Anda di halaman 1dari 13

14 CREATIVITY AND INNOVATION MANAGEMENT

Innovation Intermediaries: Why


Internet Marketplaces for Technology
Have Not Yet Met the Expectations
Ulrich Lichtenthaler and Holger Ernst

A few years ago, internet marketplaces for technology, e.g., yet2.com, received great attention.
In the light of open innovation processes, it was assumed that they could be an appropriate
means to overcome the imperfections in the markets for technology. Little is known about the
performance of these innovation intermediaries, and very limited information is provided by
the firms that run the marketplaces. Therefore, we have interviewed intellectual property and
technology managers in 25 medium-sized and large industrial companies, who represent the
potential licensees and licensors in the internet exchanges. The results show relatively limited
success rates of internet marketplaces regarding the number of technology transactions that
have been initiated, particularly in comparison with the hopes that had initially been placed
in these tools. Moreover, important problems and recent trends in these web-enabled ex-
changes are identified, and propositions are developed regarding major consequences for
initiating and managing technology transactions.

Introduction the internet could help firms to overcome


these market imperfections. The examples of

I n recent years, the markets for technology


have received great attention from research-
ers and practitioners (Guilhon, 2001; Gans &
successful pioneering companies, e.g., IBM,
which have realized great benefits from
technology licensing, further increased the
Stern, 2003). In these markets, firms acquire great hopes (Kline, 2003; Chesbrough,
and commercialize technological knowledge to 2007). In particular, internet marketplaces
complement and capitalize on their technology for technology were expected to encourage
portfolios (Clarke & Rollo, 2001; de Weerd- inter-organizational technology transactions. A
Nederhof & Fisscher, 2003). In contrast to variety of companies, which were often backed
the markets for most products and services, by venture capital, have emerged to facilitate
the markets for technology have remained technology trade through internet platforms.
imperfect (Cesaroni, 2004; Lichtenthaler & Prominent examples are yet2.com, NineSigma,
Ernst, 2007). As technological knowledge is InnoCentive, and the Patent & Licenses
usually commercialized by selling products Exchange (Bauman, 2000; Huston & Sakkab,
and services, the markets for technology are 2006). While their service offerings differ, most
not common (Gans & Stern, 2003; Van Looy, of these firms try to become the central web-
Martens & Debackere, 2005). At the same time, enabled marketplace for trading technological
there are many imperfections in these markets, knowledge (Bauman, 2000; Chesbrough, 2006).
which result in high transaction costs (Arora, Because of these great hopes, there is now –
Fosfuri & Gambardella, 2001; Davis & Harri- several years later – also great interest in the
son, 2001). These two phenomena are mutually performance of these marketplaces (Howells,
dependent because a reduction of the imperfec- 2006; Huston & Sakkab, 2006). Very little is
tions would lead to a stronger use of the tech- known about their success regarding the
nology markets, which would reduce some of number of technology transactions that have
their deficiencies (Lichtenthaler, 2007). been initiated, and hardly any information is
Along with the ‘new economy’ hype, many distributed by the firms that run the market-
researchers and practitioners assumed that places. Therefore, we have asked the potential

Volume 17 Number 1 2008 © 2008 The Authors


doi:10.1111/j.1467-8691.2007.00461.x Journal compilation © 2008 Blackwell Publishing
INNOVATION INTERMEDIARIES 15

beneficiaries of these marketplaces about their ture on systems and networks of innovation,
experiences. We have interviewed intellec- and (4) research into service organizations
tual property and technology managers of (Howells, 2006). The first line of research has
technology-intensive companies, who repre- identified the role of intermediaries in iden-
sent the potential licensees and licensors tifying partners, helping package technology,
in these markets. Accordingly, this article selecting suppliers and providing support in
addresses the following central questions. deal making (Watkins & Horley, 1986; Seaton &
What are the experiences of industrial firms Cordey-Hayes, 1993). The second stream has
regarding internet marketplaces for technol- addressed intermediaries as organizations,
ogy? Why have internet marketplaces for tech- whose key function is their brokering role in
nology not yet met the great expectations of the technology transfer process (Hargadon &
researchers and practitioners? The remainder Sutton, 1997; McEvily & Zaheer, 1999). The
of the paper is structured as follows. In the third line of research has underscored the role
next section, we provide a brief overview of of public and private intermediaries that help
previous research. Afterwards, the research companies to adapt specialized solutions to the
design is described. Subsequently, the results needs of individual user firms (Stankiewicz,
of the study are presented before highlighting 1995; Lynn, Reddy & Aram, 1996). The fourth
some recent trends in the field. On this basis, stream has highlighted the bridging roles that
we discuss theoretical and managerial impli- certain types of service firms play in innovation
cations and develop propositions regarding systems (Howells, 1999; Miles, 2000).
major consequences for initiating and manag- Regarding more general research into inter-
ing technology transactions. Finally, opportu- firm exchanges, transaction cost theory needs
nities for further research are presented. to be tailored to the specific characteristics
As such, this article offers several contribu- of the technology markets (Seely Brown &
tions. It is among the first empirical studies on Duguid, 1998). In particular, firms may influ-
internet marketplaces for technology to analyse ence their transaction costs in the medium to
their managerial implications. In the light of long term by developing dynamic capabili-
increasing interest in technology transactions ties of trading technology based on learning
(Rivette & Kline, 2000; Grant & Baden-Fuller, effects. The examples of successful pioneering
2004), it deepens our understanding of the dis- firms in out-licensing support this capability-
crepancies between a few successful pioneer- based view of outward technology transfer
ing firms in trading technology and many (Davis & Harrison, 2001; Kline, 2003). More-
others. Moreover, it contributes to overcom- over, the capability-based perspective has
ing the under-emphasis on empirical research received great attention in inward technology
into technology intermediaries (Spulber, 1999; transfer, above all in the literature on absorp-
Howells, 2006). Accordingly, this research tive capacity (Cohen & Levinthal, 1990; Zahra
deepens our understanding of managing & George, 2002). In conclusion, there are
technology transactions and realizing value various lines of research that have deepened
from technology in open innovation systems our understanding of intermediaries in the
(Gassmann, 2006; van der Meer, 2007). Finally, markets for technology, but the insights into
our findings have implications for emerging their roles are limited, especially regarding
themes in knowledge management, e.g., internet marketplaces for technology (Licht-
organizational boundaries (Arora, Fosfuri & enthaler, 2005; Howells, 2006).
Gambardella, 2001; Santos & Eisenhardt,
2005). These issues have been highlighted as
areas ripe for further study in recent reviews Research Design
of the literature on intermediaries (Howells,
2006), knowledge management (Argote, In the light of the limitations of previous
McEvily & Reagans, 2003), technology exploi- research and increasing technology trade, it is
tation (Lichtenthaler, 2005), and open innova- the goal of this study to gain insight into the
tion (West, Vanhaverbeke & Chesbrough, 2006). intermediating role of internet marketplaces
for technology. The study’s focus is on the
experiences of medium-sized and large indus-
Past Research trial companies whose main business is inter-
nal technology exploitation. Accordingly, these
Interest in the role of technology intermediar- firms focus on the application of technologies
ies has emerged from various fields over the in their own products and services (March,
past 20 years (Spulber, 1999; Chesbrough, 1991; Cesaroni, Di Minin & Piccaluga, 2005).
2006). These fields include: (1) literature on Thus, we have analysed the internet-based
technology transfer and diffusion, (2) research technology exchanges neither of start-up com-
into managing innovation processes, (3) litera- panies nor of firms that provide mainly R&D

© 2008 The Authors


Journal compilation © 2008 Blackwell Publishing Volume 17 Number 1 2008
16 CREATIVITY AND INNOVATION MANAGEMENT

services. Nearly all of the companies in the the questionnaire. Furthermore, additional
sample have at least considered or have documents, e.g., company-internal analyses of
already realized technology transactions as the licensing transactions and company-external
technology source and recipient. Therefore, all publications, were studied. Next, the memoing
firms could be analysed regarding potential process was followed to record patterns that
inward and outward technology transfer. the interviewer noted within and across cases
A thorough review of previous research has (Yin, 2003). Each interview was structured to
shown that technology trade through internet facilitate within-case as well as subsequent
marketplaces has not yet been examined in cross-case analyses (Miles & Huberman, 1994).
detail (Lichtenthaler, 2005; Howells, 2006). After these analyses, the implications that are
Accordingly, a qualitative research design was presented in this article were drawn.
chosen to respond to the need for deep under- In companies with a dedicated licensing
standing, local contextualization, and causal unit, this unit’s head was interviewed. In com-
inference (Miles & Huberman, 1994). Our dis- panies without a dedicated unit, we talked to
cussion of past research has demonstrated that the head of the corporate intellectual property
these needs apply to the analysis of firms’ department. In ten companies, a second person
experiences with internet marketplaces for from the R&D department, who is not directly
technology. Hence, the case study method was occupied with licensing, was interviewed. By
chosen because of the study’s exploratory drawing on the insights of this second person,
character. In the light of a highly complex a more detailed picture of a firm’s experiences
research object, the case study method allowed could be gained. Altogether, 35 persons were
for a flexible and comprehensive examination interviewed in 25 German and Swiss compa-
of the issues. The process of conducting case nies. The firms’ average R&D intensity is about
studies followed the suggestions that have 6 per cent. Seven of these firms are active in the
been given in seminal works on case study chemical/pharmaceutical industry; nine are
research (Eisenhardt, 1991; Yin, 2003; Eisen- active in the automotive/machinery industry;
hardt & Graebner, 2007). Thus, our approach and the other nine firms are active in the
was similar to the designs of case study-based semiconductors/electronics industry. With an
works that have been published recently in average of 8,457 employees and average rev-
leading journals (Schweizer, 2005). enues of €2,135 million, the companies in the
Through the focused selection of medium- sample are relatively large.
sized and large industrial companies, different We followed a sampling strategy in which
experiences with internet marketplaces could we sought variance regarding the topics analy-
be analysed (Miles & Huberman, 1994). Tech- sed in this study. In particular, the choice of
nology trade was studied at the organizational industries was influenced by prior research,
level and at the level of specific technology which reported different functions of technol-
transfer projects. By applying the firm-level ogy licensing in these industries (Grindley &
view, the overall experiences were analysed. Teece, 1997; Teece, 1998; Rivette & Kline, 2000).
By examining specific projects, the firms’ tech- As the purpose of the study was deepening
nology transfer processes were studied in the our understanding of internet marketplaces
context of a specific project. Only the simul- for technology, the sample was not selected
taneous analysis of the micro level of projects to ensure representation of the population of
and the macro level of corporate experiences all medium-sized and large industrial firms.
allowed for drawing implications for managing Instead, the sample was selected to include
technology trade (Miles & Huberman, 1994). sufficient variation to explore factors relating
Besides analysing firms from various indus- to the internet marketplaces. Despite participa-
tries, the sample comprises firms where tion being voluntary, the sample was not a self-
licensing plays different roles regarding its selected group of firms. As the following
importance, objectives and management. Thus, section shows, there was sufficient variance in
the experiences of these firms provided differ- the managerial approaches of firms to internet
ent perspectives on technology marketplaces. marketplaces for technology. This sampling
After five preliminary unstructured inter- process followed prior works in leading jour-
views, questionnaires were used as a basis for nals (e.g., Edmondson, Bohmer & Pisano,
semi-structured interviews in the final study. 2001).
This procedure ensured comparability and
ample opportunity for unobstructed narration.
The data collection process followed Yin
Results
(2003). During the interviews, the interviewer
Current Practice
took notes and typed them up each night.
All data were included in writing up of the All companies are well aware of the potential
cases, even when not specifically requested in benefits of internet marketplaces and have at

© 2008 The Authors


Volume 17 Number 1 2008 Journal compilation © 2008 Blackwell Publishing
INNOVATION INTERMEDIARIES 17

least studied the web pages of different service which sharply contrast the euphoria that
providers in detail. In various cases, however, existed several years ago. Nearly all firms that
no consideration had been given to actually have not actively tried to realize technology
putting technologies into the marketplaces deals are informed surprisingly well about
because the strategy of these firms focused the unsuccessful activities of other companies
exclusively on the application of technologies regarding the number of technology transac-
in their own products. Similarly, various com- tions that have been initiated through the mar-
panies did not have any interest in licensing in ketplaces. The limited success of these firms
technologies through these platforms because has been communicated through informal
of their focus on internal R&D. By contrast, inter-firm networks. On this basis, only two of
many firms have actively tried to use the mar- the 25 companies wanted to give the internet
ketplaces by offering technologies or search- marketplaces another chance in the short
ing in detail for interesting technologies. In to medium term by offering a considerable
general, the firms that addressed the internet portion of their technology portfolios on
marketplaces most actively are the firms that yet2.com and closely screening further
also carry out internal activities of initiating marketplaces. One firm even plans to assign
technology transactions more actively. a person exclusively to the co-ordination
For instance, most of the firms that offered of its technology offerings on yet2.com and
various technologies on the internet market- other internet marketplaces, particularly with
places also have a dedicated internal organiza- regard to an adequate preparation and docu-
tional unit that is directed towards managing mentation of the technologies. Regarding tech-
technology licensing activities. This finding nology acquisition, most companies still plan
points to the complementary character of to search the internet platforms or post a notice
internet marketplaces and a firm’s internal of a technology need when trying to identify
activities of identifying technology transfer potential technology sources in the future.
opportunities. Finally, these complementary However, these firms do not expect to realize
activities may result in a portfolio of inter- many licensing transactions by means of the
firm technology transactions that comprises marketplaces.
various contractual forms, e.g., licensing agree-
ments, strategic alliances and joint ventures.
Licensors’ Perspective
Some of these technology-based relations even
ended up in a transfer of parts of organiza- According to the industry experts, the most
tional units beyond the transfer of technolo- severe deficit of internet marketplaces is that
gical knowledge, i.e., acquisitions in inward the commercialization of technology through
technology transfer and spin-offs in outward these platforms constitutes a relatively unsys-
technology transfer. For example, one contact tematic approach because it does not add-
evolved into a strategic alliance that eventually ress specific technology customers. Instead,
resulted in the acquisition of a part of a rela- the firm’s intention to license technological
tively small firm by one of the large chemical knowledge is communicated very broadly.
firms in the sample. Furthermore, offering a technology through
In general, the success rate of relying on the internet is a relatively passive approach.
internet marketplaces for technology has been This offer merely constitutes an invitation
relatively low with regard to the number of to treat because the initiative for the actual
technology transactions that have been ini- technology transaction has to come from the
tiated, particularly in comparison with the potential licensee. An additional reason why a
hopes that had initially been placed in the mar- first inquiry has often not occurred is inherent
ketplaces. Many industrial firms have invested in the technologies that have been offered. In
substantial time and resources in preparing many cases, the source firms have put rela-
and documenting technologies for the internet tively unattractive technologies in the data-
exchanges and in searching for suitable tech- bases. The main aim behind these offers was
nologies. For instance, several firms have set the optimization of the technology portfolio by
up internal projects with participants from dif- externally leveraging technologies of relatively
ferent organizational units to decide on their limited value.
technology offerings. However, most compa- Accordingly, the success rate of commercial-
nies have not realized any technology transac- izing technology through these marketplaces
tion by means of web-enabled platforms. The measured by the number of technology trans-
maximum of transactions for a single company actions that have been initiated is relatively
has been one out-licensing agreement and one low. Thus, it is necessary to offer a substantial
in-licensing agreement. portion of the technology portfolio to arrive at
As a result, most industry experts have rela- a single technology transaction. However, this
tively reserved attitudes to these marketplaces, open approach is often impossible because of

© 2008 The Authors


Journal compilation © 2008 Blackwell Publishing Volume 17 Number 1 2008
18 CREATIVITY AND INNOVATION MANAGEMENT

the concerns of top management and high- In many cases, the focus of the internet
ranking R&D employees. While these reluc- exchanges is still on the technological fields
tant attitudes are partly based on rational of the websites’ founding members.
arguments following corporate strategy, they If a particular technology need exists, it may
are often complemented by irrational feelings therefore be easier to direct the resources for
of individuals, who are resistant to the idea of identifying potential technology sources to
transferring a firm’s technology assets. This other channels. Examples of more systematic
resistance is particularly strong if the technolo- approaches are patent analyses and a firm’s
gies are of relatively high value or close to a networks. These networks not only encompass
firm’s core technologies. Furthermore, offer- formal relationships with other firms, e.g.,
ing a large number of technologies requires strategic alliances, but also informal personal
substantial resources. A thorough presentation relationships, e.g., inter-firm contacts between
of the technologies is essential to generate technology or intellectual property experts.
interest from potential licensees. Because Furthermore, potential licensors may be
of these resource requirements, many firms observed in many cases as a part of regular
argue that the time needed to identify tech- technology intelligence processes. If no spe-
nology customers can be put to better using cific technology need exists, the search for
other – more proactive – commercialization technologies in internet marketplaces is a
channels. random approach with limited chances of ini-
This is particularly true in cases where a tiating a technology transaction. Because of
firm may describe possible applications of a increasing technology convergence, the tech-
technology in relative detail. If these ideas nology descriptions on the web pages often do
exist, potential licensees may be identified in a not include the specific application for which
more direct way by relying on the firm’s exist- the technology need exists. Thus, the identifi-
ing business relationships, i.e., buyers, suppli- cation of a technology still requires a creative
ers and competitors, or on its contacts in other element by matching the particular technology
industries through formal and informal net- with the application that the person who is
works. As a result, internet marketplaces cur- searching the marketplace has in mind. For
rently do not seem to be an appropriate means this challenge, posting a technology need does
to significantly reduce the transaction costs in not represent a solution because it merely
the markets for technology from the perspec- transfers the need to establish a link from the
tive of potential licensors. Moreover, the chal- potential licensee to the potential licensor.
lenge of identifying interesting applications An additional problem of externally acquir-
before actively commercializing technology is ing technological knowledge is the fact that a
not overcome. Because of the interdependen- firm will be continually observed by the poten-
cies between the limited use of the technology tial licensor regarding infringements of its
markets and the problems inherent in them, intellectual property rights if no agreement is
which may not directly be offset by web- reached between the parties. This may happen
enabled exchanges, this vicious circle is likely for a number of reasons, e.g., inappropriate
to persist in the future – at least to a certain prices or characteristics of the technologies.
degree. Finally, this process may lead to infringement
lawsuits. In this context, one intellectual prop-
erty expert frankly stated: ‘Nobody likes to pay
Licensees’ Perspective license fees’. In addition to these practical dif-
Similar to the licensors’ perspective, industry ficulties, these factors are also brought forward
experts consider the unsystematic approach to justify the ‘Not Invented Here’ syndrome,
to be the main disadvantage of identifying and i.e., negative attitudes to the acquisition of
acquiring technology by means of internet external technology. In particular, this bias
marketplaces. Usually, it is difficult or impos- may be found among R&D experts, who often
sible to find an appropriate technology for a tend to invent around the intellectual property
specific technology need. Despite containing rights of other firms instead of attempting to
large numbers of technologies, one reason for get a licence for these technologies.
this problem is the limited number of tech-
nologies that are offered in the marketplaces.
Integrated Perspective
While this limitation is inherent in a database
approach, it is aggravated by the fact that many A comparison of the licensors’ and licensees’
of the technologies represent residual knowl- perspectives shows major similarities between
edge, which is of relatively low value and these views. The main problem of internet
unused in the source firms. Moreover, the exchanges is the unsystematic nature of
number of technologies that are offered in one partner identification. Because of the limited
particular technological field is often limited. success rate in identifying and realizing

© 2008 The Authors


Volume 17 Number 1 2008 Journal compilation © 2008 Blackwell Publishing
INNOVATION INTERMEDIARIES 19

transactions, the search process requires con- At the beginning, yet2.com focused on its
siderable resources. As technology transfer internet-based infrastructure (Bauman, 2000).
through web-based exchanges constitutes only Potential licensors put their offers online,
one of a number of channels, the alternative whereas potential licensees could search for
ways appear more promising to many firms, technologies in the database. Recently, how-
particularly if a detailed idea exists for apply- ever, yet2.com seems to have realized that
ing a technology. Thus, internet marketplaces the complexity of technological knowledge
may only mitigate the difficulty of linking requires a more active approach to exchanging
technologies to appropriate applications or technology. This new understanding of tech-
vice versa, but this still represents the critical nology transactions has led yet2.com to sub-
managerial challenge. In addition, the impor- stantially transform its business model (Jahn,
tance of cultural barriers has to be highlighted, 2005). Before this reorientation, yet2.com had
although they are not a problem specific to about 80 employees, who were occupied
internet-based exchanges. These cultural bar- mainly with marketing and acquiring new
riers often prevent a more active approach to users of its internet platform. After redirecting
trading technology. In many cases, they may the business model, yet2.com employs about
therefore be considered the underlying cause 20 people, who are not primarily occupied
of refraining from technology transactions. with marketing but with actively facilitating
An integrated perspective also points to technology transactions. Thus, yet2.com no
some industry differences. Firms from the longer focuses exclusively on its internet data-
chemical/pharmaceutical industry appear to base. The internet platform still constitutes an
have initially attributed a higher importance to important feature, but yet2.com attempts to
technology licensing through internet market- play a more active role in connecting licensors
places than firms from the other industries. and licensees. Thus, the business model has
However, chemical/pharmaceutical compa- been transformed from focusing on the web-
nies also seem to internally manage their enabled infrastructure towards concentrating
licensing activities more proficiently than on a more active approach to technology
firms from the other industries. Thus, the data brokering.
support prior research, which has underlined Therefore, the 20 employees at yet2.com
the high importance of licensing transactions comprise mainly scientists and engineers,
in this sector. Accordingly, these firms are now often with PhD degrees in their technological
relatively reluctant to use internet market- fields. Their knowledge is used to facilitate
places for technology because alternative chan- deals on technology packages instead of focus-
nels, e.g., informal inter-firm networks, seem ing on patent rights (Jahn, 2005). These new
to have provided an essential avenue for initi- service offerings led to approximately ten tech-
ating technology transactions in this sector in nology transfers in 2004. This figure is con-
the past. Similarly, the importance of internet trasted with the 90,000 registered users, which
marketplaces appears to be surprisingly low underlines the difficulties in facilitating tech-
in the electronics/semiconductors industry nology transactions. As a result of the new
although the relevance of licensing in this strategic approach, however, yet2.com expects
industry has been described in relative detail to strongly increase the number of deals that
in prior research. By contrast, the potential of are closed as a result of its brokering activities
internet marketplaces for technology is con- in the coming years (Jahn, 2005). Similar to the
sidered surprisingly high in the automotive/ strategic changes at yet2.com, various other
machinery industry. As technology licensing internet marketplaces for technology that
in this sector has received limited attention were created in recent years, e.g., NineSigma,
in prior research, it deserves further study to pursue a more active approach to facilitating
offer a better understanding to firms aiming at technology exchanges. Thus, a major portion
optimally utilizing their technologies in this of their service offerings refers to active bro-
field. kering, whereas databases only represent
additional infrastructure to facilitate deals.
Thus, yet2.com’s reorientation is not a singular
development. Instead, it may represent a new
Discussion approach to internet marketplaces, which links
them to active forms of technology brokering.
Recent Trends
Very recently, major changes have occurred in
Theoretical and Managerial Implications
the strategic approach of various internet mar-
ketplaces. While these developments could be The limited success rates of internet exchanges
observed in various marketplaces, they appear with regard to the number of technology
to have influenced in particular yet2.com. transactions that have been initiated have

© 2008 The Authors


Journal compilation © 2008 Blackwell Publishing Volume 17 Number 1 2008
20 CREATIVITY AND INNOVATION MANAGEMENT

various consequences for managing technol- firms to enhance their benefits from rely-
ogy transactions. In particular, some problems ing on intermediaries in the markets for
of internet marketplaces do not apply to other technology.
types of intermediaries, which offer consulting
services beyond introducing technologies in Furthermore, companies may rely on the
databases (Bryant & Reenstra-Bryant, 1998; knowledge embedded in their inter-
Sawhney, Prandelli & Verona, 2003; Howells, organizational networks (Madhavan, Koka &
2006; Verona, Prandelli & Sawhney, 2006). Prescott, 1998; Grant & Baden-Fuller, 2004).
Accordingly, industrial firms could rely more These formal and informal ties may lead
on agents (Bidault & Fischer, 1994; Morgan & directly to technology transactions, and they
Crawford, 1996), who help a company to pro- may also provide information and indirect
actively identify technology customers or reac- contacts to other firms which may finally faci-
tively identify infringers of its intellectual litate technology transactions (Gulati, 1999;
property. Similarly, the recent developments of Hislop, 2002). In addition, these networks may
internet marketplaces, which tend to offer help to increase the technology push and
integrated services including a more active market pull effects in a firm’s licensing activi-
component, may help to overcome the deficits ties. For instance, most large pharmaceutical
of pure databases. As such, our analyses point firms openly communicate their intention to
to the superiority of accessing integrated license in technologies, and they have estab-
service offerings of intermediaries that go lished dedicated licensing units. This open
beyond internet-related databases. Therefore, approach has strengthened technology push
we posit the following proposition: effects, i.e., technology offers that the phar-
maceutical firms receive from biotechnology
Proposition 1: Integrated service offerings companies (Rothaermel & Deeds, 2004;
help firms to enhance their benefits from Gassmann & Reepmeyer, 2005). By contrast,
relying on intermediaries in the markets for an advanced example of combining market
technology. pull effects and networks is IBM’s website
alphaWorks (http://www.alphaworks.ibm.
Moreover, firms should attempt to com), which was created in 1996 by IBM’s
adequately use their own knowledge, which is internet division hoping that outside compa-
distributed across the organization (Ernst, nies and developers would contribute ideas
Leptien & Vitt, 2000; Basadur & Gelade, 2006), about bringing the programs to market
in order to link technologies and applications (Wolpert, 2002). Today, thousands of persons
(Kogut & Zander, 1992; Cillo, 2005). This are using the web site, on which over 200 tech-
finding is consistent with prior research into nologies, usually at the early stages of devel-
managing licensing transactions (Gallini & opment, are available for download, including
Winter, 1985; Anand & Khanna, 2000; Agrawal, the option to license these technologies. The
2006; Lichtenthaler, 2007). A successful positive effects of complementing intermedi-
approach to this central challenge of exchang- ary services with the knowledge embedded in
ing technology could be the ‘functional market a firm’s inter-organizational networks, which
concept’. This concept emphasizes ‘thinking go beyond a company’s internal activities,
in functions’ by focusing on technologies as suggest the following proposition:
means to reach various objectives, thus sepa-
rating a technology from a certain context Proposition 3: Complementing intermedi-
(Weiß, 2004). In particular, diversified firms ary services with inter-firm networks helps
may rely on the overlapping knowledge bases firms to enhance their benefits from rely-
of their business units and technological fields ing on intermediaries in the markets for
to identify licensing opportunities (Brockhoff technology.
& Chakrabarti, 1988; Griffin & Hauser, 1996).
Furthermore, the identification of exchange Usually, a main strength of internet market-
partners may be integrated into a firm’s places is their cross-industry character
regular technology intelligence processes (Johansson, 2004; Chesbrough, 2006). For
(Gassmann & Gaso, 2004; Frishammar & instance, an electronics firm that we inter-
Hörte, 2005). Thus, it appears beneficial to rely viewed had licensed a technology to a chemi-
on intermediary services as a complement cal company through an internet platform.
rather than as a substitute for a firm’s internal Thus, dividing marketplaces into industry
activities (Wenger & Snyder, 2000; Verona, areas does not seem beneficial. However, the
Prandelli & Sawhney, 2006). Accordingly, we IBM example has shown that leading compa-
suggest the following proposition: nies may create their own marketplaces to
enlarge and intensify their offline networks.
Proposition 2: Complementing intermedi- This approach may help to combine personal
ary services with internal activities helps contacts with the advantages of web-based

© 2008 The Authors


Volume 17 Number 1 2008 Journal compilation © 2008 Blackwell Publishing
INNOVATION INTERMEDIARIES 21

tools. The emphasis on networks may help to their benefits from relying on intermediar-
reduce some deficiencies of the marketplaces ies in the markets for technology.
because it contributes to a realistic view of
Intermediaries in general and internet mar-
managing technology transactions (Ford, 1988;
ketplaces for technology in particular may
Bessant & Rush, 1995; Sawhney, Verona &
mitigate the market imperfections that result
Prandelli, 2005). In particular, the develop-
from these technology and market characteris-
ment of internal capabilities of managing
tics (Shohet & Prevezer, 1996; Lichtenthaler &
technology transactions seems to be inevit-
Ernst, 2006). However, the markets for tech-
able. Internal capabilities are important for
nology will likely remain less perfect than the
co-ordinating external service providers, e.g.,
markets for most products and services. More-
by thoroughly preparing technology offers in
over, the nature of technological knowledge
the marketplaces. By suggesting a relationship
contributes to explaining the differences be-
between internal competencies and organiza-
tween some markets, where intermediation
tional boundaries, this study has provided
works efficiently, and other markets, e.g.,
support for competence-based perspectives
technology markets, where intermediation
in boundaries research, which go beyond
remains difficult despite information and com-
efficiency-based analyses, e.g., transac-
munication technologies that facilitate inter-
tion costs (Fisscher et al., 2001; Santos &
mediary services (Granstrand, 2000; Howells,
Eisenhardt, 2005). Similar to the development
2006). In particular, intellectual property rights
of alliance capability, learning effects in co-
may function as a facilitator of technology
ordinating the service offerings of intermedi-
transactions. The analysis of Arora, Fosfuri
aries likely have positive effects (Sawhney &
and Gambardella (2001) suggests that ‘stron-
Prandelli, 2000; Lichtenthaler & Lichtenthaler,
ger IPRs [intellectual property rights] can
2004; Kale & Singh, 2007), and they suggest the
enhance the efficiency of technology transfers,
following proposition:
and hence encourage the diffusion of technol-
Proposition 4: Developing dynamic capa- ogy, including parts of the technology that
bilities of co-ordinating intermediary ser- patents do not protect’ (Arora, Fosfuri & Gam-
vices helps firms to enhance their benefits bardella, 2001, p. 117; see also Williamson,
from relying on intermediaries in the 1991). The fact that intellectual property rights
markets for technology. work particularly well in specific industries
and technology areas, e.g. in the chemical
In addition, it has to be highlighted that industry, has contributed considerably to the
technological knowledge is an idiosyncratic emergence of markets for technology in these
good (Steele, 1989; Fosfuri, 2006). Apart from fields (Levin et al., 1987; Teece, 1998; Arora
the fact that technologies are dynamically & Fosfuri, 2000; Cesaroni & Mariani, 2001).
evolving, Granstrand (2000) has identified the Therefore, firms should respond to these
following six major properties of technological differences in the appropriability regimes by
knowledge, not all of them shared by other aligning their intermediary services with
types of knowledge. Technology has an arti- the particular situation (Chesbrough, 2006;
fact link, it has a science link and, in general, a Howells, 2006). Hence, we propose:
relatively high degree of codifiability. Further-
more, it has a practical purpose, it is linked to Proposition 6: Aligning the intermediary
globally oriented common systems for its services with appropriability regimes helps
operationalization and assessment, and it may firms to enhance their benefits from rely-
be protected by patent rights (Granstrand, ing on intermediaries in the markets for
2000). Besides the challenges of actually trans- technology.
ferring technology, the characteristics of tech-
nological knowledge lead to appropriability
issues, which exist in all types of intellectual Conclusion
property regimes (Cummings & Teng, 2003;
Pisano, 2006). Thus, the technology source Simultaneous to the ‘new economy’ bubble,
often has to actively support the technology there seems to have been an exaggerated hope
transfer to ensure successful technology to overcome the imperfections in the markets
absorption at the recipient (Amesse & Cohen- for technology by means of internet ex-
det, 2001; Agrawal, 2006). This is necessary if a changes. Today, these marketplaces have not
firm enters an agreement as a licensor or as a yet met the great expectations of most
licensee (Teece, 1998; Arora, Fosfuri & Gam- researchers and practitioners. Instead, they
bardella, 2001). Accordingly, we propose: merely represent an additional way of identi-
fying technologies or applications. While the
Proposition 5: An active support of the hopes in the beginning may have been unreal-
technology transfer helps firms to enhance istic, there are possibilities for improving the

© 2008 The Authors


Journal compilation © 2008 Blackwell Publishing Volume 17 Number 1 2008
22 CREATIVITY AND INNOVATION MANAGEMENT

current situation. The new approach of internet Bidault, F. and Fischer, W.A. (1994) Technology
marketplaces, which goes beyond providing Transactions: Networks over Markets. R&D Man-
infrastructure to include additional consulting agement, 24, 373–86.
services, appears to be a promising avenue. Brockhoff, K. and Chakrabarti, A. (1988) R&D/
Marketing Linkage and Innovation Strategy:
In particular, it takes into account that most
Some West German Experience. IEEE Transac-
technology exchanges do not constitute arm’s tions on Engineering Management, 35, 167–74.
length transactions because technological Bryant, T.A. and Reenstra-Bryant, R.A. (1998) Tech-
knowledge is an idiosyncratic good. nology Brokers in the North American Software
As the volume of technology trade likely Industry: Getting the Most out of Mismatched
continues to increase, the market imper- Dyads. International Journal of Technology Manage-
fections may simply be reduced by higher ment, 16, 281–90.
numbers of technology transactions. In addi- Cesaroni, F. (2004) Technological Outsourcing and
tion, increasing technology transactions may Product Diversification: Do Markets for Technol-
change the organizational cultures of many ogy Affect Firms’ Strategies? Research Policy, 33,
1547–64.
companies towards more open approaches
Cesaroni, F. and Mariani, M. (2001) The Market for
to transferring technology. In the light of Knowledge in the Chemical Sector. In Guilhon, B.
growing technology transactions, future (ed.), Technology and Markets for Knowledge:
studies may help to deepen our understanding Knowledge Creation, Diffusion and Exchange within
of the role of internet marketplaces for tech- a Growing Economy. Kluwer Academic Publishers,
nology. In particular, large-scale empirical Dordrecht, pp. 71–97.
studies constitute an interesting avenue for Cesaroni, F., Di Minin, A. and Piccaluga, A. (2005)
further research. These studies may analyse Exploration and Exploitation Strategies in Indus-
firms’ propensity to rely on intermediaries and trial R&D. Creativity and Innovation Management,
the intermediaries’ impact on the performance 14, 222–32.
Chesbrough, H. (2006) Open Business Models: How to
of corporate licensing strategies. These studies
Thrive in the New Innovation Landscape. Harvard
may lead to results that are equally relevant Business School Press, Boston, MA.
to academics and practitioners. Chesbrough, H. (2007) The Market for Innovation:
Implications for Corporate Strategy. California
Management Review, 49, 45–66.
References Cillo, P. (2005) Fostering Market Knowledge Use in
Innovation: The Role of Internal Brokers. European
Agrawal, A. (2006) Engaging the Inventor: Explor- Management Journal, 23, 404–12.
ing Licensing Strategies for University Inventions Clarke, T. and Rollo, C. (2001) Capitalising Knowl-
and the Role of Latent Knowledge. Strategic Man- edge: Corporate Knowledge Management Invest-
agement Journal, 27, 63–79. ments. Creativity and Innovation Management, 10,
Amesse, F. and Cohendet, P. (2001) Technology 177–88.
Transfer Revisited from the Perspective of the Cohen, W.M. and Levinthal, D.A. (1990) Absorptive
Knowledge-Based Economy. Research Policy, 30, Capacity: A New Perspective on Learning and
1459–78. Innovation. Administrative Science Quarterly, 35,
Anand, B.N. and Khanna, T. (2000) The Structure 128–52.
of Licensing Contracts. Journal of Industrial Eco- Cummings, J.L. and Teng, B.-S. (2003) Transferring
nomics, 48, 103–35. R&D Knowledge: The Key Factors Affecting
Argote, L., McEvily, B. and Reagans, R. (2003) Man- Knowledge Transfer Success. Journal of Engineer-
aging Knowledge in Organizations: An Inte- ing & Technology Management, 20, 39–68.
grative Framework and Review of Emerging Davis, J.L. and Harrison, S.S. (2001) Edison in the
Themes. Management Science, 49, 571–82. Boardroom: How Leading Companies Realize Value
Arora, A. and Fosfuri, A. (2000) The Market for from Their Intellectual Assets. John Wiley & Sons,
Technology in the Chemical Industry: Causes and New York.
Consequences. Revue d’economie industrielle, Edmondson, A.C., Bohmer, R.M.J. and Pisano, G.P.
317–34. (2001) Disrupted Routines: Team Learning and
Arora, A., Fosfuri, A. and Gambardella, A. (2001) New Technology Implementation in Hospitals.
Markets for Technology: The Economics of Innovation Administrative Science Quarterly, 46, 685–716.
and Corporate Strategy. MIT Press, Cambridge, Eisenhardt, K.M. (1991) Building Theories from
MA. Case Study Research. Academy of Management
Basadur, M. and Gelade, G.A. (2006) The Role Review, 14, 532–50.
of Knowledge Management in the Innovation Eisenhardt, K.M. and Graebner, M.E. (2007) Theory
Process. Creativity and Innovation Management, 15, Building from Cases: Opportunities and Chal-
45–62. lenges. Academy of Management Journal, 50, 25–
Bauman, N. (2000) Technology Licensing Ex- 32.
changes. Research Technology Management, 43, Ernst, H., Leptien, C. and Vitt, J. (2000) Inventors
13–15. Are Not Alike: The Distribution of Patenting
Bessant, J. and Rush, H. (1995) Building Bridges for Output Among Industrial R&D Personnel. IEEE
Innovation: The Role of Consultants in Technol- Transactions on Engineering Management, 47, 184–
ogy Transfer. Research Policy, 24, 97–114. 99.

© 2008 The Authors


Volume 17 Number 1 2008 Journal compilation © 2008 Blackwell Publishing
INNOVATION INTERMEDIARIES 23

Fisscher, O.A.M., Visscher, K., Pearson, A. and Howells, J. (2006) Intermediation and the Role of
Weisenfeld, U. (2001) Research and Development Intermediaries in Innovation. Research Policy, 35,
as a Competence Creating Business in a Business. 715–28.
Creativity and Innovation Management, 10, 251–8. Huston, L. and Sakkab, N.Y. (2006) Connect and
Ford, D. (1988) Develop Your Technology Strategy. Develop: Inside Procter & Gamble’s New Model
Long Range Planning, 21, 85–95. for Innovation. Harvard Business Review, 84, 58–66.
Fosfuri, A. (2006) The Licensing Dilemma: Under- Jahn, T. (2005) Marktplatz für Ideen. McK Wissen,
standing the Determinants of the Rate of Technol- 82–7.
ogy Licensing. Strategic Management Journal, 27, Johansson, F. (2004) The Medici Effect: Breakthrough
1141–58. Insights at the Intersection of Ideas, Concepts, and
Frishammar, J. and Hörte, S.A. (2005) Managing Cultures. McGraw-Hill, New York.
External Information in Manufacturing Firms: Kale, P. and Singh, H. (2007) Building Firm Capa-
The Impact on Innovation Performance. Journal of bilities through Learning: The Role of the Alliance
Product Innovation Management, 22, 251–66. Learning Process in Alliance Capability and
Gallini, N. and Winter, R. (1985) Licensing in the Firm-Level Alliance Success. Strategic Manage-
Theory of Innovation. RAND Journal of Economics, ment Journal, 28, 981–1000.
16, 237–52. Kline, D. (2003) Sharing the Corporate Crown
Gans, J.S. and Stern, S. (2003) The Product Market Jewels. MIT Sloan Management Review, 44, 89–93.
and the Market for ‘Ideas’: Commercialization Kogut, B. and Zander, U. (1992) Knowledge of the
Strategies for Technology Entrepreneurs. Research Firm, Combinative Capabilities, and the Replica-
Policy, 32, 333–50. tion of Technology. Organization Science, 3, 383–97.
Gassmann, O. (2006) Opening Up the Innovation Levin, R.C., Klevorick, A.K., Nelson, R.R. and
Process: Towards an Agenda. R&D Management, Winter, S.G. (1987) Appropriating the Returns
36, 223–8. from Industrial Research and Development.
Gassmann, O. and Gaso, B. (2004) Insourcing Cre- Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 3, 783–820.
ativity with Listening Posts in Decentralized Lichtenthaler, U. (2005) External Commercializa-
Firms. Creativity and Innovation Management, 13, tion of Knowledge: Review and Research
3–14. Agenda. International Journal of Management
Gassmann, O. and Reepmeyer, G. (2005) Organiz- Reviews, 7, 231–55.
ing Pharmaceutical Innovation: From Science- Lichtenthaler, U. (2007) The Drivers of Technology
Based Knowledge Creators to Drug-Oriented Licensing: An Industry Comparison. California
Knowledge Brokers. Creativity and Innovation Management Review, 49, 67–89.
Management, 14, 233–45. Lichtenthaler, U. and Ernst, H. (2006) Attitudes to
Granstrand, O. (2000) The Economics and Management Externally Organising Knowledge Management
of Intellectual Property: Towards Intellectual Capital- Tasks: A Review, Reconsideration and Extension
ism. Edward Elgar Publishing, Northampton, MA. of the NIH Syndrome. R&D Management, 36, 367–
Grant, R.M. and Baden-Fuller, C. (2004) A Knowl- 86.
edge Accessing Theory of Strategic Alliances. Lichtenthaler, U. and Ernst, H. (2007) Developing
Journal of Management Studies, 41, 61–84. Reputation to Overcome the Imperfections in
Griffin, A. and Hauser, J.R. (1996) Integrating R&D the Markets for Knowledge. Research Policy, 36,
and Marketing: A Review and Analysis of the 37–55.
Literature. Journal of Product Innovation Manage- Lichtenthaler, U. and Lichtenthaler, E. (2004) Alli-
ment, 13, 191–215. ance Functions: Implications of the International
Grindley, P.C. and Teece, D.J. (1997) Managing Multi-R&D-Alliance Perspective. Technovation,
Intellectual Capital: Licensing and Cross- 24, 541–52.
Licensing in Semiconductors and Electronics. Lynn, L.H., Reddy, N.M. and Aram, J.D. (1996)
California Management Review, 39, 8–41. Linking Technology and Institutions: The Innova-
Guilhon, B. (2001) The Emergence of the Quasi- tion Community Framework. Research Policy, 25,
markets for Knowledge. In Guilhon, B. (ed.), 91–106.
Technology and Markets for Knowledge: Knowledge McEvily, B. and Zaheer, A. (1999) Bridging Ties: A
Creation, Diffusion and Exchange within a Growing Source of Firm Heterogeneity in Competitive
Economy. Kluwer Academic Publishers, Dor- Capabilities. Strategic Management Journal, 20,
drecht, pp. 21–40. 1133–56.
Gulati, R. (1999) Network Location and Learning: Madhavan, R., Koka, B.R. and Prescott, J.E. (1998)
The Influence of Network Resources and Firm Networks in Transition: How Industry Events
Capabilities on Alliance Formation. Strategic (Re)shape Interfirm Relationships. Strategic Man-
Management Journal, 20, 397–420. agement Journal, 19, 439–59.
Hargadon, A. and Sutton, R.I. (1997) Technology March, J.G. (1991) Exploration and Exploitation in
Brokering and Innovation in a Product Develop- Organizational Learning. Organization Science, 2,
ment Firm. Administrative Science Quarterly, 42, 71–87.
716–49. van der Meer, H. (2007) Open Innovation – The
Hislop, D. (2002) The Client Role in Consultancy Dutch Treat: Challenges in Thinking in Business
Relations during the Appropriation of Technical Models. Creativity and Innovation Management, 16,
Innovations. Research Policy, 31, 657–71. 192–202.
Howells, J. (1999) Research and Technology Out- Miles, I. (2000) Services Innovation: Coming of Age
sourcing and Innovation Systems: An Exploratory in the Knowledge-Based Economy. International
Analysis. Industry and Innovation, 6, 111–29. Journal of Innovation Management, 4, 371–89.

© 2008 The Authors


Journal compilation © 2008 Blackwell Publishing Volume 17 Number 1 2008
24 CREATIVITY AND INNOVATION MANAGEMENT

Miles, M.B. and Huberman, A.M. (1994) Qualitative and Diffusion of Industrial Automation in
Data Analysis: An Expanded Sourcebook. Sage, Sweden. In Carlsson, B. (ed.), Technological
Beverly Hills, CA. Systems and Economic Performance: The Case of
Morgan, E.J. and Crawford, N. (1996) Technology Factory Automation. Kluwer, Dordrecht, pp. 165–
Broking Activities in Europe – A Survey. Interna- 210.
tional Journal of Technology Management, 12, 360– Steele, L.W. (1989) Managing Technology: The Strate-
7. gic View. McGraw-Hill, New York.
Pisano, G. (2006) Profiting from Innovation and the Teece, D.J. (1998) Capturing Value from Knowledge
Intellectual Property Revolution. Research Policy, Assets: The New Economy, Markets for Know-
35, 1122–30. How, and Intangible Assets. California Manage-
Rivette, K.G. and Kline, D. (2000) Rembrandts in ment Review, 40, 55–79.
the Attic: Unlocking the Hidden Value of Patents. Van Looy, B., Martens, T. and Debackere, K. (2005)
Harvard Business School Press, Boston, MA. Organizing for Continuous Innovation: On the
Rothaermel, F.T. and Deeds, D.L. (2004) Exploration Sustainability of Ambidextrous Organizations.
and Exploitation Alliances in Biotechnology: A Creativity and Innovation Management, 14, 208–21.
System of New Product Development. Strategic Verona, G., Prandelli, E. and Sawhney, M. (2006)
Management Journal, 25, 201–21. Innovation and Virtual Environments: Towards
Santos, F.M. and Eisenhardt, K.M. (2005) Organiza- Virtual Knowledge Brokers. Organization Studies,
tional Boundaries and Theories of Organization. 27, 765–88.
Organization Science, 16, 491–508. Watkins, D. and Horley, G. (1986) Transferring
Sawhney, M. and Prandelli, E. (2000) Communities Technology from Large to Small Firms: The Role
of Creation: Managing Distributed Innovation in of Intermediaries. In Webb, T., Quince, T. and
Turbulent Markets. California Management Review, Watkins, D. (eds.), Small Business Research. Gower,
42, 24–54. Aldershot, pp. 215–51.
Sawhney, M., Prandelli, E. and Verona, G. (2003) de Weerd-Nederhof, P. and Fisscher, O. (2003)
The Power of Innomediation. MIT Sloan Manage- Alignment and Alliances for Research Institutes
ment Review, 44, 77–82. Engaged in Product Innovation. Two Case
Sawhney, M., Verona, G. and Prandelli, E. (2005) Studies. Creativity and Innovation Management, 12,
Collaborating to Create: The Internet as a Plat- 65–75.
form for Customer Engagement in Product Weiß, E. (2004) Functional Market Concept for Plan-
Innovation. Journal of Interactive Marketing, 19, ning Technological Innovations. International
4–17. Journal of Technology Management, 27, 320–30.
Schweizer, L. (2005) Organizational Integration of Wenger, E.C. and Snyder, W.H. (2000) Communi-
Acquired Biotechnology Companies into Phar- ties of Practice: The Organizational Frontier.
maceutical Companies: The Need for a Hybrid Harvard Business Review, 78, 139–45.
Approach. Academy of Management Journal, 48, West, J., Vanhaverbeke, W. and Chesbrough, H.
1051–74. (2006) Open Innovation: A Research Agenda. In
Seaton, R.A.F. and Cordey-Hayes, M. (1993) The Chesbrough, H., Vanhaverbeke, W. and West,
Development and Application of Interactive J. (eds.), Open Innovation: Researching a New
Models of Industrial Technology Transfer. Tech- Paradigm. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp.
novation, 13, 45–53. 285–307.
Seely Brown, J. and Duguid, P. (1998) Organizing Williamson, O.E. (1991) Comparative Economic
Knowledge. California Management Review, 40, Organization – The Analysis of Discrete Struc-
90–111. tural Alternatives. Administrative Science Quar-
Shohet, S. and Prevezer, M. (1996) UK Biotechnol- terly, 36, 269–96.
ogy: Institutional Linkages, Technology Transfer Wolpert, J.D. (2002) Breaking Out of the Innovation
and the Role of Intermediaries. R&D Management, Box. Harvard Business Review, 80, 76–83.
26, 283–98. Yin, R.K. (2003) Case Study Research: Design and
Spulber, D.F. (1999) Market Microstructure: Interme- Methods. Sage Publications, Newbury Park, CA.
diaries and the Theory of the Firm. Cambridge Uni- Zahra, S.A. and George, G. (2002) Absorptive
versity Press, Cambridge. Capacity: A Review, Reconceptualization, and
Stankiewicz, R. (1995) The Role of the Science and Extension. Academy of Management Review, 27,
Technology Infrastructure in the Development 185–203.

© 2008 The Authors


Volume 17 Number 1 2008 Journal compilation © 2008 Blackwell Publishing
INNOVATION INTERMEDIARIES 25

Ulrich Lichtenthaler (Ulrich.Lichtenthaler@


whu.edu) is an assistant professor of
Technology and Innovation Management at
WHU – Otto Beisheim School of Manage-
ment, Vallendar, Germany. His research
interests include technology exploitation,
technology transfer, interfirm alliances and
licensing. He has published in the Journal
of Product Innovation Management, Journal
of Business Venturing, Research Policy, IEEE
Transactions on Engineering Management,
International Journal of Management Reviews,
R&D Management, California Management
Review and other journals.
Holger Ernst is professor at WHU – Otto
Beisheim School of Management, Vallendar,
Germany where he holds the Chair for
Technology and Innovation Management.
He was visiting professor at the Kellogg
School of Management, Northwestern Uni-
versity, Evanston, IL, USA in 2005 and 2006.
His main research interests are in the fields
of technology and innovation management,
intellectual property management, new
product development and entrepreneur-
ship. He has published in the Journal of
Product Innovation Management, Interna-
tional Journal of Management Reviews, Journal
of Engineering and Technology Management,
IEEE Transactions on Engineering Manage-
ment, Research Policy and R&D Management.
He consults multiple European organiza-
tions in the area of technology, patent and
innovation management.

© 2008 The Authors


Journal compilation © 2008 Blackwell Publishing Volume 17 Number 1 2008

Anda mungkin juga menyukai