Anda di halaman 1dari 16

JFI-BENZSCHAWEL:Layout 1 12/10/10 10:21 AM Page 40

Credit Default Swaps:


A Cash Flow Analysis
TERRY BENZSCHAWEL AND ALPER CORLU
It is illegal to make unauthorized copies of this article, forward to an unauthorized user or to post electronically without Publisher permission.
The Journal of Fixed Income 2010.20.3:40-55. Downloaded from www.iijournals.com by BARUCH COLLEGE on 03/12/11.

TERRY BENZSCHAWEL credit default swap (CDS) contract in Exhibit 1. The exhibit shows an example of
is a managing director at Citi
Institutional Clients Group
in New York City, NY.
terry.l.benzschawel@citi.com

ALPER CORLU
A is an agreement to exchange a spec-
ified set of coupon payments in
return for the right to receive the
par face value of a reference obligation after the
particular obligor undergoes a credit event.
a CDS written on $10 million of notional with
reference to firm XYZ. The buyer of protec-
tion makes quarterly payments, the premium leg,
for as long as there is no credit event or until
the maturity of the contract, whichever comes
is an associate at Citi Insti- The parties involved in the contract are a pro- first. The CDS premium, even if trading with
tutional Clients Group tection buyer, who pays the coupons or premiums constant coupon and upfront fee, is often
in New York City, NY.
alper.corlu@citi.com
(usually quarterly), and a protection seller, who expressed as an annual amount in basis points.
receives the premiums, but must pay the buyer Also, contracts from a given firm are commonly
the par value of an eligible security in exchange issued at a number of standard maturities, with
for that security in the event of a default, bank- the most common term being five years. The
ruptcy, or restructuring.1 protection seller agrees to pay the buyer the
In more recent versions of the standard face value of the CDS contract if XYZ under-
CDS contract, the protection buyer makes an goes a credit event and the buyer of protection
upfront payment set by the seller and pays a delivers to the seller the defaulted security or
standard running 100 bp or 500 bp premium its cash equivalent.2
that depends on the riskiness of the reference The advantages of having a liquid credit
obligor. (Even for the new contract, the upfront default swap market are well known. Prior to
cash flow and fixed spread premium can be the development of the CDS market, investors
converted to an effective spread premium). had few options for hedging existing credit
The CDS contract is usually obligor-specific, exposures or entering a short credit position.
referring to either a corporate or sovereign In such cases, investors would have to borrow
entity. The securities that are eligible for bonds in an over-the-counter market, being
delivery to the protection seller in event of subject to poor liquidity and high financing
default, the reference obligations, are typically from costs. In addition, typical fixed-rate corporate
a single class of debt (unsecured bonds, loans, bonds have huge exposure to interest-rate
or subordinated bonds, etc.), but can be asset movements, which is often undesirable for
specific. investors wishing to make pure credit plays.
For most purposes, both the CDS contract The relatively tight bid–ask spreads of CDS
with upfront payment and standard coupon and contracts and, in particular, CDS index prod-
that with no upfront payment and market-based ucts have provided extremely efficient means
coupons can be represented using the diagram for investors to express views on credits of

40 CREDIT DEFAULT SWAPS: A CASH FLOW ANALYSIS WINTER 2011


JFI-BENZSCHAWEL:Layout 1 12/10/10 10:21 AM Page 41

EXHIBIT 1
Representation of a Typical CDS Contract Prior to April 2009
It is illegal to make unauthorized copies of this article, forward to an unauthorized user or to post electronically without Publisher permission.
The Journal of Fixed Income 2010.20.3:40-55. Downloaded from www.iijournals.com by BARUCH COLLEGE on 03/12/11.

Notes: The protection buyer makes regular coupon payments to the protection seller and the contingent exchange of a reference obligation in exchange for payment
of its face value in case of a credit event. More recent contracts have an upfront cash payment to the seller of protection and either a 100 bp or 500 bp running
coupon but can still be represented as in the exhibit.

firms and countries around the world. Furthermore, the CDS are synthetic bonds with implicit funding at LIBOR.
CDS contract has provided the building block for other, To that end, we examine the CDS as asset-swap model
more complicated partitioning of credit exposure via such and its potential limitations. In addition, we suggest a
synthetic products as single-tranche CDOs (S-CDOs), pricing method based on analyses of specified and expected
whereby investors can express a view on credit correla- CDS cash flows that, combined with estimates of phys-
tion with specific risk profiles, and options on CDS, ical default probabilities and recovery values, provides an
whereby investors take positions on credit spread volatility. alternative perspective for evaluating CDS risk and rela-
Despite the wide success of CDS contracts as finan- tive value.
cial instruments, recent turmoil in the credit markets have
exposed vulnerabilities in the CDS market. For example, CASH BOND EQUIVALENT OF CDS
the lack of a central clearinghouse for CDS trades has
revealed systemic and firm-specific weaknesses in the It is nearly axiomatic among CDS investors that a
ability to effectively manage counterparty risk. In addi- CDS contract can be replicated by long and short posi-
tion, conventions for trading CDS have enabled trading tions in cash bonds by the seller and buyer of protection,
practices that, by enabling investors to go short with little respectively, who can borrow the reference obligation in
or no initial investment, have contributed to the unprece- the repo market (Kumar and Mithal [2001] and Kakodkar
dented volatility in cash and synthetic credit markets since et al. [2006]).3 That is, the no-arbitrage argument of the rela-
mid-2007. Furthermore, pressure from buyers of protec- tionship between credit default swaps and corporate bonds
tion via CDS has been blamed for contributing directly, states that one can replicate the premium leg of the CDS
at least in part, to the failure of some firms. Although CDS with a long position in the reference obligation combined
have been widely criticized for their role in the current with a fixed-for-floating interest-rate swap and the payout
credit crisis, an aspect of the CDS market that has been leg with a short position in the reference bond and a repo
largely unrecognized or overlooked is that current methods agreement to borrow that security. For example, Exhibit 2
for pricing and hedging CDS may be inadequate and/or shows the cash flows for each leg of the CDS contract in
problematic. For example, we question some assumptions Exhibit 1 represented as an asset-swap. Clearly, replicating
that underlie the widespread application of risk-neutral each leg of the CDS contract involves several operations
pricing theory to CDS; one of which implies that firms’ by both buyer and seller of protection. The no-arbitrage

WINTER 2011 THE JOURNAL OF FIXED INCOME 41


JFI-BENZSCHAWEL:Layout 1 12/10/10 10:21 AM Page 42

EXHIBIT 2
No-Arbitrage Model for CDS Where the Buyer of Protection Is Long a Bond Financed at LIBOR along with an
Interest-Rate Swap and the Protection Seller Is Short the Reference Obligation and Has Borrowed the Bond via Repo
It is illegal to make unauthorized copies of this article, forward to an unauthorized user or to post electronically without Publisher permission.
The Journal of Fixed Income 2010.20.3:40-55. Downloaded from www.iijournals.com by BARUCH COLLEGE on 03/12/11.

Note: This representation assumes that all parties can finance all transactions at LIBOR and that there is no cost to the protection seller to repo the reference asset.

model is widely, if only implicitly, assumed by most market assume that the bond is a fixed-rate instrument purchased
participants. The asset-swap and CDS equivalence is at par. To pay for the security, the protection buyer bor-
reflected in the Z-spread,4 the common measure of adjusting rows the par amount times the notional from a bank, call
cash bond spreads for comparison with CDS premiums, and it bank 1, at LIBOR.5 The coupons from the borrowed
by methods for estimating the cash–CDS basis as the spread bond are used for two purposes. First, the obligor enters
to the interest-rate swap curve (Choudhry [2006]). Given into a five-year fixed-for-floating rate swap to generate
the general acceptance of the no-arbitrage argument three-month LIBOR to make quarterly interest payments
between cash bonds and CDS and because we argue that on the loan for the bond. The remainder of the coupon,
this argument has limitations, we consider in detail the no- the amount above the five-year swap rate, is paid out as a
arbitrage model from the perspectives of both buyers and premium to the protection seller. The fact that the buyer
sellers of protection. of the bond must finance the transaction at a rate assumed
to be LIBOR is the reason that the cash versus CDS basis
The Protection Buyer is referenced to the bond’s Z-spread.
As long as the bond pays coupons to the buyer of
A depiction of a five-year CDS contract as an asset- protection, the buyer can finance the bond and pass the
swap between the buyer and seller of protection appears spread premium to the protection seller. If there are no
in Exhibit 2. Consider first the protection buyer who agrees credit events prior to maturity of the CDS and the ref-
to make regular premium payments to the protection seller erence bond, the interest-rate swap expires and the
as long as there is no credit event or until the maturity of bond’s obligor pays the face value to the protection
the CDS, whichever comes first. To replicate this with a buyer, which is used to repay bank 1 for the initial loan.
cash bond, the buyer of protection must purchase a five- However, if the reference obligor triggers a credit event
year bond issued by the reference obligor. For this example, prior to CDS maturity, the buyer of protection is due

42 CREDIT DEFAULT SWAPS: A CASH FLOW ANALYSIS WINTER 2011


JFI-BENZSCHAWEL:Layout 1 12/10/10 10:21 AM Page 43

the face value of the bond times the notional from the security is then delivered to the counterparty in the orig-
protection seller. The protection buyer can use the payoff inal short sale by the protection seller and the borrowed
to deposit in bank 2 earning LIBOR and use the bond is returned as the repo is unwound whereby the seller
LIBOR proceeds to enter into a floating for fixed-rate of protection pays the lender the loss on the borrowed bond
swap until the remaining maturity of the initial five- (i.e., face value minus recovery). Finally, the fixed-for-floating
year swap. This way, at the maturity of both interest-rate rate swap is offset by a floating–for–fixed swap for the
swap contracts, the net payout will be zero and the buyer remaining time to maturity.
of protection withdraws the deposit in bank 2 and uses
the proceeds to repay the principal on the original loan The CDS–Cash Bond Basis
It is illegal to make unauthorized copies of this article, forward to an unauthorized user or to post electronically without Publisher permission.

from bank 1.
Finally, it should be noted that the demonstration of The previous example is used to explain why, in an
The Journal of Fixed Income 2010.20.3:40-55. Downloaded from www.iijournals.com by BARUCH COLLEGE on 03/12/11.

the no-arbitrage model of the cash bond versus CDS rela- arbitrage-free setting, the break-even CDS premium
tion is not unique. One could devise other combinations should be identical to the asset-swap spread on a bond
of bond purchases and sales, borrowing arrangements, priced at par. Because of this, when investors wish to com-
interest-rate swap agreements, and repurchase agreements pare market risk premiums between CDS and their ref-
to equate cash bonds and CDS. The importance of the pre- erence bonds, they often use the Z-spread, which is a
sent demonstration is that all of these mechanisms involve spread to the LIBOR curve.6 Despite their assumed the-
transactions in markets whose price determinants may oretical equivalence, Z-spreads on cash bonds and their
differ from those of the deliverable obligations, giving rise corresponding default swap spreads are rarely the same, and
to non-credit-related influences on both bond spreads the difference between them is called the basis. For example,
and CDS premiums. Furthermore, these factors may affect Exhibit 3 shows the CDS minus cash bond basis for firms
one side of the buyer/seller relationship and not the other. in the North American investment-grade CDS index
(CDX.NA.IG)7 from December 2005 through April
The Protection Seller 2009. From the inception of the CDX index in 2003, the
basis had typically been 10 bps–20 bps positive (CDX
Consider now the CDS as asset-swap from the per- premium greater than the average of its constituent’s bond
spective of the seller of protection as depicted in the right- Z-spreads), but since 2006, the basis has largely been neg-
hand side of Exhibit 2. Recall that the protection seller ative, with average bond spreads exceeding CDX.NA.IG
receives quarterly payments from the protection buyer premiums by as much as 250 bps.
unless there is a credit event before the maturity of the Given the complexity of the relationship between
CDS. If a credit event is triggered prior to maturity, how- a firm’s reference bond and its CDS, as demonstrated in
ever, the protection seller must pay the protection buyer Exhibit 3, it is not surprising that the basis between cash
the face value of the reference obligation times the notional bonds and CDS is rarely zero. In fact, there are a variety
of the CDS contract. To replicate the payout profile of of market factors, technical details, and implementation
the protection seller in the cash bond market, one can sell frictions that underlie the basis. Some of the well-known
short the reference security, deposit the sale proceeds in factors that influence the basis are as follows:
a bank at LIBOR, and enter into a fixed-for-floating swap.
The fixed leg of the swap is combined with the premium • Method of calculating the basis (e.g., Z-spread,
from the protection buyer to pay the coupon on the bor- I-spread, C-spread)
rowed security. As for the protection buyer, the model • Imbalances between market demand for buying and
assumes that the seller of protection can borrow and lend selling protection
at LIBOR and that none of the securities trade as special • Differences in liquidity premiums for a firm’s cash
in the repo market. and synthetic assets
Assume now that the reference obligor triggers a credit • Impact of “cheapest to deliver” cash asset
event prior to maturity. The protection seller receives the ref- • Funding versus LIBOR
erence security in exchange for the face value of the secu- • Cash reference assets trading away from par value
rity times the notional. The seller makes that payment from • Difference in conventions for accrued interest on
funds deposited in the bank at inception. The reference bonds and CDS premiums

WINTER 2011 THE JOURNAL OF FIXED INCOME 43


JFI-BENZSCHAWEL:Layout 1 12/10/10 10:21 AM Page 44

EXHIBIT 3
Historical CDS vs. Cash Bond Basis for Firms in the North American Investment-Grade CDS Index,
December 2005–May 2009
It is illegal to make unauthorized copies of this article, forward to an unauthorized user or to post electronically without Publisher permission.
The Journal of Fixed Income 2010.20.3:40-55. Downloaded from www.iijournals.com by BARUCH COLLEGE on 03/12/11.

Source: Citi and Markit Partners.

• Counterparty risk exposure THE STANDARD MODEL


• Risk from different definitions of “default” for cash FOR CDS VALUATION
and synthetic assets
• Choice of calculation conventions for the basis and The standard framework for interpreting CDS values
hedge ratios and risk management is the reduced-form model. In prac-
• Bonds trading tight to LIBOR (such as AAA rated tice, the reduced-form model takes as input the market
bonds) have non-negative CDS premiums CDS premium and U.S. Treasury rates and solves, in a
risk-neutral setting, for the default probability that results
Details of the factors underlying the cash versus CDS in equal expected present values of premium and con-
basis are described in detail elsewhere (Kumar and Mithal tingent legs. A popular version of that model has been
[2001], Choudhry [2006], Kakodkar et al. [2006], King proposed by Hull and White [2000] based on the reduced-
and Sandigursky [2007], and Elizalde et al. [2009]), so are form approach of Duffie and Singleton [1999] and a
not discussed further in this article. We list these factors detailed description appears in O’Kane and Turnbull
only to illustrate the large number of factors that influ- [2003]. In the reduced-form approach the credit event
ence the CDS–cash basis. The contributions to the basis process is modeled in continuous time as a hazard rate
from the various sources that include funding rates, swap that represents the instantaneous probability of the firm
spreads, and the repo market provide limitations to the defaulting at a particular time. Within the risk-neutral
utility of the “no-arbitrage” argument as applied to credit setting, the present value of a security is the expected
default swaps and their cash bond asset-swaps. That is, value of its cash flows discounted at the risk-free rate. For
unambiguously distinguishing the effects of all the fac- example, let the time of default be denoted as τ and assume
tors contributing to the current basis is extremely diffi- that RV is a random amount recovered if default occurs
cult. Furthermore, hedging all the factors identified as before the end of the period, T (i.e.,τ ≤ T ). Then, a risky
underlying the basis, even if known, is also difficult given zero-coupon security can be viewed as a combination of
the available market instruments. Finally, as we describe two securities: one that pays $1 at time T if the issuer does
in detail in the following sections, there are other serious not default and one that pays RV if default occurs before
objections to the no-arbitrage explanation for the spread or at maturity. This can be expressed in terms of the risk-
relationship between CDS and their cash asset referents. neutral expectations (E 0Q ) as:
These are discussed after the introduction of the standard
method for valuing CDS in the risk-neutral setting.  − T rdt   − τ rdt 
v 0 = E 0Q e ∫0 1(τ >T )  + E 0Q e ∫0 RV(τ ≤T )  (1)
   

44 CREDIT DEFAULT SWAPS: A CASH FLOW ANALYSIS WINTER 2011


JFI-BENZSCHAWEL:Layout 1 12/10/10 10:21 AM Page 45

Within this framework, it has proved con- EXHIBIT 4


venient to model default events using a Poisson Representation of the Contingent Leg of a Credit Default Swap
counting process as introduced by Jarrow and in the Risk-Neutral Setting
Turnbull [1995] where the cumulative risk-neu-
tral probability of default in the interval from 0 to
t is given by

Q
  t Q

CPD = 1 − E exp  − ∫ λudu 
t 0 (2)
It is illegal to make unauthorized copies of this article, forward to an unauthorized user or to post electronically without Publisher permission.

  0  
The Journal of Fixed Income 2010.20.3:40-55. Downloaded from www.iijournals.com by BARUCH COLLEGE on 03/12/11.

where λ is the instantaneous jump to default or


default intensity. For any given interval from t – 1 to
t, the probability of default by time t conditional on
survival up to time t – 1 can be obtained as follows:

CPDtQ − CPDtQ−1
pQt ,t −1 = t −1 (3)
∏ i =1
(1 − pQi ,i−1 )

Because the default probabilities in Equa-


tions (2)–(3) are derived in the risk-neutral set-
ting, their values can be inferred from market prices
of CDS contracts. As noted before, a CDS contract
has two cash flow streams—a premium leg and a
In the risk-neutral pricing framework, the CDS
contingent leg. The premium leg consists of quarterly fixed
spread at the initiation of the contract is assumed to reflect
payments made by the protection buyer to the seller until
equal present values of the premium and the contingent
maturity or until a credit event occurs, whichever is first.
legs. Because the protection buyer makes the quarterly
On the contingent leg, the protection seller makes a single
payments of amount c/4 (where c is the annualized pre-
payment dependent on the occurrence of a credit event,
mium or CDS spread) conditional on the survival of the
usually default. Although the contingent payment is the
reference entity with probability 1 – CPDQ, the present
face value of the reference bond, the protection buyer must
value of the premium leg equals
deliver the reference security or its equivalent value to the
protection seller. Thus, the amount of contingent payment 4T
cT
can be modeled as the face amount multiplied by (1 – RV), PVpremium = ∑ dt ∗ (1 − CPDtQ ) ∗ (4)
where RV is the recovery rate immediate after default, t =1 4
expressed as percentage of the face.
The pattern of potential contingent leg payouts of where dt denotes the risk-free discount factor from t = 0
a CDS is represented in Exhibit 4. On each time step in to t quarters and T is the maturity of the CDS in years.
the exhibit, a credit event occurs with probability pt,t–1 or On the contingent leg, the protection seller makes a pay-
survives with probability 1 – pt,t–1. As described previ- ment 1 – RV only if a credit event has occurred in a par-
ously, if the firm defaults, the seller pays an amount whose ticular time interval with probability CPDtQ − CPDtQ−1.
value is the equivalent of the face minus the recovery Hence the present value of the contingent leg is calcu-
value, 1 – RV in Exhibit 4, and the contract terminates. lated as follows:
Otherwise, the firm survives until the next period in which
it again either defaults or survives. The exhibit illustrates 4T

how marginal default and survival probabilities accumu- PVcontingent = ∑ dt ∗ (CPDtQ − CPDtQ−1 ) ∗ (1 − RV ) (5)
t =1
late over time up until default or maturity.

WINTER 2011 THE JOURNAL OF FIXED INCOME 45


JFI-BENZSCHAWEL:Layout 1 12/10/10 10:21 AM Page 46

EXHIBIT 5
Cumulative Risk-Neutral Probabilities of Default by Maturity for Various Credit Rating Categories, March 19, 2010
It is illegal to make unauthorized copies of this article, forward to an unauthorized user or to post electronically without Publisher permission.
The Journal of Fixed Income 2010.20.3:40-55. Downloaded from www.iijournals.com by BARUCH COLLEGE on 03/12/11.

Source: Citi and Markit Partners.

Finally, setting these two present values equal we Exhibit 5 shows average cumulative risk-neutral
arrive at the following expression for the CDS premium: default probabilities for March 19, 2010, for credit ratings
from AAA to CCC. Risk-neutral default probabilities
4 ∗ ∑ t4=T1 dt * (CPDtQ − CPDtQ−1 ) *(1 − RV ) increase monotonically with maturity for all rating classes.
cT = (6)
∑ 4t =T1 dt * (1− CPDtQ ) As expected, the risk-neutral default probabilities are sig-
nificantly higher as credit quality decreases, being lowest
Much of the modeling effort regarding CDS involves for AAA securities and highest for CCC averages.
determining the term structure of firms’ cumulative risk-
neutral default rates over the life of the contract. Using LIMITATIONS OF THE
Equation (6) and an assumed fraction of face value recov- ASSET-SWAP MODEL OF CDS
ered in default, we can determine the values of cumula-
The traditional no-arbitrage model of the CDS as an
tive default rates, CPDtQ , at each node in the lattice in asset-swap has proved useful for understanding the relation-
Exhibit 4. For example, assume that we have as input a ship between bonds and CDS and has aided the develop-
firm’s market derived CDS spreads for a range of matu- ment of the CDS market. However, large displacements in
rities, e.g., c (T = 0.5), c(T = 1.0 ), ..., c (T = 10). The cum- cash and CDS markets and the 300 bp fluctuation in the
ulative risk-neutral probability of defaults, CPDtQ , can then CDS versus cash bond basis for investment-grade credits in
be obtained from this CDS term structure using a boot- recent years have highlighted limitations of that interpretive
strapping procedure: We first extract CPD0Q.5 using c(0.5) framework. There are other concerns as well. These include:
and then obtain CPD1Q using c(1) and CPDQ0.5 obtained in
the first step. The process continues until we obtain CPDtQ • potential profit or losses from interest-rate swap posi-
for all maturities in the CDS term structure. tions on an asset-swap in the event of default that
would not occur with a CDS;

46 CREDIT DEFAULT SWAPS: A CASH FLOW ANALYSIS WINTER 2011


JFI-BENZSCHAWEL:Layout 1 12/10/10 10:21 AM Page 47

• failure to account for the cost of risk on the mark- sold the bond short and terminates the repo (or arranges
to-market of positions in the replicating portfolio a reverse repo).8 Assume that, prior to default, swap rates
arising from changes in swap and repo rates as well have increased. Presumably, the price of the fixed-rate
as changes in either party’s credit risk; borrowed bond will have decreased from par value due
• differences in the price of protection for holders of to an overall rise in rates that is independent of its credit
different bonds issued by the same obligor but priced quality. This has a couple of effects. First, the borrower of
in the market at different relationships to par; the bond is now paying a higher rate than LIBOR on the
• consistent positive CDS premiums for AAA rated face value of the bond at its current market price. That
credits, which almost always trade at premiums to is, a new buyer would have to make a lower absolute pay-
It is illegal to make unauthorized copies of this article, forward to an unauthorized user or to post electronically without Publisher permission.

LIBOR, are inconsistent with the asset-swap analogy ment to fund that same bond at that lower price. Fur-
of CDS. thermore, an investor wishing to enter into a CDS contract
The Journal of Fixed Income 2010.20.3:40-55. Downloaded from www.iijournals.com by BARUCH COLLEGE on 03/12/11.

on that bond will have to buy protection on less than full


Profitability of Asset-Swaps face value of the bond. Under those circumstances, one
in a CDS Replicating Portfolio might expect the CDS price to change as marginal buyers
of protection for bonds bought at less than par, whose
Consider first the mark-to-market sensitivities of a coupon spread to LIBOR remains that of the original
buyer and seller of protection that enter into each side of buyer, will require less total protection since the CDS
an asset-swap replication of a CDS contract as depicted contract is written on par face value, as demonstrated in
in Exhibit 2. For such investors, the structure of the repli- the following section.
cating trade will allow them to meet their contractual
payoffs as if each were involved in a CDS trade. However, Failure of the Law of One CDS Price
investors in the replicating long- and short-CDS portfo-
lios will have additional exposures, even assuming that the Another issue with the CDS as asset-swap analogy
reference bond is trading at par and each side is able to is that the value of credit protection on a single obligor
borrow at LIBOR. For example, the buyer and seller of will differ for investors of its bonds with different coupons
protection will be exposed to movements in swap rates at the same maturity. For example, consider three bonds
from the swap contract. For example, if swap rates rise, all from the same issuer whose indicative information appears
else equal, the buyer of protection will have unrealized in Exhibit 6. Assume that Bond 1 is a five-year bond issued
profit on the swap position that it has obtained at a pre- today at par with a coupon of 7%, approximately equal
viously lower rate and the seller will have a mark-to- to the yield of a BBB rated bond on June 15, 2009. Now
market loss. This is not an immediate issue for either consider another bond, Bond 2, originally issued with a
investor, aside from potential credit exposure and/or 15-year maturity exactly 10 years ago by the same issuer
margin calls, because the protection buyer must continue as Bond 1. At the time Bond 2 was issued, the obligor
to fund the LIBOR swap from the fixed bond proceeds was a much better credit and was able to issue the bond
and the seller of protection will continue to receive the at par with a coupon of 3.4%. However, now that the
increased LIBOR from their bank. Another problem
results from the fact that changes in the CDS contract
may not mirror those of the underlying bonds. That is, E X H I B I T 6
the investor in an asset-swap is exposed to the CDS Indicative Data for Three Five-Year Senior Unsecured
versus cash basis. As shown in Exhibit 3, changes in the Bonds at Par, Discount, and Premium Prices Relative to Par
basis can be large and have moved as much as several
hundred basis points over several months.
Consider also what happens if the bond issuer in
an asset-swap defaults. The seller of protection must
deliver the notional times the par face value of the ref-
erence obligation to the protection buyer in return for
the reference security. The protection seller passes the
reference security to the counterparty to which it has

WINTER 2011 THE JOURNAL OF FIXED INCOME 47


JFI-BENZSCHAWEL:Layout 1 12/10/10 10:21 AM Page 48

obligor is BBB rated, investors are demanding a 7% yield issued 10 years ago as a 15-year bond at 3.4% and now
and Bond 2 is trading at a discounted price of 85. Finally, has 5 years to maturity. Assume that we bought Bond 2
consider a third bond issued five years ago at par, when on June 15, 2009, at 85, a price well below the par value
borrowing by B rated credits required a coupon of 10.6%. of Bond 1. Since both Bond 1 and Bond 2, while trading
At the current coupon rate of 7%, that bond is now trading at 100 and 85, respectively, will have a 40% recovery of
at 115. face value in default, we might require less default pro-
The risk-neutral cumulative probability of default, tection if we owned Bond 2 than if we owned Bond 1.
CPDtQ , at any maturity for this obligor can be calculated Since CDS are quoted in units of 100 points of face value,
from the obligor’s par yield curve and the U.S. Treasury the need for less protection on Bond 2 should translate
It is illegal to make unauthorized copies of this article, forward to an unauthorized user or to post electronically without Publisher permission.

yield curve. For example, to find the risk-neutral default into fewer CDS contracts for a given notional amount of
probability for the 0.5-year par bond, CPD0Q.5, we assume a bonds than for Bond 1 (or an equal number of contracts
The Journal of Fixed Income 2010.20.3:40-55. Downloaded from www.iijournals.com by BARUCH COLLEGE on 03/12/11.

recovery value (in this case 40% of principal) and solve for at a lower spread premium).
the CPDQ0.5 that equates the cash flows from the 0.5-year par We determine the necessary premium on a CDS for
bond to the value of 100 when discounted by the corre- default protection on 100 face of Bond 2. Let N2 be the
sponding Treasury yield. This process is repeated at regular notional amount of protection that we need to buy to neu-
intervals over the life of the bond in question. The resulting tralize the default risk of Bond 2. To break even in default,
CPDtQ curve for the BBB rated par bonds on June 15, 2009, the buyer of Bond 2 will need to get 45 points per 100 face
appears in Exhibit 7. (i.e., 85 – 40) from the protection seller. In terms of CDS
Within the CDS as asset-swap model, we can use the contract, this should be equal to N2 * (1 – RV/100). Thus,
Q
values for CPDt at various maturities in Exhibit 7 to cal- equating these two values, we have
culate the expected premium of a credit default swap via
Equation (6). The value for the premium obtained using  RV 
85 − 40 = N 2 ∗  1 − (7)
U.S. Treasury discount curves is 414 bp per annum. We  100 
can approximate this premium as a yield spread to LIBOR
by subtracting the difference between LIBOR and Trea-
sury spot rates on June 15, 2009, a difference of 48 bps. and therefore N2 = 75. Because Bonds 1 and 2 are from
Thus, our estimate of a five-year CDS premium for this the same obligor, we can solve for the premium, c, using
BBB obligor is roughly 366 bps. the same risk-neutral default probabilities and recovery
Now consider Bond 2, the discount bond issued by rate that we used for Bond 1. The resulting value of c is
the same obligor as Bond 1. As mentioned, Bond 2 was 275 bps per annum.
In fact, a simple way to determine the CDS pre-
mium adjustment required for a bond trading away from
EXHIBIT 7 par is to realize that the relative premium between a par
Risk-Neutral Default Probabilities as a Function and non-par bond from the same firm is directly pro-
of Maturity Implied by BBB Bonds and U.S. Treasury portional to their losses in default. That is, for the example
Par Yield Curves, June 15, 2009 of Bonds 1 and 2,

c non-par 85 − RV 45
c par = 100 − RV ⇒ c non-par = 60 × c par = 275 bp (8)

CDS contracts are quoted in units of 100 face regard-


less of the prices of bonds eligible for delivery in default,
so what is the correct “fair” price of a CDS protection
on an obligor having issued Bonds 1 and 2? Clearly, analysis
based on the risk-neutral credit curve would suggest two
different prices for CDS protection per 100 notional of
Bonds 1 and 2; 366 bps per annum on Bond 1 and

48 CREDIT DEFAULT SWAPS: A CASH FLOW ANALYSIS WINTER 2011


JFI-BENZSCHAWEL:Layout 1 12/10/10 10:21 AM Page 49

275 bps per annum on Bond 2. Similarly, for Bond 3 from receive $75 from the CDS contract and the recovery
this same obligor, having a 10.6% coupon and trading at value of $40 on the excess 25 points of face not
115 for 100 notional, our analysis suggests that the price delivered into the contract (i.e., $10), thereby recov-
of CDS protection necessary to recover the price in default ering their investment. Investor C, having paid $115
is 458 bps. for 100 face of bond, buys 125 units of CDS pro-
One implication of the foregoing analysis is that, for tection to cover potential loss of investment from
a firm having bonds with different market prices relative default. That is, in default, investor C will receive
to par, the cost of protecting one’s original principal can $125 from the CDS contract but must deliver an
vary significantly, thereby providing potential arbitrage additional 25 units of face at a recovery value of $40
It is illegal to make unauthorized copies of this article, forward to an unauthorized user or to post electronically without Publisher permission.

opportunities. For example, consider three investors, A, B, into the CDS contract at a cost of $10.
and C, where A owns 100 face of Bond 1 in Exhibit 6,
The Journal of Fixed Income 2010.20.3:40-55. Downloaded from www.iijournals.com by BARUCH COLLEGE on 03/12/11.

B owns 100 face of Bond 2, and C owns 100 face of In each scenario, we assume a constant default rate
Bond 3. Investor A will pay $100 for Bond 1, whereas of 0.28% (i.e., the annual historical rate for a BBB credit)
investor B pays only $85 for Bond 2 and investor C pays over the five-year contract term. Exhibit 8 displays the
$115 for Bond 3, assuming that the bonds all trade at internal rates of return (IRRs) for investors A, B, and C
equivalent cash flow yields.9 Suppose each investor buys under two different default scenarios for each of the two
protection on their respective investments to cover poten- hedging scenarios. The first row in Exhibit 8 shows that
tial losses from default and, based on the risk-neutral investor A has an expected IRR of 3.4% under average
default curve in Exhibit 7, assume that the cost of CDS default conditions but a return of only 1.7% if default
protection on 100 face is 3.66% per annum. Now, con- occurs within the first six months. Consider for com-
sider expected returns from two different hedging sce- parison the returns for investor B. In Case 1, buying pro-
narios involving investors A, B, and C. tection on 100 face of CDS, IRRs under historical default
rates for investors A and B are similar. The 0.3% advan-
Case 1: Investors A, B, and C each buy CDS on 100 tage for investor A in Case 1 results from the larger
units of face and pay $3.66 a year until maturity or coupon on the par bond and occurs despite the 15-point
default. advantage in cases of default for investor B. However,
Case 2: Investor A again purchases protection of 100 this advantage for investor A will only result on average.
units of face at $3.66. However, investor B now buys That is, as shown in the far right column of Exhibit 8,
CDS protection on only 75% of the outstanding if the issuer defaults in the first six months, investor B will
face of the bond purchased at $85.10 In default, B will have windfall gains of 39%, owing to the 15 points of

EXHIBIT 8
Returns from Investing in Hypothetical BBB Rated Par and Non-Par Bonds for CDS Protection
Bought for Full Face Value of Bonds or Adjusted for Loss Given Default

Note: The average cumulative five-year default rate for a BBB rated credit is roughly 1.4%.

WINTER 2011 THE JOURNAL OF FIXED INCOME 49


JFI-BENZSCHAWEL:Layout 1 12/10/10 10:21 AM Page 50

excess return on the 100 face of CDS protection. the greatest downside risk. More importantly, however,
Exhibit 8 displays IRRs for investor C in Case 1 that these examples reveal clear limitations of the CDS as asset-
are the reverse of those for investor B. That is, for average swap analogy as a general framework for relating bond
default scenarios, investor C performs slightly better than prices to CDS spreads.
investor A (and B), but for early default, investor C suf-
fers a huge loss of 22% on the initial $115 investment. ANALYSIS OF CDS CASH FLOWS
In Case 2, investor B buys CDS protection on only
75% of the outstanding face. Investor B’s annual premium Given the limitations of the CDS as asset-swap
payments therefore will be only $2.75 per unit face per framework described in the previous section, we introduce
It is illegal to make unauthorized copies of this article, forward to an unauthorized user or to post electronically without Publisher permission.

annum per unit of bond face owned. In this case, the a simplified approach to evaluating CDS contracts and
expected IRR for investor B increases to 4.1%, exceeding explore its usefulness for interpreting market data on CDS
The Journal of Fixed Income 2010.20.3:40-55. Downloaded from www.iijournals.com by BARUCH COLLEGE on 03/12/11.

investor A’s IRR of 3.4%. The advantage in expected spreads. In the proposed cash flow framework, we value
returns to investor B under historical default rates results the premium and contingent legs as sums of the discounted
from a combination of relatively low default rates and the values of their expected cash flows under physical mea-
“pull-to-par” at maturity under conditions of no default. sure. For example, Exhibit 9 displays expected cash flows
However, should a default occur in the first six months, from premium and contingent legs of a hypothetical one-
B’s IRR will be only 0.4%, because B, while having his year CDS contract. The values of cpdi are expected cumu-
investment protected, receives little benefit from the pull lative probabilities of actual defaults from time t = 0 to
to par at maturity. The expected IRR for investor C in t = i.11 Notice that the size of the premium payments
Case 2, owner of the premium bond, is lowest at 2.9%, shown on the left-hand side in Exhibit 9 decreases over
owing to the large premium required for 125 points of time, reflecting the fact that their probabilities of payment
CDS protection. However, for an early default, investor decrease as the likelihood of survival decreases over time.
C has a greater IRR than investor A and investor B in Case The contingent payments appear on the right-hand side
2. of Exhibit 9. Over any quarterly interval, expected average
The foregoing analysis has several implications for CDS payouts in default are typically smaller than their
investors in bonds and CDS. First, it is clear that the associated premiums. That is because the larger payouts
risk–reward aspects of CDS protection will differ for are weighted by the probabilities of default. In order to
investors in par and non-par securities from the same issuer. determine the size of the payouts in default one must
In fact, it is not clear which hedging strategy is best for non- assume a recovery value for the reference security. In addi-
par securities as each has its advantages and disadvantages. tion, when valuing the CDS under physical measure we
Buying and hedging discount bonds appears to be the best must also assume a term structure of physical default rates.
overall strategy, whereas investing in premium bonds has For now, we can assume that we know precisely the term

EXHIBIT 9
Example of Quarterly Cash Flows from Premium Leg (left-hand panel) and Contingent Leg (right-hand panel)

Note: L is the Loss Given Default of a Hypothetical One-Year CDS Contract (cash flows not drawn to scale).

50 CREDIT DEFAULT SWAPS: A CASH FLOW ANALYSIS WINTER 2011


JFI-BENZSCHAWEL:Layout 1 12/10/10 10:21 AM Page 51

structure of physical default rates for all tenors for all credit ordered by ratings and show only slight adjustments with
rating categories. We will consider the implications of changes in the credit cycle. However, breakeven spread
estimating those probabilities in a later section. premiums required by sellers of protection vary by more
To can calculate the present values of the premium than a factor of 10 over the cycle.
and contingent legs under physical measure using similar We can compare market CDS spreads with the
equations as those for risk-neutral pricing in Equations (4) inferred breakeven spreads to determine CDS risk pre-
and (5), except we substitute cpdt for CPDtQ such that miums above the calculated compensation for default. That
is, we use market values of CDS premiums to infer the
4N
cT excess compensation required by sellers of protection, who
It is illegal to make unauthorized copies of this article, forward to an unauthorized user or to post electronically without Publisher permission.

PVpremium = ∑ dt ∗ (1 − cpdt ) ∗ (9) are “long” credit exposure, for their large promised pay-
t =1 4
outs in the event of default. Exhibit 11 displays CDS spreads
The Journal of Fixed Income 2010.20.3:40-55. Downloaded from www.iijournals.com by BARUCH COLLEGE on 03/12/11.

by tenor and rating category for the same three points in


and the credit cycle as in Exhibit 10. Notice that, like breakeven
CDS spreads, market CDS premiums also vary greatly over
4N
the credit cycle. For example, CDS spreads in the top left-
PVcontingent = ∑ dt ∗ ( cpdt − cpdt −1 ) ∗ (1 − RV ) (10)
t =1
hand panel, obtained during the high-liquidity, pre-crisis
period, are relatively tight with even CCC spreads below
1,000 bps. In contrast, the CDS spreads in the middle panel
Unlike in the risk-neutral setting there is, a priori,
near the height of the crisis are nearly a factor of 10 larger
no expected premium that relates the PVs for the con-
than those three years earlier. Finally, as the crisis abated
tingent and premium legs. Our approach is to first calcu-
in 2010, spreads have returned to roughly their pre-crisis
late a breakeven premium, bT, as the annualized quarterly
levels, as shown in the bottom panel.
premium necessary to equate the present values of the
The tables in the right-hand portion of Exhibit 11
contingent and premium legs as calculated using expected
display by rating and tenor the CDS risk premiums (i.e.,
physical cash flows. That is,
the excess CDS spreads over breakeven values) at the cor-
responding points in the credit cycle. Notice that, although
4 ∗ ∑ 4t =T1 dt * (cpdt − cpdt −1 ) * (1 − RV ) most values for the risk premium in the tables are posi-
bT = (11)
∑ t4=T1 dt * (1 − cpdt ) tive, during periods of relatively low spread levels, the risk
premiums for high-quality names have been negative. Of
(Note that within the asset-swap framework, bT course, it is possible that the relatively small negative risk
would correspond to the CDS premium.) premiums reflect errors in our assumed default probabil-
To calculate breakeven CDS premiums, we need ities and/or recovery values. However, some of these neg-
estimates of physical default probabilities such as those ative values are a sizable fraction of their estimated
shown in the left-hand panels of Exhibit 10 for several breakeven spread premiums. If correct, these negative risk
points in the credit cycle. Each plot shows cumulative premiums suggest that, for relatively high-quality credits
default curves by rating. Default rates are obtained from at short tenors, sellers of protection during periods of high
historical data and combined with values obtained from liquidity did not receive sufficient compensation to cover
a market-based Merton-type model as described in the their average expected payouts in default. More gener-
Appendix.12 The physical CPD values at the left in ally, spread premiums above those required to compen-
Exhibit 10 are used along with the assumption of an sate for default can be quite large relative to breakeven
average 40% recovery value in default to generate the spreads, particularly during periods of market stress as
breakeven CDS premium curves in the corresponding shown in the middle table of Exhibit 11.
right panels of the exhibit. The top plots are for the high It is important to note that the inferred negative risk
liquidity, tight spread environment of March 2006, with premiums in the top and bottom tables of Exhibit 11
values in the middle panels taken at cyclical wide spreads, would likely not be evident within the CDS as bond asset-
and those in the lower graphs from a more average spread swap framework. That is, since CDS spreads in the asset-
and default environment. Notice that default curves are swap framework are thought to be spreads over LIBOR
rather than simple cash flows, adding LIBOR to the CDS

WINTER 2011 THE JOURNAL OF FIXED INCOME 51


JFI-BENZSCHAWEL:Layout 1 12/10/10 10:21 AM Page 52

EXHIBIT 10
Estimates of Physical Cumulative Default Probabilities (left-hand side) and Breakeven CDS Premiums
(right-hand side) by Credit Rating and Tenor for Three Different Points in the Credit Cycle
It is illegal to make unauthorized copies of this article, forward to an unauthorized user or to post electronically without Publisher permission.
The Journal of Fixed Income 2010.20.3:40-55. Downloaded from www.iijournals.com by BARUCH COLLEGE on 03/12/11.

Note: Breakeven CDS premiums are calculated using Equation (6) and the corresponding default probabilities and a recovery rate in default of 40%.
Source: Citi and Moody’s Investors Service.

premium would result in a greater spread than those shown equivalent hypothesis including difficulties in replicating
for breakeven. However, it would seem difficult to escape a bond synthetically in the CDS and repo markets and
the conclusion that in these times of high liquidity and different implicit CDS premiums for an obligor’s bonds
tight credit spreads, sellers of CDS protection have been of the same maturity but trading at different prices rela-
undercompensated for their risk. tive to par. We also examined an alternative approach to
CDS valuation, one that uses assumed physical default
SUMMARY AND IMPLICATIONS rates as opposed to risk-neutral default rates. The implied
cash flows from each leg under physical measure were
We examined the assumption that credit default then discounted at appropriate risk-free rates and the
swap (CDS) contracts can be replicated by bonds funded resulting breakeven premiums were compared to the
at LIBOR along with an interest-rate swap and a repur- market-implied CDS spreads. Results were presented for
chase agreement. We find limitations of the bond–CDS various rating categories and tenors for several points in

52 CREDIT DEFAULT SWAPS: A CASH FLOW ANALYSIS WINTER 2011


JFI-BENZSCHAWEL:Layout 1 12/10/10 10:21 AM Page 53

EXHIBIT 11
CDS Spreads and Difference between CDS Spreads and Breakeven Spreads by Rating Category
and Tenor for Three Different Points in the Recent Credit Cycle
It is illegal to make unauthorized copies of this article, forward to an unauthorized user or to post electronically without Publisher permission.
The Journal of Fixed Income 2010.20.3:40-55. Downloaded from www.iijournals.com by BARUCH COLLEGE on 03/12/11.

Source: Citi and Markit Partners, Inc.

the credit cycle. The methodology enables measurement APPENDIX


of the minimum amount of risk premium compensation
that must be required by the protection seller to break ESTIMATING PHYSICAL DEFAULT
even for expected default. Our analyses reveal that, at PROBABILITIES
times, market CDS premiums for high-quality credits
were often insufficient to compensate sellers of protection A critical assumption underlying the proposed method-
for expected payouts from default. Furthermore, analyses ology is that cumulative default functions over time are known
for all credits. Fortunately, the credit rating agencies, such as
of CDS cash flows under physical measure highlight asym-
Moody’s and Standard & Poor’s, have compiled extensive sta-
metries between risk premiums received by investors in
tistics on cumulative default rates for issues with given initial
bonds versus CDS that are not evident from similar com- ratings. A summary of those ratings appears in Exhibit A1.
parisons within the CDS as asset-swap framework. Cumulative rates by year are shown out to 15 years, but data
are available for out to 30 years.13 Thus, by knowing the agency

WINTER 2011 THE JOURNAL OF FIXED INCOME 53


JFI-BENZSCHAWEL:Layout 1 12/10/10 10:21 AM Page 54

EXHIBIT A1
Cumulative Default Probabilities for Bonds by Rating Category as a Function of Years since Issuance, 1920–2006
It is illegal to make unauthorized copies of this article, forward to an unauthorized user or to post electronically without Publisher permission.
The Journal of Fixed Income 2010.20.3:40-55. Downloaded from www.iijournals.com by BARUCH COLLEGE on 03/12/11.

Source: Data are from Moody’s Investors Service.

credit rating (or an analyst’s or model equivalent rating), one can 3


This assumes no premium for counterparty risk. Typi-
derive the probabilities of default for each successive time period. cally, counterparty risk has been mitigated by requiring coun-
One problem with using historical default rates for deter- terparties to post margin in response to mark-to-market losses
mining default probabilities is that default rates are credit-cycle- on CDS contracts. Throughout this discussion, we can con-
dependent, ranging from over 12% in some years to less than 1% sider CDS as being traded between AA rated banks whose
in others (Altman [2003]). Thus, in practice, we use a Merton- funding rates are LIBOR.
based contingent claims analysis model to derive estimates of 4
The Z-spread is the yield spread of a bond referenced
default probabilities from one to five years and historical values to the zero-coupon swap curve rather than the riskless zero
after that. For example, Exhibit A1 shows default probabilities curve usually inferred from U.S. Treasury yields.
out to 15 years constructed as a combination of marginal default 5
Throughout this example, we assume that both obligors
rates in years 1–5 from Sobehart and Keenan’s Hybrid Proba- are able to fund at LIBOR and that none of the securities in
bility of Default (HPD) model14 and marginal rates from rating question are trading as special in the repo market. Within the
agencies historical studies after that. For bonds longer than 15 no-arbitrate theory, the lack of LIBOR financing and frictions
years, we fix the marginal rate at the 15-year value for that rating in borrowing the securities in the repo market are responsible,
category. Although there are slight kinks in the default func- at least in part, for the fact that there is rarely a non-zero basis
tions at five years where the model and historical data meet, between cash bonds and their corresponding CDS.
smoothing techniques could be used to adjust those rates. Since 6
The CDS premium is commonly, but inappropriately,
we think that the best estimate of marginal default rates after five called the CDS spread based on its assumed relationship to the
years are average values, we use those. Finally, a preferred method spread to LIBOR of its reference bond. While useful in some
would be to implement the entire pricing model described circumstances, calling the CDS premium a spread obscures the
herein using stochastic default probabilities and stochastic and fact that, unlike bond coupons of which the spread is a fraction
negatively correlated recovery values. Although we have imple- of the entire cash flow, the premium constitutes the entire pay-
mented that methodology in other applications (Benzschawel ment from the protection buyer.
et al. [2005]), we have not yet explored the implications of those 7
The CDX.NA.IG is a basket of 125 North-American
methods on our estimates of risky discount rates. investment-grade CDS contracts. A new index is issued every
six months. For a detailed description of CDS indexes, see
ENDNOTES Markit Partners [2008].
8
We assume for the moment that there is no cost of ter-
1
In fact, determination of what constitutes a credit event minating the repo (i.e., that repo rates on the security have not
can be quite complex and a matter of some debate. In general, changed). Of course, any change in that rate would only com-
a credit event is a legally defined event that includes bankruptcy, plicate matters as well.
9
failure-to-pay, or restructuring. The ISDN and Markit Partners In fact, those bonds might not all trade at the same cash
have devised a procedure whereby consenting parties may resolve flow yield due to the different losses on all three bonds in default.
the issue of a credit event via binding arbitration (Markit Part- For example, assuming a 40% recovery value, investor A would
ners [2009]). lose 60 points in default, whereas investors B and C would lose
2
There are many sources for a basic overview of the credit 45 and 75 points, respectively.
default swap contract. For example, see Rajan [2007].

54 CREDIT DEFAULT SWAPS: A CASH FLOW ANALYSIS WINTER 2011


JFI-BENZSCHAWEL:Layout 1 12/10/10 10:21 AM Page 55

10 Elizalde, A., S. Doctor, and Y. Saltuk. Bond-CDS Basis Hand-


Since CDS contracts trade in units of 100 face of prin-
cipal, it is not possible to buy protection on only 75 points. book. JP Morgan, 2009.
However, for any reasonably sized position, one could purchase
protection on exactly 75% of the outstanding face value of their Hull, J., and A. White. “Valuing Credit Default Swaps I: No
bond investment. Counterparty Default Risk.” The Journal of Derivatives, 8 (2000),
11 pp. 29-40.
Of course, we can not directly observe physical default
rates and must estimate those using credit ratings’ historical
default rates or some other model-based estimate. In fact, risk- Jarrow, R., and S. Turnbull. “Pricing Options on Derivatives
neutral default rates cannot be observed directly either, requiring Subject to Credit Risk.” Journal of Finance, Vol. 50, No. 1 (1995),
an assumed recovery rates. Still, we have an additional source pp. 53-85.
It is illegal to make unauthorized copies of this article, forward to an unauthorized user or to post electronically without Publisher permission.

of uncertainly under the physical measure resulting from esti-


mates of physical defaults. Kakodkar, A., S. Galiani, J.G. Jonsson, and A. Gallo. Credit Deriv-
The Journal of Fixed Income 2010.20.3:40-55. Downloaded from www.iijournals.com by BARUCH COLLEGE on 03/12/11.

12 atives Handbook, Vol. 1. Merrill Lynch, 2006.


Estimates of physical default probabilities are critical
for pricing under physical measure and our approach is to take
historical cumulative default rates and modify them for credit King, M., and M. Sandigursky. “The Added Dimensions of
cycle dependence using a hybrid structural/statistical default Credit: A Guide to Relative Value Trading.” In The Structured
model. Credit Handbook, edited by A. Rajan, G. McDermott, and R. Roy,
13 pp. 111-144. New York, NY: John Wiley and Sons, 2007.
See Corporate Default and Recovery Rates, 1920–2007,
Moody’s Investors Service, February 2008, and Default, Transi-
tion and Recovery: 2007 Annual Global Corporate Default Study and Kumar, P., and S. Mithal. “Relative Value between Cash and Default
Rating Transitions, Standard & Poor’s, February 5, 2008. Swaps in Emerging Markets.” Salomon Smith Barney, 2001.
14
The HPD model combines a contingent claims approach
of Merton with an Altman-like statistical approach. See Sobe- Markit Partners. “Markit Credit Indices: A Primer.” Markit
hart and Keenan [2002, 2003]. Partners, 2008.

——. “The CDS Big Bang: Understanding the Changes to the


REFERENCES Global CDS Contract and North American Conventions.”
Markit Partners, 2009.
Altman, Edward I. “Market Size and Investment Performance
of Defaulted Bonds and Bank Loans: 1987–2002.” Journal of O’Kane, D. Modeling Single-Name and Multi-Name Credit Deriv-
Applied Finance, Vol. 13, No. 2 (2003), pp. 43-53. atives. Wiley, 2009.

Benzschawel, T., L. Lorilla, and G. McDermott. “Effect of Sto- O’Kane, D., and S. Turnbull. “Valuation of Credit Default
chastic and Correlated Defaults and Recoveries on CDO Swaps.” Lehman Brothers, 2003.
Tranche Returns.” The Journal of Structured Finance, Vol. 11, No.
2 (2005), pp. 44-63. Rajan, A. “A Primer on Credit Default Swaps.” In The Structured
Credit Handbook, edited by A. Rajan, G. McDermott, and R. Roy,
Benzschawel, T., J.-H. Ryu, J. Jiang, and M. Carnahan. “Rela- pp. 17-37. New York, NY: John Wiley and Sons, 2007.
tive Value among Corporate Credits.” Quantitative Credit Ana-
lyst 5, Citigroup (February 2, 2006), pp. 7-23. Sobehart, J., and S. Keenan. “Hybrid Contingent Claims Models:
A Practical Approach to Modeling Default Risk.” In Credit
Bohn, J. “A Survey of Contingent-Claims Approaches to Risky Ratings: Methodology, Rationale and Default Risk, edited by
Debt Valuation.” Journal of Risk Finance, Vol. 1, No. 3 (2000), pp. M. Ong, pp. 125-149. UK: Risk Books, 2002,
53-70.
——. “Hybrid Probability of Default Models.” Quantitative
Choudhry, M. The Credit Default Swap Basis. New York, NY: Credit Analyst 3, Citi Markets and Banking, September 10, 2003,
Bloomberg Press, 2006. pp. 1-25.

Duffie, D., and K. Singleton. “Modeling Term Structures of


Defaultable Bonds.” Review of Financial Studies, Vol. 12, No. 4 To order reprints of this article, please contact Dewey Palmieri at
(1999), pp. 687-720. dpalmieri@iijournals.com or 212-224-3675.

WINTER 2011 THE JOURNAL OF FIXED INCOME 55

Anda mungkin juga menyukai