Anda di halaman 1dari 11

Industrial Development in India: Some Reflections on Growth and Stagnation

Author(s): Deepak Nayyar


Source: Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. 13, No. 31/33, Special Number (Aug., 1978), pp.
1265-1267+1269+1271+1273+1275-1278
Published by: Economic and Political Weekly
Stable URL: https://www.jstor.org/stable/4366860
Accessed: 06-05-2019 12:43 UTC

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
https://about.jstor.org/terms

Economic and Political Weekly is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend
access to Economic and Political Weekly

This content downloaded from 202.41.10.5 on Mon, 06 May 2019 12:43:26 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Industrial Development in India
Some Reflections on Growth and Stagnation
Deepak Nayyar

The sluggishness of industrial growvth, which has persisted for more' than 10 years, can no longer
be attributed to short-term problems and obviously needs sy stematic analysis.
This paper seeks to analyse the factors underlying the marked deceleration in the rate of industrial
growth, which transformed a scenario of relatively rapid industrialisation into a situa(ition of persistent
quiasi-stagnation.
Section II of the paper examines the trends in induistrial production and establishes the fact of de-
celeration in growth. Section IH provides a critical review of the alternative explanations for stagnation in
tMe industrial sector. Section IV attempts to focus attention on factors uwhich have, in a relative s,ense,
been neglected by the literature on the' subject, and explores the relationship betweeni incomze distribution,
the demand factor and industrial growth. Section V is directed touards developing a uinified hypothesis
about the sluggishness of growth in India's industrial sector since the mid-1960s.

I stagnation in the industrial sector. growth is discernible from a cursory


Section IV attempts to focus attention study of the Table, and is confirmed

Introduction on factors which have, in a relative by a few soimple computations. During


sense, been neglected by the literature the decade 1955-65, total industrial
AT first sight, the record of industrial
on the subject, and explores the rela- production increased at an average
growth in India since Independence
tionship between income distribution, annual rate of 7.8 per cent, while
appears impressive. In the quarter
the demand factor and industrial manufzacturing output increased at 7.6
century from 1950 to 1975, indus-
growth. Section V is directed towards per cent. In the following decade,
trial production more than quadrupl-
developing a unified hypothesis about 1965-75, the rates drooped to 3.6 per
ed. What is more, this growth was
the sluggishness of growth in India's cent and 3.1 ner cent respectively.
accompanied by a marked diversifica-
industrial sector since the mid-1960s. These are point to point compound
tion of the industrial structure, which
growth rates. In order to take account
is reflected in the wide range and
of all the observations in the two
complexity of goods now manufactur- II
periods, we fitted a semi-log trend to
ed in India. However, a mere glance
the indices for both total industrial
at the aggregate data reveals that the Trends in Industrial Ploduction
pro(lutction an(d manifaetuiring (Series
pace of industrial development has It is rather difficult to outline the B), only to find that the results were
been somewhat uneven over time. In trends in industrialisation because remarkably similar.,
the period 1951-65, industrial produc- there is no complete time series on
tion increased at an average rate of The reader would notice that the
the index numbers of industrial pro-
7.7 per cent per annum. This rate drop- above exercise on growth rates ignores
duction which spans the entire period.
ped rather sharply to 3.6 per cent per 1976, a year in which industrial pro-
In fact, changes in base years mnake
annum during the decade 1965-75. duction registered an unprecedente(d
inter-temporal comparisons problema-
In retrospect, it is clear that the increase of 10 per cent over the pre-
tic. All the same, there is overwhelm-
poor performance, which became dis- ceding y-ear. This omission is delibe-
ing evidencNe in support of the proposi-
cernible in the middle and late 1960s, rate, because the revival of 1976 was
tion that the mid-sixties witnesse(d a
was neither an aberration nor a tem- more apparent than real. It was the
dramatic decline in the rate of indus-
porary deviation from the trend, but outcome of a phenomenal bumper lhar-
trial growth: the average annuial rate
the beginning of a long-term structu- vest and the unusual political circum-
during the decade beginning 1965
ral problem. The sluggishness of stances of the time. The government
turned out to be less than half what
industrial growth, which has persisted stepped up public sec.tor production
it was in the preceding fifteen years.
for more than ten years, can no lon- irrespective of whether the ouitput
However, it might be argued that
ger be attributed to short-term pro- could be utilised, so that there' was
starting from a small base, all growth
blems and obviously needs systematic a rapid accumulation of stocks in in-
rates appear unusually large and,
analysis. While the problem area is termediate goods such as* steel and
therefore, one might be overstating
vast, the object of this paper is a coal. A higher level of output and
the 'degree of deceleration in growth.
limited one. It seeks to analyse the improved capacity utilisation followed
In an attempt to circumvent this
factors underlying the marked decelera- from government policy towards its
legitimate problem, the present essay
tion in the rate of industrial growth, work force, when the Emergencvy laws
considers 1955 as the base year for all
which transformed a scenario of rapid were used extensively to eliminate
comparisons. While such a method
industrialisation into a situation of strikes and all other fornis of indus-
might not eliminate the bias altogether,
persistent quasi-stagnation. trial disputes.' But these policies did
it should certainly reduce the n.agni-
Section II examines the trends in not transform the industrial scene in
tude.
industrial production and establishes the private sector. Indeed, private
the fact of deceleration in growth. Table 1 sets out the available data corporate investment during 1976-77
Section III provides a critical review on the indices of production in the was, in absolute terms, significantly
of the alternative explanatiotns for industrial sector. A slackening of lower than it had been in 1975-76.2

1265

This content downloaded from 202.41.10.5 on Mon, 06 May 2019 12:43:26 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Special Number August 1978 ECONOMIC AND POLITICAL WEEKLY

TABLE 1 INDEx NUmiaERS OF INDUS-1TIAL PRODUCTION it might h4ve been more pronounced
in some industries than in others.
Series A 1956=100 Series B .1960=100 Series C 1970=100
Year . _ _ - The mid-sixties were, obviously, the
General Manufac- General Manufac- General Manufac- turning point. This is brought out
Index turing Index turing Index *turing even more clearly in Table 3, which is
based on an alternative industrial
1955 91.9 91.6 (72.7) (73.8) classification but the source of primary
1956 100.0 100.0 ( 78.4) ( 79.6) data is the same. From the viewpoint
1957 104.2 103.3 ( 82.7) ( 83.4)
1958 107.7 106.2 ( 84.4) ( 84.8) of macro-economic analysis, a usc-
1959 116.8 114.9 ( 90.3) ( 90.5) based classification is certainly more
1960 130.2 127.9 100.0 100.0 interesting; unfortunately, however,
1961 141.0 137.9 109.2 109.2 data in this series do not extend back
1962 152.9 149.2 119.8 119.6.
1963 167.3 162.9 129.7 129.1 beyond 1960. Nevertheless, the avail-
.1964 177.8 173.6 140.8 141.2 able statistics do highlight the drama-
1965 187.7 182.3 153.8 154.0 tic deceleration in growth of the capi-
1966 192.6 186.0 153.2 151.7
tal-goods sector. The table also shows
1967 152.6 149.6
1968 163.0 158.7 that the fate of intermediate goods
1969 175.3 170.6 industries was roughly similar, although
'1970 184.3 178.9 100.0 100.0 the drop in the growth rate was not
1971 186.1 178.9 104.2 104.2
as steep. The basic industries group
1972 199.4 191.4 110.2 110.1
1973 200.7 193.4 112.0 112.2 (constituted by electricity, tnining,,
1974 (210.7) (102.2) 114.3 113.0 fertilisers, heavy' chemicals, cement
1975 (219.9) (207.7) 119.3 116.1 and basic metals), on the other hand,
1976 131.6 127.7
fared a little better in so far as the
rate of growth remained at a reason-
Note: For Series B, the figur
able level even after the deceleration
respectively. Those relating
and have been set in. It is worth noting
taken from that growth C
The figureo for 1974-75,
in the consumer goods industries was ho
using the ratio of the 1970 inciex in Seriec B to that in Series C as the con- always significantly below the average
version factor.
for the industrial sector. In the 1960s,
Source: CSO, Statistical Abstract, India, annual issues.
it was sustained at a respectable level

Given this context, it would be reason- by a rapid expansion in the output of


Log Iip _
able to infer that the industrial per- consumer durables. However, even
-4.6440 + 0.2387t - 0.0014t2
formance in 1976 did not mark the the modest growth disappeared in the
(0.0338) (0.00026)
1970s as the pace of expansion in the
beginning of the end of stagnation.: R2 = 0.99; DW = 1.03
No, did it mean a return to the trend durable goods industries slackened
Log I m= markedfy.
rate witnessed earlier, ouite simplv
-4.8486 + 0.2480t - 0.001 5t2 It needs to be stressed that the
because the factors which propped up
(0.Q371) (0.00029) evidence presented so far relates only
growth in 1976 were not sustainable
R= 0.99; DW = 0.95 to the organised factory sector. Given
in the long run. As such, it'is hardly
In both cases, the estimated values of the paucity of published data, it is
surprising that industrial outpbt in
'c' turned ouit to he negative, and almost impossible to assess how the
1977 is expected to be just about 4
per cent higher than the previouis year. significant at the 1 per cent level of performance of the small-scale sector
probability, thereby providing defini- would influence the overall trends in
From the above, it seems obvious tive evidence of a deceleration in the industrial production. Available infor-
that 1976 was an abnormal year whicl rate of growth. mation suggests that small-scale indus-
cannot serve as a point of reference tries account for roughly 15 per cent
or comparison. In the following dis- The picture of deceleration is sub- of the total value of industrial produc-
cussion, therefore, we shall focus at- stantiated further if we examine data tion.5 Thus, it would seem that the
tention on the trends in industrial at a disaggregated level. Table 2 out- statistical evidence outlinqd in the
production until 1975. Our choice of lines the trends in output starting preceding pages is a reasonable indi-
terminal year is perfectly justifiable, from the two-digit level of the CSO cator of the trends in industrial out-
particularly as the primary purpose of industrial classification. While the put. In any case, the performance of
this paper is to analyse the, long term composition of industrial production the small-scale sector should be re-
shifts in the pace of industrialisation. certainly changed, over time, taken flected in the level of industrial pro-
together, the ten manufacturing in- duction (originating in registered large-
In ordersto pinpoint changes in the dustry groups selected for the Table scale units) in so far as it provides
rate of industrial growth, for the contributed approximately 90 per cent inputs to, or purchases them from the
period 1955-1975, we fitted the equa- of the total output in manufacturing, factory sector.
tion Log Y = a + bt + ct' to thg throughout the peripd under review.4 As a starting point for dis'cussion,
data in Table 1, Series B, where 'Y' is A comparison of the average annual it might be useful at this stage to
either the general index kf industrial growth rates in the period 1955-1965 recapitulate the salient features of the
procluction (Iip ) or the index of with the corresponding ones in 1965- pattern of industrial development in
manufacturing (Im), and 't' is the 1975 conclusively shows that the slow- India over the past three decades. In
time period. The following results down in growth occurred across the the vears following Independence,
were obtained frbm the exercise:. board in the industrial sector, though infrastructural developments and

1266

This content downloaded from 202.41.10.5 on Mon, 06 May 2019 12:43:26 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
ECONOMIC AND POLITICAL WEEKLY Spedial Number August 1978

TABLE 2: COMPOSITION AND TIME PROFILE OF INDUSTRIAL GROWTH IN INDIA

Weights Index Numbers of Production: Average Growth Rate:


Industry Group 1960=100 1960=100 Per Cent Per Annum

1955 1965 1975 1955-65 1965-75

Food products 12.09 75.9 122.2 171.2 4.9 3.4


Beverages and tobacco 2.22 61.7 147.6 200.9 9.1 3.1
Textiles 27.06 94.1 114.8 1 2.0 2.0 -0.5
Chemicals and chemical products 7.26 60.1 152.6 306.9 9.8 7.2
Non-metallic mineral products 3.85 53.7 149.1 243.3 10.8 5.0
Basic metals 7.38 53.3 180.9 242.3 13.0 3.0
Metal products 2.51 54.1 205.6 310.0 14.3 4.2
Machinery : non-electrical 3.38 35.5 320.9 623.6 24.6 6.9
Electrical machinery and appliances .05 49.0 208.2 443.8 15.6 8.0
Transport equipment 7.77 99.2 205.3 149.4 7.6 -3.2

All Manufacturing 84.91 73.8 154.0 207.7 7.6 3.1


Mining and Quarrying 9.72 74.6 131.7 189.8 5.9 3.7
Electricity 5.37 51.5 190.9 461.8 14.0 9.2
Total Industrial Production 100.00 72.7 153.8 219.9 7.8 3.6

Note: The figures in the last two columns of the table have been co
Source: CSO, (a) For the 1960 weights and for 1965 index numbers
numbers, Commerce, Annual Number, Bombay, 1968, pp 287-90
weights, and have also been compiled by the CSO; of "Basic Stat
New Delhi, 1976, p 46. (c) The index numbers for 1975 have b
CSO Monthly Abstract of Statistics, July 1977, pp 27-30. To
of the 1970 index in the two series, for each industry group, a

import substitution in the consumer might be worthwhile. cause the economy should have return-
goods sector stimulated industrial pro- ed to even keel after the event. It did
Soon after the slowdown in growth
duction. After that phase, in the late not. In retrospect, it is clear that the
became discernible, the problems of
1950s and early 1960s, the high rate the industrial sector were frequently disappearance of the short-term pro-
of industrial growth was sustained by blems has not mheant a revival of indus-
pttributed , to exogenous factors or
investment in the capital goods sec- trial growth.
random occurrences. While this
tor and in basic intermediate goods view is not widely held now, its adhe- There is a second, more long-term,
industries. Starting around 1965, rents have not disappeared altogether. view of industrialisation in India,
there was a marked deceleration in the The emphasis has varied but, inter which does not concern itself with the
rate' of' growth, which led to a near problem of deceleration in growth,
alia, short term analysis draw atten-
stagnation of industrial ouitput in the tion to the following: (a) the wars of but stresses the difficulties arising
early 1970s. The little growth that 1962, 1965 and 1971 which diverted from the industrial policies pursued
did take place in the period 1965- potential public investment into un- l)y the government. The volumes by
1970 was largely attributable to infra- Bhagwati and Desai (1970) and
prodpctive uses; (b) the successive
structural basic industries and to con- droughts of 1965-66 - 1966-67, and Bhagwati and Srinivasan (1975) pro-
sumer durables. However, the expan- later 1971-72 - 1972-73, which re- vide an elaborate exDosition of this
sion in luxury goods industries also stricted the supply of raw materials view. It is argued that the complex
came to an end thereafter. The and the demand for industrial goods buteaucratic system of licensing,
ostensible revival in 1976 was a con-, from the agricultural sector; (c) supply restrictions and controls led not only
sequence of special circumstances, and constraints which became more pro- to inefficiencies but also to a misallo-
did not mean a return to the trend nounced in the late 1960s, in the form cation of resources. What is nmore,
growth rate of earlier 'years. of infrastructural bottlenetks (power the cumulative effect of these policies
and transport) or shortages of interme- became an obstacle to growth. Thus,
III diate goods; (d) the oil crisis of 1973 Bhagwati and Srinivasan (1975, p 245)
which 'led to considerable industrial conclude that:
Alternative Explanations of
-dislocation and severe balance of pay- India's foreign trade regime, in con-
Deceleration and Stagnation iunction with domestic licensing
ments difficulties.
Several explanations 'have been ad- policies in the industrial sector, led
vanced to account for the sluggish- In the early stages, it is hardly sur- to economic inefficiencies and
prising that policy makexs in govern- impaired her economic performance
ness of industrial., growth since' the
... The policy framework was detri-
mid-sixties. Of these, in my view at ment and economists outside stressed Jne9tal, on balance, to the growth
least, two sets are clearly inadequate the importance of these occurrences.6 of the economy by adversely influ-
essentially because they do iiot get to Even now, it would be naive to deny encing export oerformance, by waste-
the core of the problem. On 'the other- that such occurrences had a signifi- ftil inte(r'indu.strial and inter-finn
allocation of resources, by permit-
hand, there are explanations which cant impact on the level of industrial
ting and encouraging expansion of
are perfectly plausible and merit care- production at the time. 'Nith the excess capacity and by blunting com-
ful discussion. Before we move -on to benefit of hindsight, however, it seems petition and hence the incentives for
such a critical review, however, a fairly obvious that the aforesaid ran- cost-consciousness and quality im-
dom factors cannot account for the provement.7
brief sketch of the inadequate hypo-
theses about industrial 'stagnation persistence of stagnation, simply be- Such analysis, however, does not

1267

This content downloaded from 202.41.10.5 on Mon, 06 May 2019 12:43:26 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
ECONOMIC AND POLITIcfAL WEEKLY Special Nuifiber Aitust 1978

TABLE 3 DECELERATION OF GROWTH IN THE INDUSTRIAL sion to enter into a discussion


SECTOR, of these
1960-1974
(average annual percentage increase in production) issues here. For the sake of analysis,
therefore, let us grant the proposition
(1) (2) (3)
that there has been a slackening of
Weights 1960-65 1965-70, 1970-75
Industry Group (1960=100) growth in the agricultural sector and
that *this may have had an adverse
Basic industries 25.11 10.4 6.2 5.2
effect on industrialisation in the recent
Capital goods industries 11.76 19.5 -1.7- 5.1
Intermediate goods industries 25.88 7.0 2.5 2.6 past. Available evidence, on balance,
Consumer goo ds industries 37.25 5.0 3.9. 1.6 probably lends supoort to such a
(i) Durable goods (5.68) 10.7 8.4 2.4 hypothesis.
(ii)Non-durablegoods . (31.57) 38 2.7 1.5
Nevertheless, it is important to pose
Total Industrial Production 100.00 9.0 3.3 3.6
the simple question: is this a sufficient
Note: (a) The figures in the Table have been calculated
explanationfrom the index
for the persistence of numb
industrial production, as point to point compound growth rates. industrial stagnation? For if it were,
(b) Columns (1) and (2) are derived from the series on index numbers of
industrial production with 1960 as base year, whereas column (3) is deri-a risumption of steady growth in agri-
ved from the new series with 1970 as base year. culture would revive and stimulate
industrial production. In my view,
Source: RBI, "Report on Currency and Finance", 1974-75, Volume II, p 26 and 1975-
76, Volume II, p 28.. .however, the explanation is ony
partial, on account of the reasons set
throw much light on the problem posed, importance of the agricultural sector out below. -Thus, while agricultural-
in this essay. One can, after all' ask: arises, in principle, from its over- expansion might be 'a necessarv con-
(1) Why did the industrial sector per-' whelming share in production and dition for sustained industrial growth,
form satisfactorily until 1965, in spite consumption. Quite apart from that, it is by no means a sufficient condition
of these policies, and why did, it not however, its performance has a directin the present Indian context.
respond to liberalisation thereafter, or impact on the pace of industrialisation,
now? (2) Why did other economies, through the following mechanism. A 'eIchnical change, improved inputs,
operating in a framework similar to. slow increase in agricultural produc- more resources or even successive bum-'
that of India, achieve significantly tion would act as a brake on hidus- per harvests would increase agricultu-
higher rates of industrial growth? trial growth if: (i) a surplus of wage ral production. If there is a balanced
These questions are seldom raised; let goods and/or investible resources is growth in crop output, it would almost

alone answered, primarily because the not forthcotning; (ii) the supply of certainly increase the marketed sur-
authors are interested in a 'coinpletely agricultural raw materials is restricted;plus of raw materials and food, but
different set of issues.' or (iii) the demand for industrial goodsthese surpluses might not be available
Much of the literatur'e cited above is constraine4. On the 'other hand, a on the terms necessary to revive indus%.
is preoccupied with an evaluation of 'rapid expansion in agricultural cutput trial growth. Past experience suggests
would, 'through the same linkages, that a secular movement of the inter-'
import substitution strategies and the-
economic efficiency of indu-strialisation. provide a sustained stimulus to growthsectoral terms of trade in favour of the
It' is hardly surprising, therefore, that in the industrial sector. agricultural sector, operating through
relatively little attention is paid to the It is only to be eXpected that diffe- a squeeze on profits, might have held
process of groPwth. In any case, neo- rent authors would emphasise differer.tback industrial expansion. ' hakra-
classical writing on the subject is factors avnd outline different mecha- varty (1974> notes thi? point in his
essentially static in conception, and nisms through which such linkages analysis, but ascribes the shift in rela-
operate. Following this general line tive prices to the deceleration in,
largely ignores inter-temporal con-
of argument, however, a niumber of growth of agricultural output. How-
siderations. Even the limited analysis
of growth effects is often derived from scholars, notably Chakravarty (1974), ever, it is likely that the landlord
static allocative efficiency criteria.8 Raj (1976) and Vaidyanathan (1977) class, through political influence, mani-
pulated the inter-sectoral termns of
Other typotheses about the decelera- have sought to explain the sluggish
growth of. industrial output, since the trade in its favour (Mitra, 1977), and
tion of industrial growth in the past
decade, with a few exceptions, hinge mid-sixties, in terms of, the meairemight well do so in the future. In
on two basic themes: 'the performance growth in agricultural production. It such circumstances, an improved per-
of the agricultural sector and the level is possible to argue about the numbers formance in agriculture would not
ensure industrial growth. An increase
,of investment in the economy.- Detail- and debate about the trends, as inrdeed
ed discussion of these contributions a few economists have,9 but it is diffi-in agricultuiral production may not be
cult to dispute the .`b1asis of such a suffi'cient on other counts either. While
to the literature is a task outside the
fundamentalist explanation. Once the it' would lead to an increase in the
scope of this paper. For our purpose,
fact of deceleration in the growth total income of the farm sector, there
it -would be sufficient to provide a
critical review of the more important of agricultural output is accepted, can be little doubt that the bulk of
there remains the question of factors increments in income would be apprq-
contributions, with a focus on salient
features, and examine the extent to responsible for it, which, in turn, priated by those who own the means
have
of production: landlords and ridh
been discussed at length in the litera-
which they provide satisfactory expla-
ture; they range from te;hnologicalfarmers. But unless incomes accrue to
nations.
the poor, the demand for industrial
factors on the one land, to the insti-
(A) PERFORMANCE OF AGRICULTURAL tutional framework and property rela-' goods from the rural majority
wage
SECTOR cannot relive. We shall return lo this
tions in agriculture on the other. 'It
issue later in the paper.
would 'involve too much of a dig,res-
For an economy such, as India, the

1269

This content downloaded from 202.41.10.5 on Mon, 06 May 2019 12:43:26 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
ECONOMIC AND POLITICAL WEEKLY Special Number August 1978

(B) LEVEL OF INVESTMENT domestic resources to the extent it ments in the economic surpluis and
should have. Second, net aid inflows was therefore capable of investment,
During the decade 1955-65, real
rose very sharply in the 1970s, from channelled resources into speculation,
investment in the economy increased
their lowest ever level of Rs 159 luxury goods, construction and the
rapidly but the pace of expansion
like.
slackened markedly thereafter, notably in 1972-73 to Rs 1153 crores
crores
in 1975-76, around which level thev In the framework set out above,
in the public sector.10 The share of
gross domestic capital formation in have since remained,'1'but Public in- ste:l)ing up the rate of investment in
vestment has failed to oick up. the public sector should provide an
GDP which attained a peak level of
Patnaik and Rao (1977) put forward obvious solution to the problem of
19,7 per cent in 1966-67, declined a
little in subsequent years and fluctuat- a much more perceptive and interest- industrial stagnation. However, Pat'
ed around an average level of 17 per ing hypothesis about industrial stag- naik. and Rao believe that there are
cent in the period 1967-67 - 1974-75 nation. -They advance an explanation limits on the expansion of public in-
(Government of India, 1976, pp 30-1). in terms of the circumstances leading vestment. In the short run, given the
The trend was much the same for to (i) a decrease in public investment, reserves of food and foreign exchange,
gross fixed capital formation in the and (ii) a loss of stimulus for private deficit financing might appear siniple
public sector. Thus some economists investment; both these occurrences, it enough, but it does imply a, serious
have attempted to explain the slow- is suggested, were a natural conse- threat of inflation,U2 which would res-
down in industrial growth in terms of quence of the earlier growth process. trict the room for manoeuvre. Any-
the stagnation in investment. There The impressive industrial growth un- way, in the long run, a sustainable
are two, rather different, variants of til 1965 followed from a rapid ex- increase in public investment must be
this hypothesis. pansion of public investment on the
backed by a mobilisation of domestic
Consider first, the paper by Sri- one hand and public expenditure on
resources or, in effect, a major shift
nivasan and Narayanh (1977). They the other. While the former ensured
of the economic surplus from the pri-
start from two sets of observations for the supply of basiq industrial inputs,
vate sector to the public sector.
the period since the mid-sixties: (i) a the latter generated a demand for
slackening of real investment, parti- goods manufactured in the pr ivatc The basic thrust of this hypothesis
cularly in the public sector and sector. At the same time, the strategy is perfectly acceptable but, as an ex-
(ii) a deceleration in the rate of indus- of import substitution implemented planation and prescription, it renains
trial growth. It is stressed that these through protection, virtually guaran- incomplete. The reasons underlying'
developments constituted a inarked teed a market for domqstic produ- my view are as follows. First, the
departure from the trends established cers, thereby providing a steadv sti- failure on the part of the pri%ate sec-
'in the first three Five-Year Plans. The mulus for private investment. This tor to invest its accumulating resour-
authors go on to argue that the stagna- process of growth was not sustained ces productively cannot be attributed
tion of real investment, especially for 'two reasons. In the first place, to the stagnation in public investment
import substitution was nothing but
public investment, is among the princi- alone. Surely, the profitabilitv of pri-
pal causes of sluggish industrial deve- a transient stimulus which lasted so vate. investment. is a relevant consi-
lopment, and if -the economy is to long as the local markets remained deration which depends, among other
surmount its present crisis there uncaptured. Second, and possibly
should things, on the pattern of consumer
more important, there wag a nmarked expenditure and demand in the over-
be a vigorous expansion of public
investment. Towards that end, they deceleration in the growth of public whelmingly, important home market.
believe, recourse to deficit financing is investment and expenditure. buring Second, even if we assume that re-
perfectly possible given the enormous the period 1960-61 - 1964-65, gross sources could f omehow be n'obilised
reserves of food and foreign exchange. fixed capital formation in the public to step up public investment, would
The thesis is somewhat simplistic. It sector increased at 9.1 per cent per it revive industrial growth on its
does not even attempt to analyse the annum whereas total expenditure of own? Possibly not. Public investment
factors underlying the slowdown in the 'government increased even faster may have made for rapid industrial
public investment, nor does it trace at 13.2 per cent per annum, both ex- growth until the mid-sixties and its
.the reasons why this failure of the decline may have been responsible for
pressed in ,terms of constant prices.
In the following years, 1964-65 - the stagnation thereafter. It does not,
public sector restrained industrial
197.3-74, these rates dropped to 0.7 per however, follow that public invest-
growth. Reading between the lines,
one can discern an implicit view that cent and 2.0 per cent respectively ment by itself would do the trick
large net inflows of foreign aid until (Patnaik and Rao, p 126). As a result, .now, simply because the nature of the
1965 sustained high levels of public basic 'inputs manufactured in the problem is different. Let me elabo-
investment, which, in turn, had com- public sector became scarce, while rate. In the early stages of industria-
plementarities with private invest- the demand for several outouts manu- lisation, outlets for Dublic invest-
ment. Problems arose once the sour- factured in the private sector tapered ment posed no 'problem and resour-
ces of aid began to dry up, ultimate- toff. In this manner the deceleration ces were used to develop basic. in-
ly leading to stagnation. in investment led to a deceleration in dlustries. But, at the present juncture,
Such analysis is open to criticism industrial growth. The authors are the avenues for public investment in
on two counts. First, it assumes that careful to tie up the loose ends in the industrial sector are not unlimit-
aid supports investment alone and the argument. They explain that the ed. There already exist substantial
not, even in part, consumption. As a level of investment stagnated primari- underutilised capacities in the capital-
matter of fact, substantial aid inflows ly because the government failed to goods and intermediate-goods indus-
in the period 1955-65 might have pro- mobilise' resources for the public sec- tries. More public investment al6ng
vided the government with a soft op- tor. On the other hand, the private the same lines would only create fur-
sector, which appropriated the incre- ther excess capacity and* compound
tion, enabling it to avoid mobilising

1271

This content downloaded from 202.41.10.5 on Mon, 06 May 2019 12:43:26 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
ECONOMIC AND POLITICAL WEEKLY Special Number August 1978

difficulties, unless there is a growth the industrial sector, Prima facie, Given the fact of presistent quasi-
in the final goods sector which ab- demand factors might appear some- stagnation, which has been with as for
sorbs these capacities. In other words, what unusual, even Keynesian, as an a decade, we can take the argument
the supply of investible resources in explanation of low levels of industrial further. Upto, a point, it is possible to
the hands of the government is not output in an economy such as India, bring abolit rapid industrialisation
the only constraint on public invest- but they might well be very signifi- through import replacement in the
cant at
ment. A demand for such invgstment the present stage of develop- consumer goods sector and through
is as crucial; for public investment ment. investment in the creation of a capital-
is not something autonomous which Given the overwhelming importance and interimediate-goods sector. Ulti-
can be stepped -up irrespective of ap- of the agricultural sector, private con- miiately, however, the pace of industria
propriate outletW, nor can it create its sumer expenditure obviously depends, lisation can only be sustained if
own demand. It is worth stressing, there
to a large extent, on farm incomes. It is a growth in the domestic mar-
however, that the compqsition of pub- follows that slow growth in agricul- ket, because the production capacities
lic investment doeg provide the gov- ture could reitrain the dem'nd for created in the investment goods sec-
ernment with a policy variable in so far mantifactured goods. and, consequent- tor must be absorbed by final consu-
as it determines the extent of direct ly, hold back industrial expansion. mer demand. But, in a market economy
and indirect employment creation This point is stressed by Rai (1976), where the distribution of income is un-
which, in turn, would determine the who notes that regions characterised equal, the demand base might be very
growth in consumer demand. Hence, by moderately high and stable rates narrow in terms of population spread.
the investment-mix iii the public sec- of agricultural growth have also ex- That was and, indeed, is the case in
tor would 'matter as much as the rate
perienced high growth rates in in)dus- India. For the year 1964-65, using Na-
of investment. try.13 Looking at aggregate demand, tional Sample Survey data, it has been
To recapitulate, it would appear however, might be 91ightly mnislead- estima-ted that, in the rural sector, the
ing, and it is important to consider richest 10; per cent of the population.
that the best of the hypothesis about
sluggish industrial growth, outlined it in the context of income distribu- was responsible for 32.2 per cent of

so far, are partial and somewhat in- tion. The reason is simple. In an eco- the total consumption of industrial

complete. If this was not the case, nomy where the bulk of the consump- goods, whereas the poorest 50 per cent
tion, , production and investment accounted for only 22 per cent of the
starrnation should have disappeared by
now. After all: there have been no decisions are made through the mar- total. Consumption inequalities were
ket mechanism, it is income distri- even more pronounced in the urban
exogenous shocks since fhe oil crisis
in 1973; licensing, controls and, trade bution which determines the pattern sector, where' the top decile pur-
policies have all been liberalised; the of consumer expenditure as well as chased 39.3 per cent of the industrial
demand and, hence, the composition goods and the bottom five deciles
constraints imposed by agricultural
production have been significantly re- of industrial output. absorbed just'19.9 per cent of the to-
The Bagchi (1970) thesis, which tal.14
laxed by a succession of good mon-
soons; the limit on public investment derives from this basic proposition, is Clearly, a large proportion of the
is not as rigid any more, what with as follows. The unequal income distri- demand for industrial products origi-

the existing reserves of food and bution (that exists) is reinforced by nates from a narrow segment of the

foreign exchange. Yet, there is little the process of growth for it is, the population. However, manufactured

evidence of sustained industrial growth private sector which owns the n'ieans goods sold to the relatively few rich

on the horizon. Thus it is imnperative of production and, as such, appro- can use up only so Much, and no more
that we probe further and work to, priates the increments in, income. The bf the capacity in the intermediate-
wards a coherent and unified hypo- government is unable to exercise and capital-goods sector. Only a' broad-
thesis. effective control over the allocation based demand for mass-consumption
of resources between: (a) consump- goods can lead to a full utilisation of
tion and saving - as reflected in the capacity (and generate sustainable in-
IV
creases In' output), but that in turn
failurp to mobilise' domestic resour-
Income Distribution and the ces for investment; and (b) 'essential' requires incomes for the poor. Thus
Demand Factor and 'non-essential' consumption -- as anl unequal income distribution, operat
It is my contention that a satis- revealed by the excessive importance ing through the demand factors, might
factory explanation of stagnation of luxury goods in industrial' produc- well restrict the prospects of sustain-
cannot afford to ignore the relation- tion. Therefore, it is not possible for ed industrial growth. At an aside, let
ship between income distribution, the the government to maintain a high me stress that one does not have to
demand factor and industrial growth. rate of investment irrespective of the be an urnderconsumptionist to hold
So far, relatively little attention has unequal income distributibn and the this view. What has just been describ-
been paid to this aspect of the prob- demand pattern generated by it. In ed is not uncommon to crises in
lem. The only exceptions are a paper this analysis, Bagchi considered the capitalist economies. From time to
by Bagchi (1970), parts of a recent period 1951-68, towards the end time, it ig possible that inadequate de-
book by Mitra (1977) and, to some of which the slowdown in growth mand might constrain growth. While
extent, an article by Raj (1976). In wvas just about discernible. The pri- higher wages *for workers might im-
this section, therefore, I shall attempt mary object of his paper was to -high- prove the Situation, they would lead to
to sketch a preliminary ' hypothesis light the problems which arose in the a squeeze on profits and investment.
which concentrates attention on con- execution of the Mahalanobis' strate- In other words, solving o;ne problem
sumer demand and income distribution gy, and to pinpoint the reasons for exacerbates the other.
as possible factors underlying the- its failure to generate a balanced and The hypothesis outlined above can
persistent sluggishness of gr owth in sustained industrial growth. only be teZsted through careful empiri-

1273

This content downloaded from 202.41.10.5 on Mon, 06 May 2019 12:43:26 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
ECONOMIC AND 'POLITICAL WEEKLY Special Number August 1978

cal work and further research. Of goods industries were the only outlet, economy poised for a period of un-
course, the assimilation - of direct, apart from speculation, trade and con- interrupted growth, which represents
quantitative evidence on the relation- struction. The point relates clearly to a break from industrial stagnation?
ship between income distribution and the urban industrial bourgeoisie and Probably not. While overt healthy sign.
industrial growth might turn out to be the large affluent farmers.' In this con-provide policy markers with con-
an elusive pursuit. Indeed, for this text, however, the rich peasantry in the siderabJe room for manoeuvre, and
particular issue, one might have to countryside remains a puzzle, for it isthtere exists a potential industrial
rely on indirect evidence. But even unlikely that their consumption of capitalism in India today faces pro-
that would require another paper: a basic industrial goods reached satura- blems that have become familiar in the
task we shall set aside for the futuire. tion point so quickly. past decade. Indeed, the nature of the
For the present, it is sufficient that the crisis has not changed very much in
Available evidence on inter-sectoral
hypothesis is plausible and, green the last two years.
resource. flows reveals some interesting
available information, cannot be re- None of the recent occurrences have
trends in demands. On the basis of
jected out of hand. The recent work data drawn Ifrom the NSS, Sau (1974)created incomes for the poor, either
o*f Ashok Mitra posits a mechanism has shown that the percentage of per in the urban sector or in the rural
through which a worsening income capita consumer expenditure spent on sector. Thus there is no new demand
distribution might have retarded indu- industrial goods declined over the for manufactured wage goods which
strialisation in India. A statistical period 1952-53 - 1964-65, rather could sustain industrial growth. Con-
analysis by Ranjit Sau, though some- sharply in rural India but less markedly sider, for a moment, the rural poor.
what out of date, provides limited in the urban sector. More important,Successive
he bumper harvests might have
evidence in support. -The persistent found that the decline was far more increased incomes in the agricultural
sluggishness of industrial growth, in a pronounced in the case of the poorer sector. But whose incomes? There can
situation otherwise characterised by sections of the population, particularly be little doubt that much of the bene-
plenty, further points to income distri- the bottom five deciles. From these fit has accrued to large landowners and
bution and the demand factors as im- findings, Sau concludes that the mar- rich peasants; not to the rural poor.
portant elements in a complete ex- ket for industrial consumption goods Even in the heyday of the green re-
planation of stagnation. was shrinking over the years, which is,volution, therefore, stagnation in the
It has been argued by Mitra (1977) in a sense, correct. But it is worth industrial sector was not transformed
that the redistribution of income noting that these trends did not dis-into growth. As for the urban 'poor,
attempted in the country via the rupt the process of industrialisation. among whom it is possible to identify
nmanipulation of l relative prices in Indeed, this was also a period of rapidthe industrial working class, the situa-
favour of agriculture and against indu- industrial growth. One can only pre- tion probably deteriorated during the
stry is a major factor responsible for sume that the industrial expansion Emergency regime. A- stringent in-
the deceleration in industrial growth occurred in spite of the constraints comes policy coupled with the' com-
since the mid-sixties.15 He suggests imposed by income distribution and pulsory deposit scheme and the legisla-
that: "the shifting terms of trade have consumer demand;. I shall return to tion on bonus payments effectively
been instrumental in eroding the level this issue towards the end of the squeezed the real income of this group.
of real incomes of the majority of the essay. While the government has done al-
population in both urban areas and From, our viewpoint, it would be far most nothing towards raising the ' in-
the countryside". The causation is more interesting to examine the chang-comes of the poor, a large number of
straightforward enough. An increase in ing pattern of consumer expenditure recent policies have been directed to-
foodgrain prices, which accompanied and the trends in demand during the wards stimulating consumption of the
the change in inter-sectoral relative period 1965-75. While such an exercise higher income groups and encouraging
prices, squeezed the non-food expendi- is not possible here, a rough calcula- investment in the private corporate
ture of the urban as well as the rural tion from the CSO national accounts sector. The policies introduced to
poor, because there was no corre- statistics does suggest that an increase meet these objectives are reduction
sponding increase in their incomes and in relative food prices did squeeze the of indirect taxes on luxury goods, a
food remained a preponderant item, in demand for manufactured goods after substantial cut back in income taxes
their budget."6 After a time, higher 1965. In -terms of current prices, the payable by the rich, 'a delicensing of
prices of agricultural commodities, proportion of private final consumption indusitries, and an open door policy
operating through an escalation of raw expenditure in the economy devoted to towards multinational corporations.
material and wage costs, led to an cereals and cereal substitutes rose from However, the response of the economy
across the board increase in industrial 27.4 per cent in 1965-66 to 32.7 per has been slow and investment in the
prices, so that the demand for manu- cent in 1974-75, whereas the propor- industrial sector has not revived. Con-
factured products was squeezed fur- tion spend on industrial. goods fell sequently, the government is rather
ther. The end result was that the de- from 23.1 per cent to 19.3 per cent.'7 puzzled by the fact that investment
mand for mass consumer goods in the The present dilemma - of the Indian has failed to pick up in spite of poli-
economy levelled off. economy, more than anything else, cies designed to remove all possible
In principle, the industrial sector highlights the importance of the de- constraints and to create an environ-
could have been compensated for this mand factor in industrial performance. ment conducive to industrial growth.'8
loss by an expansion in demand on There have been three successive bum- But the static level of investxnent is
part of the rich, who appropriated the per barvests, the stockpile of food is not surprising in the context of our
bulk of the growth in income. But estimated at 18 milfion tons, and hypothesis. After all, an increased pro-
this did not happen because their foreign exchange reserves stand at an duction of consumer goods destined
avenues for further consumption were unprecedented level of Rs 4,500 crores. for the richer sections of the popula-
limited. For them, luxury consumer Where does all this point to? Is the tion can utilise th'e existing 'produc-

1275

This content downloaded from 202.41.10.5 on Mon, 06 May 2019 12:43:26 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Special Number August 1978 ECONOMIC AND POLITICAL WEEKLY

tion capacities only to a limited ex- at the expense of the rest of the domestic capitalists could not have on
tent; it cannot bring about a sustained population. It would mean a rupture of their own (Chattopadhyay, 1970). At
increase in industrial output. the ruling. class alliance and a dumping the same time, an over increasing level
The argument presented so far has of the rural oligarchy somewhere along of public expenditure gave rise to a
one important lacuna; it also has an the line. Recent policies such as the demand for outputs manufactured in
underconsumptionist flavour that may subsidy on fertilisers, priority in pub- the corporate sector. As an aside, it is
not appeal to some. Critics might well lic investment to irrigation, and high worth noting that this modus operandi
ask if it is. possible for India to circum- procurement prices all point to the of fostering X industrialisation was not
vent the demand problem at home and continued existence of the rural oli- different. from the tactics of state
repea.t the Brazilian experience of garchy as a potent force in the Indian capitalism elsewhere in the world,
'successful' capitalist development. pclity.19 Unless there is a change in though it might have been at a later
Given an underutilised intermediate- the class character of the Indian State, stage in history. But that was not all.
and capital-goods sector, a declining and the government opts squarely for The plolicies of import substitution, im-
r'ate of investment, and a luxury goods industrial capitalists, the Brazilian plemented through protection, reinforc-
sector that has run out of steam, the model is unlikely to materialise in the ed the demand stimulus. Local
Brazilian model must appear as a stubcontinent.
capitalists were not only guaranteed
rather attractive option to policy ma- The moral of the story, if one emer- existing markets but were also ensur-
kers. Such a path of development ges, is that in an economy such as ed a future in so far as the excess de-
inter alia, has three essential ingredi- India, where the domestic market is mand attributable to import restric-
ents: (a) external markets - which overwhelmingly important, steady and tions would continue to provide mar-
are necessary to get around the domes- continuous industrial growth requires kets, at least in the medium-term.
tic vdemand bottleneck; (b) foreign a broad-based and increasing mass Given this background, the sequence of
cap-ital - which provides resources as consumer demand. In a fundamental industrial development is hardly sur-.
well as technology; and (c) a domin- sense, therefore, sustained industriali- prising. In the years following Inde-
ant class of industrial canitalists - in satiol can only be based on a growth pendence, infrastructural developments
whose interest state power is exercis- Of th6 internal market.
and import substitution in the
ed; their consumption forms the basis consumer goods sector stimulated in-
of the home market Iand they also v dustrial pro_duction. Thereafter, the
provide the savings for investment. Towards a Possible Hypothesis high rate of industrial growth in the
Consider each in turn.
The preceding discussion sought to late 1950s and early 1960s was sus-
Export led growth is a curiously focus attention on income distribution tained by investment, on the part of
rnaive prescription for the problems and the demand factor simply to com- the government, in the capital goods
faced by the Indian economy, and is for the relative neglect in the sector and in basic intermediate goods
pensate
tiot a feasible proposition. The. reasons existing Jiteraflure. The intention was industries. During this phase of rapid
underlying my view have been develop- not to minirmise the importance of development, a reasonable rate of ex-
ed, at length, elsewhere (Nayyar, 1976). other factors. Indeed,' no explanation pansion in agricultural output ensur-
Suffice it to say that the problem forofthe uneven pace of industrial ed the supply of food - the basic
Indian exports is a problem of produc- development, in the Indian context, viage good - and raw materials,
tion. In the ultimate analysis, exports can be logically complete without re- thereby allowing industrialisation to
can be increased on a sustainable ference to both public investment and be sustained at a moderate pace which
basis only if there is a growth inthe real
agricultural sector. Therefore, it Was, against the back-drop of colonial
national income. Therefore, export
would be useful to recapitulate and history, unprecedented. However, it
performance is likely to be determin-
draw together the strands of the should be stressed that the growth in
ed by economic growth rather than the
different arguments outlined so far. industrial production was more direct-
other way round. - There is also very
Such an approach, to the extent it ly attributable to public investment
little evidence to suggest that foreign
provides a macro-economic view of the
and protection.
capital would flow into India in large
growth process, should, hopefully, In retrospect, the negative impact of
amounts. This is because transnational
facilitate our understanding of the agricultural performance on industrial
corporations are extremely cautiousproblem and might even suggest policy development turned out to be far
about their decision to relocate prescriptions.
pro- Towards this end, I more significant. Starting' around the
duction where it affects global opera-
shall attempt to formulate a unified, mid-sixties, growth in the agricultural
tions, as in export-oriented manufactur-
albeit tentative, "hypothesis about the sector began to slow down, for reasons
ing. The same international firms are
factors responsible for the transition that have been discussed at- length in
far less worried about choosing sites
from rapid industrial growth to the the literature. Food prices began to
for'-a horizontal spread, and setting up
point of quasi-stagnation, and for the rise and raw materials became scarce,
production units in India to cater for
persistent sluggishness of growth in the so that the indirect support provided
local markets. The essential point is
irndustrial sector since the mid-sixties. by agriculture to industrialisation di-
that the internationalisation of produc-
The impressive expansion of indu- minished markedly. As the inter-sec-
tion is limited to a finite number of
strial out,put in the period 1950-65 can toral terms of trade shifted in favour
countries, of which Brazil is one, but
be explained as follows. Public invest- of the agricultural sector, even the re-
it will be long time before it spreads
ment, in Iarge doses, created an infra- duced support was now available to
to India. In the Indian context, how-
structure and set up intermediate the industrial sector on less favour-
ever, the most important proble'm is
goods industries, so as to ensure a able terms. Difficulties were com-
the difficulties that will arise in the
supply of inputs to the private sector. pounded by the fact that the principal
fOstering of an urban industrial elite
In doing so, it carried out a task the sources of industrial growth in the
1276

This content downloaded from 202.41.10.5 on Mon, 06 May 2019 12:43:26 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
ECONOMIC AND POLITICAL WEEKLY Special Number August 1978

first phase also waned in their impact. lution: limited because it could use be stepped up, it would not suffice un-
There was a dramatic deceleration in only so much and no more of the ca- less adequate attention is paid to the
the growth of real public expenditure pacity in the capital- and intermedi- composition of investment, so that it
and investment.20 The proximate cau- ate-goods sector; temporary because leads to employment creation and in-
ses of this -occurrence might appear to the demand for luxury goods on the comes for the poor, if not directly at
lie in the wars which diverted invest- part of a small fraction of the popula- least as a s*econd-order effect.
ment to unproductive uses, or the suc- tion is likely to reach saturation point. Let me conclude. For sustained in-
cessive droughts of the mid-sixties The alternative of export led growth, dustrial growth, it is essential not only
which generated unforeseen consump- we have noted earlier, is not feasible to mobilise savings of the rich, for in-
tion needs, but, in the ultimate analy- in the Indian case. Therefore, the vestment but also to channel incre-
sis, it was a direct eonsequence of the utilisation of excess capacity and sus- ments in income to the poor which, in
government's failure to mobilise do- tained industrial growth both require turn, would generate a broad-based de-
mestic resources. a demand for mass consumption goods. mand for industrial goods. Unless these
A question immediately springs to In this context, it is worth stressing conditions are satisfied, stagnation will
mind: is it possible that accelerated that creating incomes for the poor is only reappear after a time. Stepping up
investment in the private corporate sec- not a simple matter of redistribution of public investment, supported by an
tor could have sustained growth? In through taxes and subsidies, for in a inflow of foreign resources, can only be
the circumstances, the answer is a de- market economy such as India the dis- a temporary and partial solution. It
finite no. In the first place, the aom- tribution of incomes is closely related cannot generate a process of sustained
plementarities between public and pri- to, and cannot be divorced fromr, industrialisation in India.
vate investment in India have always ownership of the means of production. [Some of the ideas developed in this
been rather important. Moreover, The -demand factor needs to be essay were first outlined in a note pre-
the market stimulus provided by singled out not only because it has pared for an informal discussion group
at University College, London, in Janu-
import substitution also disappear- received little attention so far, but also
ary 1977, and a prelimfinary version of
ed. It was, almost by defi- because it does explain, in - part, the the paper was presented to a seminar
nition, a transient stimulus which present crisis in the economy and the on 'Industrialisation in India' at the
could last only so long as the existing persistent sluggishness of industrial Centre for Studies in Social Sciences,
Calcutta, in December 1977. I would
markets were uncaptured and excess growth. Moreover, it has obvious po-
like to thank the participants in both
demand remained. Once these oppor- licy implications. Successive bumper places for their critical comments and
tunities were taken up, a growth of haryests, the unprecedented stockpile searching questions, which enabled me
the domestic market was essential. of food and massive foreign exchange to revise the paper for publication.]
ENve,n after import substitution ranreserves
out have, at least for the time
Notes
of steam, for a while, investment being, removed the supply constraints.
I Statements originating in official
could be sustained by expansion in Yet there is little evidence of a return
sources provide confirmation. For
the capital goods sector and in basic to the earlier trend rate or of sustained instance, the government's Econo-
industries, as indeed it was during industrial growth. Why? Inter alia, mic Survey for 1975-76 stressed the
1960-65. But it was not possible to it is because the lack of a mass do- fact that the number of man-days
ccntinue with the creation of capaci- mestic demand for industrial goods lost through industrial disputes fell
from 6 million in July-September
ties in these sectors, for ultimately, has surfaced as a problem.
1974 to 1.5 million in July-Septem.-
even their existence depends upon de- Given the political aspects of the ber 1975. It also emphasised the
mand in the final goods sector. situation, a radical redistribution of progressive decline in work time
It would be perfectly legitimaite to income might be unattainable. What lost since July 1975 as a possible
ask why industrial growth came up factor underlving the spurt in in-
about stepping upo the rate of invest-
dustrial output.
against the demand barrier since 1965 ment which is frequently thought of 2 It has been estimated that net
and not earlier for, after all, income as a possible solution? Such a strategy capital formation in the private in-
distribution was unequal right a,t the is clearly difficult in the case of pri- dustrial sector during 1976-77 was'
start, so that the majority of the Indian Rs 537 crores as compared to
vate investment, because investment
Rs 848 crores in 1975-76; see The
population was not in the market for decisions in the corporate industrial
Economic Times, New Delhi, Janu-
industrial products.21 The answer is sector follow signals provided by the ary 1, 1978, p 1. These figures, it
relatively straightforward. Irrespectivemarket mechanism; hence, they de- is worth noting, are in terms of
of the income distribution at the time, pend on the state of demand, the pat- current prices.
there was an assured domestic market, tern of consumer expenditure and, 3 For a careful and convincing ex-
position of this view, see Patnaik
the size of which was determined by ultimately, the existing income distri- and Rao (1977).
the level of imports and the state of bution. On the other hand, in terms 4 The share of manufacturing in
excess demand for importables. This of policy, public investment does pro- total industrial production, how-
guaranteed source of demand was ex- ever, d' lined a little over time,
vide some room for manoeuvre. In
from 88.85 per cent in 1956 to
hausted once import substitution in the long run, however, the rate of 84.91 per cent in 1960 and 81.08
consumer goods was virtually comple- public investment itself depends on per cent in 1970.
te, and the capacities created in the the ability of the government to 5' The latest census of .,small scale
capital-goods and intermediate-goods mobilise domestic resources, for other- irKiustries estimates the gross value
transcended the prevalent needs of the of their output at Rs 2,603 crores
wise a serious threat of inflation re-
in 1972 (Government of India, 1977,
final goods sector. The demand for mains; the reserves of food and foreignp 2). Unfortunately, data for the
industrial goods generated by the elite
exchange do not entirely solve this pro-corresponding period are not avail-
did, to some extent, support the pro- blem once speculation enters the pic- able in the case of factory sector
cess of growth in the 1960s, but it because the usual annual survey of
ture. What is more, even if the rate of
industries was not carried out in
was only a limited and temporary so- investment in the pulblic sector could 1972. But twe do know that in

L277

This content downloaded from 202.41.10.5 on Mon, 06 May 2019 12:43:26 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Special Number August 1978 ECONOMIC AND POLITICAL WEEKLY

1971-72 the gross value of output 16 Cf Patnaik (1972). it is assumed,


in the registered manufacturing Government of India (1977): "Report
of course, that the absolute level
units was Rs 14,980 crores (Gov-
on the Census of Small Scale Indus-
of food consumption is maintain- trial Units", New Delhi, Development
ernment of India, 1976, p 103). ed; in fact, it might also be cut
Thus, the share of the small scale Commissioner, Small Scale Industries.
back if the erosion of real incomes
sector in the gross value of total is large enough. Mitra, A (1977): "Terms of Trade and
industrial output works out at Class Relations", London, Frank Cass.
17 The proportion devoted to food
14.8 per cent. While this figure Nayyar, D (1976): "India's Exports and
(excluding edible oils, sugar and
might not be entirely accurate, it Export Policies in the 1960s", Lon-
salt which are also manufactures)
is a reasonable approximation. don, Cambridge University Press.
increased, at the same time, from
Patnaik, P (1972): "Disproportionality
51.3 per cent to 55.2 per cent. These
6 See, for example, Economic Sur- Crisis and Cyclical Growth", Econo-
vey, 1968-69, Government of India,percentages have been computed mic and Political Weekly, Annual
New Delhi, pp 10-11. For a critical from the data in Government of Number, February, pp 329-36.
evaluation of this view, see Bagchi India (1976), pp 26-27. In our cal- Patnaik, P and Rao, S K (1977): "1975-
(1970) pp 184-187. culation, the category of industrial 76: Beginning of the End of Stagna-
goods includes pan, tobacco, into- tion?", Social Scientist, January-Fe-
7 Bhagwati and Desai (1970, p 4919) xicants, clothing, footwear,, fuel, bruary, pp 120-38.
are more elaborate in discussion power, furniture, furnishings, Raj, K N (1 976) : "Growth and Stag-
but less definite in conclusion. household equipment and miscel- natioin in Indian Industrial Develop-
Their final chapter begins as fol- laneous goods.
merit", Economic and Political Week-
lows: "It seems to us manifest, 18 See, for example, a recent state- ly. November 26, pp 1987-89.
even though policy analysis in eco- ment by H M Patel, the Finance 223-36.
nomic questions can rarely be' as Minister: "We have in fact re- Sau, R (1974): "Some Aspects of Inter-
definitive as in the natural scien- moved all constraints on invest- Sectoral Resource Flows", Economic
ces, that Indian planning for in- ment. We have not put any fresh and Political Weekly, Special Num-
dustrialisation suffered from exces- htirdles to investment. If it does ber, August, pp 1277-84.
sive afttention to targets down to not pick up, the reasons are some- Srinivasan, T N (1977): "Constraints on
product level, and a, wasteful phy- what deeper to seek. I frankly con- Growth and Policy Options: A Com-
sical approach to setting and im- fess I have not found an answer to ment". Economic and Political Week-
plementation thereof, along with a my satisfaction", The Times of ly. November 26, pp 1987.89.
generally inefficient framework of
eco;nomic policies designed to re- India, New Delhi, February 10, Sritiivasan, T N and Narayana, N S S
gulate . the growth of industrialisa-
1978, p 1. (1 977): "Economic Performance
tion." 19 For a lucid discussion on the poli- since the Third Plan and Its Impli-
tical power of the rural oligarchy cations for Policy", Economic and
8 See, for instance, Bhagwati and Sri- Political Weekly, Annual Number
and its implications for economic
nivasan (1975), Ch 13; also; p175. February, pp 225-39.
development in India, see Mitra
9 See Srinivasan (1977) and the sub- (1977). Vaidyanathan, A (1977): "Constraints
sequent interchange with Vaidya- on Growth and Policy Options"
20 The factors responsible for the re-
nathan (1977) in Economic and duction in public expenditure are
Economic and Political Weekly,
Political Weekly. September 17, pp 1643-50 and De-
discussed in Patnaik (1972). cember 17, pp 2105-9.
10 For evidence on this point, see Raj 21 Even in 1952-53, the richest 10 per
(1976) and Srinivasan and Nara- cent of the population was respon-
yana (1977). sible fot 32.7 per cent of the total
1.1 Cf Economic Survey, 1976-77, consumption of industrial goods in
Lipton Tea (India)
Government of India, New Delhi, the rural sector and 36.8 per cent
1977, p 44. of the total in the urban sector.
LIPTON TEA (INDIA), incorporated
12 Accoirding to Patnaik and Rao The share of the poorest 50 per
in WAest Bengal recently to acquire, as
cent was 23.6 per cent and 19.7
(1977), the danger of inflation a going concern, the Lipton group of
per cent respectively; cf Sau
arises once we allow for specula- (1974).
tion. Corresponding to the 18 mil- companies in India, will dilute its for-
lion tons of food-stocks and eign shareholding some time in the last
Rs 3,800 croTres of foreign exchange References quarter of 1978 through fresh issue of
reserves; there is an en&rmous
amount of liquidity in the eco- Bagchi, A 4K (1970): "Long-Term Con-equity shares of Rs 10 each at par annd
nomy. In this context, deficit fin- straints on India's Industrial Growth, an offer for sale by Unilever to the
ancing might generate inflationary 1951-1968", in E A G Robinson and Indian public. The new Indian company
expectations which, in turn, might M Kidron (eds) "Economic Develop-
will thus acquire the undertakings of
induce people holding these liquid ment in South Asia", London, Mac-
resources to switch from money in- millan. Lipton (India), Caampbell and Company
to commodities, thereby pushing Bhagwati, J and Desai, P (1970): "In- (South India), assets and liabilities of
up, prices. dia : Planning for Industrialisation", the Indian branch of Lipton. It also
London, Oxford University Press.
13 Apart from the demand factor, Raj proposes to acquire, at par. all the
also specifies other linkages bet- Bhagwati, I and Srinivasan, T N (1975):
"Foreign Trade Regimes and Econo- shares in the capital of Heath and Com-
ween agricultural and industrial
growth. For an interesting, but mic Development: India", New York, pany (Calcutta) and Brindavan Proper-
different, analysis of how a shQrt- National Bureau of Economic Re- ties. The company will have an issued
search.
age of agricultural wage 'goods and subscribed share capital of Rs 3.75
would affect the demand for indus- Chakravarty, S (1974): "Reflections on
the Growth Process in the Indian crores. After dilution, Unilever- will be
trial goods, see Patnaik (1972).
Economy", Hyderabad, Administra- its sole non-resident shareholder. The
14 Cf Sau (1974); the richest 20' per tive Staff College of India. Lipton group in India has an annual
cent accounted for 48.4 per cent of Chattopadhyay, P (1970): "State Capi-
talism in India", Monthly Review, tumover of about Rs 75 crores and
the total consumption of industrial
goods in rural India, and 55 per March. has a good past -record of profits. Lipton
cent of the- same in urban India. Government of India (1976): "Na- teas now account for 30 per cent of
tional Accounts Statistics: 1960-61 packeted teas sold in India. The com.
15 For a detailed and succinct exposi- - 1974-75", New Delhi, Central
tion of the argument, see- Mitra Statistical O)rganisation, Ministry panyofhas a significant export business,
(1977), Chapter 10, pp 141-169. Planning. too, in both bulk and packet teas.

1278

This content downloaded from 202.41.10.5 on Mon, 06 May 2019 12:43:26 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms

Anda mungkin juga menyukai