Anda di halaman 1dari 6

Research Policy 31 (2002) 185–190

Editorial

1. Introduction Several of the papers discuss the need to define


the limits for the innovation system in geographical
This issue of Research Policy brings together a and economic space—national versus technological
number of scholars who have made important con- and sectoral systems. This is true for the papers by
tributions to the analysis of innovation systems. The Lundvall et al., Carlsson et al. and Malerba. Another
modern version of the innovation system concept was important theme addressed especially in the papers by
introduced in a booklet on user–producer interaction Nelson and Coriat/Weinstein is the need to develop
and product innovation (Lundvall, 1985, p. 55). It a concept of institution that distinguishes it from and
was brought to an international audience by Freeman relates it to organisation and technology. The paper by
(1987) and by some of the contributions in Dosi et al. Niosi points to the need for a more precise approach to
(1988) (see Freeman, 1988; Nelson, 1988; Lundvall, study the performance of national innovation systems.
1988). Niosi and colleagues gave an early critical In this introduction, we will not try to make a sum-
perspective on the concept (Niosi et al., 1993). Bo ming up on all the issues raised in the papers. We will
Carlsson and his colleagues introduced the concept reflect upon three questions. Why study systems of
of technological system in the beginning of the 1990s innovation? How does the concept relate to economic
(Carlsson et al., 1992). Malerba introduced the con- theory? How to design the analysis if the major aim is
cept of sectoral innovation systems in the second half to understand and contribute to regional and national
of the nineties but it has roots back in his earlier work development?
(Malerba and Orsenigo, 1993). Coriat worked with
a concept similar to national innovation systems but 1.1. Why study innovation systems?
more focused on the national characteristics of the
manufacturing sector under the heading of ‘Made in In this issue, innovation systems are introduced
France’ (see Taddei and Coriat, 1993). at three different levels. The papers by Freeman and
The aim of this issue is to take stock of the field Lundvall et al. analyse innovation systems as spa-
of research and to define some of the most important tial and economic–political entities. The focus is
tasks ahead. Several of the papers raise important mainly on national innovation systems. The article by
methodological issues and aims at clarifying central Carlsson et al. is about technological systems and the
concepts connected to the innovation system ap- one by Malerba about sectoral systems. At all three
proach. Most of the articles were first presented at levels, we can separate out three possible objectives
the 1999 DRUID Summer Conference on Innova- for the analysis. The first is to enhance the understand-
tion Systems at Rebild Bakker. The two introductory ing of historical processes of economic evolution. The
papers by Freeman and by four Aalborg economists second is to establish a basis for decision-making and
(Lundvall, Johnson, Dalum and Andersen) have been policy. The third is to contribute to theory.
added to the selection in order to give more full While the major direction in Freeman’s contribu-
coverage of the subject. tion is toward the first objective it also gives some
The paper by Freeman gives an effective demonstra- important hints to theory. The emphasis on the match
tion of the usefulness of the concept for understanding and mismatch between structure and institutions
the history of the wealth of nations over long periods. as fundamental for the relative success of regional

0048-7333/02/$ – see front matter © 2002 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved.
PII: S 0 0 4 8 - 7 3 3 3 ( 0 1 ) 0 0 1 4 3 - 3
186 Editorial / Research Policy 31 (2002) 185–190

and national institutions and his distinction between including a given stock of publicly shared techni-
passive and active learning systems give important cal knowledge, engage in making rational choices.
signposts for future theoretical work. On the basis of this set of assumptions, normative
The contribution by Lundvall et al. is mainly add- conclusions about how the economic system should
ressed to policy issues in more and in less developed be organised are drawn. This theoretical perspective,
economies. It uses the system’s concept to demon- where scarcity is at the core of the analysis and where
strate the need to integrate and co-ordinate different there is little room for genuine uncertainty, might
policy areas that tend to be seen as separate and be useful for the analysis of partial and short term
independent. Again there are elements in the analysis issues. It is less adequate though for the analysis of
that have theoretical implications. The idea of isolat- economic development.
ing an economic sphere where institutions and social When the objective of the analysis is to understand
elements are absent is not at all useful when the fo- economic development the process of innovation—
cus is on innovation as an interactive process. The the on-going creation and diffusion of new products
system perspective may thus be seen as a remedy to and processes—must be taken into account. Today,
exaggerated specialisation both in policy making and the rate of change in these dimensions is rapid and
academic research. the firm which were to use all its efforts to allocate
The analysis of technological system contributes existing resources in a better way, while sticking to
primarily to the first two types of objectives. It im- the same product and the same techniques, would not
proves the understanding of how specific technolo- only stagnate; it would gradually become increasingly
gical fields have evolved in an interaction between go bankrupt because its products would become less
firms and knowledge institutions. It may be especially and less in demand.
helpful in supporting industrial policy and techno- In this perspective, it becomes clear that the in-
logy policy when it comes to promote new emerging formation and knowledge that agents already have,
technological systems. But it also helps to qualify may be less important than their learning capability.
innovation theory by helping us to understand what Again, in a rapidly changing world, the well-informed
are general and technology specific characteristics of and knowledgeable agent—be it an individual or a
innovation processes. collective unit—would soon find him/her/themselves
The analysis of sectoral systems of innovation is by-passed by competitors if he/she/they did not learn
perhaps the approach most closely related to a specific anew and this includes learning to do new things and
sub-field in economic theory. It represents an original to handle new situations as well as getting access to
contribution to industrial economics with its emphasis new information.
on industrial dynamics. At the same time, it offers One basic intention behind the concept of national
decision makers in the private and public sector with systems of innovation is thus to change the analytical
a taxonomy that may help them to avoid the trap of perspective from allocation to innovation and from
generalising policies without taking sector specificities decision-making to learning. This can be illustrated in
into account. the following way Table 1.
The emphasis on the three objectives is different It should be noted that the learning perspective can
but the three levels of analysis have in common that be applied also to allocation. This is the case in cer-
they aim at understanding economic dynamics in a tain Austrian contributions where the entrepreneur in
systemic context. By sharing this aim they present a connection with the market process is obtaining profit
critical perspective on standard economics. through exploiting the void of ignorance separating
suppliers from users (Kirzner, 1979). It should also be
1.2. Innovation systems and economic theory noted that certain aspects of the process of innovation
have been approached from a neo-classical perspec-
Neo-classical and new-classical economics focus tive of rational choice (selection of R&D-projects,
on problems of allocation in a general equilibrium allocation of R&D-resources as a process of ratio-
context. The basic perspective is one were agents nal choice). It is only when we combine innovation
with given preferences and amounts of information, and learning in the analytical perspective that we
Editorial / Research Policy 31 (2002) 185–190 187

Table 1
The NSI-perspective is evolutionary and takes into account innovation and learning
Allocation Innovation

Rational choice Neo-classical economics Management of innovation


Learning Austrian economics Evolutionary economics

effectively transcend the limits of the neo-classical impact upon how the economic agents behave and how
paradigm. firms perform.
For instance it is not reasonable to analyse a pro- If institutions define how things are done and how
cess of learning and innovation without bringing learning takes place it is the economic structure which
fundamental uncertainty into the picture. To do so affects what is done, and therefore, what is learnt.
would boil down to the contradictory assumption It should not be too controversial to argue that the
that learners already knew everything which could economic structure differs between countries. For in-
be learnt in advance and that innovators knew all stance, international specialisation is at the very core
possible outcomes of the process of innovation. of neo-classical trade theory. What is important is that
The NSI approach is also critical to derived dog- the specialisation reflects advantages that have been
mas about the general superiority of pure markets and created by cumulative processes of learning rather
of maximum flexibility in the conditions of workers. than ‘natural’ comparative advantages. The economic
It reflects the assumption that innovation is rooted structure and the pattern of specialisation will reflect
in processes of interactive learning and interactive accumulated learning and at the same time it will be
learning does not thrive in pure markets. Especially a major factor in determining the direction of future
in labour markets, industrial relations and inter-firm learning and innovation. This reflects the fundamental
relationships, elements of ‘rigidity’ of long-term assumption behind the system of innovation approach:
non-market relationships involving authority, loyalty that interactive learning is rooted in routine activities
and trust are necessary to make learning possible. The and that most search activities will be closely oriented
pure market economy would if it could be reproduced toward problems emanating from the existing set of
in reality get close to what Schumpeter defined as economic activities.
a state of Circular Flow. Little learning would take
place, few innovations would be introduced and the 1.4. Do institutions shape structure or is it the
economy would be stagnant. It would definitely be structure that determines the institutional set-up?
another world than modern capitalism.
Among those who recognise that national differ-
1.3. On the importance of institutions ences exist some have argued that the differences em-
and economic structure anate mainly from structural characteristics (Breschi
and Malerba, 1997). In principle, the composition of
The focus on interactive learning evokes also the the economy in terms of sectors or technologies may
important role of economic structure and institutions explain completely the institutional differences bet-
in determining the rate and direction of innovative ween countries. If this were the case a kind of revised
activities. Institutions understood as norms, habits and neo-classical history might be constructed. First,
rules are deeply ingrained in society and they play a countries became specialised in specific products—
major role in determining how people relate to each reflecting for instance the relative scarcity of factors
other and how they learn and use their knowledge (see of production and raw materials. Given the resulting
the contributions by, respectively, Richard Nelson and specialisation the institutional characteristics were
Coriat and Weinstein in this issue). In an economy established.
characterised by on-going innovation and fundamental Others have taken the opposite road and try to
uncertainty the institutional setting will have a major demonstrate that the institutional set-up is a major
188 Editorial / Research Policy 31 (2002) 185–190

factor in determining the specialisation of the nati- levels of dynamism that all have an impact on wealth
onal economy (Guerreri and Tylecote, 1997). They creation. First, the capacity utilisation, allocation and
try to predict the pattern of technological and sectoral the on-going reallocation of given resources as rela-
specialisation of the national economy by character- tive prices change are important for wealth creation
ising it in terms of its institutional characteristics. (neo-classical and Kirznerian dynamics). Second, so
Both these perspectives may be partially right. On will the introduction and diffusion of innovations and
the one hand it is reasonable to assume that the his- the introduction and growth of new industries on the
torical pattern of specialisation which often had its basis of a given set of competences (Schumpeterian
roots in access to natural resources has affected the and Penrosian dynamics). Third, one major outcome
institutional set-up. Once this institutional set-up has of investment in knowledge production or of learning
become established it is reasonable to assume that it processes is the creation of new competences and this
will attract those industries which are most compat- may be what determines performance in the very long
ible with it. The two perspectives converge in their run (learning economy dynamics).
emphasis of the fact that the two dimensions of the To analyse sectoral, technological and national sys-
innovation system are interdependent. tems along these lines may be useful. In some more
This interdependence is one reason why it is mean- stable sectors and technologies (construction, transport
ingful to apply a system’s perspective. But some care and retailing) neo-classical dynamics may be most
should be exercised to avoid simplistic functionalist important while in the most dynamic (software and
reasoning. As a matter of fact the main reason for knowledge intensive business services) the creation
differences in performance between national systems of new competences are crucial for performance.
may be that the degree of matching between struc- National systems may be more or less prone to sup-
ture and institutions differ among countries (see the port these different kinds of dynamics. The Japanese
contribution by Freeman). Institutions may be rooted model (cross-ownership, long term employment and
far back in social history and they might be slow to supplier contracts) promoted Schumpeterian and
adapt to the change in economic structure. Therefore, learning economy dynamics in a more stable context
one should not expect a one to one correlation and while the present US success in Hi tech seems to
the kind of analysis referred to above could have as reflect the combination of institutions that are more
its most important outcome a better understanding of successful in a context of accelerating rates of change
why a complete matching does not appear and how (high mobility in labour markets and venture capital).
this affects the performance of systems of innovation.
1.6. National innovation systems
1.5. Innovation systems and economic dynamics in the learning economy

One of the themes discussed in the paper by The national innovation system approach gained
Carlsson et al. and in the paper by Malerba is how to ground as empirical findings through the 1970s and
define the limits of an innovation system. It is almost 1980s revealed that innovations reflect a process where
trivial to say that the appropriate definition must feed backs from the market and knowledge inputs
reflect the intentions of the use of the concept. In what from users interact with knowledge creation and en-
follows we will discuss the appropriate definition trepreneurial initiatives on the supply side. These rela-
under the assumption that the objective is to under- tionships and interactions between agents involved
stand the performance in terms of wealth creation and non-market relationships and they were presented as
sustainability of a national economy. organised markets with elements of power, trust and
One of the most fundamental characteristics of the loyalty (Lundvall, 1985). It was also demonstrated that
innovation system approach is that it opens up for different national contexts offered disparate possibil-
understanding economic dynamics and socio-economic ities for establishing organised markets. A series of
development. At the same time it is important to reco- studies pointed, for instance, to the long term develop-
gnise that economic performance may reflect more ment of selective inter-firm relationships in Japan and
or less dynamic capabilities. We may separate three contrasted them with the arm’s length relationships
Editorial / Research Policy 31 (2002) 185–190 189

predominating in the Anglo Saxon countries (Dore, to combine bench-marking with insights of systemic
1986; Sako, 1990). characteristics of national economies. What appears
The specific character of user–producer relation- as a good practise in one systemic context will often
ships may still be seen as one of the factors that prove to be less so in another.
structure and separate regional and national innova- The complexities of benchmarking may also be
tion systems. The transformation of the economy to stated in terms of the vocabulary on different orders
a state with more rapid change points to a need to of dynamics introduced above. Some institutions and
supplement this perspective with one where human practises may promote first order (neo-classical) dy-
resources and competence building in general comes namics, others second order dynamics and finally a
more into focus. The point is that in more and more third type may support third order dynamics. Rather
sectors firms are confronted with an increasing trans- than locating best practises there will be a need for
formation pressure reflecting the combined impact of diversity in institutions and practises so that systems
new technology, deregulation and the entrance of new strike a reasonable balance between the different
competitors at the global level. This transformation orders of dynamics.
pressure gives a premium to organisations that have To benchmark states of systems may also be less
the capability to renew their competences. For firms interesting than to compare the dynamic properties of
in the exposed sectors the alternatives are either to innovation systems. One interesting exercise would
move to a lower cost region and close down or to be to compare how national and regional systems ex-
enhance its competence building capacity. This can posed to similar types of transformation pressure cope
be done by building competence in house, by hiring with these given the constellation of institutions and
competent personnel in the labour market or by en- structure. Why did the Swedish and the Danish econ-
tering into closer and more intense and close network omy within a decade change place in terms of GNP
relationships. This indicates that a system’s approach per capita (GNP per capita was 20% higher in Sweden
to the performance of national systems needs to focus and now it is 20% higher in Denmark)? What forms of
not only upon network relationships but also on edu- transformation in terms of adjustment, innovation and
cation and training, the dynamics in the labour market competence-building took place in the two systems?
and the diffusion of new forms of organisation (with
learning organisation characteristics).
References
1.7. Benchmarking national innovation systems
Breschi, S., Malerba, F., 1997. Sectoral innovation systems.
In: Edquist, C. (Ed.), Systems of Innovation: Technologies,
Recently, there has been an explosive growth in institutions and organizations. Pinter Publishers, London.
the interest for ‘benchmarking’ national economies Carlsson, B., Eliasson, G., Granberg, A., Jacobsson, S.,
in different dimensions. The idea that there are more Stankiewicz, R., 1992. Sveriges teknologiska system och fram-
or less efficient ways of organising innovation related tida konkurrensförmåga (The Swedish technological system and
its prospective comptetitiveness). Report from the STS-Project.
activities has been accepted in the European Union Dore, R., 1986. Flexible Rigidities: Industrial Policy and Structural
and currently there are many different initiatives em- Adjustment in the Japanese Economy, 1970–1980. Athlone
anating from Bruxelles. The rational core of bench- Press, London.
marking is that it promotes reflection on how you do Dosi, et al. (Eds.), 1988. Technology and Economic Theory. Pinter
things and that you may be inspired by how it is done Publishers, London.
Freeman, C., 1987. Technology Policy and Economic Performance:
elsewhere—it promotes ‘learning by comparing’. Lessons from Japan. Pinter Publishers, London.
On the other hand, the idea that there in specific Freeman, C., 1988. Japan: a new national system of innovation?
areas exist general ‘best-practise’ that ought to be dif- In: Dosi, et al. (Eds.), Technology and Economic Theory. Pinter
fused to all other countries is unsound. The reason that Publishers, London.
it is unsound is of course that what is ‘best’ practise Guerreri, P., Tylecote, A., 1997. Interindustry differences in
technical change and national patterns of technological
will depend on the context and that there are systemic accumulation. In: Edquist, C. (Ed.), Systems of Innovation:
differences between countries. Therefore, a process of Technologies, Institutions and Organizations. Pinter Publishers,
successful policy learning and policy perfection needs London.
190 Editorial / Research Policy 31 (2002) 185–190

Kirzner, I.M., 1979. Perception, Opportunity and Profit: Studies Sako, M., 1990. Buyer–supplier relationships and economic
in the Theory of Entrepreneurship. Chicago University Press, performance: evidence from Britain and Japan. Ph.D. Thesis,
Chicago. University of London, London.
Lundvall, B.-Å., 1985. Product Innovation and User–Producer Taddei, D., Coriat, B., 1993. Made in France, Paris, Librairie
Interaction. Aalborg University Press, Aalborg. Generale Francaise.
Lundvall, B.-Å., 1988. Innovation as an interactive process: from
user–producer interaction to the national system of innovation.
In: Dosi, et al. (Eds.), Technology and Economic Theory. Pinter
Publishers, London. Esben Sloth Andersen∗
Malerba, F., Orsenigo, L., 1993. Technological regimes and firm
Bengt-Åke Lundvall, Henrik Sorrn-Friese
behaviour. Industrial and Corporate Change 19 (1), 45–71.
Nelson, R.R., 1988. Institutions supporting technical change in the Copenhagen Business School, Aalborg University
United States. In: Dosi, et al. (Eds.), Technology and Economic Fibigerstraede 4, 9220 Alaborg, Denmark
Theory. Pinter Publishers, London. ∗ Corresponding
Niosi, J., Saviotti, P., Belon, B., Crow, W., 1993. Natural systems author. Fax: +45-98-156013
of innovators: In search of a workable concept. Technology in E-mail address: esa@business.auc.dk
Society 15 (3), 207–227. (E.S. Andersen)

Anda mungkin juga menyukai