Anda di halaman 1dari 11

Micro-Credit and Rural Poverty

An Analysis of Empirical Evidence


This paper reviews empirical evidence on NGO-led micro-credit programmes in several
developing countries, and compares them with state-led poverty alleviation schemes in India.
The study shows that micro-credit programmes have been able to bring about a marginal
improvement in the beneficiaries’ income. However, the beneficiaries have not gained much
by way of technological improvements, given the emphasis on ‘survival skill’. Also, in
Bangladesh the practice of repayment of Grameen Bank loans by making fresh loans from
moneylenders has resulted in the creation of ‘debt cycles’.

PALLAVI CHAVAN, R RAMAKUMAR

If we can come up with a system which generation and skill improvement, and The paper is divided into four sections.
allows everybody access to credit while financial viability. In Section I, we bring out the context in
ensuring excellent repayment – I can give We are aware that given the multi- which the NGO-led micro-credit alternative
you a guarantee that poverty will not last dimensional nature of poverty, an attempt has emerged in the literature and in policy
long. to understand the impact of any programme making. In Section II, we discuss the
or institution on poverty would require a concept and features of micro-credit insti-
Muhammad Yunus (1994) study of a number of indicators. However, tutions, beginning with Grameen Bank. In
in the literature on micro-credit, poverty Section III, we review the available em-
This summit is to celebrate the success of
mainly refers to income poverty. We have pirical evidence on micro-credit
millions of determined women who have
transformed their lives from extreme pov-
followed the same connotation in this paper programmes and institutions in compari-
erty to dignified self-sufficiency through and have chosen the performance indica- son with state-led credit-based poverty
micro-credit programmes… This summit tors accordingly. We have also incorpo- alleviation programmes and institutions in
is about creating a process that will send rated the indicator of financial viability. India based on the selected indicators. We
poverty to the museum... We will create The issue of financial viability has been also discuss the issues involved in the
a poverty-free world. a matter of wide criticism in recent years expansion and replication of Grameen-
in the context of state-led credit institutions. type programmes and institutions across
Muhammad Yunus, speaking at the Hence we feel that it is important to analyse various countries. Finally, in Section IV,
Micro-credit Summit, Washington, it in the case of NGO-led micro-credit we provide a summary of the findings from
February 1997; reproduced in Yunus institutions, which are being recommended the review.
(1999: 245-46) as the alternative to state-led institutions
in several developing countries. I

T
his paper is an enquiry into the For analysing these indicators, we use Introduction
claim that NGO-led micro-credit is the available empirical evidence on a set
an effective and financially viable of selected NGO-led micro-credit-based Credit is important in the lives of the
alternative to the existing methods of ad- programmes and institutions being imple- rural poor in a developing economy. As
dressing rural poverty through the provi- mented across several developing coun- the distribution of land in the countryside
sion of credit. The emergence of micro- tries. We place this evidence in a compara- remains skewed, the majority of the rural
credit as an alternative in recent years has tive perspective with the available evi- population is left with an inadequate re-
questioned the fundamentals of the rural dence on some of the existing state-led source base for production. Faced with a
credit system in developing countries for and credit-based poverty alleviation weak social security system to fall back
channelling credit to the poor. Following programmes and institutions in India. We upon, this section of landless or near-land-
this, transformation – even substitution – are aware that state-led institutions aimed less rural population is forced to depend
of the existing rural credit system with a at channelling credit to the poor do not upon credit for its livelihood. It was this
micro-credit-based system is being recom- function on the same lines as the micro- understanding that led various developing
mended and followed. In this paper, we credit institutions. However, there are countries to make credit an integral part
review the performance of the NGO-led similarities in their objectives and certain of their poverty alleviation programmes.
micro-credit system on the basis of a set operational features, such as the nature of The conception and implementation of such
of selected indicators. These indicators activities supported and size of loans programmes were often based on the broad
are: targeting the poor, increase in earnings provided, for undertaking a meaningful principles of social banking in several
and asset holding of the poor, employment comparison. developing countries including India.

Economic and Political Weekly March 9, 2002 955


Social banking can be described as “the collateral in order to secure access to credit their families.7 The defining criteria used
elevation of the entitlements of previ- [Swami 1979]. Further, in the absence of are thus the size of loans8 and the targeted
ously disadvantaged groups to formal decentralised planning and administration population comprising micro-entrepre-
credit even if this may entail a weakening of poverty alleviation programmes through neurs, particularly women micro-entrepre-
of the conventional banking practices” institutions such as the panchayats, there neurs, from low-income households. These
[Copestake et al 1984].1 Under this policy, were problems in targeting the poor ben- loans are generally offered without any
the initiative and direct involvement of eficiaries [RBI 1990, Osmani 1989, collateral.
the state was central to the development Swaminathan 1990].3 The scheme of micro-credit as conceived
of the banking system. In India, this policy With increasing criticism of the state-led by Grameen Bank has been based on
led to nationalisation of major commercial formal credit system and its utilisation for innovative financial practices. It attempts
banks in 1969, adoption of the directed poverty alleviation, in recent years coun- to resolve the problem of targeting men-
lending programme, development of credit tries have moved towards new mecha- tioned earlier either directly by specifying
institutions such as Regional Rural Banks nisms of lending such as micro-credit. the member’s eligibility requirement on
(RRBs), and implementation of the Inte- Micro-credit has been claimed to be a the basis of asset ownership or indirectly
grated Rural Development Programme solution to most of the problems that by making the loan amount small and
(IRDP), a credit-based poverty alleviation originated out of the state’s efforts to laying down other conditions, such as
programme implemented through com- alleviate poverty using the instrument of attendance at the weekly member meet-
mercial banks. These policy measures credit [Yunus 1999]. ings, so that the non-poor are discouraged
resulted in widening the “geographical from borrowing [Hulme and Mosley
spread and functional reach” of commer- I 1996a].9
cial banks in rural areas in the period that Micro-Credit: Concept It attempts to overcome the screening
followed the nationalisation of banks and Features problem through group formation.10 The
[Shetty 1997: 253]. Further, there was also concept of group borrowing is driven by
some improvement in the access of rural The implementation of any formal lend- the idea that solidarity among like-minded
poor – consisting largely of marginal and ing programme directed towards the poor people living in similar social and eco-
small peasants and the landless rural labour is often beset by three important nomic conditions is crucial to the success
force – to bank credit at concessional rates difficulties.4 The first is the problem of of this programme. This group can be used
[Chavan 2001]. exact targeting, which would ensure that to understand the character and proposed
In the process of pursuing the broader there are no type I or type II errors5 [Cornia loan use of each of the members. More-
objectives of social banking, however, and Stewart 1991]. Secondly, it faces the over, the loans are given only for activities
certain weaknesses crept into the system screening problem of distinguishing the that cannot go wrong in terms of repay-
of banking in general and rural banking good (creditworthy) from the bad (not- ment of the loan or it turning into a bad
in particular. First, it was argued that though so-creditworthy) borrowers. This is be- investment [Hulme and Mosley 1996a].
the efforts were aimed at improving the cause the poor borrowers do not generally These are activities such as poultry raising,
distribution of formal credit among the maintain any accounts of their past busi- paddy husking, cattle fattening, rice and
landless and near-landless rural popula- ness activity or furnish any documented other seasonal crop trading, handloom
tion through schemes such as IRDP, bank business plan for which they are seeking weaving and grocery shop keeping.
credit largely remained concentrated in the loan. Thirdly, these agencies may not be Finally, the problem of monitoring the
hands of the landed population [Nagaraj able to monitor and ensure productive loan usage and enforcement is taken care
1981]. Secondly, it was argued that the usage of the loans. Further, if the loan of individually as well as through the
banking system could not fully adapt to repayment runs into a problem, they group.11 The bank insists on putting the
the task of poverty alleviation on account may not be able to take legal action loan to the use specified by the borrower
of the lack of provision of consumption against the borrowers, often on account strictly within a period of seven days.
credit.2 Finally, the system of directed of the absence of any collateral. Here, the Further, it follows a system of weekly
lending was criticised as it resulted in the problem is of enforcing the repayment of repayment of small amounts. This is done
creation of non-profit making assets on loans. Costs incurred to take care of the as “parting with large amount of cash at
account of poor repayment of loans [RBI last two problems mainly comprise the the end of a loan period is often psycho-
1991]. ‘transactions costs’ of lending. On account logically trying for the borrowers” [Yunus
This is not the place to probe into the of a high level of transactions costs in- 1999: 61].
reasons behind these weaknesses. How- curred in lending to the poor, formal With such innovative practices,
ever, they had a certain bearing on the fact lending agencies often leave the poor Grameen Bank has risen to fame for its
that development of the banking system unbanked [Yunus 1999]. The scheme of performance in targeting and repayment
remained isolated and was not made part micro-credit that has emerged with the rates. Following its example, several other
of a broader socio-economic transforma- establishment of Grameen Bank has aimed institutions have been set up for provi-
tion in the countryside. Land reform, for at addressing these problems in certain ding micro-credit in Bangladesh and in
example, was the most important step innovative ways.6 many developing countries. Apart from
needed for such a transformation. Land Micro-credit, as defined by Grameen the state-controlled Bank Rakyat Indo-
remained inequitably distributed, and in- Bank, symbolises small loans extended to nesia and Badan Kredit Kecamatan in
equities in the access to credit followed the poor for undertaking self-employment Indonesia, all such institutions, such as
the inequities in land distribution. This projects that would generate income and BRAC (Bangladesh), Banco Sol (Bolivia),
was because borrowers needed land as enable them to provide for themselves and SANASA (Sri Lanka) and Muzdi Fund

956 Economic and Political Weekly March 9, 2002


(Malawi), are non-governmental in nature beneficiaries were selected, was extremely tuted 94 per cent of the bank’s borrowers
(NGOs) and depend for funding on inter- poor. Independent evaluations by Nabard [Yunus 1999].
national donors such as IFAD, SIDA, and the Planning Commission estimated Mosley and Hulme (1998), in their cross-
OECF, OXFAM and CARE. that on an average, the percentage of country analysis, found that success in
ineligible beneficiaries in IRDP were about targeting varied significantly between
III 15-26 per cent; in some places it was even different programmes (Table 1). They
Evaluation estimated to be between 40 per cent and examined the impact on poverty of 13
50 per cent [Nabard 1984, GoI 1985, cited major credit provision programmes and
In this section, we attempt to review the in Guhan 1986]. Dreze (1990) argued that institutions across seven countries, includ-
performance of a selected set of NGO-led only one among the eight households in ing RRBs from India. Among those
micro-credit programmes and institutions the poorest decile (the ‘unambiguously programmes that had a declared policy of
that provide credit for poverty alleviation poor’ population) received any benefit from targeting, all had achieved a poor to non-
in developing countries. As mentioned IRDP. The average beneficiary income in poor ratio of over 90 per cent, except RRBs
earlier, we adopt a comparative approach his study village was twice as high as the in India, which had a ratio of only 38 per
for analysing the performance of these cut-off income specified under the cent.14
micro-credit programmes and institutions programme. He also found that none of the Notwithstanding its success in targeting,
vis-à-vis the state-led programmes and landless households in the village received an ‘exclusion problem’ has been reported
institutions in India. any benefit through IRDP. even in the case of Grameen Bank [Osmani
For this analysis, we have selected Swaminathan’s (1990) study villages 1989]. As per the findings of the Bangla-
Grameen Bank, BRAC, and TRDEP of were in two states, West Bengal and Tamil desh Agricultural Survey, in 1983-84 about
Bangladesh, BancoSol of Bolivia, PTCCS Nadu. She found significant differences in 66 per cent of households with less than
of Sri Lanka, the Muzdi Fund and SACA the targeting efficiency of IRDP in these 0.5 acres of land (the declared target group
of Malawi and the KREP Juhudi Scheme states. In West Bengal, only 7.5 per cent for Grameen Bank) in Bangladesh were
and KIE-ISP of Kenya. The state-led of the sampled beneficiaries were not primarily agricultural labour households
poverty alleviation programmes and insti- eligible for assistance. By contrast, in Tamil (ibid.). This proportion should have re-
tutions chosen for comparison from India Nadu, 24-27 per cent of the beneficiaries flected in their share among the beneficia-
are the Integrated Rural Development were not eligible for assistance. Under ries of Grameen Bank. However, Hossain
Programme (IRDP)12 and regional rural some specific categories, this leakage (1988) found that only 20 per cent of
banks (RRBs)13 . extended even up to 50 per cent in Tamil beneficiaries had agricultural labour as
Nadu. their principal/secondary occupation be-
An important constraint in such an By absolute contrast, Grameen Bank has fore they joined the bank. Among these,
analysis has been the limited number of reported high success in reaching its tar- only 8.4 per cent had agricultural labour
studies that evaluate the actual impact of geted population. According to Hossain as their principal occupation.
the NGO-led micro-credit programmes on (1988), only 4.2 per cent of borrowers in Increase in earnings and asset holdings
the earnings and employment of the ben- the Grameen Bank were outside the target of the poor: There are several method-
eficiaries. Most of the available studies group (those with less than 0.5 acres of ological problems in handling the issue of
narrowly focus on their “programmatic land). Osmani (1991), after a review of earnings. Any study about earnings and
success” [Rahman 1999: 67], where the studies, pointed out that most of the ben- assets is beset with several difficulties,
principal variables studied are the number eficiaries belonged to the bottom 40 per such as under-reporting, recall bias in
of beneficiaries, amount of credit disbursed, cent of the income scale. About 95 per cent recording incomes from previous years
recovery rate, and profit flows among of the loans from Grameen Bank reached and inaccurate evaluation of earnings in
others. the target group and only 5 per cent went kind. In the absence of properly main-
The performance indicators used in this to non-target groups. Another important tained accounts in the case of small house-
review are discussed below. achievement in targeting for Grameen Bank hold enterprises, commonly observed in
Targeting the poor: As we shall show in was the high percentage of women among rural areas, the problem of income mea-
this section, micro-credit programmes and the borrowers. In 1998, women consti- surement is likely to be more acute.
institutions have generally performed better
than the state-led institutions for credit Table 1: Proportion of Poor among Beneficiaries, Selected Credit Programmes
provision in reaching the targeted poor and Institutions, 1992
population. Agency Number of Percentage of Borrowers
The performance of IRDP in targeting Borrowers below Poverty Line
has been found to be strikingly poor [Dreze
Bolivia: BancoSol 51,000 29
1990, Swaminathan 1990, Kurian 1987, Bangladesh: Grameen Bank 1,050,000 95+
Nabard 1984 and GoI 1985, cited in Guhan Bangladesh: BRAC 598,000 95+
1986]. An expert committee of the Re- Bangladesh: TRDEP 25,000 90+
Sri Lanka: PTCCS 702,000 52
serve Bank of India (RBI) on IRDP found
India: RRBs 12,000,000 44
that, in many states, even the necessary Kenya: KREP Juhudi 2,400 -
preliminary surveys of the families below Kenya: KIE-ISP 1,700 0
the poverty line had not been conducted Malawi: SACA 400,062 7
Malawi: Mudzi Fund 223 -
[RBI 1993]. It also found that the atten-
dance at village assemblies, where the Source: Compiled from Mosley and Hulme (1998), Table 1.

Economic and Political Weekly March 9, 2002 957


It has been pointed out by Swaminathan 0.5 acres of land) in the ‘control villages’ Hulme (1998). They undertook a compari-
(1990) that the methodology of calculating by about 43 per cent.17 Further, their son of income ‘before and after’ taking
income changes requires accurate estimates income level was higher by 28 per cent loans from RRBs. They compared income
of base year as well as final year incomes. than target group members in the ‘project levels of a borrower group of 100 with a
A reliable method can be to calculate villages’ who did not borrow from Grameen control group of 50 for each credit insti-
income mobility of households given that Bank. The difference was highest for the tution.18
one has income data collected during the absolutely landless beneficiaries followed From these two studies, we have pre-
two corresponding years. We found that by the marginal landowners. In another sented in Table 2 the figures of average
only Swaminathan’s study adopted such study, Todd (1996) reported a positive annual change in family income19 of
a methodology. Using panel data set for income impact on the women borrowers borrowers and the control sample. Among
a village in Tamil Nadu between 1977 from her study area. the programmes that they studied, benefi-
(before IRDP) and 1985 (after IRDP), she Apart from the gains in income, studies ciaries of RRBs recorded the highest annual
found that the overall share of productive from Bangladesh found that there was change in family income during 1988-
assets in total wealth remained unchanged smoothing of income and consumption for 92.20 When compared with the percent-
over the period. There was no difference borrower households due to micro-credit age change in income of borrowers from
in the patterns of income mobility between [Morduch 1998, Zaman 1999, Khandkar the control group, RRB beneficiaries
beneficiaries and non-beneficiaries be- 1998, cited in FAO 2000]. While Khandkar recorded a rise of 191 per cent. Table 2
tween 1977 and 1985. She concluded that found that increase in and smoothing of also gives information regarding the
the income impact of IRDP loans on the consumption occurred together, in change in income over the previous year
beneficiaries was only marginally posi- Morduch’s study, smoothing of consump- (as a per- centage of the control group)
tive.15 tion was not accompanied by an increase. for all borrowers and for borrowers
Other studies, following mostly the recall The period of retaining assets was longer below the poverty line. We find that the
methods for past-income calculations, have for Grameen Bank participants than for increase in incomes for those below the
found that there was only a marginal rise IRDP beneficiaries [Kurian 1987, Rath poverty line was one of the highest for
in income for IRDP beneficiaries. Kurian 1985, Hossain 1988]. In the case of IRDP, RRBs at 133 per cent with only BRAC
(1987), reporting results from a country- the share of households not keeping assets exceeding it.
wide survey of IRDP beneficiaries, found gained through IRDP for more than two However, the increase in incomes for the
that about 84 per cent of the households years varied from 25 per cent to 50 per cent poorest beneficiaries of RRBs was not
enjoyed a positive increment in income [Kurian 1987, Rath 1985]. However, in the impressive. Mosley (1996a) studied the
after a period of two years. Within these, case of Grameen Bank, Hossain (1988) impact of RRBs on different income classes
about 38 per cent of the households en- found that there was a threefold increase of beneficiaries. He found that though “the
joyed an increase in income of about 50 within a period of 27 months in the amount difference between the income change of
per cent.16 In another review of IRDP, of working capital employed by members’ beneficiaries (of RRB) and the control
Guhan (1986: 32) reached the conclusion enterprises started with Grameen loans. group is positive,…amongst borrowers
that IRDP “channelled funds on a hitherto Further, it was also found that the number below the poverty line it is on an average
unprecedented scale for creating supple- of cattle owned by the members increased negative” (pp 260-61). About 34 per cent
mentary incomes amongst the relatively by 26 per cent every year (ibid). of the poor borrowers in his sample “crossed
poor in rural areas all over India”. How- The literature on the impact of RRB the poverty line”21 in a period of one year,
ever, he pointed out that it “failed to loans on the income of the borrowers is which accounted for about 12 per cent of
generate incomes to the expected levels” relatively limited. The only available es- the whole sample.
(ibid p 31). timate used for the present analysis has Based on the studies reviewed, we
Studies on Grameen Bank have, in been obtained from a study by Hulme and conclude that both NGO-led micro-credit
general, shown a positive change in the Mosley (1996a, 1996b) and Mosley and and state-led credit institutions have led
income of the beneficiaries [Hossain 1988,
Hulme and Mosley 1996a, Todd 1996, Table 2: Impact of Loans on Family Incomes of Beneficiaries
Khandkar and Chowdhary 1996]. How- Agency Annual Average Change in Change in Average Rise in Income
ever, all these studies use the recall method Family Income, 1988-92 Income of in the Year Prior to Survey
and therefore, their results are likely to (in Per Cent) Borrowers (as Per Cent of Control Group)
suffer from memory bias. Further, unlike toControl
Borrowers Control Sample Sample All Borrowers
studies on IRDP, studies on Grameen Bank (in Per Cent) Borrowers Poverty Line
have not attempted to isolate the income (1) (2) (3) (4)=(2/3) (5) (6)
flows from assets acquired through loans.
Bolivia: BancoSol 28.1 14.5 193 270 101
On account of the second problem, we Bangladesh: Grameen Bank - - - 131 126
have relied more on studies that have Bangladesh: BRAC 19.8 13.8 143 143 134
compared beneficiary income with a con- Bangladesh: TRDEP 38.7 30.6 126 138 133
Sri Lanka: PTCCS 15.6 9.9 157 157 123
trol group income, rather than its own India: RRBs 46.0 24.0 191 202 133
income at an earlier period. Kenya: KREP Juhudi 1.5 1.1 133 133 103
Based on his field survey, Hossain (1988) Kenya: KIE-ISP 0.5 0.4 125 125 -
found that Grameen Bank borrowers in the Malawi: SACA 2.8 1.6 175 175 -
Malawi: Mudzi Fund 1.4 1.2 117 117 101
‘project villages’ had higher income than
the target group (those owning less than Source: Hulme and Mosley (1996a), Table 4.1 and Table 8.1.

958 Economic and Political Weekly March 9, 2002


to positive but only marginal increases in ciaries after receiving the loans [Hossain and 26 per cent respectively. Those who
the earnings of their beneficiaries. How- 1988, Mosley 1996b, Montgomery and adopted new technology were found to
ever, given the methodological problems Bhattacharya 1996]. Hossain (1988) found reap higher benefits than others under all
associated with studies on income changes, that 20 per cent of the borrowers of the schemes. In Kenya, under the Juhudi-
more empirical evidence is required in bank were earlier unemployed. There was supported enterprises, a majority of the
order to substantiate such a conclusion. a small movement away from agricultural borrowers sought credit solely for
Employment generation and skill improve- labour towards vocations like poultry working capital to undertake “what they
ment: Before examining the question of farming, livestock raising, processing and knew best” [Buckley 1996: 325]. From
employment generation, it would be useful manufacturing, trading and shopkeeping. these studies, it appears that the number
to consider the debates about the benefits On average, the number of days of family- of borrowers adopting new technology
of generating self-employment and wage employment per month went up by 11 to under the micro-credit schemes have been
employment. Scholars have taken two 15 days.22 In the case of BancoSol in few in number.
extreme positions on this issue. Dandekar Bolivia, only 38 per cent of the borrowers One important reason for the poor adop-
(1986), Rath (1985) and Dreze (1990) have experienced an increase in employment tion of new technology is the absence of
argued that the generation of wage em- days after taking the loans [Mosley 1996b]. any skilled training to borrowers under the
ployment through large-scale public The remaining 62 per cent of the borrowers micro-credit schemes. Imparting skills is
works is the most effective strategy for the either experienced a decrease or no change crucial for undertaking new investments
alleviation of poverty. Contrary to this, in employment days. Further, a majority and adopting new technology. The phi-
others like Dantwala (1986) have sup- of those who got more employment were losophy guiding Grameen Bank is that the
ported the strategy of generating self- from the higher income classes [Mosley poor do not need to be given any skill to
employment opportunities towards achie- 1996b]. For SANASA in Sri Lanka, Hulme, utilise the loans as they have an inherent
ving this aim. While the latter school fo- Montgomery and Bhattacharya (1996) skill, which Mohammed Yunus calls “sur-
cuses on rationales, such as self-reliance, found that for non-agricultural loans, the vival skill” [Yunus 1999: 140]. It is the
the former school has pointed out that increase in family employment was only presence of this inherent skill that “keeps
market uncertainty and heavy debts can 0.7 persons per enterprise. However, there them alive even when they are poor” (ibid).
erode the self-reliance of poor entrepre- was an increase in employment of four Hence it is believed that the provision of
neurs as well as their entitlement to em- persons per household in the case of paddy credit per se would transform the borrow-
ployment [Dreze 1990]. loans (ibid). ers into able entrepreneurs. In our opinion,
Osmani (1989) has taken a more bal- Studies indicated that micro-enterprises this repudiates the importance of mod-
anced position on this issue. He has argued completely failed in generating non-fam- ern skills and technology. Credit pro-
that the choice between self- and wage- ily employment. From their cross-country vided by micro-credit programmes on this
employment is contingent on the previous studies, Hulme and Mosley (1996a) report principle may provide temporary income
character of employment of the beneficia- that between the borrowers and the control relief to the beneficiaries but would keep
ries. He has cited studies on Grameen group of non-borrowers, there was a dif- them in a perpetual state of technological
Bank, which have found that most of the ference of only one employee per enter- backwardness. It is only through a sus-
borrowers after taking loans have followed prise. In the case of SANASA, only 8 per tained transfer of modern technology
their pre-loan occupations. This is largely cent of the borrowers reported increase in along with credit that such programmes
in line with the Grameen Bank philosophy the number of paid employees in their can be of help in dealing with the problem
that people can do those activities better, activity [Hulme, Montgomery and of poverty.
which they have been accustomed to before Bhattacharya 1996]. The average increase Financial viability: Of the various factors
taking the loans. Thus it follows that in employment was one employee per that determine the financial viability of a
borrowers who have some entrepreneurial enterprise for non-farm loans and 4.5 credit institution, we have selected three
experience can handle self-employment employees per household for crop loans. factors for the present analysis. They are
ventures better than others and would Buckley (1996), reporting a study on KREP costs of default, administrative costs and
succeed in raising their income levels. Juhudi credit scheme in Kenya, found that dependence on subsidies.
Rightly enough, studies on Grameen ben- the increase in employment from these
eficiaries have shown that relatively suc- schemes was less than 0.5 employees per Costs of Default
cessful borrowers have had some prior enterprise. In the case of RRB loans in
knowledge of the market [Hossain 1988]. India, the average increase was reported Minimising the costs of default is crucial
Conversely, those who have no experience to be only 0.6 employees per enterprise for the sustainability of any credit provi-
in self-employment, such as agricultural [Mosley 1996a]. sion programme or institution. The de-
labourers, are likely to be benefited less This takes us to the issue of technology fault rates of IRDP and RRB loans in
by this system of credit. Hence there will used in these enterprises. Hulme and India have been very high. In the case
be need for promoting wage-employment Mosley (1996a) found that the percentage of IRDP, the default rate on advances
programmes for this section of the rural of borrowers who invested in new tech- granted by public sector banks as a
population. nology was only 33 per cent in their “high percentage of demand increased from 58.7
The focus of Grameen Bank, as noted impact schemes” and 7.5 per cent in “low per cent as in 1991 to 69.1 per cent in 1993
earlier, has been on the generation of self/ impact schemes”.23 In the case of RRBs, [RBI 1993]. In her field study in West
family-employment. Studies indicated that 12 per cent of the borrowers invested in Bengal (in 1988-89), Swaminathan (1990)
the number of days of family employment new technology, while in BRAC and found that the local bank branch reported
increased slightly for micro-credit benefi- BancoSol, this proportion was 8 per cent a default rate on IRDP loans of 45 per cent.

Economic and Political Weekly March 9, 2002 959


About 75 per cent of borrowers in the loans through short-term loans from High levels of cross-financing deplete the
village did not have any overdue at the time moneylenders “with a promise to the lender capital of the loan, and reduce the value
of survey. In her field study in Tamil Nadu that the borrower will return the amount of the new loan that is used to repay or
(in 1985), she found that only 12.5 per cent (usually with interest) after receiving the service the old. The process turns into a
of the borrowers had fully repaid the loans new loan from the Grameen Bank” (ibid, ‘vicious cycle’ as smaller investments into
directly productive enterprises yield less
(ibid). p 78). This meant that the borrowers began
returns, thus requiring even higher loans
The default rate among the respondent a new Grameen loan “with a deficit on the
the next time to repay the original loan.
borrowers of Grameen Bank was only 3.3 capital”. This, according to Rahman, led It erodes the profitability of any enterprise,
per cent in 1985 [Hossain 1988]. This level to the creation of “debt cycles” for the especially if a high interest loan is taken
was maintained during the nineties [Yunus borrowers (ibid). from the informal market [Sinha and Matin
1999]. In another important study in Madhupur 1998: 72].
Mosley (1996a) analysed default rates thana in northern Bangladesh, Sinha and
for RRB loans and found that during Matin (1998) found that 94 per cent of Administrative Costs
1983-91, the average default rate was 47.5 micro-credit borrowing households in their
per cent. The six-month arrears rate of village were also indebted to informal sources Information about the administrative
RRBs in 1992 was the highest among the of credit. Target group households (with costs25 incurred by credit institutions is
13 institutions that Mosley and Hulme less than 0.5 acres of land) depended on provided by Hulme and Mosley (1996a)
(1998) examined across different coun- one informal sector loan every 10 weeks, (Table 4). During 1988-92, the adminis-
tries (Table 3).24 While RRBs had a six- while the frequency was 12 weeks in the trative costs (as a percentage of total
month arrears rate of 42 per cent, the case of non-target group households. portfolio) were the lowest for RRBs (on
same for Grameen Bank was 4.5 per They noted that “most of the informal average 8.1 per cent per annum). For
cent and for BRAC 3 per cent. In the case loans repaid with Grameen loans were Grameen Bank and BRAC, they were 12.3
of RRBs, between 1982 and 1992, there taken to repay earlier Grameen loans” (ibid, per cent and 40.0 per cent respectively for
was a fall in the overdue rates, from 50.0 p 70-71). Among the target group house- the same period. Over the years, the ad-
per cent to 32.9 per cent of total lending holds, 45 per cent of the amount of infor- ministrative costs for Grameen Bank ap-
(ibid). mal sector loans was utilised for repaying peared to have increased. Total adminis-
However, there have been two major loans taken from micro-credit institutions, trative costs increased from 4 per cent of
arguments against low default rates on including Grameen Bank. Among the non- total liability to about 7 per cent between
Grameen Bank loans. First, sizewise de- target group households, this share was 15 1984 and 1986 [Hossain 1988]. As a share
composition of the repayment rates indi- per cent. Sinha and Matin concluded that, of the portfolio or the amount of loans, it
cates that low default rates have been
confined to loans of very small size Table 3: Default Rate, Cost of Credit and Subsidy Dependence Index
[Hossain 1988]. Default rates tended to
Agency 6-Month Arrears Real Interest Rates SDI
increase with the increase in the loan size Rate (Per Cent) (Per Cent) (1988-92 Average)
(ibid). Default rates among the first-time
and the second-time borrowers were 0.4 Bolivia: BancoSol 0.6 45 135
Bangladesh: Grameen Bank 4.5 15 142
and 1.2 per cent respectively. For the third- Bangladesh: BRAC 3.0 11 199
time borrowers, this rate increased to 6.6 Bangladesh: TRDEP 0.0 - 199
per cent and in the case of fourth-time Sri Lanka: PTCCS 4.0 11 226
India: RRBs 42.0 3 133
borrowers, it further rose to 9.5 per cent Kenya: KREP Juhudi 8.9 9 217
(ibid). The number of people with no Kenya: KIE-ISP 20.2 -1 267
overdue installments decreased from 96.7 Malawi: SACA 27.8 7 398
per cent for the first-time borrowers to 61.0 Malawi: Mudzi Fund 43.4 8 1884
per cent for the third-time borrowers and Source: Compiled from Mosley and Hulme (1998), Table 1.
32.9 per cent for the fourth-timer borrow-
ers (ibid). Table 4: Components of Cost Structure
Secondly, studies have found that the (average levels as percentage of total portfolio, per annum)
prompt and regular repayment of loan Agency Cost Components
installments has largely occurred through i a a1 a2 a3 a4 p
cross-financing from other informal Bolivia: BancoSol 8 28 17 4.5 4 3 1
sources of credit and not through the returns Bangladesh: Grameen Bank 3.5 12.3 4.3 6 2 1 5
from the investment undertaken with the Bangladesh: BRAC 0 40 16 5 2 14 3
Bangladesh: TRDEP 0 100 16 5 2 77 -
loan. There are two important studies that Sri Lanka: PTCCS 1 17 - - - - 4
bring out this aspect of the operation of India: RRBs 9.7 8.1 6 - - 2 42
Grameen Bank. Rahman (1999), in a study Kenya: KREP Juhudi 0 33 19 3 9 2 9
in Tangail district, has pointed out that Kenya: KIE-ISP 0 27 9 - 6 12 20
Malawi: SACA 0 11 8 - - 3 28
most of the timely repayments were not Malawi: Mudzi Fund 0 722 238 1.5 67 415 43
made out of incomes flowing from assets
Notes: i – Borrowing interest rate; a – Total administrative costs; a1 – Loan supervision costs; a2 –
gained, but through further borrowing from Insurancecosts;a3 –Research,trainingandsupportofotherinstitutions;a4 –Othercosts;p–Costs
private moneylenders. Many borrowers in of default; a1, a2, a3 and a4 are components of a.
Rahman’s village repaid Grameen Bank Source: Hulme and Mosley (1996a), Table 3.2.

960 Economic and Political Weekly March 9, 2002


increased from 8.6 per cent to 18.1 per cent in raising their income levels and being Grameen-Type Models: Some
during the same period.26 able to save. Issues in Expansion and
Comparison of administrative costs Rahman argued that high costs of credit Replication
with costs of default for various financial amounted to transferring high administra-
institutions indicated that these two moved tive costs onto the poor borrowers [Rahman In relation to the expansion and repli-
in inverse direction. High rates of repay- 1999]. He identified this shift as the major cation of NGO-led micro-credit institu-
ment helped these banks achieve higher cause for the existence of “debt cycles”, tions, two questions need to be answered.
profit levels every year. However, in order which were discussed in the last sub-sec- First, is the model of micro-credit set by
to maintain such high rates of repayment, tion. Rahman also pointed out that when- Grameen Bank viable in Bangladesh itself
these banks had to invest considerable ever Grameen Bank increased the salary after it expands its operation? In other
resources in administering the loans. The of its staff, the increase in cost was shifted words, can Grameen Bank, once expanded
existence of high administrative costs to the borrowers through raising interest into a macro-level programme, avoid the
of micro-credit institutions has been rates (ibid). drawbacks of a large-scale credit-based
noted in many studies [Bhat and Tang poverty alleviation programme like IRDP
1998].27 What might appear paradoxical Subsidy Dependence and institutionalise itself into a sustainable
has been the co-existence of high admini- scheme for poverty alleviation? As Osmani
strative costs and high levels of profit. Most of the rural credit programmes and (1989: 2) has put it, “the issue is not how
The answer to this paradox can be found institutions are subsidised. In the case of well the Grameen Bank has done so far
in the fixation of interest rates by these state-led programmes, this subsidy is borne … [it] is how well this strategy is likely
institutions. Interest rates for micro- by the government while in the case of to work as a major anti-poverty programme,
credit were fixed high in order to com- NGO-led institutions, it is mainly borne once its scale is expanded many times…”.
pensate for high transaction costs or by domestic and international private Secondly, is this model replicable in other
cuts in subsidies. The nominal interest donors. We have compared these lending countries, like India, as an effective
rate on the loans from Grameen Bank institutions on the basis of their depen- programme for credit-based poverty alle-
was kept stable at 16 per cent per annum dence on subsidies; the dependence has viation? Let us attempt to probe into these
till 1991. It was subsequently raised to been captured by an index called the questions.
20 per cent. This was 8 per cent higher Subsidy Dependence Index (SDI), devel- First, we argue that the relatively smaller
than the market rate in Bangladesh [Rahman oped by Yaron (1992). SDI represents the scale of operation of Grameen Bank has
1999]. per centage increase required in the on- been its greatest advantage in evading the
The real rate of interest on Grameen lending rate such that the dependence on problems encountered in a large-scale credit
loans, as noted by Osmani (1989), was subsidies can be completely eliminated for provision programme or institution. A
about 18 per cent compared with 12-15 per a given institution.28 comparison of the magnitude of opera-
cent charged by the state agencies in the The SDI calculated by Hulme and Mosley tions of Grameen Bank and state-led credit
1980s. In their study, Mosley and Hulme (1996a) for credit institutions is given in institutions in India reveals the limited
(1998) also found that the real rates of Table 3. As seen from the table, SDI was scale of operation of the former. In 1992,
interest for micro-credit institutions were over 100 per cent for all institutions. Among Grameen Bank had just 1.05 million
generally higher than those charged by the other institutions, RRBs had the least SDI borrowers. In the case of RRBs, the num-
state-sponsored programmes and institu- of 133 per cent. For Grameen Bank, this ber of borrowers was 12 million in 1992
tions (Table 3). During 1992, the real was higher at 142 per cent (ibid). [Mosley and Hulme 1998]. 30 In the
interest rate on Grameen Bank loans was High dependence on subsidies has been 1990s, Grameen Bank expanded its
15 per cent, while for RRBs it was only another route – other than increasing in- operations – in terms of the number of
3 per cent. terest rates – through which micro-credit beneficiaries and disbursement of credit
We argue that high rate of interest on agencies have been able to evade the – in Bangladesh. By November 2000, it
loans is effectively a burden on the in- negative impact of high administrative had branches in 40,212 villages, which
comes of the poor. Further, given the low costs. During the late 1980s, if subsidies spread across 46.7 per cent of the total
capital intensity of investments made had been removed, Grameen Bank would villages in Bangladesh.31 The number of
through micro-credit and the resultant have incurred losses [Hossain 1988]. In borrowers of Grameen Bank had increased
low profit margins, high rates of interest 1986, the loss thus incurred on credit to 2.4 million by November 2000. By
dampen the possibility of any significant operations was 5.7 per cent of the out- contrast, by March 2000, the borrowers
savings on the part of the poor borrowers. standing loans. The SDI of Grameen Bank from RRBs numbered 11.8 million [RBI
As the poor largely borrow for meeting has risen over the years [Khandker et al 2000a: 9]. In other words, the number of
consumption-related requirements, the 1995]. Moreover, the periods that have borrowers of Grameen Bank formed only
burden of high interest rates is felt even witnessed a decline in SDI have been the about 20 per cent of the borrowers of
more strongly by them. Among Grameen periods of increasing rates of interest (ibid). RRBs.
Bank borrowers in their study village, Sinha In other words, heavy dependence on Regarding the amount disbursed, till
and Matin (1998) noted that 34 per cent subsidies has been an intrinsic feature of April 2000, Grameen Bank had disbursed
of the loans from micro-credit institutions the micro-credit institutions.29 Based on a cumulative amount (for a period of 25
were spent for household food consump- the foregoing analysis, it can be con- years) of taka 1,36,986 million (equivalent
tion and 32 per cent in repaying other cluded that the financial viability of to about $ 3,228 million).32 If we consider
micro-credit loans. Such a high levy, in our micro-credit institutions has been fragile the year 1987-88, when the IRDP advances
opinion, is a barrier for poor households in nature. peaked, we find that advances during that

Economic and Political Weekly March 9, 2002 961


single year were around Rs 17,790 million IV The micro-credit programmes and insti-
at current prices (roughly equivalent to Conclusions tutions have been operating profitably on
$ 1,271 million). This formed around 39 account of remarkably high repayment rates
per cent of the cumulative amount dis- This paper reviewed the available em- on loans. The repayment rate in the case
bursed by Grameen Bank till 2000.33 The pirical evidence on NGO-led micro-credit of Grameen Bank, for example, was as
data presented here need not be used for programmes and institutions implemented high as 97 per cent in 1998. Such repay-
a strict comparison of the two programmes. across various developing countries. The ment has been made possible by incurring
We have presented these figures only to objective was to judge the performance of high administrative costs. The negative
indicate the scale of operation of Grameen these programmes and institutions on the effect of these costs on the profit levels
Bank vis-à-vis the state-led credit basis of a set of four indicators in com- has been counterbalanced, first by raising
programmes in India. Evidently, the scale parison with the state-led credit-based interest rates on loans, and second, by
of operation of Grameen Bank has been poverty alleviation programmes and relying more on subsidies. This exposes
smaller than the state-led programmes and institutions, such as, the IRDP and RRBs the fragile financial health of such
institutions. in India. programmes and institutions.
The implementation of a poverty alle- The review indicated that NGO-led We conclude that NGO-led micro-credit
viation programme is commonly beset with micro-credit programmes and institutions, programmes and institutions given their
certain “mismatches” [Osmani 1991].34 such as Grameen Bank, have been success- small scale of operation have been suc-
The drawbacks encountered in the case of ful in reaching their target groups of poor cessful in targeting and generating profits.
IRDP also had a bearing on such mis- more effectively than the state-led With an increase in their scale, however,
matches among other factors [Osmani programmes and institutions. However, they may experience similar constraints in
1991, Swaminathan 1990, Nagaraj 1999]. even these have not been free of the “ex- targeting as large-scale poverty alleviation
One way to reduce the mismatches is the clusion problem” in targeting. With due programmes like IRDP. Further, on ac-
adoption of local level planning in the recognition of the methodologial prob- count of an increase in their costs of
implementation and monitoring of the lems involved in accounting income operation, their dependence on subsidies
poverty alleviation programmes [Nagaraj change, the study led to the conclusion that is likely to grow, weakening their financial
1999, RBI 1990]. Local-level planning micro-credit programmes and institutions viability. However, claims such as these
can be described as the identification, have generated a positive change in the need to be substantiated with the help of
mobilisation and allocation of all the re- incomes of beneficiaries, but this change carefully obtained empirical evidence on
sources at the local level. In this context, has only been marginal. A similar result micro-credit programmes and institutions
it may be noted that a relatively better has been noted in the case of IRDP and in the years to come.
performance of IRDP was observed in RRBs in India. This is not to say that credit is the sole
West Bengal, where the programme was Micro-credit programmes and institu- means of addressing the problem of rural
implemented through panchayats tions have generated a positive impact on poverty. An improvement in the living
[Swaminathan 1990]. the number of days of family employment. conditions of the rural poor requires among
We argue that the small scale of opera- However, their performance in the genera- other things, agrarian reforms, democratic
tion of Grameen Bank has acted in its tion of wage employment has been poor. decentralisation, public action towards
favour, helping to keep any mismatch of Further, given the principle of “survival better educational and health facilities and
supply and demand at a lower level. An skill” that has driven institutions, such as the maintenance of a public food distri-
institution such as Grameen Bank, by virtue Grameen Bank, there has not been any bution network for the poor.
of being an NGO, is more likely to function discernible contribution to the improve-
in an uncoordinated fashion with other ment of skills and technology adopted by A Note on Micro-Credit Policy
institutions involved in the provision of the beneficiaries. Hence the available inIndia
credit as well as institutions constituted evidence indicates that Grameen-type credit
for planning of other resources in the programmes and institutions, at their cur- There are certain fundamental differ-
rural economy. Hence local-level plan- rently small scale of operation, have made ences between the current policy on micro-
ning, as defined earlier, may be difficult a ‘minimalist impact on the earnings and credit in India and that in other developing
to implement in a social security system employment generation for the rural poor. countries, such as Bangladesh.
built on the basis of NGOs such as
Grameen Bank. As a result, the kind of Table 5: Number of Self-Help Groups Formed by Public Banks and Loans Provided,
mismatches observed for IRDP may be India, 1992-93 to 2000-01
difficult to avoid for micro-credit pro- Year Number of SHGs Bank Loans Provided Refinance
grammes and institutions, such as (Rs Crore) (Rs Crore)
Grameen Bank, once they expand their 1992-93 255 0.29 0.27
scale of operation. 1993-94 620 0.65 0.46
Secondly, as noted earlier, the finan- 1994-95 2122 2.44 2.13
1995-96 4757 6.06 5.66
cial viability of Grameen Bank has been 1996-97 8598 11.84 10.65
fragile even at a smaller scale of opera- 1997-98 14317 23.70 21.39
tion. An expansion in scale is likely to 1998-99 32995 57.07 52.09
result in a rise in transaction costs lead- 1999-00 94645 192.98 150.13
2000-01 213213 480.87 400.74
ing to an increase in its reliance on
subsidies. Source: Annual Report, 2000-01, Table 7.1, Nabard, Mumbai.

962 Economic and Political Weekly March 9, 2002


Contrary to the Grameen-type models In the light of the above approach to the annual conference on Money and Finance at the
tried out in other countries, Indian banking supply of micro-credit in India, certain Indira Gandhi Institute of Development Research,
Mumbai. We thank the participants of the
policy has attempted to involve the public issues need to be discussed. First, the supply conference, especially Malabika Roy, for their
banking network in the provision of micro- of micro-credit takes place through the comments. Errors and omissions, if any, are ours.]
credit to the poor through self help groups vast institutional network of rural banking
(SHG). A paper by Nabard has referred to in the country built during the post-bank 1 The conventional bank practices are aimed at
the Indian policy on micro-credit as “re- nationalisation period. The utilisation of high recovery rates, caution in lending
decisions, commercial stability through deposit
lationship banking”, against “parallel this network for experimenting in an in- mobilisation [Copestake et al, 1984, Wiggins
banking” in other countries [Jayaraman novative method of lending needs to be and Rajendran 1987].
2001: 18). Public banks adopt the ap- appreciated. 2 We are grateful to S L Shetty for pointing this
proach of group lending and peer moni- Secondly, studies indicate that adopting out to us during discussions.
toring for lending to the SHGs. Such a the method of group lending through SHGs 3 Shetty (1997) has argued that some of the
weaknesses, such as the poor profitability under
policy has three variants that differ in the could reduce the lending and supervision the banking system was not purely on account
mode of linkage between the banks and costs of public banks [Puhazhendi 1995] of directed lending, as often argued, but had
borrowers; all three have been encouraged and raise repayment rates [Karmakar 1999, a bearing also on the defaults on loans taken
by Nabard for the provision of rural credit Puhazhendhi and Satyasai 2000]. How- by bigger borrowers. He has also argued that
in India (ibid). ever, as the available studies till date are in order to overcome the weaknesses in the
development of public sector banking,
In variant I, the public bank acts as a self limited in number, more field studies are “periodic evaluation” and adoption of
help group promoting institution (SHPI), required to pass any judgment on the corrective steps were required. Though a
“takes initiatives in forming the groups, outcome of the SHG experiment. number of committees were set up to review
nurtures them over a period of time and Thirdly, the utilisation of the public the operation of the banking system in the
then provides credit to them after satisfy- banking network for the supply of micro- period following bank nationalisation in India,
their recommendations were often not followed
ing itself about their maturity to absorb credit does not necessarily mean the con- up as desired (ibid p 254).
credit”.35 In variant II, public banks and tinuation of public regulation or account- 4 For a detailed discussion of these difficulties,
borrowers (SHGs) are linked through ability in its operations. It has been pointed see Hulme and Mosley (1996a).
facilitating agencies, which are either out that it is “desirable and appropriate to 5 This implies that under no circumstances are
NGOs working locally or government support evolution of a self-regulatory the poor excluded from the benefits of the
programme (Type I) while the non-poor can
agencies. 36 It differs from variant I as the mechanism for micro-finance institutions, become its beneficiaries (Type II).
formation and nurturing of the SHGs is the such as NGOs (MFIs), which would pre- 6 Grameen Bank is a statutory financial institution
responsibility of the facilitating agency. scribe codes of conduct and ground established in Bangladesh in 1983. In 1999,
Direct loans are provided to the group rules” [RBI, 2001: 307]. Hence the degree the government and the borrowers held 12 and
after the banks gain confidence about the of accountability of NGO-led micro- 88 per cent of its paid-up capital respectively
[Karmakar 1999].
viability of lending to the group. In variant credit institutions in India still remains 7 Source: <http://www.grameenfoundation.org>
III, both the facilitating and intermediating unclear. 8 The smallness of the size of loans differs from
functions are played by the NGOs. The Fourthly, the supply of credit through country to country. In India, for example, a
functions of forming groups, nurturing public banks may not ensure that the interest ceiling of Rs 25,000 has been fixed for defining
them and providing credit to them are rates in SHG loans will not exceed the micro-credit [RBI 1999].
9 The asset eligibility criterion of the bank
performed by NGOs, while banks confine ceiling fixed by the RBI for small loans. specifies that the member should be from a
themselves to providing credit to NGOs. In fact, RBI’s Monetary and Credit Policy household having less than half an acre of
According to Nabard, this variant is prac- for 1999-2000 has stated that “while small cultivated land or assets of the value equivalent
tised in regions where the banks “are not loans directly given by banks will continue to less than one acre of medium quality land
in a position to even finance SHGs pro- to be subject to the interest rate ceiling as [Hossain 1988].
10 In order to seek loans from Grameen Bank,
moted and nurtured by other agencies”.37 prescribed by the RBI from time to time, borrowers have to approach the bank in a
Data on SHGs show that the number of interest rates applicable to loans given by group consisting of five members. Of the five,
SHGs formed through public banks has banks to micro-credit organisations or by only two are given loans at the first stage. After
grown rapidly in the 1990s; their number these organisations to their members/ben- monitoring the repayment behaviour of these
has risen sharply in the second half of the eficiaries will be left to their discretion” two for some time (generally, a month), the
next two are provided loans and finally the last
last decade (Table 5). Among the three [RBI 1999a: 13]. Interest rates are fixed person, who is the chairperson of the group,
variants, variant II has been the most in such a manner that they provide a margin gets his/her loan. Thus the behaviour of every
numerous [Puhazhendi and Satyasai 2000]. to the banks as well as to the NGOs. The member of the group is monitored rigorously
Nearly 70 per cent of all the SHGs were empirical evidence has shown that these at every stage by the bank staff [Yunus 1999].
of the kind of variant II, while 16 per cent rates have been higher than the rates 11 The group helps in monitoring and enforcing
repayment from each of the members. If any
and 14 per cent of the groups belonged to charged on loans directly taken from banks member defaults he/she faces penalty in the
variants III and I respectively. Neverthe- [Karmakar 1999, Puhazhendhi and form of ostracism and loss of social standing.
less, an evaluation paper by Nabard makes Satyasai 2000]. -29 Thus it is evident that though the loans are
the case that variant III “is likely to be offered without any personal collateral, they
found more convenient by banks for credit involve social collateral [Hulme and Mosley
Notes 1996a]. Further, a repeat loan is not sanctioned
linkage in the coming years, when very [We are grateful to C L Dadhich, V K Rama- till the accounts of all the group members are
large number of SHGs would be required chandran, S L Shetty and Madhura Swaminathan settled [Hossain 1988].
to be linked by small sized branches of for their comments and useful discussions. A draft 12 IRDP has been the most important poverty
banks” (ibid, p 17). version of this paper was presented at the third alleviation programme of the government of

Economic and Political Weekly March 9, 2002 963


India, which was initiated in 1980. It provides without undertaking a survey of regular The data for the total number of villages in
a combination of loan and subsidy to rural employment. Bangladesh (86,038) was obtained from a
families (an identified target group of rural 23 ‘High impact’ schemes were those for which Web site of the government of Bangladesh
poor belonging to families below poverty the growth in the income of borrowers was http://www.bangladeshgov.org/reb/
line) for acquiring suitable income more than 50 per cent of that of the control about_reb.htm.
generating assets and self-employment group [Hulme and Mosley 1996a]. 32 Cumulative amount disbursed refers to the
opportunities to enable them to cross the 24 Six month arrears rate has been defined as the cumulative amount disbursed by the bank
poverty line. In terms of magnitude, this value of loans, which are six months or more for all the years of its operation from 1976,
has been one of the largest programmes of in arrears, as a proportion of total value of when the bank started off by lending $27
its type in the world for the alleviation of loan portfolio [Hulme and Mosley, 1996a, to 42 people in a village in Bangladesh. See
poverty [GoI, Ninth Plan 1997]. p 43, 82]. http:/www.grameen-info.org/bank/
13 RRBs are state owned banks in India, established 25 Administrative costs constitute a major portion lookbs.html.
in 1975, functioning exclusively in the rural of total transaction costs of a credit institution. 33 During the 1990s, the advances through IRDP
areas to provide credit to small and marginal Transaction costs include costs of information, have fallen in India as a consequence of the
farmers, agricultural labourers, artisans and negotiations, monitoring and enforcement of financial liberalisation measures [Rama-
small entrepreneurs at cheap interest rates contracts [Bardhan 1989]. chandran and Swaminathan 2000, Chavan
(RRB Act, 1976, cited in Maheswari, 1995). 26 To a certain extent, this was due to the salary 2001]. For the sake of comparison, if we
14 Those who achieved more than 90 per cent increase effected for the Grameen Bank staff take the advances through IRDP in 1998-99,
targeting were Grameen Bank, BRAC, in 1985. However, a major part of this cost, it was Rs 21,730 million at current prices
TRDEP and Malawi Mudzi Fund. Mosley’s as noted by Hossain (1988), was due to (roughly equivalent to $ 517 million), which
survey was conducted in 1992, before it expansion activities of the bank, such as formed about 16 per cent of the cumulative
was declared by the government that RRBs opening of new branches. amount disbursed by Grameen Bank till
could give 40 per cent of their loans to the 27 Bhat and Tang (1998) argued that the inability 2000.
non-poor. to reduce administrative costs lied at the root 34 Tracing common links from different countries,
15 Jean Dreze (1990) pointed out that the size of Grameen Bank and other micro-credit Osmani (1991) has highlighted the neglect of
of loans from IRDP was not high enough to institutions failing to grow into financially three types of matching that underlie the “basic
ensure a high income gain. After calculating self-sufficient lending organisations. Rahman economics of a massive self-employment
the possible gains from IRDP loans, Dreze (1999) drew attention to how Grameen Bank programme”. They are (1) matching between
found that even if one assumed a high marginal incurred high administrative costs to ensure the structure of output and the existing or
productivity of capital for the assets, the high repayment rates: “…the loan operation prospective pattern of demand for that output,
resultant increase in income for the policy emphasises a strong supervisory measure produced by the supply of an asset; (2) matching
beneficiaries was only marginal. to ensure borrower’s use of their loans for between the structure and quantum of assets
16 This finding, however, has been disputed by income generation and to pay instalments from acquired by the household and its existing or
Osmani (1989) on two grounds. Firstly, Kurian their earned incomes. In this system, the group prospective supply of assets; and (2) matching
calculated income levels without netting the chairperson and the bank’s centre chiefs were between the type of assets and the pre-existing
loan amount borrowed (liable to be repaid) and obliged to supervise the loan use immediately resources of a household. The empirical
secondly, it was not clear if he adjusted the after the loan was disbursed. Upon their evidence of such mismatches in imple-
income figures into constant prices before satisfactory investigation, they reported it to mentation can be found in Swaminathan
comparing between the two periods. Osmani the bank worker. The bank worker then had (1990). Regarding the first mismatch, she
has argued that if simple adjustments were to inspect the investment and verified the found that in West Bengal, IRDP schemes
made for these two factors, the increase in report of the group with a written description supplied too many cycle-rickshaws for the
income might remain an illusion. of the investment to the branch manager. In beneficiaries, while there existed an
17 Hossain conducted a census-type survey of 15 addition, the investment of the borrower was insufficient demand for their services. The
villages, which had Grameen branches in 1985. further supervised by the responsible branch IRDP schemes’ failure to supply a sufficient
These villages were divided into ‘project manager and programme officer from the area number of high-yielding and cross-bred milch
villages’ and ‘control villages’. ‘Project office” (p 75). cattle to all, leading to supply of low quality
villages’ were villages with Grameen Bank 28 SDI has a lower bound of –100 per cent, but breeds was an example of the second mismatch.
branches that were more than three years old. no upper bound [Yaron 1992]. SDI of zero As an example for the third mismatch, she
‘Control villages’ were those with Grameen indicates full self-sustainability for an found that households were given cattle and
Bank branches that were less than three years institution. SDI of 100 indicates that a doubling sheep, when they did not own or have access
old. ‘Control villages’ were selected such that of lending rate is required for a complete to any grazing land.
they were similar to ‘project villages’ in land elimination of subsidies (ibid). 35 See http://www.nabard.org/roles/mcid/
distribution and occupational structure 29 Though not related to the issue of financial shglinkbank.htm.
[Hossain 1988: 14]. viability, an important matter associated with 36 Some examples of government agencies
18 The control group in Hulme and Mosley (1996a, the dependence on subsidies is the role of acting as a facilitator for the formation of
p 11) were “selected to be as similar as possible donor agencies. The preferences of such SHGs are the District Rural Development
to the borrower group except for the agencies are likely to exert a strong influence Agency (DRDA) in Andhra Pradesh, by the
characteristic of not having received a loan on the operation of the micro-credit agencies. District Women Development Agency
from a case study institution”. It is pointed out that in order to ensure aid (DWDA) in Rajasthan and zilla parishads in
19 These incomes are real incomes, deflated by from its donors, these agencies are likely to Karnataka. For details, see Jayaraman (2001,
the difference in inflation rates between the adopt measures that may pay off in the short p 31-32).
national currency and the US dollar [Hulme run [Petras 1997]. If the aim is to institutionalise 37 See http://www.nabard.org/roles/mcid/
and Mosley 1996a]. the social security net, such as establishing shglinkbank.htm.
20 However, this figure needs to be interpreted institutions providing finance against poverty,
with caution because, as can be seen from long-term planning is called for. NGOs with References
Table 2, the same was also observed in case their dependence on aid from external agencies
of the control group during this period. may not be suitable towards achieving this end. Bardhan, Pranab (1989): The Economic Theory
21 Mosley used the poverty line as suggested by 30 In the long list of “replications of Grameen of Agrarian Institutions, Oxford University
Dutt and Ravallion (1994, cited in Mosley Bank” given in et al (1995), none could boast Press, New York.
1996a). a membership of over 14,000 (see Appendix Bhat, Nitin and Shui-Yan Tang (1998): ‘The
22 These figures should be interpreted with caution C in the original). Problem of Transaction Costs in Group-Based
because, as Hossain (1988) admits, it is difficult 31 See http://www.grameen-info.org/bank/ Microlending: An Institutional Perspective’,
to calculate the number of days of employment supdates.html for the data on Grameen Bank. World Development, 26 (4), April, pp 623-37.

964 Economic and Political Weekly March 9, 2002


Buckley, Graeme (1996): ‘Financing the Jua Kali Khandkar, Shahidur R and Osman H Chaudhury In India, (Chairman: A M Khusro), Reserve
Sector in Kenya: The KREP Juhudi Scheme (1996), “Targeted Credit Programmes and Bank of India, Mumbai.
and Kenya Industrial Estates Informal Pro- Rural Poverty in Bangladesh”, discussion paper – (1991): Report of the Committee on the Financial
gramme’ in Hulme and Mosley (1996b). 336, World Bank, Washington. System (Narasimham Committee), Reserve
Cornia, G A and F Stewert (1993): ‘Two Errors Kurian, N J (1987): ‘IRDP: How Relevant is it?’, Bank of India, Mumbai.
of Targeting’, Economic Policy Series, Economic and Political Weekly, 22 (52), – (1993): Expert Committee on Integrated Rural
UNICEF International Child Development pp A161-A176. Development Programme – Interim Report,
Centre, Italy. Maheswari, Shriram (1995): Rural Development Reserve Bank of India, Mumbai.
Chavan, Pallavi (2001): ‘Some Features of Rural in India: A Public Policy Approach, Sage – (1999a): Statement by Dr Bimal Jalan, Governor,
Credit in India with Special Reference to Tamil Publications, New Delhi. Reserve Bank of India on Monetary and Credit
Nadu: A Study of the Period after Bank Morduch, J (1998): ‘Does Microfinance Help the Policy for the Year 1999-2000, Mumbai,
Nationalisation’, MPhil, Thesis submitted to Poor? New Evidence from Flagship Pro- available at http://www.rbi.org.in/sec17/
the Indira Gandhi Institute of Development grammes in Bangladesh’, HIID, Harvard 7029.pdf.
Research, Mumbai. University. – (1999b): Report on Micro Credit, Micro Credit
Copestake, James, John Howell and Steve Wiggins Mosley, Paul (1996a): ‘India: Regional Rural Special Cell, Central Office, Mumbai.
(1984): ‘The Structure and Management of Banks’ in Hulme and Mosley (1996b). – (2000a): Basic Statistical Returns of Scheduled
Formal Rural Credit in Madurai and Ramnad – (1996b): ‘Metamorphosis from NGO to Commercial Banks in India – Summary Tables,
Districts’, Research Report No 1, The Commercial Bank: The Case of BancoSol in 2000, DSAC, Mumbai.
University of Reading, UK. Bolivia’ in Hulme and Mosley (1996b). – (2001): ‘Developmental Issues in Micro-Credit’,
Dandekar, V M (1986): ‘Agriculture, Employment Mosley, Paul and David Hulme (1998): speech by Jagdish Capoor, RBI Bulletin, March,
and Poverty’, Economic and Political Weekly, ‘Microenterprise Finance: Is there a Conflict pp 305-309.
21 (38-39), pp A90-A100. Between Growth and Poverty Alleviation?’, Sinha, Saurabh and Imran Matin (1998): ‘Informal
Dantwala, M L (1985): ‘Garibi Hatao: Strategy World Development, 26 (5), pp 783-790. Credit Transactions of Micro-Credit Borrowers
Options’, Economic and Political Weekly, Nabard (1984): Study of Implementation of IRDP, in Rural Bangladesh’, IDS Bulletin, 29 (4),
March 16. mimeo, Mumbai. pp 66-80.
Dreze, Jean (1990): ‘Poverty in India and the Nagaraj, K (1981): Structure and Inter-Relations Shetty, S L (1997): ‘Financial Sector Reforms in
IRDP Delusion’, Economic and Political of the Land, Labour, Credit and Product India: An Evaluation’, Prajnan, 25 (3-4),
Weekly, 25 (39), pp A95-A104. Markets of South Kanara, Unpublished PhD pp 253-287.
Food and Agriculture Organisation (2000): The Thesis, Indian Statistical Institute, Kolkata. Swaminathan, Madhura (1990): ‘Village Level
State of Food and Agriculture: Lessons from – (1999): ‘Labour Market Characteristics and Implementation of IRDP: Comparison of West
the Past 50 Years, Food and Agriculture Employment Generation Programmes in India’ Bengal and Tamil Nadu’, Economic and
Organisation of the United Nations, Rome. in Barbara Harriss-White and S Subramanian Political Weekly, 35 (13), March 31.
Government of India (1985): Evaluation Report (eds) Illfare in India, Sage Publications, Swamy, Dalip S (1979): ‘Land and Credit Reforms
on IRDP, Planning Commission, New Delhi. New Delhi. in India’, Social Scientist, 8 (11), pp 3-13.
Guhan, S (1986): ‘Rural Poverty Alleviation Osmani, S R (1989): ‘Limits to Alleviation of Todd, Helen (1996): Women at the Centre:
in India: Policy, Performance and Poverty through Non-Farm Credit’, Grameen Bank Borrowers after one Decade,
Possibilities’, paper presented at the Franco- Bangladesh Development Studies, 17 (4), Westview Press, Boulder, Colorado.
Indian Colloquium on Technological Choices pp 1-18. Wiggins, Steve and S Rajendran (1987): Rural
for Rural Development, Montpellier, – (1991): ‘Social Security in South Asia’ in E Banking in Southern Tamil Nadu:
France, 18-20 March; reproduced in Ahmad, J Dreze, J Hills and A Sen (eds) Social Performance and Management, Final
S Subramanian (ed) India’s Development Security in Developing Countries, Clarendon Research Report No 3, The University of
Experience: Selected Writings of S Guhan, Press, Oxford. Reading, UK.
Oxford University Press, New Delhi, 2001, Petras, James (1997): ‘Imperialism and NGOs in Yaron, J (1992): ‘Rural Finance In Developing
pp 15-46. Latin America’, Monthly Review, 49 (7), Countries’, World Bank, Washington.
Hossain, M (1988): ‘Credit for Alleviation of December. Yunus, Muhammad (1994): ‘Does the Capitalist
Rural Poverty: The Grameen Bank in Puhazhendhi, V (1995): ‘Transaction Costs of System Have to be the Handmaiden of the
Bangladesh’, Research Report No: 4, Lending to the Rural Poor: Non-Governmental Rich?’, Keynote address delivered at 85th
International Food Policy Research Institute, Organisations and Self-Help Groups of the Rotary International Convention held in
Washington. Poor as Intermediaries for banks in India’, The Taipei, Taiwan, on June 12-15, 1994 <http:/
Hulme, David and Paul Mosley (1996a): Finance Foundation for Development Cooperation, /www.gdrc.org/icm/grameen-
against Poverty, Volume 1, Routledge Brisbane, Australia. keynote.html>
Publications, London. Puhazhendhi, V and K J S Satyasai (2000): ‘Micro Yunus, Muhammad (1999): Banker to the Poor
Hulme, David and Paul Mosley (1996b): Finance Finance for Rural People: An Impact – Micro-Lending and the Battle against
against Poverty, Volume 2, Routledge Evaluation’, Study Report, National Bank for World Poverty, Pacific Affairs, New York.
Publications, London. Agriculture and Rural Development (Nabard), Zaman, H (2000): ‘Assessing the Poverty and
Hulme, David, Richard Montgomery and Mumbai. Vulnerability Impact of Micro-Credit in
Debapriya Bhattacharya (1996): ‘Mutual Rahman, Aminur (1999): ‘Micro-Credit Initiatives Bangladesh: A Case study of BRAC’,
Finance and the Poor: A Study of the Federa- for Equitable and Sustainable Development: Background paper prepared for WDR, 2000/
tion of Thrift and Credit Cooperatives Who Pays?’, World Development, 27 (1), 2001, World Bank, Washington.
(SANASA) in Sri Lanka’ in Hulme and Mosley January, pp 67-82.
(1996b). Ramachandran, V K and Madhura Swaminathan
Jayaraman, B (2001): ‘Micro-Finance: Retrospect (2000): ‘Rural Banking and the Poor:
and Prospects’, occasional paper – 20, National Institutional Reform and Rural Credit Markets Subscription Numbers
Bank for Agriculture and Rural Development in India’, Paper presented at the DESTIN
(Nabard), Mumbai. Conference on ‘New Institutional Theory, Subscribers are requested to note
Karmakar, K G (1999): Rural Credit and Self- Institutional Reform and Poverty Reduction’,
help Groups: Micro-Finance Needs and London School of Economics and Politics, their Subscription Numbers Men-
Concepts in India, Sage Publications, New September 7-8, 2000. tioned on the wrappers and quote
Delhi. Rath, Nilakanta (1985): ‘Garibi Hatao: Can IRDP these numbers when correspond-
Khandkar, Shahidur R, Baqui Khalily and Zahed Do It?’, Economic and Political Weekly, 20
Khan (1995): ‘Grameen Bank: Performance (6), pp 238-246. ing with the circulation depart-
and Sustainability”, Discussion Paper 306, RBI (1990): Committee on Agricultural Credit: ment.
World Bank, Washington. A Review of the Agricultural Credit System

Economic and Political Weekly March 9, 2002 965

Anda mungkin juga menyukai