Anda di halaman 1dari 14

9.3.

4 Siegels Exchange Rate Paradox


dQ t Q t R t R f t dt 2 t t dW1 t 2 t 1 2 dW2 t

Q t R t R f t dt 2 t dW3 t

9.3.16

In (9.3.16), the mean rate of change for the exchange


rate Q(t) is R(t) - Rf(t) under the domestic risk-neutral
measure P .
From the foreign perspective, the exchange rate is 1/Q(t),
and one should expect the mean rate of change of 1/Q(t)
to be Rf(t) - R(t).
This turns out not to be as straight forward as one might
expect because of the convexity of the function f(x) = 1/x.

Example:
Exchange rate of 0.9 euros to the dollar:
1 euro 1.1111 dollars
If the dollar price of euro falls by 5%:
1 euro 0.95 1.1111 = 1.0556 dollars
This is an exchange rate of 1/1.0556=0.9474 euros to
dollars. The change from 0.9 euros to the dollar to
0.9474 euros to the dollar is a 5.26% ( = 1/0.95 - 1)
increase in the euro price of the dollar, not a 5% increase.

We take f x

1
1
2
so that f x 2 and f x 3 . Using 9.3.16 , we obtain
x
x
x

1
d df Q
Q
f Q dQ

1
f Q dQdQ
2

1
1
R f R dt 2 dW3 22 dW3dW3
Q
Q
1
R f R 22 dt 2 dW3

Q t

9.3.24

The mean rate of change under the domestic risk-neutral measure is R f R 22 ,


not R f R.

1
is resolved if we
x
switch to the foreign risk-neutal measure, which is the appropriate one for derivative
However, the asymmetry introduced by the convexity of f x

security pricing in the foreign currency. First recall the relaptionship (9.3.20)
dW3
In terms of W3

t 2 t dt dW3 t dW3 t 2 t dt dW3

t , we may rewrite 9.3.24 as


f
1 1
d R f R dt 2 dW3

Q Q

Under the foreign risk-neutral measure, the mean rate of change for
as expect.

(9.3.25)
1
is R f R,
Q

Under the actual probability measure P , however, the asymmetry remains.


When we begin with (9.3.4), which shows the mean rate of change of the

exchange rate to be t under P\, and then use the Ito-Do


eblin formula, we
obtain the formula 9.3.27 below
dQ t t Q t dt 2 t Q t dW3 t

9.3.4

1 1
1
2
d

t
dt

2 t dW3 t

9.3.27

2
Q t
Q t Q t
1
Both Q and
have the same volatility. However, the mean rates of change
Q
1
of Q and
are not negatives of one another.
Q

9.3.5 Forward Exchange Rates


We assume in this subsection that the domestic and foreign interest rates are constant
and denote these constants by r and r f , respectively. Recall that Q is units of domestic
currency per unit of foreign currency. The exchange rate from the domestic viewpoint
is governed by the stochastic differential equation (9.3.16)
dQ Q t r r f dt 2 t t dW 1 t 2 t 1 2 t dW 2 t

Therefore
money market account
r r f t
e
Q t
money market account
is a martingale under P , the domestic risk-neutral measure.
proof :
r r f t

d e
Q t

r r

r r

r r f t

e
e

dt Q t e

Q t dt e

r r f t

r r f t

Q t 2 t dW 3 t

r r f t

r r f t

dQ t

Q t r r f dt 2 t dW 3 t

At time zero, the (domestic currency) forward price F for a unit of foreign
currency, to be delivered at time T , is determined by the equation
E e rT Q T F 0
The left-hand side is the risk-neutral pricing formula applied to the derivative
security that pays Q T in exchange for F at time T . Setting this equal to zero
determines the forward price. We may solve this equation for F by observing
that it implies
r r f T
r f T

e F E e Q T e E e
Q T e Q 0

which gives the T -forward (domestic per unit of foreign) exchange rate
rT

rT

r f T

F e

r r T
f

Q 0

The exchange rate from the foreign viewpoint is given by the stochastic differential equation (9.3.25)
1 1 f
f
f
2

r
dt

t
dW
t

t
1

t
dW



2
1
2
2 t

Q t Q t
Therefore,
r f r t
1
e
Q t
f

is a martingale under P , the foreign risk-neutral measure.


At time zero, the (foreign currency) forward price F f for a unit of domestic currency to be delivered
at time T is determined by the equation
r f T 1
E e
Ff

Q T

The left-hand side is the risk-neutral pricing formula applied to the derivative security that pays
in exchange for F f (both denominates in foreign currency) at time T . Setting this equal to zero
determines the forward price. We may solve this equation for F f by observing that it implies
f
f
f
1 rT f r f r T 1 rT 1
e r T F f E e r T
e E e
e
Q
T
Q
T
Q 0

which gives the T -forward (foreign per unit of foreign) exchange rate
r f r T 1 1
Ff e
Q 0 F

1
Q T

9.3.6 Garman-Kohlhagen Formula


We assume the domestic and foreign interest rates r and r f and the volatility 2
are constant. Consider a call on a unit of foreign currency whose payoff in
domestic currency is Q t K . At time zero, the value of this is

rT

E e Q T K

In this case, (9.3.16) becomes

dQ t Q t r r f dt 2 dW3 t
from which we conclude that

Q T Q 0 exp 2 W3 T r r f 22 T
2

Define
Y

W3 T
T

so Y is a standard normal random variable under P . Then the price of the call is

E e rT Q T K

1 2

rT
f
E e Q 0 exp 2 TY r r 2 T K
2


This expression is just like (5.5.10) with T , with Q 0 in place of x, and with r f in place

of the dividend rate a. According to (5.5.12), the call price is


f

E e rT Q T K e r T Q 0 N d e rT KN d

9.3.28

where
Q 0
1 2
f
log

2 T

K
2
2 T

and N is the cumulative standard normal distribution function. Equation (9.3.28) is calles the
Garman - Kohlhagen formula.
d

r
c t , x E e x exp Y r a 2 K
2


c t , x xe aT N d , x e rT KN d , x

(5.5.10)
(5.5.12)

9.3.7 Exchange Rate Put-Call Duality


Recall the numeraire M f t Q t , which is the domestic price of the foreign money
market account. The Radon-Nikodym derivative of the foreign risk-neutral measure
with respect to the domestic risk-neutral measure is
D T M f T Q T
dP

Q 0
dP
f

f
1
f
D
T
M

T Q T d P for all A F
P A

A
Q
0

Thus, for any random variable X ,


D T M f T Q T
E X E
X
Q 0

(9.3.17)

A call struck at K on a unit of domestic currency denominated in the foreign currency

pays off
K units of foreign currency at expiration time T . The foreign
Q
T

currency value of this at time zero, which is the foreign risk-neutral expected value of
the discounted payoff, is

f
1
f
E D T
K

Q T

D T M f T Q T

1
f
E
D T
K
Q 0

Q T

E D T 1 KQ T

Q 0

K
1

E D T Q T
Q 0
K

K
This is the time-zero value in domestic currency of
puts on the foreign
Q 0
exchange rate. More specifically, a put struck at

1
on a unit of foreign
K

currency denominated in the domestic currency pays off Q T units


K

of domestic currency at expiration time T . The domestic currency value of this


put at time zero, which is the domestic risk-neutral expected value of the
dicounted payoff, is

1

E D T Q T
K

K
The call we began with is worth
of these puts.
Q 0

1
The foreign currency price of the put struck at
on a unit of foreign currency is
K

1
1

E D T Q T
Q 0
K

The call we began with has a value K times this amount. When we denominate
both the call and the put this way in foreign currency, we can then understand the
final result. Indeed, we have seen that the option to exchange K units of foreign
currency for one unit of domestic currency (the call) is the same as K option to
1
exchange
units of domestic currency for one unit of foreign currency (the put).
K
Stated in this way, the result is almost obvius.

Anda mungkin juga menyukai