Anda di halaman 1dari 344

Applied Evolutionary Economics and Economic Geography

Applied Evolutionary Economics and Economic Geography


Edited by

Koen Frenken
Utrecht University, The Netherlands

Edward Elgar
Cheltenham, UK Northampton, MA, USA

Koen Frenken 2007 All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system or transmitted in any form or by any means, electronic, mechanical or photocopying, recording, or otherwise without the prior permission of the publisher. Published by Edward Elgar Publishing Limited Glensanda House Montpellier Parade Cheltenham Glos GL50 1UA UK Edward Elgar Publishing, Inc. William Pratt House 9 Dewey Court Northampton Massachusetts 01060 USA A catalogue record for this book is available from the British Library Library of Congress Cataloguing in Publication Data European Meeting on Applied Evolutionary Economics (4th : 2005 : Utrecht, Netherlands) Applied evolutionary economics and economic geography / edited by Koen Frenken. p. cm. Summary: The volume Applied Evolutionary Economics and Economic Geography is the fourth book published by Edward Elgar on applied evolutionary economics and stems from the fourth European Meeting on Applied Evolutionary Economics (EMAEE) held in Utrecht, 1921 May, 2005. ... The present volume Applied Evolutionary Economics and Economic Geography aims to advance empirical methodologies in evolutionary economics, this time with a special emphasis on geographyfrom the Preface. Includes bibliographical references and index. 1. Evolutionary economicsCongresses. 2. Economic geographyCongresses. I. Frenken, Koen, 1972 II. Title. HB97.3E84 2005 330.1dc22 2006017913

ISBN 978 1 84542 845 7 Printed and bound in Great Britain by MPG Books Ltd, Bodmin, Cornwall

Contents
List of gures List of tables List of boxes List of contributors Preface 1. Introduction: applications of evolutionary economic geography Ron A. Boschma and Koen Frenken PART I ENTREPRENEURSHIP 27 vii ix xi xii xiv

2. The Cambridge high-tech cluster: an evolutionary perspective Elizabeth Garnsey and Paul Heernan 3. Sophia-Antipolis as a reverse science park: from exogenous to endogenous development Michel Qur PART II INDUSTRIAL DYNAMICS

48

4. The evolution of geographic structure in new industries Steven Klepper 5. Constructing entrepreneurial opportunity: environmental movements and the transformation of regional regulatory regimes Brandon Lee and Wesley Sine 6. Absorptive capacity and foreign spillovers: a stochastic frontier approach Jojo Jacob and Bart Los PART III NETWORK ANALYSIS

69

93

121

7. Informational complexity and the ow of knowledge across social boundaries Olav Sorenson, Jan W. Rivkin and Lee Fleming
v

147

vi

Contents

8. Networks and heterogeneous performance of cluster rms Elisa Giuliani 9. Social networks and the economics of networks Daniel Birke PART IV SPATIAL SYSTEMS 10. Diversity, stability and regional growth in the United States, 19752002 Jrgen Essletzbichler 11. Inter-regional knowledge ows in Europe: an econometric analysis Mario A. Maggioni and T. Erika Uberti 12. Explaining the territorial adoption of new technologies: a spatial econometric approach Andrea Bonaccorsi, Lucia Piscitello and Cristina Rossi PART V PLANNING

161 180

203

230

256

13. Evolutionary urban transportation planning? An exploration Luca Bertolini Index

279

311

Figures
1.1 2.1 2.2 2.3 2.4 2.5 2.6 2.7 2.8 3.1 3.2 3.3 3.4 3.5 4.1 4.2 4.3 4.4 4.5 4.6 Evolutionary economic geography applied at dierent levels of aggregation High-tech rms in Cambridgeshire, 19602004 Changing sectoral growth patterns among Cambridge high-tech rms Firm turnover (turbulence) in the Cambridge high-tech sector Comparison of survival rates for cohorts of Cambridge high-tech rms Companies with founders from Cambridge University engineering departments New rms started by founders and employees of Acorn Computers Industrial inkjet printing spin-outs originating in Cambridge Biotech rms originating in 12 Cambridge University departments Cumulative number of organisations and employment Cumulative number of organisations and employment (ICT) Cumulative number of organisations and employment (life sciences) Size distribution of ICT rms The geography of ICT activities Entry, exit and number of producers in the television industry, 19461989 Percentage of television producers in New York, Chicago and Los Angeles, 19461989 Entry, exit and number of producers in the automobile industry, 18951966 Percentage of automobile producers in the Detroit area, 18951941 Entry, exit and number of producers in the tire industry, 19011980 Percentage of tire producers in Ohio, 19061980
vii

4 31 33 34 35 36 37 38 40 49 52 53 59 61 71 72 75 76 81 81

viii

Figures

6.1 7.1 7.2 8.1

9.1 9.2 9.3 9.4 10.1 10.2 11.1 11.2 12.1 12.2 13.1 13.2a 13.2b

Labour productivity growth decomposition 125 Landscape without interdependence 149 Landscape with maximal interdependence 150 Types of networks: (a) BI network in CP; (b) KN network in CP; (c) BI network in BVC; (d) KN network in BVC; (e) BI network in CV; (f) KN network in CV 167 Number of subscribers in the UK 184 Development of subscriber market shares 185 Distribution of distances between nodes 190 Interaction network of students 192 Volatility, diversity, growth 216 Relationship between volatility and growth/diversity 218 Co-patent network, 19982002, including Oberbayern, Darmstadt, Dsseldorf and le de France 244 Co-patent network, 19982002, excluding Oberbayern, Darmstadt, Dsseldorf and le de France 245 Distribution of ICT adoption and added value per inhabitant across Italian provinces: the Three Italies 263 ICT adoption and added value per employee, univariate LISA 264 Changes in the built-up area and infrastructure in the Amsterdam region, 19672001 299 Coping with uncertainty in planning 307 Coping with irreducible uncertainty in planning (or chaos) 307

Tables
Two types of regional innovation policy Summary statistics and correlations for state-avoided cost analysis 5.2 GEE model predicting state-avoided costs 6.1a Summary statistics of 17 5-digit ISIC industries: levels 6.lb Summary statistics of 17 5-digit ISIC industries: average annual growth rates 6.2 Stochastic frontier estimates for 17 5-digit industries 6.3 Decomposition of productivity growth, 19851996 6A.1 Industrial classication 7.1 Rare events logit models of the likelihood of a focal patent receiving a citation from a future patent 8.1 Firm characteristics by cluster 8.2 Collection of key variables 8.3 Descriptive statistics and correlation matrix 8.4 Probit estimations with marginal eects 9.1 Gender and nationality of respondents 9.2 Frequencies for choice criteria 9.3 Do you know which operator your friends/family/ partner use? 9.4 Local network density 9.5 Mobile phone operators and nationality 9.6 Determinants of choosing the same operator 9.7 Predicted probabilities of using the same operator 9.8 Friendship determinants 9.9 Predicted probabilities of calling each other 10.1 Correlates of volatility 10.2 BEA area rankings by stability, diversity and growth 10.3 Basic statistics of dependent and independent variables 10.4 Correlation coecients between dependent and independent variables 10.5 Determinants of volatility 11.1 Pearson and Spearman correlations between knowledge ow variables 11.2 QAP correlation between knowledge ow variables
ix

1.1 5.1

15 110 111 132 134 136 140 144 156 168 169 173 174 187 188 188 190 193 194 194 195 196 213 217 219 220 221 239 240

Tables

11.3 11.4 12.1 12.2 12.3 12.4 12.5 12.6 12.7 12.8 13.1

Network analysis indices of knowledge ow structures Gravity equation for knowledge ows ICT adoption: descriptive statistics ICT adoption in macro areas Ranking of Italian provinces by ICT adoption and per capita income in 2001 Spatial dependence tests for the dependent variable Specication of dependent and independent variables Correlation matrix Standard OLS models Spatial lag and spatial error models Overview of dierent domains of change in the Amsterdam urban region, 19461999

242 247 261 261 262 264 265 266 267 269 285

Boxes
13.1 The late 1960s and early 1970s: a transport and land use policy transition dissected 13.2 The late 1980s and early 1990s: a land use policy transition dissected 292 294

xi

Contributors
Luca Bertolini Amsterdam Institute for Metropolitan and International Development Studies (AMIDSt), University of Amsterdam, The Netherlands. Daniel Birke Nottingham University Business School, University of Nottingham, UK. Andrea Bonaccorsi Facolt di Ingegneria, Universit di Pisa, Italy.

Ron A. Boschma Urban and Regional Research Centre Utrecht (URU), Utrecht University, The Netherlands. Jrgen Essletzbichler Department of Geography, University College London, UK. Lee Fleming Harvard Business School, Cambridge, MA, USA. Koen Frenken Urban and Regional Research Centre Utrecht (URU), Utrecht University, The Netherlands. Elizabeth Garnsey Centre for Technology Management, Institute for Manufacturing, University of Cambridge, UK. Elisa Giuliani Science Policy Research Unit (SPRU), University of Sussex, Brighton, UK. Paul Heernan Centre for Technology Management, Institute for Manufacturing, University of Cambridge, UK. Jojo Jacob Eindhoven Centre for Innovation Studies (ECIS), Eindhoven University of Technology, The Netherlands. Steven Klepper Department of Social and Decision Sciences, CarnegieMellon University, Pittsburgh, PA, USA. Brandon Lee School of Industrial and Labor Relations, Cornell University, Ithaca, NY, USA. Bart Los University of Groningen, The Netherlands.

xii

Contributors

xiii

Mario A. Maggioni Department of International Economics, Development and Institutions (DISEIS) and Faculty of Political Science, Catholic University, Milan, Italy. Lucia Piscitello Milano, Italy. Dipartmento di Ingegneria Gestionale, Politecnico di

Michel Qur Centre National de la Recherche Scientique Groupe de Recherche en Droit, Economie, Gestion (GREDEG), France. Jan W. Rivkin Harvard Business School, Cambridge, MA, USA. Cristina Rossi Scuola Superiore SantAnna, Pisa, Italy.

Wesley Sine Johnson Graduate School of Management, Cornell University, Ithaca, NY, USA. Olav Sorenson Rotman School of Management, Toronto, Canada.

T. Erika Uberti Department of International Economics, Development and Institutions (DISEIS) and Faculty of Political Science, Catholic University, Milan, Italy.

Preface
The volume Applied Evolutionary Economics and Economic Geography is the fourth book published by Edward Elgar on applied evolutionary economics, and stems from the fourth European Meeting on Applied Evolutionary Economics (EMAEE) held in Utrecht, 1921 May 2005. The rst volume edited by Paolo Saviotti (Applied Evolutionary Economics, 2003) was the founding volume. The second volume edited by John Foster and Werner Hlzl (Applied Evolutionary Economics and Complex Systems, 2004) dealt with empirical applications of complex systems theory. The third volume edited by Andreas Pyka and Horst Hanusch (Applied Evolutionary Economics and the Knowledge Based Economy, 2006) discussed the role of knowledge in the modern economy from an evolutionary perspective. As with previous volumes, this one also aims to advance empirical methodologies in evolutionary economics, but with a special emphasis on geography. We have seen a growing, mutual interest between economic geography and evolutionary economics in recent times. In particular, after the 2001 Schumpeter Prize winning work by Steven Klepper on the spatial evolution of industries and the innovative applications of social network analysis by Stefano Breschi, Francisco Lissoni, Elisa Giuliani and others, evolutionary scholars have become interested in the geography of industries and networks. These two meso levels of analysis will be central in the book. New developments on the interface between geography and evolutionary economics also take place at the micro level, in particular, the geography of entrepreneurship, and at the macro level, in particular, the dynamics of spatial systems as reected in the uneven growth of cities, regions and nations. The micro and macro levels will supplement the meso level in the book. The book thus consists of a four-layer structure as follows. Part I: Entrepreneurship (micro); Part II: Industrial Dynamics (meso); Part III: Network Analysis (meso); and Part IV: Spatial Systems (macro). The book opens with an introductory chapter and ends with a policy chapter on planning. Many people have contributed to this book. First, I would like to thank the authors who have all written excellent chapters. Their eorts show the value added of an evolutionary approach in economic geography. Second, I would like to thank the 125 participants of the fourth EMAEE held in Utrecht. The conference theme being geography, innovation and networks, the event was unique in bringing together economists and geographers to
xiv

Preface

xv

exchange ideas and advance our common understanding of economic geography. Third, I would like to thank the members of the scientic committee for their review work and the members of the local organising committee for preparing the conference. Special thanks go to Anet for her excellent planning of the conference, to Jesse for the IT support, and to Siebren for his personal assistance. Finally, I gratefully acknowledge the nancial support of the Urban and Regional research centre Utrecht (URU), the Netherlands Graduate School of Housing and Urban Research (NETHUR), the Royal Netherlands Academy of Arts and Sciences (KNAW), the Netherlands Organisation for Scientic Research (NWO), and the Utrecht municipality. Koen Frenken Utrecht, March 2006

1. Introduction: applications of evolutionary economic geography


Ron A. Boschma and Koen Frenken
1. INTRODUCTION

Economic geography is the eld of study that deals with the uneven distribution of economic activities in space. Two conicting theories are currently inuential in the eld: institutional economic geography and the new economic geography. Institutional economic geography is dominated by scholars with a geography background and is akin to institutional economics (Hodgson, 1998). At the risk of oversimplication, institutional economic geography argues that the uneven distribution of wealth across territories is primarily related to dierences in institutions (Whitley, 1992; Gertler, 1995; Martin, 2000). The new economic geography has been developed by neoclassical economists (Krugman, 1991; Fujita et al., 1999; Brakman et al., 2001), who view uneven distributions of economic activity as the outcome of universal processes of agglomeration driven by mobile production factors. Recent debates between geographers and economists have been erce and with little progress (for example, Martin, 1999; Amin and Thrift, 2000; Overman, 2004). The lack of cross-fertilisation between the two disciplines can be understood from two incommensurabilities between institutional and neoclassical economics (Boschma and Frenken, 2006). First, institutional economic geography and new economic geography dier in methodology. Institutional economic geographers tend to dismiss a priori the use of formal modelling. Instead, they apply inductive, often, casestudy research, emphasising the local specicity of real places. By contrast, the new economic geography approaches the matter deductively using formal models based on neutral space, representative agents and equilibrium analysis. Proponents of the latter approach do not value, or even reject altogether, case-study research. Second, the two theories dier in core assumptions regarding economic behaviour. The new economic geography aims to explain geographical patterns in economic activity from utility-maximising actions of individual agents. By contrast, institutional scholars start from the
1

Introduction

premise that economic behaviour is best understood as being rule guided. Agents are bounded rational and rely heavily on the institutional framework, which guides their decisions and actions. Institutions are embedded in geographically localised practices, which implies that localities (real places) are the relevant unit of analysis. Institutions play no role in neoclassical models, or only in a loose and implicit sense. They are not regarded as essential to economic explanations, and their study should therefore be best left to the sociologists, as Krugman once put it (Martin, 1999: 75). Evolutionary economic geography can be considered a third approach in economic geography. Evolutionary economists argue that the explanation to why something exists intimately rests on how it became what it is (Dosi, 1997: 1531). Rather than focusing on universal mobility processes underlying agglomeration (neoclassical) or the uniqueness of institutions in specic territories (institutional), an evolutionary economic geography views the economy as an evolutionary process that unfolds in space and time. In doing so, it focuses on the path-dependent dynamics underlying uneven economic development in space (Martin and Sunley, 2006). In particular, it analyses the geography of rm dynamics (such as the geography of entrepreneurship, innovation and extinction) and the rise and fall of technologies, industries, networks and institutions in dierent localities. In this view, uneven economic development requires an understanding of the Schumpeterian process of creative destruction at dierent levels of spatial aggregation (cities, regions, nations, continents). Even though evolutionary economics goes back at least to the seminal contribution by Nelson and Winter (1982), evolutionary approaches to economic geography are fairly recent (Arthur, 1994; Swann and Prevezer, 1996; Boschma, 1997; Rigby and Essletzbichler, 1997; Storper, 1997; Boschma and Lambooy, 1999; Antonelli, 2000; Canils, 2000; Klepper, 2001; Maggioni, 2002; Breschi and Lissoni, 2003; Bottazzi et al., 2004; Brenner, 2004; Werker and Athreye, 2004; Boschma and Wenting, 2005; Essletzbichler and Rigby, 2005; Martin and Sunley, 2006). The dierence between evolutionary economic geography and both new and institutional economic geography can be summarised as follows (Boschma and Frenken, 2006). An evolutionary approach to economic geography is dierent from new economic geography in that it attempts to go beyond the heroic assumptions about economic agents and the reduction of geography to transportation costs. At the same time, evolutionary economic geography also diers from institutional economic geography in that an evolutionary approach explains territorial dierences not primarily by referring to dierent institutions, but from dierences in the history of rms and industries residing in a territory. An evolutionary analysis may well take into account the role of institutions though, but in a co-evolutionary perspective (Nelson, 1995).

Introduction

Methodologically, evolutionary economic geography diers from both institutional and new economic geography in that it combines all research methodologies: case-study research, surveys, econometrics, theoretical modelling exercises and policy evaluation can, in principle, all be based on evolutionary theorising. The present volume, Applied Evolutionary Economics and Economic Geography, aims to further develop an evolutionary economic geography. It does so by bringing together a selected group of excellent scholars coming from business studies, economics, geography, planning and organisational sociology. All contributors share an interest in explaining the uneven distribution of economic activities in space and the historical processes that have produced these patterns. The heterogeneity in backgrounds was overcome by a common understanding of the evolutionary nature of spatial processes. The end result is a volume of 13 chapters on various topics organised under the headings of entrepreneurship, industrial dynamics, network analysis, spatial systems and planning. The volume also reects the variety of research methodologies characterising applied evolutionary economics, including case-study research (Garnsey and Heernan, Chapter 2; Qur, Chapter 3; Lee and Sine, Chapter 5; Bertolini, Chapter 13), duration models (Klepper, Chapter 4), data envelopment analysis (Jacob and Los, Chapter 6), complexity theory (Sorenson et al., Chapter 7), social network analysis (Sorenson et al., Chapter 7; Giuliani, Chapter 8; Birke, Chapter 9; Maggioni and Uberti, Chapter 11), spatial econometrics (Essletzbichler, Chapter 10; Bonaccorsi et al., Chapter 12) and gravity modelling (Maggioni and Uberti, Chapter 11).

2. EVOLUTIONARY ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY: MICRO, MESO AND MACRO APPLICATIONS


Boschma and Frenken (2006) argued that applications of evolutionary economic geography primarily fall under four categories: rm, industry, network and spatial systems. Their scheme also underlies the structure of the book with the various chapters being organised under one of these four headings. Following Figure 1.1, the categories follow from aggregating rms to their relevant meso levels of the industry in which they compete and the networks in which they exchange commodities and share knowledge. Aggregating in turn the meso levels to the macro level, one obtains the macro level of spatial systems. Following this scheme, localities in spatial systems, be it cities, regions or countries, can be characterised by their sector composition and their position in spatial networks, and structural changes herein over time (Castells, 1996).

Introduction

Policy (Chapter 13)

Macro

Spatial systems (Chapters 1012)

Meso

Industrial dynamics (Chapters 46)

Network analysis (Chapters 79)

Micro

Entrepreneurship (Chapters 23)

Introduction (Chapter 1)

Source: Adapted from: Boschma and Frenken (2006, p. 293).

Figure 1.1 Evolutionary economic geography applied at dierent levels of aggregation

Introduction

Entrepreneurship We consider evolutionary economic geography to involve a synthesis of evolutionary economics and economic geography. Following evolutionary economics, our starting point is the rm, which competes on the basis of its routines and core competences that are built up over time (Nelson and Winter, 1982). Organisational routines and core competences consist for a large part of learning-by-doing and tacit knowledge, which are hard to codify and dicult to imitate by other rms (Teece et al., 1997; Maskell, 2001). Consequently, organisations are heterogeneous in their routines, and persistently so (Klepper, Chapter 4; Giuliani, Chapter 8). Models can thus no longer rely on assuming a representative agent, but have to account for heterogeneous rms. This variety provides the fuel for selection processes, which causes some rms to prosper and grow and others to decline and possibly exit. From this evolutionary process of rm dynamics based on competition, innovation and selection, an emergent spatial pattern of economic activity arises. This evolving economic landscape, as reected by spatial heterogeneity in rms routines, can be understood as the joint outcome of geographical proximity (enhancing innovation and imitation) on the one hand, and spatial dierences in selection conditions on the other (Boschma and Lambooy, 1999; Essletzbichler and Rigby, 2005). In the context of economic geography, rm location, or more generally, the locational behaviour of rms, is the central explanandum (Stam, 2003). Demographically, the evolutionary economic process unfolding in space and time is driven by entry of new rms, exit of incumbent rms and relocation of incumbent rms. Through this process, new routines are being diused in space. From an evolutionary perspective, one does not analyse new rm location solely as the outcome of rational decisions directed by price dierentials, as in neoclassical theory, or in terms of comparing institutional frameworks in dierent areas, as in institutional theory. Rather, one is interested in the history of the founder and key employees of a new venture to account for routines transferred from a previous activity, and how that aects their survival. And, to understand uneven rates of regional entrepreneurship and entrepreneurial success, one is interested in the spatial distribution of resources required to start up a new business. As entrepreneurs require resources (capital, labour, networks, knowledge) to start new ventures, and resources tend to concentrate in space, as in urban areas (Hoover and Vernon, 1959) or specialised clusters (Porter, 2000), the probability of starting a new venture can also be made dependent on territorial conditions. This is not to say that price dierentials (the neoclassical view) and place-specic institutions (the institutional view) do not matter. Rather, prices and institutions only condition the range of possible

Introduction

economic behaviours and their locations, while the actual behaviours are determined by the path-dependent history of actors involved in particular territorial settings (Boschma and Frenken, 2006). The core concept of path dependence can also be fruitfully applied to rm location. Location decisions by rms are heavily constrained by the past. For example, many rms just start at locations where the founder lives, due to bounded rationality, or because the founder is socially embedded in local networks, and it is well known that most spin-os locate near the parent rm (Cooper and Dunkelberg, 1987; Klepper, 2001). In either case, previous decisions taken in the past determine the location decision of a new rm. Path dependence also aects the probability of relocation as rms are expected to display a considerable degree of locational inertia. The probability of relocation decreases over time as a rm develops a stable set of relations with suppliers and customers and sunk costs accumulate in situ (Stam, 2003). Of course, even though path dependence constrains relocation of the rm, one can expect the rm to outsource parts of the production to low-wage locations, in particular, activities that rely less on the organisational and core competences built up in situ over time (see Vernon, 1969). The probability and economic success of o-shoring, however, depends on a rms capability to transfer its routines to dierent localities (Kogut and Zander, 1993). Research has paid special attention to the geography of high-tech entrepreneurship (Hall and Markusen, 1985; De Jong, 1987; Aydalot and Keeble, 1988; Saxenian, 1994; Stuart and Sorenson, 2003). New high-tech rms are commonly thought to fuel employment growth and regional economic development. In the present volume, we focus on two exceptional European regions that have been successful in fostering high-tech entrepreneurship in information and communication technology (ICT). The two cases concern Cambridge, UK and Sophia-Antipolis near Nice. The development of Cambridge as a high-tech region can be understood as resulting from an endogenous evolutionary process of entrepreneurs setting up business and hereby improving the conditions for new ventures to occur (Garnsey and Heernan, Chapter 2). The endogenous process encompassed the founding of companies by members of the university, spin-os, the rise of local suppliers and the emergence of specialist labour markets. This process, however, has not been entirely automatic. Once congestion became problematic and university regulations were perceived unfavourable for entrepreneurship, collective action resulted in institutional reform. Thus, the history of the Cambridge region illustrates both the endogenous nature of entrepreneurship and the co-evolutionary process of entrepreneurship, regional development and institutional change. Another example of successful regional development is the science park of SophiaAntipolis. However, its development was far from endogenous. Rather the

Introduction

process was triggered by the presence of a few large companies, a favourable living environment and a visionary man (Qur, Chapter 3). Interestingly, the process transformed from being triggered by external factors into a more endogenous process from the early 1990s onwards. The endogenous nature of the more recent history is evidenced by the fact that even though some larger rms left the park in the early 1990s to go to larger agglomerations such as Paris and London, employees decided not to leave the region, but to start their own ventures instead. In this particular case, it is the employee rather than the rm that shows locational inertia. Thus, the two cases of Cambridge and SophiaAntipolis are dierent yet equally successful in the creation of new high-tech rms (see also, Garnsey and Longhi, 2004). Industrial Dynamics Starting from the rm, the rst meso level of aggregation that is specically important in evolutionary economic geography is the industry level. In this context, the main phenomenon to be explained is the process of spatial concentration or de-concentration of an industry over time. Arthur (1994) developed two simple evolutionary models of spatial concentration by spin-o and by agglomeration economies (see also, Boschma and Frenken, 2003). In the spin-o model an industry comes into being as a Polya process of rms giving birth to rms giving birth to rms and so on. This process is known to have played an important role in the rapid growth and spatial concentration of several industries, including the concentration of the US automobile industry in the Detroit area (Klepper, 2001), the ICT sector in Silicon Valley (Saxenian, 1994) and the biotechnology sector in Cambridge, UK (Keeble et al., 1999). Klepper (2001, 2002) extended the spin-o model in an industry lifecycle model, which synthesises ve assumptions: routines are heterogeneous; spin-os inherit the routines of parent rms; more successful rms grow faster; larger rms produce more spin-os; and worse-performing rms are forced to exit due to competition. The rst four mechanisms ensure that the region that hosts early, experienced and successful entrants will come to dominate the industry. In contrast to Arthurs spin-o model, this truly concerns a process of inheritance in which the experience of parent rms is inherited by spin-os with a positive impact on their survival rates. The fth mechanism of cost competition at the sector level asymmetrically aects regions, causing the region hosting the less successful rms to decline, leaving the region hosting the successful companies to dominate the industry. Typically, cost competition becomes erce only after an industry has developed for a number of years, that is, after product standardisation has taken place and innovation shifts to process innovation

Introduction

in line with the product life-cycle hypothesis (Abernathy and Utterback, 1978). The result is a shakeout forcing many rms to exit the industry, which strongly aects the spatial distribution of the industry since routines are heterogeneous and unevenly spread. The predictions of the model can be tested econometrically in a relatively straightforward way using duration models (Klepper, 2001, 2002). Arthurs (1994) second model of agglomeration economies assumes that new rms start up rather than spin o from incumbent rms. The location choice of a new rm can therefore not be automatically determined by the location of the parent company: the location of the rm becomes a choice decision. Arthur assumes that each rm has a locational preference for one particular region. While Arthur is far from explicit on this matter, this heterogeneity in preferences can stem from bounded rationality yet may also be given an empirical meaning: start-ups typically locate their business in the region where the founder lives and/or held previous employment. Agglomeration economies arising from spatial concentration of rms operating in the same industry, cause the industry to concentrate in one single region even though the individual rms have dierent individual preferences. The reason is that once one region has attracted slightly more entrants than other regions, a critical threshold is passed, and suddenly all rms will opt for this one region: a case of spatial lock-in. In an empirical context, the outcomes of the spin-o model are not easily distinguishable from the outcomes of the agglomeration economies model. We have, indeed, two dierent explanations for the same phenomenon of spatial concentration of an industry. As spin-o dynamics and agglomeration economies may well contribute to spatial concentration simultaneously, the challenge for empirical research is to disentangle both processes so as to assess their presence and importance. One out of the few studies that have attempted to do so is Kleppers (2001) study of the US automobile industry. In his econometric analysis, he included a dummy for being located in the Detroit area. The dummy showed no positive eect on the survival of rms, which suggests that agglomeration economies were not present. The use of a Detroit control variable, however, can be questioned, since a subset of rms within the Detroit area may have beneted from each others presence through local networks (Giuliani, Chapter 8) or rms may have beneted from knowledge spillovers over a longer distance (Jacob and Los, Chapter 6). Despite this shortcoming, the result by Klepper (2001) strongly suggests that the concentration of the US automobile industry in Detroit can be attributed mainly to the self-reinforcing dynamics of successful rms creating successful spin-os, and so on. A study by Boschma and Wenting (2005) on the spatial evolution of the British automobile sector came to similar conclusions regarding the

Introduction

self-reinforcing nature of spin-o dynamics, which, in the British case, led to a concentration in the BirminghamCoventry area. However, Boschma and Wenting also accounted for the presence of related industries (such as coach and cycle making) in a region as a potential source of agglomeration economies, which was shown to have a positive eect on the survival rate of rms. Thus, the local presence of related industries appeared to be benecial due to, for example, knowledge spillovers and skilled labour, yet the local presence of a high number of rms operating in the same industry turned out to be harmful due to increased competition, lowering the survival chances of new entrants. Another recent elaboration on Kleppers model is by Cantner et al. (2005), whose methodology using instrumental variable estimation allows for post-entry innovation. In doing so, the survival probabilities are not only dependent on initial conditions of entrants, but also on the research and development activities they undertake during their lifetime. These contributions suggest that survival analysis is a promising research methodology in evolutionary economic geography. Importantly, in an evolutionary context, spatial concentration (or its absence) is not only an outcome of a process of industrial evolution, but also aects an industrys further evolution. This recursive relationship is central in another empirical tradition in industrial dynamics known as organisational ecology or rm demography (Hannan et al., 1995; Carroll and Hannan, 2000; Stuart and Sorenson, 2003; van Wissen, 2004). First, geographical concentration of industrial activities can generate positive feedbacks on entry rather than performance. This means that an industry can become concentrated through a self-reinforcing process of entry triggering more entry. Second, geographical concentration of rms increases the level of competition and makes entry less likely. This negative feedback set limits to spatial concentration. Typically, positive feedbacks operate at the start of an industry life cycle, while negative feedback takes over after a certain threshold of spatial concentration is passed. Interestingly, the two processes causing positive and negative feedbacks may well operate at dierent spatial scales depending on the type of industry (Jacob and Los, Chapter 6). In industries where demand is local and knowledge spillovers more global, one expects negative feedbacks to operate at a lower spatial level than positive feedbacks, resulting in a more even spatial distribution (Hannan et al., 1995). However, in markets where competition is global, but knowledge spillovers rather local, the reverse may well be the case. Institutions also aect the spatial evolution of industries. From an evolutionary perspective, the question is not so much whether particular institutions triggered the development of a particular industry in a certain region, but rather how institutions have co-evolved with the emergence of a new sector (Nelson, 1995). The co-evolutionary perspective is important

10

Introduction

because it acknowledges that innovations leading to new sectors often require the restructuring of old institutions and the establishment of new institutions (Freeman and Perez, 1988). Examples of the co-evolution of new sectors and institutions are the rise of the synthetic dye industry in the second half of the nineteenth century in Germany (Murmann, 2003) and the evolution of the UK retail banking industry from the 1840s to the 1990s (Consoli, 2005). In their study of the spatial diusion of the renewable energy technology, Lee and Sine (Chapter 5) also emphasise the dierential institutional changes occurring in dierent American states. Network Analysis Networks provide another unit of analysis. Unlike the competitive nature of industrial dynamics, network relationships are less competitive and of a more complementary nature. One important aspect of networks in evolutionary economic geography is that these act as vehicles for knowledge spillovers. A key research question is then to determine whether knowledge diusion and innovation is more a matter of being in the right place, in the right network, or in both (Boschma and Ter Wal, 2006). Social network analysis provides a rich toolbox for the analysis of the structure and evolution of networks (Wasserman and Faust, 1994; Carrington et al., 2005). What is more, there is a lot of interest in theorising about networks and network formation starting from the pioneering work by Granovetter (1973) and Burt (1982) to more recent, but already classic contributions of Watts and Strogatz (1998) and Barabasi and Albert (1999). In evolutionary economics, interest in networks stems primarily from the increasing importance of networks among high-technology rms (Hagedoorn, 1993; Powell et al., 1996), while geographical studies have shown the role of networking in clusters (Uzzi, 1996; Maskell and Malmberg, 1999). The central question has been whether agents prot from simply being co-located or whether network relationships are required to carry these knowledge ows. A related question is whether geographical proximity facilitates the formation of network links. An innovative study by Breschi and Lissoni (2003) found that, using co-inventor data to indicate social networks and patent citations to indicate knowledge ows, geographical localisation of knowledge spillovers can be largely attributed to social networks and labour mobility. This study shows considerable progress over the study by Jae et al. (1993), who treated geographical space as a black box. The BreschiLissoni study suggests that geographical proximity is neither a necessary nor a sucient condition for knowledge spillovers to occur. Rather, knowledge diuses through social networks, which are dense between proximate actors, but also span across the globe.

Introduction

11

Network analysis between rms in specialised clusters is another eld in which social network analysis can be fruitfully applied. Using survey data, Giuliani (2005) has been able to map the business and knowledge networks among wine producers in three dierent clusters. She found that the the distribution of connectivity is much more skewed in knowledge than in business networks, which suggests that only a few central rms prot from knowledge spillovers. This hypothesis has been put to the test in a followup study presented in this volume (Giuliani, Chapter 8), in which it is shown that a rms centrality in knowledge networks is indeed positively aecting innovative performance, even after controlling for heterogeneity in internal competencies. A recent study by Boschma and Ter Wal (2006) on a footwear district in southern Italy tends to suggest that the absorptive capacity of rms is indirectly related to their innovative performance, through having non-local instead of local relationships. That is, the higher the absorptive capacity of a district rm, the better it is connected to organisations outside the district, which, in turn, impacts positively on their innovative performance. These studies show that social network analysis is a powerful tool in analysing the geography and structure of knowledge networks and the eect of a rms network position in these networks on its performance. In a similar fashion, the concept of regional innovation systems (Cooke et al., 1998) can be operationalised empirically more systematically by mapping the various network relations of actors that are part of the regional system with other actors within and outside the regional system. Evolutionary theorising has also argued that, due to bounded rationality, consumers also rely on personal networks. As a result, certain decisions by central actors can propagate through the network, leading many consumers to opt for the same product (Cowan et al., 1997; Plouraboue et al., 1998; Solomon et al., 2000). The strength of these networks eects, and the geographical nature of such personal networks, can also be explored empirically using social network analysis. A nice example of such an approach is the study by Birke (Chapter 9), who conducted a survey among students asking them about their personal networks and their choice of mobile telephone operator so as to analyse the eect of personal networks on the choice of operator. Hitherto, the use of social network analysis in evolutionary economics has been almost exclusively static. A future challenge is to understand the spatial evolution of networks. This requires longitudinal data and methods to analyse the dynamics of networks over time. An inuential theoretical model of network dynamics is the model by Barabasi and Albert (1999). In this model, a network grows as new nodes connect to a network. Nodes are assumed to attach themselves to other nodes with a probability proportional

12

Introduction

to the latters connectivity. This principle is known as preferential attachment, which means that a new node prefers to link with a well-connected node so as to prot from its connectivity. Well-connected nodes will then tend to become even more connected, while peripheral nodes in the network will tend to remain peripheral. The resulting distribution of connectivity will be extremely skewed (scale free). Which of the nodes becomes the central node is path dependent, and thus unpredictable, although early entrants will have a much higher probability of becoming central than later entrants. The stochastic logic underlying the BarabasiAlbert model of network formation has also been applied to the spatial evolution of networks where new nodes can occur anywhere in space, and connections between nodes are made dependent on both geographical space (negatively) and preferential attachment (positively). The resulting topology and spatial organisation of a network can then be understood as a purely stochastic and myopic sequence (Andersson et al., 2003, 2006) that may generate hub-and-spokes networks, as observed in infrastructure networks (for example, Guimer and Amaral, 2004; Barrat et al., 2005). Empirical research in this eld, however, has still been rather limited. Spatial Systems Aggregating sectors and networks to the macro level of spatial systems, one obtains a model of the growth of localities (cities, regions, countries), as depending on their sectoral composition and global network position, and the structural changes herein occurring over time. The sectoral logic underlying the evolution of spatial systems is better known as the process of structural change (Freeman and Perez, 1988; Boschma, 1997, 2004). Cities and regions that are capable of generating new sectors with new product life cycles will experience growth, while cities and regions that are locked into earlier specialisations with mature life cycles will experience decline. Importantly, there is no automatic economic or political mechanism to ensure that cities or regions will successfully renew themselves. Rather, one expects localities in most instances to experience decline after periods of growth due to vested interests, institutional rigidities and sunk costs associated with previous specialisations (Grabher, 1993). There are, however, still very few systematic evolutionary studies on convergence and divergence at dierent spatial scales (for example, Pumain and MoriconiEbrard, 1997; Canils, 2000). This can be partly understood from the demanding data requirements for systematic analysis of long-term dynamics, especially if one is interested in analyses at subnational levels. A particularly popularly topic in economic geography concerns the role of variety in regional growth. Economic theory has long been focused on

Introduction

13

explaining economic growth by a combination of growth in inputs and eciency improvements (Solow, 1957). The underlying qualitative nature of economic development, in terms of the variety of sectors or the variety of technologies, has been addressed only rarely. One can distinguish three types of relationships between variety and economic development (Frenken et al., 2005, 2006). The rst approach centres on variety, knowledge spillovers and growth, which has become a central theme in what is called new growth theory. It has been argued that, apart from spillovers occurring between rms within a sector, spillovers also occur between sectors, which are commonly referred to as Jacobs externalities, after Jacobs (1969). A second way to relate variety to regional economic development is to view variety as a portfolio strategy to protect a region from external shocks in demand (Essletzbichler, Chapter 10). In this context, one also speaks of regional diversication analogous to corporate diversication as a risk-spreading strategy. A third type of relationship between variety and economic development concerns the long-term eect of variety on the economic system. An economy that does not increase the variety of sectors over time, will suer from structural unemployment, and will ultimately stagnate. In this view, the development of new technologies and sectors in an economy is required to absorb labour that has become redundant in existing sectors (Pasinetti, 1981, 1993; Saviotti and Pyka, 2004). This process underlying long-term growth has major geographical implications, when new sectors emerge in other areas than the ones where old sectors are located. This would imply that labour becomes redundant primarily in areas where the old sectors are concentrated, while new employment is primarily created in new areas. This imbalance may be counteracted by labour migration from old to new areas and by rm migration in the opposite direction. Although many empirical studies have analysed the eects of variety on regional growth in the past decade or so, some methodological issues in empirical research remain. First, the measurement of variety is not trivial. For example, one would like to distinguish between related variety underlying spillovers and unrelated variety underlying the portfolio eects (Frenken et al., 2006; Essletzbichler, Chapter 10). Second, explaining regional phenomena requires a careful econometric specication so as to allow dierent eects to take place at dierent spatial levels of aggregation. For example, the rate of regional growth or the rate of regional information technology (IT) adoption can be made dependent on the rate of growth in neighbouring regions through the use of spatial autocorrelation econometrics (Essletzbichler, Chapter 10; Bonaccorsi et al., Chapter 12). The network perspective also lends itself for aggregation to the macro level. By aggregating networks between rms to the locations of these rms, one obtains inter-city and inter-regional networks. The underlying concept

14

Introduction

of network cities has become very common among geographers (Pred, 1977; Hohenberg and Lees, 1995; Castells, 1996). The central idea underlying the concept of network cities holds that connectivity contributes both to urban economic growth and to urban inequalities. Examples of empirical studies that map urban networks include networks based on the ties between headquarters and subsidiaries of multinational organisations (Taylor, 2001; Alderson and Beckeld, 2004), on transportation networks (Matsumoto, 2004) or IT infrastructure (Moss and Townsend, 2000). In these views, cities can develop a more central network position by attracting corporate headquarters or functioning as transportation or IT hubs. The concept of inter-city networks can also be applied to inter-regional networks, as the contribution by Maggioni and Uberti (Chapter 11) shows. Regions acting as central hubs in the development and diusion of knowledge will be more central in these networks, while other regions will stay more peripheral. Network position is thus expected to aect regional growth, as central hubs will receive more, and more relevant, knowledge spillovers. Using Tinbergens (1962) gravity model from international trade theory, one can also analyse to what extent geographical distance aects the strength of knowledge ows between any two regions. This question has also been taken up by Maggioni and Uberti (Chapter 11). As for the study of rm networks, the dynamic analysis of urban and regional networks is still in its infancy. Understanding the structure of a network at one moment in time requires an understanding of the evolutionary process that has given rise to such structures. An interesting research avenue is to analyse the determinants of changes in network structures in a spatial system. For example, does the accession of Eastern European countries reorganise the hierarchy in the European city system? And, historically, can we relate the rise and fall of cities to their changing positions in global knowledge networks around emerging technologies and infrastructures (Pumain, 1997)?

3.

POLICY

The contributions in the present volume focus on understanding spatial phenomena from an evolutionary perspective. General policy implications are often hard to draw, if only because evolutionary theorising leaves room for small events to have long-lasting eects. Some may even go a step further to suggest that evolutionary analysis often shows the limited potential of policy makers to truly inuence long-term geographical patterns of economic growth. For example, Kleppers (Chapter 4) conclusion that the US automobile industry became concentrated in Detroit for accidental

Introduction

15

reasons, suggests that eorts to attract new industries to a particular city or region have a low probability of success. What matters most is to have competent entrepreneurs, the presence and actions of which are hard to inuence by policy. Similarly, the success story of Sophia Antipolis (Qur, Chapter 3) suggests that its success is unique and dicult to copy. The process of regional development was set in motion by external factors such as climate, the presence of multinationals, the international airport, and one visionary man. And, in the case of Cambridge, regional development was fuelled by its excellent university as well as by the benets of the Greater London area at just one hour from Cambridge (Garnsey and Heernan, Chapter 2). Even if policy implications of evolutionary economics are inherently dicult to derive, a growing number of evolutionary economists are trying to draw some policy implications (Perez and Soete, 1988; Metcalfe, 1995; Foray, 1997; Nelson, 1999; Lambooy and Boschma, 2001; Chang, 2003). The point of departure is that the focus on static eciency in neoclassical economics is to be replaced by dynamic eciency (Nelson and Winter, 1982). In other words, one is not only interested in the allocation of scarce resources present today, but also in the opportunities to create new resources in the future. In the context of economic geography, the question becomes how to design policies that promote dynamic eciency at urban and regional levels. Boschma (2005) distinguished between two types of regional policy: evolutionary and revolutionary (Table 1.1). Evolutionary regional policy takes the specic local context and industrial structure as the starting point. It is a ne-tuning policy that aims to strengthen the connectivity between the elements of the regional system. In these circumstances, local policy makers have few degrees of freedom, yet are more likely to be successful as long as their actions are localised, that is, focused on reproducing and strengthening the existing structures. In other words, the local environment Table 1.1 Two types of regional innovation policy
Revolutionary type of policy Generic policy Restructuring of institutional framework Stimulating new connections Stimulating diversity More degrees of freedom More uncertainty

Evolutionary type of policy Location-specic policy Fine-tuning Strengthening existing connectivity Beneting from specialisation Few degrees of freedom Less uncertainty
Source: Adapted from Boschma (2005).

16

Introduction

determines to a large extent available options and probable outcomes of regional policy. The goal of a revolutionary regional policy, by contrast, is the restructuring of the social and institutional framework by constructing new regional systems, increasing diversity and a high degree of openness regarding the inow of labour, capital and knowledge. In these circumstances, local policy makers have more degrees of freedom, but at the cost of a higher degree of uncertainty regarding the actual outcome of regional policy making and its success. Since path dependence is less relevant, it is less meaningful to account for the location-specic context as a starting point for regional policy. Radically new trajectories of industrial development build on generic conditions, because the existing actors and institutional environment are unlikely to provide the specic stimuli. The case of Sophia Antipolis seems to be a good example of such a development. The paradox of regional policy holds that it can be very eective and successful in conserving economic activity by means of evolutionary policies, yet it has diculty triggering, or even opposes new economic activity necessary for long-term development. Note, however, that evolutionary and revolutionary policies are not mutually exclusive. One can pursue netuning policies in existing sectors while improving the generic conditions for revolutionary change to take place. However, such a two-goal policy requires careful policy making, because policies designed for one goal may in practice hamper the achievement of the other one. A way to combine both objectives is to enhance the creation of new industrial trajectories, be it new technologies or new sectors, by means of building upon the existing competence base of rms, employers and employees in the region. Radical innovations often stem from the (quite unexpected) recombination of existing technologies in entirely new ways (Levinthal, 1998). A famous example has been the rise of an environmental sector after the decline of the mining industry in the Ruhr area. A broad engineering base in the Emilia Romagna region provided a fertile ground for the emergence of a broad range of industries such as ceramics, food packaging, robotics, car manufacturing and agricultural machinery during the post-war period (Boschma, 2004). Another example is the birth of the automobile industry in the CoventryBirmingham area in England, which was partly determined by the strong presence of the bicycle and carriage industry (Boschma and Wenting, 2005). This policy captures the importance of creating related variety in a region, which broadens a regions sectoral base, while fostering knowledge spillovers between the sectors (Frenken et al., 2005, 2006). Another domain of policy, which is of crucial importance for urban and regional economic growth, is infrastructure provision. The growth of agglomerations is limited by the capacity and quality of its infrastructure

Introduction

17

networks. For this reason, successful regional policy always requires a complementary transportation infrastructure policy. Again, Sophia Antipolis serves as a successful example (Qur, Chapter 3), while Cambridge suered precisely from a mismatch between its economic development and infrastructure provision (Garnsey and Heernan, Chapter 2). Adopting an evolutionary approach to transportation planning in the agglomeration of Amsterdam, Bertolini (Chapter 13) attempts to derive some general guidelines for planning. Given the inherent and irreducible uncertainty about the future regional development and landuse claims, urban transportation systems should be capable of resilience, that is, still function properly in the face of change. At the same time, if necessary, the system must also be responsive to change, that is, it must be adaptable. In transport systems, resilience is best shown by the network morphology and multi-modality, while adaptability is foremost a property of the policy system. The link between the two is important: in the case of Amsterdam, the resilience of the transport network morphology has been a condition for the adaptability of land use and mobility management policies, because it allowed a choice at all times between substantially dierent policy courses.

4.

DISCUSSION

Using the micromesomacro scheme in Figure 1.1 as a framework, we have discussed various applications of evolutionary economics in the eld of economic geography. The common denominator in these approaches is to view spatial structures as the outcome of historical processes, and as conditioning but not fully determining economic behaviour. The explicit historical nature of evolutionary analysis, however, poses demanding requirements for empirical research. One needs to collect time-series data of evolving populations, be it from technologies, sectors, networks, cities or regions, and to apply appropriate methodologies to analyse the data collected. The contributions by Klepper (Chapter 4), Jacob and Los (Chapter 6) and Essletzbichler (Chapter 10) are ne examples of the use of econometric techniques applied to time-series data. However, other methodologies are also available to fruitfully apply evolutionary economics. For example, case-study research, combining written and oral sources, can provide an understanding of long-term planning processes (Bertolini, Chapter 13) and the multi-faceted process of regional development (Garnsey and Heernan, Chapter 2; Qur, Chapter 3). Static analysis, although dealing with snapshots of an otherwise evolving process, can also be approached from an evolutionary perspective, for example, by deriving

18

Introduction

hypotheses on expected inequalities in network positions (Giuliani, Chapter 8) or rates of technology adoption (Bonaccorsi et al., Chapter 12). Nevertheless, such phenomena could be understood better if time-series data were available. Apart from data limitations and methodological challenges ahead, there are still a number of conceptual weaknesses that hamper the application of evolutionary economics to economic geography: for example, the concept of routines still needs to be rened (Becker, 2004), and their role in the development of multi-locational organisations is still quite unclear (Stam, 2003, 2006); and the evolutionary theory of the rm has little to say about multinational organisations, exceptions aside (Kogut and Zander, 1993; Cantwell and Iammarino, 2003). Another key concept in evolutionary economics is path dependence. Yet, its fruitful application in economic geography is still surrounded by a number of unsolved issues (Martin and Sunley, 2006). Finally, as Breschi and Lissoni (2001) have argued at length, the concept of knowledge spillovers is, both conceptually and empirically, still ill-dened. Despite the growing number of studies on knowledge spillovers, the mechanisms underlying such spillovers are still poorly understood as well as to what extent these mechanisms are sector and/or region specic. Furthermore, the importance of knowledge spillovers may be specic for the geographical distance over which they occur. The more important information ows typically stem from more distant locations, a geographical principle that might reect the strength of weak ties (Granovetter, 1973). However, research that takes into account global spillovers is still scarce (Jae and Trajtenberg, 1999). In this light, the contributions by Jacob and Los (Chapter 6) and Maggioni and Uberti (Chapter 11) are especially important. The big question regarding the unequal distribution of wealth among nations needs to be addressed more often and more systematically. An evolutionary economic geography may provide a new understanding of coreperiphery patterns at dierent spatial scales as evolutionary outcomes of path-dependent dynamics. Such an approach would combine the Schumpeterian analysis of structure change with the spatial process of agglomeration and global networking. However, evolutionary growth theory (as does growth theory more generally) still lacks an explicit spatial structure. A challenge ahead is to transform evolutionary growth theory into a theory explaining the evolution of uneven distribution of economic activities in space. In all, recent research, including the chapters in this volume, has shown the value added of an evolutionary approach in economic geography. An evolutionary economic geography aims to improve our theoretical and empirical understanding of the economy as an evolutionary process that

Introduction

19

unfolds in space and time. Starting from the seminal contribution by Nelson and Winter (1982) and its theoretical elaborations in subsequent works (Dosi et al., 1988; Dopfer, 2005), a number of frameworks are being developed that specically deal with geographical issues, including location theory and entrepreneurship, the spatial evolution of sectors, the geography of social networks, the evolution of spatial systems, and urban and regional planning. Methodologically, a variety of approaches are being pursued ranging from case-study research and social network analysis to duration models and spatial econometrics. Theoretically coherent and methodologically open, an evolutionary perspective is helpful in understanding the specic histories of rms and regions using a framework that is less restrictive than the neoclassical paradigm, yet more generally applicable than the institutionalist approach. It is time to take geography seriously in applied evolutionary economics.

BIBLIOGRAPHY
Abernathy W.J. and Utterback, J. (1978), Patterns of industrial innovation, Technology Review, 50: 417. Alderson, A.S. and Beckeld, J. (2004), Power and position in the world city system, American Journal of Sociology, 109: 81151. Amin, A. and Thrift, N. (2000), What kind of economic theory for what kind of economic geography?, Antipode, 32(1): 49. Andersson, C., Frenken, K. and Hellervik, A. (2006), A complex network approach to urban growth, Environment and Planning A, 38: 194164. Andersson, C., Hellervik, A., Lindgren, K., Hagson, A. and Tornberg, J. (2003), Urban economy as a scale-free network, Physical Review E, 68(3): 036124 Part 2. Antonelli, C. (2000), Collective knowledge communication and innovation: the evidence of technological districts, Regional Studies, 34(6): 53547. Arthur, W.B. (1994), Increasing Returns and Path Dependence in the Economy, Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press. Aydalot, P. and Keeble, D. (eds) (1988), High Technology Industry and Innovative Environments: The European Experience, London and New York: Routledge. Barabasi, A.L. and Albert, R. (1999), Emergence of scaling in random networks, Science, 286(5439): 50912. Barrat, A., Barthelemy, M. and Vespignani, A. (2005), The eects of spatial constraints on the evolution of weighted complex networks, Journal of Statistical Mechanics, Art. No. P05003. Becker, M.C. (2004), Organizational routines. A review of the literature, Industrial and Corporate Change, 13(4): 64377. Boschma, R.A. (1997), New industries and windows of locational opportunity. A long-term analysis of Belgium, Erdkunde, 51: 1222. Boschma, R.A. (2004), Competitiveness of regions from an evolutionary perspective, Regional Studies, 38(9): 100114. Boschma, R.A. (2005), Rethinking regional innovation policy. The making and breaking of regional history, in G. Fuchs and P. Shapira (eds), Rethinking

20

Introduction

Regional Innovation and Change: Path Dependency or Regional Breakthrough?, Dordrecht: Springer, pp. 24971. Boschma, R.A. and Frenken, K. (2003), Evolutionary economics and industry location, Review of Regional Research, 23: 183200. Boschma, R.A. and Frenken, K. (2006), Why is economic geography not an evolutionary science? Towards an evolutionary economic geography, Journal of Economic Geography, 6(3): 273302. Boschma, R.A. and Lambooy, J.G. (1999), Evolutionary economics and economic geography, Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 9: 41129. Boschma, R.A. and Ter Wal, A.L.J. (2006), Knowledge networks and innovative performance in an industrial district. The case of a footwear district in the south of Italy, Industry and Innovation, forthcoming. Boschma, R.A. and Wenting, R. (2005), The spatial evolution of the British automobile industry, Papers in Evolutionary Economic Geography 05.04, http:// econ.geog.uu.nl. Bottazzi, G., Dosi, G., Fagiolo, G. and Secchi, A. (2004), Sectoral and geographical specicities in the spatial structure of economic activities, Laboratory of Economics and Management (LEM) Working Paper 200421, www.lem. sssup.it/. Brakman, S., Garretsen, H. and Marrewijk, C. van (2001), An Introduction to Geographical Economics, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Brenner, T. (2004), Local Industrial Clusters. Existence, Emergence and Evolution, London and New York: Routledge. Breschi, S. and Lissoni, F. (2001), Knowledge spillovers and local innovation systems: a critical survey, Industrial and Corporate Change, 10(4): 9751005. Breschi, S. and Lissoni, F. (2003), Mobility and social networks: localised knowledge spillovers revisited, Centre of Research on Innovation and Internationalization (CESPRI) Working Paper 142, www.cespri.unibocconi.it/. Burt, R.S. (1982), Toward a Structural Theory of Action: Network Models of Social Structure, Perception, and Action, New York: Academic Press. Canils, M. (2000), Knowledge Spillovers and Economic Growth. Regional Growth Dierentials across Europe, Cheltenham, UK and Northampton, MA, USA: Edward Elgar. Cantner, U. Dreler, K. and Krger, J.J. (2005), Knowledge compensation in the German automobile industry, Jenaer Schriften zur Wirtschaftswissenschaft, 11/ 2005. Cantwell, J.A. and Iammarino, S. (2003), Multinational Corporations and European Regional Systems of Innovation, London: Routledge. Carrington, P.J., Scott, J. and Wasserman, S. (eds) (2005), Models and Methods in Social Network Analysis, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Carroll, G.R. and Hannan, M.T. (2000), The Demography of Corporations and Industries, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Castells, M. (1996), The Rise of the Network Society, Oxford: Blackwell. Chang, H.-J. (2003), Kicking away the ladder: infant industry promotion in historical perspective, Oxford Development Studies, 31(1): 2132. Consoli, D. (2005), The dynamics of technological change in UK retail banking services. An evolutionary perspective, Research Policy, 34: 46180. Cooke, P., Uranga, M.G. and Extebarria, G. (1998), Regional innovation systems: an evolutionary perspective, Environment and Planning A, 30: 156384.

Introduction

21

Cooper, A.C. and Dunkelberg, W.C. (1987), Entrepreneurial research: old questions, new answers and methodological issues, American Journal of Small Business, 11: 1123. Cowan, R., Cowan, W. and Swann, G.M.P. (1997), A model of demand with interactions among consumers, International Journal of Industrial Organization, 15(6), 71132. De Jong, M.W. (1987), New Economic Activities and Regional Dynamics, Netherlands Geographical Studies no. 38, Amsterdam: Royal Netherlands Geographical Society. Dopfer, K. (ed.) (2005), Evolutionary Principles of Economics, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Dosi, G. (1997), Opportunities, incentives and the collective patterns of technological change, Economic Journal, 107(444): 153047. Dosi, G., Freeman, C., Nelson, R., Silverberg, G. and Soete, L. (eds) (1988), Technical Change and Economic Theory, London: Pinter. Essletzbichler, J. and Rigby, D.L. (2005), Competition, variety and the geography of technology evolution, Tijdschrift voor Economische en Sociale Geograe, 96(1): 4862. Foray, D. (1997), The dynamic implications of increasing returns: Technological change and path dependent ineciency, International Journal of Industrial Organization, 15(6): 73352. Freeman, C. and Perez, C. (1988), Structural crisis of adjustment, business cycles and investment behaviour, in Dosi et al. (eds), pp. 3866. Frenken, K., van Oort, F.G., Verburg, T. and Boschma, R.A. (2005), Variety and regional economic growth in the Netherlands, Papers in Evolutionary Economic Geography 05.02, http://econ.geog.uu.nl. Frenken, K., van Oort, F.G. and Verburg, T. (2006), Related variety, unrelated variety and regional economic growth, Regional Studies, forthcoming. Fujita, M., Krugman, P. and Venables, A.J. (1999), The Spatial Economy. Cities, Regions and International Trade, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Garnsey, E. and Longhi, C. (2004), Complex processes and innovative places: the evolution of high tech Cambridge and Sophia-Antipolis, International Journal of Technology Management, 28(36): 33655. Gertler, M.S. (1995), Being there: proximity, organization, and culture in the development and adoption of advanced manufacturing technologies, Economic Geography, 71: 126. Giuliani, E. (2005), The structure of cluster knowledge networks: uneven and selective, not pervasive and collective, Danish Research Unit for Industrial Dynamics (DRUID) Working Paper 2005-11, www.druid.dk. Grabher, G. (1993), The weakness of strong ties: the lock-in of regional development in the Ruhr area, in G. Grabher (ed.), The Embedded Firm: On the SocioEconomics of Interrm Relations, London and New York: Routledge, pp. 25578. Granovetter, M. (1973), The strength of weak ties, American Journal of Sociology, 78(6): 136080. Guimer, R. and Amaral, L.A.N. (2004), Modelling the world-wide airport network, European Physical Journal B, 38(2): 3815. Hagedoorn, J. (1993), Understanding the rationale of strategic technology, Strategic Management Journal, 14(5): 37185. Hall, P.G. and Markusen, A.R. (eds) (1985), Silicon Landscapes, Boston, MA: Allen & Unwin.

22

Introduction

Hannan, M.T., Carroll, G.R., Dundon, E.A. and Torres, J.C. (1995), Organizational evolution in a multinational context: entries of automobile manufacturers in Belgium, Britain, France, Germany, and Italy, American Sociological Review, 60(4): 50928. Hodgson, G.M. (1998), The approach of institutional economics, Journal of Economic Literature, 36(1): 16692. Hohenberg, P.M. and Lees, L.H. (1995), The Making of Urban Europe 10001994, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Hoover, E.M. and Vernon, R. (1959), Anatomy of a Metropolis: The Changing Distribution of People and Jobs in New York Metropolitan Region, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Jacobs, J. (1969), The Economy of Cities, New York: Vintage Books. Jae, A.B. and Trajtenberg, M. (1999), International knowledge ows: evidence from patent citations, Economics of Innovation and New Technology, 8: 10536. Jae, A.B., Trajtenberg, M. and Henderson, R. (1993), Geographic localization of knowledge spillovers as evidenced by patent citations, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108(3): 57798. Keeble D., Lawson, C., Moore, B. and Wilkinson, F. (1999), Collective learning processes, networking and institutional thickness in the Cambridge region, Regional Studies, 33(4): 31932. Klepper, S. (2001), The evolution of the U.S. automobile industry and Detroit as its capital, Paper presented at 9th Congress of the International Joseph A. Schumpeter Society, Gainesville, FL, March. Klepper, S. (2002), The capabilities of new rms and the evolution of the U.S. automobile industry, Industrial and Corporate Change, 11(4): 64566. Kogut, B. and Zander, U. (1993), Knowledge of the rm and the evolutionary theory of the multinational corporation, Journal of International Business Studies, 24: 62546. Krugman, P.R. (1991), Increasing returns and economic geography, Journal of Political Economy, 99(3): 48399. Lambooy, J.G. and Boschma, R.A. (2001), Evolutionary economics and regional policy, Annals of Regional Science, 35: 11331. Levinthal, D.A. (1998), The slow pace of rapid technological change: Gradualism and punctuation in technological change, Industrial and Corporate Change, 7: 21747. Maggioni, M.A. (2002), Clustering Dynamics and the Location of High-Tech-Firms, Springer: Heidelberg. Martin, R. (1999), The new geographical turn in economics: some critical reections, Cambridge Journal of Economics, 23(1): 6591. Martin, R. (2000), Institutional approaches in economic geography, in E. Sheppard and T.J. Barnes (eds), A Companion to Economic Geography, Oxford and Malden, MA: Blackwell, pp. 7794. Martin, R. and Sunley, P. (2006), Path dependence and regional economic evolution, Papers in Evolutionary Economic Geography 06.06, http://econ. geog. uu.nl. Maskell, P. (2001), The rm in economic geography, Economic Geography, 77(4): 32944. Maskell, P. and Malmberg, A. (1999), Localised learning and industrial competitiveness, Cambridge Journal of Economics, 23(2): 16786. Matsumoto, H. (2004), International urban systems and air passenger and cargo ows: some calculations, Journal of Air Transport Management, 10(4): 23947.

Introduction

23

Metcalfe, J.S. (1995), Technology systems and technology policy in an evolutionary framework, Cambridge Journal of Economics, 19: 2546. Moss, M.L. and Townsend, A.M. (2000), The Internet backbone and the American metropolis, The Information Society, 16: 3547. Murmann, J.P. (2003), Knowledge and Competitive Advantage: The Co-evolution of Firms, Technology, and National Institutions, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Nelson, R.R. (1995), Co-evolution of industry structure, technology and supporting institutions, and the making of comparative advantage, International Journal of the Economics of Business, 2(2): 17184. Nelson, R.R. (1999), The sources of industrial leadership: a perspective on industrial policy, De Economist, 147: 118. Nelson, R.R. and Winter, S.G. (1982), An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change, Cambridge, MA and London: Belknap Press. Overman, H.G. (2004), Can we learn anything from economic geography proper?, Journal of Economic Geography, 4: 50116. Pasinetti, L.L. (1981), Structural Change and Economic Growth, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Pasinetti, L.L. (1993), Structural Economic Dynamics, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Perez, C. and Soete, L. (1988), Catching up in technology: entry barriers and windows of opportunity, in Dosi et al. (eds), pp. 45877. Phelps, N.A. (2004), Clusters, dispersion and the spaces in between. For an economic geography of the banal, Urban Studies, 41(56): 97189. Plouraboue, F., Steyer, A. and Zimmerman, J.-B. (1998), Learning induced criticality in consumers adoption pattern: a neural network approach, Economics of Innovation and New Technology, 6: 7390. Porter, M.E. (2000), Location, competition, and economic development: local clusters in a global economy, Economic Development Quarterly, 14: 1534. Powell, W.W., Koput, K.W. and SmithDoerr, L. (1996), Interorganizational collaboration and the locus of innovation: networks of learning in biotechnology, Administrative Science Quarterly, 41(1): 11645. Pred, A. (1977), City-Systems in Advanced Economies, London: Hutchinson. Pumain, D. and Moriconi-Ebrard, F. (1997), City size distributions and metropolisation, Geojournal, 43(4): 30714. Rigby, D.L. and Essletzbichler, J. (1997), Evolution, process variety, and regional trajectories of technological change in US manufacturing, Economic Geography, 73(3): 26984. Saviotti, P.P. and Pyka, A. (2004), Economic development by the creation of new sectors, Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 14(1): 135. Saxenian, A. (1994), Regional Advantage, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Solomon, S., Gerard, W., de Arcangelis, L., Jan, N. and Stauer, D. (2000), Social percolation models, Physica A, 277: 23947. Solow, R.M. (1957), Technical change and the aggregate production function, Review of Economics and Statistics, 39: 31220. Stam, E. (2003), Why butteries dont leave: locational evolution of evolving enterprises, Dissertation, Utrecht University. Stam, E. (2006), A process model of locational change: implications for an evolutionary economic geography, in A. Pyka and H. Hanusch (eds), Applied

24

Introduction

Evolutionary Economics and the Knowledge-Based Economy, Cheltenham UK and Northampton, MA, USA: Edward Elgar, pp. 14365. Storper, M. (1997), The Regional World: Territorial Development in a Global Economy, London: Guilford Press. Stuart, T. and Sorenson, O. (2003), The geography of opportunity: spatial heterogeneity in founding rates and the performance of biotechnology rms, Research Policy, 32(2): 22953. Swann, P. and Prevezer, M. (1996), A comparison of the dynamics of industrial clustering in computing and biotechnology, Research Policy, 25: 113957. Taylor, P.J. (2001), Specication of the world city network, Geographical Analysis, 33: 18194. Teece, D., Pisano, G. and Shuen, A. (1997), Dynamic capabilities and strategic management, Strategic Management Journal, 18(7): 50933. Tinbergen, J. (1962), Shaping the World Economy: Suggestions for an International Economic Policy, New York: 20th Century Fund. Uzzi, B. (1996), The sources and consequences of embeddedness for the economic performance of organizations: the network eect, American Sociological Review, 61(4): 67498. Vernon, R. (1969), International investment and international trade in the product life-cycle, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 80: 190207. van Wissen, L. (2004), A spatial interpretation of the density dependence model in industrial demography, Small Business Economics, 22(34): 25364. Wasserman, S. and Faust, K. (1994), Social Network Analysis: Methods and Applications, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Watts, D.J. and Strogatz, S.H. (1998), Collective dynamics of small-world networks, Nature, 393: 44042. Werker, C. and Athreye, S. (2004), Marshalls disciples: knowledge and innovation driving regional economic development and growth, Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 14: 50523. Whitley, R. (1992), Business Systems in East Asia: Firms, Markets and Societies, London: Sage.

PART I

Entrepreneurship

2. The Cambridge high-tech cluster: an evolutionary perspective


Elizabeth Garnsey and Paul Heernan
1. INTRODUCTION

New knowledge-based rms emerge and grow around centres of learning and research. A process akin to ecological succession occurs as resources in the local science base are converted into and attract business activity, giving rise to a richer, more diverse economic habitat. To gain a better understanding of these developments we need to examine how processes of change operate over time. Cambridge provides an exemplar of endogenous formation of a high-tech cluster through spin-o, agglomeration and institutional adaptation. The importance of the strong science base at Cambridge is universally acknowledged, but the evolutionary micro processes through which its inuence was exerted require further elucidation. Positive externalities providing incentives to rms to cluster in an area are not necessarily present at the time of the emergence of a new cluster of activity. Explanations in terms of measurable externalities beg the question of the evolutionary processes which gave rise to them. In other high-tech centres (Simmie et al., 2004), spillover eects have resulted from government spending on infrastructure, from large company investments, from metropolitan structures and defence spending on information technology (IT). These inuences were absent in the case of Cambridge. After identifying the conceptual building blocks, we then examine indices of the growth of high-tech clusters in the Cambridge area. Underlying these aggregate trends are self-reinforcing mechanisms involving business spinouts and networks of knowledge diusion. Case studies illustrating these processes, in the clustering of scientic instrumentation, information and communication technology (ICT), technical design consultancies and biotechnology, further develop the thesis. Global linkages of Cambridge rms and the local process of institutional transformation in the region, resulting from collective action of local rms, reveal how global and local connections interact.

27

28

Entrepreneurship

2.

CLUSTERING AS AN ENDOGENOUS PROCESS

While traditional approaches in economic geography explained the location of industry in terms of exogenous factors such as demand or international trade eects, more recently endogenous factors have been identied as drivers of local clustering. In particular, spillover eects are said to shape location decisions where rms derive benet from local investments, the cost of which they do not themselves bear (Breschi and Lissoni, 2001). Value chain considerations shaping location decisions of rms are sometimes subsumed under spillover and sometimes treated as an alternative externality aecting location decisions. From an evolutionary perspective, the most striking feature of Cambridge as a high-tech centre is the way in which participants transformed the area, creating the very externalities that are assumed to be attributes of the area in leading accounts. Although local rms undoubtedly beneted from the university infrastructure, particularly ventures incubated within university departments, the concept of knowledge spillovers does not fully explain spin-out activity. University scientists can create their own rms to capture returns from their intellectual capital; they do not have to allow commercial rms to reap the gains from their intellectual capital, as is implied by the free-rider connotations of spillover (Zucker et al., 1998). Patents oer means of attracting capital through the prospects they oer for appropriating returns. However, the formal and informal relationships that these scientists develop with commercial organisations extend well beyond the market relations identied by Zucker et al. Through the operation of their networks, academic entrepreneurs have been among those creating a more favourable local business environment. The other endogenous determinant of clustering recognised in the literature, relates to local supply chain benets. This approach sees clusters as geographic concentrations of interconnected companies and their specialised suppliers, service providers and rms in related industries, together with associated institutions (Porter, 1990). Supply chain benets stem from co-locating with suppliers and customers, with a consequent lowering of transport and coordination costs, while co-location may also provide information about new input technologies and potential products (Krugman, 1991). Co-locating with customers provides information about their market needs, and may oer economies of scale to suppliers. But supply chain eects are not spillovers in that they do not oer free-rider gains (Zucker et al., 1998). Firms must invest time and eort in internalising supply chain externalities through deliberate measures in order to benet from labour availability, to reach price agreements, to establish partnerships or make procurement arrangements. Firms in competition

The Cambridge high-tech cluster

29

with each other will only co-locate if they can achieve such benets and overcome any disadvantages in having nearby competitors. Information on supply chain arrangements that work well is diused over time on a cumulative basis. The customers of Cambridge high-tech companies are international rather than local, and relatively few of them have local suppliers in their specialised production chain. However, they do benet from wider value chain externalities (Krugman, 1991). We shall see that high-tech rms in the Cambridge area currently make use of value chain complements or substitutes for the rms internal activities, in particular by outsourcing to local legal and business services. These have been attracted to the area by the presence of high-tech rms, illustrating the endogenous dimension of the transformation of the area. For knowledge-intensive rms, access to specialised labour is a key feature of local value chain advantages. However, it is not only the supply of new graduates that has become an asset of the locality, but a labour market of experienced specialised professionals, another outcome of cumulative processes. Explanations of local clustering in terms of positive externalities have largely adopted cross-sectional methodologies to identify the determinants of clustering (Breschi and Lissoni, 2001). This method is unable to explain why clusters emerged in some places and not in others before such time as these externalities became local attributes. In contrast, Arthur (1994) developed two evolutionary models to explain spatial clustering, showing how chance occurrences may lead to a set of cumulative factors favouring the growth of a specic location, a nding anticipated by Maruyamas work on positive feedback (Maruyama, 1963). The rst is a dynamic model in which rms sequentially choose locations on the basis of agglomeration economies, including skilled labour markets, specialised suppliers and knowledge spillovers. Arthur showed that local concentrations of rms in a given industry are neither fully determined by geography for example, local resource endowments, transport potential and rm requirements nor entirely a matter of historical chance, as assumed in competing theories of industrial location. Instead, both geographic attractiveness and accidental historical order of choice come into the equation, with various outcomes following from upper limits to agglomeration benets. A second model by Arthur (1994) is based on industry formation through spin-o (or spin-out1). Clustering can be explained by a sequential process in which the probability of a region producing spin-os at time t 1 is dependent on the relative number of rms that located at time t. By drawing randomly, at each time t, one rm that produces a spin-o, an evolving spatial distribution of rms in an industry is simulated. Typically,

30

Entrepreneurship

the resulting spatial distribution is highly skewed, because some regions will by chance have a relatively high number of spin-os early on and, subsequently, these will produce further spin-os. The outcome of the spino model is dependent on the assumption that spin-os locate in the same region as the parent company, since without this assumption one would obtain a random location model, but the assumption that spin-os locate near the parent is empirically robust (Cooper and Dunkelberg, 1987; Klepper, 2001). The departure of members of one rm to found another, on a friendly or hostile basis, was recognised in the 1970s by Cooper in the San Francisco Bay area where spin-outs from Shockley and Fairchild were celebrated (Cooper, 1971) as well as in a study of clustering of the US automobile industry in Detroit (Klepper, 2002). Arthurs approach is illuminating in exploring the interplay of chance and cumulative process manifest in path dependence (Boschma and Frenken, 2003). In particular it highlights the mechanisms of spin-os and of agglomeration economies which are likely to operate simultaneously. The contribution of these models lies in demonstrating the principle that even for regions equivalent in terms of institutions and endowments, the incidence of specialist clusters will be highly uneven because it occurs through chance events that set in motion a self-amplifying process in which success breeds success. Arthurs abstract models are designed to exclude a variety of other causal factors inuencing the emergence of local activity, among which are culture, institutions and endowments. In the following analysis, we observe that the endowment represented by Cambridge University provided critical conditions for the emergence of local industry through clustering. This endowment can be viewed either as systematic or as a chance initial condition, depending on whether the geography of the universitys location or the historical accident of its location is emphasised. Exogenous factors were also at work in the form of international demand for high-tech products and services to which Cambridge companies responded. But as Arthurs model predicts, endogenous spin-o and agglomeration economies have played the major role in the emergence of high-tech industry in Cambridge. In this chapter, clustering is related above all to the inter-generational spin-out process in Cambridge. The rms in question are connected locally by mobile people and knowledge to a greater extent than by supply relations, and operate in value chains that have global reach. We show that the cumulative, path-dependent nature of local value creation and appropriation processes is the source of their locational impact, to an extent ignored by the static methodologies of literature that neglect evolutionary processes.

The Cambridge high-tech cluster

31

3. THE EMERGENCE OF THE CAMBRIDGE HIGHTECH CLUSTER


Cambridgeshire is located northeast of London; the county extends 1300 square miles and had a population of about 700 000 at the turn of the millennium. Local rms are active in IT, advanced electronics and engineering, materials, instrumentation, biotechnology and research services, developing the emerging and early diusing technologies characteristic of high-tech sectors (Butchart, 1986). The development of high-tech industry in the Cambridge region has been rather exceptional, also labelled the Cambridge phenomenon (Garnsey and Cannon-Brookes, 1993; Heernan and Garnsey, 2002; Keeble, 1989; Keeble et al., 1999). From about 50 rms in the mid-1960s, by 1985 there were over 300 rms and 16 000 jobs in the Cambridge high-tech sector. A consultants report had identied extensive spin-out activity (Segal et al., 1985). By the end of the century there were more than 1200 technologyrelated rms (depending on denitions and area); these rms employed 36 000 people, approximately 10 per cent of the total Cambridgeshire workforce (Figure 2.12). By 2000, the combined turnover of technology-based enterprises was over 3.5 billion sterling (Heernan and Garnsey, 2002).3 The recession of the early 1990s reduced employment in the larger, older rms in electronics and instrumentation, but new rms and specialisations arose, restoring technology-employment totals. Manufacturing declined as
Firms 1400 1200 1000 800 600 400 200 0
19 92 19 96 20 00 19 60 19 64 19 68 19 72 19 7 19 8 19 8 19 8 20 04 6 0 4 8

Source: 196082 gures based on Garnsey and Cannon-Brookes (1993); 1984 and 1986 gures interpolated; data since 1988 derived from Cambridgeshire County Council Employment database, as described in Heernan and Garnsey (2002), extended to 2004 and excluding Peterborough. The data dier from those used by PACEC (2003), which examined high-tech activity over the Greater Cambridge Partnership area, a wider area than Cambridgeshire.

Figure 2.1

High-tech rms in Cambridgeshire, 19602004

32

Entrepreneurship

a proportion of high-tech activity as service activities increased, as in the UK economy at large. Figure 2.2 shows the changing distribution of rms and employment across a selection of high-tech sectors (Butchart, 1986). Software rms were the largest single group, reecting both extensive IT expertise and low barriers to entry. Instrumentation, and research and development (R&D) were also important sectors, the latter being the largest employer. Biotechnology-related rms accounted for 15 per cent of rms and 29 per cent of employment by 2004. Absolute numbers of Cambridge high-tech manufacturing rms were on the increase until the 2004 survey (in contrast with gures for the same sectors in the UK). High-tech employment in the area in and around Cambridge4 fell by about 5 per cent between 2002 and 2004, but the number of rms remained unchanged in the face of the technology slump and collapse in market valuations that followed the boom of the 1990s. The Cambridge phenomenon has grown mainly through the entry of new enterprises, most of these remaining small. The mean size of rms in 2004 was 33, less than that in 1988 (38), though median size increased slightly from 6.5 to 7. It must be noted, however, that a skewed rm-size distribution is universal and applies over time as well as nationally and regionally; only a small proportion of any cohort of rms grow to become major employers over time (Storey, 1994). It requires a large pool of start-ups to generate a few major companies. Firms of small size dominate in high-tech Cambridge to a lesser extent than is found across the UK as a whole as seen when relevant sectors are matched (Heernan and Garnsey, 2002). The continued expansion of high-tech activity depended, however, on the entry of new rms exceeding exit rates. Between 1989 and 2004 the mean number of new high-tech rms registered by the local authorities in Cambridge each year was 67, but about 47 rms closed or moved away (Figure 2.3) Local capability to sustain new rms is shown by survival rates. Figure 2.4 shows that survival rates for Cambridge technology-based rms were consistently higher than the regional and national averages, and compared well with survival rates reported in other studies (see Kircho, 1994; Slatter, 1992; Storey, 1994). This graph suggests that Cambridge rms had superior capabilities compared to the UK average.

4.

CASE STUDIES OF CAMBRIDGE CLUSTERS

Scientic Instrumentation The earliest Cambridge high-tech cluster was of scientic instrumentation rms, a response to the rise of the science departments of Cambridge

Number of firms
10 000 9 000 8 000 7 000 6 000 5 000 4 000 3 000 2 000 1 000 0
19 88 19 19 19 19 90 92 94 96 19 98 20 00 20 02 20 04

Employment
Telecommunications Electrical engineering IT hardware IT services IT software

350

300

250

200

150

100

33

50

Research and development Biotech Instrumentation

8 98

0 99

92 94 96 98 00 02 04 19 19 19 19 20 20 20

Source:

Calculated from County Council records.

Figure 2.2 Changing sectoral growth patterns among Cambridge high-tech rms

34 250 200 150 100 50 0 50 100 150

Entrepreneurship

New firms Lost firms Net effect

1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004


Source: Calculated from County Council records.

Figure 2.3

Firm turnover (turbulence) in the Cambridge high-tech sector

University in the nineteenth century. By the 1980s this cluster included Cambridge Instruments, UniCam and other Pye (Philips) sites employing several thousand in the area. Large numbers of managers and technicians in more recently founded rms gained experience in these companies. However, venerable rms such as Cambridge Scientic Instruments, founded by Charles Darwins son Horace, like many other UK manufacturing rms, proved unable to adapt to rapid technological change and international competition (Koepp, 2002). They were acquired and downsized in a series of retrenchments and new, much smaller rms were formed by former managers and technicians. By the late 1990s all the older instrumentation companies had been acquired and de-merged. The instrumentation sector now includes about 100 rms in the Cambridge region with very diverse products. Some newer ones have responded to international opportunities by addressing expanding markets for automating biotechnology research. The presence of biotech networks in the area has been a factor in the recognition of lab automation opportunities and in access to relevant competence in the life sciences. But overall, the capability of the area in instrumentation is less than could be expected from the concentration of science laboratories.5 There was a failure of established rms to maintain a leading role in the area such as Hewlett Packard achieved in

The Cambridge high-tech cluster


110% 100%

35

1989/90 cohort
% Firms remaining

90% 80% 70% 60% 50% 40% 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10


Years after start-up

1991/92 cohort 1993/94 cohort 1995/96 cohort 1997/98 cohort UK East 1995 UK 1995

Note: ONS rates are based on value-added tax (VAT) registrations and deregistrations which excludes some small rms. Source: National and regional data obtained from ofce of National Statistics (ONS).

Figure 2.4 Comparison of survival rates for cohorts of Cambridge high-tech rms (with regional and national averages) Silicon Valley (Saxenian, 1994) or to be renewed through governmentuniversity manufacturing modernisation initiatives such as were undertaken elsewhere in the US (Best and Forrant, 2000). ICT The information technology sector has shown the highest rates of new rm formation, reecting demand for IT products and services and low barriers to entry. There has been no ocial audit of companies founded by members of the University of Cambridge. Only rms in which the university took out equity are registered, a very small proportion of the total originating in the university. New evidence shows that over a hundred companies were founded by members of the university computer science department, about 80 per cent located in the UK and about 50 per cent in the Cambridge area.6 IT companies have also originated from other departments, above all the engineering department, which has been the source of a diverse set of new technologies and rms mainly located in the area (Figure 2.5). As with most populations of new rms, only a small proportion of departmental spin-outs have grown to above average size,

36

Entrepreneurship

Failed Vivamer 2002 Chem Eng Acquired Splashpower 2002 2000 Cool Analgesia 2001 Univ IP/ equity Alphamosaic 2001 1990 Still in existance Cirocco 2001 CCL1960 in 2002 Blue Technologies 2001 Chem Eng 1980 Cambridge Semiconductors 2000 1970 Delcam 1968 Jumpleads 2000 Shearline Precision Engineering 1973 TopExpress 1979 Acq Vulcan Machines 2000 Adder Technology 1984 Cambridge ChyGwyn 1999 Synoptics 1985 University Cambridge Flow HRM Software 1986 Engineering Solutions 1999 Department Qudos 1986 failed Acq CAM 3D 1999 CRISP 1999 Transversal 1998 Spark Ltd 1998 CMIL 1998 Sintefex Audio Lab 1997 Richard Marshall Ltd 1996 Cambustion 1987 JMEC 1989 Asymptote 1989 CEDAR Audio 1989 PCME 1991 Biorobotics 1992 Acq Granta Design 1993

Softsound Ionotec Entropic 1995 Acq 1995 Acq 1995

Figure 2.5 Companies with founders from Cambridge University engineering departments but several rms founded by former students have become leading companies in their sector, including, for example, Autonomy. Several hardware pioneers did not survive the maturation of the microcomputer industry. But Acorn Computers, founded in 1979, illustrates the inuence that an originating rm can have on its progeny. The founders of Acorn Computers, Hermann Hauser and Chris Curry, drew on expertise from the University Computer Lab to develop an innovative microcomputer, the production of which was subcontracted outside the area. Acorns explosive growth was stemmed by a sudden slump in consumer demand in 1984 and overcommitment to suppliers. The company only survived through acquisition by Olivetti. Acorns proprietary operating system came under competition from the new industry standard, MS-DOS. Under Olivettis ownership, Acorn attempted to pioneer the Network Computer in an international strategic partnership that fell through, the Network Computer being a product before its time. Acorn was wound up in 1999 so as to realise for Olivetti the value of its shares in ARM, and to create the new spin-out, Element-14. Acorn had funded the development of ARMs technology before spin-out and was its rst customer. Acorn Computers

The Cambridge high-tech cluster


Icora Semiconductor, 2003 Real VNC, 2002 Ubisense (Ubiquitous Systems), 2002 Level 5 Networks (Cambridge Internetworking), 2002 Cambridge Broadband, 2000 (Cambridge Network Ltd, 1998) Adaptive Broadband, 1998 E*Trade UK, 1998 Amadeus Capital Partners, 1997 NetChannel Ltd, 1996 NetProducts Ltd, 1996 IPV (Telemedia Systems), 1995 Electronic Share Information Ltd, 1993 Advanced Displays SynGenix, 1992 1985 ABC, 1988 IXI Ltd 1990 EO Inc. (with AT&T) Orbis 1978 Pogo Mobile Solutions, 2002 Commtag, 2000 Element 14, 1999 Xemplar Education, 1996 nCipher, 1996 STNC, 1993 ANT, 1993

37

ARM, 1990
GIS, 1985
Clearswift (Net Tel Computer Systems),1982

ACORN Founders Pre 1980

IQ Bio, 1981 Qudos Technology Ltd, 1985 Harlequin Ltd, 1986

ATM 1993, VIRATA

1995 Vocalis, 1992 2000 2005

Figure 2.6 New rms started by founders and employees of Acorn Computers was a learning organisation for the whole area, providing experience to many local entrepreneurs and managers. The range and depth of competence developed at Acorn made it possible for former members to start large numbers of local spin-outs (Figure 2.6). A further 20 rms were founded by employees leaving ARM to start a business.7 Technical Design Consultancies A cluster unique to Cambridge is made up of technical design consultancies working with leading international clients. These have become repositories of a wide range of competence, technical and managerial. They engage in prototype and small-scale production as well as advisory consultancy. The pioneer, Cambridge Consultants Ltd (CCL), founded by former members of the chemical engineering department in 1960, attempted to establish a manufacturing unit in their early days. Lack of competence in manufacturing led to a cash ow crisis and acquisition by A.D. Little. Thereafter the company specialised in technical services, a sector in which rms can minimise the sunk costs that often undermine UK ventures. Figure 2.7, below, shows the spin-outs from CCL. When employees wished to use CCLs intellectual property (IP) to develop a product, CCL helped

38

Entrepreneurship

them with seed capital, taking out equity in such ventures (Auton and Biddle, 2001). Former CCL employees later spun out other design consultancies, via another consultancy with a local oce. One of these, The Technology Partnership (TTP), has been the source of several further spinouts. TTPs sales were under 20 million in 2001, but with its combined spin-outs, sales were over 80 million.8 Industrial Ink Jet Printing Largely spinning out of CCL is a cluster of Cambridge rms that have achieved global expansion on the basis of a common set of technologies. Figure 2.7 depicts the genealogy of seven local industrial ink jet printing companies (Imaje is located in France and Willett in Corby). By around 2000 the ink jet printing rms employed over 3000 directly and their custom provided further jobs in PCB and precision engineering rms in the regions. They were dominant in international markets for non-impact product identication, a smaller market than the major market for small business and desktop ink jet printing. Their revenues were estimated at
2000 Inca Digital Printers 1990 1980 1970 Biodot Xennia

Xaar

Linx

Cambridge Consultants Limited

Domino Printing Sciences

Willett Imaje

Elmjet

Figure 2.7

Industrial inkjet printing spin-outs originating in Cambridge

The Cambridge high-tech cluster

39

500 million in 2000.9 The production chain is international; ink jet printing (IJP) rms source jewels from Switzerland, pumps from the US and precision components from many other sources, but they also share some local suppliers. The rms do not formally collaborate, or regularly supply each other, but interviewees report frequent informal interaction and linkages resulting from their common origins and the mobility of sta. IJP customer companies in the area have helped local PCB and precision engineering suppliers to upgrade their performance; these contractors were then able to help other customers in the area to upgrade their products and production process. Local IJP clients remain an important source of custom for local suppliers, but subassemblies came to be sourced internationally as the industry matured. The role of leading rms in production networks is conrmed by the experience of Domino Printing Sciences, which grew to over 1000 employees and had a particular impact on suppliers in eastern England such as Hansatech in Kings Lynn. The industrial IJP rms continue to provide a local labour market skilled in relevant competences. When ink jet technologies were adopted by new entrants developing advanced materials such as light emitting polymers (Cambridge Display Technology and Plastic Logic) they were able to hire professional sta with experience in the local IJP cluster, demonstrating the role of job mobility in the diusion of competence in the area. However, at technician and operator levels, IJP rms found it dicult to recruit skilled personnel at competitive rates, and it was partly for this reason that Videojet (the acquirer of Elmjet) moved out of the Cambridge area, while Xaars manufacturing function was relocated as a result of a merger. Biotechnology The biotech cluster clearly illustrates the interaction of endogenous and exogenous inuences. There are about 110 biotech companies in the Cambridge area, 40 or so indigenous spin-outs from university departments and local research institutes, the others being local start-ups or external entrants. Because biotech has extensive applications, these companies embody a wide range of competence in diverse life sciences, instrumentation, chemistry and computing. Twelve dierent university departments were the source of the biotech companies recognised by the university as spin-outs because they embody university IP and equity. The nautilus form of Figure 2.8 illustrates the increasing incidence of biotech spin-out activity over time. Among the 42 rms shown in Figure 2.8, there were 20 in biopharm therapeutics and three in biopharm diagnostics, all of these engaged in R&D activities. Only one rm, Cambridge Antibody Technologies, was

40

Entrepreneurship
40 41 38 39 42

37 36 35 34 33 32 31 30 29 28 27 26 25 24 23 22 21

2 1

4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11

1980 1985 1990 14 1995 20 19 18 2000 2005 17 16 15 13

12

Notes: 1. Celltech, 1980 2. Anity Chromatography, 1987 3. Cantab Pharmaceuticals, 1989 4. Cambridge Antibody Technology, 1990 5. Cambridge Sensors, 1991 6 BioRobotics, 1993 7. Microbial, 1994 8. Hexagen, 1996 9. Cambridge Combinatorial, 1996 10. Metris Therapeutics, 1996 11. Cambridge Biotransforms, 1997 12. RiboTargets, 1997 13. Biotica Technology, 1997 14. Cambridge Bioclinical, 1997

15. 16. 17. 18. 19. 20. 21. 22. 23.

24. 25. 26. 27. 28.

Cambridge Drug 29. Discovery, 1997 Kudos, 1997 30. AdproTech, 1997 31. Abcam, 1998 32. Sense Proteomic, 33. 1998 34. Paradigm 35. Therapeutics, 36. 1998 37. Solexa, 1998 Cambridge 38. Microbial 39. Technologies, 1999 40. Clinical & Biomedical 41. Computing, 42. 1999 De Novo Pharmaceuticals, 1999 Astex Technology, 1999 Diversys, 2000 Avidis, 2000 Cool Analgesia, 2001

Cambridge Biotechnology, 2001 Akubio, 2001 Purely Proteins, 2002 Genepta, 2002 Smart Holograms, 2002 Daniolabs, 2002 Blue Gnome, 2003 Vivamer, 2003 Diagnostics for the Real World, 2003 Ionscope, 2003 Ampika, 2003 Cambridge Lab on Chip, 2003 Protein Logic, 2003 Novexin, 2004

Source: Research Services, Cambridge University.

Figure 2.8 Biotech rms originating in 12 Cambridge University departments

The Cambridge high-tech cluster

41

in integrated drug discovery and production. The remaining spin-outs were supporting drug discovery through bioinformatics (10) and specialist services, devices and supplies (8). Ownership changes have been considerable, with over a quarter of the biotech spin-out ventures being acquired or merged. Local biopharm ventures together with attracted rms are suciently numerous to provide a local labour market in commercial life sciences. As the cluster has matured, the professional networks formed with companies elsewhere and around local career structures have become increasingly signicant.10 The strength of life sciences in the university and location of the Medical Research Council and other research institutes in the area ensured that as market applications for biotech emerged, Cambridge would be a leading centre. This was conrmed when a number of biotech incubators were established in the late 1990s and the Human Genome project was sited locally. Spin-outs were attracted from big pharmaceuticals and from other universities. Case histories reect complex alliances and recongurations. For example, Enzymatics, originally nanced by British Sugar, was closed when its funding was terminated, but its IP became the endowment of a local spin-out, Chiroscience, which later merged with Celltech, sold to a Belgian pharmaceutical company in 2004.

5. INTERNATIONALISATION AND INSTITUTIONAL ADAPTATION


The case studies all show that the emergence of high-tech clusters has been largely an endogenous process driven by spin-outs and emerging agglomeration advantages. Two accompanying processes that have further nurtured the clustering processes deserve further attention. First, the increasing international linkages of Cambridge rms and the transformation of institutions such that they have become more supportive for the further development of high-tech clusters. Internationalisation New rms in the area struggled to obtain investment, reecting the shortterm focus of capital markets and rates of return that are higher in other more cartelised, less innovative activity in the UK economy. The introduction of standardised credit rating by British banks did not favour innovative businesses. Until the late 1990s, venture capital in the area consisted in three funds investing in about ve ventures each among all Cambridge high-tech companies. Financial conditions improved when high returns on US tech-based

42

Entrepreneurship

investments changed the investment climate at the turn of the century. By the late 1990s, several hundred million pounds worth of venture capital was under management in the area through new venture capital funds seeking to invest in technology-based rms in Cambridge and beyond. Further seedcapital initiatives by the new government in favour of the commercialisation of science-based technology programmes were undertaken. A few highprole Cambridge rms realised the nancial advantage of their booming share prices. Cambridge companies survived the Internet boom and crash better than elsewhere because of the diversity of applications and markets. The attraction of international rms to the area has been a relatively new development (Garnsey and Longhi, 2004). But the ability of the area to attract inward investment had earlier been demonstrated by international acquisition of local enterprises. A 1993 study showed that the most promising Cambridge high-tech enterprises were prone to acquisition, reducing the pool of companies with prospects for independent growth (Shah and Garnsey, 1993). This pattern has continued with the acquisition of a range of promising young Cambridge companies by US corporations in particular. There is case-study evidence (for example, Acorn, CIS, Smallworld and BioRobotics) that acquisition reduces innovative potential by subjecting the acquired unit to corporate strategic priorities. A counter-eect is that inward investment through acquisition stimulates further spin-out activity in the area. Although high-tech rms in Cambridge are linked locally by common origins of their members and local expertise, their production networks are more international than local. Cambridge high-tech rms are highly export oriented; even the technical design consultancies report that the majority of their clients are international. Export performance was outstanding even before the high-tech boom. The need to establish relations with customers overseas from start-up stage makes considerable demands on young Cambridge companies; those engaged in micro-global eorts cannot take the easier route of building initial relationships with domestic customer and supplier companies which is open to many US start-ups. The need for new rms to build the foundations for growth from the outset through a structure of alliances was the lesson drawn by local rms from earlier experience in the area. New business models developed by Cambridge rms involve licensing and establishing close linkages with manufacturing partner rms globally. Alliance capabilities are needed to reach multiple markets and are facilitated by international networks developed by local entrepreneurs. Cambridge enterprises that include ARM and CDT have demonstrated that licensing can secure substantial returns provided that the technologies are well protected and have multiple market applications.

The Cambridge high-tech cluster

43

Institutional Adaptation The Cambridge University long operated as a community of scholars made up of colleges and departments rather than as a conventionally managed organisation; the central administration was minimal until after 2000 and did not have the means or inclination to manage technology transfer centrally. From 1986, British universities had rights to IP in work funded by the research councils. The Cambridge University was unusual in vesting this entitlement to inventors on its sta. In laissez-faire mode, no active support for technology transfer was provided in the early period. But the administration of the university did not prevent faculty members from developing commercial applications or starting new businesses so long as they carried out their teaching and research duties. In professional communities moral pressures can be brought to bear on individuals who fail to conform to norms and expectations. Cambridge academics are embedded in a network of obligations, collegial and departmental in a university with a strong research and teaching ethos. Entrepreneurial academics who undertook business activities over and above their academic duties and used the revenues to fund research students and departmental research were able to alter a climate of opinion that had earlier been hostile to business activity by academics. The transformation of Cambridge from intellectual retreat to high-tech centre took place initially as enterprising IT experts associated with the university detected and responded to growing economic demand for information technology. By the 1970s, expertise in science and technology developed at Cambridge University was diusing from research into business activity. By 1995, the Science Park housed over 70 rms and 3500 jobs. The Innovation Centre founded by St Johns College became the nodal centre of the Cambridge Phenomenon.11 Local and central government were unsupportive of business expansion in Cambridge. But the authorities were unable to stem the expansion in technology enterprise. After years of spontaneous expansion, Cambridge high-tech companies faced problems they could not solve on an individual basis. Inadequate public transport and shortages of housing and skilled technical labour had become signicant constraints on growth and had not been addressed by government. Informal linkages were rapidly mobilised to create a formal network to provide a voice for the high-tech community. Among the aims of the Cambridge Network was to improve access to US markets and funding for Cambridge high-tech rms, drawing on contacts forged by entrepreneurs who had strong US connections. Business networks in the Cambridge area extended their reach into the policy arena. Since 1997, Cambridge entrepreneurs have taken part in government policy

44

Entrepreneurship

making. Local government ocials and businesses formed the Greater Cambridge Partnership, recognising that a larger territory than the city and its villages was the appropriate unit for sustainable development. Whether Cambridge could or should be the hub of a new high-tech region remained controversial; strong anti-growth feeling and concern about the polarisation of the labour market coexisted with advocacy of economic potential. Working groups were set up to encourage related expansion in the region and beyond. Local recognition of the nance gap for rms developing emerging technologies and the extent to which US technology enterprise has beneted from much higher levels of government support, for example, through Defense Advanced Research Agency (DARPA) and Small Business Innovation Research and (SBIR) programmes, resulted in lobbying for a bill, sponsored by a Cambridge Member of Parliament, providing for more grant and procurement support on the US model to high-tech ventures in the UK.

6.

CONCLUSION

In summary, endogenous developments in Cambridge encompass the founding of companies by current and former members of the university, clustering stimulated by serial spin-outs from originator rms, the rise of local suppliers and, especially signicant, the emergence of specialist labour markets. These developments depended on demand for high-tech output and exerted attraction eects through business services drawn to the area, through the implantation of international subsidiaries, inward investment via acquisition and the attraction of venture capital funds. Together these processes, endogenous and exogenous, contributed to the development of local competence and capabilities resulting in the formation and success of many new rms. While the process of transformation has many features in common with ecological succession in the natural world, this new economic habitat developed its own identity and local consciousness at a higher-order level. The creation of a favourable selection environment was the unintended outcome of many local decisions, but over time a sense of purpose was created in the local high-tech community whose champions set out deliberately to attract resources to the area. The need for such action points to the limitations of spontaneous expansion unsupported by regional or technology policy. It is dicult to isolate the eects of knowledge networks around a strong science base in places where many other inuences have been at work. Co-determinants elsewhere include earlier industrial experience (Oxford), government spending on infrastructure (Sophia-Antipolis),

The Cambridge high-tech cluster

45

large company eects (Siemens in Munich, Eriksson in Stockholm), metropolitan inuences (London, Paris) and defence spending and procurement (Silicon Valley, Route 128). But in the Cambridge area there was minimal impact from exogenous investment inuences such as have contributed to local spillover eects for technology-based rms elsewhere. Thus Cambridge provides unique evidence of the economic potential of a knowledge-based centre as the engine of expansion of innovative industry.

NOTES
1. The term spin-out is sometimes used to convey the third mission of the universities, the transfer and exploitation of intellectual property (Research Services, University of Cambridge). In this usage the term university start-up company is used to refer to businesses founded by students and faculty and former or current members the university, but not making use of university intellectual property (IP) or lacking a university equity stake. We use the term spin-out in the inclusive sense long used in the research literature and ocial spin-out company for those started with university IP or equity. Total employment 351 170, based on the 1997 Employment census, adjusted by the Cambridge County Council Research Group. The number of rms and levels of employment reported here are derived from an adjusted dataset, rened from that used by the County Council which employs a less restrictive denition of high-tech and counts operating units rather than rms. Alternative denitions of high-tech activity are used by PACEC (2003), based on the wider Greater Cambridge Partnership area, and by the Cambridge investment consultancy, Library House, for their commercial database. For continuity and comparability we used SIC categories rather than non-standardised categories devised for high-tech activities. The methodology for this calculation is described in Heernan and Garnsey (2002). Dened here as South Cambridgeshire and the City of Cambridge. The data presented in Figures 2.3 and 2.4 were derived from the Cambridgeshire County Council Employment database, as described in Heernan and Garnsey (2002). For the purposes of this chapter, the data have been extended to 2004, but the area covered has been restricted to the City of Cambridge and the adjacent South Cambridgeshire area, which have a concentration of rms originating in the university. For example, while manual DNA sequencing originated in Cambridge, automated gene sequencing equipment essential to the Human Genome project was developed by Advanced Biosystems in California. Cambridge Ring Newsletter. University of Cambridge Computer Science Department, 2004. Robin Saxby, Chairman of ARM, Diebold Conference, LSE, 28 April 2004. TTP records kindly made available by the company. Calculations by Alan Barrell, former CEO of Domino Printing Sciences and Willetts. Caspar and Karamanoz (2003) argue that non-university ties are more important than university ties to the Cambridge biotech cluster from a study of recent spin-outs, but do not examine changes over time in the cluster and its origins. By 1969 Cambridge was already a centre of applied science; 25 per cent of the research and technical sta of the university were involved in applied research supported by outside funding (Garnsey and Cannon-Brookes, 1993). Cambridge University scientists took part in international networks, as a result of which they were the rst to recognise the benets to academic science departments of having companies sited locally to help commercialise scientic inventions, provide research collaboration and jobs for graduates. Social networks in the university and city encouraged innovation, with social interaction

2.

3. 4.

5. 6. 7. 8. 9. 10. 11.

46

Entrepreneurship
across professional groups through college and community connections. Individual managers of banks local branches became part of an emerging business community and were able to provide overdrafts on a discretionary basis. Individuals among college administrators championed the Science Park and Innovation Centre (Garnsey and Longhi, 2004).

REFERENCES
Arthur, W.B. (1994), Increasing Returns and Path Dependence in the Economy, Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press. Auton, P. and Biddle, H. (2001), Successful spin-outs, by design, Arthur D. Little Prism, Issue 1. Best, M.H. and Forrant, R. (2000), Regional industrial modernization programmes: two cases from Massachusetts, European Planning Studies, 8(2): 21123. Boschma, R.A. and Frenken, K. (2003), Evolutionary economics and industry location, Review of Regional Research, 23: 183200. Breschi, S. and Lissoni, F. (2001), Knowledge spillovers and local innovation systems: a critical survey, Industrial and Corporate Change, 10(4): 9751005. Butchart, R.L. (1987), A new UK denition of the high technology industries, Economic Trends, No. 400, February 1987, Crown Copyright. Caspar, S. and Karamanoz, A. (2003), Commercializing science in Europe: the Cambridge biotechnology cluster European Planning Studies, 11(7): 80521. Cooper, A. (1971), Spin-os and technical entrepreneurship, IEEE Transactions on Engineering Management, 18(1): 26. Cooper, A.C. and Dunkelberg, W.C. (1987), Entrepreneurial research: old questions, new answers and methodological issues, American Journal of Small Business, 11: 1123. Garnsey, E. and Cannon-Brooke, A. (1993), The Cambridge phenomenon revisited: aggregate change among Cambridge high technology rms since 1985, Entrepreneurship and Regional Development, 5: 179207. Garnsey, E. and Longhi, C. (2004), Complex processes and innovative places: the evolution of high tech Cambridge and Sophia-Antipolis, International Journal of Technology Management, 28(36): 33655. Heernan, P. and Garnsey, E. (2002), Technology and knowledge based business in the Cambridge Area: a review of the evidence, Centre for Technology Management Working Paper 2002/01, University of Cambridge. Keeble, D. (1989), High-technology industry and regional development in Britain: the case of the Cambridge phenomenon, Environment and Planning C, 7(2), 15372. Keeble, D., Lawson, C., Moore, B. and Wilkinson, F. (1999), Collective learning processes, networking and institutional thickness in the Cambridge region, Regional Studies, 33(4): 31932. Kircho, B.A. (1994), Entrepreneurship and Dynamic Capitalism: The Economics of Business Firm Formation and Growth, Westport, CT: Praeger. Klepper, S. (2001), Employee startups in high-tech industries, Industrial and Corporate Change, 10(3): 63974. Klepper, S. (2002), The evolution of the U.S. automobile industry and Detroit as its capital, Paper presented at 9th Congress of the International Joseph A. Schumpeter Society, Gainesville, FL, March. Koepp, R. (2002), Clusters of Creativity: Enduring Lessons on Innovation and Entrepreneurship from Silicon Valley and Europes Silicon Fen, Chichester: Wiley.

The Cambridge high-tech cluster

47

Krugman, P. (1991), Increasing returns and economic geography, Journal of Political Economy, 99(3): 48399. Maruyama, M. (1963), The second cybernetics: deviation-amplifying, mutual causal processes, American Scientist, 51: 16479. PACEC (2003), The Cambridge Phenomenon Fullling the Potential, Report for the Greater Cambridge Partnership, Public and Corporate Economic Consultants, Cambridge. Porter, M. (1990), The competitive advantage of nations, Harvard Business Review, MarchApril: 7393. Saxenian, A. (1994), Regional Advantage: Culture and Competition in Silicon Valley and Route 128, Cambridge, MA and London: Harvard University Press. Segal Quince Wicksteed Ltd. (1985), The Cambridge Phenomenon: The Growth of High Technology Industry in a University Town, 2nd edn, 1990, Cambridge, UK. Shah, S. and Garnsey, E. (1993), The acquisition of high tech rms: evidence from Cambridge, Judge Institute Research Papers in Management, University of Cambridge. Simmie, J., Siino, C., Zuliani, J., Jalabert, G. and Strambach, S. (2004), Local innovation system governance and performance: a comparative analysis of Oxfordshire, Stuttgart and Toulouse, International Journal of Technology Management, 28 (36): 53459. Slatter, S. (1992), Gambling on Growth, Chichester: Wiley. Storey, D. (1994), Understanding the Small Business Sector, London: Routledge. Zucker, L., Darby, M. and Brewer, M. (1998), Intellectual human capital and the birth of U.S. biotechnology enterprises, American Economic Review, 88(1): 290306.

3. Sophia-Antipolis as a reverse science park: from exogenous to endogenous development


Michel Qur
1. INTRODUCTION

The Sophia-Antipolis science park is often presented in the media as a European model of science park development. There are obvious reasons for that, especially because of the historical background of the experiment. The park started from scratch in the 1970s and reached an impressive stage of accumulation whereby more than 25 000 jobs are now in existence on site. We shall argue that the park constituted a unique experiment due to the fact it has to be considered as a reverse science park as the university and research institutions joined the park only at a later stage. A related feature of the park holds that for a long time its development has drawn on exogenous sources. Only recently have some developments become truly endogenous, rendering the success of the park more complicated to assess. Section 2 will discuss the historical patterns characterising the SophiaAntipolis project. From these background conditions, Section 3 explores a more specic issue, which is the capability of that project to transform itself into a real science park project, encouraging and beneting from local entrepreneurial initiatives. Section 4 deals with a general discussion about that transformation, with a specic insistence on governance issues and more in particular with a discussion about how innovation opportunities progressively emerge locally. Section 5 focuses on innovative behaviours arising from local interactive learning in information and communication technology (ICT) activities, in accordance with either the type of rms involved in these processes or internalexternal interactions. Section 5 also deals in more detail with the policy implications of that transition towards a science park functioning in ICT activities. Concluding remarks about the sustainability of the Sophia-Antipolis science park and local policy making will be provided in the nal section.

48

Sophia-Antipolis as a reverse science park

49

2. SOPHIA-ANTIPOLIS: MAIN HISTORICAL CHARACTERISTICS


The usual denition of a science park requires the existence of complementary resources in a similar location, namely academic resources including training and research capabilities, and high-tech start-ups that either result from or interact with the local research environment. These background conditions are usually complemented by any kind of governance structure favouring the connecting dimension among those components. What characterises Europe with regard to the governance and regulation of science parks is the wide variety of mechanisms and the diversity of governance structures aimed at ensuring the development of experiments (Gaard and Qur, 1996; Qur, 1998). The governance structures vary considerably among European countries, from university or even private structures in Anglo-Saxon types of regulation to public-owned oces as well as private/public specic organisations in countries such as France, Italy and/or Germany. The Sophia-Antipolis science park is an original example for discussing types of governance mechanisms appropriate to encouraging innovation and business opportunities from local learning and interactions among various economic actors. Partly this results from the genesis of the project, which is quite recent (35 years ago), and partly from the dierent developmental stages faced by the project. Figure 3.1 depicts the quantitative accumulation from the mid-1970s and it demonstrates the unique character of the project.
2000 1800 1600 1400
Legal entities

25 000

20 000
Employment

1200 1000 800 600 400 200 0


19 75 19 77 19 79 19 81 19 83 19 85 19 87 19 89 19 91 19 93 19 95 19 97 19 99

15 000

10 000

5000

Years Cumulative number of legal entities

Cumulative employment

Source: Sophia Antipolis Enterprise Management Sophia Antipolis Cte dAzur (SAEMSACA), Sophia-Antipolis.

Figure 3.1

Cumulative number of organisations and employment

50

Entrepreneurship

Initially, Sophia-Antipolis was planned to be a city of science, culture and wisdom. The genesis of the science park was a purely private initiative, instigated by Pierre Latte. Latte was a member of the board of the ENSMP (cole Nationale Suprieure des Mines de Paris), one of the socalled French Grandes coles, and what he had in mind was to establish a sort of community of scientists in the South of France beneting from the Sun Belt eect. He targeted one of the few landscapes still available locally, which was a forest near the village of Valbonne, seven kilometres north of the city of Antibes. The enterprise started in 1969 and the rst buildings were erected in 1972. However, the project collapsed nancially; the infrastructure costs were extremely high and the private organisation involved was unable to survive the mismatch between costs and benets within the rst years of implementation. The initial project could have come to a halt at this point, since no real accumulation process had taken place when the private initiative was withdrawn. However, this has not been the case due to a transformation process from a private to a public governance structure. The local public authorities (the Conseil Gnral des Alpes Maritimes: CGAM) have retained the project with the aim of complementing the local economy with other types of activity that were thought to be compatible with the dominant character of tourism. The local environment (the Cte dAzur) traditionally depends on tourism activities and it was a central concern for the public authorities to diversify without damaging that dominant economic infrastructure. High-tech activities were thought to be acceptable in the sense that their relative image and perception in the public would not endanger tourist ows. From 1977, the Sophia-Antipolis experiment shifted from a purely private to a public initiative in which the CGAM has played a critical role. The latter empowers the local Chamber of Commerce to manage the experiment. This change of governance goes hand in hand with a change in both the concept and the content of the project: from a City of Science, Culture and Wisdom to the concept of an International Industrial Park. Local public authorities favoured the location of research and development (R&D) units of international rms, that is, they aimed to attract external resources that would diversify the economy of the Cte dAzur. A deliberate choice not to accept the location of manufacturing activity was made and the selective character of attracting R&D units was due to the search for compatibility with tourism. From that time, a change in public support was also important. Not only did the public authorities take over from the initial private initiative in order to ensure the physical infrastructures, but they also developed an active advertising strategy in order to promote the location at the international level and in the United States in particular. As

Sophia-Antipolis as a reverse science park

51

a result, a change in the scale of the experiment occured and a progressive accumulation of external resources assured the sustainability of the project (Longhi and Qur, 1997; Qur, 1997). The shift in governance has ensured the quantitative success of the project. In that period, from 1977 to the end of the 1980s, the park exhibited a spectacular accumulation process of external activities (see Figure 3.1). This particular (second) stage of development can be characterised by the following structural patterns:

an inuential resilience from the private (individual) initiative, even if local authorities have moved away from the initial concept to a standard international industrial park; a spectacular process of accumulation of external resources, mainly R&D units from large international rms; a site attractiveness mainly due to public infrastructures and utilities used by tourism activities on the Cte dAzur (international airport, accommodation facilities, congress facilities and so on) a heterogeneous accumulation process, as far as sectoral patterns are concerned and, as a consequence, a very low level of local connections and interactive learning on site; and an important dependence of local units from exogenous (internationally wide) rm decision making.

These structural characteristics induced an obvious fragility in the sustainability of the experiment. However, this stage can also be thought of as a necessary step to ensure and secure a local mass eect and the emergence of local interactions among the components of the park. The almost random accumulation process resulted in the progressive specialisation into two major activity areas: ICTs and life sciences. ICTs include software, telecom and image engineering activities but also electric, electronic and micro-electronic activities, automation, and signal and system engineering. This gave rise to a number of R&D activities that are quite large and diversied, resulting in potential opportunities for interactions. Moreover, this potential has been enhanced by the location of public research institutes working in the same knowledge domains. Figure 3.2 shows the accumulation process in the ICT activities during the 1990s. It especially shows how ICT activities have faced a transition phase and escaped from a relative quantitative stagnation to increase again from the mid-1990s onwards. By 2000, ICTs accounted for about 75 per cent of high-tech local employment. They originated from either large domestic companies such as Air-France, Thals and Tlmcanique/Schneider or large foreign ones such

52
300 250
Legal entities

Entrepreneurship
12 000 10 000
Employment

200 150 100 50 0 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 Years Cumulative number of legal entities Cumulative employment 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000

8 000 6 000 4 000 2 000 0

Figure 3.2

Cumulative number of organisations and employment (ICT)

as Amadeus, Accenture and DEC/Compaq. Both types of rms located their R&D activity in the park, which complemented the accumulation of public research resources locally. If ENSMP was already among the rst actors locating in Sophia-Antipolis, research units from CNRS (Centre National de la Recherche Scientique: National Centre for Scientic Research), INRIA (Institut National de Recherche en Informatique et Automatique) and the University of Nice-Sophia-Antipolis nally formed a critical mass that favoured the existence of business opportunities through endogenous interactive learning. The situation in life science activities is dierent, because no similar mass eect has been reached. No such eclectic accumulation as in ICT activities has been obtained and there are no more than 50 local rms involved in those activities. During its development, the park beneted from R&D units from rms such as Dow Chemical, Dow Corning, Wellcome, Allergan, Rohm & Haas, Aventis and others. These units were acting essentially in activities such as ne chemistry, pharmaceuticals and dermatology. In that respect, business opportunities stemming from the diversity of capabilities that have been accumulated locally are not easy to develop. Most of these local units are internally oriented, as they often have an exclusive customer located at the international level. As such, they are not very interactive with other actors in the park, since they function mostly as an internal service provider. Some of the units are more research oriented, such as Cird/Galderma and Cordis/Zeneca, but their local relationships are still very limited. Thus, within-park opportunities through interactive learning are not well developed. Figure 3.3 reports the quantitative accumulation in those sectors and demonstrates the lack of a signicant mass eect in life sciences.

Sophia-Antipolis as a reverse science park


60 50 40 1500 30 1000 20 10 0 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 500 2500

53

2000
Employment

Legal entities

Cumulative number ofYears entities legal

Cumulative employment

Figure 3.3 Cumulative number of organisations and employment (life sciences) In sum, by the turn of the 1990s, the rst stage of the experiment had resulted in an obvious quantitative success as about 700 rms involving about 10 000 employees were located in that area which was, to reiterate, just a forest 20 years earlier. As such, this characteristic made the SophiaAntipolis park quite unique in Europe, as no similar pattern of R&D accumulation in such a short time period has been found elsewhere. A second stage of the experiment began at the turn of the 1990s. At that time, there was a cyclical crisis in ICT activities, which provoked an increased instability and volatility in local R&D units. This endangered the sustainability of the project, and from 1990 to 1995, no real improvement in employment accumulation was possible. The quantitative observation expressed a transition phase in the local accumulation regime. On the one hand, no serious candidate to locate in Sophia-Antipolis was available, probably due to increasing competitive pressure from other European countries (see Section 3); on the other, some of the R&D units that were at the source of the success left the park, under pressure from external (international) headquarters and their related decision making on how to organise R&D and business units in Europe. Curiously, this business-cycle crisis has beneted the park as it has induced a change in the accumulation regime, from an exogenously driven process to a more endogenous process of entrepreneurial initiatives. The local process of accumulation was again sensitive from 1995 but is now much more the result of an internally driven process than one of externally driven accumulation of resources. Since the mid-1980s, the Sophia-Antipolis park has become a European model of a science park. This is somewhat misleading. Sophia-Antipolis should be properly thought of as a reverse science park, as the local university was

54

Entrepreneurship

one of the last institutions to join the process of local development. The location of PhD training from the university system has occurred only since the mid-1980s, but has been extremely powerful in favouring the previous transition from an exogenous-towards an endogenous-driven process of growth. Beyond the university system, the progressive accumulation of research institutes, especially in ICT sectors, has also favoured the transition towards a more traditional type of science park development. From the mid-1990s, the major structural patterns characterising the economic working of the park can be characterised by:

a larger inuential role of the university of Nice-Sophia-Antipolis in that transition; a modest but steady improvement in the accumulation of academic and public research resources, beyond the local university; a substitution of large R&D units by more endogenous entrepreneurial initiatives (especially in ICT activities); and a more interactive process of localised learning allowing for exploring innovative business opportunities on a large scale from the local environment (the emergence of a local entrepreneurial climate and culture).

From this rough historical description of the Sophia-Antipolis park, one can provide some insights about the local process of growth as well as about the governance mechanisms that allow for such a successful experiment. The passage of time has progressively revealed two major sets of activities (ICT and life sciences). However, the Sophia-Antipolis experiment is exhibiting quite a large economic bio-diversity, which makes the experiment unique and distinctive. Furthermore, due to exogenous forces, the park could reach a critical mass in ICT activities, which appears to be a necessary condition for innovative opportunities to arise. However, such a mass eect cannot in itself be a sucient condition for endogenous development to be sustainable. It has to be complemented by further eorts, especially from local public authorities, including physical infrastructures, governance mechanisms and innovation policy eorts. This is the issue discussed in the next section.

3. THE GOVERNANCE OF A SCIENCE PARK: LESSONS FROM THE SOPHIA-ANTIPOLIS EXPERIMENT


The governance of the Sophia-Antipolis science park has become a central issue in order to guarantee the sustainability of the project in the future. To

Sophia-Antipolis as a reverse science park

55

understand the context of policy making, we rst need to understand the structural factors that have inuenced the evolution and governance of the park. Among these factors are the Cte dAzur Sun Belt eects, which are as various as the existence of an attractive international airport, local infrastructures facilities and the sunny climate. But these factors also encompass more dedicated eorts such as an active advertising policy developed by local policy makers when they decided to follow up the project. The main cyclical factor was the need from extra-European rms to locate some of their R&D facilities in Europe. Basically, the European market was perceived to be so complicated for legal and governmental reasons that rms needed to benet from some local R&D facilities, adjusting their product portfolios to the decentralised and complicated local legislations that characterised Europe at that time. As such, Sophia-Antipolis was a good candidate to adjust correspondingly with intra-European customers. In that respect, the quality of physical infrastructures on the Cte dAzur that was inherited from tourism activities has been a positive factor that has made that location competitive relative to other potential choices within Europe. Second, the mass eect in ICT activities has also been enhanced by academics and public research organisations. Due to the inuential role of Pierre Latte, some training and research activities have been located in that area from the starting phase. However, training and research infrastructure has not experienced a similar growth trend as private R&D units. Nevertheless, the infrastructure has progressively supported quite a signicant volume of employment currently involving about 2000 individuals and 5000 students on site. Part of this improvement is due to national decision making, which deliberately decided to locate some research units from the French CNRS or from other public research institutes including the aforementioned ENSMP, INRIA and ADEME (Agence de lEnvironnement et de Matrise de lEnergie). Part of this improvement is due to an increasing interest from the University of Nice-Sophia-Antipolis in the park from the mid-1980s onwards, when the university decided to locate PhD training related to ICT and life science activities in the park. Third, the mass eect resulting from an active international advertising strategy and the accumulation of academic resources has provoked a signicant change in the local growth regime. Both factors changed the driving force of local growth from an exogenous-driven process to a more endogenous one. The period of that transition regime corresponds to the early 1990s to the mid-1990s. At that time, a crisis occurred locally, primarily due to a cyclical downturn, leading to a decreasing attractiveness of the Sophia-Antipolis park for R&D units of large international rms and even to the departure of some of them from the park. The reason for the structural shock was on the one hand an inuential eect of the European

56

Entrepreneurship

Union (EU) integration process and, on the other, an improvement in knowledge about the EU market for local R&D units. In short, there was a lack of relative competitiveness with the Sophia-Antipolis park, as far as traditional comparative cost advantages were concerned. Furthermore, the crisis has also been the source of a transition in the local growth regime. Most of the individuals concerned with the intra-EU mobility process were not convinced and decided to stay on the French Cte dAzur for personal reasons. As such, they tried to engage in individual business by developing entrepreneurial initiatives locally. As a consequence, the transition enhanced local interactions and favoured the development of a local labour market for high-skilled capabilities. This improvement in the labour market for highly qualied personnel is to be thought of as a consequence of the success of the park in its capability to shift towards a more endogenous growth development, that is, to behave as a real science park. This evolution has also been favoured by the progressive accumulation of academics, public research personnel and PhD students on site. A stock of around 2000 individuals acting in academic and public research institutes added to a volume of 5000 students is part of the transition as it has been extremely useful in supporting the previous entrepreneurial initiatives. Some institutions have taken a particularly active role in the process; for example, INRIA has been especially active in launching entrepreneurial initiatives from internal research projects. Moreover, other institutions such as ETSI (European Telecom Standard Institute) have had a specic inuence in attracting European rms in telecom activities and in contributing in a local distinctive European capability in that sector. Both institutions have been particularly helpful in favouring the local sustainability of the transition towards a more endogenous process of accumulation. Fourth, the most spectacular dimension of the transition lies in the birth of a huge number of high-tech very small rms, the results of complicated combinations of individuals from R&D units, PhD students and public research fellows. These combinations emerge locally almost as a reactive strategy to either not leaving the Cte dAzur, or being unable to nd a suitable position in the public research system. However, new business opportunities from local interactive learning have been quantitatively spectacular. Moreover, it is not simply a business-cycle eect of the dotcom revolution that occurred around 2000; it is a real process of transformation of the park that leads us to question its ability to behave as a real science park and to discuss the transition towards an actual local innovation system. As a consequence, the governance of the project is at stake as the initial advertising policy that ensured its success has also been questioned. What kind of policy initiative is needed to ensure the success of the transformation process is now becoming a real issue.

Sophia-Antipolis as a reverse science park

57

Fifth, and as a consequence of the previous remark, the transition results in a new eect: a much higher volatility of local rms. As far as ICT activities are concerned, it is possible to identify a group of about 300 rms locally. However, when that group is traced back from the start of the 1990s, more than double that number of ICT rms have been located in the park. We can identify a population of 345 rms that disappeared from SophiaAntipolis within that period. This is a sign of structural weakness, especially because ICT rms are still very small in size and do not depend on a local market base. Thus, a local mismatch between R&D units from large international rms and small and very small high-tech rms is still a problem, as far as a discussion about the existence (or not) of a real local system of innovation is concerned. Therefore, it would be interesting to discuss further the ability of rms to participate in the transformation of the park, especially because the variety of strategies to deal with and accompany that transformation is high. The ability of the territory to behave as a science park where innovation can occur from interactive learning among the local components can be questioned from dierent viewpoints. In what follows, the implications of the change towards a more endogenous accumulation process will be considered in more detail.

4. SOPHIA-ANTIPOLIS AS A SCIENCE PARK: CRITICAL GOVERNANCE ISSUES


To obtain a deeper understanding of the park, it is useful to distinguish between three main categories of rms that are developing innovative behaviour locally: (i) R&D units of large international rms; (ii) small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs); and (iii) spin-os/starts-ups. These categories are quite dierent and, as such, call for dierent kinds of governance mechanisms as well as dierent kinds of public policy. R&D Units of Large International Firms From the mid-1970s, the park development has been based on the match between supply and demand. The supply was the availability of square metres and/or oces in an attractive area surrounding the Cte dAzur; the demand was the need of large international rms to adjust their product portfolio to specic requirements from European countries. As we have already indicated, the location of R&D units in Sophia-Antipolis has progressively been challenged by other European locations. At the turn of the 1990s, some R&D units located in Sophia-Antipolis considered alternative

58

Entrepreneurship

locations in Europe Ireland or Scotland for clear advantages in terms of high-qualied labour costs; southern Germany or northern Italy when they wanted to improve interactions with their main or representative European customers; Paris or London when their EU location was dealing more extensively with nancial and/or administrative matters. As a consequence, the relative advantages of Sophia-Antipolis progressively diminished and those R&D units either relocated elsewhere in Europe or downsized their local units in terms of employment. Note, however, that these rms had little involvement in local learning with other actors in the park, be it other rms or public research institutions. R&D units were mainly dedicated to intra-rm activity and used as an exclusive provider of internal services for other units of the company. As such, their embeddedness in the local economic environment was weak. Moreover, subcontracting activities were mostly non-local, too. Thus, these R&D units were fully dependent on external decision making that was also internationally driven and unaected by local policy making. Therefore, even though these R&D units of international rms ensured the quantitative success of the Sophia-Antipolis park, they were not fundamental to local interactive learning. Nevertheless, two caveats apply. First, the external threat to relocate stemming from internal rm hierarchy had a positive eect on local interactions. Proving the existence of complementary resources locally was perceived as the best means of avoiding a departure from the park. Therefore, those R&D units developed localised interactions and learning as a sort of reactive strategy in order to enhance the local attractiveness and to avoid moving from Sophia-Antipolis. Second, a signicant number of individuals concerned with the relocation process decided not to leave the South of France but to engage in new local independent businesses. They refused the related mobility to other parts of Europe and developed entrepreneurial initiatives locally. Moreover, some of the local R&D units (such as Lucent on site, but also Alcatel, IBM and Texas Instruments in the immediate vicinity) encouraged the transition themselves and favoured the establishment of intra-entrepreneurial support (such as in-house incubators). The transition to a more endogenous type of development is thus partly the result of a reactive strategy of R&D units of large rms that were not fully convinced about the wisdom of leaving the site. Yet, this reactive strategy was not pervasive enough to prevent some rms from relocating their R&D units. Small and Medium-sized Enterprises A main weakness of the Sophia-Antipolis park lies in the lack of technological SMEs. There are very few of them, as the Cte dAzur has never

Sophia-Antipolis as a reverse science park


180 160 140
Legal entities

59

120 100 80 60 40 20 0 0 to 10 11 to 50 51 to 100 101 to 300 Employment 301 to 500 501 and more

Figure 3.4

Size distribution of ICT rms

been an industrial area. Most of the rms that are emerging locally do not reach the critical size seen as necessary for real SMEs. Figure 3.4 illustrates this argument by considering the size patterns of the mass eect reached in ICTs. Most of the ICT rms located in Sophia-Antipolis have fewer than 50 employees. Obviously, this characteristic makes these SMEs quite vulnerable locally. There are basically no local markets as the area does not benet from an industrial infrastructure. As a consequence, the SMEs have diculty developing and growing locally. They essentially depend on a very small number of customers and that factor makes their development unlikely to be locally sustainable in the long term. As a consequence, improving their growth sustainability means either that they expand in geographical terms and have to develop towards a market base that is no longer local (mainly Bordeaux, Toulouse, Montpellier and Marseille), or that they merge or make contractual agreements with larger rms that can be perceived as a guarantee to secure their development (especially in nancial terms and in related rm investment). Local Spin-os and Start-ups From the discussion about the two previous rm types, it is obvious that many rms created locally are partly the result of the crisis when R&D units from large rms decided to create local spin-os. The latter are the source for the existence of technological SMEs that exploit market niches from their Sophia-Antipolis location in diverse activities such as technological expertise and computer services (system design, software, network engineering and so on). A strategic positioning of these SMEs is part of the dotcom revolution. They are not fully part of the impressive economic development of e-business applications, but they provide the technological

60

Entrepreneurship

logistics to develop innovation in those activities. As such, these SMEs are more technology oriented and appear critical to ensure the technological improvement and related logistics to the so-called dotcom revolution. Therefore, these rms have not suered so much from the recent dotcom crisis and have succeeded in surviving and even improving their technological expertise and capabilities despite the cyclical downturn. The existence of these SMEs has also been favoured by a general improvement in scienceindustry relationships within the French context. In a country where the academic environment has been extremely isolated from industry, a real change has occurred during the last decades. Each university and public research institute is now trying to engage and develop connections with rms. This national transformation has obviously beneted the entrepreneurial climate in Sophia-Antipolis. The academic and public research systems have become more receptive to the idea of engaging with private actors and developing professional relationships with the latter (contractual terms, patents and licence agreements, and so on). The improvement in the professional character of negotiations related to the whole range of scienceindustry relationships has mutually beneted local interactive learning and the development of business initiatives stemming from complementarities between private and public expertise, essentially, in the eld of ICT activities (Qur and Ravix, 1997). Another general trend is the development of intermediation through venture capital initiatives and the availability of a diversied intermediation supply. This concerns not only venture capital as traditionally dened, but also other intermediaries. The latter can be purely private (such as business angels), purely public (such as academic incubators established by the Law on Innovation from 1999), or semi-public. These changes have triggered many more interactive relations within the park and, more generally, the emergence of a local entrepreneurial climate and endogenous business opportunities.

5. THE GOVERNANCE OF THE TRANSFORMATION TOWARDS A SCIENCE PARK MODEL: POLICY IMPLICATIONS
In order to behave as a real science park, the Sophia-Antipolis experiment has to encourage a transformation from exogenous to endogenous development. The necessary condition for such a transformation is the existence of a signicant critical mass eect. It is obvious that the latter has been reached only in ICT activities. This is why the following discussion is centred on ICT and the way interactions occur and take place in a business environment, which is obviously larger than the frontiers of the

Sophia-Antipolis as a reverse science park


Local interactions

61

Hardware activities

Operators

Equipment providers Applications development

Software activities

Global interactions

Figure 3.5

The geography of ICT activities

Sophia-Antipolis park itself. Figure 3.5 makes the point in a more synthetic manner. It oers a more comprehensive framework on how innovative behaviours through local interactive learning take place in a larger marketplace. The gure represents the distribution of ICT activities in a type and space framework. Of course, this is just a rough approximation of a stylised fact representation of those ICT activities. But it helps the discussion as the matrix between the type of activity and the importance of local versus non-local relationships provides a synthetic view about the dominant characteristics of innovative rms behaviours through interactive learning in the Sophia-Antipolis environment. Most of the telecom providers (operators) located in the park are not extremely active locally. Even France Telecom, which could be thought of as having a localised advantage, cannot be considered as a central actor in local innovative behaviours. These rms are essentially interested in absorbing positive benets from local capabilities but in a unilateral way. The main concern of this category of rms is external, that is, non-local, and the park is an exploratory potential that can be helpful in order to reect on the future of markets and services as well as to benet from attractive human resources. However, their active participation in localised innovation processes is weak. They benet from an image eect and they can also oer higher earnings to specic human resources that are revealed as useful to them from the working of the park. But this is a sort of predating strategy (both conscious and unconscious) that does not fully benet the overall entrepreneurial climate.

62

Entrepreneurship

Telecom equipment providers, however, have a pivotal role in the economic working of the park. On the one hand, they are participating in an industrial context which implies that they will be identied and act as global players. On the other, they are apparently more active in terms of local interactive learning than operators. In that respect, telecom equipment providers consider Sophia-Antipolis to be a technological platform where they can test technological opportunities thanks to local technological start-ups. Moreover, the location of specic institutes like ETSI and public research institutions is essential to them in order to secure innovative investment. In that respect, local collaborations are a means of exploring and dening new market opportunities. The latter include networking and connectivity interfaces, technical compatibility between dierent equipment and standards and so on. Such an experimental process is basically the result of the local accumulation of external resources that creates a diversied productive environment where diverse and various capabilities are possibly complementing each other. Some equipment suppliers have even developed in-house incubators in order to benet from that variety of capabilities existing in the park. This gives to the park, at least for specic types of activities, a status of European experimental project enhancing the reputation of Sophia-Antipolis as one of the leading locations in Europe as far as particular telecom activities are concerned. Application and service providers represent the category of rms for which interactive learning is the most developed and possibly most benecial. It is possible to distinguish two types of rms. First, SMEs that succeeded in taking an active part in the e-economy, that is, those that beneted from the dotcom revolution and, as such, enhance the SophiaAntipolis image eect. However, success stories have been relatively few and probably did not contribute signicantly to the local economy. In fact, many of these rms disappeared from the local environment when acquired by large external rms. As such, local entrepreneurship then benets the rest of the world economy instead of beneting the local economy. This is largely the case for rms such as Respublica, Lybertysurf, Echointeractive or Odisei. High-tech SMEs can also be obliged to connect more densely with their main customers and suppliers, which leads local entrepreneurial initiatives to relocate in other locations in order to secure their market and application bases. The second category of rms is science and technology-based SMEs that develop technological support and services on the application side of the so-called new economy. Here, the interesting aspect is that these rms are the result of local interactive learning among dierent components, including public research institutes, PhD student projects, spin-os and so on. They are the most important result of the transition phase in the

Sophia-Antipolis as a reverse science park

63

accumulation process from an exogenous towards an endogenous type of development. A byproduct of these ventures is the higher local sustainability as they develop distinctive capabilities that would not be possible to reproduce easily from another location. Thus, the localised character of their innovativeness is the best guarantee for the sustainability of the Sophia-Antipolis park. Any departure from Sophia-Antipolis should result in high transition costs and in a risk for rms interested in beneting from SME expertise. As a consequence, the second category of rms is the one that best expresses the transformation of Sophia-Antipolis towards an actual science park. Finally, it is important to stress that the number of such rms (about 20) is relatively small in compared with the whole set of resources acting locally in ICT activities. On the whole, the gap between the success in the media of SophiaAntipolis as a science park and the actual eect of innovation based on interactive learning and resulting in new high-tech start-ups is quite important. It stressed that Sophia-Antipolis can be considered as a real science park but only for a subset of ICT activities for which all the necessary components for a science park have reached a sucient mass eect to favour such endogenous initiatives. This observation brings us back to the park governance issue and to discuss in more detail what kind of policy making is appropriate to encourage and accelerate the transformation of the science park. What is particularly clear from the development of the park is that policy making has almost exclusively been concerned with the provision of physical infrastructures. This is of course a peculiar characteristic due to the historical background of the project (which started from scratch in the 1970s). The proactive character of policy making has basically been to advertise the project properly at the international level. However, such a policy has quite exclusively been based on promoting the local physical infrastructures. As a consequence, there is no real policy that has been concerned with the internal understanding of localised and interactive learning within the dierent components of the science park. Endogenous development has mainly been thought of as a natural process that should derive automatically from the accumulation mass eect. Obviously, it is not and the previous transformation depicted from ICT activities questions seriously the ability of policy making to encourage the economic sustainability of that experiment. Moreover, ensuring the accumulation of resources stemming from endogenous development is a dicult issue. On the one hand, it still has to face the intrinsic unstable character of international players (telecom operators and some equipment providers as well) for which external decision making is still the dominant regulation for their location in Sophia-Antipolis. As such,

64

Entrepreneurship

these rms have a low level of sensitivity to any kind of local public decision making. On the other hand, endogenous SMEs are dicult to secure in the park as the economic climate is traditionally not a marketplace for these high-tech rms. With tourism still dominating the local economy, policy is still relatively unconcerned with high-tech activities. With regard to local policy making, three main issues can be addressed in relation to the sustainability of the economic transformation of SophiaAntipolis and its transition towards a real science park. First, the role of physical infrastructures is not to be denied. If the park is now a leading place in Europe for some ICT activities, it is basically to be found in the choice of local policy makers to invest in a high-broadband telecom network based on a breoptic technology within the park by the 1980s. This choice has had a considerable impact on the site attractiveness from that time and has been crucial for ICT rms located in Europe to test for high volumes of information exchange and the related development of new applications. In other words, the quality of local infrastructures is still a necessary, if not a sucient, condition for the economic sustainability of the park. However, what type of infrastructures are appropriate for the future of the park is probably something that should currently be elaborated within the framework of the park and in deeper connection with private actors. This is apparently not the case as the connections between private and public decision making are weak. The connectivity between private and public decision making within the framework of the park to dene the physical infrastructures appropriate to its future development is a challenging issue for the sustainability of the park. Second, within the last decade, dierent forms of collective coordination among local private and public actors have emerged. Specic associations and thematic clubs have developed, most of them in a spontaneous way in order to favour local coordination and collective innovative projects on a local base. Some of them are in fact the result of a reactive strategy to deal with the risk of departure from the park. It was a means of bargaining more eectively with external decision making to justify the need to stay on site. This mechanism has been complemented by another trend, which is the emergence of a local market for some local SMEs within the park. Technology and business consulting rms, intellectual property rights and nance-oriented rms are parts of a logistical infrastructure to high-tech SMEs. Such consulting infrastructure is progressively transforming the Sophia-Antipolis park into a real marketplace. Both eects are part of a transformation process from an exogenous to an endogenous mode of development. However, both mechanisms are also disconnected from public policy concern. There is, however, a need for a more eective way to deal with the interplay between private and public characteristics of that

Sophia-Antipolis as a reverse science park

65

transformation. Policy makers can no longer consider interactive innovative learning as the result of a spontaneous order. They have to think about proper investment favouring the coordination of all the actors that are part of that shift towards a more endogenous type of development. Third, for a long time the Sophia-Antipolis park was perceived as an isolated island in the Cte dAzur environment. This is less and less true as the connectivity of rms located in the park to the environment is increasing. The improvement of localised innovative learning in ICT activities also implies complementing R&D with non-R&D activities (prototyping, designing and testing applications and so on). The latter require other capabilities and relationships with various sorts of markets. As far as local capabilities are available, this process can be expanded locally through all sorts of connections to other rms in the surrounding environment. To mention one example, one challenge is to connect the dominant local economic activity (tourism) to the park in a more developed perspective. Tourism is an interesting application area where ICT activities can be applied in various ways to improve innovation in that sector. The distinctive capabilities accumulated in the park in areas such as wireless and Global System for Mobile Communications (GSM) technologies can certainly be combined in original ways for tourism applications. However, this again requires from policy making a forecasting ability to deal properly with such challenges. Altogether, the critical issues show the diculty of developing policies supporting the transition of the science park from an exogenously driven to an endogenously evolving economy. To most local policy makers, however, the dominant perception is still that the endogenous character of local development should be a natural result of the accumulation process. However, this is obviously not the case as endogenous development can be hampered by local constraints and global trends (Garnsey and Heernan, this volume).

6.

CONCLUDING REMARKS

The Sophia-Antipolis experiment is unique. The main factor explaining the success of the project lies in the general advantages exhibited by the French Riviera that were well suited to large multinational companies for locating in Sophia-Antipolis either European administrative centres or R&D units. At that rst stage of its development, Sophia-Antipolis was exogenously driven and the experiment exhibited a signicant comparative advantage regarding other potential locations in Europe. However, the economic working of Sophia-Antipolis was vulnerable, because innovative activities

66

Entrepreneurship

were not based on local relations. Nevertheless, the park has beneted from a large accumulation of external (international) resources that has been a necessary condition to ensure its quantitative success and to create the required conditions to shift to real science park dynamics. The latter occurred 20 years after the starting phase of the experiment and the situation seems to be improving in recent years. However, the transformation is still modest in quantitative terms in comparison with the overall accumulated activities in the location and does not really benet from an active and appropriate support from local policy making. The transition, essentially limited to ICT activities, is to be thought of as a sort of spontaneous change, mostly due to incentives from individuals not to leave the enjoyable Cte dAzur environment, which is essentially the result of behaviours from private actors. As a consequence, the transition is still very fragile and should be central for policy making (Qur, 1999). The latter should concentrate on understanding the transition and dening more precise intervention to encourage its sustainability. This is still thought to be necessary in order to make the park viable in the medium term.

REFERENCES
Gaard, J.L. and Qur, M. (1996), The diversity of European regions and the conditions for a sustainable economic growth, in X. Vence Deza and J.S. Metcalfe (eds), Wealth from Diversity, Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic. Longhi, C. and Qur, M. (1997), The Sophia-Antipolis project or the uncertain creation of an innovative milieu, in R. Ratti, A. Bramanti and R. Gordon (eds), The Dynamics of Innovative Regions, Aldershot: Ashgate, pp. 21936. Qur, M. (1997), Sophia-Antipolis as a local system of innovation, Economia & Lavoro, 34: 25972. Qur, M. (1998) (ed.), Les Technopoles en Europe, Enjeux et Atouts de la Diversit, Paris: AFT/DATAR. Qur, M. (1999), Innovation, growth, and co-ordination through institutions: a discussion about innovation systems , in O. Fabel, F. Farina and L.F. Punzo (eds), European Economies in Transition, London: Macmillan, pp. 13147. Qur, M. and Ravix, J.L. (1997), Production de connaissance et institutions innovatrices: le chercheur-entrepreneur, Revue dconomie Industrielle, 79: 21332

PART II

Industrial Dynamics

4. The evolution of geographic structure in new industries


Steven Klepper*
1. INTRODUCTION

In recent years there has been a resurgence of interest among economists in questions related to geography. In part spurred by the clustering of economic activity in Silicon Valley, attention has focused on why certain industries agglomerate narrowly in one or a few regions. Ellison and Glaeser (1997) developed an index to measure geographic clustering in industries. It calibrates the extent to which clustering in an industry exceeds what would be expected merely on the basis of the chance location of a limited number of plants of unequal size. Their ndings suggest that some degree of agglomeration is the norm, but the kind of extreme clustering present in Silicon Valley is the exception. While clustering in some industries can be explained by the uneven geographic distribution of a key input, instances of clustering like in Silicon Valley seem to reect a deeper process at work. Exactly what that process is and why its eects vary across industries has been the object of much theorizing in recent years. Testing of the new theories of geography, though, has lagged behind. The object of this chapter is to review recent evidence and theorizing on the evolution of a select group of new industries to probe the determinants of the geographic structure of industries. Modern theories of geography feature the inuence of agglomeration economies on the location of producers. Such economies can derive from the sharing of inputs whose production involves increasing returns, labor market pooling that facilitates a better match between the needs of rms and the skills of workers, and spillovers of knowledge that are mediated by distance (see Marshall, 1920). Other mechanisms, such as rms locating closer to demanders to economize on transportation costs, can also induce agglomeration (Krugman, 1991). All of these benets impart a selfreinforcing character to agglomerations. The more rms in an area then the greater agglomeration benets, and the greater such benets then the more rms will be drawn to an area and the better rms in the area will perform.
69

70

Industrial dynamics

Congestion costs, in the form of higher land prices and compensating wage dierentials, ultimately limit the extent of agglomerations. Until that limit is reached, though, all rms located in agglomerated areas benet from the externalities resulting from their collective presence. If agglomeration economies are inuential, it might be expected that industries would agglomerate around regions where successful early entrants located. Such regions would initially produce more output, employ more labor, and be subject to more innovation, all of which would contribute to agglomeration economies that would attract subsequent entrants and enhance the performance of rms located there. There has been little empirical investigation of the evolution of the geographic structure of new industries, but Klepper (2003) argues that this is not the way either the automobile or television receiver industries evolved. Both industries were initially characterized by a large number of producers and then experienced sharp shakeouts and evolved to be tight oligopolies. The automobile industry became famously agglomerated around Detroit, MI even though production in the Detroit area was initially negligible and early entry provided a decided competitive advantage (Klepper, 2001). Television producers were initially heavily concentrated in just three cities: New York, Chicago and Los Angeles. Even though early entry was also advantageous in TVs (Klepper, 2002a), over time New York and Los Angeles lost all their producers and Chicago did not grow, causing the industry to become more dispersed over time. Klepper (2003) advanced a hypothesis based on the ideas of organizational birth and heredity to explain the evolution of the geographic structure of both industries. Subsequently Buenstorf and Klepper (2005a, 2005b) explored the evolution of the geographic structure of the pneumatic tire industry, which was also famously agglomerated around a single city, Akron, Ohio. Similar to autos and television receivers, initially many rms produced tires and then the industry experienced a sharp shakeout and evolved to be a tight oligopoly. Unlike automobiles, the industry was concentrated around Akron from its outset, and over time the agglomeration of the industry there grew. Buenstorf and Klepper (2005a, 2005b) investigated the extent to which agglomeration economies inuenced the location and performance of tire rms. They concluded that it was not primarily agglomeration economies but similar forces to those operating in the automobile industry that caused the industry to become so heavily agglomerated. We review the evolution of the market and geographic structure of the automobile, television receiver and tire industries in order to gain insights into the primary forces governing the agglomeration of industries.1 We begin with television receivers, which is the easiest to understand and provides a useful backdrop for the automobile and tire industries. Next we

The evolution of geographic structure in new industries

71

consider the evolution of the automobile industry, followed by the evolution of the tire industry. We conclude with observations about the importance of organizational heredity and birth in shaping industry agglomeration.

2.

TELEVISION RECEIVERS

The annual number of entrants, exits, and producers of television receivers in the United States over the 194689 period based on listings in Television Factbook (Warren Publishing Company) is presented in Figure 4.1. A total of 177 rms entered the industry, most of them by 1951. Experimental television systems were introduced prior to the Second World War, but the war delayed the start of the industry until 1946. RCA and DuMont were the rst rms to begin producing in 1946. Many rms followed soon after, reecting the rapid growth in the sales of television receivers. Entry peaked in 1948 at 54 rms, and by 1955 entry was negligible. The number of rms rose from 1946 to 1949, reaching a peak of 105 in 1949, and then fell sharply. International competition, initially from Japan, began in the late 1960s when roughly 30 US-based producers were left in the industry. At that point RCA and Zenith were the top two US producers of television receivers, accounting for 39 per cent of US sales of black and white TVs and 48 per cent of the sales of color TVs, and the four-rm concentration 120 100 80 60 40 20 0 1940 Producers Entrants Exits

1950

1960

1970

1980

1990

2000

Source: See Klepper (2003).

Figure 4.1 Entry, exit and number of producers in the television industry, 19461989

72
120% 100% 80% 60% 40% 20% 0% 1940 1950 1960
Source: See Klepper (2003).

Industrial dynamics

% NY producers % Chicago producers % LA producers

1970 1980 1990 2000

Figure 4.2 Percentage of television producers in New York, Chicago and Los Angeles, 19461989 ratios in black and white and color TVs were 61 and 65.5 per cent, respectively. International competition mounted over time and the number of US-based rms fell steadily. By 1989 only three US producers were left in the industry, all of which were destined to exit within a short period. Klepper (2003) analysed the location of the TV producers, which was heavily concentrated in three US cities: New York, Chicago and Los Angeles. Although these three cities accounted for only 15 per cent of the US population, 73 per cent of television producers entered in the three cities, with 44 per cent entering in New York, 15 per cent in Chicago and 14 per cent in Los Angeles. Figure 4.2 presents the annual percentage of television producers based in each of these three cities from 1946 to 1989. New York initially contained over 50 per cent of the television producers, but over time this percentage declined sharply. By 1970 New Yorks share had declined to 20 per cent, and by the end of the 1970s no rm was based in New York. Firms were slower to enter in Los Angeles, but by the mid1950s, 20 per cent of the producers were located there. Subsequently the share of producers in Los Angeles fell sharply, and by the mid-1970s no rm was based in Los Angeles either. Chicago accounted for around 25 per cent of television producers in the initial years of the industry. It maintained its share through about 1980, after which its share increased sharply as the number of rms dwindled from eight to three. Thus, at the start of the industry, television producers were heavily concentrated in three cities, but from the mid-1950s until 1980 the collective share of producers in the three cities declined from 70 to 25 per cent.

The evolution of geographic structure in new industries

73

The evolution of the location of the television producers was greatly inuenced by the location of rms in the radio industry. Entry, exit and the location of radio producers was reconstructed from annual listings of radio producers in Thomas Register of American Manufacturers (Thomas Publishing Company; see also Klepper and Simons, 2000; Klepper, 2003). At the start of the television industry, 266 US rms produced radios. They were heavily concentrated in New York, Chicago and Los Angeles, which accounted for 33, 15 and 7 per cent, respectively, of all radio producers in 194548. Of the 177 television entrants, 58 or approximately one-third diversied from the radio industry, and nearly all began producing television receivers where they produced radios. Thus, it is not surprising that among the 58 diversiers, 55 per cent of them located in New York, Chicago and Los Angeles, which mirrors the fraction of radio producers in the three cities. Perhaps more surprising is that among the remaining 119 entrants, 82 per cent also located in these same three cities, especially in New York and Los Angeles, which accounted for 53 and 18 per cent, respectively, of these entrants (Klepper, 2003). Klepper and Simons (2000) demonstrated that the radio producers that diversied into the television industry tended to be the largest and most experienced ones, and they tended to enter earlier than other entrants into the TV industry. They also found that the diversiers from the radio industry had much lower hazards of exit at all ages than non-radio diversiers, and among the radio diversiers, the larger ones had much lower hazards at all ages. Indeed, 13 of the top 14 television producers over the history of the industry were diversiers from the radio industry, and four of the top ve television producers were among the top ve radio producers as of 1940 (the other radio producer among the top ve in 1940 was among the top 10 TV producers). The location of the leading radio producers was the dominant force shaping the location of TV producers in the long run and the evolution of the geographic structure of the industry. Only one of the top radio producers was located in New York, and it accounted for only 11 per cent of the sales of the top radio producers as of 1940, and Los Angeles had no leading radio producer as of 1940. With the leading radio producers ultimately dominating the television industry, New York and Los Angeles were destined to experience a sharp decline in their share of television producers as the industry proceeded through its shakeout. Chicago had ve of the top 16 radio producers that jointly accounted for 38 per cent of the sales of the leading radio producers as of 1940. Correspondingly, Chicago had three of the top 10 television producers and maintained its share of television producers over time. The other leading radio producers were scattered throughout the Northeast and Midwest. Many of these rms,

74

Industrial dynamics

including RCA, Philco and GE, became leading television producers. They survived much longer than other rms, and as a result the base location of television producers became increasingly dispersed throughout the Northeast and Midwest as the industry evolved. In a statistical analysis of rm hazard rates, New York and Los Angeles rms had higher hazards of exit than rms located elsewhere, but once the background and time of entry of rms was controlled, there were no signicant dierences in the hazard rates of rms by region (Klepper, 2003). International competition further contributed to a geographic dispersal of television production. While US rms maintained their base locations, they increasingly moved their operations into low-wage countries in order to counter foreign competition (Levy, 1981, pp. 26178). But this did not head o their demise. They were behind the technological frontier, especially regarding the use of semiconductor technology. They lost much of their market share to Japanese rms that had pioneered the use of semiconductor components in radios and that were consistently ahead of the US rms in the use of semiconductor components in television receivers (La France, 1985). Television receivers illustrate a few themes that are pertinent to automobiles and tires. First, rms in related industries are important seeds for rms in a new industry, and their location is an important determinant of where entrants into the new industry locate. Second, the pre-entry experience of rms has a profound eect on their ability to compete. In televisions, experience in radios was so signicant that no new rm was successful in the industry over the long term. Consequently, over the long run the base location of the leading radio rms was the dominant inuence on the location of television producers. Third, agglomeration economies were not a major factor shaping the base location of television producers. Two of the three regions where rms were concentrated declined over time, and regional dierences in rm performance were largely due to dierences in their preentry experience rather than any inuence of the regions themselves. Finally, as the number of US rms declined, the leading rms increasingly moved their production into lower-wage areas, further dispersing production.

3.

AUTOMOBILES

The annual number of US entrants, exits and producers of automobiles from the start of the industry in 1895 through 1966 based on a list compiled by Smith (1968) is presented in Figure 4.3. Only rms that produced a nonnegligible number of automobiles are included, which encompassed 725 rms through 1966 (see Klepper, 2002a). In contrast to televisions, entry

The evolution of geographic structure in new industries

75

300 250 200 150 100 50 0 1880 Producers Entrants Exits

1900

1920

1940

1960

1980

Source: See Klepper (2003).

Figure 4.3 Entry, exit and number of producers in the automobile industry, 18951966 was initially low, reecting the limited demand for automobiles when they were introduced. Subsequently entry grew, peaking at 87 rms in 1907. Entry remained high for the next three years and then declined to an average of 15 rms per year for the next 12 years, after which it became negligible. The number of rms peaked at 272 in 1909, after which it fell steadily despite average annual output growth of over 20 per cent during the next 15 years. By 1941 only nine rms were left in the industry. As of 1911, the top two rms in the industry, Ford and General Motors, accounted for 38 per cent of the output of automobiles. They increased their joint market share to over 60 per cent by the 1920s and with Chrysler, which emerged out of two early entrants in the 1920s, they jointly accounted for over 80 per cent of the output of the industry by the 1930s. The industry became famously agglomerated around Detroit, MI, but initially no rm produced a non-negligible number of automobiles in the Detroit area. Figure 4.4 reports the annual percentage of producers based in the Detroit area from the start of the industry through 1941, when only nine rms were left in the industry.2 No producer was located in the Detroit area until 1901, when Olds Motor Works began production in Detroit and Lansing, MI. Olds was the rst great rm in the industry. After Olds entry the percentage of automobile producers in the Detroit area steadily rose into the 1910s, when it peaked at over 20 per cent. It then fell back a little but rose again after 1920, exceeding 50 per cent by 1941. The rms based

76
70 60 50 40

Industrial dynamics

% Detroit producers 30 20 10 0 1880

1900

1920

1940

1960

Source: See Klepper (2003).

Figure 4.4 Percentage of automobile producers in the Detroit area, 18951941 in the Detroit area were extraordinarily successful. By the mid-1910s they produced 13 of the 15 leading makes of automobiles, and over 60 per cent of automobiles were produced in Michigan, nearly all in the Detroit area. Although 69 producers entered the industry in 1895 to 1900 before any producer entered in the Detroit area, Detroit nonetheless became the capital of the US automobile industry by the mid-1910s, and it maintained its hegemony for many years thereafter (Klepper, 2001). Entry was far more dispersed geographically than in televisions. Michigan had more entrants than any other state, but it accounted for only 18.6 per cent of the 725 entrants through 1966, followed by New York with 13.5 per cent and Ohio with 12.3 per cent. Thus, the top three states accounted collectively for 44.7 per cent of the entrants whereas the top three cities in televisions accounted for 73 per cent of the entrants. This largely reects that the leading seeding industries for automobiles were considerably more dispersed geographically than the radio industry. Klepper (2001) identied rms that diversied into autos or were founded by an individual who headed a rm in another industry based on the listings in Smith (1968) and the brief histories of automobile rms in Kimes (1996). The industry from which the greatest number of these two types of entrants came was carriages & wagons. In a statistical analysis of the location of automobile entrants, Klepper (2003) found that states with more carriage & wagon production not only had more entrants originating from the

The evolution of geographic structure in new industries

77

carriage & wagon industry but also more of other types of entrants as well. Unlike radio producers, which were concentrated in three cities, the carriage & wagon industry was dispersed throughout the Northeast and Midwest, with the top three states accounting for only 32 per cent of all carriage & wagon producers. Moreover, among US states Michigan was ninth in terms of carriage & wagon producers and fourth in terms of value of carriage & wagon production. The second most important seeding industry for automobiles was bicycles, which was also dispersed throughout the Northeast and Midwest, and few bicycle rms were located in Michigan. Consequently, the geographic dispersion of entrants and the slow start of the industry around Detroit were predictable. Similar to televisions, automobile entrants that diversied from other industries, particularly carriages & wagons, bicycles and engines, had lower hazards of exit at all ages, as did new rms founded by individuals who headed rms in these industries (Klepper, 2001). But diversiers were far less important in automobiles than televisions. Whereas 33 per cent of the entrants into the television industry diversied from the radio industry, only 16.6 per cent of entrants into the automobile industry were diversiers from any industry (Klepper, 2003). In large part this reects the novel technological challenges faced by automobile rms. Automobiles soon required precision manufacturing to produce interchangeable parts, manufacturing was done on an unprecedented scale, and technological progress was far more rapid than had occurred in carriages & wagons and other related industries. Consequently, experience in related industries was much less valuable in automobiles than in televisions. This opened up opportunities for new rms, especially rms with one or more founders that previously worked for an incumbent automobile rm, which are called spin-os. Klepper (2001) identied the spin-o entrants and the rms their founders previously worked for, dubbed their parents, based on the brief rm histories in Kimes (1996). Approximately 20 per cent of entrants into automobiles were spin-os, most of which were founded by top managers or heads of incumbent rms. At their peak in 1916, spin-os accounted for 11 of the 15 leading makes of automobiles. Nearly all of these spin-os descended from the leading automobile producers in the sense that their founders had worked for one of these rms (Klepper, 2001, 2005). Statistical analyses indicated that the annual likelihood of a rm having employees leave to start spin-os was greater for better-performing rms, and on average better-performing rms had better-performing spin-os (Klepper, 2001). One explanation for these patterns is that leading incumbent rms provided a superior venue for employees to learn about organizational best practices, especially top employees. Top rms were also magnets for talented individuals, which is another

78

Industrial dynamics

possible reason why their spin-os performed so well. Spin-os formed for various reasons. Among the top rms, many of them arose from internal disputes about strategy and technology, reecting control struggles that were common in the early years of the industry (Klepper, 2005). In large part because of the inuence of Olds Motor Works, spin-os played a key role in the concentration of the industry around Detroit. Olds Motor Works had been a successful producer of steam and gasoline engines before it entered the automobile industry. Its manufacturing and marketing experience enabled it to become the rst rm to sell over 1000 automobiles in a year, selling more than 5000 by 1904. Olds subcontracted all of its parts, which involved orders of unprecedented size, to various local rms, providing its subcontractees with invaluable experience. Two of these rms were instrumental in the formation and success of Cadillac and Ford Motor Co., both of which were located in Detroit Another one of Olds subcontractors initially nanced Buick, which was located in Flint, MI near Detroit. Buick was the cornerstone of the later merger that formed General Motors. This same contractor also co-founded another successful rm, Maxwell-Briscoe, which later evolved into Chrysler. Olds Motor Works, Cadillac, Ford Motor Co. and Buick/General Motors were among the most successful early automobile producers, and they collectively unleashed a spin-o juggernaut that propelled Detroit to become the automobile capital of the United States. They were the most prolic parents in the industry, reecting the greater rate of spin-os among the better rms. Olds had more descendants than any other rm in the industry, and in total 41 rms descended from Olds, Cadillac, Ford and Buick/General Motors. These rms mainly located in the Detroit area, reecting the general tendency for spin-os to locate close to their parents (Klepper, 2001). Together Olds, Cadillac, Ford and Buick accounted for 11 of the 13 spin-os that produced leading makes of automobiles after 1903, with each rm spawning at least two of these spin-os. Consequently, by the mid-1910s nearly all the leading makes of automobiles were made by rms based in the Detroit area. With the leading makes accounting for over 80 per cent of the output of the industry, Detroit rms totally dominated the industry. Indeed, what distinguished Detroit was primarily its spin-os, which accounted for 48 per cent of the entrants in Detroit versus only 15 per cent of the entrants elsewhere. Moreover, spin-os in Detroit greatly outperformed spin-os elsewhere, whereas the rest of the entrants in Detroit performed comparably to their counterparts elsewhere. In a statistical analysis, the superior performance of rms in Detroit was conned to its spin-os, and their superior performance in turn was largely attributable to their superior heritage rather than being located in Detroit (Klepper, 2001).

The evolution of geographic structure in new industries

79

The leading rms remained based in Detroit, but over time they conducted more of their business outside of Detroit as they established branch assembly plants throughout the United States. It was much cheaper to ship parts rather than a nished car. Consequently, if a rm had sucient output to accommodate multiple plants of minimum ecient size then it made sense to build branch assembly plants closer to the market. Ford, the largest producer in the 1910s, was the rst to build branch assembly plants in the 1910s. It was followed by General Motors in the 1920s and later Chrysler and two of the other large automobile rms in the 1930s (Rubenstein, 1992). While this caused auto production to become more dispersed over time, Michigan still accounted for over 40 per cent of the output of automobiles as of 1931, and the leading rms remained based in the Detroit area. Some of the lessons that emerge from automobiles are similar to TVs. Like TVs, rms in related industries, such as Olds, were important seeds for the new industry. Also like TVs, there was enormous heterogeneity in entrants in terms of their pre-entry experience that persistently aected their performance. The key dierence between autos and TVs was that spin-os were competitive with, if not superior to, diversiers. This reected both the limited relevance of prior industries to autos and possibly the distinctive opportunities within rms, particularly the leading rms, for high-level employees to learn valuable tacit organizational knowledge that they could apply to their own rms. With better rms having higher spin-o rates and better-performing spin-os, the spin-o process eectively led to a build-up of rms and activity around the leading rms in the industry. This was especially potent in autos because of the location of four of the most successful early rms in one narrow region, fueling a great agglomeration of activity there. The four rms were connected through Olds, which was the catalyst for the agglomeration of the industry around Detroit. But the other three were important parents of spin-os, and their creation near the industry leader added another random element to the agglomeration process that could help explain why agglomerations as extreme as autos are rare. Indeed, while Detroit was part of the manufacturing belt dating back to the 1860s, it was hardly the most likely place for the automobile industry to agglomerate. Its development was largely attributable to the inuence of Olds Motor Works and the inherent randomness in the location of any one rm. Agglomeration economies from locating near other producers do not appear to have been a major factor in causing the industry to agglomerate around Detroit. Indeed, the establishment of branch assembly plants throughout the US by the leading rms is indicative of the potential disadvantages of the leading rms clustering in one area. It is notable that it took the industry leaders to exploit the advantages of assembling cars

80

Industrial dynamics

outside of Detroit. This is indicative of the diculty of imitating the leaders of the industry from afar, no doubt in part due to the tacit knowledge the leaders possessed. It is also suggestive of why the leading rms had more and better spin-os their high-level employees had access to valuable tacit knowledge about how to structure their own rms. The evolution of the market structure of the automobile industry may have inuenced the evolution of its geographic structure, though not directly. The TV industry also experienced a shakeout and evolved to be an oligopoly, yet its geographic structure evolved in an opposite direction to autos. Moreover, the hegemony of Detroit was established before the shakeout in the automobile industry began. It is possible, though, that the eventual drying up of entry that characterized the industry after 1925 eliminated a force that could have unseated the leaders and conceivably reduced the concentration of the industry around Detroit.

4.

TIRES

The annual number of entrants, exits and producers of tires in the United States over the 190580 period based on listings in Thomas Register of American Manufacturers is presented in Figure 4.5. With the initial demand for automobiles limited, the demand for tires was initially modest and entry started out low. Subsequently it grew for many years, peaking in the early 1920s before falling o sharply and becoming negligible by 1930. A total of 533 rms entered the industry through 1930, after which no signicant rm entered. The number of rms peaked in 1922 at 278 and then went through a long shakeout despite robust output growth interrupted only by the Great Depression. Only 51 rms were left in the industry in 1940, and by 1970 only 24 rms were still in the industry. The industry evolved to be a tight oligopoly dominated by Goodyear, Goodrich, Firestone and U.S. Rubber (Uniroyal). Together these four rms accounted for over 53 per cent of the output of the industry in 1926, which they increased to over 70 per cent by 1933 and then subsequently maintained (Klepper, 2002a). Similar to automobiles, the tire industry became heavily concentrated around a single city, Akron, OH, located in the northeastern part of Ohio near Cleveland. Figure 4.6 reports the annual percentage of 1930 and earlier entrants that were located in Ohio from 1906 to 1980. For the rst 25 years or so Ohio generally accounted for between 20 and 30 per cent of all producers, but after 1930 the percentage of rms in Ohio rose steadily and by 1959 it exceeded 50 per cent. Firms in Ohio, especially around Akron, were distinctly successful, and by 1935 over 65 per cent of the output of tires was produced in Ohio (Buenstorf and Klepper, 2005b). Much of this output was

The evolution of geographic structure in new industries


300 250 200 150 100 50 0 1880 Producers Entrants Exits

81

1900

1920

1940

1960

1980

2000

Source: See Buenstorf and Klepper (2005b).

Figure 4.5 Entry, exit and number of producers in the tire industry, 19011980
70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 1900 % Ohio producers

1920

1940

1960

1980

2000

Source: See Klepper and Buenstorf (2005b).

Figure 4.6

Percentage of tire producers in Ohio, 19061980

produced by Goodyear, Goodrich and Firestone, all of which were based in Akron. But rms in northeastern Ohio also dominated the next cadre of rms. As of 1920, six of the next 20 largest rms were located in Akron, and four others were located nearby in northeastern Ohio (ibid.).

82

Industrial dynamics

Like automobiles, Ohio had more tire entrants than any other state, but it accounted for only 24 per cent of all the entrants through 1930, followed by New York with 15 per cent, New Jersey with 14 per cent, Pennsylvania with 8 per cent and Illinois with 7 per cent. Klepper (2002) and Buenstorf and Klepper (2005b) identied the entrants into tires that diversied from another industry, which in most cases was the rubber industry. Similar to TVs and autos, in a statistical analysis Buenstorf and Klepper (2005a) found that states with more rubber producers had more tire entrants that were diversiers and also more of other types of entrants, and within Ohio counties with more rubber producers had more diversifying entrants. Similar to Michigan and autos, Ohio was not the leading state in terms of rubber producers, but was fth in 1890 with 3.5 per cent of US rubber producers. While diversiers had lower hazards of exit on average than other types of entrants, diversiers accounted for only 15.6 per cent of all entrants, similar to automobiles. In part, this reects that automobile tires represented a considerable break from prior rubber products. Bicycle tires did not readily scale to automobiles, tire manufacturing was much more complex than other rubber products, and tires were subject to much more technological change than other rubber products. Thus, like automobiles opportunities existed for regions that were not well stocked with rms in related industries. Within Ohio, the most important rubber producer at the start of the tire industry was BF Goodrich, which was located in Akron, where the (limited number of) rubber producers in Ohio were concentrated. Goodrich was a leading bicycle tire producer and successful producer of other rubber products, and like Olds Motor Works it was an important catalyst for the industry in Akron. It produced the rst pneumatic automobile tire in 1896 and immediately became one of the leading producers of tires. Goodrich was inuential in four other early tire rms locating and prospering in Akron Diamond Rubber, which merged with Goodrich in 1912, Kelly-Springeld, Firestone and Goodyear. Diamond was a 1894 rubber spin-o from Goodrich. Goodrich produced Kelly-Springelds initial carriage tire based on a patented design before Kelly-Springeld initiated the production of automobile tires in Akron in 1899. Goodrich also initially produced tires for Firestone after its entry in Akron in 1900 and then supplied Firestone with prepared rubber and fabric when it began producing its own tires in 1903. Finally, Goodyear was founded in 1898 by the son of one of the original nanciers of Goodrich that subsequently also operated a rubber rm (Buenstorf and Klepper, 2005b). With ve leading rms located in Akron early on, the stage was set for spin-os to play a key role in the further development of the industry around Akron. Buenstorf and Klepper (2005a) traced the origin of the

The evolution of geographic structure in new industries

83

126 rms that entered in the state of Ohio through 1930. Like Detroit, spinos accounted for a disproportionate share of the entrants that originated from the Akron area 58 per cent of the 36 entrants that originated in Summit County (the home of Akron) were spin-os versus 35 per cent of the other entrants originating elsewhere in Ohio. Most of them were formed by high-level employees, similar to the automobile industry. Furthermore, the bulk of the spin-os that originated in Ohio entered in either the same or a contiguous county to where their employer was located (ibid.). A statistical analysis of the rate at which employees left Ohio rms to form spin-os revealed that the highest spin-o rate among Ohio producers occurred in the leading Akron rms, followed by the next tier of leading producers in Ohio (ibid.). In an analysis of rm performance (Buenstorf and Klepper, 2005b), rms located in the Akron area had lower hazards than rms located in the rest of Ohio and outside of Ohio. Similar to Detroit, the distinctive performance of the rms in the Akron area was conned to the spin-os located there. Furthermore, among all spin-os in Ohio, those that descended from the leading rms or the second tier of leading producers had lower hazard rates, suggesting that the superior performance of the Akron spin-os was largely attributable to their heritage. Buenstorf and Klepper (2005a) traced where entrants in Ohio originated, which for diversiers was where they previously produced, for spinos where their parents were located, and for start-ups where their founders previously worked. Not only did spin-os tend to locate in or close to their county of origin, but so did diversiers and other start-ups. In a statistical analysis of the county where entrants located given their county of origin, Buenstorf and Klepper (2005a) found that the number of tire producers and the population of an entrants county of origin did not positively inuence its likelihood of entering there. However, these same characteristics inuenced whether an entrant located in a distant county. Figueiredo et al. (2002) found similar patterns for modern Portuguese entrepreneurial start-ups. One interpretation of these ndings is that entrants have valuable knowledge about their home region, such as where to nd labor, input suppliers, transportation and even sources of knowledge spillovers, but they lack this knowledge about other regions. Consequently, even if their home region is not well stocked with rms in their industry and other industries and local markets for labor, inputs and so on are thin, they still know where to secure their needs. Without this knowledge about other regions, they would be better o locating in regions with more rms in their industry and in other industries because such regions would have better developed local markets to supply their needs. While the entrants in Ohio tended to locate near their geographic roots, when they established branch plants they tended to locate these away from

84

Industrial dynamics

their base location, similar to autos. In the 1920s, the leading tire producers established branch manufacturing plants throughout the United States to save on transportation and labor costs (Jeszeck, 1982). This intensied after 1935 due to increasing militancy on the part of the union representing tire workers (ibid.), causing the share of tire production in Ohio to decline. Similar to the automobile industry, it was the leading rms that were in the vanguard of exploiting the advantages of more remote areas. Their willingness to set up plants outside of Ohio is suggestive of the limited advantages of locating in Akron. Consistent with this, Akron was not a major draw for either start-ups or spin-os that originated elsewhere, and a number of spin-os that originated in Akron did not locate there (Buenstorf and Klepper, 2005a). The lessons from the tire industry closely parallel those from autos. Firms from the rubber industry, the most closely related industry, were important seeds for tire entrants, but spin-os were also signicant competitors. There was great heterogeneity among entrants in terms of their pre-entry experience that persistently aected their performance. One rm was a key catalyst for activity around Akron, both through its eects on other early Akron producers and through the spin-os that it and the other successful Akron producers disproportionately spawned. As a consequence, the industry became extremely agglomerated around an unlikely region, reecting both the randomness in the location of any one rm and the unlikely combination of early rms in one narrow region that was critical to the extreme agglomeration of the industry there. Agglomeration economies did not appear to play a major role in the agglomeration of the industry around Akron, and branching by the leaders eventually reduced the agglomeration of the industry there. The evolution of the market structure of the industry, particularly the eventual drying up of entry after 1930, may have contributed to the geographic concentration of the industry, but this concentration was established well before the industry underwent a shakeout.

5.

OBSERVATIONS

Various themes emerge from the study of the three industries regarding the evolution of the geographic structure of new industries. The Location of Firms in Related Industries Inuences Where Entrants Locate In all three industries, the location of rms in related industries inuenced the location of entrants into the new industry. This was most apparent in

The evolution of geographic structure in new industries

85

televisions, where both diversiers and other entrants concentrated in the three cities where the radio rms were clustered. In both autos and tires, regions with more rms in related industries also had more diversiers and other entrants. But rms in related industries were more dispersed in autos and tires than TVs, so entrants were more dispersed in these two industries than TVs. The radio industry may also have had more inuence on the location of TV producers than any related industry had on autos and tires because of the greater overlap between radios and TVs than any product had with either autos or tires. This was reected in the much higher fraction of entrants that were diversiers (from the radio industry) in TVs than autos and tires. The inuence of related industries on entry into TVs, autos and tires suggests two points. First, rms need competence to compete in a new industry, and one source of that competence is experience in related industries. Indeed, the fact that diversiers in all three industries had lower hazards of exit on average than other entrants suggests that experience in a related industry was an important source of competence in all three industries. Second, diversifying entrants do not venture far geographically from their roots, which also appears to have been the case for spin-os and other startups. Buenstorf and Kleppers (2005a) ndings concerning the location of Ohio tire entrants suggests that entrants locate close to their roots to exploit valuable local knowledge they possess based on their pre-entry experience. Consequently, an important determinant of regional entry into a new industry is the stock of local rms that could provide the competence needed to succeed in the new industry. Incumbents Can Also be Important Sources of Competence Just as rms in related industries appear to be an important source of competence for a new industry, in autos and tires incumbent rms also appear to have been an important source of such competence, especially the leading incumbents. The leading rms had higher rates of spin-os, and on average their spin-os were better performers than spin-os from lesser rms. Moreover, their spin-os were certainly competitive with if not superior performers to diversiers from related industries, suggesting that the leading incumbent rms were also an important source of competence for entrants. The superior performance of spin-os from the leading rms could reect that these organizations had more to pass down to ospring. Alternatively, it could reect that better rms attracted better managerial talent and more talented individuals founded superior rms. Judging from the dominance of the industry by diversiers from the radio industry, spin-os were not competitive in TVs. Two factors may have been

86

Industrial dynamics

at work. Radios and TVs overlapped considerably in terms of technology and marketing whereas autos and tires represented a greater break from past products. Consequently, diversiers from radios may have had a greater advantage in TVs than any kind of diversier had in autos and tires, limiting the opportunities for new rms in TVs relative to autos and tires. Second, demand initially grew much faster in TVs than autos and tires, which may have limited opportunities for later entrants of all kinds, including spin-os. Klepper (2002a) developed a model of shakeouts in which earlier entrants have a head start in building up a market for their products, which enables them to apply their research and development over a larger output, providing them with a competitive advantage. Spin-os naturally enter later because they require a gestation period, in the form of employees gaining experience in incumbent rms. Consequently, they will be at a greater disadvantage in markets in which demand initially grows rapidly, as occurred in TVs relative to autos and tires. Consistent with this, entry became negligible within 10 years of the start of the TV industry whereas it continued much longer in autos and tires. The Spin-o Process Can Induce Agglomerations around Successful Firms In both autos and tires, better rms had higher spin-o rates. Spin-os (and other entrants) did not venture far from their geographic roots, so entry was greater around successful rms. The spin-os of successful rms also performed better than other spin-os and were competitive with, if not superior to, diversiers from related industries in autos and tires. Consequently, over time activity built up around successful early producers, especially in Detroit and Akron, where successful early auto and tire producers were concentrated. Entry in Detroit and Akron was disproportionately composed of spinos and it was spin-os in both regions that performed distinctly well, suggesting that the spin-o process alone can give rise to agglomerations. On the other hand, it is conceivable that the agglomerations in both Detroit and Akron were driven by agglomeration economies, which could give rise to the same patterns of entry being concentrated in agglomerated areas and rms in agglomerated areas performing better than rms elsewhere. But if agglomeration economies were the primary cause of the agglomerations in autos and tires, then entrants of all kinds should have been attracted to Detroit and Akron. Moreover, entrants of all types should have performed better in Detroit and Akron than their counterparts elsewhere. Yet in both areas entry was disproportionately composed of spin-os and only spinos performed better than their counterparts elsewhere. Furthermore, nearly all the spin-os in Detroit and Akron had parents located there and

The evolution of geographic structure in new industries

87

so were not drawn from other regions. Judging from Buenstorf and Kleppers (2005a) ndings for tires, spin-os (and other types of entrants) that originated from agglomerated regions were also no more likely to locate in their home region than spin-os that originated elsewhere. Thus, agglomeration economies do not appear to have played a major role in fostering the agglomerations in either autos or tires. The TV industry is also instructive about the power of spin-os versus agglomeration economies to generate agglomerations. Agglomeration economies would have been expected to operate as strongly in TVs as autos and tires. Yet despite the extraordinary concentration of entrants in three narrow areas, the TV industry became less agglomerated over time. What appears to have been missing was a spin-o process that generated rms that were competitive with the leading diversiers. This further suggests that the key to the agglomerations of the auto and tire industries was the spin-o process and not agglomeration economies. The Spin-o Process Can Magnify an Early Cluster of Leading Firms into an Extraordinary Agglomeration Within the rst 10 years of the auto and tire industries, most of the leading producers in autos and tires were present in Detroit and Akron. The setting was ripe for the spin-o process to magnify the initial cluster of leading rms in each region, and this is precisely what occurred. Consequently, over time the percentage of rms and activity around Detroit and Akron increased and both regions evolved to account for over 60 per cent of activity in their industries. While establishment-level data are not available to compute the EllisonGlaeser (1997) index of geographic concentration, conservative estimates would put both industries in the tail of manufacturing industries in terms of geographic concentration. Having so many early leaders in one narrow region is surely an uncommon event, which would explain Ellison and Glaesers (1997) nding that agglomerations as extreme as autos and tires are rare. On the other hand, even if the early leaders of an industry were not as clustered as in autos and tires, the spin-o process would still be expected to cause activity to build around successful early rms. Activity would still agglomerate, but it would be dispersed across more regions than in autos and tires. This could explain Ellison and Glaesers nding that activity in most manufacturing industries agglomerates to some degree, but generally much less so than in autos or tires. In both autos and tires, the early leaders did not all locate in Detroit and Akron by chance. Rather, one rm in each region Olds Motor Works in autos and BF Goodrich in tires played a key role in other successful

88

Industrial dynamics

producers being located nearby. Both rms were fertile sources of spin-os, but their inuence was broader. Olds provided valuable experience to its local subcontractors, some of whom later entered or nanced the ventures of others, while Goodrich supplied inputs and sometimes initially manufactured tires for local tire rms. In both industries, input markets were not yet well developed, and so expertise accumulated in one rm redounded to the benet of others nearby. This is a form of spillover, but it is of somewhat dierent variety than the externalities featured in modern theories of agglomeration economies. It is restricted to a small number of connected rms in a region and is consistent with the ndings of Breschi and Lissoni (2002) concerning how technological knowledge is transmitted across rms. The importance of a single rm helps explain how the agglomerations in autos and tires got established in an unexpected place. Neither Detroit nor Akron was particularly distinguished in terms of activity in related industries or anything else that would have fueled an agglomeration there. On the other hand, both regions were located in the so-called manufacturing belt and certainly had a healthy amount of activity in related industries. As chance would have it, both ended up with a diversier from a related industry that became the rst outstanding performer in its industry. This was the seed for the agglomerations that emerged in both regions. With a single rm having so much inuence on the agglomeration process, chance can play a big role in whether and where an agglomeration gets established. Again, the TV industry is instructive about the circumstances in which chance can have such a big inuence on the location of an industry. Without a strong spin-o process in TVs, no rm had the kind of inuence on the location of the TV industry as either Olds or Goodrich. Consequently, rms ended up congregating where rms in the radio industry were concentrated, limiting the possibility of activity clustering in an unexpected area. Agglomerations and Shakeouts Are Not Directly Related Clearly, the forces underlying shakeouts do not lead to agglomerations, as the TV industry illustrates. Moreover, by the time the shakeouts began in autos and tires, Detroit and Akron were already well established as the centers of activity in their respective industries. Thus, the shakeouts in autos and tires do not seem to have played a critical role in the agglomeration of either industry. But characteristic of shakeouts is the drying up of entry, as occurred in all three industries after their shakeouts began. This removed a force that potentially could have undermined the agglomerations that formed in autos and tires. Therefore, indirectly the agglomerations in autos and tires might have been promoted by the shakeouts both industries experienced.

The evolution of geographic structure in new industries

89

Ultimately, though, the forces underlying the shakeouts in both autos and tires appear to have caused both industries to become less agglomerated. Both industries were characterized by scale economies at the plant level, which no doubt led rms initially to enter with a single plant. Judging from the actions of the leading rms, though, the economies were not so overwhelming as to preclude the establishment of branch plants by the largest rms in the industry. Thus, as both industries consolidated and the leaders took over an increasing share of the industrys output, the leading rms established branch plants, which they generally located away from their base locations to save on transportation and labor costs. With the leading rms generally based in Detroit and Akron, this eventually caused the agglomerations in autos and tires to decline over time. The same forces also led the TV industry to become more dispersed over time as rms moved some of their operations oshore to take advantage of lower labor costs. Dumais et al. (2002) found that in manufacturing industries branch plants generally are de-agglomerating in the sense that their location and use causes employment to move away from agglomerated areas over time. They found that the main force sustaining agglomerations was the greater longevity of plants in agglomerated areas. Again, the ndings for autos, tires and TVs are instructive about the forces possibly at work. Judging from Buenstorf and Kleppers (2005a) ndings for tires, rms did not choose their initial locations to minimize the costs of production but to exploit local knowledge they had accumulated through their pre-entry experience. Thus, when branch plants were established, it was natural to locate them away from where the rms were based, which was generally in agglomerated areas. Furthermore, agglomerations themselves can raise the cost of production such as by land prices being bid up, necessitating the payment of compensating wage dierentials. In tires, the agglomeration of activity in Akron also no doubt facilitated the union organization of workers, and militancy on the part of the union contributed to rms setting up branch plants elsewhere. The greater longevity of plants in agglomerated areas could result from a spin-o process comparable to the one that operated in autos and tires. Firms in agglomerated areas would be better performers and thus their plants would be longer lived. Three Industries Do Not Make a General Theory Generalizing based on three industries is certainly dangerous, but there is enough evidence from other industries to suggest that the forces at work in auto, tires and TVs are operative in other industries as well. Sorenson and Audia (2000) found that in the footwear industry, entry was more likely in agglomerated areas even though rms had higher hazards of exit in these

90

Industrial dynamics

areas. They interpreted this as a reection of the natural tendency of entry to concentrate near incumbents even in the absence of agglomeration economies, consistent with the spin-o process in autos and tires. Gordon Moore of Intel fame, along with his co-author, implicated spin-os in the semiconductor industry as the primary basis for the agglomeration of activity in Silicon Valley (Moore and Davis, 2004). The analog to Olds and Goodrich was Fairchild, whose ospring were so numerous that they were dubbed Fairchildren. Moore and Davis (2004) have a particularly interesting discussion of why working in an incumbent semiconductor rm provided distinctive organizational knowledge that enabled high-level managers to form their own successful spin-os. A few studies analyse the spin-o process in specic industries without linking it explicitly to geography, and their ndings are also consistent with those for autos and tires. In both the disk drive (Franco and Filson, 2000; Agarwal et al., 2004) and laser industries (Klepper and Sleeper, 2005), spinos performed distinctively well. In both industries more successful rms had higher spin-o rates, which also appears to have been the case among semiconductor rms located in Silicon Valley (Brittain and Freeman, 1986). In disk drives, the spin-os of more successful rms were also better performers, which appears to have been associated with an (involuntary) transfer of technology and marketing expertise from parents to their spin-os. Questions Abound about the Evolution of Industry Geographic Structure The interpretation of the evolution of the geographic structure of the auto, tires and TV industries raises many questions. Firms are assumed to dier from the outset in terms of their competence based on their pre-entry experience. But what exactly does the pre-entry experience of rms provide them and how does this inuence their performance not just initially, but for many years after entry? Spin-os played a key role in the agglomeration of both autos and tires. Why do spin-os occur, why are they more prevalent among the leading rms, and what drives the correlation between the performance of spin-os and their parents? Under what conditions do successful early entrants galvanize other rms to form and prosper nearby? More generally, what are the mechanisms that inuence the transmission of knowledge across rms in the same industry and between suppliers and producers, and how is this mediated by geographic distance? These are just some of the questions raised by the evolution of the three industries. Hopefully, further examination of the way the geographic structure of new industries evolves will shed light on these questions and on the fundamental drivers of agglomerations and the geographic structure of industries.

The evolution of geographic structure in new industries

91

NOTES
* Helpful comments were provided by an anonymous referee. Support is gratefully acknowledged from the Economics Program of the National Science Foundation, Grant No. SES-0111429. 1. The review of the evolution of the market structure of the three industries is primarily based on Klepper (2002a). The review of the evolution of the geographic structure of the three industries is primarily based on Klepper (2001, 2002b, 2003, 2005) for automobiles, Klepper (2003) for TVs, and Buenstorf and Klepper (2005a, 2005b) for tires. 2. Firms established branches and moved within a 100-mile radius of Detroit. Accordingly, the market area around Detroit was dened to correspond to this 100-mile radius (Klepper, 2001).

REFERENCES
Agarwal, Rajshree, Raj Echambadi, April M. Franco and M.B. Sarkar (2004), Knowledge transfer through inheritance: spin-out generation, development and survival, Academy of Management Journal, 47, 50122. Breschi, Stefano and Francisco Lissoni (2002), Mobility and social networks: localised knowledge spillovers revisited, mimeo, Bocconi University, Milan. Brittain, Jack W. and John Freeman (1986), Entrepreneurship in the semiconductor industry, mimeo, University of California, Berkley, CA. Buenstorf, Guido and Steven Klepper (2005), Regional birth potential, agglomeration economies, and home bias in the location of domestic entrants, mimeo, Max Planck Institute, Jena. Buenstorf, Guido and Steven Klepper (2005b), Heritage and agglomeration: the Akron tire cluster revisited, mimeo, Max Planck Institute, Jena. Dumais, Guy, Glenn Ellison and Edward L. Glaeser (2002), Geographic concentration as a dynamic process, Review of Economics and Statistics, 84, 193204. Ellison, Glenn and Edward L. Glaeser (1997), Geographic concentration in U.S. manufacturing industries: a dartboard approach, Journal of Political Economy, 105, 889927. Figueiredo, Octavio, Paulo Guimaraes and Douglas Woodward (2002), Homeeld advantage: location decisions of Portugese entrepreneurs, Journal of Urban Economics, 52, 34161. Franco, April M. and Darren Filson (2000), Knowledge diusion through employee mobility, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, Sta Report 272. Jeszeck, Charles A. (1982), Plant dispersion and collective bargaining in the rubber tire industry, PhD dissertation, University of California, Berkeley. Kimes, Beverly R. (1996), Standard Catalog of American Cars, 18051942, 3rd edn, Iola, WI: Krause Publications. Klepper, Steven (2001), The evolution of the U.S. automobile industry and Detroit as its capital, mimeo, Carnegie Mellon University, Pittsburgh, PA. Klepper, Steven (2002a), Firm survival and the evolution of oligopoly, RAND Journal of Economics, 33, 3761. Klepper, Steven (2002b), The capabilities of new rms and the evolution of the U.S. automobile industry, Industrial and Corporate Change, 11, 64566. Klepper, Steven (2003), The geography of organizational knowledge, mimeo, Carnegie Mellon University, Pittsburgh, PA.

92

Industrial Dynamics

Klepper, Steven (2005), The organizing and nancing of innovative companies in the evolution of the U.S. automobile industry, in Naomi Lamoreaux and Kenneth Sokolo (eds), The Financing of Innovation, Cambridge, MA: forthcoming. Klepper, Steven and Kenneth L. Simons (2000), Dominance by birthright: entry of prior radio producers and competitive ramications in the U.S. television receiver industry, Strategic Management Journal, 21, 9971016. Klepper, Steven and Sally Sleeper (2005), Entry by spinos, Management Science, 51, 1291306. Krugman, Paul (1991), Increasing returns and economic geography, Journal of Political Economy, 99, 48399. La France, Vincent A. (1985), The United States television receiver industry, PhD dissertation, Pennsylvania State University, University Park, PA. Levy, Jonathan D. (1981), Diusion of technology and patterns of international trade: the case of television receivers, PhD dissertation, Yale University, New Haven, CT. Marshall, Alfred (1920), Principles of Economics, London: Macmillan. Moore, Gordon and Kevin Davis (2004), Learning the Silicon Valley way, in Timothy Bresnahan and Alfonso Gambardella (eds), Building High-tech Clusters: Silicon Valley and Beyond, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 739. Rubenstein, James M. (1992), The Changing US Auto Industry, London: Routledge. Smith, Philip H. (1968), Wheels within Wheels, New York: Funk & Wagnalls. Sorenson, Olav and Pino G. Audia (2000), The social structure of entrepreneurial activity: geographic concentration of footwear production in the United States, 19401989, American Journal of Sociology, 106, 42461. Thomas Publishing Company (19051980), Thomas Register of American Manufacturers, New York: Thomas Publishing Company. Warren Publishing Company, Television Factbook, vols 559, Washington, DC: Warren Publishing Company.

5. Constructing entrepreneurial opportunity: environmental movements and the transformation of regional regulatory regimes
Brandon Lee and Wesley Sine*
1. INTRODUCTION

Past research on the geographic distribution of economic activity has focused primarily on specifying the conditions that sustain economic clusters rather than explaining regional variance in the conditions (that is, opportunities) that facilitate the emergence of new economic forms. Therefore, to understand when and where entrepreneurial opportunity exists, theory must explain how information and resources for entrepreneurial activity come to be disproportionately massed in some places and at some times (Romanelli and Schoonhoven, 2001: 41). Economic geographers have begun to address this question by focusing attention on institutional geography those social, political and culturalcontextual elements that enable, constrain, and refract economic development in spatially dierentiated ways (Martin, 2000: 79). In this chapter, we advance the institutional geography agenda by investigating how dierences in regional collective action aect state regulatory regimes and hence, opportunities for economic activity. Recent developments in organization theory that integrate social movement theory into accounts of the emergence, change and decline of institutions (Davis and Thompson, 1994; Fligstein, 1996; Rao et al., 2000; Davis et al., 2005) provide a fruitful avenue for understanding variation in the creation and existence of regional entrepreneurial opportunity. Research in both entrepreneurship and economic geography has largely neglected the role that social movements play in generating new opportunities for entrepreneurs. While a substantial body of work has outlined how the characteristics of regions impact economic and entrepreneurial activity (Weber, 1909; Marshall, 1922; Harris, 1954; Arrow, 1962; Piore and Sabel, 1984; Romer, 1986; Jae et al., 1993; Zucker et al., 1998; Almeida and Kogut,
93

94

Industrial dynamics

1999; Sorenson and Audia, 2000; Stuart and Sorenson, 2003), there is little research on how regional collective action inuences geographic variation in the success of new industries and technologies. Increasingly, scholars have shifted attention away from the characteristics and abilities of the lone entrepreneur (McClelland, 1961) and toward the demand side of entrepreneurship (Thornton, 1999), with work centering on the impact of exogenous shocks or changes in the environment that stimulate opportunities for new types of economic activity and organizational forms (Schumpeter, 1934; Thornton, 1999; Sine and David, 2003). These environmental shocks or jolts provide a catalyst for action. Jolts disrupt the routines and practices of individual organizations (Meyer, 1982) and can precipitate institutional decline for entire industries and organizational elds (Tushman and Anderson, 1986; Greve, 1995; Homan, 1999). Technological change and innovation, deregulation, demographic shifts and changing consumer preferences can alter the relative value of information and resources in such a way as to catalyse new types of economic activity. While these exogenous shocks are often necessary for the creation of new opportunities, they are not sucient in and of themselves. Extant research, however, reveals little about how these broader changes create and eliminate entrepreneurial opportunities and therefore this topic merits greater scholarly attention (Eckhardt and Shane, 2003). To address this gap, we draw upon research that suggests the creation of new forms (and opportunities for new forms, as we argue in this chapter) is not only a political process (Stinchcombe, 1965), but also a collective one (Fligstein, 1996; Rao et al., 2000; David et al., 2005; Davis et al., 2005). Taking this approach, we link exogenous change to the creation of entrepreneurial opportunity by examining how social actors engage in framing processes and the mobilization of resources (McAdam, 1996). By so doing, we clarify the mechanisms responsible for translating broader technological, economic and demographic disruptions into concrete entrepreneurial opportunities. Work in organization theory that employs the social movement framework generally does so in the context of industry participants seeking to change existing intra-industry arrangements or extra-industry constraints on their industry (for example, Fligstein, 1996; Davis and McAdam, 2000; Swaminathan and Wade, 2001). However, often, free-rider problems may impede collective action by industry participants and trade associations may not form until a later point in the industry life cycle (Rao, 2004). Taking a dierent approach, we suggest that broader social movements themselves, while potent motors for social change, also have the capacity to generate new markets and possibilities for entrepreneurial activity. In so doing, we answer calls to re-examine the linkages between organizational

Constructing entrepreneurial opportunity

95

dynamics and broader societal changes (Stinchcombe, 1965; Perrow, 1986, 2002; Friedland and Alford, 1991; Stern and Barley, 1996; Scott, 2001; Lounsbury and Ventresca, 2002). While the outcomes of social movements are understudied (Giugni, 1998, 1999), scholarly consideration of their inuence on markets and entrepreneurial activity is even more scant (but see Schneiberg, 2002; Lounsbury et al., 2003). To address this shortcoming, we examine how social movements inuenced entrepreneurial opportunity creation in the US electrical power industry from 1978 to 1992. Prior to 1978, it was largely impossible for small, independent power producers using renewable energy technologies (RETs) to sell electricity to the US power grid. In 1978, federal legislation required incumbent utilities to purchase power from independent power producers. However, the federal government delegated all decision making and enforcement of the particulars of these regulations to state governments, opening the door for wide variation in the degree to which state-level regulation supported independent power producers. In this chapter, we use historical and quantitative analysis to examine the eect of state environmental movement membership on regional regulatory environments for RET entrepreneurs. By examining how social movements shape the creation of regulatory environments across US states, we account for geographic variation in entrepreneurial opportunity (Romanelli and Schoonhoven, 2001). In the next section, we outline how social movement organizations construct entrepreneurial opportunity in nascent industries. We then provide a brief history of the US electric power industry. This is followed by a historical narrative focused on how environmental social movements inuenced state level incentive structures for entrepreneurs interested in developing ventures using alternative energy technologies. We then explain the data and methods employed and conclude with the analysis and a discussion of the results.

2.

THEORY

Social Movements and Entrepreneurial Opportunity Increased scholarly attention has focused on the role that collective action plays in the construction, change and devolution/destruction of institutions, technology regimes and new organizational forms (Garud and Van de Ven 1989; Davis and Thompson, 1994; Fligstein, 1996; Rao et al., 2000; Davis et al., 2005; Hargrave and Van de Ven, forthcoming). Because new forms, industries and technologies never emerge in empty social space,

96

Industrial dynamics

processes of resource assembly, legitimation and integration require collective action (Sine and David, 2003). Change and innovation within a eld or market generally comes from peripheral players that engage in collective action but do not have a stake in, or benet from existing institutional congurations (Leblebici et al., 1991). Collective challenges to existing institutions or technologies have been increasingly theorized through a social movement lens to explain how collective eorts contest existing institutions and construct new institutions and organizational forms that embody shared interests and goals. For example, in their account of the emergence of the organic food industry, Lee and Lounsbury (2005) show how local coalitions of organic farmers collectively acted to distinguish organic from conventionally grown food by developing and rening a process theory of how food should be cultivated. By collectively organizing and embodying that theory in standards and certication procedures, organic farmers successfully created a new category of products termed organic. This collective work created a solid jurisdictional boundary around the organic food category that infused these products with value over and above similar products that were not labeled organic, allowing organic farmers and retailers to charge more for their products. In a similar vein, Schneiberg (2002) demonstrates how re mutuals emerged as a new form to solve coordination problems that were not adequately addressed by either markets or hierarchies. These mutuals represented a means by which property owners and agriculturalists resisted economic centralization and drew upon anti-company politics and agrarian protest to forcefully articulate and instantiate an alternative model of organizing and managing risk in a new organizational form. Finally, David et al. (2005) show how in the early 1900s institutional entrepreneurs publicly identied particular problems associated with the emergence of the corporate form (Chandler, 1990). The dramatic changes in size and scope of rms resulted in a new set of challenges for both owners and managers that institutional entrepreneurs such as Arthur Little, Edwin Booz and James McKinsey argued were best addressed by external consultants well versed in contemporary social and natural science. These institutional entrepreneurs and the rms and industry associations they formed worked together to create and proselytize problemsolution models that proposed using external consultants with established categories of expertise such as psychology or chemistry for solving organizational problems. Due to the collective eorts of these early pioneers, within less than a decade, management consulting became an established part of the business landscape. Drawing upon these studies, we suggest that localized collective action eorts can lead to the construction of regional entrepreneurial opportunities

Constructing entrepreneurial opportunity

97

by framing problems and solutions and constructing and utilizing mobilizing structures (McAdam, 1996). We dene framing as a collective attribution process through which people can voice their grievances, specify the underlying logic of those grievances, and articulate and promulgate a solution (see Snow et al., 1986; Snow and Benford, 1988; Benford and Snow, 2000). Mobilizing structures are those formal and informal vehicles by which people engage in collective action (McCarthy, 1996). We argue that formal social movement organizations employ frames and mobilizing structures to create legal environments that facilitate particular types of entrepreneurial activities. Legal and Regulative Structure Weber (1978) explicated the states role in fostering and shaping markets: Law can . . . function in such a manner that, in sociological terms, the prevailing norms controlling the operation of the coercive apparatus have such a structure as to induce, in their turn, the emergence of certain economic relations (667, emphasis added). Law and state regulation, through instrumental as well as normative and culturalcognitive means, inuences the creation and subsequent expansion of new markets (Dobbin, 1994; Fligstein, 2001; Fligstein and Stone Sweet, 2002). In their study of the railroad industry in Massachusetts, Dobbin and Dowd (1997) found that material support from the state increased the number of foundings of railroad rms. Similarly, Lomi (1995) shows how direct policy eorts codied in law led to the diusion of cooperative banks to rural areas in Italy where private stock banks were not willing to do business. Wade et al. (1998) demonstrate how state governments can curb particular economic practices. They nd that during the Prohibition period in the United States, regulations at the state level were eective at barring in-state breweries, yet these regulations unintentionally spurred brewery foundings in adjacent states where these regulations did not exist. Over time, however, as the number of states with prohibition laws increased there was a decrease in brewery foundings in all states. These accounts, particularly the work by Wade and colleagues, demonstrate that policy governing economic activity has direct eects on organizational founding dynamics and that regulation can vary by region. However, we have little understanding of the origins and impetus for this type of regulation and what accounts for the variation in its adoption. Attempting to specify the mechanisms of legal structure diusion, recent work (Schneiburg and Bartley, 2001; Strang and Bradburn, 2001; Ingram and Rao, 2004; Schneiberg and Soule, 2005) oers a more nuanced understanding of the origins, antecedents and factors that account for regulation

98

Industrial dynamics

within a market. Schneiberg and Bartley (2001), for example, nd that in the early US re insurance industry, more robust regulation was likely to be enacted when marginal groups such as farmers and small businesses challenged big business in the political arena. Legal and regulatory structure within a region or locale can also serve as a mechanism that generates variation in agglomeration processes. Local institutions can structure access to resources and provide cognitive models that are important in the emergence of new rms (Suchman et al., 2001). While it is generally accepted that institutional forces work at a level that transcends regional boundaries, some of the most important ones operate more narrowly, within particular geographically or functionally bounded organizational communities (Suchman et al., 2001: 357). For example, in a recent study of liquidity events and their eect on initial public oerings, Stuart and Sorenson (2003) nd that urban areas in states that are lax in their enforcement of non-compete clauses experience greater new venture formation. Further, they nd that enforcement of those non-compete clauses lessens the eects of liquidity events on founding rates. This study supports Suchman et al.s (2001) claim that, Among the various institutional structures that might regulate the ow of resources and models to new rms, law occupies a particularly important place (362). In the following section, we draw upon historical and archival documentation to develop an analytical narrative that demonstrates the role that environmental social movements played in contesting existing methods of producing electricity. Through their collective eorts, they facilitated the construction of a regulatory environment that provided the necessary incentives for entrepreneurs to begin selling renewable energy on the grid.

3.

CONTEXT: THE US POWER INDUSTRY

Until the late 1970s, electric utilities depended almost exclusively on a combination of oil, coal, large hydroelectric facilities, and to a lesser extent natural gas and nuclear technology to generate power. Other than a few small experimental facilities, utilities did not generate power using nonhydro renewable sources (US Department of Energy, 2001). This is not to say that there was no interest in renewable technologies. For example, the rst wind turbine that produced electricity was built in 1888, and since that time a long line of fringe alternative power enthusiasts have promoted their respective technologies. However, prior to 1978, the electric utility industry consisted of vertically integrated utilities that generated and distributed electricity. Utilities largely rejected RETs because they were viewed as expensive and risky

Constructing entrepreneurial opportunity

99

when compared to the highly developed traditional generation technologies. Utilities controlled both power generation and distribution in particular regions. Renewable energy technologists could thereby only access regional wholesale and retail energy markets with the cooperation of the local utility. These utilities often resisted interconnection with independent generators because interconnection would likely increase their costs and utilities were not eager to distribute power generated by potential competitors. Since utilities could lock out these potential competitors by refusing interconnection, oering below market prices for independently produced power, and charging higher-than-average prices for back-up power (Hirsh, 1999: 813), there were no foundings of independent power generation facilities that sold electricity to the grid prior to 1978. This situation changed dramatically when in 1973 a Saudi oil embargo on the United States caused oil prices to more than double, reaching $25 a barrel in 1973. Further disruptions to oil supplies in 1978 pushed oil prices to $50 a barrel, ve times the 1972 price of oil. Utilities attempted to reduce their reliance on oil by converting to expensive solid-fuel plants but despite those eorts, electric prices remained high. These price increases motivated policy makers to search for other ways to generate electricity that would decrease the countrys dependence on foreign oil, thereby providing institutional entrepreneurs fertile opportunities to promote new technological agendas to these same policy makers (Sine and David, 2003). Environmental activists brought these agendas to national attention by questioning existing energy policies and practices. As early as the late 1960s, growing awareness of the harmful environmental eects of coal- and oilburning power plants and fear of nuclear power increased the hostility of many environmental groups toward electric utilities (Fenn, 1984: 512). Large, established environmental groups such as the Sierra Club, the Audubon Society, the Union of Concerned Scientists and others began to actively promote an energy conservation agenda that included increased use of renewable energy and more ecient use of energy from all sources (McCloskey, 1992; McLaughlin and Khawaja, 2000). Advocates of RETs argued that while these new technologies were relatively underdeveloped compared to coal- and oil-based technologies, they had several qualities that made them potentially better sources of power than conventional means. First, unlike coal, oil and gas, the process of generating power with RETs does not produce air or water pollution, making its environmental footprint smaller than that of large-scale hydroelectric plants. Moreover, unlike coal, the production of renewable energy does not require large mines or, as in the case of oil, run the risk of spills. Second, RETs are local sources of energy and thereby promote local jobs. Finally, given technological progress, RETs had the future potential of being priced similarly to

100

Industrial dynamics

energy produced by traditional sources. However, like most claims about future technology progress, this last point was highly uncertain.1 In reaction to the energy crisis and pressure from pro-conservation and renewable energy advocates, the National Energy Act (NEA) was passed in 1978 and section 210 of this law, the Public Utility Regulatory Policies Act (PURPA), allowed entrepreneurs to construct qualifying non-utility facilities free from the constraints of traditional utility regulation. Under section 210, utilities were required to interconnect with qualifying non-utility power plants (that is, qualifying facilities) and purchase power from qualifying facilities at utilities cost of generation (which came to be known in the industry as avoided cost). Independent power plants qualied under section 210 if they used alternative energy resources such as wind, solar, biomass, garbage, wood, sewage sludge and other lower-grade fuels, or used cogeneration technology. Section 210 provided the legal structure at the national level that allowed alternative energy entrepreneurs to interconnect with and sell electricity to utilities. However, the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC) left the interpretation and enforcement of section 210 to state governments. Social Movements and the US Power Industry Social movements deinstitutionalize existing beliefs, norms and values embodied in extant forms and establish new forms that instantiate new beliefs, norms and values (Rao et al., 2000: 238). For social movements to be successful in these deinstitutionalization and institutionalization projects, movements must at the outset engage in the production and maintenance of meaning for constituents, antagonists and bystanders (Benford and Snow, 2000: 613). Producing and maintaining collective meaning (that is, collective action frames) includes three important processes: diagnostic, prognostic and motivational framing. Diagnostic framing involves creating a shared understanding of a problematic condition that is in need of change and ascribes culpability to someone or something for the problem. Prognostic framing denotes the generation of a solution to the problem, and motivational framing refers to the construction of the rationale for engaging in collective action (Benford and Snow, 2000). Beginning in the early 1970s, environmental movement organizations engaged directly in diagnostic, prognostic and motivational framing to advocate the use of renewable energy. Diagnostic framing Suchman (1995) argued that the recognition and articulation of a problem for which there is no adequate solution is the rst step required for creating

Constructing entrepreneurial opportunity

101

change in taken-for-granted ways of doing something (Scott, 2001). The process of developing a description of, and detailed evidence about, a problem, its cause and its negative consequences, focuses the attention of the public and powerful actors on unsolved diculties (Edelman et al., 1999; Sine and David, 2003). Unanswered problems provide a social location for new solutions and simultaneously delegitimate existing institutional arrangements that are not adequately addressing or solving the problems (Cohen et al., 1972). Educating relevant actors and the public about problems catalyses solution generation processes as relevant actors engage in sensemaking and collective problem solving (Mezias and Scarselletta, 1994; Weick, 1995). The public articulation and elaboration of problems creates opportunities for institutional entrepreneurs to persuasively argue for the implementation of new practices and attracts pools of alternative solutions. Prior to the 1970s, the US environmental movement took little notice of energy policy. However, after the publication of Rachel Carsons Silent Spring (1962), members of the environmental community engaged in framing coherent, consistent and salient critiques of the nations dependence on fossil fuels and nuclear power. The core idea emanating from these critiques was that the growing level of energy consumption was not sustainable. The most extreme advocates believed that modern technological systems were not simply malfunctioning or manifesting ineciencies; they were in some profound sense unable to preserve the environment, and the social and political structures that had produced those technologies could not make sucient improvements to prevent a serious ecological disaster (Laird, 2001: 122). Relatively unchallenged prior to the 1973 oil embargo, in the mid-1970s the energy sector found itself subject to intense scrutiny, with its technologies, resources and underlying values being challenged (Laird, 2001). One of the earliest and most eective critics of US energy policy was environmentalist Amory Lovins. In a strategic and creative way, Lovins eectively reframed the energy problem. Instead of assuming an increased demand for energy, Lovins argued that people demand delivered services such as comfortable rooms, light, vehicular motion, food, tables, and other real things (Lovins, 1976: 78). Lovinss perspective suggested that the problem is not simply where to get more energy, of any kind, from any source, at any price, but rather how to supply just the amount, type and source of energy that will provide each desired service at least cost (Lovins and Lovins, 1974: 26). In sum, Lovins argued that the real energy problem lies in the mismatch of energy supply to end-use needs in scale and quality. By articulating the energy problem as a mismatch rather than a problem of supply, Lovins invoked the metaphor of someone who is unable to ll the

102

Industrial dynamics

bathtub because the water keeps running out. Instead of thinking of the problem as having too small a water heater, the problem lies in not having a plug (Lovins and Lovins, 1974; Lovins, 1976). The energy problem gained greater salience as Lovins ascribed blame for energy shortages to shortsighted pricing policies. Instead of basing energy decisions on current average costs, as is common in the industry, Lovins advocated the use of long-run marginal costs, which would include capital costs associated with the construction of new centralized power plants. This was important because in many cases the cost of new capacity was substantially larger than past power facilities. He eectively argued that the legal infrastructure of the time essentially subsidized the true costs of nonrenewable energy by not accounting for externalities such as associated environmental degradation and not taking into account future costs of additional capacity. Prognostic framing Prognostic framing, or the generation of solutions, is closely associated with diagnostic framing (the articulation of problems) (Gerhards and Rucht, 1992). Lovinss critique of US energy policy and his reframing of the energy problem naturally dovetailed with the solutions he proposed. To remedy the problems he described, he proposed to do more with less energy through the use of energy-ecient technologies, allowing exactly the same output of goods and services. Another key characteristic of the solution included technologies that relied on renewable energy ows that matched user needs in both scale and quality (Lovins, 1976). By scale, Lovins suggested that large energy production facilities be utilized for large uses and small energy production technologies be used for small sources, such as a passive solar design to heat a home. By quality, he meant that expensive forms of energy, such as electricity, should be reserved for applications where electricity is appropriate and indispensable, such as for smelting, subways and other kinds of mechanical work, and not be used to perform small jobs such as domestic space heating. Implicit in his solution was the decentralization of energy systems to redress the supply/demand mismatch. Lovinss creative reframing of the energy problem and its associated solutions had an immediate and profound impact on the energy policy debate. He was attacked repeatedly for his position, yet responded articulately and rapidly to each criticism. One author noted,
He presented a thorough critique of conventional thinking about energy policy and the most creative and sophisticated arguments in favor of solar energy to date. His analysis provided a rationale for a group of growing importance in the solar movement those who based their attachment to solar energy on beliefs

Constructing entrepreneurial opportunity

103

about the nature of environmental problems and the relationship of energy technologies to them. (Laird, 2001: 126)

However, his work did not exclude more mainstream supporters, because it was grounded in economic eciency, suggesting that his approach would be cheaper than the existing one. Furthermore, while Lovinss approach was consistent with ecological values, he argued repeatedly that it did not require them, suggesting that his approach could coexist with more conventional values like economic rationality (Laird, 2001). Lovinss diagnostic and prognostic framing of energy issues gained resonance because the frame was consistent with both environmental and costbenet logics and therefore empirically credible (Benford and Snow, 2000). Consequently, this new energy frame gained acceptance from environmental groups that in turn promulgated and reinforced it through articles, studies and newsletters. For example, the president of the Sierra Club, in a letter to its members said, there is, however, a positive choice that can be made a soft path alternative energy plan, one based on conservation and renewable sources. If adopted, it could solve our most pressing energy problems faster, cheaper and more cleanly than Carters plan (Snyder, 1979: 4). The Union of Concerned Scientists (UCS) completed a study in 1980 that critiqued both the current system and the industrys nuclear alternative and set out to provide an answer to the question, if not nuclear power, what? (UCS, 1980: xvii). In the introduction to their study they state:
It is now abundantly clear that the world has entered a period of chronic energy shortages that will continue until mankind has learned to harness energy from renewable sources. . . . In the face of these mounting diculties, a long-term strategy emphasizing major improvements in energy productivity (with an attendant reduction in energy growth) and a reliance on renewable energy derived from the sun[2] emerges as the clearest and most sensible solution to the great challenge we and future generations face. . . . We believe that the strategy outlined in this study can help ease the burden of transition to a benign and sustainable energy future for the United States. (UCS, 1980: 21)

For the UCS, renewable energy provided a sensible solution to competing solutions such as nuclear power:
On the other hand, we believe that most, if not all, of the major environmental and societal risks posed by a large-scale breeder future could be avoided in a well-planned solar energy economy.[3] A solar energy future would in some ways be simpler and in other ways more complex than a breeder future. While the individual solar technologies are, in themselves, much less complicated than breeder reactors, the design and integration of a comprehensive solar energy

104

Industrial dynamics

system would involve a greater degree of sophistication than a system based entirely on breeders. However, the resulting system would be more exible, less dangerous, better adjusted to the diverse energy needs of this complex industrial state, and thus a more stable basis for the nations continued prosperity than any system based on nuclear ssion. (Ibid.)

Studies conducted by Friends of the Earth, the Audubon Society and the Sierra Club all provided a solid basis for critiquing existing technology and power generating sources and at the same time, advocated the use of alternative energy. For example, the UCS strongly advocated for wind, suggesting that it was the most viable, safe, benign and easily commercialized of all alternative energy technologies:
Wind represents a large and nondepletable energy resource that can be utilized with minimal impact on the environment, producing no air and thermal pollution and requiring no water in its utilization. The simplicity of wind technology will allow for rapid deployment in comparison to many other energy technologies. Finally, the economic prospects of wind systems are quite promising. There are barriers as well to the widespread use of wind power, but none should prove insurmountable. (Ibid.: 145)

Through eective framing, these social movement organizations provided meaning and momentum to eorts to change the structure of electricity production in the United States. They served as sounding boards, amplifying the importance and urgency of fostering the development of alternative energy sources. The development and subsequent promulgation of these frames became the basis for the mobilization of resources in support of RETs in Congress and among the rank-and-le membership of environmental groups. Motivational framing and resource mobilization Mobilizing structures are forms of organization available to social movement actors that include informal friendships, neighborhood and work settings that facilitate and structure collective action (Tilly, 1978), and formal organizations that embody and attempt to achieve the preferences and goals of a broader social movement (McCarthy and Zald, 1977). For the purposes of this chapter, we focus on formal social movement organizations (SMOs) as the key mobilizing structures used to recruit members, obtain and distribute material resources, disseminate information, provide protocols of action for members to follow, and facilitate a common cognitive framework among their members. For example, the Sierra Club served as a principal mobilizing structure for collective eorts to advocate RETs and develop supportive regulative structure. The elaborate organizational

Constructing entrepreneurial opportunity

105

structure of the Sierra Club (chapters in all 50 states) coupled with the exibility to accommodate more informal and proactive activities in promoting RETs made it a potent organization for altering political landscapes. An article in a 1970 newsletter described the relationship between formal organizational structure and grassroots action in mobilization eorts:
Perhaps the most important aspect of chapters and groups is that they are the Clubs grassroots interface with the public. Some hold monthly membership meetings open to the public, with speakers and lm programs. Others have organized speaker bureaus and presented programs to community groups. Many chapters publish excellent newsletters, which carry articles on local conservation campaigns, as well as scheduled activities. A few have opened community conservation centers, either with their own resources or in cooperation with other environmental organizations. Very often, it is at the group level that the nuts and bolts work of the conservation campaigns is carried out providing manpower to gather data, prepare lawsuits, testify at public hearings, inuence public ocials, and generate the enthusiasm and dedication that will carry to state and national levels, attracting support for our cause. . . . It is often at the group level that a conservation issue was rst recognized, and then brought to the attention of the chapter and to the Board of Directors, possibly to become one of the clubs priority campaigns nationally. The process is reversed, though, when appeals go out from the Clubs national oces to chapter and group leaders to activate telephone chains and get wires into Washington! The key element in this complex structure, besides funds, public support and sta, is an informed, active membership. (Billings, 1971: 21)

A bridging concept between mobilizing structures and framing processes is motivational framing (Benford and Snow, 2000), which provides the rationale for engaging in collective action. Important aspects of this type of framing include articulating the severity of the problem, the urgency for action, and the ecacy and propriety of a specic action (ibid.: 617). In the case of renewable energy, environmental groups provided a rationale for its members to support and advocate alternative energy sources by issuing a call to action, outlining the specic, urgent action to be taken, and emphasizing the consequences of inaction. For example, the Audubon Society, an organization whose primary focus had little to do with energy policy, provided a strong rationale for its members to engage in political action:
It is not enough to be convinced that the solar/conservation approach is the most economic and environmentally benign energy strategy. If organizations like Audubon and the many environmentally oriented individuals who make up the membership of such organizations are unable to communicate to their neighbors and governmental leaders both the merits and the urgency of the solar/eciency approach, then the goals of this Plan and others like it will not be met. In that case, the energy growth point of view of organizations like the Edison Electric

106

Industrial dynamics

Institute will dominate public policy debates, and the possibility of achieving economic growth without energy growth will be lost in the next decade. (National Audubon Society, 1984: 523)

This example illustrates the Audubon Societys call to action and describes the kind of political action to be taken (communicating with neighbors and government leaders), the need for urgency (goals must be met), and the eects of inaction (the Edison Electric Institute dominating public policy debates). Other types of activities prescribed by this environmental organization included increasing public awareness, scrutinizing state and local energy plans, lobbying at all levels of government, involving the community in studying local energy problems, and calling upon experts at universities to analyse the benets of conservation for taxpayers (ibid.: 105). The Sierra Club constructed a similar mobilization frame and leveraged its formal and informal organizational structure to mobilize its members to promote regulatory change:
The threat posed by President Carters proposals is so great, and the need for action by every member so urgent that the board of directors has called for the mobilization of the Clubs full resources for this Emergency Energy Campaign. Only a massive outpouring of grass-roots concern can transform the present political climate, encouraging Congress to drop the damaging proposals and enact more rational energy alternatives. Intensive organizing eorts have already been set in motion, and letter writing and media contacts have begun. All Sierra Club chapter and group leaders will be receiving regular updates as this campaign speeds along. (Snyder, 1979: 5) It is time for face-to-face mobilization. Conservationists must start meeting with their elected ocials and candidates to tell them what they, as voters, expect and want. We need to stand up at rallies and ask, politely, but persistently, why Congress solved the energy crisis by putting most of the money into the least promising and most expensive technologies, the synthetic fuels. . . . If, in the next six months, every Sierra Club member would just once personally attend and participate in a political event, it would make a world of dierence. (Coan and Pope, 1980: 1113, 47)

Environmental memberships readily accepted the mobilization frames promulgated by the leadership of environmental organizations and their call for political activism. In fact, comprehensive surveys of Sierra Club members reveal that their commitment reected the directives, goals, and aspirations of the clubs leadership. A survey in 1971 revealed signicant commitment among the organizations rank-and-le membership manifest in their political activism: 60 per cent said that they sent their views on conservation matters to government ocials at least once in the past year, with 15 per cent reporting nine or more communications; 40 per cent of the

Constructing entrepreneurial opportunity

107

members attended one or more political meetings or rallies in the last year and 27 per cent reported devoting time to one or more political causes (Coombs, 1972). Following the oil crisis of 1973, and the Three Mile Island incident of 1979, energy policy was at the fore for both the rank-and-le members and leaders of the Sierra Club. A second survey in 1979 revealed a membership highly committed to changing energy policy. The opening sentence of the story that introduced the results of the survey read:
A new broadened Sierra Club motto might be in order. It might read: . . . To preserve, explore and enjoy the nations wilderness, parks, forests and natural areas, to clean the nations air and water, to protect wildlife, promote the development of alternative, renewable energy resources and conserve energy to further this goal. (Emphasis added, Utrup, 1979: 16).

This second survey found that one-third of the members felt that energy issues needed more eort on the part of the Club. Energy was also the third most popular issue that Club members showed a willingness to spend more time working on: 75 per cent of members expressed a strong interest in solar power, with the remainder expressing some or little interest (ibid.). These surveys demonstrate that the logics advocated by the Sierra Club leadership that framed conventional energy technology as an environmental problem and RET as a solution were accepted and enacted by the membership. In this section, we have provided qualitative evidence that suggests environmental movement organizations eectively framed energy problems and solutions, provided a rationale for action to their members, and marshaled resources through mobilizing structures to create favorable regulatory climates for independent power rms using RETs. Given the intensity and scope of activities engaged in by these social movement organizations, we hypothesize that higher levels of social movement activity in a state will increase the likelihood of a favorable regulatory environment for rms using RET.

4.

DATA AND METHODS

We test our hypothesis by examining the eects of Sierra Club membership on avoided cost rates. We draw on panel data that capture US state energy regulation from 1980 to 1992. Dependent Variable Our dependent variable is the average size of a states avoided costs in a given year. Although the federal government loosely dened avoided cost

108

Industrial dynamics

(the cost avoided by a utility for not generating the same amount of power), it was left up to the states to establish a precise denition. Consequently, the formula for constructing avoided cost varied from state to state. In some states, it was based on the cost of fuel of the most likely alternative while other states took into account capital costs. Calculations that took into account capital costs tended to be controversial because they varied tremendously depending on the type of technology used (that is, nuclear technology was more expensive than coal technology). Other sources of ambiguity included the choice of fuel type to use as the baseline to calculate the cost of generation. In other words, were public utility commissions to dene avoided costs by the most expensive type of fuel used in a utilitys portfolio or its least expensive? Further, should the public utility commissions assume high or low interest rates? Because of these ambiguities, there were substantial dierences in how states calculated avoided costs and consequently, their amounts. Our data on avoided costs come from three sources: Solar Law Reporter (1981), Energy User News (198285), and Avoided Cost Quarterly (198692). Independent Variable We obtained state-level Sierra Club membership data. During the period of our study, the Sierra Club was one of the three largest environmental organizations in the United States (McCloskey, 1992). We chose the Sierra Club membership data due to the organizations size and status within the environmental community. We also acquired yearly state-level membership data from the UCS and found their membership distribution across US states to be highly correlated with that of the Sierra Clubs (0.88). Membership data from the Audubon Society and several other large environmental organizations were not available because such information was not retained during the late 1970s and 1980s. Control Variables Our model controlled for the following state characteristics: per capita gross state product, change in gross state product, state population, congressional voting record on energy issues,4 and net electricity imports. We also controlled for the availability of land with constant streams of highquality wind because wind turbines were the most common RET used by independent power entrepreneurs during our study period. Because the regulatory climate may be aected by the extent to which regulators are willing to monitor compliance and punish rms for not following formal regulations or informal norms, we also controlled for the activism of state

Constructing entrepreneurial opportunity

109

utility commissions. To assess commission activism, we measured the number of rate cases per utility, comprehensive audits per utility, comprehensive audits of private utilities, and total audits per utility. Audits provide a good measure of regulatory oversight because the purpose of audits is to verify the information given to the commission by utility companies. More audits conducted by a public utility commission are indicative of an involved and active state commission. Rate cases examine a utilitys nancial information to verify the justication for current or proposed rates. Utilities view audits and rate cases as highly disruptive and expensive. Excessive audits and rate cases can be viewed as either punitive measures or as a way of ensuring compliance with state regulatory policies. These data come from the National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) annual utility surveys. Model Specication and Estimation We measure the impact of environmental social movement organizations on the regulatory climate using avoided costs as the dependent variable. This variable indicates the extent to which a states regulatory climate is supportive of alternative energy. We use panel data for each state-year between 1980 and 1992. The analysis begins in 1980 because this is the earliest date that states dened avoided costs. We employ a generalized estimating equation to predict the size of the avoided cost and corrected for common biases in the analysis of longitudinal data introduced by autocorrelation among residuals by assuming an unstructured error correlation. We used the STATA XTGEE command with the unstructured correlation option. An advantage of this model is that it does not assume that panels are uncorrelated. We used robust variance estimators in our analyses, reducing problems associated with heteroskedasticity and misspecication of the error structure (Allison, 1999). We also estimated the models using the ar 1 option, but found no signicant dierence in the results. We used a variance ination factor test to ensure that our models were not signicantly aected by multicollinearity and found that the factor scores in both models presented were less than 5, suggesting an acceptable level of multicollinearity (Chatterjee and Price, 1991).

5.

RESULTS

Summary statistics are provided in Table 5.1. In Table 5.2, we present the results of the generalized estimating equation predicting supportive regulatory climate. Several control variables signicantly predict the amount of

Table 5.1 Summary statistics and correlations for state-avoided cost analysis
S,D. 0.22 0.00 0.11 0.35 0.03 0.05 0.28 0.20 0.16 0.01 0.16 0.12 0.29 0.11 0.01 0.19 0.23 0.20 0.17 0.08 0.12 0.31 0.84 0.05 0.03 0.04 0.04 0.11 0.08 0.03 0.01 0.09 0.45 0.01 0.22 0.25 0.01 0.11 0.06 0.03 0.10 0.20 0.02 0.25 0.41 0.00 0.03 0.01 0.17 0.04 0.14 0.19 0.02 0.01 0.36 0.01 0.13 0.04 0.11 0.22 0.04 0.25 0.44 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12

Variable

Mean

110

0.35 0.10 0.43 0.15 0.05 0.45 0.01 0.07 0.01 0.01 0.06 0.22

0.13 0.11 0.24

1. Avoided costs (cents/kWh) 2.79 1.26 2. GSP per capita 0.02 0.01 3. Class 3 & 4 wind availability 49 333.94 79787.24 4. State population (ln) 4 6 92 763 5076 695 5. Change in Gross State 7.34 4.97 Product (GSP) 6. Net electricity imports 0.54 2.13 (million kWh) 7. Rate cases per utility 0.17 0.25 8. Comprehensive audits per 0.06 0.16 utility 9. Comprehensive audits 1.19 3.22 private utilities 10. Audits per utility 0.50 2.44 11. Congressional voting 49.65 20.71 record/10 12. Environmental 9.07 23.03 membership/1000

Note:

All correlations greater than 0.11 are sig. at 0.05 level.

Constructing entrepreneurial opportunity

111

Table 5.2
Variable

GEE model predicting state-avoided costs


Avoided cost Model 1 Model 2 24.485 (48.746) 0.000 (0.000) 0.928** (0.287) 0.004 (0.020) 0.111 (0.082) 0.080 (0.640) 0.334 (1.615) 0.024 (0.067) 0.017 (0.046) 0.021** (0.007) 0.634* (0.255) 9.164** (2.684) 24.45
0.05; **p 0.01. Standard errors are in parentheses.

Control variables GSP per capita Class 3 & 4 wind availability State population (ln) Change in GSP Net electricity imports Rate cases per utility Comprehensive audits per utility Comprehensive audits private utilities Audits per utility Congressional voting record/10 Independent variable Environmental membership/1000 Constant Chi squared statistic
Note: p 0.10; *p

27.135 (47.371) 0.000* (0.000) 0.429* (0.174) 0.004 (0.017) 0.098 (0.078) 0.248 (0.588) 0.549 (1.429) 0.054 (0.057) 0.007 (0.044) 0.021** (0.007)

11.367** (3.074) 34.58

the avoided cost in a given state. The availability of windy land is signicant and negatively correlated with state-avoided costs. This is unusual because one would expect that state governments would create legal structures that take advantage of local natural resources. Instead, we nd the opposite to be true: regulators are less likely to try and use incentives to motivate wind power entrepreneurship in locations with substantial endowments of windy land. This suggests that state governments use incentives to compensate for shortages of natural resources in areas where constituents value wind power. We also nd that states with smaller populations and states

112

Industrial dynamics

with congressional representatives who have a history of voting in favor of environmentally friendly energy policies are also more likely to have higher avoided costs. The results in Table 5.2 support our hypothesis; environmental group membership positively and signicantly predicts avoided costs. An increase in Sierra Club membership of 1000 increases the size of a states avoided costs by 0.63 cents per kWh.

6.

DISCUSSION AND CONCLUSION

In this chapter, we have shown how regional dierences in social movement organization membership impacted the creation of supportive regulatory environments for renewable energy entrepreneurs. Prior to 1978, electric utilities dominated the production and distribution of electricity in the US. These organizations enjoyed regional monopolies and local legal structures that had evolved over four decades to accommodate the needs and interests of this organizational form. Thus, state legal structures were highly attuned to incumbent utilities and did not support other organizational forms such as independent power. For example, the retail price utilities charged customers for electricity was regulated and determined by public utilities commissions on a cost-plus basis which was dened as a utilitys cost of generation plus a fair prot. However, states did not have a procedure for determining the wholesale price of renewable electricity generated by independent power plants, leaving it up to utilities to determine whether and at what price to purchase independent power. Moreover, the existing regulatory structure supported coal, natural gas and oil production through a variety of tax incentives and permitting systems. A similar supportive regulatory infrastructure did not exist for independent power companies using RETs. Transforming these regional regulatory environments to support a new organizational form (independent power generators using RET) was a necessary condition for entrepreneurial activity in this sector. Environmental movement organizations paved the way for the emergence of independent power using RETs by framing energy generation as not only an economic decision, but also a moral one. Environmental movement organizations promulgated this frame via their regional chapters. These chapters mobilized local members to promote renewable energy and directly engaged local constituents via educational programs, public relations and direct lobbying of state governments. By the early 1980s, over half of the more than 100000 members of the Sierra Club were dedicating some time each week to supporting this agenda. In regions where the Sierra Club had a sizeable membership, political landscapes that favored incumbent utilities

Constructing entrepreneurial opportunity

113

and their non-renewable technologies were transformed to support independent power producers using RETs. Our data demonstrate that much of the impact of national environmental organizations was quintessentially local. Although the public relations arms of the national organizations promulgated these new frames via the media nationwide, states support for these new organizational forms varied substantially. States with large and active Sierra Club or UCS chapters were signicantly more likely to dene avoided costs in such a way as to create opportunities for entrepreneurs using renewable energy technologies. Based on these ndings, this chapter contributes to existing theory in four ways. First, unlike past work on industry emergence that treats regulatory structures as xed and immutable environmental attributes (Russo, 2001), we view regulatory structures as socially constructed and dynamic (Edelman, 1990). We apply a co-evolutionary perspective on technical change, markets and institutions (Nelson, 1995). Regulation tends to foster inertia and path dependency and generally reects and supports the interests and goals of dominant organizational forms (Fligstein, 1996, 2001). As such, dominant organizational forms defend and seek to preserve these favorable regulations. Consequently, such regulatory structures are dicult and expensive to change and because no single rm possesses the necessary resource base and scope to precipitate such substantive regulatory change, collective action is necessary. Regions with a strong presence of collective actors supportive of new categories of economic activity are more likely to see regulatory change that favors these new sectors. Building on research from the institutional tradition (Schneiberg and Bartley, 2001; Scott, 2001), our study shows that regulatory environments that supported renewable energy were more likely in regions with large environmental organization memberships such as the Sierra Club and the UCS. It is important to note that environmental groups did not endorse renewable energy because of its apparent economic eciency. Nor was the emergence of RETs an instance of an inevitable outcome of technological change. Rather, environmental groups advocated RETs because they had a more benign eect on the environment a critical externality that the regulatory environment at that time did not take into account. These social movement organizations worked to create a set of rules and incentives that supported technical solutions aligned with ideologically-driven preferences for renewable energy and conservation. Second, our work advances an institutional approach to economic geography using an evolutionary perspective (Thrift and Olds, 1996; Crang, 1997; Martin, 2000; Sine and Lee, 2006). Storper and Walker note that socio-institutional structure is an essential underpinning of ecient capitalist production (1989: 5). Institutional theorists likewise contend that

114

Industrial dynamics

economic activity is socially and institutionally situated and embedded in social and political structures (DiMaggio and Powell, 1983; Granovetter and Swedberg, 1992; Scott, 2001). The primary intent of an institutionalist approach to economic geography is to understand to what extent and through which means are the processes of geographically uneven capitalist economic development shaped and mediated by institutional structures (Martin, 2000: 79). However, anecdotal evidence and theorizing have not specied how supportive regulatory structure emerges at the regional and local level and what precise role it plays in regional economic development (ibid.: 88). By bringing the theoretical lens of social movements to bear on the question of spatial variation of economic opportunity, we provide new analytical leverage to these questions. Our research suggests the importance of considering how pre-existing regional dierences in non-economic sectors can shape economic outcomes. In the case study presented in this chapter, social movements promulgated particular norms and values also constructed the cultural and regulatory infrastructure for entrepreneurs using RET. Third, we contribute to social movement literature by emphasizing the important local eects that movements have on regional economies. While past research on social movements has demonstrated how ideas diuse across regions, there has been little research on how movements change local environments to foster new economic activity (but, see Schneiberg and Soule, 2005). For example, research has demonstrated how social movements such as the temperance movement grew and eventually inuenced the ability of organizations to sell alcohol (Sandell, 2001), but we know little about how these activities inuenced the rise of other sectors such as carbonated soda at the local level. Giugni (1999) has called for more empirical research that examines the relationship between social movements and social change by considering how the outcomes of social movements vary across dierent contexts. By emphasizing regional dierences in social movement activity and its impact on the transformation of regulatory environments, this research provides evidence of the causal link between regional social movement activity and social and economic change. Finally, this case study demonstrates how existing mobilizing structures of social movement organizations can be leveraged to eectively advance new social agendas. In less than 10 years, environmental organizations eectively mobilized their members to help spread an obscure set of ideas about energy generation technologies throughout the US and embed it in both national and regional regulatory structures. It is precisely the ability of environmental organizations to redirect and broaden mobilizing eorts to include advocating RET through its organizational structure and preexisting repertoires of action that led to these dramatic regulatory changes

Constructing entrepreneurial opportunity

115

in such a short period of time. We nd that years of promoting the protection of the environment led to the unanticipated consequence of a constituency ready to support renewable energy generation technologies. Once the national organization made the connection between environmental values and methods of energy generation, local chapters went to work creating fecund environments for this type of commercial enterprise.

NOTES
* 1. This research was supported by the Initiative for Future Agriculture and Food Systems Grant no. 2001-52104-11484 from the USDA Cooperative State Research, Education, and Extension Service. The uncertainty of the economic rationale of RETs in the 1980s is further illustrated by the fact that during our study the cost of power generation using RETs was always signicantly higher than that of conventional technology, and many experts predicted that this would not change for decades. Because the sun drives global climatic systems, energy derived from the sun includes solar thermal, photovoltaic, wind, biomass, ocean thermal energy conversion, tidal power, wave power, ocean current, and salinity gradient energy systems (UCS, 1980). A solar economy refers to an economic system in which all energy is generated using renewable energy sources. These data were obtained from the League of Conservation Voters which annually tracks the voting records of individual members of Congress on environmental-related legislation. We narrowed the counts to legislation strictly related to energy production.

2. 3. 4.

REFERENCES
Allison, P. (1999), Multiple Regression: A Primer, Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage. Almeida, P. and B. Kogut (1999), Localization of knowledge and the mobility of engineers in regional networks, Management Science, 45: 90517. Arrow, K.J. (1962), The economic implications of learning by doing, Review of Economic Studies, 29: 15573. Benford, R.D. and D.A. Snow (2000), Framing processes and social movements: an overview and assessment, Annual Review of Sociology, 26: 61139. Billings, L. (1971), Sierra Club 1970: New chapters, groups, growth and change , Sierra Club Bulletin, 2022. Chandler, A.D. (1990), Scale and Scope: The Dynamics of Industrial Capitalism, Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press. Chatterjee, S. and B. Price (1991), Regression Analysis by Example, New York: John Wiley & Sons. Coan, G. and C. Pope (1980), Energy 1979 what happened and why, Sierra, January/February, 1113, 47. Cohen, M.D., J.G. March and J.P. Olsen (1972), A garbage can model of organizational choice, Administrative Science Quarterly, 17: 125. Coombs, D. (1972), The club looks at itself, Sierra Club Bulletin, July/August, 359. Crang, P. (1997), Cultural turns and the reconstitution of the economic, in R. Lee and J. Wills (eds), Geographies of Economies, London: Arnold, pp. 315.

116

Industrial dynamics

David, R.J., W.D. Sine and H.A. Haveman (2005), Exploiting institutional change: entrepreneurship in the legitimation of new organizational forms, Paper presented at the Administrative Sciences Association of Canada Annual Meetings, Toronto, 2831 May. Davis, G.F. and D. McAdam (2000), Corporations, classes, and social movements, in B.M. Staw and R.I. Sutton (eds), Research in Organizational Behavior, Vol. 22, New York: Elsevier, pp. 193236. Davis, G.F., D. McAdam, W.R Scott and M.N. Zald (2005), Social Movements and Organization Theory, Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press. Davis, G.F. and T.A. Thompson (1994), A social movement perspective on corporate control, Administrative Science Quarterly, 39: 14173. DiMaggio, P.J. and W.W. Powell (1983), The iron cage revisited: institutional isomorphism and collective rationality in organizational elds, American Sociological Review, 48: 14760. Dobbin, F. (1994), Forging Industrial Policy: The United States, Britain, and France in the Railway Age, Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press. Dobbin, F. and T.J. Dowd (1997), How policy shapes competition: early railroad foundings in Massachusetts, Administrative Science Quarterly, 42: 50129. Eckhardt, J. and S. Shane (2003), Opportunities and entrepreneurship, Journal of Management, 29: 33349. Edelman, L.B. (1990), Legal environments and organizational governance: the expansion of due process in the American workplace, American Journal of Sociology, 95: 140140. Edelman, L.B., C. Uggen and H. Erlanger (1999), The endogeneity of legal regulation: grievance procedures as rational myth, American Journal of Sociology, 105: 40654. Fenn, S. (1984), Americas Electric Utilities: Under Siege and in Transition, New York: Praeger. Fligstein, N. (1996), Markets as politics: a politicalcultural approach to market institutions, American Sociological Review, 61: 65673. Fligstein, N. (2001), The Architecture of Markets: An Economic Sociology of Twentyrst Century Capitalist Societies, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Fligstein, N. and A. Stone Sweet (2002), Constructing polities and markets: an institutionalist account of European integration, American Journal of Sociology, 107: 120645. Friedland, R. and R. Alford (1991), Bringing society back in: symbols, practices, and institutional contradictions, in W.W. Powell and P.J. DiMaggio (eds), The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 31136. Garud, R. and A.H. Van de Ven (1989), Innovation and the emergence of industries, in A.H. Van de Ven, H. Angle and M.S. Poole (eds), Research on the Management of Innovations, Cambridge, MA: Ballinger, pp. 489532. Gerhards, J. and D. Rucht (1992), Mesomobilization: organizing and framing in two protest campaigns in West Germany, American Journal of Sociology, 98: 55595. Giugni, M.G. (1998), Was it worth the eort? The outcomes and consequences of social movements, Annual Review of Sociology, 98: 37193. Giugni, M.G. (1999), How social movements matter: past research, present problems, future developments, in M.G. Giugni, D. McAdam and C. Tilly (eds), How Social Movements Matter, Minneapolis, MN: University of Minnesota Press, pp. xiiixxxiii.

Constructing entrepreneurial opportunity

117

Granovetter, M. and R. Swedberg (1992), The Sociology of Economic Life, Boulder, CO: Westview Press. Greve, H.R. (1995), Jumping ship: The diusion of strategy abandonment, Administrative Science Quarterly, 40: 44473. Hargrave, T.J. and A.H. Van de Ven (Forthcoming), A collective action model of institutional innovation, Academy of Management Review. Harris, C.D. (1954), The market as a factor in the location of industry in the United States, Annals, Association of American Geographers, 44: 31548. Hirsh, R. (1999), Power Loss: The Origins of Deregulation and Restructuring in the American Electric Utility System, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Homan, A.J. (1999), Institutional evolution and change: environmentalism and the US chemical industry, Academy of Management Journal, 42: 35172. Ingram, P. and H. Rao (2004), Store wars: the enactment and repeal of anti-chainstore legislation in America, American Journal of Sociology, 110: 44687. Jae, A.B., M. Trajtenberg and R. Henderson (1993), Geographic localization of knowledge spillovers as evidenced by patent citations, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108: 57798. Laird, F. (2001), Solar Energy, Technology Policy, and Institutional Values, Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press. Leblebici, H., G.R. Salancik, A. Copay and T. King (1991), Institutional change and the transformation of interorganizational elds: an organizational history of the U.S. radio broadcasting industry, Administrative Science Quarterly, 36: 33363. Lee, B.H. and M.D. Lounsbury (2005), Instituting industry governance: the organizational and legal bases of U.S. national organic food standards, Paper presented at the American Sociological Association annual meeting, Philadelphia, 1316 August. Lomi, A. (1995), The population ecology of organizational founding: location dependence and unobserved heterogeneity, Administrative Science Quarterly, 40: 11144. Lounsbury, M.D. and M. Ventresca (2002), Social structure and organizations revisited, in M.D. Lounsbury and M.J. Ventresca (eds), Research in the Sociology of Organizations, Vol. 19, New York: JAI/Elsevier, pp. 336. Lounsbury, M.D., M. Ventresca and P. Hirsch (2003), Social movements, eld frames and industry emergence: a culturalpolitical perspective on U.S. recycling, Socio-Economic Review, 1: 71104. Lovins, A.B. (1976), Energy strategy: The road not taken?, Foreign Aairs, 55: 6596. Lovins, A.B. and L.H. Lovins (1974), Energy solutions abound: just look around!, Business and Society Review, 82: 2631. Marshall, A. (1922), Principles of Economics, London: Macmillan. Martin, R. (2000), Institutional approaches in economic geography, in E. Sheppard and T.J. Barnes (eds), A Companion to Economic Geography, Malden, MA: Blackwell, pp. 7794. McAdam, D. (1996), Introduction: opportunities mobilizing structures and framing processes, in D. McAdam, J.D. McCarthy and M.N. Zald (eds), Comparative Perspectives on Social Movements: Political Opportunities, Mobilizing Structures, and Cultural Framings, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 2340. McCarthy, J.D. (1996), Constraints and opportunities in adopting, adapting, and inventing, in D. McAdam, J.D. McCarthy and M.N. Zald (eds), Comparative

118

Industrial dynamics

Perspectives on Social Movements: Political Opportunities, Mobilizing Structures, and Cultural Framings, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 14151. McCarthy, J.D. and M.N. Zald (1977), Resource mobilization and social movements: a partial theory, American Journal of Sociology, 82: 121241. McClelland, D.C. (1961), The Achieving Society, Princeton, NJ: Van Nostrand. McCloskey, M. (1992), Twenty years of change in the environmental movement: an insiders view, in R.E. Dunlap and A.G. Mertig (eds), American Environmentalism, Philadelphia, PA: Taylor & Francis, pp. 7788. McLaughlin, P. and M. Khawaja (2000), The organizational dynamics of the U.S. environmental movement: legitimation, resource mobilization, and political opportunity, Rural Sociology, 65: 42239. Meyer, A.D. (1982), Adapting to environmental jolts, Administrative Science Quarterly, 27: 51537. Mezias, S.J. and M. Scarselletta (1994), Resolving nancial reporting problems: an institutional analysis of the process, Administrative Science Quarterly, 39: 65478. National Audubon Society (1984), The Audubon Energy Plan, New York: National Audubon Society. Nelson, R.R. (1995), Co-evolution of industry structure, technology and supporting institutions, and the making of comparative advantage, International Journal of the Economics of Business, 2: 17184. Perrow, C. (1986), Complex Organizations: A Critical Essay, New York: Random House. Perrow, C. (2002), Organizing America: Wealth, Power, and the Origins of Corporate Capitalism, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Piore, M.J. and C.F. Sabel (1984), The Second Industrial Divide: Possibilities for Prosperity, New York: Basic Books. Rao, H. (2004), Institutional activism in the early American auto industry, Journal of Business Venturing, 19: 35984. Rao, H., C. Morrill and M.N. Zald (2000), Power plays: social movements, collective action and new organizational forms, in B.M. Staw and R.I. Sutton (eds), Research in Organizational Behavior, Vol. 22, New York: Elsevier, pp. 23982. Romanelli, E. and C. Schoonhoven (2001), The local origins of new rms, in C. Schoonhoven and E. Romanelli (eds), The Entrepreneurship Dynamic: Origins of Entrepreneurship and the Evolution of Industries, Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, pp. 4067. Romer, P.M. (1986), Increasing returns and long-run growth, Journal of Political Economy, 94: 100237. Russo, M.V. (2001), Institutions, exchange relationships, and the emergence of new elds: regulatory policies and independent power production in America, 19781992, Administrative Science Quarterly, 46: 5786. Sandell, R. (2001), Organizational growth and ecological constraints: the growth of social movements in Sweden, 1881 to 1940, American Sociological Review, 66: 67293. Schneiberg, M. (2002), Organizational heterogeneity and the production of new forms: politics, social movements and mutual companies in American re insurance, 19001930, in M.D. Lounsbury and M.J. Ventresca (eds), Research in the Sociology of Organizations, Vol.19, Oxford: JAI, pp. 3989. Schneiberg, M. and T. Bartley (2001), Regulating American industries: markets, politics, and the institutional determinants of re insurance regulation, American Journal of Sociology, 107: 10146.

Constructing entrepreneurial opportunity

119

Schneiberg, M. and S. Soule (2005), Institutionalization as a contested, multilevel process: the case of rate regulation in American re insurance, in G. Davis, D. McAdam, W.R. Scott and M. Zald (eds), Social Movements and Organization Theory, Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press, pp. 12260. Schumpeter, J.A. (1934), The Theory of Economic Development: An Inquiry into Prots, Capital, Credit, Interest, and the Business Cycle, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Scott, W.R. (2001), Institutions and Organizations, Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage. Sine, W.D. and R. David (2003), Environmental jolts, institutional change, and the creation of entrepreneurial opportunity in the U.S. electric power industry, Research Policy, 32: 185207. Sine, W.D. and B.H. Lee (2006), The winds of change: antecedents of entrepreneurial activity in the emerging wind power industry, Working paper, Cornell University. Snow, D.A. and R.D. Benford (1988), Ideology, frame resonance, and participant mobilization, in B. Klandermans, H. Kriesi and S. Tarrow (eds), From Structure to Action: Social Movement Participation Across Cultures, Greenwich, CT: JAI Press, pp. 197217. Snow, D.A., E.B. Rochford, S.K. Worden and R.D. Benford (1986), Frame alignment processes, micromobilization, and movement participation, American Sociological Review, 51: 46481. Snyder, T.A. (1979), Our energy future a time to choose, Sierra, September/ October: 45. Sorenson, O. and P.G. Audia (2000), The social structure of entrepreneurial activity: geographic concentration of footwear production in the United States, 19401989, American Journal of Sociology, 106: 42461. Stern, R.N. and S.R. Barley (1996), Organizations and social systems: organization theorys neglected mandate, Administrative Science Quarterly, 41: 14662. Stinchcombe, A. (1965), Social structure and organizations, in J. March (ed.), Handbook of Organizations, Chicago: Rand McNally, pp. 14293. Storper, M. and R. Walker (1989), The Capitalist Imperative: Territory, Technology, and Industrial Growth, Oxford: Blackwell. Strang, D. and E. Bradburn (2001), Theorizing legitimacy or legitimating theory? Neoliberal discourse and HMO policy, 197089, in J.L. Campbell and O. Pedersen (eds), The Rise of Neoliberalism and Institutional Analysis, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, pp. 12958. Stuart, T. and O. Sorenson (2003), Liquidity events and the geographic distribution of entrepreneurial activity, Administrative Science Quarterly, 48: 175201. Suchman, M.C. (1995), Managing legitimacy: strategic and institutional approaches, Academy of Management Review, 20(3): 571610. Suchman, M.C., D.J. Steward and C.A. Westfall (2001), The legal environment of entrepreneurship: observations on the legitimation of venture nance in Silicon Valley, in C. Schoonhoven and E. Romanelli (eds), The Entrepreneurship Dynamic: Origins of Entrepreneurship and the Evolution of Industries, Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, pp. 34982. Swaminathan, A. and J.B. Wade (2001), Social movement theory and the evolution of new organizational forms, in C. Schoonhoven and E. Romanelli (eds), The Entrepreneurship Dynamic: Origins of Entrepreneurship and the Evolution of Industries, Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, pp. 286313.

120

Industrial dynamics

Thornton, P. (1999), The sociology of entrepreneurship, Annual Review of Sociology, 25: 1946. Thrift, N. and K. Olds (1996), Reguring the economic in economic geography, Progress in Human Geography, 20: 31137. Tilly, C. (1978), From Mobilization to Revolution, Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley. Tushman, M.L. and P. Anderson (1986), Technological discontinuities and organizational environments, Administrative Science Quarterly, 31: 43965. Union of Concerned Scientists (UCS) (1980), Energy Strategies Toward a Solar Future: A Report of the Union of Concerned Scientists, Cambridge, MA: Ballinger. United States Department of Energy (2001), Annual Energy Report, US DOE website, www.eia.gov, September. Utrup, K.A. (1979), How Sierra Club members see environmental issues, Sierra, March/April: 1418. Wade, J.B., A. Swaminathan and M.S. Saxon (1998), Normative and resource ow consequences of local regulations in the American brewing industry, 18451918, Administrative Science Quarterly, 43: 90535. Weber, A. ([1909] 1928), Theory of the Location of Industries, translated by C.J. Friedrich, Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Weber, M. (1978), Economy and Society: An Interpretive Sociology, New York: Bedminister Press. Weick, K.E. (1995), Sensemaking in Organizations, Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage. Zucker, L., M. Darby and M. Brewer (1998), Intellectual human capital and the birth of U.S. biotechnology enterprises, American Economic Review, 88: 290306.

6. Absorptive capacity and foreign spillovers: a stochastic frontier approach


Jojo Jacob and Bart Los*
1. INTRODUCTION

In the literature on economic growth in developing countries, international technology ows have gained growing attention. International technology can ow from the originating country to the receiving country in several ways. Among them, foreign direct investment (FDI) and trade in intermediate inputs have been the subject of a great deal of empirical work. Most studies choose rms or plants as units of analysis and adopt a neoclassical production function framework, in which the average response of the endogenous productivity variable to a change in one of the exogenous variables (such as the intensity of FDI and trade in intermediate inputs) is estimated by means of classical regression analysis. Although econometric scrutiny does not always conrm strong anecdotal evidence, the majority of studies do nd signicant positive impacts of international ows.1 Most studies adopt an approach based on production functions, often by means of panel data regressions. One of the most prominent disadvantages is the impossibility of obtaining an understanding of the causes of observed heterogeneity. Rather, the focus of these studies is on representative behaviour (or, average behaviour). Deviations from this behaviour are merely seen as realisations of a random noise process. If, for example, productivity performances show an increasing variance over time, the production function approach does not yield any insights, as the eect is just an increase in the variance of the stochastic random noise process. In this chapter, we borrow an interesting alternative approach from a subeld in econometrics called stochastic frontier analysis (SFA) to study labour productivity growth in Indonesian plants.2 Typical techniques belonging to this subeld do not estimate average relationships between variables, but relationships for best-practice plants. Furthermore, they enable researchers to use plant characteristics as potential explanations of
121

122

Industrial dynamics

the extent to which other plants performances fall below best practice. In the context of our chapter, this implies that we shall estimate relationships between inputs (capital, labour) and output (value added) for best-practice rms for several years, to get indications of the degree to which international technology spillovers aected productivity growth. Simultaneously, we shall link the underperformance of other rms to variables that relate to the evolutionary concept of absorptive capacity (Cohen and Levinthal, 1990), such as labour quality, presence and strength of links to foreign markets, ownership, experience and so on. The results are quantications of the failure to fully assimilate international technology spillovers, and thereby to raise productivity to its potential level.3 The organisation of the chapter is as follows. In Section 2, we shall briey review some theories of productivity growth that are relevant for our empirical approach. Section 3 proposes our methodology. It deals with the appropriate technology accounting framework and discusses the way in which frontiers and distances to these frontiers are estimated. Section 4 is devoted to data issues. Special attention will be paid to the procedures we adopted to clean the dataset. In Section 5, we shall present our results. Section 6 concludes and proposes a few directions for future research.

2. SELECTED THEORIES ABOUT PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH


Convergence (or its absence) of labour productivity levels has attracted a lot of attention, both from economic theorists and from more empirically oriented scholars. Although it is hard to classify theories in a eld characterised by synthesis and hybridisation, roughly two categories of theories can be discerned. We follow Nelson and Pack (1999) in using the labels accumulation and assimilation theories. Accumulation theories basically assume that raising capital intensities (be it physical capital or human capital) automatically leads to labour productivity growth, although increasingly more investment is required for a given productivity gain. In this view, labour productivity growth is governed by movements along the production function of a given country, sector or rm under consideration. This perspective implies that accumulation of capital is the cause for growth in labour productivity. Assimilation theories challenge this view. Here, technology is seen as something that does not automatically and immediately ow across rms or countries. Instead, only rms or countries that have invested suciently in their absorptive capacities will be able to turn innovations developed elsewhere into productivity gains for themselves. In the view of assimilationists,

Absorptive capacity and foreign spillovers

123

policies to stimulate entrepreneurship and eagerness to learn have been much more important. Such a view on macroeceonomic performance can, with relatively minor modications, be transferred to studies at rm or plant level. The resource-based view of the rm (see Teece, 2000, for example) stresses that long-run rm performance is mainly determined by learning capabilities. In this chapter, we shall dierentiate between two barriers to attaining productivity levels attained by better-performing plants. The rst type of barrier relates most strongly to issues mentioned above. Pack (1987) and Van Dijk (2005, Ch. 8) show that plants that are similar in terms of the types of machines installed attain widely varying productivity levels.4 Apparently, learning and organisational capabilities are not identically distributed across plants, which shows up in dierent productivity gures for plants with more or less identical equipment installed. The second type of barrier is quite closely associated with what Abramovitz (1989) labelled technological incongruence. A similar idea has recently been proposed in the form of a formal model by Basu and Weil (1998). They dened technologies as particular combinations of inputs, or, in other words, capitallabour ratios. New knowledge is only appropriate for a range of such technologies. Firms or countries will in the short run only be permitted to benet from innovations if these relate to technologies that are comparable to the ones operated.5 In the longer run, non-appropriate innovations can become appropriate if the rm or country invests to such an extent that it shifts its technology to a capital intensity level comparable to the innovating rm or country.6 The predictions concerning convergence and divergence of productivity levels that follow from the Basu and Weil model are based on the assumption that more capital-intensive technologies allow producers to attain higher maximum levels of labour productivity. Los and Timmer (2005) showed that both types of barriers to catch-up play an important role in the empirics of macroeconomic growth. We adopt several parts of their methodology to investigate how innovations, changes in absorptive capacity and technologies operated contribute to the productivity growth experiences at the plant level in Indonesias manufacturing sector.

3.

METHODOLOGY

In this section, we shall describe the empirical methodology we use. First, we shall outline how we decompose labour productivity growth (or decline) of a plant into the eects of innovation, assimilation and equipment

124

Industrial dynamics

upgrading which creates potential for spillovers. Next, we shall discuss the estimation methods required to arrive at quantications of these eects. In the third subsection, we shall describe the empirical model. Identifying the Sources of Growth Los and Timmer (2005) decomposed labour productivity growths rates of a group of countries, between 1970 and 1990, into the eects of movements towards the frontier, or changes in technical eciency (assimilation), movements of the frontier (innovation), and capital deepening (creating potential). The decomposition form itself was popularised by Kumar and Russell (2002), but Los and Timmer were the rst to link their results to the theories discussed in the previous section. Our approach starts from a similar perspective. It is novel in the sense that it explicitly relates the decomposition results to observable characteristics of the plants. Figure 6.1 shows a plants actual labour productivity levels y0 and y1, in an industry with production frontiers f 0 and f 1, for periods 0 and 1, respectively. The labour productivity change (y1/y0) of this plant can be decomposed in the following way: y1 y0 or (1 yT ) (1 yA ) (1 yC ) (1 yI ). (6.2) yc yd y1 ya yd y0 ya yb
0.5

y y yb yd a c

0.5

(6.1)

In the rst term on the right-hand side (1 yA ) , a value of yA larger than 0 indicates that the plant under consideration has increased its labour productivity for the technology operated. In other words, it indicates that the plant has been able to bring about an increased exploitation of technological potential as compared to the maximum productivity observed for the equipment operated. We call this the assimilation eect.7 The second explanatory factor (1 yC ) indicates the changes in labour productivity due to increases in capital intensity alone. While a higher capital intensity in itself does not generate higher labour productivity, it can lead to an upward shift in the attainable or the target productivity levels, depending on the slope of the frontier. Therefore, a value greater than 0 for yC can be interpreted as creating potential. The third factor (1 yI ) points to the eect of localised technological change that results in the upward shift of the production frontier. Assuming that the plants capital intensity remains

Absorptive capacity and foreign spillovers

125

Y/L

yd yb

F(1)

yc ya y1 y0 * (1)

F(0)

* (0)

C/L

Figure 6.1

Labour productivity growth decomposition

constant, a positive value for yI indicates that it has beneted from an increase in the maximum attainable labour productivity levels for the given technologies. We call this the innovation eect. Los and Timmer (2005) estimated the productivity frontiers for the beginning and end periods using data envelopment analysis (DEA). We follow a similar approach, but with the key dierence that we derive the frontier labour productivity levels by means of stochastic frontier analysis (SFA). This change of method has advantages and drawbacks. The major drawback is that truly localised innovation cannot be modelled, as the estimated elasticity of foreign research and development (R&D) spillovers (the source of technological change) is the same across the full range of technologies. As a result, the shifts in the frontier labour productivity levels always amount to an identical proportional growth rate

126

Industrial dynamics

across the full range of technologies. The distance to the frontier, however, can well change, thereby allowing potentials for spillovers to change. The major advantage is that the location of the frontier is not very sensitive to measurement errors for a small number of rms. As is well known (see, for example, Coelli et al., 1998), DEA results can be distorted quite a bit. In view of the sizeable measurement and reporting errors that are often found in plant-level surveys, especially in developing countries, we feel that the net advantage of SFA as compared to DEA is clearly positive. Estimation Method In recent years, a number of studies have employed stochastic frontier estimations for estimating and explaining ineciencies of rms and plants in industries. Until recently, the standard approach was a two-stage estimation procedure, in which the production frontier is rst estimated. In the second stage, the resulting ineciencies (the vertical distances from the observed productivities to the estimated frontier) are regressed on rmspecic variables (see, for example, Pitt and Lee, 1981).8 Estimation in the second stage, however, contradicts the assumption of identically distributed ineciency eects that underlies the estimation of the stochastic frontier in the rst stage. To overcome this methodological problem, several authors have suggested single-stage procedures for simultaneously estimating both the stochastic frontier and ineciency functions. The Battese and Coelli (1995) model is one such approach. Consider the following production function for panel data: yit Xit
it,

(6.3)

where yit is the dependent variable corresponding to the ith plant and time t, X is a vector of explanatory variables, and it is the composite error term. It consists of a white noise error vit: vit ~ iid N(0, 2 ) and uit. The two sets v of disturbances are assumed to be independent. The uits are non-negative random variables associated with technical ineciencies, and are assumed to be independently (but not identically) distributed as truncations (at zero) of the N( it, 2 ) distribution, with: u
it

Zit ,

(6.4)

in which Z is a vector of observable, non-stochastic explanatory variables associated with technical ineciency, and is a vector of unknown coecients.

Absorptive capacity and foreign spillovers

127

In this model, the maximum likelihood method is used for the simultaneous estimation of the parameters of the frontier and technical ineciency models, that is, estimation of the values of the unknown parameters s, s, u2 and v2. We computed the estimates using the FRONTIER software package (Coelli, 1996). Battese and Coelli (1995) also provide an expression for the conditional expectation of exp( uit) given eit. The maximum likelihood estimation of this function is used to estimate the technical eciency index of the ith rm at time t, based on expected values conditional on the observed values of the explanatory variables in X and Z. When the productivity frontier is expressed in logarithms, the technical eciency index (TEI) can be expressed as follows: TEIit exp( uit ). (6.5)

This index has a value between 0 and 1, with 0 (uit ) indicating the least ecient, and 1 (uit 0) the most ecient plants. Changes in TEI as dened in equation (6.5) denote a part of the actual shift in labour productivity. When a change in TEI causes an upward shift, as in Figure 6.1, it can be interpreted as associated with the assimilation of technology-specic knowledge. It is that part of the assimilation eect which can be explained by the changes in the indicators of absorptive capacity, given their estimated coecients from the SFA model. The remainder of the upward shift cannot be explained, and is calculated as the dierence between the actual growth in labour productivity and the predicted growth in labour productivity derived from the SFA model. The Empirical Model We begin with a production frontier of the CobbDouglas form, augmented to account for technological change. In most developing countries, and especially so in Indonesia, foreign technology is the key source of technological progress, because of the virtual absence of own technological eorts. We account for technology ows from abroad by constructing a measure of international R&D stock (IRD). The augmented production function is dened as follows: Yit AEitLitIRDt , (6.6)

where, Yit is value added of plant i at time t, E is total energy use (as a proxy for capital goods use, as further explained below), L is total number of workers, and IRD is the international R&D stock representing the technology ows available to all plants in the industry (see the following section

128

Industrial dynamics

for a fuller description of the variables). The variable IRD is interpreted to be the driver of shifts in the production frontier in a given industry. Dividing Y and E by L and taking logarithms, equation (6.6) becomes yit lit a (eit lit ) IRDt
it,

(6.7)

where the lower-case symbols denote variables in logarithms. In the transformation of equation (6.6) to (6.7), we impose the assumption of constant returns to scale in the rival inputs labour and energy.9 We use equation (6.7) as the frontier function that will be estimated simultaneously with the ineciency function, based on the procedure described in the previous subsection. Given that technology-embodied inputs have often shown to be an important channel of foreign technology diusion, a plants access to imports might be a good proxy of its access to foreign technology. Access to a source of technology does not, however, imply that the acquisition of technology is guaranteed. This is because technology is not entirely codied, and indeed often takes a highly tacit form (Polanyi, 1958). Therefore, the extent to which a plant is able to absorb knowledge related to new technologies, also known as a plants absorptive capacity (Cohen and Levinthal, 1990), can depend on the quality of its labour force. Evenson and Westphal (1995) proxied this quality by the proportion of scientists and engineers in a plants workforce. The ownership structure of a plant can also be a signicant factor inuencing the capacity to assimilate knowledge. A plant with foreign management control might be expected to run more productively than, for example, a non-professional, family-controlled enterprise. The foreign connection may enable the former to adapt itself much more quickly than the latter to global changes in technology, production relations and so on. The performance of enterprises as compared to other enterprises with similar technologies may also depend on its size. As noted by Tybout (2000), in many developing countries, the demand for manufactured products is skewed towards simple items which can be eciently produced using cottage techniques. An opposite eect would be the operation of Schumpeterian dynamics that leads to greater learning eorts by large rms. This may result from scale economies, availability of internal resources in the presence of imperfect markets and/or uncertainties, synergies between technological, production, marketing and distribution activities, and so on. The empirical evidence, mostly pertaining to advanced economies, shows no consensus, however (see Marsili, 2001, for an overview). Another factor that may inuence technical eciency is the age of a plant. Experienced plants may enjoy the benets of learning by doing. As Klepper

Absorptive capacity and foreign spillovers

129

(2002) argues, with increases in competitive conditions rms with greater experience have greater leeway in enhancing their capabilities. Keeping these considerations in mind, we consider the following absorptive capacity variables for the mean ineciency model represented by equation (6.4): Zit: Accessit; LQualit; Foreignit; Agei; Sizeit, where, Access represents access to technology spillover, dened as the share of imported intermediate inputs in total intermediate inputs; LQual stands for the quality of labour at a plant, dened as the share of non-production (white-collar) workers in total employment; Foreign represents the proportion of foreign ownership in a plant; Age is measured as the dierence between the year of inception and the year of operation; and Size is dened as the logarithm of the total number of workers. A nal aspect to consider is the inuence on technical eciency of factors observable only to the managers of a plant, which are not reected in survey-based dataset like ours. As a result, such rm-specic eects (or heterogeneities) may be related to other regressors of the model, which may cause biased results. To overcome this problem, we adopt a specication that incorporates plant xed eects in the ineciency model.

4.

DATA ISSUES

Our analysis focuses on the manufacturing sector of a developing country, Indonesia. Our main data sources are two large plant-level datasets, backcast and Statistic Industri (SI), constructed by the Indonesian Bureau of Statistics (Badan Pusat Statistik, BPS) (see Appendix A of Jacob and Los, 2005, for a detailed description of the data sources, variables, cleaning processes and so on). The datasets cover all large and medium-sized plants in the manufacturing sector of the country, from 1975 to 2001.10 After applying cleaning procedures to account for duplications, reporting errors and data entry errors, we focus our analysis on industries dened at a low level of aggregation (5-digit classication). This allows us to investigate productivity for sets of plants with homogeneous activities. Since the panel data SFA approach is data intensive, we select 17 industries for which at least 10 plants are included in the data set (see Appendix Table 6A.1). The industries under investigation are quite diverse, which allows us to identify inter-industry dierences in the importance of absorptive capacity for productivity performance. Studies aiming at explaining total factor productivity (TFP) growth are often hindered by immeasurable uctuations in capacity utilisation.

130

Industrial dynamics

Although we do not study TFP growth but labour productivity growth, we encounter similar problems: Our technologies are dened by capital intensities, that is, ratios between a (quasi-) xed input and a much more variable input. We circumvent this problem by proxying a plants capital use by its energy consumption, about which much information is available in our dataset.11 This is also convenient from a practical point of view, since our data on energy use cover a much longer time span than those on investment on which we should base our capital stock estimates. As a determinant of labour quality, we do not have detailed information about skills in our database for a suciently long period. Therefore, we proxy dierences in skill level of labour force across plants by dierences in the share of non-production workers in the total workforce. Finally, we should describe how we estimate international R&D stocks that capture technology ows. Since Indonesian rms generally do not undertake any formal R&D activities themselves, it can safely be assumed that new technology must come from abroad (Hill, 1996). Our admittedly poor, but widely accepted assumption if suitable output indicators of innovation are not available, is that technology production is proportional to R&D expenditures. We have data on R&D expenditures by industry for 10 countries that together account for approximately 60 per cent of the imports to Indonesia and about 85 per cent of the total OECD R&D expenditure. The selection of this sample is justied because empirical evidence suggests that it is not the intensity of import per se that matters, but rather the distribution of the countries of origin. The more you import from highly R&D intensive countries, the larger the impact of foreign R&D (Lichtenberg and van Pottelsberghe de la Potterie, 1998, p. 1483). Apart from imports, technology purchase, technology collaboration and exports by Indonesian rms as well as foreign investment in the domestic market can all act as carriers of technology spillovers. To accommodate these dierent channels of technology ow, we do not weight foreign R&D stock by the volume of imports to Indonesia, which is a standard approach in the spillover literature. Instead, we consider solely the technological proximity between the foreign and domestic industries to weight the foreign R&D stock. The specic channels of foreign technology ows are introduced in the ineciency function. In the rst step, foreign R&D stock is weighted by an index of technological distance between the sector of origin and the sector of destination. We use a patent-based measure of technological distance between sectors derived by Verspagen (1997) from the EPO (European Patent Oce) data. In the second step, the resulting R&D stock is weighted by an index of technological congruence between sectors in the advanced economy and Indonesia that are comparable in terms of their classication code. This

Absorptive capacity and foreign spillovers

131

weight accounts for inter-country dierences between sectors. It captures the idea that an industry in a follower country benets more from the global pool of technology, the greater its technological congruence with industries in advanced countries. The resulting international R&D stock at the industry level can be expressed in terms of the following equation: IRDj (t) (RDckPkjScj )(t), (6.8)

c, k

where IRDj is the international R&D stock resulting from technology ows available to all plants in the Indonesian industry j; RDck is the R&D stock in sector k of partner country c; Pkj is an element of the patent information ow matrix P, and it captures the ow of sector ks R&D eorts to sector j; and Scj is the technological congruence between sector j of Indonesia and the same sector of its partner country c. Scj is derived by comparing the input coecient vectors for sector j in the two countries. It takes a value of 1 if sector j is perfectly similar in the two countries, and zero in the event of complete dissimilarity between them (see Appendix B of Jacob and Los, 2005). Given the fact that the R&D data we use are available only at a level of aggregation of 2, 3 and, in a few cases, 4-digit (ISIC Rev. 2), IRDj in the above equation corresponds to these levels. To generate IRD at the 5-digit level, we constructed similarity indices between the two sets of classications, using their respective input coecients vectors.

5.

RESULTS

Results for Frontier and Ineciency Estimation We begin by documenting some summary statistics of the variables used in the SFA model in 17 5-digit-industry, plant-level samples. Table 6.1a shows the means and standard deviations across plants of the levels of the variables. Table 6.1b shows similar statistics of the average annual growth rates of the variables. The highest average labour productivity level and growth rate is found for drugs (35222). The lowest average values for these two variables are found for tobacco (31410) and clay tiles (36422), respectively. The former industry is also found to have the lowest average energy intensity, while plywood (33113) has the highest. Plants in garments (32210) recorded the fastest average growth in energy intensity, while those in crumb rubber (35523) recorded the slowest growth. Plants in paints (35210) could benet from the biggest pool of relevant R&D done in foreign countries. The smallest pool is found for sawmills (33111). In other

Table 6.1a Summary statistics of 17 5-digit ISIC industries: levels


Egy/lab IRD Age Foreign Access Lqual Size

Industry (ISIC)

Plants

Val/lab

31171

22

31179

27

0.006 (0.027) 0.033 (0.134)

31410

15

31420 0.032 (0.151)

34

32114

68

132 0.032 (0.132) 0.065 (0.197) 0.045 (0.139)

32121

26

32130

20

32210

74

33111

13

33113

20

33211

17

34200

45

3.782 (4.925) 6.502 (6.495) 3.241 (3.521) 8.472 (8.500) 7.836 (7.151) 5.069 (2.867) 9.469 (5.964) 6.632 (6.830) 20.489 (12.767) 20.194 (8.183) 9.099 (4.172) 11.421 (8.181)

1.221 (1.026) 5.761 (5.073) 0.364 (0.661) 0.801 (0.983) 30.881 (32.014) 2.996 (2.109) 8.846 (6.301) 1.144 (1.248) 650.563 (600.405) 3928.307 (4241.68) 6.223 (4.811) 3.802 (5.118)

5.137 (0.000) 8.536 (0.000) 7.030 (0.000) 7.532 (0.000) 36.293 (0.000) 29.681 (0.000) 50.235 (0.000) 35.502 (0.000) 1.907 (0.000) 3.684 (0.000) 4.654 (0.000) 98.361 (0.000)

17.182 (7.624) 19.759 (15.421) 25.967 (10.542) 30.059 (14.033) 20.794 (9.159) 24.846 (12.699) 16.950 (9.202) 16.716 (10.996) 14.346 (5.757) 10.400 (3.144) 17.618 (10.588) 24.122 (16.939)

0.023 (0.044) 0.074 (0.165) 0.001 (0.004) 0.048 (0.105) 0.062 (0.136) 0.074 (0.144) 0.084 (0.214) 0.130 (0.199) 0.005 (0.016) 0.024 (0.035) 0.056 (0.081) 0.113 (0.133)

0.087 (0.069) 0.177 (0.160) 0.071 (0.063) 0.099 (0.065) 0.117 (0.070) 0.106 (0.067) 0.144 (0.083) 0.094 (0.066) 0.179 (0.071) 0.152 (0.060) 0.159 (0.060) 0.260 (0.121)

151.996 (160.860) 308.573 (407.210) 182.561 (120.635) 734.493 (984.163) 484.556 (550.715) 265.920 (260.919) 340.538 (350.749) 501.825 (680.247) 452.494 (577.791) 1445.056 (766.116) 319.110 (396.681) 169.704 (116.685)

35210

13

35222

46

35523

20

0.165 (0.262) 0.247 (0.349) 0.242 (0.430)

35606

29

133

36422

18

27.484 (30.403) 28.679 (22.037) 17.594 (16.738) 7.259 (5.550) 3.335 (1.675)

3.332 (3.062) 4.854 (5.229) 329.395 (243.739) 7.526 (5.669) 2.255 (1.673)

321.818 (0.000) 211.064 (0.000) 16.434 (0.000) 14.390 (0.000) 38.812 (0.000)

25.500 (17.239) 20.261 (10.031) 16.850 (3.843) 14.638 (4.998) 22.722 (15.973)

0.354 (0.233) 0.686 (0.243) 0.000 (0.000) 0.587 (0.242) 0.024 (0.069)

0.293 (0.153) 0.399 (0.195) 0.162 (0.067) 0.139 (0.058) 0.069 (0.071)

162.660 (104.254) 233.133 (133.355) 239.948 (85.367) 332.158 (400.633) 135.398 (73.559)

Notes: (i) Val/lab value added per employee; Egy/lab energy use per employee; Size number of employees; IRD international R&D stock in real 1990 purchasing power parity (PPP) US dollars (millions). Value added and energy are in thousands of real 1990 PPP US dollars. (ii) See main text for the denitions of the other variables. (iii) See Appendix Table 6A.1 for industry denitions. (iv) Means, standard deviations in brackets.

Table 6.1b Summary statistics of 17 5-digit ISIC industries: average annual growth rates
Val/lab 0.038* 0.044 (0.062) Egy/lab IRD Foreign Access Lqual Size

Industry (ISIC)

Plants

31171

22

31179

27

31410

15

0.271 (0.296) 0.102 (0.583) 4.327*

31420 0.025 (0.044)

34

32114

68

134 0.099 (0.164) 0.003 (0.005) 0.019 (0.027)

32121

26

32130

20

32210

74

33111

13

33113

20

33211

17

34200

45

0.191 (0.160) 0.209 (0.211) 0.409 (0.365) 0.195 (0.228) 0.262 (0.208) 0.219 (0.207) 0.366 (0.513) 0.286 (0.260) 0.314 (0.210) 0.196 (0.156) 0.263 (0.377) 0.214 (0.178) 0.232 (0.488) 0.218 (1.538) 0.236 (2.084) 0.088 (0.327) 0.469 (2.822) 0.735 (0.442) 0.920 (3.295) 1.033 (4.609) 0.010 (0.764)

0.243 (0.178) 0.304 (0.371) 0.550 (1.034) 0.978 (2.950) 0.208 (0.287) 0.270 (0.225) 0.195 (0.212) 2.417 (17.706) 0.179 (0.330) 0.326 (0.410) 0.128 (0.152) 0.274 (0.256)

0.056 (0.000) 0.056 (0.000) 0.056 (0.000) 0.056 (0.000) 0.028 (0.000) 0.028 (0.000) 0.028 (0.000) 0.028 (0.000) 0.032 (0.000) 0.032 (0.000) 0.032 (0.000) 0.047 (0.000)

0.062 (0.078) 0.100 (0.156) 0.108 (0.165) 0.401 (1.703) 0.069 (0.110) 0.114 (0.142) 0.090 (0.086) 0.175 (0.492) 0.108 (0.126) 0.202 (0.298) 0.037 (0.084) 0.089 (0.126)

0.043 (0.063) 0.066 (0.071) 0.067 (0.103) 0.030 (0.057) 0.051 (0.069) 0.051 (0.064) 0.077 (0.083) 0.074 (0.114) 0.051 (0.051) 0.108 (0.092) 0.120 (0.075) 0.034 (0.065)

35210

13

35222

46

35523

20

0.025 (0.026) 0.005 (0.036) 0.022 (0.039)

0.169 (0.882) 0.014 (0.304) 0.656*

135

35606

29

36422

18

0.233 (0.226) 0.432 (0.608) 0.314 (0.153) 0.268 (0.202) 0.174 (0.091) 0.157 (0.336) 0.212 (0.292)

0.350 (0.321) 0.247 (0.216) 0.100 (0.174) 0.310 (0.340) 0.233 (0.246)

0.039 (0.000) 0.061 (0.000) 0.030 (0.000) 0.030 (0.000) 0.019 (0.000)

0.058 (0.091) 0.039 (0.079) 0.069 (0.101) 0.066 (0.097) 0.117 (0.192)

0.047 (0.053) 0.042 (0.063) 0.016 (0.033) 0.108 (0.098) 0.038 (0.046)

Note:

* The growth rate of the variable under consideration is positive in only one observation. For other notes, see Table 6.1a.

136

Industrial dynamics

Table 6.2 Stochastic frontier estimates for 17 5-digit (ISIC Rev. 2) industriesa
Industry (ISIC Rev. 2) Constant Egy/lab IRD 31171 31179 31410 31420 32114 32121 32130 32210

5.132 11.661 (1.765)* (19.375) 0.121 0.111 (0.039)* (0.040)* 0.885 1.413 (0.114)* (0.225)*

Production function 5.484 3.450 27.665 (5.993) (0.998)* (5.495)* 0.047 0.056 0.169 (0.025)* (0.086) (0.029)* 0.244 0.852 1.050 (0.382) (0.089)* (0.314)*

33.378 54.907 38.426 (6.428)* (11.056)* (3.900)* 0.139 0.122 0.090 (0.037)* (0.053)* (0.022)* 1.403 2.543 1.626 (0.376)* (0.533)* (0.229)* 1.933 (1.286) 0.105 (0.232) 1.649 3.313 (1.373) (0.718)* 0.011 0.037 (0.201) (0.083) 0.630 (0.255)* 0.164 0.258 (0.485) (0.111)* 0.184 0.220 (0.685) (0.376) 0.194 0.061 (0.114)* (0.056) 0.206 0.342 (0.811) (0.447) 20 74 240 888

1.701 (0.406)* Age 0.251 (0.120)* Foreign 0.312 (0.293) Access 0.651 (0.330)* Lqual 0.688 (0.231)* Size 0.292 (0.093)* Gamma 0.126 (0.049)* Plants 22 Observations 264

Constant

(Mean) Ineciency function 3.924 3.049 0.220 4.296 (18.938) (1.132)* (0.972) (0.786)* 0.219 0.769 0.028 0.370 (0.144) (0.426)* (0.333) (0.180)* 1.409 4.408 (0.364)* (11.460) 0.049 7.028 0.311 0.039 (0.442) (4.324) (0.999) (0.149) 1.445 1.967 0.119 0.903 (0.338)* (1.499) (0.997) (0.356)* 0.261 0.535 1.097 0.119 (0.116)* (0.183)* (0.214)* (0.074) 0.601 0.765 0.542 0.492 (1.917) (0.107)* (0.220)* (0.537) 27 15 34 68 324 180 408 816

0.022 (0.179) 0.581 (0.496) 0.021 (0.100) 0.821 (0.082)* 26 312

Notes: a Standard errors are in parentheses; * signicant at 10%. (i) Egy/lab e/l. (ii) See main text for the denitions of the other variables. (iii) See Appendix Table 6A.1 for industry denitions.

variables too, dierences are noticeable. For example, the access-tospillover variable has a maximum average value of nearly 0.70 (drugs, 35222) and a minimum average value of less than 0.01 (crumb rubber, 35523). Foreign ownership is absent in eight of the 17 industries. Average foreign ownership grew fastest in garments (32210), while it declined in macaroni (31171) and crumb rubber (35523).12 Another noticeable feature in both Tables 6.1a and 6.1b is the high standard deviations reported for many of the variables across plants in the industries considered. Quite often, the standard deviation is larger than the mean value. This

Absorptive capacity and foreign spillovers

137

33111

33113

33211

34200

35210

35222

35523

35606

36422

1.746 (2.131) 0.043 (0.052) 0.869 (0.150)* 1.627 (0.691)* 0.048 (0.171) 0.860 (0.785) 0.623 (1.037) 0.020 (0.862) 0.410 (0.223)* 1.000 (0.000)* 13 156

14.732 (8.177)* 0.180 (0.039)* 0.466 (0.537) 1.607 (0.582)* 0.221 (0.227) 2.767 (3.456) 2.181 (2.197) 2.717 (1.055)* 0.039 (0.185) 0.442 (0.179)* 20 240

12.599 (1.025)* 0.062 (0.043) 1.391 (0.071)* 0.298 (0.818) 0.088 (0.240)

Production function 24.417 20.476 14.688 (1.031)* (4.554)* (1.464)* 0.072 0.122 0.006 (0.035)* (0.049)* (0.031) 0.818 1.580 1.332 (0.056)* (0.237)* (0.077)*

27.614 20.899 40.764 (4.848)* (1.521)* (15.799)* 0.147 0.165 0.144 (0.045)* (0.039)* (0.040)* 2.126 1.765 2.832 (0.288)* (0.090)* (0.850)* 0.360 (0.210)* 0.137 (0.026)* 0.111 (0.428) 0.153 (1.029) 0.456 (0.217)* 0.010 (0.127) 0.000 (0.000)* 20 240 1.520 3.564 (0.629)* (4.923) 0.304 0.505 (0.180)* (0.211)*

(Mean) Ineciency function 1.135 2.671 2.051 (0.426)* (1.360)* (0.600)* 0.117 0.200 0.305 (0.123) (0.260) (0.132)* 1.103 0.122 (0.422)* (0.391) 0.946 0.142 0.007 0.215 (0.947) (0.257) (0.228) (0.116)* 0.581 0.670 0.431 0.652 (1.202) (0.401)* (0.673) (0.342)* 0.240 0.088 0.499 0.477 (0.278) (0.085) (0.205)* (0.120)* 0.224 0.249 0.354 0.092 (0.128)* (0.044)* (0.095)* (0.021)* 17 45 13 46 204 540 156 552

0.119 (0.136) 1.713 (0.764)* 0.238 (0.143)* 0.096 (0.027)* 29 348

0.974 (0.418)* 0.696 (0.764) 0.319 (0.144)* 0.456 (0.875) 18 216

phenomenon reects the highly dual structure of the Indonesian manufacturing sector, described in detail by, among others, Hill (1996). Table 6.2 reports the SFA estimation results. For brevity, we do not report the estimation results for the plant dummies included in the ineciency function. The results for the frontier production function show that the coecients of both energy intensity, Egy/Lab, and the international R&D stock representing knowledge spillovers, IRD, have a positive sign in most industries. The estimated coecients of energy intensities for the slopes of the productivity frontiers are generally fairly small, however, and even statistically insignicant at the 10 per cent level for four industries. This implies that it does not pay o very much for plants just to invest more, as is suggested by advocates of accumulationist theories. Consequently, accumulation alone cannot be considered as an important source of productivity growth in Indonesian manufacturing.13

138

Industrial dynamics

The sensitivity of the frontier to increases in foreign R&D appears to be prominent. Apparently, the best-practice plants in Indonesia reaped substantial fruits from technological spillovers from abroad. The coecient for this variable was statistically signicant for 10 of the 17 industries studied, at the 10 per cent level. Our main interest lies in understanding the factors that cause deviations from the best-practice technology. The estimate for the variance parameter (Gamma in Table 6.2) that corresponds to the estimated share of the ineciency term in the variance of the composite error term has a positive sign in all industries, and is signicant in most industries (12 industries). This should be considered as evidence for the idea that ineciency eects contribute substantially to the variety of labour productivity levels indicated by positive standard deviations for this variable. A negative sign for the coecient of a variable indicates a negative impact of that variable on ineciency. Among all the variables, changes in labour quality (LQual) variable provide the most promising explanation for changes in comparison to best-practice performance. Its coecient has a negative sign in most industries (11 out of 17), and is statistically signicant in seven industries. Foreign ownership (Foreign) has a signicantly negative coecient only in three of the nine industries in which the shares held by foreign rms are positive in one or more establishments. For the remaining industries, changes in the degree of foreign ownership do not appear to matter for assimilation. It might well be that a linear specication of the ineciency eects is not most appropriate here. Explorations to use multiple-regime econometrics (to identify critical values of the degree of foreign ownership), however, are beyond the scope of this chapter, if only because such analyses have hardly been attempted in the SFA branch of econometrics. We argued before that access to spillover (Access) is likely to exert a major inuence on the technical eciency of plants. However, this variable yielded a negative coecient in only eight industries, with statistical signicance limited just to three industries. One reason for this result could be the narrowness of our measure of access to spillover as it does not consider the import of capital goods. Second, the import intensity of intermediate inputs use is rather low in most industries as may be required to generate sucient within-plant variations. An additional, and probably the most important, cause of very few signicant results is the huge measurement errors that characterise datasets like ours. Although, we did clean the data extensively, it is unlikely that this has removed all measurement errors. The Age variable demonstrated a favourable impact on assimilation in a majority of the industries. A negative sign for its coecient in 11 out of a total number of 17 industries appear to suggest that a plants ability to

Absorptive capacity and foreign spillovers

139

assimilate knowledge spillovers from similar best-practice plants increases with its experience. As argued by Klepper (2002), under competitive pressures, rms with greater experience are better positioned to enhance their capabilities. Our period of analysis covers the export-oriented phase hence, the more competitive phase of industrialisation in Indonesia. We may therefore conclude that rms which have been in operation for a longer period of time have been more successful in enhancing their technological and managerial capabilities, and therefore in meeting the challenges of increased competition. The nal variable to be discussed is Size, which displays considerable inter-industry variations in its inuence. It had an adverse impact on assimilation in a majority of the industries (a positive coecient in 11, with statistical signicance in ve industries). Of the six remaining industries where its inuence has been favourable, in ve cases the coecients displayed statistical signicance. The discussion so far has revealed that changes in deviations from best practice (due to plant-specic factors) are a signicant determinant of a plants labour productivity growth. In the following subsection we extend these results by decomposing labour productivity growth into that resulting from the shifts in the frontier of an industrys technology, capital deepening and eciency gains (or losses). We provide theoretically grounded interpretations for the contributions of these three factors to average labour productivity growth in an industry. Results for the Decomposition Analysis We decomposed plant-level labour productivity growth during the 198596 period in each of the 17 industries under consideration. We then calculated their industry average using the geometric average of the initial and nal year employment shares of plants as the weight.14 Table 6.3 shows the decompositions of average labour productivity growth rates during the 198596 period. The rst column shows the compound annual average growth in labour productivity and the second column, the period growth rate of productivity. The remaining columns represent the contribution of the four components to (period) labour productivity growth. All industries experienced a positive growth in labour productivity during this period, with important inter-industry variations as may be expected of a heterogeneous group of industries. In a majority of the industries, we see that productivity growth resulted from a combination of assimilation (unexplained) and innovation. While the former was the main contributor in most of the industries, the latter was the leading contributor in industries like paints & varnishes, plastics and rubber. Explained assimilation was a major

140

Industrial dynamics

Table 6.3

Decomposition of productivity growth, 19851996


Period growth (%) 8.022 6.412 4.733 4.295 3.447 5.854 8.637 1.896 10.037 0.252 5.810 5.414 13.254 7.504 6.871 3.529 8.944 Contribution to productivity growth Explained assimilation 3.776 1.783 6.928 1.818 0.717 0.253 1.103 0.092 0.991 0.997 2.623 0.077 1.098 0.307 0.578 0.193 4.219 Unexplained Innovation Potential assimilation 0.414 3.172 2.668 0.448 1.579 3.330 4.033 0.828 6.520 0.240 5.081 3.694 4.496 3.247 1.913 1.177 0.268 3.826 4.857 1.152 2.158 0.875 2.641 6.141 1.010 3.081 0.721 3.627 1.659 8.102 3.943 4.816 2.586 5.199 0.007 0.165 0.679 0.129 0.277 0.136 0.435 0.034 0.554 0.216 0.274 0.139 1.753 0.006 0.436 0.426 0.206

Industry Annual (ISIC growth Rev. 2) (%) 31171 31179 31410 31420 32114 32121 32130 32210 33111 33113 33211 34200 35210 35222 35523 35606 36422 0.704 0.567 0.421 0.383 0.309 0.518 0.756 0.171 0.873 0.023 0.515 0.480 1.138 0.660 0.606 0.316 0.782

Note: See Appendix Table 6A.1 for industry denitions.

contributor in about ve industries important among which were tobacco, plywood, cigarettes and clay tiles. The contribution of creating spillover potential was very limited in all industries. This result is mainly due to the at shapes of the estimated frontiers. Increasing capital intensity hardly contributes to a higher potential labour productivity. In other words, learning or assimilation potentials remained more or less stagnant.

6.

CONCLUSIONS AND FUTURE RESEARCH

In this chapter, we proposed an SFA approach to study labour productivity growth in the Indonesian manufacturing sector (in the late 1980s and early 1990s). We focused specically on the eects of inows of foreign technology and the role of absorptive capacity changes on plant-level dierences in productivity growth. Our main ndings are that foreign R&D played a signicant role in moving the productivity frontier in an upward direction. Hence, the inow

Absorptive capacity and foreign spillovers

141

of technology was an important source of productivity growth for bestpractice plants. The creation of spillover potential (by investing to use more capital-intensive technologies) barely contributed to labour productivity growth, since relations between capital intensity and labour productivity were almost non-existent for best-practice plants. As a consequence, shifting to higher capital intensities hardly implied more potential spillovers to benet from. This nding is clearly at odds with the major assumptions underlying the accumulationist theories of growth. Assimilation (movements towards the frontier) played an important role. We could distinguish between two kinds of assimilation eects. The rst type could be explained by our absorptive capacity indicators, such as labour quality and degree of foreign ownership. For many industries, we found estimation results that underline the importance of building absorptive capacity for assimilating knowledge from best-practice rms that operate similar technology. In a quantitative sense, however, these eects were often dwarfed by the second kind of assimilation eects. These unexplained assimilation eects were very big and dominated the composite eect. The importance of unexplained assimilation is worrisome on the one hand, in the sense that we cannot explain much. On the other hand, it conrms our feeling that much heterogeneity of plants is not captured by survey-based datasets. Our absorptive capacity indicators are rough ones, and are subject to considerable measurement error. In our view, more indepth case studies (like Pack, 1987, and Van Dijk, 2005) oer much better opportunities for assessing the importance of foreign technology and dierences in absorptive capacity. Studies like ours can play a useful role in investigating to what extent case-study results can be generalised. In that sense, the next steps along the lines of the present chapter could be to probe further into the inter-industry dierences concerning the estimation results and to link such dierences to dierences in the types of technologies used. Industrial taxonomies, for example, as proposed by Pavitt (1984) might constitute an interesting and worthwhile starting point in this respect.

NOTES
* A rst version of this chapter was presented at the European Meeting on Applied Evolutionary Economics 2005 (Utrecht, The Netherlands). Useful comments by participants and, in particular, Koen Frenken and Fabio Montobbio are gratefully acknowledged. An extensive overview of empirical studies was recently given in Keller (2004). A modern textbook is Kumbhakar and Lovell (2000). The analysis can be conceived as an empirical approach to part of the technologyassimilation model of Nelson and Pack (1999).

1. 2. 3.

142
4. 5. 6.

Industrial dynamics
Pack (1987) studied the performance of textile plants in Kenya, the Philippines and the UK. Van Dijk (2005) focused on the productivity levels of paper-making plants in Indonesia and Finland. Basu and Weil (1998) illustrate this concept by arguing that new knowledge pertaining to the very capital-intensive maglev trains in Japan will not be useful to transporters in Bangladesh using very capital-extensive bullock cart technologies. Atkinson and Stiglitz (1969) introduced the concept of localised learning by doing by which they suggested that rms improve the productivity of a particular mix of capital and labour over time. Basu and Weil (1998) extended this notion by emphasising the importance of localized knowledge spillovers. Below, we shall argue that our estimation framework allows us to decompose assimilation eects into explained assimilation (explained by means of absorptive capacity indicators) and unexplained assimilation. For a recent survey, see Wang (2003). The scale of operation could be important in learning, for instance because big rms often have more contacts with suppliers, are often more strongly represented in professional associations and so on. To investigate the learning eect of scale, we include the variable plant size in our ineciency function. We shall limit our analysis to the 198596 period due to the better quality of the data since 1985 and to the crisis of 199799. This approach dates back to the seminal neoclassical macroeconomic growth accounting study by Jorgenson and Griliches (1967). In Tables 6.1a and 6.1b, the standard deviations for the variable IRD always equal zero. This is due to the fact that we dened the international R&D stocks as industry-level variables (see Section 4). It should be noted, however, that this result might be partly due to the fact that new equipment is often more energy saving than more outdated machinery. Consequently, rises in energy consumption might overestimate rises in capital intensity. Prior to deriving the industry average, the multiplicative components of the decomposition equation were transformed, by taking their logarithms, into additive components.

7. 8. 9.

10. 11. 12. 13. 14.

REFERENCES
Abramovitz, M. (1989), Thinking About Growth, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Atkinson, A.B. and Stiglitz, J.E. (1969), A new view of technological change, Economic Journal, 79, 5738. Basu, S. and Weil, D.N. (1998), Appropriate technology and growth, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113, 102554. Battese, G.E. and Coelli, T.J. (1995), A model for technical ineciency eects in a stochastic frontier production function for panel data, Empirical Economics, 20, 32532. Coelli, T.J. (1996), A guide to FRONTIER Version 4.1: a computer program for stochastic frontier production and cost function estimation, CEPA (Centre for Eciency and Productivity Analysis) Working Paper, No. 7, University of New England, Department of Econometrics, University of New England, Armidale. Coelli, T.J., Rao, D.S.P. and Battese, G.E. (1998), An Introduction to Eciency and Productivity Analysis, Boston, MA: Kluwer Academic. Cohen, W. and Levinthal, D. (1990), Absorptive capacity: a new perspective on learning and innovation, Administrative Science Quarterly, 35, 12852. Evenson, R. and Westphal, L. (1995), Technological change and technology strat-

Absorptive capacity and foreign spillovers

143

egy, in T.N. Srinivasan and J. Behrman (eds), Handbook of Development Economics, Vol. 3, Amsterdam: North-Holland, 220929. Hill, H. (1996), The Indonesian Economy since 1966: Southeast Asias Emerging Giant, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Jacob, J. and Los, B. (2005), The impact of international technology spillover and absorptive capacity on productivity growth in Indonesian manufacturing rms, Paper presented at the European Meeting on Applied Evolutionary Economics (EMAEE), Utrecht, May 1921. Jorgenson, D.W. and Griliches, Z. (1967), The explanation of productivity change, Review of Economic Studies, 34, 24983. Keller, W. (2004), International technology diusion, Journal of Economic Literature, 62, 75282. Klepper, S. (2002), The capabilities of new rms and the evolution of the US automobile industry, Industrial and Corporate Change, 11(4), 64566. Kumar, S. and Russell, R.R. (2002), Technological change, technological catch-up and capital deepening: relative contributions to growth and convergence, American Economic Review, 92, 52749. Kumbhakar, S.C. and Lovell, C.A.K (2000), Stochastic Frontier Analysis, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Lichtenberg, F.R. and van Pottelsberghe de la Potterie, B. (1998), International R&D spillovers: a comment, European Economic Review, 42(8), 148391. Los, B. and Timmer, M. (2005), The appropriate technology explanation of productivity growth dierentials: an empirical approach, Journal of Development Economics, 77, 51731. Marsili, O. (2001), The Anatomy and Evolution of Industries: Technological Change and Industrial Dynamics, Cheltenham, UK and Northampton, MA, USA: Edward Elgar. Nelson, R.R. and Pack, H. (1999), The Asian miracle and modern growth theory, Economic Journal, 109, 41636. Pack, H. (1987), Productivity, Technology, and Industrial Development: A Case Study in Textiles, Oxford and New York: Oxford University Press. Pavitt, K. (1984), Sectoral patterns of technical change: towards a taxonomy and a theory, Research Policy, 13, 34373. Pitt, M.M. and Lee, L.F. (1981), The measurement and sources of technical eciency in the Indonesian weaving industry, Journal of Development Economics, 9, 4364. Polanyi, M. (1958), Personal Knowledge: Towards a Post-Critical Philosophy, Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Teece, D.J. (2000), Managing Intellectual Capital, Oxford: Oxford University Press. Tybout, J.R. (2000), Manufacturing rms in developing countries: how well do they do and why?, Journal of Economic Literature, 38, 1144. Van Dijk, M. (2005), Industry evolution and catch up: the case of the Indonesian pulp and paper industry, unpublished PhD thesis, University of Eindhoven. Verspagen, B. (1997), Estimating international technology spillovers using technology ow matrices, Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, 133, 22648. Wang, H.-J. (2003), A stochastic frontier analysis of nancing constraints on investment: the case of nancial liberalization in Taiwan, Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, 21, 40619.

144

Industrial dynamics

APPENDIX 6A
Table 6A.1
No. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17

Industrial classication
ISIC Rev. 2 31171 31179 31410 31420 32114 32121 32130 32210 33111 33113 33211 34200 35210 35222 35523 35606 36422

Industry Macaroni, spaghetti, noodles etc. Bakery products Dried tobacco and processed tobacco Clove cigarettes Weaving mills except gunny and other sacks Made-up textiles except wearing apparel Knitting mills Wearing apparel made of textiles (garments) Sawmills Plywood Furniture and xtures, mainly wood Printing, publishing and allied industries Paints, varnishes and lacquers Drugs and medicines Crumb rubber Plastics, bags, containers Clay tiles

PART III

Network Analysis

7. Informational complexity and the ow of knowledge across social boundaries


Olav Sorenson, Jan W. Rivkin and Lee Fleming
1. INTRODUCTION

Scholars from a variety of backgrounds economists, sociologists, strategists and students of technology management have sought a better understanding of why some knowledge disperses widely while other knowledge does not. In this quest, some researchers have focused on the characteristics of the knowledge itself (for example, Polanyi, 1966; Reed and DeFillippi, 1990; Zander and Kogut, 1995) while others have emphasized the social networks that constrain and enable the ow of knowledge (for example, Coleman et al., 1957; Davis and Greve, 1997). This chapter examines the interplay between these two factors. Specically, we consider how the complexity of knowledge and the density of social relations jointly inuence the movement of knowledge. Imagine a social network composed of patches of dense connections with sparse interstices between them. The dense patches might reect rms, for instance, or geographic regions or technical communities. When does knowledge diuse within these dense patches circumscribed by social boundaries but not beyond them? Synthesizing social network theory with a view of knowledge transfer as a search process, we argue that knowledge inequality across social boundaries should reach its peak when the underlying knowledge is of moderate complexity.1 To test this hypothesis, we analyse patent data and compare citation rates across three types of social boundaries: within versus outside the rm, geographically near to versus far from the inventor, and internal versus external to the technological class. In all three cases, the disparity in knowledge diusion across these borders is greatest for knowledge of an intermediate level of complexity.

147

148

Network analysis

2.

THE TRANSFER OF COMPLEX KNOWLEDGE

Our hypotheses build on two themes in the literature. First, the transfer of knowledge from one party to another typically requires eort on the part of the recipient to ll gaps in the transmitted knowledge and to correct transmission errors. The acquisition of knowledge therefore is best seen not as the receipt of a complete, well-packaged gift, but rather as a search process. Second, social networks, and consequently the social boundaries that shape them, critically inuence that search process. Knowledge Receipt as Search Following the lead of evolutionary economists (Nelson and Winter, 1982), we think of a unit of knowledge as analogous to a recipe. The list of ingredients might include both physical components and processes. The recipe further explains how to combine these components and processes in what order, in which proportions, under what circumstances to achieve a desired end. Viewing knowledge as a recipe leads naturally to thinking of innovation as a search for new recipes. Following a long tradition beginning at least as early as Schumpeter (1939) we explicitly model innovation as a search process; inventors explore the space of possible combinations of ingredients (that is, recipes) for new and better alternatives. In discussing this process, we adopt the idea of a tness landscape as a metaphor for the characteristics of the search space. Innovators search these landscapes for peaks and plateaus, which correspond to good recipes, useful inventions and protable strategies. Once a useful innovation has been discovered, transferring its recipe, even between cooperative actors, can fail for at least two reasons. First, the recipient usually does not fully understand the original recipe, as a result of imperfections in the transfer process. He/she must therefore begin a search for the missing information and to correct the errors in his/her (imperfect) copy of the recipe. Second, the local ingredients and the experience of the recipient rarely match those of the sender; recipients may therefore need to adapt the original recipe to their own context. Knowledge recipients do not act as passive beneciaries; they actively search, recreate and build upon the original recipes. In this process, the transfer of certain types of recipes is particularly dicult. For instance, knowledge characterized by causal ambiguity (Lippman and Rumelt, 1982), a high degree of tacitness (Polanyi, 1966), or dicult codication (Zander and Kogut, 1995) may resist transfer because any communication of such recipes proceeds only with many and large gaps. Our focus, however, is on the informational complexity of transferred

Informational complexity and the ow of knowledge across boundaries

149

knowledge. We consider a piece of knowledge complex if it comprises many elements that interact richly (Simon, 1962), and we pay special attention to the intensity of interdependence among the ingredients in a recipe. To connect the degree of informational complexity to the characteristics of the space that inventors search, we use Kaumans NK model (Kauman, 1993; see also Frenken and Nuvolari, 2004). N denotes the number of (binary) elements in a system while K represents the degree to which these components interact in determining the tness of a particular conguration of components. In our context, N is the number of ingredients used in a recipe, and K is the richness of the interactions between those ingredients. To understand better the way in which the model relates interdependence to the search process, consider two examples with N 3. Figure 7.1 depicts a tness landscape for a recipe with no interdependence between its components. Each vertex represents a dierent potential conguration; the arrows connecting them show paths towards higher tness levels. When K 0, Kauman randomly assigns a tness from the uniform unit distribution to each value (0 or 1) of each element. The overall tness value for a particular conguration is the average of each elements tness contribution. As one can see, any starting point on this landscape leads to the unique optimum (011). Figure 7.2, on the other hand, illustrates an example with N 2. The value of the tness contribution for each component then depends not just on its value but also on the values of two other components. Each component therefore can contribute any of eight (2 2 2) dierent tness levels. Kauman again randomly assigns these values from the uniform unit
110 (0.43)
wi

111 (0.67)

123 000 001 010 011 100 101 110 111

w1 0.8 0.8 0.8 0.8 0.4 0.4 0.4 0.4

w2 0.6 0.6 0.7 0.7 0.6 0.6 0.7 0.7

w3 0.2 0.9 0.2 0.9 0.2 0.9 0.2 0.9

i 1

N 0.53 0.77 0.57 0.80 0.40 0.63 0.43 0.67

100 (0.40)

101 (0.63) 010 (0.57) 011 (0.80)

000 (0.53)

001 (0.77)

Note: This relatively correlated landscape has only one minimum and one maximum, 100 (0.40) and 011 (0.80), respectively. The component tness contributions come from a uniform [0,1] distribution.

Figure 7.1

Landscape without interdependence (N

3, K

0)

150

Network analysis
110 (0.40) 100 (0.37) 111 (0.63)

123 000 001 010 011 100 101 110 111

w1 0.5 0.6 0.2 0.8 0.4 0.9 0.7 0.9

w2 0.8 0.2 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.8 0.4 0.7

w3 0.6 0.1 0.3 0.5 0.2 0.9 0.1 0.3

i 1

wi

N 0.63 0.30 0.40 0.47 0.37 0.87 0.40 0.63

101 (0.87) 010 (0.40) 011 (0.47)

000 (0.63)

001 (0.30)

Note: This relatively uncorrelated landscape has multiple local minima, 001(0.30) and 100 (0.37), and maxima, 000 (0.63) and 101 (0.87).

Figure 7.2

Landscape with maximal interdependence (N

3, K

2)

distribution. Even in this simple example, one can see that interdependence complicates search; depending on where one begins, an agent using a simple hill-climbing algorithm could arrive at either the global maximum (101) or a local one (000). Complex knowledge resists transfer by making it dicult for a recipient to ll transmission gaps. On the landscapes depicted, a gap is equivalent to not knowing the correct value for the global optimum of one of the three elements. Interdependence produces two eects that undermine the recipients attempts to regenerate the original recipe (that is, identify the optimum). First, small errors in transmission cause large problems when ingredients cross-couple in a rich manner. Second, interdependence leads to a proliferation of local peaks. These peaks undermine improvement through incremental search because changing any single element degrades the quality of the outcome (Kauman, 1993). As a result, searchers frequently nd themselves trapped on local peaks (that is, inferior recipes) when faced with high interdependence. Complexity and Access to a Template Success in acquiring and employing complex knowledge depends crucially on access to the original success, which serves as a template (Nelson and Winter, 1982: 11920; Winter, 1995). For reasons considered below, individuals vary in their degree of access to the template. Superior access facilitates the receipt of knowledge by allowing the recipient to commence search with fewer errors and by permitting him/her to solicit advice from

Informational complexity and the ow of knowledge across boundaries

151

the source during the search process. Consider two actors, both attempting to assimilate a valuable piece of knowledge but who dier in their access to the template. The rst has superior, though still imperfect, access to and understanding of the original, successful recipe. The second has far poorer access. How valuable is the rst actors superior access to the template during the search process? We contend that the value depends on the complexity of the knowledge being transferred. Suppose rst that the ingredients used in the recipe do not interact (that is, K 0). In this situation, the rst actors access to the template does not produce a persistent advantage. Through routine, incremental search, the second actor can reconstruct the recipe. Few local peaks threaten to trap the poorly informed recipient. As a result, both actors eventually fare equally well; search on the part of a recipient can easily substitute for highdelity transmission. Next consider knowledge with an intermediate degree of interdependence. Local peaks now appear, but they remain relatively few in number. The wellinformed actor begins his/her search near, but not precisely at, the original optimal set of ingredients. Through incremental search, he/she can nd the proper combination of ingredients. The second actor, who begins his/her search farther from the target and receives less guidance about the direction in which to explore, more likely becomes ensnared on some local peak, away from and inferior to the original success. Here superior template access gives the rst actor an advantage the second cannot recreate through search. Finally, imagine a piece of maximally interdependent knowledge (that is, K N 1): ingredients depend on one another in an extremely delicate way. Local peaks now pervade the landscape and neither actors incremental search will likely build on the original knowledge with any success. The rst actors superior access to the template thus has little value beyond the seconds inferior access. Taken together, these arguments imply that the advantage of superior but imperfect access to the template reaches its peak at moderate levels of interdependence between knowledge components (Rivkin, 2001, develops this argument further, with the aid of simulations). Social Boundaries and Template Access Access to the template depends on the distribution of social relations, which provide the channels through which valuable information ows (Hgerstrand, 1953; Coleman et al., 1957). These social relations do not link actors at random. Rather, sociologists have consistently noted and demonstrated that networks concentrate within the boundaries of communities and organizations. Our study tests the salience of three types of

152

Network analysis

social boundaries organizational memberships, geographic regions and technological communities in structuring social networks, and concomitantly inuencing the ow of knowledge. Consider organizational boundaries rst. A rm attempting to replicate and build on its own prior success has better access to its knowledge than would an outside imitator, both because fellow members of an organization share codes, specialized languages and beliefs that facilitate high-delity transmission (Arrow, 1974) and because strong interpersonal ties and dense social networks inside a rm provide access to the template (Granovetter, 1985). As argued above, the value of this access peaks for transmitting knowledge of intermediate complexity: Hypothesis 1 The advantage in receiving and applying knowledge that members of the same rm have over members of dierent rms reaches its maximum for knowledge of intermediate interdependence. In other words, the insiders advantage over the outsider has an inverted Ushaped relation to the interdependence of the knowledge. Actors belonging to the same geographic unit (for example, city, country or state) as the innovator also have superior access to the template. The geographic concentration of social relations reects a variety of factors: the greater odds that individuals in close proximity encounter one another (Festinger et al., 1950), the high costs of maintaining distant ties (Zipf, 1949; Boalt and Janson, 1957), and the prevalence of local cultures (Benedict, 1934). We therefore expect that actors physically close to a source of knowledge have better access to it: Hypothesis 2 A nearby knowledge recipients advantage in receiving and applying knowledge over a distant recipient peaks for knowledge of intermediate interdependence. To the extent that networks localize geographically, even within a rm, organizations nd it dicult to diuse knowledge beyond its point of origin. Within a rm, then, we expect simple knowledge to spread broadly and highly complex knowledge to remain isolated within a single team or department. Knowledge of moderate complexity, however, should spread within a rm to the edges of a facility or locale, but not to geographically distant installations: Hypothesis 3 Within a rm, a nearby knowledge recipients advantage in receiving and applying knowledge over a distant recipient reaches its maximum for knowledge of intermediate interdependence.

Informational complexity and the ow of knowledge across boundaries

153

An analogous argument applies to technological communities (also called communities of practice, dened in terms of cognitive proximity). Actors who work in the same technological domain as an inventor have superior access to the template. Universities, trade associations, professional societies, industry consortia and work experience foster dense social connections within such technological communities. These communities also develop common knowledge and communal languages that can facilitate knowledge transfer. Membership within a common technological community thus engenders superior access to the template, which should have its greatest impact when the target knowledge displays moderate interdependence: Hypothesis 4 The advantage in receiving and applying knowledge that a member of a technological community has over a non-member of the community reaches its maximum with knowledge of intermediate interdependence.

3.

EMPIRICAL CORROBORATION

To test these hypotheses, we analysed prior art citations to all US utility patents granted in May and June of 1990 (n 17 264). The data came from the Micro Patent database and NBER public access data on patents (Hall et al., 2001). As in many previous studies, we view a prior art citation as evidence of knowledge diusion. Our statistical approach involves estimating the likelihood that a focal patent receives a citation from a future patent as a function of several factors: the interdependence of the knowledge underlying the focal patent, the status of the citing patents inventor as an insider or outsider on some dimension with respect to the focal patent, the interaction of interdependence and insider/outsider status, and a set of control variables. The results of the estimation allow us to examine how the likelihood of insider citation compares to the likelihood of outsider citation and, crucially, whether the gap between the two probabilities peaks when the focal patent embodies moderately interdependent knowledge. Our unit of analysis is a patent dyad, one patent issued in May or June of 1990 and one issued later that may or may not cite the rst. Hence our approach conceptually follows that of other studies of the likelihood of tie formation in this case, the likelihood that a future patent builds on the knowledge embodied in one of our focal patents. Specically, our analysis follows Sorenson and Stuart (2001) in adopting a case-control approach to analysing the formation of ties. We begin by including all cases of future

154

Network analysis

patents, from July 1990 to June 1996, that cite any of our 17 268 focal patents: 60 999 in total. Since these citations occur, the dependent variable for these cases takes a value of 1 to denote a realized citation. In addition, we pair each of the 17 268 focal patents with four future patents that do not cite it (but that could have), with the dependent variable set to zero. From this set of 130 071, we restrict our analysis to the dyads in which both inventors reside in the United States, leaving us with a set of 72 801 dyads. Interdependence For each dyad, we measure the complexity of the knowledge in the focal patent, k, by observing the historical diculty of recombining the elements that constitute it (Fleming and Sorenson, 2001). Though the metric involves intensive calculation, the intuition behind it is simple: a technology whose components have, in the past, been mixed and matched readily with a wide variety of other components has exhibited few sensitive interdependencies and receives a low value of k. The measure takes the subclasses identied in a patent as proxies for the underlying components (see Fleming and Sorenson, 2004, for survey-based validation of the measure). We compute k in two stages. Equation (7.1) details our calculation of the ease of recombination, or inverse of interdependence, for each subclass i used in patent j. We rst identify every use of subclass i on patents from 1980 to 1990. The denominator is simply the tally of the number of patents with a classication in subclass i. To compute the numerator, we count the number of dierent subclasses appearing with subclass i on previous patents. Hence, our measure increases as a particular subclass combines with a wider variety of technologies, controlling for the total number of applications. This term captures the ease of combining a particular technology. Ease of recombination of subclass i Ei (7.1)

Count of subclasses previously combined with subclass i . Count of previous patents in subclass i

To create our measure of interdependence for an entire patent, we invert the average of the ease of recombination scores for the subclasses to which it belongs (equation 7.2). Interdependence of patent j Kj Count of subclasses on patent j . Ei
j i

(7.2)

Informational complexity and the ow of knowledge across boundaries

155

Social Boundaries Three variables capture the insider/outsider status of the potential citing inventor with respect to the holder of a focal patent. The variables reect membership in organizational, regional and technical communities. Same assignee is set to one if two patents in a dyad share a common owner and is zero otherwise. Geographic proximity is equal to the natural log of the distance in miles between the rst inventors listed on the two patents in a dyad multiplied by negative one (so that we expect larger values to increase the likelihood of citation). Same class is set to one if two patents belong to the same primary technological class a proxy for shared membership in a community and is zero otherwise. In all three cases, we test our hypotheses by interacting k and its square with the proxy for the density of social networks whether due to rm boundaries, geographic proximity, or technological similarity. The benets of social proximity should peak for inventions of moderate complexity. The regressions also include several control variables. Subclass overlap is the number of subclasses that the two patents in the dyad have in common divided by the number of subclass memberships for the (potentially) citing patent. An activity control estimates the typical number of citations received by a patent in the same technological areas as the focal patent (see Fleming and Sorenson, 2001). Recent technology is the average reference number of the patents listed as prior art, a measure of the closeness of the patent to the technological frontier. We also include counts of the number of backward patent citations and backward non-patent citations, the number of class memberships, and the number of subclass memberships for the focal patent. We report robust standard errors and correct for potential bias in logistic regression of rare events (King and Zeng, 2001).

4.

RESULTS

The results appear in Table 7.1. Model 1 tests hypothesis 1 by interacting k and k2 with same assignee. As expected, membership within the same rm produces the greatest diusion advantage over outsiders for knowledge of intermediate complexity, as evidenced by the positive coecient on k same assignee and the negative coecient on k2 same assignee. The interactions between geographic distance and interdependence in model 2 tests hypothesis 2, again showing strong support. Model 3 tests hypothesis 3 by re-estimating model 2, but only for dyads where both patents belong to the same rm. In essence it asks: does geography still matter for

156

Network analysis

Table 7.1 Rare events logit models of the likelihood of a focal patent receiving a citation from a future patent
Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Only same assignee 4.821 (0.359) 4.208 (0.117) Model 4 Model 5

k k2 k k2 k k2 k k2 same assignee same assignee ln (dist) ln (dist) same class same class

1.687 (0.302) 0.892 (0.082) 2.969 (0.515) 3.420 (0.203)

1.526 (0.307) 0.793 (0.074)

1.444 (0.321) 0.704 (0.098)

0.835 (0.131) 0.794 (0.044)

6.047 (0.213) 4.566 (0.074) 3.019 (1.146) 1.396 (0.363) 0.432 (0.281) 0.499 (0.030) 3.837 (0.302) 4.114 (0.316) 0.477 (0.388) 0.096 (0.165) 0. 001 (0.014) 0.019 (0.005) 0.041 (0.138) 0.001 (0.044) 9.206 (0.684) 22 255.9 72 801

Same assignee ln (dist) Same class Subclass overlap Activity control Recent technology Backward patent citations Backward nonpatent citations Number of classes Number of subclasses Constant Log-likelihood N Note: p 0.05; p same assignee 1.

0.343 (0.280) 0.499 (0.031) 3.800 (0.306) 4.230 (0.316) 0.393 (0.287) 0.122 (0.171) 0.002 (0.013) 0.018 (0.006) 0.070 (0.140) 0. 016 (0.045) 9.224 (0.714) 22 262.4 72 801 0.01; p

0.389 (0.276) 0.428 (0.031) 3.663 (0.307) 4.190 (0.317) 0.389 (0.287) 0.195 (0.170) 0.013 (0.013) 0.014 (0.006) 0.054 (0.140) 0. 021 (0.045) 9.953 (0.703) 22 261.4 72 801

0.500 (0.066) 1.878 (0.394) 3.767 (0.349) 0. 746 (0.248) 0.010 (0.309) 0.025 (0.008) 0.126 (0.037) 0.456 (0.249) 0.170 (0.048) 7.148 (1.208) 2 294.1 6 497

1.070 (0.362) 0.359 (0.107) 6.231 (0.555) 9.851 (0.273) 0.885 (0.139) 1.025 (0.066) 5.733 (1.032) 5.409 (0.330) 0.172 (0.278) 0.354 (0.029) 3.448 (0.299) 4.150 (0.314) 0.466 (0.289) 0.024 (0.151) 0. 002 (0.014) 0.011 (0.005) 0.052 (0.137) 0.010 (0.044) 9.162 (0.675) 22 251.1 72 801

0.001. Model 3 includes only those dyads for which

Informational complexity and the ow of knowledge across boundaries

157

knowledge diusion within rms? In support of hypothesis 3, the results reveal that even within rm boundaries, social networks inuence the ow of knowledge, with the greatest disparity between local diusion and distant diusion arising for knowledge of moderate interdependence. Model 4 tests the salience of technological communities. Once again, the estimates show strong support; the impact of technological community membership on citation probability peaks for intermediate k. Model 5 includes all three measures of social proximity simultaneously and shows that each has an independent and signicant eect when estimated together, in support of hypotheses 1, 2 and 4. As expected, the value of superior access to the template reaches a maximum for knowledge of moderate interdependence, regardless of whether the superior access comes from organizational membership, geographic proximity, or technological community membership. In addition to being signicant, the eects have substantial economic import. For simple or highly complex knowledge, the insider has no greater likelihood than the outsider of attaining and building on the knowledge in a focal patent. For knowledge of moderate complexity at the gap-maximizing levels of k, a rm insider is 218 per cent more likely than an outsider to transfer knowledge eectively; an inventor located in the same zip code is 160 per cent more likely to absorb the knowledge in a region than one at the average distance ( 665 miles); and a technological insider is 238 per cent as likely as a technological outsider to build on knowledge in the class.

5.

DISCUSSION

Our analyses considered the impact of superior access to some original knowledge on the likelihood of diusion as a function of knowledge complexity, using three indicators of social proximity. All knowledge recipients, near and far, compete on equal footing when assimilating simple knowledge. Highly complex knowledge, on the other hand, equally resists diusion to both classes of would-be recipients. For knowledge whose ingredients display a moderate degree of interdependence, however, superior but imperfect access to the template translates into better knowledge reproduction. Thus in our patent data, the largest gap between the ability of a close recipient to build on prior knowledge relative to the ability of a distant recipient arises when the cited patent involves moderate interdependence. Our ndings speak to the question, when does inequality of knowledge arise across social borders? One might initially suspect that highly complex knowledge, the most dicult to reproduce, would create the greatest

158

Network analysis

inequality. But this intuition ignores the fact that inequality in its sharpest form requires some diusion: to create the most inequity across social boundaries, knowledge must creep up to the edge of the thick patch of connections in which it originated but not beyond. This phenomenon, we have argued, most likely occurs for moderately complex knowledge. Thus, for example, one might expect industries based on moderately complex knowledge to display especially wide intra-industry dispersion in long-run nancial returns. Our argument may also shed light on a conundrum of the literature on economic geography. Explanations for agglomeration based on information spillovers assume that membership in a local community allows rms to benet from the knowledge developed by other rms in the region, but that rms outside the region are excluded from these benets (for example, Marshall, 1890; Arrow, 1962). What type of knowledge would have such a characteristic? The literature to date has focused on tacit knowledge, but typically uses the term simply to refer to uncodied (as opposed to uncodiable) knowledge (an endogenous outcome of rms decisions to invest in codication; Brkel, 2005). Our results, building on Kaumans NK model, point to a dierent (presumably more exogenous) dimension: informational complexity. Industries that rely on moderately complex knowledge might be especially likely to display geographic agglomeration (for empirical corroboration, see Sorenson, 2004). Our empirical results come from patent data alone, but the basic logic of our hypotheses applies to knowledge in general, not just the knowledge underlying inventions (see Wolter, 2006, for a model based on interdependence in production). Hence, future research might usefully examine these dynamics across a wide range of applications including organizational learning, the diusion of management practices, knowledge management, and the sustainability of knowledge-based competitive advantage.

NOTE
1. This version describes the intuition underlying our theoretical model and reports novel empirical results. For those interested in a more detailed description of the theoretical model, see Rivkin (2001) and Sorenson et al. (2004).

REFERENCES
Arrow, Kenneth J. (1962), The economic implications of learning by doing, Review of Economic Studies, 29: 15573.

Informational complexity and the ow of knowledge across boundaries

159

Arrow, Kenneth J. (1974), The Limits of Organization, New York: Norton. Benedict, Ruth (1934), Patterns of Culture, New York: Houghton-Miin. Boalt, Gunnar and C.G. Janson (1957), Distance and social relations, Acta Sociologica, 2: 7397. Brkel, Tom (2005), The spatial dimension of knowledge transfer and its economic implications, Working paper, Max Planck Institute of Economics (Jena). Coleman, James S., Elihu Katz and Herbert Mendel (1957), The diusion of an innovation among physicians, Sociometry, 20: 25370. Davis, Gerald F. and Henrich R. Greve (1997), Corporate elite networks and governance changes in the 1980s, American Journal of Sociology, 103: 137. Festinger, Leon, Stanley Schacter and Kurt W. Back (1950), Social Pressure in Informal Groups, New York: Harper. Fleming, Lee and Olav Sorenson (2001), Technology as a complex adaptive system: evidence from patent data, Research Policy, 30: 101939. Fleming, Lee and Olav Sorenson (2004), Science as a map in technological search, Strategic Management Journal, 25: 90928. Frenken, Koen and Alessandro Nuvolari (2004), The early development of the steam engine: an evolutionary interpretation using complexity theory, Industrial and Corporate Change, 13: 41950. Granovetter, Mark S. (1985), Economic action and social structure: the problem of embeddedness, American Journal of Sociology, 91: 481510. Hgerstrand, Torsten ([1953] 1967), Innovation Diusion as a Spatial Process, Chicago: University of Chicago. Hall, Bronwyn H., Adam B. Jae and Manuel Trajtenberg (2001), The NBER patent citations data le: lessons, insights and methodological tools, National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 8498, Cambridge, MA. Kauman, Stuart A. (1993), The Origins of Order, Oxford and New York: Oxford University. King, Gary and Langche Zeng (2001), Logistic regression in rare events data, Political Analysis, 9: 13763. Lippman, Steve and Richard Rumelt (1982), Uncertain imitability: an analysis of interrm dierences in eciency under competition, Bell Journal of Economics, 13: 41838. Marshall, Alfred (1890), Principles of Economics, London: Macmillan. Nelson, Richard R. and Sidney G. Winter (1982), An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change, Cambridge, MA: Belknap. Polanyi, Michael (1966), The Tacit Dimension, New York: Anchor Day. Reed, Richard and Robert J. DeFillippi (1990), Causal ambiguity, barriers to imitation, and sustainable competitive advantage, Academy of Management Review, 15: 88102. Rivkin, Jan W. (2001), Reproducing knowledge: replication without imitation at moderate complexity, Organization Science, 12: 27493. Schumpeter, Joseph (1939), Business Cycles, New York: McGraw-Hill. Simon, Herbert A. (1962), The architecture of complexity, Proceedings of the American Philosophical Association, 106: 46782. Sorenson, Olav (2004), Social networks, informational complexity and industrial geography, in D. Fornahl, C. Zellner and D. Audretsch (eds), The Role of Labour Mobility and Informal Networks for Knowledge Transfer, Berlin: Springer-Verlag, pp. 7996.

160

Network analysis

Sorenson, Olav, Jan W. Rivkin and Lee Fleming (2004), Complexity, networks and knowledge ow, Harvard Business School Working Paper No. 04-027, Cambridge, MA. Sorenson, Olav and Toby E. Stuart (2001), Syndication networks and the spatial diusion of venture capital investments, American Journal of Sociology, 106: 154688. Winter, Sidney G. (1995), Four Rs of protability: rents, resources, routines, and replication, in C. Montgomery (ed.), Resource-based and Evolutionary Theories of the Firm: Towards a Synthesis, Boston, MA: Kluwer, pp. 1478. Wolter, Kerstin (2006), Divide and conquer? The role of governance for the adaptability of industrial districts, Advances in Complex Systems, forthcoming. Zander, Udo and Bruce Kogut (1995), Knowledge and the speed of transfer and imitation of organizational capabilities: an empirical test, Organization Science, 6: 7692. Zipf, George K. (1949), Human Behavior and the Principle of Least Eort, Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley.

8. Networks and heterogeneous performance of cluster rms


Elisa Giuliani*
1. INTRODUCTION

This chapter explores the relationship existing among the heterogeneous nature of rms in industrial clusters, their structural position in local networks and their performance. Following the rising interest for spatially agglomerated industrial rms (Piore and Sabel, 1984; Pyke et al., 1990; Porter, 1990; Krugman, 1991) and their learning and innovative potential (for example, Maskell, 2001a; Pinch et al., 2003), this chapter shows empirically that the performance of rms in clusters is related to rm-level knowledge endowments and their position in the knowledge network. A starting argument of this chapter is that of questioning the widely accepted view that knowledge is diused in clusters in a rather pervasive and unstructured way, and that this is what aects the enhanced performance of cluster rms as compared to isolated ones. Most economists and economic geographers share this view. On the one hand, in fact, economists stress the public nature of knowledge (Arrow, 1962) and argue that geography facilitates inter-rm learning and innovation because of localized knowledge spillovers (for example, Jae et al., 1993); on the other, recent work done by economic geographers argues that it is not geography per se that matters for innovation, but it is a common institutional endowment and rms relational proximity (later dened), which facilitate the diusion of knowledge and enhance collective learning in clusters (for example, Maskell and Malmberg, 1999; Capello and Faggian, 2005). A reason for this is the often presumed co-occurrence of rms business interactions and knowledge ows a view consistent with the Marshallian industrial atmosphere metaphor (Marshall, 1920). An increasing number of studies have, however, started to highlight that, in spite of a general homogeneity of conditions in the cluster, rms perform dierently (Lazerson and Lorenzoni, 1999; Rabellotti and Schmitz, 1999; Camison, 2004; Molina-Morales and Martinez-Fernandez, 2004; Zaheer and Bell, 2005). In line with this, some have expressed their conceptual
161

162

Network analysis

discontent about the pervasive and unstructured view of clusters innovation (see, for example, Breschi and Lissoni, 2001), and others have examined how key notions of evolutionary economics may be incorporated into economic geography (Boschma and Lambooy, 1999; Boschma and Frenken, 2006). In this vein, some have pointed out the need to understand the heterogeneity of cluster rms performance and the characteristics of a cluster innovative process, by bringing rm-level learning into the analysis (Bell and Albu, 1999; Maskell, 2001b; Martin and Sunley, 2003). Using a combination of network analysis (Wasserman and Faust, 1994) and econometrics, this chapter carries out an empirical study of three wine clusters Colline Pisane and Bolgheri/Val di Cornia in Italy and Colchagua Valley in Chile. It shows that rms perform dierently within clusters and that such dierences are due to both rm knowledge bases and to their degree of embeddedness in the local knowledge network. In contrast, interrm relational proximity is a less powerful factor aecting rm performance. The chapter concludes by drawing implications for the concept of clusters in economic geography.

2. GEOGRAPHY, RELATIONAL PROXIMITY AND THE DIFFUSION OF KNOWLEDGE: IMPLICATIONS FOR FIRM PERFORMANCE
The process of knowledge diusion and generation in clusters of rms has traditionally been based on dierent reinterpretations of the Marshallian, externality-driven, world of industrial districts. Several empirical studies have in fact elaborated on the Marshallian notion of knowledge spillovers, referring to Marshalls description of industrial districts as a place where:
The mysteries of the trade become no mysteries; but are as it were in the air, and children learn many of them, unconsciously. . . . Good work is rightly appreciated, inventions and improvements in machinery, in processes and the general organisation of the business have their merits promptly discussed: if one man starts a new idea, it is taken up by others and combined with suggestions of their own; thus it becomes the source of further new ideas. (Marshall, 1920, p. 225; emphasis added)

He envisaged two mechanisms by which knowledge spillovers were generated, the rst one was through the embodied capabilities acquired by workers being part of the district and the second one was the sharing of ideas among businessmen, a process which Allen (1983) has dened collective invention (see also Nuvolari, 2004). In Industry and Trade (1919), Marshall dened this as industrial atmosphere, highlighting its sticky nature:

Networks and heterogeneous performance of cluster rms

163

But an industry which does not use massive material, and needs skill that cannot be quickly acquired, remains as of yore loth to quit a good market for its labour. Sheeld and Solingen have acquired industrial atmospheres of their own; which yield gratis to the manufacturers of cutlery great advantages, that are not easily to be had elsewhere: and the atmosphere cannot be moved. (Marshall, 1919, p. 284; emphasis added)

Thus, the industrial atmosphere was conceived as a highly idiosyncratic meso characteristic of districts. Several scholars have advanced in this eld and have elaborated on the original Marshallian ideas. My argument here is that most of the studies undertaken in this direction have taken a meso perspective to analyse learning, innovation and performance in clustered rms. As such, they have given less emphasis to the micro, and to how the micro can aect the meso. Among these studies, I shall consider here only the most inuential contributions of both economists and economic geographers. As anticipated in the introduction, the economists view is that knowledge spillovers, which are by denition a public good (Arrow, 1962), tend to be highly localized (Jae, 1989; Jae et al., 1993), a property that links conceptually geography and innovation. Within this stream of studies, robust empirical evidence has shown that a relationship exists between spatial clustering, knowledge spillovers and rms innovative performance (for example, Audretsch and Feldman, 1996; Feldman, 1999; Baptista, 2000). This empirical evidence has led scholars and policy makers to believe that geography matters for innovation and for competitiveness (for example, OECD, 2001). As an example, in his work on industrial clusters and nations competitive advantage, Porter (1998) connects the processes of learning and innovation in clusters to the Marshallian atmosphere concept, stating that the information ow, visibility, and mutual reinforcement within such a locale give meaning to Alfred Marshalls insightful observation that in some places an industry is in the air (p. 156). He notes moreover that more important, however, is the inuence of geographic concentration on improvement and innovation (p. 157), since proximity increases the speed of information ow within the national industry and the rate at which innovations diuse (p. 157). This view supports the idea that geography matters for innovation and, implicitly, for economic performance. Some economic geographers seem to have moved beyond that. It has been argued that geographic proximity per se is not sucient to generate learning, and that other forms of proximity are required for inter-rm learning and innovation to occur (Boschma, 2005). Among these, great emphasis is given to the role of social proximity also known as relational proximity (for example, Maskell and Malmberg, 1999; Amin and Cohendet, 2004).

164

Network analysis

Industrial clusters, being a spatially localized set of economic activities, are in fact envisaged as embedded economies (Granovetter, 1985) where social relationships, such as friendship and kinship, are entangled with productive ones. More specically, relational proximity is believed to favour the formation of relational capital, dened as a sort of productive thickening based on market and cooperative inter-rm relationships (Scott, 1998). The relational capital, favouring the interaction of productive agents and the diusion of tacit knowledge (Howells, 2002) is nally said to be the substratum of collective learning (Capello, 1999). Relational proximity and embeddedness are thus considered to operate at the meso level and perform several functions in the context of innovation (Oerlemans and Meeus, 2005), favouring rm performance accordingly. In a recent study on several district areas in Italy, Capello and Faggian (2005) nd support for the importance of relational capital in fostering the innovative performance of rms. They therefore argue that
[R]egional economists are . . . correct in underlining that not only are intra-rm characteristics crucial for innovation, but also (and maybe most of all) that the location of rms in an area where the local labour market and the tight links with suppliers foster the exchange of local knowledge are vital for innovation. (p. 82; emphasis added)

In sum, current approaches to the analysis of clusters mainly focus on explaining why rms that are part of an industrial cluster tend to perform better than isolated ones. An underlying, implicit assumption, is that rms that are part of the same industrial cluster will benet more or less equally from the presence of external economies at the local level (Marshall, 1920) and, more specically, from a common geographical, sectoral and relational proximity. However, an increasing number of studies have recently started to highlight that, in spite of a general homogeneity of meso conditions in clusters, rms perform dierently (Lazerson and Lorenzoni, 1999; Rabellotti and Schmitz, 1999; Camison, 2004; Molina-Morales and Martinez-Fernandez, 2004; Zaheer and Bell, 2005).

3. WHAT AFFECTS HETEROGENEOUS PERFORMANCE IN CLUSTER FIRMS?


Understanding the factors that lead to heterogeneous rm performance in industrial clusters requires that the focus of analysis shifts from the meso to the micro. As suggested by Lazerson and Lorenzoni (1999) and more recently by Maskell (2001b), individual rms are the key actors in the development of territorial clusters. In line with this, my argument here is that it

Networks and heterogeneous performance of cluster rms

165

is the characteristics of rms, and their inherent heterogeneity, that generate (or inhibit) the conditions at the meso level that ultimately enhance cluster rm performance. Thus, it is a micro to meso perspective that this chapter takes, rather than the meso to micro one commonly found in the cluster literature. Accordingly, the performance of rms should be explored by considering the interplay between their internal resources and the external, meso conditions present in the cluster. The relationship between rms internal resources and performance has already been investigated by many scholars (Barney, 1991; Grant, 1996). Starting from the evolutionary theory of the rm (Nelson and Winter, 1982), I consider rms in the cluster as being characterized by heterogeneous knowledge bases. By knowledge base I mean here the set of information inputs, knowledge and capabilities that inventors draw on when looking for innovative solutions (Dosi, 1988, p. 1126). Knowledge is seen as residing in rms skilled knowledge workers, who embody tacit capabilities. At the same time, knowledge is not merely the sum of each individuals knowledge, since it resides in the organizational memory of the rm. As Nelson and Winter (1982, p. 63) put it:
The possession of technical knowledge is an attribute of the rm as a whole, as an organized entity, and it is not reducible to what any single individual knows, or even to any simple aggregation of the various competences and capabilities of all the various individuals, equipments, and installations of the rm.

The knowledge base is, moreover, considered here as the result of a process of cumulative learning, which is inherently imperfect, complex and path dependent (Dosi, 1997) and which delivers persistent heterogeneity between the rms in the economic system and, understandably, in a cluster. Such heterogeneity, in turn, deepens the uniqueness of resources deployed by rms and explains dierent growth rates and performance (Penrose, 1959). It is reasonable, moreover, that rms that have stronger knowledge bases will perform better than others in the cluster, as they will have easier access to external knowledge and rejuvenate their internal capabilities accordingly (Cohen and Levinthal, 1990). This chapter will explore the following research question: how does the heterogeneity in rm knowledge bases relate to their performance? The important issue here is, however, not simply whether micro-level conditions aect performance, but what is their interaction with the external environment in the cluster. Innovation rarely occurs in isolation, and, as emphasized by most of the cluster literature, the degree to which rms are embedded in local networks inuences their performance (Molina-Morales and Martinez-Fernandez, 2004; Capello and Faggian, 2005; Zaheer and Bell, 2005). Being relationally embedded in a cluster means that rms interact

166

Network analysis

frequently on business-related matters. For example, if entrepreneurs are members of the same local consortium they will meet at local events and discuss their productive activities. Similarly, if two rms share machinery, their technical employees will meet and discuss their appropriate use. All these interactions generate a trustworthy environment in the cluster, which may facilitate the sharing of information and knowledge, thus enhancing the overall rm capabilities to innovate. In a previous study on wine clusters (Giuliani, 2006), I have shown that business interactions of this type occur in a pervasive way, resembling what Marshall called industrial atmosphere. This means that rms show a rather homogeneous behaviour in interacting with the rest of the rms in the cluster. This is a relevant property because, if it is true that rms benet from being embedded in the local network of business interactions, their performance will be homogeneously distributed. The interaction for business-related matters is only one of the several informal networks formed by rms in clusters (Boschma, 2005). In fact, dierent types of networks are likely to carry dierent informational content and they may aect rm performance dierently (Gulati, 1998; Rodan and Galunic, 2004). In Giuliani (2006), I disentangle the knowledge network, based on the transfer of knowledge for the solution of technical problems, from the overall network of business interactions (Figure 8.1). The structural properties of the knowledge network suggest that it is built on a more selective basis, if compared to the network of business interactions. This means that knowledge diuses in clusters in a less pervasive and serendipitous way than is commonly envisaged by the economists and economic geographers. This property may have important implications on the distribution of rm performance in clusters. Given its selectivity, if rm performance is aected more by the degree of embeddedness in the knowledge network than in the network of business interactions, it is reasonable to expect an uneven distribution of rm performances.

4.

DATA AND METHOD OF ANALYSIS

Collection of Data This study is based on micro-level data, collected at the rm level in three wine clusters in Italy and Chile, namely: Colline Pisane (CP), Bolgheri/Val di Cornia (BVC) and Colchagua Valley (CV). The analysis has required careful data collection through interviews. Interviews were carried out with the skilled workers (that is, oenologists or agronomists) and the survey was directed to producers of ne wines. This analysis includes only horizontal relationships among rms that operate as wine producers, whereas vertical

Networks and heterogeneous performance of cluster rms

167

(a) BI network in CP

(b) KN network in CP

(c) BI network in BVC

(d) KN network in BVC

(e) BI network in CV

(f) KN network in CV

Note: BI stands for business interaction; KN for knowledge; CP for the Colline Pisane cluster; BVC for the Bolgheri/Val di Cornia cluster; CV for the Colchagua Valley cluster. Source: Giuliani (2006) (based on UCINET-Netdraw; Borgatti et al., 2002).

Figure 8.1

Types of networks

168

Network analysis

Table 8.1

Firm characteristics by cluster


Cluster CP (N 32) 91 9 0 100 0 3 88 9 53 9 31 6 CV (N 32) 28 66 6 81 19 22 13 66 24 16 38 19 BVC (N 41) 90 4 6 95 5 7 93 24 22 23 15

Characteristics of rms by:

(a)

Size (employees) Small (119) Medium (2099) Large ( 100) (b) Ownership Domestic Foreign (c) Organization structure 1. Part of a group, vertically integrated rms 2. Part of a group, vertically disintegrated rms 3. Independent, vertically integrated 4. Other (e.g., cooperatives) (d) Year of localization Up to 1970s 1980s 1990s 2000s

Note: The numbers refer to percentages within the respective cluster.

linkages are not explored here. Data were gathered using the universe of ne wine producers populating the three clusters,1 32 in CP, 41 in BVC and 32 in CV, making a total of 105 rms. Further information about the population of rms is reported in Table 8.1. Apart from general background and contextual information, the interviews were designed to obtain information that would permit the development of quantitative indicators in three key areas: (i) the knowledge base of rms; (ii) the degree of embeddedness of rms in the network of business interactions; and (iii) the degree of embeddedness of rms in the network of knowledge. These are summarized in Table 8.2. Econometric Estimation The analysis is based on an econometric estimation, using a Probit model with marginal eects. The estimations are carried out on the aggregate data

Networks and heterogeneous performance of cluster rms

169

Table 8.2

Collection of key variables

1. Knowledge base In the literature, this concept, a key element in the analysis here, is described in terms of the knowledge base of the rm, often associated with training, human resources and R&D. Correspondingly, the structured interviews sought detailed information about: (i) the number of technically qualied personnel in the rm and their level of education and training (human resources), (ii) the experience of professional sta in terms of months in the industry (months of experience); (iii) the number of other rms in which they had been employed (number of rms), and (iv) the intensity and nature of the rms experimentation activities (experimentation intensity) an appropriate proxy for knowledge creation eorts, since information about expenditure on formal R&D would have been both too narrowly dened and too dicult to obtain systematically. 2. Network of business interactions In the questionnaire-based interview, relational data were collected through a roster recall method: each rm was presented with a complete list (roster) of the other rms in the cluster, and was asked the question reported below: With which of the cluster rms mentioned in the roster do you interact for business matters? [Please indicate the frequency of interaction according to the following scale: 0 none; 1 low; 2 medium; 3 high] 3. Network of knowledge interactions* In the questionnaire-based interview, relational data were collected through a roster recall method: each rm was presented a complete list (roster) of the other rms in the cluster, and was asked the questions reported below: i. If you are in a critical situation and need technical advice, to which of the local rms mentioned in the roster do you turn? [Please rate the importance you attach to the knowledge linkage established with each of the rms according to its persistence and quality, on the basis of the following scale: 0 none; 1 low; 2 medium; 3 high]. ii. Which of the following rms do you think have beneted from technical support from this rm? [Please indicate the importance you attach to the knowledge linkage established with each of the rms according to its persistence and quality, on the basis of the following scale: 0 none; 1 low; 2 medium; 3 high].
Note: * Respondents were asked to rate each of the mentioned relationships on a scale of 0 to 3. A value of 0 is given when no linkage is formed. A value of 1 corresponds to an occasional knowledge linkage with limited content in terms of quality of the knowledge ow, whereas a value of 3 corresponds to a persistent knowledge linkage that carries negrained knowledge. It is worth remembering here that this study was designed to collect cross-sectional data only. Therefore, the relational data gathered through the above-mentioned roster studies refer to the very recent past in which the interviews have been carried out (maximum of two years).

170

Network analysis

obtained by pooling together the three clusters variables. Since data are coming from three dierent geographical clusters of rms, I applied the Moulton method (Moulton, 1990) to control for the possibility that the random disturbances in the regression are correlated within each cluster. Dependent Variable Performance at the rm level is measured here by an indicator of the quality achieved by each rms wines. The quality of worldwide wines is annually assessed and rated by international panels of experts and published in several specialized wine journals (for example, Wine Spectator, Decanter, Wine Enthusiast and Robert Parkers Guide). Having a wine rated by any of these international specialized journals is, rst, an acknowledgement of the qualitative properties of the wines, and second, a very powerful marketing device for a rm, since experts ratings strongly inuence market prices (Nerlove, 1995; Combris et al., 1997, 2000; Landon and Smith, 1997). The performance of a rm is therefore seen here as its capacity to develop new wines, which are valued as quality wines by international experts. The indicator adopted in this chapter is drawn from one of the above international wine journals: Wine Spectator.2 This journal wine rating is based on the quality assessment of an international panel of expert oenologists, who review more than 12 000 wines each year in blind tastings. After tasting, oenologists assign a score to each wine brand according to a 100point scale, ranging from 100, when the wine is of outstanding quality, to 50 when it is of poor quality.3 Certain information is listed with each rated wine: the wine vintage, the wine area and the market price. The indicator used here (RATING) is valued 1 when any of the rms wines has been assigned at least 70 points in years 200204, the minimum threshold for a wine to be considered of drinkable quality and to be recommended by the journal. It is valued 0 otherwise. A lag of two years is allowed between the year in which the interviews were carried out and the vintage of the most recent rated wines. It is worth noting that the majority of the wines tasted are submitted to Wine Spectator by the wineries or their US importers. Additionally, the journal spends substantial eort in buying and reviewing wines that are not submitted, at all price levels. Accordingly, a rms wines may not be rated for three main reasons. First, due to a selection bias, rms with poorquality achievements will have little incentive to send their wines to the journal for assessment. Second, US importers will not recommend and signal wines to Wine Spectator when they consider them of poor quality. Third, Wine Spectator itself selects out all the wineries producing very poor-quality wines. These considerations suggest therefore that rms

Networks and heterogeneous performance of cluster rms

171

whose wines are not rated tend to be poor performers. The same applies for rms whose wines are rated but are assigned less than 70 points. Using Wine Spectator as a unique source of information, however, may pose some robustness problems. Even if it is highly unlikely that a successful winery will not be spotted by the journal, it is still possible that some wineries are overlooked. In order to control for that, I correlated RATING and two other indicators drawn from Wine Spectators ratings the sum of scores per planted vineyard hectares (SSH) and the average price of rated wines normalized by the average price of rated wines in the cluster (PRICE) with an indicator of the relative performance of rms in the cluster as perceived by its members.4 I nd strong correlations between the perceived performance and the three Wine Spectator indicators: RATING (0.65**), SSH (0.65**) and PRICE (0.62**). These results suggest that the performance indicator RATING is robust enough to measure the quality of wines achieved by cluster rms. Independent Variables Firm knowledge base (KB) The knowledge base of the rm is measured by extracting a factor from the principal component analysis of the four variables listed in Table 8.2 (Point 1). The factor explains more than 75 per cent of variance and it has been calculated considering the pooled sample of rms. Embeddedness in the network of business interactions (BI_DC) This variable measures the extent to which a rm has established linkages for business matters with other rms in the cluster. The existence of a business interaction is mapped by the question in Table 8.2 (Point 2). The degree centrality of the network of business interactions (BI_DC(j)) is considered here a proxy of rms the relational embeddedness in the cluster. It is measured by the extent to which an actor j is central in a network on the basis of the ties that it has directly established with other i actors of the network ( (x(ji))). This measure uses undirected dichotomous data. The value has been normalized by its theoretical maximum (g 1), where g is the number of rms in each cluster. BI_DC( j) (x(ji) ) g 1.

Embeddedness in the knowledge network (KN_DC) This variable measures the degree to which a rm is central in the knowledge network, mapped using questions (i) and (ii) in Table 8.2 (Point 3). Also in this case the embeddedness of rms is measured by actor-level

172

Network analysis

degree centrality (KN_DC). This measure uses undirected dichotomous data. The value has been normalized by its theoretical maximum (g 1), where g is the number of rms in each cluster: KN_DC(j) Control Variables I control here for the following rm-level variables that are commonly associated with performance: the size of rms, measured by the log of employees (LEMP), the age of the rm (AGE), measured as the number of years since the start of operations until 2002. The ownership (OWN) which is a dummy variable indicating whether the rm is foreign (1) or domestic (0) owned. I also control for the type of organization. As shown by Table 8.1, rms in the clusters have four dierent types of organizational structures: ORG1 corresponds to rms that are part of a national group and perform all phases of the production process within the cluster; ORG2 refers to rms that are also part of a national group but perform only part of the production process, usually grape-growing, within the cluster; ORG3 refers to rms that are independently owned and that perform all production phases in the cluster, where the headquarter is also located; nally, ORG4 represents a residual category including cooperatives. (x( ji) ) g 1.

5.

EMPIRICAL RESULTS

Table 8.3 reports the descriptive statistics and the correlation matrix and Table 8.4 the results of the Probit estimation. Model 1 in Table 8.4 includes only the control variables, showing that only size is positively related to the likelihood of a rm being rated by Wine Spectator and therefore with its performance. Model 2 shows that the value of rm knowledge base is strongly and positively related to performance, a result that is in line with several other recent contributions (for example, Camison, 2004; Zaheer and Bell, 2005). This is explained by the fact that rms that have better-educated or moreexperienced knowledge workers (Drucker, 1993), and that carry higher internal experimentation intensity, are more likely to exploit knowledge for the generation of successful innovations (March, 1991). This in turn drives a rm to achieve higher performances (Wernerfelt, 1984). Model 3 provides support for the view that rms that interact for business matters are more likely to be good performers. This result is consistent with the fact that being co-located in the same industrial cluster, and being

Table 8.3
LEMP AGE OWNER ORG1 ORG2 ORG3 ORG4 KB

Descriptive statistics and correlation matrix


BI_DC KN_DC

Mean Std dev.

RATING

173
1.00 0.07 0.75*** 0.06 0.51*** 0.03 0.17* 1.00 0.44*** 0.03 0.09 0.12 0.35***

RATING LEMP AGE OWNER ORG1 ORG2 ORG3 ORG4 KB BI_DC KN_DC 1.00 0.01 0.18* 0.34*** 0.23*** 0.42*** 0.07 0.66*** 0.22*** 0.43*** 1.00 0.09 0.05 0.04 0.06 0.01 0.09 0.14 0.05 1.00 0.41*** 0.05 0.28*** 0.05 0.21*** 0.04 0.22*** 1.00 0.38*** 0.43*** 0.09 0.26 1.00 0.08 0.00 0.12

0.30 1.99 32.61 0.07 0.10 0.04 0.83 0.03 0.00 26.69 8.11

0.46 1.39 66.95 0.25 0.31 0.19 0.38 0.17 1.00 17.05 8.30

1.00 0.47*** 0.14 0.08 0.19* 0.31*** 0.26*** 0.11 0.50*** 0.37*** 0.64***

1.00 0.22*** 1.00 0.52*** 0.55***

1.00

Note:

* Signicant at 10%; ** Signicant at 5%; *** Signicant at 1%. Based on Pearson coecients.

174

Network analysis

Table 8.4
Dependent variables

Probit estimations with marginal eects


Model 1 Control variables only dF/dx (s.e.) Model 2 Knowledge base only Model 3 Knowledge base with BI_DC dF/dx (s.e.) 0.058 (0.052) 0.001 (0.000)** 0.015 (0.138) 0.067 (0.231) 0.181 (9.296)*** 0.006 (0.003)** Model 4 Knowledge base with KN_DC dF/dx (s.e.) 0.064 (0.071) 0.000 (0.000)*** 0.146 (0.084) 0.022 (0.334) 0.083 (0.017)*** Model 5 Knowledge base with BI_DC and KN_DC dF/dx (s.e.) 0.063 (0.770) 0.000 (0.000)*** 0.146 (0.082) 0.024 (0.335) 0.085 (0.018)*** 0.000 (0.001) 0.026 (0.006)*** 96 33.698371 0.4092

dF/dx (s.e.) 0.063 (0.070) 0.000 (0.000)*** 0.146 (0.082) 0.024 (0.335) 0.085 (0.018)***

LEMP AGE OWNER ORG3a KB BI_DC KN_DC N Log pseudolikelihood Pseudo R2

0.140 (0.052)** 0.000 (0.000)* 0.019 (0.099) 0.067 (0.225)

96 46.003222 0.1934

96 41.330488 0.2745

96 38.942215 0.3170

0.027 (0.005)*** 96 33.722975 0.4087

Note: * Signicant at 10%; ** Signicant at 5%; *** Signicant at 1%. aORG1, ORG2 and ORG4 have been dropped due to collinearity.

embedded in the local network, may facilitate access to relevant information or may ease inter-rm transactions. In this case, rms may benet from several types of externalities and enhance their performance accordingly. This evidence seems to support the view that both intra-rm resources and relational proximity matter for rm performance (Capello and Faggian, 2005). However, no evidence is found that the latter matters more than the former. Model 4 nds a strong and positive relationship between the degree of rms embeddedness in the knowledge network and their performance. This is in line with most of organizational sociologys literature (for example, Powell et al., 1996; Smith-Doerr and Powell, 2003), since the access to external sources of knowledge for the solution of internal problems favours innovation and enhances rm performance. The interesting result here is that the coecient of KN_DC is higher in Model 4 than the

Networks and heterogeneous performance of cluster rms

175

coecient of BI_DC in Model 3. Furthermore, when both BI_DC and KN_DC are considered in the estimation (Model 5), BI_DC ceases to be signicant, while both KB and KN_DC persist in being positive and strongly signicant.5 The results of this study indicate that both rm internal capabilities, and the degree to which rms are embedded in local networks, matter for their performance. However, it is relevant to note that it is a specic type of network that aects performance most: the knowledge network. It is reasonable to argue that this is connected to the structural properties of this network. As illustrated by Giuliani (2006), the knowledge network is formed on a selective rather than pervasive, collective basis. This is due to two factors: rst, rms with stronger knowledge bases have more to transfer and are understandably more likely to be targeted by other rms for technical advice. Second, rms with stronger knowledge bases will seek technical advice from equally advanced rms, thus targeting rms with strong knowledge bases in their search for external knowledge (Giuliani and Bell, 2005). On the basis of this, communities of knowledge are formed in clusters by a restricted group of equally advanced rms. An implication of selectivity is that the knowledge that is circulated within the community is likely to be of valuable content, which in turn enriches the knowledge base of the member rms and, consequently, their performance. It is therefore reasonable to argue that this evidence casts doubts on the importance of meso-level conditions, such as geographical, sectoral and relational proximity, for performance. More convincingly, it seems that knowledge endowments aect performance both directly and indirectly through the generation of a local knowledge network, which serves to enhance individual rms capabilities.

6.

CONCLUSION

This chapter has attempted to understand the factors that inuence rm performance in industrial clusters. Taking an evolutionary approach to this domain of studies, it has shown that the heterogeneous distribution of rm knowledge bases is related to their performance, both directly and indirectly through the participation in the local knowledge community. Following up on a previous study (Giuliani, 2006), this novel empirical evidence shows that, in spite of pervasive business interactions, the performance of rms is unevenly distributed in the clusters. The econometric estimations provide support for this and show that rm performance in clusters depends on their internal capabilities (that is, knowledge bases) and their capability of being connected to the local knowledge network. More importantly, this empirical evidence seems consistent with the fact that

176

Network analysis

similar meso characteristics that is, the geographic and relational proximity of rms constitute the substratum neither for collectively shared knowledge ows (Giuliani, 2006). On this basis, two considerations can be raised. First, one should be extremely careful in associating the concept of industrial clusters with enhanced performance and competitiveness, even when rms are geographically and relationally proximate. Instead, more rigorous studies should be carried out in the future that analyse the interplay between rms, the cluster knowledge network, and performance. Second, as recently suggested by Markusen (2003), more rigorous analysis in regional studies will provide better indications for policy makers. Indeed, this study supports the view that cluster performance is more likely to be enhanced by strengthening rms knowledge bases rather than by pooling rms together in the same geographical area (as is the case of technopoles (OECD, 2000)) or by promoting inter-rm networking per se (UNCTAD, 2001; UNIDO, 2001).

NOTES
* The author would like to thank Gustavo Crespi and Koen Frenken for comments on a previous version of this chapter. Thanks go also to Marcelo Lorca Navarro, Cristian Diaz Bravo, Erica Nardi and Elena Bartoli for their support during eldwork. Financial support by the UK Economic and Social Research Council (PTA-026-27-0644) is also gratefully acknowledged. The lists of rms are drawn from ocial sources: the S.A.G. (Servicio Agricola y Ganadero) for Chile and the provinces of Pisa and Livorno for Italy. The choice of the journal was done on the basis of two criteria: free availability on the web and coverage (countries, vintages, wine areas). The rating is based on the following criteria: 95100 Classic: a great wine; 9094 Outstanding: superior character and style; 8589 Very good: wine with special qualities; 8084 Good: a solid, well-made wine; 7079 Average; drinkable wine that may have minor aws; 6069 Below average; drinkable but not recommended; 5059 Poor; undrinkable, not recommended. The questionnaire included a question asking the respondents to name the rms in their cluster that they perceived as having achieved high performance in terms of quality of wines and commercial success. Given the existence of a positive relationship between two of the independent variables, KB and KN_nDC (Giuliani, 2005), simultaneous equation modelling would have given more robust or insightful econometric estimations. This model is applied in other forthcoming works by the author.

1. 2. 3.

4. 5.

REFERENCES
Allen, R.C. (1983), Collective invention, Journal of Economic Behaviour and Organization, 4: 124.

Networks and heterogeneous performance of cluster rms

177

Amin, A. and Cohendet, P. (2004), Architectures of Knowledge: Firms, Capabilities and Communities, Oxford: Oxford University Press. Arrow, K.J. (1962), Economic welfare and the allocation of resources for invention, in R.R. Nelson (ed.), The Rate and Direction of Inventive Activity, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University, pp. 60926. Audretsch, D. and Feldman, M.P. (1996), R&D spillovers and the geography of innovation and production, American Economic Review, 86: 63040. Baptista, R. (2000), Do innovations diuse faster within geographical clusters?, International Journal of Industrial Organization, 18: 51535. Barney, J.B. (1991), Firm resources and sustained competitive advantage, Journal of Management, 17: 99120. Bell, M. and Albu, M. (1999), Knowledge systems and technological dynamism in industrial clusters in developing countries, World Development, 27: 171534. Borgatti, S.P., Everett, M.G. and Freeman, L.C. (2002), Ucinet 6 for Windows, Harvard, MA: Analytic Technologies. Boschma, R.A. (2005), Proximity and innovation: a critical assessment, Regional Studies, 39(1): 6174. Boschma, R.A. and Frenken, K. (2006), Why is economic geography not an evolutionary science? Towards an evolutionary economic geography, Journal of Economic Geography, 6(3): 273302. Boschma, R.A. and Lambooy, J.G. (1999), Evolutionary economics and economic geography, Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 9: 41129. Breschi, S. and Lissoni, F. (2001), Knowledge spillovers and Local Innovation Systems: a critical survey, Industrial and Corporate Change, 10: 9751005. Camison, C. (2004), Shared, competitive and comparative advantages: a competencebased view of industrial-district competitiveness, Environment and Planning, A36: 222756. Capello, R. (1999), Spatial transfer of knowledge in high technology milieux: learning versus collective learning processes, Regional Studies, 33: 35365. Capello, R. and Faggian, A. (2005), Collective learning and relational capital in local innovation processes, Regional Studies, 39(1): 7587. Cohen, W.M. and Levinthal, D.A. (1990), Absorptive capacity a new perspective on learning and innovation, Administrative Science Quarterly, 35(1): 12852. Combris, P., Lecocq, S. and Visser, M. (1997), Estimation of hedonic price equation for Bordeaux wine: does quality matter?, Economic Journal, 107: 390402. Combris, P., Lecocq, S. and Visser, M. (2000), Estimation of hedonic price equation for Burgundy wine, Applied Economics, 32: 96167. Dosi, G. (1988), Sources, procedures and microeconomic eects of innovation, Journal of Economic Literature, 26: 112071. Dosi, G. (1997), Opportunities, incentives and the collective patterns of technological change, Economic Journal, 107: 153047. Drucker, P. (1993), Post Capitalist Society, New York: Harper Business. Feldman, M.P. (1999), The new economics of innovation, spillovers and agglomeration: a review of empirical studies, The Economics of Innovation and New Technology, 8: 525. Giuliani, E. (2006), The selective nature of knowledge networks in clusters: evidence from the wine industry, Journal of Economic Geography, in press. Giuliani, E. and Bell, M. (2005), The micro-determinants of meso-level learning and innovation: evidence from a Chilean wine cluster, Research Policy, 34(1): 4768.

178

Network analysis

Granovetter, M. (1985), Economic action and social structure: the problem of embeddedness, American Journal of Sociology, 91: 481510. Grant, R.M. (1996), Toward a knowledge-based theory of the rm, Strategic Management Journal, 17: 10922. Gulati, R. (1998), Alliances and networks, Strategic Management Journal, 19: 293317. Howells, J.R.L. (2002), Tacit knowledge, innovation and economic geography, Urban Studies, 39(56): 87184. Jae, A.B. (1989), Real eects of academic research, American Economic Review, 79: 98499. Jae, A.B., Trajtenberg, M. and Henderson, R. (1993), Geographic localization of knowledge spillovers as evidence from patent citations, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 188: 57798. Krugman, P. (1991), Geography and Trade, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Landon, S. and Smith, C.E. (1997), The use of quality and reputation indicators by consumers: the case of Bordeaux wine, Journal of Consumer Policy, 20: 289323. Lazerson, M.H. and Lorenzoni, G. (1999), The rms that feed industrial districts: a return to the Italian source, Industrial and Corporate Change, 8: 23566. March, J.G. (1991), Exploration and exploitation in organizational learning, Organization Science, 2(1): 7187. Markusen, A. (2003), Fuzzy concepts, scanty evidence, policy distance: the case for rigour and policy relevance in critical regional studies, Regional Studies, 37: 70117. Marshall, A. (1919), Industry and Trade, London: Macmillan. Marshall, A. (1920), Principles of Economics, London: Macmillan. Martin, R. and Sunley, P. (2003), Deconstructing clusters: chaotic concept or policy panacea?, Journal of Economic Geography, 3(1): 535. Maskell, P. (2001a), Towards a knowledge-based theory of the geographical cluster, Industrial and Corporate Change, 10: 92143. Maskell, P. (2001b), The rm in economic geography, Economic Geography, 77(4): 32944. Maskell, P. and Malmberg, A. (1999), Localised learning and industrial competitiveness, Cambridge Journal of Economics, 23(2), 16786. Molina-Morales, F.X. and Martinez-Fernandez, M.T. (2004), How much dierence is there between industrial district rms? A net value creation approach, Research Policy, 33: 47386. Moulton, B.R. (1990), An illustration of a pitfall in estimating the eects of aggregate variables on micro units, Review of Economics and Statistics, 72(2): 3348. Nelson, R.R. and Winter, S.G. (1982), An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change, Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press. Nerlove, M. (1995), Hedonic price function and the measurement of preferences: the case of Swedish wine consumers, European Economic Review, 39: 1697716. Nuvolari, A. (2004), Collective invention during the British Industrial Revolution: the case of the Cornish pumping engine, Cambridge Journal of Economics, 28(2): 34763. Oerlemans, L.G. and Meeus, M.T.H. (2005), Do organizational and spatial proximity impact on rm performance?, Regional Studies, 39(1): 89104. Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) (2000), Local partnership, clusters and SME globalisation, Conference for Ministers responsible for SMEs and Industry Ministers, Bologna, Italy, 1415 June.

Networks and heterogeneous performance of cluster rms

179

Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) (2001), Innovative Clusters: Drivers of National Innovation Systems, Paris: OECD. Penrose, E. (1959), The Theory of the Growth of the Firm, Oxford: Blackwell. Pinch, S., Henry, N., Jenkins, M. and Tallman, S. (2003), From industrial districts to knowledge clusters: a model of knowledge dissemination and competitive advantage in industrial agglomerations, Journal of Economic Geography, 3: 37388. Piore, M.J. and Sabel, C.F. (1984), The Second Industrial Divide: Possibility for Prosperity, New York: Basic Books. Porter, M. (1998), On Competition, Cambridge, MA: Harvard Business Review Series. Porter, M. (1990), The Competitive Advantage of Nations, London: Macmillan. Powell, W.W., Koput, K.W. and Smith-Doerr, L. (1996), Interorganizational collaboration and the locus of innovation: networks of learning in biotechnology, Administrative Science Quarterly, 41: 10645. Pyke, F., Becattini, G. and Sengenberger, W. (1990), Industrial Districts and Interrm Co-operation in Italy, Geneva: International Institute for Labour Studies. Rabellotti, R. and Schmitz, H. (1999), The internal heterogeneity of industrial districts in Italy, Brazil and Mexico, Regional Studies, 33(2): 97108. Rodan, S. and Galunic, C. (2004), More than network structure: how knowledge heterogeneity inuences managerial performance and innovativeness, Strategic Management Journal, 25: 54162. Scott, A.J. (1998), Regions and the World Economy: The Coming Shape of Global Production, Competition and Political Order, Oxford and New York: Oxford University Press. Smith-Doerr, L. and Powell, W.W. (2003), Networks and economic life, in N. Smelser and Swedberg, R. (eds), The Handbook of Economic Sociology, London and Princeton, NJ: Russell Sage Foundation and Princeton University Press. UNCTAD (2001), World Development Report: Promoting Linkages, Geneva, New York: United Nations Conference on Trade and Development. UNIDO (2001), Development of Clusters and Networks of SMEs, Vienna: United Nations Industrial Development Organization. Wasserman, S. and Faust, K. (1994), Social Network Analysis: Methods and Applications, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Wernerfelt, B. (1984), A resource-based view of the rm, Strategic Management Journal, 5: 17180. Zaheer, A. and Bell, G.G. (2005), Beneting from network position: rm capabilities, structural holes and performance, Strategic Management Journal, 26: 80925.

9. Social networks and the economics of networks


Daniel Birke*
1. INTRODUCTION

The work by Arthur (1989) and the other literature on path dependence are prominent in many evolutionary arguments. Path dependence arises in increasing return technologies and describes the property that for many technologies, historically small events can have a profound and lasting impact on the development path of technologies. It is well understood that technologies with increasing returns can exhibit multiple equilibria and that these equilibria can often be local rather than global optima. Causes for increasing returns can be learning and network eects. The models of path dependence, however, have been based on rather simple assumptions about the choice behaviour of consumers in markets with network eects. The empirical question remains: how do consumers choose between rival products in a market with network eects? Consumers interact with other consumers in a variety of ways. Information about products and services is often spread by word of mouth and individuals are more likely to choose a product about which they have heard from a friend or which they have tried out with the help of a friend. In many cases, consumers also try to associate themselves with their peer group by consuming similar goods, try to imitate consumption behaviour of groups which they regard as having higher social status and try to distinguish themselves from groups with lower social status (see Cowan et al., 1997). Network eects have been treated in the literature mainly as an only positive peer eect, where every individual is a peer of everyone else, that is, where this peer eect is anonymous. Here, we analyse the impact of peer groups on choice behaviour applied to the case of mobile telephony. After the seminal article of Rohlfs (1974), and the inuential papers of Farrell and Saloner (1985) and Katz and Shapiro (1985), there has been a plethora of theoretical studies into the nature of network eects and by now network eects theory has reached a rather mature state. The literature on network eects typically distinguishes between two types of such
180

Social networks and the economics of networks

181

eects: direct and indirect. Direct network eects refer to the case where users directly benet from other users of the same network. In mobile telecommunications, a direct network eect arises when a user can call a larger set of other users. Indirect network eects, on the other hand, arise because bigger networks support a larger range of complementary products and services. In second generation mobile networks, indirect network eects are only of second-order signicance, but they will play an increasing role after the introduction of third generation networks, where usage will be heavily inuenced by the availability of data services. Mobile networks are highly compatible with each other from a technical point of view. Users typically do not experience any quality dierence between calls made to the same network and calls made to other networks. Network eects are mainly induced by network operators through higher prices for calls to other networks (o-net calls) than for calls to the same network (on-net calls). This pricing strategy is pursued by operators in most European countries. In a previous paper (Birke and Swann, 2006), we have shown that choice of mobile phone operators is strongly coordinated within households and that this eect is far more important for operator choice than the eect of overall network size. This is interesting in the context of the network eects literature, as an often assumed equivalence between direct and indirect network eects hinges on the assumption that only overall network size matters and not who is on the network. Whereas this assumption seems tenable for markets with indirect network eects, it is doubtful for markets with direct network eects. In these markets, consumers are interested primarily in which of their interaction partners uses the same technology and rather less in the overall number of users. This chapter looks directly at operator choice in a social network. For this purpose, we conducted a survey of a class of undergraduate students at Nottingham University Business School, asking them to identify their social network and lling in a questionnaire about their mobile phone usage. We thus were able to obtain a relatively well-bounded network. Obviously, students do have a social network apart from their university class, but the results show that interaction between students was strong within class and that students coordinated operator choice within this social network and in particular among students sharing geographical origin. Network data analysis exhibits two distinctive features that have to be addressed by the researcher. First, observations are not independent of each other. We shall try to overcome this problem of structural autocorrelation by using a technique called quadratic assignment procedure for permutationbased estimation of standard errors (see Krackhardt, 1988). Second, observations often are not drawn from a random sample. In our case, the student sample is a convenience sample and we certainly cannot claim to be close to

182

Network analysis

a random sample. This limits the generalisability of the results, but, as we shall discuss later, it also yields some interesting results that we would not have obtained with a random sampling approach. This chapter is organised as follows. Section 2 discusses social network analysis and its usefulness for researchers interested in evolutionary economics. Section 3 gives a brief introduction to the UK mobile telecommunications market. Section 4 outlines the approach taken with the survey. It presents descriptive analysis of students attitudes towards mobile telecommunications and a description of the social network within the class. This is followed by a graphical and statistical analysis. Section 5 discusses the results.

2. SOCIAL NETWORK ANALYSIS AND EVOLUTIONARY ECONOMICS


Research on social networks (and indeed networks in general) has increased rapidly in the last two decades and is undertaken in a variety of dierent disciplines (see Borgatti and Foster, 2003). Social network analysis (SNA) has its root in sociology and in its early years has been widely used to analyse interaction between individuals. These interactions can take on a variety of forms, from friendship over business to sexual relationships. However, SNA is not limited to social networks, but can be applied to the analysis of networks in general. Economics has been slow to make use of advances in social network analysis and only recently have such studies been conducted in higher numbers and especially in elds associated with evolutionary economics (see, for example, Breschi and Lissoni, 2004; Giuliani, this volume; Maggioni and Uberti, this volume). Why is social network analysis particularly helpful for researchers in the tradition of evolutionary economics? SNA is inherently relational, contextual and systemic, which is similar to how many researchers associated with evolutionary economics see the world and their discipline. Evolutionary economics emphasises the role that diversity of people or organisations plays for the understanding of economic processes (see Metcalfe, 1998). Furthermore, constraints in learning and in the selection process make evolutionary economics much more inclined to structural theories of economic interaction than mainstream economics, where most of the interactions occur in an (anonymous) marketplace. Both, learning and selection environment are argued to be highly localised both socially and geographically (see Antonelli, 1995) and one main reason for this localisation is the underlying structural patterns of interaction. A central theme of evolutionary economics is the importance of innovation and a rich variety of academic papers focus on the innovation

Social networks and the economics of networks

183

process. Closely intertwined with this topic is the role of knowledge and how knowledge is acquired by rms. It is generally recognised that a high percentage of knowledge is not readily codiable and is transmitted through direct interaction between individuals. The paper by Cowan and Jonard (2004), for example, is work along these lines; it looks at the relationship between network structure and diusion performance in a knowledge barter process and is based on the idea of small-world networks. In general, there is high interest among researchers in the evolutionary tradition in using agent-based simulations to capture economic phenomena and here again in particular in innovation research (see, for example, the discussion in Frenken (2006) and the references therein). A common theme to a lot of this work is a rejection of the standard assumption of uniform agents interacting with other agents through an anonymous marketplace. Network structure plays an important role as an underlying assumption of how agents interact or as a key parameter that is varied and analysed by the researcher. However, for simplicity the literature often assumes completely regular network structures or easy network generation mechanisms and it is therefore important to confront these models with empirical ndings. In the recent past, there has also been an increasing interest in empirical work examining and using network structure. Cantner and Graf (2005) employ SNA to describe and analyse the evolution of the innovator network in the town of Jena, Germany and Giulianis chapter in this volume looks at knowledge networks in the Italian and Chilean wine industry. Other works, like Murmanns (2003) book on the economic history of the dye industry, have used social network analysis in a descriptive way to portray the academic industrial dye knowledge network in the nineteenth century. Likewise, there is a growing literature in sociology about how economic transactions are embedded in social relationships (see Uzzi, 1996). Friendship ties with competitors, for example, have been found to improve the performance of hotels in Sydney due to enhanced collaboration, mitigated competition and better information exchange (see Ingram and Roberts, 2000). These networks can further be used for the eective social enforcement of rules and norms of doing business. Contrary to these contributions, this chapter will focus exclusively on the demand side of the market an area that remains scarcely studied.

3. THE MOBILE TELECOMMUNICATIONS INDUSTRY IN THE UK


In the United Kingdom, there are four main Global System for Mobile Communications (GSM) operators: Vodafone, O2, T-Mobile and Orange

184
60 50 40 30 20 10

Network analysis

No. of subscribers

Figure 9.1

and a purely third generation operator: 3. O2 (Cellnet) and Vodafone started operation in 1985 with analogue mobile networks.1 There had been relatively slow growth until the entry of T-Mobile (One-to-One) and Orange after 1993 introduced stronger competition to the market. However, the market really took o with the widespread use of prepaid cards, which made mobile telephony attractive for the mass market and especially for low-usage consumers. Although a rst prepaid tari was launched by Vodafone in September 1996, prepaid usage became popular only after mid-1998. As Figure 9.1 shows, this led to a period of rapid expansion in the number of subscribers, which lasted roughly until early/mid-2001. After the burst of the stock market bubble in mid-2001, operators cleaned up their customer base of inactive consumers (note the short decline in Figure 9.1) and have since continued to grow, but this time more gradually and with a stronger focus on increasing the average revenue per user (ARPU) and on upgrading prepaid customers to post-paid customers. In 2004, operators alone generate around 11 billion of revenues per year. However, as the market is by now reaching saturation with a penetration rate of over 85 per cent, future revenue growth has to come from an increased ARPU rather than from a bigger customer base. In May 2000, the four GSM operators and 3 were awarded licences for third generation Universal Mobile Telephone System (UMTS) networks for about 4 billion each. Many expect that 3G networks will further boost revenues in the mobile telecommunications market. In 2003, 3 introduced the rst third generation network in the UK. After a slow start, the company now has over 3 million users. The other companies recently followed with their own third generation networks.

Q 1 1 Q 994 1 1 Q 995 1 1 Q 996 1 1 Q 997 1 1 Q 998 1 1 Q 999 1 2 Q 000 1 2 Q 001 1 2 Q 002 1 2 Q 003 1 20 04

Number of subscribers in the UK (in millions)

Social networks and the economics of networks


40% 35% 30% 25% 20% 15% 10%
4 1 Q 998 2 1 Q 999 4 1 Q 999 2 2 Q 000 4 2 Q 000 2 20 Q 01 4 2 Q 001 2 2 Q 002 4 2 Q 002 2 2 Q 003 4 2 Q 003 2 20 04

185

Vodafone O2 T-Mobile Orange

Figure 9.2

Development of subscriber market shares

Especially interesting for our analysis is the development of market shares (see Figure 9.2). At the end of 1998, the market was dominated by the incumbent operators O2 and Vodafone, which together accounted for almost 70 per cent of the market. However, by the beginning of 2001 this lead had dissipated and subscriber market shares were levelled. Today, the market is about equally split among the four GSM operators.2 The ability of T-Mobile and Orange to catch up with the incumbent operators is somewhat unique to the UK market and is dierent from, for example, the German market in which the two biggest operators (T-Mobile and Vodafone) still control about 80 per cent of the market and have reported stable market shares in recent years. With strong network eects present in the market, this catch-up by T-Mobile and Orange is surprising, as network eects result in a strong tendency towards higher market concentration. It could be argued that the development in the UK market is due to the high compatibility between networks. However, in Birke and Swann (2006) we showed that network eects do play an important role in the adoption of mobile telephones and in operator choice.

4. COORDINATION OF CHOICE OF MOBILE PHONE OPERATORS


The Survey To analyse how consumers coordinate their choice of mobile phone operator with their social network, we looked at a network from a class of undergraduate students. We expected mobile phones to be a rather important tool of interaction for this group and the network to be rather well

186

Network analysis

bounded with a high percentage of intra-network interaction. The sample consists of students from a second-year undergraduate course called Economics of Organisation B, which was held at Nottingham University Business School in spring 2005. Most students from this course study for a three-year degree and have been studying together in a variety of other courses for about 18 months. Although most students can be expected to use their mobile phone to interact with many people outside the class, a reasonably regular interaction between the students can be assumed. The questionnaire on which the survey is based consists of two parts. In the rst part, we asked students for some demographic details and about their attitudes and behaviour with regard to mobile phones. Information on operator choice and demographic variables like gender and nationality are used as input for the regression analysis. The other answers are mainly used to gain insights into how the respondents use their mobile phones and for a rst descriptive analysis. In the second part of the questionnaire, students were handed out a list of course participants and were asked to identify themselves and the people they communicate with. The exact wording of the question was Please tick the people that you call.3 Thus, we are able to build up a network of the relevant communication relations within the class. Both parts took about 10 minutes to ll in and were distributed and collected during one session of Economics of Organisation B. A total of 236 students registered for this course. From these students, 171 lled in the rst part of the questionnaire (the questions part) of whom 158 were identied as students from the course list. Of the remaining 13 students, three respondents indicated that their name was not on the list and another 10 did not identify themselves. To every student for whom we did not receive an identied questionnaire (which mostly included students who missed class), we sent out a reminder email and consequently received another four responses. In total, this resulted in 175 completed question parts and 159 completed roster parts, which is a response rate of 74 and 67 per cent, respectively. For most of the descriptive statistics, all 175 responses are used and for all analysis relating to social networks only the subsample of 159 students is used. All of the students are undergraduate students and are almost of the same age. There is about an even number of male (48 per cent) and female (52 per cent) students among the respondents. Importantly for our analysis, the share of foreign students is rather high, with only slightly over half of the students originating from the UK and with another 8 per cent coming from other European countries (see Table 9.1). Chinese students are the second biggest group in the course (22 per cent). The high number of foreign students is interesting for us, as we expect that students who come to the UK primarily to study would have a social

Social networks and the economics of networks

187

Table 9.1

Gender and nationality of respondents


British Other European 9 (64.3%) 5 (35.7%) Chinese 6 (15.4%) 33 (84.6%) Other Asian 4 (23.5%) 13 (76.5%) Africans 5 (50%) 5 (50%) The Americas 0 3 (100%) Total 84 (48%) 91 (52%)

Male Female

60 (65.2%) 32 (34.8%)

network that revolves more around their university class than that of British students. As can also be seen from Table 9.1 the majority of Chinese and other Asian students are female, while the majority of English and other European students are male. Criteria for Choice of Mobile Phone Operator A rst option to analyse why the respondents chose their operators is to ask them directly about their choice criteria. Table 9.2 gives the response frequencies for a number of criteria. Quality, special oers, cost of calls and operator choice of friends and family all seem to be important. The obvious drawbacks of directly asking respondents about their choice criteria are the diculties of comparing the relative importance of the dierent factors. Furthermore, it is not always clear whether the given answers are the actual reasons for choosing an operator or whether it is an ex post rationalisation of the choice process. Quality of the network, for example, is named as an important criterion by most respondents. However, the quality of the four GSM networks in the UK is roughly equivalent in terms of most quality characteristics such as network coverage, international roaming and customer service.4 We might rather measure the general importance that the respondents attribute to quality when choosing a product than the particular importance for mobile phone networks. Of course, a precondition for consumers coordinating their operator choice is some knowledge about what operators their peers use. This is far from given, as mobile networks are hard to identify from telephone numbers. In the UK, there are several hundred prexes associated with the dierent networks.5 This is contrary to, for example, Germany where there are only 23 prexes, which makes it far easier to identify people who are using the same operator especially in the earlier years of mobile phone adoption when not all of these prexes were used. In general, operator identication from telephone numbers is easier in smaller countries where fewer dierent prexes are needed to cover all subscribers.

188

Network analysis

Table 9.2

Frequencies for choice criteria


Strongly Agree Neither Dis- Strongly Dont agree nor agree disagree know (1) (2) (3) (4) (5)

Quality of the network (e.g. network coverage, roaming possibilities etc.) Special oer Cost of calls, text messages in general It is cheaper, because my friends/family use the same network Cost of handset Handsets available from this operator More services available (games etc.) Good customer service

27

80

28

11

52 48 49

59 62 43

31 25 38

10 16 19

6 4 9

2 2 1

28 21 3 15

55 43 21 49

41 40 54 55

17 31 46 16

9 14 26 13

4 5 4 7

Table 9.3

Do you know which operator your friends/family/partner use?


Know it Know it for some 80 (46.5%) 22 (13.7%) Dont know it 14 (8.1%) 16 (9.9%) 18 (22.5%)

My friends My family members My partner

78 (45.4%) 123 (76.4%) 62 (77.5%)

Information on who else is using the same network therefore has to be obtained by other channels in the UK. It seems likely that the availability of this information is directly linked to the closeness of two individuals in the social network. This information could then be obtained either through direct conversation or through identifying the operator from a mobile phone. The latter requires that the name or logo of the operator is conspicuously placed on the mobile phone, which is only the case for cobranded mobiles. In recent years, operators try to raise the awareness of their brand and increasingly place their logos on mobile phones next to the logos of the mobile phone manufacturer, or mobile phones exclusively carry the brand of the network operator. According to Table 9.3, respondents claim to know the mobile network operator for a high percentage of their peers. Especially the operators

Social networks and the economics of networks

189

used by family members and partners are known by the large majority. The lower gure of knowledge for operators used by friends is an indicator that operator coordination between friends might be lower than within households. Network Statistics Besides an analysis of individual respondents, we can also analyse the characteristics of the social network as a whole. A rst measure characterising the overall network is its density. For directed graphs, it is calculated as L/N(N1) with L being the number of lines present and with N (N1) giving the maximum number of lines potentially present in a directed network of N people. In our case, N is the number of students that lled in the roster of the questionnaire, which is 159. In total, 815 dierent relations were identied. However, 195 relations are to non-respondents in the class and only 620 are to respondents, resulting in a density of g 620/(159*158) 0.0247. At the individual level this network density stems from an average of 3.90 nominations. It is hard to judge whether this is a rather dense or a rather loose network. Overall network density obviously depends on network size, as people have only a limited capacity to communicate with other people. Furthermore, our measure of Who do you call? can be assumed to refer to rather close contacts compared, for example, with the question Who do you know?. Network density can also be measured at an individual level, that is, one can calculate the network density of each individuals network. If individual x has n friends, then this local network density measure gives the percentage of ties present between the n friends. Individual 1, for example, has six friends. Those six friends have 28 ties between each other, out of a possible t n(n 1) 6*5 30 ties, resulting in a local network density of 1 0.93. Table 9.4 gives the frequencies of local network density for dierent numbers of friends. The local networks observed in the course are rather tight cliques with an average local density of 0.52. Rather dense cliques should favour a coordination of operator choice. Table 9.4 also shows that local network density decreases with the number of friends. Clearly, larger networks are less closely interconnected. If every node in a graph is connected to all other nodes via a path, then the graph is said to be connected and consists of one single component. If there are disconnected subsets, several components exist. The number of components can be calculated in two dierent ways. First, one can calculate the number of weak components, that is, two persons are in the same component, if one of them can reach the other. Second, strong components require that both persons can reach each other. In undirected or

190

Network analysis

Table 9.4

Local network density


No. of friends 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 Mean 2 138

No. of 28 28 22 26 15 7 7 3 0 observations Local network 0.71 0.57 0.47 0.48 0.41 0.41 0.33 0.35 density

0.1 0.52

18% 16% 14% 12% 10% 8% 6% 4% 2% 0% 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12

Figure 9.3

Distribution of distances between nodes

symmetrical networks, these measures coincide, but in our case, we have a directed network and consequently we get two measures. Calculating weak components, we end up with three components in the network (plus two students who only nominated students who did not respond). The largest component consists of the large majority of students altogether 146 students are part of this component (92 per cent). The next largest component consists of nine students and then there is a third group of two students who nominated each other, but did not nominate anyone else (and were not nominated by other students). The result is an indication that the class network can really be seen as one network. The average distance between two reachable nodes in the network is 5.7 (s.d. 2.3) with a maximum of 12 steps needed to reach the nal node. Out of a potential N(N 1) 159*158 25122, 18151 pairs can reach each one another (72 per cent). The distribution of distances between these pairs is displayed in Figure 9.3. The distances are roughly normally distributed and the distribution has a mode of 6. Although the large majority of nodes belong to the same component, the average path length is rather long and has a considerable variance, which

Social networks and the economics of networks

191

already hints at some clustering in the network, which can be further analysed using graphical techniques. Graphical Analysis of Social Network Social networks can very usefully be analysed by graphical representations of these networks, in particular in the case of medium-sized networks with a couple of hundred nodes.6 Figure 9.4 depicts the social network within the class of students, based on their communication pattern. It is a directed graph and arrows depict the direction of the nominations from the roster. The graph was created using a spring embedding algorithm from UCI-NET, which is based on the idea of simulating the social network graph as a system of mass particles. Nodes are the mass particles and the edges are springs between the particles, while the algorithm tries to minimise the energy of this system. Some form of clustering immediately becomes obvious. First, shapes of the objects, depicting nationalities, are highly clustered. Chinese students for example (up triangles) almost exclusively communicate with other Chinese students. At the bottom right of the graph, there is a group of Asian students who even form a distinct component and have only communication links within the group. This is the second largest component from the previous section. Two Spanish students form the third largest component, which can also be found at the bottom right of the graph. Finally, there are two isolates at the upper left. Second, the graph shows a clustering of shades, which are depicting main operator chosen.7 This clustering of shades clearly occurs along nationality lines. Chinese students are in the majority using Vodafone and similar tendencies can be observed for other nationalities. However, there also seems to be a coordination of operators within nationalities, that is, also within nationalities students that call each other tend to use the same mobile phone operator. The strong correlation of operator choice within nationalities also becomes clear by a cross-tabulation of nationality and operator used (see Table 9.5). Almost 80 per cent of Chinese students choose Vodafone. Similarly, almost half of the British students opted for an O2 mobile, whereas six out of 10 Africans use T-Mobile. Regression Results The original data of communications patterns are organised in a square matrix of 159 rows and columns with 1s indicating a communication relationship and 0s indicating the absence of a communication relationship. As is common for network data, diagonal values are not allowed. For a

Key
Vodafone Virgin Orange Other operators 3 T-Mobile O2

192

Shapes British

Other European

Chinese

Other Asians

Africans

The Americas

Figure 9.4

Interaction network of students

Social networks and the economics of networks

193

Table 9.5

Mobile phone operators and nationality


British Other Chinese European 3 (23.1%) 5 (38.5%) 2 (15.4%) 0 0 3 (23.1%) 13 Other Asian Africans 2 (20%) 0 2 (20%) 6 0 0 10 The Americas 0 1 (33.3%) 0 0 (60%) 1 (33.3%) 1 (33.3%) 3 Total 23 (13.5%) 54 (31.8%) 24 (14.1%) 12 (7.1%) 3 (1.8%) 54 (31.8%)

10 (11.1%) O2 42 (46. 7%) Orange 17 (18.9%) T-Mobile 6 (6.7%) Virgin 2 (2.2%) Vodafone 13 (14.4%) Total 90

5 3 (13.5%) (17.7%) 1 5 (2.7%) (29.4%) 2 1 (5.4%) (5.9%) 0 0 0 0

29 8 (78.4%) (47.1%) 37 17

regression analysis, this matrix is transformed into dyadic relationships (relationships between two nodes). We therefore get N(N 1) 25122 dierent dyads. When using network data, the assumption of ordinary least squares (OLS) and logit models that observations are independent fails. Observations are clearly not independent as there are at least N 1 dyads involving every individual. This correlation between observations involving the same nodes stems, for example, from the fact that it is far more likely to have the same operator as your friends if you use an operator with a high market share in the network. This would result in a positive correlation between observations from the same row or column and consequently, while parameter estimates are unbiased, estimated p-values overstate the signicance level. One possibility to adjust for incorrect standard errors is the quadratic assignment procedure (QAP) as proposed by Krackhardt (1987, and 1988) for social network data. The idea of QAP is to permute rows and columns of the original data matrix for the dependent variable and then to re-estimate the original regression model. This process is reiterated to obtain an empirical sampling distribution from which QAP p-values are calculated. Details of the estimation procedure used are described in Birke and Swann (2005). We are estimating a logit model with same_operator as the dependent variable. This variable takes on the value 1 if two students use the same operator and 0 otherwise. There are four independent variables that are constructed in a similar way: same_nation (respondents of the dyad have the same nationality/come from the same group of nations as dened

194

Network analysis

above), friend8 (respondents call each other on their mobile phone), same_sex (nodes have the same gender) and same_payment (respondents use the same type of payment: contract versus pre-paid). Table 9.6 shows the results from a logit estimation of the model with QAP p-values. Same_nation, friend and same_sex are highly signicant and show the expected sign, conrming the graphical analysis from Figure 9.4. Two respondents of the same nationality, who are friends and of the same sex are signicantly more likely to use the same operator. Same_nation and friend have a particularly high signicance level and in fact no permutation resulted in a parameter estimate higher than the observed values from the original regression. Same_sex is still signicant at the 5 per cent level, but the coecient is far lower than the other two. To get a better intuition of the importance of the dierent variables, Table 9.7 lists the predicted probabilities of having the same operator for a number of constellations. For two respondents who are friends, of the same nationality and of the same gender, there is an almost 50 per cent probability that they also use the same operator. On the other hand, for two respondents who dont call each other, are not of the same nationality and not of the same gender, this probability is only 18 per cent. Most of this variation is due to the friend and same_nation parameters. The model from Table 9.6 excludes the operator 3, because of its dierent pricing structure. Analysing the same model for dierent operators yields a positive coecient for the friend parameter for all operators, but 3.9 This is further support for our hypothesis that network Table 9.6 Determinants of choosing the same operator
Parameter estimates same_nation friend same_sex same_payment Constant 0.814 0.676 0.130 0.041 1.434 QAP p-values p p p p p 0.000 0.000 0.014 0.426 0.000

Table 9.7

Predicted probabilities of using the same operator


Not same nationality Same nationality 0.32 0.34 0.45 0.47

Not friends Friends

Not same sex Same sex Not same sex Same sex

0.18 0.20 0.28 0.30

Social networks and the economics of networks

195

eects are the reason for consumers coordinating their operator choice. Operator 3 is the only UK operator that typically does not induce network eects, but rather oers packages of calling time regardless of the network to which calls are made. The incentive for 3 users to coordinate with their peers is therefore lower. This can also clearly be seen in Figure 9.4, where 3 users are evenly distributed over the graph. The results are also contrary to the argument that learning eects or word of mouth might be the prime cause of this coordination. The third generation network and handsets of 3 are arguably more dicult to master than other mobile phones and we would expect a coordination of operator choice for 3 if these eects were strong. The correlation of operator choice within nationalities is particularly interesting and this might have several causes. All UK operators also operate networks in a number of other countries; sometimes under the same brand, sometimes under dierent brands. Non-UK students might have simply continued to use the same operator they already used in their home country. However, concentration of operators worldwide is far lower than in the market for mobile phone handsets. Furthermore, most students come from countries where these operators do not have a network, as most operators have a rather European focus. This coordination of operators within nationalities might be due to common unobserved characteristics and attitudes of respondents with the same background or it could be a coordination mechanism. We therefore regress friend on same_nation and same_sex. Both having the same nationality and being of the same sex are important predictors of friendship between two respondents (see Table 9.8). Students from the same nation and from the same sex interact far more frequently. Both parameters are highly signicant, but the coecient of same_nation is about three times bigger than for same_sex. Like for operator choice, we can again calculate the predicted probabilities for dierent constellations (see Table 9.9). The predicted probability of an interaction between two respondents is generally rather low, but for two respondents from the same nationality and the same sex this probability is 10 times higher than for two respondents of dierent nationalities and dierent gender. Table 9.8 Friendship determinants
Parameter estimates same_nation same_sex Constant 1.823 0.701 5.119 QAP p-values 0.000 0.000 0.000

196

Network analysis

Table 9.9

Predicted probabilities of calling each other


Not same nationality Same nationality 0.036 0.069

Not same sex Same sex

0.006 0.012

The group of students for which coordination is strongest are Chinese students who in the large majority used Vodafone. To the best of our knowledge, at the time of the survey10 there was no special tari oered by Vodafone targeting Chinese students (like, for example, cheap calls to China) and Vodafone does not have an own network in the PRC, which students might have used prior to their study in England.11 Asking fellow students why Chinese students choose Vodafone as their operator, they replied that other Chinese students told them on arrival that all Chinese students use Vodafone and that they should also use it, if they want other people to call them. This has afterwards also been conrmed by other Chinese students and by students from other nationalities.12 If nationality is a strong determinant of friendship, it is a good choice to use the same network as other people from the same nation in order to reduce the number of o-net calls. Furthermore, even when accounting for this eect, friends are still more likely to choose the same operator.

5.

DISCUSSION

We have shown that consumers coordinate their choice of mobile phone operators not only within households, but also in their wider social network. We further found that this depends on the price dierence between on- and o-net calls induced by most operators. Like the results from Birke and Swann (2006), this is further evidence that in markets with direct network eects it matters to the consumer who is on the same network. In this respect, direct network eects are dierent from indirect network eects, where only the total number of users matters. As discussed earlier, the sample on which this chapter is based is far from random and it is therefore dicult to generalise the ndings to, say, the British population. The high percentage of foreign students might have favoured the results to a certain extent. However, we can also observe a strong coordination of operators among British students. Furthermore, it can be assumed that a signicant part of a students communication takes place outside the Economics of Organisation B class. Results from the survey (and common sense) suggest that, for example, calls to the partner

Social networks and the economics of networks

197

are a signicant share of all calls. Consequently our results might rather understate the extent of coordination between close friends. In further research using calling records from land lines, we have found that the large majority of calls are made to three to ve parties, but that these interaction partners vary over time. If this also holds for mobile phones then, at any one point in time, it should be relatively straightforward to coordinate operator choice with these peers. If geographical origin of students is an important predictor of friendship, then these geographical patterns might be even more stable than the friendships existing at the time of choosing the operator (for international students this typically is the time of arrival to the UK). The results pertaining to dierences in interaction within and between students from dierent nationalities are interesting in their own right. First, they show that not only is geographic distance an important factor in many diusion and coordination processes but also geographic origin. Second, the analysis gives a powerful illustration of how individual choice can be constrained by network structure. Even if coordination of consumption choices in markets with global network eects is important, dierent operators (or technologies) can easily coexist with one another due to local network eects, as long as global network eects are not too strong. Finally, we can speculate that Chinese students overwhelmingly using Vodafone might be a case of path dependence where a relatively small past event made some Chinese students choose Vodafone as their operator and where it is now benecial for new arrivals to choose Vodafone simply because the large majority of other Chinese students use the same operator. The empirical analysis in this chapter focuses on one specic point in time and therefore cannot capture dynamics in the system. A longitudinal analysis based on social network data is even harder to achieve than for traditional datasets, due to the more severe consequences of missing values and the related problems with sampling new participants. However, this analysis could in theory be done relatively easily with access to electronic data on mobile calling patterns between individuals. This would also directly relate the frequency and cost of interactions with network choice. By using electronic calling records, it would be possible to get a far bigger sample size, which in theory could include all subscribers to a particular network. The obvious diculty here is the condentiality of this data and the resulting reluctance of companies to grant access to it. This chapter has demonstrated the fruitfulness of the use of social network analysis techniques for the analysis of economic problems. One drawback of SNA is the need for network data which is often not readily available. With the digitalisation of many aspects of society, much more

198

Network analysis

network data are easily accessible in electronic forms to researchers nowadays. However, there remains a considerable number of research areas that require the collection of primary data by the researcher, which is an approach traditionally seldom pursued by economists. Social network analysis enables a more realistic and rich modelling of many economic decision-making processes and therefore in many cases justies the additional eorts in data collection. Although this should be benecial to economics as a whole, as we have argued, this could be particularly interesting for work in the tradition of evolutionary economics.

NOTES
I am grateful to Peter Swann, David Paton, Robin Cowan, seminar participants at Chimera, University of Essex, Nottingham University Business School and participants at the EMAEE conference in Utrecht, The Netherlands for helpful comments. I would also like to acknowledge nancial support from the University of Nottingham Business School and the ESRC. The analysis has been conducted using the econometrics package STATA, SAS and the social network software UCI-NET and PAJEK. 1. See Valletti and Cave (1998) for an analysis of the UK market from 1985 to 1998. 2. Note that this holds for subscriber market shares. Although there has been a similar trend in revenue market shares, Vodafone still boasts the highest revenue, as its customers generate a higher ARPU. 3. For simplicity, we shall call respondents who communicate with each other friends in the rest of the study. 4. See Birke and Swann (2006) for details. 5. Number portability also makes it more dicult to identify mobile networks from telephone numbers. However, in the UK, less than 7 per cent of all mobile numbers are ported (Q3 2004). 6. See Freeman (2005) for an overview of graphical representations for social network analysis. 7. Some of the respondents had up to three dierent mobile phone operators. Most of them indicated a main operator used; for three respondents the main operator was decided randomly as no information about which operator was mainly used was obtainable. 8. The friend matrix has been symmetrised for the regression analysis, that is, we assume that if a tie is not reciprocated, this is because the respondent forgot to nominate the interaction partner and not because it is a true one-way relationship. This is a standard assumption of social network analysis. The results are virtually the same when using the non-symmetrised matrix. 9. The coecient for Orange is not signicant, but has the right sign. 10. More recently, special international taris have been oered by some operators. O2 has taken the lead here and there is anecdotal evidence that some Chinese students are switching to O2 to prot from these discounts. 11. Vodafone has a minor stake in China Mobile, but it is a rather small stake (approximately 3.27 per cent) and is most likely not known to the average consumer. 12. One of the comments I received from international seminar and conference participants was that they encountered similar coordination mechanisms when they moved abroad. *

Social networks and the economics of networks

199

REFERENCES
Antonelli, C. (1995), The Economics of Localized Technological Change and Industrial Dynamics, Dordrecht etc.: Kluwer Academic Publishers. Arthur, W.B. (1989), Competing technologies, increasing returns, and lock-in by historical events, Economic Journal, 99(394), 11631. Birke, D. and Swann, G.M.P. (2005), Social networks and choice of mobile phone operator, Nottingham University Business School: Industrial Economics Division Occasional Paper Series, No. 2005-14. Birke, D. and Swann, G.M.P. (2006), Network eects in mobile telecommunications an empirical analysis, Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 16(1): 6584. Borgatti, S.P. and Foster, P.C. (2003), The network paradigm in organizational research: a review and topology, Journal of Management, 29(6), 9911013. Breschi, S. and Lissoni, F. (2004), Knowledge networks from patent data: methodological issues and research targets, in Glnzel, W., Moed, H. and Schmoch, U. (eds), Handbook of Quantitative Science and Technology Research, Dordrecht: Kluwer, pp. 61343. Cantner, U. and Graf, H. (2005), The network of innovators in Jena: an application of social network analysis, Paper presented at the 4th European Meeting on Applied Evolutionary Economics (EMAEE), 1921 May, Utrecht, The Netherlands. Cowan, R., Cowan, W. and Swann, G.M.P. (1997), A model of demand with interactions among consumers, International Journal of Industrial Organization, 15(6): 71132. Cowan, R. and Jonard, N. (2004), Network structure and the diusion of knowledge, Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control, 28(8): 155775. Farrell, J. and Saloner, G. (1985), Standardization, compatibility, and innovation, RAND Journal of Economics, 16(1): 7083. Freeman, L.C. (2005), Graphic techniques for exploring social network data, in Carrington, P.J., Scott, J. and Wasserman, S. (eds), Models and Methods in Social Network Analysis, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 24869. Frenken, K. (2006), Technological innovation and complexity theory, Economics of Innovation and New Technology, 15(2): 13755. Ingram, P. and Roberts, P.W. (2000), Friendships among competitors in the Sydney hotel industry, American Journal of Sociology, 106(2): 387423. Katz, M.L. and Shapiro, C. (1985), Network externalities, competition, and compatibility, American Economic Review, 75(3): 42440. Krackhardt, D. (1987), OAP partialling as a test of spuriousness, Social Networks, 9(2): 17186. Krackhardt, D. (1988), Predicting with networks: nonparametric multiple regression analysis of dyadic data, Social Networks, 10(4): 35981. Metcalfe, J.S. (1998), Evolutionary Economics and Creative Destruction, The Graz Schumpeter lectures, London: Routledge. Murmann, J.P. (2003), Knowledge and Competitive Advantage. The Co-evolution of Firms, Technology, and National Institutions, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Rohlfs, J. (1974), A theory of interdependent demand for a communications service, Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 5(1): 1637.

200

Network analysis

Uzzi, B. (1996), The sources and consequences of embeddedness for the economic performance of organizations: the network eect, American Sociological Review, 61(4): 67498. Valletti, T.M. and M. Cave (1998), Competition in UK mobile communications, Telecommunications Policy, 22(2): 10931.

PART IV

Spatial systems

10. Diversity, stability and regional growth in the United States, 19752002
Jrgen Essletzbichler*
1. INTRODUCTION

Recent years have witnessed important changes in economic governance systems represented as a scalar shift of economic and political power from national states to supra-national entities and subnational entities such as cities and regions (Jessop, 1990, 1994; Brenner, 1998, 2004; Scott, 1998). Cities, regions and city-regions are increasingly forced into direct competition with each other that prompts regional policy makers to actively design and shape regional economic development (Harvey, 1989; Leitner and Sheppard, 1998). Baden-Wrttemberg, the Third Italy and Silicon Valley exemplify the paradigmatic model of economic development that other regions attempt to emulate (Bartik, 1996). Regional policies are designed to attract clusters of functionally related industries with high growth potential although the value of cluster-based policies is not uncontested (Hudson, 1999; Lovering, 1999; Begg, 2002; Martin and Sunley, 2003; Boschma, 2004; Kitson et al., 2004). Duranton and Puga (2000: 533) caution that many of these policies seem to lack a clear rationale or even to be based on common misconceptions. The value of industrial specialization for regional economic development is uncertain as theoretical and empirical work on specialization and diversity of cities suggests (Baldwin et al., 2003; Black and Henderson, 2003; Duranton and Puga, 2000, 2001; Feldman and Audretsch, 1999; Henderson, 1997; Henderson et al., 1995). In particular, there appears to be a trade-o between growth and stability of regional economies that is largely ignored by policy makers (Baldwin and Brown, 2004). This chapter examines the relationship among diversity, growth and stability of regional production systems. Empirical work by regional scientists and new geographical economists yields ambiguous results. While Kort (1981) and Baldwin and Brown (2004) nd strong evidence for a positive
203

204

Spatial systems

relationship between stability and diversity and a negative relationship between employment growth and diversity, Attaran (1986) and Smith (1990) contest these ndings. Overall, the review by Dissart (2003) suggests that more diversity leads to more stability and less growth in unemployment. The regional science literature is strongly focused on the identication of empirical relationships, while the theoretical links are not fully developed (Conroy, 1974, 1975; Siegel et al., 1995; Chandra, 2003). New geographical economists examine the theoretical and empirical relationship between diversity and economic growth (Krugman, 1991; Glaeser et al., 1992; Henderson, 1997; Brakman, et al., 2001). Some of these researchers are inuenced by the ideas of Alfred Marshall (1920) and Jane Jacobs (1969) linking variety (technological and/or industrial) to external economies, eciency of regional production systems and economic growth (Henderson, 2003). Conclusions from both areas of research have potentially important policy implications. Should regional policy makers stimulate or curtail the production of diversity to foster regional economic growth? Should policy makers focus on generating conditions for high rates of economic growth or should they focus on minimizing growth rate uctuations? The existing work has developed important theoretical arguments to understand the relationship between diversity and growth (Henderson, 1988; Glaeser et al., 1992, Quigley, 1998), but the relationship between diversity and stability has been undertheorized. In part, this might be explained by the inuence of neoclassical economics on regional science and new geographical economics focusing on market competition as the only allocation mechanism. Although formulated at the level of the rm, these concepts have been scaled up to the regional and national levels (Porter,1990, 1998). What is often overlooked is the fact that rm competition is based on very dierent principles from regional competition. While rms have to maximize prots to stay in business, regions cannot go bankrupt (Krugman, 1994). Furthermore, regional policy makers are responsible to dierent interests in the region including the provision of technical and social infrastructures and social services. Only if it is assumed that increased regional eciency translates into welfare gains for everybody can the exclusive focus on economic growth be justied. Instead of using economic growth as a vehicle to achieve other goals such as equity or sustainability, higher rates of economic growth become the policy target. This exclusive focus on growth might be problematic if it leads to a reduction in technological, industrial, social and institutional diversity in the region. Because growth rates are maximized if less-ecient routines, technologies, skills and industries are eliminated, this is likely to be the case. A lack of diversity might reduce the adaptive potential of the region to future change.

Diversity, stability and regional growth in the United States

205

This chapter addresses explicitly the trade-o between regional employment growth and regional economic stability drawing on insights from evolutionary theory and ecological economics. Evolutionary theories highlight the importance of diversity as fuel for the selection process (Nelson, 1995). Selection winnows on existing variation and, given a stable selection environment and no introduction of new diversity, will ensure that only the most ecient entities survive. In reality, new diversity is added through innovation and rm entry and coupled with a continually changing environment, eciency and optimality criteria are perpetually redened. Perfect adaptation towards a global optimum is therefore impossible (Hodgson, 1993, 1997). Applications in evolutionary economics focus primarily on the impact of rm diversity in populations of competing rms on population (for example, industry) averages. In this work, Fishers principle is employed, stating that the rate of change is proportional to the variance in eciency characteristics (for example, prot rates, unit costs or productivity levels) (Metcalfe, 1994, 1998). Recent work suggests that intra-population dynamics has to be linked to interpopulation dynamics and include selection processes at various analytical scales such as the rm, industry, region and nation (Gowdy, 1992; Andersen, 2004). Moving the focal level to the regional scale complicates the analysis considerably. Ecological economists and evolutionary biologists have long argued that a trade-o between adaptive eciency and the adaptability (the ability to adapt to environmental changes) of ecosystems exists (Gould and Lewontin, 1979; Levins and Lewontin, 1985; Vrba and Gould, 1986). Like ecosystems, regions might be confronted with an explicit trade-o between adaptation and exible adaptivity/resilience. Adaptation refers to the optimal adjustment to current environmental circumstances. Adaptation is achieved through enhanced eciency of individual agents (for example, through innovation and imitation) and the elimination of redundant features such as undesired skills, inecient technologies, industries, organizations and institutions. While boosting current eciency levels (and rates of economic growth), lower levels of diversity decrease the likelihood of pre-adaptive features and the potential to react to changing environmental conditions ushered in by technological paradigm shifts, exogenous shocks or changes in the institutional environment (Holling, 1973, 2001). However, there are limits on the extent of diversity. Without commonalities between dierent entities, no synergies arise, and certain eciency thresholds necessary for the economic survival of regions might never be reached. In this chapter, the theoretical arguments from evolutionary theory and ecological economics are summarized to put the trade-o between regional economic diversity and regional economic growth on stronger theoretical

206

Spatial systems

foundations. For this purpose, Section 2 reviews work by evolutionary theorists and ecological economists and their emphasis on the relationship among diversity, growth and stability. Section 3 presents a simple empirical model that links regional economic diversity to stability and growth and Section 4 concludes this chapter.

2.

DIVERSITY, STABILITY AND GROWTH

The case for diverse regional production systems hinges on the premise that diversity reduces volatility1 (or enhances stability). Stability is seen as a positive property of regional production systems for two reasons. First, high levels of volatility are often coupled with higher rates of unemployment, because contracting economies destroy jobs and release workers and because it takes time to match workers to new jobs. Second, high volatility complicates planning decisions to provide adequate investment in technical and social infrastructures (Schoening and Sweeney, 1992; Baldwin and Brown, 2004). The maintenance of diversity is therefore useful from a policy point of view. However, diversity aects not only stability but also regional eciency by stimulating or constraining innovation, technology spillovers and suppliercustomer interaction (Jacobs, 1969). Whether or not diversity will generate external economies through spillovers is likely to depend on the exact mix of industries, rms, workers, organizations and institutional practices in a region. Too much diversity might stie the formation of spillovers through a lack of synergies. Too little results in increasing specialization and makes the region vulnerable to changes in technological paradigms, demand and supply shocks. Current market-driven policies largely based on David Ricardos theory of comparative advantages drive the formation of trade areas and the globalization process. The erosion of national boundaries is likely to result in increasing regional specialization. This might increase overall eciency (at the supra-national or global level) but at the expense of increased vulnerability at the subnational or regional level. Unfortunately a theoretical discussion of these intertemporal and interspatial trade-os is largely absent from economic geography. A substantial body of literature theorizing these trade-os, however, is emerging in evolutionary theory, ecological economics and complex systems analysis (Giampietro and Mayumi, 1997; Holling, 2001, 2004; Rammel and van den Bergh, 2004; Ulanowicz, 1997). In the following, the arguments emerging from this literature are summarized. Although there are limitations to the transferability of knowledge and concepts from the physical and biological sciences to the social realm, some of the conclusions from this literature pertain to all complex, adaptive

Diversity, stability and regional growth in the United States

207

systems (Giampietro and Mayumi, 1997). The review of this literature is not expected to generate a series of testable hypotheses but a series of general principles on the relationship among diversity, stability and growth of regional production systems that can be explored through empirical work. Evolutionary Theory, Diversity and Stability Diversity and selection Evolution is driven by the creation and destruction of diversity. Diversity is expressed as variation at the genetic level, as biodiversity at the level of ecosystems, as technological diversity at the level of industries, as industrial and institutional diversity at the level of regions and countries. In biological systems, diversity is created by random mutation. In socio-economic systems, diversity is generated primarily by the processes of innovation and plant entry (Nelson and Winter, 1982; Saviotti and Metcalfe, 1991; Hodgson, 1993; Dosi and Nelson, 1994; Nelson, 1995; Saviotti, 1991, 1996; Rigby and Essletzbichler, 1997, 2006; Essletzbichler and Rigby, 2005a, b). Reduction of diversity is driven by imitation and selection. Selection rewards those species, rms, regions or countries that are best adapted to narrow conditions at the moment. In this sense, selection operates as a short-term adaptive force (Rammel and Staudinger, 2002). Adaptation is interpreted as temporary feature providing a benet over its alternatives under specic environmental conditions (Rammel and van den Bergh, 2003: 123, emphasis added). This view on adaptation has a number of important implications relating to questions of optimality, eciency, equilibrium and causal relationships. Without going into details about debates on adaptationism in evolutionary biology (see, for instance, Gould and Lewontin, 1979; Depew and Weber, 1995), a few clarications need to be made in the context of this contribution. Spencer interpreted selection as a process that guaranteed the survival of the ttest. In this view, selection is regarded as a (global) optimization process. This reading of selection entails a closed universe, one that can be described by a unique and optimal equilibrium conguration towards which the system gravitates. Natural selection is the mechanism that ensures that this state will be reached eventually. In equilibrium, only those traits, species and populations survive that are perfectly adapted to environmental conditions describing this equilibrium. In equilibrium a global optimum is reached. This view of evolution was adopted by neoclassical economists who interpreted competitive markets as selection environments that ensured that only rms with optimal technologies and organizational routines survived. Because ineciency was considered to be

208

Spatial systems

only a transitory phenomena, diversity in rm behavior could be ignored and rms be treated as if they were prot maximizers (Friedman, 1953). During the movement towards global optimum, diversity becomes eliminated (see Vromen, 1995). In the absence of changing environmental conditions and creation of new diversity, selection would indeed reduce variation until only the prot maximizers would survive (Alchian, 1950; Jovanovic, 1982; Iwai 1984a, b; Metcalfe and Gibbons, 1986; Metcalfe, 1994, 1998). In reality, rms are confronted with moving targets in the form of shifting tness landscapes, continuous introduction of new diversity in the form of innovation and technological change, random shocks and non-linear feedback mechanisms and complex patterns of interactions whose outcomes cannot be predicted ex ante. In this environment of uncertainty and unpredictability, optimization must be understood as local and myopic (Nelson, 1995). In that sense it might be better to talk about survival of the tter or suciently t (Rammel and van den Bergh, 2003) or survival of the tting (Boulding, 1981). According to this view, selection does not entirely eliminate diversity. Although the persistence of diversity might be undesirable from a neoclassical point of view, the rejection of the existence of a global optimum makes diversity in the form of redundant, suboptimal and inecient technologies, skills, rms and industries not only acceptable but a necessary condition for long-term survival of rms and regions. Diversity, optimality and stability As in regional science, the exact relationship between diversity and stability is still debated in ecological theory (Holling, 2001; Rammel and Staudinger, 2002). In ecology, diversity is negatively related to stability if species diversity reects a diversity in functional entities in an ecosystem with minimum redundancy (Rammel and Staudinger, 2002: 305). Translated to economic geography, this case would describe a region with a diversity of sectors whose technological inputs and demand are highly correlated, that is, whose inputoutput structures are almost identical. In this case, the existing industrial diversity would not protect the region from demand shocks and/or shifts in technological paradigms (Wagner and Deller, 1998; Frenken et al., 2005). Independent of the specic expression of diversity, the rejection of the assumption of a global optimum complicates denitions of eciency2 suggesting that current regional policies based on some notion of economic and social eciency are driven by the ideology of eciency (Bromley, 1990) and not derived from solid theoretical foundations. In the presence of shifting adaptive landscapes and moving equilibria, the focus on eciency

Diversity, stability and regional growth in the United States

209

(in the maximum power sense) entails a prioritization of short-term adaptation/optimization that comes, potentially, at the expense of long-term stability. If optimality exists it will be temporary, because through evolution, selection, and innovation it is easily transformed into maladaptive traits. Under such conditions, diversity is a key element of long term stability and even survival (Rammel and van den Bergh, 2003: 127). Diversity, enhanced adaptive exibility and evolutionary potential One of the main arguments to maintain diversity is its role as repertoire of alternative options, which increases the probability that pre-adaptations to altered conditions exist. This is referred to as evolutionary potential (ibid.). While selection operates as a short-term adaptive force that reduces diversity to narrow and temporally adapted features, selection does not guarantee survival in the long run (Matutinovic, 2001). Diversity persists because of imperfect adaptation and the counter acting inuence of other sorting mechanisms. Selection rewards those individuals or rms that are relatively more ecient (generally characterized by lower inputoutput ratios) but a rms competitive position is also improved by exaptation and exogenous shocks (Gowdy, 1992). For instance, exaptation could refer to an increase in eciency of suppliers of a rm A that translates into lower costs of inputs and in turn a lower inputoutput ratio of rm A. This improvement of eciency is achieved without any actual technological or organizational changes by rm A. Exogenous shocks, such as a rise in energy prices, can inuence rm As eciency through a shift in relative prices of input factors. Firms that use relatively small amounts of energy will improve their eciency relative to rms that use larger amounts of energy (for an empirical example, see Berman and Bui, 2001). Selection is thus only one of many sorting mechanisms that drive evolution. Exaptation and exogenous shocks might stimulate diversity, because these sorting mechanisms might reward relatively inecient rms. Diversity might therefore be as much an evolutionary outcome as specialization. Within bounds, regions should therefore embrace rather than eliminate redundancy. In ecology, redundancy of agents (and pathways) stands for ecosystem overhead. Ulanowitz in Matutinovic (1992) argues that ecosystem overhead evolves: (1) as a response to the opportunity for the complete use of available resources (eciency in the second law sense); (2) to prevent system brittleness; (3) to preserve its adaptive response and creativity; and (4) to preserve its reliability (Matutinovic, 2002: 434). Similarly, there are good reasons for economic systems to embrace overhead or redundancy. From an evolutionary point of view, rms, institutions, regions and countries are likely to be forced into a trade-o between realizing short-term

210

Spatial systems

prots (adaptation to current conditions to achieve a local optima) and long-term exibility to enhance the adaptive potential and the ability to react to technological paradigm shifts, exogenous shocks and industrial shifts (Schtz, 1999). Mayumi and Giampietro (2001: 13, emphasis added) suggest that long-term (regional) competitiveness is achieved through increases in eciency . . . by amplifying the most performing activities, without eliminating completely the obsolete ones. From a regional point of view this entails a strengthening of existing well-performing sectors (probably clusters) but without completely eliminating those rms and sectors that appear less ecient and redundant at present. This view also resonates with arguments made by innovation system researchers (Lundvall and Johnson, 1994; Edquist, 1997). Contrary to biological systems, socio-economic systems actively produce diversity. This means that the diversity-selection feedback works much faster in social systems and hence, any reduction in diversity might be translated more rapidly into adaptability problems. Furthermore, economic systems are often characterized by increasing returns based on internal and external economies, cumulative technological change, learning and network externalities and complementary production factors that can result in path-dependent evolution and lock-in. Diversity helps to break lock-in and path dependence (Grabher, 1993; Arthur, 1994; Grabher and Stark, 1997). Diversity at the level of the region refers to diversity in labor (skills), rms, industrial sectors, organizations and institutional environments but also the network connections between local and non-local agents (Granovetter, 1973; Grabher and Stark, 1997; Matutinovic, 2002). Diversity can thus be seen as a risk-minimizing strategy similar to portfolios in business economics (Chandra, 2003). The theoretical arguments on the relationships among diversity, stability and resilience are rather general and biology, ecology and complex adaptive systems theory have yet to solve the exact linkages between them. Despite these shortcomings, the theoretical arguments put forward demonstrate that a narrow policy focus on regional eciency is problematic. Strategies to maximize eciency in the short term might pose problems for economic prosperity over longer time horizons and hence, prioritize implicitly the needs of current generations at the expense of future generations. To complicate matters further, the impact of economic policies will lead to conicting outcomes not only at various temporal but also at various spatial scales. Competition between regions might yield positive economic returns for some regions, but also result in the unnecessary duplication of infrastructure, services and organizations that appear wasteful from the perspective of the national state (Harvey, 1989; Hubbard and Hall, 1998). On the other hand, regional specialization might result in

Diversity, stability and regional growth in the United States

211

positive region-specic externalities that maximize wealth at the national level at the expense of intra-regional diversity (Krugman, 1991; Fujita et al., 1999, Neary, 2001). Nations might manage risks by maintaining a portfolio of specialized regions similar to assets of companies. Decline in some regions will be compensated by growth in other regions. In this case, the national scale receives priority over the regional scale where the average well-being of national citizens will increase at the expense of declining welfare in declining regions. If these intertemporal and interspatial tradeos do indeed exist, the trade-os at various temporal and spatial scales have to be made explicit in regional policy templates rather than hidden behind the assumption that free markets will lead to a (global) welfare optimum. While evolutionary theory provides us with interesting insights into the trade-o between diversity, stability and growth, the exact relationship between technological and industrial diversity and economic growth and stability have been insuciently developed so far. The relationship between diversity and economic growth has been addressed extensively by new geographical economists (this literature cannot be discussed in this chapter but for overviews on the new geographical economics, see Martin (1999), Sheppard (2000a, b), Neary (2001), Duranton and Puga (2004), Frenken et al. (2005) and Robert-Nicoud (2005) and for an empirical attempt to disentangle the eects of urbanization and localization economies on metropolitan labor productivity, see Rigby and Essletzbichler (2002)) while regional scientists applied portfolio theory to examine the empirical relationship between diversity and stability. Industrial Diversity and Portfolio Theory In business economics and industrial organization, the concept of portfolio refers to the valuation of the collection of a companys assets to examine the impact of product diversity on corporate protability growth. The basic underlying principle is that diversity of assets reduces risk. Ideally a company diversies into technologically related industries/products in order to maximize economies of scope, but also industries that are characterized by unrelated demand in order to protect overall sales from demand shocks in individual product markets. This reasoning has a striking similarity to the arguments by Giampietro and Mayumi (1997) on the behavior of complex adaptive systems. Although regions cannot go bankrupt in the same way as corporations do, regions expand and contract over the business cycle. Regional contraction manifests itself through plant closures, low entry rates and a shrinking employment base. Once a negative cumulative cycle is set in motion it is often hard to switch to a new path of regional

212

Spatial systems

economic growth, to attract businesses and jobs. In severe cases of economic decline, regions are confronted with very fast rates of employment decline. This is particularly the case if the economic base is dependent on a few companies and/or industrial sectors. If individual plants are closed down because of structural problems occurring in this sector, related industries follow rapidly and whole areas can be transformed into ghost towns in a short period of time. Detroit in the United States, Liverpool in the UK, Ivanovo in Russia and Halle in Germany are examples of these unfolding processes (Oswalt, 2004). Although the region does not go bankrupt in the same sense as rms do, capital has to be scrapped, workers laid o and, in the case of prolonged crisis, have to move to other regions. In most circumstances, not all sectors of an economy decline at the same time or at equal rates. Borrowing from portfolio theory, it is therefore possible to think of regional diversication as a strategy to reduce the risk of economic decline. Developing a portfolio of industries whose demand is largely uncorrelated might be a useful strategy of regions to avoid big uctuations in rates of economic growth and to shield them in part from economic decline during recessions (Baldwin and Brown, 2004). Clearly these arguments are rather abstract and require renement. The same levels of regional diversity might result from very dierent industry mixes, and some of them might be more favorable than others. Even if the levels of regional diversity remain constant, the underlying industry mix of regions might change over time. And nally, what are the appropriate temporal and spatial scales to examine the evolution of regions? Diversity might be useful for the long run at the expense of short-run economic growth. Regional economic specialization might yield high levels of eciency that benet actors at the regional and national scales and that maintain industrial diversity at the national scale. Frenken et al. (2005) describe new geographical economics and portfolio approaches as static because variety at a single point in time relates to regional growth. Boschma and Lambooy (1999) argue that urbanization economies and Jacobs externalities are more important during the emergence of new industries and technological paradigms when industries have not yet generated their specic skills, or supplier and institutional requirements, but that localization economies might become more important once these factors are created (see also Boschma and Frenken, 2003). This literature is important as it brings a dynamic perspective to the literature and demonstrates how industrial and technological diversity inuence regional growth at various stages of industry life cycles, but regions are somehow considered as containers in which industrial evolution unfolds. Instead of following a single industry (or cluster) through time and space, it is possible to start with regions and examine the relationship between the

Diversity, stability and regional growth in the United States

213

distribution of characteristics within regions and the changes in regional aggregates such as growth, productivity, protability and stability. This avenue is pursued in the following empirical analysis: regions are conceptualized as an assembly of industries and the distribution of employment among these industries (indicating regional industrial diversity/concentration) is expected to exert an inuence on changes in regional economic growth and stability.

3.

EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS

The empirical part of this chapter is based on employment data from the US county business patterns (19752002). The goal of the analysis is the establishment of a negative statistical relationship between economic growth and stability and a positive relationship between industrial diversity and economic stability at the level of the economic areas of the Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) through the application of spatial econometric techniques. In order to measure the impact of industrial diversity on regional volatility, it is necessary to control for the inuence of additional explanatory variables. The choice of variables is informed by the theoretical discussion and empirical work in regional science (for example, Baldwin and Brown, 2004). Regional stability/volatility is measured as the variance of annual regional employment growth rates. According to Baldwin and Brown, the variance will be inuenced by the diversity of a regions industrial structure, the variance of its industries growth rates and the covariance between those growth rates. The correlates of volatility are chosen from a set of structural characteristics of regions. The names, denitions and expected signs of these variables are summarized in Table 10.1. The simplest and most widely used measure of diversity is probably the Herndahl index (Duranton and Puga, 2000; Chandra, 2003; Baldwin and Table 10.1
Variable name HERF75 GROWTH SIZE75 PLSIZE75 R75

Correlates of volatility
Variable description Herndahl measure of diversity/specialization (1975) Average annual compound rate of growth Total employment in 1975 Average plant size (total employment per plant 1975) Percent of employment in resource based industries (SIC 12, 13, 14, 21, 24, 29) Hypothesized sign

214

Spatial systems

Brown, 2004). Experimentation with entropy measures of diversity did not change the conclusions of the chapter. The Herndahl index H of a BEA region r is measured as Hr s2 ir (10.1)

where sir Eir iEir and Eir refers to employment in sector i in BEA region r. The index varies between 1 (all employment is concentrated in one sector) and 1/n (employment is distributed equally among all sectors). A higher value indicates greater concentration of employment in fewer sectors (lower diversity), while a lower value indicates a more even distribution of employment across sectors (higher diversity). The index has been constructed for the base year (1975) using the 1972 SIC3 3-digit system. Based on the theoretical discussion on diversity and volatility, a positive relationship between the level of concentration (a high Herndahl index) and volatility (high variance of annual growth rates) is expected. Employment levels and growth rates are also expected to relate to volatility. Although it is expected that total regional employment is correlated with diversity and hence, the eect of employment size subsumed by the eect of diversity on volatility, Malizia and Ke (1993) argue that larger regions are more stable than smaller regions and that size (measured as total employment) might have a positive eect on regional stability independent of the eect of diversity. The impact of size on volatility will also depend on the geographic concentration of markets for products. If rms in larger regions sell a larger share of their product in local markets, then the growth rates of a regions industries are more likely to be correlated because they will be dependent on the same market and subject to the same economic shocks. In this case, larger regions will be more volatile than smaller regions even if they are characterized by similar levels of industrial diversity. The relationship between size and volatility is therefore ambiguous. Malizia and Ke found a U-shaped relationship between growth and volatility, suggesting that regions that have concentrations in fast-growing industries have higher growth rates, while regions with concentrations in fast-declining industries have lower growth rates. On the other hand, more diverse regions are characterized by more stability and average growth rates. The U-shaped relationship between growth and volatility has been conrmed by Baldwin and Brown (2004) for Canadian census regions and manufacturing industries. Contrary to the U-shaped relationship detected by Malizia and Ke and Baldwin and Brown, a linear (positive) relationship between growth and volatility for BEA regions was discovered (see Figure

Diversity, stability and regional growth in the United States

215

10.2, below). The squared growth rate was thus omitted from the set of independent variables. The average plant size in a region is expected to exert a positive inuence on regional economic stability because smaller plants are generally newer and more likely to exit the industry than larger plants (Davis et al., 1996; Baldwin et al., 1998). Furthermore, large rms tend to produce a variety of commodities and are thus less vulnerable to market uctuations aecting a particular product. Product variety tends to be lower in smaller rms which will decrease their ability to adapt to market uctuations aecting a specic product. Hence, we would expect a negative relationship between average plant size and volatility. The negative correlation coecient between average plant size and stability conrms this relationship (see Table 10.4, below). Baldwin and Brown (2004) add export shares and the share of employment in dierent types of industries (for example, resource based) as explanatory variables. Unfortunately, export data are not available for BEA regions but the share of regional employment in resourced-based industries was included. It can be expected that regions with a high share of resourcebased industries such as mining, agriculture and forestry, logging, lumber and petroleum, are characterized by higher volatility in growth rates, because resource-based economies are often inuenced by global (that is, exogenous) price uctuations. A positive relationship between the share of resource-based industries and volatility is expected. The data used in this analysis are based on county business patterns from 1975 to 2002. The data have been aggregated to the level of BEA regions because they are probably closest to functional economic regions in the US (similar to labor market regions or travel-to-work areas in Europe) (Johnson and Kort, 2004). County business patterns provide employment, establishment and wage data for SIC 4-digit industries between 1975 and 1986. For many counties, actual gures have been suppressed and replaced by employment size classes. Because of the large amount of undisclosed information (in particular for smaller counties) and in order to reduce measurement error, county employment at the SIC 4-digit level has been aggregated to SIC 3-digit employment and the diversity measures have been calculated at the SIC 3-digit level. If information for individual counties was not reported at the SIC 3-digit level, the average value of the employment size class (for example, 10 for employment size class 019) was used to impute the missing information. Because counties were then aggregated to the new BEA regions, measurement error will be relatively small and is unlikely to inuence the results. Changes in county and BEA denitions have been considered in order to keep the geography constant over the whole period. Overall, the dataset spans 27 years and includes the 177 BEA areas of the continental United States.

216

Spatial systems

(a)

(b)

(c)

Key (1 = lowest; 5 = highest) 1 2 3 4 5

Source: County Business Patterns, 19752002.

Figure 10.1

Volatility (a), diversity (b), growth (c)

Figure 10.1 maps the key variables volatility, diversity and growth for the 177 BEA areas. Growth and volatility are measured over the whole period from 1975 to 2002 while diversity is measured for the base year, 1975. Table 10.2 lists the top 10 and bottom 10 cities with respect to stability, diversity and growth. Figure 10.1 and Table 10.2 reveal the following geographic pattern. The regions characterized by the highest levels of stability tend to

Table 10.2
Stability 0.0003942 0.0004523 0.0004589 0.0005026 0.0005044 0.0005127 0.000566 0.0005689 0.0005821 0.0006064 0.0023583 0.0024352 0.0024807 0.0025731 0.0028575 0.0031622 0.0034569 0.0039636 0.0039645 0.0042717 0.0114437 0.0114459 0.0115646 0.0344388 0.0345258 0.035662 0.0372476 0.0376502 0.0415241 0.0416221 0.0693846 0.0725675 0.0740087 0.0108033 0.0108467 0.0112099 0.0107762 Phoenix, AZ Fayetteville, AR-MO Bend, OR Flagsta, AZ Sacramento, CA-NV Colorado Springs, CO Orlando, FL State College, PA Waterloo, IA Springeld, IL Erie, PA Bualo, NY Odessa, TX Davenport, IA-IL Cleveland, OH Pittsburgh, PA Port Arthur, TX Harrisburg, PA Jackson, MS 0.0104357 0.0105806 Austin, TX Sarasota, FL Little Rock, AR 0.0103007 Las Vegas, NV 6.87 5.98 5.42 5.16 5.05 5.01 4.94 4.77 4.72 4.70 1.06 1.02 0.94 0.90 0.89 0.89 0.86 0.80 0.80 0.76 BEA area Diversity BEA area Growth

BEA area rankings by stability, diversity and growth

Rank

BEA area

2 3

Philadelphia, PA-NJDE-MD Lincoln, NE New York, NY-NJ-CTPA Albany, NY

5 6 7

Dover, DE Richmond, VA Harrisburg, PA

217

8 9 10 168 169 170 171 172 173 174 175 176 177

Scranton, PA Omaha, NE-IA Rochester, NY San Angelo, TX Pendleton, OR Eugene, OR Sarasota, FL Farmington, NM Reno, NV Odessa, TX Lafayette, LA Casper, WY Bend, OR

New York, NY-NJ-CTPA Memphis, TN-MS-AR Atlanta, GA-AL Philadelphia, PA-NJDE-MD Dallas-Fort Worth, TX Chicago, IL-IN-WI Columbia, SC Morgantown, WV Bend, OR Port Arthur, TX Pueblo, CO Reno, NV Odessa, TX Flagsta, AZ Waterloo, IA Gulfport, MS Las Vegas, NV

Source:

County Business Patterns, 19752002.

218

Spatial systems

be concentrated in the Mid-Atlantic region including areas such as Philadelphia, New York and Rochester, while among the most volatile are many of the resource-based economies of Oregon, Texas and Wyoming. The most diverse regions are those surrounding large urban areas such as New York, Philadelphia, Dallas, Chicago, Atlanta or Memphis, while the more specialized areas tend to be either resource-based economies or those focusing on tourism such as Las Vegas or Reno. The fastest-growing regions are located in Florida and the southwest of the country and include retirement areas and high-tech centers. The slowest-growing regions are found in the old manufacturing heartland and include regions such as Bualo, Cleveland and Pittsburgh. Although some regions score high/low on several variables, others do not follow a clear pattern. Figure 10.2 plots the relationship between volatility on the vertical axis and growth/diversity on the horizontal axes. Both relationships are positive and signicant at the 0.0001 level. Descriptive statistics of all dependent and independent variables as well as the logarithmic values are presented in Table 10.3, while the raw correlation coecients are presented in Table 10.4. Table 10.3 highlights considerable variation in diversity, growth and stability, although the variation is considerably smaller than for Canadian Census regions (Baldwin and Brown, 2004). The correlation coecients reveal that most of the independent variables are correlated with stability. Table 10.4 indicates that specialized regions and those characterized by higher rates of economic growth, smaller employment size and smaller average plant size tend to be more stable (that is, have lower variances of growth rates). Also of interest is the positive relationship between growth and diversity: specialized regions appear to grow more rapidly but are also characterized by higher volatility. Table 10.3 suggests the presence of extreme outliers with respect
Volatility 0.0045 0.004 0.0035 0.003 0.0025 0.002 0.0015 0.001 0.0005 0 0 0.02 0.04 Growth 0.06 0.08 Corr = 0.31 (p = 0.0001) 0.0045 0.004 0.0035 0.003 0.0025 0.002 0.0015 0.001 0.0005 0 0 0.02 0.04 Diversity 0.06 0.08 Corr = 0.44 (p = 0.0001) Volatility

Source: County Business Patterns, 19752002.

Figure 10.2

Relationship between volatility and growth/diversity

Diversity, stability and regional growth in the United States

219

Table 10.3
Variables

Basic statistics of dependent and independent variables


n 177 177 177 177 177 177 177 177 177 177 177 177 Mean 12.56 0.02 2.53 336 866.00 12.71 0.05 2.43 4.01 0.84 11.91 2.52 3.36 Std dev. 6.38 0.01 1.09 680 227.00 2.89 0.05 0.43 0.35 0.44 1.19 0.23 0.88 Minimum 3.94 0.01 0.76 11288.00 7.56 0.01 1.37 4.58 0.27 9.33 2.02 5.16 Maximum 42.72 0.07 6.87 6561322.00 19.80 0.29 3.75 2.60 1.93 15.70 2.99 1.25

VARGROWTH HERF75 MGROWTH EMP75 PLSIZE75 R75 LOGVARGROWTH LOGHERF75 LOGMGROWTH LOGEMP75 LOGPLSIZE75 LOGR75

Source: County Business Patterns, 19752002.

to the dependent and independent variables that might drive overall results. Hence, the natural logarithms of the variables are taken to remove the eect of those outliers. Table 10.4 suggests that the linear relationships between the logged variables tend to become stronger. The basic regression model estimated may be written as: y X , (10.2) where y is an N 1 vector of observations on the dependent variable, X is an N K matrix of observations on K independent variables, is a K 1 vector of regression coecients, and is an N 1 vector of errors assumed to be normally and independently distributed. As discussed above, the dependent variable is the variance of regional growth rates (VARGROWTH) and the independent variables are HERF75, GROWTH, EMP75, PLSIZE75 and R75. Figure 10.1 suggests considerable spatial autocorrelation in the dependent variable. Employing spatial contiguity weights, a Morans I value of 0.3348 (signicant at the 0.001 level) suggests the presence of strong spatial autocorrelation of the independent variable. In the presence of spatial autocorrelation, ordinary least squares (OLS) estimates may be inconsistent (Anselin, 1988; Anselin and Rey, 1991). Spatial dependence is of two basic forms, error dependence and lag dependence. In the spatial error model the errors can no longer be assumed independent and identically distributed and the regression model takes the following form: y X W , (10.3)

220

Spatial systems

Table 10.4 Correlation coecients between dependent and independent variables (p-values in parentheses)
VARGROWTH HERF75 MGROWTH EMP75 PLSIZE75 VARGROWTH HERF75 MGROWTH EMP75 PLSIZE75 R75 1 0.44 (0.0001 0.31 (0.0001) 0.21 (0.0042) 0.39 (0.0001) 0.60 (0.0001) 0.44 (0.0001) 1 0.09 (0.246) 0.22 (0.003) 0.13 (0.0796) 0.30 (0.0001) 0.31 (0.0001) 0.09 (0.246) 1 0.15 (0.0514) 0.30 (0.0001) 0.03 (0.7212) 0.21 (0.0042) 0.22 (0.003) 0.15 (0.0514) 1 0.44 (0.0001) 0.23 (0.0018) 0.39 (0.0001) 0.13 (0.0796) 0.30 (0.0001) 0.44 (0.0001) 1 0.37 (0.0001) R75 0.60 (0.0001) 0.30 (0.0001) 0.03 (0.7212) 0.23 (0.0018) 0.37 (0.0001) 1

LOG LOG LOG LOG LOG VARGROWTH HERF75 MGROWTH EMP75 PLSIZE75 LOG VARGROWTH LOGHERF75 LOG MGROWTH LOGEMP75 LOGPLSIZE75 LOGR75 1 0.50 (0.0001) 0.29 (0.0001) 0.42 (0.0001) 0.42 (0.0001) 0.48 (0.0001) 0.50 (0.0001) 1 0.04 (0.6416) 0.49 (0.0001) 0.25 (0.0007) 0.29 (0.0001) 0.29 (0.0001) 0.04 (0.6416) 1 0.16 (0.0343) 0.30 (0.0001) 0.07 (0.3718) 0.42 (0.0001) 0.49 (0.0001) 0.16 (0.0343) 1 0.78 (0.0001) 0.48 (0.0001) 0.42 (0.0001) 0.25 0.0007 0.30 (0.0001) 0.78 (0.0001) 1 0.45 (0.0001)

LOG R75 0.48 (0.0001) 0.29 (0.0001) 0.07 (0.3718) 0.48 (0.0001) 0.45 (0.0001) 1

where is the spatial autoregression coecient, W is an N N matrix of spatial weights representing the geography of the observational units (BEAs), and is an N 1 vector of errors assumed to possess the usual properties. In this form, spatial dependence inuences the error term only and it has been shown to inuence the power of tests for heteroscedasticity and the structural stability of regression coecients. In the spatial lag model, the standard regression equation may be rewritten as: y Wy X , (10.4)

where is the spatial autoregression coecient. In this form, the value of the dependent variable at a particular location is jointly determined by its

Diversity, stability and regional growth in the United States

221

Table 10.5
Variables

Determinants of volatility
Model 1 OLS Linear VARGROWTH 4.87* (2.05) 182.09** (4.70) 1.60** (4.90) 4.54 10e7 (0.81) 0.25 ( 1.72) 58.94** (8.30) Model 2 OLS Log-linear LN VARGROWTH 5.27** (14.03) 0.53** (6.39) 0.24** (4.15) 0.05 (1.25) 0.38* ( 2.06) 0.15** (4.75) Model 3 ML spatial lag Log-linear LN VARGROWTH 3.87** (8.41) 0.44** (8.41) 0.16** (2.89) 0.02 (0.44) 0.21 ( 1.19) 0.11** (3.52) 0.37** (4.67) Model 4 ML spatial error Log-linear LN VARGROWTH 5.14** (12.76) 0.48** (5.85) 0.18** (2.93) 0.04 (1.01) 0.38 ( 1.89) 0.12** (3.57)

Form Dependent variable Constant (LN)HERF75 (LN)MGROWTH (LN)EMP75 (LN)PLSIZE75 (LN)R75 W_lnvargrowth (Lambda) R-square (adj.) Log-likelihood AIC SC

0.43** (4.83) 0.515 512.161 1036.32 1055.38 0.462 47.8736 107.747 126.804 2.58425 2.35506 21.76** 27.38** 0.539p 36.8477 87.6953 109.928 8.57 0.537p 36.8319 85.6638 104.720 8.97

Diagnostics for heteroscedasticity BreuschPagan 51.22** KoenkerBasset 14.79* Diagnostics for spatial dependence LM-ERROR 5.85* LM-LAG 5.51*

Notes: OLS ordinary least squares; ML maximum likelihood; **, *, : signicant at the 0.01, 0.05, 0.1 levels; spatial weights are based on queen spatial contiguity of BEA areas; p indicates a pseudo R-square measure, because the standard R-square is invalid in ML estimation. AIC Akaike information criterion; SC Schwartz criterion.

values at other locations and OLS estimation is no longer consistent (Anselin and Rey, 1991). The results of the linear model are presented under Model 1 in Table 10.5. Specialized and faster-growing regions and those with higher shares of resource-based industries are characterized by more volatility in growth rates. All relationships are signicant at the 0.01 level. The average plant size

222

Spatial systems

is negatively related to volatility, supporting the theoretical arguments discussed above. The relationship is signicant at the 0.1 level only. The size of the region is positively related to volatility, lending some support to Fujita et al.s (1999) argument that the demand for products in large regions is more likely to be correlated, exacerbating demand shocks. However, Table 10.4 revealed high correlations between regional size and most other independent variables, suggesting that the size eects might have been picked up by other variables (for example, HERF75). Furthermore, Table 10.5 shows that the positive relationship between EMP75 and VARGROWTH is not statistically signicant. In addition to the parameter estimates and t-values, a set of diagnostic statistics have been added. An adjusted R-square value of 0.515 indicates a relatively good t of the original model. However, tests on heteroscedasticity and spatial dependence reveal that both are present in the model. Heteroscedasticity could have been the result of correlated spatial errors. However, even after correcting for spatial lags/errors, heteroscedasticity posed a problem. The scatterplots depicted in Figure 10.2 seemed to suggest that the variance of volatility increases with higher rates of both growth and diversity, and that no single variable could be easily identied to cause heteroscedasticity. Gujarati (2003) suggests that the log transformation of variables often helps to eliminate heteroscedasticity. Model versions 24 present the results for the log-linear models. The fact that parameter estimates can be interpreted as elasticities is an added advantage of the log-linear model. Model 2 presents the results for the OLS estimates without correction for spatial dependence. The signs of the parameter estimates for the log-linear version do not change, although the parameter estimate for average plant size is now signicant at the 0.05 level and the adjusted R-square value indicates a moderately worse model t. On the other hand, the BreuschPagan and KoenkerBassett tests reveal no heteroscedasticity, while spatial dependence is still present in the models. Lagrange multiplier tests suggest the presence of both spatial lag and spatial error. Model 3 provides the results for the spatial lag model. The model results are based on maximum likelihood estimation and the values in parentheses are z- rather than t-values. The signs of the parameter estimates are consistent with those of Models 1 and 2. The negative estimate for the size of plants is no longer signicant, but all the goodness-of-t measures indicate a clear improvement from model version 2. Furthermore, the parameter estimate for the spatially lagged dependent variable is positive and signicant at the 0.01 level. The results suggest that volatility of growth in a region is also inuenced by volatility of growth in the neighboring regions. The results for the spatial error model (Model 4) are similar to the results of the spatial lag model. The estimate for average plant size is signicant again at the 0.1 level and the goodness-of-t statistics suggest an

Diversity, stability and regional growth in the United States

223

almost identical performance when compared to the spatial lag model. The spatial lag parameter, , is also positive and signicant at the 0.01 level. Anselin (1988, 1992) advises using performance indicators such as the log-likelihood, Akaike information or Schwartz criteria to inform model selection. Because the performance indicators for both models are almost identical, no obvious choice for the best model emerges. Because the parameter estimates are very similar and since the purpose of the model is not predication but the establishment of statistical relationships between variables, this does not pose a major predicament. Independent of the exact model specication, a comparison of the elasticities suggests that a change in diversity has the highest impact on change in regional economic stability, followed by a change in average growth rate and the change in share of resource-based industries (keeping in mind that the impact of average plant size is barely signicant). The results conrm the work by other researchers and highlight the importance of industrial diversity for regional economic stability.

4.

CONCLUSION

This chapter employed evolutionary theory to develop arguments on the trade-o between short-term adaptation and long-term adaptability. At present, little thought is given to the potentially negative impacts of clusterbased regional policies predicated on the spatial concentration of functionally integrated sectors. The concentration of economic activity in a few economic areas is likely to boost short-term productivity growth and prot rates through the exploitation of externalities based on the local skill base, knowledge spillovers, and traded and untraded interdependencies. The negative side of specialization is a decline in adaptive exibility, the ability to react to continually changing economic environments. The chapter examined the relationship among stability, growth and diversity for 177 BEA areas over the 19752002, period using employment data from county business patterns. The analysis revealed a strong positive relationship between diversity and stability on the one hand, and growth and instability, on the other. While these results conrm work in other countries and provide some credibility to evolutionary theories of regional economic change, it is important not to overstate the results. Although regional economic stability is desirable because it facilitates planning for technical and social infrastructure and avoids the pitfalls of fast growth (congestion, rising house prices, environmental degradation, overinvestment in infrastructure), stability (small variances in growth rates) coupled with economic decline is problematic if the decline is rapid and investments have to be written o

224

Spatial systems

rapidly. In other words, from a policy point of view, it still has to be worked out what kind of regional stability is desirable, bearing in mind the trade-o between growth and stability. Furthermore, the Herndahl index provides a general measure of industrial diversity, but does not capture the degree of functional relation between sectors. Regions can contain a large number of dierent but functionally integrated economic sectors that react in a similar fashion to demand shocks. The impact of diversity on stability will be inuenced strongly by the degree of functional integration of sectors and hence, future work will have to pay more attention to this aspect of diversity (Frenken et al., 2005). However, based on insights from evolutionary theory and the empirical results, industrial, institutional, skill, technological and social diversity should be elevated to a general principle of regional economic development even at the cost of short-term welfare losses. This is imperative if we drop the assumptions of global optimality and equilibrium.

NOTES
* This research was partially funded by an Annual Grant of the University of Southampton (A2001/19). I would also like to thank Koen Frenken for valuable comments on an earlier draft of this chapter. The usual disclaimer applies. 1. Volatility is interpreted as the opposite of stability and will be measured as the variance in annual rates of employment change. 2. Ecology oers three dierent notions of eciency: (1) rst law eciency, or simply the fraction of energy input that appears as output; (2) eciency in the second law sense where resources are being used more thoroughly by a diverse set of agents, having dierent single-use eciencies (the most ecient agent is the one that eects the most complete use of the available resource, regardless of the rate of use); (3) eciency in the maximum power sense, where an agent uses a resource to provide either the quickest return or the greatest rate of output (Matutinovic, 2002: 433). Economics prioritizes denition (3). From a maximum power eciency perspective, less-ecient rms are considered redundant. Second law eciency is generally absent from economic policy discourse although it might be desirable from an equity point of view. 3. Standard Industrial Classication.

REFERENCES
Alchian, A. (1950), Uncertainty, evolution and economic theory, Journal of Political Economy, 58: 21122. Andersen, E.S. (2004), Population thinking and evolutionary economic analysis: exploring Marshalls Fable of Trees, Danish Research Unit for Industrial Dynamics (DRUID) Working Paper, 04-05. Anselin, L. (1988), Spatial Econometrics, Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic. Anselin, L. (1992), SpaceStat tutorial: a workbook for using SpaceStat in the analysis of spatial data, Santa Barbara: NCGIA National Center for Geographic Information and Analysis.

Diversity, stability and regional growth in the United States

225

Anselin, L. and S. Rey (1991), The performance of tests for spatial dependence in linear regression models, Geographical Analysis, 23: 11031. Arthur, B. (1994), Increasing Returns and Path Dependence in the Economy, Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press. Attaran, M. (1986), Industry diversity and economic performance in U.S. areas, Annals of Regional Science, 20: 4454. Baldwin, J., T. Dunne and J. Haltiwanger (1998), A comparison of job creation and job destruction in Canada and the United States, The Review of Economics and Statistics, 80: 34756. Baldwin, J.R. and W.M. Brown (2004), Regional manufacturing employment volatility in Canada: the eects of specialization and trade, Papers in Regional Science, 83: 51941. Baldwin, R.E., R. Forslid, P. Martin, G.I.P. Ottaviano and F. Robert-Nicoud (2003), Economic Geography and Public Policy, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Bartik, T. (1996), Strategies for economic development, in R. Aronson and E. Schwartz (eds), Management Policies in Local Government Finance, Washington, DC: International City/County Management Association for the ICMA University, pp. 287311. Begg, I. (ed.) (2002), Urban Competitiveness, Bristol: Policy Press. Berman, E. and L. Bui (2001), Environmental regulation and productivity: evidence from oil reneries, Review of Economics and Statistics, 83: 498510. Black, D. and V. Henderson (2003), Urban evolution in the US, Journal of Economic Geography, 3: 34372. Boschma, R.A. (2004), Competitiveness of regions from an evolutionary perspective, Regional Studies, 38: 100114. Boschma, R.A. and K. Frenken (2003), Evolutionary economics and industry location, Review of Regional Research, 23: 183200. Boschma, R.A. and J.G. Lambooy (1999), Evolutionary economics and economic geography, Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 9: 41129. Boulding, K. (1981), Evolutionary Economics, Beverly Hills, CA: Sage. Brakman, S., H. Garretsen and C. van Marrewijk (2001), An Introduction to Geographical Economics, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Brenner, N. (1998), Global cities, glocal states: global city formation and state territorial restructuring in contemporary Europe, Review of International Political Economy, 5: 137. Brenner, N. (2004), New State Spaces, Oxford: Oxford University Press. Bromley, D. (1990), The ideology of eciency: searching for a theory of policy analyses, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 19: 86107. Chandra, S. (2003), Regional economy size and the growth-instability frontier: evidence from Europe, Journal of Regional Science, 43: 95122. Conroy, M.E. (1974), Alternative strategies of regional industrial diversication, Journal of Regional Science, 14: 3146. Conroy, M.D. (1975), The concept and measurement of regional industrial diversication, Southern Economic Journal, 41: 492505. Davis, S.J., J.C. Haltiwanger and S. Schuh (1996), Job Creation and Destruction, Cambridge, MA and London: MIT Press. Depew, D. and B. Weber (1995), Darwinism Evolving, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Dissart, J.C. (2003), Regional economic diversity and regional economic stability: research results and agenda, International Regional Science Review, 26: 42346.

226

Spatial systems

Dosi, G. and R. Nelson (1994), An introduction to evolutionary theories in economics, Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 4: 15372. Duranton, G. and D. Puga (2000), Diversity and specialization in cities: why, where and when does it matter?, Urban Studies, 37: 53355. Duranton, G. and D. Puga (2001), Nursery cities: urban diversity, process innovation and the life-cycle of products, American Economic Review, 91: 145477. Duranton, G. and D. Puga (2004), Micro-foundations of urban agglomeration economies, in V. Henderson and J.-F. Thisse (eds), Handbook of Regional and Urban Economics, vol. 4. Amsterdam: North-Holland, pp. 2063117. Edquist, C. (1997), Systems of Innovation: Technologies, Institutions and Organizations, London and Washington, DC: Pinter. Essletzbichler, J. and D.L. Rigby (2005a), Technological evolution as creative destruction of process heterogeneity: evidence from US plant level data, Economic Systems Research, 17: 2545. Essletzbichler, J. and D.L. Rigby (2005b), Competition, variety and the geography of technology evolution, Tijdschrift voor Economische en Sociale Geograe, 95: 4862. Feldman, M. and D. Audretsch (1999), Innovation in cities: science-based diversity, specialization and localized competition, European Economic Review, 43: 40929. Frenken, K., F.G. van Oort, T. Verburg and R. Boschma (2005), Variety and regional economic growth in the Netherlands, Papers in Evolutionary Economic Geography no. 05.02. Utrecht University, Urban and Regional research center Utrecht. Friedman, M. (1953), Essays in Positive Economics, Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Fujita, M., P. Krugman and A.J. Venables (1999), The Spatial Economy: Cities, Regions and International Trade, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Giampietro, M. and K. Mayumi (1997), A dynamic model of socioeconomics systems based on hierarchy theory and its application to sustainability, Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 8: 45369. Glaeser, E., H. Kallal, J. Schenkman and A. Shleifer (1992), Growth in cities, Journal of Political Economy, 100: 112652. Gould, S.J. and R.C. Lewontin (1979), The spandrels of San Marco and the Panglossian paradigm: a critique of the adaptionist programme, Proceedings of the Royal Society of London series, 205(1161): 58198. Gowdy, J.M. (1992), Higher selection processes in evolutionary economic change, Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 2: 116. Grabher, G. (1993), The weakness of strong ties: the lock-in of regional development in the Ruhr area, In G. Grabher (ed.), The Embedded Firm, New York and London: Routledge, pp. 25577. Grabher, G. and D. Stark (1997), Organizing diversity: evolutionary theory, network analysis and postsocialism, Regional Studies, 31: 53344. Granovetter, M. (1973), The strengths of weak ties, American Journal of Sociology, 78: 136080. Gujarati, D.N. (2003), Basic Econometrics, 4th ed. New York: McGraw-Hill. Harvey, D. (1989), From managerialism to entrepreneurialism: the transformation in urban governance in late capitalism, Geograska Annaler, 71B(1): 217. Henderson, J.V. (1988), Urban Development: Theory, Fact and Illusion, Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Diversity, stability and regional growth in the United States

227

Henderson, J.V. (1997), Externalities and industrial development, Journal of Urban Economics, 42: 44970. Henderson, J.V. (2003), Marshalls scale economies, Journal of Urban Economics, 53: 128. Henderson, J.V., A. Kuncoro and M. Turner (1995), Industrial development in cities, Journal of Political Economy, 103: 106785. Hodgson, G. (1993), Economics and Evolution, Cambridge: Polity Press. Hodgson, G. (1997), Notes on reductionism and emergence, Available on request from the author. Holling, C.S. (1973), Resilience and stability of ecological systems, Annual Review of Ecology and Systematics, 4: 123. Holling, C.S. (2001), Understanding the complexity of economic, ecological, and social systems, Ecosystems, 4: 390405. Holling, C.S. (2004), From complex regions to complex worlds, Ecology and Society, 9(11), available at www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol9/iss 1/art11/ Hubbard, P. and T. Hall (1998), The entrepreneurial city and the new urban politics , in T. Hall and P. Hubbard (eds), The Entrepreneurial City: Geographies of Politics, Regime and Representation, New York: John Wiley, pp. 123. Hudson, R. (1999), The learning economy, the learning rm and the learning region: a sympathetic critique to learning, European Urban and Regional Studies, 6(1): 5972. Iwai, K. (1984a), Schumpeterian dynamics II: technological progress, rm growth and economic selection Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 5: 32151. Iwai, K. (1984b), Schumpeterian dynamics: an evolutionary model of innovation and imitation, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 5: 57798. Jacobs, J. (1969), The Economy of Cities, New York: Vintage. Jessop, B. (1990), State Theory, University Park, PA: Pennsylvania State University Press. Jessop, B. (1994), Post-Fordism and the state, in A. Amin (ed.), Post-Fordism: A Reader, Oxford: Blackwell, pp. 25179. Johnson, K.P. and J.R. Kort (2004), 2003 redenition of the BEA economic areas, Survey of Current Business, November: 6875. Jovanovic, B. (1982), Selection and the evolution of industry, Econometrica, 50(3): 64970. Kitson, M., R. Martin, and P. Tyler (2004), Regional competitiveness: an elusive yet key concept?, Regional Studies, 38: 9919. Kort, J.R. (1981), Regional economic instability and industrial diversication in the U.S., Land Economics, 57: 596608. Krantz, R. (2002), Employment in business services: a year of unprecedented decline, Monthly Labor Review, April: 1724. Krugman, P. (1991), Increasing returns and economic geography, Journal of Political Economy, 99: 48399. Krugman, P. (1994), Competitiveness: a dangerous obsession, Foreign Aairs, March/April: 117. Leitner, H. and E. Sheppard (1998), Economic uncertainty, inter-urban competition and the ecacy of entrepreneurialism, in T. Hall and P. Hubbard (eds), The Entrepreneurial City: Geographies of Politics, Regime and Representation, New York: John Wiley, 285307.

228

Spatial systems

Levins, R. and R. Lewontin (1985), The Dialectical Biologist, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Lovering, J. (1999), Theory led by policy: the inadequacies of the New Regionalism (illustrated from the case of Wales), International Journal of Urban and Regional Research, 23: 37995. Lundvall, B.-A. and B. Johnson (1994), The learning economy, Journal of Industry Studies, 1: 2342. Malizia, E.E. and S. Ke (1993), The inuence of economic diversity on unemployment and stability, Journal of Regional Science, 33: 22135. Marshall, A. (1920), The Principles of Economics, London: Macmillan. Martin, R. (1999), The new geographical turn in economics: some critical reections, Cambridge Journal of Economics, 23, 6391. Martin, R. and P. Sunley (2003), Deconstructing clusters: chaotic concept or policy panacea?, Journal of Economic Geography, 3: 535. Matutinovic, I. (2001), The aspects and the role of diversity in socioeconomic systems: an evolutionary perspective, Ecological Economics, 39: 23956. Matutinovic, I. (2002), Organizational patterns of economies: an ecological perspective, Ecological Economics, 40: 42140. Mayumi, K. and M. Giampietro (2001), The epistemological challenge for modelling sustainability: exploring the dierence in meaning of risk, uncertainty and ignorance, Paper prepared for the EC High Level Scientic Conference ESEE Frontiers 1: Fundamental Issues of Ecological Economics, Cambridge, UK, 47 July. Metcalfe, S. (1994), Competition, Fishers principle and increasing returns in the selection process, Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 4: 32746. Metcalfe, S. (1998), Evolutionary Economics and Creative Destruction, London and New York: Routledge. Metcalfe, S. and M. Gibbons (1986), Technological variety and the process of competition, Economie Applique, 39: 493520. Neary, J.P. (2001), On hypes and hyperbolas: introducing the new economic geography, Journal of Economic Literature, 39: 53661. Nelson, R.R. (1995), Recent evolutionary theorizing about economic change, Journal of Economic Literature, 33: 4890. Nelson, R. and S. Winter (1982), An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Growth, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Oswalt, P. (ed.) (2004), Schrumpfende Stdte. Stdtischer Wandel im Zeichen von Postfordismus und Globalisierung, Hatje Canz Verlag. Porter, M. (1990), The Competitive Advantage of Nations, New York: Free Press. Porter, M. (1998), Clusters and the new economics of competition, Harvard Business Review, NovemberDecember: 7798. Quigley, J.M. (1998), Urban diversity and economic growth, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 12: 12738. Rammel, C. and M. Staudinger (2002), Evolution, variability and sustainable development, International Journal of Sustainable Development and Global Ecology, 9: 305. Rammel, C. and J.C.J.M. van den Bergh (2003), Evolutionary policies for sustainable development: adaptive exibility and risk minimizing, Ecological Economics, 47: 12133. Rigby, D.L. and J. Essletzbichler (1997), Evolution, process variety and regional trajectories of technological change in US manufacturing, Economic Geography, 73: 26984.

Diversity, stability and regional growth in the United States

229

Rigby, D.L. and J. Essletzbichler (2002), Agglomeration economies and productivity dierences in US cities, Journal of Economic Geography, 2: 40732. Rigby, D.L. and J. Essletzbichler (2006), Technological variety, technological change and the geography of production techniques, Journal of Economic Geography, 6: Forthcoming. Robert-Nicoud, F. (2005), The structure of simple New economic Geography models (or, on identical twins), Journal of Economic Geography, 5: 20134. Saviotti, P. (1991), The role of variety in economic and technological development, in P. Saviotti and S. Metcalfe (eds), Evolutionary Theories of Economic and Technological Change, Chur: Harwood Academic Publishers, pp. 172208. Saviotti, P.P. (1996), Technological Evolution, Variety and the Economy, Cheltenham, UK and Brookeld, USA: Edward Elgar. Saviotti, P.P. and J.S. Metcalfe (1991), Present development and trends in evolutionary economics, in P.P. Saviotti and J.S. Metcalfe (eds), Evolutionary Theories of Economic and Technological Change, Chur: Harwood Academic Publishers, pp. 130. Schoening, N.C. and L.E. Sweeney (1992), Proactive industrial development strategies and portfolio analysis, Review of Regional Studies, 22: 22738. Schtz, J. (1999), The value of systemic reasoning, Ecological Economics, 31: 239. Scott, A.J. (1998), Regions and the World Economy, Oxford and New York: Oxford University Press. Sheppard, E. (2000a), Geography or economics? Conceptions of space, time, interdependence and agency, in G.L. Clark, M.P. Feldman and M.S. Gertler (eds), The Oxford Handbook of Economic Geography, Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 99119. Sheppard, E. (2000b), Competition in space and between places, in E. Sheppard and T. Barnes (eds), A Companion to Economic Geography, Oxford: Blackwell, pp. 16986. Siegel, P.B., T.G. Johnson and J. Allwang (1995), A structural decomposition of regional economic instability: a conceptual framework, Journal of Regional Science, 35: 45770. Smith, E.D. (1990), Economic stability and economic growth in rural communities: dimensions relevant to local employment creation strategy, Growth and Change, 21: 318. Ulanowicz, R.E. (1997), Ecology, the Ascendent Perspective, New York: Columbia University Press. Van den Bergh, J.C.J.M. (2004), Evolutionary thinking in environmental economics; retrospect and prospect, in J. Foster and W. Hlzl (eds), Applied Evolutionary Economics and Complex Systems, Cheltenham, UK and Northampton, MA, USA: Edward Elgar, pp. 23975. Vrba, E.S. and S.J. Gould (1986), The hierarchical expansion of sorting and selection: sorting and selection cannot be equated, Paleobiology, 10: 21728. Vromen, J.J. (1995), Economic Evolution: An Enquiry into the Foundations of New Institutional Economics, London and New York: Routledge. Wagner, J.E. and S.C. Deller (1998), Measuring the eects of economic diversity on growth and stability, Land Economics, 74: 54156.

11. Inter-regional knowledge ows in Europe: an econometric analysis


Mario A. Maggioni and T. Erika Uberti*
1. INTRODUCTION

The aim of this chapter is to analyse the impact of knowledge on regional economic development and, consequently, on regional disparities across ve major European countries: France, Germany, Italy, Spain and the United Kingdom. In particular our focus is on the nature of knowledge, not only as a xed cost in the production process (leading to scale economies), an investment good (inuenced by accumulation and depreciation dynamics) and an experience good (whose quality attributes can be detected only upon using, or consuming, the good), but also as a relational good displaying network externalities. In this chapter we analyse the manifold nature of knowledge through the analysis of four distinct but complementary phenomena (Internet hyperlinks, European research networks, European Patent Oce (EPO) co-patent applications, Erasmus student mobility) which characterise knowledge as an intrinsic relational structure (directly) connecting people, institutions and (indirectly) regions across ve European countries. Two main research questions are addressed: the rst deals with the notion of regional disparities; the second refers to the dierent concepts of distance, namely geographical, functional and sectoral. Regional disparities can no longer be dened only in terms of statistical dierences in the values of standard macroeconomic indicators. Knowledge matters more and more in dening both the level and the growth rate of a given region GDP (Sapir et al., 2004). For this reason, new relational indicators have to be built and compared in order to develop a new kind of (relational) analysis able to complement the usual attributional one. Traditionally, regional economic disparities have been ascribed to peripherality measured by the distance from the main centres of population and economic activity and/or to a high level of dependence on declining sectors (mainly mature industries). The scale of regional and
230

Inter-regional knowledge ows in Europe

231

other disparities, as well as the political approach and the specic policy instruments used at the European level to deal with this problem, have changed very much over the years. Europe is lagging behind the USA in terms of growth and investments in knowledge infrastructures, but this general statement, while true, hides a huge variance across European regions and nations (DG Enterprise, 2003). In the last 15 years, income dierences among European member states have been strongly narrowing while the process has been matched with a widening of the inter-regional variance within single countries (Martin, 1998). All this casts a shadow on the whole range of European regional policies, explicitly designed to reduce geographical imbalances and strengthen regional cohesion, and raises questions about the consequences of the future Europe enlargement, as the gap is expected to widen. A very odd and worrying aspect of the European context is that the productive capacity agglomeration process as a consequence of market forces may become too strong and risky to be socially unacceptable. In addition, at the Lisbon 2000 European Council, the European Union (EU) set itself the ambitious goal of becoming the most competitive and dynamic knowledge-based economy in the world, capable of sustainable economic growth with more and better jobs and greater social cohesion (European Commission, 2000) and the Council requested the Commission to report annually on the structural indicators of progress in member states towards the EUs strategic goal. These calls for robust evidence and rigorous monitoring of outcomes led to the development of a set of comprehensive structural indicators to underpin further analyses. In particular, it is interesting to study the dierent eects of geographical, functional and sectoral distance on the relational activity of dierent territories. This is the object of the present analysis which, within a gravitational framework, looks at four dierent relational variables (Internet hyperlinks, European research networks, EPO co-patenting applications and Erasmus student ows) between 110 European NUTS2 (Nomenclature des Units Territoriales Statistiques) regions located in ve European countries: Germany (40 regions), Spain (16), France (22), Italy (20) and United Kingdom (12). Gravitational models usually include geographical distance (based on geodesic path or road distance) between two areas to capture a series of distance-related phenomena which are dicult to measure (such as: transport costs, time elapsed during shipment, synchronisation costs, communication costs, transaction costs and cultural distance). Here, we use geographical distance, calculated as the shortest road distance existing between two NUTS2 capitals, but we add two concepts of distance, the functional distance, calculated as the dierence (in absolute value) between the level of innovative performance of dierent regions (based on

232

Spatial systems

the Regional Summary Innovation Index (RSII) contained in the European Innovation Scoreboard (EIS) and the sectoral distance (based on the sectoral distribution of the patenting activity). The chapter is organised as follows: Sections 2 and 3 describe the variables used in the dierent analyses; Section 4 presents dierent types of correlations (Pearson, Spearman and quadratic assignment procedure); Section 5 illustrates the use of social network analysis to detect structural properties of dierent knowledge exchange ows; Section 6 is devoted to the econometric analysis of two gravitational models; and Section 7 concludes.

2.

FOUR TYPES OF KNOWLEDGE FLOWS

Krugman, in his Geography and Trade, stated that knowledge ows . . . are invisible; they leave no paper trail by which they may be measured and tracked (Krugman, 1991, p. 53). Jae et al. (1993, p. 578) reacted to the previous statement by suggesting that knowledge ows do sometimes leave a paper trail, in the form of citations in patents. Because patents contain detailed geographical information about their inventors, we can examine where these trails actually lead. We attempt to move the approach a little further by focusing on four knowledge-based relational phenomena: digital information exchange (transmitted through Internet hyperlinks), participation in the same research networks (funded by the EU Fifth Framework Programme), EPO co-patent applications and Erasmus student exchange ows. Through these variables we attempt to measure the intrinsic relational structure of knowledge ows which directly connects people and institutions and, indirectly, regions, across ve European countries. These four variables capture dierent types of knowledge (spanning from pure tacit to pure codied knowledge) and dierent stages of the knowledge creation process. Although information and communication technologies (ICTs) reduce communication and transmission costs, the nature of knowledge and its creation process are very complex and require social processes involving dierent modalities of interactions. Even in the Internet era, face-to-face relations remain crucial (Feldman, 2002). It is worth noting that the relational variables considered in the analysis span the entire spectrum of relational aspects of knowledge creation, suggesting alternative ways to detect the knowledge trail: from a new and non-material way of information exchange (that is, Internet hyperlinks), to physical and virtual institution-based interactions developed to improve knowledge creation (that is, research networks) by exchanging mostly

Inter-regional knowledge ows in Europe

233

codied knowledge, to physical and virtual individual-based relationships aimed at developing marketable innovations (that is, co-patent applications) by exchanging mostly tacit knowledge and know-how, to the physical movement of people leaving their own region in order to acquire a part of their university education in a foreign institution (Erasmus student exchange). Digital Information Exchange (through Internet Hyperlinks) The recent diusion of ICTs, and in particular of the Internet, stimulated several analyses to measure the diusion of such a phenomenon across countries, regions, cities, ethnic groups and social classes in order to map the current state and to detect the presence of a digital divide. Dierent indicators may be used to detect the diusion of ICTs. The simplest way is to measure the endowment of the ICT equipment (that is, the number of Internet hosts, personal computers and broadband connections) and, more generally, all telecom infrastructures that allow ecient connections. A second way concerns the measurement of the access conditions to ICT services, in terms of the market structures (and prevailing pricing strategies) of the relevant markets (telecoms, Internet service providers (ISPs) and so on). Another way is related to the use of ICT, which may be detected by measuring the number of people on-line, to time spent on-line, to size of dierent on-line activities (e-commerce, e-government and so on). A further way concerns the relational nature of the physical infrastructure of the Internet (comprising cables, routers, satellite and radio connections), and of the www (world wide web), the Internet virtual interface and service platform that allows us to visualise and exchange the information. Since the www is a network of web pages linked through Internet hyperlinks, it can be used to map the inner structure of communication channels and to detect the producers and consumers of digital information. When an Internet hyperlink button is clicked, the content of the target web page is transferred to the clicking computer. One may thus think that the web page containing the hyperlink button acts as an importer of digital information and the target web page represents the information exporter or, more precisely, think of an Internet hyperlink as an index of revealed comparative advantages in the production of specic types of digital information. Internet hyperlinks therefore may be used as an indicator of potential use,1 since the existence of a hyperlink from one web page to another signals the willingness of the owner of one page to import digital information from another and increases the probability that the targeted web page is actually accessed.2 One may argue that the number of Internet

234

Spatial systems

hyperlinks in a web page is uninformative since the inclusion of a new hyperlink button is not constrained by a monetary budget as it does not cost anything. However, the presence of buttons within a page is subject to a harder graphical budget constraint. Web design handbooks show that while the number of hyperlinks is a key element in determining the attractiveness of a web page, such attractiveness is a non-monotonic function of the number of hyperlinks: it is good to have a few buttons but not too many. The www has been thoroughly analysed by mathematicians, physicists, information scientists and engineers,3 in order to detect its structure and development laws. Albert and Barabasi (2002) argue that the www has a scale-free topology in which a small number of central web pages are very popular (are targeted by a huge number of hyperlinks), while the rest of the web is composed of peripheral pages which are almost unconnected and virtually unknown. Other studies show that dierent typologies of web pages have dierent organisational structures. Some types of web pages (that is, those of universities and newspapers) display a random network structure in which there are a few extremely central and extremely peripheral nodes, while most of the nodes are targeted by a number of hyperlinks around the average (Maggioni and Uberti, 2005). Uberti and Maggioni (2004) analysed the connectivity of web pages of dierent institutions (universities, local authorities and chambers of commerce) at the regional level and showed that universities are the most active traders of digital information. In this chapter we therefore include the number of Internet hyperlinks between 308 university web pages located in German, Spanish, French, Italian and UK regions at the NUTS2 level.4 We chose these 308 universities, members of the European University Association (EUA), located in Germany, Spain, France, Italy and the United Kingdom. The selected sample accounted for 51 universities in France, 61 in Germany, 53 in Italy, 45 in Spain and 95 in the UK. However, its representation of the total population of European universities largely diers from country to country because of the exclusion of Hochschulen (in Germany) and coles Suprieures (in France) which are not members of the EUA. Since our analysis is devoted to the analysis of information and knowledge ows, we transposed the matrix of the Internet hyperlinks (that is, the presence of an Internet hyperlink from region j to country i, is analysed as the presence of an information channel owing in the opposite direction, from region i to region j). Research Networks Since the early 1980s, the EU has promoted the creation of research consortia (among rms, universities, research centres and public agencies) in

Inter-regional knowledge ows in Europe

235

order to increase the competitiveness of the European industry and to foster intra-European cohesion through the exchange and diusion of scientic and technological knowledge. In both the Single European Act and the Maastricht Treaty (Article 130G), the European institutions have been given competence in the area of science and technology and have developed several actions in order to promote research and development (R&D), create European networks, coordinate R&D and stimulate the European mobility of researchers (Breschi and Cusmano, 2004). Framework programmes always constituted the main planning instrument and funding source for R&D policies in the EU, but as time passed, priorities changed: the latest programmes have shifted the emphasis from supply-side factors, central in the design of the rst policies, to diusionoriented projects and the increase of central skills and knowledge among Europeans (ibid., p. 752). In 1998, the European Council and the European Parliament approved the Fifth Framework Programme (5FP), a programme with a dierent structure from the previous ones, valid for ve years (from 1998 to 2002), and nanced with about 15 million. This 5FP is divided into 10 thematic and horizontal programmes, and provides for 12 dierent types of contracts.5 In our analysis we focus on two contracts explicitly dedicated to the establishment and use of scientic networks, namely thematic network contracts and research network contracts whose coordinator is a university located in one the 110 regions of the sample, and we included all participants located in these regions, irrespective of their typology (that is, universities, research centres or business organisations). Co-patents Patents (and patent applications) are one of the most established output indicators of innovative activities. Since the seminal contribution of Scherer (1965), patents have been used in the economic literature (Griliches, 1981, 1990), in order to measure knowledge spillovers and other spatial externality eects which, in contrast to what was argued by Krugman (1991), do leave a paper trail (Jae et al., 1993). The constitution of the EPO in Munich in 1973 allowed researchers to use a common dataset to analyse the innovative performance of dierent European countries and regions. In particular, Paci and Usai (2000) and Breschi and Lissoni (2004) have developed systematic analyses of patenting activity throughout Europe at dierent NUTS levels, showing the existence of signicant clustering phenomena (whose agglomeration indices are even higher than those registered by high-tech manufacturing) within a coreperiphery geographical pattern.

236

Spatial systems

Later studies analyse patent data as relational variables. Unlike Breschi and Lissonis (2004) analysis on patent citations, Maggioni and Usai (2005) look at patents as a relation between inventors and applicants at NUTS2 level and study the distributions of these relationships within dierent European countries. They seek industry-specic patterns and test the hypotheses of a diused brain-drain dynamics by which peripheral regions host inventors, but do not exploit the economic outcomes of their scientic and technological creativity since applicants (mostly rms) are located in the core regions. In this chapter we consider another relational aspect of patents: the coinvention process. Co-invention (and thus co-patenting) is a process involving both tacit and codied knowledge exchanges. For this reason it implies a series of both face-to-face and over-a-distance relationships between inventors. This is why it is interesting to analyse the relative importance of geographic versus functional distance as forces shaping the interregional (international) structure of this knowledge ow network. Out of a total of more than 170 900 patent applications belonging to every International Patent Classication (IPC) section (coming from inventors located in the above-mentioned ve countries in the 19982002 period) extracted by the CRENoS les which were based on the original EPO database we selected only those patents whose applications were recorded by more than one inventor. Next we split each patent into equal shares attributed to each inventor. We then added these data for each NUTS2 region in order to built a matrix in which a generic cell ij represents the share of patents6 recorded jointly by inventors located in regions i and j (where regions i and j could belong to dierent nations). A total of nearly 30 000 co-patents was detected. Erasmus Student Exchange The Erasmus student exchange represents another relevant part of the spectrum of relational activities involving knowledge ows among European regions: the mobility of tertiary education students, who represent the basic channel for international training and education.7 The Erasmus programme, introduced in 1987 and, since 1995, part of the Socrates programme8 is a European programme devoted to fostering higher education and to creating a European dimension of education. Its popularity, in terms of student participation, is constantly increasing, and has undoubtedly widened after the Lisbon Council emphasised the enforcement of education and training, and student mobility as important goals to be achieved. The Erasmus student exchange reects several important features, equally contributing to [strengthening] the whole fabric of relations existing

Inter-regional knowledge ows in Europe

237

between the peoples of Europe (European Commission, 2005): the institutional integration among European countries; the openness of national tertiary systems; and the relative attractiveness of a country, either in terms of its culture or in terms of the reputation of its tertiary education system. As in the case of digital information owing through hyperlinks, we are interested in the ow of knowledge; hence we consider the region in which the hosting university is localised as the emitting region (region i) of the knowledge ows embedded in the learned students returning to their receiving region (region j) after their period of study abroad.9

3. EXPLANATORY (ATTRIBUTIONAL AND RELATIONAL) VARIABLES


In this chapter we use some attributional variables to detect dierences in the knowledge-based characteristics of 110 European regions. The attributional variables include: GDP, R&D intensity (the ratio between total R&D expenditure and GDP), and three measures of distance (or dissimilarity): the geographical distance (based on road distance between capitals), the functional distance (based on the RSII contained in the EIS), and the sectoral distance (based on the 2-digit sectoral composition of regional patent application10). What follows is a brief description of variables, their transformations and data sources. Note that throughout the chapter, subscript i refers to the emitting region and j to the receiving region, while I and J refer to countries. GDPi and GDPj: Gross domestic product of regions i and j expressed in purchasing power standards (pps). GDP data, expressed in millions of euros refer to year 2000. RDi and RDj: Research and development intensity of regions i and j. It is calculated as the ratio between the regional levels of gross expenditure on research and development (GERD) and GDP and refers to various years. GDistij: Geographical distances among 110 European regions are calculated according to the shortest road distance (in kilometres) between regional capitals. The notion of regional capital implied the use of a certain degree of arbitrariness since NUTS2 levels are administrative meaningful entities in Italy, Germany, Spain and France, but not in the UK. In this last case we used population as the selecting criteria to

238

Spatial systems

identify the most relevant city (which we called capital), irrespective of the presence of an administrative capital. FDistij: Functional distance is measured as the dierence (taken in absolute value) of the values registered by the two regions on the RSII contained in the EIS. The RSII measures the European technological leadership and ranks the absolute innovative performance of European regions. It is calculated by re-scaling the regional values of the 13 available indicators11 according to the following formula, and then taking the unweighted average of the re-scaled values per each region:
m

RSIIjJ

f 1

XfjJ min(XfjJ ) , max(XfjJ ) min(XfjJ )

(11.1)

where XfjJ is the value of an indicator f for region j in country J, and m is the number of available indicators for the j region (DG Enterprise, 2003). This composite index is based in data recorded on dierent years but ocially refers to 2003. (DG Enterprise, 2003). SDISTij: Sectoral distance is measured as the inverse of the technological nearness index (Moreno et al., 2005) calculated as a correlation coecient between the sectoral composition of patent application registered by region i and by region j at the EPO in the 19972000 period. CONTIGij: Contiguity, or adjacency, is a dummy variable which takes the value 1 for contiguous regions (that is, which share a border), and 0 elsewhere.12 COUNTRYIJ: A dummy variable which is used to control for xed national eects both on the emitting and the receiving regions.

4. FOUR TYPES OF KNOWLEDGE FLOWS: A CORRELATION ANALYSIS


This section shows some results on the correlation existing between the four dependent variables we used to describe knowledge ows (Internet hyperlinks, research networks, co-patents and Erasmus student ows) used in the econometric exercise. In particular we shall focus our attention on simple

Inter-regional knowledge ows in Europe

239

Table 11.1 Pearson and Spearman correlations between knowledge ow variables


Pearsons correlation Diginfoij RNij Diginfoij RNij Patij Erasij 1.000 0.458 0.167 0.331 Patij Erasij Spearmans rank correlation Diginfoij RNij 1.000 0.313 0.276 0.322 Patij Erasij

Diginfoij 1.000 RNij 0.264 1.000 Patij 0.339 0.212 1.000 Erasij

1.000 0.058 1.000 0.241 0.196 1.000

correlation (Pearson), rank correlation (Spearman) and quadratic assignment procedure (QAP) correlation coecients. Table 11.1 presents both Pearsons simple correlation coecients and Spearmans rank correlation coecients for our relational dependent variables. All coecients are positive and signicant, showing that the four variables selected for the analysis measure dierent elements of the same phenomenon: information and knowledge ows. Digital information and research networks, on one side, and digital information and Erasmus exchange, on the other side, show the highest correlation coecients.13 This may be interpreted as a sign of complementarity between virtual and physical interactions among European universities (and regions). One may also note that the high correlation coecient between research networks and the Erasmus exchange programme shows the existence of hysteresis in the university inter-regional (and international) relationships. Once a relationship is established, both professors and students continue to exploit it. The EU attempts to build research networks aimed at producing not only pure research, but also applied research and marketable innovations which seem to be partially successful: in fact Pearsons correlation between research networks and co-patenting is quite high (0.264).14 We further analysed the relationships among these knowledge ows by using the QAP correlation, a bootstrap method that computes correlation indices between entries of two square matrices and assesses the frequency of random measures as large as actually observed. The QAP algorithm proceeds in two steps. In the rst step it computes Pearsons correlation coecients between corresponding cells of the two data matrices. In the second step, it randomly (synchronously) permutes rows and columns of one matrix and re-computes the correlation to the other matrix. The second step is carried out hundreds of times (in our case: 5000 times) in order to compute the proportion of times that a random measure is larger than or equal to the observed measure calculated in step 1. A low proportion

240

Spatial systems

Table 11.2

QAP correlation between knowledge ow variables


Pearsons correlation Diginfoij RNij 1.000 0.062 (0.040) 0.245** (0.036) 1.000 0.103 (0.048) 1.000 Patij Erasij

Diginfoij RNij Patij Erasij

1.000 0.302** (0.031) 0.220** (0.043) 0.270** (0.038)

Note: ** Signicant at 5%; standard error in parenthesis.

(smaller than 0.05) suggests a strong relationship between the two matrices that is unlikely to have occurred by chance (Borgatti et al., 2002). Table 11.2 shows the results of such a procedure.15 The highest correlation is registered for research networks and Internet hyperlinks (0.302), followed by Erasmus student ows and Internet hyperlinks (0.270), conrming the simple correlation results and showing the high complementarities between these ows of knowledge. QAP procedure shows that the correlation between co-patenting and research networks and co-patenting and Erasmus exchange ows (which registered low Spearman and Pearson correlation coecients) is not signicant, indicating the persistence of frictions between dierent worlds (that is, the business and academic environments). Although the sample of research networks included in the analysis has been selected,16 hence suers from some biases, these results may also show that EU programmes seem to fail in connecting dierent actors, hence these actions need to be redened to be really eective across dierent institutions (and in particular between prot and non-prot organisations).

5.

NETWORK ANALYSIS OF KNOWLEDGE FLOWS

Network analysis (NA) uses quantitative techniques, derived from graph theory, to study and describe the structure of interactions (edges) between given entities (nodes) (Wasserman and Faust, 1994). Initially used by sociologists and ethnologists to study complex personal interactions, NA has recently been used in economic analyses (Snyder and Kick, 1979; Maggioni, 1993 and 2000; Leoncini et al., 1996; Uberti, 2002; Breschi and

Inter-regional knowledge ows in Europe

241

Cusmano, 2004; Breschi and Lissoni, 2004) to analyse institutional, technological and commercial relationships among agents, industries, regions and countries. Therefore, in this chapter, 110 NUTS2 European regions are treated as nodes, while their dierent knowledge ows are treated as edges. Orthodox approaches describe the innovation process through an atomistic principle that assumes the existence of individual utility maximisation procedures and does not take into account the wider social, economic and institutional framework. By contrast, NA highlights some relevant structural features.
The behaviour of a node (in terms of strategy and performance) has to be interpreted in terms of both structural limits and internal features. Internodal relationships must be examined from two complementary perspectives: the single nodes and the whole systems perspective. Neither a single node nor a pair of nodes can be meaningfully analysed, when isolated from the system framework (holistic principle). Systems display a surprisingly intrinsic fractal nature: both the macro level (whole system) and the micro level (nodes) are composed by a plurality of structurally interrelated elements. The interdependence of observations does not hinder NA techniques, allowing a wider use of this methodology even when more traditional statistical and econometric techniques based on pure attributional variables suer. (Bramanti and Maggioni, 1997, p. 327)

In the following analysis we shall use the density and clustering coecients as the index of systemic connection. Density is dened as the ratio between the actual number of edges e and the maximum number of directed edges in a network composed of n nodes17 or: D e n(n 1) . (11.2)

The clustering coecient of node i characterises the extent to which nodes adjacent to it are adjacent to each other (Watts, 1999): Ci
i

(11.3)

where vi is the number of nodes connected to i and is the total number of possible edges in is neighbourhood. The clustering coecient for the whole network is obtained by averaging the clustering coecient of all nodes in the network. The networks analysed in the chapter describe dierent knowledge ows: co-patenting and research networks are symmetric, and Internet hyperlinks and Erasmus exchange ows are a-symmetric. In the latter case, for each

242

Spatial systems

node an outdegree (number of outward connections) and an indegree (number of inward connections) have been calculated. Furthermore, NA indices have been calculated from a dichotomized version18 of the original innovation ow matrices. The customary procedure implies the choice of an appropriate (often ad hoc) threshold; however, it must be considered that the choice of a given threshold is strategic because dierent values produce dierent dichotomised networks. In this analysis we choose the network average as the threshold value. In order to detect the most central actor within the system and the denition of a scale of hierarchy (inequality), centrality and centralisation indices have been designed.19 Formally, the degree centralisation of a network (system) of n nodes (regions) can be dened as follows: (C* b 1)(n Cib ) 2) , (11.4)

C ib

(n

where C* is the centrality value of the most central region in the system and b the denominator reects the maximum level of centrality obtainable in a system of n regions. The centralisation indices (which lies between 0 and 1) measure the dierence in centrality levels between the most central region and the others. A high centralisation index identies a very hierarchic system where dierences in positions are maximised, and a pivotal node exists. A low centralisation index identies a structure where most of the positions are similar and interchangeable. Table 11.3 shows the network indices for dierent knowledge ows. Density indices of dichotomised networks show that the digital information and the co-patenting networks are the least dense, while the research network is the most dense. The data show that knowledge ows do not spread evenly between European regions, which suggests that traditional face-to-face interactions remain one of the most active phenomena of knowledge creation, although virtual ones are cheaper. Table 11.3 Network analysis indices of knowledge ow structures
Density Clustering Isolated nodes Centralisation Outdegree Diginfoij RNij Patij Erasij 0.111 0.240 0.140 0.199 0.741 0.542 0.727 0.464 33 15 22 3 0.425 0.361 0.281 0.586 Indegree 0.379 0.361 0.281 0.410

Inter-regional knowledge ows in Europe

243

The ranking based on clustering coecient is almost the opposite of the density-based one. This can be explained by referring to the number of isolated nodes. The most clustered networks (digital information and copatenting) have many isolated nodes (private club structure): meaning that if one region is connected to another one, then it is very likely that the same region is also connected to the original node neighbours. Centralisation indices show that, in general, the Erasmus student network is the most centralised, while co-patenting is the least centralised network. However since Internet hyperlinks and Erasmus are asymmetric, while research networks and co-patenting are symmetric it is more useful to consider each couplet in isolation. As far as symmetric relationships are concerned, research networks exhibit a more hierarchical regional structure than co-patenting ones, suggesting that educational institutions are tied for better or worse to the regions performance, while individual inventors are more evenly diused and their interactions follow a more uniform pattern. The co-patenting network has a rather non-hierarchic structure due to the presence of some very central regions (Oberbayern, Darmstadt, Dsseldorf and le de France) and to a series of other regions that are connected not exclusively to the most central ones but also with their national neighbourhood. In fact, by removing the most central nodes from the network, highly connected national islands emerge (see Figures 11.1 and 11.2). As far as a-symmetric relationships are concerned, Erasmus student ows display a more hierarchical structure (some European regions are highly engaged in the Erasmus programme either as a source or a destination of student ows, while others are almost not involved) than the digital information one (dierences in the number of hyperlinks are not so relevant). The dierence in centralisation values (referred to as outdegree and indegree) of the Erasmus programme may be interpreted as the existence of a larger dierence in participation in the Erasmus programme of dierent European regions as recipients of students than as senders (a greater number of regions send their students abroad, but their destination is concentrated in a smaller number of regions). A similar (although smaller) dierence is shown by the centralisation indices of the digital information networks. European regions show a greater dierence in their information exports than in their information imports. In other words while universities (and regions) are more similar in the number of hyperlink buttons inserted in their web pages, few universities (and regions) record a larger share of total Internet hyperlink destinations.

Yorkshire and the Humber

244

Figure 11.1

Co-patent network, 19982002, including Oberbayern, Darmstadt, Dsseldorf and le de France

Yorkshire and the Humber

245

Figure 11.2

Co-patent network, 19982002, excluding Oberbayern, Darmstadt, Dsseldorf and le de France

246

Spatial systems

6.

GRAVITY EQUATIONS

Looking for the source of regional disparities we use gravity equations in order to assess whether geographic distance was responsible for such a phenomenon (that is, peripherality exogenously causes poor performances of regions, therefore determining the polarisation of a rich core and a depressed periphery) or whether functional distance (that is, dierence in the scientic and technological levels) endogenously plays a major role in determining the existence of a much more dense core (the network of more advanced regions) and a residual sparse set of relations within the periphery. Finally, we tested the inuence of the similarity/dissimilarity of the productive structure of dierent regions by detecting the eects of sectoral distance (measured through patent activity) on knowledge ows. The gravity equation model is a powerful tool of empirical analysis to explain social interactions (for example, international trade, foreign direct investment, migration and tourism) according to the existence of attracting and impeding forces. This range of models is derived from the law of universal gravitation proposed by Isaac Newton in 1687, which stated that gravitational force between masses decreases with the distance between them, according to an inverse-square law. . . . [T]he theory notes that the greater an objects mass, the greater its gravitational force on another mass (Wikipedia, 2005). In the economic literature these models are commonly used to explain international trade: bilateral trade between two countries is proportional to their economic mass (that is, GDP or population) and inversely related to their geographical distance. These models have been a successful tool for empirical analysis since the 1960s: the signs of parameters of importing and exporting countries GDPs are positive, roughly equal to unity and signicant, and the sign of geographical distance is negative and signicant (Tinbergen, 1962; Poyhonen, 1963). Recently this empirical success has been theoretically demonstrated (Anderson, 1979; Bergstrand, 1985; Helpman, 1988; Deardor, 1998; Feenstra, 2002; Dalgin et al., 2004). We specify a gravitational model which explains the level of a particular type of knowledge ows between two generic regions i and j as a function of a series of relational and attributional variables. All variables are taken in logs in order to interpret the estimated coecients as elasticities. The generic dependent variable, KFij, stands for four dierent typologies of knowledge ows: digital information (KFij Diginfoij), research networks (KFij RNij), co-patenting (KFij Patij), or Erasmus student exchange (KFij Erasij); the independent variables are as dened in Section 3. Table 11.4 shows the results of eight ordinary least squares (OLS)

Table 11.4 Gravity equation for knowledge ows


Research networks RNij (IIa) Functional distance (IIb) Sectoral distance (IIIa) Functional distance (IIIb) Sectoral distance (IVa) Functional distance (IVb) Sectoral distance Co-patents Patij Erasmus students Erasij

Digital information ows Diginfoij (Ib) Sectoral distance

(Ia) Functional distance

Independent variable GDPi

GDPj

RDi

RDj

247
0.403** (0.118) 7.400*** (0.397) 6709 1.454*** (0.067) 11643 0.218 109.79 0.217 110.37 0.541 636.37 0.052** (0.017) 1.346*** (0.066) 11772 10.215*** (0.477) 4623 0.642 679.38

GDistij

Contigij

0.758*** (0.021) 0.594*** (0.021) 0.236*** (0.026) 0.033 (0.026) 0.445*** (0.038) 0.139 (0.098)

0.075*** (0.004) 0.075*** (0.004) 0.041*** (0.005) 0.041*** (0.005) 0.024*** (0.007) 0.015 (0.017)

0.733*** (0.025) 0.733*** (0.025) 0.394*** (0.030) 0.394*** (0.030) 0.580*** (0.039) 0.975*** (0.072)

0.604*** (0.018) 0.441*** (0.018) 0.056** (0.024) 0.137*** (0.024) 0.032 (0.037) 1.169*** (0.154)

FDistij

0.761*** (0.021) 0.600*** (0.022) 0.240*** (0.026) 0.035 (0.027) 0.449*** (0.038) 0.168** (0.100) 0.051** (0.016)

0.076*** (0.004) 0.076*** (0.004) 0.045*** (0.005) 0.045*** (0.005) 0.020** (0.006) 0.011 (0.017) 0.020*** (0.003)

0.748*** (0.025) 0.747*** (0.026) 0.391*** (0.030) 0.392*** (0. 030) 0.525*** (0.043) 1.098*** (0.074) 0.004 (0.018)

0.621*** (0.018) 0.461*** (0.018) 0.065* (0.025) 0.140*** (0.024) 0.008 (0.038) 1.220*** (0.158) 0.033** (0.014)

SDistij

Constant

Number of observations R-squared F-test

7.678*** (0.411) 6513

0.520*** (0.135) 9.539*** (0.465) 4752 0.643 695.77

8.960*** (0.446) 5100 0.359 264.54

0.677*** (0.108) 9.525*** (0.441) 5194 0.365 276.19

0.539 608.92

Note: *** signicant at 1%; ** signicant at 5%; * signicant at 10%; robust standard error in parenthesis; country dummies are included in all regressions but not reported.

248

Spatial systems

regressions,20 where we considered alternatively functional and sectoral distance in the regressors. Regression (a): ln(KFij )
0 1ln(GDPi ) 2ln(GPDj ) 6Contigij 3ln(RDi ) I 4ln(RDj ) ij

5ln(GDistij )

7ln(FDistij )

Regression (b): ln(KFij )


0 1ln(GDPi ) 2ln(GPDj ) 6Contigij 3ln(RDi ) I 4 (RDj ) ij

5ln(GDistij )

7ln(SDistij )

where I indicates country dummy variables and, ij and ij are standard error terms. Table 11.4 presents the results of the econometric analysis.

Regression I describes the structure of information ows running through Internet hyperlinks established between European universities. These ows are positively inuenced by both regions GDP, conrming the existence of a positive relation between the economic size of a region and its involvement in ICT (in terms of endowments, access and use) which may well lead to a digital divide phenomenon. Note also the coecient of the emitting region is slightly larger than that of the receiving one. A positive and signicant coecient is registered by the R&D intensity of the emitting region, while the coecient of the receiving region is not signicant. This suggests that the level of intensity of innovation inputs of a region determines the visibility of the local universitys website (perhaps via a relationship between public funding of R&D and university relevance21), while the positioning of hyperlink buttons follows a dierent logic. Geographical distance is negative and signicant suggesting that, at least for our sample of university websites, the advent of the Internet did not cause the death of distance.22 Digital relationships are considered in academia as complementary to physical ones and faceto-face contacts are still crucial. It is, however, worth noting that the coecient of the contiguity variable is also negative and signicant. Such a result may be explained in terms of a limited use of Internet-based information ows between neighbouring universities and some hidden forms of spatial competition on the local pool of prospective students. Functional distance bears a signicant and neg-

Inter-regional knowledge ows in Europe

249

ative coecient, thus signalling that university networks of relations as measured by Internet hyperlinks tend to develop between similar regions. A similar result is shown by the measure of sectoral distance, perhaps suggesting the existence of a deep relation between a regions industrial structure and the characteristics of its universities. Regression II analyses the joint participation of research institutions belonging to dierent regions in two dierent types of research network under the fth EU research framework programme. These ows are positively inuenced by both regions GDP, conrming the existence of a positive relation between the economic size of a region, its research potential and its scientic networking activity. The R&D intensity coecients of the emitting and receiving regions are positive and very similar, suggesting that the propensity to be involved in the network is positively correlated with the scientic and technological level of both regions. The coecient of geographical distance is negative and signicant; however, its size is very small, suggesting a limited inuence of spatial eects in this activity whose aim is explicitly to link research units from dierent places all over Europe. This is conrmed by the insignicance of the coecient on contiguity. The coecients of both functional and sectoral distance are negative and signicant: meaning that both the scientic and technological levels and the sectoral specialisation of a region play a positive role in determining the probability of joining the same research network. In other words, research networks have a club structure in which agents match with others that are similar. If this is the case, then research networks cannot be used as policy tools to support cohesion and inclusiveness since their structure is a segmented one in which stronger regions cooperate with other stronger ones, and weaker with weaker. It is also worth noting that the coecient on the sectoral distance has a higher value than the geographic distance. Regression III describes the structure of scientic relationships, which derives from the exchange of knowledge and know-how between European inventors. Co-patenting relationships are strongly and positively inuenced by both regions GDP and R&D intensity; the coecients of both variables are very similar. This conrms that both size (that is, larger and richer regions have a greater number of patentable inventions) and technological level play an important role in determining the amount of knowledge exchange needed to develop a patentable innovation. Geographic distance has a signicant and negative coecient. This could be explained in terms of the need for face-to-face contacts in the R&D activity (based on tacit knowledge exchange) leading to a patent application. Since the

250

Spatial systems

coecient of functional distance is not signicant, we focus the attention on model b in order to test whether the sectoral distance plays a more relevant role. This is exactly the case: the negative and signicant coecient shows that a common sectoral specialisation of the technological activity of the two regions is important to determine the level of scientic collaboration between inventors. The positive and signicant coecient on contiguity registered in both specications (a and b) conrms Jae et al.s (1993) results and shows that the innovation process is deeply rooted in a given territory and that knowledge spillovers easily overcome regional borders. The coecient of the geographic distance is larger than not only the coecient of the functional distance (not signicantly dierent from zero) but also the coecient of the sectoral distance: in the innovation process space does matter. Regression IV looks at student ows within the Erasmus programme. As already explained, since in this chapter we are focusing on knowledge ows, we consider the region in which the hosting university is localised as the emitting region of the knowledge ows embedded in the learned student returning to his/her original and receiving region after their studies. Regional GDP and R&D intensity coecients are signicant and positive. Larger, richer and technologically advanced regions are more aware of the advantages of an international education process and more involved in this programme. The coecients on both functional and sectoral distance are negative and signicant, while the coecient of geographical distance is insignicant. Taken together, this may be interpreted as showing that the Erasmus programme does foster the geographical mobility of European students but not as much as cohesion and convergence of the scientic level of European regions. Geographical distance does not inuence the ow of Erasmus students; however, students from top regions (in terms of their respective RSII) tend to study abroad in better foreign regions than their counterparts coming from the bottom regions.

In every model shown in Table 11.4 country dummies included in the estimation to take into account the institutional factors of the emitting and receiving regions which may be determined by national characteristics record signicant coecients. The regression constant in the gravitational models literature refers to a regional xed eect which is sometimes interpreted as an indirect measure of remoteness (that is, the distance of one region to every other region). If one accepts this reasoning, our results support the common wisdom that peripheral (in a geographical sense) regions are also peripheral in a functional sense and that knowledge and

Inter-regional knowledge ows in Europe

251

information ows have a hierarchically segmented structure with limited evidence of a ltering-down process.

7.

CONCLUSION

The reduction of regional disparities has been one of the main targets of EU policies since its very beginning. However, the digital revolution has given new meanings to this concept. Per capita GDP and unemployment rates are still relevant economic indicators, but so are knowledge and ICT indicators (in terms of endowments, access and use). This chapter which focuses on the structure of knowledge ows as measured by four distinct but complementary variables (Internet hyperlinks, research networks, EPO co-patent applications and Erasmus student mobility) has underlined the intrinsic relational nature of knowledge. We showed that there is a positive correlation between knowledge exchange ows and that these ows are inuenced by dierent types of distance: geographical, functional and sectoral. NA techniques showed that Erasmus student ows and Internet hyperlinks have a more hierarchical structure in their outdegree than in their indegree. These results conrm the existence of a polarised centreperiphery hierarchy of European regions which is reected in the structure of knowledge ows.23 The NA perspective showed that although the co-patent network displays some international relations connecting European regions, co-patenting still remains a mainly intra-national activity, mostly connecting regions in the same nation. By using a gravitational model we demonstrated that, far from the claim of the death of distance, geographical distance is still relevant for determining the structure of inter-regional knowledge ows. Functional and sectoral distance also play a crucial role, suggesting that knowledge ows easily between similar (according to their scientic, technological and sectoral characteristics) regions. Convergence between lessdeveloped regions towards income levels of richer regions in the EU is thus hampered by the observed network dynamics. If the EU intends to build a truly European research area in which the networking of centres of excellence acts as a catalyst for backward areas, this target may still be far away.

NOTES
* The authors would like to thank S. Beretta, B. Dettori, M. Nosvelli, M. Riggi, G. Turati and S. Usai for fruitful discussions, and M. Gio for research assistance. The following

252

Spatial systems
people and institutions have been helpful in the process of unpublished data gathering: N. Poupard and P. Vareschi (UK SocratesErasmus Council, London), M. Preda (Istituto di studi su popolazione e territorio, Universit Cattolica del Sacro Cuore, Milan); S. Usai and B. Dettori (Centre for North South Economic Research (CRENoS), Universit degli Studi di Cagliari) and M. Thelwall (School of Computing and Information Technologies, University of Wolverhampton). We acknowledge the nancial support of the Ministry of Education, University and Research (MIUR) under the Research Project Dinamica strutturale: tecnologie, reti, istituzioni (2003131274_001). While it is possible for a single website to count and map all access, it is extremely dicult to collect this information on a wider scale since it would involve the cooperation of the web masters of all websites. A further conrmation of the informational content of Internet hyperlinks relates to the fact that several search engines (and in particular the popular Google) use hyperlink counting as ranking criteria of web pages since they consider it a good proxy of the quality and relevance of the web page. A new discipline (webmetrics) devoted to the analysis of the www using bibliometric procedures has been created, as well as a scientic association (the International Society for Scientometrics and Informetrics, ISSI) (Maggioni and Uberti, 2005). The retrieval of Internet hyperlinks following Thelwall and Smith (2002) was run in 2003 using Altavista, a public search engine. Cooperative research contracts, coordination of research actions, cost-sharing contracts, demonstration contracts, explanatory awards, explanatory awards (demonstration), explanatory awards (thematic network), preparatory, accompanying and support measures, research grants (individual fellowship), research network contracts, study contracts, assessment contracts and thematic network contracts. Some of these contracts are assigned to single applicants (that is, research grants), while others require the creation of research networks among the participants (that is, research and thematic network contracts). A patent registered by three inventors located in three distinct regions i, j and z, would be split into n*(n 1) cells and, respectively, into i with j and z, j with i and z, and z with i and j. Hence an invention co-patented by three individuals in three dierent regions is registered with a value of 0.1666 in the cells corresponding to six dierent couplets. The EU has devoted a new programme to post-graduate student exchange (ErasmusMundus); it started in 2002 and has not yet been adequately monitored, hence in this analysis we focus only on the Erasmus student ows. The Socrates programme is the European programme for education, and includes eight actions; it was developed to promote the European dimension and to improve the quality of learning by encouraging cooperation between the participants countries (European Commission, 2005). The data are courtesy of the UK SocratesErasmus Council, the UK National Agency responsible for the administration of the Erasmus programme in the UK. Data kindly provided by CRENoS. The RSII indicators are: population with tertiary education; participation in lifelong learning; employment in mediumhigh and high-tech employment; employment in hightech services; public R&D; business R&D; EPO high-tech patent applications; EPO patent applications; share of innovative enterprises in the manufacturing and service sectors; innovation expenditures in manufacturing and in services; and sales of new to the rm but not new to the market products. Sometimes a regional border in our sample may also be a national border, and borders are a signicant variable in many empirical papers based on the gravitational model. However, we did not distinguish between these two cases since, with the joint use of the contiguity and country dummies, we are able to identify these cases. With the exception of a Spearman correlation between co-patents and digital information. The lower value for the Spearman correlation could be partially explained by the typology of the research networks considered in this study, which excludes those coordinators that are not universities.

1. 2.

3. 4. 5.

6.

7. 8.

9. 10. 11.

12.

13. 14.

Inter-regional knowledge ows in Europe


15. 16. 17.

253

These correlations were calculated using binary matrices dichotomised according to the average of raw matrices: the cell ij value above the mean would be registered 1 and 0 otherwise. See Research networks in Section 2. For symmetric networks with undirected edges, the density is calculated as follows: D 2e [n(n 1) ].

18.

19.

20.

21. 22. 23.

A value equal to 1 is substituted for the actual value of the edge when it is greater than or equal to the cut-o; and 0 when the actual value is smaller than the cut-o. The use of valued versus unvalued networks is widely discussed in the literature (Wasserman and Faust, 1994). In the econometric analysis performed in Section 6, networks have been used in their valued (that is, containing all dierent numerical values) version, while in this section networks are dichotomised according to their average. If both degree centrality (for the single node) and centralisation (for the whole system) indices are used on a directed network, then it must be stressed that inward and outward measures (relative to the inward and outward links of a node) are, in general, not equal. In the chapter, therefore, centrality and centralisation indices without any further specication identify the outward measure of the indices. Since we are mainly interested in the signicance and signs of the coecient, simple OLS estimation provides valid results. Alternative estimation procedure (either count data models or OLS with BoxCox transformation) would allow detailed analysis of the coecient values. In terms of international ranking of its research output. This is reinforced by the fact that the coecient of the geographical distance is larger than the coecient of the functional distance and (slightly) the coecient of the sectoral distance. A larger number of regions send their students abroad, but their destination is concentrated in a small number of regions. Also, it is easier to be the origin of a hyperlink than to be the target.

REFERENCES
Albert, R. and Barabasi, A.L. (2002), Statistical mechanics of complex networks, Reviews of Modern Physics, 74, 4799. Anderson, J.E. (1979), A theoretical foundation for the gravity equations, American Economic Review, 69, 10616. Bergstrand, J.H. (1985), The gravity equation in international trade: some microeconomic foundations and empirical evidence, Review of Economics and Statistics, 71, 47481. Borgatti, S.P., Everett, M.G. and Freeman, L.C. (2002), UCINET 6 for Windows: Software for Social Network Analyis, Cambridge, MA: Harvard, Analytic Technologies. Bramanti, A. and Maggioni, M.A. (1997), The dynamics of milieux: the network analysis approach, in Ratti, R., Bramanti, A. and Gordon, R. (eds), The Dynamics of Innovative Regions, Aldershot: Ashgate pp. 32141. Breschi, S. and Cusmano, L. (2004), Unveiling the texture of a European research area: emergence of oligarchic networks under EU framework programmes, International Journal of Technology Management, 27, 74772. Breschi, S. and Lissoni, F. (2004), Knowledge networks from patent data: methodological issues and research targets, CESPRI Working Papers 150, Centre of Research on Innovation and Internationalization (CESPRI), Milan.

254

Spatial systems

Dalgin, M., Mitra, D. and Trindade, V. (2004), Inequality, nonhomothetic preferences, and trade: a gravity approach, NBER Working Paper Series 10800, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA. Deardor, A. (1998), Determinants of bilateral trade: does the gravity work in a neoclassical world?, in Frankel, J.A. (ed.), The Regionalization of the World Economy, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 732. DG Enterprise (2003), 2003 European Innovation Scoreboard, Technical Paper No. 3, Regional innovation performances, http:// trendchart.cordis.lu/, accessed January 2005. European Commission (2000), The Lisbon strategy for economic, social and environmental renewal, available at http://europa.eu.int/comm/lisbon_strategy/ index_en.html, accessed February 2005. European Commission (2005), http://europa.eu.int/comm/education/index_en.html, accessed: February 2005. Feenstra, R.C. (2002), Border eects and the gravity equation: consistent methods for estimation, Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 49, 491506. Feldman, M.P. (2002), The Internet revolution and the geography of innovation, International Social Sciences Journal, 54, 4756. Griliches, Z. (1981), Market value, R&D and patents, Economic Letters, 7, 1837. Griliches, Z. (1990), Patent statistics as economic indicators: a survey, Journal of Economic Literature, 28, 1661707. Helpman, E. (1988), Imperfect competition and international trade: evidence from fourteen industrial countries, in Spence, A.M. and Hazard, H.A. (eds), International Competitiveness, Cambridge, MA: Ballinger. Jae, A.B., Henderson, R. and Trajtenberg, M. (1993), Geographic localization of knowledge spillovers as evidenced by patent citations, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108, 55798. Krugman, P. (1991), Geography and Trade, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Leoncini, R., Maggioni, M.A. and Montresor, S. (1996), Intersectoral innovation ows and national technological systems: network analysis for comparing Italy and Germany, Research Policy, 25, 41530. Maggioni, M.A. (1993), Network analysis of regional industrial dynamics and local economic policies, paper presented at the 5th Society for the Advancement of Socio-Economics (SASE) conference, New York, 2528 March. Maggioni, M.A. (2000), Intersectoral innovation ows within and between nations and regions: network analysis and systems of innovation, in Punzo, L., Farina, F. and Fabel, O. (eds), European Economies in Transition, London: Macmillan, pp. 14873. Maggioni, M.A. and Uberti, T.E. (2005), Webmetrics, in Pagani, M. (ed.), Encyclopedia of Multimedia Technology and Networking, London: Idea Group Inc., pp. 109195. Maggioni, M.A. and Usai, S. (2005), Patents as relations: the organisation and the evolution of the innovative activity in two European countries, paper presented at the Open Conference on Knowledge and Regional Economic Development, Barcelona, 911 June. Martin, P. (1998), Can regional policies aect growth and geography in Europe?, World Economy, 21, 75774. Moreno, R., Paci, R. and Usai, S. (2005), Spatial spillovers and innovation activity in European regions, Environment and Planning A, 37: 17931812.

Inter-regional knowledge ows in Europe

255

Paci, R. and Usai, S. (2000), Technological enclaves and industrial districts. An analysis of the regional distribution of innovative activity in Europe, Regional Studies, 34, 97104. Poyhonen, P. (1963), A tentative model for the volume of trade between countries, Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, 90, 939. Sapir, A., Aghion, P., Bertola, G., Hellwig, M., Pisani-Ferry, J., Rosati, D., Vials, J. and Wallace, H. (2004), An Agenda for a Growing Europe: The Sapir Report, Oxford: Oxford University Press. Scherer, F.M. (1965), Firm size, market structure, opportunity and the output of patenting inventions, American Economic Review, 55, 1097125. Snyder, D. and Kick, E.L. (1979), Structural position in the world system and economic growth, 19551970: a multiple network analysis of transnational interactions, American Journal of Sociology, 84, 1096126. Thelwall, M. and Smith, A. (2002), Interlinking between Asia-Pacic university web sites, Scientometrics, 55, 33548. Tinbergen, J. (1962), Shaping the World Economy: Suggestions for an International Economic Policy, New York: 20th Century Fund. Uberti, T.E. (2002), Flussi commerciali, tecnologici ed informativi: elementi per unanalisi strutturale del processo di globalizzazione, doctoral thesis, Milano: Universit Cattolica del Sacro Cuore. Uberti, T.E. and Maggioni, M.A. (2004), Infrastrutture ICT e relazionalit potenziale. Un esercizio di hyperlinks counting a livello sub-nazionale, Quaderno Diseis 0402, Milano: Universit Cattolica del Sacro Cuore. Wasserman, S. and Faust, K. (1994), Social Network Analysis: Methods and Applications, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Watts, D. (1999), Small Worlds: The Dynamics of Networks between Order and Randomness, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Wikipedia (2005), Low of universal gravitation, http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/ Law_of_universal_gravitation, accessed April 2005.

12. Explaining the territorial adoption of new technologies: a spatial econometric approach
Andrea Bonaccorsi, Lucia Piscitello and Cristina Rossi*
1. INTRODUCTION

The idea that information and communication technology (ICT) will reduce the economic importance of geographic distance has been expounded energetically in post-Internet literature (Cairncross, 2001). According to this view, the New Economy works in a space rather than a place, transport costs will be drastically reduced, distance will be less important, and peripheral regions will benet from opportunities that are not available in an economy based on manufacturing industry (Negroponte, 1995; Kelly, 1998; Compaine, 2001). Since it is mostly based on non-material and human capital investment, ICT oers new areas of potential growth to regions or areas that have historically suered from isolation, high transport costs or a lack of private and public physical infrastructure. Consequently, according to this view, the concentration of income opportunities and wealth should decrease over time. Although other predictions have also been made in the debate over the impact of the digital economy (for example, UNDP, 2001; Norris, 2002), this view is still prevalent. However, the reality is not so rosy. Not only are there huge disparities in the intensity with which ICT is adopted across countries, but big dierences still persist within industrialised countries. Indeed, dierences in economic development still shape the rate of the adoption of these technologies, at rm, regional and national levels. The reasons for these stylised facts have been investigated at length in recent years. This chapter contributes to current literature in several ways. First, it focuses on intra-national or regional dierences, which is a much less explored dimension of the digital divide. Second, it uses a new metric for ICT adoption, namely the number of second-level Internet domain names registered under the country code Top Level Domain (ccTLD) .it. Finally,
256

Explaining the territorial adoption of new technologies

257

it explicitly combines the analysis of determinants with a spatial econometric approach. The chapter is organised as follows. Section 2 surveys the literature on the digital divide and the relation between local development and adoption of ICT. Section 3 describes data and methodology. Section 4 contains a description of the model and the empirical results. Section 5 summarises the main conclusions of the chapter.

2. THE LOCAL DIGITAL DIVIDE: THE RELATION BETWEEN DEVELOPMENT AND ICT ADOPTION
The conceptual link between economic development and ICT adoption is a widely researched issue in economics literature. It can be claimed that the nature of ICT makes it possible to overcome territorial peripherality. Unlike traditional heavy and light manufacturing investment, ICT may increase regional attractiveness as a strategic location factor, thus enhancing territorial competitiveness (Gillespie et al., 1989; Kraemer and Dedrick, 1996; Steinmuller, 2001; Camagni and Capello, 2005). The successful experiences of Ireland and India as emerging regions in the provision of software services, due to the availability of ecient communication infrastructures, are often quoted. Contrary to most expectations, however, the overall empirical reality is one of big geographic dierences in the rate of ICT adoption, which seems to reinforce rather than reduce disparities and inequalities.1 Most studies have revealed astonishing dierences in Internet and computer penetration between North America and Europe on the one hand and African and Asian countries on the other (see Chinn and Fairlie, 2004, for a comprehensive survey of this literature). These disparities have mainly been explained in relation to dierences in income, but also in human capital, telecommunication infrastructures (Dasgupta et al., 2001; Oyelaran-Oyeyinka and Lal, 2003; Pohjola, 2003; Wallsten, 2003), demographic variables and regulatory regimes (Wallsten, 2003).2 Although these explanations are fairly convincing, it is puzzling as to why there is still scant evidence of a process of convergence on the part of less-developed countries in the adoption of these technologies. Less investigation has been devoted to the local dimension of the phenomenon; indeed digital inequalities do not divide only developed from developing countries but also regions within the same country (local digital divide; see, for instance, Gareis and Osimo, 2004; Ramsay, 2004). Both developed and developing countries suer from severe regional disparities in ICT adoption. Evidence has been gathered with reference to the United States (NTIA, 2002; Mills and Whitacre, 2003), Canada (Dryburgh, 2001),

258

Spatial systems

Portugal (Nunes, 2004), Spain (Billon Curras and Lera Lopez, 2004), Italy (Bonaccorsi et al., 2002; Assinform, 2004) and China (Qingxuan and Mingzhi, 2002; Wensheng, 2002). One clear-cut stylised fact that emerges from this literature is that regional disparities are at least as important as cross-country dierences, at least within industrialised nations. In Italy, for instance, Bonaccorsi et al. (2002) found that the geographic concentration of Internet adoption is much greater than that of population or income. This would seem to suggest that, far from reducing regional disparities, ICT actually reinforces them. Empirical studies have shown that the determinants of local inequalities are associated with economic, social and demographic disparities. In particular, dierences in the spatial diusion of ICT have been explained in terms of dierences in technological levels, infrastructural endowments (Marrocu et al., 2000; Iammarino et al., 2004) and local spillover eects (Jae et al., 1993; Audretsch and Feldman, 1996; Galliano and Roux, 2004). However, local inequalities might also be inuenced by spatial factors. Investigating the geography of second-level domain names in Portugal (.pt), Nunes (2004) recently proposed that the Internet might contribute to reinforcing the tendency to territorial disintegration, promoting geographic disparities in a more pronounced way than is the case in the real economy space. He found that the role of ICT in overcoming spatial inequalities in Portugal is less important than expected, since these technologies, far from changing the existing spatial structure, are deeply inuenced by it. The importance of a spatial perspective for the analysis of Internet adoption has been addressed by Aztema and Weltevreden (2004) and by Weltevreden et al. (2005), who combine a conventional innovationadoption approach with a detailed geographical analysis to study the adoption of business-to-consumer e-commerce by Dutch retailers. In line with the most recent studies, mainly framed within models of technology diusion (Geroski, 2000), several groups of factors that potentially inuence the territorial adoption of ICT were distinguished (for an excellent recent survey, see OECD, 2004). One category of factors that are positively related to ICT adoption concerns the local technological endowment and the relevant absorptive capacity. The latter refers both to the ability of rms to assess technological opportunities (which depends on their endowment of human and knowledge capital, Cohen and Levinthal, 1989), and to learning eects. The former may arise from earlier use of ICT or a predecessor of a specic ICT element which already embodies constituent elements of later applied, more advanced vintages (McWilliams and Zilberman, 1996). In addition, according to Hollenstein (2004: 41).

Explaining the territorial adoption of new technologies

259

[T]hese aspects of absorptive capacity refer to the standard epidemic model of technology diusion and to the relevant information spillovers from users to non users of the technology. This model basically states that a rms propensity to adopt a technology at a certain point in time is positively inuenced by the present (or lagged) degree of its diusion in the economy as a whole or in the industry to which the rm is aliated.

A second category of variables concerns market characteristics. It has been amply demonstrated that the sectoral specialisation of a region impacts signicantly upon the adoption of ICT (Pohjola, 2003). Likewise, the characteristics of rms have traditionally been employed as explanatory variables in most studies on adoption. In particular, rm size captures the Schumpeterian hypothesis about the positive relation between innovativeness and dimensional scale. The same holds for rm age, although the theoretical arguments are not conclusive (positive experience eects versus negative adjustment cost eects in the case of older rms, see Lal, 2001; Hollenstein, 2004). The adoption of ICT may also be aected by the market conditions in which rms are operating, particularly the competitive pressure to which they are exposed. In markets where competition is stronger, rms are expected to be more inclined to innovative activities or rapid technology adoption (Porter, 1990; Majumdar and Venkataraman, 1993; Feldman and Audretsch, 1999; Hollenstein, 2004). Finally, we explicitly take into account the role that spatial externalities play in current thinking about innovative activity (see Audretsch, 2003).

3.

METHODOLOGY AND DATA

Domain Names as a Proxy for ICT Adoption The term ICT encompasses a wide range of technologies. According to the Canadian Statistics Bureau, it includes desktop and laptop computers, software, peripherals and connections to the Internet that are intended to full information processing and communications functions.3 Such a variety poses severe methodological problems when it comes to measuring the level of territorial adoption of these assets. According to Pohjola (2003), two kinds of metrics reveal disparities in ICT adoption across countries: data on ICT equipment and its use, and indicators of ICT spending. Most of the studies that have analysed geographical inequalities at the international level have identied ICT with the Internet, focusing on the number of Internet hosts (OECD, 2001; Kiiski and Pohjola, 2002) and users (Norris, 2002; NTIA, 2002),4 although restricting the issue of

260

Spatial systems

dierences in ICT adoption simply to Internet access is misleading (Oden and Rock, 2004). Indeed, while data regarding Internet hosts are readily available and highly reliable (Press, 1997; Wolcott et al., 2001),5 this metric suers from two major shortcomings: the data are gathered only at a national level and they do not provide any information about the adopters. Regional-level analysis benets from the availability of larger sets of indicators, ranging from the share of sales of electronic goods to mobile phones; survey data are also available.6 Recently, the use of domain names as a proxy of Internet diusion has been proposed (Zook, 2000; Zook et al., 2004). Domains may be a valid proxy for ICT adoption, mainly because they operationalise the intention to actively supply contents through the Net. Those who register a domain name use the Internet in a more conscious manner, with a view not only to demanding but also to adding content to it.7 In general, the registration of a domain name by a rm is the rst step towards setting up a website through which to present their products or even to undertake electronic commerce activities. Domains therefore provide an underestimation of ICT adoption8 as: (i) ICT adoption does not necessarily involve registering a domain; and (ii) Internet service providers (ISPs) often oer their users room (on their servers) for adding new content. Thus, domains constitute a lower bound as any registrant is unquestionably an ICT adopter. Additionally, every domain name is uniquely associated with a registrant whose geographical location and nature are unambiguously recorded in the databases of the organisations that manage the ccTLD (Mueller, 1998; Grubesic, 2002). The availability of information at the subnational level makes domains a valid metric to explore the territorial dimension of ICT adoption, while data on the nature of the registrants make it possible to take into account dierent adoption determinants for dierent populations of potential adopters. In the present study, domain name registrations by Italian rms are used as a proxy for ICT adoption at the NUTS3 (Nomenclature des Units Territoriales Statistiques) level (103 provinces). In the 200203 period, the Institute of Informatics and Telematics (IIT) of the National Research Council (CNR), the SantAnna School of Advanced Studies and the University of Pisa built up a database of domain name registrations, organised on a subregional basis into dierent categories of actors (individuals, business rms, universities and research centres, third sector associations and local government bodies). Data were extracted from the databases of the registrations under the ccTLD .it that are managed by the Italian Registration Authority (RA) hosted by IIT. A total of 500 000 domain names were inspected for classication; multiple names registered by the same registrant were carefully checked and eliminated.

Explaining the territorial adoption of new technologies

261

The Empirical Evidence on ICT Adoption in Italy: The NorthSouth Divide In order to use domain name registrations as a proxy for the level of ICT adoption, the penetration rate in each province was calculated as the percentage of rms in the province that had at least one domain name registered in the RA databases as of July 2001. Table 12.1 summarises the descriptive statistics of the variable. As expected, the data show the existence of a NorthSouth divide. The regions of Italy are highly dierentiated from social, cultural, demographic and economic points of view, and ICT adoption is no exception. The gures in Table 12.2 reveal that the level of ICT adoption in Italy is quite low, with an average penetration rate of less than 4 per cent, and that dierences between the macro areas are highly signicant (the KruskallWallis test is signicant at p 0.01). No southern province ranks in the top 50. The best-performing province in the South ranks 55th, with just eight northern provinces below that position. Conversely, the 20 worst-performing provinces are all located in the South (see Table 12.3 for the top 10 and bottom 10 positions). The geographical disparities in ICT adoption mirror the inequalities in economic development (measured by value added per employee) both among and within geographical macro areas (Figure 12.1). As the analysis of the map in Figure 12.1 suggests a possible spatial autocorrelation with regard to the provinces located in the NorthCentre, the overall pattern in the local spatial pattern was disaggregated by means of the local indicator of spatial association (LISA). In fact, Figure 12.2 shows the emergence of 3 H-H clusters, all located in the NorthCentre, and 2 L-L Table 12.1
ICT adoption

ICT adoption: descriptive statistics


No. 103 Min 1.20 Max 9.11 Mean 3.76 Std dev. 1.65 Skewness 0.42 Kurtosis 2.72

Table 12.2
Area North Centre South Total

ICT adoption in macro areas


No. 46 21 36 103 Mean 4.76 4.40 2.11 3.76 Std dev. 1.31 1.29 0.66 1.65 KruskalWallis test p-value

0.000

262

Spatial systems

Table 12.3 Ranking of Italian provinces by ICT adoption and per capita income (PCI) in 2001 top 10 and bottom 10 provinces
Ranking Ranking Province ICT PCI (NUTS3) adoption 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 94 95 96 97 98 99 100 101 102 103 1 4 53 26 2 17 21 25 28 12 82 95 101 84 91 103 100 102 98 75 Milano Firenze Bolzano Lecco Bologna Torino Varese Udine Como Roma Benevento Potenza Agrigento Brindisi Matera Caltanissetta Vibo Valentia Crotone Enna Campobasso Region (NUTS2) Lombardia Toscana Trentino Alto Adige Lombardia Emilia Romagna Piemonte Lombardia Friuli Venezia Giulia Lombardia Lazio Campania Basilicata Sicilia Puglia Basilicata Sicilia Calabria Calabria Sicilia Molise Macro region ICT (NUTS1) adoption North Centre North North North North North North North Centre South South South South South South South South South South 9.1 7.1 6.7 6.5 6.5 6.4 6.3 6.2 6.2 6.2 1.5 1.5 1.5 1.4 1.4 1.3 1.3 1.3 1.2 1.2

clusters in the South. This is in line with Fabiani et al. (2003), who found very big dierences between rms in the South of Italy and in the North and Centre in the rate of adoption of almost all ICTs. Iammarino et al. (2004) highlight the same divide as far as the production of ICT is concerned. In addition, Figure 12.2 also evidences that ICT adoption is more locally concentrated than added value per employee.9 Following the literature on the spatial distribution of innovation (Audretsch and Feldman, 1996; Audretsch, 2003), spatial dependence was expected to exist between the observations. As Le Sage notes, spatial dependence in a collection of sample data observations refers to the fact that one observation associated with a location which we might label i depends on other observations at locations j i (Le Sage, 1998: 3). Table 12.4 reports the results of tests normally used for detecting spatial dependence.10 ICT adoption is the percentage of rms in each province that

Explaining the territorial adoption of new technologies North

263

North

Centre

Centre

South

South

Std Deviation: ICT_END 1.202.11 (19) 2.113.77 (37) 3.775.42 (26) 5.427.08 (19) > 7.08 (2)

Std Deviation: VAA 9 704.0012 978.30 (25) 12 978.3017 276.21 (19) 17 276.2121 574.13 (44) 21 574.1325 872.04 (13) > 25 872.04 (2)

Figure 12.1 Distribution of ICT adoption and added value per inhabitant across Italian provinces: the Three Italies had at least one domain name registered as of 2001. All three tests conrm the existence of a spatial dependence, and we can conclude that the adoption of ICT by each province i is related to the adoption of other provinces j i. This shows that geography matters.

264
ICT adoption

Spatial systems
Added value per employee, LISA

LISA Chister Map Not Significant HighHigh LowLow LowHigh HighLow

Figure 12.2

ICT adoption and added value per employee, univariate LISA

Table 12.4 Spatial dependence tests for the dependent variable (ICT adoption)
Morans ICT adoption Gearys c ICT adoption Getis & Ords G ICT adoption
Note:

I 0.589 c 0.480 G 0.053

E(I) 0.010 E(c) 1.000 E(G) 0.044


0.01.

Sd(I) 0.064 Sd(c) 0.080 Sd(G) 0.002

z 9.385 *** z 6.494 *** z 6.001 ***

two-tail test; *** signicant at p

4. ECONOMETRIC MODELS OF TERRITORIAL ICT ADOPTION


First of all a standard cross-section specication was estimated. Using the variables mentioned in Section 2, ICT adoption was modelled as a func-

Explaining the territorial adoption of new technologies

265

Table 12.5
Variables

Specication of dependent and independent variables


Description Percentage of rms that have registered at least one domain name Source Registration authority for the ccTLD .it elaboration

Dependent variable ICT ADOPTION

Explanatory variables Absorptive capacity PATENTS

PUBLICATIONS

Ratio of the number of patents granted by the United States Patent and Trademark Oce (USPTO) in each province in the 199199 period and the number of rms in that province Ratio between the number of scientic publications by university researchers in each province and the number of rms in that province Percentage of districtual local units

USPTO elaboration

ISI Citation Index databases elaboration

Competition COMPETITION Characteristics of rms SIZE Sectoral composition STRUCTURE

Infocamere elaboration ISTAT

Ratio of the number of employees and the number of rms in manufacturing Percentage of rms in the primary sector. This is a dummy variable that assumes value 0 if the province is below the national average, 1 otherwise

Infocamere elaboration

Technological endowment INFRASTRUCTURE Facilities and networks for telephony and telematics (Index of endowment, Italy 100) Controls DUMMY METROPOLITAN DUMMY NORTH Dummy variable, value 1 for metropolitan, 0 otherwise Dummy variable, value 1 for northern provinces, 0 otherwise

Istituto Tagliacarne

Our elaboration Our elaboration

tion of a provinces absorptive capacity, the characteristics of rms, the sectoral composition of the province and technological endowment. Checks were also made for urbanisation economies. A dummy was inserted to address the NorthSouth divide. The proxies employed, and their statistical descriptives and correlations, are reported in Tables 12.5 and 12.6.

Table 12.6 Correlation matrix


PATENTS 1.000 0.428 0.305 0.256 1.000 0.378 0.227 INFRASTRUCTURE PUBLICATIONS COMPETITION

Variable

SIZE

266

SIZE PATENTS INFRASTRUCTURE PUBLICATIONS COMPETITION

1.000 0.520 0.256 0.188 0.378

1.000 0.001

1.000

Explaining the territorial adoption of new technologies

267

Table 12.7
Variable

Standard OLS models


Model OLS 1 Coecient OLS 2 Coecient 0.207 ( 0.350)

Constant PATENTS PUBLICATIONS COMPETITION SIZE STRUCTURE INFRASTRUCTURE DUMMY NORTH DUMMY METROPOLITAN Adj. R-squared: F-statistic Log likelihood Akaike information criterion Schwarz criterion Morans I (error) Robust LM (lag) Robust LM (error)
Note: Standard errors in brackets; *** p-value

1.174* (1.797) 0.464* (1.594) 0.352*** (2.899) 0.011*** (3.781) 0.276 (1.481) 0.199 (0.993)

1.602*** (7.120) 1.975*** (5.349) 0.749 44.477*** 122.698 261.396 282.474 1.817* 0.999 0.000
0.01; ** p-value 0.05; Obs.

0.256** (2.326) 0.008*** (3.144) 0.479*** (3.056) 0.116 (0.614) 0.011*** (5.223) 1.408*** 6.907 1.260*** (3.511) 0.800 59.196*** 111.059 238.118 259.196 2.224** 0.001 1.324
103.

Table 12.7 reports the results from two ordinary least squares (OLS) specications; as they are highly correlated, the variables PATENTS and INFRASTRUCTURE are included alternately. As expected, ICT adoption is positively inuenced by:

Local absorptive capacity: the coecient of the variable PATENTS is positive and signicantly dierent from zero at p 0.10, as is the one for PUBLICATIONS, which is signicant at least at p 0.05.

268

Spatial systems

Characteristics of rms: SIZE is positive, although it is signicant at p 0.01 only in the second specication. Sectoral composition of the province: this seems to play no role in explaining the dependent variable, although it is worth noting that it is strongly and positively correlated with the variable SIZE (Pearson correlation index 0.517, p-value 0.000); we might therefore hypothesise a positive contribution of STRUCTURE to ICT adoption. Market conditions: the variable COMPETITION is positive and highly signicant (p 0.01), revealing that competitive pressure is crucial in stimulating ICT adoption at the local level. However, the proxy utilised (percentage of districtual local units per province) might also be considered a proxy for imitation processes among rms in their use of new technologies. Technological endowment: as expected, technological infrastructures dedicated to telephony and telematics (INFRASTRUCTURE) positively and signicantly aect (at p 0.01) ICT adoption in the province.

Given that in Italy there is a signicant NorthSouth divide in social, cultural, demographic and economic terms, the dummy variable NORTH highlights spatial heterogeneity in ICT adoption. Likewise, the dummy for metropolitan areas reveals that ICT adoption is aected by urbanisation economies, which is in line with the literature on the role of cities in the diusion of the Internet (see, for instance, Zook, 1999).11 It is worth observing that even when controlling for spatial heterogeneity (through the inclusion of the dummy variable), the diagnostics for spatial dependence signal the possible existence of spatial autocorrelation. In both specications, Morans I tests proved signicant at least at p 0.10, although none of the robust LM tests was signicant.12 Therefore, following Anselin (1988, 2004) and Anselin and Moreno (2003), spatial lag and spatial error models were run in order to disentangle the spatial eect. The results of the spatial models, reported in Table 12.8, show that the coecient lambda is highly signicant at least at p 0.05, suggesting that spatial dependence might work through omitted variables with a spatial dimension (that is, that the errors from dierent provinces are spatially correlated, see Abreu et al., 2004). The spatial lag of the dependent variable (W_ICT) also turned out to be signicant (at p 0.05), although only in the rst specication, revealing that the adoption of new technology in a given province depends not only on the values of the explanatory variables in the province, but also on ICT adoption in other provinces.

Explaining the territorial adoption of new technologies

269

Table 12.8
Variable

Spatial lag and spatial error models


Model Spatial lag 1 Coecient Spatial error 1 Coecient 1.979*** (3.007) Spatial lag 2 Coecient 0.230 ( 0.405) 0.153 (1.542) Spatial error 2 Coecient 0.599 (0.888)

Constant W_ICT PATENTS PUBLICATIONS COMPETITION SIZE STRUCTURE INFRASTRUCTURE DUMMY NORTH DUMMY METROPOLITAN Lambda R-squared: Log likelihood Akaike info criterion Schwarz criterion LR test

1.017 (1.559) 0.213** (2.117) 0.385 (1.387) 0.355*** (3.106) 0.010*** (3.406) 0.185 (1.056) 0.226 1.192

0.534* (1.867) 0.331*** (2.993) 0.010** (3.692) 0.059 (0.321) 0.331* (1.691)

1.190*** (4.022) 2.031*** (5.848)

1.652*** (6.312) 1.977*** (5.789) 0.290** (2.428) 0.778 121.213 258.427 279.505 2.969*

0.260** (2.491) 0.007*** (2.861) 0.397*** (2.6069) 0.081 ( 0.451) 0.0100*** (5.141) 1.117*** (4.125) 1.323*** (3.872)

0.249*** (2.582) 0.008*** (3.272) 0.274* (1.675) 0.025 (0.136) 0.011*** (5.793) 1.407*** (5.618) 1.313*** (4.089) 0.369*** (3.286) 0.829 108.568 233.137 245.215 4.982**

0.776 121.045 260.09 283.803 3.306*

0.818 110.092 238.184 261.896 1.935

Note: Standard errors in brackets; *** p-value

0.01; ** p-value

0.05; Obs.

103.

5.

CONCLUSIONS

This chapter contributes to the literature on the determinants of the adoption of new technologies at the local level in several ways. First, it corroborates some robust ndings in current literature. It was found that variables describing the vitality of general economic activity are relevant. Economic environments with traditional economic activities are less vibrant in ICT adoption: the larger the proportion of rms in the primary sector, the lower the intensity of advanced-level Internet use. This general eect is reinforced

270

Spatial systems

by a specic technological eect related to ICT: the higher the index of technological endowment, measured in terms of the local-level telecommunications network, the greater the probability of advanced-level use of ICT. These ndings corroborate the notion that very traditional, highly material investments play a major role in explaining the local digital divide. As anticipated in the literature on telecommunications investment (Biehl, 1982; Gillespie et al., 1989; Kraemer and Dedrick, 1996), regional development may be adversely aected by disparity in the level of infrastructure. Contrary to expectations, the spatial diusion seems to follow the existing geography of development rather than dramatically changing it. Our results are also consistent with existing evidence on the geographic concentration of ICT production and dierences in the adoption of ICT by rms in Italy (Pagnini, 2002; Fabiani et al., 2003; Iuzzolino, 2003; Iammarino et al., 2004). It must be admitted that our data do not capture the structure of ICT supply, but rather the structure of demand or utilisation. Firms are only part of the adoption process as described by our data on domain names. At the same time, it is clear that general economic factors and the localisation and activity of rms in these industries strongly inuence ICT utilisation in the business sector, in households and in society at large. Second, the adoption of ICT is strongly inuenced by the level of knowledge available at the province level, as measured by the ow of patent registrations and scientic publications. This eect was related to the notion of absorptive capacity, and a clear analogy was drawn with the idea that only rms that invest in in-house R&D are able to capture externally created knowledge. According to our results, areas that are poor in general technological activity and in research are less likely to make active use of ICT, thus suggesting the benets from local eects of human capital accumulation. While this eect may be intuitive for production activities, due to input pooling and knowledge spillovers (Ellison and Glaeser, 1997; Pagnini, 2002), it is interesting to observe how important it is for the adoption of new technologies as well. In addition, the larger the proportion of rms in a province that is part of an industrial district, the more intense the adoption of ICT, thus conrming the positive impact of competitive pressure. This contributes to the debate about the ability of industrial districts (mainly based on small and medium-sized rms in traditional industries) to absorb ICT, but also casts some light on the role of the imitation processes that motivate rms to choose new technologies. Third, a spatial econometric approach was specically introduced for the analysis of the relationship between the digital divide and the adoption of new technologies. Spatial proximity is very important as spillovers ow across provinces. However, as the empirical literature has shown (Jae

Explaining the territorial adoption of new technologies

271

et al., 1993; Keller, 2002) that benets from spillovers actually decline with distance, peripherality is still expected to be an obstacle to ICT adoption. As a matter of fact, our empirical evidence regarding Italy shows that areas far from centres suer from severe diculties in adjusting to new technology. Consequently, there is a need for models that include contiguity matrices at further levels of spatial lags. Finally, the crucial role of complementarities is well reected in our data. The literature on the impact of ICT on productivity and economic growth has strongly emphasised the crucial importance of the coexistence and coevolution of investment in physical infrastructure and equipment, investment in human capital and profound changes in organisational structures and procedures in both the private and public sectors (Brynjolfsson, 1993; Brynjolfsson and Hitt, 1996; Bresnahan et al., 1999; Black and Lynch, 2001; OECD, 2004).

NOTES
We gratefully acknowledge Koen Frenken, an anonymous referee and the participants at the 4th EMAEE Conference, Utrecht, May, 1921 2005 for their insightful comments and suggestions. 1. According to the OECD (2001), the digital divide refers to the gap between individuals, households, businesses and geographic areas at dierent socio-economic levels with regard both to their opportunities to access information and communication technologies (ICTs) and to their use of the Internet for a wide variety of activities. 2. The cost of monthly connection to broadband services is estimated to be 0.9 per cent of average income in Japan, 1.2 per cent in Belarus and 9.1 per cent in Cameroon (Fundacin AUNA, 2004). 3. See www.statcan.ca/english/freepub/81-004-XIE/def/ictdef.htm. 4. An analysis of cross-country diusion of personal computers can be found in Caselli and Coleman (2001). 5. For instance, every six months Network Wizard publishes the results regarding all the TLD on its website, whereas the RIPE (http://www.ripe.net) publishes the data about the ccTLD in its area (Europe, North Africa, Middle East) on a monthly basis. Hosts belong to the so-called endogenous metrics, which are obtained in an automatic or semiautomatic way from the Internet itself (Diaz-Picazo, 1999). The organisations that manage the dierent ccTLD and gTLD perform the hostcount under their TLD on a regular basis and provide these data on the Web or by File Transfer Protocol (FTP). 6. The bi-annual survey A nation on line, conducted on more than 3,000 US citizens (NTIA, 2002), collects data on the number of PCs purchased by families and the activities they carry out on the Internet. 7. Domain grabbing must also be taken into account. However, this phenomenon does not aect our data, as the unit of analysis is the registrant rather than the domain: multiple registrations were discarded from the database. 8. It is worth observing that hosts suer from the same drawback. Indeed, hostcount programs do not reach private networks (Intranets) and machines protected by rewalls. The use of dynamic Internet Protocol (IP) addresses by ISPs should also be taken into account. In addition, they are prone to overestimation due to a number of factors, for instance the association of multiple IP addresses with the same computer. *

272
9. 10.

Spatial systems
There is a considerable amount of literature about the spatial concentration of economic activity (for a review of this literature, see Arbia, 2001). The most general specication for the matrix was used, that of geographical distance between the centroids of provinces i and j (km). However, as the specication of the spatial weights is contentious in the literature, alternative contiguity matrices (Rookbased and Queen-based contiguity) were also tried, but the results did not change substantially. The results of these alternative models have not been reported here, but are available on request. A common proxy for urbanisation economies is population density, but this is not a valid option with regard to Italy. The whole country is highly populated (average population density: 191.7 inhabitants per square kilometre), and when the provinces were ranked by population density, it turned out that several of the top 10 ranking provinces do not contain big cities. Lagrange multiplier tests were used to assess the extent to which remaining unspecied spatial spillovers may be present in the estimation of expression (see Anselin, 1988; Florax and Nijkamp, 2004; Arbia, 2006).

11.

12.

REFERENCES
Abreu, M., de Groot, H.L.F. and Florax, R.J.G.M. (2004), Spatial patterns of technology diusion: an empirical analysis using TFP, Tinbergen Institute Discussion Paper 2004-079/3. Anselin, L. (1988), Spatial Econometrics: Methods and Models, Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publishers. Anselin, L. (2004), Exploring spatial data with GeoDa: a workbook, www.geoda. uiuc.edu/pdf/geodaworkbook.pdf. Anselin, L. and Moreno, R. (2003), Properties of tests for spatial error components, Regional Science and Urban Economics, 33, 595618. Arbia G. (2001), Modelling the geography of economic activities on a continuous space, Papers in Regional Science, 80, 41124. Arbia G. (2006), Spatial Econometrics: Statistical Foundations and Applications to Regional Convergence, Springer: Berlin. Assinform (2004), Rapporto sullinformatica e le telecomunicazioni in Italia, Assinform, Milan. Audretsch, D. (2003), Innovation and spatial externalities, International Regional Science Review, 26, 16774. Audretsch, D.B. and Feldman, M.P. (1996), Knowledge spillovers and the geography of innovation and production, American Economic Review, 86, 63040. Aztema, O.L.A.C. and Weltevreden, J.W.J. (2004), Adoption of B2C commerce by retail outlets at city centres: the role of place, products and organisation, Paper presented at the international specialist meeting on ICT, everyday life and urban change, Doorn, The Netherlands, 47 November. Biehl, D. (1982), The contribution of infrastructure to regional development, Commission of the European Communities, Infrastructure Study Group, Final Report. Oce for Ocial Publications of the European Communities, Luxembourg. Billon Curras, M. and Lera Lopez, F. (2004), The NorthSouth digital divide in information and communication technologies development: the case for Spains regions, Paper presented at the 44th European Congress of the Regional Science Association, 2529 August.

Explaining the territorial adoption of new technologies

273

Black, S. and Lynch, L. (2001), How to compete: the impact of workplace practices and information technology on productivity, Review of Economics and Statistics, 83(3), 43445. Bonaccorsi, A., Martinelli, M., Rossi, C. and Serrecchia, I. (2002), Measuring and modelling Internet diusion, Paper presented at the Danish Research Unit for Industrial Dynamics (DRUID) Summer Conference, Copenhagen, 68 June. Bresnahan, T.F., Brynjolfsson, E. and Hitt, L.M. (1999), Information technology, workplace organization, and the demand for skilled labor: rm-level evidence, NBER Working Paper 7136, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA. Brynjolfsson, E. (1993), The productivity paradox of information technology, Communication of the ACM, 36(12), 6777. Brynjolfsson, E. and Hitt, L. (1996), Paradox lost? Firm-level evidence on the returns to information systems, Management Science, 42(4), 54158. Cairncross, F. (2001), The Death of Distance: How the Communications Revolution Will Change Our Lives, Cambridge, MA: Harvard Business School Press. Camagni, R. and Capello, R. (2005), ICT and regional competitiveness in the era of Internet, The Annals of Regional Science, 39(3), 42138. Caselli, F. and Coleman, W.J. (2001), Cross-country technology diusion: the case of computers, NBER Working Paper 8130, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA. Chinn, M.D. and Fairlie, R.W. (2004), The determinants of the global digital divide: a cross country analysis of computer and Internet penetration, Discussion Paper 881, Economic and Growth Center, Yale University, New Haven, CT. Cohen, W.M. and Levinthal, D.A. (1989), Innovation and learning: the two faces of R&D, Economic Journal, 99, 56996. Compaine, B.M. (2001), The Digital Divide: Facing a Crisis or Creating a Myth?, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Dasgupta, S., Somik L. and Wheeler, D. (2001), Policy reform, economic growth and the digital divide: an econometric analysis, World Bank Working Paper 2567, Washington, DC. Diaz-Picazo, G.F. (1999), An analysis of international Internet diusion, PhD Thesis, MIT, Cambridge, MA. Dryburgh, H. (2001), Changing our ways: why and how Canadians use the Internet, Statistics Canada, Housing; Family and Social Statistics Division, Catalogue no. 56F004MIE, No. 3. Ellison, G. and Glaeser, E.L. (1997), Geographic concentration in U.S. manufacturing industries. A dartboard approach, Journal of Political Economy, 105(5), 889927. Fabiani, S., Schivardi, F. and Trento, S. (2003), Quale impresa italiana investe in tecnologie digitali?, in S. Rossi (ed.), La Nuova Economia. I fatti dietro il mito, Bologna: Il Mulino, pp. 12550. Feldman, M. and Audretsch, D. (1999), Innovation in cities: science-based diversity, specialization and localized competition, European Economic Review, 43, 40929. Florax, R. and P. Nijkamp (2004), Misspecication in linear spatial regression models, in K. Kempf-Leonard (ed.), Encyclopaedia of Social Measurement, San Diego: San Diego Academic Press. Fundacin AUNA (2004), eEspaa 2004, IV Informe anual sobre el desarrollo de la Sociedad de la Informacin en Espaa, www.fundacionauna.com/areas/25_ publicaciones/publi_251_4.asp, accessed on 28th September 2006.

274

Spatial systems

Galliano, D. and Roux, P. (2004), Spatial inequalities in the adoption of information and communication technologies. The case of French industrial rms, Paper presented at the 4th Congress on Proximity Economics. Proximity, Networks and Coordination, Marseille, 1718 June. Gareis, K. and Osimo, D. (2004), Benchmarking regional performance in the information society: turning it into practice, Paper presented at the Workshop Measuring the information society: what, how, for whom and what?, 5th Annual Conference of the Association of Internet Researchers, Brighton, UK, 1922 September. Geroski, P. (2000), Models of technology diusion, Research Policy, 29, 60325. Gillespie, A., Goddard, J., Hepworth, M. and Williams, H. (1989), Information and communications technology and regional development: an information economy perspective, Science, Technology and Industry Review, 5, 86111. Grubesic, T.H. (2002), Spatial dimensions of Internet activity, Telecommunications Policy, 26(78), 36387. Hollenstein, H. (2004), The decision to adopt information and communication technologies (ICT): rm-level evidence from Switzerland, in OECD (2004), Ch. 3. Iammarino, S., Jona-Lasinio, C. and Mantegazza, S. (2004), Labour productivity, ICT and regions. The resurgence of the Italian dualism?, LLEE Working Document 12, Luiss Lab on European Economics. Iuzzolino, G. (2003), Si producono in Italia, e dove, le tecnologie digitali?, in S. Rossi (ed.), La Nuova Economia. I fatti dietro il mito, Bologna: Il Mulino, pp. 95124. Jae, A.B., Trajtenberg, M. and Henderson, R. (1993), Geographical localisation of knowledge spillovers, as evidenced by patent citations, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 58, 57798. Keller, W. (2002), Geographical localisation of international technology diusion, American Economic Review, 92, 12042. Kelly, K. (1998), New Rules for the New Economy. Ten Ways the Network Economy is Changing Everything, London: Fourth Estate. Kiiski, S. and Pohjola, M. (2002), Cross-country diusion of the Internet, Information Economics and Policy, 14, 297310. Kraemer, K.L. and Dedrick, J. (1996), IT and economic development: international competitiveness, in V.H. Dutton (ed.), Information and Communication Technologies. Visions and Realities, Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 61111. Lal, K. (2001), The determinants of the adoption of information technology: a case study of the Indian garments industry, in M. Pohjola (ed.), Information Technology, Productivity and Economic Growth, Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press. Le Sage, J.P. (1998), Econometrics toolbox, www.spatial-econometrics.com, 17 November 2004. Majumdar, S.K. and Venkataraman, S. (1993), New technology adoption in US telecommunications: the role of competitive pressures and rm-level inducements, Research Policy, 22, 52136. Marrocu, E., Paci, R. and Pala, R. (2000), Estimation of total factor productivity for regions and sectors in Italy. A panel cointegration approach, Centre for North South Economic Research (CRENOS) Working Paper, 00/16. McWilliams, B. and Zilberman, D. (1996), Time of technology absorption and learning by using, Economics of Innovation and New Technology, 4, 13954. Mills, B.F. and Whitacre, B.E. (2003), Understanding the non-metropolitan metropolitan digital divide, Growth and Change, 34(2), 21943.

Explaining the territorial adoption of new technologies

275

Mueller, M. (1998), The battle over Internet domain names: global or national TLDs?, Telecommunications Policy, 22(2), 89107. Negroponte, N. (1995), Being Digital, New York: Knopf. Norris, P. (2002), Digital Divide: Civic Engagement, Information Poverty, and the Internet Worldwide, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. NTIA (National Telecommunications and Information Administration), Economics and Statistics Administration (2002), A nation online: how Americans are expanding their use of the Internet, www.ntia.doc.gov/ntiahome/dn/nationonline_ 020502.htm, 3 October 2004. Nunes, F. (2004), The geography of .pt top level domain, Paper presented at the 44th European Congress of the European Regional Science Association, Porto, 2529 August. Oden, M. and Rock, K. (2004), Beyond the digital access divide: toward meaningful measures of information, Paper presented at the 5th Annual Conference of the Association of Internet Researchers, Brighton, UK, 1922 September. Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) (2001), Understanding the digital divide, www.oecd.org/dataoecd/38/57/1888451.pdf, 1 October 2004. Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) (2004), The economic impact of ICT. Measurement, evidence and implications, www1.oecd. org/publications/e-book/9204051E.PDF, 1 October 2004. Oyeralan-Oyeyinka, B. and Lal, K. (2003), The Internet diusion in Sub-Saharan Africa: a cross-country analysis, Discussion Paper of INTECH, Institute for New Technology, United Nations University. Pagnini, M. (2002), Misure e determinanti della agglomerazione spaziale nei comparti industriali italiani, Banca dItalia, Discussion Paper 452, October. Pohjola, M. (2003), The adoption and diusion of ICT across countries: patterns and determinants, in D.C. Jones (ed.), New Economy Handbook, San Diego, CA: ElsevierAcademic Press, pp. 77100. Porter, M. (1990), The Comparative Advantage of Nations, New York: Free Press. Press, L. (1997), Tracking the global diusion of the Internet, Communications of the ACM, 40(11), 1117. Qingxuan, M. and Mingzhi, L. (2002), New economy and ICT development in China, Information Economics and Policy, 14(2), 27595. Ramsay, R. (2004), The Internet and its geographic dilemma: constructing the digital divide, Paper presented at the 5th Annual Conference of the Association of Internet Researchers, Brighton, UK, 1922 September. Steinmuller, W.E. (2001), ICTs and the possibilities of leapfrogging by developing countries, International Labour Review, 140(2), 193210. United Nations Development Programme (UNDP) (2001), Human Development Report 2001. Making New Technologies Work for Human Development, Oxford, UK and New York: Oxford University Press. Wallsten, S. (2003), Regulation and Internet use in developing countries, AEI Brookings Joint Center for Regulatory Studies Related Publications 03-8, Washington, DC. Weltevreden, J.W.J., de Kruif, K., Atzema, O.A.L.C., Frenken, K. and van Oort, F.G. (2005), The b2c e-commerce landscape of the Dutch retail sector, Paper presented at the 45th Congress of European Regional Science Association (ERSA), Free University, Amsterdam, The Netherlands, 2327 August.

276

Spatial systems

Wensheng, W. (2002), Bridging the digital divide inside China, Paper presented at the 3rd Annual Conference of the Association of Internet Researchers, Maastricht, NL, 1316 October. Wolcott, P., Press, L., McHenry, W., Goodman, S. and Foster, W. (2001), A framework for assessing the global diusion of the Internet, Journal of the AIS, (2)6. Zook, M.A. (1999), Internet cities of the United States and the world: understanding new geographies, Paper presented at the Cities in the Global Information Society Conference, Newcastle upon Tyne, UK, 2224 November. Zook, M.A. (2000), Internet metrics: using hosts and domain counts to map the Internet globally, Telecommunications Policy, 24(6/7), 61320. Zook, M.A., Dodge, M., Aoyama, Y. and Townsend, A. (2004), New digital geographies: information, communication, and place, in S.D. Brunn, S.C. Cutter, and J.W. Harrington (eds), Geography and Technology, Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publishers, pp. 15576.

PART V

Planning

13. Evolutionary urban transportation planning? An exploration


Luca Bertolini
1. INTRODUCTION

For urban transportation planners these are challenging times. On the one hand, and in spite of all the hype about dematerialization of society, physical mobility systems appear ever more crucial in granting individuals and organizations the access to the spatially and temporally disjointed resources they need to thrive or even just to survive. On the other, because of a heterogeneous mix of mounting nancial and scal constraints to infrastructure expansion, and growing awareness of and social resistance to the negative impacts of mobility, the traditional predict and provide approach to planning is no longer an option. Practical concerns are echoed by more fundamental critiques (see, for instance, Dimitriou, 1992; Giord, 2003). Central to this more fundamental criticism is the contention that conventional planning methods do not adequately account for the irreducible uncertainty of developments aecting transport and its relationship with the broader context. Uncertainty is, of course, inherent to any future-oriented activity. There are, however, dierent forms of uncertainty. As discussed by Van der Heijden (1996), a rst form of uncertainty is risk, where there is enough historical precedent in terms of similar events to allow the estimation of probabilities for various outcomes (this is the core realm of forecasting); structural uncertainties are a second form, where the event, while still conceivable in terms of chains of cause and eect, is unique enough not to provide any indication of likelihood (think of the complex interplay of rising wealth, social emancipation, mass motorization and urban decentralization, as it unfolded in industrialized nations in the post-war period); a third form, unknowables, is where the event cannot even be imagined (think of the 1973 oil crisis). While all three forms of uncertainty may apply at any time, the likelihood of uncertainties of types two and three increases as the time horizon gets longer and the system gets more complex (that is, with more components and more relationships), up to a point
279

280

Planning

where prediction is no longer possible. As a discipline that also deals with the long term and with highly complex systems, urban transportation planning should also be able to come to terms with fundamentally unpredictable events, that is, irreducible forms of uncertainty (the second and the third forms). Yet, a convincing response is still lacking. In the words of Meyer and Miller (2001, p. 519): No aspect . . . is as pervasive to the [transport planning] process, and yet as often ignored, as uncertainty. In response, Meyer and Miller stress the need to improve present land use and transportation models. More adequate forecasting models would need to explore the full range of system responses (short and long run) to a broad variety of policy combinations (transportation, land use and other), and do this at the level of individual responses (by means of disaggregated behavioural models). However, and crucially, they also recognize that Even with ideal . . . models, uncertainty will still exist with respect to the exact nature of future activity systems (p. 340). Banister (2002, p. 141) strikes a similar note:
Some of the limitations of the TPM [transport planning model] have been met by the ILUTM [integrated land use transport model]. But the complexity of the land development process, travel decisions and the rapidly changing forms of industry, of population structure, of lifestyles, and of the use of time all contrive to make progress dicult, if not impossible.

This chapter attempts to take this more fundamental level of criticism to its logical conclusion. In particular, its aim is to explore if and how an evolutionary approach to urban transportation planning can help to overcome some of the limits mentioned above, and develop planning methods that can usefully complement forecasting-based ones. The inspiration is drawn from much more advanced conceptualizations in other disciplines, and most notably evolutionary economics and the application of complexity theory to the understanding of cities. Evolutionary and complexity approaches seem especially appropriate because they both recognize the high level of interdependency between the dierent components of the system and the limits to dealing with such interdependency by means of prediction, because of irreducible uncertainty. Building upon this line of reasoning, two core hypotheses are formulated with respect to the object and the scope of urban transportation planning. The rst hypothesis is that the urban transportation system indeed behaves in an evolutionary, complex fashion. The second, related hypothesis is that because of this, urban transportation policies also need to focus on enhancing the resilience and the adaptability of the system. Changes in transport and land use development patterns and policies and in the broader context in

Evolutionary urban transportation planning?

281

the post-war period in the Amsterdam region are analysed in order to illustrate the two core hypotheses. In the conclusions more general implications are drawn.

2.

AN EVOLUTIONARY APPROACH

Evolutionary thinking originated in the natural sciences but is increasingly being applied in the social sciences and most explicitly in economics (Nelson and Winter, 1982; Dosi and Nelson, 1994; van den Bergh and Fetchenhauer, 2001; Boschma et al., 2002). Intriguing parallels can also be found in works adopting theories and methods of the emerging science of complexity and particularly the concept of self-organization most notably including applications to the analysis of cities (Allen, 1997; Portugali, 1999; Batten, 2001; but see also the earlier work by Jacobs, 1961). Characteristically of all these streams of work, the assumption of (a single) equilibrium as the natural state of the system is questioned, and attention is rather directed to far-from-equilibrium processes of change. It is acknowledged that dierent social actors can react dierently to similar system-wide perturbations, depending on both the specicities of the local context and their personal features. Individual decisions and actions eventually cumulate into development processes that are both path dependent as earlier experiences largely determine the response to new stimuli and unpredictable as even small, local dierences can have (due to self-reinforcing mechanisms) big, global consequences. Underlying this thinking is the recognition that social systems are complex systems, that is, that they are systems characterized by a high degree of interdependency between a wide range of components and processes. Such complexity fundamentally bounds the rationality of social actors. A focus on evolutionary economics can help further develop the argument. While there are dierent interpretations within the eld, some basic principles are aptly captured by the notion of microevolution introduced by Nelson and Winter (1982). According to Nelson and Winter, because of irreducible uncertainty, the existence of transaction costs and the diculty of change in the short term, rms tend to follow organizational routines, or proven ways of conducting business, rather than consider each time all possible alternative courses of action. On the other hand, the evaluation of current routines can lead rms to make adjustments and even substitution. The results of such a search process are, however, also uncertain. Furthermore, because past experiences inuence both existing routines and the search for new ones, dierent rms will

282

Planning

typically have dierent routines and try dierent alternatives, resulting in a variety of economic behaviour. Eventually, the actual performance of a rm will constitute the major incentive to maintaining or changing a routine. Such performance is largely determined by the characteristics of the selection environment, that is, the interplay of demand and supply in the marketplace. The selection environment is not a static entity either, as it will also change as a result of the accumulation of rm-specic processes. In this sense, there is co-evolution between the market and individual rms. The resulting economic reality is one characterized by continuous successions of disturbances and adaptations, which preclude the attainment of a stable equilibrium. Continuous change means that initially successful routines can become less ecient or eective, or even have unexpected consequences. There is no once-and-for-all optimal routine. Furthermore, the nature of the process underlies the incremental nature of change, and the diculty of more than marginally altering an existing routine. The risk that rms be locked in in a non-optimal routine is therefore always present. The implication is that beyond a certain threshold, marginal change will not suce and coordinated change will be required. However, because it is uncertain which routine will be able to break the impasse, diversity of and competition among alternatives should be stimulated. It is precisely such redundancy of routines that makes the economic system resilient, that is, capable of continuous performance in the face of changing, uncertain circumstances. The above conceptualization of economic reality can also be usefully applied to the object of this chapter. Existing transport and land use policies can be seen as organizational routines. The broader, changing urban socio-demographic and economic context can be seen as the selection environment in which existing policies must continuously prove their worth and the search process for better policies takes place. As also policies, in their turn, aect the selection environment, there is co-evolution between environment and policies. The analogy further suggests that there is no universally valid, optimal policy. Accordingly, while learning from practical experience elsewhere and from theoretical models is important, the value of a solution can only be appreciated in a specic, continuously evolving situation. Understanding the unique set of opportunities and constraints determined by a given historical development path and local conguration of factors is thus crucial. However, because of limits to predictability, only real-life policy experiments (Szejnwald Brown et al., 2004), that is, actual engagement with the selection environment, can give full understanding of these. At the same time, recognition of the unpredictability of the outcome particularly when the long

Evolutionary urban transportation planning?

283

term is concerned should also result in recognition of the need to look for ways of improving the ability of the system to react and perform in the face of unforeseen (and unforeseeable) change. More specically, an urban transport and land use system capable of performing in the face of unpredictable change would be, in the rst place, one capable of continuing to function in the face of change, that is, it must be a resilient system. This seems particularly important for system components that cannot change rapidly, or easily (such as a transportation network morphology). Second, it would be a system capable of changing itself in response to change in the socio-economic environment, that is, it must also be an adaptable system. This would especially apply to system components that, given their nature, can change relatively swiftly (think of a road-pricing regime). As the requirements of resilience and adaptability might be contradictory, nding a workable balance between them lies at the heart of the task. Building upon this line of reasoning, two core hypotheses can be formulated with respect to the object and goals of urban transportation planning. The rst hypothesis is that the urban transport system indeed behaves in an evolutionary, complex fashion. The second, related hypothesis is that because of this, urban transportation policies also need to focus on enhancing the resilience and the adaptability of the system. Changes in the transport and land use development patterns and policies and in the economic and socio-demographic context in the Amsterdam region in the post-war period are analysed in the following sections to illustrate the two core hypotheses. The goal of this exercise is not so much that of providing an interpretation, let alone a conclusive one, of these events, but rather that of exploring to which degree they can be characterized as evolutionary and complex. For this purpose, the two core hypotheses are further articulated in the following sub-hypotheses: 1. The behaviour of the urban transport system can be characterized as evolutionary and complex because: the system alternates periods of incremental, quantitative change and periods of radical, qualitative change, or system transition phases; in all periods, change in the system is path dependent, that is, existing patterns of transportation networks, land uses and transport and land use policies limit the scope for change; however, during transition phases both the scope for policies to inuence the outcome and the unpredictability of such an outcome are greatest. Because of path dependency, policies need to:

2.

284

Planning

3.

build upon the unique set of opportunities and constraints for change determined by a specic historical development path and local combination of factors. Because of unpredictability, policies need to: increase the resilience of the system, that is, its ability to keep functioning in the face of unexpected change. This seems especially important for the shape of transportation networks, as this is relatively dicult/slow to change; increase the adaptability of the system, that is, its ability to react to unexpected change. This seems especially important for land use regulations and mobility management measures, as these are relatively easy/fast to change.

Developments in the Amsterdam region are summarized in Table 13.1, Boxes 13.1 and 13.2 and Figure 13.1. In the following section, they will be used to illustrate the two sets of hypotheses.

3.

ILLUSTRATING THE HYPOTHESES

The Nature of Change Behaviour of the urban transport system in the Amsterdam case can be characterized as evolutionary and complex because: The system alternates periods of incremental, quantitative change and periods of radical, qualitative change, or system transition phases. The alternating of periods of (more predictable) quantitative change and periods of (less predictable) qualitative change, or transition phases can be observed in all the domains of change described in Table 13.1. This pattern of development is best shown by the existence of trend-breaking points. Trend-breaking points are dened here as changes in the nature of development rather than in the amount of development (for instance a shift from an industry- to a service-based economy as opposed to a change in the rate of growth of an economy). For clarity, in the following transitions the dierent streams of change will be discussed sequentially. This should not conceal the fact that they are in reality strongly interrelated. Some feel for these interdependencies can be obtained from Boxes 13.1 and 13.2, where two major transport and land use policy transitions are discussed in some detail.

Table 13.1
Land use policy 1935: Amsterdam general expansion plan (AUP); concentrated, starlike urban expansion as alternative to suburbanization Limited central business district (CBD) forming in the city centre; extensive public housing developments in the rest of the city; train/tram supported suburbanization elsewhere in the region Land use Transport policy Transport 1876: AmsterdamNorth Sea Canal opens (shifting the focus of harbour activity from east to west) 1889: Central Station opens (separating harbour from city) 1917: Schiphol opens as military airport

Overview of dierent domains of change in the Amsterdam urban region, 194619991

Period

Socio-demographic

Economic

Pre1946

Relative economic stagnation

285
National 1958: national report introduces Randstad (rim city) and Groene Hart (green heart) concepts, In the city centre: CBD forming and slum clearance In the periphery: new residential

1946 58

Amsterdam from 770,000 to 870,000 inhabitants (postwar maximum)

1901: rst plan for a freight railway ring around Amsterdam 1935: (AUP) cyclable distance from the city centre denes the outer limit of urban expansion, provincial roads and tram lines connect city and surroundings, accessibility of the harbour is a central concern, land reservations for future tangential roads, canals and freight railways are constructed 1955: (rst city centre report) the study of an underground railway system is proposed, discussions and

Infrastructure 1958: Schiphol becomes the national airport

Table 13.1
Land use policy which are to guide land use planning in the west of the Netherlands for the rest of the century neighbourhoods (west); expansion of industrial and harbour sites alternative plans follow Land use Transport policy Transport Mobility Growth of commuting towards Amsterdam and other regional centres

(continued)

Period

Socio-demographic

Economic

Demographic trends: rst positive, later negative migration balance (towards suburbs and abroad)

286
In the city centre: rst urban renewal and later neighbourhood regeneration In the periphery: new residential National In the second half of the 1960s and up to the end of the 1970s concentrated decentralization policy growth centres at around 30

Local 1955: rst city centre report, envisaging its radical transformation (will not be adopted) 195865: plans for peripheral residential expansions

1959 84

Amsterdam from 870,000 to 675,000 inhabitants (postwar minimum)

Demographic trends: negative national

General trends: sustained growth of the economy until the early 1970s; long period of decline following the rst oil crisis (1973) and

National 1966: national motorway plan (in the region often following existing historical routes, such as the A2 towards Utrecht, but

Modal split region (home to work) 1947: Public transport 75% Car 5% Bike 20% 1960: Public transport 67% Car 16% Bike 18% Infrastructure Expansion of the motorway network, little investment in the railways, plans for new canals are abandoned 196691: realization

continuing into the 1980s

Spatial trends: rms move to the urban periphery and the suburban centres, in search of cheap space and/or labour; the harbour declines and the airport grows strongly In the suburbs: development of growth centres (Purmerend, Almere, Hoofddorp)

km from the major cities From the beginning of the 1980s compact city policy densication of existing centres and suburban growth close (at 1530 km) to the major cities

neighbourhoods; further expansion of industrial and harbour sites; increasingly also oce developments

also including new tangents, such as the A10 motorway ring)

287

migration balance, positive international migration balance National migration: traditional households (families) to the suburbs, smaller households to the city International migration: Turks and Moroccan guest workers in the 1960s, bringing over their families in the 1970s; growing share from Dutch Antilles and Suriname (following independence in 1975) Mobility Longer and more car-based trips; congestion especially in the centre Growth of commuting towards Amsterdam and, more notably, other regional centres

of the motorway ring A10, largely using existing rights of way 1960s: runway expansion of Schiphol airport 1972: AmsterdamNorth Sea canal broadened and deepened 197897: Schiphol railway connections open 197782: east line underground railway opens

Cultural trends: emergence of mass consumption, new lifestyles, emancipation of women, youth culture

Local Urban renewal debates See Box 13.1: The late 1960s and early 1970s: a transport and land use policy transition dissected 197481: structure plan parts A, B and C; shift of focus from urban design to planning process, preservation of the residential function in old neighbourhoods, identication of sub-centres on the urban fringe, studies

Local Underground railway debates See Box 13.1: The late 1960s and early 1970s: a transport and land use policy transition dissected 1975/1976/1978: rst trac circulation plan; a balance between accessibility and liveability is needed, the means are public transport (most notably the tram), a limited, coarse primary road network, a restrictive parking policy in the city centre, and new cycle routes 1982: draft transport structure plan; the focus is on improving the existing situation

Table 13.1
Land use policy for a residential conversion of the eastern harbour and on an incremental approach Land use Transport policy Transport Modal split region (home to work) 1960: Public transport 67% Car 16% Bike 18% 1971: Public transport 41% Car 46% Bike 13%

(continued)

Period

Socio-demographic

Economic

288
In the city centre: new housing and cultural and leisure facilities National Since 1988: urban nodes policy; development to be concentrated in the major cities Since 1991: VINEX neighbourhoods policy; residential expansion to be In the periphery: new residential neighbourhoods; residential National 1988: Second transport structure plan; double goal of improving both accessibility and liveability, to be achieved by reducing mobility by car, through a mix of

1985 99

Amsterdam from 675,000 to 725,000 inhabitants

Demographic trends: less suburbanization, more births, more immigrants than in the

General trends: structural change and strong recovery of the economy since the second half of the 1980s and in the 1990s; growth concentrated in business services,

Bike share in the city (all trips) 1950: ca. 80% 1975: ca. 25% Infrastructure 197897: Schiphol railway connections open 198788: Almere and Flevoland railway connections open 1990: Amstelveen surface light rail line

preceding period

logistics, ICT and new media, leisure and tourism

realized within or adjacent to the existing city

conversion of older harbour sites (east); further expansion of younger industrial and harbour sites (west, southeast)

pricing and location policies, and selective infrastructure improvements

opens 1991: Zeeburgertunnel opens (completion of the motorway ring A10) 1997: surface metro ring line opens 1997: Piet Heintunnel opens (road link connecting reconverted eastern docklands to motorway ring) Modal split region (home to work) 1971: Public transport 41% Car 46% Bike 13% 1991: Public transport 22% Car 60% Bike 18%

289

Cultural trends: growing appreciation of urban living; older urban neighbourhoods increasingly popular; continuous growth of ethnic minorities (up to 36% in 1999); emergence of ethnic neighbourhoods in the periphery Local 1980s: while existing plans (growth centres, new motorways and railways) are implemented in the rest of the region, Amsterdam adopts a compact city policy 1985: structure plan The city central; compact city, high densities and functional mix, housing-led, consolidation of the historical centre 1991: structure plan Amsterdam; downsizing of the peripheral expansions; ambitious redevelopment plan Local 1985: (structure plan) the metro has become a no-no, In the suburbs: focus on expansion housing developments of the tram network, diused (but strongly enforcement, small constrained by noise improvements, boundaries around coordination and Schiphol airport and maintenance (also nature preservation because of nancial areas); oce and problems) industry 1986: following developments recurring congestion (concentrated of the Coentunnel around airport and and strong growth of motorway corridors) the airport, construction of a new City centre trends, western motorway 197599 tangent (the A5) is Inhabitants 11% decided Dwellings 39% Late 1980s: a study Jobs 24% of the Chamber of Oces 10% Commerce shows the Restaurants/cafes new possibilities of

Spatial trends: continuing deconcentration but also geographical specialization of economic activity (new media, leisure and tourism in the city centre, business services and ICT in the peripheral subcentres logistics around the airport, harbour and motorways)

Table 13.1
Land use policy for the IJ banks 40% 53% Shops Land use Transport policy Transport Bike share in the city (all trips) 1975: ca. 25% 1996: ca. 35%

(continued)

Period

Socio-demographic

Economic

290

IJ-banks debates See Box 13.2: The late 1980s and early 1990s: a land use policy transition dissected 1996: structure plan Open city; denitive abandonment of plans for western expansions, focus on the green structure, the South Axis will become the main business centre, the IJ banks will develop a liveworkleisure mix, a new subcentre in Amsterdam North is indicated

tunnelling without disruption of the existing urban fabric 1991: (structure plan) several new infrastructure developments are envisaged, including the new western motorway tangent and railway freight line, a new north south metro line, a light rail ring line, and a light rail line to connect the reconverted eastern dockland area 1993: regional transport plan (RVVP); the goal is to improve accessibility while preserving liveability, the most important means are reduction

of the growth in car-kilometres and a modal shift to public transport and bike

291

Note: 1. The two demographic trend-breaking points of 1959 (from population growth to population decline in Amsterdam) and 1985 (from decline to growth) are used to distinguish three main phases. This is done for convenience and does not imply that these are also relevant dates for other streams of change, including more qualitative aspects of demographic development.

Sources: Honig (1996); Rommerts (1997); Bruhze and Veraart (1999); Dijkstra et al. (1999); Regionaal Orgaan Amsterdam (2000, 2004); Wintershoven (2000); Brand (2002); le Clercq (2002); Dienst Ruimtelijke Ordening Amsterdam (2003a, 2003b); Poelstra (2003); Terhorst and van de Ven (2003); Centraal Bureau voor de Statistiek (www.cbs.nl).

292

Planning

BOX 13.1

THE LATE 1960s AND EARLY 1970s: A TRANSPORT AND LAND USE POLICY TRANSITION DISSECTED

The 1960s are the theatre of an extensive production of far-reaching urban renewal and infrastructure plans for Amsterdams historic city, following a rst city centre report in 1955. The underlying philosophy seems straightforward: population growth is to be accommodated in new expansions on the urban periphery and in growth centres in the region (in line with national policy), service growth is to be concentrated in an enlarged and restructured city centre, and a new underground urban railway network is to be developed to link the new concentrations of population, jobs and services. The new transportation system is seen as a tool to reinforce the position of the city centre in the region, and as a way to ght mounting congestion there (by both providing an alternative to the car and giving the car more space above ground). From 1963 to 1966 an urban railway ofce is installed to work out the plans. Conclusion of the study is to start with the construction of an eastern line connecting the central railway station to urban renewal areas in the centre and the newly planned southeastern urban expansion and to follow later with a northsouth line. However, and signalling expert disagreement, an alternative, incremental plan is also developed, envisaging a rst phase with a northsouth line only and expansion of the bus and tram network as a substitute at least for the time being for an extensive underground railway network. Other plans follow, including in 1967 one by the American professor D.A. Jokinen who proposes a system of radial urban motorways to connect a drastically restructured city centre. This plan in particular has a shock effect on a public opinion increasingly concerned with the fate of the historic city. In 1968, however, conicting plans and ongoing discussions notwithstanding, the city council decides in principle to build the underground railway. The decade of urban renewal debates also seems to reach its resolution point with the publication in 1969 of rigorous plans envisaging the demolition of as many as 75 000 dwellings in the historic city. While there is still enough consensus on the policy course within the city council, the railway and urban renewal proposals meet unexpected, strenuous resistance from the public. Leading the contestation is an unorthodox coalition of local inhabitants fearing displacement and emerging urban youth movements wanting to

Evolutionary urban transportation planning?

293

afrm their alternative visions of urban life. The planning machinery seems, however, unstoppable. In 1970 an agreement is reached with the national state on nancing the eastern line and in the same year the city council decides to start its construction as well as preparations for a northsouth line. Shortly thereafter disapproval starts. The contestation, however, explodes and people take to the streets, seamlessly merging with protest against urban renewal. Popular pressure mounts to the point where the city council has to reverse its decisions. The rst change is regarding land use. In 1972 the council decides to build houses instead of a throughway on top of the inner-city section of the underground railway tunnel. Amendments to transport follow: in 1974 the council decides to complete the eastern line but to halt indenitely further implementation of the rest of the plan. The decision does not immediately calm the situation, and in 1975 there are violent riots against the underground railway. The rst stretch of the eastern line opens in 1977, but a year later the policy change of course is made ofcial. With regard to land use, a local government report sanctions the shift by trading urban renewal with building for the neighbourhood, that is, incremental, housing-led adaptation of the historic city, without displacement of the existing inhabitants. A trafc circulation plan performs the same function for transport, by stressing the need to strike a balance between accessibility and liveability, and to do this by means of improvement of the existing tram system, development of a coarse primary road network, a restrictive parking policy in the city centre, and new cycle routes. The contrast between the vision of the city and its transport system before and after these turbulent years can still be appreciated at a glance in the Mr. Visser plein, where the underground railway eastern line enters the medieval city centre. Looking towards the periphery of the city one sees a large trafc thoroughfare anked by modern, tall ofce buildings. Looking towards the centre one sees a much smaller street with plenty of space for bicycles and pedestrians and a mix of preserved and new residential buildings, with mostly small-scale retail on the ground oor. In between the two is the mouth of a never completed road tunnel, since converted into an indoor playground. In the Nieuwmarkt underground railway station, pictures of the 1975 riots remind us how this all came about.
Sources: Honig, 1996; Dijkstra et al., 1999; le Clercq, 2002; Dienst Ruimtelijke Ordening Amsterdam, 2003a; Poelstra, 2003.

294

Planning

BOX 13.2

THE LATE 1980s AND EARLY 1990s: A LAND USE POLICY TRANSITION DISSECTED

In the late 1980s, while the municipality is struggling to attract ofce developments to the IJ banks area next to Amsterdam Central Station, an intense, spontaneous market dynamics is taking place at peripheral locations along the southern and western motorway rings (see Figure 13.1, below). The traditional orientation of the city on its port on the north side, which the IJ banks project tries to continue, is thus being subverted by an orientation of new developments towards the south side, better connected with the airport and the rest of the Randstad. In 1988 an exhibition and publication (ARCAM, 1988) rst gives a synthetic, and to many shocking, impression of the new spatial reality taking shape. Putting together information on plans and projects until then available to the general public only in piecemeal form, the independent ARCAM foundation shows how peripheral developments are turning Amsterdam inside out. The answer of the municipality to this evidence remains ambiguous. The ofcial policy is that IJ banks is the most important location to develop, in order to reinforce the economic base of the city centre, and that developments along the motorway ring are not to be allowed. But the possibility that rms leave or bypass the city which desperately needs both the jobs and the land rents they carry with them altogether is too great a risk to adopt a hard stance.Thus, one after the other, exceptions to the policy are made to allow companies to remain or locate at least within the city boundaries. Nothing more, though: in 1993, an ofcer of the municipality still declares: An integral vision [for peripheral developments] has no priority. Sometimes you just have to allow something in order to avoid rms escaping to competing locations (Van Nierop, 1993, p. 95). However, this approach is meeting with growing criticism. Market actors lament that an urban design framework and coordination of development would boost property demand and values in the southern urban fringe. Also, concerned local district authorities (these are the lower-level municipal governments installed in 1990) protest that transformations are occurring without reference to one another or to the context, making local impacts difcult to identify and to manage. Quite strikingly, the big transport infrastructure

Evolutionary urban transportation planning?

295

providers and operators the department of public works, the national railway company (NS) and the local transport company (GVB) are not participating in the debate at this point. However, ambitious interventions and plans that will boost the accessibility of the southern urban fringe are in train, quite independently from the urban development debate. These include a light rail ring line, a northsouth underground railway line, capacity and connection improvements in the national and regional railway networks, and high speed train links to France and Germany. In the early 1990s, unfolding events are making the position of the municipality increasingly difcult. While little happens at IJ banks, exceptions continue to accumulate along the ring: later on the municipality itself will estimate the amount of ofce space thus developed at around 300 000 m2! Also, the large bank concern ABN-AMRO demands the authorization to build its headquarters next to Zuid station, on the southern urban fringe, exacerbating tensions that are also maturing inside the municipality. Then comes the proverbial last straw: in February 1994, the private partner of the IJ banks initiative withdraws, because of a lack of faith in the nancial feasibility of the operation. A policy U-turn appears inevitable. In the spring of 1994, following the local elections, a programme agreement is voted by the new council, in which a new policy is indeed agreed. With regard to IJ banks, rather than an ofce concentration, a mixed livework area will be aimed at, anchored to activities in the cultural and tourist spheres, thus reinforcing the emerging character of the historic city centre. Along the Zuidas (south axis), an ofce district of international standing will be promoted, bringing together in an integrated plan developments that are at the moment occurring piecemeal. Contradicting what was afrmed only a year earlier, the city council states that: For the Zuidas, the area for large-scale ofces, an integral plan will be prepared in order to avoid the situation whereby the development continues incidentally (reported in Gemeente Amsterdam, 1996).
Sources: ARCAM (1988); Van Nierop (1993); Gemeente Amsterdam (1996); Bertolini and Spit (1998).

Socio-demographic transitions There are two trend-breaking points in the population development of Amsterdam: in 1959, when the population in the central city starts to decline in absolute terms, and in 1985, when it starts to grow again. Contributing to this are other

296

Planning

demographic trend-breaking points (Wintershoven, 2000): 1973, when the national migration balance rst starts improving; 1975, when the birth rate in the city rst starts to rise again; the 1970s, when the international migration balance becomes positive (albeit it has been strongly uctuating since then). Crucially, change is not just of a quantitative nature. In particular, the 1960s and 1970s were also a period of radical, and fairly abrupt cultural change, including farreaching phenomena such as the emergence of mass consumption, female emancipation, a youth culture and so on. While many of the new lifestyles thrived in the city, the more traditional, middle-class family households started a massive migration to the suburbs. Later on, and further enriching the picture, the 1980s and 1990s saw the emergence of a new, extensive multicultural dimension in the city fuelled by national and international migration trends, but also and perhaps more surprisingly a return to urban living by choice. Economic transitions As far as economic trends are concerned there is a rst major trend-breaking point in the 1970s, when, following global developments epitomized by the rst oil crisis of 1973, and after a long period of sustained growth, the urban, regional and national economy all fall into a decline that will last until the second half of the 1980s. Older centres in the region, such as Amsterdam and Haarlem, are the worst hit. The 1990s were, on the contrary, growth years, with the Dutch economy consistently performing above the European average and the Amsterdam economy performing above the national average. The economic upheaval of the 1990s is of a decisively qualitative nature: growth has taken place within the context of a radical shift from an industry-based, nationally coordinated economy to a service-based, rapidly globalizing economy, and has been spurred by the emergence of new leading sectors and locations as business and nancial services in the southern urban fringe, tourism, leisure and new media in the historic city centre, logistics in the airport area. The emergence of Schiphol airport as one of a few major European passenger and freight hubs is tightly linked to all this. Land use policy transitions The 1970s are also a major transition phase in land use policies. These are years of extreme policy turbulence, resulting in a radical change of course. This is particularly the case in the dominating attitude towards the historic city centre, where a shift from transformation to conservation occurs (see Box 13.1). This shift will also have a long-standing impact on land use policy elsewhere (think of the emergence and consolidation of the notion of complementary subcentres in the urban periphery, where oce

Evolutionary urban transportation planning?

297

growth banned from the historic city centre has been increasingly accommodated). A second period of land use policy instability can be observed at the beginning of the 1990s, with the failed attempt at a large-scale, CBD-like redevelopment of the IJ banks, adjoining the historic city centre (see Box 13.2). In contrast to these recurring city centre turbulences, policies concerned with expansions in Amsterdams urban periphery and in the suburbs show much less debate and a remarkable stability (essentially the acceptance of decentralization, albeit in concentrated form). Land use transitions Changes in land use policies appear to have been both a consequence and a factor of actual land use changes (see land use column in Table 13.1). In both Amsterdam and the Netherlands, land use policies in the post-war period can be seen as a reaction to wider urbanization trends rst and suburbanization trends later. On the other hand, the conservative policies for the city centre adopted at the end of the 1970s have been a factor in determining the unique land use mix that has developed there in the subsequent, partial reurbanization phase (see City centre trends, 197599 in Table 13.1). More indirectly, they have also had a role in the emergence of alternative centres in the periphery and in the suburbs, which has assumed a systematic rather than incidental character following the disappearance of expansion opportunities in the historic city centre. There are sharp discontinuities in both broader trends and local policies: the shift from urban expansion to suburbanization as the dominating force in the early post-war years, the partial counterweight provided by reurbanization trends since restructuring of the economy in the late 1980s, and the transitions in land use policy discussed in Boxes 13.1 and 13.2. Transport policy transitions The land use policy debate in the 1960s and 1970s has been mirrored by intense transport policy debate in the same period (see Box 13.1). Also in this case the focus was the historic city centre, here in the form of contestation of urban motorway and, particularly, railway plans. The resulting shift in transport policy was perhaps even more pronounced than that in land use policy, with an eective halt to both urban motorway and urban railway expansion and a shift to an approach dominated by mobility management and marginal infrastructure interventions (see the trac plans of the 1970s in Table 13.1). Only during the 1990s, and on the condition of there being no harm to the existing urban fabric will new urban infrastructure proposals be allowed to re-enter the political arena (see the local transport policies in the 198599 period in Table 13.1). Even then, the no-harm condition appears to have

298

Planning

been a main rationale determining which links were going to be given priority, at least in terms of implementation (compare the relatively short time span from plan to realization of the elevated light rail ring line that opened in 1997 with the much longer and contested planning and development process of the underground northsouth line, which is set to open in 2011). Transport transitions Finally, continuities and discontinuities also characterize actual infrastructure and mobility developments. During the whole period, and particularly since the second half of the 1960s, the motorway system has been dramatically expanded. The same can be said of the inter-regional railway network. The change was far from quantitative alone, as the superimposition of motorway and railway tangents on the existing radial systems profoundly aected the relative accessibility of locations in the region. These developments, illustrated in Figure 13.1, have had profound, largely unanticipated impacts on mobility and activity patterns in the region. The implications of the new structure (the emergence of a new, polycentric and unstable set of activity centres and mobility ows) seem to have been fully appreciated only in the 1990s, when perception of the need to address issues at the urban regional scale has become ubiquitous.

As far as mobility is concerned the main radical change in the period under examination is the advent of mass motorization. Even in this case, policy makers were at rst caught o guard, if not by the phenomenon in itself, certainly by its pervasiveness. However, the reaction as matured through the transport policy transition phase mentioned above and discussed in Box 13.1 produced, at least within the historic city centre, a set of measures that have long been able to manage mobility (see the local transport plans of the 1970s and 1980s in Table 13.1). The impact of this policy shift on actual behaviour is perhaps best epitomized by the reversal in the decline in bike use since the 1970s (see trends in Bike share in the city in Table 13.1), which has fundamentally contributed to give Amsterdam an exceptional share of non-motorized trac (at 51 per cent of all trips in 1995 it is by far the highest in the industrialized world in a large sample of cities analysed by Kenworthy and Laube, 2005). Change in the system is path dependent, that is, existing patterns of transportation networks, land uses and transport and land use policies limit the scope for change. The issue of path dependency is a wide-ranging one, cutting across multiple aspects and dierent layers of economic, social and cultural trends. There is

Evolutionary urban transportation planning?

299

Built-up area Railways Motorways Purmerend Centre Zaandam

1967

Amsterdam

Haarlem Schiphol Airport Haarlemmermeer N 5 km Amstelveen

Built-up area, 1967 Built-up area, 19672001 Railways, 1967 Purmerend Railways, 19672001 Motorways, 1967 Motorways, 19672001 Amsterdam Centre, 1967 Centre, 19672001 Haarlem Schiphol Airport Haarlemmermeer N 5 km Amstelveen Zaandam

2001

Almere

Source:

Adapted from Jansen (2003).

Figure 13.1 Changes in the built-up area and infrastructure in the Amsterdam region, 19672001

300

Planning

path dependency in facts, but also in ideas, and the two are intertwined. Adequate treatment would require much more than a couple of paragraphs. Its consideration in this chapter will have to be limited and will only refer to land use and transport morphological aspects. The existence of opportunities for and constraints to policy change determined by the existing urban and network morphology is seen here as evidence of path dependency. The pre-existing shape of land uses and transport infrastructure has conditioned subsequent developments in the Amsterdam region in many ways. The pre-war modernization of the Amsterdam city centre was comparatively late and limited in nature. This can be related to the comparatively late and limited industrialization of the Netherlands, but also to the sheer size of the city centre itself, in its turn a legacy of the global role of Amsterdam in the seventeenth century (Terhorst and van de Ven, 2003). The existence of such a large, preserved city centre was a factor that rst hampered large-scale urban renewal and later favoured the policy shift from transformation to conservation as described in Box 13.1. While there have since been attempts to somewhat turn away from this decision (see Box 13.2), the halt to large-scale, downtown-like restructuring of the city centre has up to now proved irreversible, even if reasons have shifted (rst largely because of social resistance, and later largely because of market preferences: compare Boxes 13.1 and 13.2). With regard to infrastructure, there is also a long line connecting the radial road and railway structure in place before the war, infrastructure plans and land reservations dating from as early as the rst half of the twentieth century, and actual transport and land use developments in the period under discussion. Just focusing on the road and rail tangents that have proved so crucial for successive developments, the most important decisions and actions contributing to the nal result include: land reservations for a railway freight line around the city made at the beginning of the twentieth century; land reservations for local roads made in the 1932 Amsterdam general expansion plan; the opening starting in the 1970s and proting from those rights of way of railway links to connect the airport of Schiphol to the rest of the country (a national government-led process); the realization since the 1970s of a motorway ring as part of the national motorway plan of 1966 partly using the reservations for the freight line and partly those for the local roads; and the realization in the 1990s of a light rail line following the route of the airport railway links. The transport systems that were eventually put in place are of a totally dierent nature from anything even thinkable prior to the war (not roads but motorways, not freight but passenger rail). Analogously, the national motorway and railway planners of the 1960s and 1970s were not anticipat-

Evolutionary urban transportation planning?

301

ing (if at all concerned with) signicant impacts on the urban form. However, previous decisions largely determined where new infrastructure developments, and thus indirectly also land use developments, were to occur. The unique network morphology that eventually emerged, with a combination of radial and tangential connections, both road and rail, intersecting well inside the existing urban fabric, and since providing the infrastructure backbone to urban and regional development (see Figure 13.1), would never have emerged in this form without such early land reservations and national infrastructure plans. During transition phases both the scope for policies to inuence the outcome and the unpredictability of such an outcome are greatest. Proof for the rst part of this hypothesis (scope) is the occurrence of qualitative (rather than quantitative) change consistent with policy goals. Evidence for the second part (unpredictability) is the concomitant occurrence of qualitative change that was not aimed at. Let us focus on the main policy transition phase, the late 1960s and early 1970s (see Box 13.1). This was a unique period because instability in dierent domains connected (think of the central role of the emerging youth culture in the contestation of urban renewal plans), resulting in radical policy change. It can be argued (even if it should be tested in more detail) that it is precisely because of this diused turbulence that such radical, deliberate change was possible. In other periods policy seems rather a reaction to broader, stable (and thus dicult to reverse) trends, having at best the eect of marginally conditioning the outcome (as with the relative concentration of suburbanization). On the contrary, qualitative policy change in the 1970s resulted in qualitative actual change, as documented above. The nal outcome, however, was largely unpredicted. The conservative land use and transport policies in the city centre not only helped to preserve, as desired and expected, its residential function. They were also, unexpectedly and unwillingly, a factor in its later gentrication and the development of a burgeoning tourist and leisure industry there (Terhorst and van de Ven, 2003). Furthermore, constraints on city centre development indirectly helped shift the focus of economic activity in the region towards the emerging centres in the periphery and the suburbs, not an entirely unforeseen but certainly at the time not even a deliberate policy goal. As far as mobility is concerned, while the outcome of the policy turn in the 1970s within the city (fewer cars, more bikes, and a more liveable public space) was by and large an explicit goal, the related development of a diused, multi-centred urban region where the car dominates and adequate public transport is lagging behind was not.

302

Planning

Policy Implications While still exploratory and necessarily limited in scope, the analysis above does provide some evidence that the Amsterdam land use and transport system has changed in an evolutionary, complex fashion, in the sense dened by the rst set of hypotheses. Periods of incremental change have been followed by periods of radical change, path dependency has played a decisive (in this chapter only supercially explored) role, and transition phases have been characterized by both possibilities to aect the outcome and inability to predict it. Let us now move to the second set of hypotheses. These posit that because the systems behaved in an evolutionary, complex fashion, successful policies needed to: Build upon the unique set of opportunities and constraints for change determined by a specic historical development path and local combination of factors. The fact that successful policies (that is, policies that have achieved their declared goals) have such characteristics is seen as verication of this hypothesis. Successful policies in Amsterdam in the period under examination have explicitly or implicitly recognized the specicity of the city, that is, the existence of path dependency. This seems true in phases of both incremental and radical change. Again, the discussion will be limited here to the morphological aspects. The repeated failure of attempts at radical transformation of Amsterdam city centre and the success of more conservative land use and transport policies there are the clearest example (see Boxes 13.1 and 13.2). It is also important, however, to underline here that the acknowledgement of path dependency by no means implies that radical change is by denition impossible, or should not be striven for. The urban and regional structure that has ultimately emerged in Amsterdam is profoundly dierent from the pre-existing one (see Figure 13.1). In the case of the conservative policies for the city centre, Terhorst and van de Ven (2003) even contend that it is has been precisely this freezing of the built environment there that, by limiting the scope for large-scale, coordinated transformation, has paradoxically given the market unprecedented freedom to re-shape land uses on the micro level, in often surprising ways. The system-wide eects of the implementation of relatively undisruptive, but still very far-reaching infrastructure developments as the expansion of the motorway system and inter-regional railway links on the urban fringe and in the region are another case in point.

Evolutionary urban transportation planning?

303

In both examples above the actual impacts and particularly the emergence of a strongly polycentric urban system diered greatly from anything most were able to imagine at the time. Actually applying policies (that is, experimenting) seems to have been necessary to realize the full implications. The crucial question for change-minded policy makers seems then to be the following. How to identify interventions that are able to disrupt the present functioning of the system as little as possible while aecting its future development as much as possible? At the same time, the limits to the predictability of the outcome should also make us aware of the need to increase the resilience and adaptability of the system, which leads us to the next two hypotheses. Increase the resilience of the system, that is, its ability to keep functioning in the face of unexpected change. This seems especially important for the shape of transportation networks, as this is relatively dicult/slow to change. The fact that successful policies were policies that have proved eective in qualitatively dierent contexts (that is, both before and after trend-breaking points) is seen as evidence for this hypothesis. There are several examples of resilient interventions in the Amsterdam case. It is especially the shape of the infrastructure networks (not their function!) that seems to have had this characteristic. The combination of motorway and railway radials and tangents has proved able to support a wide variety of developments across the whole period, including shifting foci of economic and social activity, dierent transport technologies, and the two major policy transitions described in Boxes 13.1 and 13.2. The necessity of robust choices with respect to network morphology seems all the more crucial as the Amsterdam case also shows how alterations in its basic shape are extremely dicult to implement (think of the failed attempts at infrastructure penetration into the historic city centre, and conversely of the positive role of long-standing land reservations in its expansion). An intriguing policy question follows. Is it possible to identify in advance such resilient interventions, and if so how? I shall get back on this in the conclusions. Increase the adaptability of the system, that is, its ability to react to unexpected change. This seems especially important for land use regulations and mobility management measures, as these are relatively easy/fast to change. The fact that, in order to be eective, policies that were not resilient in the sense discussed in the previous section needed to be adapted, is seen as

304

Planning

proof for this hypothesis. The Amsterdam case also shows several examples of policy adaptation, particularly as far as land use policy and the mobility management side of transport policy are concerned. The most poignant example seems, once again, the radical change of course of transport and land use policies in the 1970s (see Box 13.1). Such adaptation has been an essential condition for the development of the new, quite successful policy mix that at least as far as the historic city is concerned has shown to be viable up to the present day (whether this will also hold for the future is, of course, a dierent matter). Policy change proved, however, all but a natural process. A decade of intense conict including violent riots and a policy trauma that is still felt in the city was needed to achieve it. In many ways, the existing plans and planning institutions appear to have been, at least initially, hampering rather than promoting adaptation. A somewhat dierent picture is oered by the land use policy transition of the early 1990s (see Box 13.2). Here, also, the capability to adapt has been an essential condition for the development of what most now see as a much more eective strategy for dealing with the reality of a multi-modal, multi-centred urban region. However, in contrast to the 1970s, the transition seems to have occurred in a much less traumatic manner (perhaps a sign that the planning system has become more adaptable?). The policy question is thus whether and how such policy transitions could be made easier, or how the adaptability of policies could be increased. In other words: how can policies be made more responsive to (unexpected) reactions from the society at large? But also: how can this be done without reducing too much the just as necessary stability of the policy context, that is, its resilience? This issue will also be addressed in the conclusions.

4.

DISCUSSION AND CONCLUSIONS

The central contention of this chapter is that an urban transport and land use system capable of supporting economic and socio-demographic change is also one capable of continuing to function in the face of change, that is, it must be a resilient system. Second, an urban transport and land use system capable of supporting economic and social change must be able to change itself in response to change in the socio-economic environment, that is, it must also be an adaptable system. The Amsterdam case shows both the workings of resilience and adaptability, and specic ways (that is, ways that take account of path dependency) of achieving them. The resilience of the system is perhaps best shown by a transport network morphology (the combination of radial and tangential links, both road and rail) that has provided a relatively stable base for the radical shift from a

Evolutionary urban transportation planning?

305

monocentric to a polycentric urban structure. The adaptability of the system is perhaps best shown by the (ultimately) successful re-shaping of the policy course, particularly in terms of land use and mobility management, in response to systemic crises. There is a link between the two. The resilience of the transport network morphology has been a condition for the adaptability of land use and mobility management strategies, because at all times it has allowed a choice between dierent land use and mobility management strategies. However, the Amsterdam case also shows the limits of a purely rational approach (in the sense of rational choice, as in Simon, 1957, 1969; March and Simon, 1958) to achieving resilience and adaptability. The present network morphology is the result of a very long chain of decisions and actions, often unconsciously or unwillingly contributing to the nal result. The land use and mobility management policy mix also emerged after a protracted period of conicts and contradictions, and many eects were not anticipated. These limits to predictability are by no means specic of the Amsterdam context. In Britain for instance, the expectation that, following the development of new radial and tangential roads, growth would still take place in the city centre was long undisputed, while no model had anticipated inner-city decline or massive decentralization (Banister, 2002). In terms of decision making, the approach emerging from the Amsterdam case seems to contain elements of both the incremental model (Lindblom, 1959, 1968; Braybrooke and Lindblom, 1970) and the rational model (Simon, 1957, 1969; March and Simon, 1958). It is incremental in that it points to the role of the existing, historically grown situation in shaping the discussion around problems and solutions. It is rational in its attempts at drawing implications from the awareness of the long-term implications of decisions, particularly as they might aect the very scope for choice at a later stage. This characterization by no means implies that such a decision-making model was deliberately pursued in Amsterdam. Rather, it emerged through an often-painful process of trial and error. The interesting question is, of course, what more conscious eorts in this direction would deliver, in Amsterdam and elsewhere. This preliminary, exploratory analysis points to both research and policy challenges. As far as research is concerned, there is a need to gain both greater depth and greater breadth. Greater depth is most notably needed in order to more fully capture the dynamics of transition phases. In particular, the complex interplay of path dependency (of both facts and ideas) and unpredictability, and of possibilities of and limits to inuencing the outcome need to be understood better. Most notably, greater breadth is needed in order to test the applicability to other geographical contexts of the proposed characterization of developments and of ways of achieving

306

Planning

resilience and adaptability. As far as policy is concerned, the practical implications of an urban transportation planning also geared at increasing resilience and adaptability of the system should be further elaborated upon. In addition, the complementarities with other, forecasting-based approaches should be explored. What sort of urban transportation planning would this lead to? A reference to Christensens (1985; see also Giord, 2003) classic characterization of uncertainty in planning can help make a rst step. According to Christensen (Figure 13.2a) planning problems and approaches can be characterized in terms of the uncertainty about goals and the means to achieve them (or technology). The term technology is used here in the broad sense of means to achieve goals. In this respect a transportation system is a technology, but also a parking regime, or a marketing campaign. Furthermore, the term is inclusive of the economic, social and cultural institutions that identify the context in which a technology is developed and applied. Dierent sorts of uncertainty require dierent planning approaches. When goals are not agreed and the technology is unknown there is chaos. In Christensens interpretation these are untreatable planning issues, and uncertainty needs somehow to be reduced in order to proceed. When feasible, this should certainly be the preferred option. However, in many (even if by no means all) situations uncertainty seems not reducible. What to do then? Abstracting from the discussion of the Amsterdam case, Figure 13.2b sketches a possible approach. The starting point is the observation that even when goals are not agreed a distinction can be made between goals that are independent of the future technological context (as promoting the growth of the urban economy) and goals that are not (as promoting the growth of a specic economic sector in a specic location). Analogously, even when the technology is unknown a distinction can be made between a technology that only has the potential to serve limited goals (as a transportation system connecting a limited number of places in a limited number of ways) and a technology that has the potential to serve more goals (such as a transportation system connecting more places in more ways). When goals are both not agreed and dependent on a specic future technological context and technologies are both unknown and can only serve limited goals, options should be kept open, thus preserving the adaptability of the system. On the contrary, not agreed goals that are independent of the technological context and unknown technologies that can serve many goals are, at least potentially, robust goals and technologies and should, with reference to Christensens characterization, be bargained over and/or experimented with. Because of the limits to predictability, only actual bargaining and experimentation or policy experiments will tell how true this potential is. If this does prove to be the case, policies should be brought further

Evolutionary urban transportation planning?

307

Goal Agreed known 1. Programming Not agreed 2. Bargaining

Technology

3. Experimentation unknown

4. Chaos

Source: Christensen (1985).

Figure 13.2a

Coping with uncertainty in planning Not agreed goal Independent of the technological context Dependent on the technological context Robust technology, redefine goal Experiment bargain

Unknown technology

Can serve single goals

Can serve multiple goals

Robust goal, redfine technology

Keep options open

Source: Authors own work.

Figure 13.2b

Coping with irreducible uncertainty in planning (or chaos)

308

Planning

towards implementation, as they are likely to improve the resilience of the system. If not, the need to keep options open will be reintroduced. It is through such a recursive, exploratory process that the system can gain both resilience (by means of robust measures) and adaptability (by means of keeping options open). There is, however, a caveat. The above suggests that in cases of irreducible uncertainty and insucient robustness, options should always be left open. However, it is easy to think of situations where action might still be desirable (think of the development of an innovative transportation system with highly uncertain, but potentially highly rewarding impacts). The approach sketched above could still be useful. First, it will point to the need to keep exploring ways of increasing the resilience and adaptability of the action (perhaps the innovative transportation system can be broken down into smaller components and realized in a more incremental, experimental way?). Second, when further redesign is not deemed possible, it will make explicit that decision makers are taking a risk with an unpredictable outcome. In political (rather than technical) terms this can still be acceptable (or even desirable, as taking risks has always been considered a hallmark of leadership). Even in this last case, however, allowance should be made for learning, that is, to treat implementation as much as possible as a policy experiment. Economic and socio-demographic changes shape urban transport and land uses, but the latter provide in their turn a still essential physical support to the former. In the face of rising complexity and persisting uncertainty about the future, planners should devote more energy to understanding the evolutionary, complex nature of change in urban land use and transport systems, and, accordingly, to nding ways of promoting their resilience and adaptability. This would complement other, forecasting-based approaches, and allow transport providers to develop and transport users to choose between dierent ways of moving around, both in the shorter and, most importantly, the longer term. The latter appears all the more urgent in the face of real uncertainty about the future viability of the presently dominating transport solutions and a tendency not to recognize this by those taking decisions. In this respect, the classic denition of sustainability proposed in the Bruntlandt report (World Commission on Environment and Development, 1987) still provides a poignant evaluation criterion. How does a particular transport and land use policy aect the possibility of future generations making their own mobility choices? An exploratory attitude seems essential, as the answer will be dierent in dierent contexts, and contexts will keep changing, unpredictably.

Evolutionary urban transportation planning?

309

REFERENCES
Allen, P.M. (1997), Cities and Regions as Self-Organizing Systems: Models of Complexity, Amsterdam: Gordon & Breach. ARCAM (Amsterdam Centre for Architecture) (1988), Boom Town Amsterdam, Amsterdam: ARCAM. Banister, D. (2002), Transport Planning, 2nd edn, London and New York: Spon Press. Batten, D.F. (2001), Complex landscapes of spatial interaction, Annals of Regional Science, 35(1): 81111. Bertolini, L. and T. Spit (1998), Cities on Rails, London: Spon Press. Boschma, R., K. Frenken and J.G. Lambooy (2002), Evolutionaire Economie. Een Inleiding, Bussum: Coutinho. Brand, A. (2002), Het stedelijke veld in opkomst. De transformatie van de stad in Nederland gedurende de tweede helft van de twintigste eeuw, PhD dissertation, University of Amsterdam. Braybrooke, D. and C. Lindblom (1970), A Strategy of Decision, New York: Free Press. Bruhze, A.A. de la and F. Veraart (1999), Fietsverkeer in Praktijk en Beleid in de Twintigste Eeuw, Den Haag: Ministerie van Verkeer en Waterstaat. Christensen, K.S. (1985), Coping with uncertainty in planning, APA Journal, Winter: 6373. Dienst Ruimtelijke Ordening Amsterdam (2003a), Stadsplan Amsterdam. Toekomstvisies op de ruimtelijke ontwikkeling van de stad. 19282003, Rotterdam: Nai Uitgevers. Dienst Ruimtelijke Ordening Amsterdam (2003b), Structuurplan Amsterdam. Kiezen voor stedelijkheid, Amsterdam: Dienst Ruimtelijke Ordening Amsterdam. Dijkstra, C., M. Retisma and A. Rommerts (1999), Atlas Amsterdam, Bussum: Thoth. Dimitriou, H. (1992), Urban Transport Planning: A Developmental Approach, London and New York: Routledge. Dosi, G. and R.R. Nelson (1994), An introduction to evolutionary theories in economics, Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 4: 15372. Gemeente Amsterdam (1996), De Zuidas Amsterdam, Amsterdam: Gemeente Amsterdam. Giord, J.L. (2003), Flexible Urban Transportation, Oxford: Elsevier Science. Honig, R. (1996), Railinfrastructuur in Amsterdam. Trein, metro, sneltram, in planAmsterdam, 2(9/10): 126. Jacobs, J. (1961), The Death and Life of Great American Cities, New York: Random House. Jansen, A. (2003), Co-evolutie van infrastructuur en verstedelijkingsstructuur, Masters Thesis, University of Amsterdam. Kenworthy, J. and F. Laube (2005), An international comparative perspective on sustainable transport in European cities, European Spatial Research and Policy, 12(1): 1150. le Clercq, F. (2002), Planologie en mobiliteit in Amsterdam, in H. Knippenberg and M. van Schendelen (eds), Alles heeft zijn plaats. 125 jaar Geograe en Planologie aan de Universiteit van Amsterdam, 18772002, Amsterdam: Askant, pp. 399419. Lindblom, C. (1959), The science of muddling through, Public Administration Review, 19: 7988. Lindblom, C. (1968), The Policy-Making Process, Englewood Cli, NJ: Prentice-Hall.

310

Planning

March, J. and H. Simon (1958), Organizations, New York: Wiley. Meyer, M.D. and E.J. Miller (2001), Urban Transportation Planning, 2nd edn, New York: McGraw-Hill. Nelson, R. and S. Winter (1982), Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Poelstra, H. (2003), Eerst infrastructuur, dan beleid, in Dienst Ruimtelijk Ordening, Gemeente Amsterdam (ed.), Stadsplan Amsterdam. 19282003, Rotterdam: Nai uitgevers, pp. 11829. Portugali, J. (1999), Self-Organization and the City, Berlin: Springer. Regionaal Orgaan Amsterdam (2000), Evaluatie Regionaal Verkeer en Vervoerplan, Amsterdam: Regionaal Orgaan Amsterdam. Regionaal Orgaan Amsterdam (2004), Regionaal Verkeer en Vervoerplan, Amsterdam: Regionaal Orgaan Amsterdam. Rommerts, A. (1997), De dynamische regio. De ruimtelijke opbouw van de regio Amsterdam, in planAmsterdam, 3(8/9): 133. Simon, H. (1957), A behavioral model of rational choice, in H. Simon (ed.), Models of Man, New York: Wiley, pp. 24160. Simon, H. (1969), Sciences of the Articial, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Szejnwald Brown, H., P.J. Vergragt, K. Green and L. Bechicchi (2004), Bounded socio-technical experiments (BSTEs): higher order learning for transitions towards sustainable mobility, in B. Elzen, F.W. Geels and K. Green (eds), System Innovation and the Transition to Sustainability, Cheltenham, UK and Northampton, MA, USA: Edward Elgar, pp. 191219. Terhorst, P. and J. van de Ven (2003), The economic restructuring of the historic city centre, in S. Musterd and W. Salet (eds), Amsterdam Human Capital, Amsterdam: Amsterdam University Press, pp. 85101. van der Bergh, J. and D. Fetchenhauer (2001), Voorbij het Rationele Model: Evolutionaire Verklaringen van Gedrag en Sociaal-Economische Instituties, Den Haag: NWO/MaGW Van den Heijden, K. (1996), Scenarios: The Art of Strategic Conversation, Chichester: John Wiley & Sons. Van Nierop, I. (1993), Verdichting rond Stations, Masters Thesis, University of Amsterdam. Wintershoven, L. (2000), Demograsch Eeuwboek Amsterdam. Ontwikkelingen tussen 1900 en 2000, Amsterdam: Dienst Ruimtelijke Ordening Amsterdam. World Commission on Environment and Development (1987), Our Common Future, Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Index
absorptive capacity in rms 11 and foreign spillovers 12144 and ICT adoption 2589 and innovation 11 productivity growth see productivity growth and technologies 128, 129 Accenture 52 Acorn Computers 367, 42 adaptationism in evolutionary biology 2078, 209 institutional, Cambridge 434 agents bounded rational 2, 6 co-location of 10 eciency of 205 interaction of 183, 210, 241, 249 representative 12, 5 see also networks agglomeration automobile industry 70, 868, 90 automobile industry, US 7, 8, 1415, 30, 70, 7480 creative destruction 2 extraordinary 878 and information spillovers 158 and infrastructure 1617 and innovation 70 mobile production factors 1, 2 and patents 235 and performance 70 and production costs 89 productive capacity in Europe 231 radio industry 73, 74, 77, 86 and shakeouts 889 and spin-os 30, 868 television receiver industry 70, 714, 77, 79, 856, 89 tire industry 84, 868, 90 and wealth distribution 1, 18 see also clusters agglomeration economies and automobile industry 868, 90 location choice 8, 6970, 7980, 868, 90 new rm location 8 and related industries 9 as spillover 88 spin-os 30 and television industry 74, 7980 and tire industry 84, 868 see also path dependency; spin-os Air France 51 Alchian, A. 208 Allergan 52 Amadeus 51 Amin, A. 1, 163 Amsterdam see Netherlands Andersson, C. 12 Antonelli, C. 2, 182 ARM 367, 42 Arrow, K. 93, 152, 158, 161, 163 Arthur, W.B. 2, 7, 8, 2930, 180, 210 Attaran, M. 204 Audretsch, D. 163, 258, 262 Audubon Society 99, 104, 1056 automobile industry agglomeration 70, 868, 90 and agglomeration economies 868, 90 agglomeration in US 7, 8, 1415, 30, 70, 7480 geographic structure, evolution of 7690 heterogeneity 79 incumbents as source of competence 856 knowledge diusion 8, 9, 16 knowledge, tacit 79, 80 mergers 78 networks 8 pre-entry experience 79 related industries, inuence of 88 311

312 seeding industries 767, 79 shakeouts 889 spillovers 88 spin-os 778, 79, 85, 86, 878, 90 subcontracting 78, 79, 88 technological progress 77 UK 89, 16 Aventis 52 Aydalot, P. and D. Keeble 6 Aztema, O. and J. Weltevreden 258

Index chemical engineering department 37 clustering 30, 3141 customers, international 29, 30 Defense Advanced Research Agency (DARPA) 44 Element-14 36 entrepreneurship 434 entry barriers, low 35 rm turnover 34 Greater Cambridge Partnership 44 Human Genome project 41 ICT 3541, 43 industrial ink jet printing 389 Innovation Centre 43 instrumentation sector 345 internationalisation 412 IP rights 36, 378, 39, 41, 43 Medical Research Council 41 Network Computer 36 networks 28, 39, 434 new business models 42 new entrants 32, 357, 39, 41, 42, 43 outsourcing 29, 39 scientic instrumentation 325 Small Business Innovation Research (SBIR) 44 spin-os 289 spin-outs 3541, 42 survival rates 32, 35 technical design consultancies 378, 42 technology transfer 43 university links 35, 39, 40 US investment 412, 43, 44 venture capital 412 Cambridge Antibody Technologies 3941 Cambridge Consultants Ltd (CCL) 378 Cambridge Display Technology and Plastic Logic 39 Cambridge Instruments 34 Cambridge Scientic Instruments 34 Camison, C. 161, 164, 172 Canada, ICT regional disparities 257 Canils, M. 2, 12 Cantner, U. 9, 183 Cantwell, J. and S. Iammarino 18 Capello, R. and A. Faggian 161, 164, 165, 174

Baldwin, J.R. and W.M. Brown 2034, 206, 212, 21314, 215, 218 Baptista, R. 163 Barabasi, A. and R. Albert 10, 1112, 234 Barrat, A. 12 Basu, S. and D. Weil 123 Battese, G. and T. Coelli 126, 127 Becker, M. 18 Begg, I. 203 Bell, M. 162, 175 Bertolini, Luca 279310 biotechnology research, Cambridge 7, 27, 31, 32, 33, 34, 3941 Birke, Daniel 180200 Black, D. and V. Henderson 203 Bonaccorsi, Andrea 25676 Borgatti, S. 167, 182, 240 Boschma, Ron A. 124, 30, 162, 163, 166, 203, 212, 281 Bottazzi, G. 2 Brakman, S. 1, 204 Brenner, T. 2 Breschi, S. 2, 10, 18, 28, 29, 88, 162, 182, 235, 236, 240, 241 Brundtland Report 308 Buenstorf, G. and S. Klepper 70, 80, 81, 823, 84, 87, 89 Buick/General Motors 78 Burt, R. 10 business angels 60 Cadillac 78 Cambridge academic entrepreneurship 28 Acorn Computers 367, 42 bioinformatics 41 biotechnology research 7, 27, 31, 32, 33, 34, 3941

Index Carrington, P. 10 Carroll, G. and M. Hannan 9 Castells, M. 3, 14 CDT 42 Celltech 41 Chandra, S. 204, 210, 213 Chang, H.-J. 15 Chile, wine clusters analysis 16676 China, ICT regional disparities 258 Chiroscience 41 Christensen, K. 306 Chrysler 79 Cird/Galderma 52 CIS 42 clusters Cambridge 30, 3141 embeddedness in 164, 1656, 168, 1714 as endogenous process 2830 geographic 69 heterogeneous performance, eects on 1646 heterogeneous performance and networks 16179 and innovation 162, 163, 172 local supply chain benets 289 network analysis 10, 11, 24045 and patents 235 spatial, evolutionary models 29 specialised 5, 30 and spin-os 2930 US 30, 70 wine in Chile 16676 see also agglomeration Cohen, W. and D. Levinthal 122, 128, 165, 258 Coleman, J. 147, 151 collective action, and technological change 956 collective invention 162 comparative advantage theory 206 competition and co-location 29 competitive advantage 163 cost 78 in Europe 235 and exiting rms 7 international 9, 34, 74 and regional development 204, 210, 257

313

and spatial concentration 9 US 74 complexity complex knowledge transfer 14853 informational and knowledge diusion 14760 urban transportation planning 280, 281, 308 congestion 6, 70, 223 connectivity 11, 12, 14, 15, 62, 64, 65 see also networks consumers and bounded rationality 11 co-locating with 28 and market networks 180 networks 11 peer eect 180 preference changes 94 and social status 180 convergence 12, 122, 123, 257 Cooke, P. 11 Cordis/Zeneca 52 Cowan, R. 11, 180, 183 Crang, P. 113 creative destruction 2 DARPA (Defense Advanced Research Agency) 44 data envelopment analysis 125, 126 Davis, G.F. 93, 94, 95, 147 De Jong, M. 6 DEC/Compaq 52 defence spending 45 deregulation 94 developing countries, technological progress 127, 257 Diamond Rubber 82 DiMaggio, P. and W. Powell 114 disk drive industry 90 Dissart, J. 204 diversity evolutionary potential 12, 205, 206, 2078, 20911 in rms 208 Herndahl index 21314 and innovation 15, 207, 210 in new industries 77 optimality and stability 2089 and path dependency 210 portfolio theory 21113

314

Index employment levels Cambridge 312, 33 Sophia-Antipolis science park 49, 51, 523, 55, 56, 59 US county business patterns 21323 see also unemployment entrepreneurial opportunity construction 93120 diagnostic framing 100102 legal and regulative structure 978 motivational framing and resource mobilization 1047 prognostic framing 100, 1024 and social movements 957, 100, 104 US power industry see US power industry entrepreneurship academic 28 Cambridge 434 and clusters see clusters co-evolutionary process of 6 and collective action 957 competent, importance of 15 and corporate form, problems with 96 demand side 94 endogenous nature of 6 and evolutionary economic geography 57 and geographical proximity 5 high-tech 6 and productivity growth see productivity growth regional, uneven rates of 5 Sophia-Antipolis science park 53, 54, 56, 60, 62 environmental movement, US 99, 101, 103, 1057, 10911 Enzymatics 41 EPO co-patenting applications 2313, 2356, 238, 2427, 24950 Erasmus student ows 2313, 2367, 23840, 243, 2467, 250 Eriksson 45 Essletzbichler, Jrgen 2, 5, 20329 ETSI (European Telecom Standard Institute) 56, 62 Europe agglomeration and productive capacity 231

and productivity levels 123 radio industry 73, 86 regional development 13, 16, 20423, 205 as risk-minimizing strategy 210, 211 and selection 205, 2078, 210 Sophia-Antipolis science park 50, 52, 60, 62 stability and growth 20613 and survival 208 tire industry 82, 83 US 20329 US county business patterns employment data 21323 Domino Printing Services 38, 39 Dopfer, K. 19 Dosi, G. 2, 19, 165, 207, 281 dotcom revolution 56, 5960, 62 see also ICT Dow Chemical 52 Duranton, G. and D. Puga 203, 211, 213 duration models 8 Echointeractive 62 economic geography 93, 206, 208 economic growth decline and vested interests 12 eciency improvements 13 and rm success 7 inputs growth 13 product life cycles 8, 12 and regional development 204, 20613 and routines 204 Sophia-Antipolis science park 67, 15, 16, 17, 556 and spillovers 13 uneven 2, 5 urban 14 and variety 13, 204 see also productivity growth Edison Electric Institute 105, 106 eciency adaptive 205, 20710 dynamic and static 15 and specialization 212 electrical power industry, US see US power industry Ellison, G. and E. Glaeser 69, 87, 270 Elmjet 39

Index competitiveness 235 EPO co-patenting applications 2313, 2356, 238, 2427, 24950 Erasmus student ows 2313, 2367, 23840, 243, 2467, 250 Fifth Framework Programme (5FP) 235 income levels 231 inter-regional knowledge ows 23055 Internet hyperlinks 231, 232, 2334, 238, 239, 240, 242, 243, 2467, 248 knowledge ows network analysis 24045 Lisbon 2000 European Council 231, 236 Maastricht Treaty (Article 130G) 235 mobile networks pricing strategy 181 R&D facilities from extra-European rms 55 research networks 231, 232, 2345, 23840, 242, 243, 2467, 249 Single European Act 235 Sophia-Antipolis science park see Sophia-Antipolis science park evolutionary biology adaptationism 2078, 209 survival in 207 evolutionary economic geography applications of 124, 162, 1634 case-study research 3 and entrepreneurship 57 and institutions 2 macro levels 3, 4, 12, 13 meso levels 3, 4, 7, 163, 164, 165 methodology 3 micro levels 4, 163, 164, 165 network analysis 1012, 24045 new industries see new industries path dependency 2, 6, 18 spatial concentration 9 survival analysis 9 territorial dierences 2 see also geographical distance; geographical proximity; institutional economic

315

geography; new economic geography evolutionary economics diversity and selection 12, 205, 206, 2078, 20911 and innovation 5, 1823 and knowledge diusion 183 regional development 15 and routines 18, 2078 social network analysis 1112, 1823 and social network theory 1823 spatial clusters 29 urban transportation planning see urban transport planning evolutionary growth theory 18 Farrell, J. and G. Saloner 180 FDI 121, 246 Feldman, M.P. 163, 203, 232 Firestone 80, 81, 82 rms absorptive capacity and innovation 11 in agglomerated regions see agglomeration clusters see clusters co-location 29 core competencies 5 diversity in 208 economic behaviour, variety in 282 economic growth and success 7 embeddedness of 164, 1656, 168, 1714 evolutionary growth theory 18, 165, 2812 exiting 7, 8, 57, 74 founder history and location 5, 6, 8 heterogeneous 5, 11, 129, 16179 high-tech 6, 10 innovation in see innovation internal resources 165, 174 knowledge diusion see knowledge diusion location behaviour 5, 6, 28, 29 migration 13 and networks see networks new entrants see new entrants non-local relationships 11 outsourcing 6, 29

316

Index see also evolutionary economic geography Germany environmental sector 16 synthetic dye industry 10 university Internet hyperlinks 234 see also Europe Gertler, M.S. 1 ghost towns 212 Giampietro, M. and K. Mayumi 206, 207, 211 Giord, J. 279, 306 Giugni, M. 95, 114 Giuliani, Elisa 11, 16179 Glaeser, E. 69, 87, 204, 270 Goodrich 80, 81, 82, 878 Goodyear 80, 81 Grabher, G. 12, 210 Granovetter, M. 10, 18, 114, 152, 164, 210 gravity equations 24651 Guimer, R. and L. Amaral 12 Gulati, R. 166 Hagedoorn, J. 10 Hall, P. and A. Markusen 6 Hannan, M. 9 Hansatech 39 Harris, C. 93 Harvey, D. 203, 210 Heernan, Paul 2747 Henderson, J. 203, 204 heterogeneity accumulation process in SophiaAntipolis science park 51, 524, 56 automobile industry 79 eects on clusters performance 1646 rms 5, 11, 129, 16179 in industry and labour productivity 139 knowledge bases 165 performance of clusters and networks 16179 routines 7, 8 in routines 7, 8 Sophia-Antipolis science park 51, 524, 56 spatial in ICT adoption 268

performance and geographical proximity 1624, 1745 productivity levels see productivity levels in related industries 845 relational proximity 161, 1624 relocation 5, 6 routines in 5, 8 size and spin-os 7 spatial concentration 7, 8, 9 supply chain externalities 28 technology sharing 128 Fleming, Lee 14760 Fligstein, N. 93, 94, 95, 97 footwear industry 11, 8990 Foray, D. 15 Ford Motor Co. 75, 78, 79 France engineering sector 16 infrastructure 17, 44, 50 science-industry relationships 60 Sophia-Antipolis science park 67, 15, 16, 17, 44, 4866 university Internet hyperlinks 234 see also Europe free-riders, and collective action 94 Freeman, C. 10, 12 Frenken, Koen 124, 30, 149, 162, 208, 211, 212 Friedland, R. and R. Alford 95 Friends of the Earth 105 Fujita, M. 1, 211 Galliano, D. and P. Roux 258 Garnsey, Elizabeth 7, 2747 General Motors 75, 79 geographic attractiveness 29 clusters 69 geographical distance 5, 163, 2312 gravity equations 24651 see also evolutionary economic geography geographical proximity and entrepreneurship 5 and knowledge diusion 10, 14, 18, 1523, 1557, 161, 1624 networks and 10 and performance 1624, 1745 social boundaries and 152, 155, 157

Index and technical eciency 129 tire industry 84 in urban transportation planning 279 Hewlett Packard 345 high-tech region, Cambridge 6, 15, 17, 2747 SMEs 57, 5860, 624 see also ICT Hodgson, G. 1, 205, 207 Hohenberg, P. and L. Lees 14 Holling, C.S. 205, 206, 208 Hudson, R. 203 Human Genome project 41 ICT and absorptive capacity 2589 Cambridge 3541, 43 domain names as proxy for adoption 25964 dotcom revolution 56, 5960, 62 high-tech entrepreneurship 6 infrastructure 14 Internet hyperlinks 2314, 23840, 2423, 2468 local digital divide 2579 and market characteristics 259 new technologies, territorial adoption of 25676 regional disparities 257, 258 regional disparities, US 257 Sophia-Antipolis science park 512, 535, 57, 5961, 635 spatial econometric approach to inequalities 25676 spatial heterogeneity in 268 territorial adoption, econometric models of 2649 see also high-tech incumbents as source of competence 856 India, ICT 257 Indonesia labour productivity analysis 12144 see also productivity growth industry de-concentration of 7 dynamics 4, 710 geographic structure, evolution of 90 life-cycle model 7

317

organisational ecology 9 self-reinforcing process 9 see also rms infrastructure Sophia-Antipolis science park 50, 51, 54, 55, 63, 64 UK 17, 305 innovation and agglomeration 70 and clusters 162, 163, 172 and collective action 96 and diversity 15, 207, 210 and evolutionary economics 5, 1823 and rms absorptive capacity 11 and industrial dynamics 94 Innovation Centre, Cambridge 43 network analysis 1012, 183, 24045 and new sectors 10 patents see patents post-entry 9 process 78 and productivity growth 123, 1245 as search process 148, 149 Sophia-Antipolis science park 49, 54, 56, 57, 6065 spatial distribution 262 and technology levels 123 in UK 41 see also spillovers; patents; R&D INRIA 56 institutional economic geography applications of 1, 93, 11314 case-study research 12 see also evolutionary economic geography institutions co-evolutionary process 910 and collective action 956, 100 and environmental shocks 94 frameworks 56 new 10 reform of 67 rigidities 12 and spatial evolution 910 theory 5 intellectual property 36, 378, 39, 41, 43, 64 interactive learning, Sophia-Antipolis science park 52, 56, 57, 60, 61, 623

318 international trade theory, gravity model 14 internationalisation, Sophia-Antipolis science park 5051, 55, 56, 578 Ireland, ICT 257 Italy cooperative banks in rural areas 97 domain name registrations 26064 footwear industry 11 ICT regional disparities 258 patents 267, 269 territorial ICT adoption 2649 Third Italy 203 university Internet hyperlinks 234 wine clusters analysis 162, 16676 see also Europe Iwai, K. 208 Jacob, Jojo 12144 Jacobs, J. 13, 204, 206, 212, 281 Jae, A.B. 10, 16, 93, 161, 163, 232, 235, 250, 258, 27071 Japan, semiconductor technology 74 Jessop, B. 203 Jovanovic, B. 208

Index Erasmus student ows 2313, 23640, 243, 2467, 250 and evolutionary economics 183 face-to-face interaction 106, 232, 236, 242, 248, 249 and geographical proximity 10, 14, 18, 1523, 1557, 161, 1624 global knowledge 14, 18 gravity equations 24651 and informational complexity 14760 inter-regional in Europe 23055 Internet hyperlinks 2314, 23840, 2423, 2468 knowledge receipt as search 14850 location choice 29 network analysis, Europe 24045 and network structure 10, 183 and new entrants 83 and relational proximity 9, 161, 1624 research networks 231, 232, 2345, 238 social boundaries 10, 1513, 1558, 1634 and technological communities 152, 153, 155, 157, 166 tire industry 88 types of 2327 US utility patents analysis 1538 see also spillovers Kogut, B. and U. Zander 6, 18, 934, 147, 148 Kort, R. 203 Krackhardt, D. 181, 193 Krugman, P. 1, 2, 28, 29, 69, 161, 204, 211, 232, 235 labour migration 13 mobility 10, 39 skilled 9, 29 labour productivity stochastic frontier analysis 12144 Lambooy, J. 2, 5, 15, 162, 212 large company eects 45 laser industry 90 Lazerson, M. and G. Lorenzoni 161, 164 learning-by-doing 5, 1289

Katz, M. and C. Shapiro 180 Kauman, S. 14950, 158 Keller, W. 271 Kitson, M. 203 Klepper, Steven 2, 6, 7, 8, 9, 30, 6992, 1289, 139 knowledge causal ambiguity 148 codied 1489, 158, 2323, 236 tacit 5, 148, 158, 164, 165, 232, 233, 236 knowledge bases, heterogeneous 165 knowledge diusion in automobile industry 8, 9, 16 and central hubs 14 and clusters see clusters complex knowledge transfer 14853 complexity and access to template 15051, 1567 and economic growth 13 EPO co-patenting applications 2313, 2356, 23840, 2437, 24950

Index learning, interactive 52, 56, 57, 60, 61, 623 Lee, Brandon 93120 Leitner, H. and E. Sheppard 203 Levins, R. and R. Lewontin 205 Levinthal, D.A. 16, 165, 258 licensing 42 Lisbon 2000 European Council 231, 236 Lissoni, F. 2, 10, 18, 28, 29, 88, 162, 182, 235, 236, 241 localization economies 212 location choice agglomeration economies 8, 6970, 7980, 868, 90 co-location 289 heterogeneity 8 knowledge diusion 29 localities growth model 12 and spillovers 27, 28 value chain considerations 28 lock-in, spatial 8, 12, 210, 282 Los, Bart 12144 Lounsbury, D. and M. Ventresca 95 Lovering, J. 203 Lovins, Amory 1013 Lybertysurf 62 Maastricht Treaty (Article 130G) 235 McAdam, D. 94, 97 McCarthy, J. 97, 104 Maggioni, Mario A. 2, 23055 Malizia, E. and S. Ke 214 Markusen, A. 6, 176 Marshall, A. 69, 93, 158, 161, 1623, 164, 204 Martin, R. 1, 2, 18, 93, 113, 114, 162, 203, 211, 231 Maruyama, M. 29 Maskell, P. 5, 10, 161, 162, 163, 164 Matutinovic, I. 209, 210 Metcalfe, J.S. 15, 182, 205, 207, 208 mobile telecommunications industry operator choice criteria 1879, 1936 UK 18398 Molina-Morales, F. and M. MartinezFernandez 161, 164, 165 Moore, G. and K. Davis 90 Moulton, B. 170 MS-DOS 36

319

multinationals 14, 18, 45 Sophia-Antipolis science park 578 see also oligopolies Neary, J. 211 Nelson, R.R. 2, 9, 15, 113, 122, 205, 207, 208 and S.G. Winter 2, 5, 15, 19, 148, 150, 165, 207, 281 neoclassicism and economic geography 1, 204 and price dierentials 5 Netherlands Amsterdam land use policy 28590, 2945, 2967, 299, 300, 301 Amsterdam urban transportation planning 283, 284308 infrastructure 17 Internet adoption 258 see also Europe networks agent interaction 183, 210, 241, 249 aggregation 1314 analysis 1012, 24045 Cambridge 28, 39, 434 cities 14 cluster rms heterogeneous performance 16179 and clusters 10, 11, 24045 consumer 11 dynamics model 1112 economics of 180200 externalities 210, 230 and geographical proximity 10 global knowledge 14, 18 hub-and-spoke 12 indirect eects 181 infrastructure 12 and innovation 1012, 183, 24045 inter-city 1314 inter-regional 1314 and knowledge diusion 10, 183 see also knowledge diusion local 8 market, and consumers 180 mobile telephony see mobile telecommunications industry and multinationals 14 preferential attachment 12

320

Index co-evolution of 910 and regional policy 16 new technologies, territorial adoption of see ICT Nottingham University Business School social network survey 1812, 18598 Nuvolari, A. 149, 162 Odisei 62 Oerlemans, L. and M. Meeus 164 o-shoring 6 Olds Motor Works 78, 79, 878 oligopolies 70, 80 see also multinationals Olivetti 36 organic food industry 96 organizations and collective action 956, 105 and consultancy use 96 development of multi-locational 18 environmental shocks 94 membership 152 routines 2812 theory 93, 945 outsourcing 6, 29, 39, 74 Overman, H. 1 Paci, R. and S. Usai 235 Pack, H. 122, 123, 141 patents and agglomeration 235 and clusters 235 EPO co-patenting applications 2313, 2356, 238, 2427, 24950 and networks 28 see also innovation: R&D path dependency and cumulative process 30 and diversity 210 evolutionary economic geography 2, 6, 18 technology 180 urban transportation planning 2834, 298300, 302 see also agglomeration economies; spin-os Pearson coefcients 173, 232, 239, 240, 268

quadratic assignment procedure 181, 193 research (Europe) 231, 232, 2345, 23840, 242, 243, 2467, 249 small-world 183 social network theory see social network analysis Sophia-Antipolis science park 51, 62 transportation 14 see also agents; connectivity new economic geography development of 1 diversity and economic growth 204 geographical distance see geographical distance geographical proximity see geographical proximity methodology 1, 2 see also evolutionary economic geography; geographical distance; geographical proximity new entrants and agglomeration economies 8 bounded rationality 8 Cambridge 32, 357, 39, 41, 42, 43 and diversity 212 and knowledge diusion 83 location choice 8 Sophia-Antipolis science park 49, 54, 56, 5960 spatial distribution of 5, 9 survival analysis 5, 7, 8, 9, 32, 35 new growth theory 13 new industries automobile industry see automobile industry and collective action 94 diversication 77 evolution of geographic structure in 6992 outsourcing 74 radio industry agglomeration 73, 74, 77, 86 seeding industries 767 television receiver industry agglomeration 70, 714, 77, 856, 89 tire industry see tire industry new sectors

Index Penrose, E. 165 Perez, C. 10, 12, 15 performance, and agglomeration 70 Perrow, C. 95 Philips 34 Pinch, S. 161 Piore, M. and C. Sabel 93, 161 Piscitello, Lucia 25676 planning framework programmes, EU 235 and regional development 206 urban transportation see urban transportation planning Plouraboue, F. 11 Polanyi, M. 147, 148 policy evaluation 3, 4 freedom 15, 16 implications 3, 4, 1417 Porter, M. 5, 28, 161, 163, 204 portfolio theory 13, 31113 Portugal entrepreneurial start-ups 83 ICT regional disparities 258 Powell, W. 10, 114, 174 Poyhonen, P. 246 Pred, A. 14 price dierentials 56 product life-cycle hypothesis 8, 12 product standardisation 78 product variety 215 production costs, and agglomeration 89 production location see location choice productivity growth accumulation theories 122 assimilation theories 1223, 124 capital deepening (creating potential) 124 and convergence 12, 122, 123, 257 data envelopment analysis 125, 126 decomposition analysis 13940 and diversity 123 estimation method 1267 frontier and ineciency estimation 1319 source identication 1246 stochastic analysis 12144 see also economic growth proximity geographical 5, 10, 152, 155, 157, 175 relational 163, 175 social 155, 157, 163, 175 spatial 270 Pumain, D. 12, 14 Pye (Philips) 34 Pyke, F. 161 Qur, Michel 4866 Quigley, J. 204

321

R&D Europe, facilities from extraEuropean rms 55 and new entrant survival 9 research networks 231, 232, 2345, 238 Sophia-Antipolis science park 50, 51, 523, 54, 55, 56, 578, 65 spillovers (Indonesia) 1256, 1278, 13039 see also innovation; patents Rabellotti, R. and H. Schmitz 161, 164 radio industry agglomeration 73, 74, 77, 86 Rammel, C. and van den Bergh, J. 206, 207, 208, 209 Rao, H. 93, 94, 95, 97, 100 Reed, R. and R. DeFillippi 147 regional development co-evolutionary process of 6 and competition 204, 210, 257 and convergence 12, 122, 123, 257 diversication 13, 20423 diversity 13, 16, 20423, 205 and economic growth 204, 20613 and economic survival 205 evolutionary 15 external shocks in demand 13 and rm success 7 gravity equations 24651 and ICT see ICT infrastructure provision 1617 inter-regional knowledge ows in Europe 23055 inter-regional networks 1314 and new sectors 16 and planning decisions 206 portfolio theory 13, 31113

322

Index Scott, A. 164, 203 Scott, R. 95, 101, 113, 114 selection and diversity 205, 2078, 210 spatial dierences 5 shakeouts 889 Sheppard, E. 203, 211 Siemens 45 Sierra Club 99, 103, 1045, 10612 Simmie, J. 27 Sine, Wesley 93120 Small world 42 SMEs Small Business Innovation Research (SBIR), Cambridge 44 Sophia-Antipolis science park 56, 57, 5860, 623, 64 Smith, E. 204 social boundaries and geographical proximity 152, 155, 157 knowledge diusion 10, 1513, 1558, 1634 social movement organizations (SMOs) 104, 109, 11415 social movement theory 93, 945, 114 social network analysis 180200 and evolutionary economics 1112, 1823 and knowledge diusion 147, 1513, 155 network statistics 18991 regression results 1916 social status and consumers 180 social proximity 155, 157, 1634, 175 Solomon, S. 11 Sophia-Antipolis science park academic incubators 60 business angels 60 collaboration, local 62 competitiveness 55, 56 diversication 50, 52, 60, 62 employment levels 49, 51, 523, 55, 56, 59 entrepreneurial initiatives 53, 54, 56, 60, 62 governance of 49, 5051, 5460, 63 GSM technologies 65 historical characteristics 4954, 63

renewability 12 revolutionary 15 spatial autocorrelation econometrics 13 spatial lock-in 8 and specialization 21011 stability 20613 US 20329 US county business patterns employment data 21323 variety in 1213, 16, 204, 212 see also individual industries relational proximity 175 and knowledge diusion 9, 161, 1624 renewable energy technology, US power industry 10, 95, 98100, 1027, 108 resources, creation of new 15 Respublica 62 Ricardo, D. 206 Rigby, D. 2, 5, 207, 211 Rivkin, Jan W. 14760 Robert-Nicoud, F. 211 Rodan, S. and C. Galunic 166 Rohlfs, J. 180 Rohm & Haas 52 Romanelli, E. and C. Schoonhoven 93, 95 Romer, P. 93 Rossi, Cristina 25676 routines disruption of 94 and economic growth 204 and evolutionary economics 18, 2078 heterogeneous 7, 8 organizational 2812 variety in 5, 6 Sapir, A. 230 Saviotti, P.P. 13, 207 Saxenian, A. 6, 35 Schneiberg, M. 95, 96, 97, 98, 114 Schoening, N. and L. Sweeney 206 Schumpeter, J. 2, 18, 94, 128, 148 science parks reverse 534 Sophia-Antipolis see SophiaAntipolis science park

Index ICT 512, 535, 57, 5961, 635 infrastructure 50, 51, 54, 55, 63, 64 innovation 49, 54, 56, 57, 6065 intellectual property rights 64 interactive learning 52, 56, 57, 60, 61, 623 internationalisation 5051, 55, 56, 578 life sciences 51, 523, 54, 55 networking 51, 62 PhD training 54, 55, 56, 623 policy implications 6065 R&D 50, 51, 523, 54, 55, 56, 578, 65 relocations 62 as reverse science park 534 SMEs 56, 57, 5860, 623, 64 spin-os, local 5960, 623 telecom equipment providers 62, 63, 64 and University of Nice 52, 534, 60 venture capital 60 Sorenson, Olav 6, 9, 89, 94, 14760 Spain ICT regional disparities 258 university Internet hyperlinks 234 spatial clusters 29 concentration 7, 8, 9, 223 econometric approach to inequalities in ICT 25676 heterogeneity in ICT adoption 268 lock-in 8, 12, 210, 282 new entrants distribution 5, 9 proximity 270 systems 1214 Spearman correlations 239, 240 specialization 12, 15, 29, 203, 206, 21011, 212, 221 Sophia-Antipolis science park 51 spillovers absorptive capacity and foreign 12144 and agglomeration 158 agglomeration economies 88 automobile industry 88 and economic growth 13 free-riders 28 high-tech centres 27 and location choice 27, 28

323

R&D (Indonesia) 1256, 1278, 13039 stochastic frontier analysis 12144 technology 1289 tire industry 88 utility patents analysis for 1538 variety underlying 13 in wine production 11 see also knowledge diusion spin-os agglomeration economies 30 agglomeration inducement 30, 868 automobile industry 778, 79, 85, 86, 878, 90 Cambridge 289 and clusters 2930 disk drive industry 90 and rm size 7 inherited routines 7 laser industry 90 model 7, 89 Sophia-Antipolis science park 5960, 623 television industry 86, 87, 88 tire industry 823, 84, 85, 868, 90 in UK 6, 16 see also agglomeration economies; path dependency spin-outs 30 Cambridge 3541, 42 Stam, E. 5, 6, 18 start-ups see new entrants Stern, R. and S. Barley 95 Stinchcombe, A. 94, 95 stochastic frontier analysis, labour productivity see productivity growth Storper, M. 2, 113 Strang, D. and E. Bradburn 97 structural change 12 Stuart, T. and O. Sorenson 6, 9, 94, 98 Suchman, M. 98, 100101 sunk costs 12 survival and diversity 2089 in evolutionary biology 207 new entrants 5, 7, 8, 9, 32, 35 sustainability

324 Sophia-Antipolis science park 51, 53, 545, 56, 63, 64 urban transportation planning 308 Swaminathan, A. and J. Wade 94 Swann, P. and M. Prevezer 2

Index labour costs 84 location of branch plants 834 related industries, inuence of 88 seeding industries 84 shakeouts 889 spillovers 88 spin-os 823, 84, 85, 868, 90 trade unions 84 transportation costs 84 trade associations 84, 94 transportation network morphology 283, 301, 302 and urban networks 14 see also urban transportation planning Uberti, T. Erika 23055 UK automobile sector 89, 16 Cambridge high-tech region see Cambridge infrastructure 17, 305 innovation in 41 investment levels 41 mobile telecommunications industry 18398 new sector co-evolution 10 Oxford 44 related industries 9 retail banking industry 10 specialist labour markets 6 spin-os 6, 16 standardised credit rating 41 university Internet hyperlinks 234 venture capital 37, 41 Ulanowicz, R. 206 uncertainty 15, 16, 17 in urban transportation planning 27980, 283, 284, 3068 unemployment 204, 206 structural 13 see also employment levels UniCam 34 Union of Concerned Scientists 99, 103 Uniroyal 80 universities academic entrepreneurship 28 Cambridge see Cambridge Erasmus student ows 231, 232, 233, 2367

Taylor, P. 14 technical eciency, and heterogeneity 129 technological communities 152, 153, 155, 157, 166 congruence 123, 13031 proximity 130, 153 technological change 34, 94 and collective action 956 technologies and absorptive capacity 128, 129 capital-intensive 123 communities 152, 153 FDI 121 path dependency 180 and plant age 1289 recombination 16 rise and fall of 2 similar, between enterprises 128 spillovers 1289 technology transfer 90 variety 204 Teece, D. 5, 123 Tlmcanique/Schneider 51 television industry agglomeration 70, 714, 77, 79, 856, 89 and agglomeration economies 74, 7980 spin-os 86, 87, 88 Thals 51 The Technology Partnership (TTP) 38 Thrift, N. 1, 113 Tilly, C. 104 Tinbergen, J. 14, 246 tire industry agglomeration 84, 868, 90 and agglomeration economies 84, 868 diversication 82, 83 geographic structure, evolution of 7690 heterogeneity 84 input markets 88

Index Internet hyperlinks 234 manufacturing modernisation initiatives, US 35 PhD training, Sophia-Antipolis science park 54, 55, 56, 623 University of Nice 52, 534, 60 see also Sophia-Antipolis science park urban economic growth 14 urban transportation planning Amsterdam 283, 284308 complexity of 280, 281, 308 evolutionary approach 279310 heterogeneity in 279 path dependency 2834, 298300, 302 sustainability 308 system resilience 3034, 308 transportation network morphology 283, 301, 302 uncertainty in 27980, 283, 284, 3068 variety in 280, 303 urbanization economies 212 US automobile industry agglomeration 7, 8, 1415, 30, 70, 7480 clustering 30, 70 competition, international 74 county business patterns employment data 21323 diversity, stability and regional growth 20329 electrical power industry see electrical power industry, US environmental movement 99, 101, 103, 1057, 10911 re insurance industry 96, 98 government-university manufacturing modernisation initiatives 35 ICT regional disparities 257 institutional changes, dierential 10 investment in Cambridge high-tech industries 412, 43, 44 National Energy Act (NEA) 100 oil crises 99, 101, 107 outsourcing 74 power industry 98107 Prohibition period and breweries 97

325

Public Utility Regulatory Policies Act (PURPA) 100 radio industry agglomeration 73, 74 railroad industry, Massacheusetts 97 renewable energy technology 10, 98100, 1027, 108 Route 128 45 semiconductor technology 74 Shockley and Fairchild spin-outs 30 Silicon Valley 7, 345, 45, 69, 90, 203 and Sophia-Antipolis science park 5051 television receiver industry agglomeration 70, 714, 79, 80, 85 tire industry agglomeration see tire industry utility patents analysis for spillovers 1538 US power industry 98112 diagnostic framing 100102 environmental movement 99, 101, 103, 1057, 10911 hypothesis data and methods 10712 motivational framing and resource mobilization 1047 prognostic framing 100, 1024 renewable energy technology 10, 95, 98100, 1027, 108 Uzzi, B. 10, 183 van den Bergh J. 206, 207, 208, 209, 281 Van Dijk, M. 123, 141 van Wissen, L. 9 variety in economic behaviour of rms 282 and economic development 13, 204 labour productivity 138 product 215 in regional development 1213, 16, 204, 212 in routines 5 in spillovers 13 of strategy in science parks 49, 57, 62 strategy in Sophia-Antipolis science park 49, 57, 62 technological 204

326 in urban transportation planning 280, 303 venture capital Cambridge 412 Sophia-Antipolis science park 60 UK 37, 41 Videojet 39 Vrba, E. and S. Gould 205 Vromen, J. 208 wage dierentials 70, 89 Wagner, J. and S. Deller 208 Wassermann, S. and K. Faust 10, 162, 240 Watts, D. 10, 241 wealth distribution 1, 18 Weber, A. 93

Index Wellcome 52 Weltevreden, J. 258 Werker, C. and S. Athreye 2 Wernerfelt, B. 172 Whitley, R. 1 wine production and clusters 162, 16676 and spillovers 11 Winter, S.G. 2, 5, 15, 19, 148, 150, 165, 207, 281 Xaar 39 Zaheer, A. and G. Bell 161, 164, 165, 172 Zander, U. 6, 18, 934, 147, 148 Zucker, L. 28, 93

Anda mungkin juga menyukai