Anda di halaman 1dari 258

ROLE OF LOCAL COMMUNITIES AND INSTITUTIONS IN INTEGRATED RURAL DEVELOPMENT

Report of the APO Seminar on Role of Local Communities and Institutions in Integrated Rural Development held in Islamic Republic of Iran, 15-20 June 2002 (ICD-SE-3-01) This report was edited by Dr. Chandrasekera M. Wijayaratna, Agricultural/Natural Resources Economist, Institutional Strengthening Specialist, Auckland, New Zealand. The opinions expressed in this publication do not reflect the official view of the Asian Productivity Organization. For reproduction of the contents in part or in full, the APOs prior permission is required. Asian Productivity Organization, 2004

CONTENTS

Foreword Part I Part II Summary of Findings . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1 Resource Papers 1. Role of Local Communities and Institutions in Integrated Rural Development Chandrasekera M. Wijayaratna . . 2. Local Communities and Institutions: Realizing Their Potential for Integrated Rural Development Norman Uphoff . . 3. What Makes Effective Local Organizations and Institutions in Natural Resource Management and Rural Development Robert J. Fisher . . 4. Institutionalization of Peoples Self-organizing Actions for Rural Development: Comparative Analysis of Micro-finance Organizations in Rural Thailand, Philippines, and Indonesia Shinichi Shigetomi . . Country Papers 1. Bangladesh Abdul Aziz Talukder 2. Republic of China Shih-jui Tung 3. Fiji Akhill Chand 4. India R. K. Tripathi 5. Islamic Republic of Iran (1) Hassan Hashemi Daran 6. Islamic Republic of Iran (2) Hossein Mahdidoust 7. Islamic Republic of Iran (3) Javad Sayahi Kashi 8. Islamic Republic of Iran (4) Masoud Motamedi 9. Nepal Dirgha Man Shrestha 10. Pakistan Abdul Sattar 11. Philippines Adeliza F. Gabalfin 12. Sri Lanka R. D. S. Jayatunga 13. Thailand Sanit Suwansorn 14. Vietnam Tran Viet My . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

34 63 85

97

Part III

120 132 141 144 168 175 185 190 194 208 217 228 239 246

Part IV

Appendices 1. List of Participants, Resource Speakers, and Secretariat . . . . . . . . . . . . 251 2. Program of Activities . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 255

SUMMARY OF FINDINGS

BACKGROUND In the development of rural communities in Asia and Pacific, the coordination of various rural development activities has been indispensable to maximizing and sustaining rural development efforts. This has been accomplished in a major way with the adoption of an Integrated Rural Development (IRD) strategy in many countries. The IRD programs usually require the establishment of a central coordinating organization at the national level. The experiences in the implementation of such programs, however, reveal that the new central organization would merely create an additional stratum of bureaucracy and has not been effective in coordinating the various activities done by different sectors in the rural development efforts. Accordingly, some IRD programs such as those in Sri Lanka, Nepal and Malaysia have set up coordinating mechanisms at the lower levels involving project offices and local government units in the identified project areas. With the decentralized manner of project implementation, peoples participation in the process of rural development has been stressed and made an indispensable component of the program. Under such circumstances, the role of local institutions such as local government units, both formal and informal local organizations like cooperatives, culture groups, and NGOs, is becoming more important for sustainable rural development and realizing integration of various rural development efforts. It is useful, therefore, to undertake a comparative analysis of the role of local communities and institutions for IRD projects in member countries, and to identify innovative approaches through benchmarking efforts for the future direction to be pursued in this respect. Accordingly, the present seminar examined the role of various stakeholders in IRD based on the experiences and findings of the past Integrated Community Development (ICD) program activities.1 Objectives The objective of the Seminar was to undertake a comparative study by way of examining the nature, role and functions of local communities and various local institutions in member countries in terms of sustainable integrated rural development and their future directions. Methodology The Seminar consisted of technical inputs by resource paper presentations, experience sharing through country paper presentations, learning from the field through field visits and summing-up session. The seminar included individual assignments, small group workshops and plenary discussions. The workshops have been structured through a participatory process at plenary sessions and at the end of each workshop, the groups presented the output to the plenary. At the plenary sessions, issues emerged from small groups were discussed and

The ICD program has been implemented by the Asian Productivity Organization since 1996. -1-

debated to reach consensus. This process has contributed to reflect and internalize the learning of the seminar. The major topics covered during the seminar were as follows: a) b) c) d) Review of historical evolution of IRD in member countries with special attention to the role of local communities and institutions; Identification of local communities and institutions and definition of their nature: such as local government units; local organizations (formal/informal and historical/new), NGOs, etc; Comparison of such local communities and institutions in member countries; and Future direction of role of local communities and institutions for sustainable IRD.

Participants The seminar was participated by 13 participants from 11 APO member countries; Bangladesh, Republic of China, Fiji, India, Islamic Republic of Iran (3), Nepal, Pakistan, Philippines, Sri Lanka, Thailand and Vietnam. Three observers from the host country also attended the seminar. Majority of them were government officers responsible for rural community development in respective member countries, and a few of the participants were from NGO and academia involved in rural community development. Three international resource persons, from Australia, Japan, and New Zealand contributed to the seminar. The facilitator from the host organizations, Ministry of Jihad for Agriculture, the Islamic Republic of Iran, conducted the entire process of the seminar. HIGHLIGHTS OF RESOURCE PAPERS The following are the highlights of resource papers presented at the seminar. Role of Local Communities and Institutions in Integrated Rural Development This paper examined the role of local communities and institutions in IRD. More specifically, it emphasized on the role of two major actors: a) local government; and b) community organizations and institutions under the category of local communities. In addition, the role of NGOs and the organized private sector was examined briefly. First, the paper submitted a brief account on the evolution of rural development approaches and the recent emphasis on decentralization and its impact on IRD. Next, the paper elaborated on the shared roles and responsibilities in rural development (especially after decentralization). Effective IRD, which cuts across multiple sectors, is a multidisciplinary affair and it is difficult to separate the roles of different stakeholders. This discussion was followed by brief accounts on the specific roles of: a) local government; b) local communities; c) NGOs; and d) organized private sector. Subsequently, with special reference to local communities, the paper examined the role of capacity-building. Following this, constraints on effective IRD were examined. In the past, rural development had been adversely affected by top-down approaches to development and has become supply-driven in many countries. On the contrary, recent developments in decentralization advocate a demand-driven strategy and have the merit of considering the specific demands and potential of each locality. The local government institutions and local community organizations could establish a collaborative partnership in undertaking the responsibility for developing a local vision and strategy; and designing/ planning, allocating resources, implementing and monitoring/evaluating of development

-2-

activities that would better cater the local needs. They would jointly become the driving force towards development, develop a sense of shared ownership and become managers of their development initiatives. An important function of the central government would be the formulation and implementation of policies to facilitate the effective functioning of the new roles assumed by the other actors. With decentralization, local governments will have to assume greater responsibilities and would become the focal centers for local development. Local governments have to be effectively linked with the national levels as well as with local communities. They would be expected to undertake certain activities hitherto performed by the central government, such as certain legal and regulatory functions and the provision of services like extension. In addition, especially with increased demand and diversification of economic activities mainly due to the growing emphasis on globalization and associated changes, they would be entrusted with extra responsibilities. These may include guiding local communities, especially at the take-off stage, facilitating the capacity-building of local communities, catalyzing the interactions between the community organizations and the organized private sector, installation of monitoring mechanisms, etc. For effective IRD, local communities should be organized themselves to undertake planning and managing development and are expected to take over the management of support services. To achieve sustainability, the challenge is to facilitate and institutionalize a process through which rural communities themselves would evolve local organizations to satisfy their own local needs. Effective utilization of social capital can be singled out as the most important role of local communities in IRD. As a prerequisite for accumulation and the effective mobilization of social capital for community development, improving or upgrading the human capital is crucial. Developing skills of the individuals in a given society will enhance the quality and quantity of the output of social capital such as the collective action. Matured organizations may wish to expand their scope, for instance by expanding their economic activity. Then the organizational structure should be adjusted for efficient handling of these new tasks and roles. One of the most important roles of community organizations and institutions would be to link community with external markets and supply services. In this regard, sustainable financial institutions geared to better serving the needs of medium-, small, and micro-enterprises including sound and efficient banking systems and capital markets should also be promoted. Peoples companies or similar institutions may be more appropriate at that stage. They may have better legal power and recognition and are readily accepted by the organized private sector. This is important for business ventures. Usually, NGOs help reduce government domination at local level. It is suggested that the major role of NGOs in IRD is to facilitate institutional development/strengthening in the communities. At the community level, in order to achieve effective and sustainable rural development, the challenge is to facilitate and institutionalize a process through which rural communities themselves would evolve local organizations to satisfy their own local needs. For this, a catalytic process or a planned intervention into the community is required. Such a catalytic effort should be strong enough to generate the internal dynamism of the community and controlled enough not to dominate it. And, experienced and effective NGOs could bridge this gap and play a catalytic role. Also, in collaboration with the members of other participating organizations, local officials of relevant agencies, and resource persons such as technical experts; the NGOs could pave the way for participatory monitoring and evaluation (M&E) and management information systems.

-3-

Globalization has now become an unavoidable process and an organized local community should have the capacity to consider it as an opportunity rather than a threat. In this, an effective partnership between the organized private sector and organized communities would be mutually beneficial. And, initially, local governments could facilitate this process. The challenge would be to make rural people active partners in the global economy and improve their living standards. Major obstacles to the effective participation of local communities and institutions in IRD include: resource constraints, including financial, human and physical such as rural infrastructure; problems of accountability and lack of transparency; political conflicts and inadequacies in support services. In addition, there is a need for institutional mechanisms to coordinate the decisions taken by a large number of individuals at community level, between communities and between communities and other actors such as the government (at different levels) and the organized private sector. Local Communities and Institutions: Realizing Their Potential for Integrated Rural Development2 There are various reasons why local communities and local institutions have not played more effective roles in rural development. These include: internal conflicts, lack of education, experience and skill, a psychology of dependency and a correlated sense of inefficacy, domination by certain local groups, unfavorable policy environment, over centralization of government, psychology of paternalism, certain financial interests and divisions along ethnic or other social faultiness. This paper examined the results of a comparative study involving 16 countries across Asia and summarized the most systematic efforts to conceptualize and organize thinking on this subject and provided the mental tools for making assessments. The fruits of rural development, agricultural, economic, social and human, were measured in physical terms. Indicators covered the period 1950-70 and included: grain yields, rates of increase in grain yield, per capita agricultural production, fertilizer application, life expectancy, infant mortality, per capita caloric intakes, literacy rates, school enrolment, population growth, and income distribution. Indicators selected for possible causal explanations included: autonomy of local institutions, linkage to higher-level institutions, roles they played in rural development, and the extent of local participation in development activities. Scores were assigned on a scale of 0-3 to the upward and downward linkages of communication and cooperation and subsequently looked at basic functions of rural development. It turned out that the 16 cases fell into two fairly distinct sets, which we characterized as more organized and less organized, according to both criteria: China, Egypt, Israel, Japan, Rep. of Korea, Sri Lanka, Taiwan, and Yugoslavia fell into the first category, and Bangladesh, India, Indonesia, Malaysia, Pakistan, Philippines, Thailand and Turkey. The more organized country cases were far ahead of the less organized ones first in absolute agricultural performance, and in relative increases over a period of 20 or 25 years, and with regard to total agricultural production per capita. In the social domain, demographic and other measures likewise showed a clear advantage for the more organized cases. In less than two decades these two sets of countries had diverged dramatically in many respects. This study was conducted in 1974, and at a later stage, after analyzing 150 cases of rural local
2

In the absence of Prof. Norman Uphoff, Dr. Chandrasekera M. Wijayaratna presented this paper. -4-

organizations around the world (49 countries from Latin America, Africa, Asia and the Middle East), it has been found out again that, very substantial, systematic and statistical support for the proposition that local organization, and particular linkage variables, contributed to better rural development performance. Vertical linkage was thus a contributing factor to multidimensional success in rural development. Similarly, but even more strongly, horizontal linkage with organizations at the same level contributed to better rural local organizational performance. A combination of horizontal and vertical linkage added to this effect. Also, there is a curvilinear relationship between local organizations linkage with the government and their performance. It was found that where governments undertake to establish local organizations at their own initiative, unilaterally, in what is characterized as a top-down manner, the performance was mediocre. Successful organizations could be established when government or non-governmental actors approached communities in a non-imperative manner, seeking to foster bottom-up capacities. This is characterized as a catalytic approach. This means that organizational structures, purposes and procedures are not imposed from outside but rather are developed together with rural communities, so that their directions and leadership are thoroughly understood and supported. Catalysts are different from change agents or extension personnel in that they are not promoting a particular change or new technology. Instead, they try to help communities build up their own capacities. In defining local communities, the paper submitted the following propositions: a) communities are not always natural social units; b) communities are often not cohesive, harmonious social entities; c) communities do not exist in isolation; and d) community development too often lacked connections to technical expertise. The paper suggested that what is local should be best understood in an analytical framework that covers the range of development decision-making and activities, from the individual to the international level. The community or village level is one we are most familiar with, in part because it has a very visible manifestation: a set of dwellings, and associated residents, clustered together or at least designated by common agreement to belong to a particular village. Such communities are usually to some extent self-governing, with designated persons in roles of authority, formal or informal. The group level is generally below the community level and individuals and households are not considered as local. Strengthening the capabilities for local level development, which involve more than just one local level, is crucial for advancing peoples productivity and well-being. The most successful organizational systems supporting rural development encompassed multiple sectors as well as multiple tiers group, community, locality, subdistrict, district, and on upwards. Institutions on the other hand, are a category that overlaps with organizations. Institutions can best be understood as complexes of norms and behaviors that persist over time by serving some socially valued purposes. Most analysis identifies and contrasts two sectors public and private, with the latter being a residual, including all that is not public. The paper defined a third sector which has no agreed designation. It differs from the public sector in that it does not act with state authority, but rather with the social authority generated by agreement among members. It differs from the public sector in that middle sector organizations are accountable to members who have constituted them. There can also be hybrids. Four tasks or activities essential for effective action, whether in the public sector, the private sector, or the middle sector: decision-making; resource mobilization and management;

-5-

communication and coordination; and conflict resolution. These tasks (activities) are performed or undertaken mostly through sets of roles, which are backed up by a variety of rules, precedents and procedures, with ensuing networks of relationships that create capacity for cooperation and for mutually beneficial collective action. These are the elements of what is increasingly referred to as social capital. The paper provided a detailed account on realizing the potential of local communities and suggested the following: a) the beneficial social changes are best promoted through a learning process approach; b) oftentimes, the provision of outside resources can discourage the contribution of local resources to development efforts; c) for development to occur, there must be positive-sum dynamics, where net benefits result from investment, training and other activities; d) assisted self-reliance is useful; e) avoid paternalist and populist extremes; f) barriers to self-reliance including lack of relevant knowledge and technical skills, internal conflict, limited financial resources, isolation, etc.; g) a pure bottom-up approach may not achieve a broad transformation of rural areas (and therefore); h) a combination of top-down and bottom-up initiatives, with a catalytic strategy should be the focus; i) identify and evaluate problems first, then seek and test solutions; j) build capacity; and k) bureaucratic reorientation. What Makes Effective Local Organizations and Institutions in Natural Resource Management and Rural Development? The aim of this paper was to explore experiences of local organizations and institutions and identify some key lessons. The main focus was on natural resource management (NRM), especially common property resource (CPR) management. The paper used the term organization to refer to a structure of recognized and accepted roles. Institution was used to refer to visions, shared norms, agreed rules and behaviors. A distinction was made between indigenous and sponsored local organizations. In indigenous organizations the initiative for formation comes from within the community. In sponsored organizations the initiative comes from outside. The paper analyzed some cases of indigenous forestry management systems in Nepal. The two cases discussed show how organizational features (formal roles) tend to be less important than institutional factors. In fact, organizational features were not always present. These systems for common property resource management were based on a users group (a group of resource users with mutually recognized use rights) rather than on formal administrative-political boundaries. Some lessons from Nepal include: a warning about the danger of assuming that there are no existing local institutions just because there are no committees or other formal features (the danger of assuming a local institutional vacuum); problems with outside agencies imposing standardized organizational forms; and the importance of recognizing rather than forming local organizations. The idea that form follows function was proposed as a basic principle of local organizations. The point was that people set up organizations in a form, which they think will meet their objectives. Organizational features will only be as complex as necessary to fulfill the functions. Organizational features change as the situation (and function) changes. While it is often assumed that IRD may require multifunctional organizations, this does not apply to organizations for common property regimes unless the same users have rights to all resources involved (without non-users being involved). The fact that users groups for forests and irrigation systems are often quite distinct demonstrates this point. There are some situations, such as the Ahupuaa system in Hawaii (where social and resource boundaries all

-6-

coincide and are within the same watershed boundaries), in which multifunctional NRM institutions can work. A common factor involved in effective local organizations, is that effective local organizations have real power to make decisions. Otherwise participation is essentially meaningless. Although the paper emphasized CPR management organizations and institutions, it has been pointed out that many general rural development organizations also focus on a single function. Some comments are made regarding general community development organizations where multiple functions are involved. In order to address the need for coordination and integration, such organizations: need genuine decision-making authority; need to represent a local constituency and answer downwards; and cant be responsible for everything. There is a risk that attempts to integrate and coordinate development activities can lead to a return to centralized planning and work against effective local organization. The dilemma is how to achieve integration without undermining community-driven initiatives. Based on discussions in the paper some proto-principles for effective local organizations have been proposed by way of summary. Institutionalization of Peoples Self-organizing Actions for Rural Development: Comparative Analysis of Micro-finance Organizations in Rural Thailand, Philippines, and Indonesia This paper discussed how we could install an endogenous and sustainable mechanism of peoples self-organizing actions into a local social system. To reach to this purpose, this paper focused on communal organizations rather than each formal organization for rural development (development organization). Communal organizations are organizations that work as a platform of making development organizations. They consist of endogenously formed social organization and local administrative organization formed by the government. The characteristics of communal organization define the form of development organizations and the way of making development organizations. This paper presented the cases of micro-finance organizations (MFOs) as an example of development organizations and investigates why MFOs in Thailand, the Philippines and Indonesia show clear contrasts each other. It also showed salient features of social organizations and local administrative organizations in each country and also uniqueness of the combination of these two types of organizations. In Thailand, especially in its northeast region, the administrative village (muban) and indigenous village community identically overlap to form the communal organization. It is not so difficult to make a sustainable organization with considerable number of participants within the village boundary. A pool-and-distribution and cooperative type is, therefore, adopted as an adequate form of MFO by development agencies. In the rural Philippines, communal organizations are composed of dyadicly-woven social organizations and administrative village (barangay) without any communal background. It is reasonable for NGOs to apply the Grameen Bank model, the strategy to limit membership in each group as small as around five and to bypass the administrative village for organizing people. In Indonesia, especially in Central and Eat Java, a kind of mismatch between social organizations and local administrative bodies is seen. The desa system has institutions to control villagers but not to facilitate villagers self-organizing actions. Coexistence of a bank managed by desa and small-scale groups directly organized by NGOs reflect such a situation of communal organizations in this area.

-7-

Based on empirical studies, the paper formulated policy implications for making rural organizations, especially for installing an endogenous and sustainable system of peoples self-organizing. Firstly, paper suggested to focus on the structure of communal organization in each locality to distinguish adequate form of development organization and adequate method of organizing people. Even if the savings group is successfully operated in Thailand, this organization should not be introduced into an area like rural Philippines that has no locality-based community. Additionally, the Grameen type organization is not the efficient model in areas like Java and Northeast Thailand where the larger size of collectively bound group is easily formed. As for the method of organizing, the administrative village plays key role in Northeast Thailand, while informal social groups and social relationships should be focused as the initiator of organizing in the other two areas. There seems to be adequate pattern between the forms of MFO, the way of organizing people and structure of communal organization in each locality. Next, one has to develop a methodology to distinguish the characteristics of communal organizations in project sites. It is assumed that each locality has a set of social organizations and local administrative organizations as communal organizations. Therefore, it is indispensable to know what kind of functions each organization has and how they are combined each other. The following three factors are required to communal organization that may work as a facilitator of making development organization. One is a sense of unity among local people. In other words, we have to know in which sphere or group of people with whom they feel most comfortable to get together. The second factor is the institution of collective decision-making, or the institution for manifesting each ones needs and coordinate them as a common target. Without such institutions, the organizational process may not proceed smoothly. The third element is the institution of enforcement. People cannot feel sure about the rewards of organization, unless there is a system for policing deviations of members. One should identify which locality unit can be the organizer equipped with these functions for making development organizations. Lastly, if one cannot find adequate communal organizations, one should consider the reformation of local administrative system. For example, the reformation of subdistrict level administration (tambon) in Thailand has provided wider opportunities to change tambon to a communal organization for expanding savings groups beyond the boundary of muban without sacrificing its stability. The mismatch of formal and informal local organizations in rural Java suggests a need for reformation of the local administrative system. At any rate, the designers of local administrative system should take into account whether the design installs a mechanism of facilitating endogenous and sustainable efforts of local residents for development. Finally, the author suggested that the analysis would help readers to understand why local people or outside development agencies in these three countries took different strategies for securing loan through organizational activities. HIGHLIGHTS OF COUNTRY PAPERS Bangladesh This country paper discussed the process and institutional and organizational arrangements related to rural development and present the countrys planning approach. Rural development is not confined to one aspect; instead it is a package of economic and social activities with the ultimate objective of upgrading the living conditions of rural people,

-8-

now and in the future. Therefore, the areas include infrastructure, production, health, sanitation, family planning, etc. The lowest unit in rural areas of Bangladesh is the village. The village inhabitants include farmers, fisherman, weavers, blacksmiths, artisans, traders, laborers, etc. Therefore, in order to upgrade the lifestyle of the rural people, programs are being implemented to promote economic growth and social progress, to create employment, to improve income, etc. The projects sponsored by the government and other agencies have the components mainly with the objective of rural development of the country such as infrastructure development. To be effective all these programs and projects must address the problem of poverty. Towards this, the Forth Five-Year Plan pursued an employment-led growth policy. The focus of the policy was to promote greater opportunities for eradicating poverty. The objectives of the plan, for the rural development and institutions sector were to: a) reduce rural poverty by means of increasing gainful employment and income opportunities on sustainable basis through expansion of the productive sectors; b) develop rural institutions; c) improve technology and skills for production activities and improve the access of rural poor to means of production; d) facilitate agricultural development through institutional support and expansion of irrigation; e) improve basic infrastructure; and f) promote the participation of women in rural development. Many organizations working for rural development in Bangladesh mostly operate through small groups. Government departments, autonomous bodies, NGOs and cooperatives are involved in small group activities. There are some commonalities in the operation of the groups. There is, however, a marked divergence in the nature of their respective programs, formation of groups and in organizing the group activities. Bangladesh is basically village-based country. Here the development of the village reflects the real development of the nation. The country has vast experience in rural development strategies and policies. Bangladesh Academy for Rural Development (BARD), Rural Development Academy (RDA) and Bangladesh Cooperative Academy (BCA) formulated and developed different rural development models for developing nations, in general. At present, the concept of peoples participation in community development has found very effective in rural development in Bangladesh. Republic of China The purpose of this paper was to illustrate the organization structure in rural development in Taiwan on the one hand, and to delineate the role of local communities and institutions in integrated rural development on the other. Problems encountered and the prospects are discussed as well. The smallest rural community unit in Taiwan is addressed to the borough or so-called Tsuen or Li, which is under the administration of township government. Primarily three systems are implementing in rural development projects. They are official administration system, farmers association system, and the non-profit organization system. Among which the former one is government-administrated, while the other two are more nongovernmentally-administrated or self-administrated. The governmental community development plan in Taiwan was initiated in 1965. To accelerate community development, the Ministry of Interior encourages existing communities to establish a local institution named community development association to assist the Tsuen/Li office. A community development association is regularly divided into sections of representative assembly, board of directors, and board of supervisors. The members of

-9-

representative assembly are selected from the community residents and possess supreme authority in determining development policies. The members of board of directors and supervisors are elected by the representatives to be responsible for managing and supervising the community development affairs, respectively. An executive chief is nominated by the board of directors to take charge of community affairs and to be the community speaker. The community development association in Taiwan is expected to play the role of a resource deliverer, a coordinator, or a facilitator. The agricultural extension section of farmers association traditionally is of great importance in promoting rural development, though its major concern is on farmers, fishermen, and agriculture. It is much more emphasizing the training of human resources rather than hardware construction. Agents of the agricultural extension section usually consists of members specialized in farming affairs, home economics, and youth affairs. In terms of role, it simultaneously takes the roles of resource distributor, trainer, facilitator, coordinator, and farm management consultant. Increasing non-profit organizations have actively partaken in rural development on the ground of humane and environmental concerns. The involved institutions range from environmental protection groups, cultural rebuilding foundation, local history studio, to associations related to sustainable development. Given that the cumulative chemicals produced by conventional farming in the past decades have acutely spoiled most of the arable land, progressive numbers of institutions advocating sustainable agriculture or organic culture have risen these years. In terms of role-playing, a non-profit organization could play roles of animator, innovator, renovator, facilitator and educator. The paper concluded that, despite the increasing numbers of community development associations and farmers associations, the substantial achievements and pace of rural development based on these two approaches is not as expected, probably owing to overwhelming governmental domination on decision-making of community affairs. Leaving the local community more space in deciding development strategy is thus suggested. To gain success in rural development, the government-administrated organizations have to work with the farmers associations and the NPOs, particularly the latter. Fiji Fiji is a multiracial society and due to its remoteness and geographical location in the South Pacific with approximately 330 islands. The Ministry of Fijian Affairs and Local Government has been reorganized. Fijian affairs became part of a combined Ministry of Fijian Affairs and Rural Development. The provincial councils have a developmental role, in parallel with the advisory councils provided for Indo-Fijians, under the same department of rural development. Under the central government there are divisional commissioners and below that are the district officers. There are two types of officers at this (district) level: one for indigenous Fiji people (called Roko-Tui) and another one (called the district officer) for multi-ethnic people or all other ethnic groups dominated by the Indo-Fijians. Under the district officer (for multi-ethnic people) there is the chairman and District Advisors Council (DAC). The parallel organization for indigenous Fijians is the Mata Ni Tikinas. Below this, in parallel to advisors, is the Turaga Ni Koros. Turaga is the head of the village. And, there are about eight villages in Mata Ni Tikinas. People have village meetings to discuss the needs and projects. Turaga Ni Koros then meet with Mata Ni Tikinas to discuss the projects. Both parties meet at the district level to decide priorities and the district officer coordinate these meetings.

- 10 -

At the community level the local government units, i.e., city/town councils and the district officers community workers undertake development projects. Since 60 percent of the population is in rural sector the Ministry of Regional Development and Multi-Ethnic Affairs is very instrumental in undertaking development planning, project implementations and resources mobilization. The projects could cover a wide range of rural needs such as: housing, roads, bridges, water supply, etc., in the form of self-help projects. There are also projects involving overseas donor agencies funding which is the responsibility of central government. The project proposals are submitted to the line ministries/departments for assessment and evaluation which is discussed with the Ministry of National Planning. India This country paper presented an overview Local Self-governance (LSG) system in India for implementing the Integrated Rural Development (IRD) at grassroots level and its linkages with various institutions involved in the process of IRD. In particular, the role of local organizations and institution in the programs and activities concerning rural development has been highlighted with a thrust on orientation, capacity-building and empowerment of local communities and sustainability of grassroots level LSGs. Future strategies including new institutional arrangements facilitating convergence and integration of the IRD efforts of different local level institutions and organizations have been discussed in detail. In India, Panchayati Raj Institutions (PRIs) have emerged, as an effective mechanism for taking over IRD efforts at grassroots level after the 73rd Constitutional Amendment 1992. Though Constitutional provisions offer a great deal of avenues for these LSGs to play a prominent role in IRD, their growth varies across states because of local situations and inadequate provisions in the state legislations. In India there is plethora of local level organizations and institutions involved in rural development because of the large area of the country and vast regional diversities. Some of these organizations like NGOs, Community-based Organizations (CBOs), private sector institutions and local level groups have been extremely successful in implementing IRD programs, mobilizing communities and orienting them towards rural development. If one takes a review of rural development programs initiated by the Government of India, it reveals that most of the IRD initiatives revolve around poverty alleviation mainly because of predominance of rural poor in the country. Rural development programs have been reorganized in new form with an in-built mechanism for enhanced community participation, empowerment of underprivileged groups and women. With the changing global scenario and rampant economic recession IRD is faced with greater challenges. Future strategies, therefore, call for initiatives, which enhance the competency of human resources, facilitate sustainable use of natural resources and divert investment towards critical infrastructure instead of subsidies. There is also an urgent need for greater devolution of powers to local governments with broad-based resources and a more predominate role in decision-making concerning rural development. In conclusion the paper suggested new institutional arrangements at grassroots level, which facilitate greater participation of different stakeholders, through convergence and integration of efforts/resources directed towards micro-level plans drawn up with active involvement of all of them. Concerted efforts towards massive orientation and capacitybuilding to improve the level of competency of human resources would go a long way in achieving the goal of rural prosperity.

- 11 -

Islamic Republic of Iran (1) The result of 50 years of planning in Iran, in terms of rural development, has led to better living condition for villagers. But the important point is that the change is not very significant and there is a long way to achieve the best results of cooperation, participation and local community development. The policies and programs of governmental and non-governmental organizations need theoretical framework such as integrated local community development and institutional setup that can provide a structure for their activities in the various fields of rural development. For the proper development of rural areas, Iran needs a continuous and consistent approach devoid of contradictions. It should involve people through participation at local levels. The local councils in rural areas should be strengthened. Because at present, the system of local councils aim at building is an important link between the people and government. Years of rural development in Iran have fallen short of expectation. The most significant problem has been the way in which local communities and institutions were promoted. Top-down approaches and external promotion had prevented the evolution of community-driven institutions and the active participation of rural people. Rural institutions failed to develop in to true, member-based, self-help entities. The relationship between government and communities and institutions must be redefined to create an environment, which would be more conductive to develop rural areas. Direct support to institutions and cooperatives should be limited to training of officials and members and establishment of control mechanisms to protect members in trusts. The challenge here is to breathe new life into the local communities and institutions in order to capitalize on their substantial human and physical capitals. It is recommended that a new development policy be adopted that would help the IRD system to convert to being a genuinely community-based and managed movement. The role of such movement under the new economic reality could be in such areas as: input supply on a commercial basis, crop marketing and processing, technical services such as extension and pest control, savings and loan activation and machinery services. In Iran the rural development projects have been designed and prepared through government agencies during the past five decades of planning with the least or lack of participation of rural people. It must be emphasized that this kind of centralized planning has been organized through centralized oil revenue. Now, with the limited oil revenue in the future, with the necessity for more decentralization and privatization; peoples participation is very critical to the whole process of rural development. Islamic Republic of Iran (2) After the revolution, one of the actions adopted under Imam Khomeinis direction was the formation of a foundation named Jihad-e-Sazandegi (Jihad for Construction), which worked in Irans villages with the aim of agricultural and rural development and poverty reduction. In the year 1983, Jihad-e-Sazandegi was converted to a Ministry. In 2002 it was combined with the Ministry of Agriculture as the Ministry of Jihad for Agriculture. Within this Ministry is a Deputy of Extension and Popular Participation whose task is to enable the integrated rural community development through training, extension and popular participation in rural development programs. In all communities there are various forms of collective participation and simple traditional mechanisms for group actions or activities. Alongside with governmental and nongovernmental organizations, a great number of such traditional organizations are
- 12 -

administered through local leadership or co-thinking. However, their efficiency cannot be increased and they are unlikely to expand their activities beyond local levels. Presently, new types of grassroots organizations are being created and developed which are actively involved in the development process alongside the cooperatives and other kinds of governmental organization and establishment. The major characteristics of grassroots or popular organizations are: i) voluntary formation: more often these organizations tend to form in accordance with the common felt needs of local people; ii) independence and autonomy: grassroots organizations are managed and controlled by people themselves through their own initiative; iii) popular funding: their members and people of the community mainly provide capital and assets needed by grassroots organizations; iv) nearness to community: local people tend to have a sense of belonging and attachment to these organizations; and v) non-profit nature: grassroots organizations are not looking for economic benefits, rather they are directed towards either fulfilling local needs or accomplishing development objectives. Grassroots organizations have some important functions including information delivery and promotion of new ideas, communication facilitation, counseling and research, planning, implementation and training. Local traditional institutions have often been based on mutual help, embodied as cultivating groups or commodity exchange or for temporary collective actions (such as participation for providing expenses needed for marriage). Cooperative is very important in Iran. They are mainly involved in producing and supplying agricultural inputs as well as in other supportive activities such as granting credits or offering training and instructions. As the second type of grassroots organization, NGOs are generally active in urban areas and mainly deal with urban issues or problems. They have recently emerged in rural areas. Islamic Councils are another form of grassroots organization. Their members come directly from the community. Government must relinquish its control over the development process, so as to leave the space for communities to take their own initiatives for preserving and making sustainable use of resources. To this end, it should take a major role in supporting grassroots organizations. Islamic Republic of Iran (3) In order to understand rural management in Iran, it is necessary to look at the historical background. During the Safavid era considerable development took place in both economic and social arena, but the progress was demolished in the Qajar period. During both of these periods, the people who worked the land were not the real owners, leading to a lack of motivation for land development and increased productivity. In 1963, during the Pahlavi period, land reform legislation was introduced. Then, in 1975, the Act to Organize Rural Associations and Village Centers of Government (Dehbany) was passed, creating a radical change and dividing power and authority between several institutions such as rural cooperatives, rural associations, houses of Justice and Dehban (a person responsible for village affairs). Following the Islamic Revolution, Jihad-e-Sazandegi (Campaign for Construction) was founded to rehabilitate rural areas and improve rural living standards. An act was passed in 1982 to establish Islamic Councils (or rural councils). Elections were held, but new general elections were not held until 1999. According to the Law on Rural Council Elections, any village with at least 20 families or 100 people is permitted to organize a rural council. Elections were held in 32,677

- 13 -

villages out of 36,000 villages. A total of 107,293 members had been elected, including 2,564 women. According to the law villages with a population over 1,500 have five members, and villages with a population under 1,500 have three. One role of the Islamic Council is to plan and classify village needs. It also implements programs and can establish special commissions to carry out tasks. A Dehyar is appointed by the council to implement its decisions. Islamic Republic of Iran (4) The rate of change in rural communities in Iran in recent decades has been significant. According to the 1966 census, 38 percent of the population (23 million) lived in rural areas. Over the previous 44 years, the urban population increased 6.1 times and the rural population only by 1.8 times. In 1966, the number of rural settlements was 68,000, of which 31,765 had a population of less than 100, with limited economic power and low access to welfare services. The number of villages with a large population is growing and low population villages are decreasing. Rural development problems include shortages of job opportunities, economic insecurity, low standards of housing, poor welfare conditions and lack of suitable conditions for financial investment in various sectors, including agriculture. The main goals of rural development are the extension of social justice and distribution of the benefits of economic growth among the rural people, in order to provide a high standard of living. Objectives set to achieve these goals within the Third Five-Year Plan include equipping all villages with electric power, increase in the number of villages with potable water to 70 percent (from 47 percent), and increase in the number of villages with sewerage. A number of strategies are intended to achieve these goals and objectives, including: i) organizing rural development through structural change to the production system, with suitable utilization of productive resources and suitable technology; ii) renovation of rural organization system aiming at necessary coordination, decentralization, prevention of parallel and similar activities and transparency of roles and duties; iii) supporting the establishment of small-scale institutions to provide facilities to rural residents; and iv) encouraging villagers to participate in different social and economic activities through teamwork. Implementation policies and procedures have been listed in the paper. Key policies and procedures are: 1) to determine the role and duties of different organizations related to rural development, aiming at rural reorganizing and elimination of similar activities; and 2) to transfer some of the implementation activities of the government to the Islamic Councils and NGOs. Nepal The country paper started with a short description of Integrated Rural Development Program (IRDP) and its evolution in Nepal. The future direction of IRDP focuses on drawing attention towards the role of local communities and organization for peoples participation at the grassroots level. Village level planning and implementation procedure are presented in diagrammatic form showing the linkages between the national plan and village level CBOs. The paper discussed the Participatory District Development Program (PDDP), a new planning approach that has been developed and reviewed in 17 districts of Nepal. Given the priority of putting the people first in the Village Development Program (VDP), the PDDP has been initiated with the support from the United Nations Development Program (UNDP) and Norwegian Agency for International Development (NORAD) in close cooperation with
- 14 -

local government and local institutions. It offers new opportunities for competent participation of people at the grassroots level in the planning and implementation process. In addition, the paper discussed the role of local institutions and organization in terms of four topics: i) the role of local development consumer groups (users committees), which receive direct benefits from projects; ii) the role of local NGOs and CBOs including traditional and modern community organizations (COs); iii) the process of village development through social mobilization; and iv) presentation of private-public partnerships in local community. This approach stresses a multiplicity of sources for initiatives and decision-making, allowing a wide range of alternative institutions and funding mechanisms for IRD programming. The process of village development through social mobilization was the main focus of the paper. The village development process is geared towards empowering rural Nepal to rise above the poverty trap. It urges communities, both men and women, towards self-reliance and self-governance by encouraging them to group into broad-based, multipurpose COs. The impact of the PDDP in 17 districts has been evaluated. Within the PDDP there is a four-step Village Development Program Process (VDPP): such as a) formation of COs; b) graduation of CO (maturation and small-scale activities); c) activating community-based entrepreneurial skills service; and d) implementing priority productive investments. The paper concluded that there is no better alternative to an IRD approach involving local community participation for mobilizing broad-based COs in a fruitful development process. Pakistan The paper was focused on Agha Khan Rural Support Program (AKRSP), which has worked over the past 20 years in the Northern Areas and Chitral (NAC) to foster and strengthen the capacity of participatory local institutions that could sustainably carry out collective action-based development in the region. AKRSP commenced its activities in the Gilgit region of the Northern Areas (NAs) in 1982, and extended its activities on a trial basis in 1983 to the Chitral district of the North-West Frontier Province (NWFP). During 1986, the complete range of AKRSPs were introduced in Chitral and the Baltistan region of the NAs. The six districts of the program area have a combined population of approximately one million, consisting of about 111,000 households, in over 1,100 villages, settled on an area of 74,200 km2. The region is rugged and mountainous, located among the four of the highest mountain ranges. Local institutions and NGOs fostered in the region exist and function at various levels. At the village level, a network of more than 3,973 village organizations and womens organizations has been capacitated to undertake local development initiatives. Today, these organizations are successfully managing a range of activities including local infrastructure creation, NRM, savings and credit, and small-scale enterprise development. At the bigger valley level, many of these village organizations have come together to create cluster groups with the mandate of initiating larger projects and activities that benefit households simultaneously in several villages. Finally, at the local area level, AKRSP has helped develop local NGOs and other development organizations charged with yet broader sets of functions including helping build capacity of smaller village institutions, operating and managing social sector facilities, protecting and enhancing CPRs, and working with government line departments to help influence local development outcomes. To this end, capacity-building

- 15 -

services provided to these NGOs include intensive trainings in management, financial accounting, proposal development, and fundraising; linking them to possible funding sources; and exposure visits and workshops for their enhanced sensitization and awareness. Today, there are a growing number of such institutions providing development services in various parts of the NAC. Several of them have been able to access funding and resources from government and non-government agencies. Prominent among these include, for example, the Naunehal Development Organization, Khunjerab Village Organization, and the Baltistan NGO Network. During the course of the past 19 years, one of the most striking developments has been that the government departments have recognized the organized communities as valid partners for development. Different social sector programs offered by government are being largely implemented through an effective and laudable partnership between communities, NGOs, and government departments. Philippines This country paper discussed the role of local communities, which included the agrarian reform beneficiaries and their organizations, NGOs and local government units in the implementation of agrarian reform community (ARC) development program. Considering that Philippine economy depends on agriculture and most of those that are below poverty threshold are in the rural areas; the author suggested that the disparity in the distribution of resources and powerlessness remain the two big challenges in rural development. The discussion commenced with the brief description of the local administration in the Philippines, the historical underpinnings of the government system that provides the concept of participation of the local communities in the implementation of rural development projects. Likewise, local government units participation as mandated in the Philippine Local Government Code of 19991. In addition, a brief description of other key players in the rural development work such as peoples organization (POs), NGOs, and cooperatives and farmers associations has been presented. Next, the paper submitted the salient features of the agrarian reform community development framework. The ARC definition, guiding principles, the approaches and the key components defined the anchorage for participation of the different stakeholders in the implementation of the framework. The highlights of the paper presented the important role of the Agrarian Reform Beneficiaries (ARBs), POs and NGOs in the actual implementation of the program. Data based on the actual field realities have been presented to support the discussion. In conclusion, the paper stressed the need for people and the community in the implementation of IRD programs. The main lesson drawn from the experience in agrarian reform program and rural development was that, proactive participation of the people, local community, organizations and institutions have positive results in the lives of the very people subject for development. Sri Lanka This country paper started with a general introduction by explaining the necessity of rural development in Sri Lanka. This was supported by an account on historical background of rural development in the country. Further, it explained the relevant concepts, approaches and overall strategies of Integrated Development Programs in Sri Lanka.

- 16 -

The paper then discussed in detail the local communities and institutions which are involved in the IRD activities such as local government organizations with their administrative system at local the level, local political bodies that have engaged in rural development activities, and the community-based organizations involved in the same to overcome problems which are commonly related with the rural communities. Such constraints include: insufficient income due to less productivity of agriculture; inadequate knowledge on resources management; health and nutrition; infrastructure such as roads, electricity, etc. By listing formal and informal local level organizations and institutions, the paper explained their major role related to rural development programs. Historical background, composition, activities and functions of the local community and institutions have been discussed. The overall objectives of the local communities and institutions that involved in rural development activities is the alleviation of the poverty by improving the socio-economic condition and the living standard of rural people. The main implemented strategy was to provide subsidies. However, this system has not completely succeeded. The local level government institutions and communities, such as Divisional Secretariat (Pradeshiyalekam Karyalaya), Provincial Councils in both terms Palathsabawa and Pradesiyasabawa, Agrarian Services Centers, Farmers Societies (Awamangaliyadhara Samithiya), etc. are well organized and well established in the Island-wide and are well known by the people. In addition, the paper quoted the salient features of IRD efforts in Sri Lanka with special attention to the role of the local communities and institutions. Further, the paper submitted future directions of IRD programs efforts in Sri Lanka. Thailand This paper focused on the involvement of NGO in rural development. More specifically, it described the work of an NGO, namely, Population and Community Development Association (PDA). PDA consists of about 600 staff and 16 community development centers nation-wide, implementing nearly 20 development programs. To achieve its goals, PDA adopt following major strategies: i) promoting participation; ii) recreational activities to cultivate harmony; iii) appropriate technology; iv) simple, easy to understand and convenient methods; v) revolving loan funding; and vi) promoting partnerships with the private sector business companies. PDA focuses on institutional strengthening and specifically develop rural community capacity in income-generating activities, health and education development. In addition, it encourages maintaining equity and eradicates pockets of rural poverty. PDA-assisted development process has achieved the following: improved quality of rural life, village-based work opportunities and additional income, significant improvement in business skills, institutional development, improving community infrastructure and expanding markets for village products. Vietnam Commune is the cell of Vietnam rural society. Seventy-five percent of countrys population lives in rural, mountainous area. The process of 15 years of innovations and economic reformation had made much more changes in economy, society and improved partly Vietnamese rural face. In the past, over 1,000 years, Vietnam used to be a colony of empires, but national traditions remained. But nowadays, in the new period, communes
- 17 -

have displayed defects to limit rural social development. Developing rural areas means promoting community and promoting commune. It is an integrated approach of rural development from production, health, education, and family planning, etc. to increasing womens role, and so on. To do that, the whole society has to participate and local communities and institutions should perform a greater role. Administrative organization of Vietnam has four levels: central, province or city, district, and commune. Under the commune is the hamlet, but it is not really an administrative level. In Ho Chi Minh city, local government (district, commune) has the responsibility for making conditions to implement projects within area. Setting up and implementing projects require the cooperation of institutions and associations. According to the stipulated functions and duty, each institution or association has to do different activities regarding development. Services related to agriculture and rural development are extremely important. There are a lot of units belonging to services such as: Center for Technology, Science and Agricultural Extension, Center for Water and Rural Environmental Hygiene, Branch of Immigration and New Economic Area Development, etc. They are direct units responsible for designing and implementing projects. These projects are based on the practical demand of respective communities, and at the same time also are on short-, middle- and long-term plans approved by city or the central government. From now to 2005, many projects will be conducted, which would concentrate on poor communes in suburban areas. Such projects include: building rural infrastructure; treating waste and dirty water; protecting plants; promoting rural professions; abolishing illiteracy; guiding how to give up poor via programs of agricultural, forestry, industrial, salty extension, etc. In conclusion, the paper stated that the IRD in Vietnam is not the responsibility of one organization, but is the duty of the whole society. The ultimate purpose is to improve standard of living in rural areas, reduce the distance between the rich and poor, between rural and city and, between plain and mountainous area. It is hoped to achieve these in future. FIELD VISIT On the fifth day of the seminar, participants visited the Hableh Rood Watershed and the Lazoor village in the Tehran district. In the previous day, a special presentation has been arranged on the field visit and the watershed project. This was followed by a discussion. The project is financed jointly by the local communities and the UNDP. An NGO facilitates the process. The main watershed project covers 1,160,000 ha and covers parts of Tehran and Semnan districts. However, the field visit was limited to Lazoor and its subwatershed. The most active leader of the community presented the objectives of the project, community participation and the organizational arrangements. This was followed by a discussion session and a field tour. The objectives of the projects are to achieve appropriate and significant improvements in living standards and to demonstrate a model of development, which could be replicated elsewhere. There are Islamic Councils at the village level. In addition, there is a Coordinating Committee (CC), with 90 members (75 male and 15 female) to provide technical expertise and a Central Core Group (CCG) with seven members (four men and three women) for designing and presenting specific project proposals. The Islamic Council handles projects that are accountable to both the government and the community while the CC handles projects that are accountable exclusively to the people.

- 18 -

The salient features of this unique experiment are: i) project and its sub-components are planned and implemented by the people; ii) all the sub-components are financed by the community, either partly or fully; iii) participation is at a higher level, collective decisionmaking; iv) womens participation is encouraging but still males dominate; v) a high degree of transparency in all matters, decision-making is visible; vi) leadership dominates; vii) division of tasks/responsibility is clear: for example, there are committees for specific purposes; viii) strong unity and cohesiveness; and ix) diversification of activities as the organizations matures. For example, they focus on new crops, rural industries and even plan to form peoples companies. In addition, the organizations are active in socio-cultural (including religious) activities. When participants walked across the watershed, it was evident that community people through organized group action had completed lot of activities related to watershed management combined with income generation. For example, the micro-environment is changing due to natural resources conservation methods adopted after the project. There are check dams, conservation bunds, silt traps, flood protection reservoirs, spillways, strip planting, etc. Consequently the area cropped has increased and the community is cultivating new crops. SYNTHESIS OF WORKSHOP OUTPUTS Workshop 1: Discussion/Reflection on Resource Papers Following the presentation of the resource papers, participants identified a number of key issues and questions arising from the resource papers. Four groups were formed and each group discussed one topic. At the end of the discussions, presentations were made. Brief summaries of the discussions under each selected issue are given below: 1. Roles and Responsibilities of Local Self-governance Among the roles/responsibilities identified were: making the links between local communities and the government; identifying problems and prioritizing projects and programs; facilitating all aspects of development in local life; integrating different programs of IRD; natural resource management. 2. Costs/Benefits of IRD; Potentialities/Weaknesses; Monitoring; How to Integrate; Planning; Role of Government in Facilitating IRD Some key points discussed were the role of government in integrating larger projects and programs based on plans formulated by the local community. In addition the group discussed the costs, benefits and potentialities. Motivating and empowering communities were identified as key roles and potentialities. 3. Evolution of Small/Simple Local Organizations/Institutions From Meeting Simple/Smaller Needs to Meeting More Complex Needs The group produced lists of simple needs and complex needs. It also identified positive (supporting) and negative (inhibiting) factors affecting the evolution from simple to complex (multipurpose) organizations. Positive factors included: an open system, legal/policy support, financial support, and unity within the community, awareness/knowledge, capacity/ experience and motivation. Negative factors were: a closed system, lack of effective local government and NGOs, lack of awareness/education/knowledge, poor planning, degradation of natural resource base and lack of participation.

- 19 -

4. Capacity-building of Local Organizations for Greater Responsibilities in Rural Development The group agreed that diversified, sustainable, and equitable economic and human development is promoted through building organizational and individual competence and confidence. In this regard, the required capacities are: technical skills (including financial and management skills), transparency, checks and balances and capacity to bargain and negotiate. Workshop 2: Identification of Local Organizations and Institutions in Participants Countries At the beginning, the seminar had concentrated on official structures. The purpose of this workshop was to briefly review the system of governance in respective countries and to start looking at the community level and organizations initiated by community members. In the introduction, a distinction was made between organized behavior and organizational structure. People sometimes do things in an organized way (based on shared ideas and values institutions) without there being any recognizable structure of roles. An example is the vareh system in Iran, in which a small group of people group together to share the costs of milk marketing by pooling their production and taking turns to deliver milk to the market, with the person who does the task each day paying all costs and taking all the income. The workshop focused on these unstructured institutions as well as structured organizations. Participants were asked to prepare cards individually on their countries (perhaps getting feedback and ideas in small groups). These were then posted on flip charts and presented briefly. Prior to this exercise, the participants studied the summary of the APO seminar on Effective Decentralization for Community Development, which was held in Sri Lanka from 23 to 31 March 2001. The seminar examined the systems of governance in participating countries. After the country paper presentations, the participants prepared comparable information sheets on governance system in their respective countries. A summary of these data and information on the status of decentralization and local governance was given to the participants of the present seminar and each participant was expected to improve and upgrade that database. The output has been synthesized and is presented in annex I, Table A-1. Next, the participants identified the informal organizations in the rural sector. The output (Annex II) included many good examples of indigenous local organizations and institutions. The institutions included such practices as labor exchange systems and indigenous savings groups (Dhukuti in Nepal). Organizations included irrigation management, and committees set up for purposes such as crime prevention and funeral assistance. Most of the groups were concerned with single functions. These could be further divided into social functions and economic or resource management functions. Workshop 3: Reflections on Field Trip Participants were asked to write on cards (individually) the observations and insights obtained from the field trip. The results were then posted and grouped. Following were the major observations: i) people in Lazoor were aware of problems and activities; ii) there was effective participatory planning; iii) the community was unified; iv) women are starting to participate; v) there is some uncertainty about the future, especially due to migration and aging population; vi) government support is weak; vii) some participants thought there was some evidence of top-down decision-making; and viii) there was also a very clear example of local (indigenous) organization not related to the project. The irrigation system is at least 200 years old and works very well. The organization is simple (each main channel is managed by a separate group of users) but effective.
- 20 -

It is important to note that it is impossible to draw really clear conclusions on a field trip like this, with a large formal meeting, lack of opportunity to meet with a diverse range of villagers and lack of time to gain villagers confidence before asking sensitive questions about conflict and problems. All that can be done is to get an overview and some hints of issues. However, during the walk-through the watershed and the village, a lot was done in the time available. Workshop 4: Analyzing Local Organizations So far the Seminar has looked at sponsored local organizations and identified some indigenous local organizations and institutions. The next step (for this workshop) was to analyze the effectiveness of the indigenous local organizations discussed earlier. Subsequently, in the final workshop the aim would be to consider what types of local organizations have potential for expanded roles in integrated rural development. Dr. Fisher (resource speaker) presented a series of characteristics of effective local organization as a basis for analysis. Each characteristic has an associated question. Such questions are listed below: i. The authority to make and implement decisions * How the decisions are made? ii. Clear objectives identified by members (people join organizations because they agree something needs to be done). * Why do people join? iii. Responsibility downwards (to members) not upwards (to government or NGOs) * Are decision-makers responsible to members? iv. Transparent processes of decision-making and implementation * Are decisions made and implemented openly? v. Sense of equity * Do people feel that benefits and rights are fairly distributed? vi. Not too complicated (form follows function) * Is the organizational structure more complicated than necessary? Participants were then formed into groups and asked to look at examples of indigenous local organizations from their countries (or other examples mentioned in the seminar) on the basis of these questions. Three groups each briefly presented outcomes of their discussions on three local organizations: i) womens credit groups (the presentation focused on a composite of experiences of womens credit groups in several countries rather than on a single specific credit group); ii) the Lazoor project; and iii) the vareh system. All three presentations demonstrated a good analysis of the organizations, although two of them were sponsored rather than indigenous. The methodology can, of course, be applied to any local organization, sponsored or indigenous. One warning was discussed (actually repeated from the reflection workshop) in relation to the analysis of the Lazoor project. It is possible to get information in the forms of hints from a formal organization such as the field trip meeting, but the process is artificial and it is impossible to reach firm conclusions, particularly about real levels of participation. Participation might be much better than the meeting process might suggest.

- 21 -

Workshop 5: Local Institutions in Integrated Rural Development Dr. Shinichi Shigetomi and Dr. Wijayaratna, each gave brief presentations. The former discussed the role of local organizations in local governance while the latter discussed a conceptual framework and practical ways to catalyze a process through which local communities develop local organizations into multifunctional business entities so that they take a real role in development. In order to bring the seminar to a conclusion, two questions related to these presentations need to be explored: i. How can we identify local institutions that have potential for governance? ii. How can we adopt or utilize local institutions for (integrated) rural development? Two groups were formed and each asked to explore one of these questions. Group 1 Presentation: How to identify local institutions that have potential for governance? The group identified a number of factors including: * Which organizations have the best experiences (good experiences breed confidence and sense of unity)?; * Values and norms related to integrated development; * Significant functions and activities; * Religious center or leadership (Leadership is important); and * Human and natural resources. Group 2 Presentation: How to adopt and utilize local institutions for integrated rural development? The overall approach of the group was based on creating a system of community participation at different levels. Specific points were as follows: * Strengths and weaknesses; * Capacity-building; * Create mechanisms of coordination between stakeholders; * Action plan; * Select enterprises with active involvement of community; * Define structure of management; * Strategy for resource utilization; * Plan for partnerships with the private sector; * Means of dispute settlement; and * Link rural areas and urban areas. Final Task: Personal Commitment Participants were asked to write commitments (individually) based on the question: Given what you have learned at this seminar, what will you do differently from now on? Some examples were read out. These included the following: i. ii. iii. iv. Conducting studies on communities; Try to be more aware of community development; Integrate informal organizations into monitoring systems, and Document efforts on local initiatives and efforts.

- 22 -

CONCLUSION The resource papers and country papers provided useful inputs to the seminar participants to debate and brainstorm the subject. The field visit provided a good opportunity to see the rural area in Iran, and to observe the field level practices of development efforts and, more specifically the role performed by respective local communities and institutions. The workshops and plenary sessions provided a forum for such debate and discussions on the issues. Throughout the process of the seminar, importance of Social Capital, which includes positive human network in a community and trust among villagers that in turn would lead to collective action for integrated and sustainable rural development, has been recognized. Social Capital is rather strong in existing local organizations and institutions than in newly created project organizations. It also became clear that most of the APO member countries have already established comprehensive administrative structures and organizations to implement the IRDP. However, it also became clear that the study on structure of local communities, which are the venue of IRDP, is not sufficient or well-equipped. Consequently, the receiving mechanism of IRPD at the local level has scope for further improvement. In most cases of past IRDP, project organizations in a community have been created by respective projects without much consideration on the existing organizations and institutions in the community. The participants of the seminar have identified the potential to utilize the existing organizations and institutions for IRDP, instead of establishing new organizations by the projects. This kind of discussion has reminded the participants to consider and examine the structure of existing organizations and institutions in a community before launching any development activities including IRDP.

- 23 -

Table A-1. Local Governance System of APO Member Countriesa 1. Bangladesh Level National Region/zone Province District Subdistrict Village
- 24 -

Annex 1

Local Name Desh Division Zila Thana Union Moza/Gram

Number 6 64 496 4,451 64,000

Approximate Populationb 123 million 20 million 2 million 250,000 27,000 7,000

Role/Responsibility PM, National Assembly (NA) (E)c Coordination only Commissioner (A)d, zila parishad (E) Executive officer (A), thana parishad (E) Union officer (A), union parishad (E) Cooperative-society (informal)

2. Republic of China (Taiwan) Level Local Name National Province/municipalities District Subdistrict/township Villagee Hsien/county county Shiang Tsuen/li

Number 1 4 23 379 7,402

Approximate Population 22 million 51,000 to 16.5 million 88,000 to 3.3 million 10,000 2,500

Role/Responsibility Premier (E), NA (E) Provincial/municipal government/ farmers associations (FA) Hsien government/county assembly FA/fishermens associations (FiA) Office/council FA, FiA Office/council ... To be continued

Table A-1 (Continuation) 3. Fiji Level National Province District Subdistrict Village 4. India Level Local Name Number 28 499 5,906 232,278 Approximate Population 1 billion 20 million 1 million 150,000 7,000 Role/Responsibility PM, National Assembly Chief Minister, Assembly District Deputy Commissioner/District Collector/Magistrate (A), zilla parishad (E) Block Development Officer (A) Gram/villagepanchayat (E) ... To be continued
- 25 -

Local Name Fiji Province/Division District

Approximate Population 772,665

Role/Responsibility President, Parliament, Senate, Council of Chiefs Provincial Councils/Divisional Commissioners District Officer (for Multi-Ethnic) and Roko-Tui (Fijians) (Nadroga/Navosa) Chairman & District Advisors (Multi-Ethnic) and Mata Ni Tikinas (Fijians) Advisory Councilors and Turaga Ni Koros

Village

National Hindustan State/region/province State District Zilla parishads Subdistrict Village Block panchayat samiti Village/Gram panchayat

Table A-1 (Continuation) 5. Indonesia Level Local Name Number Approximate Population Role/Responsibility

National Negara 200 million PM, NA Region/zone Propinsi 29 10 million Province Kabupaten 100 2 million Local House of Representattives, First Level, Governor District Kecamatan 500 400,000 Subdistrict Desa 4,000 50,000 Village Kampung RT, RW* 3,000 Peoples Council Note: * RT = Rukun Tetangga (neighborhood group); and RW = Rukun Warga (communal group, RW is a collection of several RTs).
- 26 -

6. Iran Level National Province District Subdistrict Village Settlement Local Name Iran Ostan Shares-stan Bakhsh Dehe-stan Abadi Number 27 252 680 1,400 70,000 Approximate Population 65 million 3 million 258,000 40,000 17,000 Role/Responsibility PM, NA (E)

... To be continued

Table A-1 (Continuation) 7. Japan Level National Region/zone Province District Subdistrict Village Local Name Kuni Chihou To-do-hu-ken Gun Shi-ku-cho-son Kyuson, buraku Number 1 47 550 3,200 10,000 2 million 10,000 3,000 Approximate Population 123 million Role/Responsibility PM (E), National Assembly (E) Coordination only Governor (E), Assembly (E) Coordination only Mayor (E), Assembly (E) Area representative (E)

8. Rep. of Korea Level National Province Subdistrict Locality Village Local Name Do, kwang-youksi Gu/si/kun Dong, myun, eup Ri, tong Number 9 70-91 Rural - 4,000, Urban - 9,300 Rural - 35,000, Urban - 56,000 Approximate Population 42 million 5 million 66,000-333,000 1,400 (R)-2,100 (U) 300 (R)- 600 (U) Role/Responsibility President (E), National Assembly (E)
- 27 -

... To be continued

Table A-1 (Continuation) 9. Malaysia Level Local Name Number Approximate Population Role/Responsibility

National Negara 22 million MP, NA (E) Region/zone Province Negeri/state 13 1.6 million CM, Assembly (E) District District 120 180,000 District Officer (A) Subdistrict Wilaya Coordination only Village JKKK*/Kampung Village Chief, JKKK (E) Note: * JKKK = Jawatan-kewasa Keselamatan dan Kemajuan Kampong (village safety and development committee).
- 28 -

10. Mongolia Level National Province District Subdistrict Village Local Name Mongolia Aimag Sum Bag Khot-ail Number 21 342 1,600 Approximate Population 2.4 million 100,000 7,000 1,500 Role/Responsibility President, NA (E)

Several household ... To be continued

Table A-1 (Continuation) 11. Nepal Level National Region/zone Province District Subdistrict Municipality and Village Settlement 12. Pakistan Level National Province (Sauba)
- 29 -

Local Name Desh Kshnetra Zone Zilla Ilaka Nagarpalika VDC Wada

Number 1 5 14 75 475 58 3,913 9 wards/VDC

Approximate Population 22 million 4 million 1 million 300,000 45,000 5,000 500

Role/Responsibility PM, NA Coordination only Coordination only District Development Council (E) Coordination only Village Development Committee (VDC) (E) VDC consists of one representative from each ward/wada (E)

Local Name Pakistan NWFP (17 million) Punjab (72 million) Sidhu (30 million) Balochistan (7 million) FATA/Capital (4 million) Division Zila Teshi Union Gaaon

Number 1 1 1 1 7+1 25 113

Approximate Population 133 million 17 74 30 7 50,000 20,000

Role/Responsibility President, National Assembly, PM Chief Minister

Division District Subdistrict Union Village

Commissioner Deputy Commissioner Assistant Commissioner Union Council (E) Number-dar (A) ... To be continued

Table A-1 (Continuation) 13. Philippines Level National Region/zone Province Cities District/municipality Subdistrict Village
- 30 -

Local Name Philippines Region Sanguniang panlalawigan Sanguniang Bayan Sanguniang Pang Lunsod Barangay (city) Barangay (municipality)

Number 15 79 1,491 3,986 37,657

Approximate Population 67 million 4 million 0.8 million 400,000 5,000 2,000

Role/Responsibility President, NA (E) Coordination only, headed by directors Governor, Board Members (E) Mayor, Council (E) Mayor, Council Barangay Captain (E) Barangay Council (E)

14. Sri Lanka Level National Region/zone Province District Subdistrict (Division) Village Local Name Sri Lanka Province District Peradeniya sabhawa Gramodaya Number 8 25 258 14,000 Approximate Population 18.7 million 2.3 million 779,000 72,000 1,300 PM, NA (E) Chief Minister and Provincial Cabinet (E) assisted by the Provincial Department (administration and professional services) District Secretariat (A) Local Governance (E), assisted by Divisional Secretariat (A) No official (administration/legal) function ... To be continued Role/Responsibility

Table A-1 (Continuation) 15. Thailand Level National Region/zone Province District Subdistrict Village 16. Vietnam Level
- 31 -

Local Name Rathasapa Changwat Ampuor Tambon Muban

Number 76 876 7,225 71,362

Approximate Population 62 million 0.8 million 62,000 8,000 1,000

Role/Responsibility PM, NA (E) Coordination only Governor (A) and Peoples Assembly (E) District Office (A) Tambon Administration Organization (TAO) (E) Village Chief (E)

Local Name

Number

Approximate Population

Role/Responsibility

National Vietnam 77 million PM, NA Region/zone Province Province 62 1.2 million Council and Committee (A, E) District District 609 127,500 Council and Committee (A, E) Subdistrict Commune 10,300 7,500 Council and Committee (A, E) Village Village 51,700 1,500 a As mentioned earlier, the participants of this seminar updated and improved the database on systems of governance Notes: prepared by the participants of a recently-held APO Seminar on Effective Decentralization for Community Development. Table A-1 presents a summary of these modified or improved database on the status of decentralization and local governance of APO member countries. Japan, Rep. of Korea, Malaysia and Mongolia were not represented at the present seminar and therefore, the data sheets prepared during the previous seminar are included here (without any modifications). Singapore and Hong Kong are not included; b in this document it means the approximate population of each local government unit; c (E) means directly elected by voting of the public. So, they are basically peoples representatives. Usually, government officials work under the supervision of elected peoples representatives such as governors, mayors; d (A) means appointment by upper strata of the bureaucracy. So they are basically government officers; and e also there are Community Development Associations (5,497).

Annex II A-2. Informal Organizations 1. Bangladesh Social Service ASSA (Agricultural Support Service Program) Swanirwar Bangladesh (SB) BRAC (Bangladesh Rural Advancement Committee) CVDP (Comprehensive Village Development Plan) Proshika Islamic foundation 2. Republic of China a) Group of Farmers Right Promotion (to advocates and defend farmers rights), formed by farmers who felt that they are being unfairly treated. Mostly come from non-members of farmers association. b) Tzy-chi Charity Group: to redistribute resources to the poor or victims. Formed by residents willing to do charity. Most of the members are Buddhists. 3. Fiji Ramayan Mandalis: Crime Prevention Committees Death and Relief Societies: Cane Access Road Committee Water Project Committee: Electricity Project Committee Graham Sudhar Society: School Committee Fire Prevention Committee: Vegetables Farmers Society Sugarcane Growers Council: Womens Crisis Center 4. India Temple Festival Committee Ethnic Groups for Social Support Yuvak Mandals Himachal Pradesh Gaon Sudhar Sabha, Himachal Pradesh Women Credit Group, Andhra Pradesh Anti-addiction Group of Women, Haryana Vegetable Grower Farmers Group (for marketing Orissa) Mushroom Grower Farmers Group, Orissa Shramdaan 5. Islamic Republic of Iran Community-based Organizations NGOs Traditional Systems: Shirvareh: Livestock Northern Iran Boneh: Irrigation arid areas Sahra: Grazing mountainous areas Damgah: Waterfall trapping Mazandaran province of Iran Mosha: Land cultivation - general Heyat: Religious general 6. Nepal Dhukuti dhikuri system: savings group for community Parma/bali system: help for agriculture, labor contribution, turn by turn Bhajan mandal: ritual singing group (mostly old people) Guthi system: help for monument preservation/social activities ceremony, marriage, etc. Ama samuha: womens anti-drug, medicine campaign group

- 32 -

7. Pakistan Zakat Committee: Water Users Committee Women Development Committee: Flood Protection Musical Cultural Society: Environmental Protection Society Village Education Society: Timber Society Welfare Society: Forestry Crime Prevention Committee: Agriculture Development Committee Peace Committee: Funeral Committee 8. Philippines (Endogenous groups/institutions) Damayan: For help in deaths, health, wedding, etc. Hermanola mayor: Usually done every year, wherein a family is assigned to manage the fiesta. This is a local community tradition. Bayanihan: Farm members of the group agree to work on ones farm to the next and so on. Transfer of family from one place to another. 9. Sri Lanka Thrift and Credit Societies Death Donation Societies Temple Societies Shramadana (organized voluntary labor) Village Sports Clubs and Youth Societies Mahila Samithi (womens societies) 10. Thailand Rai kok vegetable production group Ban Deng chicken group Lam Sai Yong ) ) savings groups Nong Sai ) Nong Ta Kai silk weaving group Nang No funeral society NGOs like the Population and Community Development Association (PDA). 11. Vietnam a) Agricultural extension club at commune level: It has many groups belonging to different professions such as plant group, fish group, and animal group, etc. Each group consists of 15-30 persons and they meet periodically (e.g. monthly). b) Purposes: help each other on such aspects as technology; receive/organize new seeds and new animals; support each other in terms of capital based on savings; guide members in obtaining loans from Agriculture Bank; raising funds such as for abolishing hunger and reducing poverty, solving conflicts, etc.

- 33 -

1. ROLE OF LOCAL COMMUNITIES AND INSTITUTIONS IN INTEGRATED RURAL DEVELOPMENT


Dr. C. M. Wijayaratna
Institutional Strengthening Specialist and Agricultural/Natural Resources Economist Auckland New Zealand

I. INTRODUCTION Despite the massive rural-urban migration, nearly two-thirds of people in the AsiaPacific region live in rural areas and rural development has been a pivotal mechanism in the overall economic strategy of most of the countries. Many countries in the region have adopted a variety of programs and projects to alleviate poverty and to uplift the general wellbeing of the rural people. Even the more urbanized economies of Eastern and Southeastern Asia have adopted strategies to accelerate social and economic development in rural areas, to make rural areas attractive, both in economic and social dimensions, and to reduce urban migration. Such strategies included restructuring and modernizing agriculture, promotion of agro-industries and creating special economic zones in rural areas, enhancing community facilities and fiscal incentives. The developing countries on the other hand, have adopted policy measures and implemented special programs and projects aimed at poverty alleviation, employment generation and improving general well-being of rural masses. The realization of effective rural development requires complementary efforts, for example: a) developing and strengthening local institutional capacities; b) improving rural infrastructure and related services; c) a supportive policy framework (e.g., policies to promote financial intermediaries in the rural areas); d) developing agriculture as well as rural industries and other off-farm activities; e) provide education, skill training, health and other essential services; and f) most importantly, measures to ensure socio-economic and environmental sustainability of such efforts. In addition, development programs and projects should be responsive to the needs of the poor and promote their active participation. Therefore, an integrated program would be more effective. This paper examines the role of local communities and institutions in Integrated Rural Development (IRD). Local Communities and Institutions A wide range of institutions and organizations1 could be included under local communities and institutions. These would range from government institutions on extreme,

In this paper we do not treat institutions and organizations separately. For a detailed account on the distribution between them, refer Uphoff, 1986 and 1997. Institutions are complexes of norms and behaviors that persist over time by serving some collectively valued purposes, while organizations are structures of recognized and accepted roles, formal or informal (Uphoff, 1986:8-10, quoted in Uphoff, 1997, p.6). - 34 -

to peoples organizations (focusing on collective action) on the other. Uphoff (2001) identified nested levels of decision-making and action, ranging from the individual level up to the international level. At the lower end, there are three levels of decision-making and action that do qualify as local in the sense that people within them know each other, or have a chance to know each other. Local refers to relationships where some common interest exists and is understood, and people are willing and able to engage in collective action. Above local levels, they can participate as citizens, but within local arenas they have a bond of membership. The community or village level has a very visible manifestation: a set of dwellings, and associated residents, clustered together or at least designated by common agreement to belong to a particular village. The group level is generally smaller than the community level, because most groups are subsets of persons within communities. Capabilities for local-level development are crucial for advancing peoples productivity and well being (Uphoff, 2001). In this paper, under the broad classification of local communities and institutions, we emphasize on the role of two major actors: a) local government at lower levels2 will be considered under the category of local government (which is considered as a crucial institution in IRD); and b) community organizations and institutions, including, cooperatives, farmers/people companies, farmers organizations, other types of peoples associations, such as credit unions, savings societies, educational institutions, clubs, etc., are considered under the category of local communities. In addition, the role of (NGOs) and the Organized Private Sector (OPS) will be examined briefly. Common understanding on the concept of IRD and clarity on responsibilities and roles of different stakeholders is vital. The role of the government in community development is changing and therefore, it would be important to clarify and identify the specific roles of the government vis--vis the local communities. It is in this context that this paper would examine the roles of local communities and institutions in IRD. First, the paper will submit a brief account on the Evolution of Rural Development Approaches and the recent emphasis on Decentralization and its impact on IRD. This section will explain how the IRD projects3 came into being the shortcomings realized during the implementation process of IRD projects, and the recent developments/modifications to the IRD project approach, such as Regional Rural Development, especially as a response to Decentralization of Governance. Next, the paper will elaborate on the Shared Roles and Responsibilities in Rural Development (especially after decentralization). Obviously, effective IRD, which cuts across multiple sectors, is a multidisciplinary affair and it is difficult to separate the roles of different stakeholders. This will be followed by brief accounts on the specific roles of: a) government with special emphasis on that of local government; b) local communities; c) NGOs; and d) OPS. Subsequently, with special reference to local communities, the paper

See Section III and Tables A-1 and A-2 in the Appendix for a classification of governance under decentralization.. Throughout this paper, we use IRD to represent its true meaning whereas IRD projects are special type of projects and they were expected to follow an integrated approach to rural development. - 35 -

will examine the role of capacity-building. Following this, the discussion will turn to Constraints on Effective IRD. The final section of the paper is devoted to summary and conclusions. II. EVOLUTION OF RURAL DEVELOPMENT APPROACHES In the past, international donors and governments in the developing countries followed a sectoral approach in their development efforts. However, there were shortcomings in this approach and it has been established that sectoral investments alone would not adequate for rural development. While this approach has the potential for improving the provision of public services, it is clear this usually promotes deconcentration of sectoral line Ministries and Departments and prevents effective decentralization. Also, it does not address crosssectoral issues. Hence, it has been realized that, in order to achieve the expected benefits of the decentralization efforts, sectoral investments/programs need to be linked with decentralized integrated development efforts. In the 1960s, the international donors and recipient governments started Integrated Rural Development Projects (IRDPs) and Area Development Projects (ADPs), mainly with the aim of alleviating rural poverty. These projects followed a multi-sectoral and regional approach and included such components as: agricultural development, education, road infrastructure, health services, etc. Despite the fact that these were focused on specific regions, more often than not, the IRDPs adopted a centrally-planned local development approach and involved expensive external advisory inputs. It has been often argued that IRD projects have been adversely affected by top-down approaches to development planning and has become supply-driven in many countries. Policies, development strategies and even programs and projects designed at the top by government authorities, sometimes with donor assistance, did not necessarily take into account the demands and the capacity of local populations. Consequently, such efforts did not address the specific problems of different communities and social groups. There was very little flexibility during downstream implementation and a learning process was not visible. In certain countries, special implementing authorities have been established, while in other cases, the government agencies were responsible for implementation. Also, this top-down style had contributed to the dependency of local communities on direct external assistance, especially from central government, through donor-funded projects. For example, most of the investment and inputs for rural infrastructure development in the past few decades came mainly through direct government support or from special projects such as IRDPs, usually supported by bilateral and international donors and development agencies. Another major dilemma in the public provision of these services has been the tendency to put inadequate emphasis on user maintenance and cost recovery. In the late 1980s, there was a debate on the IRD project approach. For example, a World Bank-sponsored study identified the major gaps/problems associated with IRD projects including the following (IBRD, 1987): i. ii. iii. iv. v. Difficulties encountered in linking and integrating with government institutions; Top-down and inflexible/rigid approach; Solutions are not matched with regional realities; Lack of participation of the local communities; and Weak concepts.

- 36 -

Out of these, the inadequate involvement of local communities could be considered as the most critical issue. With this experience, some donors diverted the attention towards sectoral programs while few others focused on poverty-specific programs and regional development. One of the most striking features of this latter category of projects is to focus on specific areas. Recent developments in the decentralization processes have provided opportunities for a new approach towards IRD. A new concept has emerged; namely, Regional Rural Development with emphasis on spatial dimension of development. For example, in Sri Lanka, IRD projects are being replaced by the Regional Economic Advancement Programs (REAP), which are focusing on employment and income generation in the regional economy through strengthening the local service system for micro, small and medium enterprises, including agriculture. We believe that the recent advancements in decentralization have enhanced the scope for IRD through increasing the potential for Shared Roles and Responsibilities in Rural Development at local levels. Next section of the paper will examine this concept. III. DECENTRALIZED GOVERNANCE AND SHARED ROLES AND RESPONSIBILITIES IN RURAL DEVELOPMENT As stated in Section I, effective IRD, which cuts across multiple sectors, is a multidisciplinary affair and it is difficult to separate the roles of different stakeholders. For example, it is hard to separate the roles of different stakeholders in strategic planning for IRD, assessing the availability of resources (internal and external), designing alternative develop-ment plans, selection and implementation of such plans, and monitoring and evaluation (M&E). In this context, this section will discuss some concepts and areas of shared roles and responsibility of local governments, communities and others such as the OPS and NGOs. In many countries, now there is a tendency to decentralize authority and responsibility for rural development. Decentralization strengthens democracy and civic responsibility, and enhances the potential for community-level interventions. In addition, governance closer to communities will be more accountable to the downstream and the communities will have better opportunities to participate in the design, implementation, and monitoring of development efforts. Development of community consciousness is important for community development. And, it is important to respect the felt needs of respective local communities. These are the needs as perceived and felt by the community and could be different from those needs which have been identified by outsiders. People should be consulted and informed of different choices. Effective decentralization could lead to an institutional transformation, which is more conducive to such a regional approach. Particularly, the local government institutions and local community organizations could establish a collaborative partnership in undertaking the responsibility for developing a local vision and strategy; and designing/ planning, allocating resources, implementing and monitoring/evaluating of development activities that would better cater the local needs. They would jointly become the driving force towards development, develop a sense of shared ownership and become managers of their development initiatives. In the past, rural development had been adversely affected by top-down approaches to development and has become supply-driven in many countries. Policies, development strategies and even programs and projects designed at the top by government authorities,
- 37 -

sometimes with donor assistance had failed to adequately take account the demands and the capacity of local populations. On the contrary, decentralization advocates a demand-driven strategy and has the merit of considering the specific demands and potential of each locality. Decentralization can take place in different ways with different degrees of intensity. It could cater effectively to public needs by bringing planning and decision-making closer to people, provide opportunities for beneficiary participation and community management of its own development and help reduce inequity and instability. After decentralization, as the individuals access to the required services and supplies cannot be assured through bureaucratic modes, the evolution of new forms of organized service delivery is imperative. Community organizations and the private sector should assume this responsibility in a business mode. Recently, the APO organized a seminar on Effective Decentralization for Community Development. The seminar examined the systems of governance in participating countries. After the country paper presentations, the participants prepared comparable information sheets on governance system in their respective countries. A summary of these data and information on the status of decentralization and local governance and a comparative overview of the same are given in Tables A-1 and A-2 in the Appendix.4 The seminar concluded that in most countries, there is already some institutional framework in place within which effective community development can be promoted. Hence, it is a matter of adding appropriate roles, procedures and powers to existing structures, and of modifying present relationships to become more productive and participatory. The comparison of systems of governance, from the center to lowest level revealed that the systems of governance among countries are diversified but there are some common elements. At the same time, it seems that the smallest administrative units in some countries, such as Village Development Committee (VDC) in Nepal and Tambon Administration Organization (TAO) in Thailand, are too large for development initiatives by local people to be effective. The most appropriate level for decentralization for effective community development is one where it is possible for people to have face-to-face interaction, leading to collective action and self-help. Depending on the pattern of settlement and size of communities, this may be a single village or a set of hamlets often called the ward level, e.g., in India and Nepal or a set of villages often called the locality level, e.g., the tambon in Thailand. These basic units may become more effective if they are subdivided into smaller groups for collaborative work at the lowest level. The success of decentralization depends on many factors such as: stage of development; quality of governance at different levels; effective devolution of responsibility and authority to local levels; transformation of public institutions and change in attitude; availability of resources including financial, human, physical and natural; quality of the

The information sheets were not validated. The objective of the information sheet preparation was to grasp the local governance system by comparative overview. Hence the participants have been requested to provide a general overview, instead of looking for more accurate statistics and detailed explanation. The data included in these sheets, therefore, are tentative and unvalidated nature. Based on the information sheets developed by the participants, the summary was originally prepared in a form of a Comparative Overview by a resource person of the seminar, Prof. Norman Uphoff (Table A-2). Subsequently, the format of the information sheets has been modified and Table A-1 has been prepared by Akira Munakata, APO Program Officer (Community Development). - 38 -

information available to decentralized units; strength of local organizations and local governments; participation of local people and adherence to local priorities; preparation of decentralized units local governments, communities and others to market realities and competition; accountability and transparency; efficient management of financial and other resources; effective M&E system; vertical and horizontal integration, especially the efficient management of interactions among different actors community organizations, local governments, private sector and the central government; and effective mechanisms for managing conflicts (Wijayaratna, 2001). There are constraints associated with decentralization and local governments and communities have to manage them efficiently. For example, it may take time to resolve many of the constraints prevailed prior to decentralization. Such problems may include resource constraints, lack of accountability and transparency, political conflicts, and inadequacies in support services. Another problem confronted with decentralization is the economies of scale. Especially in small countries, this may act as a constraint in resource utilization, including human resources. If they are distributed thinly, as demanded by a typical process of decentralization, this could affect efficiency. Scale economies in agriculture, industry, trade and other services could also affect production. Regionalization could be a solution and regional centers for planning and managing development as well as regional specialization in production and trade, etc. could be attempted. These are shared responsibilities and the local governments and communities should collaborate in such ventures. It is also clear that the roles and responsibilities assigned or allowed to different actors; namely, the central government, local governments, communities and the OPS, would depend on the type of decentralization and the effectiveness of such instruments such as the policy framework and legal system, institutional framework, fiscal system and resources, etc. To elaborate further, roles and responsibilities of different actors under decentralization would depend on issues such as: to what extent the decentralized units are assigned with the authority of policy formulation and the access and management of financial and other resources?; to what extent the geographical boundaries and resource limits are assigned and the economies of scale are affected?; and what are the institutional arrangements, organizational strengths, coordinating mechanisms available at different levels and within and across different units? This implies that local capacity building becomes a crucial part of this new approach. This subject will be examined later in this paper. IV. ROLE OF LOCAL GOVERNMENT Past approaches of central governments as providers, owners and managers of rural development have resulted in the nurturing and perpetuating of a dependency syndrome, which effectively prevented the rural community being developed as valuable human resource. In other words, this process has had negative effects in developing human capital stocks. And, the direct state involvement in community development has been on the decline in the recent past. There is however, a need for continued central government involvement in the rural sector, but it should be different from the approaches and strategies adopted in the past. As the individual villagers access to the required services and supplies cannot be assured through bureaucratic modes, the evolution of new forms of organized service delivery is imperative. And, the government, especially the central government, should perform a facilitating role. This section will first examine the changing role of government, in general. Subsequently, the role of local government will be examined.

- 39 -

Role of Government In the past the respective governments have intensively involved in protecting, preserving and developing the local communities and incurred heavy expenditure as direct assistance in the form of the creation and management of economic and social infrastructure, technical assistance, for example in the form of extension, etc. In doing so, the governments, with the influence and assistance of the donor community, have adopted different concepts and approaches of socio-economic development in different names and at different times. However, the approaches adopted have been guided more by welfare-oriented considerations than development and they have been bureaucratic and highly patronizing. There were little or no mechanisms included to create a sense of belonging of these activities/programs to the local communities (Wijayaratna, 1997). This process has had negative effects in developing human capital stocks. At the same time this process has negatively influenced the social capital investment and its outputs such as collective action. However, with the governments finding it increasingly difficult to maintain even the minimum levels of support to the rural communities, mainly because of budgetary constraints and with increased evidence of success in experiments involving beneficiaries in managing rural development, there has been a growing tendency for respective governments and the donor community to adopt participatory or shared management processes, mainly as a strategy to reduce heavy expenditure on rural development in general and on rural infrastructure, in particular. Relative inefficiencies in the government bureaucracies in delivering support services to the rural sector have also motivated the respective governments to look for participatory and joint or collaborative processes. Therefore, governmental support in facilitating a process of more intensified and strengthened organizational activities on the part of the local people, needs special emphasis. In addition, the policy imperatives of governments on privatization need to be implemented in a manner that would promote the interest of the large rural segment of the population. With the creation of a competitive environment to ensure quality and fair cost, these policies will have to be implemented to benefit the ordinary villagers than to strengthen the intermediaries (Wijayaratna, 2002). An important function of the government would be the formulation and implementation of policies to facilitate the effective functioning of the new roles assumed by the other actors. This includes preparation and adoption of legislature and other regulatory mechanisms; managing fiscal policies; looking after the interests of different groups; ensure the participation of civil society; sustainable utilization of natural resources, etc. Government commitment is a necessary condition for the sustainability of rural organizations. In certain areas, sustainability of organizations is restricted due to inadequate policy support. In certain other areas, different perception on participation by different actors, chiefly the bureaucrats, including policy makers hinder the development and sustainability of organizations. An efficient and carefully designed legal framework to support the efforts of local organizations is essential, especially in areas where the procedures and structures of the decision-making process of the public service are oriented much more towards control than to innovative and creative work. For instance, it is prudent to provide local organizations with legal rights to participate in decision-making bodies at higher levels. In addition, the state, especially at the take-off or initial stages of this transition, will have to provide technical support and guidance, including research and extension, M&E at macro levels and prediction and forecasting the trends of development. Government at different levels central, regional and local should undertake the responsibility of updating the knowledge of local

- 40 -

organizations and people on technology, resources, policy environment and potential external links such as markets and trade. Governmental support in facilitating a process of more intensified and strengthened organizational activities on the part of the people needs special emphasis. Moreover, government commitment is a necessary condition for the sustainability of rural organizations in many countries, especially at the initial stages of social mobilization. Role of Local Government With decentralization, local governments will have to assume greater responsibilities and would become the focal centers for local development. For example, in Korea, local governments are supposed to perform comprehensive functions that affect citizens welfare and quality of life (Choe, 2001). These include: a) b) c) d) e) f) administrative matters pertaining to boundaries, internal organization and finance; promotion of local economy; regional development; environmental protection; education, sports, and culture; and fire protection and safety.

In addition, local governments usually responsible for improving the welfare of their residents. This responsibility would include functions such as the following: installation and operation of social welfare facilities; water supply and purification; nurturing of local business; local development projects; establishment and operation of schools, kindergartens and elementary, junior, and senior high schools; and prevention of fire and fire fighting. Also, certain national and provincial affairs are delegated to local governments. These include: 1) vaccination; 2) quarantine stations for contagious diseases; 3) extermination of rats and insects; 4) national tax collections by city/kun offices and provincial tax collections by city/kun offices; 5) collection of national river utility and occupancy fees; 6) disaster relief work of city/kun; 7) maintenance, repair and management of national roads; 8) collection of national road occupancy fees; 9) public health centers and operation of rural guidance institutions; and 10) protection of resident livelihoods (Choe, 2001). Local governments have to be effectively linked with the national levels as well as with local communities. They would be expected to undertake certain activities hitherto performed by the central government, such as certain legal and regulatory functions and the provision of services like extension. In addition, especially with increased demand and diversification of economic activities mainly due to the growing emphasis on globalization and associated changes, they would be entrusted with extra responsibilities. These may include guiding local communities, especially at the take-off stage, facilitating the capacity-building of local communities, catalyzing the interactions between the community organizations and the OPS, installation of monitoring mechanisms, etc. Assuming that they are now adequately empowered with responsibilities and authorities related to the access and management of resources and have decision-making powers devolved through the decentralization process, they should be in a position to promote and institutionalize decentralized planning and ensuring the local financing of community development. Moreover, these local bodies should be transformed as facilitators for integrating the local communities with the OPS and with the national and international levels.
- 41 -

Greater efficiency, transparency and accountability are expected with decentralization or with the shifting of authority from the center to the local level. Local governments are closer to the communities/people and are more knowledgeable about local potential and needs. On the other hand, local people would develop better relationships with their local governments and begin to trust local officials. Hence, accountability and transparency are expected to be improved with decentralization. There are other advantages in empowering local governments: response to local needs would become much quicker, information for the formulation local programs and projects would be readily available, as the government is closer to the people and especially to community organizations, abusing and corruption would be less, effectiveness in raising as well as utilization of revenues would be high, and the overall efficiency of managing development should be enhanced. Therefore, it is suggested that decentralization, if planned and implemented in a proper way, could enhance the overall development of a particular country. Thus, conflicts between the center and the periphery would be detrimental and the interactions between the two should be managed efficiently and partnerships should be developed. V. ROLE OF LOCAL COMMUNITIES For effective IRD, local communities should be organized themselves to undertake planning and managing development and are expected to take over the management of support services. This process takes time and a blue print approach or a ready-made model should not be adopted. Instead, it should be treated as an evolutionary process. In the past, the great potential (social wealth) of peoples participation was not generally viewed very seriously. Participation of community people has been limited to giving information (including in many Participatory Rural Appraisal [PRA] exercises), for top-down planning, receiving material incentives and other passive forms. Interactive participation and planned mobilization of social capital were largely missing. Unlike in huge business firms, in rural communities, where a large number of smallscale entrepreneurs making uncoordinated decisions, there is a need for institutional mechanisms to coordinate the decisions. A rational institutional framework is necessary to involve these mini decision-making units through organizational activities and to sustain such processes. Also, many of the rural people in many of these countries do not possess the strength to participate actively in a market economy, strengthening of social capital and collective action should help them benefit from the process of globalization. To achieve sustainability, the challenge is to facilitate and institutionalize a process through which rural communities themselves would evolve local organizations to satisfy their own local needs. As a prerequisite for accumulation and the effective mobilization of social capital for community development, improving or upgrading the human capital is crucial. Developing skills of the individuals in a given society will enhance the quality and quantity of the output of social capital such as the collective action. Moreover, many other problems may occur due to unplanned and ad hoc formation of rural organizations in a rush. These may include rural elite taking the leadership or organizations, conflicting goals and vague objectives, inadequate or lack of participation by the membership, unacceptable patterns of benefit distribution and malpractice and corruption. Also, in countries with long traditions of dependency on government services, building institutional capacity within communities for achieving self-reliance would be a formidable task. The intervention methodology requires potential members (of the rural communities)

- 42 -

to promote association, interaction and cooperation with each other; develop their perception of problems and needs; and then begin a process of exploring how these needs could be met. In effect, what needs to be done is to make a planned intervention into the community. Carefully selected and well-trained catalysts or change agents could make such interventions. And, as explained later in this paper, experienced and committed NGOs could provide such services. Especially with decentralization, local communities are expected to assume greater responsibility for community development. Community organizations/institutions will become the pivotal instruments responsible for managing community development, which include the assessment of community needs/demands as well as the potential such as the resources available internally and externally planning and implementing development programs; maintaining information systems; providing goods and services; developing and maintaining rural infrastructure; interacting effectively with local governments and the OPS; developing partnerships and sharing responsibilities; managing conflicts; and monitoring and evaluating community development. Hence, the capacity of community organizations as well as the effective utilization of the wealth of social capital would become important determinants of decentralization. Effective Utilization of Social Capital Effective utilization of social capital can be singled out as the most important role of local communities in IRD. Major factors that contributed to demand for utilizing social capital in IRD include: a) declining role of the government; b) the growing demand for improved and diversified infrastructure in rural areas; c) relative inefficiencies in the government bureaucracies in rural development, including the delivering of support services to the rural sector; and d) the experience in efficiency improvements that have been effected through local community participation in development. Many countries have had traditional systems of participatory and collective behavior of rural communities. And, most of such countries are now building on such traditions to accelerate rural development. As rural people in many of these countries do not possess the strength, as individuals, to participate actively in a market economy, strengthening of social capital and collective action should help them benefit from the process of globalization. Peoples participation in IRD and partnerships between the government, people and the private sector should be viewed in this context. Community participation and the role of the community, both as organizations/ institutions and individuals in IRD, is not something that can be set once for all in a particular pattern. It is an evolutionary dynamic process and there is a need for institutional mechanisms to coordinate the decisions taken by a large number of individuals. To achieve sustainability, the challenge is to facilitate and institutionalize a process through which rural communities themselves would evolve local organizations to satisfy their own local needs.5 As a prerequisite for effective mobilization of social capital for IRD, improving or upgrading the human capital is crucial. Developing skills of the individuals in a given society will enhance the quality and quantity of the output of social capital such as the collective action. Social capital is an asset that can produce streams of benefits that can be measured, such as income. Mutually Beneficial Collective Action (MBCA) is the most common benefit

For an in-depth discussion on this subject, especially relate to the countries in Asia and the Pacific, refer Wijayaratna, 2002. - 43 -

or outcome of social capital. It should be stressed that, here we include only the MBCA or collective action that generates benefits to the society as a whole and not only to the individual. Collective action aimed at purely self-centered purposes and at the expense of others is excluded. Hence social capital is different from other types of capital; namely, physical, natural resources and human capital and is expected to produce goods that are more public than private. In general, either structural or cognitive forms of social capital can be identified. Roles, rules, procedures, and precedents as well as social networks that establish patterns of social interaction can be included under the category of structural form of social capital while the cognitive form is characterized by norms, values attitudes and beliefs. The latter category of social capital creates a supporting environment that motivates beneficiaries in MBCA. The structural form provides mechanisms for collective action and facilitates the process. For example, established roles for cooperation will facilitate decision-making, resource mobilization, communication, and conflict resolution. As we are concerned about the utilization of social capital in IRD, it is clear that improving or upgrading the human capital is crucial. For example, developing specific skills of the individuals in a given society will enhance the quality and quantity of the output of social capital such as the collective action. Investment in education, skill development, nutrition, etc. would strengthen the stock of human capital. Usually, there is a growing concern about the need for improving human capital. However, investing social capital in IRD is a novel approach. The four basic functions of structural social capital that could facilitate and support MBCA would be: * * * * if people are to work together predictably, fruitfully, efficiently, they need to have roles supplemented by rules, procedures and precedents for making decisions. to mobilize resources and manage these, there need to be some designated roles for this, supported by rules, procedures and precedents. there should also be roles, rules, procedures and precedents for communicating efficiently and effectively, and for coordinating activities that are decided upon. finally, whenever conflicts arise or are incipient, there should be roles, rules, procedures (processes), and precedents for resolving these, so that disputes do not impede collective action and are, if possible, prevented.

These may be accomplished through formal or through informal roles. Therefore, societies are not limited to just formal social structures. Informal structures roles with associated rules, procedures and precedents can also be as effective as formal relationships (Uphoff and Wijayaratna, 2000). Moreover, the two forms of social capital are interrelated and one may not exist without the other. For clarification, let us investigate what happens in catalyzing the development of a farmers organization. The catalyst/change agent will first try to help people change attitudes and values. More often than not, this will be done on individual basis. Then she/he promotes favorable interactions among people with the aim of creating organization. The formation of actual organization will come later. What we suggest here is that, usually the cognative form of social capital accumulates (or come) first in this process. The structural form or the organization (or institutions for that matter) comes as a consequence or as the logical next step. The organization/institution will produce MBCA

- 44 -

say, for example, cleaning an irrigation canal or undertaking group production or marketing to reduce transaction costs. Now, the profit so generated is also a stream of benefits. When social capital is used or mobilized, MBCA is generated and MBCA could be used to generate profits. In promoting small farmer companies we had argued that if communities could organize and mobilize social capital, the resulting MBCA would increase, not only societal benefits (like reduced conflicts, environmental protection, etc.) but also the individual profits. The pattern of distribution of benefits and costs is an important factor motivating individuals to organize for collective action. If a certain type of collective action reduces the cost to the individual or when the individuals experience more equity in the distribution of profits generated from collective action, then they would be attracted to participate actively in such group action. The common benefit derived from group action should be distributed in a manner acceptable to the individual member. And, the individual member must have the right to enjoy freely her or his share of profit derived from group action. In addition, if there is a need for sharing responsibilities in order to increase individual profits or if there exist interdependence of different roles such as producers, collectors, processors, store or warehouse keepers, managers, etc. it implies comparative advantage for local organizations. Therefore, it would be beneficial if the communities utilize social capital in developing and managing such services. Few selected areas related to IRD, where social capital could effectively be utilized, are explained below. Social Capital and Rural Infrastructure6 More often than not, the rural infrastructure had been recognized as a public good and, in general, the establishment, maintenance as well as control and improvement had been considered to be the responsibility of the state. Usually high costs are associated with the establishment of rural infrastructure. However, once the infrastructure is developed, the marginal cost of consumption of that facility by an additional member of the community approaches zero. This would act as a disincentive for an individual or a private firm to produce such public goods. Hence, the collective action has the comparative advantage in handling certain infrastructure. With increased and diversified economic as well as noneconomic activities in the rural areas, and because the respective governments increasingly find it difficult to provide and maintain rural infrastructure, there is a growing demand for investing social capital. Local governments and communities should find out which rural infrastructure would have the comparative advantage to be handled by them selves. In addition to the benefits generated, the selection of rural infrastructure (to be developed and managed by the rural community) should also be judged on the basis of the capacity of respective communities and local governments. For example, they may take the responsibility for rural roads, especially for farm to market roads and, obviously, the provincial or central authorities would be responsible for the major roads. Similarly, the basic agricultural production would be the responsibility of the individual tiller while the input services, storage, marketing and processing/value addition, etc. and the development and the management of related infrastructure would be the responsibility of the local organization/company.

A detailed analysis on social capital and rural infrastructure was presented to an earlier seminar of APO. See Wijayaratna, 2002. - 45 -

Social Capital for Diversified Economic Activities Matured organizations may wish to expand their scope, for instance by expanding their economic activity. Then the organizational structure should be adjusted for efficient handling of these new tasks and roles: it may be diversified and division of management and labor may be necessary to undertake special functions. Peoples companies or similar institutions may be more appropriate at that stage. They may have better legal power and recognition and are readily accepted by the OPS. This is important for business ventures. For example, companies for agro-based industries could establish legal contracts with OPS companies for forward sale of agricultural products. Moreover, peoples companies are independent business organizations that could avoid political and other problems (Wijayaratna, 1997 and 2002). Such group action would also eliminate the problem of economies of scale and reduce transaction costs as well as the risk of credit agencies. Social Capital for Input-Output and Financial Markets One of the most important roles of community organizations and institutions would be to link community with external markets and supply services. In this regard, sustainable financial institutions geared to better serving the needs of medium, small, and micro enterprises including sound and efficient banking systems and capital markets should also be promoted. It would be useful to assist the development of sustainable financial institutions geared to better serving the needs of medium, small, and micro enterprises including sound and efficient banking systems and capital markets. Especially, the provision of credit directly to the individual users through statesponsored programs, or donor-driven projects has been a salient feature in rural areas of many developing countries. First, the practice has proved to be unsustainable since it breeds defaulters with the end result of writing off loans by political processes. Second, it does not lead to recognizing the importance of improving users creditworthiness that could lead to action, improving credit rating of the individual user. Third, it does not recognize the important transactions with community organizations dealing with viable economic ventures in which the individual users are a part. Fourth, it demands certain types of collateral that small-scale users find difficult to produce. Fifth, it involves time-consuming and complex processes of bureaucracy or red tape. Sixth, it incurs heavy administration costs. Because of such costs and high rates of default, the interest rates, if not subsidized, are exorbitantly high. This is true for some existing banking systems as well. The traditional subsidized credit programs of the government had taken the form of a relief or rescue operation to small farmers. This was a burden on the government budget. These deficiencies do not facilitate the emergence of a production environment that would motivate users to engage in profitable economic ventures, especially in an open market setting. In this context, it is proposed to facilitate the establishment of: a) New organizations, such as community organizations that are structured to deal with community business such as peoples companies, where small-scale users could collectively plan their individual economic ventures, and use community action on discipline for credit repayment. Information systems: on technologies related to crops of comparative advantage, processing/value-added, markets, transport, legal contracts, banking, etc. Novel mechanisms among lending institutions to lower transaction costs, and offer better packages of support with relaxed procedures in supply of credit.

b) c)

- 46 -

In addition, efficient management of input supplies and out put disposal by community organizations could reduce costs and increase profits of individual members of a particular organization. The benefit or the profit margin of the individual members will significantly influence viability of group action. VI. ROLE OF NON-GOVERNMENTAL ORGANIZATIONS7 Usually, NGOs help reduce government domination at local level. We suggest that the major role of NGOs in IRD is to facilitate institutional development/strengthening in the communities. At the community level, in order to achieve effective and sustainable rural development, the challenge is to facilitate and institutionalize a process through which rural communities themselves would evolve local organizations to satisfy their own local needs. For this, a catalytic process or a planned intervention into the community is required. Such a catalytic effort should be strong enough to generate the internal dynamism of the community and controlled enough not to dominate it. The intervention methodology requires potential members (of the rural communities) to promote association, interaction and cooperation with each other; develop their perception of problems and needs; and then begin a process of exploring how these needs could be met. In effect, what needs to be done is to make a planned intervention into the community. Carefully selected and well-trained catalysts or change agents could make such interventions (Wijayaratna, 1985). Our experience with small farmers organizations suggests that these ideal features are not found frequently in state-sponsored organizing processes. Instead, local organizations are formed (and not evolved from within the communities) by field officials not to fulfill peoples needs, but merely to follow the orders of the superior officials or to satisfy the politicians. And, experienced and effective NGOs could bridge this gap and play a catalytic role. Facilitating the Evolution of Self-correcting Mechanisms To attain self-reliance, local organizations need to adopt self-correcting mechanisms on a continuous basis. An experienced and committed NGO could help local organizations and institutions to internalize participatory self-assessment procedures to measure and monitor the performance of the organization as well as the development and management processes. In collaboration with the members of other participating organizations, local officials of relevant agencies, resource persons such as technical experts, the NGO could pave the way for participatory (M&E) and Management Information Systems (MIS) especially at the planning and initial stages of adoption. Such a planning process and M&E would help the membership to articulate a possible future vision for their organizations. The Need for Dynamic and Forward-looking NGOs It should be evident from earlier discussion that, with the diversified and expanded functions expected from the local communities and institutions, the role and functions of the change agency/agent or facilitator/catalyst should also be changed. The added roles of a facilitator/catalyst in such situations would include:
7

Usually, NGOs are different from rural peoples organizations in that they are generally not grassroots organizations or community organizations. And, in general, the NGOs are funded from outside. - 47 -

i. identify and estimate market potential: e.g., for selected agricultural enterprises and agro-processing, assist in the scheduling of production in a given area, inform the community organization and other technical officers (such as the extension and credit, input supplies) of the availability of markets for enterprises that would match with the agro-climatological and socio-economic conditions of the area and for the selected processed products; ii. estimate the production of these selected enterprises jointly with the community organization and then arrange for forward contracts with identified markets/buyers. In this way, the facilitator/NGO will link the community organizations with potential markets/private sector firms; iii. assist the rural community in monitoring the feasibility of meeting the contractual agreements: For this, the catalyst/NGO will join the staff of local government and other staff of the community company/organization and assist them to monitor, whether there are any constraints faced by the rural community in the markets, production and processing, etc., which may affect the quantities and quality standards included in the forward contracts or other agreements; iv. arrange for expert advice as well as other needs of the organization/company. These will include all aspects of markets, marketing and processing farm products, storage, packing, transport, etc. The objective is to help evolve the required business mode of operation within the organization/company; and v. Be accountable community organizations. It should be noted, however, that in some cases, due to the relative inefficiency in government agencies or due to the lack of effective community organizations at the grassroots level, funding agencies have tended to load new tasks onto NGOs, whether or not they are suited to such tasks. Looking ahead, and in the context of reduced role of governments, the NGOs will come under increasing pressure as alternatives, especially to government agencies. VII. ROLE OF THE PRIVATE SECTOR In open market economies, liberalization not only results in an increased withdrawal of government interventions, but also leaves economic activities open to the market forces. In areas where central government had played an important role, the reforms or the adjustment and stabilization programs would induce private sector participation for increased efficiency and to reduce the burden to government. And, with decentralization, governments role as a service provider will be diminished. Therefore, this gap needs to be bridged by the private sector and community organizations. In addition, as discussed earlier, a variety of new activities, including production of goods and services, would be introduced. In the context of national budget constraints, many countries seek private sector involvement. For example, in developing rural infrastructure, certain developing countries already adopting a mode of rehabilitate, operate, and transfer, with the private sector firms, especially on road construction along high traffic routes. A toll system of fees would be explored along such routes. This system works on the principle that as long as such infrastructure yields significant net benefits to the users, these same users would be willing to pay for the privilege to use them. Globalization has now become an unavoidable process and an organized local community should have the capacity to consider it as an opportunity rather than a
- 48 -

threat. It has been argued that the developing countries could benefit from participation in the global economy. Freeing prices and liberalization of trade have the potential for enhanced private sector participation and creating opportunities for new investments and jobs, and promoting more efficient use of resources and higher productivity. In addition, access to external resources and direct foreign investment could be expected with the liberalization of capital flows. Direct investment by foreign investors may also encourage the transfer of technology, managerial expertise, and skills. Under such circumstance, an effective partnership between the OPS (local and international) and organized communities would be mutually beneficial. And initially, local governments could facilitate this process. Positive response of communities to globalization and making use of the globalization process creatively to the advantage of local communities would be important. The challenge would be to make rural people active partners in the global economy and improve their living standards. Peoples companies or similar institutions may be more appropriate vehicles for achieving such an effective partnership with the private sector, and to integrate communities with the external business environment. They may have better legal power and recognition and are readily accepted by the OPS. This is important for business ventures. Sustainable financial institutions geared to better serving the needs of medium, small, and micro enterprises, efficient banking systems and capital markets would be required for effective IRD. And, business organizations of the community people, such as peoples companies, should have the capacity to deal with such service providers. Group action, which would generate from social capital would gain such capacities and also eliminate the problem of economies of scale and reduce transaction costs as well as the risk of financing institutions. As mentioned elsewhere in this paper, in a dynamic environment, the institutions and organizations should be adjusted for efficient handling of new tasks and roles: it may be diversified, division of management and labor may be necessary to undertake special functions. It was also clear that effective integration of communities with the external markets and even with the global economy would be essential for effective IRD. Hence, effective partnerships between the community people and the private sector would become crucial. An effective partnership may occur when two or more parties have common objectives and would be based on agreements. Then there will be collaborative activities among interested groups, based on a mutual recognition of respective strengths and weaknesses. Shared agenda, joint decision-making, deep commitments and mutual benefits would constitute a partnership. VIII. CAPACITY-BUILDING AT LOCAL LEVELS Building the capacities of institutions at different levels is critical for them to effectively perform their respective roles. At the micro level the capacity of the community should be enhanced, with special emphasis on that of the leaders of the community organizations for them to become the owners and implementers of the development efforts, and to deal effectively with the local government units, NGOs and the OPS. At the same time, local government institutions need to be oriented and their skills and capacity should be strengthened towards community-oriented planning. At the national level, capacities need to be developed and attitudes need to be changed to provide a favorable policy, fiscal and institutional support.

- 49 -

Enhancing Local Capacity for Resources Management and Development Planning 1. Local Planning and Implementing Units/Centers It is proposed to establish and strengthen Local Planning and Implementing Units/Centers, representing local government institutions and community organizations. Such local planning centers need to be equipped with technical expertise that possess adequate knowledge and experience on development planning procedures, implementing methods and M&E. Such planners should know novel methods of participatory planning the conventional Rapid Rural Appraisals (RRAs) and PRAs are time-consuming and less effective. More often than not PRA/RRA are being used merely as knowledge generation activities, especially for outsiders. Instead, participatory appraisals should be considered as a first step of an action program and aimed at developing a package of interventions. For example, in rural resources planning, interventions may be related to technology, organization/institutions, resources and policy. More specifically it should focus on a process of participatory appraisal of the current levels of management of (internal and external) resources, participatory design of a future vision and goals of reconciling environmental concerns and production goals, and the development of collaborative action plans to achieve such goals. Also, the accuracy of PRA can be improved if its use is integrated with other techniques such as: advanced mapping and incorporating more of external (in addition to indigenous) inputs, statistical sampling, direct measurement, and the use of objectively verifiable indicators and rigorous analytical tools. Decentralized planning units should maintain an integrated and accessible information systems, especially on the resources available to the community and for M&E. Similarly, the training and skill development needs of local organizations and institutions that are engaged in new tasks are of different types and are of continuous in nature. Changing technology and the expansion of activities of the local organizations with their maturity will call for new kinds of training and skill development. Also, the matured organizations will enter into transactions and business with outsiders such as the OPS. Therefore, the sustainability of the organizations will depend, among other things, on the knowledge and skills of their managers and those who are entrusted with specific functions. For example, training on financial management, acquiring skills in managing different types infrastructure, etc., are essential, especially for a multifunctional organization. A healthy and rigorous financial management system should be an integral component of an organization undertaking financial transactions. Organizations will have to develop their own financial plans, maintain proper records on financial transactions, assess their own financial activities (self-assessment) and establish and maintain an effective system of internal control. 2. Communication Technology in Capacity Building Utilization of communication technologies in rural development in developing countries is gaining momentum at present. In this regard, the Village Pay Phone initiative of the Grameen Bank, which is aimed at reducing poverty through the economic empowerment of women in rural Bangladesh, provides an excellent example. The Grameen Group provides credit to village women to purchase cellular phones. The phone owners could then rent out the phones to other members of the community for a fee and also provide messaging and incoming call services. The Grameen goal is to serve 500,000 subscribers in six years. Already there is evidence of: a) increased savings, investment and incomes; b) improved farm productivity and small farmer profits, for example through the enhanced access to market/price information and to better markets; c) improved investment on childrens

- 50 -

education; and d) better access to public services. However, there are challenges: cell phone technology is relatively expensive (compared to land phones) but it has been difficult to integrate with the national landline telecommunication system. Such obstacles need to be removed. When the pace and scale of flow of information across the globe is considered, it is clear that there exist a tremendous potential for human resources development. For example, if the access to Internet is enhanced, many people in the developing world, who are excluded from such gains in human development at present, could benefit from that technology. And, the marginal cost of connecting individuals and groups for exchanging ideas and experience as well as providing opportunities for knowledge and skill development through the Internet is negligible. As the Internet communication plays a crucial role in the globalization process, this option should not be overlooked. To assist in the identification of potential opportunities, the information must encompass a wider range. Information on resources, production technologies, and infrastructure as well as on value-added production and marketing, etc., becomes important when attempting to discover new economic potentials. The objectives of the information systems are manifold. First, the information on new and sustainable technologies, relevant to the activities undertaken by the local communities, should flow down from appropriate sources to the local organizations. Such technology should be affordable by the respective communities and viable. Second, information on opportunities available for local users such as banking and credit facilities, market and processing, etc. should be made available to the local organization. Third, the flow of information on policy, legal and regulatory aspects and information on relevant government or private sector collaboration/assistance and on the work of other relevant user groups/local organizations is of significant importance for pronounced growth and sustainability of local organizations involved in IRD. A continuous flow of information is required to enrich the implementation process facilitating interaction, debate and resolution. The prudent use of information technology (IT) in the generation, process and analysis of information needed is crucial to support the planning, implementation and evaluation of IRD. For this, the local communities and institutions may use a MIS and a rigorous self-M&E activity through a participatory procedure. It may review the progress and employ a feedback/correcting/warning mechanism to ensure that inputs, work schedules targeted outputs and other related actions are proceeding according to plan. Similarly, the training and skill development needs of organizations that are engaged in new tasks are of different types and are of continuous in nature. Changing technology and the expansion of activities of the local organizations with their maturity will call for new kinds of training and skill development. For example, training on financial management, acquiring skills in managing different types infrastructure, etc., are essential, especially for a multifunctional organization. 3. Coordination Mechanisms There is a need for effective coordination mechanisms at different levels as well as cutting across different hierarchical levels to ensure effective rural development. And, it is important to coordinate, not only the activities within communities, or the decisions taken and activities performed by the large number of people at the community level, but also the activities between communities and other actors of the rural development process, such as the local governments and, outsiders like the service providers at different levels, and the activities between those outsiders. For example, coordination between different national,

- 51 -

provincial or local government agencies dealing with development is important in mobilizing scarce resources to achieve maximum efficiency and impact. One of the most critical problems of rural development in many countries is the existence of several government agencies/departments, which often duplicate, instead of coordinating activities. Moreover, it has become even more important to establish adequate coordination among donors, development agencies, NGOs, etc., at all levels. 4. Monitoring and Evaluation The degree to which the local communities have control over local resources and the degree, to which they manage their development, could be regarded as good indicators for measuring the success of participatory IRD or the success of community-driven development. At the same time it is important to effectively link the decentralized local units, community organizations and their activities, especially the economic ventures/business, with outer environment, including international markets. Similarly, one could examine the degree to which local people recognize their rights and responsibilities and to what extent other actors respect those rights. In both these aspects, community organizations could play a dominant role. Organizations could ensure the equitable participation by community members. To attain self-reliance, local communities and institutions need to adopt monitoring and self-correcting mechanisms on a continuous basis. They could use participatory selfassessment procedures to measure and monitor the performance of the institutions and organizations as well as the development and management processes. Involvement of the community organizations, local officials of relevant agencies, resource persons such as technical experts and the partners of the OPS, including participating NGOs, at the planning stages, etc. will pave the way for participatory M&E and MIS. Such a planning would help the membership to articulate a possible future vision for their organizations. Database management and assisting the organization in the self-evaluation process should be an essential function and contribution by the facilitators. IX. OBSTACLES TO EFFECTIVE PARTICIPATION OF LOCAL COMMUNITIES AND INSTITUTIONS IN IRD Major obstacles to the effective participation of local communities and institutions in IRD include: resource constraints, including financial, human and physical such as rural infrastructure; problems of accountability and lack of transparency; political conflicts; and inadequacies in support services. Usually the central governments always emphasize the commitment to decentralization and reliance on local authorities. However, certain central governments do very little in practice there is a struggle for control rather than sharing authority; financing is centralized and sufficient funds are not allocated to local governments; in a donor-driven development process, the externally-funded projects are handled by the central governments; and thereby restricting the sources of funding for the local governments. In many developing countries, development is project-driven and the majority of the projects are donor-driven. Most of such projects are managed by the center and therefore, the local governments may lack the expertise and financial resources to effectively manage development and to cope up with the present trends such as the pace of globalization and trade relations. With decentralization, local governments would have the power to raise revenue through different ways, such as tax, cost recovery or user charges and local and

- 52 -

international borrowing, etc. However, many local authorities have a poor record of revenue collection and raising funds through other means. Hence, more often than not, they depend on funds transferred from the central government. This would remain as a constraint for sometime. It is important to transfer the essential services such as financial and human, to the local units, at least at the take-off stage. The private sector, including the NGOs, could also fill certain gaps. At the same time adequate measures should be taken to develop the skills and raise resources (such as tax revenue and service charges for financial needs) at local levels. Similarly, despite the fact that expertise on local needs and environment are at local levels, the expertise in planning and managing development, which is in short supply, is at national levels. How could local governments maintain a cadre of skilled set of officials, including planning expertise, high-caliber managers, M&E experts, etc? For this, the local governments have to be competitive with the OPS. If they fail to pay competitive salaries/remuneration packages to their good employees they would lose such people. On the other hand, in many countries, government employees are assured of lifetime employment and there is no adequate incentives or rewards for good work. For example, promotions are given on the basis of seniority or factors other than efficiency. Another constraint would be the inadequacies in support services, training and the supply of information. Therefore, training and skill development, especially in relation to the goods and services of economic sectors would become crucial. Similarly, the generation of information related to such aspects as technology, macro-economics and policy framework, trade and markets both domestic and international; as well as the flow of information to local levels, which may not be efficient at present, need to be improved. The local level too is not homogenous. There are different interest groups with conflicting goals. At the same time, linking local level with the regional level and the national level could be difficult. There could be center versus periphery conflicts as well. It has been reported that in Korea, the local autonomy system is burdened with formidable constraints that stem from the age-old traditional political culture steeped in authoritarianism and the centralization of power. Politicians in Seoul and bureaucrats in the central government hesitated to decentralize power to local governments. They believed that local diversity was a fiction and that a small country like Korea should be run by the central government with little local administrative discretion (Choe, 2001). Unless such conflicting interests and rivalries are managed properly, the benefits of decentralization may not be achieved. Lack of clarity of and the adherence to the responsibilities and accountabilities by different actors also act as a constraint. Such responsibilities and accountabilities may relate to various aspects of development like planning and managing development including fiscal and other resources, transparency, monitoring and evaluation, etc. X. CONCLUSIONS Effective IRD, which cuts across multiple sectors, is a multidisciplinary affair and it is difficult to separate the roles of different stakeholders. In the past, rural development had been adversely affected by top-down approaches to development and has become supplydriven in many countries. On the contrary, recent developments in decentralization advocate a demand-driven strategy and have the merit of considering the specific demands and potential of each locality.

- 53 -

The local government institutions and local community organizations could establish a collaborative partnership in undertaking the responsibility for developing a local vision and strategy; and designing/planning, allocating resources, implementing and monitoring/ evaluating of development activities that would better cater the local needs. They would jointly become the driving force towards development, develop a sense of shared ownership and become managers of their development initiatives. An important function of the central government would be the formulation and implementation of policies to facilitate the effective functioning of the new roles assumed by the other actors. With decentralization, local governments will have to assume greater responsibilities and would become the focal centers for local development. Local governments have to be effectively linked with the national levels as well as with local communities. They would be expected to undertake certain activities hitherto performed by the central government, such as certain legal and regulatory functions and the provision of services like extension. In addition, especially with increased demand and diversification of economic activities mainly due to the growing emphasis on globalization and associated changes, they would be entrusted with extra responsibilities. These may include guiding local communities, especially at the take-off stage, facilitating the capacity-building of local communities, catalyzing the interactions between the community organizations and the OPS, installation of monitoring mechanisms, etc. Usually, NGOs help reduce government domination at local level. It is suggested that the major role of NGOs in IRD should to facilitate institutional development/strengthening in the communities. For effective IRD, local communities should be organized themselves to undertake planning and managing development and are expected to take over the management of support services. At the community level, in order to achieve effective and sustainable rural development, the challenge is to facilitate and institutionalize a process through which rural communities themselves would evolve local organizations to satisfy their own local needs. For this, a catalytic process or a planned intervention into the community is required. Effective utilization of social capital can be singled out as the most important role of local communities in IRD. As a prerequisite for accumulation and the effective mobilization of social capital for community development, improving or upgrading the human capital is crucial. Matured organizations may wish to expand their scope, for instance by expanding their economic activity. Then the organizational structure should be adjusted for efficient handling of these new tasks and roles. One of the most important roles of community organizations and institutions would be to link community with external markets and supply services. Peoples companies or similar institutions may be more appropriate at that stage. This is important for business ventures. Globalization has now become an unavoidable process and an organized local community should have the capacity to consider it as an opportunity rather than a threat. In this, an effective partnership between the OPS and organized communities would be mutually beneficial. REFERENCES Asian Productivity Organization, 2001. Proceedings of the Seminar on Effective Decentralization for Community Development, 23-31 March 2001, Sri Lanka (unpublished).

- 54 -

Choe, Chang Soo, 2001. Country Paper (Rep. of Korea) presented to the APO Seminar on Effective Decentralization for Community Development, 23-31 March 2001, Colombo, Sri Lanka (unpublished). IBRD, 1987. World Bank Experience with Rural Development, 1965-1986, Washington D.C. Uphoff, Norman and C. M. Wijayaratna, 2000. Demonstrated Benefits from Social Capital: The Productivity of Farmer Organizations in Gal Oya, Sri Lanka, 2000", World Development, No. 28, Vol. 11, November 2000. Uphoff, Norman, 1986. Local Institutional Development: An Analytical Sourcebook with Cases, Kumarian Press, West Hartford, CT. ----------, 1997. Institutional Capacity and Decentralization for Rural Development, paper presented to the FAO Technical Consultation on Decentralization and Rural Development. ----------, 2001. Decentralization and Good Governance: A Framework of Decentralization for Sustainable Community Development, paper presented at the APO Seminar on Effective Decentralization for Community Development, 23-31 March 2001, Sri Lanka (unpublished). Wijayaratna, C. M., 1985. Involvement of Farmers in Water Management in Gal Oya, Sri Lanka in Participatory Experiences in Irrigation Water Management: Proceedings of the Expert Consultation on Irrigation Water Management held in Yogyakarta and Bali, Indonesia, 16-22 July 1984, 117-32, FAO. ----------, 1997. Role of Farmer Companies in the Sri Lankan Rural Economy, Sri Lanka Journal of Agrarian Studies, Vol. 9, Nos.1 and 2. ----------, 2000. Rural Community Development in Asia and the Pacific, paper presented at the APO Multi-country Study Mission on Integrated Community Development (ICD), 23-30 November 2000, Taoyuan, Republic of China (unpublished). ----------, 2001. Decentralization and Community Development: The Organizational Challenges, paper presented at the APO Seminar on Effective Decentralization for Community Development, 23-31 March 2001, Sri Lanka (unpublished). ----------, 2002. Social Capital and Rural Infrastructure: Strengthening the Active Participation of Local People, in Infrastructure for Community Development, Proceedings of the APO Seminar on Rural Infrastructure Development held from 24 October to 2 November 1999, Tehran, Islamic Republic of Iran, APO, Tokyo, Japan.

- 55 -

Appendix Table A-1. Local Governance System of APO Member Countriesa 1. Bangladesh
Level National Region/ zone Province District Subdistrict Village Local Name Desh Division Zila Thana Union Moza/Gram Number 6 64 496 4,451 64,000 Approximate Populationb 123 million 20 million 2 million 250,000 27,000 7,000 Role/Responsibility PM, National Assembly (NA) (E)c Coordination only Commissioner (A)d, zila parishad (E) Executive officer (A), thana parishad (E) Union officer (A), union parishad (E) Cooperative-society (informal)

2. Republic of China (Taiwan)


Level National Province/ municipalitie District Subdistrict Villagee Local Name Number 1 4 Hsien/county Shiang Tsuen/li 23 379 7,402 Approximate Population 22 million 51,000 to 16.5 million 88,000 to 3.3 million 10,000 2,500 Role/Responsibility Premier (E), NA (E) Province/municipal government/ farmers associations (FAs) Hsien government/county assembly/FA Office/council Office/council

3. Fiji
Level National Local Name Fiji Approximate Population 772,665 Role/Responsibility President, Parliament, Senate, Council of Chiefs Provincial Councils District Officer/Divisional Commissioner

Province Province District/Division Division Village Village

... To be continued

- 56 -

Table A-1 (Continuation) 4. India


Level Local Name Number 28 478 5,913 227,697 549,132 Approximate Population 1 billion 20 million 1 million 150,000 7,000 1,800 Role/Responsibility PM, National Assembly (E) Chief Minister, Assembly (E) Commissioner (A) zila parishad (E) Commissioner (A), panchayat samiti (E) Gram panchayat (E) One ward representative for 500 people

National Hindustan State/region State Province Zilla parishads District Subdistrict Village Block/panchayat samiti Gram panchayat

5. Indonesia
Level National Region/zone Province District Subdistrict Village Local Name Negara Propinsi Kabupaten Kecamatan Desa Kampung RT, RW* Number 29 100 500 4,000 Approximate Population 200 million 10 million 2 million 400,000 50,000 3,000 Role/Responsibility PM, NA Local House of Representatives, First Level, Governor

Peoples Council

Note: 6. Iran

* RT = Rukun Tetangga (neighborhood group); and RW = Rukun Warga (communal group, RW is a collection of several RTs).

Level National Region/zone Province District Subdistrict Village Settlement

Local Name Iran Ostan Sharestan Bakhsh Dehe-stan

Number 27 252 680 1,400

Approximate Population 65 million 3 million 258,000 40,000 17,000

Role/Responsibility PM, NA (E)

... To be continued

- 57 -

Table A-1 (Continuation) 7. Japan


Level National Region/zone Province District Subdistrict Village Local Name Kuni Chihou To-do-hu-ken Gun Shi-ku-cho-son Kyuson, buraku Number 1 47 550 3,200 10,000 2 million 10,000 3,000 Approximate Population 123 million Role/Responsibility PM (E), National Assembly (E) Coordination only Governor (E), Assembly (E) Coordination only Mayor (E), Assembly (E) Informal committee

8. Rep. of Korea
Level National Province Do, kwang-youksi Subdistrict Gu/si/kun Locality Dong, myun, eup Village Ri, tong Local Name Number 9 70-91 Rural - 4,000, Urban - 9,300 Rural - 35,000, Urban - 56,000 Approximate Population 42 million 5 million 66,000-333,000 1,400 (R)2,100 (U) 300 (R)600 (U) Role/Responsibility President (E), National Assembly (E)

9. Malaysia Level Local Name Number Approximate Population Role/Responsibility

National Negara 22 million MP, NA (E) Region/zone Province Negeri/state 13 1.6 million CM, Assembly (E) District District 120 180,000 District Officer (A) Subdistrict Wilaya Coordination only Village JKKK*/Kampung Village Chief, JKKK (E) Note: * JKKK = Jawatan-kewasa Keselamatan dan Kemajuan Kampong (village safety and development committee). 10. Mongolia Level National Province District Subdistrict Village Local Name Mongolia Aimag Sum Bag Khot-ail Number 21 342 1,600 Approximate Population 2.4 million 100,000 7,000 1,500 Role/Responsibility President, NA (E)

Several household ... To be continued


- 58 -

Table A-1 (Continuation) 11. Nepal


Level National Region/zone Province District Subdistrict Village Settlement Local Name Desh Region Zone Zilla Ilaka VDC Ward Number 1 5 14 75 475 3,913 9 Approximate Population 22 million 4 million 1 million 300,000 45,000 5,000 500 Role/Responsibility PM, NA Coordination only Coordination only District Development Council (E) Coordination only Village Development Committee (VDC) (E) VDC consists of one representative from each ward/ward (E)

12. Pakistan Level National Province (Sauba) Local Name Number Approximate Population Role/Responsibility CM, NA

Pakistan 133 million NWFP (17) 1 Punjab (72) 1 Sidhu (30) 1 Balochistan (7) 1 FATA/Capital (4) 7+1 Division Division 25 District Zila 110 50,000 Subdistrict Teshi Union Union 20,000 Village Gaaon Note: * Figures in parentheses are in million. 13. Philippines Level National Region/zone Province District Subdistrict Village Local Name Philippines Region Province Municipality Barangay Citio Number 16 78 1,526 41,939 Approximate Population 67 million 4 million 0.8 million 400,000 1,500

Commissioner Deputy Commissioner Assistant Commissioner Union Council (E) Number-dar (A)

Role/Responsibility President, NA (E) Coordination only, Governor, Council (E) Mayor, Council (E) Barangay Captain (E) Barangay Council (E) ... To be continued

- 59 -

Table A-1 (Continuation) 14. Sri Lanka


Level Local Name Number 8 25 258 14,000 Approximate Population Role/Responsibility

National Sri Lanka Region/zone Province Province District Subdistrict (Division) Village District Peradeniya sabhawa Gramodaya Mandalaya

18.5 millionn PM, NA (E) 2 million 750,000 58,000 1,000 Provincial Cabinet (A) Provincial Council (E) District Secretariat (A) Divisional Secretariat (A) No official (administration/legal) function

15. Thailand
Level Local Name Number 76 876 7,225 71,362 Approximate Population 60 million 0.8 million 62,000 8,000 1,000 Role/Responsibility PM, NA (E) Coordination only Governor (A) and Peoples Assembly (E) District Office (A) Tambon Administration Organization (TAO) (E) Village Chief (E)

National Rathasapa Region/zone Province Changwat District Subdistrict Village Ampuor Tambon Muban

16. Vietnam Level Local Name Number Approximate Population Role/Responsibility

National Vietnam 77 million PM, NA Region/zone Province Province 62 1.2 million Council and Committee (A, E) District District 609 127,500 Council and Committee (A, E) Subdistrict Commune 10,300 7,500 Council and Committee (A, E) Village Village 51,700 1,500 a Notes: Singapore and Hong Kong are not included; b in this document it means the approximate population of each local government unit; c (E) means directly elected by voting of the public. So, they are basically peoples representatives. Usually, government officials work under the supervision of elected peoples representatives such as governors, mayors; and d (A) means appointment by upper strata of the bureaucracy. So they are basically government officers.

- 60 -

A-2. A Comparative Overview of Systems of Governance by Level (focus is on rural areas)


National Korea (42 million) Provincial/Regional Province (7, 9) Do [2.6 million] Urban: 7; Rural: 9 Province (2+2)a [51,000 to 16.7 million] Province and city FAs (4/3) Province (61) [1.2 million] Prefecture (23) Hsien [3.3 million to 88,000] District FAs (23) District (609) [127,500] District Subdistrict County (91) Kun [66,000] (Urban: 69/ 72,264-333,000) Township (379) Shiang [47,000] Township FAs (268) Commune (10,300) [7,500/commune] Tambon (7,225) Tambon Administration Organization [8,000] Kecamaten (500) (sub-regency) [400,000] Desa (4,000) [50,000] Farmers associations Village (51,000) [1,500/village] Village Muban (63,000) [1,000]+HH clusters Kampung Locality Locality (929) Eup/ Myun [6,000] Saemaul Undong Village Village (33,000) Ri [350] (Urban Tong 56,000,600) Village (7,402) Tsuen [2,500] or Li

China (ROC) (22 million) Farmers associations (FAs) Vietnam [77 million] Thailand [60 million] Indonesia [200 million] Malaysia [22 million] India [1 billion] - 61 -

Province (75) District (846) Changwat Administration Amphor [62,000] Organization [800,000] Propinsi (29) (province) [5-10 million] State (13) [1.6 million] Region (5) State (28+8) State government Kabupaten (100) (regency) [2 million] District (120) [180,000] District (478) Zilla parishad [2 million]

Village (1,300) [1,800] Village committees Village/ward (1.5-2 million) [500]

Block (5,913) Panchayat (227,697) Panchayat samiti Gram panchayat [4,000] [150,000]

... To be continued

A-2. Continuation
National Nepal [22 million] Bangladesh [130 million] Provincial/Regional Region (5) Zone (Anchal) (14) [1.5 million] Division (6) [20 million] District District (75) District Development Council [300,000] District (64) Zilla parishad [2 million] District (25) [750,000] District (252) Sharestan [250,000] District government Subdistrict Ilaka (475) [45,000] Thana (496) Thana parishad [240,000] Division (258) Pradestya sabhawa [58,000] Subdistrict Bakhsh (680) [40,000] Subdistrict government Soum (342) [5,000] [1,000-1,500 HH] Locality VDC area (3,913) Village Development Council [5,500] Union (4,451) Union parishad [25,000] Village Ward Ward committee (100-200 HH) Village (64,000) [2,000]

Sri Lanka Province (9) [18.5 million] Provincial council [2 million] Iran [65 million] - 62 Mongolia (2.4 million) Fiji Province (27) Ostan [2.4 million] Provincial government Aimag (21) [900,000] [10,000 HH]

G.S.N. area (14,000) Village (20-30,000) [1,000] [50-300] [Gramodaya Mandalaya] Locality (1,400) Dehestan [17,000] Rural Islamic Councils (32,826) Villages+Settlements (70,000+) Rosta/abadi [350-400] Bag (1,681) [1,500; 100-250 HH] Neg nutgiinkhan [20-50 HH] Khot ail (encampment) [2-12 HH] Village N.A.

Province Provincial Council

District District Advisory Council/Divisional Tikina Council

Locality Commissioners/planning officers Turaka Ni Koro

Notes:

* Two provinces and two municipalities. Functioning levels are underlined. Number of units at each level is shown in parentheses, and population per level shown in brackets. Some previous institutions are shown in brackets and italics.

2. LOCAL COMMUNITIES AND INSTITUTIONS: REALIZING THEIR POTENTIAL FOR INTEGRATED RURAL DEVELOPMENT
Prof. Norman Uphoff1
Director Cornell International Institute for Food and Agriculture and Development (CIIFAD) Cornell University New York U.S.A.

INTRODUCTION This seminar is motivated by an appreciation of the many contributions that local communities and local institutions can make to more effective and broad-based rural development. However, this result is still usually more a potential than a reality. This seminar will consider concepts and principles and will assess and synthesize experience that can assist governments, NGOs, and communities themselves in pursuing integrated rural development more effectively, i.e., development that will be efficient, equitable, and sustainable. Such development should be undertaken with the efforts and, indeed, with the leadership, not just the cooperation, of communities and local institutions. There are various reasons why local communities and local institutions have not played larger and more effective roles in rural development. Some of these reasons are due to the communities and institutions themselves; but more are attributable to the situations in which communities and institutions find themselves. Internal conflicts, lack of education, experience and skill, a psychology of dependency and a correlated sense of inefficacy, domination by certain local groups having no real interest in social and economic change, these are all factors that have constrained local actions for rural development. At the same time, there has seldom been a policy environment that really favors and supports local action, given the urban bias that is common in most countries. The overcentralization of government has kept decisions and control over financial resources at the national or sometimes provincial level, not allowing these to reside at local levels. A psychology of paternalism, which assumes greater wisdom and virtue among the more educated classes, has precluded sharing or delegation of responsibility. Certain financial interests which benefit from extracting resources from communities through credit, market or other transactions impede and obstruct real rural empowerment. Sometimes, divisions along ethnic or other social fault-lines discourage decisionmakers from trusting communities to work cooperatively within a larger national framework, thereby exacerbating the feelings and tensions that fuel division. All these conditions can contribute to situations where the ideas, energies and talents of rural people, along with their

In the absence of Prof. Norman Uphoff, Dr. C. M. Wijayaratna presented this paper. - 63 -

material resources, do not get mobilized for economic and social advancement, both of communities and of the nation. This brief listing of various obstacles makes clear that this issue of engaging and strengthening local communities and institutions in integrated rural development is a very complex issue. There are problems within communities that need to be addressed as well as constraints at the national level. Moreover, each country situation is different from every other, given its present institutional arrangements; its history; its current economic, social and cultural situation; and its political leadership and alignments.2 This seminar will consider a range of country experiences with efforts to promote integrated rural development and the roles that local communities and institutions have or have not played. No experience has been wholly satisfactory, and all have some elements that are instructive for others learning. For systematic comparison and drawing conclusions, it is important to have a common conceptual framework for discussing differences and similarities. This paper summarizes the most systematic efforts to conceptualize and organize thinking on this subject. Some examples of country and case experience will be given, but the purpose is not to assess existing situations. Rather it is to provide the mental tools for making such assessments, speaking in general terms that can, with appropriate and usually minor changes, be applied to any country. The APO recognizes the value of local communities and institutions and therefore wishes to support systematic thinking and documentation on their roles as a contribution to greater productivity through integrated rural development. A COMPARATIVE SURVEY OF ASIAN EXPERIENCE Macro Analysis The authors own involvement in this subject began in 1972, almost 30 years ago, when as chairman of the Rural Development Committee at Cornell University, I headed a large research project, supported by USAID, to evaluate country experiences with rural development across Asia. Sixteen countries were selected to represent a wide range of experience and political and institutional arrangements, beginning with the Peoples Republic of China, the Republic of China (Taiwan), Japan, and the Republic of Korea in East Asia; then Indonesia, Malaysia, Philippines and Thailand in Southeast Asia; Bangladesh, India, Pakistan and Sri Lanka in South Asia; and Egypt, Israel, Turkey and Yugoslavia in the west (stretching the geographic definition of Asia a bit to have greater variety of cases). The fruits of rural development, agricultural, economic, social and human, were measured in physical terms to avoid the possible bias of currency valuations (and devaluations). This was a period in which the Physical Quality of Life Index (PQLI) had been developed (Morris, 1969) to free comparisons of monetary distortions and to get at the real things that matter to people. Accordingly, the team gathered data from UN, FAO and other sources on agricultural performance: grain yields per hectare from early 1950s to early 1970s, which reflected ability to meet basic (staple) needs; rates of increase in grain yield during this period, to assess
2

For those who are interested in some historical perspective on these latter factors, see Moores survey (1967) of the social, economic and political revolutions of England, France, the United States, Russia and China, and the not-made revolution in India. It offers interesting explanations for the differences among countries political evolution. - 64 -

relative gains as well as absolute performance; rates of increase during this period in per capita agricultural production, to have an encompassing measure of agricultural performance. In addition, rates of fertilizer application were examined as an indicator of modernization of agricultural techniques. On meeting human needs, the following were compared: life expectancy, rates of infant mortality (the data were too incomplete to compare also maternal mortality); per capita caloric intakes; rates of literacy for the adult population; and school enrollment for the school-age population. Moreover, the rates of population growth, which indicated how far countries were into the demographic transition which takes pressure off the natural resource base and fiscal resources of a country and; more complex variables such as income distribution as a measure of equality/inequality, and personal security, have been considered. However, as the intention was to make an evaluation based on non-monetary variables, the levels of per capita income were not considered, at least initially. As possible causal explanations, different factors (independent variables) in the realm of local institutions and organization that could account for differences in these productivity and welfare measures (dependent variables) were assessed. Analysis commenced by looking at autonomy of local institutions at their linkage to higher-level institutions and the roles they played in rural development, and at the extent of local participation in development activities. This latter factor proved to be too difficult to quantify reliably, so the team deferred further work on this very important factor until a later date (Cohen and Uphoff, 1980). Autonomy also turned out to be elusive since quantitatively it was hard to determine, except post facto (and tautologically), when autonomy was different from impotence. So the team focused on linkages and roles, which were very fruitful variables. After doing monograph-length case studies on all of the cases, published in Uphoff (1982-83), the interdisciplinary working group, plus the invited outside experts who participate in the analytical exercise, converted detailed qualitative descriptions into simple numerical scorings and rankings that could be analyzed quantitatively. Scores were assigned on a scale of 0-3 to the upward and downward linkages of communication and cooperation by looking at common levels of decision-making and action, starting from the village or community level and working up to the subdistrict and district and regional levels. The cases were distinguished in terms of the frequency of communication upward or downward and the likelihood that cooperation would be forthcoming. The range, on a scale of 100, was 13-32. Then the team looked at basic functions of rural development, assigning 100 points across them: 50 for provision of various agricultural development inputs (water, fertilizer, credit, technical information, and marketing up to 10 each); and up to 10 each for planning and goal setting, control over bureaucratic performance, making claims for more and better support, integration of services, and resource mobilization. These points were then allocated among institutions and decision-makers at different levels as analyzed above. Different channels for decision-making and action were considered: the local government system, cooperatives or farmers associations, private sector, and political parties. This gave the investigating team a way of objectifying in comparative quantified terms how large a role did local institutions of various kinds play in planning, implementing and evaluating rural development efforts. The range, on a scale of 100, was 6-57. When this analysis had been done, independently of any consideration of dependent variables (for which the team had not compiled data on yet), it turned out that the 16 cases fell into two fairly distinct sets, which were characterized as more organized and less organized, according to both criteria: China, Egypt, Israel, Japan, Rep. of Korea, Sri Lanka,
- 65 -

Taiwan, and Yugoslavia fell into the first category, and Bangladesh, India, Indonesia, Malaysia, Pakistan, Philippines, Thailand and Turkey.3 It turned out that there were very definite differences in mean scores/levels between the two groups, as seen from Table 1. The more organized country cases were far ahead of the less organized ones first in absolute agricultural performance, and in relative increases over a period of 20 or 25 years, and with regard to total agricultural production per capita. In the social domain, demographic and other measures likewise showed a clear advantage for the more organized cases. Table 1. Comparative Performance of Less Organized and More Organized Country Cases with regard to Rural Development Indicators Less More Organized Organized Average yield for cereals (kg/ha) 1970-72 1975-77 Increase in cereal yields (1952-56 = 100) 1970-72 1975-77 Per capita agricultural production (1952-56 = 100) 1970-72 1975-77 Life expectancy, 1972 (years) Infant mortality, 1974 (deaths/1,000) Population growth rate, 1970 (percent) Adult literacy, 1972 (percent of population over 15 years) Physical quality of life index, 1977 Source: Uphoff and Esman, 1974. 1,677 1,908 138 159 108 113 54 104 2.8 39 52 3,097 3,480 166 189 135 147 64 53 2.1 73 75

The relationship was so strong and consistent that the analysts suspected that they might have committed a serious methodological error by not considering the possible role of per capita income as a measure of economic productivity. Income differences were not calculated because the team was not going to use a monetary yardstick to measure rural development success as a dependent variable. But possibly greater wealth could explain the differences between more and less organized cases, as an independent variable, since the former countries were evidently richer than the latter. So, after completing the analysis of all the other variables the UN statistical yearbooks were examined to figure out what were the

The data and scoring are all explained in more detail in Uphoff and Esman (1974). For purposes of comparative analysis, we used data from Japanese experience before World War II, after which there was external intervention involved in Japanese institutional development. In fact, there was much continuity of patterns before the war (starting with the Meiji restoration) and afterwards (see Aqua, 1982). A contemporary analysis and grouping would show some changes in these sets, partly because the implications of this analysis have been taken seriously by governments, particularly in Southeast Asia. - 66 -

per capita income differences for each group, weighted in terms of countries population size.4 In 1970, the most recent year for which the team could get data for all cases, it was found that the more organized countries had an average per capita income of US$352, and the less organized countries were US$119, a three-fold difference (these averages five years later, for 1975, were US$740 and US$185, respectively.) It thus looked like the study was going to become inconclusive because the current income differences were so substantial. But when the team calculated the average incomes for 1953, the first year for which the analysts could get comparable statistics about 20 years earlier, it was revealed that there was essentially no difference in the per capita income levels for the two groups: US$74 and US$78, respectively, a non-significant differential (Uphoff and Esman, 1974 and 1983). In less than two decades these two sets of countries had diverged dramatically in many respects from a starting point that was practically the same when measured in economic terms. The team could not, and did not try to, claim that the strength of center-local linkages and the extent of local institutions involvement in rural development functions would explain this large differential. For one thing, correlation does not prove causation. But the independent variable was one that was relevant to the dependent variable measures, and the difference was so great that most persons who read the study, especially if they knew something about the functioning of the respective countries, concurred that the factor of local organization probably made a significant contribution to rural development, not just in one respect but in a well-rounded way. Micro Analysis Some years later, when Esman and the author did a subsequent, detailed study of a large number of specific local organizations in rural development, the team found again very substantial, systematic and statistical support for the proposition that local organization, and particular linkage variables, contributed to better rural development performance (Esman and Uphoff, 1982). The team could find fairly detailed documentation on 150 cases of rural local organizations around the world (49 countries from Latin America, Africa, Asia and the Middle East). They were selected in a kind of random walk through the literature, so there was no bias in case selection based on knowledge of whether the local organization in question was successful or not. Cases were read carefully and scored by graduate student evaluators on scales of 1-5, using quantitative data where available, and converting qualitative (descriptive) information into numerical form. Eight functions were evaluated (the same as used in the 1974 study), 14 structural variables, such as number of functions (single function to comprehensive), initiative for creation (from outside initiative to members own efforts), gender composition of membership (all female to all male), social composition (from great heterogeneity to relative homogeneity), and size (under 50 members to over 1,000); 17 environmental variables such as topography, infrastructure, income distribution, settlement patterns, literacy, community norms, and political support; then 12 performance assessments, the latter being the dependent variables or criteria of success. These were summarized into an overall performance score, also scaled 1-5. This was amenable to univariate and multivariate analysis, to both

Both sets had a very large country, China and India, relatively poor; and a small one, Israel and Malaysia, relatively rich. - 67 -

correlations and regressions, and even factor analysis. Additionally, six common problems and four sets of roles were also assessed in purely qualitative terms. This paper is not the place to report the results of extensive analysis. The team was pleased to find that the relationships emerging from micro (case) analysis were very consistent and congruent with those from the previous macro (country) analysis, supporting the earlier evidence and inferences. This paper will, however, report some of the findings. Results given in Table 2 illuminate the factor of linkage, defined in terms of two-way communication and cooperation, since this is important for thinking about the role of local communities and institutions in rural development. Table 2. Average Performance Scores of Rural Local Organizations (N = 150) with regard to Their Linkages, Both Vertical and Horizontal Average Performance Score* Vertical Linkage, i.e., within organization One tier (no vertical linkage) Two-tier organization Three-tier organization Federation (four tiers or more) Horizontal Linkage, i.e., between organizations No horizontal linkages Occasional/informal horizontal linkages Regular/formal horizontal linkages Vertical + Horizontal Linkages No vertical linkage Two-tier organization Three or more tiers Total Vertical Linkage + Size of Base Organization No vertical linkage Two-tier organization Three or more tiers 45 84 117 143 41 143 200 No Horizontal Linkages 36 34 75 (74) (18) (16) (N) (81) (33) (12) (24) (113) (28) (9) Horizontal Linkages 140 (5) 146 (14) 166 (18) 151 (37)

41 (108)

Membership in Base Organization Under 100 31 (35) 106 (15) 134 (12) Over 100 61 (18) 110 (10) 108 (15)

Total 75 (62) 87 (43) Source: Esman and Uphoff, 1982: 149-152. Note: * Overall performance was scored according to a local organizations contributions to economic gains, social benefits, equity effects, reduced social or gender discrimination, and participation (empowerment) at community level. Number of cases is under 150 in breakdowns where not all cases could be reliably scored on both variables.

- 68 -

It was quite evident, as seen from the previous country-level analysis, that local organizational structures which have two tiers or more, considering also the effectiveness and reliability of communication and cooperation between organizational levels, were more successful than those, which existed as simple, unattached organizations. Vertical linkage was thus a contributing factor to multidimensional success in rural development. Similarly, but even more strongly, horizontal linkage with organizations at the same level contributed to better rural local organizational performance. A combination of horizontal and vertical linkage added to this effect, as seen from the average performance scores by group. As also seen from Table 2, multi-tiered, vertically linked rural organizations performed better when their base organization was smaller, rather than larger. This confirmed one of the conclusions of our 1974 study, that multi-tiered organizations would be better than single-tier organizations because they could combine economies of (larger) scale with the benefits of greater solidarity. Another interesting aspect of linkage was the finding of a curvilinear relationship between local organizations linkage with the government and their performance. Having no linkage was not the best situation, and being extremely linked with government agencies or personnel was the worst. Best performance was seen where there was low linkage, meaning no interference and a high degree of local initiative and decision-making, or high but not extreme linkage (Table 3). This analysis indicates that the extreme closeness to or distance from the national government is not desirable; linkage is something to optimized rather than maximized in either direction. This is not a surprising conclusion, but it was interesting to see that there was quantifiable evidence on this point across many cases. Table 3. Average Performance Scores of Rural Local Organizations (N = 150) with regard to Their Linkages with Government Agencies No linkage (autonomy) 107 (19) Low linkage 162 (19) Moderate linkage 63 (28) High linkage 99 (43) Extreme linkage (control) 7 (41) Source: Esman and Uphoff, 1982: 153-155. Further evidence on this relationship came from looking at how (by whom) the local organizations were initiated, comparing performance scores across five categories (Table 4). It was found that where governments undertake to establish local organizations at their own initiative, unilaterally, in what is characterized as a top-down manner (about one-third of the cases analyzed), the performance was mediocre. Not surprisingly, when the initiative came from those persons who became the members or constituents of the organizations, success was many times greater.5

When performance was correlated with various environmental factors that have been suggested in the literature could account for better or poorer performance (e.g., physically favorable conditions, better resource endowments, greater literacy, higher income levels, or low partisanship), the only environmental variables that were statistically significant (at the 0.05 level) were community norms (0.20, in the expected direction of stronger participatory and egalitarian norms favoring local organization performance), and social stratification and (continued...) - 69 -

Table 4. Average Performance Scores of Rural Local Organizations (N = 150) with regard to Initiative for Creating the Organization Local residents themselves 153 (14) Local leaders 138 (26) Shared initiative (government/local) 50 (24) Government in conventional mode 16 (53) Catalysts (government or NGO) 114 (33) Source: Esman and Uphoff, 1982: 163-167. In fact, successful organizations could be established when government or nongovernmental actors approach communities in a non-imperative manner, seeking to foster bottom-up capacities. This was characterized as a catalytic approach. This means that organizational structures, purposes and procedures are not imposed from outside but rather are developed together with rural communities, so that their directions and leadership are thoroughly understood and supported. Again, this was not a surprising finding, but it was impressive to see such strong statistical support for what is generally known on the basis of general principles of psychology, particularly the motivation of ownership. This question of how local organizations can be fostered or strengthened through catalytic strategies is an important one, beyond the scope of this paper, but presumably it will be discussed during the seminar, with reference to particular country experiences. It has been addressed on the basis of analyzing 30 cases of successful rural development in Uphoff, et al. (1998: 53-56; see also Uphoff, 1986: 207-209, for a general discussion; and Uphoff, 1996, for a successful case study). Catalysts are different from change agents or extension personnel in that they are not promoting a particular change or new technology. Instead, they try to help communities build up their own capacities for identifying and solving problems, emphasizing autonomous action and self-reliance. The term catalyst, coming from chemistry, implies that the external persons are evoking a potential that already exists, rather than making local people do things that are externally conceived and promoted. In the process of discussion, some consensus usually emerges that integrates local understandings and interests and that also meshes with the objectives of outside agencies, provided that outsiders want for the communities what serves local interests and needs. DEFINING LOCAL COMMUNITIES This is enough empirical consideration of the proposition that community action and institutions can contribute significantly to integrated rural development. In order to evaluate

(...continued) heterogeneity (0.20 and 0.18, in the opposite direction, suggesting that organizations could succeed in spite of these characteristics of their social milieu). Such low correlations, even if they are statistically significant (because of the large sample), would explain only about 4 percent the observed variation in performance, a trivial amount. Most environmental explanations were correlated less than 0.10 with local organizational performance, indicating that what people make of their environment is more important than the environment itself (see Esman and Uphoff, 1985: 104-128). This is an encouraging finding that proposes there are more degrees of freedom than in the usual deterministic predictions made in social science. - 70 -

and promote local communities potential for supporting rural development, it is important to have some clear concept and analysis of what is meant by communities. There was in the 1950s and 1960s a strong worldwide effort made, i.e., in many countries, to promote what was called community development, but it lost support in the 1970s and became a largely discredited concept (Holdcroft, 1978). Many of the principles were and still are quite valid identification of felt-needs, encouragement of self-help, assumption of local responsibility but there were some important limitations in the approach, which should be kept in mind when trying to engage local communities now more actively in integrated rural development. i. What get identified as communities are not always natural social units, and thus they may lack the kind of identity and solidarity that the community development approach assumed. Very often, communities are administrative entities, i.e., convenient units created to serve bureaucratic or political purposes, in which case they are not the real locus of peoples interest and activity. ii. Communities are often not cohesive, harmonious social entities but are divided by religious, familial, clan or other separations, making for a considerable level of conflict. The community development approach too often assumed that the basis for local cooperation existed, when in fact, processes and capacities for conflict resolution and for collective action needed to be nurtured as a precondition for local effectiveness. iii. Further, it was not adequately appreciated that communities do not exist in isolation, as units functioning independently from other communities and various institutions. Programs that focused on the community tended to ignore the many linkages that are needed, with other communities and with institutions beyond the community. iv. When undertaken as a separate activity, community development too often lacked connections to technical expertise that could assist in solving problems with biophysical or economic origins, instead being undertaken only as a social process. Community organizers and technical personnel carried on their development activities without involvement in each others efforts. This shortcoming could be eliminated by truly integrated approaches to rural development, but unfortunately, such integration has been more the exception than the rule.6 The term community development has been superseded in many places by the more sophisticated term community-based development, referring not to development of, by and for the community as a natural, harmonious, separate social unit but rather to development efforts which have a strong basis in communities, but are not limited to them or defined by them. Rather the processes involve communities, often as the starting point, but they engage smaller groups that are not whole communities or that cross community

One of the first major efforts at community development was undertaken by Cornell University in the early 1950s in Peru, in the well-known Vicos experiment. There were many reasons why it failed after some initially encouraging responses from the community. One major reason was the failure of the anthropologists who conducted the program to deal with technical problems of potato production, especially with diseases, as potatoes were a necessary preoccupation of the local people (Lynch, 1982). - 71 -

boundaries and often knit together numbers of communities in joint activities. Communities are a base for development, but development efforts are not coterminous with communities. A more inclusive designation is local development, which is more encompassing and broad-gauged, but with the same objectives and similar philosophy. Our work at Cornell has suggested that what is local should be best understood in an analytical framework that covers the range of development decision-making and activities, from the individual to the international level. In Figure 1, three levels could be seen at which people can take decisions and act together in what is often referred to as collective action based on some perception of common interests and mutual benefit. 1. INTERNATIONAL LEVEL 2. NATIONAL LEVEL 3. REGIONAL/PROVINCIAL/STATE LEVEL 4. DISTRICT LEVEL 5. SUBDISTRICT LEVEL LOCAL LOCAL LOCAL 6. LOCALITY LEVEL Sets of communities having economic and social connections 7. COMMUNITY/VILLAGE LEVEL Persons/households having a common residence location 8. GROUP LEVEL Membership based on some common characteristic or interest 9. HOUSEHOLD LEVEL 10. INDIVIDUAL LEVEL Figure 1. Hierarchy of Levels of Decision-making and Action for Development Source: Uphoff, 1986: 11. The locality, community and group levels all qualify as local in that at these levels, people know or are able to know each other as individuals or relatives. There is some presumption that there will be cooperation among them for interests ranging from mutual protection and deterrence of attacks to solidarity and pooling of resources for joint advantage. Just a few persons are able to make decisions and to act effectively at the national or international levels. They are far from local. Also, the first level below the national one the region, province or state is remote from most people. Regions or provinces of large countries are commonly larger than small nations, in population if not in area. Indeed, in a country like India, some districts are larger than certain countries. So these higher (larger)

- 72 -

units are aggregations of citizens (voters, taxpayers) who have only tenuous bonds among themselves. They will have a common allegiance, but not common interests, experiences and friendships. Districts and subdistricts are similar in that they are basically administrative units, not aggregations of persons who know and care about each other. As suggested above, as one works down the analytical hierarchy shown in Figure 1, one comes to three levels of decision-making and action that are usefully regarded as local in the sense that people at these levels know each other, or have a chance to know each other. Accordingly, they are more likely to feel some shared stake and be willing to cooperate, and even to make some sacrifices for others because they perceive that they have some interests in common. I would define the term local, expressing the common sense of the word, as referring to relationships where people are willing and able to engage in collective action because they recognize and appreciate that some common interest exists. Above local levels, people can participate as citizens, but within local areas they have some bond of mutual identity and sense of membership. A. The locality level encompasses a set of villages or communities that identify with each other, based on certain economic and/or social relationships. People in a locality may come to one of the villages regularly for marketing their produce and buying goods, or there may be a rotating market that moves among the villages on fixed days. People in such communities know each other, worship together, may play sports together, are likely to intermarry, all the while maintaining their membership and identity in particular villages that are part of this larger locality.7 This level often has no legal or juridical status, but it is a social and historical reality. B. The community or village level is the one which is most familiar with, in part because it has a very visible manifestation: a set of dwellings, and associated residents, clustered together or at least designated by common agreement to belong to a particular village. Such communities are usually to some extent self-governing, with designated persons in roles of authority, formal or informal, to make decisions on behalf of the residents (members).8 C. The group level is generally below the community level, because most groups are subsets of persons within communities. But many groups are larger than single villages and have members who live in a number of different communities, so this level can also be above the community level. Concern with this level leads to a focus on aggregations of persons who are united by some particular trait, characteristic or interest, such as a common occupation, the same gender, a single religion, a love of sports, shared ethnicity, etc., rather than by living in close proximity.

This concept of locality has been systematically treated in Johnson (1970), and it is related to broader development theory in Owens and Shaw (1972). It derives from central place theory which is associated with Christaller (1966) and others contributing to the theory of regional planning. Communities are not necessarily happy or united places; there can be feuds and even fights, and even periods in which the social life of a community is moribund. But the fact of living in close proximity, and the advantages of having some cooperation and mutuality usually maintain at least some civility and often promote an effective level of shared activity. In fact, in communities traditionally there have been mechanisms for resolving or containing conflict. - 73 -

Below the group level, there is the household level, where a small number of people live together, related by marriage or by commensality (eating together), with some pooling of financial resources. Problems of decision-making and collective action within households are not as complex as with groups, communities and localities. The latter are larger and interests are more diverse than within households; also household authority roles are wellestablished. Households are very important in development planning and action, being relatively cohesive units for decision-making and action. Finally, there is the individual level, where individuals decide and act only for themselves. Individuals are not considered as local and neither the households are referred to in this way because these are everywhere. In contrast, there is a degree of uncertainty as to whether localities, communities and groups will act collectively and act effectively or whether they will leave all decisions and efforts to households and individuals or to higher levels of government. In all situations where development has been vigorous, there have been self-energized and self-managing groups, communities and/or localities that take initiative to identify needs and to find solutions to problems. Accordingly, capabilities for local-level development involve multiple levels of decision-making and action for advancing peoples productivity and well-being. Accordingly, capabilities for local-level development, which involve more than just one local level, are crucial for advancing peoples productivity and well-being. Thus it is appropriate for this seminar to focus on how local institutions operating at several levels can be strengthened to contribute to integrated rural development. ANALYZING LOCAL INSTITUTIONS It is similarly important to recognize that the local institutions, which can contribute to integrated rural development, operate across three sectors, not just one or two. This was one of the major findings of our 1974 study assessing rural development experience across Asia. The most successful organizational systems supporting rural development encompassed multiple sectors as well as multiple tiers group, community, locality, subdistrict, district, and on upwards. Most analysis identify and contrast two sectors public and private, with the latter being a residual, including all that is not public. This is, however, a rather crude breakdown, and one could be better informed and develop better strategies if one thinks in terms of three sectors, with significant sub-sectors at local levels. The public sector encompasses all institutions and organizations that are constituted by state authority and operate with that authority backing up their decisions. This authority can be delegated, and in federal systems, where certain authority has been passed on to provincial or lower-level bodies, they are acting as part of the public sector. The private sector includes institutions and organizations that are constituted by individuals (usually groups of individuals) acting outside of the realm of the state, seeking to achieve privately defined objectives. The most common objectives are economic, to produce and sell goods or services for the benefit of owners, investors, inventors and employees, but they can be social as well or instead. The third sector has no agreed designation. It has been called variously the participatory sector, the voluntary sector, the membership sector, the self-help sector, or the collective action sector (Uphoff, 1993). It differs from the public sector in that it does not act

- 74 -

with state authority, but rather with the social authority generated by agreement among members. It differs from the public sector in that middle sector organizations are accountable to members who have constituted them (this difference will be made clearer in Figure 2). This third sector is similar to the public sector in that it is operating for social purposes, not just individually defined interests, and it shares with the private sector a flexibility that the more bureaucratic public sector usually lacks. Thus this sector operates in the middle of a continuum between the public and private sectors, having some similarities with each at the same time it has some differences. These are fairly abstract distinctions. It will be helpful to identify a set (continuum, range) of categories of local institutions that are relevant for promotion of integrated rural development. These are shown in Figure 2 below. Public Sector Local Administration (LA) Local Government (LG) Middle Sector Member Organizations (MOs) Cooperatives (Coops) Private Sector Service Organizations (SOs) No-for-profit organizations/ institutions Clients, beneficiaries Private Businesses (PBs) Profitoriented

Bureaucratic Political institutions institutions

Local organizations; can become institutions

People relate to these institutions/organizations in different roles, i.e., as: Citizens, voters, taxpayers Citizens, voters, taxpayers Members, contributors Member Customers, employees, investors

Figure 2. Continuum of Local Institutions by Sector Source: Adapted from Uphoff, 1993. Local administration and local government are both part of the public sector, operating with the support of state authority, but the first is an extension of the central or provincial government, while the latter is expected to function as an agent of local populations, its decision-makers chosen by and accountable to them. Local administration is only indirectly and often rather remotely accountable to local populations, through national processes of decision-making and accountability. At the other end of the continuum, one finds businesses (corporations, companies, micro-enterprises) which operate on a for-profit basis and a great variety of not-for-profit organizations (NGOs, foundations, charitable institutions) which are parallel to businesses but have no profit motive directing their decisions. Rather, some other purpose has brought together the personnel and financial resources to operate. In the middle are multiplicities of organizations, which are constitute of members, serve their interests and are accountable to them. Businesses and charitable organizations operate according to the policies and purposes of their respective boards of directors and their chief executives. This distinction can be made quite concrete by suggesting how the provision

- 75 -

of health services at local levels is different across this continuum, particularly in terms of how persons being served can hold service providers accountable for their performance. * A Ministry of Health hospital would come under the category of local administration (LA), with patients getting whatever services are due to them as citizens of the nation. Any complaints would have to be made through their member of parliament, who would then deal with Ministry personnel at higher levels to try to get satisfaction. A local government (LG) hospital would operate under the local council, using tax revenues from local citizens, though possibly with some part of expenses paid by the national government. Patients would come to this hospital as constituents and local taxpayers. They could complain to their ward or town councilors about any problems and would be likely to find it easier to get satisfactory responses. A hospital could be run as a cooperative, with member-families having contributed funds (share capital) to establish it. They would elect a board of directors to oversee the operations of a medical staff who are their employees. The staff would be treating patients who are members of the cooperative and who thus own the health facility. Problems would be taken up at meetings where members set the agenda and make decisions by voting. A charitable hospital (SO) run by a religious order or a foundation would provide health services, usually charging a fee but not aiming to make a profit. It could give free service to the extent that private or public funds can be mobilized for this purpose, but if it cannot operate with a balanced budget, including contributions, it will cease to operate. If a patient does not like the services provided, he or she can go elsewhere, having no right of control over the services as in a cooperative hospital. A private hospital (PB) is established with private capital, though some public funds may have been received. It operates on a for-profit basis, trying to provide quality services that justify the fees that must be paid for them. As with a charitable hospital, any dissatisfied patient is free to go elsewhere.9

These categories are intended to simplify a usually complicated situation. There can be problems of terminology; for example, when an institution that is called local government in fact is really more accountable to higher levels of government than to its constituents and operates bureaucratically, in which case it is practically speaking local administration. There can also be hybrids, where an actual organization has characteristics that fit more than one category. Farmer companies are an emerging kind of local organization that is a membership organization or a cooperative but that operates essentially as a private business. Also, some cooperatives serve members of the public as well as their own members, in which case they function in much the same way as businesses. So one should appreciate that this is an analytical scheme, not a concrete classification. These categories were constructed to show differences and similarities that illuminate alternatives in institutional development. The key difference to be considered is the relationship that the form and structure of an institution/organization has with community

This assumes that the hospital, like all of the other kinds, is operating within existing laws. If any hospital is violating the law, it can be charged in court, taking the problem into the public sector for some resolution, though this can be more difficult if the hospital in question is a public sector institution. - 76 -

members: are they citizens, or constituents, or members, or beneficiaries, or customers? There are many ancillary roles as well: taxpayers, voters, office-bearers, clients, employees, investors, etc. Which roles can lead to the best support for communities and to the greatest contributions to rural development? This is a very important and pragmatic question. Depending on the circumstances, needs and opportunities, any one of these alternatives could be the most desirable, or the least. Distinguishing between Organizations and Institutions Thus far, the terms institutions and organizations have been used fairly interchangeably, making no consistent distinction between them. This is how they are generally used, as if the two words are equivalent, indeed practically identical. But if they were, there would be no need for two terms. The following discussion is based on concepts and differences that are rooted in the English language, and not exactly the same in other languages. However, the difference that is being focused on can be found in most other languages, so this is not a unique semantic concern. This does not represent as important a set of concepts and issues as presented above, but it is worth giving some thought to the overlap between these two terms, both of which are important for integrated rural development. The basic functions that any organizations must perform are common across all sectors and all levels. The following analysis was developed for improving irrigation management (Uphoff, 1986a), but it applies to development efforts across the board. Four tasks or activities essential for effective action, whether in the public sector, the private sector, or the middle sector: * * * * decision-making; resource mobilization and management; communication and coordination; and conflict resolution, whenever necessary.

These tasks (activities) are performed or undertaken mostly through sets of roles, which are backed up by a variety of rules, precedents and procedures, with ensuing networks of relationships that create capacity for cooperation and for mutually beneficial collective action. These are the elements of what is increasingly referred to as social capital,10 though here they will be considered more broadly with regard to organizational capacity. Such relationships, which affect peoples expectations of what others will or should do, as well as ones own expectations of ones own desirable or necessary actions, can be considered as structural in that they structure human interaction, through role, rules, precedents and procedures. These things are essential for all social organization in that they are needed to coordinate peoples behavior and make it more predictable. When decisionmaking and activity are purely to promote individual interests, there is no need for the third and fourth functions, and the first two are much simpler. But to accomplish any larger objectives, all four activities must occur (the fourth can be made unnecessary by activities that avert conflict or build solidarity so that conflict does not arise; but conflict must be addressed in some way, whether by resolution or by avoidance.)

10

See Uphoff (2000) presenting this analytical framework for understanding social capital, and also Krishna and Uphoff (2001) for an empirical application of this framework in the Indian state of Rajasthan. - 77 -

In addition, one should consider also cognitive and normative aspects of organizational capacity. These originate in ideas and values that relate to and influence peoples thinking, ideals, expectations and consequent behavior. The more that people have thoughts and norms which make them expect and want cooperative action, at local levels or beyond, the more effective will be the existing roles, rules, etc. that structure social interaction. This is itself a very large and complex subject, which would not be discussed here. It is worth noting, however, that the relationship between organizations and institutions manifests some of these issues. Organizations are, generally speaking, structures of recognized and accepted roles, whether formal or informal. They may or may not have institutional status, i.e., widespread respect, support, cooperation, etc. Things, which are considered to be institutions, on the other hand, can expect to receive respect, support, cooperation, etc. An organization like a local branch of a bank is not an institution, even if the parent bank of which it is a part, e.g., Citibank or the Bank of India, has become an institution. A bank branch functions as an organization, without any sense of permanence and without any broad social appreciation and support. It can disappear without anyone caring except those persons directly affected (employees, depositors), whereas the demise of a bank that enjoys institutional status has broad repercussions, social and psychological, not just financial. Institutions are a category that overlaps with organizations; some institutions, such as the Central Bank, are also organizations, while other institutions, like money, are not. Institutions can best be understood as complexes of norms and behaviors that persist over time by serving some socially valued purposes (Uphoff, 1986: 8-10 and 1994). These two definitions may seem fairly abstract, but they are constructed to be able to make some generalizations about organizations as distinguishable from institutions, recognizing that there is, in many cases, overlap, where institutions are also organizations, and vice versa, certain organizations qualify also as institutions. Examples that parallel the distinctions made above regarding money and banks would be: Institutions that are Not Organizations Higher education Land tenure Free enterprise Collective bargaining Marriage Institutions that are Also Organizations University of Delhi Government Land Registry Mitsubishi Corporation Trade Union Federation The Thai Royal Family Organizations that are Not Institutions A student club A surveying firm A new small business A union local Your family or mine

For the purpose of understanding how to achieve or ensure sustainable integrated development, one should recognize that organizations that have acquired a degree of institutional standing, i.e., have now institutional attributes, will have more capacity to get cooperation and achieve their goals because of the legitimacy and status that they have acquired in the minds of many if not all members of the public. The resources of legitimacy and status that they receive from the public are not material and are not tangible; but they have many concrete effects on the ability of actors in organizational or institutional roles to get objectives realized (Ilchman and Uphoff, 1998). Accordingly, it is important to understand how organizations and institutions differ in terms of their characteristics and dynamics. Institutions enjoy more of the soft resources that

- 78 -

are important for carrying out development programs than do organizations. These resources are difficult to denominate and they cannot be allocated, only accumulated and drawn on to get cooperation and compliance. But this is valuable when it comes to programs like agricultural extension, public health, feeder roads, reforestation, and rangeland management. Most planning and policy-making for development concerns the allocation of money. While financial resources are usually a necessary condition for development progress, they are almost never a sufficient condition. Moreover, preoccupation with funds often diverts attention from mobilizing and utilizing the full range of resources needed for effective management, no matter what the sector. Accordingly, when thinking about organizational capacities, at whatever level, for integrated rural development, one should consider all of the factors that can contribute to institutionalization of organizations (Uphoff, 1994) and give thought to cognitive and normative factors as well as structural and more material ones. REALIZING THE POTENTIAL As noted at the beginning, this paper will deal with factors and dynamics that have much potential, but this is seldom fully realized. One cannot be certain that by introducing a certain role or by enacting a detailed constitution that there will be supportive and productive responses. One of the most important insights in rural development theory of the past 20 years is the recognition that beneficial social changes are best promoted through a learning process approach rather than by designing and trying to implement blueprints for organization (Korten, 1980; and Uphoff, et al., 1998: 20-34). This can be seen from a collection of case studies of successful experiences with rural development around the world, written up by the innovators and protagonists who promoted these initiatives (Krishna, et al., 1997).11 Pump-priming Assistance It is important to recognize that external assistance can have no or negative effects, rather than the intended positive results. To use the language of game theory, the outcomes of assistance efforts can be positive-sum (net gains, with more gains than losses), zero-sum (no net gains, because losses equal gains), or negative-sum (a situation with net losses, because total losses are more than total gains). Oftentimes, the provision of outside resources can discourage or deter the contribution of local resources to development efforts, which has a negative-sum effect. When outside actors move in, local actors may conclude that their efforts are not needed or not wanted, or are inferior and thus not worth making. This has happened all too often in the history of development assistance, whether from international agencies and foreign governments to developing countries, or from a national government to its own regions, districts or

11

The cases from Asia include the Bangladesh Rural Advancement Committee (BRAC) and the Grameen Bank from Bangladesh, the Amul Dairy Cooperative model and Rajasthan Watershed Conservation in India, the Integrated Pest Management Program in Indonesia, the Orangi Pilot Project in Pakistan, the National Irrigation Administration program for participatory irrigation management in the Philippines, the SANASA Savings Movement and the Gal Oya Water Users Associations in Sri Lanka, and the Population and Development Association in Thailand. - 79 -

communities. Less serious, but still not good for development, is the zero-sum situation where outside resources simply displace and substitute for local efforts. For development to occur, there must be positive-sum dynamics, where net benefits result from investment, training and other activities. The metaphor that is most vivid in this regard is that of pump-priming, where one pours a little water into the top of a hand-pump, to moisten the materials in the valve and help create the vacuum and suction which will draw water from underground supplies. Often there may be ample supplies in the ground, but to get them lifted to the surface where they can be useful, some investment is needed, and the expectation is that a long-lasting flow can be established. This is a concept, which I have analyzed previously in terms of assisted self-reliance, a seemingly paradoxical idea but in fact fundamental for development (Uphoff, 1988; and Uphoff, et al., 1998: 34-43). Avoiding Both the Paternalist and Populist Extremes After receiving all the case studies on rural development experience in Asia discussed above, and after reading and analyzing them (Uphoff and Esman, 1974), one of the conclusions was that governments should avoid two counterpoised and extreme views if they were to support rural development effectively. The first was based on thinking of rural populations as not just poor in economic terms, but weak, uneducated and largely incapable of helping themselves. In such a situation, a paternalistic approach is justified, as the more educated classes need to take the initiative to plan, direct, control and evaluate development efforts, given the deficiencies of the rural population. This view, which was called the paternalist fallacy assumes that those with more education have sufficient wisdom and virtue to manage development, and the main responsibility of rural people is to accept and cooperate with government or other external instructions. Such a description is an obvious caricature, almost humorous in a democratic era when most of the public have indeed acquired at least basic education and expect that their ideas as well as their needs and rights will be respected. Yet this has been the mental foundation for top-down methods of planning and implementing development that have prevailed in most countries, even those with formal democratic structures and procedures. Going to the opposite extreme is not, however, the solution. The team identified a mirror-image way of thinking the populist fallacy which assumed that rural people have sufficient wisdom and virtue by themselves to achieve their own development if only the educated class, the bureaucrats, businessmen and politicians, not to mention consultants and advisors, would stand back and let the people do everything for themselves. This is a caricature as well, because as discussed above, here are many shortcomings and limitations which rural people face, some in their own capacities and others in the ways they are presently organized for decision-making and action. There can be lack of relevant knowledge and technical skills, but also internal conflict, limited financial resources, isolation, and other barriers to effective developmental activity. Thus a pure bottom-up approach can at most achieve isolated local successes, not a broad transformation of rural areas. Thus the team concluded that development would be best promoted through a combination of top-down and bottom-up initiatives, with a catalytic strategy where outside resources (and actors) were used to build up local capabilities for decision-making and action. Community needs and capacities are the focus of such efforts, rather than preconceived solutions from outside. The latter remind us of the young boy who was given a hammer as a birthday present and who soon discovered that every nail he saw needed to be pounded in

- 80 -

(more). He began using that hammer on every nail he came across. Too often in development, professionals from respective disciplines each have a hammer that they have acquired, a solution that they try to promote in all kinds of situations hybrid seeds, chemical fertilizers, rural credit, micro-enterprises, market centers, etc. It is very important that solutions be promoted that are indeed appropriate to the problems and needs people have, and indeed, that these problems and needs are the starting point for development efforts (if only because this approach mobilizes more local support, cooperation and resources). To have solutions looking for problems to solve, rather than identify and evaluate problems first, seeking and testing solutions in a through way, is wasteful of resources. But it is the predominant mode of development, with each government department or donor agency more oriented to providing solutions than to successful problem solving. In this day and age, it is no longer fashionable for there to be rampant paternalism. Yet one finds a subtle form of this in the solution-driven rather than problem-directed mode of development. An integrated rural development should always proceed in the latter manner, not going to the extreme of pure populism, but with peoples needs, knowledge and capabilities as the focal point and starting point for development efforts. This is the strategy, which was analyzed in Uphoff, et al. (1998). Building Capacity This analysis points toward the need to build capacities in rural areas as well as within national and international agencies to strengthen and support local decision-making and action. Capacity-building is a very popular term these days in donor circles, yet it is not clear that there is a solid understanding of what this means. Since the focus here is on the local levels, I would suggest that this term covers particularly the establishment and more important strengthening of local institutions as shown in Figure 2, recognizing that most more better viewed as organizations than institutions because they have not acquired, as a result of their accomplishment and of peoples resulting appreciation, the status and qualities of institutions. To strengthen organizations, one has to focus on, as suggested above: decision-making roles and processes, resource mobilization and management, communication and coordination, and conflict resolution. As these functions are effectively performed, organizations will build up acceptance, loyalty and commitment that enable them to function even more effectively, thereby further enhancing their institutional status (Uphoff, 1994). As suggested above also, this is best done by catalytic methods (Uphoff, 1996), where the initial focus is not on accomplishing a particular task decided from outside (introduction of hybrid varieties, better animal health, or forest replanting, for example), but on supporting local capacities for identifying and acting to solve critical needs of the group, community, locality or region. This makes clearer that outsiders expect to play facilitating more than operational roles, and that responsibility for implementation as well as maintenance rests with local levels, backed as necessary by district, regional or national institutions. This leads toward more self-reliant approaches. To emphasize the importance of local-level capacity-building is not to divorce this from substantive tasks (such as introducing hybrid varieties, improving animal health, etc.) Indeed, the productivity of institutional capacity, and hence its sustainability, hinges very much on the benefits it can produce through accomplishing certain tasks, so capacity should be thought of in terms of capacity for ..... rather than just capacity for its own sake.

- 81 -

For this process to be effective, higher-level institutions need to be oriented more toward facilitative and supportive roles than toward the usual directive and controlling ones. Some years ago, David Korten and I introduced the concept of bureaucratic reorientation (1981), discussing how outside agencies can prepare themselves and build their own capacities for working with communities and other local bodies in a more collaborative manner. This has been elaborated in Uphoff, et al. (1991: 170-197). Just as the best strategies will combine bottom-up and top-down approaches, so too is capacity-building to be done at multiple levels, even in international donor agencies, if there is to be successful development at the grassroots. When one talks about capacity-building, there is an implication that this is a prerequisite for effective development work, suggesting that this is to done first, so that communities, government agencies and NGOs can then proceed better with their work in the field. However, just as capacity-building is best pursued in conjunction with accomplishing specific tasks, it is something most appropriately undertaken as part of the development process, rather than as a precursor. In December 1997, the FAO sponsored a large consultation in Rome on decentralization for rural development, cosponsored with the World Bank, GTZ and other agencies. It was interesting to see that the working group on capacity building for decentralization in which I served as a resource person reached the clear conclusion that capacity-building was not a sequential matter but an integral one. Participants recalled how in an earlier era, the argument was used that colonized countries should be first prepared before being given responsibilities for self-government. It was said that these populations lacked the education, the experience, the cultural values, etc. for self-rule. While this had some logical appeal, the fact was that the quickest and best way to acquire capacities for democratic self-government was by accepting and exercising these responsibilities, learning by doing. There was a consensus that with regard to capacity-building for decentralization, the best approach was to proceed with this, making appropriate efforts and investments in training, education, cross-visits, etc. so that persons with responsibility for decentralized decision-making and implementation could learn from each other as efficiently as possible. This would involve sharing successes and failures, trying always to build up knowledge from both in a purposive learning process (Korten, 1980). Strengthening local as well as regional and national institutions for integrated rural development is a large subject, and one where there are no one-size-fits-all solutions. For this reason, exchanging experience, good and bad, is probably the most fundamental kind of support that can be given. This is the purpose for the organization of this APO seminar. REFERENCES Aqua, Ronald, 1982. Local Institutions and Rural Development in Japan, in N. Uphoff (ed.) Rural Development and Local Organization in Asia, Vol. II: East Asia, 328-393. Macmillan, New Delhi. Christaller, W., 1966. Central Places in Southern Germany, Prentice-Hall, London (originally published in German, 1933).

- 82 -

Cohen, John M., and Norman Uphoff, 1980. Participations Place in Rural Development: Seeking Clarity through Specificity, World Development, 8:3, 213-235. Esman, Milton J., and Norman Uphoff, 1982. Local Organizations: Intermediaries in Rural Development Cornell University Press, Ithaca, New York. Holdcroft, Lane E., 1978. The Rise and Fall of Community Development in Developing Countries: A Critical Analysis and an Annotated Bibliography, MSU Rural Development Paper No. 2, Department of Agricultural Economics, Michigan State University, East Lansing, MI. Ilchman, Warren F., and Norman T. Uphoff, 1998. The Political Economy of Change, Transaction Books, New Brunswick, NJ (first published in 1969 by the University of California Press). Johnson, E. A. G., 1970. The Organization of Space in Developing Countries, Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA. Korten, David C., 1980. Community Organization and Rural Development: A Learning Process Approach, Public Administration Review, 40:5, 480-511. Korten, David C. and Norman Uphoff, 1981. Bureaucratic Reorientation for Participatory Rural Development, NASPAA Working Paper No. 1, National Association of School of Public Affairs and Administration, Washington, D.C. Krishna, Anirudh, Norman Uphoff, and Milton J. Esman (es.), 1997. Reasons for Hope: Instructive Experiences in Rural Development, Kumarian Press, West Hartford, Conn. Krishna, Anirudh, and Norman Uphoff, 2001. Mapping and Measuring Social Capital: A Conceptual and Empirical Study of Collective Action for Conserving and Developing Watersheds in Rajasthan, India, in Christian Grootaert and Thierry van Bastelaar (eds.), Title of Social Capital Book, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK (forthcoming). Lynch, Barbara D., 1982. The Vicos Experiment: A Study of the Impacts of the Cornell-Peru Project in a Highland Community, AID Special Evaluation Study No. 7., U.S. Agency for International Development, Washington, D.C. Moore, Barrington, Jr., 1967. The Social Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy: Lord and Peasant in the Making of the Modern World, Beacon Press, Boston. Morris, Morris D., 1969. Measuring the Condition of the Worlds Poor: The Physical Quality of Life Index, Pergamon Press, for the Overseas Development Council, New York. Owens, Edgar, and Robert DeArcy Shaw, 1972. Development Reconsidered, D. C. Heath, Lexington, MA.

- 83 -

Uphoff, Norman, 1982-83. Rural Development and Local Organization in Asia, Vol. I: Introduction and South Asia; Vol. II: East Asia; and Vol. III: Southeast Asia and Conclusions, Macmillan, New Delhi. ----------, 1986. Local Institutional Development: An Analytical Sourcebook with Cases, Kumarian Press, West Hartford, CT. ----------, 1986a. Improving International Irrigation Management with Farmer Participation: Getting the Process Right, Westview Press, Boulder, CO. ----------, 1988. Assisted Self-reliance: Working With, rather than For, the Poor, in John P. Lewis (ed.) Strengthening the Poor: What Have We Learned?, 47-59, Transaction Books, for the Overseas Development Council, New Brunswick, NJ. ----------, 1993. Grassroots Organizations and NGOs in Rural Development: Opportunities with Shrinking States and Expanding Markets, World Development, 21:4, 607-622. ----------, 1994. Revisiting Institution Building: How Organizations Become Institutions, in N. Uphoff (ed.) Puzzles of Productivity in Public Organizations, 199-215, Institute of Contemporary Studies Press, San Francisco. ----------, 1996. Learning from Gal Oya: Possibilities for Participatory Development and Post-Newtonian Social Science, Intermediate Technology Publications, London. ----------. 2000. Understanding Social Capital: Learning from the Analysis and Experience of Participation, in Partha Dasgupta and Ismail Serageldin (eds.) Social Capital: A Multifaceted Perspective, 215-249, World Bank, Washington, D.C. Uphoff, Norman and Milton J. Esman, 1974. Local Organization for Rural Development: Analysis of Asian Experience, Rural Development Committee, Cornell University, Ithaca, New York (republished with all the country case studies and more current data in Uphoff, 1982-83). ----------, 1983. Comparative Analysis of Asian Experience with Local Organization and Rural Development, in N. Uphoff (ed.) Rural Development and Local Organization in Asia, Vol. III, 263-399, Macmillan, New Delhi. Uphoff, Norman, Milton J. Esman, and Anirudh Krishna, 1998. Reasons for Success: Learning from Instructive Experiences in Rural Development, Kumarian Press, West Hartford, CT and Vistaar Publications, New Delhi. Uphoff, Norman, with Priti Ramamurthy and Roy Steiner, 1991. Managing Irrigation: Analyzing and Improving the Performance of Bureaucracies, Sage Publications, New Delhi.

- 84 -

3.

WHAT MAKES EFFECTIVE OF LOCAL ORGANIZATIONS AND INSTITUTIONS IN NATURAL RESOURCE MANAGEMENT AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT
Dr. Robert J. Fisher

Consultant Leichhardt, NSW Australia

INTRODUCTION The importance of local organizations and institutions in rural development is widely recognized and has become a part of the development policy in many countries. Despite this, the actual integration of these institutions and organizations in development practice has often been ineffective. The author believes that there are two main reasons for this. In some cases the real commitment of governments and government agencies to serious recognition of and support of local organizations has been very limited. The second reason is that understanding of the sociological basis for effective organizations is relatively weak within government agencies. An underlying aim of the seminar on The Role of Communities and Institutions in Integrated Rural Development is to identify some principles that can be applied to support local organizations. Along with some of the other resource papers, this paper explicitly addresses that aim. However, it is based on a somewhat different approach and is meant to complement rather than duplicate the other papers (specifically those by Uphoff and Wijayaratna.) The other papers are explicitly focused on integrated rural development (IRD). While fitting broadly into that theme, this paper focuses particularly, but not exclusively, on local organizations and institutions in natural resource management, particularly in the management of common property resources. One of the reasons for this focus is that the author wants to suggest that multipurpose (or multifunctional) organizations, which are sometimes associated with integrated rural development, are often inappropriate for natural resource management, while they may be appropriate to other aspects of rural development or community development. DEFINITIONS AND CONCEPTS In this paper, the discussion of definitions will revolve around a number of distinctions. Uphoff (1986) distinguishes between organizations and institutions. He uses the term organization to refer to a structure of recognized and accepted roles. Institution refers to a set of shared norms and behaviors. According to Uphoff, some institutions are also organizations, but not all are. Some implications of this definition will be discussed later in this paper. It is useful to make another distinction, this time between indigenous and sponsored local organizations (Fisher, 1989). The basis of the distinction is that the

- 85 -

initiative for establishing indigenous (or endogenous) organizations comes from within a community whereas the initiative for setting up sponsored organizations comes from outside the community (usually from government). Within the sponsored category it is possible to make a further distinction. Some sponsored local organizations (such as some elected local governments) are set up by external initiative, but are locally controlled. Others are under external control by governments or government agencies. Discussions of community-based organizations often fail to distinguish between organizations in terms of who initiated them and, even more importantly, who controls them (who makes the decisions). This paper argues that these are essential factors underlying the effectiveness of local organizations. The final distinction is a distinction between indigenous and traditional organizations. Discussions of local organization and local resource management practices tend to use the terms interchangeably. The author prefers to avoid the word traditional in most cases, since it implies that something is old and is often assumed to mean that it is unchanging. The evidence makes it overwhelmingly clear that local organizations and institutions are quite dynamic and respond quickly to change. This is important, because local practices are often dismissed as irrelevant on the basis of assumptions that they are old and unchanging. CASE STUDIES OF INDIGENOUS FOREST MANAGEMENT SYSTEMS IN NEPAL As a basis for discussion of factors involved in effective local organizations, this paper will first present a brief discussion of indigenous forest management systems in Nepal, including two case studies. Nepal has become rather well known in the literature on participatory natural resource management for its community forestry program. Under this program use rights to government-owned forest are transferred to communities on a permanent basis subject to an agreement about the way the forest will be managed (including the arrangements for distributing forest products within the community). In the early days of community forestry the transfer of management responsibility was to local government units then called panchayats.1 Efforts were made to establish new panchayat-based community forestry committees to be responsible for community forests. It was assumed that there was something of a local institutional vacuum in terms of forest management and the new organizational arrangements were attempts to fill that vacuum. However, research in the late 1980s showed that there were many local forest management systems operating based on indigenous organizations and institutional arrangements (see, for example, Fisher, 1989, 1991a, 1991b, 1993, and 1994; Fisher, et al., 1990; and Messerschmidt, 1984, 1986, and 1987). These systems provided lessons for the later development of the community forestry program. Two examples of indigenous systems are discussed below (the case studies are presented in the present tense referring to the time of study late 1980s and early 1990s.) Case 1: Panday Ban2 Panday Ban is a patch of about 7 ha of forest on a slope below a road in Kabhre Palanchok district. The users of the forest consist of about 35 households living in two

The panchayat system collapsed in 1990 and Village Development Committees replaced panchayats. This case was reported in Nepal-Australia Forestry Project (NAFP) 1990 and the wording of this account is based closely on Fisher (1993). - 86 -

hamlets on the hillside below the forest. The forest is a mixed broadleaf forest, with good regeneration and is generally well protected. The technical practices involved in forest management are very simple and are presented in a number of rules about forest use: * * * Leaf litter can be collected at any time except during the monsoon; Dry fuel wood, rhododendron flowers, grass and small bushes can be collected at any time; and Cutting of green wood or green leaves is completely forbidden.

The rules are very conservative and quite modest changes (such as pruning and removal of selected trees) would enable increased harvest of forest products without damage to forest regeneration. In 1990, the social arrangements involved all members of the user group (the residents of the two hamlets) who watched the forest for infringements. Previously there was a system of rotating responsibility for watching the forest. All member households were listed on a piece of paper, which was placed inside a piece of bamboo. The bamboo was circulated to people in turn and, according, to the order in which the names appeared, a household member spent a day guarding the forest from transgressors. No committee was involved either in 1990 or in the past. Case 2: Mahankal Ban3 Mahankal Ban consists of about 14 ha of mixed broadleaf forest, located in Sindhu Palchok district to the east of the Kathmandu valley. There are some abandoned agricultural terraces inside the forest area. According to local accounts, protection was commenced in 1963 because the forest was in poor condition. Under protection the forest regenerated and was in a healthy condition by the late 1980s. A number of villages surround the forest, which is on a slope. Of these villages, the main (primary) users come from Archale village, which is located below the forest. People from two other villages have secondary rights, as do some people who live seasonally in goths (temporary shelters, usually associated with livestock grazing). The use rights are as follows (Fisher, et al., 1990: 44): i. Primary users are allowed to collect grass and dry wood from the ground (they are not allowed to cut green timber or even dry branches still attached to trees). They are able to collect the fruit of the Katus trees when it appears (every two years). This represents a considerable source of income. ii. Secondary users living in goths have the same rights as primary users during their period of residence. When living in their normal residences they are not allowed to collect firewood. iii. Other secondary users are also entitled to collect grass and Katus fruit, but are never allowed to collect firewood. iv. Grazing is free, but the number of livestock is small because fodder species are not readily available.

Mahankal Ban was first documented as part of a research project carried out under the joint auspices of the NAFP and the International Center for Integrated Mountain Development (ICIMOD). The account here is based largely on Fisher, et al., 1990 and Fisher, 1994. - 87 -

These use rights reflect strong emphasis on protection. The permitted uses minimize interference with shrub and tree growth, thus encouraging regeneration. Although the rules are quite clear in prohibiting harvesting of live wood, in fact some pruning of branches for fuel does occur (NAFP, 1990). It seems that the illicit pruning is tolerated as a source of fuel wood for poorer families. Interestingly, pruning is done very carefully so as not to unduly damage tree growth, suggesting that the ethic of sadupayog (wise use) is widely accepted, even when necessity forces people to cut wood for fuel. The social arrangements for forest management at Mahankal Ban have gone through a number of stages. In the first stage (from the beginning of the protection system in the early 1960s), there was no formal organizational structure: there were no forest watchers and there was no committee. Later a committee was established and at one time a forest watcher was employed with money collected from households in the user group. Later, the watcher was paid with money from the project. Although the committee ceased to function, the management system continued. It appears that formal organization really was not particularly important to the functioning of the system. Several prominent high caste men had been prime movers behind the establishment of the system and these men continued to be rather dominant. They were sometimes criticized by other villagers for preventing the imposition of less restrictive rules about forest use. The relatively high degree of adherence to the rules seems to have been the result of a combination of a relatively high degree of consensus about the need for forest protection, combined with a reluctance to upset embedded social relationships (Fisher, 1994). Tolerance of limited and necessary cheating no doubt contributed. Discussion Indigenous forest management systems in Nepal are highly varied in terms of organizational arrangements and institutional forms. These two case studies represent only a small portion of the variety, which exists. Within the context of this variation, it is possible to make some generalizations: * The indigenous systems were built around a group of people with mutually recognized (and unofficial) rights to use resources. These user groups amounted to a communities of interest with reference to a particular area of forest. The user groups were not based on formal political-administrative (panchayat) boundaries. In fact a major problem with the original practice of implementing community forestry through the panchayats was that they represented the wrong people for common property forest management because they ignored use rights. Giving forests to panchayats was regarded by some users as giving away our forests. Organizational aspects are highly variable and, in fact, sometimes no organizational features (in the sense of Uphoffs recognized structure of roles) exist at all. Interestingly, within the same local system, organizational features may be present at some times and not at others (Mahankal Ban). While organizational features seem to be very much optional, all effective indigenous systems have institutional features (sets of shared rules/norms, values and behaviors).

The relationship between organizational features and institutional features in indigenous Nepali forest management systems can be illustrated in terms of a house model (Fisher, 1993) (Figure 1). In this model, agreed rules, shared values and shared behaviors can

- 88 -

be seen as an institutional base (the walls of the house). This base must always be present(there must always be agreed rules and shared behaviors, or nothing will happen in terms of collective action). The roof of the house represents an organizational superstructure made up of roles such as committee member, chairperson, or forest watcher. This superstructure can be different in shape in different cases and may sometimes be missing.

Figure 1. A House Model of Indigenous Forest Management Systems in Nepal Source: Adopted from Fisher, 1993.

In indigenous systems the walls are essential. The roof cannot be built without the walls and is not always necessary. To take the analogy further, in the case of sponsored systems emphasis is often placed on building the roof, but not much effort is put into building the walls needed to support the roof. Indisputably, it is often true that Forest Departments setting up community level forest management arrangements concentrate on forming committees (usually according to standardized rules about membership and procedures) rather than spending time working with communities to build consensus about what (if anything) needs to be done and how it should be done. This does not only apply to Nepal, and it does not only apply to forest management. It is frequently true of many efforts by government agencies to establish community organizations. In the case of community forestry in Nepal before indigenous systems were studied, the absence of visible organizational features (the roof of the house) usually lead to forest officials failing to notice the less obvious, but more important, institutional base. The result was the incorrect assumption that there was a local institutional vacuum (Fisher, 1990). This tendency of government agencies to ignore (or not see) existing indigenous
- 89 -

arrangements and to concentrate on establishing new organizations is fairly common in government organization building activities. The tendency of government agencies to build new organizations is associated with another tendency the tendency to establish these along the lines of standard form or structure. This usually involves specified rules about executive positions, membership and constitutional rules of procedure. Standardization like this can lead to distorting effects: * * Requirements for representation by local officials (elected or appointed) may place power in the hands of people who previously had no interest in a resource and who were not part of the mutually recognized community of resource users. Existing arrangements for intra-community conflict resolution may be lost in new constitution al arrangements.

It is understandable that government agencies dealing with large numbers of communities would want to deal with somewhat similar organizations in order to simplify such things as record keeping, financial allocations and so on. Nevertheless, administrative convenience often occurs at the cost of effective organizations. We know that community members support indigenous organizations because these organizations meet some of their needs. The more the organization is designed externally and the more decisions are made externally, the more likely it is that felt-needs will not be met. One further point that can be made from the Nepal experience is that there are strong tendencies within local communities, which encourage people to follow rules established through locally managed and transparent processes. In rural communities, people live within complex patterns of reciprocal social relationships. There are kinship ties, marriage ties and patron-client relationships; some people depend on others to work for them, others are dependent on others to earn income. Such embedded social relationships make people interdependent, and thus provide incentives to cooperate with others. It is just this type of interdependence that many common property theorists forget when trying to understand the basis of common property management (Fisher, 1994). There is nothing about any of this that idealizes communities. Conflict and inequality are quite normal in communities. Sometimes these conflicts are so great that cooperation becomes impossible. But often, even in the context of hierarchical social relationships, cooperation occurs. Form Follows Function The key reason for the variation in organizational arrangements in natural resource management systems in Nepal (and indigenous local organizations of all kinds in Nepal and elsewhere) can be summed up in the phrase form follows function4 (which translates to structure depends on function). What this means is that people will set up organizational and institutional arrangements that they think will meet their objectives. In fact, arrangements, which do not work or involve too many transaction costs will either disappear or be modified.5 This is why people who

I dont know where this aphorism originated, but I thank Don Gilmour (personal communication) for his clear statements about its application. This is not to say that community-initiated systems always get it right. Obviously that is not true, but they often get closer to a working model than government-sponsored systems. - 90 -

want to manage a small patch of forest surrounded by a fairly coherent group of users (as in Panday Ban) do not need much in the way of formal roles. Everyone contributes just by keeping their eyes open for people breaking rules. Where the group of users is more diverse (and the resource is more difficult to observe) other arrangements such as paid watchers might be advisable (Mahankal Ban). If experience shows that most people follow the rules, this may become unnecessary. Where achieving objectives is more complex (such as in an irrigation management system several kilometers long and involving several otherwise largely unrelated villages), more complex organizational arrangements may be appropriate. From this point of view, a problem with the standardized organizational models associated with bureaucracies is that they impose one form to fit different functions, imposing unnecessary transaction costs in some cases and failing to meet situation specific needs in others. MULTIFUNCTIONALITY AND COMMON PROPERTY MANAGEMENT It is a premise of IRD that different types of development activities should be integrated rather than implemented by different sectoral departments. This has sometimes been extended to the idea that community organizations concerned with development ought to be multifunctional. At first sight this seems quite reasonable and this sort of idea is common. However, the authors experience and analysis suggest that multi-functionality is often inappropriate for natural resource management, particularly where common property resources are involved. In the case of common property management the main reason is that effective management must focus on the needs to recognize all mutually recognized users (those who have an interest in seeing the resource maintained and whose behavior will most directly affect the resource). In addition to involving all the users, effective common property organizations will generally exclude people who dont have a recognized interest in the resource. For a multifunctional organization to manage more than one common property resource, the recognized user group would need to coincide. This usually does not happen. For example, the users of irrigation systems in mountainous areas tend not to be the same as the users for forests in the same area. Irrigation systems follow a long line and the users are those along the line who take water from it and are responsible for managing it. In mountain areas irrigation canals tend to follow rivers and cross through a number of microwatersheds. Forests tend to be on ridges or valleys and the users tend to come from villages surrounding them. Only a small number of users for a particular forest would be users of a particular irrigation system and the users of the irrigation system would include users from a number of different forests. Many of the forest users would have no interest in managing the canal and canal users would have interests in only one or two forests. The transaction costs of a system big enough to cover all the forests and the canal would be very high. There are cases, however, where different conditions make a multifunctional system appropriate. For example, in Hawaii the traditional resource management system involved integrated management of whole watersheds. This was possible (perhaps even necessary)6

Contemporary Hawaiians claim that the decline of integrated watershed management in the colonial period has led to a serious environmental crisis, particularly in regard to water pollution and flooding. Efforts are being made to reinvigorate the ahupuas system. - 91 -

because of the specific physical shape of Hawaiian island landscapes. The islands in Hawaii are effectively the tops of tall mountains growing out of the sea. The tops of the mountains are tall and the slopes steep. Watersheds (ahupuaa) tend to be quite distinct. In traditional Polynesian society, each ahupuaa was occupied by a particular clan ruled by a chief. The resources of the watershed (including forests, grazing areas, farming land, irrigation systems and fishing areas inside the reef) were managed as a whole by the chief on behalf of the clan members. This was possible because the social and resource boundaries (for all resources) fell within a clearly defined and manageable territory. Multfunctional management was, therefore, possible. Again, organizational form (the hierarchical clan structure) follows function. VOLUNTARY NATURAL RESOURCE MANAGEMENT ORGANIZATIONS So far this paper has concentrated on organizational and institutional aspects of natural resource management, mainly related to resources held as common property. The discussion will now turn to another aspect of natural resource management, which has quite different organizational implications. It was argued earlier that effective organizations for the management of common property resources should represent all right holders and be accepted by them and that they should not represent people who are not right holders. There is another type of community-level natural resource management organization, which is voluntary. Voluntary associations for farmers interested in improving management of various on-farm activities (i.e., on private land) are quite common. An example would be voluntary interest groups for poultry raising. Such a group might have joint meetings with extensionists to learn improved techniques, or purchase equipment or medicines to be shared among members. Another example might be a dairy cooperative, which functions to provide improved market access. In these cases, non-membership of some farmers does not usually pose a problem for members, whereas non-cooperation in a common property system would. PARTICIPATION AND DECISION-MAKING Participation is very much an overused and misused term. It has many different meanings and distinctions between these meanings are rarely made clearly. Arnstein (1969) identified a number of different types of process, which have all been lumped together as participation. She presented these in the form of a ladder in which token types of participation were placed at the bottom and forms of participation involving genuine citizen power were placed at the top (Figure 2). The principle of ranking is essentially the extent to which participants have real powers over decision-making. This is a very useful model. It is proposed that the crucial reason why local people often fail to participate in sponsored local organizations is that they do not feel that these organizations meet their needs, because the real decision-making power is located outside the organization. In other words, organizational objectives are set by others (such as government, or government agencies). Perhaps one of the most important factors in effective local organizations (indigenous or sponsored) is whether participants have a genuine input in setting objectives and making decisions about matters that affect their lives.

- 92 -

8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1

Citizen control Delegated power Partnership Placation Consultation Informing Therapy Manipulation

) ) )

Degree of citizen power

) ) ) ) ) )

Degree of Tokenism

Non-participation

Figure 2. Arnsteins Ladder of Citizen Participation Source: Arnstein, 1969. GENERAL COMMUNITY DEVELOPMENT ORGANIZATIONS It is appropriate at this point to make a few remarks about general community organizations (those not concerned specifically with natural resource management). This paper has mainly focused on local organizations and institutions concerned with natural resource management, partly because it is important to draw attention to some special characteristics of organizations and institutions for natural resource management and partly because I wish to question the tendency of some development practitioners to put too much importance on multifunctional organizations. Much of what has been said above is relevant to local organizations concerned with development in fields besides natural resource management. The importance of developing a sound institutional base (agreed vision, rules, practices) applies to all effective organizations. Warnings against overemphasis on standardized structure also apply broadly, as do the comments made in the last section about decision-making as the key issue in participation. Many local organizations in rural development are of the voluntary or interest group type. Organizations supporting schools, health clinics or other resources, and micro-credit organizations are of this type. Such organizations are generally concerned with a single function. The other type of local organization is the type of organization that performs the function of integrating efforts. This is often the function of local government. Regarding multifunctional local organizations (the type that perform the integrating and coordinating functions), the following propositions are in order: * * * They need to have genuine decision-making authority (and not just be implementing decisions made from above). They need to represent a local constituency and be answerable downwards rather than upwards. They should not be responsible for everything, especially where other groups can perform particular tasks more effectively.

- 93 -

CONCLUSION Much of what has been said in this paper might be interpreted as a challenge to the way we go about Integrated Rural Development, although the broad idea of IRD is obviously sensible. A potential problem with IRD is that the emphasis on integration can easily turn into an emphasis on centralized planning, which works against effective local level decisionmaking and which has demonstrably not worked well in rural development or natural resource management in the past. This presents a real dilemma for governments and perhaps the only way out of the dilemma is for governments is to think in terms of setting up platforms in which various local organizations and stakeholders can negotiate solutions to local development and resource management issues. Rather than setting specific objectives for local level development and resource management, governments (supported by NGOs and other organizations) can play essential roles such as providing technical support, assisting with capacity development and providing mediation and facilitation between competing interests. I would like to conclude this paper by summarizing some of the key lessons, which could be considered in thinking about what makes effective local organizations and institutions. It would be unrealistic to think of these points as some sort of design principles, but there seem to e some useful insights to be considered. The lessons are: * * * * * * organizations and institutions for common property resource management need to involve all mutually recognized users. where effective local institutional and organizational arrangements exist, these should be recognized, supported and strengthened rather than replaced. establishing sponsored organizations on the basis of standard structures should be avoided. effective local organizations are often concerned with a single function. While interests may sometimes expand to involve other activities, it is not advisable to impose multiple functions. where new organizations are being established, processes for developing institutional arrangements (vision, agreed rules/norms and practices) are more important than organizational structure and should come first. effective local organizations need to have the capacity (and right) to make meaningful decisions about objectives and implementation rather than having these imposed from above (the capacity to make meaningful decisions does not preclude making these decisions in collaboration with others, but it does require meaningful negotiations, without predetermined outcomes, in such cases). where new organizations are being established, processes for developing institutional arrangements (vision, agreed rules/norms and practices) are more important than organizational structure and efforts at community organization should place priority on the dialogue and negotiations needed to establish these.7

This is not a simple matter of developing institutional substructure and organizational superstructure in two separate steps. Once the process of negotiation and dialogue has led to formation of organizational features, the process of dialogue and negotiation needs to be continued and institutional features (especially norms and rules) will further evolve as part of an iterative process. - 94 -

REFERENCES Arnstein, Sherry R., 1969. A Ladder of Citizen Participation, Journal of the American Institute of Planners, Vol. 35: 216-224. Fisher, R. J., 1989. Indigenous Systems of Common Property Forest Management in Nepal, Working Paper No. 18, Environment and Policy Institute, East-West Center, Honolulu. ----------, 1990. Institutional Incompatibility in Community Forestry: The Case of Nepal, in Jefferson Fox and R. J. Fisher (eds.) Community Organizations and Government Bureaucracies in Social Forestry, Working Paper No. 22, pp. 11-26, Environment and Policy Institute, East-West Center, Honolulu. ----------, 1991a. Studying Indigenous Forest Management Systems in Nepal: Toward a More Systematic Approach, Working Paper No. 30, Environment and Policy Institute, EastWest Center, Honolulu. ----------, 1991b. Local Organizations in Community Forestry, in Cor Veer and Jim Chamberlain (eds.) Local Organizations and Community Forestry Extension in Asia, Food and Agricultural Organizations of the United Nations, Bangkok. ----------, 1993. Creating Space: Development Agencies and Local Institutions in Natural Resource Management, Forests, Trees and People Newsletter, No. 22, pp. 4-11, FAO. ----------, 1994. Indigenous Forest Management in Nepal: Why Common Property is Not a Problem, in Michael Allen (ed.) Anthropology of Nepal: People, Problems and Processes, Mandala Book Point, Kathmandu. Fisher, R. J., Hukum Bahadur Singh, Deepak Raj Pandey and Helmut Lang, 1990. The Management of Forest Resources in Sindhu Palchok and Kabhre Palanchok Districts of Nepal, Mountain Populations and Employment Discussion Paper Series 8, ICIMOD, Kathmandu. Messerschmidt, Donald A., 1984. Using Human Resources in Natural Resource Management Innovations in Himalayan Development, Working Paper WSM I/1, ICIMOD, Kathmandu. ----------, 1986. People and Resources in Nepal: Customary Resource Management Systems in the Upper Kali Gandaki, in Panel on Common Property Resource Management, Common Property Resource Management, National Academy Press, Washington, D.C. ----------, 1987. Conservation and Society in Nepal: Traditional Forest Management and Innovative Development, in Peter D. Little and Michael M. Horowitz (eds.) with A. Endre Nyerges, Lands at Risk in the Third World: Local Level Perspectives, pp 373397, Westview, Boulder CO.

- 95 -

Nepal Australia Forestry Project, 1990. Gaunle Ko Ban Byavastha: Indigenous Forest Management in Nepal, film produced by Worldview International Foundation, Nepal for NAFP. Uphoff, Norman, 1986. Local Institutional Development: An Analytical Sourcebook with Cases, Kumarian Press, West Hartford, CT.

- 96 -

4. INSTITUTIONALIZATION OF PEOPLES SELF-ORGANIZING ACTIONS FOR RURAL DEVELOPMENT: COMPARATIVE ANALYSIS OF MICRO-FINANCE ORGANIZATIONS IN RURAL THAILAND, PHILIPPINES, AND INDONESIA
Dr. Shinichi Shigetomi
Researcher Institute of Developing Economies (IDE) Chiba Japan

INTRODUCTION This paper discusses how to install an endogenous and sustainable mechanism of peoples self-organizing actions into a local social system. A significant body of literature has already argued the importance of peoples organizations for rural development (Uphoff and Esman, 1974; and Oakley, et al., 1991). However, organizing rural people has not always been an easy task (Esman and Uphoff, 1984, p.35; Cernea, 1985, p.11; and Yogo, 2000, p.21). Many organizations malfunction and then dissolve within a short period. The respective governments and other development agents, then, have to focus their attention on the formed organizations, or resume creating new organizations. This is not to say that rural people have been unorganized. Rather, they formed traditional organizations, such as labor exchange groups and mutual financing associations, for their economic survival. Such traditional types of organizations, however, cannot cope with the changes brought on by economic development. Now, the scale of each villagers economic activity is growing, and economic transaction among farmers and traders happens more frequently. Competition for economic survival becomes more and more serious. Under these circumstances, people form new types of rural organizations in order to secure more resources than those secured through traditional organizations or individualistic methods, such as market transactions. People become more conscious about calculating the cost and benefit in their participation to the organization. Then they closely watch on the management of organizations. Now the managerial capability that benefits the organization, as well as the formalized management system that realizes fair resource distribution among the members, is indispensable (Luhmann, 1964). With this in mind, it is no easy task for the governmental and non-governmental development agencies to form and sustain rural organizations. We focus on the endogenous and sustainable system of peoples self-organizing because it reduces the administrative cost associated with starting organizations and creates more effective organizations. The endogenous mechanism is necessary because it induces

- 97 -

peoples spontaneous efforts to organize themselves.1 The sustainable mechanism here means not only that organizations have staying power but also there is a built in mechanism, for managing and adapting to the environmental change, even to the extent disbanding and starting from scratch. The endogenous and sustainable system for self-organizing implies that local people are able to mobilize resources both inside and outside their locality and combine them to meet their needs. Framework of Analysis When we talk about the importance of peoples organizations for rural development, we usually mean organizations that implement development projects. We call them development organizations in this paper. However, even before rural people are organized into development organizations, they have already been members of other types of local organizations. For example, they may belong to neighborhood organizations, consanguineous groups, and village communities. At the same time, they belong to a local administrative organization. These organizations are not narrow in scope, but rather serve as a social instrument for maintaining peace and order among local people, as well as facilitating the peoples efforts for making their organizations. Therefore, we call this type of organization as communal organizations here.2 Communal organizations are important for making development organizations because of the following reasons: * Communal organizations can be organizers of development organizations. The endogenous process of organizing does not start without an endogenous organizer. Even though an outsider initiates the project, there needs to be a group of people to contact for the initial organizing process. Communal organizations, if necessary, scrap and remodel development organizations. Communal organizations may have institutions that guide local peoples behaviors for collective action.3 Development organizations bring economic benefit for the members only after they successfully cooperate with each other. They must have, in advance, tools to control each others conducts. Such a social system may enhance the stability of development organizations.

In this way, when we intend to organize local people in rural development projects, it is indispensable to conceptually distinguish development organizations and communal organizations and understand the role of communal organizations.

This does not mean that there is no need of assistance from outside agencies. However, without endogenous mechanism, such assistance does not successfully mobilize rural people for organizations. This concept includes local administrative organizations as well as social organizations which Yogo (2000, pp.21-22) defines as those maintaining the social relations of people that are peculiar to the structural conditions of a local community and serve as mechanisms to accumulate and transfer their organizational experiences from one generation to another. In this paper, I use the term institution as the rules of the game in a society or, more formally, are the humanly devised constraints that shape human interaction (North, 1990, p.3). - 98 -

There are two types of communal organizations. One is endogenously formed organizations or groups, in other words, social organizations. The other is exogenously formed organizations, such as local administrative bodies. Both of them have institutions of guiding the members behaviors. While those of the former are informal and traditional, the latter has formal system backed by the states authority. It is not new to stress the importance of social background in making rural organizations. Most researchers, however, place more importance on the endogenous communal organizations. This is reasonable to some extent because development organizations formed by local administrative bodies have often failed to show good performance. However, the government cannot contact local people without local administrative bodies. The governmental effort for rural development should not be undervalued since it provides more resources for a wider area than other development agencies like NGOs.4 Based on the above conceptualization, this paper intends to discuss the following issues: * The features of communal organizations in each locality determine the adequate form and the feasible method for forming development organizations. This does not mean the communal organization is only the determinant factor. Rather, I will assert that this factor is important along with other factors like economic feasibility.5 The features of social organizations and local administrative bodies determine the uniqueness of communal organizations in each locality. This does not mean only the individual features of each organization but also the combination of the two organizations.

The following discussion will use micro-finance organizations (MFOs) as the example of development organizations. In order to contrast how communal organizations determine the form of development organizations, the paper will examine the cases of Thailand, the Philippines, and Indonesia. CONTRASTING MICRO-FINANCE ORGANIZATIONS IN THAILAND, THE PHILIPPINES, AND INDONESIA For the purposes of this paper, I will focus on MFOs that are formed by local people in order to secure loans for their economic well-being. Even though there are indigenous mutual financing organizations in many developing countries, our focus will be on MFOs that are formed in development projects promoted by governmental or non-governmental sectors. Observing the situation of rural areas in the three countries, Thailand, the Philippines, and Indonesia, we find clear contrasts in the form of popular MFOs in terms of the fund source and control system of members for securing loan repayment (Figure 1).

This does not mean that we can neglect NGOs programs. However, generally speaking, the NGOs projects cover very limited sites because of their resource limitation and intensive commitment to a project site. In another paper, I have discussed why economic feasibility itself does not explain the feasibility of organization? (Shigetomi, forthcoming). - 99 -

Major Institution for Controlling Members Behavior Law and/or States Authority Organization Bank Desa (Indonesia) Savings Group (Thailand) SHG (Indonesia) Bank Type Cooperative Type Grameen Group (Philippines) Peer Group Type Collective Consent Dyadic Social Relationship

Name of Each Type

Main Source of Funds

Internal Common Resource Type Pool and Distribution Type

Each Member Outside Agencies Name of Each Type

Receiver Type

Figure 1. Comparison of Micro-finance Organizations Source: Prepared by the author.

In Thailand, the dominant form of MFO is the savings group. This is an MFO that pools the members funds and makes loans to some of the members (pool-and-distribution type). This organization, which invariably has a considerable number of members, 80 on average, relies on the collective consent of members for controlling each others conducts (cooperative type). The leaders of the village community, especially in the case of the northeast region, organize and manage this organization. The role of outside agencies is limited to bringing ideas of organization and information about management methodology. In the Philippines, especially its Central and Southern Luzon areas, NGOs tend to apply Grameen Bank replicas for their rural finance program. In this form of MFO, the fund is provided by the outside development agencies (receiver type). Local people are asked to form small groups, generally around five members. This implies that every member has very close mutual relationships, which serves as social pressure for securing loan repayment to the fund provider (peer group type). Outside agents play crucial roles not only in providing loan but also in organizing people and supervising each group. In Indonesia, especially in Central and East Java, NGOs tend to promote self-help groups (SHG) with around 20-30 members, and provide funds for loans to the group (receiver type). Since its membership is larger than the Grameen group, it relies on collective consent beyond personal relationships to regulate the members behavior (cooperative type).6 NGOs do not believe that local administrative bodies can be the organizer of these types of

However, since the group size is much smaller than savings group in Thailand, SHG may be able to rely on dyadic relationship in order to control members behavior. - 100 -

MFOs. However, at the same time, the administrative village (desa) shows their capability by managing a bank called Bank Desa (BD) for many decades. The fund for loan is owned by the organization itself (internal common resource type). The villagers access the fund as customers rather than as organization members. Therefore, the organization relies on formal authority backed by regulations rather than on mutual consent for cooperation for controlling peoples behaviors (bank type). Why does such a contrast happen? The following discussion illustrates the structure of communal organizations that defines the uniqueness of each MFO. Thailand In rural Thailand, the savings group is the dominant form of MFO. The governmental agencies, as well as the NGOs, usually expect village leaders to organize villagers by themselves. It is not typical that outside agencies provide funds for this MFO; rather, they offer only ideas and some technical instructions on how to have better management. 1. Local Administrative System in Rural Areas The structure of the local administration in Thailand is illustrated in Figure 2. Province (Changwat) National Government District (Amphoe) Subdistrict (Tambon) Village (Muban) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) Government agencies

) ) ) ) )

Self-administrative

Figure 2. Local Administrative Hierarchy in Thailand (Rural) Source: Prepared by the author.

Administrative levels down to the district are part of the central government administration. Subdistricts (tambon) and administrative villages (muban) are under the administration of village representatives. On average, the size of a muban was 144 households or 746 persons in 1990, while a tambon had about 1,300 households or 6,700 residents (National Statistical Office [NSO], Thailand, 1991 and1992). As the basic unit of village autonomy under the local administrative system, a muban exhibits two major characteristics. One is that priority is given to demarcating mubans by the geographical conglomeration of their residents. Since introducing the muban as the local administrative unit in early 20th century, the government has designated spontaneously unified settlements of people into a muban as much as possible. The size of a muban is based
- 101 -

on the range over which people can maintain their acquaintanceship. Another major characteristic is that village headmen have traditionally been selected from villagers by the villagers themselves. Thus village headmen elections reflect the social relationships of the villagers themselves. Administrative villages in Thailand have thus been formed for the most part by taking into consideration the unity and social relationships of the village residents themselves. In contrast to mubans, tambons had little function of self-governance until 1994. One tambon consists of more than 1,000 households and 6,000 people on average, making it difficult for the residents to have face-to-face relationships over the village boundaries. Also, tambons did not have any regular budget for administration. Since there are mubans as official units of local administration under each tambon, the governmental projects are mostly implemented by the mubans. As a result, the tambon used to be just a pipeline through which the resources from the government went to each muban. However, since 1994, many tambons have been converted to Tambon Administrative Organizations (TAOs) that have their own budget, assembly and regular staffs. This reform was crucial because it has created a new communal structure for organizing local people in development projects. We will discuss the implication of this reform later. 2. Structure and Functions of Village Community7 The feature of an endogenous village community in Northeastern Thailand can be illustrated as follows. Nearly every village settlement, generally a clustered shape, has its own shrine of a guardian spirit for protecting the entire settlement from the evil spirits that were believed to inhabit the surrounding forest. In order to protect the entire village, the villagers must accept their common responsibility as residents and define who should enjoy the collective protection. Through such traditional beliefs and rituals, people have created a sense of we-feeling at this indigenous village level. Furthermore, the indigenous village becomes the unit for a number of collective activities. The most popular ones are those related to Buddhist temples in the village.8 In order to construct and maintain temple facilities and to have festivals, villagers organize themselves to gather and manage resources (materials, money and labor) at certain intervals. Villagers sometimes organize collective activities around utilizing common natural resources such as swamps as well. Through such common resource management, villagers have been expanding their capability to engage in collective actions. As mentioned already, the administrative village has generally been formed in indigenous village in Northeastern Thailand. This means that the villagers commonly have two institutions for organizing themselves: the administrative village and the indigenous village. As the members of an indigenous village, people have we-feeling and have accumulated the experiences of collective activities through temple affairs. On the other hand, they do have formal institutions for collective decision-making, such as village meetings and village development committee. Then, the villagers utilize the institution of administrative village even for organizing activities concerned to indigenous unit, such as temple activities. On the contrary, the administrative unit can mobilize the sense of unity at the indigenous unit.

7 8

This part is extensively based on Shigetomi, 1998a, Chapter 3. Ninety-five percent of Thailands population is Buddhist. The temples are a common sight in rural areas of the country. - 102 -

3. Micro-finance Organizations in Rural Thailand9 Historically speaking, the first MFO in Thailand was a credit cooperative promoted by the government in the early 20th century. It was a small organization with less than 20 members, which relied on the funds from the government (receiver type). It failed to show sustainability and efficiency, and thus was replaced by large-scale agricultural cooperatives that were semi-governmental institutions rather than peoples organizations. Later, the Bank of Agriculture and Agricultural Cooperatives (BAAC), a government bank for rural finance, started to provide loans directly to individual farmers. However, its loans were confined to agricultural purposes. Because of the complicated procedure of application, many farmers were, and are still today, reluctant to borrow such a small amount of money from BAAC. These limitations of BAAC have allowed informal sources such as moneylenders who require a high rate of interest to be active in the financial market of rural Thailand. 4. Formation of Savings Group The above-mentioned condition in the rural financial market provides the economic opportunity for creating savings groups (klum omsap). The idea of this MFO has been implemented in rural Thailand since the mid-1970s. In this organization, the members deposit their savings together on a regular basis, usually once a month. Members declares the amount of monthly savings they will contribute at their entry and are then obliged to keep this promise (compulsory savings). Then the gathered deposit is lent to the members. The loan rate is, in most cases, 2 percent per month. The profit is shared by the members according to the amount of savings. It requires guarantors instead of collateral, but the loan amount often exceeds the deposit amount of borrower and his/her guarantors. The members are limited to those living in the same locality, mostly in the same village, for the convenience of savings and availability of mutual control. The leaders of the savings group operate all the management. Regional distribution of savings groups under the supervision of Community Development Department is given in Table 1. Both the government and NGOs have promoted savings groups. The number of savings groups has been increasing steadily. According to Table 1, savings groups comprise 19 percent of the total number of administrative villages in 1996. It should be noted that this Table shows only groups established by the government, and does not take into account other savings groups established by individuals and NGOs. 5. Why are Savings Groups Dominant? Organizational characteristics of savings groups in rural Thailand can be summarized as follows: First, as members are mostly poor villagers, the amount of deposit given by each member is consequently very small. Therefore, it is necessary to have a considerable number of members in order to secure economic scale. The average membership of savings groups is more than 80, which is significantly larger than that of credit cooperatives. Secondly, the organizers are the village leaders. Even though the idea of savings groups is brought by outside agencies in most cases, this organization cannot be established without the villagers motivation and consensus formation. After the group is founded, the local leaders become the managers of the group. They take responsibility for every aspect of operation, such as receiving deposits, accounting, lending, collecting debt, and distributing profit. The outside agencies can assist, but just to provide advice for better management.

This section is based on Shigetomi, 1998b. - 103 -

Table 1. Number and Size of Savings Groups by Region in Thailand (only the group under the supervision of Community Development Department, March 1997) Number of Percentage to the Total Members per Group Region Groups Number of Villages* (persons) Lower North Central East West Lower Northeast Upper Northeast Upper North Upper South Lower South 824 1,035 665 542 3,136 2,747 940 673 615 15.9 16.6 15.5 11.9 21.6 25.1 16.1 17.4 15.8 69 78 70 115 63 80 108 119 165

Whole Kingdom 11,177 18.9 85 Source: Community Development Department, Thailand, 1997, pp.5-8. Note: * The collection date of this figure is not known, but seem to be around 1996-97. Thirdly, membership is usually limited to the residents of an administrative village (muban), especially in the northeastern region. As explained before, people have a sense of unity at the administrative village level because it usually coincides with the indigenous village. It is natural that the people accept the project as their villages project and start recruiting members from within the same village. Another aspect of the muban is its formal institution for collective decision-making. It is quite appropriate for the outside agencies, including NGOs, to regard the administrative village as the platform for organizing people. 6. Reformation of Communal Organization for Further Development Such a structure of communal organization, however, can be an obstacle to the development of savings groups. When a savings group tries to enlarge the sphere of members beyond the village boundary, it has to face the lack of social unity among members. This lack of cohesion may make the organization vulnerable. The issue of size and stability is a central dilemma of savings group (Shigetomi, 1998c). This limitation is rooted in the fact that the tambon was not a unit that worked as a communal organization for making development organizations. However, after the reformation of the tambons organizational structure in 1994, it now has the assembly of peoples representatives, staffs for professional administration, and a budget for supporting development. At the same time, the muban still keeps its function of mobilizing peoples collective actions. This new setting of local administrative system allows the new tambon organization to work as a body for making federations of savings groups at the village level. This new set of communal organizations may break the size-and-stability dilemma of development organizations in rural Thailand. The Philippines NGOs in the Philippines tend to apply a receiver and peer group type MFO for their micro-finance projects. They usually organize local people directly rather than persuade village leaders to do so. This phenomenon stands in clear contrast to the Thai case. 1. Barangay as an Administrative Village The barangay is the local administrative body that directly governs rural people in the Philippines (Figure 3).

- 104 -

President

Supreme Court

Province

Highly Urbanized City

Intermediate Apple Court Regional/Metro Trial Court Municipal Trial Circuit Court

Municipality

Component City

Barangay

Barangay

Barangay

Barangay Justice Committee

Figure 3. Local Administration Ladder of the Philippines (Barangay and Upper Units) Source: Prepared by the author with reference to Ocampo and Panganiban, 1987.

The barangay as a social unit existed even before the colonial period under Spain. Most of them were small kinship gatherings with 15-100 households in the Luzon inland area (Corpuz, 1997, pp.13-15; and Jocano, 1998, pp.155-156). During the colonial regime of Spain, people who sparsely populated rural area were gathered into a pueblo, the terminal unit of local administration with about 500 households of residents (Corpuz, 1997, p.25). A quarter of those residents was called the barrio and regarded as the town subdivision of the pueblo (Romani and Thomas, 1954, pp.2-3). Each barrio had a barrio lieutenant who was assigned by the provincial governor. Later, those who had been forced to live in a pueblo gradually moved away from the township and formed a kind of breakaway barangay. The priest of church in the pueblo did not neglect these people in the new settlements and started to visit them regularly. Later, a small chapel was built in the settlements (Corpuz, 1997, p.56). In this way, the barrio became an administrative unit in the rural area. Now, the pueblo is called municipality, while the barrio has been renamed barangay. This system was in effect for the post-independent period. However, the role of the barangay has been changing in the following three ways: firstly, the government has been increasing resources allocated to the barangay, since it is considered the body for implementing rural development policy (Po, 1980, pp.31-32).10 Secondly, the barangay receives more authorities to govern its residents. Each barangay has its council for making decisions on its own matters. The residents directly elected the councilmen and the village headman, or Barangay Captain. By Barrio Charter enacted in 1960, the barrio became a legal

10

During Marcoss regime, the government brought more resources to barangay than ever (Wurfel, 1988, p.130). Barangay received one-fourth of Special Highway Fund, while the national government provided 20 percent of National Internal Revenue Tax to local government. Barangay Development Fund was established too (Po, 1980, p.69). - 105 -

body and gained the authority to collect taxes by itself. President Marcos promoted the barangays authority and utilized it for his own political purposes. Thirdly, the procedure of administration has been highly formalized. Barangay council enacted the barangay ordinances to control or coordinate the residents conducts. Barangay justice was formed to exercise jurisdiction to some extent. The method for implementing such authority is also regulated by law. For example, the law specifies that the barangay ordinance should be discussed in three readings of the barangay council, and outlines what should be done in each reading. There are several thick manuals on the procedure of the barangay administration published for the village leaders (Ayson and Abletez, 1985; Flores and Abletez, 1995; and Ortiz, 1996). 2. Structure of Social Organizations The average population size of a barangay in Central Luzon and Southern Tagalog region was around 2,000 persons, or 320 households, in 1995 (National Statistical Coordination Board [NSCB], the Philippines, 1997). This is more than twice the size of a muban in Thailand. A barangay tends to keep its boundary regardless of population increase once it is established. From 1980 to 1996, the number of barangays increased only 5 percent (National Census and Statistical Office [NCSO], the Philippines, 1981, pp.31-32; and NSCB, 1997). Consequently, it is not rare to find thousands of households in a barangay in Central and Southern Luzon. In the large barangays, the social relationship among the residents has become loose. In contrast, Thai muban tends to be divided if its population becomes too large to maintain face-to-face relationships among the residents. In fact, the number of mubans increased around 22 percent from 1981 to 1996 (NSO, 1981 and 1996). Each barangay has chapels. People recognize them as belonging to the village. People also organize a fiesta, an annual festival for worshiping the patron saint of the village. However, the chapel does not have its priest living in the village, and villagers contribution to the chapel is largely limited to once a year, the time of fiesta.11 Even though there is a patron saint that is assumed to protect the entire village, there is no ritual that connects the existence of the patron saint to the fate of the entire village. The sense of protection by the patron saint is weak among villagers nowadays. The barangay has few communal resources. Its popular assets are barangay halls, healthcare centers, daycare centers, and basketball courts. These do not require many maintenance activities collectively organized by villagers. A sense of communal holding of these assets is weak, too. In this way, the sense of collectivity among the villagers of a barangay is weaker than that of a northeastern Thai village. This does not mean that a cooperative spirit is lacking in Filipino villagers, but that it appears in different manner. Valsan (1970, p.214) and Hayami and Kikuchi (2000, pp.168-169) find cooperative actions between dyadicly related people and within small groups. Abueva (1969, p.470) describes such Philippine communities as individualistic and unorganized and their primary attachments and loyalties are to their nuclear family, their kins and neighbors. Jocano (1988, pp.11, 93) writes outside of the family, the neighborhood is the only larger social unit which provides the venue for local affairs. Jocano analyzes further that neighborhood in the villagers sense does not necessarily mean a geographical sphere but rather closeness in terms of human relationship. With such close human relationships between two people, cooperative actions are smoothly organized in rural Philippines.

11

On the contrary, in case of Thai temple, monks live in the temple compound, which makes villagers mobilize their resources daily for the monks survival. - 106 -

3. Micro-finance Organizations in Rural Philippines The Government of the Philippines has always promoted some form of cooperative in the rural area. The first serious attempt was to create Farmers Cooperative Marketing Associations (FACOMA), large cooperatives that had an average of 582 members in 1957 (Rocamora and Panganiban, 1975, p.76). There was no mutual control working among the members and there were serious financial problems four-fifths of cooperatives were operating at a loss and two-thirds had arrears in 1959 (Po, 1980, p.61). The second attempt was establishing Samahang Nayon (SN) during Marcos regime. SN was formed at the barangay level with the membership no more than 200 persons. The funds were gathered from its members. These pool-and-distribution type MFOs, however, could not become self-reliant cooperatives in most cases (Po, 1980, pp.78, 84). The failure of these cooperatives does not mean that there was no economic need for micro-finance activities. Rather, moneylenders are still active in the rural Philippines (Agabin, 1998). After the liberalization of the financial market in the late 1980s, credit cooperatives and Grameen Bank replicas are popular forms of MFOs in rural Philippines. Grameen Bank is a micro-finance program that originated in Bangladesh in order to provide small loans to the local poor without requiring collateral or charging high-rate interest. People are instructed to create a five-member group that takes joint responsibility for the repayment of the loan provided by the outside fund source. The dominance of Grameen-type organizations in the Philippines stands in good contrast to the other two countries. Therefore, this paper will focus on this type of MFO.12 4. Micro-finance Organizations under NGOs Projects As for the situation of NGOs MFOs, the Philippine Coalition for Microfinance Standards (PCMS) has surveyed 223 organizations among all 300 NGOs running microfinance activities in 1997 (Dingcong and Joyas, 1998; and Agabin, 1998).13 The survey showed that most of the NGOs let people organize small groups of less than 10 members (Table 2). It is infeasible for such a small organization to rely on their own funds for lending activities. Among the 36 active NGOs surveyed in detail by PCMS, 18 NGOs used grouplending methods, and 13 of them applied a Grameen Bank-like system (Agabin, 1998, p.35). This data indicates that most of the peoples organizations supported by NGOs in the Philippines are receiver and peer group types, especially Grameen bank replicas. Table 2. Distribution of group Size of the Micro-finance Programs of the NGOs Size of the Group Number Rural-based Groups* 1- 9 10-24 25-49 Over 50 Total Source: Note: 38 24 15 3 23 19 12 3

80 57 Survey questionnaire for the inventory of the NGOs in savings and credit. The form is in Dingcong and Joyas, 1998. * Not less than half of activity area is rural.

12

Most of credit cooperatives in rural Philippines are very small (less than 50 membership) and receiver type organizations. I have discussed its characteristics in the other paper (Shigetomi, forthcoming). The author aggregated the figure from original answer sheets with cooperation of PCMS. - 107 -

13

Similar to the Grameen Bank in Bangladesh, those NGOs let local people form a group of around five members. The NGOs provide training to enhance norms of members before lending. Then, the NGOs provide loans to one of the members under the condition that the group takes responsibility of repayment. The borrower pays back the principle with its interest according to the weekly repayment plan. The NGO worker comes up every week to collect the repayment and closely monitor the performance of each group. The mutual control among small groups of people, together with the close supervision of an outside agency (NGO), is crucial for the success of this MFO. 5. Why is Grameen-type Dominant? The Grameen Bank model, the popular type of NGO-supporting MFO, was introduced into the Philippines after unsuccessful attempts by other types of MFOs. For example, CARD (Center for Agricultural and Rural Development), before it was one of the initiators of the Grameen-type system, formed an association of about 45 landless workers in each target barangay and provided loans to the association. However, CARD faced delinquency problems eight months after implementing the project, because the group size was too big for the leaders to control members conduct. Then, it applied a Grameen system. It is successful in the Philippines because, according to CARD, the group size is small enough for people to control each other.14 Such experiences have important implications. It suggests that a small group of five members can utilize social relationships to foster mutual control among members. In the Grameen system, local people choose their neighbors with whom they have close relationships as the members of the same group. As mentioned before, cooperative actions in Philippine rural society are possible along dyadic relationships rather than in a collectively organized group. Therefore, if the group size is as small as five or so, all the members may be interwoven by dyadic cordial relationships. In other words, NGOs understand how to utilize these close social relationships among rural people in order to create a successful MFO. When NGOs try to organize people, they tend to bypass the barangay. Initially, they send their workers to the barangay captain and ask him/her to call a meeting about their project. The NGO explains their project to the attendants and persuades people to form a group. When the NGO identifies those who intend to join the program, they investigate whether each applicant satisfies the conditions of program. After the training course, the NGO formally admits the membership and lets them submit applications for loans. The NGO provides loans only after the application is approved. In this process, the role of the barangay captain is simply to call a village meeting; thus, the NGO, not the barangay captain, is the organizer of local people.15
14 15

Interview at CARD and its project sites in September 2000. Bypassing the barangay administration is not only the strategy for the NGOs focusing on micro-finance activities, but also for rural development NGOs like PRRM (Philippine Rural Reconstruction Movement). Usually, the worker of PRRM stays in the target village and tries to get to know informal leadership and the resource allocation in the community. Then the worker assists people to identify the problems that should be tackled together. In this way, an issue-specified group is formed and it may change the target of activity according to the necessity of local people. This is the way that PRRM organizes local people and expands the village level activities except the case of an Ifugao ethnic groups village that has strong unity centered by their (continued...) - 108 -

The barangay cannot be utilized for organizing people for the following reasons: Firstly, since many barangays in central and southern Luzon area are big as 400 households or more, the social relationships among the villagers are becoming loose. Secondly, local people have not formed any sense of unity at the village level. The barangay as a local administrative body was historically formed by the rulers needs rather than local peoples necessity for self-governance. It lacks an endogenous institution that fosters a sense of unity at the village level. Indonesia Indonesian NGOs tend to promote small membership, around 20-30, for their microfinance projects. They do not expect local administrative bodies to be the organizer, but instead rely on social organizations as the platform of MFOs. However, the administrative village (desa) shows that it is capable of managing the village bank that is not seen in the other two countries. This contradictory phenomenon represents the uniqueness of the Indonesian case. 1. Desa and Village-level Local Administration16 The hierarchy of local administration in rural Indonesia is illustrated in Figure 4. The desa and the units under desa are local units administered by a representative of local people, while the other administrative bodies are the agencies of national and regional government. Since the candidates for desa chief are screened by local government before the election by the local people (Schiller, 1996, p.173), those who are unfavorable for the government cannot be the chiefs.17 The chief of dusun is nominated by the desa chief and designated by district chief. However, it is impossible to neglect local peoples view for appointing a dusun chief, since his/her duties are closely related to the daily life of local people. The chief of lower units under dusun, Rukun Tetangga (RT, neighborhood group) and Rukun Warga (RT, communal group; RW is a collection of several RTs), are decided through the consultation between the residents. Therefore, even though the desa is regarded as the local government in rural areas, the government maintains the system of intervention about the assignment of desa chief, who has strong authority about the assignment of leaders in the lower units for administration.

15

(...continued) leaders. PRRM is reluctant to rely on the barangay administration because the formal leaders may be changed in the next election of barangay captain in three years. The NGO also fears that its activity may be misunderstood as part of political activities of local leaders who often have connections with local and/or national politicians. The description here is based on the situation before the reformation of local administrative system beginning in 2001. Schiller (1996, p.174) surveyed 40 desas during 1979 and 1981, and found that 40 percent of candidates were disqualified. Even after seated as chief, if they were regarded as uncooperative to the government, the government dismissed some chiefs. - 109 -

16

17

National Government Province (Propinsi) Regency (Kapupaten) District (Kechamatan) Administrative Village (Desa) Dusan RW RT Figure 4. Structure of Local Administration in Rural Indonesia Source: Prepared by the author with references from Morita (1998) and Mizuno (1998).

The size of desa in Java is quite large. On average, in 1995, there were 1,100 households and 4,600 persons in a desa (Badan Pusat Statistik [BPS], Indonesia, 1995 and 1998). Desas with more than 2,000 households are not rare. Even a dusun generally has more than 200 households, and those with more than 400 households are not exceptional. It is often the case that a RW is identical to a dusun in size. At approximately 40 households, the RT is the smallest unit. The desa has institutions for decision-making (Lembaga Masyarakat Desa [LMD] = village community institution) and policy implementation (desa secretariat and Lembaga Ketahanan Masyarakat Desa [LKMD] = village community resilience institution). LMD is composed of dusun chiefs and the other leaders of social organizations in the locality. Since desa chiefs assigned both the members of LMD and LKMD during the Suharto regime, ordinary local people had little opportunity to express their opinion on the village administration. In the units under desa, there is no formal system of consultation and decision-making among the residents. If a chief feels compelled to consult the residents, he/she invites the villagers for an informal meeting. In some villages, however, there is a tradition at the dusun level to have an annual meeting called bancha-an, as well as a meeting every 35 days (selapanan). Each desa has its own budget. In the provinces of Java, it secures 70 percent of its total revenue from internal sources, which comes mostly from communal land and various kinds of fees (Kano, 1987). Besides land, desas have healthcare centers, a desa hall and the other resources. In this way, desa is not just an agent of central government but also an autonomous body with its own resources. The administrative units under the desa have no such autonomous budget or assets except a communal cemetery. Although officially the desa has no judicial authority, it is not uncommon for villagers to unofficially sanction those who violate the peace and order of the locality.

- 110 -

In the administrative units under the desa, some collective activities called gotong royong are organized among the residents. It is commonly practiced for night-watch rotation (ronda) and infrastructure maintenance by the chief of the dusun or RT. If there is a dispute related to the land, the desa chief will be the arbitrator. The dusun chief usually deals with other disputes. 2. Endogenous Social Organizations in Rural Java According to Kishi (1967), there used to be an indigenous unit of settlement, called desa in the colonial Java. This was a community that worshiped a village spirit and had communal lands. However, during late 19th century and early 20th century, the Dutch consolidated these desas into new and larger desas as administrative villages. A 1906 law transferred the communal properties of the indigenous villages transferred to the new administrative villages. Therefore, the present desa is not originated in indigenous community. Kano (1990) has compared the historical records of Central Java in 1846 with his field survey results of 1987, and found that the villages with less than 100 households in 1846 have become five times larger in 1987. Kano also shows that all of the land in two villages surveyed in a Central Java land title survey in 1860s was communal land (ibid, p.108). At the same time, the villages in earlier years had a shrine for worshiping the village ancestor, village festivals, and a sense of unity as a village (Jay, 1969, pp.292, 323; and Boomgaard, 1991, p.295). The leaders were from the kinsmen of early settlers who governed the village (Kano, 1990, p.99; and Boomgaard, 1991, p.291). Such communities with wefeeling, communal resources and a system for self-governance were integrated into an administrative village, the present desa. Kano assumes that the dusun used to be the indigenous desa, but it has not maintained the social unity as its population increased. Besides these organizations for local administration, there are many social organizations in rural Java, such as groups for literacy education, groups for reading the Koran, cemetery maintenance organizations, singers groups, dance clubs, sports groups, organizations related to mosques, zakat (donation) organizations, and savings groups (Mizuno, 1998; and Shimagami, 2001). Nearly every village has arisans (a kind of rotating savings and credit associations [ROSCAS]). People in rural Java put much emphasis on the social aspect of arisan.18 Simpan-pinjam, another type of traditional micro-finance activity also has social function since its deposits are spent for celebrating Lebaran, the end of Ramadan (Soemardjan, 1963, p.21; and Kawagoe, et al., 1992). 3. Micro-finance Organizations in Rural Indonesia The government of Indonesia established many cooperatives under the Cooperative Act of 1958. However, in 1967, three-fourths of them were dissolved under Suhartos New Order and village unit cooperative (Koperasi Unit Desa [KUD]) was newly introduced. KUD, in spite of its name, does not stand at the desa level, but at the kechamatan (district) (Thorbecke and van der Pluijm, 1993, p.266). Therefore, this cooperative does not rely on any communal organizations from the beginning. KUD took a strategic role in the Bimas program for promoting the green revolution (Kern, 1986, 110; and Soemardjan and Breazeale, 1993, p.118), but the rate of arrears was around 50 percent in 1983. Currently, people in rural Indonesia cannot access soft loans if they do not have collateral, generally land ownership (Patten and Rosengard, 1991, pp.68-70; and Mizuno,

18

The stake in each rotation is equal for every participant. It means that the first person who gets the collected money will benefit at most (Mizuno, 1999: 212-213). Therefore, the participants have a little fun deciding who takes the money each time (Bouman and Moll, 1992: 215). - 111 -

1999, p.201). As Mizuno argues in detail, most of the land in rural Java is left without a land title (Mizuno, 1997).19 Informal moneylenders do not require collateral, but charge a high rate of interest, sometimes 25 percent a month. This may be one reason that people have formed traditional mutual loan and savings groups such as arisan and simpan-pinjam. However, as mentioned already, these organizations do not seek continuous fund accumulation. In case of arisan, the members cannot calculate when he or she will get the loan, because they decide a loan receiver by drawing lots. Consequently, there is still an economic opportunity for MFOs that support economic development of local people. 4. Small Group Formation by NGOs NGOs in Indonesia place importance on forming small groups of local people as MFOs. One group has around 20-30 members, which, in most cases, is larger than the Grameen-type groups in the Philippines and smaller than the savings group in Thailand. For example, Bina Swadaya, one of the largest rural development NGOs in Indonesia, has been encouraging local people to form SHGs for micro-finance since 1988 (Seibel and Parhusip, 1992, p.244). In this project, Bina Swadaya borrows money from commercial banks and relends it to SHGs. According to Bina Swadaya, there are many social organizations, including arisan and simpan-pinjam, indigenously formed by local people. Bina Swadaya assesses these social groups and then short-lists them as the beneficiaries of its loan program. Bina Swadaya tends to choose the groups with membership of 15-25 people. Since most arisans have 10-30 members (Geertz, 1962,p.245; and Kawagoe, et al., 1992, p.227), Bina Swadaya seems to follow the size that people indigenously regard as adequate. Bina Desa, another active rural development NGO, also encouraged villagers to form SHGs of 20-25 members and provided some funds to the group for financing activities. Bina Desa contacted informal leaders of localities, not the desa administration, to organize local people. These leaders talked about the economic problems of villagers on the occasion of Majelis taklim (a meeting for religious activities of Islam) and persuaded villagers to form a group for economic activity. 5. Desa Bank Even though NGOs bypass the desa for organizing local people, many desas in Central and East Java have been managing a bank-type MFO called Bank Desa for a long time (Kern, 1986, p.120). It was established in 1908 with initial capital from lumbung desa (desas rice bank)20 or BRI (Bank Rakyat Indonesia), a government bank focusing on rural finance. Today, most of the BDs are under the supervision of BRI. Generally, a new BD receives its initial funds from BRI. BDs are concentrated in East and Central Java. According to the database of BPS (Central Board of Statistics), BDs exists in more than 20 percent of total desas in Central and East Java (Table 3). Some lumbung desas now function as BDs too.

19

In case of Mizunos village survey in West Java, only 14 percent of households had a land title in 1986 (Mizuno, 1999, p.208). This means that many rural populations are excluded from the formal loan market. Lumbung desa was originally a traditional institution formed by local people. In 1898, Ph.D. De Wolff van Westerrode, Assistant Resident in Purwokerto, Central Java set up it as a formal institution (Suharto, 1991, p.4). Initial capital was villagers paddy. At the beginning, the paddy is lent out to those who provided the initial paddy. Later, every villager came to be allowed to borrow it. Repayment was done by paddy. - 112 -

20

Table 3. Number of Desa with Bank Desa and Lumbung Desa in Java, 1996 Region West Java Central Java Yogyakarta Desa with BD or Lumbung Desa Number 631 2,354 119.2 As percent of all desa 8.8 27.6 27.2 Desa with BD Number 471 1,771 100 As percent of all desa 6.6 20.8 22.8 Desa with Lumbung Desa Number 179 829 31 As percent of all desa 2.5 9.7 7.1 Source: BPS Statistics Indonesia, Survey on Village Potency, 1996.

East Java 2,379 28.2 1,779 21.1 885 10.5

Up to the present, the desa has been the unit of BD. The desa chief is the first commissioner and he/she assigns two other commissioners from the villagers. BD has a professional accountant called JTU (juru tata usaha). The salary of commissions and JTU are calculated from the loan outstanding of BD and paid from the profit of BD. BRIs local branch recruits JTU.21 Loan disbursement and collection of BD are carried out as follows: Once a week, BD opens its office. The JTU visits the desa and works for loan disbursement and debt collection with the commissioners. The interest rate was 3-4 percent per month with a repayment period of 3-4 months. There is no need for customers to prepare collateral or guarantors. Every villager of the desa can be the applicant of the loan at the BD. The commissioners know the customers well, so that the procedure for lending is very simple, which attracts local people. Therefore, this is a bank type organization and local people are customers rather than the members of organization even though the beneficiaries are limited to the residents of that village. According to BRIs statistics, more than 60 percent of the loan is repaid without delay. If including the amount of still possible to repay, more than 70 percent is expected to be collected. It is considerably higher than the repayment rate of KUD loans in the Bimas program. 6. Communal Organizations behind the Two Contrastive MFOs Why is the BD successful? As previously mentioned, BD can collect more than 70 percent of the loan. This is possible because the commissioners, especially the desa chief, have motivation and authority to secure repayment. Since the fund of BD is a common property of desa, its chief has more incentive to collect the money compared with the money from the outside. Moreover, 20 percent of BDs profit is sent to desas general budget. At the same time, the desa chief has authority backed by the state. The JTU also plays a crucial role for the sustainability of BD. JTUs have high educational background and receive training for professional accounting skills at BRI. JTU is not hired by desa, which makes its position independent from the desa chief. This prevents collusion between a JTU and the desa chief related to accounting. On the contrary, SHGs rely on social organizations, including arisan and simpanpinjam. They are organizations with collective consent and clear membership, and mostly

21

But the authority of assignment and dismissal is given to bupati, the regency chief. - 113 -

consist of 20-30 members. Moreover, there are many informal leaders in rural Java, such as religious leaders of Islam. The richness of social organizations in rural Java is illustrated by the fact that Bina Swadaya had to shortlist indigenous groups to form SHG. However, the desa administration fails to mobilize such capability of local people. Rather, its capability is shown in managing a bank-type organization and controlling its villagers conduct as the customers. Its subunits like dusun and RT also lack institutions to facilitate peoples self-organizing actions. That is why NGOs do not intend to utilize formal local administrative systems, but informal social organizations. It seems that there is a mismatch between endogenous and exogenous systems for organizing local people in rural Java. CONCLUSION In this paper, we have analyzed the social system that determines the form of peoples organizations and self-organizing actions by focusing on MFOs as an example. In Thailand, especially in its Northeast region, the administrative village (muban) and indigenous village community identically overlap to form the communal organization. Creating a sustainable organization with a considerable number of participants within the village boundary seems not so difficult for the village leaders. A pool-and-distribution and cooperative type is, therefore, adopted as an adequate form of MFO by development agencies. In the rural Philippines, communal organizations are composed of dyadicly-woven social organizations and administrative village (barangay) without any communal background. It is reasonable for NGOs to apply the Grameen Bank, the strategy to limit membership in each group as small as around five and to bypass the administrative village for organizing people. In Indonesia, especially in Central and Eat Java, we see a kind of mismatch between social organizations and local administrative bodies. The desa system has institutions to control villagers but not to facilitate villagers self-organizing actions. Coexistence of a bank managed by a desa and small-scale groups directly organized by NGOs reflect such a situation of communal organizations in this area. Policy Implications for Making Rural Organizations This summarized empirical study has the following policy implications for installing an endogenous and sustainable system of peoples self-organizing. Firstly, we should focus on the structure of communal organization in each locality to distinguish adequate forms of development organizations and adequate methods of organizing people. Even if the savings group is successfully operated in Thailand, this organization should not be introduced into an area like the rural Philippines that has no locality-based community. Additionally, Grameen type organizations are not the efficient model in areas like Java and Northeast Thailand where the larger size of collectively bound group is easily formed. As for the method of organizing, the administrative village plays a key role in Northeast Thailand, while informal social groups and social relationships should be focused as the initiator of organizing in the other two areas. There is a suitable form of MFO according to the structure of communal organization in each locality. Next, we have to develop a methodology to distinguish the characteristics of communal organizations in project sites. We assumed that each locality has a set of social organizations

- 114 -

and local administrative organizations as communal organizations. Therefore, it is indispensable to know what kind of functions each organization has and how they are combined with each other. The following three factors are required for communal organizations that may work as a facilitator of creating development organizations. * First is a sense of unity among local people. In other words, we have to know in which sphere or group of people with whom they feel most comfortable to get together. Axelrod (1984, pp.146-148) has also proved, by using game theory, that if a certain group of people shares a sense of affiliation, they develop cooperation. The second factor is the institution of collective decision-making, or the institution for manifesting each ones needs and coordinate them as a common target. Without such institutions, the organizational process may not proceed smoothly. The third element is the institution of enforcement (North, 1990, p.57). People cannot feel sure about the rewards of organization, unless there is a system for policing deviations of members. We should identify which locality unit can be the organizer equipped with these functions for making development organizations.

* *

Lastly, if we can find no adequate communal organization, we should consider the reformation of the local administrative system. For example, the reformation of subdistrict level administration (tambon) in Thailand has provided wider opportunities to change tambon to a communal organization for expanding savings groups beyond the boundary of muban without sacrificing its stability. The mismatch of formal and informal local organizations in rural Java suggests a need for reformation of the local administrative system. At any rate, the designers of local administrative system should take account whether the design installs a mechanism of facilitating endogenous and sustainable efforts of local residents for development. REFERENCES Abueva, Jose V., 1969. Local Government, Community Development, and Political Stability, in J. V. Abueva and Raul P. de Guzman (eds.) Foundations and Dynamics of Filipino Government and Politics, pp.468-475, Bookmark, Manila. Agabin, Melza H., 1998. Philippine Microfinance NGOs: At the Crossroads?, Developing Standards for Microfinance Project, Makati. Axelrod, Robert, 1984. The Evolution of Cooperation, Basic Books, New York. Ayson, F., J. Abletez, 1985. Barangay: Its Operation and Organization, National Book Store, Navotas. Badan Pusat Statistik (BPS), 1995. Statistical Year Book of Indonesia 1995, Jakarta. ----------, 1998. Statistical Year Book of Indonesia 1998, Jakarta.

- 115 -

Boomgaard, Peter, 1991. The Javanese Village as a Cheshire Cat: The Java Debate Against a European and Latin America Background, The Journal of Peasant Studies, 18(2): 288-304. Bouman, F. J. A. and H. A. J. Moll, 1992. Informal Finance in Indonesia, in Dale W. Adams and Delbert A. Fitchett (eds.) Informal Finance in Low-income Countries, pp.209-223, Westview Press, Boulder, San Francisco, Oxford. Cernea, M. Michael, 1985. Sociological Knowledge for Development Projects. Cernea, M. Michael (ed.), 1991. Putting People First: Sociological Variables in Rural Development, pp.3-21, Oxford University Press, New York. Corpuz, O. D., 1997. An Economic History of the Philippines, University of the Philippines, Quezon City. Dingcong, Claremce G. and Lalaine M. Joyas, 1998. Profile of Philippine Microfinance NGOs: A Nationwide Survey, Coalition for Microfinance Standard, Makati. Esman, Milton J. and Norman T. Uphoff, 1984. Local Organizations: Intermediaries in Rural Development, Cornell University Press, Ithaca. Flores, Casino O. and Jose P. Abletez, 1995. Barangay: Its Government and Management (Revised Edition), Manila. Geertz, Clifford, 1962. The Rotating Credit Association: A Middle Rung in Development, Economic Development and Cultural Change, 10(3): 241-263. Hayami, Yujiro and Masao Kikuchi, 2000. A Rice Village Saga: Three Decades of Green Revolution in the Philippines, MacMillan Press, London, Barnes and Noble, Boston. Jay, Robert, 1969. Javanese Villagers: Social Relations in Rural Modjokuto, MIT Press, Cambridge, Mass. Jocano, F. Landa, 1988. Social Organization in Three Philippine Villages: An Exploration in Rural Anthropology, Centro Escolar University, Manila. ----------, 1998, Filipino Prehistory: Rediscovering Precolonial Heritage, Punlad Research House, Manila. Kano, Hiroyoshi, 1987. Indoneshia no Seiji Taisei to Gyousei Kikou (Political and Administrative System of Indonesia), in Yoshiyuki Hagiwara, Eiji Murashima (eds.) ASEAN Shokoku no Seiji Taisei, pp.23-52, Institute of Developing Economies, Tokyo. ----------, 1990, Jawa Sonraku Shi no Kensho (Continuity and Change of Javanese Villages: The Case of Ungaran), Toyo Bunka Kenkyujo Kiyo, No.111, pp.33-129.

- 116 -

Kawagoe, Toshihiko, Kunio Ohkama and Al Sri Bagyo, 1992. Collective Actions and Rural Organizations in a Peasant Economy in Indonesia, The Developing Economies, 30(3): 215-235. Kern, James R., 1986. The Growth of Decentralized Rural Credit Institutions in Indonesia, in Colin MacAndrews (ed.) Central Government and Local Development in Indonesia, pp.101-131, Oxford University Press, Singapore. Kishi, Koichi, 1967. Jawa no Sonraku Soshiki ni tsuite no Oboegaki Dessa to Karurahan ni tsuite (A Note on Village Organizations in Jawa: with Focus on Desa and Kelurahan), Toyo Bunka, (43):23-48. Krom Kan Phatthana Chumchon (Community Development Department [CDD]), 1997. Klum omsap phua kan phalit: kho thet ching, khomun, kho sananae (Saving Groups for Production: The Facts, Data and Policy Proposal), Bangkok. Luhmann, Niklas, 1964. Funktionen und Folgen Formaler Organization, Duncker and Humbolt, Berlin. Mizuno, Kosuke, 1997. Indoneshia ni okeru Tochiken Tenkan Mondai Shokuminchi-ki no Kindaihou Tochiken no Tenkan Mondai wo chushin ni (Conversion of Land Titles in Indonesia: with special reference to Land Titles Registered Modernly in Colonial Era) in K. Mizuno (ed.) Tonan Ajia no Keizai Kaihatsu to Tochishoyu Seido, pp.115-154, Institute of Developing Economies, Tokyo. ----------, 1998, Indoneshia ni okeru Sonraku Gyosei Soshiki to Jumin Soshiki Nishi Jawapuriangan Kochi Nouson no Jirei (Rural Administrative Organizations and Peoples Organizations in Indonesia: Case Study in Priangan Highland, West Jawa), in Hiroyoshi Kano (ed.) Tonan Ajia Nouson Hattenn no Shutai to Soshiki Kindai Nihon tono Hikaku kara , pp.222-256, Institute of Developing Economies, Tokyo. ----------, 1999. Indoneshia no Jiba Sangyou Ajia Keizai Saisei no Michi toha nanika? (Community-based Industries in Indonesia: The Perspective of Revitalizing Asian Economy), Kyoto University Press, Kyoto. Morita, Akira, 1998. Indoneshia [Indonesia], in A. Morita (ed.) Ajia no Chihou Seido, pp.167-193, University of Tokyo Press, Tokyo. National Census and Statistical Office (NCSO), the Philippines, 1981. Philippine Yearbook 1981, Manila. National Statistical Coordination Board (NSCB), the Philippines, 1997. 1997 Philippine Statistical Yearbook, Makati City. National Statistical Office (NSO), Thailand, 1981. Statistical Yearbook Thailand 1976-80, Bangkok.

- 117 -

----------, 1991, 1992 and 1996. Statistical Yearbook Thailand 1990, 1992 and 1996, Bangkok. North, Douglass C., 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. Oaklay, Peter, et al., 1991. Projects with People: The Practice of Participation in Rural Development, International Labour Office, Geneva. Ocampo, Romeo B. and Elena M. Panganiban, 1987. The Local Political System in Asia, Seoul University Press, Seoul. Ortiz, Juanito S., 1996. The Barangay of the Philippines, 1996 Edition, Hiyas Press, Quezon City. Patten, Richard H. and Jay K. Rosengard, 1991. Progress with Profits: The Development of Rural Banking in Indonesia, ICS Press, San Francisco. Po, Blondie, 1980. Rural Organizations and Rural Development: A Documentary Study, in Marie S. Fernandez (ed.) Rural Organizations in the Philippines, pp.1-123, Institute of Philippine Culture, Ateneo de Manila University, Manila. Rocamora, J. Eliseo and Corazon Conti Panganiban, 1975. Rural Development Strategies: The Philippine Case, Ateneo de Manila University, Manila. Romani, John H. and M. Ladd Thomas, 1954. A Survey of Local Government in the Philippines, Institute of Public Administration, University of the Philippines, Manila. Schiller, Jim, 1996. Developing Jepara: State and Society in New Order Indonesia, Monash Asia Institute, Clayton. Seibel, Hans Dieter and Uben Parhusip, 1992. Linking Formal and Informal Finance: An Indonesian Example, in Dale W. Adams and Delbert A. Fitchett (eds.) Informal Finance in Low-Income Countries, pp.239-248, Boulder, San Francisco, Oxford. Shigetomi, Shinichi, 1998a. Cooperation and Community in Rural Thailand: An Organizational Analysis of Participatory Rural Development, Institute of Developing Economies, Tokyo. ----------, 1998b. Noson Kyodou Kumiai no Sonritsu Jouken Shinyou Kyoudou Soshiki ni miru Tai to Nihon no Keiken (How Can Rural Cooperatives Develop beyond the Village Community?: A Comparative Analysis of Thailand and Japan), in Hiroyoshi Kano (ed.) Tonan Ajia Nouson Hattenn no Shutai to Soshiki Kindai Nihon tono Hikaku kara , pp.179-219, Institute of Developing Economies, Tokyo. ----------, 1998c. Community Development and Local Administrative Hierarchy: How Can a Community-based Development Break the Fetters of Community? in Kasetsart

- 118 -

University (ed.) Proceedings: International Seminar of Sustainable Human Resource Development and Community Development in Asia and the Pacific, pp.42-47, 13-15 May 1998 at Kasetsart University, Bangkok, Thailand. ----------, forthcoming. Rural Organizations and Development the Social Background for Collective Action, in Takamasa Akiyama and Donald Larson (eds.) Dynamics of Rural Development in East Asia, The World Bank, Washington, D.C. Shimagami, Motoko, 2001. Jawa Nouson ni okeru Jumin Soshiki no Inboryushon Suharuto Seiken-ka no Sonraku Kaihatsu no Ichi Sokumen (Organizaitonal Involution in Rural Java: A Characteristics of Village Development under the New Order), Tonan Ajia Kenkyu, 38(4): 512-551. Soemardjan, Selo, 1963. The Dynamics of Community Development in Rural Central and West Java: A Comparative Report, Department of Asian Studies, Monograph Series of Modern Indonesia Project, Cornell University, Ithaca. Soemardjan, Selo and Kenon Breaseale, 1993. Cultural Change in Rural Indonesia: Impact of Village Development, Sebelas Maret University Press, Surakarta. Suharto, Pandu, 1991. Small or Peoples Credit Institutions in Indonesia, Jakarta, (mimeo). Thorbecke, Erik and Theodore van der Pluijm, 1993. Rural Indonesia: Socio-economic Development in A Changing Environment, New York University Press, New York. Uphoff, Norman and Milton J. Esman, 1974. Local Government for Rural Development: Analysis of Asian Experience, Rural Development Committee, Cornell University, Ithaca. Valsan, E. H., 1970. Community Development Programs and Rural Local Development: Comparative Case Studies of India and the Philippines, Praeger Publications, New York. Wurfel, David, 1988. Filipino Politics: Development and Decay, Cornell University Press, Ithaca. Yogo, Toshihiro, 2000. Local Communities in Development Process An Analytical Framework, in Local Social Development, pp.17-30, report of the APO Seminar on Training Method for Integrated Local Community Development: International Trainers Training on Local Social Development held from 27 July to 8 August 1998 in Sri Lanka, APO, Tokyo.

- 119 -

1. BANGLADESH
Abdul Aziz Talukder
Deputy Registrar Cooperative Department Ministry of Local Government, Rural Development and Cooperatives Dhaka

INTRODUCTION Bangladesh is bounded by India on the west, the north, and the northeast and Myanmar on the southeast and the Bay of Bengal on the south. The area of the country is 56,977 miles2 or 1,47,570 km2. Except the hilly regions in the northeast and the southeast, some areas of highlands in the north and northwestern part, the country consists of low, flat and fertile land. A network of rivers of which the Padma, the Jamuna, the Teesta, the Brahmaputra, the Surma, the Meghna, and the Karnaphuli are important, and their tributaries numbering about 230 with a total length of about 24,140 km covering the country flow down to the Bay of Bengal. Heavy silts deposited by rivers during the rainy season are thus continuously enriching the alluvial soil. ADMINISTRATIVE STRUCTURE FROM CENTRAL GOVERNMENT TO LOCAL LEVEL INSTITUTIONS Historical Background The territory constituting Bangladesh was under the Muslim rule for over five and a half centuries from 1201 to 1757 A.D. Subsequently, it was under the subjugation of the British after the defeat of the last sovereign ruler, Nawab Sirajuddowla in 1757. The British ruled over the entire Indian subcontinent including this territory for nearly 190 years from 1757 to 1947. During that period Bangladesh was a part of the British Indian province of Bengal and Assam. With the termination of British Role in August 1947 the subcontinent divided into India and Pakistan. Bangladesh was then a part of Pakistan. It appeared on the world map as an independent and sovereign state on 16 December 1971 following the victory at the War of Liberation from 25 March to 16 December 1971. Administrative Structure The form of government in Bangladesh in unitary. A parliamentary system of government headed by Prime Minister is responsible to run the country. The Prime Minister is assisted by a council of ministers. A minister heads each ministry. A civil servant designated as secretary who is a permanent secretary of the government assists the minister. Under each ministry, there are subordinate bodies like director, etc. which are responsible for the execution of the government policies. For administrative purpose, the country is divided into six divisions; Divisional Commissioner who belongs to the civil service and who acts for the Central Government

- 120 -

heads each division. There are other divisional officers under various line ministries who are to implement the plan and programs of the respective ministries. There are 64 districts under the six divisions. To administer all development activities of the district, the Deputy Commissioner acts as the coordinator of all departments functioning in a particular district. He also exercises the authority of the Central Government. There are other district level officers also in the district of the line ministries who are responsible for implementing plans and programs of the respective ministries. The district is again divided into a number of Upazillas and Thanas. At present there are 496 upazillas and thanas of which 36 are in metropolitan cities and 4,451 union parishads, which are all in the rural areas. Under control of district administration, Upazilla Nirbahi officer who also belongs to the civil service heads upazilla level administration. Other officers of the line ministries are posted in the thana level to implement plans and programs of the respective ministries. For convenience to form local level government institutions, each thana is subdivided into a number of unions and then again into villages. Local government bodies in cities and urban areas are called City Corporation Municipality or Pourashava, respectively. Of late, there are four city corporations and 127 municipalities in the country. The local government institutions like zilla parishad, upazilla parishad, union parishad, municipalities and the city corporations are run by the public representatives elected direct election and these local institutions are autonomous. This hierarchical arrangement is illustrated in Figure 1 below:

Ministry
Divisions Districts Upazilla Union Parishad Figure 1. Hierarchy of Government Institutions RURAL DEVELOPMENT IN BANGLADESH Community development means an improvement in the quality of life of the country people. It includes the process of development of both economic and social sectors. In Bangladesh more than 77 percent people live in the rural areas. Most of the rural people are poor and living below the poverty line. For example, if the level of nutritional intake is taken as the indicator, 69 percent of the population falls below the line. So rural development has become the focal point for all development efforts in Bangladesh. The rural area of Bangladesh has villages as its lower unit. The village inhabitants include rural farmers, fishermen, weavers, blacksmiths, artisans, traders, laborers, etc. Therefore, in order to upgrade the rural lifestyle of such people, programs have been

- 121 -

implemented to promote economic growth and social progress, to create employment, to raise income level of the rural poor, etc. Rural development is a multi-disciplined slow achievement program requiring multisectoral intervention. All national organizations, NGOs and other community-based organizations are required to take intra-organizational coordinated activities. The first institutional intervention in rural development was made in 1904 when Cooperative Credit Societies (CCS) were introduced. Subsequently, union-based multipurpose cooperatives were introduced in 1954 by the name Village Agriculture and Industrial Development (VAID) program. Later on Commilla Approach Cooperatives program was introduced in 1961, where the village-based agricultural cooperatives were linked with upazilla (subdistrict) central cooperatives. Again to address the landless, women and the poor, Comprehensive Rural Development Program was launched to reduce rural poverty through participation of rural poor in production and proper distribution of income and resources. The importance of providing community participation was underlined in the Fifth Five-Year Plan (1997-2002) both within local government institutions and through local institution building. The objectives of rural development include poverty eradication, creation of employment, income generation, expansion of productive sectors, development of rural institutions like formal cooperatives and informal groups, improvement of basic physical infrastructure in rural areas, facilitate agricultural development and promote participation of women in rural development, etc. In the development process, participatory local level planning is essential. Bottom-up decision-making process should be emphasized and the coordination between the local level organizations is essential. It is felt that effective peoples participation in decision-making and implementation process is essential for development. So a bottom-up participatory process with emphasis on local level initiative was encouraged under Fifth Five-Year Plan for socioeconomic development in Bangladesh. Rural Development Policies and Programs Rural development means an improvement in the quality of life of the rural people. It includes the process of development of both economic and social sectors. The economic aspect refers to infrastructure, production, employment and income generation and the social aspect refers to education, health, sanitation, family planning, etc. So, rural development is not confined to one activity, it is a package of economic and social activities with the ultimate object of upgrading the living condition of the rural poor. The projects sponsored by the government and other agencies have the components mainly with the object of rural development of the country such as infrastructure development, agricultural development, para-agricultural activities, agricultural marketing, non-farm income generation activities, health and nutrition, rural institutions and human resource development. Poverty being the most pressing problem in the rural areas of Bangladesh, for a rural development plan to be meaningful, it must continue to effectively address the problem of poverty. For this, the Fourth Five-Year Plan pursued an employment-led growth policy. The focus of the policy was to promote greater opportunities for the rural poor for productive employment in both farm and non-farm sectors of the economy. Keeping alleviation of rural poverty as the end in view, the objectives of the plan of the rural development and institutions sector was to:

- 122 -

i. reduce rural poverty by means of increasing gainful employment and income opportunities on a sustained basis through expansion of the productive sectors; ii. develop rural institutions; iii. improve technology and skills for productive activities and ensure better access of the rural poor to the means of production; iv. facilitate agricultural development through institutional support and expansion of irrigation; v. improve basic physical infrastructure (roads, markets) in the rural areas; and vi. promote participation of women in rural development. Small Group Approach In Bangladesh about 80 percent of the total population live in the rural areas. The rural economy is characterized by low productivity, subsistence agriculture, unemployment and high rate of population growth. From this national point of view, development of agriculture in Bangladesh is of paramount importance. About 85 percent of the total population directly or indirectly depended on agriculture for their livelihood, it accounts for 58-60 percent of the GNP and constitute more than 50 percent labor force. But paradoxically, it is a fact that more than 40 percent of the total work force is unemployed. This situation is due to the outcome of excessive dependence on agriculture, which ultimately creates an inactive atmosphere in other professional groups of the country. Hence diversification of rural economy to ensure optimum utilization of domestic resources and simultaneous improvements in agricultural productivity can invigorate the countrys economy for absorbing the vast unemployed labor force of the country. This necessitates creating an atmosphere of spontaneous involvement of the common people with a maximum extent of effective mass participation by all professional groups. This in turn would be possible by mobilizing the resources of the nation through small groups. Moreover, in Bangladesh, there are wide scopes for the rural women to contribute to rural development by the following field of activities: Bamboo, cane, wood works, mat making, paddy pulse making, goat fathering or raising, tailoring, kitchen gardening, sewing and embroidery, bee keeping, poultry and duck raring and other handicrafts, sericulture, pisciculture, weaving, sanitation, health care and family planning. Also, in the rural areas by forming small occupational group like youth, farmers, porter, smiths, plumber, cobblers, carpenters, weavers, fishermen, small traders, the following activities can be performed for income generation and self-employment: Pond fishing, nursery plantation, kitchen gardening, tailoring, wood carpeting, blacksmithing, weaving, cattle, fish and poultry raising, social aforestration, small trading, fruit cultivation, milks cow, bee keeping, umbrella mending, rickshaw van, bull-cart weeding, missionary, and embroidery. Organizations working for rural development in Bangladesh mostly operate through small groups. Government departments, autonomous bodies, NGOs and cooperatives are involved in small group activities. There are some commonalties in the operation of the

- 123 -

groups. There is, however, a marked divergence in the nature of their programs, formation of groups or in organizing the group activities. DEVELOPMENT PLANNING SYSTEM AND CENTRAL PLANNING PROCESS The Planning Commission of the Planning Ministry regulates all development plans of the government. The Planning Commission is responsible for approving and implementing the development projects. In spite of that, the Parliament is the highest authority for different development project. The National Parliament decides the direction of the total development process. National Economic Council (NEC) headed by the Prime Minister determines the policy and guidelines for development. Executive Committee of the National Economic Council (ECNEC) also headed by the Prime Minister approves all the development projects other than the aided projects. The project concept papers (PCP) are also considered and approved by ECNEC. The implementing authority of the development project submits the project proposal in the form of PCP through respective ministers to the Planning Division. The Planning Division scrutinizes the proposal and places it before pre-ECNEC. The proposal, which has to be considered viable, placed for consideration and approval to the ECNEC. After approval, the proposal comes back to the respective ministry where a Project Performa (PP) is prepared. The implementing agency implements the project according to the PP. The PCP directs the location and the beneficiaries of the project. Thus a link has been established between Central Government and the village level. In the local level planning, the objective of a particular project is determined by the beneficiaries by means of a base-line survey. Usually, local level planning is formulated through participatory methods, implying bottom-up planning. In most cases, bottom-up planning process has been encouraged by the government. Besides government plans and programs, the number of NGOs are involved in the development process. They are engaged in the activities for socio-economic upliftment of the rural poor. The donors support the NGOs to supplement the governments delivery system to reach the poor and to play a more creative role. Some of these NGOs are very effective in terms of both beneficiary coverage and investment and, they have the ability to reach the poor and address the issues of poverty alleviation. Some of the prominent NGOs are Bangladesh Rural Advancement Committee (BRAC), Proshika, and Association for Social Advancement (ASA). A number of state-run commercial banks have also been participated in poverty alleviation programs through providing micro-credit to the landless and small farmers. Likewise, Grameen Bank has so far disbursed Tk.72.45 billion to a total number of beneficiaries over two million peoples. Development Plans of Rural Development Agencies 1. Department of Cooperatives Department of Cooperatives (DOC) is the pioneer organization working in the rural areas for over a century. Before independence, the DOC was the only organization working on community basis. The DOC implemented Thana Irrigation Program (TIP) when there was food deficit in the country. With the formation of agricultural cooperative in this region,

- 124 -

mechanized cultivation, adopting high-yielding varieties (HYVs), use of chemical fertilizers, etc. have been introduced to the farmers. Modern fishing equipment was also supplied to the fishermens programs through DOC. A number of poverty alleviation programs have been implemented and regular training for income-generating activities and management training has been offered to the cooperators. 2. Bangladesh Rural Development Board Bangladesh Rural Development Board (BRDB) has both cooperative and informal group networks to eradicate poverty as well as rural development all over Bangladesh. It operates micro-credit programs to finance its clientele groups for poverty alleviation. BRDB has been proved as an effective organization in poverty eradication of the country. 3. Local Government Engineering Department The LGED under the Ministry of Local Government, Rural Development and Cooperatives is implementing rural development infrastructure development projects, particularly construction of rural roads, growth centers, water structures, etc. which help generate employment in the rural areas. During 1998/99 to 1999/2001, 290 million man-days of work had been created. During July-February 1998-99, about 23 million man-days of work had been created in which 22.2 million were in the rural areas. 4. The Rural Maintenance Program The RMP started since 1983 with food aid from Canada, is playing an important role in alleviation of poverty. The phase I and phase II of program were implemented by the Ministry of Disaster Management and relief in collaboration with Cooperative American Relief Everywhere (CARE). The phase III of RMP has been transferred to the LGED in July 1995. The tenure of the phase III has been stipulated for the period 1995-2001. The principal objective of these program is to create employment and income for destitute women (owning land less than 0.5 acres) by engaging them in the maintenance of roads and also helping them in undertaking other income-generating activities from their accumulated savings. RMP is under implementation in 4,100 unions in 435 thanas in 61 districts. About 41,000 destitute women are expected to be benefitted in 1998-99. 5. Others Beside these there are many prominent NGOs named BRAC, Grameen Bank, ASA, Proshika, etc. in Bangladesh, which are engaged in rural development activities as local nonformal institutions. COOPERATIVE MOVEMENT IN BANGLADESH The cooperative movement started in this country with the enactment of the Cooperative Credit Societies Act 1904. Only the primary cooperatives could be organized under this Act with not less than 10 individual members. The movement was guided by the philosophy and principles to protect the poor peasants from the exploitation of landlords and moneylenders of the society, so that a poverty free socio-economy for the poor people especially of the rural areas can be made. Initially, the movement was launched by introducing agriculture credit cooperatives. But the noble intention of the activities gradually expanded to different sectors, such as fisheries, weavers, transports, milk produces, handicrafts, housing, banking, insurance, etc. for bringing about an overall upliftment for the persons of limited means as well as for having a balanced socio-economic infrastructure in the country.

- 125 -

Over the decades, though the legal and administrative framework remained same, the cooperative movement witnessed two major trends. Firstly the cooperative network became a three-tier system and the other in two-tier cooperative system. The first type traditional cooperatives are functioning from very beginning of the movement since 1904 under the direct supervision and management control of Registrar hierarchy vested to the DOC and the second type, Comilla model cooperatives, popularly known as BRDB cooperatives were functioning since mid 1960s. The new two-tier cooperatives were introduced with the intention of ensuring quick service and supply of credit and input to the members of agricultural cooperatives. Since then the BRDB cooperatives were adopted as the main approach to implement government policies and strategies for rural development. It may be mentioned that BRDB was entrusted with responsibility of supervision of two-tier cooperatives, which run parallel to the three-tier cooperatives of Registrar hierarchy. But the regulatory control of two-tier cooperative however vested to the Registrar. After the emergence of Bangladesh as an independent state in 1971, fresh ideas were generated and strategies were explored for rural development. Emphasis was laid upon cooperatives with a socialistic framework. The Constitution of Bangladesh has characterized cooperative as one of the most important sectors of economy of the country. In the years after the political change in the mid 1970s a new thrust added to the cooperative movement. Donor agencies became interested to finance cooperative-based rural development programs. For example, the World Bank, Norwegian Agency for International Development (NORAD), ADB, etc., funded largely the cooperative program to make the new two-tier cooperatives fruitful. Cooperatives of Bangladesh have been playing a vital role in introducing the use of modern cultivation, irrigation, use of HYV seeds, application of fertilizers, use of pesticides, etc. In fact bulk of the mechanized irrigation is covered under the cooperative scheme. Also, in other sectors of cooperatives have been playing an important role in the development process, such as transportation, milk production, marketing, fishery, weaving, handicraft, housing, etc. At present, there are around 1,40,000 primary cooperatives in Bangladesh having 7.5 million individual members covering approximately 450 million people which is about onethird of the total population of the country. Many of the societies are dormant, ineffective and suffer from weak and improper management practice. Cooperatives cannot survive on motivation alone. The prime need at present is to ensure quality of the society rather than quantity. The main task therefore, is to make the societies self-sustaining instead of increasing their number. There are 1,049 central or secondary level cooperatives and 20 apex or national or national level cooperative organizations in Bangladesh comprising the following cooperative sectors: banking, industry, sugarcane, fishery, milk production, marketing, transportation, housing, women, etc. There are also two national level cooperative organizations; namely, Bangladesh Jatiya Samabaya Union (BJSU), which is a member of the International Cooperative Alliance (ICA). Cooperative societies of the country are the members of BJSU. BJSU runs its day-today affairs with fund provided by its member societies. It is the voice for its affiliated members in the country. There is no government financial to the BJSU in the forms of grant or aid as in the case of Bangladesh Jatiya Palli Unnanyan Samabaya Federation (BJPUSF), which is sponsored by BRDB.

- 126 -

The Cooperative Policy and Legislation In consideration of the importance of the Cooperative Sector, the Government of Bangladesh has adopted the National Cooperative Policy in 1989 with the following important objectives and strategies: a. b. c. d. e. Increasing contribution of cooperative sector as the second sector of national economy for augmenting GDP under the constitution of the country. Ensuring participation, as creative and productive force of the underprivileged groups of the society particularly the women, the have-nots, different occupational groups and other people of limited means. Increasing the role of the cooperative sector in providing unemployed persons throughout the country especially in the relevant areas. Expanding the role of cooperatives in various sectors of GDP particularly in agriculture, small and cottage industries, trade and commerce, store and marketing, export-oriented industries and trades, etc. Ensuring cooperatives as major instruments in all economic activities in rural and urban areas for poverty alleviation, upgrading lifestyle of common man and removing the disparity that exists in haves and have-nots of different region of the country gradually. Ensuring easy access to education, healthcare and nutrition of the members of cooperative societies and their families through overall upliftment of their economic condition. Ensuring transformation of cooperative activities into a movement through institutional framework. Encouraging the members of the cooperatives to become self-managed and self-reliant, gradually. Ensuring the management of cooperative societies as democratic institution and establishing autonomy in the management. Undertaking supportive measures for the improvement of financial condition of the cooperatives as well as attaining their economic viability.

f. g. h. i. j.

In Bangladesh, the Cooperative Societies Act 2001 and cooperative societies rules regulate the cooperative societies. The DOC is responsible for administering these cooperative acts, rules and regulations promulgated from time to time. According to the laws, the cooperative society is a body corporate by the name under which it is registered and is autonomous in function. The management of every cooperative society vests in a managing committee constituted in accordance with laws and bylaws. To make the ongoing cooperative movement more affective and dynamic, the cooperative policy introduced in 1989 required to be updated. Steps are already being taken for upgrading of the cooperative policy. Cooperatives and Cooperative Department Cooperatives are basically an economic movement for the improvement of socioeconomic condition of common people. DOC came into existence with the passing of Cooperative Societies Act of 1904. Its administrative ministry is Ministry of Local Government, Rural Development and Cooperatives. All officers and staff of this sector, from department headquarters to thana level, have been actively engaged in administration of

- 127 -

cooperatives including the formulation of acts and rules, management of disputes, audits, inspection, research, publicity, extension and training activities. The DOC has been working to make the movement more dynamic. Cooperative is an effective vehicle for socio-economic improvement of the country. People of different occupations such as peasants, the weavers, the fishermen and the laborers are becoming self-reliant through cooperatives. Today cooperative is recognized as an effective vehicle for participatory development in all levels of the country. Function of the Cooperative Department The main functions of the DOC are as follows: * * * * * * * General Administration; Administration of cooperative acts/ordinance and rules; Organization registration and promotion of professional cooperatives; Statistical documentation of cooperatives; Audit and inspection of cooperatives; Monitoring and evaluation of cooperatives; and Overall extension (training and publication; planning and promotion) of cooperatives.

The DOC is headed by the Registrar of Cooperative Societies (RCS) in the rank of Joint Secretary of the Government of the Peoples Republic of Bangladesh. Additional Registrars, Joint Registrars, Deputy Registrars, Assistant Registrars, and Technical Staffs at the headquarters assist him. In the field level the Divisional Registrar, Deputy Registrars, Assistant Registrar and cooperative officers and skilled employees assist him. In the field of cooperative education and training, the principal (Additional Registrar) of Bangladesh Cooperative Academy (BCA) works under the general administration of RCS. There are nine cooperative zonal institutes (CZIs) in Bangladesh. A lot of cooperatives officers are being trained in these institutions for the upliftment of their own careers and that of the cooperative movement. The Principal (ARCS) of CZIs works under the general administration and supervision of the principal BCA. Although the main objectives of the cooperative movement are to uplift the socio-economic condition of the members of the societies, yet the cooperatives contribute, to a certain degree, to the revenue earnings of the government. In addition, in compliance with the national policy of the country to protect the environment and reducing pollution, the cooperatives with their limited resources participated by planting nearly 10 million trees to minimize environment pollution. OTHER DEVELOPMENT INSTITUTIONS NGOs 1. Bangladesh Rural Advancement Committee BRAC established in 1972 primary to carry out relief work is now working on a multidimensional approach, which includes credit, informal education for the children and the adult, primary healthcare and provision of legal advice on womens rights, etc. Nearly 2.2 million families, of which 93 percent women members, in 388 upazillas in 61 districts have been advanced loans amounting to Tk.21.72 billion till December 1997 and recovery rate is 98 percent. During this period, the savings generated by the beneficiaries amounted to Tk.1.75 billion.

- 128 -

2. Grameen Bank Established in 1983, through an ordinance, Grameen Bank started its operation as early as in 1976 under an experimental project and has expanded its activities through organizing the poor into groups and extending credit to help them generate their own income and capital about 2.28 million members of the groups, 94 percent of whom are women in about 37,937 villages have been provided with credit of about Tk.81.78 billion till December 1997 through its 1,105 branches and savings generated by the beneficiaries has amounted to Tk.6.59 billion. Loan recovery has been Tk.71.33 billion. Besides such employment and income generation activities, Grameen Bank has also undertaken housing schemes for the poor. Up to December 1997, the Bank has distributed house-building credit amounting to Tk.6.24 billion. 3. Swanirvar Bangladesh Established in 1975, the organization has been carrying out its programs of credit disbursement, population control and healthcare through formation of village committees and has covered 11,050 villages in 164 thanas. Up to December 1997, an amount of Tk.1,734.7 million has been disbursed to 0.78 million loan recipients of whom 0.54 million are women (70 percent). During this period, savings generated by the beneficiaries has amounted to Tk.213.4 million. Out of the total loans of Tk.1,734.7 million disbursed, Tk.1,535.1 million has been advanced to income-generating projects (purchase of rickshaw and cow, petty trade, rearing poultry, vegetables cultivation, cane products, etc), Tk.150 million for family planning and child care program, Tk.31.6 million for rural development, and Tk.14 million for rearing poultry and livestock. 4. Proshika Established in 1976, this organization operates in multidimensional activities. These include provision of credit, development of fishery and livestock, development of silk, irrigation programs, health and nutrition, sinking of tube-wells and distribution, environmentfriendly agriculture, social forestry and housing programs. During 1990/91-1996/97, credit amounting to Tk.3,960 million was disbursed to about 1.0 million members (40 percent women) from 156 upazillas of 48 districts. The credit recovery rate is 92 percent. A MODEL OF VILLAGE DEVELOPMENT PLAN Concept of Comprehensive Village Development Program Comprehensive Village Development Program (CVDP) is a modest effort of experimentation that would pursue increasing production, employment, income, social development and equitable distribution of benefits based on local level planning within a common and single institution for all villagers. This institution will develop common facilities and services (physical and social) as well as economic activities for the villagers. Under the CVDP concept, a multipurpose single village institution as a forum or platform is being used by all development agencies, irrespective of the type (whether they are government organizations, or NGOs). This helps gradually to reduce duplication, wastage and inefficiency in the rural development sector and in turn contribute to the development of a sustainable process to build self-managed village institutions. Objectives of CVDP as a Sample Village Development Plan i. To develop common village facilities and make available at the village level various social and economic services relating to literacy and education, population control and family planning, minimum healthcare and nutrition, income generation activities and others;
- 129 -

ii. To increase production in both farm and non-farm sector, productive employment and household income, utilizing all available resources maximally; iii. To encourage capital formation in cooperative societies; iv. To develop human resources; v. To promote greater participation of women in development activities; and vi. To ensure equitable distribution of benefits of development to all. Institutional Arrangement for CVDP In each village, there will be a village-based cooperative called the Comprehensive Village Development Cooperative Society (CVDCS). All the villagers will be the members of CVDCS. The members will be divided into different functional groups. The CVDPSs will be managed by a managing committee having a proportionate representation from each functional group, except that of the children. These are being developed as economically viable and self-reliant institutions by means of resource mobilization and commercial/business activities within the cooperative discipline. The existing cooperative societies and informal groups in the village will be gradually amalgamated with CVDPSs based on the consideration of the extent of their assets vis--vis liabilities. No new cooperative societies and groups other than CVDPSs will be promoted in the villages. Side by side the CVDPSs will have links to their upazilla level cooperative associations. The other linkage of CVDPSs will be with local government bodies at different tiers and upazilla level nation building departments, the purpose of which will be to develop common village facilities and services (physical, social and economic) and obtaining support services available at the union, upazilla (subdistrict) and districts. EVALUATION AND FUTURE DIRECTIONS Evaluation of the Impact of Communities and Institution in Integrated Community Development in Bangladesh Various experiments were carried out with local level institutions, particularly from 1958 onwards, primarily with the objective of establishing a centralized system of administration in the name of devolution of administrative authority, but in fact, to keep the people out of the decision-making process. Thus the people of Bangladesh, particularly the rural people who comprise about 80 percent of the countries population, lost almost half a century during which their participation was virtually absent from the very process of development they were supposed to be the beneficiaries of. However, in the background of lost opportunity for development and abject rural poverty, growing awareness of the people as well as deeper insight into the miserable plight of the rural poor by the civil society, the concept of decentralization and revitalization of the local level institutions started capturing the imagination of academics and policy-makers. As a result, fresh initiatives were launched during the 1980s for revitalizing local level institutions, at various tiers, and delegating to them some developmental roles along with powers to raise some resources locally. These were, however, rendered dysfunctional, through the extended arms of the Central Government, and the only local level institutions that remain still in place are the union parishads. The fundamental premise of participatory development is development by the people and for the people. Popular participation manifests in the collective endeavor by the people concerned in an organized framework to pool together to attain objectives they set for themselves and action that is stimulated by their thoughts and deliberations and over which they can exert effective control. In this context, the local level institutions become important

- 130 -

in providing the institutional fora for both empowerment of people and promotion of participatory rural development in a cost-effective and sustainable way. In this backdrop, the government, immediately on its installation, established a commission to make, an in-depth study and come up with recommendations on the forms and functions of local government institutions at different levels. Following the recommendations made by the commission, union parishads and pourashavas will be strengthened both functionally and financially. All these local government bodies will be entrusted with the responsibility to formulate and implement local level development programs/projects, manage educational institutions, run health and family welfare services and to maintain local level infrastructure. Necessary laws will be enacted to empower these local level institutions to mobilize and raise resources for local level activities thus lessening the burden on the Central Government. Law has already been passed to strengthen and broad base womens representation in union parishads. To ensure peoples participation in the development process, local level institutions will be encouraged to evolve on a spirit of self-help. They will also provide a system for efficient use of voluntary labor in various fields of the rural life, not only in production but also in community development. The government role here will be catalytic and promotional. Using the local government institutions, target groups to promote a back-to-back relationship between policies and felt-needs of the people. An important area will be rural human resource development. Land is the scarcest resource in Bangladesh. Its proper utilization is a necessity for the success of the plan, as it ensures effective employment of the rural labor force and higher output. Positive steps will be taken to provide an institutional framework for production and employment planning at the local level and ensuring better use of land, water and human resources. It is recognized that local level institutions for promotion of production, employment, voluntary consolidation of holdings, etc. cannot perform readily without adequate policy support and necessary changes in the legal system. Future Directions i. The ministries and agencies responsible for development of socio-economic infrastructure strategies must be drawn to develop those in a systematic way without avoidable duplication of activities among different agencies and levels of activity centers. The component activities should be clearly and completely identified and responsibilities properly delineated among different levels; ii. Formal and informal institutions should be allowed to function so that informal groups, in the course of time may be organized in to cooperatives; iii. As a part of employment generation strategy, a target-oriented program to promote human resource development including productive skills though formal and nonformal education and training should be implemented; iv. Poverty alleviation program should be located in distressed areas where incidence of poverty is especially high and government organizations and NGOs have not undertaken any program; v. Donor agencies should be more involved in rural development and poverty alleviation and finance the rural professional groups; vi. Donor agencies should provide especial assistance to cooperative societies, as formal groups for their sustainability; and vii. Appropriate training programs should be developed to support the rural development programs.

- 131 -

2. REPUBLIC OF CHINA
Dr. Shih-jui Tung

Associate Professor Graduate Institute of Agricultural Extension Education National Chung-hsing University Taichung

INTRODUCTION Community-based rural development has been implemented in Taiwan since 1965, and the history can even be traced back to 1955. At that time, the agricultural administration noticed the necessity for developing substantial infrastructure in rural areas. The local communities and institutions, in practice, perform crucial roles in integrating rural resources in the fulfillment of sustainable development. Recently, increased involvement of Non-profit Organizations (NPOs) in local community development not only brought in abundant voluntary human resources, but also contributed to the re-conceptualization of rural development. On 21 September 1999, a fear-provoking 7.6 magnitude earthquake shocked central Taiwan and consequently caused 2,333 deaths and 8,457 collapsed houses. The estimated economic loss of the earthquake is between US$3 billion to US$10 billion, or roughly 1.2-4 percent of the GDP. Most of the seriously damaged communities were located in the countryside rather than in urban areas. Without the substantive help of local community associations and institutions, the damage could not have been recovered. This occurrence spells out the importance of local communities and institutions in integrated rural development. Based on Taiwans experience, the purpose of this paper is twofold. First, the paper tries to illustrate the organization structure in rural development. Second, it delineates the role of local communities and institutions in integrated rural development. Problems encountered and the prospects are discussed as well. INSTITUTIONS IN RURAL DEVELOPMENT Sustainability is the ultimate goal of rural development in Taiwan. The attainment of economic and social sustainability in rural areas depends on institutional networks with the aid of cultural and social resources (Day, 1998). Taiwan rural communities have been experiencing enormous difficulties in recent years due to the increased economic depression, global trade competition, and the continuous natural disasters. As agriculture sector contributes dramatically decreasing proportion of GDP, the rural residents are generally suffering from confidence loss about the future. Local communities, under such circumstance, play the central role in rebuilding their confidence and restoring their subsistence. The term community stands for different meanings in different countries. A common definition, however, is that a community is composed of a recognized space, a group of inhabitants with intimate relationships, identical local service system, and strong community consciousness.

- 132 -

The smallest rural community unit in Taiwan is known as the Borough or Tsuen or Li which is under the administration of township government, as presented in Figure 1. The total number of tsuen is recorded as 7,756 in 2000. Community in rural areas, therefore, is primarily corresponds to a tsuen. Therefore, throughout this paper tsuen is treated as the community. According to the 2000 statistics, the average population of a tsuen is around 900 with some extremes. The tsuen residents elect their own chief every four years. A tsuen office is setup, along with the election of the chief, within the community and legitimately monitored and financially aided by the offices of township, county, and national administration units. Primarily three systems are implementing rural development projects in Taiwan. They are official administration system, farmers/fishermens association system, and the NPO system, respectively. Among them, the first is government-administrated, while the other two are more non-governmentally administrated or self-administrated. The governmental community development plan in Taiwan was initiated in 1965. At that time the plan was expected to fulfill the missions of improving community residents education, culture, social welfare, and public health on one hand, and ameliorating agricultural facilities construction on the other. To accelerate community development, the Ministry of Interior encourages existing communities to establish a local institution; namely, community development association, to assist the tsuen/li office. The community development association, thus, is officially built up and consists of local populace enthusiastic in community affairs. The original objectives proposed to accomplish are to strengthen community infrastructure construction on one hand, and on the other hand to improve the community residents productivity, income, social welfare, and moral education. A community development association is regularly divided into sections of representative assembly, board of directors, and board of supervisors with differentiated tasks. The members of representative assembly are selected from the community residents and possess supreme authority in determining development policies. The members of the board of directors and supervisors are elected by the representatives and are responsible for managing and supervising the community development affairs, respectively, and its own members designate a chairperson for each committee. An executive chief is nominated by the board of directors to take charge of community affairs and to act as the community speaker. Despite the continuous decline in agricultural hegemony in many rural areas, the sector still holds significant influence on the shaping of rural communities (Marsden, 1998). Farmers associations, as well as fishermens associations, traditionally are local organizations of great importance in promoting rural development, though their major concern is on farmers, fishermen, and agriculture. Since agriculture-related population accounts for the majority of rural inhabitants, this institution, particularly its agricultural extension section, plays impressive role in integrated rural development. The agricultural extension service has traditionally designated the rural community people as its main target populations in need of public assistances, programs, and support to help improve the welfare as well as quality of their lives. In response to impacts resulting from a variety of societal changes and along with the emerging ecological imperative, however, the concept of holistic and sustainable community development nowadays becomes a prevailing belief guiding the transformation of Taiwanese agricultural extension. The agricultural extension system, therefore, is much more emphasizing the training of human resources rather than hardware construction. Agents of the agricultural extension section usually consists of members specialized in farming affairs, home economics, and youth affairs, respectively.

- 133 -

Ministry of Interior Council of agriculture Council for Cultural Affairs Council for Economic Planning and Development

County Government Bureau of Agriculture Bureau of Construction

County Farmers Association County Fishermens Association Department of Extension

Township Administration Office Department of Agriculture Department of Construction

Township Farmers Association Township Fishermens Association Agricultural Extension Section

T Borough, Tsuen of Li Office

Community Development

Farming Affairs

Home Economic

Youth Affairs

Non-profit Organization Environmental Protection Association, Cultural Rebuilding Foundation, Local History Studio, Community Development Studio, Others

- 134 -

Representative Assembly

Directors Board

Supervisors Board

Figure 1. Organizational Structure of Integrated Rural Development in Taiwan Note: Executing line; and sponsoring line.

After the threatening earthquake in 1999, bundles of rural communities have been haunted by sequential aftershocks and debris flow which consequently leads to increasing NPOs taking part in rural community development. As a great many rural communities faced reconstruction not only in facilities and industries, but also in spiritual phase such as culture and identity, increasing NPOs have actively partaken in post-disaster rural development on the ground of humane and environmental concerns. The involved institutions range from environmental protection groups, cultural rebuilding foundation, local history studio, to associations related to sustainable development. Given that the cumulative chemicals produced by conventional farming in the past decades have acutely spoiled most of the arable land, progressive numbers of institutions advocating sustainable agriculture or organic culture have risen these years. An NPO, as Wolf (1990) mentioned, is defined as a legitimately authorized, self-administrated organization to carryout public welfare without profitsearching as the as mission. It is commonly recognized that the existence of NPOs provides solid help to the governmental institutions that a cooperative relation between these two parities shall be the best development policy for the long run (Kramer, 1987; Lipsky and Smith, 1990; and Salamon, 1992). The NPOs involved in rural development seem to exhibit more momentum, vigor, creativity and concrete ideal in dealing with development affairs than the institutions of traditional two systems, probably due to its independence and better management. Most of the NPOs recruit considerable volunteers and are financed by personal donations or enterprises sponsor, along with frequent subsidy from the government. The latter usually comes as contributions to rural development. Roles and Achievements of Local Communities and Institutions In Taiwan, the community development associations are expected to play the role of a resource deliverer, a coordinator, or a facilitator (Table 1). A resource deliverer possesses a duty to deliver and evenly allocate the resources from government to the community inhabitants. A coordinator rile is played whenever there is conflict to be solved through negotiation involving various parties, whether inside or outside of the community. The role of the facilitator relates to personal learning and improving individual literacy. This is also a role of great importance, since community residents with quality is beneficial for community development in incoming knowledge-based economy era. Table 1. Roles of Local Institutions in Integrated Rural Development Institution Relational Target Role Community development association Farmers association Rural residents Agricultural population Resource deliverer, coordinator, facilitator Resource distributor, trainer, facilitator, management consultant coordinator Resource deliverer Animator, renovator, facilitator, educator, innovator

Borough/tsuen office NPO

Rural residents Rural residents

- 135 -

To date, as shown in Table 2, a total of 5,497 communities throughout Taiwan have established community development associations with an aggregated population size of about 16.1 million which accounted for nearly 73 percent of total population in 2000. Associations and some of the community development projects are given in Table 3. Governmental help accounts for the main part of its revenue at approximately 75 percent, most of which were from the township administration office. In addition, about a quarter of the expenditure is drawn from the community itself through personal donation or imposition on inhabitants. Usually, any savings after expenditure are being used to raise community construction funds in order to benefit future development plans. The activities and groups involved in rural community development, as a whole, are fairly diversified to accommodate the needs of residents with various ages and characteristics. It is estimated that about 70 percent of the communities have set up activity centers to provide facilities and space for different types of activities. The community development associations, per se, are to provide sufficient services and facilities to the residents to empower the community and to bring about the residents feeling of belonging or community consciousness. Among the NGOs, township farmers/fishermens associations contribute a great deal in the past decades pertaining to human resource development within community. The total numbers of township farmers association and fishermens association have remained around 300 and 40, respectively since 1970. The agricultural extension section in farmers association contains a total of 1,881 extension workers in 1998 and each recruits an average of 10 members. With different relations to farmers and rural residents, it simultaneously takes the roles of resource distributor, trainer, facilitator, coordinator, and farm management consultant. In terms of organizational structure, departments of farming affairs, home economics, and youth affairs are divided to take care of farmers, housekeepers, and the youth, respectively. More than a half of the agents, in accordance with the statistics, belong to farming affairs department because of the dominant proportion of farmer in components. Most farmers affiliated with the farmers association are organized into various cropspecific groups and follow a variety of training programs and management advices. To help the farmers, housekeepers, and the adolescents efficiently learn the skills of interest, the extension agents have to act as facilitators and assist the clients knowledge transfer and learning process. Being a mediator between government officers, different resources and farmers; members of the extension section act as coordinators. At times, they are performing the role of distributors transferring resources from governmental offices to those who need such resources. Traditionally, most plans are designed and decided in a top-down manner and undertaken passively. The community development associations or the farmers associations merely obey to what has been determined by the authority. Since the national development policy takes economic growth as the first priority, the development focus has been heavily concentrated on manufacturing, construction and introduction of advanced technology. The environmental and cultural issues, as a result, are overwhelmingly neglected. The emergence of NPOs, however, brings about a whole different picture to these issues with enormous volunteer input and community inhabitants active participation. Their goals are set to offset the long-lasting loss in ecological resources and traditional culture, and to defend the welfare of the disadvantaged in the rural areas.

- 136 -

Table 2. Statistics of Community Development in Taiwan, 1996-2000


Item Total number of tsuen Total number of community development association Households joining community development program Population joining community development Membership number of community development association Number of community construction funds Financial resources From government From community itself 1996 7,569 4,495 3,447,294 13,600,735 460,523 49,520,610 39,873,384 9,647,225 1997 7,569 4,747 3,816,961 13,979,483 509,615 45,093,673 35,427,277 9,666,395 1998 7,755 4,968 3,993,048 13,782,603 533,370 46,048,427 36,101,077 9,947,350 1999 7,755 5,245 4,296,418 15,581,542 694,509 3,341 57,648,335 42,720,526 14,927,809 2000 7,756 5,497 4,930,035 16,111,715 801,447 3,807 55,124,652 41,267,056 13,857,595

Table 3. Associations and Community Development Projects Item 1996

1997

1998

1999 3,963 435,971 190,478 3,769 4,334 1,837 1,543 2,100 2,727 412

2000 3,899 80,152 157,315 3,804 4,326 1,776 1,404 1,916 2,456 388

- 137 -

Community activity centers 3,444 3,660 3,878 Training programs for specific topics Community development demonstrations Community aging clubs 3,451 3,672 3,837 Community female/housekeeper clubs 3,703 4,019 4,212 Community security squads 2,269 2,323 2,259 Community voluntary service squads 1,543 1,745 1,743 Community libraries 2,308 2,388 2,337 Community entertainment squads 2,606 2,585 2,622 Community newsletters or brochures 217 254 293 Source: City Government Statistics. Note: Numerals exclude communities without Community Development Association.

Recently, as presented in Table 4, ever-increasing organizations are established with emphasis on cultural, historical and social welfare affairs. In 2000, for example, there were more than 1,500 associations related to academic or cultural affairs, among which the majority focused on the cultural or historical issues as their foremost concern. Noticing the quickly vanishing local culture, a social movement with regard to cultural or historical rebuilding is undertaking and rightly pinpointing to the rural communities. Besides, social welfare of the peasants is another issue deserves more attention in rural areas, since the general life quality is deteriorating due to long-term economic and natural resources deprivation. The number of NPOs relevant to social welfare was reported to be 4,535 in 2000. Out of these, a considerable number of NPOs exhibit interest in the issue of rural population. Of grand interest is the rapid rise of NPOs concerned with sustainable agriculture or organic agriculture whose effort gradually awakes rural individuals from environmental ignorance. An NPO generally consists of paid staff at less than 10 and ample volunteers who are the real activists in empowering the community. In terms of role-playing, an NPO could play the roles of animator, innovator, renovator, facilitator and educator. Being an animator and an educator, the NPO members are supposed to impulse the public awareness toward social justice and hidden reality, and in the mean time to educate them. Along with the awakening of the recognition of environmental deterioration and soil degradation due to chemicals abuse, more and more NPOs set their mission at restoring the agriculture into a more sustainable one or even organic agriculture. Not only they facilitate the conventional farmers learning toward organic farming, but also educate the general consumers to appreciate organic products and farmers contribution. In addition, being creative and renovating in participating in the process, community development is an important property of NPO, which precisely differentiates themselves from the other institutions. Problems and Future Directions A self-help and bottom-up, community-based rural development has been advocated for a long while (Herbert-Cheshire, 2000) in most academic papers and shall be a guide for Taiwans rural development. Despite the increasing numbers of community development associations and farmers/fishermens associations, the substantial achievements and pace of rural development based on these two approaches in Taiwan is not as expected, probably owing to overwhelming governmental domination on decision-making of community affairs. Successful community development, in reality, requires thorough participation, partnership, and dialogue among actors throughout the community (Kelly and Vlaenderen, 1995). At present, dozens of community development associations are established only to obtain subsidy from the government. What have been accomplished most successfully is merely to strengthen the infrastructure construction such as sewage system and road rebuilding. In contrast, little has been done in the agglomeration of community residents consciousness. The policy of community development has been so much determined by the Ministry of Interior as that most of the local communities have lost their independence in decisionmaking. As a result, the participation of community inhabitants in decision-making is limited that the general people frequently exhibit indifference toward community affairs. To leave the local community more space in deciding development strategy shall be an important direction.

- 138 -

Table 4. Community Development-related NGOs in Taiwan, 1977-2000


Occupational Organization Farmers Association Number of Number of Farming Youth Affairs Affairs Agent* Agent* 735 843 916 961 972 966 1,003 1,015 1,003 691 754 689 766 770 780 783 784 783 781 845 773 737 n.a. n.a. 311 314 360 364 366 371 372 381 372 333 353 354 264 264 264 269 275 275 275 361 336 326 n.a. n.a. Social Affairs Organization Number of Home Economics Agents* 299 303 348 352 357 357 395 395 395 342 382 376 366 366 376 379 380 377 355 399 364 383 n.a. n.a. Fishermens Association 42 42 42 42 38 38 38 38 38 38 38 38 38 38 38 38 38 38 38 38 38 38 40 40 Academic/ Cultural 280 297 325 347 364 437 496 532 559 566 627 654 562 588 668 671 721 789 874 958 1,035 1,160 1,343 1,504 Social Welfare 2,001 2,132 2,203 2,350 2,526 2,750 3,037 3,233 3,427 3,546 3,677 3,565 2,114 1,695 1,791 1,996 2,298 2,559 2,874 3,073 3,417 3,684 4,120 4,535

Year Total 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 305 305 306 305 303 304 304 304 303 303 303 303 303 303 303 303 302 302 302 300 302 302 304 304

Total Number of Agricultural Extension Agents 1,345 1,460 1,624 1,677 1,695 1,694 1,764 1,791 1,694 1,764 1,791 1,770 1,786 1,770 1,807 1,783 1,812 1,896 1,959 1,933 1,904 1,881 n.a. n.a.

- 139 -

Source: Note:

The Ministry of Interior, Taiwan * Denotes statistics from farmers associations annual report.

It is affirmed that informing residents of community history or culture leads to higher participation of community residents (Walters, et al., 1999). Inputs in hardware construction alone cannot bring about residents substantive participation, if not the cultural and historical reconstruction is undertaken simultaneously. In this context issues such as: how to convert the policy decision-making route from top-down into bottom-up, and how to persuade the inhabitants to recognize their duty in community development and to play an active role in community affairs, are seen as challenges in future. For rural development to be successful, the government-administrated organizations have to work with the farmers/fishermens associations and, especially with the NPOs. REFERENCES Day, Graham, 1998. Working with the Grain? Towards Sustainable Rural and Community Development, Journal of Rural Studies 14(1): 89-105. Druker, P. F., 1990. Managing the Non-profit Organization, Harper Collins, New York. Herbert-Cheshire, L., 2000. Contemporary Strategies for Rural Community Development in Australia: A Governmentality Perspective, Journal of Rural Studies 16: 203-215. Kelly, K. and V. Vlaenderen, 1995. Evaluating Participation Processes in Community Development, Evaluation and Program Planning 18(4): 371-383. Kramer, R., 1987. Voluntary Agencies in the Welfare State, University of California Press, Berkeley. Lipsky, M. and S. R. Smith, 1990. Nonprofit Organizations, Government, and the Welfare State, Publican Science Quarterly 104(4): 625-648. Marsden, T., 1998. New Rural Territories: Regulating the Differentiated Rural Spaces, Journal of Rural Studies 14(1):107-117. Roling, N. G., and J. Jiggins, 1998. The Ecological Knowledge System, in N. G. Roling and M. Wagemakers (eds.) Facilitating Sustainable Agriculture, p..283-311, Cambridge University Press. Salamon, L. M., 1992. Americas Nonprofit Sector: A Prime, The Foundation Center, New York. Walters, B. B., A. Cadelina, A. Cardano, and E. Visitacion, 1999. Community History and Rural Development: Why Some Farmers Participate More Readily than Others, Agricultural Systems 59: 193-214. Wolf, T., 1990. Managing a Nonprofit, Prentice-Hall Press, New York.

- 140 -

3. FIJI
Akhil Chand
Assistant District Officer Fiji Government Sigatoka

INTRODUCTION Fiji is made up of about 330 islands of which nearly one-third are inhabited. The total land area is 18,333 km2 and the two major islands are Viti Levu (about 10,429 km2) and Vanua Levu (5,556 km2). The population of Fiji in 1996 was about 775,000 of which 359,495 persons lived in urban areas and 415,582 or 60 percent in the rural areas. The annual average growth rate is about 0.8 percent. Fiji has a relatively young population with about 53 percent or 43,100 persons below the age of 25 years. The economically active population in 1996 was 67 percent. Apart from the indigenous Fijians, the country has accepted many other nationalities to its shores Indians, Europeans, Chinese and many Pacific Islanders. According to the 1996 census, there were 394,999 Fijians and 336,579 Indians. The balance 5.6 percent of the population comprised of other ethnic minorities. Nearly 83 percent of the land is owned by the indigenous Fijians and the remaining 17 percent is owned by the State, Rotumans and other individuals. Only 16 percent of Fijis land mass is suitable for agriculture and are found mainly along coastal plains, river deltas and valleys. However, the country enjoys a tropical climate. Although the rainfall is highly variable, the average increases steadily from coastal areas towards inlands. The Department of Land and Surveys and the Native Land Trust Board (NLTB) are the two authorities, which undertakes the management and administration of most of the land in Fiji. Other main institutions are: the Fijian Affairs Board (FAB); the Great Councils of Chiefs; the Provincial Councils, and Chieftainship. The 20th century brought about important economic changes in Fiji. The country developed a major sugar industry, established productive copra milling, developed tourism as an important source of income and also established secondary industries. The countrys central position in the Pacific region has been strengthened by recent developments in sea and air transportation and communications. Today, Fiji plays an important role in regional affairs and is recognized as the focal point of the Asia-Pacific region. As the countrys economy is being diversified and strengthened, public expenditure is also increased and infrastructure, health and medical services and education, etc. are expanded. With such developments, the country has initiated new approaches to rural development. LOCAL GOVERNANCE AND RURAL COMMUNITY DEVELOPMENT The Ministry of Fijian Affairs and Local Government have been reorganized. The Local Government part of the Ministry has been combined with Ministry of Urban

- 141 -

Development and Social Welfare, while Fijian Affairs became part of a combined Ministry of Fijian Affairs and Rural Development. The provincial councils acquired a new developmental role, in parallel with the advisory councils provided for Indo-Fijians, under the same Department of Rural Development. Provincial councils can be understood better in the context of effective decentralization for community development. In the process of decentralization for community development in Fiji, the Central Government (Ministries and Departments) as well as the local government units, which include the city/town councils and local authorities (in coordination with the central agencies such as the Public Service Commission, Ministry of Finance and Ministry of National Planning) play a pivotal role. Under the Central Government there are divisional commissioners and below that are the district officers. There are two types of officers at this (district) level: one for indigenous Fiji people (called Roko-Tui) and another one (called the district officer) for multi-ethnic people or all other ethnic groups dominated by the Indo-Fijians. Under the district officer (for multi-ethnic people) there is the chairman and District Advisors Council (DAC). The parallel organization for indigenous Fijians is the Mata ni Tikinas. Below this, in parallel to advisors, is the Turaga ni Koros. Turaga is the head of the village. And, there are about eight villages in Mata ni Tikinas. People have village meetings to discuss the needs and projects. Turaga ni Koros then meet with Mata ni Tikinas to discuss the projects. Both parties meet at the district level to decide priorities and the district officer coordinate these meetings. Recent Trends in Rural Development As in many other countries, in Fiji too, rural areas are comparatively underdeveloped and there is a growing tendency for rural-urban migration. The recent population census shows significant trends in rural-urban migration. Government is concerned about this trend, especially because agricultural development is important for the Fijian economy. Consequently, there are rural development efforts to retain the rural dwellers by making rural life more attractive through rural development projects: for the improving of infrastructure, providing domestic water supply, electricity and creating employment opportunities at village level. Increased employment is sought through promoting agriculture, horticulture, fishing, forestry and setting up processing industries. Since 60 percent of the population is in rural sector, the Ministry of Regional Development and Multi-Ethnic Affairs is very instrumental in undertaking development planning, project implementations and resources mobilization. At the community level the local government units i.e., city/town councils, district officers, community workers undertake development projects with the view to improve services and facilities in the various townships at community level of local government, housing and environment and for regional development. Community Participation in Rural Development Rural areas of Fiji are characterized of communal way of life and property ownership system. Typically, rural people are communally arranged and organized and collective and communal efforts are a common feature in the rural life. Based on such a culture, community participation in development has been encouraged in recent years. This is also seen as a means of overcoming the difficulty faced by the government due to its limited resources. Hence, the government gives preference to projects in which the local communities share the cost and undertake the post-project maintenance. Community participation is not limited to

- 142 -

cost sharing. Instead, the local communities are increasingly becoming active partners of rural development projects. For example, the identification of rural development projects comes through a bottom-up approach, which involves the village or settlement committees, district development committees, and finally the divisional development committees which decide on the prioritized projects to be funded. First, the communities are encouraged to identify their projects. The identification of these projects is usually the results of series of systematic discussions. From these discussions, a certain number of project proposals are identified and later prioritized through a process of consensus. In order for this proposal to meet government approval a comprehensive project paper should be submitted to the district officer through the district advisory and Tikina council meetings. Once the district officer approves the allocation of government contribution, this amount is added to the communitys share of contribution and the project begins its implementation process. If skilled manpower is needed, the government is obligated to provide this. The community itself meets all unskilled labor demands. The supporting government ministries and departments are required to provide a close monitoring system on the project, hence play a general monitoring role during the implementation process.

- 143 -

4. INDIA
Dr. R. K. Tripathi

Joint Director (Extension) Directorate of Extension Ministry of Agriculture New Delhi

INTRODUCTION There has been substantial progress towards achieving economic progress in the lowand middle-income countries of the world over the last 50 years. However, the gains have not been shared equally amongst various economic groups within particular nations, the losers being usually the poor in rural areas. Such absolute and relative deprivations, in the face of growth, underline the deficiencies in various approaches towards rural development, including the efforts to improve the conditions of the rural poor. Integrated Rural Development (IRD) as an approach to rural development has been adopted in many developing countries for improving the conditions of the poor by alleviating poverty and improving the quality of life in the rural areas. The concept of IRD, its organization and approach has been undergoing continuous change to meet the emerging demands of the rural poor, concomitant with the political and socio-economic, administrative and physical set-up for its appropriate adoption. It is now being increasingly felt that the goal of growth with social justice can be achieved largely with the active participation of local communities. The Government of India has always been conscious about supporting or involving local people in development efforts. Ever since independence, the Panchayati Raj Institutions (PRIs) were conceived as a local level institution providing for linkages between village, block and the district. However, their growth varied across States, particularly, on account of socio-political reasons. The passage of the Constitution (73rd Amendment) Act 1992 marked a new era in rural development and provided constitutional status to the local bodies (PRIs) in rural areas besides outlining their functional status. Though the 11th schedule to the Constitution of India contains an impressive list of 29 developmental activities, which could be taken up by these local institutions, progress across States in adoption of these activities is at variance. While some of the States have been limiting only to the provision of civic amenities and facilities for elementary education and primary healthcare, others have expanded the horizon of local bodies in the area of land development, agricultural development and irrigation. Major constraints in broad basing the role of PRIs continues to be the condition of local communities in terms of mass poverty; large-scale unemployment; illiteracy; poor health and nutritional status; widening income disparities and low quality of life. Poor linkages between different institutions and communities further add to the slow pace of rural development. LOCAL ADMINISTRATIVE SYSTEMS AT COMMUNITY LEVEL On the basis of the recommendations of Balwantray G. Mehta Committee (1957) a three-tier system of Panchayati Raj was introduced in most of the States in the country in order to entrust community development (CD) programs to self-governing elected bodies.

- 144 -

The Constitution (73rd Amendment) Act 1992 has provided for further streamlining the functioning of the Panchayati Raj system and Constitutional Status to these local level institutions. The three-tier system of Panchayati Raj consists of Zilla Parishads (ZPs) (district council) at district level, Panchayat Samiti (PS) (federation of village assemblies) at intermediate level and Gram Panchayats (GPs) (village assembly) at the grassroots or village level. These PRIs have been vested with powers and responsibilities to undertake various activities to promote IRD. Proportionate participation of different sections of society with adequate provision (one-third) of the seats for women and weaker sections, i.e., scheduled castes and scheduled tribes is also provided. The States have also passed State Panchayati Raj Acts to facilitate the operation of the PRIs as per the States local situations. The organizational structure and management of these local self-governments, therefore, varies greatly from State to State. Though as early as 1962 a number of States had established PRIs, still a lot of variations exist in the provisions under respective State Panchayati Raj Acts. So is the financial position of these units, few of them being resource rich with a lot of say in their developmental planning, while others are still struggling to establish themselves. At present, there are 232,278 GPs, 5906 PSs and 499 ZPs in the country. These PRIs are being managed by about 2.92 million elected representatives at all levels. The Smallest Local Government Unit in India Gram Panchayat is the smallest level of governance in the Panchayati Raj system. Gram Sabha which is the general body of GP ensures community participation in the decision-making process. The local self-governance through PRIs greatly facilitates in microlevel planning by adopting a bottom up procedure. The grassroots level micro plans are developed by GPs through the Gram Sabha, which are later converged at PS and ZP level. The ZPs finally submit the aggregate proposals to District Planning Committee to finalize the District Plan. The State Assembly at State level and Parliament at national level approve the macro level plans at respectively levels developed on the basis of these micro level proposals (Figure 1). National State Parliament State Assembly

District

Zilla Parishad/ Zilla Panchayat

Block

Panchayat Samiti

Village

Gram Panchayat (Gram Sabha)

Ward

Figure 1. Local Governance Hierarchy for Rural Development in India


- 145 -

1. The Average Population Size of Gram Sabha The size of population of Gram Sabha varies across States. In a number of States Gram Sabha have been established in every village serving a population of 1,000 or more. In areas where there are no villages within 3 miles radius of a particular village, a separate Gram Sabha is established for such village even though its population is less than 1,000. If the villages are close by they are combined to form only one Gram Sabha even if population is above 5,000. The Gram Sabhas that cater for population of more than 1,000 are divided into wards. Average number of villages in a GP also varies from State to State, ranging from 1.0 in case of Tripura to 11.5 in case of Orissa and West Bengal. 2. The Basic Organizational Structure The executive bodies of the Gram Sabha constitute the village panchayat. Panchayats are elected by Gram Sabhas consisting of entire adult population of the village. The number of members ranges from 30 to 51. Seats are reserved for minority community and scheduled castes. Seats are also allotted to each constituency in proportion to its population. The relationship between Gram Sabha and the GP is the same as between the legislature and the government. Each GP is headed by a Chairperson (sarpanch/pradhan) and Ward In-charges (ward panchas). In some States there is a position of a Vice Chairperson (up-pradhan/up-sarpanch) also. In so far as the staff to the panchayats is concerned, there is provision of a Secretary in each panchayat or a Group Secretary for a group of panchayats. He also acts as a Secretary to the Gram Sabha responsible for preparing the resolutions of the Gram Sabha and placing the same before the GP meeting for follow-up action. 3. Main Role and Functions of the Panchayats Role and functions are derived from Article 243G of the Constitution which stipulates that the primary role of panchayats is in the area of development and planning, whereas implementation of programs of the economic development and social justice are to be the focal point of all their activities. In light of these stipulations each State has prescribed specific functions to the GPs under the respective State Panchayati Raj Acts. Broadly, the functions discharged by the GPs may be classified into: i. regulatory functions like permission for construction of buildings, directing removal of garbage and prohibiting the use of unhealthy water from well or tanks. ii. administrative functions that include management of panchayat land, maintenance of pastures, maintenance and disposal of abadi land, preparation and maintenance of panchayat records, etc. iii. developmental functions: panchayats are actively involved in a variety of rural development programs/schemes launched by Central/State government and other agencies. iv. agency functions: panchayats also discharge some functions as an agency of the State government and the PS. v. miscellaneous functions: panchayats are also involved in census and other departmental activities as they are nearer to the villages. Developmental Activities Entrusted to the Panchayati Raj Institutions The 11th schedule to the Constitution of India contains an impressive list of 29 developmental activities which cold be entrusted to PRIs (Box 1).

- 146 -

Box 1. 29 Subjects Assigned under the 11th Schedule to the PRIs 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. 7. 8. 9. 10. 11. 12. 13. 14. 15. 16. 17. 18. 19. 20. 21. 22. 23. 24. 25. 26. 27. Agriculture including agricultural extension Land improvements, land reforms, soil conservation Minor irrigation, watershed development Animal husbandry, dairying and poultry Fisheries Social forestry and farm forestry Minor forest produce Small-scale industries including food processing industries Khadi, village and cottage industries Rural housing Drinking water Fuel and fodder Roads, culverts, bridges, ferries and waterways Rural electrification including distribution of electricity Non-conventional energy sources Poverty alleviation programs IRD Program, Jowahar Rozgar Yojana (JRY) Education including primary and secondary schools Technical training and vocational education Adult and non-formal education Libraries Cultural activities Markets and fairs Health and sanitation including primary health centers and dispensaries Family welfare Women and child development Social welfare including welfare of handicapped and mentally retarded Welfare of weaker sections and in particular special castes (SCs) and special tribes (STs) 28. Public distribution system 29. Maintenance of community assets

These activities broadly cover the following: i. ii. iii. iv. Development of natural resources; Development and maintenance of physical infrastructure; Poverty Alleviation Programs (PAPs) initiated towards social justice; and Development of adequate, timely and quality services. The main areas covered under these activities are as follows: i. Programs for Productive Activities agriculture, animal husbandry, poultry, fishery, small-scale industries including food processing, cottage industries, fuel and fodder and irrigation;

- 147 -

ii. Land Development Programs land reforms, soil conservation, minor irrigation, water management and watershed development, wasteland development, social forestry and grazing lands; iii. Education and Cultural Activities primary schools, adult education, technical education and libraries; iv. Social Welfare welfare of the women and child development, family welfare, care of disabled and mentally retarded; v. Provisions of Civic Amenities drinking water, rural electrification, nonconventional sources of energy, rural roads, bridges, culverts, waterways, sanitation, rural housing and health; vi. Poverty Alleviation and Allied Programs for social and economic upliftment of weaker sections; vii. Maintenance of Community assets and public distribution system; and viii. Organization and Control of rural markets and village fairs. Planning for Development by Gram Panchayat The basic objective of the planning at GP is to identify the felt needs and aspirations of the people, which are to be jointly shouldered by the peoples representatives and panchayats. Such process of planning is expected to be useful in identifying the local problems and local resources, ascertaining the growth potential of the panchayats in the light of their resources enabling them not only in choosing schemes from a shelf of projects but properly sequencing the activities in such a way that forward and backward linkages are established. The inputs required for planning are to be collected primarily from the people and by themselves in the Gram Sabha meetings. Decentralized planning process begins at the GP level and all items, which can be taken up by them within jurisdiction, form part of the GP plan. All other items, which cover more than one GP, form part of the plan of the intermediate panchayat. Before finalizing the GP plan resources inventory of the village is also finalized. Sources of Revenue and Budget Every panchayat has a Village Panchayat Fund to which all allotments, general and special contributions and donations from the Central and local governments, municipalities, district boards, etc. are credited. The level of budget of different GPs varies drastically. Though a number of constitutional provisions (Box 2) exist to support these institutions to augment their funds, the financial position is not so good with respect to most of the GPs. This is mainly because of poor revenue collection, inadequacy of trained personnel, diversion of funds and misuse of resources and lack of accountability and transparency. GPs derive their income mainly from the following sources: 1. Taxes Under the provisions of the Indian Constitution as well as respective State Panchayati Raj Acts, GPs may levy taxes such as: house tax, professional tax, vehicle tax, tax on sold-out village produce, pilgrim tax, animal tax, land cess, entertainment tax, cattle tax, taxes on fairs/festivals/agricultural land/transfer of property/commercial crops, sanitary tax, drainage tax, lighting tax, water tax, tax on fisheries, etc. Types of taxes allocated to respective project implementing agencies drastically varies from State to State.

- 148 -

Box 2. Constitutional Position with respect to Resource Mobilization by Gram Panchayats i. According to Article 243H of the Indian Constitution, the State legislatures are empowered to enact laws authorizing the panchayats to levy, collect and appropriate certain specified taxes, duties, tolls and fees. Such levy, collection and appropriation will be in accordance with such procedure and subject to such limits as may be specified by the State legislatures by law. ii. Similarly, under item (ii) of sub-clause (a) of clause (1) of Article 243I of the Indian Constitution, the State Finance Commission is required to make recommendations to the State governor the principles which should govern determination of the taxes, duties, tolls and fees which may be assigned to, or appropriated by, the panchayats. iii. State Panchayati Raj Acts specify the taxes, duties, tolls and fees, which are transferred to the panchayats for their exclusive use. In most of the States, revenueraising powers are granted by the State legislatures mostly to the village-level panchayats. iv. At present, under the State Panchayati Raj Acts of Andhra Pradesh, Assam, Haryana, Himachal Pradesh, Tamil Nadu, Goa, Karnataka, Madhya Pradesh, Maharashtra, Manipur, Gujarat, Kerala, Uttar Pradesh, West Bengal, and Punjab, levy of some taxes and non-taxes by the panchayats has been made compulsory. In other States like Bihar, Rajasthan, and Orissa, exercise of the revenue-raising powers granted to the panchayats is optional.

2. Fees Under Central and State regulations, panchayats have been authorized to charge different types of fees against services extended and also fines and penalties against identified defaults. The fees may include: (a) fee for services, viz. water supply, drainage, street lighting and conservancy; (b) license fee on professional buyers, brokers and commission agents; (c) fee for registration of cattle sold, hides and skins, tea stalls and restaurants, goods on sale in market, new buildings/factories/workshops, cart stand, lodges, for use of common land and community property, fishing and fisheries, etc.; and (d) fines and penalties on encroachment, failure to take license while dealing with prohibited articles. 3. Communal Income These include income from fisheries, fairs and markets, fallen trees, cattle dropping and other rubbish, donation of land, money, shramdaan (voluntary labor), panchayat forests, government or community property. 4. Income from Project Funds Panchayats also receive funds from Central/States and other agencies for implementation of developmental projects/schemes launched by these agencies. 5. Miscellaneous This category of income includes interests and deposits, government assistance, stamp duty, sale of old articles, news papers, rent and product of land, loans and advances and district board contract work.

- 149 -

Resource Mobilization by the Panchayats Contrary to the institutional provisions for a broad range of revenue sources, financial position of the panchayats in most of the States is miserable. This is largely because of inadequate allocation of tax categories to PRIs under the concerned State Acts. The position is further aggravated with respect to GPs because of small size in terms of population and area. Moreover, the GPs are also not able to fully utilize their revenue resources because of absence of suitable guidelines or rules; lack of secretarial and other staff; unwillingness of the elected panchayats in collecting taxes and fees in their locality; unwillingness of people to pay taxes and fees because of poor services in the villages; and inability to pay taxes/fees because of poverty. Linkage of Gram Panchayats with Local Level Organizations and Groups A closer look at village scenario presents a plethora of local level organizations and institutions operating with multiplicity of efforts. Wherever GPs are active they are able to drive in the programs and priorities of these organizations/groups in there micro plans and extend desired support to these bodies. Situation is reverse, where GPs are not so active. With an environment of harmony and cooperation between GPs and different local organizations, the local self-governments could achieve a great deal of development objectives. GPs may collaborate with NGOs in the area of water management, forest management, fisheries development and other categories of income-generating activities. Relevant work done by NGOs in the area of dissemination of latest technology and awareness generation may also be positively utilized by the PRIs. Community-based Organizations (CBOs), cooperatives, private input suppliers, and government departments, all are implementing a large number of programs for rural development. The GPs provide a platform for grassroots level convergence and rationalization of the efforts of these organizations in facilitating a sustained growth and development at rural level. LOCAL LEVEL ORGANIZATIONS AND INSTITUTIONS INVOLVED IN RURAL DEVELOPMENT Local level organizations and institutions relate to those entities working very closely with the communities at locality levels involving a set of villages/communities, a single village/community associated with it or even smaller groups operating below community or village level. Those involved with rural development mainly concern the overall development of rural areas aimed at improving the living conditions of rural populace leading to poverty alleviation at large. While formal institutions are well-structured and established systems operating under set norms/work conditions, organizations are a kind of non-formal institution with a very close proximity and dependence on rural community. These local level organizations need a great deal of capacity-building and community participation to be able to extend the expected contribution in rural development. There is also another group of traditional/ informal village level institutions, which, although underscored, play a great role in rural development. These include a wide range of support services starting from village native doctor to village moneylender. A detailed indicative list of different categories of local level organizations and institutions has been attempted under Table 1.

- 150 -

Table 1. Local Level Organizations and Institutions Involved in IRD in India Organizations Village level traditional support services Village level small business enterprises Service Organizations Voluntary organizations (VOs)/NGOs, foundations, charitable organizations
- 151 -

Money lender, local purohit (priest), local astrologer, These agencies provide vital services for overall native doctor, friends club, beliefs and taboos social development at village level Fertilizer dealer, pesticide dealer, seed supplier, agri- Provide inputs and services clinics, para-techs, agribusiness centers, info-shop

Land for Tillers Freedom (LAFTI) Seva Mandir, Rajasthan

Problems of landless poor Create capacity of rural community to service their own developmental needs Voluntary Technical Corps, Kerala Act as a link between bureaucracy and people NGOs Village micro planning in Kerala Temple Festival Committee Organization of functions and festivals at rural level Center for Appropriate Technology, Kanyakumari Promotion of the application of science and technology for weaker sections Fishermen Sangam, Kanyakumari Render useful services to the fishing in credit, savings, marketing, social aware-ness and welfare Muttom Boat-building Yard, Tamil Nadu programs Introduction of appropriate crafts suited to the local Rural Women Development Society, Kanyakumari situations Devta/Mandir Committee, Kullu, Himachal Pradesh Strive for the overall development of rural women (HP) Maintenance and upkeep of temple premises and organizing religious ceremonies Primary Consumer Cooperatives, Kerala Village Forest Development Society (VFDS), HP Paraur Forest Cooperative Society, Kangra, HP Fishermen/women Cooperative Society (FMCS/FWCS), Tamil Nadu Public distribution Management of forest resources in a village Managing wasteland and forests To improve financial status of fishermen/fisherwomen

Village cooperatives

Table 1. Continuation CBOs Self-help groups (SHGs) Community Development Society (CDS), Kerala Neighborhood groups (NHGs), Kerala Women credit groups Gaon Sudhar Sabha/Village Committee, HP Village Forest Development Committee (VFDC) Village Eco-development Committee (VEDC) Village Development Committee (VDC)
- 152 -

Eradication of poverty through participatory credit and thrift scheme At GP level, formulation of schemes, projects, execution, monitoring and evaluation (M&E) identification of beneficiaries, additional resource mobilization Extending credit facilities to the members Maintenance and upkeep of village Management of forest resources in village Management of forest and resources and forest ecosystem in a village Development and implementation of micro level plans and undertaking entry-point activities Economic empowerment of women For involving youth in developmental activities For thrift and household production activity As a partner in joint forest management project in Tamil Nadu Rejuvenating the agriculture sector by safeguarding interest of farmers and laborers ... To be continued

Self-help groups (SHGs)

Women self-help group Youth groups (Yuvak and Yuvati Mandal) Thrift groups (Department of Women and Children in Rural Areas) Village forest councils Karshaka Sahaya Samiti (KSS) or farmers help group, Kottayam, Kerala

Table 1. Continuation CBOs Interest groups/ commodity groups Arivoli Mahalir Iyakkam (AMI) Beneficiary Committee, Kerala Farmer interest groups/women interest groups User groups Running fair price shop (public distribution system [PDS]) Implementation of public works For management of production, processing, marketing of particular commodity and other income-generating activities Rural community organized in small groups to make use of usufruct or produce generated by assets created under different programs through community participation Community management of water resources Facilitation of different agricultural operations Fix labor rates for different farm operations in consultation with farmers association Body of all the villages covered under a watershed responsible for approval of watershed plans and supervision of the execution of planned activities Safeguarding the rights of fish-workers Facilitates formation of women SHGs and supports women participation in rural activities ... To be continued

Associations Associations
- 153 -

Water User Associations Farmers Associations Agriculture Labor Association Watershed Associations (WAs) Tamil Nadu Fish-workers Union

Federations

Mahila Mandals

Table 1. Continuation Institutions Local self-government PRIs GP, Gram Sansad Ward Development Committee (WDC) Nyaya Panchayat Local self-government PRIs PS Community Maternity Center, Madhya Pradesh (MP) Local administration Block and village level government functionaries Banking sector Representatives of district level line department, village extension worker, village level worker, secretary to GP, agriculture assistant, veterinary assistant, village revenue worker (patwari), secretary, village level cooperative society Regional rural banks Assistant Director of Fisheries Office (ADFO), Kanyakumari Initiating the process of village level micro planning, implementation and monitoring of services Selection of beneficiaries of GPs Settlement of disputes at local government level A block level PRI for management of rural development Facilitating safe deliveries at village level Agricultural development effort for villages under a block

- 154 -

Institutional credit to rural community for development work Fisheries sector Controls the activities of fishermen/fisher-women cooperative societies and funding for fishermen welfare scheme in Tamil Nadu State Health sector Primary health centers (PHCs), community health Health and family welfare services at village level center (CHC) Training institutions Extension training center (ETC) Imparting training to members of the GPs and other local level institutions Source: National Institute of Rural Development (NIRD), 2001.

Major Local Level Organizations and Institutions The list presented in Table 1 is indicative, as the total number would be quite large, because of the size and diversity of the country. Many new institutions emerge; however, only few of them sustain and are able to contribute towards the cause of rural development. Majority of local level non-formal organization fail mainly because they lack clarity in their objectives, lack a balanced organizational structure with poor participation of communities and little or no linkage with other local institutions. Few of the local level institutions /organizations which have made visible impact on the rural development process have been elaborated in the following discussions. Non-governmental Organizations NGOs and voluntary action have been a part of historical legacy in India. Though initially operating on a limited area of charitable, social work, these organizations have assumed central place in development process during recent years because of their effective contribution in delivery of services to people, community mobilization and capacity-building of other grassroots level organizations. NGOs have found a place in governmental planning from the 8th Five-Year Plan (1992-97) onwards. The NGOs are registered institutions functioning with missionary approach and focusing on core developmental activities particularly, in agriculture and rural development. The member composition of NGOs is largely as per stipulations of the State Societies Registration Acts. They operate in a limited geographical area and usually in a limited number of fields because of paucity of staff and fund limitations. The most significant contribution of these agencies has been in the area of peoples mobilizations for education (extensive literacy), efficient land use, minor irrigation, watershed management, etc. There are a number of good NGOs functioning in different parts of the country viz. Sudguru Water Development Foundation, Dahod (Gujarat); OUTREACH, Bangalore; MYRADA, Bangalore; Seva Mandir, Udaipur, Rajasthan; Rama Krishna Mission, West Bengal. Rural Cooperatives The Indian cooperative movement is one of the biggest in the world consisting of around 488,158 cooperatives all over the country. The emergence of cooperative movement has also been almost parallel to the panchayati raj movement in the country. It was largely with the resolution of National Development Council during 1958 emphasizing the need for cooperative policy for India, which led to formal beginning of cooperative programs in the country. The Third Five Year Plan (1961-66) also identified the cooperatives and the PRIs as primary agencies for carrying out CD programs. The membership structure of the cooperatives is governed by the respective cooperative rules of the States. While the local level cooperative society in most of the States are headed by a Secretary deputed by the government the cooperatives in Gujarat and Maharashtra operate under the guidance and administration of a general body of members or elected Board of Directors. The primary functions of the village cooperative are the provision of short- and medium-term credit, supply of inputs for agriculture and allied sector, as well as marketing of agricultural produce. The cooperatives have a vast rural network covering majority of the villages in respect of dairy milk supply. However, the habit of thrift and saving has been the essential objectives of the cooperatives. The Primary Agricultural Cooperative Society (PACS) is the lowest level of credit facility provider to the farmers at the village level.

- 155 -

A comparative study of cooperatives in different State shows that in Maharashtra and Gujarat cooperatives have been doing exceptionally well in the area of sugar cooperatives and dairy cooperatives, respectively. The Anand model of dairy cooperatives in Gujarat has been recommended by a number of international organizations as a replicable model for other developing countries. Self-help Groups The emergence of SHGs in the country has been a recent development with the felt need for participatory approach in rural development. There has been growing realization that top-down, inter-personal mode of support during Green Revolution benefitted only the resource-rich and large farmers. The reducing base of the governmental institutions has further justified the need for a group approach in development with the members helping each other as a self-help group. The SHGs are informal institutions and can decide their own membership and the terms and conditions for their working. All the members of the SHGs contribute to group fund were as the matching financial assistance comes through government development programs. The fund collected is rotated as credit amongst group members for their development needs. The SHGs also establish linkages with different financing and developmental institutions and play a great role in creating a culture of selfsustenance amongst the rural communities. The different government programs under which SHGs have been formed include Watershed Development Programs, Agricultural Development Schemes, and National Watershed Development Program for Rainfed Areas (NWDPRA), Employment Schemes, etc. SHGs have been functioning very effectively in the area of brick making, labor works, household industries, fisheries, sheep farming, poultry farming, silk reeling, collection of minor forest produce, women credit and thrift mobilization, etc. Interest Groups/Commodity Groups/Activity Groups The interest groups/commodity groups have also emerged as a major partner in rural development. These are non-formal group of rural people organized together to manage the production and disposal of a particular commodity (both agricultural and allied) or activity. Farmer interest groups (FIGs)/commodity groups are informal institutions with membership of these groups ranging from 7 to 25-30. Different functions in the group are performed by an informal distribution of work, whereas leader of the group is elected by mutual consensus. Though originally these groups are non-formal at a later stage they may be registered as a society under the concerned State regulation. Under the innovations in technology dissemination (ITD) component of the World Bank-funded National Agricultural Technology Project (NATP), being implemented in selected States since November 1998. Interest groups/commodity groups have been the main focus for development. A large number of FIGs, women interest groups (WIGs) have been formed and supported to manage the production and disposal of different commodities. The district level Agricultural Technology Management Agency (ATMA) created under the project is engaged in facilitating the formation of these groups. The ATMA also extends needed support to the FIGs/WIGs in the form of technical assistance, capacity-building, linking with the credit institutions or providing revolving funds with an aim to develop these units into sustainable micro enterprises. These village groups are being federated at block level institutions like Farm Information and Advising Centers (FIACs) and further into ATMA Governing Board membership. The objective is to provide the local communities a

- 156 -

role space in decision-making and strategic planning of grassroots level agricultural development priorities. User Groups The concept of user group has been initiated under the centrally sponsored Watershed Development Program. Under this program, groups of rural community are organized around farmers farm activities like field crops, water-harvesting structures, pasture plots (sheep growers groups), etc. The main objective of these user groups is to pool their resources and efforts to create assets and then the usufruct or produce generated by these efforts are used by the group. The user group members are essentially land owners and contribute their share of cost in creating field assets like conservation structures (bunds), check dams, farm ponds, etc. The basic idea behind the user groups is with the sharing of cost of construction. The joint efforts made in the process lead to a greater degree of participation of community in planning and implementation of the activity proposed. Sharing of cost also leads to a sense of ownership in the assets leading to its proper maintenance by the community and rational utilization of usufruct by them. Farmer Associations/Federations These are larger groups of rural community involved either with the linkage and convergence of smaller groups engaged in similar activities or, taking up management/ coordination of activities being undertaken by smaller groups. Their area of operation is not limited to panchayat. Successful examples of farmer associations/federations are Water User Associations (WUAs), WAs, Mahila Mandals, Commodity Associations/Federations and the larger political lobbies of farmers. Details of few of them are illustrated below: 1. Water User Association The concept of WUAs has emerged from developments in the area of Participatory Irrigation Management (PIM) involving farmers as a major stakeholder all over the world. PIM through WUAs began in India since mid eighties with the starting of Command Area Development Program. National Water Policy 1987 had further underlined the need for progressive participation of farmers in irrigation management. However, water being a State subject PIM has been progressing in varying degrees across the States. There are a large number of successful examples of WUA in the State of Andhra Pradesh. A WUA is a registered organization with a formal structure. It has a General Body consisting of all the shareholders involving different category of farmers, the number may go beyond 180 in some cases. Area of operation is not limited to a single village. The Managing Committee consists of President, Secretary, Treasurer and farm executive members. Public Works Department is managing very big tanks and other sources of irrigation, whereas medium and smaller tanks are handed over to local bodies (GPs). Management of these irrigation services is transferred over to the WUAs, who maintain all the records, pursue a transparent administration and take up the activities like cleaning of channels, de-silting the tanks and ponds, growing plants on the banks and bunds of the lakes and tanks, fish cultivation in the tanks and ponds, etc. Each shareholder under the WUAs willingly contributes a mutually agreed share of amount based on acreage. Matching grant is released by the government, which is deposited in the fixed deposit in a bank. The interest accrued is used for maintenance of the structure in future. The government provides the constructed field channels.

- 157 -

2. Watershed Associations This is another form of participatory management, which has emerged concurrently with the WUAs and the centrally sponsored Watershed Development Program. WA is an agency comprising of all the villagers in watershed area. An executive arm of association, the Watershed Committee is also created which is responsible for executing different tasks assigned to WUAs as reporting to the association about the progress and problems in managing and execution of works. The WAs are responsible for approval of watershed plans and supervision of the execution of plan activities. They are also ensuring collection of contributions, check measurement of works, payment of wages, sharing of usufructs, formation of peoples groups, etc. 3. Federation of Womens Groups Federation of womens groups into larger organizations has greatly contributed to rural development through empowerment of women. The classical example of such a federation is Mahila Gramin Bank in Andhra Pradesh, which has emerged after federating a large number of credit and thrift groups operating at grassroots level. The Mahila Mandals in Himanchal Pradesh have been actively involved in formation of active SHGs of women under different schemes. The ITD component of NATP has also been promoting federation of women group involved in different enterprises viz. production, processing and marketing of produce from agriculture and allied sectors at block level and above. The federation in such situations plays the role of a coordinator, facilitator and capacity builder for the connected groups. Panchayat Samiti The historical background of three-tier system of PRIs and details of smallest level of PRIs, the GP has been elaborated in the previous section. PS is the block level/intermediate level PRI playing a key role in linking the village panchayats with the district level bodies. The 73rd Constitutional Amendment provides that the Chairpersons of all the GPs covered under a block could be the members of PS. In turn, Chairmen of these intermediate panchayats could be members of the district panchayat (ZP). The Members of Parliament (MPs), Members of Legislative Assemblies (MLAs) can also be members of PS or ZP. The Chairperson of PS is assisted by a Chief Executive called Block Development Officer (BDO) and has supports of Sub-divisional Inspectors, junior engineers and accounts and ministerial staff. In most of the States, unit of planning is PS and ZP acts as a coordinating/supervisory body. The PSs act as the nodal agency/in-charge for implementing the rural development works assigned to PRIs, funding to GPs, guiding them, supervising and monitoring their work. Nyaya Panchayats The Panchayat Committee of the Local Self-government Ministers Conference 1954 recommended the formulation of a Nyaya Panchayat (NP) for the area comprising 4-5 GPs. Each GP elects five persons to be nominated to NP and all the members on the NP are subdivided into five groups, one of them, functioning as a Panchayat Court administering judicial function alternately. They further recommended that more powers in terms of criminal and civil limits could be delegated to NPs provided the parties agreed to refer their cases for arbitration to such courts. NPs are functioning in all States except Assam, Andhra Pradesh, Tamil Nadu, and parts of Karnataka, Kerala, West Bengal and Nagaland.

- 158 -

Formal Institutions At village level, all departments and institutions do not necessarily have in position the required functionaries to implement the schemes and programs in agricultural/rural development. However, a few departments/agencies do have village level functionaries viz., village extension worker, village level worker (Gram Sevak), Secretary to GP, agricultural assistant, veterinary assistant, village revenue worker (Patwari), Secretary of village level cooperative societies, etc. SALIENT FEATURES OF INTEGRATED RURAL DEVELOPMENT IN INDIA ROLE OF LOCAL COMMUNITIES AND INSTITUTIONS The concept of IRD has had its main thrust on maximization of human welfare in rural areas through achieving a balance between economic growth and social justice. However, inadequacy of resources amongst rural communities because of poverty, unemployment and inequality has been the main concern of all the IRD efforts. It is therefore important to look at the historical developments in order to understand the IRD approaches and strategies initiated to address these issues. A comprehensive approach to rural development was introduced through CD programs launched in the early 1950s, when the concept of development block was brought in. This followed the emergence of PRIs during the late 1950s, which set the tone for rural development through community participation. During 1960-61 Increased Agricultural District Program (IADP) was initiated followed by Intensive Agriculture Area Program (IAAP) in 1964. These schemes propagated improved farm practices and services, which helped to Green Revolution. Because the small and marginal farmers were not able to gain much from the achievements of Green Revolution, the Small Farmers Development Agencies (SFDA) program launched during 1970 had main focus on small and marginal farmers and agricultural laborers. Food for Work program of 1977 and National Rural Employment Program in 1980 again had major initiative towards improving the quality of life in rural areas, by providing income and employment to rural poor. However, the rural poor were still deprived of significant gains because of lack of productive assets and resources needed to generate income. During 1978-79, the IRD program was launched as a major initiative towards addressing these shortcomings. A brief review of the programs launched over the last 50 years has bee attempted in Table 2. Table 2. Integrated Rural Development Strategies in India after Independence Thrust Areas Programs and Activities Institutional reforms Community development (CD) Land reforms Cooperatives PRIs Strengthening of District Rural Development Agencies (DRDAs) (1999) Council for Advancement of Peoples Action and Rural Technology (CAPART) (1986) ... To be continued

- 159 -

Table 2. Continuation Thrust Areas Infrastructure development Resource Deficient Area Program Poverty Alleviation Program

Programs and Activities Minimum Needs Program (MNP) (1974) Basic Minimum Service Program (BMSP) (1996) Drought-prone Area Program (DPAP) (1973) Desert Development Program (DDP) (1978) Integrated Watersheds Development Program (IWDP) (1989-90) Self-employment SFDA (1970-71) Marginal Farmers and Agricultural Laborers Projects (MFAL) (1970-71) IRD Program (1978) Training of Rural Youth for Self-employment (TRYSEM) (1979-80) Development of Women and Children in Rural Areas (DWACRA) (1982-83) Swarnajayanti Gram Swarojgar Yojana (SGSY) (1999) Wage Employment Rural Work Program (RWP) (1970-71) Food for Work (FFW) Scheme (1977-78) Rural Labor Employment Guarantee Program (RLEGP) (1983-84) Employment Assurance Scheme (EAS) (1993-March 2002) Jawahar Gram Samridhi Yojana (1999-March 2002) Pradhan Mantri Gram Sadak Yojana (PMGSY) (2000) Food for Work Program (FFWP) (2001-March 2002) Sampoorna Grameen Rojgar Yojana (SGRY) (2001) Rural Housing Indira Awaas Yojana (IAY) (1985) Samagra Awaas Yojana (SAY) (1999) Pradhan Mantri Gramodaya Yojana (PMGY) (2000) Social Assistance National Social Assistance Program (NSAP) (1995) Annapurna (2000)

Empowerment

Source: Note:

SGSY, JGSY, IAY, NSAP, restructured Centrally-sponsored Rural Sanitation Program (CRSP) (1999) Accelerated Rural Water Supply Program (ARWSP) Credit and thrift groups DWACRA Voluntary action Ministry of Rural Development, 2002. Years in parenthesis are the years of introduction of the program concerned.

- 160 -

Integrated Rural Development in India Current Scenario with respect to Role of Local Level Institutions and Organizations If we look at the historical development and details of programs and activities mentioned in Table 2, it is clear that the poverty alleviation and mitigation of structural inequalities has been the major thrust of IRD strategies in the country. Efforts made so far have created significant impact, however there are still 27 percent of rural poor subsisting in poverty and larger area still deficient in basic facilities needed for improving living conditions in rural India. Since, the beginning of rural development efforts it has been revealed that budgetary support alone cannot solve the problems, unless different concerned agencies and the community at large are involved in the process. A closer review of strategies adopted (Table 2) reveals that the major thrust has been to link the programs/ activities and the local level organizations, institutions and communities in a synergistic manner directed towards rural development. Institutional Reforms Creation of institutional arrangements, which facilitate effective implementation of IRD efforts, has been a priority initiative since the beginning of five-year plans in the country. It has been envisaged that institutions should be able to: a) b) c) improve local opportunities for enterprise, employment and resource generation; help communities attain greater self reliance in the provision of basic needs and services; and help communities attain self-generated and self-sustained economic and social development.

The institutional mechanisms created for management of IRD over different phases of time have been directing towards the above strategies. While, the initial CD program emphasized involvement of local communities in all kinds of rural development activities, cooperatives have emerged as a strong institutional mechanism, which facilitated socioeconomic transformation of rural India. Based on the past experiences, the 73rd Amendment has presented the PRIs as the core local governance mechanisms with a great deal of powers and responsibilities to implement IRD programs at grassroots level. In the process, the role of local communities has greatly shifted from that of a selfservice mode to an initiator, planner, implementer, regulator and a promoter. The GPs at grassroots level are capable of establishing close linkages with various formal institutions (for government support), NGOs (for capacity-building, program implementation) and CBOs (for program implementation). Institutions like DRDAs closely coordinate with PRIs to effectively manage the PAPs. CAPART is also an institution created to promote voluntary action and propagate appropriate rural technologies for the benefit of rural community. Land reforms have been considered as one of the initial measures for alleviation of rural poverty as these activities addresses the structural parameters of the rural economy, which generate the structural imbalances leading to rural poverty. Though land is a State subject, it has been on the national agenda since independence. The main objective of land reforms has been to achieve an egalitarian social structure which could eliminate the exploitation in land relations, realize the age-old goal of land to tiller, enlarge the land base of rural poor, increase agricultural productivity and infuse an element of equality in local communities. The centrally-sponsored scheme on Computerization of Land Records (CLR)

- 161 -

(1988) has been able to bring in an element of transparency and effectiveness in land resource management at rural level. Infrastructure Development Programs Rural poors lack of access to basic infrastructure facilities including health; education, food, water supply, etc. have been the greatest constraint in achieving desired results of rural development strategies. MNP (1974) was launched to improve the availability of essential needs viz. food, housing, water, etc. for the poor sections. While PDS was one of the major components of MNP, BMSP (1996) had the main objective of strengthening social infrastructure in rural areas. Both these programs directly targeted the local communities through closer linkages with various institutions, voluntary organizations involved in infrastructure augmentation. Resources Deficient Area Programs A large area of the country in semiarid zone suffers periodic drought situations because of massive soil degradation and water loss, severely affecting the rural poor. DPAP (1973) has been launched to minimize the adverse effects of drought on the production of crops and livestock and productivity of land, water and human resources thereby leading to droughtproofing of affected areas. A similar program DDP (1978) has been initiated to address the ecological balance of hot desert areas of Rajasthan, Haryana and Gujarat, cold desert of Jammu and Kashmir and Himanchal Pradesh, in addition to few district of Andhra Pradesh and Karnataka. These programs have a direct participation of local communities in planning and development of watershed areas and maintenance of assets. PRIs at all the three levels have been authorized to monitor and review the program and also to involve in direct implementation. NGOs play a major role in community motivation, organization and training. The ZP/DRDA may also select the NGOs as a project implementation agency for the watershed development projects. Poverty Alleviation Programs Poverty alleviation has been the main focus of IRD strategies achieved through different mechanisms. One of the direct means of poverty alleviation is through assured employment, apart from providing shelter (housing) and social assistance to weaker/underprivileged section of rural community. A large array of Self-employment generating programs have been launched beginning from SFDA (1970-71). The current program, SGSY (1999) has been initiated after review and restructuring the IRDP, TRYSEM and DWACRA. SGSY is the holistic program of selfemployment for rural poor covering organization of SHGs, their capacity-building, training, planning of activity clusters, infrastructure build-up, technology and marketing support. This program requires massive interaction between different stakeholders (including PRIs, banks, line departments, NGOs, etc.) for project monitoring and implementation. NGOs are principally involved in formation of SHGs, their capacity-building, credit facilitations and monitoring. Wage-employment activities have been initiated to help the poor in rural areas as a means of livelihood even during lien period when there is no production. A number of programs, RWP, FFW, RLEGP were initiated after 1970-71 but were closed in due course of time. The ongoing SGRY program (2001) has also been initiated after merging two programs, namely; EAS (1993) and JGSY (1999). Main objective of the scheme is to create

- 162 -

additional wage employment and the creation of need-based rural infrastructure. PRIs are closely involved in implementation of this scheme, ZPs and PSs implement the wage employment component and GPs are involved in creation of infrastructure apart from social audit and monitoring. Another scheme of wage employment, PMGSY (2000) has been initiated recently which aims at providing connectivity through good all weather roads to connected habitations in rural areas with a population of more than 500 in plains and 250 in hill States. Rural housing is a sector, which did not receive the deserving attention, till 1985 when the IAY was launched, which has well integrated community participation mechanism. The scheme provides assistance to Below Poverty Line (BPL) families for construction/upgrading of houses. Gram Sabha is empowered to select beneficiaries. Allotment is in the name of female member (or joint name in the household) and construction is the responsibly of beneficiary. Under PMGY, central assistance is allocated to concerned States/Union Territories (UTs), for providing/improving the outlay of BMSs including rural shelter in rural areas. SAY (1999) on the other hand is a comprehensive housing scheme aimed at ensuring integrated provision of shelter, sanitation and drinking water in selected villages. It involves beneficiary contribution of 10 percent in implementing the programs. Social assistance schemes are aimed at providing social security in case of old age, death of primary breadwinner and maternity. Under NSAP (1995), financial assistance is provided to these categories and the GPs are expected to play an active role in identification of beneficiaries. Disbursement is also held in public meeting such as Gram Sabha, GP is responsible for publicity. Another scheme for social security, Annapurna (2000) has also similar social objectives as that of NSAP. However, support is provided in the form of free food grains to the beneficiaries. GPs play a similar role as in NSAP, in addition to distributing entitlement cards to the beneficiaries. Empowerment In spite of playing a major role in rural development, women continue to be greatly cornered in most of assistance programs. To ensure that women get their share of benefits and opportunities, each scheme has been provided with women component. Particularly, SGSY provides for 50 percent SHGs exclusively of women; under JGSY, 30 percent employment opportunities are reserved for women; IAY houses are allotted in the name of women member or in joint name of household; NSAP has a major focus on women; CRSP provides construction of village sanitary complexes exclusively for women are an active partner in ARWSP; DWACRA (now merged with SGSY) had primary thrust on women. Credit and thrift groups of women supported under various schemes have greatly contributed to their empowerment. In States like Andhra Pradesh, these credit and thrift groups have emerged as a powerful organization by federating together and operating community controlled rural banks with a large membership. FUTURE DIRECTIONS OF THE IRD EFFORTS: ROLE OF COMMUNITIES AND INSTITUTIONS For many developing economies, IRD need to be revolved around: i) agricultural growth; ii) growth of rural non-farm sector; and iii) human development, population growth and rural poverty alleviation. With time, thrust of IRD efforts has also been undergoing drastic changes. Agriculture, the backbone of Indian economy, received the desired attention

- 163 -

from the Third Five-Year plan, but in the subsequent plans removal of poverty became the central concern. This was, possibly, because of the failure of agricultural growth in making a sizeable impact on rural poverty. As a consequence, the tendency to view agricultural development programs as different from those of poverty alleviation and vice versa became quite pronounced. Various PAPs also did not bring the desired impact because of failure of PAPs to integrate with the overall development strategies. Policy Initiatives In wake of globalization, economic recession and pressing demand for decentralization, IRD efforts for the future would need to focus more on bringing in linkages, integration, market orientation and empowerment of local communities in driving the vehicle of rural development. The path for development will have to be based on the growth of agriculture and allied sector, that too on small and marginal farmers in backward and dry regions. Increased investment in the upgrading of employment centered and eco-friendly agricultural technologies with adequate focus on technology generation and dissemination, irrigation and water management in irrigated areas, water use efficiency and on-farm water management in rainfed areas would need to be given due priority. Greater involvement of community groups, viz. WUGs, WUAs and WAS would act as a catalyst in the process. Development of rural infrastructure and promotion of non-farm sector in rural areas facilitates greater adoption of new technologies and an equitable growth of rural sector. This would also call for greater investment in infrastructure, roads, storage, market, education, health and women empowerment. Land reforms would require to be given due emphasis not only for equity but also for higher production. There is a need to keep a rationale between export-oriented agricultural growth and food security for rural poor. Efforts towards diversification, value addition, post-harvest processing and marketing would need to address the needs of small and marginal farmers. Increased focus on a farming systems approach would be desired step. In view of funding constraints with the governments, increased private sector investment in agriculture has to be encouraged. However private sector would not be inclined unless public investment in infrastructure and human resource development is stepped up. Public sector capacity towards such investments could be augmented by reducing subsidies in irrigation, electricity and other inputs through appropriate reforms in management of these services. While sustainable agricultural growth would continue to make a positive contribution towards rural development, non-farm opportunities would need to be enhanced to create greater employment opportunities for the rural poor. This would necessitate massive investment in PAPs to achieve high level of social development and human resource development (HRD) through better living conditions in the rural areas. Unless local communities and grassroots level institutions are deeply involved in these efforts, removal of poverty would continue to remain a dream. Role of Local Communities and Institutions With shrinking resource base, increasing burden of manpower in the wake of vast regional disparities, government would no longer be able to drive the vehicle of rural development alone, with desired pace. Sustenance of rural development would, thus, call for large-scale mobilization of local communities, institutions and all those stakeholders who matter for growth in rural economy.

- 164 -

Emergence of PRIs as an effective system of local governance, subsequent to 73rd Constitutional Amendment has created a well-structured system for peoples participation in the development process. Following steps would be urgently needed to harness the great potential of people for well-being of the people: i. A plethora of programs are being implemented by a large number of institutions in the villages. Because of this multiplicity of uncoordinated institutional efforts growth is adversely affected. There is a need for creating an appropriate institutional arrangement at village level where all the programs and activities are directed towards rural development converge. All the stakeholders including institutions, community organizations and the local communities would become a partner in micro level planning at GP level and all the program funds would be directed towards the panchayat level plan leading to greater ownership and integration of efforts. The ATMAs established under NATP at district level have created block level institutional arrangements in the form of a FIAC involving both a farmers body and technical officials body for micro level planning. The grassroots level institutions like GPs may be linked with FIACs to channel multi-agency efforts in agriculture and allied sectors. It is important that an enabling environment is created so that PRIs, other CBOs and institutions work in a symbiotic relationship rather than competing or conflicting interest groups. ii. Though a large number of programs and activities have been launched by various ministries/institutions, majority of people are not aware of them and hence deprived of the benefits. Massive awareness campaign would need to be organized about ongoing programs and activities at grassroots level. Use of modern communication tools involving print media, as well as electronic media would greatly enhance the efficacy of such measures. Information technology in particular, is emerging as a powerful tool of dissemination of knowledge. Its application needs to be promoted for creating a knowledge-base for rural technology. iii. As majority of PRI leadership is from weaker sections with inadequate education and managerial capacity, it is important to take up capacity-building of these representations towards management skills in rural development programs, knowledge of development strategies and financing with emphasis on management tools, viz. leadership styles, group dynamics and team work. An attitudinal orientation would need to inculcate, in the panchayat in-charges, an understanding that the development strategy has to focus not only on infrastructure creation but also largely on human development irrespective of class, caste and gender. iv. Local level institutions, particularly PRIs are going to drive the rural development process in the future. But unless they emerge as a sustainable entity, it will take too long to achieve the desired progress. Genuine decentralization through adequate devolution of power and resources to PRIs is an essential prerequisite. v. In order to achieve financial sustainability, it is also important that GPs look into means of revenue through taxes, fees, rents, and tolls and even by owning and or leasing common property resources in a cost-sharing mechanism. Increased initiatives of the government to route all the development programs in a village through GPs would greatly help in expanding their resource base. vi. Involvement of GPs in reorientation of rural markets to respond to the needs of local communities would greatly help in putting a check on exploitative practices. Greater

- 165 -

group mobilization of the local communities in income-generating activities and management of rural resources would need to be strongly supported by these local governments. A close monitoring and capacity-building of these groups would be prime responsibility of the GPs. A systematic federation of various community groups to the levels of local governance would help in ensuring accountability and transparency. Apart from increased involvement of CBOs and NGOs, private sector partnership may also be initiated by GPs for rural development but with due care to safe guard the interests of the rural poor. Success of development efforts would also depend on the transparency and accountability of political and administrative systems with a strong civil society represented at different levels of governance through strong local institutions and organizations. Moreover, for the development strategies to achieve the desired level of success, upgrading of human resources would be required on a long-term basis. There is no alternative to prosperity except through a knowledge-based society. REFERENCES Choudhury, R. C. and S. Rajakutty, 2000. Rural Development Charging Focus of Strategy, The Survey of Indian Agriculture 2000, pp.213-215, the Hindu, Chennai. Ekka, Alexius, 1999. Country paper in Dr. Prachanda Pradhan (ed.) Role of Institutions in Rural Community Development, pp.154-167, APO, Tokyo. Erskine, John, 1997. Sustainability Measures for Natural Resources in Ganesh Shivakoti, et al. (eds.) People and Participation in Sustainable Development, Bloomington, Indiana. Hanumantha Rao, C. H., 2001. Changing Economic Structure of the Rural Economy in Asia and the Pacific in Dr. C. H. Hanumantha Rao (ed), Rural Transformation in Asia and the Pacific, pp.66-80, APO, Tokyo. Hanumantha Rao, K., 1999. Country paper in Dr. Buddhadsa Hewavitharana (ed.) Rural Poverty Alleviation in Asia and the Pacific, pp.179-191, APO, Tokyo. Mamoria, C. B., B. B. Tripathi, 1999. Agricultural Problems of India, Kitab Mahal, pp.1950, Allahabad, India. Ministry of Rural Development, 2001. Annual Report 2000-2001, Government of India, New Delhi. ----------, 2002. Annual Report 2001-2002, Government of India, New Delhi. National Institute of Agricultural Extension Management (MANAGE), 1999. MANAGENATP Series 2, pp.1-46, Agricultural Technology Management Agency (ATMA), Hyderabad.

- 166 -

National Institute of Rural Development (NIRD), 2001. S. P. Jain (ed) Emerging Institutions for Decentralized Rural Development, Vol. I and II, pp. 1-982. Pradhan, Prachanda, 1999. Role of Institutions in Rural Community Development in Dr. Prachanda Pradhan (ed), Role of Institutions in Rural Community Development, pp.2749, APO, Tokyo. Sandhu, Rajwant, 2001. Country paper in Dr. C. H. Hanumantha Rao (ed), Rural Transformation in Asia and the Pacific, pp.151-158, APO, Tokyo. Sharma, P. N., 2000. Local Community and the Market Indian Case Study in Dr. D. A. Cruz (ed), Local Social Development, pp.42-64, APO, Tokyo. Taha, M., Om Prakash, 1989. Integrated Rural Development in India, Center for Integrated Rural Development for Asia and the Pacific, Dhaka.

- 167 -

5. ISLAMIC REPUBLIC OF IRAN (1)


Dr. Hassan Hashemi Daran
Research Expert Institute for Planning and Agricultural Economics Ministry of Jihad for Agriculture Tehran

INTRODUCTION Well-planned programs would eliminate ignorance and poverty and help improve health, housing and other socioeconomic aspects. This paper attempts to examine the advancements in rural development and the role of institutions and local communities in integrated rural development in Iran. With a total population about 65 millions, Iran is a populous country in the world with an average density of 35.3 persons/km2. Nearly 35.3 million (58 percent of total population) live in urban areas and about 25.3 million (41 percent) in rural areas. The country extends over an area of l,648 thousand km2 (16th largest country in the world). In general, Iran is mountainous and semiarid country and only about 51 million ha (31 percent of the total land) has satisfactory potentials for agricultural uses. However, 33 million ha (62 percent) of arable land have not yet been brought under cultivation. And, out of the 18.8 million ha currently allocated to agricultural production, only 50-60 percent is being utilized annually. The irrigated farmland is about 30 percent. The agriculture sector in Iran consists of four subsectors; farming, livestock, forestry and fisheries. The farming sub-sector with a 57-percent share in total value-added in agriculture is the largest. The land use pattern is summarized in Table 1. Table 1. Land Use in The Islamic Republic of Iran (total area 165 million ha) (Unit: Percent) Agricultural Desert and Rangelands and Forests Mountainous Cities Land Degraded Land Marginal Land Scrub Land 11 29 21 Source: Ministry of Agriculture, 1996. 2 30 7

The agriculture sector has a prominent place in social and economic development in Iran. It accounts for 27 percent of GDP, 23.8 percent of employment opportunities, 82 percent of food supply and 35 percent of non-oil exports, plus considerable raw materials for industrial use. In this country, almost every rural village needs credit, clean seeds, infrastructure and guidance in crops and livestock production. They also need farm machinery, marketing facilities, cooperatives, water supplies and education both fundamental and vocational. For rapid and efficient rural development, each village must be provided with all of these inputs

- 168 -

and functions. Integration of these functions and efficient management demand an active role of local communities and institutions to the highest degree. The governmental and private programs for rural improvement are being launched in Iran and they depend on local communities for their implementation. The emerging methodologies for community development assume that social improvements do not occur until the local communities actively involve and believe that development is possible. Community people themselves must be sufficiently convinced to take the initiative and the local communities, institutions and people must feel a sense of ownership. Community development is a social process by which human beings can become more competent to live with and gain some control over local aspects. It should comprise of group methods and help in the growth of personality as well. Such a process could occur when neighbors work together to serve themselves. It involves cooperative and group thinking and decisions, collective action and joint evaluation. LOCAL GOVERNANCE SYSTEM IN IRAN Iranian civilization had never been limited to cities. Settled and nomadic villages have always contributed significantly to the cultural characteristics of the country. According to the Constitution of the Islamic Republic of Iran, all branches of the governing bodies, executive and legislative are responsible for implementing development programs. For administrative purposes the country is divided into 29 provinces 252 districts, 680 subdistricts, 624 cities and about 70,000 settlements and villages. Divisions of administration system in Iran are as follows: 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. Total population of Iran: 65 million Province (ostan): 29 (each with an average population of three million) District (shares stan): 252 (average population: 258,000) Sub-district (bakhsh): 680 (average population: 40,000) Village settlement (dehe stan): 1,400 (average population: 17,000) Abadi: About 70,000. PROCESS OF RURAL DEVELOPMENT IN IRAN The objective of the governments rural development program is to address the ruralurban drift. Irans population has gone up rapidly and most of the increase has been in urban areas. The First National Development Plan was launched in 1948. This seven-year plan was basically focused on the production and export. There was no direct emphasis on rural areas or societies. Instead, the main goals of rural development had been expected to achieve through agricultural development. The Second National Development Plan was prepared in 1955 for another period of seven years. That plan too, did not have significant goals and policies for rural development. Again, the goals of rural development had been considered within the agriculture sector. Despite the fact that it lacked significant goals and polices for rural development, specific legislature had been introduced to improve social affairs and to rehabilitate rural villages. The following priorities were assigned for services in the rural areas:

- 169 -

i. Provision of clean water, road development, establishment of schools and public baths. ii. Efforts against herb pests. iii. Installing a Rural Cooperative Fund. iv. Installing electric power stations in rural areas. These goals and efforts could be considered as a good experience in rural development for the system centralized planning. The Third National Development Plan was launched between 1963-66. An important step in the development of rural society of Iran had taken place during the implementation of this plan; namely, the land reform. This reform was launched in 1962 and could be regarded as turning point of rural villages in regard to capital relations. Market-orientation of agriculture commenced at this stage and the landlord system was abolished and, therefore, villagers became the owners of the lands. With the introduction of the Fourth National Development Plan in 1968, the rural development was taken away from agriculture sector and a separate significant chapter has been allocated to itself. Based on the new definition the rural development, three main objectives had been considered by the Plan: i. Operations aimed at agricultural product promotion. ii. An effective program for the well-being of the rural people and rehabilitation of villages. iii. Social welfare and training of villagers. Along these three main components, there were specific policies for rural development. This approach was followed in the Fifth National Development Plan as well. Finally the approach of Rural Development District (RDD) was adopted during the five-year period, 1974-78. After the revolution, there were no National Development Plans in Iran for 10 years, from 1978 to 1988. Rural development efforts during these years were mainly focused on escalating social and physical infrastructure and services, mostly clean water, electricity network, roads and medical facilities. The First National Development Plan of the new government, after the revolution, was prepared in 1989. One of the most important rural development strategy launched in Iran was the Rural Rehabilitation Program. This program was mainly focused on physical planning in the large villages of rural districts. This program could be regarded as a spatial improvement in the village physical structure, using the tools of land use program. One of the other major changes in the rural development strategy after the revolution was the centralization of the operational activities of rural development into one organization; namely, the Ministry of Jihad-e-Sazandegi. This institution was responsible for rural development operations. Due to the non-bureaucratic nature of this institution at its foundation in 1979, it was successful in the implementation of rural programs. The Second National Development Plan after the revolution started in 1995 and ended in 1999. In this Plan, rural development was seen as a clear program with the following objectives: i. Implementing rehabilitation program in 900 central villages. ii. Centralizing and composing a large number of scattered villages.

- 170 -

iii. Preparing 75 rural comprehensive plans for 75 rural districts. iv. Making 33 Rural Manufacturing Zones. In this respect, peoples participation should be considered as a necessary requisite. In the recent past, the status of social services in rural areas has rapidly risen. For example, access to safe drinking water has gone up to 83 percent in rural areas and over 80 percent of the rural areas now have access to primary healthcare services. Over 49,000 km of rural roads have been paved and the rural electrification program has covered over 15,000 villages. The literacy rate has reached to 67 percent. This was 37 percent during the First and Second National Development Plan periods. Role of Agricultural Bank in Rural Development The first financial institution with clearly expressed responsibility for the agriculture sector commenced its operation as a wing of Bank Melli Iran (The National Bank of Iran) in 1930. The nations awakening and strong desire for socio-economic development instigated the decision to establish a specialized bank to provide the private sector with institutional financial means and guidance and to channel their concerted efforts towards the national economic development goals. Thus, Agricultural and Industrial Bank was established in 1933 as an independent bank. In 1969, this Bank was expressly commissioned to regulate the organization and management of the rural cooperatives. So the Bank was renamed as Agricultural Cooperative Bank of Iran (ACBI). Its main function was to improve the state of the rural cooperatives. In 1973 it was converted to a development bank called Agricultural Development Bank of Iran and in 1979 was again renamed as the Agricultural Bank. Rural Development Objectives of the Agricultural Bank The ultimate objective of the Bank is to facilitate rural development and to ameliorate the standard of living of the rural population through increasing agricultural production and productivity and the development of small rural industries and local traditional arts and crafts. In pursuit of these objectives, the Bank is empowered to grant loans to individuals and legal entities and to share, participate and undertake direct investment in agriculture-related industries. All real persons or legal entities that are, or intend to be, engaged in one of the following activities can use the Bank facilities: * * * * * * * Farming Horticulture Fishing, bee-keeping and sericulture Agro-related industries Rural industries and handicrafts, especially carpet weaving Agricultural marketing services Animal husbandry, poultry and sheep farming.

The role of the Agricultural Bank in rural poverty alleviation, rural development and the safety programs are some of the policies of this Bank. Related to this role, the main activities are as follows:

- 171 -

i. ii. iii. iv. v. vi.

Simplification of collateral conditions for small farmers; Provision of financial services to the deprived regions; Family supporting and rural womens scheme; Carpet weaving workshops and improvement program; Agricultural products insurance fund; and Relief fund for the loss-incurring farmers.

Role of the Cooperative System in Rural Development Iran has a very extensive network of cooperatives in rural areas. The most widespread form is the rural service cooperative (RSC), of which there are 4,200 branches, 24 provincial associations and a national federation called the Agricultural Cooperative Company (ACC). The provincial associations provide administrative, logistical and marketing support while the ACC issues branch licenses and coordinates policy-making and operations of the provincial associations. The system covers 90 percent of the total villages in Iran and has 4.5 million members. The RSCs are Multi-purpose Cooperatives (MPCs) whose main functions are as follows: i. ii. iii. iv. Input and equipment supply; Purchases of support price commodities; Sale of consumer goods; and Credit distribution.

The second form of service cooperative is the Agricultural Cooperative Society (ACS). The total membership of ACSs is 562,000. Each ACS is specialized in a particular activity such as poultry production or machinery services. The RSCs and the ACSs are supervised, trained and backed up by a central organization for rural cooperatives. Moshaa Production Cooperatives Moshaa Production Cooperatives with 12,800 societies and 100,000 members provide common services to peasants, who had benefitted from the land reform. Efficient production in small plots is being promoted by the Ministry of Agriculture through the cooperatives, but these cooperatives are not common (only 76 societies with 12,500 members). The cooperative system in Irans hand-woven carpet industry was introduced after the revolution. Carpet cooperatives were established in an attempt to organize and bring together the carpet weavers. The carpet weaving workshops which are scattered nationwide, supply the raw materials, upgrade the quality and quantity of the carpets, train new weavers, control the work environment, address health issues, market the products of members and promote the exports of hand-woven carpets. In addition to such cooperatives, the unions across the country have been brought together under the Nation-wide Union of Hand-woven Persian Carpet Cooperatives. The status of rural cooperatives in Iran is presented in Table 2. There are 2,984 rural cooperatives in Iran. As it can be seen from Table, the number of rural cooperatives has been decreased from 1989 to 1993. Rural Islamic Councils At present, the Rural Islamic Councils are the main local institutions for rural development. The first election of the Rural Islamic Councils was conducted in March 1999.

- 172 -

It covered 33,000 villages and 108,000 representatives were elected; out of them, only 559 people were women and the rest were men. This new peoples institution has now become the major tool of the rural development process in the country, especially in terms of village management. Table 2. The Status of Rural Cooperatives Number of Members Year Cooperatives (000 people)

Funds (Rl. billion)

Annual Capital Growth Rate

1989 3,110 4,245.9 66.2 16.6 1990 3,110 4,234.2 75.7 14.3 1991 3,102 4,367.3 84.4 11.5 1992 3,088 4,399.0 101.2 20.0 1993 2,984 5,050.2 116.6 15.2 Source: Agricultural Planning and Economic Research Institute (APERI), Ministry of Agriculture, 1996. At present, there are 33,000 village councils in different parts of Iran. The main activities of Islamic Village Councils in Iran are as follows: i. Study and identification of village needs and preparing projects for rural development; ii. Involved in peoples participation and connecting them with ministries and organizations which are related to rural activities; iii. Supervising and looking after the application of rural development projects; iv. Cooperation with authorities for the establishment, maintenance and the use of public establishments and looking after socio-economic and welfare of rural people; and v. Improving health and environmental conditions in the villages. CONCLUSIONS The living condition in rural villages in the Islamic Republic of Iran has improved to a certain extent due to five decades of national development planning. Especially after the revolution, rural areas benefitted by the development programs. However, years of rural development in Iran have fallen short of expectation. The most significant problem has been the way in which local communities and institutions were promoted. Active participation of people in rural development has been weak. External promoters determined rural development organizations and activities. As a consequence, local institutions failed to develop as true member-based self-help entities. The policies and programs of the governmental and NGOs need a better conceptual and theoretical framework. In addition, an integrated approach to local community development and appropriate institutional arrangement are prerequisites. For participatory development, the local councils in rural areas should be strengthened. They would act as an important link between the people and the government. The relationship between government and communities/local institutions must be redefined to create an environment, which would be more conductive to develop rural areas. Direct

- 173 -

support to institutions and cooperatives should be limited to training of officials and members and to the establishment of control mechanism to protect members in trusts. It is recommended to adopt a new development policy that would promote integrated rural development, which is people-based and managed by people. The role of such a movement under the new economic reality would be: input supply on a commercial basis; crop marketing and processing; provision of technical services such as extension and pest control; savings and loan activation; and machinery services. REFERENCES Agricultural Bank of Islamic Republic of Iran, 1998. Role of Agricultural Bank in Rural Development. APERI, 1996. Iran Agriculture at a Glance. Asian Productivity Organization, APO, 2000. Local Social Development, proceedings of the APO Seminar on Training Method for Integrated Local Community Development held in Sri Lanka from 27 July to 8 August, APO, Tokyo. Ministry of Islamic Interior and Organizations of Islamic Village Councils, 1999. World Bank, 1996. Report No. 11956 IRN/Islamic Republic of Iran, Services for Agricultural and Rural Development. Yogo, Toshihiro, 2000. Local Communities in Development Process An Analytical Framework, Local Social Development, APO, Tokyo.

- 174 -

6. ISLAMIC REPUBLIC OF IRAN (2)


Hossein Mahdidoust

Chief Officer Micro Producer Organizing Ministry of Jihad for Agriculture Tehran

INTRODUCTION Rural Life Irans population was 60.05 million in 1996 (Census, 1996). About 60 percent of the population lives in cities and 38 percent in rural areas. The remainder is the tribal and moving people. The population growth between 1986 and 1996 was 2.3 percent, compared to 3 percent in the previous decade. The Central, North and Northwest regions of the country are of the most crowded regions. The Central region with about 19 percent of the surface area contains 32 percent of countrys population while the East region with about 50 percent of the surface area has only 19 percent of the total. For administrative purposes, the country is divided into 29 provinces, 252 districts, 680 subdistricts and more than 70,000 settlements and villages. The Ministry of Interior appoints the heads of provincial and district administrations. Rural life in Iran, which has a long history, has undergone some transformations, both in terms of economic and social, just over the past few decades. These transformations are manifested in human resources development, increase in the participatory organization, rural dwellings and villages, ownership of water resources, irrigation and farming systems, production tools, and also in the use of manpower as well as in the economic and cultural relation with urban societies. In parallel with these changes, the structure of rural population has changed. Based on 1996 census, the total rural population of country was 23,026,293 persons in 68,125 villages. In spite of the absolute growth of the rural population in the recent decades, the proportion of rural population in comparison with the total population has decreased due to increased village-city migration and the increasing trend of converting rural centers into cities. Nevertheless, nearly 40 percent of the countrys population is still living in rural areas, something that underlines the importance of paying more attention to these areas. Major economic activities of Irans villages include cultivation, gardening, animal husbandry and handicrafts. About half of the active rural population of age 10 and above is engaged in the agriculture sector, nearly 27 percent in the industrial sector and 22 percent in the services sector. The cultivated surface area of the country is about 18 million ha and the number of domesticated animals in the villages amounts to 92 million. Historically, soil and water resources as well as economic, social, political, security and cultural conditions have influenced the spatial distribution and form of Irans villages. GOVERNMENT AND ADMINISTRATION According to the constitution of the Islamic Republic of Iran, all branches of the governing body Islamic laws under the supervision of the Valieh Faqih, the great

- 175 -

Islamic jurist, govern executive, legislative and judiciary. The president, the second highest authority, is responsible for implementing and safeguarding the constitutions provisions and coordinating all three branches of governing body. Ministry of Jihad for Agriculture After the revolution, one of the actions adopted by Imam Khomeinis directions, the Great Leader of Iran, was the formation of a foundation named Jihad-e-Sazandegi (Jihad for Construction) worked in Irans villages with the aim of agricultural and rural development and alleviation of poverty, especially in the villages. This action was developed and could attract rural peoples reliance by encouraging them to participate in activities, decision-making and considering their ideas in respect of program development, solving existing problems, budgeting and accessibility to resources. Such developments resulted in the conversion of this foundation into a ministry namely, Jihad-e-Sazandegi in year 1983. And, in the year 2002, this was combined with the Ministry of Agriculture as the new Ministry of Jihad for Agriculture. The important duties of this ministry are as follows: i. Determination of policies, strategies and required plans for development of the rural and tribal regions of the country; ii. To provide possible and active participation of people in rural areas in social and development activities; iii. To provide the required energy for the villages and constructing and maintaining rural roads; iv. To improve and perform the education and extension courses suitable for the rural entrepreneurs; v. To protect the watersheds, stabilize the movable sand and reduce the deserts; and vi. To regulate and control the market of domesticated animals, meet and other protein productions. Deputy for Extension and Popular Participation The Ministry of Jihad for Agriculture has various Deputies and organizations, each section with entrusted responsibilities. Among these sections, the duties of the Deputy for Extension and Popular Participation are more relevant to the topic. The major role of this Deputy is to support the activities of other Deputies and organizations through extension, training and attraction of peoples participation. It plays an important role in integrated rural community development of Iran. The Deputys major strategies include the following: * * * Revising and reorganizing the departments plans with emphasis on increasing the quality and effectiveness of respective missions; Reviewing and designing the internal establishments in terms of organizational structure; and Reorganizing manpower and staffing. The relevant policies are listed below: * * Supporting private sector participation in the agriculture sector; Developing extension network;

- 176 -

* * *

Designing and implementing a needs-assessment system; Organizing and promoting local grassroots institutions; and Encourage peoples participation, design appropriate organizations for rural women and human resources development. The long-term qualitative objectives are as follows:

* * * * * * *

Develop human resources and productivity; Promote organized participation among producers and beneficiaries of the sector by taking advantage of local and regional capacities; Optimizing the utilization of extensions infrastructure resources and services; Providing basic information and technical knowledge to for producers and beneficiaries; Upgrading the knowledge level as well as theoretical and technical skills of both beneficiaries and producers on a constant basis; Stabilizing appropriate sustainable employment opportunities in rural areas; and Improving organizational structure of the skilled human resources (both producers and beneficiaries) in various sub-sectors of agriculture.

The duties of the Deputy include: improve cultural and social development of rural communities; increase and develop the technical skills in order to improve rural peoples power for using their facilities to optimize production and economic condition of the villages; create and develop rural organizations and foundations in order to ensure effective peoples participation in the management of villages; mobilize and use facilities and public resources in the rural development programs; and develop the cooperative works at production, distribution as well as in services. Deputy of extension and popular participation includes some offices such as studies and planning, extension, popular participation and mobilization, training of rural people, women affairs and organizing and supporting the headquarters of extension. Each of these sections undertakes specific duties. The authorities of the Ministry of Jihad for Agriculture believe that integrated and sustainable rural development could be achieved only if the planning is made from lower to upper levels with active participation of people. The authorities and governmental experts would then play the role of supervisor, supporter and facilitator. ROLE OF GRASSROOTS ORGANIZATIONS IN RURAL DEVELOPMENT: AN OVERVIEW A needs analysis is required to facilitate the regularization of policy-making and planning activities so as to make better use of local human resources and capacities and, as a result, to break down macro-level development in to local areas. The current concern is bottom-up development with emphasis on the significant role of people. Following this, grassroots institutions as well as local and indigenous organizations should play a significant role as organized and effective establishments. In many communities one may readily see various forms of collective participation and simple traditional mechanisms for group action. Besides governmental and nongovernmental organizations a great number of such traditional organizations have been active

- 177 -

through local leadership and co-thinking. Because of their simplicity and adaptability to available resources, properties and the community-based socio-economic system, these types of participatory organization or institutions can comparatively meet the needs of the community in a more effective way. However, due to characteristics such as traditional simple structure, poor communication system and the like, not only their efficiency cannot be increased, but also they are less likely to expand their capabilities beyond local levels. Nevertheless, at present emergence and expansion of modern popular organizations, including NGOs, have facilitated bottom-up development or participatory development in a new path. These organizations often come into existence spontaneously or voluntarily by local and indigenous people with related capacities for decision and action. In some cases governments also establish and develop such organizations. Presently new types of grassroots organizations are being created and developed which are actively involved in development process alongside the cooperatives and other kinds of governmental organization and establishments. Characteristics of Grassroots Organizations and Establishments The major characteristics of grassroots or popular organizations at local level (including cooperatives and community-based organizations) as well as those of NGOs can be summarized as follows: 1. Voluntary Formation Most often, these organizations tend to form in accordance with the common felt-needs of local people. People themselves come together and undertake common activities on a voluntary basis. Apart from the fact that how they are formed, these organization might be considered as establishments where the individuals tend to maintain their membership voluntarily. 2. Independence and Autonomy Grassroots organizations are managed and controlled by people themselves and through their own initiatives. In some particular political, social, and economic contexts, however, their independence is faded away to the extent that the government deems it imperative to intervene in controlling or conducting their affairs. 3. Popular Funding Capital and assets needed by grassroots organizations are mainly provided by their members and people of the community. 4. Close Proximity to the Community Grassroots organizations take their roots from the community. No other institution is thus as much near to the community as they are. Also, local people tend to have a sense of belonging and attachment to these organizations. 5. Non-profit Nature Contrary to commercial institutes or agencies, grassroots organizations are not looking for economic benefits; rather they are dynamically directed towards either fulfilling local needs or accomplishing development objectives. The latter is particularly in accordance with national overall policies. Viable group activities, legitimate objectives, innovation, creativity, and lack of political affiliations/interests, are among many other characteristics of grassroots organizations.

- 178 -

Due to their strength and popularity, grassroots organizations perform important functions that cannot be ignored by development programs. Some of these functions are given below: 1. Information Delivery and Promotion of New Ideas Rural areas in developing countries have been always recognized as less-developed areas. As far as development of rural areas is concerned, the major role of governments has been limited to the one-sided implementation of plans and projects on a top-down planning basis. Such a trend, however, would not be workable according to the new approaches to development, in which a great deal of emphasis is laid upon the participation of people. Improvement of this process, thus calls for intermediary agencies to provide development programs and the related qualitative or quantitative objectives with the flexibility needed for corresponding them to local communitys requirements and circumstances. From this point of view, grassroots organizations not only are capable of transferring new ideas of the development programs, but also are able to create a culture appropriate to new ideas along with the transferring of needed know-how (both technical and non-technical). 2. Communication Facilitator In establishing relations with communities, grassroots organizations tend to use interpersonal communication methods so as to win the confidence of people. In addition, worldwide experiences show that these types of organizations take advantage of peculiarities that would allow them to recognize and understand objectives, functions and characteristics of other organizations. They are also well familiar with the communitys norms and values as a system. Accordingly, they can serve effectively as either intermediary institution or as appropriate communication channels to link government and NGOs together at both vertical and horizontal levels. 3. Counseling and Research Giving advice and conducting research on characteristics, potential capacities and the communitys socio-economic living standards as a whole, is another important role-played by grassroots organizations. Since they are deeply rooted in the community and are created by people from the same community, grassroots organizations can come up with efficient information on the manner of living or cultural dispositions of the communitys individuals. They may as well gather the same information on natural and economic capacities or generally about the communitys status so as to enrich the development planning process in an effective manner. Some of these organizations can conduct feasibility studies for development projects under their expertise domain. They may as well provide important basic and analytical information for drawing up and launching development projects through deliberated studies utilizing their ability to recognize the exact needs of communities and obtaining relatively adequate knowledge or information about potentialities and available resources. 4. Planning Because of limited activity span, simple structure and lack of complicated linkages, grassroots organizations tend to have simple and sometimes indigenous system for decisionmaking and planning. However short term and small scale, their planning process is in compliance with the recognized felt-needs of local people. As a result of the simple and limited nature, this sort of planning process is easily understood and grasped by people, which in turn, cause the programs or activities to be carried out with the least problems. This

- 179 -

would allow grassroots organizations to break down any macro planning, so as to correspond with local conditions. 5. Implementation Grassroots organizations possess good performing or implementing ability in some aspects. According to the specific objective and the assigned task, they may deal with activities, which can, at the same time, be regarded as development objectives. Infrastructure construction activities in rural areas are among such activities that could benefit from the participation of grassroots organizations and local people in intellectual, financial and physical terms. Some of these activities include, for instance, building public facilities such as general baths, schools, clinics or road construction. 6. Training Some grassroots organizations, particularly cooperatives and NGOs can be effective in training related to their areas of skills and in transferring of technical knowledge and necessary information about economic, environmental, social and cultural issues. They may as well provide the setting for improving the awareness level of people through employing a variety of media. Grassroots Organizations and Institutions in Iran Local traditional institutions have long been in existence in Iran mainly for mutual help. These sorts of mutual help have been embodied as cultivating groups or commodity exchange (like boneh or vara) in economic terms, and as temporary collective actions (such as participation for providing expenses needed for marriage, etc.) in social terms. Following the emergence of cooperatives and NGOs in the new era, Iran has also witnessed development of such organizations. The country experienced cooperative system as the first formal form of grassroots organizations. Since 1935, this system took its shape progressively by establishing agricultural and rural cooperatives. Land reforms in 1960 replaced the former landlordpeasant system. These organizations are mainly involved in producing and supplying agricultural inputs as well as in other supportive activities such as granting credit or offering training and instructions. Cooperative system has, thus, a longer history as compared to the other types of formal establishments. Currently some 5,120 producer, service and distribution cooperatives are actively involved in agriculture sector. As the second type of grassroots organizations, NGOs are generally active in urban areas and mainly deal with urban issues or problems. Recently these types of organizations have emerged and developed in rural areas as well. Depending on the type and field of activity, they often take measures such as offering instructions and information services or managing activities. Indigenous or local establishments have developed and evolved according to economic, social, and cultural settings of rural communities without being guided by urban intelligence or governmental agencies. Islamic Councils are another form of grassroots organizations in Iran. They are expected to play a key role in integrated rural development. A brief account on selected institutions/groups is given below: 1. Rural Islamic Councils After the omission of the traditional foundations concerning the management of the villages (such as Khans, Katkhoda) and due to the inefficiency of foundations such as justice house, there was a vacuum in public foundation at village level. This was removed

- 180 -

by the Islamic Revolution and the subsequent formation of the Rural Islamic Councils. Members of Islamic Councils come directly from the community. Major tasks of these councils include: identifying rural needs; encouraging popular participation; cooperating with other governmental agencies; etc. At present there are 720,742 and 32,836 units of Islamic Councils at town, division, and village levels. The members of Islamic Councils played the important role in transferring the villages problem to the authorities and supporting social and development projects of the villages during the last two decades. This was possible because of the suitable public base. One of the important problems of the Islamic Councils is the weakness in their legal position. Some of the duties of the Islamic Councils are as follows: * To identify needs and problems of the villages; * To attract peoples participation and associate with the executive authorities; * To supervise and pursue the performance of the plans and development projects; * To elect an efficient person as the village assistant for a period of four years; and * Introduce the said person to the governor of the district. To attract peoples participation for the rural development operations, it would be appropriate if the Rural Islamic Councils are entrusted with some planning and villagemanagement responsibilities. Also, the councils may undertake educational services, supervision and support. At present there are 32,826 villages in the country with Islamic Councils. The number of members of these councils is 102,800 (about 500 are women). The Councils are working under the supervision of the Ministry of Interior so their training is entrusted to this Ministry. 2. Rural and Tribal Extensionists* Rural and tribal volunteer extensionists are one of the most important elements for facilitating the countrys rural development process. Based on their activities they are considered as the promoters of animal husbandry, watershed management, crop production and social aspects. The total number of extensionists is about 7,100. They are working in villages and in tribal regions of the country. These extensionists are from rural and tribal communities and are familiar with the culture, traditions and attitudes of their societies. They can successfully transfer the modern methods of utilization of natural resources, animal husbandry (including domesticated animals) and health and nutrition to the rural people. Moreover, they are capable of communicating problems in rural areas to the higher authorities. In many of the villages a place called extension house has been established to organize the activities of extensionists. This place has a meeting hall, library and educational facilities, which help extensionists to implement their work. At present, there are 385 extension houses. In villages where extension houses have not been established yet, the extensionists use other public places such as rural libraries, schools and mosques. 3. Co-helpers Rural co-helpers are considered as facilitators of rural development. In general, they are educated youths of age above 25 years and elected by the Islamic Councils. These cohelpers are in-charge of rural co-help houses. Their objectives/aims are as follows: i. To organize the existing resources of the villages, especially human sources; ii. To provide suitable grounds to transfer local affairs to the people;

Extensionist: a person who is the local and technical leader of the village. - 181 -

iii. To rank the rural needs through organizing rural people and promoting participation; and iv. To reinforce the cooperation and association spirit of rural people. At present, there are 210 co-help houses in the country. In general, a co-helper heads each one and there are several associates. These persons are independent in terms of managing and financing their work. They encourage rural people to construct and maintain infrastructure. The Ministry of Jihad for Agriculture only undertakes the supervision, support and training of co-helpers. Therefore, the formation of co-help houses and employing cohelpers are considered as an appropriate step towards the institutionalization of rural development in Iran. 4. Rural Librarians Enhancing community information and knowledge level of rural people can be considered either as one of the development ends or as a requisite thereof. Therefore, the Ministry of Jihad for Agriculture took the initiative of constructing rural libraries and the training of rural librarians in the villages. The rural librarians are volunteers and motivated youths of the villages and they attempt to enhance information related to socio-cultural, religious aspects. They focus on the rural people, especially the youths. There are 2,500 libraries and 5,000 rural librarians at present and about half of them are women. The rural people, especially the youths, welcome the libraries. The libraries are generally independent and the Ministry of Jihad for Agriculture is engaged only in supporting, training, supervising and sometimes supplying of books. 5. Construction (Sazandegi) Groups The construction (sazandegi) groups are a collection of volunteer forces of rural people who have been gathered based on social motivation and the needs of the rural community. They have a common program and goals and they work under the same leadership in order to develop the villages. The objectives of such groups are as follows: i. To pave the way for labor and group activities in the village; ii. To provide confident and strong power for the executive units in the village; iii. To utilize peoples participation in performing rural development programs; and iv. To utilize the human sources and the existing financial facilities. Presently, there are 830 construction groups throughout the country. On average, each group has about 30-40 members. Role of Facilitators in Rural Development Promoting self-reliance of rural communities and the internalizing of integrated rural development could be facilitated by well-trained and motivated facilitators. A lot could be learned from the conditioned prevailed and the management styles and strategies of local and native people. These may include: identification of problems and needs; perception of rural people towards authorities; more effective innovations and better methods of production; conservation of the environment; observing sanitary principles; etc. If this learning process is followed, there is no need to impose development programs. Instead, rural development could be conformed to the reality of the rural community. Moreover, peoples participation in the identification of the problems, planning, executing and evaluation could be realized. Rural development facilitators could facilitate such a process. In general, these are from the rural volunteer forces and the Ministry of Jihad for Agriculture help these facilitators in their activities through organizing, supervising, supporting and training.

- 182 -

Training of Rural Development Facilitators Training of development facilitators is crucial for integrated rural development. Hence, the training of relevant facilitators in subjects such as facilitating principles and skills related to the duties of each of the above mentioned groups and institutions has been a major policy initiative of the Ministry of Jihad for Agriculture. The Ministry is utilizing training, supervision and support to make communities self-reliant and to internalize rural development within communities. During the period 1998-2001, the training input was equivalent to 475,000 person-days and involved Islamic Councils, directors of the cooperatives, rural librarians and rural extensionists. Other statistics shows that, in the same period, 450 meetings and national/regional training workshops have been held for librarians, co-helpers, extensionists and the members of the Islamic Councils. The educational and training needs of the facilitators are being determined on the basis of the duties entrusted and expert opinion. After the educational needs have been determined, they are examined by the experts based on their subject type, standards of the educational courses, duration, subjects/topics, training venues, etc. Training tools include video, slides, radio, television, pamphlets and educational catalogues. Correspondence training and educational meetings are also used for further information. CONCLUSION Government must, in favor of civil society, relinquish its control over the sustainable development process, so as to leave the space for communities to take their own initiatives for preserving and making sustainable use of resources. To this end, it should reinstate its major role of supporting grassroots organizations. This would allow these organizations to assist community-based organizations in achieving their objectives through enabling movements. It is imperative for popular organizations or establishment at national level to approach the organizations at community level with the purpose of learning from their experiences. In doing so popular organizations should further leave towns and cities and go hand-in-hand with local communities to find solutions to the community problems. Community organizations, by understanding their critical role at this juncture of national political space, can better take advantage of their capabilities to come up with appropriate sustainable development patterns, which might be helpful for improving the status quo and the integrity of local communities. Recognizing sustainable and integrated development as a two-sided process, with government and governmental organizations on one side and people and popular organizations on the other, it should well be realized that the process of development process also follows the same procedure. As mentioned before, popular bases of development in Iran rest upon a variety of organizations such as cooperatives, NGOs, Islamic Councils, and traditional participatory-based establishments at village, district, division, and higher levels. It should be taken into consideration that there is a need to establish an effective network to link grassroots organizations together and to the government. In the absence of such an integrated approach, these organizations have tended to work so far independently from each other in compliance with the adopted policies. Development would not be easily achieved merely by the governments function or through parts of activity systems. Development planning and management is required not only at macro level, but also at regional and local

- 183 -

levels. Hence, it is imperative to pay particular attention to regional and local capacities and potentialities. And, it is unlikely that any mechanism other than grassroots organizations can be helpful to the State in this regard. REFERENCES Cernea, Michel M., 1997. NGOs and Community Development, translated version by Gholam H. Salleh Nassb, Ministry of Jihad, 1376. Jabbari, Habib, 1997. NGOs: Concepts and Practices, Municipalities Magazine, Vol.6, 1376. Ministry of Interior, 2001. Symposium on the Role and Status of NGOs, in national and international version, first print, Tehran, 1380. Ministry of Jihad for Agriculture (MOJA). Collected reports and studies on investing and appraising cooperatives (available in MOJAs Department of Extension and Farming Systems). Patnam, Robert, 2001. Democracy and Civil Traditions, translated version by M. Taghi Delforouz, Ministry of Interior, first print, 1380. Planning and Budget Organization, 1998. Symposium on 50 Years of Development Planning in Iran, 1377.

- 184 -

7. ISLAMIC REPUBLIC OF IRAN (3)


Javad Sayahi Kashi1
Expert in Councils Affairs Ministry of Interior Tehran

INTRODUCTION In order to better understand rural management in Iran, it is suggested to study it under three distinct periods: i. Before the Pahlavi dynasty, especially the Safavid and the Qajar era: During the Safavid era considerable development in economic and social matters took place but it was demolished in the Qajar period. ii. From the Pahlavi to the Islamic Revolution: In this period the Clans Settlement Program or the land reform program was accomplished and, as a result, the traditional rural management system disappeared. iii. After the Islamic Revolution: This period may be divided into two phases: a) From the inception of the of the Islamic Republic System until the first general elections of Islamic Councils: In this period, election for the Islamic Councils was held in the rural areas by crusade for construction (Jihad-eSazandegi)2; and b) The present period, that is the period after the first Islamic Council general election held by the Ministry of Interior: The paper attempts to reflect mainly on this era. RURAL DEVELOPMENT IN IRAN: HISTORICAL BACKGROUND In ancient times, Iran was governed by a decentralized system called Satrap. Without damaging the local structure of the regions, both within the Iranian Empire and in newly conquered territories, the rulers only appointed the local chiefs as the heads of regions. The Chief had sovereign power over all regional affairs except some highly critical matters, like going to war or paying tribute, which were coordinated and decided by the central empire/government. Due to their minority, the Moslems and the Moguls conquerors established a highly centralized government. When the Safavid dynasty came to power, economic growth and social development spread all over the country. But the tribal structure of the administration led the system towards a centripetal rule. For example, when constructing dams or digging subterranean canals (qanats), which recorded a significant increase in this period, the new cultivated lands were taken by the monarch (soltan) or his

1 2

Mr. Kashi was unable to attend the Meeting, but submitted the paper. A revolutionary institution formed specifically to promote the living condition in the countryside and rural areas. - 185 -

governors or endowed (waqhf) to special personalities (sadat and religious jurisprudent) or special places (holy shrines and religious schools). Since those who were working on such lands were not the real owners, they were not attached to those lands and did not have the motivation for developing or improving productivity because any endeavor to increase production would lead to more exploitation by the owners. On the contrary to lessen the pain and avoid multiple exploitations, the farmers destroyed effective factors of production to suggest to the owners that the output or the production had decreased. Thus the owners were content with what was available and the farmers were busy with their daily routine life. Consequently, no one was bothered about growth and development. During the Qajar era the above-mentioned procedure reached its peak. In this period not only the villages but also cities were exposed to destruction. The Qajari kings put up to auction the administration and offered the princes the governance of their territories. Instead of trying to develop the acquired territories, they were only eager to exploit the people as much as possible. This was one of the causes of social unrest and domestic tension in the Qajarera. This practice continued up to the Pahlavi dynasty. Until this period, the villages were traditionally governed. Through the above-mentioned system, the Khan owned one or more villages, which were acquired, inherited or bought. However, there were villages, which had been flourished and cultivated by the Khan. He ordered via Kadkhoda3 because he lived in the capital city or at the provincial center. In each village, Kadkhoda was responsible for determining the timing and the type of plantation and also for managing the irrigation system, division of duties, supervising farmers labor and activities, issuing and payment related to land rights and the regulation of social relations such as security, arbitration, prosecution and punishment, management of rites and ceremonies. Unfortunately, it was too late when in the middle of the 2nd Pahlavi era the land reform policy was put to practice and the obstacles removed. Although villagers were attached to their land and earned livelihood, lack of saving and modern methods and techniques of production exceeded their ability to survive against cheap imports of agricultural products, a policy which was being pursued by the former regime. Division of agricultural land into small pieces eliminated the remainder of cooperative and collective work and management done by Kadkhoda. In 1963, the Act on Establishing Village Associations and Reforming the Social and Developmental Affairs was passed. This has gradually paved the way for the abolition of traditional system of management enforced by Khan via Kadkhoda. Because of the change in ownership by land reforms programs, it was not enforceable. In 1975, sanction The Act of Organize Rural Association and Village Center of Governor (Dehbany) created a new radical change. It divided power and authority between several institutions like rural cooperatives, rural associations, house of justice, and Dehban.4 Developments after the Victory of the Islamic Revolution After the Islamic Revolution the foundation called Jihad-e-Sazandegi was established. It tried to rehabilitate the rural area and improve living standards in the countryside. The young revolutionary forces and engineers were busy to create basic affairs in villages. Such

3 4

Headman of the village. Person who carries out village affairs. - 186 -

developments included roads, drinking water supply, electricity, telephone, hygiene-related affairs, libraries and teaching new methods of farming. Because of American economic sanctions, climatic problems, civil war in several provinces and imposed war to which human and material resources were allocated, it took 20 years to do such improvements. In the Islamic Republic Constitution, one chapter is allocated to councils. Interior management was left to the people via councils of province, city, district, and village. This goal was not fulfilled until 1999. Considering the necessity of establishing rural councils to improve living condition in villages, in 1982 The Act of Islamic Councils Organization was passed in Parliament. Jihad-e-Sazandegy was charged to execute this Act. Thus rural council elections took place, members were elected and they started managing villages, in cooperation with Jihad. In 1987, Low of the Islamic Councils Elections charged Interior Ministry to execute elections in all categories. However, because of the continuation of the imposed war the council elections were not held. According to official statistics, Jihad organized about 33,500 rural councils in 3,600 villages in which at least 20 families were living. In the end of this term the new elections was not held and an interregnum commenced. The authorities demanded the former elected members to continue their duties. But many of the councils have been terminated. Jihad proposed the bill of Khaneh Omran5 and Dehyar6 to protect establishments and to be in charge of village affairs. The Cabinet approved the temporary execution of above-mentioned bill. This condition continued until the general elections of Islamic Councils in 1999. Therefore, during the period from the Revolution until the general elections of councils, the rural elections had been executed by Jihad. Rural management was collective and during the interregnum elected members continued their duties. When Dehyar was in charge of village affairs he was protecting public facilities like water and electric nets. He also coordinated with Jihad in governing the village affairs. GENERAL ELECTIONS OF ISLAMIC COUNCILS By the end of the reconstruction of the damage caused by the war and with the Five Years Economic-Social and Cultural Development Program, Mr. Khatami and his political development policy were voted at the Presidential election (1997) by an overwhelming majority of voters. Later, the general election of councils was held all over the country and under four categories: city, town, district and village. On the basis of census of 1997 there were 4,405,603 rural families. And the total rural population was 23 million. In other words, 40 percent of countrys population lives in 60,000 villages, and they produce 35 percent of GNP. According to the law of Rural Councils Election any village with at least 20 families or 100 people is permitted to organize a council. Elections were held in 32,826 villages and 107,293 members were elected. Out of these, 2,564 are women. Also 22,298 persons or about 13 percent of members are Sunniest, 10 are Zoroastrian, nine members are Christians and the remaining majority are Shieaa Moslim. According to 4th article of law, in the villages with less than 1,500 people, three members had been elected. In villages with over 1,500 people, five members had been elected.

5 6

Center for village affairs. Another name for Dehban with the same meaning. - 187 -

Rural management was strengthened when rural council came to play its role. It focuses the scattered viewpoints of national, provincial and local government units. Rural council as an official institution carries out its official missions. Meanwhile the administrative council consists of all local government units. It plans and classifies the villages needs. For example, hygienic house is unable to prevent contagious diseases unless other institutions do their duties such as the supply of healthy water, cleaning passages, handling sewerage and waste. Only the councils that are native and better informed than government agents can coordinate efficiently, e.g. Nosrat Abad and Choobeendar in the province of Qazvin. PRESENT STATUS OF IRANIAN VILLAGES This section addresses such issues as: what is the actual situation of a village in Iran at present?; what sort of facilities do the villagers have?; and, what programs are required in the future? Portrait of a typical Iranian village is as follows: There is a main road, hygienic drinking water, hygienic house, electricity, telephone, school, cooperative societies, bank, veterinarian, Bassij7 base. This means the villagers enjoy basic needs. They are grateful to Jihad personnel and feel that they require of two programs: i. Protection, maintenance and management of what have already been built in order to continue on acceptable living in rural areas; and ii. Carrying out the objectives of Economic, Social and Cultural Development Programs. These include health services, standard buildings, widening and paving/ asphalting of public passages, improved sewerage system, projects to increase employment and productivity and income. In the first case it will continue on the basis of citizens right, which have been stipulated in the constitution. The relevant Ministries shall allocate adequate funding in respective annual budgets to protect them. For the second program the leadership is very important. Leadership at the center should concentrate on governmental and non-governmental aid and programs by paying attention to planning and implementation. Through the organization of councils, leadership has been created at that level. Leadership, infrastructure and appropriate programs are the (three) key factors of rural management, like the three sides of a triangle. It is necessary to explain that council election is the process of choosing leadership. And, it is necessary for the candidates to present their programs during the election campaign. Such a process would automatically specify the future program of the council. The members of the council then consult each other and make decisions in a participatory manner. Also, special commissions could be established by the council to deal with specific matters such as security, culture, education and economy. The council convenes the experts and selects one of its members as the secretary of every commission. The council can utilize those commissions for planning and assessment like it is happening in the village of Qoroq in Golestan province and in the village of Segze Abad in the Qazvin province.

Military base. - 188 -

In addition, official sessions could be held with government agents in the village like those in charge of water, electricity, telephone affairs and hygiene, director/manager of the village cooperative society, school masters and the banker. These persons could offer counsel to the village council and at the same time, transfer/link council policies to their respective offices. Finally, Dehyar is appointed by the council to implement its decisions. It is noteworthy that the governor of the district (Bakhsh) links this group to the executive and also offers counsel to them. Even in some small provinces (Shahrestan) governor convenes official sessions with the village council, like it is happening in Mahabad, a small province in western Iran.

- 189 -

8. ISLAMIC REPUBLIC OF IRAN (4)


Masoud Motamedi
Deputy Director of Housing and City and Rural Planning Bureau Management and Planning Organization Tehran

INTRODUCTION Ensuring social justice and investment in welfare services could be regarded as the major goals of rural development. Arising out of these goals are the indirect effects of increasing agricultural production and economic enhancement. These would lead to healthier societies and better living conditions. Present Situation of Rural Development The rate of change within rural communities in the recent decades in Iran has been very important from qualitative and quantitative point of view. According to 1956 census, the total population of Iran was 19 million. Out of this population, 13 million or 68 percent lived in rural areas. With the expansion and spreading of urbanization, the above proportions changed and according to the latest census (1996), just only 38 percent (23 million of population) live in rural areas. In other words, the urban population grew 6.1 times and the corresponding growth in rural areas was only 1.8. The reasons behind this proportional change of population are related to factors such as shortages of employment opportunities in rural areas, decline in agricultural productivity and limited financial investments. Based on 1996 census, there were 68,000 villages or rural settlements, scattered over the country and 31,765 of them had a population less than 100 person with limited economic power and low accessibility to welfare services. Around 5,500 rural areas are situated along the Caspian Sea and Persian Gulf, having a liner physical form. Some other rural areas are located in good areas of fertile and smooth lands and population in such areas have been increasing during the last two decades. Around 5,400 villages are within the desert areas and are unstable. They are not safe and insecure against storms. Also, about 12,000 villages are along the rivers and with floodwater, they face a high risk and could be even destroyed completely. As a result of above conditions, the most attractive villages with large populations tend to grow further and other types of villages with small populations tend to decrease in size. The villages in the first category change to urban settlements over the time. In short, the above characteristics show the instability of rural system that affects the rural economy and society-related matters. Problems and Difficulties According to 1996 census, 88 percent of the rural population use electricity, 71 percent use clean potable water and only 10 percent use telephone and post communications. Some of the problems and difficulties faced by the rural people are listed below:

- 190 -

i. Shortages of new job opportunities; ii. High degree of insecurity in economic activities; iii. Low standard of houses constructed with unsafe raw materials and traditional techniques; iv. Unorganized physical fabric and bad environmental conditions; v. Low degree of social welfare and service facilities; vi. Low degree of labor force productivity and technical education and high degree of illiteracy; vii. Lack of suitable conditions for financial investments in various sectors, particularly in agricultural activities; viii. Lack of suitable water, soil and land resources; ix. Inefficiency in the system of utilization of resources; x. Lack of efficient participation in the management system; xi. Widespread population centers, high degree of small ones and instability of many of them; xii. High degree of deterioration due to natural events such as earthquake and flooding; xiii. Lack of a comprehensive outlook/view to rural development; xiv. Lack of coordination in urban and rural development; and xv. Lack of suitable implementation structures. GOALS AND OBJECTIVES As mentioned earlier, the main goals in rural areas are the extension of social justice and distribution of the benefits of economic growth among the rural population to provide a high standard of living. In order to achieve these targets, the following objectives are formulated in the Third Five-Year Plan: i. All the villages should be supplied with electricity by the end of 2000; ii. With the establishment of water and sewerage rural companies in all the villages having potable water, such facilities will be controlled and maintained by those companies. Consequently, this network of rural institutions would increase from the present level of 47-70 percent by the end of Third Five-Year Plan (2004). Also in the villages with over 50 families, implementation of the potable water network should exceed 99 percent by the end of year 2004; iii. Implementation of the sewerage network has been emphasized as a new development activity in rural areas. Over 5 percent of rural population, living in villages with more than 200 families would be having sewerage system within the Third Five-Year Plan; iv. By the end of 2004, 82 percent of rural population will have a suitable road network; and v. Within the Third Five-Year Plan, preparation of rural guide plans would continue and the percentage of villages (over 100 families) having such plans will be increased from the present level of 18-75 percent. Strategic Policies i. Organizing rural development with the emphasis on the role and functions of the rural economy through structurally changing in the production system, by way of

- 191 -

ii. iii. iv. v. vi.

utilizing productive resources in an appropriate manner, with the use of suitable technology; Renovation of rural organizational system, aiming at decentralization, improved coordination by preventing the duplication of activities and enhancing the transparency; Supporting the establishment of small-scale rural institutions in order to provide various facilities to rural residents; Developing rural services and rural facilities according to specific norms and standards based on regional development plans; Encourage villagers to participate in different social and economic affairs through team work and to establish a feeling of confidence among them by developing and strengthening village councils; and Preparation and implementation of strategic and structural plans with the aim of coordinated development in underdeveloped rural areas, using available resources.

Implemental Policies and Procedures In order to accelerate development process in rural areas and to improve the living conditions of rural people, government is obliged to do the following: i. Determine the role and duties of different organizations related to rural development aiming at rural reorganizing and eliminating the duplication of activities by different agencies/institutions; ii. Transfer some of the implemental activities of the government body to Islamic Councils and to NGOs; iii. Preparation of regulations for infrastructure services in rural environments and offering sufficient services to them according to approved plans; iv. Support the NGOs in promoting rural savings and collecting credit payments and in providing various facilities for economic and social activities; v. Organizing rural spaces to facilitate coordinated development of agricultural, industrial and service activities, through the suitable distribution of population with sufficient services and public utilities; and vi. Support private investments with the provision of suitable facilities, emphasizing on increased employment. Government is forced to direct sufficient funds through annual plans and budgets. In doing so, the government should ensure that, by the end of the Third Five-Year Plan, all villages with more than 20 households would have suitable roads, schools, clean potable water, electricity and telephone. In order to provide sufficient employment in rural places, particularly in underdeveloped areas, a rural development fund should be established with the government money and with the help of people. In order to organize the physical fabric in rural areas and to prevent the destruction of different buildings, the Ministry of Housing and Urban Planning is obliged to conduct comprehensive studies and research. Based on such work, appropriate and sufficient rules and regulations should be formulated and submit them to related government agencies. Moreover, rural guide plans should be prepared and implemented within the framework of regional development plans.

- 192 -

In addition, in areas with adequate water and soil resources, fertile agricultural lands may be given to rural residents, particularly to youths aiming at increased employment and income. Based on feasibility studies and preferences and with due regards to environmental concerns, rural industry should be promoted with the emphasis on increased employment, particularly focusing on women and young people. Also, productive cooperatives should be promoted and educational and technical branches should be established in villages. Financial Resources For the continuation of rural development programs, within the Third Five-Year Plan, the estimated financial requirement is Rl.9,054 million. From this amount, 71 percent is decentralized provincial budget distributed between the 28 provinces and the rest of the budget is under the control of centralized government. Out of the rural development national budget, 47 percent is devoted to rural potable water. And, it is expected that, in accordance with the Third Five-Year Plan, implementation of sewerage network would be completed in villages with high population. Most of the financial resources of this sector are coming from general income and less than 10 percent of predicted resources would be from water and sewerage companies and internal sources.

- 193 -

9. NEPAL
Dirgha Man Shrestha
District Development Committee Member of Bhaktapur District Office of the District Development Committee Bhaktapur

INTRODUCTION The majority of Nepals population resides in rural areas. They are confronted with enormous problems like hunger, disease, illiteracy, etc. The immediate need is, therefore, to improve the socio-economic lives of the rural masses that are economically weak and numerically large in overall spectrum of development and growth by combating poverty, disease, and ignorance. In order to achieve these basic objectives, several developing nations including Nepal are giving priority to Integrated Rural Development (IRD) approach. It has been recognized as an effective approach to combat against the multidimensional problems of the rural areas of developing countries. Integrated Rural Development: Concept and Approach Keeping in view nature of rural problems, the planning for rural development must be multipurpose, the objectives and contents of different programs must be in mutual harmony and their implementation must be coordinated. This approach stresses integration of different programs in a relatively smaller area to make it manageable and effective. The approaches and methods for rural development strategy could differ from country to country. Many factors, such as: the country where it occurs; the stage of development of that country; the skill and wisdom of its planners and administrators; and the extent to which its citizens are informed, consulted and encouraged to participate would determine the shape it takes. Despite the considerable efforts in the past, alleviation of poverty in the rural areas has posed intractable problems. In general, the growth models tried in the past have failed to make trickle-down mechanism to reach the hardcore poor. A consensus has been reached that Integrated Rural Development Program (IRDP) is the right policy strategy for rural development in Nepal, assuming the effective enactment of decentralization bill followed by the evolution of new institutional structures. Evolution of Integrated Rural Development in Nepal The concept of rural development emerged in 1940s when development programs were operating through community participation. After the establishment of United Nations (UN), developed and underdeveloped nations formulated community-based development processes. In a changing political environment during 1950s, Nepal initiated Tribhuban Gram Bikash Karyakram (Tribhuban Village Development). With the establishment of one party system Panchayat, the program was renamed Panchayat Bikash Karyakram. In the 1970s, Small Farmer Development Program, Productive Loan Development Program and other regional relevant programs were operated as key IRD programs in Nepal. In the 1980s, the slogan of

- 194 -

Self-reliance for Rural Development emerged. This approach was developed during the period to circumvent different characteristics of rural poverty through analyzing local community characteristics, needs, situation and, dividing them into different groups through mobilizing activated local community-based organizations (CBOs). PEOPLES PARTICIPATION AND THE ROLE OF LOCAL INSTITUTIONS IN INTEGRATED RURAL DEVELOPMENT Local self-reliance institutions need to be mobilized in order to recognize and mobilize the dispersed community resources which can construct small projects, identify more needy sectors and for self-evaluation of its capacity for IRD. Roles of local institutions and organization for IRD are: i. increase the affection and reduce the cost of projects as the members of local organizations would work as volunteers; ii. follow participatory approach for rural infrastructure development and diagnosis of marginalized people in the society; iii. motivating the communities by coordinating and recognizing community needs, benefits, and capacity for project development and implementation sustainably; iv. appropriate mobilization and recognition of local resources and means; and v. utilize rural community peoples knowledge, working system and capacity for their own betterment. In Nepal, the Village Development Program (VDP), which started even before launching the First Five-Year Plan (1956-60) with the donors interest, primarily that of the World Bank; led to adoption of the IRDPs. The IRDP has been implemented to improve the living condition of the rural people by providing different goods and services in a coordinated manner and to develop rural infrastructure. In the Ninth Plan (1997-2002), the high-priority areas were: poverty alleviation; productivity increment by promoting peoples participation; strengthening institutional capacity of the local bodies (government); and the employmentgenerating projects which were constructed and maintained by the users groups. The projects focus in backward regions and communities and the poor people. The projects have been selected under the priorities determined by District Development Committee (DDCs). During the Ninth Plan, four IRDP projects have been implemented in five districts: Gulmi and Arghakhachi Rural Development Project; Gorkha Development Project; Lamajung Development Project; and Dhading Development Project. In Nepal, special emphasis is being given for the last few years, to the participative development efforts, based on the concept of decentralization for all-round national development. Development programs based on enabling self-government and peoples empowerment at the local level have been pushed forward. To accomplish this mission, resources and means have been made available to the village level through the government sector as well as non-governmental institutions. Also, emphasis has been given to mobilizing local resources on the basis of peoples participation through consumer groups. In order to make local development programs sustainable and effective, local institutions have been made fully accountable for the management of resources and means, thereby moving forward the process of their spontaneous mobilization and management. In this way, in order to

- 195 -

promote, motivate and encourage local development in line with decentralization process, His Majestys Government has formulated acts and regulations relating to local institutions. Development practitioners must believe that rural people know what is their requirement for their own development and they have the potential to participate in efforts to improve their lives. Development policy-makers, bureaucrats and front-liners/agents must believe that the rural community, however nave, simple and uneducated, do have the latent talent to seek both local alternatives and outside possibilities to solve their own problems and devise designs for their own development. Future Directions of Integrated Rural Development Programs At present, increasing peoples involvement in deciding development activities is the most challenging task for developing countries. For any project to be effective, the people/ farmers, local institutions and organizations must participate in deciding project activities required to increase productivity, to improve access to markets and to improve sustainable management of farm/forest recourses and product/market systems. Rural development through such strategies could be one of the important vehicles to achieve following basic objectives: i. Increased access to resources, their control and opportunities for income by local people; ii. Increase local investment in development; iii. Mobilization of local resources; iv. Creation of local employment opportunities; v. Increase the local sources of income; vi. Peoples active participation in development process; vii. Womens active participation in the development process; and viii. Effective implementation of decentralization at local level. Salient Features of Integrated Rural Development * Improving the life standard of local communities; * Development of different social aspects like education, health and sanitation, drinking water, employment and skills. Training and other essentials services; * IRDP must be complete within a fixed time period; * It must be community-based; and * It should be coordinated with grassroots level and there must be participatory and decentralization local governance policy. Village Level Local Administration System The Act of Local Government and Local Autonomy has provided legal rights to mobilize local resources. The Act has given more power to local governments to decide themselves in diagnosing problems, determining priorities, implementing, evaluating and arranging provisions to coordinate municipality and Village Development Committee (Gaon Bikash Samitee) (VDC) with local government DDC. At present, VDC plans are being formulated annually through Gaon Parishad (Village Assembly). In this, they consider VDC plan, DDC grant plan and the NGOs plan. All the ward members and NGOs representatives participate in the latter. Plan is implemented through different line agencies, users groups, NGOs and local CBOs. VDC play the role as the village development entity and ward

- 196 -

members coordinate settlement issues with the VDC Executive Board. VDC collect revenues from local road services, approve house maps and various other documents and, manage district grant, nation subsidy, etc. It has an annual budget of nearly US$12,820 and four personnel (Table 1). The process of plan formulation and implementation is illustrated in Figure 1. Table 1. Basic Information on Governance Level Local Name Number Average Population Role/Responsibility

National Desh 1 2,321,4681 PM, NA Regional/zone Bikash kshhetra 5 4.6 million Coordination Province Anchal 14 1.7 million Coordination only District Zilla 75 310,000 DDC (E) Subdistrict Ilaka 475 49,000 Coordination only Village Gaon bikash samitee 3,918 5,900 VDC (E) Settlement Wada 9a 650 VDCb a b Note: Wards/VDC; and consists of five representatives including one female. Role of Users Committees The users committee is the grassroots level organization that ensures peoples participation in IRD work. Users committee is formed from the mass meeting of the local beneficiaries of the concerned project. Local Governance Regulation has made it compulsory that the participation of women members in users committee should not be less than 30 percent of total members in a users committee but the number varies depend upon the size, duration and cost of the project and the area. Users committee can be a useful link between the technical office and the people. Before construction they can act as a source of information about the needs of the people and existing problems in the village. They should be consulted before designs are prepared so that their valuable inputs can be incorporate into the designs. Careful consultation with the users committee during the feasibility stage and site selection will help to eliminate future problems and bring to light special conditions and situations at the project site that might not be noticed by an engineer or technician. Besides the practical value of their advice, it is important to involve the users committee early in the life of the project so that they feel that the project is truly theirs. Without this feeling, it will be more difficult to get necessary cooperation of the users committees. Part of the cost of construction is often met through volunteer labor provided by the users committee. When this is the case, the person in-charge of the site must maintain contact with the users committee to keep them informed of the amount of labor required to keep the project on schedule and all other matters relating to the work. After construction is completed, the users committee is responsible for maintaining the system, whether it is a drinking water supply system, irrigation projects, suspended bridge, roads, trails, buildings or other projects. The technical section of DDC offers support to the users committee by providing information on maintenance procedures, and arranging for the training of village level technicians.

- 197 -

NPC* + DDC Directive

1. Plan Formulation by VDC VDC finance plans VDC plans with DDC grants Plants to be included in DDC program NGOs plan

NPC* + DDC Directive

2. Feasibility Study By VDC for all plan categories

3. Plan Selection By VDC for VDC financed plans NGOs plan

VDC plans with DDC grants Plans to be included in DDC program

Recommendation by Advisory Committee

Approval by DDC

NPC + DDC Directives

4. Implementation by DDC through Secretary/line agencies User groups NGOs

5. Project Completion and Clearance of Accounts By VDC with help of DDC personnel By DDC on the basis of VDC

Figure 1. Village Level Planning and Implementation Procedure Note: * National Planning Commission.

In the past, the users committees were more like informal bodies, and were previously called construction committees. The Local Governance Act has made formal provisions for the users committees. Role of Non-governmental Organizations Many Nepali communities and ethnic groups have a long tradition of Guthi (Trust) for public interest through CBOs. A guthi can be private or public. The purpose of traditional guthi is charity or welfare of clan or community. Some guthis have been in existence for
- 198 -

centuries with some of old traditions and customs still in practice. The written history of civil society organization dates back to 1926, when Kamdhenu, Nepal Gandhi Smarak Charkha Prachaarak Guthi (the Gandhi Memorial Spinning Wheel Propagating Trust) was founded by Tulsi Mehar. It was the first modern Nepali NGO for social reform and citizens selfreliance. In different places, religious societies like Bhajans (group of singing religious song) used to function to make the people aware of their rights and duties. After the establishment of democracy in 1951, different efforts were made for the development of NGOs. In the early 1950s the government took the leadership to launch the community development movement with the assistance of U.S.A. and India and initiated the Tribhuvan Gram Vikas Movement to improve the conditions of the rural areas. This effort led to the formation of some people-based organization. Some of the CSOs like Family Planning Association, Nepal Red Cross Society, Paropakar Sanstha were established with the initiation of the people to help the needy people. Reorientation of development activities is a process of transfer of decision-making and command over resources to peoples organizations and institutions, both from donor agencies and governments. But the national and local NGOs of the developing countries need to play a much larger catalytic role in fostering peoples participation and empowering them. In this era of globalization and unbridled market forces, local CBOs and NGOs are the only institutions that can advance the interest of people as a group. As the agencies of IRD, local NGOs can play an important and effective role in the delivery of services like community health and drinking water, income-generating activities and skill training to uneducated and marginalized rural communities. The greatest advantage in NGOs is that they are flexible in methods of communication, timing of interventions and in the mode of operations. Successful NGOs use to begin a close dialogue with people, identify their needs and work with the people for the fulfillment of qualitative targets, especially when they are not dependent on external donor funding. The process for awareness raising and confidence building in itself is recognized as a development goal. Successful NGOs have worked through organizing communities into groups for self-help, and self-development, which would help in building solidarity of the community members and empowering them. Mobilization of Non-governmental Organizations for Integrated Rural Development The role of NGOs has become increasingly important in making various activities of people-oriented IRD and also in extending services and facilities to the grassroots level. In a liberal administrative environment created after restoration of democracy, NGOs have become involved in large number in various sectors. However, the services and the scopes of activities of those NGOs, which are actively in operation, are limited and small in terms of coverage. The major problems involved in effective mobilization of such organizations include: the lack of coordination among different activities of these NGOs in conformity with social, economic and cultural characteristic and lifestyles of concerned communities; and the lack of proper record-keeping system to monitor and record activities and achievements of NGOs. In this context, NGO will be mobilized in a way to make their work complementary to the development activities carried out by the government. The important contribution made by local NGOs in socio-economic development will be objectively identified and; the nature, scope, resources and capabilities of such local community-based NGOs will be judged and they will be encouraged to work in backward communities and especially in underdeveloped remote regions. They will also be motivated to work as facilitator vis--vis local institutions

- 199 -

including DDCs and VDCs, educational institutions and various community organization (CO) and consumers. A facilitating environment will thus be created to mobilize local NGOs for IRD. An appropriate criterion will be developed for positively evaluating, monitoring and supporting the works, scope and role of NGOs. Institutional Coordination and Network in Local Governance DDC and VDC should coordinate the activities of the NGOs in their working areas so as to avoid duplicate of programs and activities. NGOs mobilization strategies play a vital role to achieve this task. CBOs, i.e., cooperatives, consumers committees, self-reliance organizations, saving and credit groups, etc. have been working in coordination with local governance to solve their own problems. VILLAGE DEVELOPMENT THROUGH SOCIAL MOBILIZATION VDP is one of the Participatory District Development Programs (PDDPs) integral components and the main channel of implementation for participatory and sustainable local governance/development. As a people-centered program, VDPs main thrust is improving livelihood at the household level for alleviating poverty. It uses social mobilization as a tool for urging local people to form their own organizations, to promote their development through their own and other resources, and to actively participate in decision-making process for improving their lives and their surroundings. VDP builds on the lessons learnt from Seed Grant Fund (SGF) activity. SGF had successfully demonstrated the value and effectiveness of the user groups as channels for managing participatory and community-based projects. The Fund had also illustrated the validity of establishing and strengthening an operational partnership between the DDCs and the targeted VDCs. Social mobilization works on the basic premise that poverty is a form of social, political and psychological disempowerment and occurs when people lack access to social base of power and productive wealth. Thus, enhancing peoples access to the social power reinforces their political power too, and an increase in productive wealth leads to improved livelihood. When people are socially empowered the atmosphere is conductive for them to group together into organizations. These organizations, through capital generating and skill enhancement activities, work for the collective benefit of the community. Components of the Village Development Program PDDPs social mobilization has two components: institutional development and economic development. The underlying assumption in the social mobilization process is that people get organized to work together if they live in close proximity and share common interests for community development. The foremost requirement in the institutional development process is that people organize themselves into COs. A CO is created around activities of maintaining importance to most of the villagers, whose continuing economic interests are best served by organizing themselves as a group. Active participation is sought from all households, without any restrictions or discriminations. This is essential for the whole society to move together in consensus and to build community-level social capital. When individuals organize themselves into broad-based groups, they have the control with which to address and tackle problems that they alone could not have done.

- 200 -

Once the social capital has been mobilized, the COs work to build up their economic capital. The people in the community need an incentive to remain organized. They require high returns from any social innovation to offset the risk involved in change, and to compensate for extra effort often required in terms of labor. Economic development provides the COs with a mechanism to capture the potential benefits of social change. To build up their economic capital, the group members deposit monetary contribution into the groups savings account during their regular meetings. The COs also supplement their income by upgrading their skills to conduct income-generating activities. COs can have access to credit capital facility established in the Local Trust Fund (LTF) to fulfill their credit needs for establishing micro enterprises and other income-generating activities. When they organize themselves, save and upgrade their skills, the COs can have access to a one-time investment through seed grant for increasing productivity, improving infrastructure, as well enhancing the COs resource management capacities. As an essential element in VDP, a seed grant is matched with cost-sharing contributions from the DDCs and VDCs (cash) and COs (kind). If required, the DDCs and the VDCs will tap the resources from district line agencies and other sources for the implementation of VDP. Figure 2 illustrates the VDP process. VDP Process Phase 1. Formation of Community Organizations Phase 2. Graduation of Community Organizations Phase 3. Activating Community-based Entrepreneurial Skills Service Phase 4. Implementing Priority Productive Investments Figure 2. The VDC Process Phase One: Formation of Community Organizations The first phase of VDP implementation is community mobilization and the formation of a broad-based multipurpose CO. The average duration of this phase can vary from one to two months. The formation of COs is initiated through a sensitization program or a series of dialogues, which forges partnership with the local communities. The aim is to mobilize and get CO members to work together to make their organizations stronger and to develop an alternative local institution to support local development. Phase Two: Graduation of Community Organizations The second phase, with an average of less than a month, tests the maturity and formation of the COs and encourage to initiate program activities which do not require external inputs or costs but which can bring the members to work together for a common

- 201 -

cause with their own resources and inputs. These include small village development activities, literacy classes for illiterate CO members, family planning activities, formation of cultural groups, clubs, etc. During this phase, each member of the CO is also encouraged to make plans for undertaking at least one farm and non-farm entrepreneurial activity that will contribute to both economic and social well-being of their village. Phase Three: Activating Community-based Entrepreneurial Skills In this phase, which takes about three months, the COs can access the LTF to undertake individual as well as collective entrepreneurial activities of their choice. During this phase, the COs can start utilizing their savings for small-scale credit purposes and can also tap on LTF credit support for initiating community-based entrepreneurial activities. Such credit support is provided to the COs based on the amount of savings they have accumulated and based on the principles of social collateral. The plan prepared and approved by the COs under phase 2 activities form the basis for identifying entrepreneurial opportunities. Support from LTF is provided to COs who have graduated or demonstrated towards self-reliance and social empowerment. Phase Four: Implementing Priority Productive Investments During this phase, which lasts for three or more months, the COs finalize the VDC plan and productive infrastructure priorities. Support is offered through the SGF to fund local investments of the COs such as irrigation projects, drinking water supply schemes, microhydro, development of higher levels of cooperative enterprises, commercial forestry and others. Where possible, it also assists them in accessing markets and enhancing their sustainable resource management capacities. Grants are only given to those projects that are sustainable and provide common benefits for all members of the CO, enhance the productivity of COs. These grants are therefore provided as a means to get the CO members to work together to make their organization stronger and to develop alternative local institutions to support local development. Progress Progress of the program is shown in Tables 2-4. HORIZONTAL AND VERTICAL LINKAGES FOR VILLAGE DEVELOPMENT An intensive efforts is made to establish working relationships between COs and sectoral line agencies at the district level, as well as to tap their resources in the social mobilization process. Once VDP is fully functional, the COs should be transformed into selfgoverning grassroots institutions. These institutions, in the long run, will act as permanentreceiving mechanism of various resources directed for local development. Public-Private Partnership A participatory approach to development entails that there must be a non-central but polycentric process of development. This approach stresses on a multiplicity of sources for initiatives and decision-making, allowing a wide range of alternative institutions and funding mechanisms for IRD. The decentralized and sustainable participatory development advocated by PDDP argues that development efforts, in order to be relevant to local needs, as well as sustainable, must be an integrated effort of all the stakeholders involved: the government line agencies, the local bodies, private organizations, NGOs and COs. Nepals rural development

- 202 -

Table 2. Program Coverage, 1998 Settlements Covered Number Covered Members Total Number of Settlements Percentage Covered Households Percentage Covered District Number of Wards

- 203 -

Acham Baglung Baitadi Banke Bhaktapur Chitwan Dadeldhura Dang Kaski Kapilbastu Kavre Myagdi Nawalparasi Nuwakot Parbat Rupandehi Tanahu Total 744 1,571 1,835 85.61 50,135

44 45 42 45 43 43 43 40 45 45 45 42 47 43 43 45 44

58 82 99 65 147 88 105 101 140 55 94 68 88 91 64 91 135

58 87 133 83 179 104 152 147 151 55 100 78 91 108 68 96 145

100.00 94.25 74.44 78.31 82.12 84.62 69.08 68.71 92.72 100.00 94.00 87.18 96.70 84.26 94.12 94.79 93.10

2,165 2,456 2,309 3,218 3,446 3,790 2,137 3,429 3,709 2,214 3,036 2,029 4,068 2,945 2,026 3,204 3,954

2,317 2,743 3,067 4,884 4,726 5,145 3,301 3,887 4,797 4,082 4,393 2,821 6,406 4,088 2,238 4,122 4,292 67,309

93.44 89.54 75.29 65.89 72.92 73.66 64.74 88.22 77.32 54.24 69.11 71.92 63.50 72.04 90.53 77.73 92.12 74.48

policy, like most other developing countries, has so far relied extensively on government agencies to implement projects that provide social services and infrastructure development. The demands, however, far exceed the capacity of the government agencies to deliver. On the other hand, the private sector has more resources, and the NGOs and womens organizations have the capacity to deliver on a sustainable basis. Contribution of the private sector is especially significant for the generation of employment and income in the nonagriculture sector and in the post-production stage in the agriculture sector. In the absence of organized institutions at the community level, these communities have not been able to exploit the resources potentials of both these sectors. Table 3. Gender Equity Indicators Factors of Progress Internal savings generated (Rs. million) Amount loaned to (percent): Men Women Number of CO members taking loan: Male members External credit mobilized from LTF (Rs. million) Amount loaned to (percent): Men Women Number of CO members taking loans (percent): Male members Female members Women in leadership positions: Women chairpersons Women managers Female village experts Family planning adoption: Men Women Note: Figures in parentheses are percent of total.

December 1999 September 2000 43.8 53 47 31,477 (50) 88.2 56 44 57 43 1,567 (42) 1,455 (39) 943 (38) 16,203 13,183 81.1 54 47 52,039 (51) 189.7 54 46 55 45 2,356 (41) 2,159 (38) 1,732 (41) 27,415 29,627

Table 4. Effects and Impacts of Village Development Program, 1998 December September Parameters Unit 1996 2000 1. Community Organizations: Organizations of males Organizations of females Mixed organizations 2. Poverty Profile: Poorest households Poor households Medium households ) Percent of ) ) households ) ) Percent of ) ) households ) 73 13 14 50 33 17 36 38 26

Change -37 24 12

29 -21 39 6 32 15 ... To be continued

- 204 -

Table 4. Continuation Parameters 3. Food Sufficiency Level: Food surplus households 9-2 months 6-9 months 3-6 months Up to three months 4. Education: School enrolment boys School enrolment girls School dropout boys School dropout girls Literacy rate Primary schools managed by COs 5. Health and Sanitation: Households with toilets Households with drinking water within 30 minutes walking distance 6. Economic Activities: Households taking loan from local moneylenders Average interest rate of local moneylenders Village cadres in agriculture (total) Village cadres in animal science (total) 7. Households Roofing Type: Tin roof Stone roof Thatch roof 8. Self-initiated Activities Community building owned by CO Length of trails that COs rehabilitated (total) Unit December 1996 6 22 24 26 22 47 32 21 25 38 0 20 52 September 2000 9 25 25 23 18 78 69 10 8 53 60 54 70 Change 3 3 1 -3 -4 31 37 -11 -17 15 60 34 18

) ) ) Percent of ) ) households ) )

) ) ) ) Percent ) ) ) ) Number Percent

) ) ) Percent ) ) ) ) ) Number ) ) Percent

50 36 0 1 10 11 11

15 23 653 292 22 33 11 149 1,366

-35 -13 653 292 12 22 0 148 1,366

Number km

1 0

Partners in Progress It was clear that the resources available in the private and public sectors should be linked and coordinated. Also, the community-level institutions should be strengthened to exploit the potential exist in the districts that PDDP has been promoting. Public-private partnership should be established among DDCs, VDCs, private organizations, NGOs, and
- 205 -

CBOs. This partnership should focus on promoting rural investment opportunities by tapping into the production capabilities of the rural communities, linking them with existing capital resources of the private sector and by exploiting existing market potentials. Such partnerships between local authorities and private sector will have a synergistic effect on the overall development of the districts joint efforts, which would be complementary to each other. This would be demand-based and pre-planned to achieve the objectives of economic development. Through public-private partnership, PDDP aims to initiate and support the mechanism for building confidence amongst the public and private sectors for the promotion of coordination, planning, and implantation of DDPs. It also aims to initiate and support the mobilization of the private sector producers, investors, marketing people and other planners together with the communities to form institutions for the enhancement of local governance, rural investment and development. Based on the success of the district and VDP, PDDP emphasizes on people-oriented, cooperative self-help efforts to implement public-private partnership in selected districts to support rural investment opportunities and also to strengthen local governance. This program envisages joint efforts by the DDCs and the private sector organizations to promote rural investment opportunities by tapping into the production capabilities of the rural communities; linking them to existing capital resources of the private sector; and by exploiting existing market potentials. Partnership between local authorities and the private sector will have a synergistic effect on the overall development of the district, as these joint efforts are complementary to each other and will be demand-based and preplanned to achieve the objectives of economic development. Support Organizations The public-private partnership is implemented through Support Organizations. The local Chambers of Commerce and Industries (CCI), which have representations from various types of private sector organizations operating in the districts, which also possess sound knowledge of the problems and opportunities for economic development that exist in the districts, are the ideal institutions as Support Organizations. Participatory Planning and Monitoring PDDP assists the DDCs to implement a trickle-up planning and monitoring process, based on the principles of participation, transparent decision-making and coordination between political bodies, technical agencies, NGOs and the communities. This process documents peoples needs and the available resources at the grassroots level and percolate it up through several prioritizing layers to the district where they are incorporated into the District Development Plan. These Plans are then forwarded to the central level to be incorporated into the National Annual Plan to receive central funding. CONCLUSION The VDP of Nepal is based on the concept of Putting the People First. It offers new opportunities for competent participation of people at the grassroots level in the planning and implementing process. It urges communities, both men and women, towards self-reliance and self-governance by encouraging them to group into broad-based multipurpose COs. The major phases of the process are: a) formation of CO; b) graduation of CO; c) activating community-based entrepreneurial skills service; and d) implementing priority productive investments. This is certainly a better alternative for local community participation in IRD.

- 206 -

REFERENCES Acharya, Bal Ram, undated. Development Sociology. Acharya, Umesh, 2001. Decentralization and Local Governance. Bista, Santosh, undated. Rural Development in Nepal. Gelal, Mani Ram, 2002. Participatory Rural Infrastructure Development in Nepal. PDDP, 2000. Making A Difference, PDDP Impact Series: 01/2000. UNDP and NORAD, 1998. Putting People First, The Year in Review.

- 207 -

10. PAKISTAN
Abdul Sattar
Deputy Chief (in-charge) Planning and Development Division Government of Pakistan Islamabad

INTRODUCTION The total area of the Islamic Republic of Pakistan is 79.61 million ha and the cultivated area is 20.96 million ha. Out of the total population of 140.5 million, about 67 percent is living in the rural areas. At present, the population growth rate is 2.15 percent per annum. The total labor force of the country is nearly 41.2 million (28.4 million in rural and 12.8 million in urban) and the unemployment rate is estimated at 5.9 percent. Nearly 33 percent of the population is living below poverty line. Agriculture contributes about 25 percent to GDP, 44 percent of the countrys workforce and sustainability of export earnings. The nonagricultural GDP, however, grew by 4.3 percent as against 3.1 percent last year. Besides agriculture, the value addition in electricity and gas distribution has also been adversely affected by drought. Pakistan presents a unique picture of experiencing a relatively stronger economic growth with poor social indicators. In other words, Pakistans growth performance and the state of social indicators appear to be incongruous. In most cases, Pakistans social indicators are not comparable with those of developing countries. It is endeavored to improve its social indicators for both economic and equity grounds. Pakistan is primarily an agriculture economy with a network of canals irrigating a major part of its cultivated land. Wheat, cotton, rice, millet and sugarcane are the major crops. Among fruits, mangoes, oranges, bananas and apples are grown in abundance in different parts of the country. The main natural resources are natural gas, coal, salt and iron. The country has an expanding industry. Cotton textile, sugar, cement and chemicals pay an important role in its economy. It is fed by cast hydroelectric power. Pakistan witnessed a prolonged and sustained period of economic growth with an annual average rate of more than 6 percent in the past three decades, fastest in the South Asia. But this economic advance has not been translated into the betterment of lives of rural poor. The income gap between the poor and the rich household has widened. Growth has failed to tickle down to the poor. Arising income inequality and poverty with other factors have accompanied the slowing down of growth in the 1990s. The incidence of calories based poverty, despite increase in per capita income of above 1 percent, almost doubled from 17.4 percent in 1987 to 30 percent in 1999-2000. The position become more delicate if a broader definition of poverty (basic needs) is taken into consideration. RURAL DEVELOPMENT SCENARIO The importance of the rural sector of Pakistan in the national economy is evident from the fact that it produces bread and butter for the entire national contributes nearly 24 percent to the GNP, earns about 50 percent of foreign exchange, employs about 46 percent of civilian

- 208 -

labor force, provides raw material for industries and serves as the main market for a large proportion of industrial products. In this respect, rural Pakistan may be legitimately termed as the backbone of the countrys economy. However, the rural poor who hold small landholdings could not produce any tangible effect on redistribution of physical assets and labor productivity. Rural development is a challenge as well as a promise. It is a challenge that baffles the policy-makers and administrators and puts their initiative, ingenuity and resourcefulness to severe test. At the same time it holds out a promise of better future and new vistas of development, modernization and progress for the vast multitudes who stand condemned to a life of poverty, disease, ignorance and the concomitant maladies that plaque an underdeveloped society. However, rural development has no magic remedy for the multifarious problems that afflict the rural people. It is, on the other hand, a painfully slow process that calls for collaborative effort of the entire community and the pooling and integration of all recourse, human and material, to combat and surmount the problems that have accumulated over centuries. It is a dynamic program that requires the development of innovative techniques and new strategies to meet the ever-changing demands of a development-oriented society. It is not concerned merely with providing a package of services and inputs leading to an improvement of physical infrastructure which constitutes the outer surface of the system, but also involves the change of attitude and the replacement of the anachronistic values and traditions with a progressive and enlightened out look and behavior patterns. The change of attitude is particularly important for public officials who are now required to give up their authoritarian stance and to work with the people and guide them, where necessary, in the task of nation building. Objectives of Rural Development in Pakistan The principal aim of rural development in Pakistan is to improve the quality of life of the rural people by improving the rural economy and living conditions in the villages. The main objectives of growth-oriented rural development strategy are the following: i. ii. iii. iv. To improve the rural infrastructure To provide the social amenities to rural people To undertake such productive projects as will satisfy the felt-needs of the people To combat unemployment and underemployment by enlarging opportunities for gainful work v. To mobilize local resources create the spirit of self-help and motivate the people for participation in rural uplift programs vi. To meaningfully integrate rural development with the national socio-economic development effort and further development of existing infrastructure.

The objective of the rural development strategy is to provide infrastructure and social amenities like construction of roads, supply of water, village electrification and provision of health and educational facilities. The strategies and approaches adopted/advocated so far can be grouped under the following major categories: * * * Growth strategy Welfare strategy Integrated rural development approaches.

- 209 -

1. Growth Strategy During 1950s and the beginning of 1960s, national and international development efforts focused on growth criteria to achieve the rapid economic development with an assumption that the benefits of development will trickle down to the poor and disadvantaged groups. The strategy could not be able to achieve its desired objectives because of peculiar technical, geo-political and socio-economic reasons. It rather resulted in intensifying the gap between the rich and poor besides creating regional imbalances. 2. Welfare Strategy Basic needs approach was adopted afterwards for socio-economic upliftment of the society or alleviation of rural poverty under the Welfare State concept. The underlying idea was to provide basic necessities of life such as food, shelter, clothing, medical and educational facilities, etc. to the poor segments of the society. The basic assumption was that the poor did not have the capability to stand on their feet so the government should help them in every sector of life. This assumption created attitude among the poor who later got the tendency of looking upon the government to solve even their petty problem. However, the limited resources of the government led to new way of thinking which focused more on involvement of people in the development process. Community-based Rural Development Approaches and Programs The lessons learnt from the failure of the past development strategies led to better understanding of the nature and complexity of rural society. Rural poverty was then the main concern of the development experts in 1970s. The causes of rural poverty were considered multiple and inter-dependent so an integrated or holistic approach involving all the relevant sectors was adopted for achieving the objectives of rural development. LOCAL GOVERNMENT SYSTEM 2000 The present government has initiated Local Government Plan 2000 to evolve Good Governance though the empowerment of civil society from district to Tehsil and village level. The reconstruction process aims to utilize to bottom-up methodology, be peoplecentered, transformation all segments of the society are be included as potential partners in the national reconstruction process. The government announced a strategy for the reconstruction of local government that addresses the agenda point on Devolution of Power at the grassroots level. This process involves the devolution of power through introduction of new District Government System for empowerment of local communities at grassroots level and the tenderization of the government and NGOs functionaries at various tiers. The new system is primarily: (i) peopleoriented; (ii) right- and responsibility-based; (iii) right to development; (iv) right to participation; and (v) right to information. The government attaches high priority to strengthening of local government institutions for ensuring effective and maximum participation of beneficiaries in the development process at grassroots level. The government believes that objectives of decentralization can be realized by associating the local government institutions and the local community organizations in planning and implementation of development programs and strengthening local leadership capabilities. The essentials of this Devolution/Local Government Plan is based on five fundamentals:

- 210 -

i. ii. iii. iv. v.

Devolution of political power; Decentralization of administrative authority; De-concentration of management functions; Diffusion of the power authority nexus; and Distribution of resources to the district level.

Presently the administrative set-up of local government comprises the districts, tehsils, and villages under the provincial governments. There are district councils, tehsil councils and union councils at district, tehsil, and village levels. The elections of the local councils were held in May 2001. The structure of the local administration system is as follows: (i) union; (ii) tehsil; (iii) town; (iv) district; and (v) city district. A union comprises one or more census villages with more or less a uniform population. Its boundaries do not cross the limits of a tehsil, or a town in a city district. A town may be as declared by the government a whole number of contiguous unions to be a town in the city district. A city district/district may be one or more tehsils within one or more adjoining districts as a city district with a population exceeding one million people having commercial industrial economy and existing administrative and municipal. The new system of local government installed on 14 August 2001 provides an integrated three-tier local government structure ranging from the smallest unit union, tehsil and district levels. The unions are organized in rural as well as urban areas across the whole district. Unions have directly elected union councils consisting of 21 member including Union Nazim and Naib Union Nazim. Union Nazims are also members of the respective district council. Likewise Naib Union Nazims are members of respective tehsil council. They provide vertical linkages between the three tiers of local government. The middle tier, i.e. the tehsil has Tehsil Nazim with tehsil municipal officers working under the control of the Tehsil Nazim. The Tehsil Council consists of Naib Union Nazims and indirectly elected Tehsil Councilors against the reserved seats of women, peasants and workers and minorities. At the top tier the district government consists of a District Nazim and district administrator. The district administrator is responsible to the District Nazim. There is just one line of authority from the district down to unions but with adequate checks and balances to ensure that it serves the people and not to rule them. The district council consists of Union Nazims and indirectly elected district councilors against the reserved seats of women, peasants, workers and minorities. For the first time in the history of Pakistan, women have been guaranteed representation of at least 33 percent at every tier of local government. This would allow empowerment of the traditionally marginalized sections of the society. The local government system envisages that large cities will be declared city districts in a phased manner. The peculiarities of these large urban centers call for variations in the administrative, municipal and police structures. These structures have already been installed in the provincial headquarters. The plan effectively addresses the specific needs and problems of urbanized districts in future. The proposed Local Government Plan integrates the rural areas with the urban local governments on the one hand, and the bureaucracy with the local governments on the other, into one coherent structure in which the district administration and police are answerable to the elected chief executive of the district, citizen monitoring by elected representatives, the civil societys involvement with development, and a system of effective checks and balances, completes the hard core of the political structure and system of the local government.

- 211 -

Role of Local Communities in Integrated Rural Development To involve people more actively in community development, grassroots organization like the village councils and citizen community boards are introduced to ensure effective integrated rural development. Village and neighborhood councils provide direct interface between the people at the grassroots and the local governance for changing attitudes and promoting community drives. The new approach in community participation enables proactive citizens to participate in community development/service through creating voluntary organizations called citizen community boards. Following are selected local level organizations functioning in Pakistan. SELECTED RURAL DEVELOPMENT PROGRAMS IN PAKISTAN The Agha Khan Rural Support Program The Agha Khan Rural Support Program (AKRSP) is a private, non-communal, nonprofit company, established by the Aga Khan Foundation to help improve the quality of life of the villagers of northern Pakistan. It was established in December 1984 with a mandate to focus on income generation in collaboration with government departments, elected bodies, national and international development agencies and commercial institutions. In particular, diversified, sustainable and equitable economic development is promoted through building the competence and confidence of local organizations and individuals, and through the provision of economic resources and opportunities. AKRSP acts as a catalyst for rural development, organize resources so that local institutional structures are gradually developed to sustain the process of development. Local institutions and NGOs fostered in the region exist and function at various levels. At the village level, a network of more than 3,973 village organizations and womens organizations has been capacitated to undertake local development initiatives. These organizations are today successfully managing a range of activities including local infrastructure creation, natural resource management, savings and credit, and small-scale enterprise development. Finally, at the local area level, AKRSP has helped develop local NGOs and other development organizations charged with yet broader sets of functions including helping build capacity of smaller village institutions, operating and managing social sector facilities, protecting and enhancing common property resources, and working with government line departments to help influence local development outcomes. To this end, capacity-building services provided to these NGOs include intensive trainings in management, financial accounting, proposal development, and fundraising; linking them to possible funding sources, and exposure visits and workshops for there enhanced sensitization and awareness. AKRSP commenced its activities in the Gilgit region of the Northern areas in 1982, and extended its activities on a trial basis in 1983 to the Chitral district of the Northwest Frontier Province (NWFP). During 1986, the complete range of AKRSP programs were introduced in Chitral and the Baltistan region of the northern areas. The six districts of the program area have a combined population of approximately one million, consisting of about 111,000 households, in over 1,100 villages, settled on an area of 74,200 km2. The region is rugged and mountainous, located among the four of the highest mountain ranges the Himalayas, Karakoram, Pamir, and the Hindukush.

- 212 -

National Rural Support Program National Rural Support Program (NRSP) was established in 1992 to set up a countrywide program for poverty alleviation. The program aims at setting up a network of grassroots organizations (community organizations) through social mobilization. NRSPs strategy is to harness peoples potential to help themselves for which NRSP provides social guidance to the organized communities. Social mobilization is the core of NRSPs philosophy. It is based on the concept that the community is the center of all development activities. It is only informed and enlarged community members who can plan and undertake sustainable grassroots developments. NRSP extends micro credit to the poor who do not have tangible collateral. In order to facilitate the community organizations and its members in the repayment of their loans in difficult times, NRSP encourages them to generate a matching saving before requesting NRSP for a loan. However, in order to ensure that this does not discourage the poorest community organization members, NRSP has set flexible ceilings for such mandatory savings. NRSP facilitates the community organizations in developing new enterprises or improving the existing ones through its vocational training program and natural resource management program. As part of the Village Improvement Program (VIP), the community organization members also receive training in business development and financial management. Balochistan Rural Support Program Balochistan Rural Support Program (BRSP) is the second province after NWFP, which accepted the modality of community-based development of rural support programs. In Balochistan where community mobilization efforts are far more difficult than the other province, BRSP performed fairly well in its initial years of operation. Village organizations were formed in 13 districts out of 26 in the province. There has been reasonable savings in these village organizations, which demonstrated the interest of the communities for the development work under participatory methodology. However, due to internal difficulties, BRSP could not continue its pace of progress and it is almost dormant for the last two years. INTEGRATED AREA DEVELOPMENT PROGRAMS IN PAKISTAN The concept of area development implies an integrated development of the program area covering all aspects of its socio-economic life, including productive sectors, which include natural resource management, social sector services and physical infrastructure. The area development approach facilitates seeking such solutions. The approach requires that the area selected for program implementation is large enough so that adequate coverage of all aspects is possible and the majority of the areas needs are met in a practical way. Besides, the size of the area should be sufficient to create economies of scale. The extent of the area to be covered by the program, at any one time will depend on the resources available. The integrated development approach would necessitate a focus on several broader issues to adequately development the area. Some of these may not be of immediate concern to ordinary villager, but may determine the extent to which local initiatives stand a chance of success. Good examples of such issues are: * * lack of all weather access roads; degradation of rangelands and loss of biodiversity;

- 213 -

* * *

low productivity of the crops and livestock production systems; rapidly dropping groundwater levels; and unexploited or untapped mineral resources.

Some of the important integrated area development programs implemented in Pakistan can be summarized as follows: Chitral Area Development Program The Chitral Area Development Program (CADP) jointly funded by International Fund for Agricultural Development (IFAD) and the Government of NWFP has been a first major intervention in Chitral for integrated area development after the AKRSP. The main purpose of the CADP was to eradiate poppy cannabis cultivation from the program area and to provide alternate means of livelihood. Dir District Development Project The Dir District Development Project (DDDP) is an integrated area development program for the district of Dir. This project is in place for over a decade now. It was designed for five years with the financial and technical assistance of the United Nation Fund for Drug Abuse Control. The Government of NWFP is a partner in funding the project. The goal of the project is to eliminate poppy cultivation and providing an alternate livelihood to the people of the district. Initially in the first phase, there was a project management unit (PMU) and a technical support unit (TSU). The PMU consisted of national staff and the project manager headed the unit while in the TSU, all the technical advisers were expatriates. Now in the second phase, the TSU has stopped functioning. The DDDP transformed gradually from a government implementing status to the formation of community organization. Initially the communities used to be consulted and now they are participating with a community development approach. The project is multi-sectoral in nature. All the sectors being dealt by the line agencies are also the focus of the DDDP. In the first phase the major interventions included construction of roads, electrification in the poppy growing valleys provision of subsidies on fertilizer seeds and introduction of improve varieties of crops and seeds. Sixtyfive km of metalled roads leading to the poppy growing valleys was constructed in the first three years of the project life. These valleys though far flung and deep into the rural areas were also electrified with a huge investment. Area Development Program Balochistan The Area Development Program Balochistan (ADPB) is one of the major interventions planned under sustainable livelihoods; with the resource poor rural people of the province as its target beneficiaries. The ADPB is planned to be a model of community-based poverty eradication and is aimed at executing peoples choices and opportunities for a secure and sustainable livelihood. The program approach being used in formulating ADPB replaces the stand-alone projects made of development support and covers a broader spectrum of integrated and area specific activities. Learning from the past experiences, this approach tries to overcome the problems, which stood in the way of creating the desired impact on the livelihoods of the target beneficiaries. It is based on analysis of an areas human needs and priorities and its physical resource base and focuses on peoples participation as the main tool to increase

- 214 -

production and productivity on a sustainable basis. The program approach is thus essentially based on two fundamental principles of area development and Pakistan. Informal/Social Institutions in Integrated Rural Development The term institution is by no means clear and does not convey the same meaning to everybody. It is probably one of the many misunderstood words, especially when one tries to interpret its technical meanings. The dictionary meanings of the word are an act of organizing, setting up, or founding. It is also defined as an established practice, law or custom. The institution has also been indicated as a society or cooperation, especially of a public character and may also include the building, which houses it. The social scientists generally agree that rural communities are different from other communities in many respects. People in rural areas tend to live in a village type of settlement. A village may contain between 20 to over several hundred families, depending upon socio-cultural and natural factors. The population density in rural areas, on the average, is lower than in the urban areas. The low population density makes it possible for agricultural occupations to continue. In rural areas, most people, therefore, earn their living through agricultural work. Only a small percentage of population is engaged in other occupations. The social relations in rural areas revolve around kinship and friends more than with other members of the community. Kinship and friendship are thus very important aspects in rural area. This does not mean that other institutions are not important. In fact, the geographical and other conditions may look similar in rural areas; they could be radically different from the socio-cultural point of view. Therefore, the socio-cultural conditions of rural community need a more comprehensive and detailed discussion especially in terms of family type, group formation and function and types of rural social relations. The social institutions in rural areas are effective means for rural community development. These institutions are numerous and different. Depending upon particular cultural trepidations of the rural society it is important for any development initiative to examine and study the particular institution in a specified rural environment. It will be wrong to assume that the rural conditions and particularly the rural institutions are the same. The major social institutions as identified in rural areas are family, kinship, education, health, economic and profession, political and administration, and belief and religious institutions. It is generally assumed that all these institutions behave jointly and independently to support promote and perpetuate the existence of the society as a whole. To identify and mobilize rural institutions for development it requires a vast amount of knowledge skill and effort including knowledge about human behavior culture and psychology skill and communication and efforts to improve human conditions. The guidelines given for development workers cannot be exhaustive. Since the institutions do not operate in isolation, linkages must be forged and established not only between the institutions but with the environment as well. Four such linkages have been identified: i) enabling linkages; ii) functional linkages; iii) normative linkages; and iv) defused linkages. The structure and working of different government institutions presently working in rural areas differ so widely. It is very difficult to propose general strategies for making structural improvements in these organizations. When one complains that local institution are not working one usually means the newly established institutions. The rural development specialists have indicated three alternatives which are: (a) to oppose and try to undermine the existing institutions; (b) to ignore and work around them; (c) to try to use and work through

- 215 -

them; or (d) to try to work with and build on them. The last two options generally make more sense. The third alternative corresponds to a promotion mode where persons in traditional social institutions are opted to work on activities essentially defined and determined from working on the pattern of organizations already familiar and accepted. Examples of such institutions could be the formation of large cooperatives for credit services from irrigation being carried by an informal cooperative system for generations. The government institutions established to provide various services can and should operate through the existing social institutions in rural areas. Sustainable development is greatly dependent on the political will of the governments, mode of governance, the capacities of a state and the abilities of its people. It also requires a legal environment under which communities are empowered to pursue programs/projects. It is a universally acknowledged fact that people are both the means and the end to development. Often this simple truth gets obscured because we are used to taking in abstractions, in aggregates in numbers. Human beings fortunately are too stubborn to lend them to becoming a mere abstraction are conveniently forgotten. REFERENCES Agha Khan Rural Support Program, 2001-2002. Annual Report. APO, 1999. Role of Institutions in Rural Community Development, proceedings of the Study Meeting on Role of Institutions in Rural Community Development, 21-29 September 1998 held in Colombo, APO, Tokyo Economic Advisor Wing, Finance Division, 2001-2002. Economic Survey of Pakistan, Government of Pakistan. Government of Pakistan, 2000-2001. Eighth Annual Report, National Rural Support Program. Israr, Ch. Israr-Ul-Haque and Hussain Ahmad, 1999. Country paper presented at APO Multicountry Observational Study Mission on Local Community Development through Revitalization of Community-based Industries, 7-16 March 1999 held in Japan, APO, Tokyo. National Reconstruction Bureau, 2000. Local Government Plan, Chief Executive Secretariat, Government of Pakistan. Pakistan Academy for Rural Development, 1990. Local Government for Rural Development in Pakistan. Planning Commission, 2001-2002. Progress Report on PSDP Projects, Government of Pakistan. ----------, 2001. Perspective Development Plan, Government of Pakistan.

- 216 -

11. PHILIPPINES
Adeliza F. Gabalfin
Chief Agrarian Reform Program Officer Bureau of Agrarian Reform Beneficiaries Development Department of Agrarian Reform (BARBD-DAR) Quezon City

INTRODUCTION Agriculture1 remains the critical economic sector in the Philippine economy. Half of the labor force is engaged in agriculture. Moreover, 80 percent of the nations wealth is controlled by the richest 20 percent. Around 50 percent of the population in the countryside is below poverty threshold. This situation is the result of inequality in the distribution of productive assets (land, income and opportunities) and powerlessness among the population in the countryside. This also causes the high level of in-migration from the rural areas to the big cities like Manila, Cebu, Cagayan de Oro, Davao, Iloilo, etc. Thus, the poverty in the Philippines is largely a rural phenomenon and that the redistributive reform holds the key to rural development. Inequality and growth are the two big challenges that necessitate to vigorously push sustainable rural development. In order to realize this, the following must be addressed/ considered: a) distribution of the productive asset (land) to the landless farming families; b) strengthen public participation, cooperation and accountability; c) active participation of the people in the designing, planning and implementing projects and in the delivery of basic services; d) enhancing and strengthening the capabilities of peoples organizations (POs), cooperatives and local institutions; e) improvement of rural infrastructure and appropriate technologies; f) facilitate investment and marketing tie-ups and opportunities; g) ensure participation of major stakeholders such as the local government units (LGUs), civil societies and business; and h) provision of basic social services such as education, health, potable water supply, etc. To ensure the sustainability of rural development programs/projects, it should be anchored on the expressed needs of the rural poor and their participation in the planning, implementation and monitoring. This paper discusses the role of the local communities (cooperatives, NGOs, POs, farmers associations/organizations and LGUs) in the implementation of agrarian reform communities (ARCs) development program as an integrated rural development model. LOCAL ADMINISTRATION IN THE PHILIPPINES Local governments are defined as political units or instrumentalities constituted by law, the peculiar or unique characteristic of which is their subordinate status to the central

Agriculture includes fisheries and forestry as well. - 217 -

government, which has substantial control over local affairs and likewise the power to tax (Sosmea, 1991:1). Before the entry of the Spaniards in 1521, the Philippines were comprised of independent socio-economic units called the barangays and sultanates. A barangay was headed by a datu who served as head of the government, as well as legislator, judge and executioner. The Spaniards cut the powers of the datu and imposed a centralized system of local government. The Royal Decree of 1583 organized the islands into provincias (provinces), pueblos (municipalities), cabildos (cities) and barrios. Power was centralized in Manila, a set-up characterizing national-local relations for the whole Spanish era. During the declaration of independence in 1989 by Emilio Aguinaldo, a local government plan was drafted organizing the towns to be supervised by commissioners and election of officials. The central government exercised full control of these towns. During the American occupation, municipal councils were created. They were composed of president and the headman of the barrios within the town. A blueprint for town organization was developed which included the election of the presidents through viva voce by the residents. The powers include the creation of police force, collection of taxes and enforcement of regulations on market and sanitation, schools, and lighting facilities among others. The centralist relationship between local and national remained. LGUs performed services for their own behalf but only acted as agents of the national government (Tapales, 1992:26). Efforts to expand and focusing on the role of local government were undertaken in 1970s. After the declaration of Martial Law, four cities2 and 13 municipalities3 were integrated under a political region and metropolitan system of governance known as Metro Manila. Changes in local government structures were made such as: change in the function of the Ministry of Local Government, creation of the Ministry of Human Settlements under the First Lady which took over the role of community development and the transfer of cooperative function to the Ministry of Agriculture. These changes resulted in greater centralization of structures. The EDSA Revolution in 1986 which brought an end to the Marcos dictatorship, paved the way to new democratic processes. The resurgence of NGOs, POs and non-traditional politicians paved the way for the enactment of the 1987 Constitution which provided new emphasis on the local government and the passage of Local Government Code (LGC) of 1991 (Tapales, 1992:33). The Code provides for a more responsive and accountable local government structure instituted through the system of decentralization. Under decentralization, LGUs shall be given more powers, authority, responsibilities and resources. The main feature of LGC is decentralization4 in three forms: de-concentration; devolution; and de-bureaucratization. It provided LGUs autonomous powers in four areas: agriculture,

2 3

Manila, Quezon City, Caloocan, and Pasay. Marikina, Pasig, Mandaluyong, Makati, Valenzuela, Taguig, Muntinlupa, San Juan, Paraaque, Las Pias, Pateros, Malabon, and Navotas. Decentralization is defined as the rational downward transfer of power within and/or outside formal organization. It refers to the basic concept of and process of shifting and delegating power and authority from a central power to subordinate level within the administrative hierarchy, in order to promote independence, responsibility and swift decision-making in adopting policies and programs to the needs of the lower level (Sosmea, 1991:61). - 218 -

health, environment and local infrastructure. LGU as defined under the LGC includes the provinces, cities, municipalities and barangays. Barangay is the basic political unit and serves as the primary planning and implementing unit of government policies, plans, programs, projects and activities in the community, and serves as forum wherein the collective views of the people may be crystallized and considered, and where disputes may be amicably settled (Figure 1). President 79 Provinces Metro Manila 12 Cities and 5 Municipalities 1,694 Barangays

1,491 Municipalities 37,657 Barangays

101 Cities 2,292 Barangays

Figure 1. Local Administration Structure in the Philippines Source: Department of Interior and Local Government, Bureau of Local Government Development.

As embodied in the Code, a barangay consists of a contiguous territory with a population of two thousand inhabitants in the rural areas. Within Metro Manila and in other highly urbanized territories a barangay may contain certified populations of least five thousand inhabitants. The Sangguniang Barangay is the legislative body of the barangay composed of punong barangay (barangay captain) and seven sangguniang barangay members (barangay council), and sangguniang kabataan chairman (barangay youth chairman) elected at large. As legislative bodies, they enact barangay ordinances relative to discharge the responsibilities conferred upon by law, promotion of general welfare of the community, tax, revenues and budgets in accordance with the provision of the LGC. However, any ordinance passed by the barangay council can only be enforced after its review by the city council or municipal council whether it is consistent with the existing law or city/municipal ordinance. Barangay budget is sourced through the collection of taxes, fees and other charges and contributions accruing to the barangay and the internal revenue allotment (IRA). However, income generated from fees and taxes must be deposited with the city or municipal treasury. Budgetary requirements of the barangay are based on the annual barangay budget for legislation of the barangay council. The total annual appropriation for personal services shall not exceed 55 percent of the total annual income. The IRA is the share of the LGU in the national revenue taxes based on the collection of the third fiscal year preceding the fiscal year as follows: a) b) c) Thirty percent on the first year of effectivity of the LGC; Thirty-five percent on the second year; and Forty percent on the third year and thereafter.

- 219 -

The share of the LGUs to the IRA for provinces, cities, municipalities and barangays is 23 percent, 23 percent, 34 percent, and 20 percent, respectively. In the Ninth Rapid Field Appraisal (RFA)5 findings showed that significant participation of civil society in local governance continues. The extent of civil society participation in local government programs and decision-making varies from one jurisdiction to another. There are local governments that can be categorized as having achieved the high level of civil society participation in governance because they actively sought partnership with NGO and PO in the planning, implementation, monitoring and evaluation of programs. Many local governments have also explored involving civil society beyond code mandated advisory local special bodies (LSBs). Respondents agree that NGO participation in local planning and localization of national programs has resulted in stronger partnership that improves the delivery of basic services. However, participation in some jurisdictions begins and ends with the accreditation of NGOs for inclusion in LSBs or initial consultation on specific initiatives, after which the LSB or the local government relationship become dormant or inactive. Instances remain where participation is determined by the attitude of the local chief executive towards NGOs/POs. The concern to be clarified constitutes meaning participation. LOCAL LEVEL ORGANIZATIONS AND INSTITUTIONS After the EDSA Revolution, there has been a paid growth of the NGOs and POs because of the new democratic space after 20 years of the Marcos dictatorship. The participation and involvement of NGOs in development is guaranteed by the Constitution. Section 16 of Article XIII provides that the right of people and their organizations to effective and reasonable participation at all levels of political, social, and economic decisionmaking shall be respected. These roles have been highlighted and given due recognition through the passage of 1991 LGC. NGOs refer to private non-profit organizations that are committed to the task of sociopolitical and -economic development and established primarily for services. NGOs are acknowledged as organized, competent and knowledgeable about community problems and issues. Some, however, were scored for their weaknesses parochialism, inconsistence in implementing plans, narrow mind-set, power struggle and ideological differences (Villarin, 1994). Victor Jose Pearanda, Secretary of Council for Peoples Development (CPD), sums up the seeming difference between NGOs development efforts vis--vis the government: a) NGOs-POs operate with limited resources; b) the government unlike NGOs, does not perceived development problems as interrelated; and c) NGOs have an advocacy component as part of their concern, not simply the delivery of basic services. Because of the complexities of the issues on the rural development, usually NGOs and POs form networks depending on the issue/s at hand. As an example, a coalition composed of 22 different networks was formed called National Coordinating Council on Local Governance Code (NCC-LG). The 22 networks are as follows: Association of Foundation (AF), Congress for Peoples Agrarian Reform (CPAR); Convergence for a Community-centered Area Development (Convergence); Council for Peoples Development; Ecumenical Center for Development (ECD); Green Forum Philippines; Kapipunan ng may Kapansanan sa Pilipinas, Inc. (KAAMPI); NGO Council for Cooperative Development (NGO-CCD); Nationwide Coalition of Fisher-folks
5

The Ninth RFA of 1991 LGC was conducted by Governance and Local Democracy (GOLD) Project. - 220 -

for Aquatic Reform (NACFAR); National Confederation (NATCCO); National Council of Churches in the Philippines (NCCP); National Council for Social Development (NCSD); National Secretariat for Social Action (NASSA); Partnership of Philippine Support Service Agency (PHILSSA); Philippine Business for Social Progress (PBSP); Philippine Federation of Peoples Economic Council (PFPEC); Philippine Institute of Non-government Organizations, Inc. (PINOI); Philippine NGO Council (PNGOC); Philippine Partnership for the Development of Human Resources in the Rural Areas (PHILDHRRA); Salinlahi; Womens Action Network for Development (WAND); and the Caucus of Development NGOs (CODE-NGO). POs usually are formations composed of local organizations in terms of structures. POs uphold the wider participation of its mass membership expressed through collective leadership and collective action. Generally, POs form alliances with similar organizations and accept conflict-confrontation and action-reflection methods in transformation of society. Other local institutions working at the grassroots level are cooperatives (categorized as primary, secondary and tertiary), irrigators associations, farmers associations, and womens associations. * * * Cooperatives have a minimum of 30 membership, operated and managed business enterprises providing services to its members and acquire legal personality through the Cooperative Development Authority (CDA) Irrigators associations, all are water users, operate and manage an irrigation system, acquires legal personality through registration to the Security and Exchange Commission (SEC) Womens association composed all women usually engaged in livelihood project to augment family income.

Other forms of organizations in the barangay include informal groups such as autosavings group, religious organizations, clubs, etc. Salient Features of Integrated Rural Development in the Philippines Rural development remains the key towards the 21st century. Its impact on the poverty alleviation, food security and sustainable growth promises to be far-reaching. Unleashing the potential inherent in the vast majority of the rural poor who rely on agriculture for employment and income can accelerate poverty reduction. A steady step towards eradicating poverty in a sustainable manner begins by empowering the rural poor and small farmers in redressing glaring rural disadvantages. Agrarian Reform: Critical in Addressing Inequalities and Growth Section 2 of the Comprehensive Agrarian Reform Law (CARL) (Republic Act [RA] 6657) mandates government to ensure that the welfare of the landless farmers and farm workers will receive the highest consideration to promote social justice and to move the nation towards sound rural development and industrialization, and the establishment of owner cultivatorship of economic-size farms as the basis of Philippine agriculture. While limited in some respects, CARL is the most progressive law on land reform in the countrys history. Its key features includes: coverage of all agricultural lands regardless of crops or tenurial status of the tiller; recognition of all workers of the land as beneficiaries provided they are landless and are willing to till the soil; provision of delivery of support

- 221 -

services to the beneficiaries; creation of an inter-agency body to coordinate program implementation; provision of arrangements (such as distribution, leasehold and productionand-profit sharing); ensure tenurial security of farmers and farm workers; creation of an adjudication body to resolve agrarian disputes; creation of an inter-agency body to coordinate program implementation; and the creation of provincial and barangay level coordinating mechanism such as provincial agrarian reform coordinating committee and Barangay Agrarian Reform Committee (BARC). AGRARIAN REFORM COMMUNITY DEVELOPMENT PROGRAM AN APPROACH TO RURAL DEVELOPMENT The Ramos administration carried the task of completing the implementation of agrarian reform. The Department of Agrarian Reform (DAR) pushed for a faster, fairer and more meaningful agrarian reform. In 1993 DAR pursued a strategy for developing viable ARCs as key strategy for sustainable rural development. The ARC strategy will serve as critical link between agricultural growth, rural industrialization, and household welfare. Section 2 of RA 7909 defines the ARC as a barangay or cluster of barangays primarily composed and managed by agrarian reform beneficiaries (ARBs) who shall be willing to be organized and undertake the integrated development of the area and/or their organizations. It authorizes DAR to package and receive grants, aid and other forms of financial assistance from any source. It provides for a minimum of one ARC in each legislative district with a predominant agricultural population. ARC framework, as a strategy for sustainable rural development, entails the development of ARCs with active participation of civil society and critical partnership with the state and the market in order to mainstream in the area-based initiative. It espouses a development alternative where the balance of economic, political power will be in the hands of the ARCs. The program emphasizes sustainability through the following: Key Players Partnership The ARC development approach is anchored on the active participation of civil society and principled partnership with the government and business sector. It shall link the ARCs to the changing economy, transforming both civil society and market forces into vehicles for civic entrepreneurship. Scale Intervention Approach Identification and selection of ARCs shall be based on: 1. Ecological Considerations In order to allow for ecological integration and sustainability, an ARC may comprise of one or two ecological zones from among the three major types of ecosystems (lowland/ agricultural, upland-forest). 2. Socio-political Considerations Physical and demographic characteristics of the barangays comprising a cluster is a critical factor in ensuring that there is a critical mass of people and community resources that can be marshaled for sustained area development.

- 222 -

3. Economic Considerations Economies of scale; sound practices of resource sustainability; potential to serve as building blocks for agro-industrial development; conducive terrain for wide private investment, etc. Focused Program Beneficiaries i. Primary focus of interventions are marginalized groups, comprising of small farmers, farm workers, agricultural lessees, subsistence fisherfolk, indigenous people and rural women in the ARCs; ii. Special focus be given to womens groups to mainstream them in the development process hand in hand with their male counterparts; and iii. Other members of the ARCs (professionals, small rural entrepreneurs and youth) will also be mobilized to support development initiatives. Gender-sensitive Program i. Drawing in the under-represented and marginalized population into the mainstream of development processes, especially the womens sector; and ii. Seeks to achieve gender equity in all the stages of community empowerment processes. Integrated Area Development i. Establishment of closer linkages between and among communities belonging to the same economic and ecological systems; and ii. Harmonious integration of a sound and viable economy, responsive government, social cohesion of the communities and ecological integration to ensure that development is a life-enhancing process. Key Components of the ARC Development Program i. Land Tenure Improvement (LTI) is a basic component in ARC development that spells the difference over other rural development programs. The Land Acquisition and Distribution (LAD) involves the physical transfer of landownership and control to the farmer beneficiaries in order to emancipate them from the clutches of the landowners; ii. Social infrastructure and local capacity-building is geared towards establishing groups, structures and social institutions that will catalyze popular participation in ARCs. These social institutions will serve as avenues for accessing support services that are necessary in improving ARC households productivity and income; iii. Sustainable, area-based rural enterprises are concerned with the improvement of agricultural production for food security and self-sufficiency in basic needs and eventually increase in farm income and improvement in quality of life of ARC households. To achieve this goal, it is necessary that ARCs have capital, appropriate technology, information, physical infrastructure and market. The key intervention points under this sub-component are: sustainable agriculture; construction and/or rehabilitation of physical infrastructure facilities; rural industrialization; investment and marketing assistance; credit assistance; and community-based resource management; and

- 223 -

iv. Basic social systems development promotes the establishment of community-based social services systems like primary healthcare, potable water supply, recreational activities, disaster management and popular education, among others. The ARC Development Players There are various people who play vital and complementary roles in the development of a viable ARC. Central to the development processes are the people in the community who would take the role and responsibility in charting their own development. Peoples participation is an essential element within the process that seeks to bring better quality of life. Participation at a more dynamic level is meaningful when it involves active partnership of various development players. The DAR and other agencies, government organizations and NGOs merely play supporting roles. i. ARC Development Facilitator: acts as the initiator, enabler and facilitator in ARC development process. Usually, she/he is the agrarian reform technologist. The development facilitator is complemented with the partner NGO called development worker and the PO in the area. The DAR shall not take direct community organizing where there are NGOs/POs doing community organizing. The development worker shall take the lead in organizing activity; ii. The ARC Development Managers: The Municipal Agrarian Reform Officer (MARO) (head of the municipal agrarian office) and the Provincial Agrarian Reform Officer (PARO) act as the area development managers at their respective level. Their major role is to orchestrate the development processes in the ARC; and iii. ARC Task Forces at Various Levels: created to provide overall direction on ARC implementation: a. National ARC Task Force: overall direction and provides technical support to the regional and provincial task forces; b. Regional Task Force: overall supervision and direction in the ARC development in the region; and c. Provincial Task Force: overall direction in ARC implementation at the ARC level. Role of Rural Communities in the ARC Development Program Participation of local community even at initial identification of any agrarian area (to become an ARC) is critical. An area to be considered as an ARC must pass the must and want criteria6 and must be endorsed by an LGU and PO through a barangay/municipal and PO resolution. NGOs are tapped to focus on the institutional development of the organizations in the ARCs. The NGOs engagements in the ARC development work varies and include community organizing, enterprise development, training, advocacy work, etc. They work in

ARC Must Criteria: area has large land with high potential to be distributed within two years, high density of potential and actual farmers, area is economically depressed, NGOs or POs are presently operating in the area; Want Criteria: farmers and farmer workers clamor to participate in Comprehensive Agrarian Reform Program (CARP) implementation, support services have been initially provided and LGUs and other institutions support CARP implementation. - 224 -

tandem with the development facilitators of DAR. In most of the foreign-assisted projects, the services of NGOs, POs, institutions and universities are tapped to focus on the institutional development component of the project. Most of the foreign donors require the services of NGOs in institutional development components. At present there are 1,415 ARCs (nationwide) located in 1,002 municipalities over 5,098 barangays. The average number of barangay per ARC is four while there is one ARC in every municipality. Land distribution in the ARCs is 592,745 ha out of a total of 1,285,323 ha. The total land scope in the ARCs is only 30 percent out of the total target of 4,290,453 ha to be distributed, nationwide. The bulk of the lands for coverage are those in coconut, sugar and other plantation areas. Farmers especially those in these areas are strong advocates for the coverage of these lands. One of the community-based local institutions is the BARCs. These are composed group of farmers, farm workers, PO/cooperatives, NGO, and LAs. BARC is playing a very important role in the CARP processes. They represent the farmers in the LAD processes and have the access to support services. Some of their functions are: land and landowner identification; mediation in land disputes; and coordination of support services. There is a total of 4,117 organized BARCs in 1,415 ARCs. The ARB organizations such as cooperatives, irrigators associations and farmers associations/organizations are the critical partners in the ARC implementation. The delivery of support services to ARBs shall be through a unified development approach. Support services are provided to the ARBs through these organizations. The reported 3,523 partner organizations in the ARCs have a total of 312,131 members. Out of the total members, 202,469 or 65 percent are ARBs. Generation of their own internal resources is through capital build-up and savings mobilizations. These internally generated resources are utilized in their own business enterprises, health insurance, trading, micro finance organizations (MFOs), irrigation services, etc. These cooperatives/irrigators associations likewise are tapped as conduits for foreignassisted projects. Like for instance, in the construction and rehabilitation of irrigation facilities, cooperatives/irrigators associations generate counterpart fund as equity for them to operate and manage irrigation facilities, post-harvest facilities, etc. They also serve as credit conduits for farmers through their re-lending scheme. Out of 3,523 organizations in the ARCs, 1,745 have availed some form of credit or financing from formal sources such as Land Bank of the Philippines (LBP), Development Bank of the Philippines (DBP), Department of Trade and Industry (DTI) and DAR. These loans are in the form of fixed asset, livelihood, and production loan. Investment and marketing assistance activities are likewise the focus of the organizations in the ARCs. Market matching and linking are undertaken by the organizations with agribusiness firms and other markets. Results of the market matching are market tie-ups with the agribusiness firms and traders. Most of the infrastructure projects, whether foreign-funded projects or locally-funded projects, are through contract or managed by Department of Public Works and Highways (DPWH) for Farm-Market Road (FMR) or by National Irrigation Administration (NIA) for communal irrigations. For the irrigation projects, farmers organizations participation starts during the construction, cost reconciliation and operation and maintenance (O&M) of facilities. During construction, they provide labor and materials and this also a means for generating equity. In the construction of FMR, farmers participation is very limited or none

- 225 -

at all. Participation of LGUs, specifically in foreign-assisted projects, is limited to counterpart equity for the construction of these facilities. In the annual reports on Agrarian Reform Community National in 2001, the computed average yield for rice was 68.97 cavan/ha.7 This is 12 percent higher than the national average of 65 cavan/ha. Coconut, the second dominant crop in the ARC has an average yield of 1.8 mt/ha. This is more than below 40 percent of the national average of 3.06 mt/ha. Corn has an average yield of 5.29 cavan/ha. This is 40 percent higher than the national average of 36 cavan/ha. The production for palay (rice) and corn has significantly exceeded the national averages. Basic social systems and services such as potable water, health and education, power supply and recreation facilities are critical to viable communities. While in most cases DAR does not provide these services, it is however, a good indication of the impact of agrarian reform to the ARBs. Provision and access to basic needs such as health can be a community effort. Health insurance for the rural community through community efforts can be a good strategy for encouraging community participation. In the pilot testing of DAR-Agraryong Pangkalusugan, health and community-based health insurance schemes in 18 ARCs show a very promising strategy for health in the rural areas. This scheme utilizes indigenous way of pulling resources for health needs. They plan and develop their own insurance policy, implement it and monitor. This is a social security and risk management strategy among the rural poor. In the final analysis agrarian reform and ARC development is worth pursuing as an integrated rural development strategy. FUTURE DIRECTIONS OF THE INTEGRATED RURAL DEVELOPMENT Efforts have been made to respond to the centuries-old problem of inequality and poverty among the rural communities. Despite the impressive economic and social gains, poverty and inequality continues to be a major challenge. The main lesson drawn from the experience in agrarian reform and rural development is that the involvement of people, local community, organizations and institutions in the implementation of any integrated rural development program is not shaped by the mere existence of a blueprint for development, policies, and coordinative mechanism. On the part of the LGUs, participation in agrarian reform does not limit by endorsing an area to become an ARC and allocating their IRA as equity counterpart in infrastructure project. In a study conducted in relation to the LGUs participation in the implementation of CARP defines that there are specific conditions, which facilitate or hinder LGU participation in agrarian reform. These factors are: a) the leadership of the local executive; b) coordination efforts between implementing agency and LGU; c) presence or absence of social pressure of the ARBs, POs and NGOs; and d) landownership structure. On the part of the POs, their full potential must be developed and capability-building interventions must be anchored on their needs. Self-organization must be enhanced. The people are not merely recipients of development projects but rather the key players in the whole development cycle.

1 cavan = 50 kg of paddy at 14 percent moisture content. - 226 -

For DAR, readiness of the whole bureaucracy to undertake a comprehensive rural development program must be considered. For the past 20 years, DARs main work was distribution of land. Most of the DAR personnel are new to the rural development work. Hence, skills and capabilities of the relevant personnel must be upgraded to enable them to handle rural development work. REFERENCES Antiporta, D. B., 1999. Agriculture and Rural Sector in Regional Perspectives: Growth, Food Security and Poverty Alleviation, M.C. 5 series of 1999, DAR. Blessing, Garcia-Glova. Local Governance and Agrarian Reform: A Focus on Two Municipalities. Sosmea, Guadioso, Jr., 1991. Decentralization and Empowerment, Local Government Foundation, Manila. Tapales, Proserpina D., 1992. History and Evolution of Philippine Local Government Administration, in Strengthening Local Administration and Accelerating Local Development, Local Government Center, UP College of Public Administration, Quezon City. Villarin, Thomas S., 1994. KAISAHAN, Occasional Paper No. 94-02.

- 227 -

12. SRI LANKA


R. D. S. Jayatunga
Assistant Director (Forestry Development) Ministry of Environment and Natural Resources Battaramulla

INTRODUCTION The economy of Sri Lanka is predominantly based on agriculture and related activities. Currently the share of the agriculture sector as a percentage of GNP is about 20 percent, which has been decreasing over the recent years due to the expansion of the manufacturing and the service sectors. The population, which has been growing at 1.4 percent per annum, was about 18.7 million in 2001. Nearly 80 percent lives in rural areas and, the population density is 283/km2 overall and 1,063/km2 in cultivated lands. The real growth rate of Sri Lankas GDP, on the average, was almost 5 percent per annum from 1990 to 2000. The estimated GNP per capita at current prices is Rs.73,528 (US$899). The Sri Lanka society was primarily based on the family and the village. The village was considered to be the focal point for economic and other socio-cultural activities. The country was predominantly rural and the arrival of western powers radically changed the situation in terms of political, social, cultural and economic conditions. As a result, the country became a multi-racial, multi-religious and multi-cultural society. Due to the commercialization and modernization of the agriculture sector, urban centers began to spring up resulting in vast disparities in economic and social conditions. The urban-rural differences have mainly driven the policy-makers to pay more attention to rural development for the spreading of economic benefits to poor farmers and village people. The Importance of Rural Development in Sri Lanka In the past, Sri Lanka demonstrated the characteristics of a dual economy composed of two sectors; the traditional agriculture sector and the modern estate sector. The latter produced crops for export such as tea, rubber and coconut1 and received adequate financial services, insurance, communication and infrastructure. On the other hand, the traditional sector predominantly confined to rural areas with subsistence crops such as paddy, vegetables, fruits and minor exports crops. This sector has undergone certain changes in the recent years and is being modernized to some extent. However, even today, in many rural areas, chena2 cultivation, irrigated and rainfed paddy and highland farming are the principle methods of cultivation under small farms. Apart from these, the traditional sector also

To some extent, coconut is an exception because of the large segment of small farmers. However, coconut farmers enjoy financial and few other services. Slash-and-burn or shifting cultivation. - 228 -

includes cottage industries, blacksmith, inland fishing, etc. And, in contrast to the modern estate sector, the traditional sector does not receive many of the required facilities. The traditional sector centers around villages. There are over 10,000 villages in 24 districts in Sri Lanka. In many villages, the Buddhist temple (spiritual development) and the tank are the two main features depicting the life of the rural people. The family, which is the nucleus of village society, is the socio-economic unit of production in the traditional agriculture sector. Most of the rural/regional development policies therefore focused on the family as the basic unit in the rural areas. The continuous history of more than 2,500 years under the Sinhalese kings was broken in 1505 after the arrival of the Portuguese, the first colonial power. Since then the Dutch (1658-1796) and finally the British (1796-1948) radically changed the social, political, cultural and economic life of the rural people. The colonial powers mainly focused their economic activities in the urban and plantation sector resulting in considerable neglect of rural-area development. The urban sector had all the required facilities, services, infrastructure and material well-being thus creating a large disparity between urban and rural sectors. In addition, the colonial powers introduced new technology, new religion, new education system, financial services, modern transport and communication mainly in the urban sector; thereby heightening the differences in the country. This transformation in society under the colonial powers left behind problems for the people of Sri Lanka when they gained independence in 1948. Therefore, the successive governments after independence in 1948 had to adopt specific policies to deal with the socio-economic disparities and underdevelopment in rural areas. Decentralization of administrative powers to sub-national level has been pursued in order to disperse the power and authority to local governments to make decisions on development activities. The process of transferring the power away from national government to local government had positive impacts on the planning and implementation of rural development. It helps to incorporate local needs into development plans, reduced delays in decision-making, increased the flexibility in administration machinery and ensures the participation of beneficiaries in development work. INTEGRATED RURAL DEVELOPMENT IN SRI LANKA The Integrated Rural Development (IRD) is a novel idea, which was to Sri Lanka in the 1970s though it had been in use in several other countries in the region. The IRD program was initiated as a vital innovation for accelerating socio-economic development in rural areas. Its rationale derives from the long felt-need for sub national level development of those districts, which are not benefitted by lead projects such as the Mahaweli Development Project, the Free Trade Zone and urban development programs. The main intention was to minimize the possible inter-district imbalances. The IRD program as a supplement to the national program consolidated the ongoing process of decentralization of administration and development. It is now regarded to be almost the fourth lead project of the country. The key influential factors leading to the introduction of the concept include: a. increasing rural poverty not being checked as envisaged by the top-down planning approach based on the trickle-down effect;

- 229 -

b. c. d. e. f.

uncoordinated rural development policies and programs taking place in the rural areas and their failure to recognize linkages within and outside the rural economy; the multidimensional and multi-sectoral nature of the rural development problems; importance of beneficiary participation and integration of rural development projects and programs so that their full benefits accrue to the poor segments of the community; ensuring popular participation in planning and implementation of rural development projects and programs; and the inefficiency of the techno-economic approach to address the complex issues of the rural sector. There are two distinct approaches in the IRD program concept: i. Related to traditional area-based, sector-oriented place-prosperity approach; and ii. Mainly concerned with target group-oriented, poverty reduction people-prosperity approach.

The key strategies of the former approach are infrastructure development and improving the service delivery mechanism. On the other hand, the latter approach pursued basic need provision, human resource development, income and employment generation, poverty alleviation and social mobilization. However, the IRD concept is not consistent; it is vague and complex. Although the IRD concept is an extended and improved version of the conventional community/rural development framework, it recognizes the need for social change, mitigation of disparities (group/gender/regions), combines human and economic development, environmental protection, institutional development, poverty reduction, women in development and improved coordination and integration of development activities with other ongoing and parallel projects and programs for optimum resource utilization and maximum benefits. However, the IRD program of Sri Lanka has not attempted to address the fundamental constraints in rural development, which are at the bottom of rural poverty. Since the IRD program was originally designed by the profit-oriented multilateral donors, they were more concerned with high rate of return, a large positive Net Present Value (NPV), and quick payback period. Therefore, most of the IRD projects did not really address the core problem of rural poverty. The macro policy framework, project environment and the social structure of the country was not given due recognition. Therefore, in some districts, the IRD program has become nothing more than a shopping list type sectoral activity rather than a carefully designed development plan with far-reaching consequences. The broad objectives of the IRD program are to bring about a significant increase in income, employment, production and living standards of the rural people; reduction of interdistrict imbalances of socio-economic development; elimination of underutilization and wasteful use of resources; elimination of bottlenecks and constraints believed to prevail in the rural areas affecting the development negatively; strengthening the institutional capacity to plan and implement rural development projects; and promotion of participation of the rural poor in development. There are mainly two different planning approaches could be identified in the IRD program framework of Sri Lanka:

- 230 -

1. Blueprint versus Process Planning Approach The blueprint (top-down sectoral approach) planning approach implies that identification and planning is oriented from the center. This approach has been mainly used by the first generation of IRD started in 1979 with Kurunegala project, followed by Puttalam and Matale projects. The blueprint-planning model was considered to be somewhat rigid in that there was little room to modify the design, project activities and structure by the recipient district. The whole planning process, implementation and project management was done by technocrats in Colombo or by the donor representative. The participation of people in the development process was very limited. They participated in the project, more as beneficiaries rather than partners of decision-makers. 2. Target Group Approach Most IRD projects are target group-oriented. A target group is a defined and identified segment of community. The target group of Sri Lanka IRD program is generally the rural poor and criteria had been developed to select the poorest of the poor. These include income level, food-stamps holders, Janasavi/Samurdhi beneficiaries, disabled, unemployed and women, etc. The target group approach implies that the project strategy is designed to ensure that the defined target group will become the beneficiaries of the project intervention. SUB-NATIONAL LEVEL INSTITUTIONS AND COMMUNITY-BASED ORGANIZATIONS The following local level institutions and community-based organizations are discussed here to explain how the rural development activities carried out to ensure the prosperity of rural development. District Secretariat/Government Agent Office (Kachcheriya) The oldest decentralized administrative system of Sri Lanka is called the Kachcheri System and was introduced by the British. During the early years, this system mainly performed tax and revenue collection and maintenance of law and order. It also coordinated the implementation of development activities in the districts. However, the power of Government Agent (GA) in making decisions in development work was somewhat limited. Hence the first attempt in the decentralization process of Sri Lanka, which took place in the late 1960s, was the strengthening of the plan implementation and coordination machinery in the districts. Under this move, GA was made the chief coordinator of the governments development work in the district. GA had the authority equal to the Deputy Head of all public sector departments operating in the districts. These measures were initially taken to speed up the implementation of agricultural development programs. However, as far as beneficiary participation in the decision-making and development work was concerned, there was very little evidence of any improvements during this period. The second stage of decentralization began in the 1970s with a view to minimizing the technical drawbacks in the Kachcheri system. The development projects and program, which are identified by the central government for the district to be implemented and the Divisional Secretary is the key person to launch such projects and programs at the grassroots level on behalf of the District Secretary. The structure and functions are discussed later in this paper. The District Political Authority System Another decentralized administrative mechanism is the District Political Authority (DPA) system. The establishment of the DPA system in 1973 was a significant landmark of

- 231 -

decentralization of administration to sub-national levels in Sri Lanka in order to enhance the living condition of the rural people. It could also be considered as an attempt to ensure the participation of beneficiaries in the development and decision-making process. It was envisaged that the DPA system would enhance the participation of people in planning, implementation and monitoring of district development work. However, the immediate objective of the DPA system was to provide political leadership to the district administration and development program. This move of the government witnessed not only the increasing politicization of the district administration, but also of over influence by politicians directly or indirectly over administrative matters. This process, in some cases, was extreme and undermined the normal functioning of the public service. Because of political support and backing some subordinate staff disobeyed superior staff making the system unworkable. However, the DPA system provided the rural poor some access to public organizations through their representatives and ensured relief for their grievances. Though there were drawbacks in the actual implementation of the DPA system it provided a means to obtain quick solution to most of the rural problems. The District Minister System In the process of the decentralization of the power of government, the District Minister System (DMS) was introduced in 1978 to replace the DPA system. Under the open economy, the government removed the subsidies and people had to fend for themselves by engaging more in economic activities. Therefore, it was the responsibility of the government to bring the people into development process in the country at all levels. One of the strategies in realizing this objective was to make the administrative system more flexible. The objective of DMS was to provide political directives to all development activities in the districts. The District Ministers were entrusted with the following functions in the districts: i. ii. iii. iv. Formulation of district development plans; Monitoring and evaluation of implementation plans; Identification of implementation constraints and bottlenecks; Identification of remedial action to speed up the implementation of development work; v. Supervision and coordination of development work and departmental activities in the district; and vi. Resolve immediate problems of the district.

The notable achievement of the DMS was the greater degree of coordination and quick decision-making at district level, since the District Minister, as the representative of the president, had a good control over the functions of almost all the public sector departments at the district. Sometimes conflicts between the Cabinet Ministers and the District Minister and between members of parliament were experienced which affected the functioning of the system negatively. But in the implementation and planning of development work, this system certainly had some positive impacts. Decentralization of administration system in Sri Lanka was considered to be necessary not only for development needs but also for ethnic considerations, particularly during the 1980s. The early decentralization packages such as the political authority and the DMS were introduced mainly to help the district development process. However, early in the 1980s, ethnic conflicts emerged with the demand for Eelam, a separate state for Tamils. Therefore,
- 232 -

the government had to give greater importance to ethnic considerations in its decentralization agenda. Thus, the District Development Council was established under the provisions made in the District Development Council Act of 35 A 1980 in which stipulates that The state shall strengthen and broaden the democratic structure of the government and democratic rights of the people by decentralizing the administration and by affording all possible opportunities for the people to participate at every level in the national life and in government. The District Development Councils The district development councils was in fact a political body comprising of Members of Parliament of the district. The function of the district development councils included the village committees thereby making the beneficiary participation in the development activities very limited. During its three-year period of existence it had a number of difficulties in discharging the duties: i. ii. iii. iv. Lack of adequate commitment by the council members to development activities; Lack of clear demarcation of functions between ministries and departments; Conflicts between the council and the District Minister and Members of Parliament; Problems with prevailing procedures, practices, rules and regulations in the public sector; v. Little involvement in the implementation of the development program; and vi. Available funds were not adequate to prepare a comprehensive development plan for the district.

The Provincial Council (Palath Sabhawa) The setting up of provincial councils (palath sabhawa) was purely done as a solution to the growing ethnic problems in the country. The idea was to devolve some of the powers of central government to the provinces within a unitary State. The provincial council comprises of elected members while a Chief Minister heads the provincial administration and its executive powers rest with the board of provincial ministers. There are five ministerial portfolios in a province including the chief ministry. In the provincial council the central government is represented by the Governor appointed by the President. The provincial council was expected to be the framework for devolution of powers between the center and the periphery. In order to keep Tamil-speaking areas together, the northern and eastern provinces have been amalgamated temporally forming a total of eight provincial councils in the country. Powers of the provincial councils were stipulated clearly in the 13th Amendment to the Constitution. Accordingly, all devolved subjects are the sole responsibility of the provinces while concurrent subjects are the responsibility of both the central government and provincial councils. However, the weak financial base, high administrative cost, party politics conflicts, lack of planning and implementation capacity, unclear producers and responsibilities made the provincial councils ineffective some provinces. It is not yet mature enough to access the effective step in the provincial and regional/rural development in Sri Lanka. The next level of the decentralized system consists of the local authorities comprising urban and municipal councils in the urban areas. The recently established Pradeshiya Shaba, an elected body, looks after the interests of the rural areas. For administrative purposes the central government has appointed Divisional Secretaries to each Division. A Pradeshiya

- 233 -

Shaba may comprise of one or two Divisions. The lowest administrative level is the Grama Niladhari [Village Officer] Division with about 20-30 Grama Niladhari Divisions per Divisional Secretary Divisions. Villages and hamlets are the smallest spatial unit where 50300 families live. Most of the rural development activities are planned for implementation in these spatial units with the active involvement of beneficiaries. The Divisional Secretariats (Pradeshiya Lekam Karyalaya) Divisional Secretariat Divisions have been established under the Act No. 42 of 1987 and the 13th constitutional reform to avoid the failures of former Assistant Government Divisions that was coming from the British colonial time, which was administered under by GA of the district. In the past, assistant GAs implemented the policy decisions and development plans formulated by ministries/central government. However, after the introduction of divisional secretariat system, all development programs implemented in rural areas were handed over to the Divisional Secretary. Therefore, the Divisional Secretary had become the coordinator and the supervisor of all development activities, which were launched in the Division by other divisional offices of State institutes. The Divisional Secretariat Divisions again subdivided to Grama Niladhari Divisions by incorporating three-four villages. The Grama Niladhari is the leader of this division and he/she looked after all government activities, which were implemented in villages by the government. The Grama Niladhari Division system is the main and important existing local level lowest administrative unit of the State and it has a very sound reputation among the public. This is because it covers the major administrative requirements of the local community that are powered by the legislative and financial mechanism of the central government handled by the Divisional Secretary. This is the wider potential system in dealing with local community in grassroots levels. Objectives of the Divisional Secretariats The major objectives of the Divisional Secretariats are listed below: i. Providing the services required by the local people; ii. Implementing, planning and monitoring of development projects and programs within the division to enhance the socio-economic condition of the local people; iii. Coordination of government officers of other institutions, local communities and institutions and, NGOs in the area to integrate the rural development activities in the division; iv. Providing subsidies to eradicate the poverty in the division, e.g., Janasaviya, Samurdhi, food-stamps, dry food, materials for housing and sanitation improvement for lowest income families of the division; and v. Providing incidental subsidies for refugees from natural disasters such as floods, cyclones, droughts, earth-slips, etc. Income and Financial Sources of Divisional Secretariat The major sources of income of the Divisional Secretariats are given below: i. Annual budget allocations of the central government; ii. Development projects and programs funded by national and international organizations; and

- 234 -

iii. By issuing of permits to transport timber, driving license, registration fees for new vehicles, marriages, births, etc. Divisional Councils (Pradeshiya Shaba) The latest development in the evolution of regional planning took place after the devolution of powers under the 13th Amendment of the Constitution and the Divisional Councils Act of 1987. It is a major landmark in the evolution of political and social institutions in Sri Lanka, as it constituted an exit from the highly centralized system to system of governance in the country. The Divisional Councils are the authority to plan, make decisions and manage public functions in respect of subjects assigned to the providence. Subjects and functions reserved for and shared between the government and the Divisional Councils have been set out in three lists under the under the 9th Schedule of the Constitution. The subjects and functions of Divisional Councils are mainly matters of regional concern and focus directly on the daily life of the people. The Divisional Council then becomes the provider of basic services to the community in the following areas: i. Public order and local government; ii. Planning and implementation of provincial economic plan; iii. Economic and social services such as land development, industries, health and education; iv. Institutional, human resources and rural development including employment, employment planning and manpower development; v. Infrastructure, urban development and environment; and vi. Trade and commerce, etc. Although the above is not an exclusive list of domains in which the Divisional Councils have a primary responsibility, it covers the major areas and is indicative of the wide range of powers and authority vested in a Provincial Council powers and functions which had hitherto remained with the center. The Janasaviya Program The Janasaviya program introduced in 1989 focused on the poorest families receiving less than Rs.700 per month as its target group. This program shifted from mere provision of consumer goods towards promoting self-reliant development among the recipients through community mobilization, income generation and education of beneficiaries. The Samurdhi Movement The Janasaviya movement was replaced by the Samurdhi (or prosperity) Movement after the Peoples Alliance Government came into office. Even though the envisaged intention is to provide greater opportunity to the poorest of the people to plan and implement their economic development, the operational framework or the implementation procedures are still being worked out. The new program stresses on family development rather than community development because other programs do the community-based development work. The families, after their improvement to a certain level, will be linked to other development projects and programs operating at different levels: divisional, district, provincial and national. Similar to the social mobilization program of the IRD program, the

- 235 -

community mobilization process of the Samurdhi Movement will organize poor people into producer groups, create awareness, generate savings, promote income-generating activities through skills development, access to credit and markets. The Janasaviya Trust Fund Another program to support poverty alleviation is the Janasaviya Trust Fund (JTF), established in 1991 and financed by the World Bank. The JTF provides credit to Janasaviya holders and other poor families earning less than Rs.1,500 per month in the rural areas. Among the four sub-funds of the JTF, the credit fund lends money to partner organizations for on lending to poor people to start up small enterprises and self-employment. The partner organizations are NGOs such as rural development societies, thrift and credit cooperative societies, etc. The Change Agent Program The Change Agent Program (CAP) was first initiated on an experimental basis in the search for a suitable strategy to reach village and mobilize people in order to educate them to be partners in development. Indicators such as increasing rural unemployment, production and income, increasing malnutrition among children and disparities in income distribution, show that the past development efforts aimed to bring about an improvement in the living standards of the rural poor have not been realized. The CAP was launched in 1978 by the government with the assistance of the UNDP and started village level action in several areas to release and mobilize the creative energy of the people. In terms of socio-economic development in rural villages, the CAP concentrated on creating and working with groups of 10-15 poor villagers to improve the cooperation among members and build confidence towards self-reliance through self-help in the group. This was achieved through an agent who lives and works with groups in the village. The focus of the program was to educate the people about the deep roots of socio-cultural, political and economic causes and relationships that made the persons poor. They were now told to make effort to extricate themselves from this vicious circle of poverty. In the context of villages where various external factors operate, it is difficult for trapped persons to get out of the circle. Therefore, the CAP attempted to awaken the rural poor by building self-reliance and confidence on their ability to create and negotiate. Social Mobilization Program and IRD Program The participatory model in IRD programs was first introduced in Hambantota as the Gramodaya Mandala Development Program in 1983 and the Assistant Government Agent (AGA) level development program in Katuwana in 1985. Further expansion took place in Ratnapura as Key Area Planning and in Matara as Backward Area Development Program. Under the participatory model, a village is considered as the basic spatial unit for planning and implementation. The poorest families of the village earning an income of less than Rs.700 per month (food-stamp holders) have been taken as the target group of the poverty reduction programs. From 1985, social mobilization was introduced as the means of mobilizing the poorest section of society. Drawing experience from the CAP and the Grameen Bank Program of Bangladesh, the social mobilization process was looked upon as the most appropriate and effective approach for reaching the target group.

- 236 -

The Agrarian Services Center Agrarian Service Centers (ASCs) are the regional offices of the Department of Agrarian Services under the purview of the Agricultural Ministry in Sri Lanka. The main purposes of the establishment of these centers are to provide assistance for farmers in terms of technical, economical and social services to enhance the productivity of agriculture. Actually this is the place that provides services and support for farmers to increase their harvest with help of the government technical/extension officers such as agriculture instructors and agricultural extension officers (KVS). Head of the ASC is the divisional officer of agriculture. Main services provided by ASCs are as follows: i. ii. iii. iv. v. vi. Seeds and seedlings at the lowest rate of prices; Fertilizer and chemicals (pesticide, fungicides, etc.) for lower prices; Technical know-how to improve the productivity; Credit for lowest interest rates; Infrastructure development in agricultural areas; and Establishment of farmers societies.

Farmers Organizations (Govisanvidanaya) These organizations are informal communities in village level formed by the ASCs. All members of the organization are farmers. The main objectives are to share experiences, work as a team by sharing labor and avoiding the intermediate interferences/exploiters when selling the output as the intermediaries earn more profits than farmers and entrepreneurs. As a community, these organizations can receive low interest loans from banks and other financial corporations with the assurance of ASCs. Death-aid Societies (Maranadhara/Awamangalliyadhara Samithiya) Almost all the families of a typical village in Sri Lanka are members of the death-aid society and nearly all the villages have separate death-aid societies for their welfare activities. Though these societies are informal, the structure of societies and functions are keenly formal and objectives are very keen because of such a society has a carder of volunteer officers such as the Chairman, Secretary, Treasurer, etc. At least once a month a meeting will be commenced to discuss the progress, events took place and collect the membership fees for the month. The main purpose this community is to help each other when a funeral occurred in the village, as these poor people have no served money to spend such an incident happened. Each and every activity of a funeral will be carried out by the members of the society and covers the financial requirements under a certain limitation. This system is a vital, most famous and efficient mechanism among villagers to assist among others when encountered unexpected incidents. Salient Features of IRD Efforts in Sri Lanka with attention to the Role of Communities and Institutions i. Government institutions involved in IRD are not in a position to continue support for rural people due to the influences of politicians; ii. As most of rural people are less educated, first of all they must be aware how their living conditions could be improved; iii. The most important and significant feature in the rural development in Sri Lanka is that all regional level State organizations are integrated in implementing development projects and programs through the Divisional Secretary or Grama Niladhari. Therefore, the Divisional Secretariat is a key institute involved in IRD; and

- 237 -

iv. Well-organized and well-coordinated development programs could be found as a joint intervention in the region and the efficiency depends on the attitudes and characters of the officers dealing with such projects. Future Directions for IRD Efforts The following are suggested as important aspects to be considered in future IRD efforts: i. Enhance the socio-economic standards of the rural people by providing employment, new sources of income and introducing new technological know-how to improve productivity; ii. Integrated effort as a team and effective coordination of projects, programs and activities to reach the ultimate goal; iii. Infrastructure development should be a major responsibility/role of community level organizations as well as NGOs; and iv. Instead of providing food and subsidies, facilitation and the provision of appropriate technical know-how related to the improvement of the quality of life and productivity should be taken as the new concept and strategy. REFERENCES Central Bank of Sri Lanka, 2001. Annual Report of the Central Bank, Colombo, Sri Lanka. Dahlen, A., 1992. Comparative Evaluation Study of the Sri Lanka Integrated Development Program, Ministry of Policy Planning and Implementation, Colombo, Sri Lanka. Gunarathne, L., 1987. The Poorest and the Poor in Sri Lanka and the Alleviation of Poverty in Sri Lanka, Central Bank of Sri Lanka, Colombo. Ministry of Finance, Planning, Ethnic Affairs and National Integration, 1995. Integrated Rural Development Program: 15 Years Experience in Sri Lanka, Regional Development Division, Sri Lanka. Ministry of Plan Implementation and Parliamentary Affairs, 1988, 1999 and 2000. Annual Program Reports of Integrated Rural Development Projects District-wise, Sri Lanka. Morapaya, R. B., 1986. Integrated Rural Development in Sri Lanka, Sterling Publishers Ltd., New Delhi. Ramakrisnan, P. S., 1987. Some Aspects of the Integrated Rural Development in Sri Lanka Past Experiences and Further Perspectives, Regional Development Division, Ministry of Plan Implementation, Colombo, Sri Lanka. Sathanadan, S., 1991. Rural Development Policy in Sri Lanka, 1935 to 1989", Journal of Contemporary Asia (xxi) 4, pp. 433-453.

- 238 -

13. THAILAND
Sanit Suwansorn
Director CBIRD-Mahasarakam Center Population and Community Development Association Bangkok

INTRODUCTION Thailand occupies an area close to 514,000 km2 and has a population of 62 million. Bangkok has a population of eight million. Thailand is the only country in the region that has not been colonized by a western power. Since the foundation of the Thai Kingdom in the seventh century, the country, under successive dynasties, had maintained its independence and a strong identity with the hinge, nation and religion, as the cornerstone of the Kingdom. Thailand is a country currently undergoing rapid changes. As a primarily agricultural nation, Thailand is expected to propel into the ranks of the newly industrialized countries (NICs) with annual economic growth rates of around 7-9 percent. Thai economic progress has undoubtedly been accompanied by social costs. For instance, the increasing gap between rich and poor has placed considerable pressure on the livelihoods of the 75-percent of villagers who occupy rural areas, leading to an increase in rural-urban migration. Obviously, there are approximately 42 million villagers earning their livelihood from agriculture and agriculture-related industries. Over 10 million of these live in poverty. The average per capita income in the capital Bangkok is US$1,000 per annum, while in the rural northeastern part of the country, where most of population are farmers, living at a subsistence level, the average is US$235 per annum. This report is organized into two main sections. The first section begins with the role and strategies of NGOs, as local institutions. The second section presents an account on an NGO implementing an Integrated Community Development (ICD) program while promoting village institutions such as women groups and cooperatives for operating the development activities by themselves. ROLE AND STRATEGIES OF LOCAL INSTITUTIONS: THE CASE OF POPULATION AND COMMUNITY DEVELOPMENT ASSOCIATION Development, both rural and urban areas, is very important for improving the quality of life of the grassroots groups in Thailand. The aim of community development is to improve the economic and social livelihood, particularly that of the poor. In the past, the traditional thinking has been that only the government must attend to the welfare of villagers. However, the role of NGOs in Thailand has dramatically increased and become significantly established. One of the large Thai NGOs or local institution working in community development is the Population and Community Development Association (PDA). It consists of 600 staff

- 239 -

and 16 community development centers nationwide implementing 20 development programs both in urban and rural areas. Mechai Viravaidya founded PDA in 1974 in Bangkok. PDAs programs are based on the belief that local people are best suited to shape and sustain their own development. Furthermore, PDA was first active in promoting family planning in urban and rural Thailand and successfully recruited 12,000 volunteers and utilized several mobile health units to distribute contraceptives to over 16,000 villagers. Achieving the aims and promoting villagers participation in development programs are not easy in rural areas. However, PDA has used various strategies such as: 1. Participation PDA staff promote both villagers and official staff joining the programs since the beginning to end of the programs. Participation includes villagers sharing costs in cash and in kind to run the project and also joining the project for improving their lives. These lead to a sense of belonging. 2. Having Fun PDA staff also try to promote villagers who participate the programs having fun or entertainment. Certainly, the easy dialogue and easy understanding words have been used. Moreover, various joyful events have been organized such as condom contest, condom night, vegetable bank sport day, vasectomy tour, and so on. 3. Appropriate Technology This strategy promotes villagers looking back to use local materials, local technologies and local wisdom holds. Villagers, certainly, can save their money and earn more incomes from using appropriate technology. PDA has been implementing and promoting this strategy nation wide for 25 years. 4. Easy and Convenient Be easy to understand and be convenient for using are the main, good and appropriate strategies that PDA have implemented for various development programs. For example, when PDA staff explain about family planning; like how to use condoms or how good vasectomy is, it is easier for the villagers to understand, when compared to medical doctors describing. Moreover, the condoms and vasectomy service are very convenient. PDA has promoted 12,000 family planning volunteers in Thailand and all can provide condoms 24 hours service. 5. Revolving Loan Fund The idea of nothing free in the world is basically promoted in PDAs development programs. Thus, the participants must pay back the loan to the project, while the very poor villagers can pay through labor instead of money. 6. Promoting Private Sectors and Business Companies Joining the Development Programs The concept of promoting private company involvement in rural and urban development has been created and developed by PDA since 1986. Furthermore, various people had agreed that, the basic idea is to mobilize the relatively untapped private companies to participate actively in rural development, especially to help in the development of basic business skills of villagers, create new jobs, and provide opportunities. The roles and appropriate strategies to convince business sector participation in development projects are as follows: a. Concept presentation: Basically, this is an in-depth explanation about the concept of private company helping villages to develop. This concept is presented to the executives of selected private companies.

- 240 -

b. Study tours: After agreeing in principle to join the rural development program, the PDA suggests the private company to form a task force plan and develop ideas on how the company can help the village. This team should then attend a study tour of the area and work out the plan. The PDA can assist the team in identifying potential program villages. c. Target area village: The task force visits potential villages to meet community leaders and the village headman. Together they can access villages needs and potential, discuss possibilities and jointly plan activities. In some of development programs, a project coordinator may be hired to implement the project in the village. d. Project planning: When the target village is selected, the task force works with villagers to develop a simple workplace. Various issues, such as time-line, budget, and coordination with many other development agencies will be scheduled. e. Sponsor approval: The senior management of the company or board of the organization approves the work plan and corresponding resource commitments before the project is formally launched. Funds for rural development activities spent by the private company are tax-deductible through the PDA. NGO Promoting Local Institution Strengthening The NGOs basically promoted activities both in household level and village level and supported activities at subdistrict and district levels. Local NGOs such as PDA have been implementing Community-based Integrated Rural Development (CBIRD) for 20 years. The activities included income generation, primary healthcare and educational programs. Firstly, it addressed the household level. Next, the village-groups were strengthened. PDA tries to stimulate villagers in implementing the activities by themselves. Various groups, including cooperatives and women groups have been established and registered. Few examples are discussed below. Local institutions such as NGOs demonstrated that there are two main goals for national rural development. The first goal is to increase productivity. For example, in an irrigation project conducted in Thailand in 1990, it was found that the area under second rice crop had increased significantly from 377,600 ha in 1976 to 704,000 ha in 1985, while yield increased from 3,250 kg/ha to 3,725 kg/ha over the same period. Interestingly, the level of yield of the second rice crop was about two times higher than the yield of the first rice crop. The increase in area and production of the second rice crop has been made mainly by the expansion of the irrigated areas. The second goal was to encourage equity and eradicate pockets of rural poverty. The study was implemented in two villages in northeast Thailand, one irrigated rice village and one rainfed rice village, and found that farm incomes of farmers in the irrigated village were higher than farm incomes of rainfed areas. Moreover, the same research showed that the living standard of irrigated households was high and they had electrical appliances such as refrigerators, color televisions, radio, motor cycles and pick-up trucks. The rural development of Thailand has concentrated on the development of infrastructure facilities to promote land productivity. These measures have improved productivity and in consequence, raised living standards in large areas of the country. More clearly, they have been supplemented by various programs, such as water supplies, animal husbandry, crop production, training courses for poor farmers, and community development programs all aimed at opening up employment opportunity for many villager groups.

- 241 -

It was also examined other countries, such as the Philippines, where the government has favored integrated rural development, and Indonesia where the government has carried out a program of intensification of rice cultivation. These programs have been supplemented by the provision of agricultural credit to farmers, partly in kind and partly in cash, and programs of social education. In addition, it was found that India and Nepal have emphasized on multidisciplinary approaches and active participation of local government agencies. Many authors have discussed various outcomes of rural development programs and their effects on both villagers and implementing organizations. The benefits from private company participation in rural development programs could be categorized into five areas: i. ii. iii. iv. v. Improved quality of life; Village-based work opportunities and additional income; Significantly improved business skills; Institutional development and communal village structures; and Expanded markets for village products.

Village organizations and local institutions promote income-generating activities. Local village organizations are a vital part of the rural development process because a village group can mobilize communities and maximize the impact of program inputs that are coming from outside the village. These local organizations include Lam Sai Yong (LSY) and Nong Sai (NS) cooperatives, Nong Ta Kai (NTK) silk production group and Rai Kok vegetable bank group. The local village organizations lead the community to unify and strengthen the power (all of them are in northeast part of Thailand). Table 1 shows that the incomes of the village organizational have significantly increased after the commencement of the ICD program. The LSY cooperative had 600 members in 1998. There were only 107 members when it was first established in 1989. Similarly, in the case of the NS cooperative, the number of members increased from 80 in 1989 to 511 in 1997. In another case study, it was found out that only two women in NTK village made silk clothes earlier for sale, but currently 55 women participate in the silk group after PDA and American Express extended support. There were 24 villagers jointly in the vegetable bank activity in Rai Kok village at the beginning of the CBIRD program, and in mid-1998, there were 90 members. In addition, two other private companies sponsored two other (new) deep-well irrigation systems in the same public land. The main income and profits of the two cooperatives came from shoemaking businesses. Table 1 shows that the income of the LSY cooperative from shoemaking business in 1997 was B15,979,785 and the profit was B727,448,28. Likewise, the NS cooperative / / made a profit of about B930,102 from shoemaking business and it received an income of / about B12,041,985.20 from the same business. Importantly, both these cooperatives had huge / funds in terms of cash (and in the bank). In 1997, the LSY cooperative had B10,709,011, and / NS cooperative had B2,486,090. Two other groups still had small funds. In particular, NTK / silk group had B168,802 in 1997. However, it could support the members efficiently in / paying dividends and marketing. By contrast, the Rai Kok vegetable group was still weak in terms of increased incomes itself and in financial management. This was because the activity had just started in 1996 and the committee did not have enough management skills. All the NCIRD villages have small amounts of funds as shown in Table 1. Normally, the local government agencies establish the village organizations to solve problems in villages.

- 242 -

Table 1. Financial Situation of Village Organizations relevant to both CIRD and NCIRD Villages (Unit: Baht)
CIRD/NCIRD Villages CIRD LSY cooperativeb NS cooperativeb NTK silkc Rai Kok vegetabled NCIRD Nong Yai Pim Nong Bua Nong Kong Wung Kra Done Kok Num Sab Members 600 511 55 24 Income 15,979,758 12,041,885 455,230 72,000 Expenses 15,252,310 11,111,882 410,589 Net Profit 727,448 930,003 44,641 Available Casha 10,709,011 2,486,090 168,802 72,000e 200,000e 8,000e 14,800e

Sources: Cooperative annual reports (1997,1998), bookkeeping, personnel communication. a Cash in hand and in the banks; b incomes, expenses and net profits of both Notes: cooperatives are from shoemaking businesses, while available cash included net profit from all businesses such as rice purchasing, lending, selling agricultural supplies; c all numbers are only from the silk business; d the vegetable committees did not conclude and audit the budget yet. The groups income is from membership fees and donation by S. C. Johnson and Son; and e all incomes were not available as these were borrowed by the members and other villagers. From direct observations and from group meetings, it appeared that the village committees manage the village organizations. This fund allowed villagers to borrow at 2 percent interest rate a month. However, this fund was not allocated to all the villagers, and only those who have close contacts with the committee members had borrowed money. When repayment date arrived, borrowers tended to continually ask to borrow again without paying back the money. The committees actually did not get the cash from those borrowers. Concerning incomes from the CIRD businesses, Table 2 indicates that the incomes from the shoe business of the LSY cooperative reduced approximately 40 percent from 1995 to 1996; while it declined very sharply (nearly 100 percent) from 1996 to 1997. The net profits from shoemaking business had been dramatically reduced (90 percent) from1995 to 1996, and 150 percent from 1996 to 1997. This was caused due to the Thai economic crisis, which gave a serious warning signal at the end of 1996, and really happened in the mid-1997. However, the net profit is not the prime concern of the cooperative. Instead, providing good jobs, good incomes, low interest rate, appropriate knowledge, agricultural inputs and marketing sources for members are considered as cooperatives significant roles. Despite the fluctuations in incomes, the two cooperatives survived the crisis, unlike many other businesses both in urban and rural Thailand. Table 3 indicates the results of the shoe business of Nong Sai cooperative. The incomes increased sharply from 1995 to 1996, but declined slightly in 1997. The reason was the cooperative operated a new shoe production line, made new shoe styles and expanded the capacity. The profit in 1996 was low since the cooperative bought new machines and reduced orders for shoe-sewing servicing causing the cooperative to operate the business without buying the raw material and facing the high risk of marketing.

- 243 -

Table 2. Financial Situation of LSY Cooperatives Shoemaking Business 1995 1996 1997 Items Baht Percent Baht Percent Baht Percent Incomes 52,946,375 100.00 30,269,120 100.00 Expenses 48,848,282 92.26 27,853,643 92.02 Net profits 4,098,093 7.74 2,415,477 7.98 Source: LSY Cooperative Annual Reports, 1997 and 1998. 15,979,758 15,252,310 727,448 100.00 95.45 4.55

Table 3. Financial Situation of NS Cooperatives Shoemaking Business 1995 1996 1997 Items Baht Percent Baht Percent Baht Percent Incomes 2,866,715 100.00 13,145,819 100.00 Expenses 2,323,012 81.03 12,713,478 96.71 Net profits 543,703 18.97 432,341 3.29 Source: LSY Cooperative Annual Reports, 1997 and 1998. 12,041,885 11,111,883 930,003 100.00 92.28 7.72

Table 4 shows the financial situation of the silk production group in 1997 and 1998. The group has to deposit adequate amount of funds in the bank to run its business. The funds deposited in the bank increased slightly from B150,000 in 1997 to B152,650 in 1998. / / Table 4. Financial Situation of NTK Silk Production Group (Unit: Baht) Items 1997 1998 Reserve cash in the bank 150,000 152,652 213,443 202,243 11,200 Income 231,570 Expense 219,270 Profit 12,300 Source: Bookkeeping, 1998 and 1999.

In the case of NTK silk weaving production, womens committees manage the group. By creating an income-generating activity for women, the ICD program empowered the participants through financial independence. Even though initially the American Express Company and the PDA supported it, the management of the activity was absolutely under the control of village women. Interestingly, the NTK silk group has its own funds, which increased slightly every year. This fund was allocated annually for the members who borrowed to invest on silk production. Although, the interest rate was quite high, 2 percent per month, all the members satisfied since they wanted the fund to be increased rapidly. However, it was still cheaper than interest rate of the rich persons loans, which were 5-10 percent a month. The group has annually paid a dividend of B70 for each principal share (of / B100). It was actually higher than the bank saving interest rate in Thailand, which was 4.5 / percent per annum (The Nation, 1998). The NTK silk production group has not yet gained legal status. Therefore, some governmental services are not yet extended to such groups. The observation from field research show that the bookkeeping system needs to be improved.

- 244 -

However, the committees do understand and work on the bookkeeping smoothly and they can also explain the accounts, etc. to members during the annual meeting. In the Rai Kok vegetable bank, the villagers began to grow the vegetables in 1997. Thus, the groups fund has not yet grown much. However, S. C. Johnson and Son had primarily donated an amount of B60,000. All members can borrow money to buy agricultural / inputs, such as fertilizer, vegetable seeds, fungicides, and pesticides. Each member initially paid an amount of B500 for a membership fee and for the irrigation system including the / water cost. This income will be used for electricity, irrigation systems maintenance costs, including the running costs, such as training, reports, promotion, and gasoline. In the near future, the vegetable bank group hopefully could survive and also have its activities managed by villagers like the two cooperatives and silk weaving production groups discussed above. CONCLUSION The villages supported by the CIRD program have obviously increased individual and village organization-level incomes. Prior to the project they seldom had jobs after the riceharvesting season. After they joined with the CIRD programs, they got more income, which helped them to live more comfortably in the villages. In addition, some of them support their childrens study at a higher level. All the villagers interviewed had incomes more than the poverty line. Although a few participants earn income less than their previous jobs, they are happy with the current situation as they have money to save, live with family, work in the village, and strengthen their organizations. Moreover, for village organizations, they enjoy incomes and benefits from implementing their business. The Thai economic turndown since 1997 directly affected these organizations, but they are still running business. Hence, these organizations are different from many companies in the country, which have already collapsed due to economic crisis. Higher level of net profit is not the prime concern of these village organizations. Instead, supporting members well-being is more important. Three village organizations, with more experience, have reached a self-reliance level, while one new group, the vegetable bank, still needs to be supervised and supported closely by both private company, NGO and government organizations. It could be concluded that the local institutions have played various roles and strategies in implementing the ICD programs. The NGO in this case is the local institution, which operated the ICD by itself. Moreover, NGO was instrumental in promoting village institutions such as cooperatives, farmer groups, and womens groups, etc. to become development agencies within the communities. Such community organizations could then undertake the role played by the NGO and the ICD would be sustainable.

- 245 -

14. VIETNAM
Dr. Tran Viet My
Vice Director Center for Technology, Science and Agricultural Extension Ho Chi Minh City

INTRODUCTION Vietnam is a long and narrow territory 2,000 km in length from north to south, but the width from west to east is only about 60 km at the narrowest place. Despite the fact that the country is rapidly changing towards industrialization and modernization, agriculture is still dominant and nearly 75 percent of population live in rural areas. And, the contribution of this area to GDP is quite large about 30-40 percent. After the revolution in 1975, Vietnam has changed significantly and created conditions for developing the economy and the society; standard of living also has been improved rapidly. Moreover, the consumption demand of the society, particularly in rural areas, is increasing at a rate. All of the above-mentioned achievements have been based on the development of communes. Commune is the basic cell of Vietnamese rural society. These communities established since the early days of Vietnamese nation, about 3,000 years ago. And they have created a history. In the past, Vietnam had to fight long wars. The country used to be a colony of China over 1,000 years, and was under rule of France for nearly 100 years. However, nations characteristics still remain, although the culture from outside had been imposed and disseminated strongly by Empires. This shows the power of commune communities. Even though the enemy has occupied the country, the communes protected their own characteristics, so the great national traditions, which were there for thousands of years, had been maintained and conserved. However, in order to develop further and to improve rural social face, Vietnamese Government is employing novel strategies and policies while conserving and making use of the age-old traditions. In this development process local communities and institutions play a major role. ADMINISTRATIVE ORGANIZATION AND THE ROLE OF LOCAL COMMUNITIES AND INSTITUTIONS IN COMMUNITY DEVELOPMENT IN HO CHI MINH CITY General Organization Vietnamese administrative organization has four levels: * * * * Central (Trung uong); Province or city (Tinh, Thanh); District (Quan, Huyen); and Commune (Lang, Xa).

- 246 -

Under the commune is the hamlet (ap), but it is not considered as an administrative unit as it does not have a separate budget. Vietnam has 61 provinces and cities. Each province or city has 10-20 districts, 10-15 communes belong to each district, and 5-10 hamlets are in each commune. Population of a province or city usually is 0.5-1.5 million, except for Ha Noi (2.5 million) and Ho Chi Minh city (5.2 million). Each district has several hundred thousand people. The population of a commune is about 10,000-30,000. In Ho Chi Minh city, some communes have more than 50,000 people. Ho Chi Minh Citys Administrative Organization Being a big city in both area and population wise, Ho Chi Minh city has 22 districts and an area of 2,093 km2. Ha Noi, the capital of Vietnam is located 1,700 km south of Ho Chi Minh. Except for districts that are established based on administrative boundaries, the city also has departments relate to the scope of society, economy, defense, politics, security, etc. Organizations and associations related to rural development in Ho Chi Minh city are as follows: Service of Education and Training; Service of Agriculture and Rural Development; Service of Planning and Investment; Service of Technology, Science and Environment; Institute of Economy; Service of Communication and Public Works; Farmers Association; Womens Association; Horticulture Association; and Youths Association, etc.

In addition, some central institutions (related to rural development) are also established in Ho Chi Minh city. Few examples are given below: University for Agricultural and Forestry Institute of Southern Agricultural Science Institute of Forestry Science Institute of Oil Plant Institute of Forest Investigation and Planning. THE ROLE OF LOCAL COMMUNITIES AND INSTITUTIONS IN INTEGRATED RURAL DEVELOPMENT Community development should adopt an integrated approach and address such activities as: improving production; employment generation; restoring traditional professions in the society; education; family planning; infrastructure development, etc. Functions and roles of institutions dealing with these different subjects of rural development will differ to each other. Local governments should be dealing with Integrated Rural Development (IRD). The annual plan of a commune has short-, medium- and long-term objectives set up by Ho Chi

- 247 -

Minh citys government (or by the Center). Local communities have to cooperate with concerning institutions. Service of Education and Training State management is concerned about improving cultural knowledge, eradicating illiteracy of people who did not have the opportunity to go to school. In each district, Educational Division has a unit to help people committees to accomplish such objectives. For eradicating illiteracy, associations such as farmers, womens and youths organizations and the NGOs play a significant role. Service of Planning and Investment Service of Planning and Investment is an organization managed by the State. Its function is to approve plans and distribute the budget to related work via projects. Planning Division belongs to districts people committee and it is a unit involved in implementation. Service of Technology Science and Environment Service of Technology Science and Environment also an organization managed by the State. It belongs to citys people committee. Its duty is to help identify and apply new technology, science and solve environmental problems (if any) of development projects. Institute of Economy This is to organize research and to set up policies related to rural areas and to develop agriculture. In order to do these effectively, there should be a set of suitable policies to stimulate production and to improve rural life. Service of Communication and Public Works This is also an organization managed by the State for building infrastructure, treating waste, etc. Service of Agricultural and Rural Development This is also a State-managed organization for developing agriculture, rural areas and communities. It always cooperate with others to promote IRD. It has many specific units and the whole service has about 800 cadres. Center for Technology Science and Agricultural Extension With 200 cadres in three levels; city, district and commune; this center has the following main functions: i. To organize research on forestry, agriculture, fisheries, animal husbandry, irrigation, etc. ii. To transfer new technology (plant, animal) and new farming systems to farmers to increase the yield of plants and animals. iii. To develop and implement rural development projects. In order to perform such tasks, the center conduct research, receive technical and scientific knowledge/achievements from within and outside the country, select appropriate knowledge/information/technology and transfer them to farmers via training courses,

- 248 -

seminars and field visits, etc. In addition, it develops cadre networks of agricultural extension at commune level. Each commune has one cadre that belongs to the district station. These comprised of progressive farmers, local cadres (association and government). And, they participate in planning and help in the development of projects for the community. Practically, agricultural extension service in Ho Chi Minh city, and in the whole country, is effectively engaged in community development activities. Besides this center, the Service of Agriculture and Rural Development also has other institutions such as: Center for Water and Rural Environment Hygiene; Branch of Immigration and New Economic Area Development; and Branch of Plant Protection, etc.

All of these institutions help in the establishment and implementation of projects such as those linked to the supply of clean water to rural people, environmental hygiene (like treating waste, dirty water, building suitable W.C., etc) and contribute to improve the standard of living of people. The above-mentioned units have 50-100 cadres each. Associations These are social/politic units. They have four levels; from central to commune. Therefore, they have formed a system, which is strong enough to participate in implementing the projects of IRD to help farmers to promote production. Other Institutes and the University These belong to the Ministry of Agricultural and Rural Development, and Ministry of Education and Training, respectively. However, their offices are located in Ho Chi Minh city. Their main duties are to organize research on farming systems, new seeds, animals and technologies and, transfer them to farmers in Ho Chi Minh city and provinces in the south. Each institute has few hundreds of officers, researchers and several sub-units. FUTURE DIRECTION OF INTEGRATED RURAL DEVELOPMENT IN HO CHI MINH CITY IRD based on commune must help enhance production, promote economic effectiveness and improve the standard of living of the rural people in Ho Chi Minh city. When changing to market mechanism, Vietnamese Government knew that the gap between the rich and the poor would be widened. The rich has had good conditions to become richer. It is inevitable. But, if appropriate policies are established and suitable sponsors and programs from central, local government, and international organizations are directed through local peoples committees and institutions, the poor will not become poorer. Central and city government must adequately invest on poor communities. For Ho Chi Minh city, in the next five years, the following projects are proposed: 1. Six Models of Rural Environmental Hygiene in 6 Districts: Nha Be, Binh Chanh, Cu Chi, Hoc Mon, Can Gio and District 2 The projects contents include: reformation of breeding cage; W.C.; treatment of waste; building environmental hygiene and construction; using suitable chemical fertilizers and

- 249 -

chemical plant protection; dissemination of information on good health; and environment protection information via television, broadcast, brochures, etc. Project has been conducting by Center for Water and Rural Environment Hygiene, in collaboration with people committees of six districts, Service of Technology, Science and Environment, Center for Technology, Science and Agricultural Extension. 2. Social and Economic Development of 20 Poor Communes in 4 Districts: Can Gio, Nha Be, Binh Chanh, District 9 The main aspects of this project are as follows: * Support to develop traditional professions. * Guide the poor to become rich via programs of agriculture, forestry, industry, etc. * Building infrastructure in communes. The Center for Technology, Science and Agricultural Extension and the branch of Immigration and New Economic Area Development have the responsibility for setting up and implementing this project. Using organic fertilizers to replace chemical fertilizers in agricultural farming at Phuoc Vinh An commune, Cu Chi district is conducted by the Center for Technology, Science and Agricultural Extension. In addition, there are activities to help farmers to change old farming systems. These include demonstrations, training courses and seminars. Projects also pay attention to eradicate illiteracy, increase cultural and environmental knowledge, improve the role of women in community development, improving health, etc. It is concluded that local community organizations and institutions have to play an extremely important role in changing the pace of rural society and economy. They are the bridge between local people and government in identifying demand, developing plans, searching resources for investment (local and international) and in implementing projects. REFERENCES Center for Technology, Science and Agricultural Extension, 2001. Project on Using Organic Fertilizers in Agricultural Farming for Sustainable Production at Phuoc Vinh An Commune, Cu Chi District, Ho Chi Minh City. Ho Chi Minh City Service of Agricultural and Rural Development, 2002. Project on Social, Economic Development at 20 of Poor Communes. Service of Agricultural and Rural Development, 2001. Project of Six Models of Rural Environmental Hygiene, Ho Chi Minh City. Statistical Office, 2002. Statistical Yearbook, Ho Chi Minh City.

- 250 -

1. LIST OF PARTICIPANTS, RESOURCE SPEAKERS AND SECRETARIAT


A. PARTICIPANTS Country Bangladesh Name/Official Address Mr. Abdul Aziz Talukder Deputy Registrar Cooperative Department Ministry of Local Government, Rural Development and Cooperatives 9/D, Motijheel C/A Dhaka Dr. Shih-jui Tung Associate Professor Graduate Institute of Agricultural Extension Education National Chung-hsing University 250 Kuo-kuang Rd. Taichung Mr. Akhil Chand Assistant District Officer Fiji Government Box 6 Sigatoka Dr. R. K. Tripathi Joint Director (Extension) Directorate of Extension Ministry of Agriculture Krishi Vistar Bhavan IASRI Campus, Pusa New Delhi - 110012 Dr. Hassan Hashemi Daran Research Expert Institute for Planning and Agricultural Economics Ministry of Jihad for Agriculture Bulvar Kashavar, Felstine Ave., No. 80 Tehran

Republic of China

Fiji

India

Islamic Republic of Iran

- 251 -

Mr. Hossein Mahdidoust Chief Officer of Micro Producers Organizing Ministry of Jihad for Agriculture Fl. 9, Bldg. 2, Fatemi Sq. Tehran Mr. Masoud Motamedi Deputy Director of Housing and City and Rural Planning Bureau Management and Planning Organization Tehran Nepal Mr. Dirgha Man Shrestha District Development Committee Member of Bhaktapur District Office of the District Development Committee Bhaktapur Mr. Abdul Sattar Deputy Chief (in charge) Planning and Development Division Government of Pakistan Room o. 428, Block P Pakistan Secretariat Islamabad Ms. Adeliza F. Gabalfin Chief Agrarian Reform Program Officer Bureau of Agrarian Reform Beneficiaries Development Department of Agrarian Reform (BARBD-DAR) Elliptical Road, Diliman Quezon City Mr. Rajamunilage D. S. Jayatunga Assistant Director (Forestry Development) Ministry of Environment and Natural Resources 82, Rajamalwatta Road Battaramulla Mr. Sanit Suwansorn Director, CBIRD-Mahasarakam Center Population and Community Development Association 6 Sukhumvit 12 Bangkok 10110

Pakistan

Philippines

Sri Lanka

Thailand

- 252 -

Vietnam

Dr. Tran Viet My Vice Director Center for Technology Science and Agricultural Extension 43 Dinh Tien Hoang St., District 1 Ho Chi Minh City

B. RESOURCE SPEAKERS (alphabetical) Mr. Esfandiar Abbassi Researcher, Rural Research Centre P. O. Box 14155-6585 Jihad Building, 4th Floor Fatemi Sq., Tehran Islamic Republic of Iran Dr. Robert J. Fisher Consultant 34 Albert Street, Leichhardt, NSW 2040 Australia Mr. Seyed Babak Mossavi Nejad Moghaddam Faculty Member, Rural Research Centre P. O. Box 14155-6585 Jihad Building, 4th Floor Fatemi Sq., Tehran Islamic Republic of Iran Dr. Shinichi Shigetomi Researcher, Institute of Developing Economies (IDE) 3-2-2 Wakaba, Mihama-ku Chiba 261-8545 Japan Dr. Chandrasekera M. Wijayaratna Institutional Strengthening Specialist and Agricultural/Natural Resources Economist 14 Cheriton Road, Howick, Auckland 1705 New Zealand C. SECRETARIAT NIPO Mr. Mohammad Kazem Ebrahimi Khorram-Abadi Managing Director

- 253 -

National Iranian Productivity Organization (NIPO) P. O. Box 15815-3694 No. 43, 11th St., Colha Sq. Tehran 14316 Islamic Republic of Iran Tel: (93)21-658209 Fax: (98)21-8955376 E-mail: nipo@systemgroup.net Ministry of Jihad for Agriculture Dr. Mohammad Hossein Emadi Deputy Minister Mr. Mohammad Motahari Expert of Productivity Committee Ministry of Jihad for Agriculture Fatemi Sq., Tehran Islamic Republic of Iran Tel: (98)21-8897191 Fax: (98)21-8897191 E-mail: sh.rousta@jihad.net APO Mr. Kunio Tsubota Director Agriculture Department Mr. Akira Munakata Program Officer (Community Development) Agriculture Department Asian Productivity Organization Hirakawa-cho Dai-ichi Seimei Building 2F 1-2-10, Hirakawacho Chiyodaku, Tokyo 102-0093, Japan Tel: (81-3)5226-3920 Fax: (81-3)5226-3950 e-mail: apo@apo-tokyo.org URL: www.apo-tokyo.org

- 254 -

2. PROGRAM OF ACTIVITIES
(15-20 June 2002) Date/Time Sat., 15 June Forenoon Activity Opening Ceremony Presentation of Resource Paper I: Role of Local Communities and Institutions in Integrated Rural Development (Part I) by Dr. Chandrasekera M. Wijayaratna Presentation and Discussion of Resource Paper II: Local Communities and Institutions: Realizing Their Potential for Integrated Rural Development (prepared by Prof. Norman Uphoff) presented by Dr. Chandrasekera M. Wijayaratna Presentation and Discussion on Resource Paper III: What Makes Effective Local Organizations and Institutions in Natural Resource Management and Rural Development by Dr. Robert Fisher Presentation and Discussion of Resource Paper IV: Institutions of Peoples Self-organizing Actions for Rural Development: Comparative Analysis of Micro-finance Organizations in Rural Thailand, Philippines and Indonesia by Dr. Shinichi Shigetomi Presentation of Resource Paper V: Role of Local Communities and Institutions in Integrated Rural Development (Part II) by Dr. Chandrasekera M. Wijayaratna Discussion session on Resource Paper V Workshop 1: Discussion/Reflections on Resource Papers Workshop 2: Preparation for Country Paper Presentation Presentation and Discussion of Country Papers Presentation and Discussion of Country Papers Presentation and Discussion of Country Papers Workshop 3: Reflections on Country Paper Presentations: Identification of Role of Local Communities and Institutions in Member Countries Briefing and Discussion on Field Visit Field Visit

Afternoon

Sun., 16 June Forenoon

Afternoon

Mon., 17 June Forenoon Afternoon Tues., 18 June Forenoon Afternoon

Wed.., 19 June

- 255 -

Thurs., 20 June Forenoon

Afternoon

Reflections of Field Visit Short Presentations on Analytical Framework for Local Institutions and Organizations by Dr. Robert Fisher Workshop 4: Analysis on Local Institutions/Organizations in Member Countries Short Presentations on Role of Local Institutions and Organizations for Integrated Rural Development by Dr. Shinichi Shigetomi and Dr. C. M. Wijayaratna Workshop 5: Analysis of Role of Local Institutions/Organizations in Member Countries Preparation of Personal Action Plans and Evaluation Closing Session

- 256 -

Anda mungkin juga menyukai