of value
creation

Focus of measurement Ends, outcomes, Means, tasks, activities


systems and practices achievements

Mechanisms for Factor markets Analogy to private value; VRIN criteria;


assessing the cost or price of construction; appropriability criteria
value of a resource transferability

Figure 1. Concepts of entrepreneurship and capabilities in private and public organizations

Progress in analyzing public organizations Addressing these issues begins with a definition
requires clear definitions so as to allow results to of public organization per se. We define public
be measurable (Dixit, 1997). Clarity is required to organizations as entities with sovereign authority
support the cultivation of knowledge, skills, and (whether primary or derived from higher authority,
incentives to achieve public goals. Public resources such as the government) over a specified constitu-
and capabilities must be well defined to enable their ency. This definition does not refer directly to the
acquisition—i.e., within strategic factor markets ‘public interest,’ which is impossible to identify
(Barney, 1986) for collectively owned, politi- comprehensively given heterogeneous preferences
cally controlled resources—and their deployment and subjective valuations (Arrow, 1951). We focus
through combination and recombination in use only on those public organizations that control
(Capron and Chatain, 2008; Maritan and Florence, resources either formally or informally. In practice,
2008). Clear performance objectives for public orga- the agencies we consider have constitutional, legis-
nizations are central to assessments of bureaucratic lative, or other formal authority to create and/or
efficiency. transfer resources through levying taxes or accruing
Copyright © 2013 Strategic Management Society Strat. Entrepreneurship J., 7: 70–91 (2013)
DOI: 10.1002/sej
74 P. G. Klein et al.

fees through some well-defined mechanism. What The nature of public resources and capabilities
distinguishes these agencies is their stewardship
over resources that are not under the control of Public resources in this context cannot be defined
any other private or public actor. Therefore, we are satisfactorily simply by reference to collective own-
examining organizations controlled by a body with ership, as many private resources are owned or con-
legally sanctioned coercion rights and decision trolled by groups (e.g., shareholders, partners, and
rights over the governance of resources and capabili- family members). A resource’s public goods charac-
ties (Hirschman, 1982; Olson, 1965). We turn first to teristics (non-excludability and non-rivalry in use)
define these public resources, then explore the rela- are also ineffective as the basis of definition; private
tionships between public resources and public orga- organizations also rely on resources that are at least
nizations, and finally consider how these public partly public goods, such as knowledge, goodwill,
resources are governed. and reputation. Hence, a meaningful definition of
public resources must distinguish between market
and nonmarket ownership and control: private
Objectives
resources are owned and/or controlled by identifi-
The definition of ‘value’ reflects the idea that all able individuals or groups operating voluntarily in a
organizations—and individuals associated with market setting, while public resources are owned by
organizations—aim to capture a return from their bodies that have the ability to use legally sanctioned
actions, action potential, and perceived advantages coercion to acquire and deploy these resources.
(Pitelis and Teece, 2010). Common goals tend to be How are the costs of public resources assessed?
qualitative and are determined through negotiation, Public organizations may own or control private
balancing, and political processes, while private resources, which are acquired in (strategic) factor
goals of actors participating in the public process markets and may have market costs (buildings, IT
often encompass such concerns as career stability, systems, lobbying skills, and reputation) (Byrd,
career advancement, and mission-based satisfaction. Sambamurthy, and Zmud, 2005; de Figueiredo and
Thus, individuals controlling resource deployment Kim, 2004), but other resources owned or controlled
in public organizations exercise discretion and judg- by public organizations may not be traded privately
ment under conditions in which their efficiency is (e.g., military capabilities, policing services, and
difficult to observe and measure. even library services). Public entities may also own
Public organizations come under scrutiny episodi- or control resources that would command higher
cally and sometimes unpredictably. The research lit- prices if they were publicly available than they do
erature in the field of public administration on ‘goal under public control. Therefore, in many cases, the
ambiguity’ (e.g., Chun and Rainey, 2006; Rainey and cost of a resource cannot be assessed by its private
Bozeman, 2000) shows how problems in specifying analog either because the uniqueness of a public
missions, directives, evaluations, and priorities frus- resource makes its opportunity cost impossible to
trate good governance, productivity, and managerial assess or because of common-pool problems and
efficiency. In practice, public organizations employ a social dilemmas (Agarwal, Croson, and Mahoney,
vast array of metrics (Carter, Klein, and Day, 1992; 2010; McCarter, Mahoney, and Northcraft, 2011;
Cavalluzzo and Ittner, 2004), few of which map Zeng and Chen, 2003).
directly to common measures used to assess entre- Several strategic entrepreneurship concepts and
preneurial value creation and capture in the private frameworks regarding the productivity of resources
sector. Government agencies tend to grow, and they in use offer benchmarks for application to public
often measure their success in terms of budgets and organizations. One such approach characterizes
personnel as well as the re-election of politicians, the resources as valuable, rare, inimitable, and non-
survival of public agencies, and the raising of rev- substitutable (VRIN) (Barney, 1991). The VRIN cri-
enues through taxes by the state. In part because of teria yield key insights about the existence of sources
systematic differences between public and private of potential for deploying resources to their highest
objectives, a common focus in public organizations value use in organizations, and they are analogous in
involves an emphasis on measuring tasks that govern the public domain to the emergence, boundaries,
resource accumulation, stewardship, and deploy- and growth of assets in a public jurisdiction that
ment, rather than the ends of value creation and compete for decision rights with other agencies
capture. seeking to control resources similarly. VRIN criteria
Copyright © 2013 Strategic Management Society Strat. Entrepreneurship J., 7: 70–91 (2013)
DOI: 10.1002/sej
Capabilities and Strategic Entrepreneurship in Public Organizations 75

are relevant in explaining in part, why the public by making its extraction difficult. Public agencies
domain (e.g., the state) exists. The property rights and organizations that contract in the public interest
protection of VRIN resources from being usurped by may capture benefits from resources through these
rival groups-states (North, 1981) and the develop- mechanisms. We submit that these theories are
ment and leveraging of these resources can be a useful for understanding the processes by which
potent source of competitive advantage for nations public organizations construct capabilities to pursue
(Porter, 1990). ostensibly public aims which, in turn, influence and
The sustainability of an organization’s capacity shape the definition of goals in the public domain.
for deploying its bundle of resources is associated We will next elaborate these processes.
with control over valuable resources that are difficult
to transfer across organizations, often because of
their (1) intangibility (Itami and Roehl, 1987), Evolutionary and behavioral dimensions of
capability deployment
(2) inimitability, (2) non-substitutability, and (4)
durability. In the public sector, critical resources can The ways in which capabilities shape an organiza-
have the same character: they are durable assets, tion’s behavior—and particularly its growth—were
which are difficult to transfer between agencies, and the subject of theorizing by Penrose (1959). These
they are unique and, thus, difficult to substitute for ideas, which were conceived primarily with refer-
achieving the agency’s mission. Sustainability crite- ence to large corporations, were subsequently linked
ria are important for explaining the behavior of to ideas in evolutionary economics (developed
public agencies, as bureaucracies often build a primarily by Nelson and Winter [1982]). This theo-
scaffolding of administrative structure on top of retical linkage emphasized that firms may be viewed
resources that may form the original basis of their as heterogeneous bundles of resources and capa-
charter. This bureaucracy is important, as it may bilities that provide services toward a particular
serve as an apparatus that initially supports the sus- objective. We maintain that this conceptualization
tainability of a public organization toward a particu- applies directly to public organizations. The theo-
lar public goal. We define bureaucracy here as a retical linkage has important applications to the
constellation of resources, capabilities, and routines, nature, growth, and boundaries of public organiza-
resting primarily on the input of labor by salaried tion, as well as the public–private nexus, as will be
managers and agents, designed to administer par- explained.
ticular resources within a public organization. Decision making inside organizations is critical to
Theories of strategic entrepreneurship also point the definition of capabilities. Therefore, the applica-
to the mechanisms by which organizations—and the tion of this perspective requires that we examine
individuals within them—claim value. These mecha- adaptive aspirations and expectations, routines,
nisms of appropriability in the private sector information processing, interdependence, organiza-
include: (1) complementarity, (2) property rights, tional coalitions, organizational learning, problemis-
(3) governance, and (4) embeddedness. Complemen- tic search, sequential decision making, subgoal
tarity arises when an organization possesses multiple pursuit, satisficing, uncertainty avoidance, and the
assets that in combination enable the achievement of quasi resolution of intrafirm conflict through the
goals, and it is analogous in the public sector to use of organizational slack (Cyert and March,
resource combinations. Property rights relate to the 1963; Pitelis, 2007; Simon, 1982; Thompson, 1967).
ability of a controlling organization to exclude others In such an environment, organizational decision
from profiting from the deployment of a key makers must be mindful of the scarcity of manage-
resource. In the public sector, proprietary benefits in rial attention available for making these complex
fulfillment of a mission achieved through property assessments and the bounds on human rationality
rights are generally observable. Governance relates that are implied as a consequence of managerial
to the organization’s ability to deploy resources limitations (Bingham et al., 2007; Kahnemann,
better than potential rivals and to extend into the Slovic, and Tversky, 1982; Ocasio, 1997; Simon,
public domain. Finally, embeddedness in the private 1947).
context relates to the ways in which an organization Ideas concerning the organizational capabilities of
builds a cluster of activities and complementary private firms apply a fortiori to public organizations.
resources around a strategically important resource Resources and capabilities are programmatic, often
and, thereby, appropriates returns from this resource have elements of tacit knowledge, and are largely
Copyright © 2013 Strategic Management Society Strat. Entrepreneurship J., 7: 70–91 (2013)
DOI: 10.1002/sej
76 P. G. Klein et al.

embedded in organizational routines (March and Tullock, 1962; Riker and Ordeshook, 1973). The
Simon, 1958). These routines serve several impor- literature on ‘nonmarket strategy’ (de Figueiredo,
tant functions, such as constituting organizational 2009; Henisz and Zelner, 2003) treats campaign
memory (Nelson and Winter, 1982), and are facili- finance, lobbying, litigation, and other political and
tated by common language and coding (Arrow, legal activity as integrated elements of firms’ strate-
1974). Routines can also serve as a truce in interor- gies for value creation and capture (Hillman and
ganizational conflict to maintain internal political Hitt, 1999; Schuler, Rehbein, and Cramer, 2002). We
stability, which enhances the efficacy of organiza- will show how neoclassical and transaction cost eco-
tional slack (Cyert and March, 1963; Nelson and nomics perspectives on public organization differ
Winter, 1982). Public organizations, lacking the from, and complement, these nonmarket approaches
feedback mechanism provided by market signals of by emphasizing resources and capabilities.
profit and loss, are particularly dependent on evolved
organizational capabilities. Also, the absence of a
clear bottom-line tends to engender ‘soft budget con- Neoclassical economics and transaction costs
perspectives to public administration
straints’ (Kornai, 1986), thereby facilitating subgoal
pursuit (Williamson, 1975). Neoclassical economics tends to explain public
Penrose’s (1959) evolutionary theory of firm organization in terms of market failure and of the
growth draws on the idea that specialization, restoration of allocative efficiency as defined by the
learning-by-doing, and intrafirm knowledge creation first fundamental theorem of welfare economics
lead to an excess capacity of resources. Entrepre- (Arrow, 1970). Early treatments of this topic focused
neurial managers in pursuit of profit aim to leverage on defense, the provision of justice, and public
these resources to capture value. Thus, entrepreneur- works to justify the State (Mueller, 2003). This
ial innovation induces slack, which motivates further approach has since developed to include ‘imperfect’
innovation. The absence of a direct profit motive in market structures (such as monopoly and oligopoly)
public organizations breaks this positive loop and other types of (positive and negative) externali-
because slack need not engender appropriable inno- ties. Coase’s (1937, 1960) logic focused on the
vation. Instead, it is more likely to be used for the ‘internalization of externalities,’ explaining hierar-
purpose of attenuating intraorganizational conflict chical organization, both private and public, as an
(Cyert and March, 1963). The growth of public orga- adaptive response to high transaction costs for some
nization in this context serves uncertainty avoidance market exchanges.
more than risk taking. Moreover, given the difficulty Coase (1964: 195) states that ‘we find a category
in relating the objectives of public entities to some ‘market failure’ but no category ‘government
notion of the public interest, public sector innovation failure.’ Until we realize that we are choosing
may destroy, not create, social value. Public entre- between social arrangements, which are all more or
preneurship may be unproductive and even destruc- less failures, we are not likely to make much
tive, rather than productive. While these possibilities headway.’ Demsetz (1969: 1) notes that ‘the view
also apply to private entrepreneurship (Baumol, that now pervades much public policy economics
1990), the incentive to pursue unproductive or value implicitly presents the relevant choice as between an
destructive activities is likely to be higher in the case ideal norm and an existing ‘imperfect’ institutional
of public entrepreneurship, precisely because of the arrangement. This nirvana approach differs consid-
lack of the profit motive. erably from a comparative institution approach in
which the relevant choice is between alternative real
institutional arrangements.’ Williamson (1996: 210)
ESTABLISHED PERSPECTIVES adds that ‘[organizational] ideals are operationally
ON PUBLIC RESOURCE irrelevant. Within the feasible subset, the relevant
ADMINISTRATION test is whether an alternative can be described that
can be implemented with expected net gains. This is
Economists since Adam Smith (1776) have written the remediableness criterion.’
about the effects of state action on business activity, Following similar logic and building on
but the application of strategic entrepreneurship and Williamson (1996), the current article maintains
management theories to nonmarket organizations that the public sector is also beset with uncer-
is only an emerging development (Buchanan and tainty, bounded rationality, asset specificity, and
Copyright © 2013 Strategic Management Society Strat. Entrepreneurship J., 7: 70–91 (2013)
DOI: 10.1002/sej
Capabilities and Strategic Entrepreneurship in Public Organizations 77

opportunism, which can provide a transaction transactions require probity, and specific configura-
(organizational) cost explanation of government tions of asset specificity, uncertainty, and probity
failure that complements public choice approaches determine the efficient choice of governance structure
(Datta-Chaudhuri, 1990; Henisz and Zelner, 2005; among market, private hierarchy or hybrid, and gov-
Mueller, 2003; Wolf, 1979). Williamson’s (1975) ernment (Williamson, 1999). Just as asset specificity
focus on limits to vertical integration in the private can give rise to a ‘hold-up’ problem, which is miti-
sector concerning internal procurement (logrolling), gated by hierarchical governance, transactions
internal expansion, and program persistence biases involving public actors can give rise to ‘probity
applies more strongly in the government sector hazards,’which are best mitigated within the structure
(Mueller, 2003). Thus, transaction costs theory is of the typical public bureaucracy (fixed rules and
useful in explicating market, public, and institutional procedures, low-powered incentives, job security,
failures, allowing a comparative assessment of imper- and an organizational culture promoting probity).5
fect alternatives rather than an unnatural focus on an However, Moe (1995) points out key differences
ideal public outcome (Eggertsson, 1990; Ostrom, between market and political organization that
1990). It predicts the boundaries of market, firm, and render the application of transaction costs theory to
public organization in terms of relative transaction politics problematic. Moe’s analysis (1995) builds
costs and, thus, explains endogenously why all pro- on the concepts of ‘political uncertainty’ and ‘politi-
duction is not organized through one big firm or by the cal compromise.’ Political uncertainty suggests that
state as a central planner (North, 1990). Just as trans- the government succeeds in ‘usurping the property
action cost and resource-based explanations are rights of others’ thereby rendering economic choices
complementary for better understanding the perfor- as different from those in the market. Under political
mance of private organizations (Villalonga and uncertainty:
McGahan, 2005), they are also complementary
for better understanding the performance of public ‘[Decision makers] would be concerned with more
organizations. than simply making efficient choices about the use
Political science research has begun to incorporate and disposition of their property. They would also be
the transaction cost economics concepts of bounded concerned with taking action to protect their rights
rationality, asset specificity, bilateral dependency, from usurpation—and with making current choices
about their property that recognize and adjust for the
and the fundamental transformation between market
possibility that other actors might seize their rights to
and hierarchical governance (Williamson, 1985) into the property in the future.’ (Moe, 1995: 123)
its analysis of political institutions and political
actions (see, e.g., Alt et al., 1999; Hall and Taylor, This reasoning does not simply imply a different
1996). Williamson (1999) submits that government setting in which transactions take place, but is more
and private action can be regarded as alternative fundamental: it is ‘uncertainty about the very basis
modes of governance—virtually everything done by of all transactions’ (Moe, 1995: 124). This political
government could, in principle, be done, or has his- uncertainty requires considerations of the specific
torically been done, by private participants—and, costs of political transactions. In this context, politi-
thus, transaction cost economics can shed light on cal compromise refers to the larger setting in which
efficient governance modes for various transactions. a transaction takes place. Any contract is the result of
For instance, exchanges in the public sphere include a bargaining process among participants making a
number of compromises to reach a mutually satisfy-
procurement transactions that are ‘akin to those of
ing solution. In politics, ‘those who are able to exer-
make-or-buy’ (Williamson, 1999: 319) and regula- cise public authority can impose their preferred
tory transactions that are ‘often beset with asset outcomes on everyone else’ (Moe, 1995: 126).
specificity’ (Williamson, 1999: 320), which make These theories illuminate fundamental issues on
transaction cost reasoning applicable. the rationale for public provision of goods and ser-
Williamson (1999) introduces a new key attribute vices, agency and governance costs associated with
in addition to asset specificity, uncertainty, and fre- alternative modes of provision, and the effect of
quency for the analysis of public transactions:
probity. Probity refers to the ‘loyalty and rectitude
5
with which certain public transactions are to be Williamson (1999) notes that probity hazards are high for
foreign affairs, tax collections, military activities, and prisons.
discharged’ (Ruiter, 2005: 292). As government pur- We later elaborate on probity hazards in our examples on mili-
ports to embody the public’s authority, sovereign tary activities and prisons.

Copyright © 2013 Strategic Management Society Strat. Entrepreneurship J., 7: 70–91 (2013)
DOI: 10.1002/sej
78 P. G. Klein et al.

probity on governance. Nonetheless, they shed little public choice approach presented state participants
insight on the static and dynamic performance as omniscient, benevolent social planners. On the
effects of organizational form. In particular, extant other hand, the Chicago School’s critique empha-
approaches take the content of public policy as a sized that this view of public organization did not
given and examine alternate organizational and gov- account for the private incentives of public agents.
ernance modes for achieving the desired policy. However, the Chicago School emphasis had its own
However, policy goals are often endogenous to the limitations (Ostrom, 1990). In particular, Eggertsson
resources and capabilities of public and private (1990) submits that Demsetz (1969) held an overly
organizations involved in policy. Like private orga- optimistic view of how property rights would
nizations, public agencies attempt to achieve and develop to internalize externalities when the gains of
sustain some sort of competitive advantage. How do internalization exceed the costs. Characteristic of
public agencies grow and diversify over time? How this optimistic view, the formulation of decision
do routines and capabilities emerge and evolve and making with regard to property rights is solely in
how do they affect actions and outcomes? To address terms of private benefits and private costs, neither of
these questions, we consider an evolutionary per- which deals with free riding problems that plague
spective on organizations. group decision making (Olson, 1965; Ostrom,
1990) nor attempts to model political processes
(Eggertsson, 1990; North 1990), which almost
The evolution of public sector resources surely influence how resources and capabilities
and capabilities
evolve.
The transaction cost framework in its early stages In short, as applied to political action, neoclas-
was comparatively static and, thus, less applicable sical economics’ attempts to explain the ‘prices’
to the growth and evolution of institutions. Later and quantities of nonmarket transactions, agency-
developments by North (1981, 1990) adopted an theoretic approaches focus on the incentives given to
historical, evolutionary perspective on economic public bureaucrats, and transaction costs theory con-
change and innovations. Here, North (1990) siders the make-or-buy decision and the efficient
explained the state in terms of the pursuit by princi- governance structures for various transactions.
pals of increased wealth (to tax) though increased However, none of these approaches fully address
efficiency and reduced transaction costs. North the political equivalent of sustained competitive
(1990) noted, however, that the pursuit of systemic advantage—why do some government bodies,
transaction cost reductions may be hindered by prin- bureaus, and agencies persist, expand, and diversify
cipals’ need to tax emerging wealth. This objective while others are dismantled, absorbed by other agen-
can lead to induced favors (transfers of property cies, or radically restructured?
rights) to organized groups (such as monopolies),
which North (1990) maintained would more easily
be taxed. Therefore, the principals’ interests may A SIMPLE MODEL OF CAPABILITIES-
differ from the interests of the larger society, which BASED PUBLIC ENTREPRENEURSHIP
could produce systematic and systemic inefficien-
cies. Moreover, the actions of the principals are con- Consider a simple model inspired by Arrow (1951)
strained by competition from other potential in which a public organization seeks to meet the
principals and rival states. needs of three citizens. Suppose that these three citi-
A focus on capabilities and governance is comple- zens commonly share interests in certain public
mentary to theories derived from North’s (1990) goods such as, for example, policing services, and
informational and transaction cost perspectives. that the public organization (akin to a local govern-
Comparative institutional analysis—not only the ment) incurs certain costs to provide these services.
choice between markets, hierarchies, and hybrids This public organization is staffed by a single
(Williamson, 1996), but also the choice among bureaucrat who develops skills over time in the effi-
public policies—is informed by consideration of cient administration of the organization’s resources.
the capabilities created, deployed, governed, and The bureaucrat may act ‘entrepreneurially’ by lever-
managed under varying institutional arrangements. aging these skills to pursue new objectives, private or
On the one hand, the welfare economics challenged public. The three citizens take turns acting as mayor
by Coase (1960, 1964), Demsetz (1969), and the to govern this public agency.
Copyright © 2013 Strategic Management Society Strat. Entrepreneurship J., 7: 70–91 (2013)
DOI: 10.1002/sej
Capabilities and Strategic Entrepreneurship in Public Organizations 79

Over time, the interests of the four actors in this used for transportation. Therefore, if the mayor
scenario evolve. Suppose that the bureaucrat, elects to invest in transportation, excessive policing
through learning and experience, can execute polic- may be avoided if the mayor can direct the bureau-
ing duties more efficiently. All else equal, the crat to devote excess capacity from policing capa-
bureaucrat can either appropriate this excess capac- bilities into transportation, but this comes at the cost
ity personally through slack or use it with probity to of additional training and other incentive costs that
enhance policing activities. Given this choice, a self- raise the community’s tax bill. Another important
interested bureaucrat weighs the costs and benefits asymmetry arises in that an election to pursue each
of each option. In this simple model, imagine that the type of goal—i.e., education, health care, transpor-
bureaucrat will choose to maximize personal ben- tation, or policing—in a particular period leads to the
efits through private appropriation, subject to the emergence of capabilities that subsequently lower
cost of appropriation not becoming prohibitive (e.g., the costs and improve the effectiveness of subse-
from an increased threat of job loss). Or, imagine quent investments in the future—but in ways that are
that the benefit from the alternative of deploying the not full tractable or measurable ex ante.
capacity broadly to create new value in the public What kinds of outcomes can arise in this simple
interest increases (e.g., from the increased fame that model? The logic in Arrow (1951) emphasizes that a
accompanies a broader span of control). Moreover, benevolent social planner would recognize the value
imagine that these costs and benefits are balanced in of the balanced development of capabilities in all
a base case scenario so that the bureaucrat is indif- four types of public goods over time and would
ferent between taking the excess capacity in slack similarly seek to constrain the bureaucrat from both
and enhanced policing. slack and overprovision to achieve an ‘optimal’ level
By contrast, the citizens are not indifferent. of policing. Yet even in the simple situation specified
Assume citizens prefer some satisfactory level of here, such an outcome is impossible to obtain pro-
policing. If the bureaucrat elects to police as inten- grammatically. As each individual actor in the situ-
sively as the new capabilities allow, the citizens are ation pursues his/her private aims, which may
policed too much. Citizen preferences instead run include benefits such as fame and satisfaction from
toward education, health care, and transportation serving as mayor, public goods may emerge and
above the satisfactory level of policing. Specifically, develop, but these public goods are an artifact of the
the three citizens in this community share prefer- alignment of private action (Ostrom, 1990). As we
ences in pairs for alternative investments for their tax note later, the achievement of such alignment can
dollars. Assume Citizens A and B have an interest in build over time as public resources and capabilities
public education; Citizens B and C have an interest develop in education, health care, and transportation.
in public health care; and Citizens C and A have an It is the intertemporal relationships that arise from
interest in public transportation. Arrow’s (1951) the dynamic evolution of capabilities that create an
social choice model demonstrates that, with three or institutionally stable rudder on the definition of aims
more conflicting sets of interests in a public setting and, thus, on resource deployment.
such as the one constructed here, no clearly defined Consider the simple situation of the three citizens
and stable conceptualization of the public interest and bureaucrat. Whoever happens to be mayor when
can be identified. In other words, the definition of the the excess capacity in policing arises—suppose
public good—and the public interest—is inherently Citizen A—must make decisions about how tax
an unstable and evolving construct. dollars are spent and particularly on how to con-
For simplicity, assume the costs of developing straint the bureaucrat from slack or excessive
resources in each area are initially the same, i.e., policing. Imagine that, at this early stage of invest-
education costs the same as health care, which costs ment, the bureaucrat’s span of control is limited
the same as transportation. And suppose that some by a modest accumulation of excess policing capac-
extra costs are borne equally by each citizen. Fur- ity and, thus, the mayor elects to develop a new
thermore, suppose that the citizens are constrained in resource, not constraining the bureaucrat. Since the
each period by their budgets so that investment in mayor, Citizen A, prefers education and transporta-
only one new type of public good is affordable in tion to health care, certainly one of these two alter-
each period. One important asymmetry that arises natives dominates. But which one? A rational mayor
across the various possible areas of investment is that may envision that, in the next period, Citizen B, who
some of the bureaucrat’s excess capacity may be shares an interest in education, will become mayor.
Copyright © 2013 Strategic Management Society Strat. Entrepreneurship J., 7: 70–91 (2013)
DOI: 10.1002/sej
80 P. G. Klein et al.

Alignment Private capture of Destruction of value


of minority Low nonoptimized through the creation
private public value of public ‘bads’
interests
with the
public
interest Bureaucratic capture of Public capture of
High nonoptimized public goods
public value

Low High

Efficiency of public
organizations in capability deployment

Figure 2. Potential outcomes in the deployment of public capabilities

Thus, to achieve benefits of multi-period scale in support investment at all and that too much policing
investment, the mayor may elect education on the by the bureaucrat initially ensues. As bureaucratic
anticipation that B will also choose education. excess capacity develops, the community may come
Under the scenario in which public goods accu- to value the redeployment of bureaucratic capacity
mulate, investments in education may occur over from policing to transportation despite not attaining
multiple periods, thus leading to an imbalanced much direct benefit from transportation. This
emphasis on education over health care and trans- outcome reflects the idea that multi-period econo-
portation and the accumulating risk that the bureau- mies of scale arise but are not too large such that at
crat seeks to act with either slack or overprovision in some point the value of leveraging the accumulated
policing. This situation may be rectified when capabilities to produce ends that are valued margin-
Citizen C becomes mayor. If efficiency in policing ally lower is too small to justify.
has not made the bureaucrat’s span of control too Figure 2 illustrates some of the possible out-
great and if the accumulated capabilities of the com- comes in this kind of simple model. The horizontal
munity for education are not too compelling, then dimension represents the degree to which the public
Citizen C as mayor may choose to levy taxes in the organization can efficiently deploy accumulated
interests of either health care or transportation, thus capabilities either by expanding existing activities
setting in motion a round-robin that will eventually or by launching new activities. The vertical dimen-
lead to the creation of a full array of public goods sion expresses the extent to which the preferences of
and, furthermore, provide an outlet for the bureau- the public decision maker (in our example, the
crat’s excess capacity in transportation. mayor) align with the preferences of the rest of the
Yet a perverse situation is also possible. To disci- community.6
pline the bureaucrat, Citizen C as mayor may elect to Consider a scenario in which the public organi-
invest in transportation. If the potential for bureau- zation’s capabilities for creating value are high and
cratic slack and/or overprovision in policing is high, the interests of citizens in the minority (in the earlier
then excessive investments in transportation may example, initially Citizens B and C) are not too far
occur as the community seeks to keep the bureaucrat out of alignment with those in power (Citizen A).
occupied. A situation may evolve in which subse- In this case, depicted in the lower-right cell of
quent investments in health care are crowded out by Figure 2, the accumulation of excess capacity and
the emergence of capabilities in policing and trans-
portation. 6
We acknowledge, however, in line with the Arrow (1951)
Alternatively, imagine that the costs of high taxes paradox, that interests will not be fully aligned in more complex
to the citizenry are too great in the first period to (real-world) scenarios.

Copyright © 2013 Strategic Management Society Strat. Entrepreneurship J., 7: 70–91 (2013)
DOI: 10.1002/sej
Capabilities and Strategic Entrepreneurship in Public Organizations 81

the development of new capabilities results in the excess capacity in policing does. Thus, the commu-
production of public goods (in our example, this nity’s capability profile develops toward a situation
occurs when the mayors drive investments in edu- of inadequate provision of education and health care
cation and transportation and the efficiency of the and increasing slack and/or excess policing by the
bureaucrat in the provision of policing is nearly bureaucrat, interrupted only by periodic redeploy-
optimal, so that neither much slack nor overprovi- ments into transportation.
sion occurs).7 The final scenario is represented in the upper-right
Now consider a second scenario: one in which the cell of Figure 2. Here, the round-robin of invest-
bureaucrat’s excess capacity cannot be easily or cost ments is not supported because the taxes required are
effectively deployed into some new value-creating too high. The efficiency of the bureaucrat at policing
activity (such as transportation). This contingency is leads to deeper and more intensive policing over
represented by the lower-left cell of Figure 2. Here, time even as these investments occur. The excess
the bureaucrat prefers not to create new public goods, capacity that arises per se leads to the creation of
but to exploit his/her excess capacity by slacking off a public ‘bad’—the bureaucratic deployment of
or policing excessively. As long as the cost of value policing capabilities becomes excessive. This out-
creation to each citizen is sufficiently low (i.e., taxes come can arise independently of the mechanisms of
are not too high), Mayor A will choose an investment ‘private’ or ‘regulatory’ capture by the mayor, in the
in education. The problem under this scenario—and sense that it is excess capacity alone in policing
the condition that leads to underinvestment in a capabilities that leads to the pursuit of objectives that
public good such as education (see, e.g., Ruggiero, are misaligned with the public interest. The commu-
Duncombe, and Miner, 2004)—is that bureaucratic nity is vulnerable to these ‘bads’ in part because of
inefficiency in the administration of education and the fracturing of value creation across the citizenry
bureaucratic efficiency in policing may lead to less in the pursuit of alternative public activities.
investment in education and more investment in While we do not offer a fully specified dynamic
transportation than would occur if the bureaucratic model, this framework does suggest possible paths
administrator did not accumulate excess capacity. for movement from one cell in Figure 2 to another.
A third scenario is represented in the upper-left For example, consider an economy in the lower-right
cell of Figure 2. Here, bureaucratic excess capacity cell, in which the public agency is using its accumu-
does not accumulate intensively, but the preferences lated capabilities to produce goods and services
of the community are not well aligned. For instance, desired by the entire community. As the bureaucrat’s
imagine that Citizen A prefers only education, capabilities continue to grow, new excess capacity is
Citizen B prefers health care, and Citizen C prefers created, beyond the level needed to satisfy commu-
transportation. Thus, as is described in the vertical nity preferences for public goods. Eventually, either
dimension of Figure 2, minorities’ interests are out the bureaucrat continues producing the same outputs
of alignment with those of the mayor. In this situa- but consumes additional slack (Niskanen, 1971)—
tion, the mayor makes an investment that reflects moving the outcome from the bottom-right cell to
his/her own preference. All citizens are required the bottom-left cell—or the bureaucrat deploys the
to pay taxes to support this idiosyncratic choice, new capabilities to producing ‘too much’ policing or
despite the lack of alignment. Similarly, in the next transportation or to producing new outputs that are
period, when Citizen B is mayor, the same mecha- not desired by the community (moving from the
nism compels investment in health care, and so on. bottom-right cell to the top-right cell). Only when
Each mayor acts to maximize his/her own private the community supports well-balanced investments
benefit and the bureaucrat engages in an inefficient in education, health care, and transportation over
level of policing in each period except when Citizen time do capabilities in each of these areas emerge to
C as mayor elects transportation. Multi-period provide an institutional rudder that preserves align-
economies of scale in education, health care, and ment and balance of investments in public goods.
transportation do not accumulate, while multi-period We next provide several examples of these kinds
of movements and submit that they are common
7
In the property rights research literature, an exemplar for the and represent an important challenge to public orga-
lower-right cell of Figure 2 is the success story in public entre- nizations. This is the case even if we assume away
preneurship of public-private partnerships for ground water
management in some areas of California in the 1960s (Ostrom, collusive behavior, regulatory capture, embedded
1990). power structures, and (other forms of) corruption.
Copyright © 2013 Strategic Management Society Strat. Entrepreneurship J., 7: 70–91 (2013)
DOI: 10.1002/sej
82 P. G. Klein et al.

EXAMPLES AND IMPLICATIONS research literature suggests that Niskanen (1971)


inefficiency is likely in representative government
The following examples illustrate the implications of and has been corroborated in the provision of fire
the model, and the capabilities lens more generally, services (Ahlbrandt, 1973; Hayes, Razzolini, and
for understanding the entrepreneurial challenges that Ross, 1998; Kristensen, 1983).
can arise through the tandem deployment of both If the interests of private citizens are not highly
public and private resources. aligned, then a major risk is the excessive provision
of what would otherwise be a desirable public
service, such as policing. One example comes from
The growth of public organizations
Benson (2008), who provides strong and growing
Bureaucratic growth has been examined extensively evidence that drug enforcement activities in the
in the political science, public choice, and public United States are excessive, suggesting a public bad
administration literatures (Downs, 1966; Meyer, (or a bad public good). Such overprovision may be
Stevenson, and Webster, 1985; Peacock and visible not only as an excessive quantity of an exist-
Wiseman, 1961), with growth attributed to a variety ing public good (Benson, 2008), but also as a new
of causes such as superior efficiency, coercive power, version of the existing good that appears to the
pervasive rent seeking, personnel dynamics, and public to be new and valuable. An example of
other factors. Our approach emphasizes a Penrosean the latter is found in Higgs’ (1987) analysis of the
model of organizational growth. growth of government in the U.S. in the twentieth
Several versions of capability development and century. Higgs (1987) noted that the expanded role
organizational expansion are consistent with our taken on by the state during the New Deal period
developed theory. In some cases, Penrosean learn- remained largely in place once the crisis passed,
ing, independent of activities outside the public leading to a ‘ratchet effect’ in which government
agency, may be enough to generate new capabilities. agencies expand to exploit perceived short-term
In other cases, the public agency’s capabilities may opportunities, but fail to retreat once circumstances
coevolve with the capabilities of other public or change. Higgs (1987) suggests that government offi-
private actors (Klein et al., 2010). Consider, for cials (regulators, courts, and elected officials), as
example, the U.S. government’s rules for allocating well as private agents (such as business executives,
radio frequencies (Coase, 1959; Faulhaber and farmers, and labor unions) developed capabilities in
Farber, 2003). The capabilities for defining property economic and social planning during crisis periods
rights in spectrum, allocating these rights, and gov- and that, due to indivisibilities and high transaction
erning their transfer and exchange did not exist until costs, tend to possess excess capacity in periods
private entrepreneurs had developed broadcasting between crises. To leverage this capacity, they
and receiving capabilities. The development of an looked for ways to keep these ‘temporary’ measures
effective legal and regulatory system, famously in place. Indeed, many New Deal agencies were
described by Coase (1959) in anticipation of the thinly disguised versions of World War I agencies
‘Coase Theorem,’ in turn, encouraged equipment that had remained dormant throughout the 1920s—
manufacturers, broadcasters, and other private actors the War Industries Board became the National
to invest in improving radio technology and provid- Recovery Administration, the War Finance Corpora-
ing more and better content. Private improvements tion became the Reconstruction Finance Corpora-
were accompanied by advances in the technical, tion, the War Labor Board became the National
monitoring, measurement, and incentive-assessment Labor Relations Board, and so on.8 In many cases the
capabilities of public authorities dedicated to the charters for the New Deal agencies were mostly
industry. copied verbatim from World War I predecessors.
In general, how will a public organization’s new Higgs’ (1987) ratchet effect illustrates that excess
capabilities be further leveraged? As discussed
earlier, if the preferences of private actors are highly 8
Historian Walter Leuchtenburg (1959: 41) states that ‘when in
aligned, then the greatest risk of appropriation may 1933 a new government came to power in the midst of a major
be bureaucratic slack (i.e., Niskanen inefficiency, crisis, it would know no way to mobilize the country save by
represented in the lower-left cell of Figure 2). This invoking the experience of World War I . . . As a result, the early
New Deal would draw [on the men] who had gained their first
risk arises especially because of escalating public governmental experience in wartime Washington and cherished
commitment to the service. The public choice their memory of it through the 1920s.’

Copyright © 2013 Strategic Management Society Strat. Entrepreneurship J., 7: 70–91 (2013)
DOI: 10.1002/sej
Capabilities and Strategic Entrepreneurship in Public Organizations 83

capacity in organizational capabilities isn’t neces- 2005; Baum and McGahan, 2011; Cabral, Lazzarini,
sary leveraged as soon as it is created, leading to and Azevedo, 2010). Private actors may be able to
smooth, continuous organizational growth, but may lower the costs of deployment initially, but subse-
remain dormant until the right economic, legal, or quently, resources may not be preserved or devel-
political circumstances arise, leading to sudden, oped in the public interest. Therefore, there may be a
discontinuous jumps in organizational size or scope conflict between preserving a resource’s value and
(Bellante and Porter, 1998). As the ratcheting deploying the resource efficiently in the short run.
process developed, the system became vulnerable to For example, in some privately run public hospitals,
private capture by various constituents to govern- highly specialized equipment has been run down in
ment (represented in the upper-left cell of Figure 2). the interest of minimizing expenses while maximiz-
ing the numbers of patients served (Porter and Teis-
berg, 2006). In some prisons and militaries,
Privatization and quasi privatization
investment in educational programs for inmates and
Another insight from our approach is that privatiza- soldiers has been significantly curtailed by private
tion and quasi privatization often involve not simply operators (although in others, these investments have
a change in ownership and governance, in which a been expanded) (Palumbo 1986; Singer 2003).
given set of activities formerly performed by public These examples provide rich and detailed opportu-
agencies are moved into the private sector, but also a nities for further research to understand how the
change in the activities in question. Thus, move- marginal benefits of publicly created capabilities
ments among the four cells in our model often differ between private and public stewards.
follow, or coincide with, changes in the ownership Stewardship of capabilities essential to the public
and governance status of the organizations perform- interest by private organizations has another key
ing those activities. facet: over time, as they develop under the gover-
Theories of regulatory capture have dealt exten- nance and control of private organizations, these
sively with the hazards and opportunities in the organizations may take on decisions that go beyond
private administration of public resources (Spulber, their governance mandate. For example, private
1989; Stigler, 1971). Yet, as our developed theory military organizations that develop unique capabili-
illustrates, the transfer of resources for the public ties for accomplishing particular operations may be
benefit is only one example of the ways in which so central to the effectiveness of sovereign war
private and public participants interact. Opportuni- operations that they may unduly influence the mili-
ties for innovation through public-private partner- tary agenda (Baum and McGahan, 2011). The result
ships, privatization, and public administration must may be the public ‘bads’ depicted in the upper-right
be carefully assessed. Consider, for example, the cell of Figure 2. Involvement in or escalation of mili-
(temporary) U.S. public ownership of General tary conflict is not in line with public preferences,
Motors. What can the government accomplish in the not because the private military organization has
stewardship of GM’s resources that could not be ‘captured’ the Defense Department, but because
accomplished when the firm was privately owned after one engagement ends, the private military
and managed? The deepest opportunities may reside company is left with excess capacity in war making
in reconfigurations of capabilities that could not be and the Defense Department is unable to redirect
pursued by a private corporation but that reflect the those capabilities toward alternative, value-creating
long-term public interest and that create new private ends. This evolution of the military-industrial
opportunity—such as the construction of a national complex is troublesome because private military
high-speed train system or the advance of new fuel organizations, such as Blackwater (renamed Xe in
efficiency standards on private vehicles. When the 2009, then again renamed as Academi in 2012) and
private sector develops capabilities that are relevant, Aegis Defense Services, profit from conflict and,
necessary, and even urgently required to satisfy the thus, are unlikely to pursue peace as a principal goal
public interest, then the hazards of interplay between even when a peaceful resolution serves the interests
public and private interests are activated. of the contracting sovereign authorities (Baum and
As another example, consider the placement of McGahan, 2011; Scahill, 2007).
publicly owned resources such as hospitals, prisons, Insights from a capabilities approach focus atten-
and military capability into the hands of private tion on the implications of governance, productivity,
agents for stewardship and deployment (Avant, and managerial practice for goal formation. Instead
Copyright © 2013 Strategic Management Society Strat. Entrepreneurship J., 7: 70–91 (2013)
DOI: 10.1002/sej
84 P. G. Klein et al.

of taking goals as fixed, Penrosean logic suggests This problem also appears in the case of prison
that excess capacity in resources leads to the pursuit privatization, which poses particular ethical, legal,
of opportunities that may not have been conceived and empirical challenges (Shichor, 1995). While
when the resources were initially deployed. A capa- some research (e.g., Segal and Moore, 2002) sug-
bilities approach emphasizes the endogeneity of gests that competitive pressures will lead to effi-
value and of conceptualizations of goals to the ways ciency in the operation of private prisons such as
in which resources are assembled. U.S. President Corrections Corporation of America (CCA) and the
Dwight Eisenhower warned of this problem in GEO Group, Inc., other research maintains that
his famous January 1961 speech on the military- competition for prison beds occurs in a constrained
industrial complex. Consider, for example, that we market that parallels the contracting problems that
have witnessed in the United States in the past have been identified in the defense industry (Camp
quarter century a dramatic increase in private sector and Gaes, 2000). Empirical results concerning the
outsourcing of many of the functions historically efficiency of private prisons are mixed, with some
performed by the military (Scahill, 2007). In a research studies finding cost savings (e.g., Segal
Penrosean process, new goals became enabled by and Moore, 2002) and others providing evidence
private subcontracting of sovereign functions (Baum against the claim that private prisons reduce costs
and McGahan, 2011). This may be a sophisticated— (e.g., Nelson, 1999). Yet others suggest improve-
and tragic—instance of private capture of nonopti- ments in the efficacy of prisons achievable through
mized private value (represented in the upper-left privatization (Cabral et al., 2010), Thus, in this
cell in Figure 2) and, perhaps, even an instance of the context, basic questions about productivity, quality,
destruction of public value, as represented in the and operational efficiencies in management are
upper-right cell. Certainly further research on this entangled with issues of better governance. These
essential question is warranted. are not simply situations of regulatory capture or
As discussed earlier, the private-military example slack, though each of these well-documented
is particularly complex, in part because of ambiguity conditions may be present. In the case of prison
in balancing the interests of minority citizens in privatization, private subcontractors must also
identifying public goals, especially in the face of deploy resources in response to complex conflicting
intense defensive claims by majority citizens and the signals about the purposes of their activities in an
enabling capabilities of private entities that stand ambiguous field where goals are negotiated and
ready for combat (Baum and McGahan, 2011). This malleable.
tension has led private military corporations to Research on the private management of pri-
challenge their responsibilities given the ambigui- sons from the fields of strategic entrepreneurship
ties about applicable institutions of governance. For and management also illustrates how a focus on
example, some private military companies have resources and capabilities can shed light on the goals
resisted attempts to subject their personnel to the that organizations pursue in the public interest. Such
Pentagon’s Uniform Code of Military Conduct, clarity is essential for reducing public exposure to
insisting that such personnel are civilians, while the destruction of value through excessive service
simultaneously claiming immunity from civilian liti- provision (i.e., ‘public bads’ as represented in the
gation in the United States under the argument that upper-right cell of Figure 2).9 One emerging area of
private military contractors are part of the U.S. Total such research deals with the quality of public
Force (Scahill, 2007). The strategic entrepreneurship outputs. For example, some research studies find that
and management literature that builds on a more
complete organizational economics approach (Baum 9
Analogous to Eisenhower’s warning of the ‘military industrial
and McGahan, 2011; Mahoney, 2005; Williamson, complex,’ in which defense contractors push for increased
military spending, we now appear to be witnessing a ‘prison
1999) deals more effectively with mitigating grave corporate complex’ in which a set of bureaucratic, political,
moral hazard problems than do classical theories of and vested economic interests encourage increased expendi-
governance based primarily on agency theory. These tures on imprisonment. Private prisons such as Geo and CCA
use lobbying, direct campaign contributions, and networking to
issues are deeply entwined in the mechanisms we encourage tough-on-crime legislation to ensure an increased
identify in our model: rather than regulatory capture, supply of prisoners (particularly for nonviolent drug offenders).
the private organizations seek clarity about the Inmate populations have increased tenfold, from less than
200,000 in 1971 to more than 2.3 million in 2008. Here is a
public interest and the boundaries of their roles and further example of a movement from the lower right-cell to the
responsibilities in fulfilling it. upper right-cell in Figure 2.

Copyright © 2013 Strategic Management Society Strat. Entrepreneurship J., 7: 70–91 (2013)
DOI: 10.1002/sej
Capabilities and Strategic Entrepreneurship in Public Organizations 85

the quality of prisons (as measured by recidivism Market co-creation as a means and outcome of
rates) may initially be improved under private gov- efficient interest alignment
ernance (e.g., Cabral et al., 2010), corresponding to
the bottom-right cell of Figure 2. However, there are The stronger possibility for unproductive and even
sound economic reasons to anticipate that there will destructive public entrepreneurship raises the specter
be pressures on private prison managers for quality of public sector and institutional failures and, thus,
shading to reduce costs (Hart et al., 1997; Kivleniece leads to the question of how to find a resolution to
and Quelin, 2012), which would destroy public value this problem. Here we submit that the concept of
as in the upper-right cell. Long-term investments by ‘market co-creation’ can help achieve this objective.
privately governed prisons to perform on dimensions Olson (2000) employed the concept of market exten-
such as education, drug reformation, and health care sion to explain how states can raise more revenues,
services may be greatly curtailed (Bedard and Frech, not only by minimizing transaction costs and attenu-
2009) by expressing balanced public objectives in ating conflict, but also by creating and enhancing
contracts that cede responsibility to private organi- markets. The emphasis on market extension-derived
zations. When such complex objectives cannot be value creation extended North’s (1990) focus on
managed, then privatization may simply be too risky transaction cost minimization and suggests that
to tolerate. A recent meta-analysis comparing pri- public organizations can create a platform for private
vately managed and publicly managed prisons indi- entrepreneurship through the creation of facilitating
cates that cost savings for private prisons are institutions. Casson (2005) submits that private
minimal and that the quality of these prisons (such as entrepreneurs and firms also can create markets.
greater skill training and fewer inmate grievances) Pitelis and Teece (2010) extend this idea by positing
was slightly better in publicly managed prisons that contributions to the creation of new markets by
(Lundahl et al., 2009).10 Further investigation into private entrepreneurs may be a key prerequisite
such critical issues cannot occur without a theoreti- for the capture of value by these entrepreneurs in
cally robust perspective that accounts for variation in markets ex post. Private organization helps achieve
the goals of transactions and in the conditions of this entrepreneurial co-creation, in tandem with
governance—which, we maintain, a capabilities customers, suppliers, and other stakeholders par-
approach can provide. ticipating in this value-creation process, including
When capabilities that are essential to the public public organizations and the state. Therefore, the
interest are controlled by private individuals, agents, interplay between public and private organizations in
or organizations, the essence of the public interest market co-creation suggests that public organiza-
may not be pursued as a consummate goal. By fol- tions and the state can strategically enhance value
lowing the rules in a perfunctory way, rather than (co-) creation. This focus extends and helps opera-
with probity (i.e., with intensity and in the spirit of tionalize Ostrom’s (1990) emphasis on institutional
the rules), actors may leverage capabilities to direct and organizational complementarities (McDermott,
organizations inefficiently and in ways that may or Corredoira, and Kruse, 2009; Rangan, Samii, and
may not foster the public interest. Activism may be Van Wassenhove, 2006).
required for alignment of public and private goals Public entrepreneurs possess and/or develop dif-
(Kivleniece and Quelin, 2012). ferential capabilities in legitimacy and institutional
change (e.g., by passing new laws and regulations),
which can help create or co-create markets. Exam-
10
Even more troublesome was the recent ‘kids for cash’ ples include legislation by the European Commis-
scandal, which unfolded in 2008 over judicial kickbacks at the sion (Convery and Redmond, 2007; Knoll and
court of common pleas in Wilkes-Barre, Pennsylvania. Two Engels, 2012) that helped in the creation of carbon
judges accepted more than $2.6 million in payments from Mid-
Atlantic Youth Services Corp, an operator of two private, for- markets (Olmstead and Stavins, 2006; Stavins, 2003)
profit juvenile facilities, in return for contracting with the and legislation aimed at promoting the use of electric
facilities and imposing harsher sentences on approximately cars in California (Calef and Goble, 2007; Kemp,
2,000 juveniles brought before their courts to ensure that the
detention centers were more fully utilized (Urbina, 2009). Eco- 2005). Such market co-creation helps generate new
nomic analyses concerning private versus public prisons rarely wealth that enables both the public and the private
fold in, across governance alternatives, different opportunities sector to benefit and, thus, satisfy their respective
of participants playing outside the rules of the game and their
different consequences. Here, informed strategic analysis is objectives. Conditions under which public entrepre-
needed. neurs are more likely to behave in ways that leverage
Copyright © 2013 Strategic Management Society Strat. Entrepreneurship J., 7: 70–91 (2013)
DOI: 10.1002/sej
86 P. G. Klein et al.

their capabilities in instituting market co-creation are in a complex interplay between public and private
complex. Furthermore, inefficiency (not efficiency) actors who may simultaneously pursue public and
has been the norm throughout history (North, 1990). private interests. The endogeneity of value (and of
Conditions of bounded rationality, myopia, and the means for realizing that value) makes theories of
intragroup conflict contribute to such inefficiency agency, transaction costs, and organizational eco-
(Williamson, 1975). However, learning over time nomics incomplete for explaining how actors deploy
and the development of shared norms and visions resources. By contrast, we suggest that critical
can help foster greater efficiency. This same logic insights emerge from an approach that accounts for
applies to pluralism, diversity, and the involvement the capabilities that arise within private and public
and strengthening of a wider set of economic actors. organizations for deploying resources in the pursuit
The ways in which excess resources are used to of value. The analysis also points to the importance
address conflict resolution and achieve legitimacy of examining the transitions in behavior that occur as
are critical mediating factors. resources and capabilities pass from private to public
Behavioral concerns (e.g., bounded rationality control and vice versa.
and opportunism) are even more relevant in the We emphasize that strategic entrepreneurship
analysis of the public domain than in the private, research applied to public issues must go beyond
precisely because the profit motive is blunted and the pure agency views of public actors on the one hand
incentive structure less clear. Nevertheless, market and idealized views of property rights evolving
extension, creation, and co-creation can be achieved toward efficiency via private contracting on the other
by leveraging differential capabilities of public and hand (Demsetz, 1969). One of the first steps required
private entrepreneurs. Analyzing under which condi- is to join private contracting models of property
tions this outcome will be more likely can be part of rights with the interest group theory of legislations
a wider positive agenda for change in the social and government—what Eggertsson (1990) calls the
interest (Mahoney, McGahan, and Pitelis, 2009). interest group theory of property rights. Empirical
In sum, modern developments in the fields of research in public choice and positive political
strategic entrepreneurship and management empha- theory shows that the characteristics and behaviors
size the requisite capabilities of private and public of public actors can be parameterized and incorpo-
actors and the coordination of market and value rated into broad-sample econometric analysis (using
co-creation. Market (and ecosystem) co-creation data, for example, on agency size and growth,
can serve as an underpinning raison d’être of both budgets, characteristics of agency management
private and public organization and can help explain teams and the regulatory code, as well as lobbying
the growth of private-public interaction. The bound- contacts between public agencies and private actors).
aries between public and private are predicated not Exploiting secondary data and collecting primary
only on dynamic transaction costs (Langlois, 1992; data on these characteristics should prove useful in
Spiller and Zelner, 1997), but also on differences examining the growth and diversification of public
in the nature of public and private resources and agencies, the persistence of agency behavior, and
capabilities. It is precisely through the combina- similar phenomena. In-depth case studies, whether
tion of these resources and capabilities that new historical (as in Higgs, 1987) or contemporary are
value may emerge, and yet, these combinations valuable as well.
accentuate the challenge of appropriate governance For theory development, a capabilities lens high-
and management. lights that the concept of market and value
co-creation and the leveraging of differential capa-
bilities to co-create value can provide insight on the
CONCLUDING REMARKS nature of the public domain and its growth, as well
as the public-private nexus. Further, ideas such as
This article applies an entrepreneurial capabilities bounded rationality, the absence of a clear objective
lens to public organization and the public-private function, and intraorganizational conflicts (as well as
nexus and maintains that these ideas are essential to ways in which organizational and incentive struc-
a more comprehensive understanding of public orga- tures emerge and can frame decisions and filter
nizations (March and Olsen, 1996; Scott, 1995). The information) can help explain the failure of many
very institutions—such as property, markets, and public organizations and entrepreneurs to pursue and
prices—that are central to private exchange emerge achieve sustainable value and market co-creation.
Copyright © 2013 Strategic Management Society Strat. Entrepreneurship J., 7: 70–91 (2013)
DOI: 10.1002/sej
Capabilities and Strategic Entrepreneurship in Public Organizations 87

Learning, diversity, and pluralism can help foster allocation. In Public Expenditure and Policy Analysis,
this outcome. Devising appropriate governance Haveman RH, Margolis J (eds). Markham: Chicago, IL;
structures to obtain this objective is critical for 59–71.
efficient public administration and can be realized Arrow KJ. 1974. The Limits of Organization. W.W. Norton:
New York.
through the leveraging of strategic and political
Avant DA. 2005. The Market for Force: The Consequences
entrepreneurship scholarship.
of Privatizing Security. Cambridge University Press:
Finally, the current article has had a message for Cambridge, U.K.
entrepreneurial managers and public policy decision Barney JB. 1986. Strategic factor markets: expectations,
makers. The growth of public-private partnerships luck, and business strategy. Management Science 32:
raises fundamental issues about alternative means of 1231–1241.
social interaction and their interrelationship. Okun Barney JB. 1991. Firm resources and sustained competitive
(1975: 13) contrasts the ‘domain of dollars’ and the advantage. Journal of Management 17: 99–120.
‘domain of rights,’ maintaining that ‘[t]he domain Baum JC, McGahan AM. 2011. Outsourcing war: the trans-
of rights is part of the checks and balances on the action cost dynamics of private military companies after
market designed to preserve values that are not the cold war. Working paper, University of Toronto,
Toronto, Canada.
denominated in dollars.’ Hayek (1960) submits,
Baumol WJ. 1990. Entrepreneurship: productive, unproduc-
however, that market mechanisms are more reliable
tive, and destructive. Journal of Political Economy 98:
guarantors of fundamental rights than their political 893–919.
counterparts. A focus on market co-creation—a posi- Bedard K, Frech HE. 2009. Prison health care: is contract-
tion strongly championed by Ostrom (1990)—can ing out healthy? Health Economics 18: 1248–1260.
help identify scope for value-creating co-action in Bellante D, Porter P. 1998. Public and private employment
the field of strategic entrepreneurship. over the business cycle: a ratchet theory of governmental
growth. Journal of Labor Research 19: 613–628.
Benson BL. 2008. The war on drugs: a public bad. Paper
presented at the Searle Center on Law, Regulation, and
REFERENCES Economic Growth, Northwestern University Law School,
Chicago, IL.
Agarwal R, Audretsch D, Sarkar MB. 2007. The process of Bingham CB, Eisenhardt KM, Furr NR. 2007. What makes
creative construction: knowledge spillovers, entrepre- a process a capability? Heuristics, strategy, and effective
neurship, and economic growth. Strategic Entrepreneur- capture of opportunities. Strategic Entrepreneurship
ship Journal 1(3/4): 263–286. Journal 1(1/2): 27–47.
Agarwal R, Croson R, Mahoney JT. 2010. The role of Bonardi JP, Hillman AJ, Keim GD. 2005. The attractiveness
incentives and communication in strategic alliances: an of political markets: implications for strategy. Academy
experimental investigation. Strategic Management of Management Review 30: 397–413.
Journal 31(4): 413–437. Brinkman J, Hoegl M. 2011. Effects of initial teamwork
Ahlbrandt R. 1973. Efficiency in the provision of fire capability and initial relational capability on the develop-
services. Public Choice 16: 1–15. ment of new technology-based firms. Strategic Entrepre-
Allison G. 1971. The Essence of Decision. Little, Brown & neurship Journal 5(1): 37–57.
Company: Boston, MA. Buchanan JM, Tullock G. 1962. The Calculus of Consent:
Alt JE, Carlsen F, Heum P, Johansen K. 1999. Asset speci- Logical Foundations of Constitutional Democracy.
ficity and the political behavior of firms: lobbying for University of Michigan Press: Ann Arbor, MI.
subsidies in Norway. International Organization 53: Byrd TA, Sambamurthy V, Zmud RW. 2005. An example of
99–116. IT planning in a large, diversified, public organization.
Alvarez SA, Barney JB. 2007. Discovery and creation: Decision Sciences 26: 49–73.
alternative theories of entrepreneurial action. Strategic Cabral S, Lazzarini S, Azevedo PP. 2010. Private operation
Entrepreneurship Journal 1(1/2): 11–26. with public supervision: evidence of hybrid modes of
Anderson BS, Covin JG, Slevin DP. 2009. Understanding governance in Brazilian prisons. Public Choice 145: 281–
the relationship between entrepreneurial orientation and 293.
strategic learning capability: an empirical investigation. Calef D, Goble R. 2007. The allure of technology: how
Strategic Entrepreneurship Journal 3(3): 218–240. France and California promoted electric and hybrid
Arrow KJ. 1951. Social Choice and Individual Values. Yale vehicles to reduce urban air pollution. Policy Sciences 40:
University Press: New Haven, CT. 1–34.
Arrow KJ. 1970. The organization of economic activity: Camp SD, Gaes GG. 2000. Private Prisons in the Uni-
issues pertinent to the choice of market versus non-market ted States: An Assessment of Growth, Performance,

Copyright © 2013 Strategic Management Society Strat. Entrepreneurship J., 7: 70–91 (2013)
DOI: 10.1002/sej
88 P. G. Klein et al.

Standards, and Training Requirements. Federal Bureau Downs A. 1966. Bureaucratic Structure and Decision
of Prisons: Washington, D.C. Making. RAND Corporation: Santa Monica, CA.
Capron L, Chatain O. 2008. Competitors’ resource-oriented Eggertsson T. 1990. Cambridge Surveys of Economic Lit-
strategies: acting on competitors’ resources through inter- erature: Economic Behavior and Institutions. Cambridge
ventions in factor markets and political markets. Academy University Press: Cambridge, U.K.
of Management Review 33: 97–121. Eisenhardt KM, Martin JA. 2000. Dynamic capabilities:
Carmeli A, Azeroual B. 2009. How relational capital and what are they? Strategic Management Journal 21(10/11):
knowledge combination capability enhance the perfor- 1105–1121.
mance of work units in a high technology industry. Stra- Faulhaber GR, Farber DJ. 2003. Spectrum management:
tegic Entrepreneurship Journal 3(1): 85–103. property rights, markets, and the commons. In Rethinking
Carter N, Klein R, Day P. 1992. How Organizations Rights and Regulations: Institutional Responses to New
Measure Success: The Use of Performance Indicators in Communication Technologies, Cranor LF, Wildman SS
Government. Routledge: London, U.K. (eds). MIT Press: Cambridge, MA; 193–206.
Casson M. 2005. Entrepreneurship and the theory of the Felin T, Zenger TR. 2009. Entrepreneurs as theorists: on the
firm. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 58: origins of collective beliefs and novel strategies. Strategic
327–348. Entrepreneurship Journal 3(2): 127–146.
Cavalluzzo KS, Ittner CD. 2004. Implementing performance Foss NJ, Klein PG. 2010. Alertness, action, and the ante-
measurement innovations: evidence from government. cedents of entrepreneurship. Journal of Private Enter-
Accounting, Organizations and Society 29: 243–267. prise 25: 145–164.
Chun YH, Rainey HG. 2006. Consequences of goal ambi- Foss NJ, Klein PG. 2012. Organizing Entrepreneurial
guity in public organizations. In Public Service Perfor- Judgment: A New Approach to the Firm. Cambridge Uni-
mance, Boyne GA, Meier KJ, O’Toole LJ, Walker RM versity Press: Cambridge, U.K.
(eds). Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, U.K.; Foss NJ, Klein PG, Kor YY, Mahoney JT. 2008. Entrepre-
92–112. neurship, subjectivism, and the resource-based view:
Coase RH. 1937. The nature of the firm. Economica 4: toward a new synthesis. Strategic Entrepreneurship
386–405. Journal 2(1): 73–94.
Coase RH. 1959. The Federal Communications Commis- Hall PA, Taylor RCR. 1996. Political science and the three
sion. Journal of Law & Economics 2: 1–40. new institutionalisms. Political Studies 44: 936–957.
Coase RH. 1960. The problem of social cost. Journal of Hart O, Shleifer A, Vishny RW. 1997. The proper scope of
Law & Economics 3: 1–44. government: theory and an application to prisons. Quar-
Coase RH. 1964. The regulated industries. American Eco- terly Journal of Economics 112: 1127–1161.
nomic Review 54: 194–197. Hayek FA. 1960. The Constitution of Liberty. University of
Convery FJ, Redmond L. 2007. Market and price develop- Chicago Press: Chicago, IL.
ments in the European Union emissions trading scheme. Hayes KJ, Razzolini L, Ross LB. 1998. Bureaucratic choice
Review of Environmental Economics and Policy 1: and nonoptimal provision of public goods: theory and
88–111. evidence. Public Choice 94: 1–20.
Cyert RM, March JG. 1963. A Behavioral Theory of the Henisz WT, Zelner BA. 2003. The strategic organization of
Firm. Prentice Hall: Englewood Cliffs, NJ. political risks and opportunities. Strategic Organization
Dacin PA, Dacin MT, Matear M. 2010. Social entrepreneur- 1: 451–460.
ship: why we don’t need a new theory and how we move Henisz WT, Zelner BA. 2005. Legitimacy, interest group
forward from here. Academy of Management Perspec- pressures, and change in emergent institutions: the case
tives 24: 37–57. of foreign investors and host country governments.
Dal Bo E. 2006. Regulatory capture: a review. Oxford Academy of Management Review 30: 361–382.
Review of Economic Policy 22: 203–225. Higgs RA. 1987. Crisis and Levithan: Critical Episodes in
Datta-Chaudhuri M. 1990. Market failure and government the Growth of American Government. Oxford University
failure. Journal of Economic Perspectives 4: 25–39. Press: Oxford, U.K.
de Figueiredo J. 2009. Integrated political strategy. Hillman AJ, Hitt M. 1999. Corporate political strategy
Advances in Strategic Management 26: 459–486. formulation: a model of approach, participation, and
de Figueiredo J, Kim JK. 2004. When do firms hire strategy decisions. Academy of Management Review 24:
lobbyists? The organization of lobbying at the Federal 825–842.
Communications Commission. Industrial and Corporate Hillman AJ, Keim GD, Schuler DA. 2004. Corporate politi-
Change 13: 883–900. cal strategies: a review and research agenda. Journal of
Demsetz H. 1969. Information and efficiency: another view- Management 30: 837–857.
point. Journal of Law & Economics 12: 1–22. Hirschman AO. 1982. Shifting Involvements: Private
Dixit A. 1997. Power of incentives in private versus public Interest and Public Action. Princeton University Press:
organizations. American Economic Review 87: 378–382. Princeton, NJ.

Copyright © 2013 Strategic Management Society Strat. Entrepreneurship J., 7: 70–91 (2013)
DOI: 10.1002/sej
Capabilities and Strategic Entrepreneurship in Public Organizations 89

Horn MJ. 1995. The Political Economy of Public Adminis- March JG, Simon HA. 1958. Organizations. John Wiley &
tration: Institutional Choice in the Public Sector. Cam- Sons: New York.
bridge University Press: Cambridge, U.K. Maritan CA, Florence RE. 2008. Political activity as strategic
Itami H, Roehl T. 1987. Mobilizing Invisible Assets. factor market competition. Paper presented at the Strategic
Harvard University Press: Cambridge, MA. Management Society Conference, Cologne, Germany.
Kahnemann D, Slovic P, Tversky A. 1982. Judgment under McCarter MW, Mahoney JT, Northcraft GB. 2011. Testing
Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases. Cambridge Univer- the waters: using collective real options to manage the
sity Press: Cambridge, U.K. social dilemma of strategic alliances. Academy of
Kemp R. 2005. Zero emission vehicle mandate in Management Review 36: 621–640.
California: misguided policy or example of enlightened McDermott GA, Corredoira RA, Kruse G. 2009. Public-
leadership? In Time Strategies, Innovation and Environ- private institutions as catalysts of upgrading in emerging
mental Policy, Sartorius C, Zundel S (eds). Edward Elgar: market societies. Academy of Management Journal 52:
Cheltenham, U.K.; 169–191. 1270–1296.
Kirzner IM. 1973. Competition and Entrepreneurship. McWilliams A, Fleet DD, Cory KD. 2002. Raising rivals’
University of Chicago Press: Chicago, IL. costs through political strategy: an extension of resource-
Kirzner IM. 1997. Entrepreneurial discovery and the com- based theory. Journal of Management Studies 39: 707–
petitive market process: an Austrian approach. Journal of 723.
Economic Literature 35: 60–85. Meyer M, Stevenson W, Webster S. 1985. Limits to Bureau-
Kivleniece I, Quelin B. 2012. Creating and capturing value cratic Growth. Walter de Gruyter: Berlin, Germany.
in public-private ties: a private actor’s perspective. Miller KD. 2007. Risk and rationality in entrepreneurial
Academy of Management Review 37: 272–299. processes. Strategic Entrepreneurship Journal 1(1/2):
Klein PG. 2008. Opportunity discovery, entrepreneurial 57–74.
action, and economic organization. Strategic Entrepre- Mises L. 1944. Bureaucracy. Yale University Press: New
neurship Journal 2(3): 175–190. Haven, CT.
Klein PG, Mahoney JT, McGahan AM, Pitelis CN. 2010. Moe TM. 1995. The politics of structural choice: toward a
Toward a theory of public entrepreneurship. European theory of public bureaucracy. In Organization Theory:
Management Review 7: 1–15. From Chester Barnard to the Present and Beyond,
Knoll L, Engels A. 2012. Exploring the linkages between Williamson OE (ed). Oxford University Press: New York;
carbon markets and sustainable innovations in the energy 116–153.
sector: lessons from the EU emissions trading scheme. In Mueller DC. 2003. Public Choice. Cambridge University
Sustainability Innovations in the Electricity Sector, Press: Cambridge, U.K.
Jansen D, Ostertag K, Walz R (eds). Springer-Verlag: Nelson J. 1999. Taft Prison Facility: Cost Scenarios.
Berlin, Germany; 97–116. National Institute of Corrections: Washington, D.C.
Kornai J. 1986. The soft budget constraint. Kyklos 39: 3– Nelson RR, Winter SG. 1982. An Evolutionary Theory of
30. Economic Change. Harvard University Press: Cam-
Kristensen O. 1983. Public versus private provision of bridge, MA.
governmental services: the case of Danish fire protection Niskanen WA. 1971. Bureaucracy in Representative
services. Urban Studies 20: 1–9. Government. Aldine-Atherton: New York.
Langlois RN. 1992. Transaction-cost economics in real North DC. 1981. Structure and Change in Economic
time. Industrial and Corporate Change 1: 99–127. History. W.W. Norton: New York.
Leuchtenburg WE. 1959. The Perils of Prosperity, 1949– North DC. 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change, and
1932. University of Chicago Press: Chicago, IL. Economic Performance. Cambridge University Press:
Luksha P. 2008. Niche construction: the process of oppor- Cambridge, U.K.
tunity creation in the environment. Strategic Entrepre- Ocasio W. 1997. Towards an attention-based view of the
neurship Journal 2(4): 269–283. firm. Strategic Management Journal, Summer Special
Lundahl BW, Kunz C, Brownell C, Harris N, Van Fleet R. Issue 18: 187–206.
2009. Prison privatization: a meta-analysis of cost and Okun A. 1975. Equality and Efficiency: The Big Tradeoff.
quality of confinement indicators. Research on Social Brookings Institution: Washington, D.C.
Work Practice 19: 383–394. Oliver C, Holzinger I. 2008. The effectiveness of strategic
Mahoney JT. 2005. Economic Foundations of Strategy. political management: a dynamic capabilities framework.
SAGE Publications: Thousand Oaks, CA. Academy of Management Review 33: 496–520.
Mahoney JT, McGahan AM, Pitelis CN. 2009. The interde- Olmstead SM, Stavins RM. 2006. An international policy
pendence of private and public interests. Organization architecture for the post-Kyoto era. American Economic
Science 20: 1034–1052. Review 96: 35–38.
March JG, Olsen JP. 1996. Institutional perspectives on Olson M. 1965. The Logic of Collective Action. Harvard
political institutions. Governance 9: 247–264. University Press: Cambridge, MA.

Copyright © 2013 Strategic Management Society Strat. Entrepreneurship J., 7: 70–91 (2013)
DOI: 10.1002/sej
90 P. G. Klein et al.

Olson M. 2000. Power and Prosperity. Basic Books: New Shah SK, Tripsas M. 2007. The accidental entrepreneur: the
York. emergent and collective process of user entrepreneurship.
Ostrom E. 1990. Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Strategic Entrepreneurship Journal 1(1/2): 123–140.
Institutional Forms of Collective Action. Cambridge Shepherd DA, McMullen JS, Jennings PD. 2007. The
University Press: Cambridge, U.K. formation of opportunity beliefs: overcoming ignorance
Palumbo DJ. 1986 Privatization and corrections policy. and reducing doubt. Strategic Entrepreneurship Journal
Review of Policy Research 5: 598–605. 1(1/2): 75–95.
Peacock AT, Wiseman J. 1961. The Growth of Public Shichor D. 1995. Punishment for Profit: Private Prisons/
Expenditures in the United Kingdom. Princeton Univer- Public Concerns. SAGE Publications: Thousand Oaks,
sity Press: Princeton, NJ. CA.
Penrose ET. 1959. The Theory of the Growth of the Firm. Short JC, Moss TW, Lumpkin GT. 2009. Research in social
John Wiley & Sons: New York. entrepreneurship: past contributions and future opportu-
Peters PG. 2001. The Politics of Bureaucracy. Routledge: nities. Strategic Entrepreneurship Journal 3(2): 161–194.
London, U.K. Simon HA. 1947. Administrative Behavior. Macmillan:
Pitelis CN. 2007. A behavioral resource-based view of the New York.
firm: the synergy of Cyert and March (1963) and Penrose Simon HA. 1982. Models of Bounded Rationality: Behav-
(1959). Organization Science 18: 478–490. ioral Economics and Business Organization. MIT Press:
Pitelis CN, Teece DJ. 2010. Cross-border market Cambridge, MA.
co-creation, dynamic capabilities, and the entrepreneurial Simsek Z, Heavey C. 2011. The mediating role of
theory of the multinational enterprise. Industrial and knowledge-based capital for corporate entrepreneurship
Corporate Change 19: 1247–1270. effects on performance: a study of small- to medium-
Porter ME. 1990. The Competitive Advantage of Nations. sized firms. Strategic Entrepreneurship Journal 5(1):
Free Press: New York. 81–100.
Porter ME, Teisberg EO. 2006. Redefining Health Care. Singer PW. 2003. Corporate Warriors: The Rise of the
Harvard Business School Press: Boston, MA. Private Military Industry. Cornell University Press:
Rainey HG, Bozeman B. 2000. Comparing public and Ithaca, NY.
private objectives: empirical research and the power of Sleptsov A, Anand J. 2008. Exercising entrepreneurial
the a priori. Journal of Public Administration Research opportunities: the role of information-gathering and
and Theory 10: 447–470. information-processing capabilities of the firm. Strategic
Rangan S, Samii R, Van Wassenhove L. 2006. Constructive Entrepreneurship Journal 2(4): 357–375.
partnerships: when alliances between private firms and Small K, Verhoef E. 2007. The Economics of Urban Trans-
public actors can enable creative strategies. Academy of portation. Routledge: London, U.K.
Management Review 31: 738–751. Smith A. 1776. An Enquiry into the Nature and Causes of
Riker WH, Ordeshook PC. 1973. An Introduction to the Wealth of Nations. The Glasgow Edition of the Works
Positive Political Theory. Prentice Hall: Englewood and Correspondence of Adam Smith. Strahan & Cadell:
Cliffs, NJ. London, U.K.
Ruggiero J, Duncombe W, Miner J. 2004. On the measure- Spiller PT, Tommasi M. 2003. The institutional foundations
ment and causes of technical inefficiency in local public of public policy. Journal of Law, Economics, & Organi-
services: with an application to public education. Journal zation 19: 281–306.
of Public Administration Research and Theory 5: 403– Spiller PT, Zelner BA. 1997. Product complementarities,
428. capabilities, and governance: a dynamic transaction cost
Ruiter DWP. 2005. Is transaction cost economics applicable perspective. Industrial and Corporate Change 6: 561–
to public governance? European Journal of Law & Eco- 594.
nomics 20: 287–303. Spulber DF. 1989. Regulation and Markets. MIT Press:
Scahill J. 2007. Blackwater: The Rise of the World’s Cambridge, MA.
Most Powerful Mercenary Army. Nation Books: New Stavins RN. 2003. Experience with market-based environ-
York. mental policy instruments. In Handbook of Environmen-
Schuler D, Rehbein K, Cramer R. 2002. Pursuing strategic tal Economics (Vol. 1): Environmental Degradation and
advantage through political means: a multivariate Institutional Responses, Mäler K-G, Vincent JR (eds).
approach. Academy of Management Journal 45: 659–672. Elsevier: Amsterdam, The Netherlands.
Scott WR. 1995. Institutions and Organizations. SAGE Stigler GJ. 1971. The theory of economic regulation. Bell
Publications: Thousand Oaks, CA. Journal of Economics 2: 3–21.
Segal GF, Moore AJ. 2002. Weighing the Watchmen: Evalu- Tamanaha BZ. 2005. On the Rule of Law: History, Politics,
ating the Costs and Benefits of Outsourcing Correctional Theory. Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, U.K.
Services. Reason Public Policy Institute: Los Angeles, Thompson JD. 1967. Organizations in Action. McGraw-
CA. Hill: New York.

Copyright © 2013 Strategic Management Society Strat. Entrepreneurship J., 7: 70–91 (2013)
DOI: 10.1002/sej
Capabilities and Strategic Entrepreneurship in Public Organizations 91

Urbina I. 2009. Despite red flags, judges ran kickback Williamson OE. 1985. The Economic Institutions of
scheme for years. The New York Times, 27 March. Capitalism: Firms, Markets, Relational Contracting.
Vandenbroucke LS. 1993. Perilous Options: Special Opera- Free Press: New York.
tions as an Instrument of U.S. Foreign Policy. Oxford Williamson OE. 1996. The Mechanisms of Governance.
University Press: Oxford, U.K. Oxford University Press: New York.
Van de Ven AH, Sapienza HJ, Villanueva J. 2007. Entrepre- Williamson OE. 1999. Public and private bureaucracies: a
neurial pursuits of self- and collective interests. Strategic transaction cost economics perspective. Journal of Law,
Entrepreneurship Journal 1(3/4): 353–370. Economics, & Organization 15: 306–342.
Villalonga B, McGahan AM. 2005. The choice among Wilson JQ. 1989. Bureaucracy: What Government Agencies
acquisitions, alliances, and divestitures. Strategic Man- Do and Why They Do It. Basic Books: New York.
agement Journal 26(13): 1183–1208. Wolf C. 1979. A theory of non-market failures: framework
Weingast B. 1995. The economic role of political institu- for implementation analysis. Journal of Law & Econom-
tions: market-preserving federalism and economic ics 22: 107–139.
development. Journal of Law, Economics, & Organiza- Zeng M, Chen XP. 2003. Achieving cooperation in multi-
tion 11: 1–31. party alliances: a social dilemma approach to partnership
Williamson OE. 1975. Markets and Hierarchies. Free Press: management. Academy of Management Review 28: 587–
New York. 605.

Copyright © 2013 Strategic Management Society Strat. Entrepreneurship J., 7: 70–91 (2013)
DOI: 10.1002/sej

Anda mungkin juga menyukai