Anda di halaman 1dari 28

Second Conference of INTERNATIONAL FORUM ON COMPARATIVE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF GLOBALIZATION

New Technology, Productivity and Contemporary Banking


Costas Lapavitsas School of Oriental & African Studies, University of London

Paper presented at the Second Annual Conference of the International Forum on the Comparative Political Economy of Globalization, 1-3 September 2006, Renmin University of China, Beijing, China.

Department of Economics School of Oriental and African Studies The University of London

Second Conference of INTERNATIONAL FORUM ON COMPARATIVE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF GLOBALIZATION


To be held at Renmin University of China Beijing, 1-3 September 2006

Paper title:

NEW TECHNOLOGY, PRODUCTIVITY AND CONTEMPORARY BANKING


Author:

Costas Lapavitsas School of Oriental & African Studies cl5@soas.ac.uk

August 2006 First Draft Not to be Quoted

New Technology, Productivity and Contemporary Banking


Costas Lapavitsas

Abstract
This paper considers the impact of new technology (telecommunications, electronics and information processing) on the operations and functions of commercial banks. The focus of analysis is on the US banking system. The paper first examines the impact of new technology on general productivity across the economy. There has been significant acceleration of productivity growth since 1995 but not in banking. Moreover, the mechanisms through which new technology affects productivity are far from clear. The paper then turns to the impact of new technology on the moneydealing and financial intermediary functions of banks. The introduction of ATMs and e-banking have transformed the operations of banks at the branch level, but they have not resulted in significant cost reductions and productivity increases. The adoption of information technology, meanwhile, has allowed for technical assessment of risk through credit scoring thus making it possible for banks to lend to large numbers of individuals and small enterprises. The business of banking has become more differentiated and focused on information processing.

1. Introduction

Banking has been transformed during the last three decades due to two broad trends: first, institutional and regulatory change associated with financial liberalisation and, second, technological change. The former includes lifting of controls on prices and quantities of credit, on the activities of financial institutions, and on international capital flows. The latter includes introduction of new technology in electronics, telecommunications and information processing. The two trends are closely connected and continually interact with each other; nonetheless, they are also distinct and it is analytically instructive to keep them separate. This paper examines some aspects of the impact of technological change on banking. The first issue considered in the paper, however, is the impact of new technology on productivity in the economy as a whole. Banking is an intermediary activity, the returns of which derive largely from industrial and commercial profits or from private incomes. Consequently, for the sources of banking profit to grow in a sustained way there must be systematic increases in productivity across the economy, reflecting the general introduction of new technology. The attitude of banks toward new technology depends, in turn, on its expected impact on bank profitability. A complicating factor in this respect has been the pronounced effect that new technology has had on the services sector, which includes banking. Thus, section 2 considers the impact technological change on general productivity during the last three decades, focusing on the US economy. New technology has had complex and ambiguous results, despite the upturn in productivity since 1995. Moreover, the mechanisms through which new technology affects productivity are not clear. In this light, section 3 examines the introduction of new technology in banking, again primarily in the USA. The impact of technological change on banking has inevitably been multifaceted. This makes it necessary to focus on selected aspects of banking in this paper. Thus, analysis turns primarily to the key functions of banks as money-dealers and financial intermediaries. The impact of technology is considered through the introduction of ATMs and electronic payments as well as the adoption of credit scoring techniques by banks. It appears that new technology has not significantly reduced bank costs, or raised productivity in banking in these respects. In view of the high profitability of banking in recent years, this creates an obvious conundrum: if banks have failed to compress costs, how have they succeeded in

making high profits? However, this topic cannot be dealt here and requires separate treatment. It should be mentioned, finally, that this paper is work in progress, part of a broader study of the transformation of finance during the last three decades. Analysis relies on a critical survey of the mainstream economics literature on this topic, drawing primarily on the US banking system, which is also the most thoroughly studied in the literature.

2. Technological change and productivity in the US economy

Technological change since the late 1970s has been most pronounced in electronics, telecommunications and information processing. Despite the rapid introduction of new technology - especially in the USA - there were no significant productivity improvements at the aggregate macroeconomic level for at least two decades after the mid-1970s. In mainstream economics this phenomenon has been called the Solow paradox, namely that You can see the computer age everywhere but in the productivity statistics (Solow 1987: 36). However, around 1995 the outlook for productivity growth changed dramatically in the USA. It is important for our purposes to consider the current relationship between new technology and productivity as well as the debates that surround it. Productivity calculations by mainstream economists show that US labour productivity began to rise rapidly around 1995 following two decades of relative stagnation. Consider the following estimates by Oliner and Sichel (2000):

Table 1. Contributions to Growth, 1974-1999. 1974-90 1991-95 1996-99 Growth rate of output Contributions from: IT capital Other capital Labour hours Labour quality 0.49 0.86 1.16 0.22 0.57 0.44 0.82 0.44 0.48 1.10 0.75 1.50 0.31 1.16 3.06 2.75 4.82

Multifactor productivity 0.33

Table 2. Contributions to Labour Productivity 1974-90 1991-95 1996-99 Growth rate of labour productivity 1.37 Contributions from: Capital deepening of IT capital Capital deepening of other capital Labour quality Multifactor productivity 0.81 0.37 0.22 0.33 0.62 0.11 0.44 0.48 1.10 0.14 0.96 1.16 1.53 2.57

Much the same picture emerges from Jorgenson, Ho and Stiroh (2004):

Table 3. Sources of US Output and Productivity Growth 1959-73 1973-95 1995-2003 Private Output Hours worked Average Labour Productivity Contributions from: Capital deepening of IT capital Capital deepening of other capital Labour quality Total Factor Productivity in IT 0.21 1.19 0.33 0.09 0.40 0.49 0.26 0.24 0.10 0.92 0.83 0.17 0.53 0.61 4.21 1.36 2.85 3.06 1.57 1.49 3.90 0.85 3.06

Total Factor Productivity in non-IT 1.03

The measured upsurge in productivity growth led initially to a debate on whether the increase indicated a regime shift. Some argued that the change was longterm and due primarily to the cumulative effect of new technologies (selectively, Oliner and Sichel 2000, 2002, Jorgenson and Stiroh 2000, Jorgenson, Ho and Stiroh 2002, 2004, Stiroh 2001, Nordhaus 2001, Basu, Fernhald and Shapiro 2001, Triplett and Bosworth 2001, Fernhald and Ramnath 2004). On the opposite side stood Gordon (1999a, 1999b, 2000) who claimed essentially that the upsurge was due to rapid growth within the Information Technology (IT) sector, and was contained within it. To put it crudely, for Gordon, computers raised productivity but only in the business

of making other computers. By the early 2000s, however, Gordon (2003, 2004) - see also Dew-Becker and Gordon (2005) - acknowledged defeat, and a consensus gradually emerged with the following features. First, it is now generally accepted that in 1995 a structural break took place in the trend of US productivity growth. Labour productivity, in particular, has accelerated rapidly, registering growth rates similar to those of the golden era of the 1950s and 1960s. This is not a cyclical result, as was confirmed by even faster acceleration of labour productivity after the burst of the technology bubble of 19992000. Judging by productivity figures alone, this phenomenon represents the end of the long downturn that engulfed the US economy after the first oil crisis of 1973-4. Solows paradox has indeed vanished in the USA. Second, the catalyst for this regime shift was provided by extremely fast productivity growth in the microprocessor industry in the 1990s (Triplett 1996, Jorgenson and Stiroh 2000). Rapid productivity growth in the microprocessor sector caused a decline of price approaching 30% in the mid-1990s, inducing substantial falls in computer prices and leading to a boom in IT investment in the second half of the 1990s. The rise in IT investment led to productivity gains in the sectors producing IT and less so in the sectors using IT. In time, a foundation was provided for acceleration of productivity growth across a broad front of economic activities. Third, rapid acceleration of Total Factor Productivity (TFP) was also observed after 1995. As is well known, TFP purports to capture the effect of unknown, residual factors on productivity, typically interpreted as a non-specific effect of technological change. An easy blunder in this connection (not infrequently found in the pages of the press) is to interpret the recent gains in TFP as evidence of the impact of IT change on productivity. This is, of course, incorrect since TFP growth refers by definition to factors unknown. Nonetheless, the acceleration of TFP growth after 1995 is further evidence of regime change in productivity growth trends. Fourth, productivity in the services sector seems also to have picked up, eventually responding to growth in IT investment. The original slowdown of productivity since the mid-1970s was very evident in services. This has been sometimes referred to as Baumols disease, i.e. that the inherent nature of services makes productivity gains less likely than in the primary or secondary sectors (Triplett and Bosworth 2000). In this respect, it is important that the most significant gains in productivity since the 1995 have been in services, mostly in wholesale, retail and

financial trading (though in securities trading and not in banking, despite the fact that banks have been leaders in introducing new technology). Within the mainstream this is taken as evidence of the broad-based nature of the transformation in productivity growth. There are, of course, very significant problems when it comes to measuring the output of the services sector, but mainstream economists are now claiming that Baumols disease has been cured (Triplett and Bosworth 2003a, 2003b, 2003c). However, the nature of the cure has not been specified. These are, in my view, the salient features of the current mainstream consensus on productivity change and new technology in the US economy. Yet, despite the emergence of consensus, the issue of the relationship between new technology and productivity since the 1970s cannot be considered fully settled. A key problem in this respect is that most of the contributions to this debate (whether for or against the consensus) are macro-level, econometrics papers. These studies (including those whose results were summarised in the tables above) normally engage in growthaccounting, decomposing output growth in the standard Solow (1957) manner:

dY/Y = dA/A + s dL/L + (1-s) dK/K

(1)

Where Y is output producing according to the production function Y = AF(L, K) and A, L and K are a multiplicative factor, labour and capital inputs, respectively. The ratio dA/A captures Total Factor Productivity (or Multi Factor Productivity) and can be estimated as a residual from (1). MFP is typically used to account for a bag of nonspecified factors including, technological innovation, managerial innovations and knowledge spillovers. Consequently, the opposing views on the trend of productivity growth are based entirely on econometric theorising at the macro level. It follows that the various contributions offer little insight into how new technology affects the manner in which labour is undertaken, including the impact of computers and other IT on the labour process. Supporters of the consensus certainly believe that new technology has had a pronounced effect on productivity, especially in the services sector, but the literature leaves us in the dark regarding the mechanism through which productivity improvement has taken place. This is not surprising, given the macroeconomic outlook, the methodology adopted and the data employed by the studies concerned.

The uncertainty regarding the actual mechanisms of productivity improvement is made worse as the productivity miracle at the macro level appears to be confined to the USA. Thus, while IT has spread in Western Europe along similar lines to the USA, productivity growth in the former (including TFP) has slowed down during this period (OMahony and van Ark 2003, Gordon 2004). Britain presents the most awkward problems in this regard, since it has registered substantial IT investment in the late 1990s and can hardly be accused of eurosclerosis (the usual culprit in mainstream explanations of worse performance by Europe compared to the USA). Yet, British productivity growth has declined during this period. 1 Similarly problematic, though for different reasons, is the further observation that US productivity growth actually accelerated after the end of the New Technology bubble, 1999-2000, despite the ensuing collapse in IT investment. Indeed, productivity has continued to improve in the USA even though IT investment had not reached the levels of 1999-2000 even by 2006. Thus, if new technologies are behind the productivity upsurge in the USA since 1995, the process is clearly deeper and more complex than it appears at first sight. For more detailed answers, therefore, it is important to look at micro (firm) level studies. There has been a modest output of such studies in the USA, which broadly agrees that new technology has indeed wrought a productivity transformation. However, it is notable that no paper has succeeded in putting forth a generally accepted explanation for the putative transformation of productivity. The strongest argument in this respect is that IT has favoured the employment of highly skilled college graduates, thus leading to changes in work and organisation practices within companies and resulting in productivity improvements (Brynjolfsson and Hitt 2000, 2003, Brynjolfsson, Hitt and Yang 2002). These effects are sometimes captured with the term intangible capital, which presumably increases through the introduction of new technology and lies at the disposal of corporations. 2 In similar spirit, it has been argued that new technology has resulted in intangible output, such as better services and more varied choice for customers. The implication of these unconvincing
1

Recent attempts to account for this paradox have resorted to the rather desperate argument that US corporations somehow deploy new technologies more effectively than British ones (Bloom, Sadun and van Reenen 2005, Sadun and van Reenen 2005). It is hard to know what to make of this claim a better cultural fit between contemporary Americans and computers, perhaps? 2 It has even been argued that the stock market somehow succeeded in capturing the effect of this mysterious capital (also called e-capital) in the valuation of New Technology stocks in the late 1990s, i.e. just before the crash (Hall 2000, 2001).

arguments is that the acceleration of productivity has been going on for some time since the late 1970s, but was badly measured. It is worth stressing in this connection that there are indeed horrendous difficulties regarding the measurement of productivity, as has been explained by Griliches (1994). These difficulties are ineluctable when economists attempt to distinguish between the value and the material sides of production. Moreover, US productivity measurements use hedonic indices to deflate price series, unlike European countries, though this practice appears not to have caused a systematic measurement difference in favour of the USA. Nonetheless, hedonic indices could still conceal a major problem for which there is no clear answer in the literature. Namely, if the output of the IT sector is considered to have risen due to the greater power of computers (even if the same volume of computers is actually produced), it follows that the measurement of output by wholesalers and retailers would also automatically rise. However, it is possible that wholesalers and retailers might have continued to do exactly what they have always done, i.e. sell x boxes of (more powerful) computers per period. In other words, the data would be registering an improvement in the productivity of retailing and wholesaling without any actual changes in work organisation and use of technology having taken place. This is a far from negligible problem given that the current productivity upsurge is supposed to draw its strength mostly from wholesaling and retailing.
3

Concluding this brief discussion, there is little doubt that a new phase of substantially faster productivity growth has emerged in the USA after 1995. The bulk of the gains in productivity have been in the services sector (with the exception of the banking sector), while manufacturing productivity has not registered significant improvement (with the exception of the IT sector). Mainstream economics attributes the change in productivity to the introduction of new technology, mostly telecommunications and information processing. By deploying growth accounting at the aggregate macro level, mainstream economists claim that the long-awaited beneficial effect of computers on the functioning of capital (especially in the sphere of circulation) has at last taken place.

The usual example for the transformation that has been apparently wrought on retailing/wholesaling by new technology is WalMart and its big box system. It is notable that the appalling labour conditions at WalMart that have been well-documented in the press and elsewhere are typically ignored by academic papers.

It is also notable that there have been no strong explanations of the microeconomic mechanisms through which new technology might have raised productivity. A prevalent assumption - often implicitly made - is that new technology improves the efficiency, organisation and range of individual work effort (particularly within the services sector) thereby inducing a regime shift in productivity growth. But the mechanisms and characteristic features of this putative change are rarely specified, particularly for office work that is typical of much of the service sector. The most influential argument in this context links the productivity transformation to a nebulous intangible capital, presumably placed at the disposal of corporations by new technology. This intrinsically weak argument is not strengthened by the observation that new technologies have apparently produced this mysterious capital only in the USA, or even only for US corporations. The difficulty of finding a persuasive microeconomic link between productivity and new technology no doubt derives from the complex and non-specific character of current new technologies, especially when compared to technological transformations of the past. The introduction of new technologies in production of steel and chemicals in the late nineteenth century, for instance, improved productivity for these basic commodities and thus had broader beneficial effects for productivity across the economy. But information technology is a diffuse, general purpose technology that applies across various fields of labour in a non-specific way (Bresnahan and Trajtenberg 1992). Its impact is thus slow, complex and indirect, along lines similar to the introduction of electricity and the telephone, rather than to introduction of specific production technologies (David 1990). Consequently, it might not be easy to differentiate between the effect of contemporary new technology on the productivity of labour as opposed to its effect on the intensity and effective duration of labour. Neoclassical studies of productivity growth typically ignore the possibility that new technologies might have raised the intensity of labour, especially in the services sector. It could be, for instance, that the rise in output per worker in recent years owes much to information technology eliminating gaps and breaks in the work effort during normal working hours. This seems more plausible than the notion that new technologies have created a nebulous intangible capital placed at the disposal of corporations. The putative effect of new technologies on productivity might also be related to the gradual colonisation of private time by computer-related work. The

beneficial effect on output could be the result of new technology prolonging the effective duration of labour, both through unpaid overtime and through the invasion of family or personal time. On casual evidence alone, it seems plausible that information technology has had a strong impact on the intensity and duration of service labour. The efforts of neoclassical economists in explaining the recent productivity shift might have borne better fruit had they also addressed the issue of whether new technologies have forced workers to labour harder and for longer hours.

3. New technology and banking

The general context within which US banks have operated since the mid1970s, therefore, has been that of productivity slowdown for two decades followed by rapid growth since 1995, though not in banking itself. Broadly speaking, the introduction of new technology has resulted in more favourable profitability conditions for banks only since the mid-1990s. Throughout this period banks have been at the forefront of introducing new technology with complex and multifaceted effects on their operations. Ascertaining the impact of new technology on banking requires, in the first instance, a theoretical framework for analysis of bank functions and profits. In this paper, banks are treated as capitalist enterprises that specialise in the following three related activities: first, money-dealing, which includes facilitating foreign exchange transactions, transmitting, providing access to and safe-keeping of money as well as clearing money-related obligations, and so on; second, financial intermediation, i.e. collecting spare money and lending it as money capital, in the course of which banks also advance their own credit to borrowers. Third, what might be called financial market mediation, i.e. facilitating participation in financial markets by non-financial corporations, for instance, through underwriting of bond issues or providing information-related services to borrowers and others. In recent years banks have also begun to undertake several other activities, above all, provision of insurance, but the theoretical classification given here is broad enough for most purposes. On this theoretical basis, there are three broad sources of bank revenue: first, profits out of money-dealing activities, second, the interest spread of financial intermediation and, third, fee income from mediating financial transactions. It is certainly true that in practice bank revenue also results from other sources, for

instance, participation in financial transactions on a banks own account. However, the three categories noted above are sufficient to capture recent trends in bank revenue. An important point to make before proceeding with the analysis refers to the applicability of the concept of productivity to banking, given that banks are intermediaries which provide services to borrowers and lenders but do not produce any well-defined output. However, banks certainly employ large numbers of highlyskilled workers whose salaries and wages are the bulk of bank costs. Consequently, the efficiency with which bank workers undertake their tasks and the impact of technology on completing these tasks are prime concerns of banks. The concept of productivity has heuristic value in this respect, providing insight into changes of bank costs. Below I discuss the impact of new technology on banking by considering the money-dealing and financial intermediation activities of banks, and bearing in mind that productivity appears not to have risen in banking in recent years. The impact on the third source of revenue, i.e. fee income, is broad and complex enough to warrant separate treatment. It should be noted, however, that the major transformation wrought by new technology with regard to fee income relates to asset securitisation. Some of the parameters of this change are indirectly considered below in connection with the financial intermediation function of banks. Fee income is connected to securitisation which, after all, has its origins in financial intermediation, specifically in the mortgage business. Moreover, securitisation involves techniques of risk management that in all essentials are also used in lending to individuals as well as to small and medium firms. The impact of new technology on these techniques is examined below.

a. Money-dealing and new technology

It is commonplace that the foreign exchange market has expanded enormously during the last three decades. The foreign exchange operations of banks have been significantly affected partly due to the acceleration of the speed of transactions and partly due to introduction of financial derivatives that rely on information technology. However, foreign exchange will be left out of account in this article because it is too broad a topic to discuss here but also because key aspects of it will be touched upon

below, especially regarding risk management. Clearing has also been dramatically affected by new technology but this too will be left out of discussion as it merits extensive separate treatment. The main concern of this section is the profound effect of new technology on the rest of the money-dealing activities of banks, including transmission, safe-keeping and ready access to money. Analytical focus is again on the USA but the trends appear to have general applicability. The most important effect of new technology in this respect has been the introduction of Automated Teller Machines (ATMs) since the 1970s. There has been no let up in the introduction of ATMs in the USA despite the passage of more than three decades:

Table 4. ATM Terminals in the USA 1996 139134 1997 165000 1998 187000 1999 227000 2000 273000 2001 324000 2002 352000 2003 371000 2004 383000 2005 396000 Source: ATM & Debit News

It is notable that, contrary to initial expectations, the spread of ATMs has not led to a decline in the number of conventional bank branches. The figures for the USA are clear:

Table 5. Bank Branches in the USA Commercial Banks Savings Institutions Credit Unions Total 1990 62346 2000 71784 2001 73027 21609 14112 14136 10160 10316 9984 94115 96212 97147

2002 73454 2003 74518 2004 76974

13940 13866 13691

9688 9369 9014

97082 97753 99679

Source: Federal Insurance Deposit Corporation; National Credit Union Administration

Some of the increase in the number of bank branches is due to the decline in the number of savings institutions since the Savings and Loans crisis of 1991, leading to absorption of their branches by banks (Osterberg and Sterk 1997). Concentration has been pronounced within the US banking system during the last two decades. Given the rapid decline in the number of commercial banks, there is no doubt that the underlying trend for the number of braches per bank has been upward:

Table 6. Number of Banks and Savings Institutions in the USA Commercial Banks Savings Institutions 1990 12329 2000 8297 2001 8062 2002 7870 2003 7752 2004 7614 2815 1589 1534 1466 1411 1345

Source: Federal Insurance Deposit Corporation; National Credit Union Administration

The conclusion is clear: advancing automation in the provision of moneydealing bank services has coincided with a second wave of branch banking in the USA (the first was more than one hundred years ago). Banks have now penetrated geographical areas and sectors of the US economy from which they were previously absent. But that has not also meant an expansion of their money-lending activities, as will be seen below. The introduction of ATMs might not have reduced the number of bank branches but its impact on banking operations has been extensive. It was initially expected that ATMs would reduce bank costs due to the difference between the costs

of individual transactions completed by ATMs and those completed in person by bank employees. Kimbal and Gregor (1995), for instance, estimated that the per-transaction cost for ATMs was $0.27 compared to $1.07 for tellers. However, things have turned out differently. The frequency with which customers use ATMs is higher than obtaining similar services from tellers, and the sums withdrawn tend to be smaller (Stavins 2000). Thus, the introduction of ATMs seems to have led to a change in the demand for money-related services: access to cash is required at all times and in geographical places that were previously out of bounds for banks. This has contributed to steadily rising ATM numbers and increased pressure on banks to expand ATM investment. Whereas banks initially provided ATMs at or near existing bank branches they now have to provide clusters of ATMs in new places, such as shopping malls. The latter are significantly more expensive to operate than ATMs placed at branches (Stavins 2000). At the same time, there has remained a strong demand for teller services provided in person by bank employees, perhaps in relation to more complex operations than cash withdrawals and deposits. The continuing demand for personal services has contributed to the steadily rising number of bank branches. These combined trends have meant that the costs of providing money-dealing services through ATMs for a given deposit base have been persistently high. Banks have attempted to deal with this problem in a variety of ways, typically through imposing charges on ATM use. Moreover, larger banks are imposing higher charges than smaller ones (Stavins 2000). Banks have also imposed institutional obstacles between customers and tellers by placing the latter away from the front desks, or even by charging customers more for transactions completed through tellers as opposed to those completed through ATMs. Yet, success in reducing costs has been elusive. It appears that the introduction of new technology in the form of ATMs might have increased the costs of providing money-dealing services for a given deposit base instead of lowering them. Generalised introduction of ATMs, however, has been only one part of the impact of technology on the money-dealing functions of banks. The adoption of the internet and the spread of electronic communications will probably prove even more significant for the money-dealing functions of banks in coming years. This process commencing in the 1990s and still in its infancy - is typically captured by the term ebanking or e-finance (Allen, McAndrews and Strahan 2002). Leaving aside clearing

and inter-bank payments (in which electronic communications have been in use for several decades), e-banking refers to a host of banking services, such as computer banking, debit cards, electronic bill payments, smart cards, stored-value cards, and so on. Several of these are forms of e-money and replace ordinary bank money or smalldenomination Federal Reserve banknotes from circulation. The proportion of US households banking by computer grew fivefold between 1995 and 2001, and the proportions using debit cards and smart cards more than doubled (Anguelov, Hilgert and Hogarth 2004). Meanwhile, the proportion of households using non-electronic banking methods of payment has declined. There can be little doubt that this is the direction that bank money-dealing services will take in the future. Nonetheless, the adoption of the new forms of payment will also face delays, while country-specific peculiarities in the use of paying methods are likely to remain, as is evidenced by the continuing prevalence of cheques as means of payment in the USA. There are complex problems attached to this phenomenon relating to the role of money in a capitalist economy and the requisite trust in particular forms of money. The spread of computers among different social groups and the familiarity of different age groups with computer practice are important in this respect. Not least is the matter of security in making payments online which require placing personal details at the disposal of unknown persons. These problems are likely to persevere thus limiting the spread of e-banking. For banks, one key attraction of internet banking is the low cost pertransaction. The consulting firm Booz-Allen & Hamilton Inc. estimated that average variable costs per transaction were about $0.01 for the internet compared to $1 or more for transactions completed through tellers (Bank of Japan, 2001, p.27). It remains to be seen, however, whether the internet and new electronic technology will succeed where ATMs failed. For one thing, the investment costs of internet banking are high, making banks the heaviest spenders on new technology within the financial sector. This raises average costs and requires a large number of accounts before internet banking begins to pay. It appears, moreover, that computer banking is more prevalent among individuals who hold higher balances and use more bank services (Hitt and Frei 2002). It is conceivable, therefore, that banks will find themselves obliged to provide new money-dealing services - requiring heavy capital investment without a substantial decline in other services. Money-dealing costs might prove persistent, as they have for ATMs.

More broadly, however, the introduction of e-banking will accelerate the transformation of the internal organisation of bank branches, a process that has been under way for some time also due to ATM introduction (Hughes and Bernhardt 1999, Hunter, Bernhardt, Hughes, and Skuratowicz 2001, Autor, Levy and Murnane 2000, 2003, Frei, Harker and Hunter 1998, Frei and Harker 2000). The role of tellers has already changed in line with increasing reliance on automated teller services. A significant proportion of tellers now have to provide more complex services which include sophisticated assessments of individual client data as well as overall economic data. Significant numbers of bank employees that used to be tellers have increasingly become sellers of banking services. The skills required by the latter are correspondingly advanced, often involving the use of information technology. By the same token, other tellers largely have to input data and to undertake simple mechanical manipulations using information technology. Therefore, banking jobs at the level of the branch have undergone a considerable upgrading as well as downgrading. While the back office employs more skilled staff to undertake complex tasks, the front desk has become relatively deskilled. In view of these complex changes, it is hardly surprising that the introduction of new money-dealing technology banks over the last three decades has not resulted in measurable productivity improvements, as was mentioned in section 2, and nor has it lowered costs. The banks have found themselves in the position of having to provide additional and unforeseen services that require heavy initial investment. The mix of labour skills needed at the branch level, meanwhile, has become considerably more complex. New technologies appear not to have reduced costs significantly in these respects. 4

b. Financial intermediation and new technology

It hardly needs stating that technological change in recent years has affected all aspects of financial intermediation. However, the strongest impact has been on the asset side of bank balance sheets, as well as off-balance-sheet. These changes cannot
4

Since clearing has not been examined, it is not possible to arrive at firm conclusions with regard to money-dealing as a whole. It should be mentioned that Bauer and Ferrier (1996) and Hancock, Humphrey and Wilcox (1999) have found that the costs of Automated Clearing House (ACH) and Fedwire services have high elasticity relative to total number of transactions. This could be an avenue through which new technology is successfully reducing bank costs.

be disentangled from the broader transformation of finance during the same period. Most prominent has been the broad decline of the share of commercial banks (and savings institutions) in total borrowing in the USA. The tendency for banks (all depository institutions) to lose share relative to pension funds and mutual funds has been well documented for some time (see, for instance, Edwards and Mishkin 1995). Moreover, large corporations rely heavily on retained profits and other internally generated funds, while obtaining external funds increasingly through the securities markets, i.e. through direct finance. However, the decline in the share of banks has not meant that they have become less important for the financial system, as was pointed out by Boyd and Gertler (1994). 5 In the new environment, banks have been earning fees by facilitating access to securities markets for large corporations. Consequently, the relationship between banks and large corporations has assumed an aspect of financial market mediation. Lending to individuals has acquired a new significance for banks. Moreover, banks have also strengthened their off-balance-sheet activities, including derivatives trading. In all these respects, new technology has been of key importance. In the remaining part of this article off-balance-sheet activities will not be directly considered. Nonetheless, the analysis of credit risk management and information processing also applies in good part to off-balance-sheet activities. Lending to individuals primarily for mortgages and consumption loans, including credit cards has become an increasing part of bank lending. Such lending has traditionally posed enormous informational problems for banks, resulting in risks that limited its scope. Ascertaining the creditworthiness of individuals and securing a reliable flow of interest payments are potentially very costly processes when large numbers are involved. Things have changed dramatically with the introduction of new techniques of credit scoring that rely on new technology, particularly on enlarged and cheap computer power. Credit scoring by banks was extensively introduced in the USA in the 1990s, the original spur coming from the earlier standardisation of individual mortgages. The technique involves the creation of borrower profiles by collecting information on a range of attributes/variables, including income, type of job, age, and credit history.
5

It is equally untrue that the decline in the share of banks in total borrowing indicates the decline of financial intermediation in general. Pension funds and money funds (as well as insurance companies) are, of course, financial intermediaries. What has changed is the dominant form of financial intermediation.

Each of the attributes is split into several classes with scores attached. Individual data on the attributes is then collected and a total score is assigned to each individual that serves as an index of riskiness. Banks typically employ a cut off point in assessing individual applications: failure to meet the threshold results in withdrawal of credit. The bank can also establish aggregate risk measurements for its balance sheet by organising the mass of the available information around a few variables (typically between seven and ten). The bank can then calculate the risk attached to its assets in relation to the sector as a whole (as distance from the sectoral averages). Using fairly complex econometrics, the bank can manage the volume and composition of its individual loans to attain a desired level of risk. 6 The introduction of credit scoring has already affected the practices and operations of banking capital in several ways. First, the enhanced ability of banks to ascertain risk levels has increased their capacity to adjust risk premia and therefore to present borrowers with a broader range of interest rates, i.e. banks are increasingly able to practice differential charging of interest rates. Second, credit scoring, other things equal, implies a lowering of the administrative costs of extending loans, thus raising the profitability of banks. Third, banks are better able to discriminate among borrowers. Given that this takes place on the basis of information collected from the existing pool of borrowers, it is possible that selection bias arises against individuals whose personal conditions are not captured by the range of variables included in risk monitoring. Fourth, the internal organisation of banks has been altered along similar lines to those mentioned in section 2. Specifically, banks have increased demand for platform staff that are familiar with information technology and can engage in technical assessment of credit. The broader significance of these developments, which are still in their infancy, cannot be underestimated. Banking capital appears to have acquired the means with which to reach sources of profit that were previously out of bounds. These sources lie within the circuit of private revenue of workers and others, rather than within the circuit of industrial and commercial capital. Techniques have been devised that allow banks to treat individual borrowers as units of an effectively homogenised mass, thus enabling risk calculations that so far appear to be reliable. This process would have been impossible without new technology allowing for quick and cheap

For an early and informative summary of the technique of credit scoring see Mester (1997).

processing of huge volumes of information. But it is also apparent that compiling the necessary information is neither easy nor cheap. Banks might be able to collect information fairly easily as far as their own customers are concerned but this is, by definition, a small part of the borrower pool with concomitantly unreliable statistical properties. Thus, one of the most pressing problems for banks currently is to create reliable databases covering the personal details of enormous numbers of individuals. Moreover, a new line of capitalist business has emerged as these databases are often run privately and information is sold commercially to banks. Credit scoring practices that were originally developed for individuals have recently begun to spread to bank lending to SMEs. The techniques are essentially the same, i.e. SMEs are treated as units of a homogenised mass to which econometric techniques are applied in order to ascertain risk relatively to sectoral averages. However, it is apparent that the logic applied to individuals cannot be directly and immediately applied to SMEs. An important problem is that SMEs differ significantly from each other in terms of the industry in which they are engaged, unlike individuals for whom the basic conditions of wage labour exhibit substantial similarities. Nonetheless, there are still sufficient similarities in practice among SMEs to allow banks increasingly to apply credit-scoring techniques. A further difficulty is the lack of reliable databases for SMEs, which is pronounced even for countries with welldeveloped financial systems, such as Japan. Much of the necessary information for the databases comes from SME income statements which tend to be understated by firms due to their tax implications, while being unsatisfactorily audited for very small firms. Nonetheless, the availability of credit scoring has meant that banks can more extensively engage in transactions-based banking, that is, extend loans on the basis of numerical and broadly quantitative information, thus treating borrowers as impersonal units at arms-length from the bank. Banks can readjust their relationship lending toward SMEs, that is, change the practice of extending loans on the basis of information collected through regular contact over long periods of time, which relies on the personal judgement of the borrower by the loans officer involved. (Berger and Udell 1995, 2002, 2003). It is apparent that these trends taken together have implications for the character of the financial system as a whole as they strengthen the arms-length, market-based aspect of bank lending. It is still far too early to draw firm conclusions regarding the significance of these developments for banks but note the following two important points. First, the

emergence of these practices has already led to diversification of the banking firm itself: banks have begun to specialise in providing and trading information suitable for processing by other banks. Such diversification, however, creates new competitive dangers for banks as there might be firms outside the financial sector that can also collect and assess financial information. Giant corporations that have skills in collecting and processing information, such as Microsoft, could enter the banking business and pose a threat for incumbents. Second, there are broad social implications from the construction of these databases, including for political democracy. The reach of financial capital into the private life of the population as a whole has never been broader and deeper. The enormous data banks that have already been constructed and placed at the disposal of banks are as nothing compared to those that are likely to emerge in the next ten years containing personal and private information that is then traded among financial institutions.

4. Conclusion

Several points made in this article are worth restating in the conclusion. First, banks in the USA have been operating within an environment of rapidly rising productivity since 1995, and hence have had broader opportunities for profit making. Second, the connection between new technology (mostly telecommunications, electronics and information processing) and rising productivity across the economy is still not clear, especially regarding the mechanisms through which new technology affects production and labour at the microeconomic level. Third, productivity in banking has not increased despite banks investing heavily in new technology. Fourth, adoption of new technology in performing the money-dealing functions of banks primarily ATMSs and e-banking - has certainly transformed the way in which banks operate. But it has also imposed high investments without delivering significant savings in the costs of banks and without visible improvements in staff productivity at the branch level. Fifth, adoption of new technology has also wrought substantial changes to the function of banks as financial intermediaries. New technology has been introduced while US banks have been losing share in the total borrowing across the economy. Banks have shifted their lending activities in the direction of individuals, drawing profits out of the circulation of private revenue. Banks have also increased the

proportion of fee income earned through mediating the entry of others in the financial markets. In this context, the introduction of new technology has altered the way banks operate in so far as it has allowed for new techniques of risk management and credit scoring. Information processing has emerged as a major new activity of banks, and banks have become more arms-length from their borrowers. But the possibility has also been opened for new competitors of banks arising outside the financial sector.

REFERENCES

Allen F., J. McAndrews and P. Strahan. 2002. E-Finance: An Introduction, Journal of Financial Services Research, vol. 22, no. 1&2: 5-27. Anguelov C., M. Hilgert, and J. Hogarth, 2004. US Consumers and Electronic Banking, 1995-2003, Federal Reserve Bulletin, Winter: 1-18. Autor D., F. Levy, and R. Murnane. 2000. Upstairs, Downstairs: Computer-Skill Complementarity and Computer-Labor Substitution on Two Floors of a Large Bank, Working Paper 7890, NBER. Autor D., F. Levy, and R. Murnane. 2003. The Skill Content of Recent Technological Innovation: An Empirical Investigation, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118 (4): 1279-1333. Bank of Japan. 2001. Technological Innovation and Banking Industry/Monetary Policy, Monetary and Economic Studies, vol. 19, no. 3, Novembe: 1-73. Basu S., J. Fernald and M. Shapiro. 2001. Productivity Growth in the 1990s: Techology, Utilization, or Adjustment, Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 55: 117-165. Bauer P. and Ferrier G. 1996. Scale Economies, Cost Efficiencies, and Technological Change in Federal Reserve Payment Processing, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 28 (4): 1004-39. Berger A. and G. Udell. 1995. Relationship Lending and Lines of Credit in Small Firm Finance, Journal of Business, 68 (3): 351-381. Berger A. and G. Udell. 2002. Small Business Credit Availability and Relationship Lending: The Importance of Bank Organisational Structure, Economic Journal, 112 (February): 32-53. Berger A. and G. Udell. 2003. Small Business and Debt Finance, in Handbook of Entrepreneurship Research, Acs Z. and D. Audretsch, (eds), Boston/Dordrecht/London: Kluwer Academic Publishers. Bloom N., R. Sadun and J. van Reenen. 2005. It Aint What You Do Its The Way That You Do I.T.: Testing Explanations of Productivity Growth Using US Affiliates, Centre for Economic Performance, London School of Economics. Boyd J. and M. Gertler. 1994. Are Banks Dead? Or Are the Reports Greatly Exaggerated?, Federal Bank of Minneapolis Qaurterly Review, Summer, 18 (3): 2-23.

Bresnahan T. and M. Trajtenberg. 1992. General Purpose Technologies: Engines of Growth?, Working Paper 4148, NBER. Brynjolfsson E. and L. Hitt. 2000. Beyond Computation: Information Technology, Organizational Transformation and Business Performance, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14(4): 23-48. Brynjolfsson E., L. Hitt and S. Yang. 2002. Intangible Assets: Computers and Organizational Capital, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity: Macroeconomics, vol. 1: 137-199. Brynjolfsson E. and L. Hitt. 2003. Computing Productivity: Firm-Level Evidence, MIT-Sloan Working Paper 4210-01. David P. 1990. The Dynamo and the Computer: An Historical Perspective on the Modern Productivity Paradox, American Economic Review, 80(2): 355-361. Dew-Becker I. and R. Gordon. 2005. Where did the Productivity Growth Go? Inflation Dynamics and the Distribution of Income, Working Paper 11842, NBER. Edwards F. and F. Mishkin. 1995. The Decline of Traditional Banking: Implications for Financial Stability and Regulatory Policy, Federal Reserve Bank of New York Economic Policy Review, July: 27-45. Fernhald J. and S. Ramnath. 2004. The acceleration in US total factor productivity after 1995: The role of information technology, Economic Perspectives, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, First Quarter: 52-67. Frei F. and P. Harker. 2000. Value Creation and Process Management: Evidence from Retail Banking, in Creating Value in Financial Services, Melnick S., P. Nayyar, M. Pinedo, and S. Seshadri, (eds), Boston/Dordrecht/London: Kluwer Academic Publishers. Frei F., P. Harker, and L. Hunter. 1998. Innovation in Retail Banking, Discussion Paper 97-48-B, Wharton. Gordon R. 1999a. Monetary Policy in the Age of Information Technology, Discussion Paper no. 99-E-12, Institute for Monetary and Economic Studies, Bank of Japan. Gordon R. 1999b. Has the New Economy Rendered the Productivity Slow-Down Obsolete?, Working Paper, Northwestern University, mimeo. Gordon R. 2000. Does the New Economy Measure up to the Great Inventions of the Past?, The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14(4): 49-74.

Gordon R. 2003. Exploding Productivity Growth: Context, Causes and Implications, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, no. 2: 207-279. Gordon R. 2004. Why was Europe Left at the Station when Americas Productivity Locomotive Departed?, Working Paper 10661, NBER. Griliches Z. 1994. Productivity, R&D, and the Data Constraint, American Economic Review, 84(1): 1-23. Hall R. 2000. E-Capital: The Link between the Stock Market and the Labor Market in the 1990s, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, no. 2, pp.73-102. Hall R. 2001. The Stock Market and Capital Accumulation, American Economic Review, 91(5): 1185-1202. Hancock D., D. Humphrey and J. Wilcox. 1999. Cost Reductions in Electronic Payments: The Roles of Consolidation, Economies of Scale and Technical Change, Journal of Banking & Finance, 23, nos 2-4: 391-421. Hitt L. and F. Frei. 2002. Do Better Customers Utilize Electronic Distribution Channels? The Case of PC Banking, Management Science, 48(6): 732-749. Hughes K. and A. Bernhardt. 1999. Market Segmentation and the Restructuring of Banking Jobs, Working Paper no. 9, Institute of Education and the Economy. Hunter L., A. Bernhardt, K. Hughes, and E. Skuratowicz. 2001. Its Not Just the ATMs: Technology, Firm Strategies, Jobs, and Earnings in Retail Banking, Industrial Labour Relations Review, 54, 2(A): 402-424. Jorgenson D. and K. Stiroh. 2000. Raising the Speed Limit: US Economic Growth in the Information Age, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, no. 1: 125-211. Jorgenson D., M.S. Ho and K. Stiroh. 2002. Projecting Productivity Growth: Lessons from the US Growth Resurgence, Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Economic Review, 3rd Quarter: 1-13. Jorgenson D., M.S. Ho and K. Stiroh. 2004. Will the US Productivity Resurgence Continue?, FRBNY Current Issues in Economics and Finance, 10(13): 1-7. Kimball R. and Gregor W. 1995. How Distribution Is Transforming Retail Banking: Changes Leading Banks Are Making, Journal of Retail Banking Services, vol. XVII, no. 3: 1-9. Mester L. 1997. What is the Point of Credit Scoring?, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadephia Business Review, September-October: 3-16. Nordhaus W. 2001. Productivity Growth and the New Economy, Working Paper 8096, NBER.

Oliner S. and Sichel D. 2000. The Resurgence of Growth in the Late 1990s: Is Information Technology the Story?, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14(4): 3-22. Oliner S. and Sichel D. 2002. Information Technology and Productivity: Where are we Now and Where are we Going?, Economic Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta, Third Quarter: 15-44. OMahony M. and B. van Ark. (eds). 2003. EU Productivity and Competitiveness: An Industry Perspective, Office for Official Publications of the European Communities: Luxemburg. Osterberg W. and S. Sterk. 1997. Do More Banking Offices Mean More Banking Services?, Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland Economic Commentary, December: 1-5. Sadun R. and J. van Reenen. 2005. Intellectual Property, Technology and Productivity, Working Paper, EDS Innovation Research Programme, London School of Economics. Solow R. 1957. Technical Change and the Aggregate Production Function, Review of Economics and Statistics, August, 39:3: 65-94. Solow R. 1987. Wed Better Watch Out, New York Times Book Review, July 12. Stavins J. 2000. ATM Fees: Does Bank Size Matter?, New England Economic Review, January/February: 13-24. Stiroh K. 2001. Is IT Driving the US Productivity Revival?, International Productivity Monitor, vol. 2: 31-6. Triplett J. 1996. High-Tech Industry Productivity and Hedonic Price Indices, OECD Proceedings: Industry Productivity, International Comparison and Measurement Issues, OECD: 119-142,. Triplett J. and B. Bosworth. 2000. Productivity in the Services Sector, Brookings Economics Papers, January. Triplett J. and B. Bosworth. 2001. Whats New about the New Economy? IT, Economic Growth and Productivity, International Productivity Monitor, vol. 2: 19-30. Triplett J. and B. Bosworth. 2003a. Baumols Disease Has Been Cured: IT and Multifactor Productivity in the US Services Industries, Brookings Economics Papers, September.

Triplett J. and B. Bosworth. 2003b. Services Productivity in the United States: Griliches Services Volume Revisited, Brookings Economics Papers, September. Triplett J. and B. Bosworth. 2003c. Productivity Measurement Issues in Services Industries: Baumols Disease Has Been Cured, FRBNY Economic Policy Review, September: 23-33.

Anda mungkin juga menyukai