Anda di halaman 1dari 196

Chapter 8

Pricing and Output


Decisions:
Perfect Competition
and Monopoly

Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,


Chapter Eight 1
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Overview

Competition and market types


Pricing and output decisions in
perfect competition
Pricing and output decisions in
monopoly markets
Implications for managerial
decisions
Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,
Chapter Eight 2
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Learning objectives
understand the four market types
compare the degree of price competition
among the four market types
explain why the P=MC rule leads firms to
the optimal level of production
explain how the MR=MC rule helps a
monopoly to determine its optimum
explain the relationship between the
MR=MC rule and the P=MC rule
describe what happens in the long run
Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,
Chapter Eight 3
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Four market types
Perfect competition (no market
power)

large number of relatively small buyers


and sellers

standardized product

very easy market entry and exit

nonprice competition
Chapter Eight
not possible
Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,
4
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Four market types
Monopoly (absolute market power,
subject to government regulation)

one firm, firm is the industry

unique product or no close substitutes

market entry and exit difficult or legally


impossible

nonprice competition
Chapter Eight
not necessary
Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,
5
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Four market types
Monopolistic competition (market
power based on product
differentiation)

large number of small firms acting


independently

differentiated product

market entry and exit relatively easy


Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,
Chapter Eight 6
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Four market types
Oligopoly (product differentiation and/or
the firms dominance of the market)

small number of large mutually


interdependent firms

differentiated or standardized product

market entry and exit difficult

nonprice competition important


Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,
Chapter Eight 7
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Four market types

Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,


Chapter Eight 8
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Four market types
Examples: perfect competition

agricultural products

financial instruments

precious metals

petroleum
Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,
Chapter Eight 9
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Four market types
Examples: monopoly

pharmaceuticals

Microsoft

gas station on edge of desert

Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,


Chapter Eight 10
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Four market types
Examples: monopolistic competition

boutiques

restaurants

repair shops

Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,


Chapter Eight 11
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Four market types
Examples: oligopoly

oil refining

processed foods

airlines

internet access
Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,
Chapter Eight 12
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Pricing and output decisions
in perfect competition
Basic business decision: entering
a market using the following
questions:
how much should we produce?
if we produce such an amount, how
much profit will we earn?
if a loss rather than a profit is incurred,
will it be worthwhile to continue in this
market in the long run (in hopes that we
will eventually earn a profit) or should
we exit? Copyright
Chapter Eight
2011 Pearson Education,
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
13
Pricing and output decisions
in perfect competition
Key assumptions of the perfectly
competitive market:

the firm is a price taker


the firm makes the distinction between
the short run and the long run
the firms objective is to maximize its
profit (or minimize loss) in the short run
the firm includes its opportunity cost of
operating in a particular market as part
of its total cost of production
Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,
Chapter Eight 14
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Pricing and output decisions
in perfect competition
Perfectly elastic demand
curve: consumers are
willing to buy as much as
the firm is willing to sell at
the going market price

firm receives the same


marginal revenue from the
sale of each additional unit
of product; equal to the
price of the product

no limit to the total


revenue that the firm can
gain in a perfectly
competitive market
Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,
Chapter Eight 15
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Pricing and output decisions
in perfect competition
Total revenue/Total cost approach:

compare the total revenue and total cost


schedules and find the level of output
that either maximizes the firms profits
or minimizes its loss

Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,


Chapter Eight 16
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Pricing and output decisions
in perfect competition
Marginal revenue/Marginal cost
approach
produce a level of output at which the
additional revenue received from the
last unit is equal to the additional cost of
producing that unit (ie. MR=MC)

Note: for the perfectly competitive firm,


the MR=MC rule may be restated as
P=MC because P=MR in perfectly
competitive market
Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,
Chapter Eight 17
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Pricing and output decisions
in perfect competition
Case A: economic
profit

The point where


P=MR=MC is the
optimal output (Q*)

profit = TR TC
=(P - AC) Q*

Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,


Chapter Eight 18
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Pricing and output decisions
in perfect competition
Case B: economic loss

The firm incurs a loss.


At optimum output,
price is below AC
however, since P >
AVC, the firm is better
off producing in the
short run, because it
will still incur fixed
costs greater than the
loss

Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,


Chapter Eight 19
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Pricing and output decisions
in perfect competition
Contribution
margin: the amount
by which total revenue
exceeds total variable
cost

CM = TR TVC

if CM > 0, the firm


should continue to
produce in the short
run in order to defray
some of the fixed cost

Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,


Chapter Eight 20
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Pricing and output decisions
in perfect competition
Shutdown point: the lowest price at which
the firm would still produce

At the shutdown point, the price is equal to


the minimum point on the AVC

If the price falls below the shutdown point,


revenues fail to cover the fixed costs and
the variable costs. The firm would be better
off if it shut down and just paid its fixed
costs
Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,
Chapter Eight 21
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Pricing and output decisions
in perfect competition
In the long run, the price in the competitive
market will settle at the point where firms
earn a normal profit

economic profit invites entry of new firms


shifts the supply curve to the right puts
downward pressure on price and reduces profits
economic loss causes exit of firms shifts the
supply curve to the left puts upward pressure
on price and increases profits

Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,


Chapter Eight 22
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Pricing and output decisions
in perfect competition
Observations in perfectly competitive markets:
the earlier the firm enters a market, the better
its chances of earning above-normal profit

as new firms enter the market, firms must find


ways to produce at the lowest possible cost, or
at least at cost levels below those of their
competitors

firms that find themselves unable to compete


on the basis of cost might want to try competing
on the basis of product differentiation instead
Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,
Chapter Eight 23
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Pricing and output decisions in
monopoly markets
A monopoly market consists of one firm
(the firm is the market)

firm has the power to set any price it


wants

however, the firms ability to set price is


limited by the demand curve for its
product, and in particular, the price
elasticity of demand
Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,
Chapter Eight 24
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Pricing and output decisions in
monopoly markets
Assume demand is
linear: it is downward
sloping because the
firm is a price setter

Assume MC is
constant
choose output
where MR=MC, set
price at P*

Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,


Chapter Eight 25
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Pricing and output decisions in
monopoly markets
Demand is the same
as before, as is MR

MC is upward sloping,
which shows
diminishing returns

set output where


MR=MC

Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,


Chapter Eight 26
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Implications of perfect competition
and monopoly for decision making
Perfectly competitive market

most important lesson is that it is


extremely difficult to make money

must be as cost efficient as possible

it might pay for a firm to move into a


market before others start to enter

Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,


Chapter Eight 27
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Implications of perfect competition
and monopoly for decision making
Monopoly market

most important lesson is not to be


arrogant and assume their ability to
earn economic profit can never be
diminished

changes in economics of a business


eventually break down a dominating
companys monopolistic power
Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,
Chapter Eight 28
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Global application
Example: Bluefin tuna

sushi restaurants operate in


monopolistic competition
bluefin tuna price determined by
perfect competition
low profit margin

Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,


Chapter Eight 29
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Herfindahl- Hirschman Index
(HHI)
The HHI is the sum of the
squares of the market shares of
each firm in the industry
A monopoly has 100 percent of the
market share

2
100 = (100 X 100) = 10,000
You cant get a bigger HHI number than 10,000. Every monopoly
would have an HHI of 10,000

Copyright 2002 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All


25-12
Herfindahl- Hirschman Index
(HHI)
The HHI is the sum of the
squares of the market shares of
each firm in the industry

Find the HHI in an industry with just two firms


Each firm has 50 percent of the market

2 2
50 + 50 = 2,500 + 2,500 = 5,000

Copyright 2002 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All


25-13
Herfindahl- Hirschman Index
(HHI)
The HHI is the sum of the
squares of the market shares of
each firm in the industry

Find the HHI in an industry that has four firms


Each firm has 25 percent of the market

2 2 2
25 + 25 + 25 + 25
2

625 + 625 + 625 + 625


2500

Copyright 2002 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All


25-14
Disadvantage of 4-firm
concentration ratio:

Doesnt give extra weight to


especially large firms

33
Herfindahl Index
(S1)2+ (S2)2+
(S3)2+...+ (Sn)2
(30)2+(25)2+(2
0)2+(10)2+
(9)2+(6)2 =
900+625+400
+100+81+36=
2142

34
Herfindahl Index
Industry X Sales Market
HI = Share
6268 Firm A 790 79%
Firm B 20 2%
Firm C 20 2%
Firm D 20 2%
15 other 10 1%
firms each
with:

Total
35 1000 100%
Herfindahl Index
Increases if the number of firms
decrease
Gives extra weight to especially large
firms

36
FTCs Ranking of Competitiveness: Concentrated
Case Study
Producers in 1985 Share
Coca-Cola 37.4%
PepsiCo 28.9
Philip Morris (7-up) 5.7
Dr. Pepper Co 4.6
R.J. Reynolds (Sunkist, Canada Dry) 3.0
Royal Crown Cola 2.9
Proctor and Gamble (Orange Crush, 1.8
Hines)
Others (supermarket brands) 15.7

37
FTCs Ranking of Competitiveness: Concentrated
Case Study
Producers in 1985 Share
Coca-Cola 37.4%
PepsiCo 28.9
Philip Morris (7-up) 5.7
Dr. Pepper Co 4.6
R.J. Reynolds (Sunkist, Canada Dry) 3.0
Royal Crown Cola 2.9
Proctor and Gamble (Orange Crush, 1.8
Hines)
Others (supermarket brands) 15.7
Herfindahl no merger
37.42+28.92+5.72+4.62+3.02 = 2324
38
Case Study
Producers in 1985 Share
Coca-Cola + Dr. Pepper 37.4+4.6=
42.0
PepsiCo 28.9
Philip Morris (7-up) 5.7

R.J. Reynolds (Sunkist, Canada Dry) 3.0


Royal Crown Cola 2.9
Proctor and Gamble (Orange Crush, 1.8
Hines)
Others (supermarket brands) 15.7
Herfindahl with merger
422+28.92+5.72+3.02 = 2668
39
Price Discrimination

price discrimination Charging


different prices to different buyers.

perfect price discrimination


Occurs when a firm charges the
maximum amount that buyers
are willing to pay for each unit.

40 of 38
Price Discrimination

Basic model: a monopolist charges:


A. Same price for all units.
B. Same price to all customers.

Changing one or both of these is called Price


Discrimination. Can one profit from this?
1st degree is different prices for both consumers
and units (both A and B are changed)
2nd degree is different prices for different units
(A changed).
3rd degree is different prices to different
consumers (B changed).
41
1st-Degree Price Discrimination

Different prices for both consumers and units.

To do this properly, a monopolist must have


strong information on:
Each individual consumers preferences.

1st degree captures the whole consumer


surplus.

1st degree is efficient.

42
FIRST DEGREE PRICE DISCRIMINATION
Perfect Price Discrimination

Sometimes known as optimal pricing, with perfect price discrimination, the firm separates the whole market into each individual consumer and charges them the price they are willing and able to pay. If successful, the firm can extract all consumer
surplus that lies beneath the demand curve and turn it into extra producer revenue (or producer surplus). This is impossible to achieve unless the firm knows every consumers preferences and, as a result, is unlikely to occur in the real world. The
transactions costs involved in finding out through market research what each buyer is prepared to pay is the main block or barrier to a businesses engaging in this form of price discrimination.
If the monopolist is able to perfectly segment the market, then the average revenue curve effectively becomes the marginal revenue curve for the firm. The monopolist will continue to see extra units as long as the extra revenue exceeds the
marginal cost of production.

43
12

1 2 3 4 5 6 1 2 3 4 5 6

Examples of 1st degree price discriminators:


Car dealerships mechanics, doctors, and lawyers (service related
business).
2nd Degree Price Discrimination

In this type of discrimination the companies are actually not able to


differentiate between the different types of consumers. This practice
creates a schedule of declining prices for different quantities. Using this
strategy the company can extract some of the consumer surplus without
knowing much about the individual consumer.
This can be seen in quantity discounts, the more you purchase the more
you save. A family pack of soap powder or biscuits tends to cost less per
kg than smaller packs. This of course discriminates against people living
alone, often pensioners and students. In some supermarkets the price per
kg of product is listed, which helps the customer by providing information
on which to base decisions on.

Examples of 2nd degree price discriminators:


Electric utilities, cable companies, internet service providers, telephone
service providers.

45 of 38
46 of 38
THIRD DEGREE PRICE DISCRIMINATION

This is the most frequently found form of discrimination


and involves charging different prices for the same
product in different segments of the market. The market
is usually separated in two ways: by time or by
geography.

47 of 38
48 of 38
Examples of Price
Discrimination.
Book publisher having a cheap
international edition of a book.
Paperbacks.
Weekend movie shows
Lower priced tickets for morning
shows
Frequent Flyer Programs.

49
Two-Part Tariffs
Example: The gym charges a fee to join and then a
per usage fee.
Definition: A two-part tariff is a per unit fee, r, plus
a lump sum fee, F.

A fixed fee is charged (often with the justification of


it contributing to the fixed costs of supply) and then a
supplementary variable charge based on the
number of units consumed. There are plenty of
examples of this including taxi fares, amusement
park entrance charges and the fixed charges set by
the utilities (gas, water and electricity). Price
discrimination can come from varying the fixed
charge to different segments of the market and in
varying the charges on marginal units consumed (e.g.
discrimination by time).

50
Other forms of price discrimination

TYING (COMPLEMENTARY
GOODS)
Bundling (DIFFERENT FROM
TYING)

51 of 38
CONDITIONS FOR PRICE
DISCRIMINATION
Market Control: First and foremost, a seller must be able to control
the price. Monopoly is quite adept at price discrimination because it is
a price maker, it can set the price of the good. Oligopoly and
monopolistic competition can undertake price discrimination to the
extent that they are able to control the price. Perfect competition,
with no market control, does not do well in the price discrimination
arena.
Different Buyers: The second condition is that a seller must be able
to identify different groups of buyers, and each group must have a
different price elasticity of demand. The different price elasticity
means that buyers are willing and able to pay different prices for the
same good. If buyers have the same elasticity and are willing to pay
the same price, then price discrimination is pointless. The price
charged to each group is the same.
Segmented Buyers: Lastly, price discrimination requires that each
group of buyers be segmented and sealed into distinct markets.
Segmentation means that the buyers in one market cannot resell
the good to the buyers in another market. Price discriminate is
ineffective if trade among groups is possible. Those buyers charged a
higher price could simply purchase the good from those who purchase
it at a lower price.

52 of 38
Chapter 9

Pricing and Output


Decisions:
Monopolistic Competition
and Oligopoly

Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,


Chapter Nine 53
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Overview

Monopolistic competition
Oligopoly
Pricing under oligopoly
Competing in imperfectly
competitive markets
Strategy: the challenge for firms
in imperfect competition
Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,
Chapter Nine 54
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Learning objectives
contrast monopolistic competition
and oligopoly

describe the role that mutual


interdependence plays in setting
prices in oligopolistic markets

illustrate price rigidity using the


kinked demand curve
Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,
Chapter Nine 55
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Learning objectives
explain how non-price factors help
firms to differentiate their products
and services

understand the five forces in Porters


model of competition

Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,


Chapter Nine 56
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Introduction
Imperfect competition

some market power but not absolute


market power
firms have the ability to set prices within
the limits of certain constraints
mutual interdependence: interaction
among competitors when making
decisions
Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,
Chapter Nine 57
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Introduction
Perfect Monopoly Monopolistic Oligopoly
Competition Competition

Market power? No Yes* Yes Yes

Mutual interdependence No No No Yes


among competing
firms?

Non-price competition? No Optional Yes Yes

Easy market entry Yes No Yes No


or exit ?

* subject to government regulation

Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,


Chapter Nine 58
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Monopolistic competition
Monopolistic competition:
characteristics

many firms
relatively easy entry
product differentiation: can set price at
a level higher than the price established
by perfect competition
use MR = MC rule to maximize profit

Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,


Chapter Nine 59
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Monopolistic competition
If earning above-normal profits,
newcomers will enter the market

market supply curve shifts out and to


the right
firms demand curve shifts down and
to the left
ultimately, in the long run, firms earn
only normal profit

Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,


Chapter Nine 60
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Oligopoly
Oligopoly is a market dominated by a
relatively small number of large firms

Herfindahl-Hirschman index (HH)


measures market concentration (max HH =
10,000; unconcentrated markets have HH <
1,000) n
HH Si2
i 1

n = number of firms in the industry


Si = firms market share
Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,
Chapter Nine 61
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Pricing in an oligopolistic
market
Mutual interdependence:
relatively few sellers create a
situation where each is carefully
watching the others as it sets its
price

Implication: kinked demand


curve model Basic assumption is
that competitor will follow a price
decrease but will not make a change
Chapter Nine
Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
62
Pricing in an oligopolistic
market
If reduce price and
competitors match the Competitors do not
price cut then move match price increases
along more inelastic
demand segment Di Competitors
match
price cuts
If increase price and
competitors do not
follow then move
along the more elastic
segment Df

marginal revenue
curve has kink (at A)
Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,
Chapter Nine 63
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Pricing in an oligopolistic
market
Price leader: one firm in the industry
takes the lead in changing prices, and
assumes that other firms:
will follow a price increase
but will not go even lower in order not
to trigger a price war

Non-price leader: firm that leads the


differentiation of products on other, non-
price attributes
Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,
Chapter Nine 64
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Competing in imperfectly
competitive markets
Non-price competition: any effort made
by firms in order to change the demand for
their product (other than the price)

Non-price determinants of demand:


tastes and preferences
income
prices of substitutes and complements
number of buyers
future expectations of buyers
financing terms
Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,
Chapter Nine 65
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Competing in imperfectly
competitive markets
Examples: of efforts by managers to
influence non-price demand
influences:
advertising and promotion
location and distribution channels
market segmentation
loyalty programs
product extensions and new products
special customer services
product lock-in or tie-in
pre-emptive new product
announcements
Chapter Nine
Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,
66
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Competing in imperfectly
competitive markets
Equalizing at the margin: economic
concept which managers can use to help
make an optimal decision
eg MR = MC is an example of

equalizing at the margin


can be used to decide the optimal expenditure
level on a non-price factor
may occur over a long period of time
firm must adjust MR, MC for the time value of
money
Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,
Chapter Nine 67
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Competing in imperfectly
competitive markets

Examples: the reality of imperfect


competition

auto industry

small retailers

global credit card issuers


Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,
Chapter Nine 68
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Oligopoly
few firms
either homogeneous or differentiated products
interdependence of firms - policies of one firm affect the
other firms : conjectural variation
substantial barriers to entry
examples: auto industry and cigarette industry
Interdependence
The importance of interdependence
is that it leads to strategic behavior.

Strategic behavior is the behavior


that occurs when what is best for A
depends upon what B does, and what
is best for B depends upon what A
does.

Oligopolistic behavior includes both


Three Basic Models
Competition in quantities: Cournot-
Nash equilibrium
Competition in prices: Bertrand-Nash
equilibrium
Collusive oligopoly: Chamberlin notion
of conscious parallelism
It is very useful to know some basic
game theory to understand these
models as well as other oligopoly
models.
Collusion and Competition

Oligopoly firms may collude (act as a


monopoly) and earn positive profits.
OR
Oligopolists may compete with each
other and drive prices down to where
profits are zero.
While it pays for firms to collude, in
order to earn positive profits, it also
pays to cheat on the collusive
agreement. If one firm cuts its price
to slightly below the others, it could
gain a lot of business.
If everyone cheats on the agreement,
however, the agreement falls apart.
Collusive agreements less likely
to succeed when
secret price cuts are difficult and costly to detect.
(Quality changes are difficult to monitor.)
market conditions are unstable. (Differences in
expectations make it difficult to reach an
agreement.)
vigorous antitrust action increases the cost of
collusion .
Some oligopolistic markets operate in
a situation of price leadership.

A single firm sets industry price


and the remaining firms charge the
same price as the leader.
Sweezys kinked demand curve
model of oligopoly
Assumptions:
1. If a firm raises prices, other firms wont follow
and the firm loses a lot of business.
So demand is very responsive or elastic to
price increases.
2. If a firm lowers prices, other firms follow and
the firm doesnt gain much business.
So demand is fairly unresponsive or inelastic to
price decreases.
The Kinked Demand Curve

P*

D
Q quanti
* ty
MR Curve
for the top part of the Demand Curve
$
D
P*
MR

Q quanti
* ty
Drawing MR Curve
for the bottom part of the Demand Curve

P*
MR

D
Q* quanti
ty
MR Curve
for the bottom part of the Demand Curve

P*
MR

D
Q* quanti
ty
The Kinked Demand Curve
and the MR Curve
$

P*
MR

D
Q* quanti
ty
The MC curve intersects the MR curve
in the vertical segment.
$
MC
P*
MR

D
Q* quanti
ty
If costs shift up slightly, but MC still
intersects MR in the vertical segment,
there will be no
change in
$ MC price. This
MC price rigidity
is seen in real
P*
world
oligopoly
markets.
D
Q* MR quanti
ty
The ATC curve can be added to the graph.
To show positive profits, part of ATC curve
must lie under part of the demand curve.

$
MC ATC
P*

D
Q* MR quanti
ty
The ATC* value can be found on the
ATC curve above Q*.

$
MC ATC
P*
ATC*

D
Q* MR quanti
ty
TC = ATC . Q

$
MC ATC
P*
ATC*

Q* MR quantity
TR = P . Q

MC ATC

P*

Q* MR quantity
Profit = TR - TC

$
MC ATC
P* profit

ATC*

Q* MR quantity
To show a firm with a loss, the ATC curve must be entirely
above the demand curve.

ATC
$

MC AVC
ATC* loss

P*

Q* MR quantity
To show a firm breaking even, the ATC curve must
be tangent to the demand curve at the kink.

$
MC ATC
ATC*= P*

Q* MR quantity
Profit Possibilities for the
Oligopolist

short run:
positive profits, losses, or
breaking even.

long run:
positive profits, or breaking even
OLIGOPOLY

GAME THEORY

game theory Analyzes oligopolistic


behavior as a complex series of
strategic
moves and reactive countermoves
among rival firms. In game theory,
firms are
assumed to anticipate rival
reactions.

92 of 38
Introduction to game theory
We can look at market situations with two
players (typically firms)
Although we will look at situations where each
player can make only one of two decisions,
theory easily extends to three or more
decisions
John Nash, the person portrayed in A Beautiful
Mind
John Nash

One of the
early
researchers in
game theory
His work
resulted in a
form of
equilibrium
named after
Three elements in every
game
Players
Two or more for most games that are
interesting
Strategies available to each player
Payoffs
Based on your decision(s) and the decision(s)
of other(s)
Game theory: Payoff matrix
Person 2
A payoff
Action C Action D matrix
shows the
payout to
Action 10, 2 8, 3 each
Person
1
A player,
given the
Action 12, 4 10, 1 decision
B of each
player
How do we interpret this
box?

Person 2
The first number
in each box
Actio Actio determines the
nC nD payout for Person
Perso
n1 Actio 10, 2 8, 3 1
nA The second
Actio 12, 4 10, 1 number
nB determines the
payout for Person
2
How do we interpret this
box?

Person 2
Example
If Person 1 chooses
Actio Actio Action A and
nC nD Person 2 chooses
Perso
n1 Actio 10, 2 8, 3 Action D, then
nA Person 1 receives a
payout of 8 and
Actio 12, 4 10, 1
Person 2 receives a
nB
payout of 3
Back to a Core Principle:
Equilibrium
The type of equilibrium we are
looking for here is called Nash
equilibrium
Nash equilibrium: Any combination of
strategies in which each players strategy is
his or her best choice, given the other players
choices (F/B p. 322)
Exactly one person deviating from a NE
strategy would result in the same payout or
lower payout for that person
Steps 1 and 2
Person 2
Assume
Action Action D that you
C are Person
1
Perso
n1 Action 10, 2 8, 3 Given that
A Person 2
chooses
Action 12, 4 10, 1 Action C,
B what is
Person 1s
best
Step 3:
Person 2
Underline
Action Action D best payout,
C given the
choice of
Perso
the other
n1 Action 10, 2 8, 3 player
A Choose
Action B,
since
Action 12, 4 10, 1 12 > 10
B underline 12
Step 4
Person 2
Now
Action C Action assume
D that
Person 2
Perso
n1 Action 10, 2 8, 3 chooses
A Action D
Here,
Action 12, 4 10, 1 10 > 8
B Choose
and
underline
Step 5
Person 2
Now,
Action C Action D assume
you are
Person 2
Perso
Action 10, 2 8, 3 If Person 1
n1
chooses A
A 3>2
underline 3

Action 12, 4 10, 1 If Person 1


chooses B
B 4>1
underline 4
Step 6
Person 2
Which
Action C Action D box(es)
have
underlines
Perso
Action 10, 2 8, 3 under both
n1
A numbers?
Person 1
chooses B and
Person 2
Action 12, 4 10, 1 chooses C

B This is the only


NE
Dominant strategy
Person 2
A strategy is
Action C Action D dominant if
that choice is
definitely
Perso made no
n1 Action 10, 2 8, 3
matter what
A the other
person
Action 12, 4 10, 1 chooses
Example: Person 1
B has a dominant
strategy of choosing B
New example
Person 2
Suppose
Yes No in this
example
that two
Perso
n1 Yes 20, 20 5, 10 people are
simultane
ously
going to
No 10, 5 10, 10
decide on
this game
New example
Person 2
We will go
Yes No through the
same steps
to
Perso
n1 Yes 20, 20 5, 10 determine
NE

No 10, 5 10, 10
Two NE possible
Person 2
(Yes, Yes) and
Yes No (No, No) are
both NE
Although (Yes,
Perso Yes) is the
n1 Yes 20, 20 5, 10 more efficient
outcome, we
have no way
to predict
No 10, 5 10, 10 which
outcome will
actually occur
Two NE possible
When there are multiple NE that are
possible, economic theory tells us
little about which outcome occurs
with certainty
Prisoners Dilemma

A criminal, Bonnie is arrested by the


police
Thrown into prison
For three days, she is told nothing

.Then
Prisoners Dilemma

We have your friend Clyde and he is


starting to talk

Should Bonnie confess?


Prisoners Dilemma
Clyde
Confess Dont Confess
Bonnie

( -8, -8) ( 0, -15)


Confess

Dont Confess ( -15, 0) ( -1, -1)


Prisoners Dilemma
Clyde
Confess Dont Confess
Bonnie

( -8, -8) ( 0, -15)


Confess

Dont Confess ( -15, 0) ( -1, -1)


Prisoners Dilemma
Clyde
Confess Dont Confess
Bonnie

( -8, -8) ( 0, -15)


Confess

Dont Confess ( -15, 0) ( -1, -1)


Prisoners Dilemma

Conclusion:

Bonnie will confess

And Clyde?
Prisoners Dilemma
Clyde
Confess Dont Confess
Bonnie

( -8, -8) ( 0, -15)


Confess

Dont Confess ( -15, 0) ( -1, -1)


Prisoners Dilemma
Clyde
Confess Dont Confess
Bonnie

( -8, -8) ( 0, -15)


Confess

Dont Confess ( -15, 0) ( -1, -1)


Prisoners Dilemma

Conclusion:

Clyde confesses also

Both get 8 years, even though if they


cooperated, they could get off with one
year each

For both, confession is a dominant


strategy: a strategy that yields a better
outcome regardless of the opponents
choice
Identifying Dominant Strategies

Sometimes in a matrix game, a player will have a strategy


that, given all of the resulting outcomes, would not be worth
playing.

Such a strategy would not be worth playing if it is never


better and sometimes worse than some other strategy,
regardless of the strategies of other players.

For a given player, strategies that are never better and


sometimes worse than other strategies are called
dominated strategies. (We can think of this as equal or
worse than all of the other strategies.)

On the other hand, a dominant strategy is one that is


sometimes better and never worse than all other strategies,
regardless of the strategies of the other players. (We can
think of this as equal or better than all of the other
strategies.)
Example : Dominant Strategy
Company B
raise prices no change lower prices

raise prices 1,1 1,-1 2,0

Company A no change 0,1 0,0 -1,1

lower prices -1,1 1,0 -1,-1

Suppose two companies face each other in a competitive market.


Suppose each has three strategies, as shown above, and the payoffs,
representing profits in hundreds of thousands of dollars for a given
year, are as given in the table.
Notice that, in this example, both companies have dominant strategies
of raising prices. Because both players have dominant strategies,
these form the equilibrium point of the game.
A game in which potential payoffs to each player is the same is a
symmetric game. Because potential payoffs are different in this game,
it is an example of a nonsymmetrical game.
Example : Dominant Strategy

Company B
raise prices no change lower prices

raise prices 0,0 -1,1 -1,2

Company no change 0,1 0,0 0,1


A
lower prices 2,-1 1,-1 0,0

This is an example of a symmetric game. Potential payoffs to each


player are the same.

Both players have dominant strategies in lowering prices. So the


combination of both strategies is an equilibrium point.
Prisoners Dilemma
What would they both decide if they could
negotiate?

They could both become better off if they


reached the cooperative solution.
which is why police interrogate suspects in
separate rooms.

Equilibrium need not be efficient.


Noncooperative equilibrium in the
Prisoners dilemma results in a solution
that is not the best possible outcome for
the parties.
Equilibrium

Nash Equilibrium: Neither player


has an incentive to change strategy,
given the other players choice
Both confess is a Nash Equilibrium

Both dont confess is not a Nash


Equilibrium, rival will always want to renege
OLIGOPOLY

FIGURE 14.6 Payoff Matrix for


Advertising Game
125 of 38
OLIGOPOLY

maximin strategy In game theory,


a strategy chosen to maximize the
minimum gain that can be earned.

126 of 38
OLIGOPOLY
REPEATED GAMES

retaliation strategy A companys


strategy that lets a competitor know
the company
will follow the competitors lead.

FIGURE 14.9 Payoff Matrix for


Airline Game 127 of 38
Chapter 10

Special Pricing Policies

Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,


Chapter Ten 128
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Overview
Cartel arrangements
Price leadership
Revenue maximization
Price discrimination
Nonmarginal pricing
Multiproduct pricing
Transfer pricing
Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,
Chapter Ten 129
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Learning objectives

analyze cartel pricing

illustrate price leadership

see how price discrimination affects


output and prices

Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,


Chapter Ten 130
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Learning objectives

distinguish between marginal pricing


and cost-plus pricing

discuss the various types of


multiproduct pricing

explain how a company can use


transfer pricing

Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,


Chapter Ten 131
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Cartel arrangements
A cartel is an arrangement where
firms in an industry cooperate and
act together as if they were a
monopoly

cartel arrangements may be tacit or


formal
illegal in the US: Sherman Antitrust
Act, 1890
examples: OPEC, IATA
Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,
Chapter Ten 132
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Cartel arrangements
Conditions that influence the
formation of cartels
small number of large firms in the
industry
geographical proximity of the firms
homogeneous products that do not
allow differentiation
stage of the business cycle
difficult entry into industry
uniform cost conditions, usually defined
by product homogeneity
Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,
Chapter Ten 133
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Cartel arrangements
In order to maximize profits, the cartel as
a whole should behave as a monopolist
the cartel determines the output which
equates MR = MC of the cartel as a whole
the MC of the cartel as a whole is the
horizontal summation of the members
marginal cost curves
price is set in the normal monopoly
way, by determining quantity demanded
where MC=MR and deriving P from the
demand curve at that Q

Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,


Chapter Ten 134
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Cartel arrangements

MCT is the horizontal sum of MCI and MCII


QT is found at the intersection of MRT and MCT
price is found from the demand curve at QT
this is the price that maximizes total industry
profits

Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,


Chapter Ten 135
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Cartel arrangements

to determine how much each firm should produce, draw a


horizontal line back from the MRT/MCT intersection
where this line intersects each individual firms MC
determines that firms output, QI and QII. Note that the
firms may produce different outputs
Key point: the MC of the last unit produced is equated
across both firms

Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,


Chapter Ten 136
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Cartel arrangements

Profits for each firm are shown as rectangles in blue

Firms may earn different levels of profit, though


combined profits are maximized
Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,
Chapter Ten 137
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Cartel arrangements
Problem: incentive for firms to cheat
on agreement, thus cartels are
unstable

Additional costs facing the cartel


formation costs
monitoring costs
enforcement costs
cost of punishment by authorities
weigh the benefits against these
Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,
costs
Chapter Ten
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
138
Cartel arrangements
Examples: price fixing by cartels

GE, Westinghouse
Archer Daniels Midland Company
Sothebys, Christies
Roche Holding AG, BASF AG

Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,


Chapter Ten 139
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Price leadership
Barometric price leadership

one firm in an industry will initiate a


price change in response to economic
conditions
the other firms may or may not follow
this leader
leader may vary

Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,


Chapter Ten 140
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Price leadership
Dominant price leadership

one firm is the industry leader


dominant firm sets price with the
realization that the smaller firms will
follow and charge the same price
can force competitors out of business or
buy them out under favorable terms
could result in investigation under
Sherman Anti-Trust Act
Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,
Chapter Ten 141
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Price leadership
DT = demand curve
for entire industry

MCD = marginal cost of


the dominant firm

MCR = summation of
MC of follower firms
in setting price,
dominant firm must
consider the amount
supplied by all firms
Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,
Chapter Ten 142
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Loss leadership pricing
retailers set very low price below
cost
this is done to capture large
customer base
retailer make up loss by charging
higher price in other items or
services
this strategy is used by large
multinationals who have deep
pockets to retain market share
Chapter Ten
Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
143
Loss leadership pricing

Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,


Chapter Ten 144
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Loss leadership pricing
Example:

Tata Motors offer low of basic small car


Nano to low income buyers
selling higher-end model to wealthy
customers to recoup loss for lower-end
model

Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,


Chapter Ten 145
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Price leadership

Demand curve facing


the dominant firm is
found by subtracting
MCR from DT
dominant firm
equates its MC with
MR from its residual
demand curve DD
the dominant firm
sells A units and the
rest of the demand (QT
A) is supplied by the
follower firms
Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,
Chapter Ten 146
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Revenue maximization
Baumol model: firms maximize revenue
(not profit) subject to maintaining a
specific level of profits
Rationale
a firm will become more competitive when it
achieves a large size
management remuneration may be related
to revenue not profits
Implication: unlike the profit maximization
case, a change in fixed costs will alter
price and output (by raising the cost curve
and lowering the profit line)
Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,
Chapter Ten 147
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Price discrimination
Price discrimination: products with
identical costs are sold in different
markets at different prices
the ratio of price to marginal cost
differs for similar products

Conditions for price discrimination


the markets in which the products are sold
must by separated (no resale between
markets)
the demand curves in the market must have
different elasticities
Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,
Chapter Ten 148
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Price discrimination
First degree price discrimination

seller can identify where each consumer


lies on the demand curve and charges
each consumer the highest price the
consumer is willing to pay
allows the seller to extract the greatest
amount of profits
requires a considerable amount of
information
Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,
Chapter Ten 149
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Price discrimination
Second degree price discrimination

differential prices charged by blocks of


services
requires metering of services consumed
by buyers

Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,


Chapter Ten 150
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Price discrimination
Third degree price discrimination
customers are segregated into different
markets and charged different prices in
each
segmentation can be based on any
characteristic such as age, location,
gender, income, etc

Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,


Chapter Ten 151
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Price discrimination

Third degree discrimination:


assume the firm operates in two markets, A and B
the demand in market A is less elastic than the demand in
market B
the entire market faced by the firm is described by the horizontal
sum of the demand and marginal revenue curves

Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,


Chapter Ten 152
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Price discrimination

the firm finds the total amount to produce by equating the


marginal revenue and marginal cost in the market as a whole: QT
if the firm were forced to charge a uniform price, it would find the
price by examining the aggregate demand DT at the output level
QT
the firm can increase its profits by charging a different price in
each market

Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,


Chapter Ten 153
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Price discrimination

in order to find the optimum price to charge in each market, draw


a horizontal line back from the MRT/MCT intersection
where this line intersects each submarkets MR curve determines
the amount that should be sold in each market: QA and QB
these quantities are then used to determine the price in each
market using the demand curves DA and DB

Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,


Chapter Ten 154
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Price discrimination

Examples of price discrimination

doctors

telephone calls

theaters

hotel industry
Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,
Chapter Ten 155
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Price discrimination
Tying arrangement: a buyer of one
product is obligated to also by a
related product from the same supplier

illegal in some cases


one explanation: a device to meter
demand for tied product
other explanations of tying
quality control
efficiencies in distribution
evasion of price controls
Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,
Chapter Ten 156
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Nonmarginal pricing
Cost-plus pricing: price is set by first
calculating the variable cost, adding an
allocation for fixed costs, and then
adding a profit percentage or markup

Problems with cost-plus pricing


calculation of average variable cost
allocation of fixed cost
size of the markup
Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,
Chapter Ten 157
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Nonmarginal pricing
Incremental pricing (and costing)
analysis: deals with changes in total
revenue and total cost resulting from a
decision to change prices or product
Features:
incremental, similar to marginal analysis
only revenues and costs that will change due
to the decision are considered
examples of product change: new product,
discontinue old product, improve a product,
capital equipment
Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,
Chapter Ten 158
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Multiproduct pricing
When the firm produces two or more
products

Case 1: products are complements in terms


of demand an increase in the quantity
sold of one will bring about an increase in
the quantity sold of the other
Case 2: products are substitutes in terms of
demand an increase in the quantity
sold of one will bring about a decrease in
the quantity sold of the other
Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,
Chapter Ten 159
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Multiproduct pricing
When the firm produces two or more
products

Case 3: products are joined in


production
products produced from one set of inputs

Case 4: products compete for


resources using resources to
produce one product takes those
resources away from producing other
Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,

products
Chapter Ten 160
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Transfer pricing
Internal pricing: as the product moves
through these divisions on the way to the
consumer it is sold or transferred from one
division to another at a transfer price

Rationale:
firm subdivided into divisions, each may be
charged with a profit objective
without any coordination, the final price of
the product to consumers may not maximize
profits for the firm as a whole
Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,
Chapter Ten 161
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Transfer pricing

Design of the optimal transfer


pricing mechanism is complicated
by the fact that

each division may be able to sell its


product in external markets as well as
internally
each division may be able to procure
inputs from external markets as well
as internally
Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,
Chapter Ten 162
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Transfer pricing
Case A: no external markets
no division can buy from or sell to an
external market
the selling division will produce exactly
the number of components that will be
used by the purchasing division
one demand curve and two MC curves
MC curves are summed vertically
set production where MR = Total MC

Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,


Chapter Ten 163
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Transfer pricing
Case B: external markets
divisions have the opportunity to buy or
sell in outside competitive markets
if selling division prices above the
external market price, the buying
division will buy from outside
if selling division cannot produce enough
to satisfy buying division demand, the
buying division will buy additional units
from the external market
Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,
Chapter Ten 164
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Other pricing practices
Price skimming
the first firm to introduce a product may
have a temporary monopoly and may be
able to charge high prices and obtain
high profits until competition enters

Penetration pricing
selling at a low price in order to obtain
market share
Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,
Chapter Ten 165
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Other pricing practices
Prestige pricing
demand for a product may be higher at
a higher price because of the prestige
that ownership bestows on the owner

Psychological pricing
demand for a product may be quite
inelastic over a certain range but will
become rather elastic at one specific
higher or lower price
Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,
Chapter Ten 166
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Global application
Example: decline of European cartels

carton-board
vitamin
copper pipe
elevator operators

Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,


Chapter Ten 167
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Chapter 11

Game Theory
and
Asymmetric Information

Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,


Chapter Eleven 168
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Overview

Game theory
Game theory and auctions
Strategy and game theory

Asymmetric information
Reputation
Standardization
Market signaling
Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,
Chapter Eleven 169
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Learning objectives
apply game theory to mutually
interdependent business decisions

explain the game called Prisoners


Dilemma

use the concept of a dominant


strategy to show how auctions can
help improve the price for sellers,
while still benefiting buyers
Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,
Chapter Eleven 170
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Learning objectives
analyze asymmetric information

understand the concepts of adverse


selection and moral hazard

explain how market signaling can


help agents make better economic
decisions when asymmetric
information exists
Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,
Chapter Eleven 171
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Game theory
Economic optimization has two
shortcomings when applied to actual
business situations

assumes factors such as reaction of


competitors or tastes and preferences of
consumers remain constant

managers sometimes make decisions


when other parties have more
information about market conditions
Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,
Chapter Eleven 172
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Game theory

Game theory: is concerned with


how individuals make decisions
when they are aware that their
actions affect each other and when
each individual takes this into
account

Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,


Chapter Eleven 173
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Game theory
Fundamental aspects of game theory
players are interdependent
uncertainty: other players actions are
not entirely predictable

Types of games
zero-sum or non-zero-sum
cooperative or non-cooperative
two-person or n-person

Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,


Chapter Eleven 174
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Games in economics
Prisoners Dilemma
two-person, non-zero-
sum, non-cooperative
always has a dominant
strategy
equilibrium is stable

confessing is dominant
strategy for each player,
no matter what other
player chooses

each player has no


incentive to unilaterally
change his strategy

Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,


Chapter Eleven 175
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Games in economics
Oligopoly pricing using
prisoners dilemma

(Low/Low) is a stable
equilibrium no
incentive for either firm
to deviate

better off at (High/High)


but it is not stable
each firm has an
incentive to deviate

(High/High) would be an
equilibrium if the
firms were allowed to
cooperate Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,
Chapter Eleven 176
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Games in economics
Example: Beach Kiosk Game: a two-
person, zero-sum, non-cooperative
game

Suppose two companies provide snacks and


sunscreen on a beach
beachgoers will spread themselves out
evenly along the beach
both companies ultimately locate at the
midpoint of the beach, otherwise the other
company has an advantage (closer to more
beachgoers

Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,


Real life example:
Chapter Eleven
location
Inc. Publishing of gas stations
as Prentice Hall.
177
Games in economics
Repeated Game: game is played
repeatedly over a period of time

in a perpetual repeated game, equilibria


that are not stable may become stable due
to the threat of retaliation

however, if number of periods is fixed,


players will have incentive to cheat in the
last period due to lack of threat of
retaliation, which will then allow them to
cheat in all periods
Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,
Chapter Eleven 178
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Games in economics
Example: assume (High, High) equilibrium reached
and both firms start off charging the high price

in the next period, if one firm cheats (charges low


price), it receives 600 in that period

other firm will change to low prices in the next


period to retaliate and both will end up at (Low,
Low) equilibrium

thus, incentive exists not to cheat in a perpetual


repeated game and (High, High) is a viable
equilibrium (unlike in the short game)

Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,


Chapter Eleven 179
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Games in economics
Simultaneous games are games in
which players make their strategy
choices at the same time

Sequential games are games in


which players make their decisions
sequentially

In sequential games, the first mover


may have an advantage
Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,
Chapter Eleven 180
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Games in economics
Consider the following payoff matrix in which firms choose
their capacity, either high or low. Suppose firm C has the
ability to move first

C would choose Low, then D would choose High

Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,


Chapter Eleven 181
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Game theory and auctions
Dutch auction (a non-cooperative, non-zero-sum
game):
each buyer describes the quantity
demanded and price to pay
starting at highest price, sum quantity
demanded up to the supply available
all product is sold at the highest price
that clears the market
Seller wants to sell at highest price, buyer wants
to buy at lowest price

Solution: every players dominant strategy is to


bid as late as possible
Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,
Chapter Eleven 182
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Strategy and game theory
Problem: in Prisoners Dilemma, players
have a dominant strategy that leads to
suboptimal results

Commitment, explicit or implicit, can be


used to achieve preferred outcomes. It
must be credible:
burn bridges behind you
establish and use a reputation
write contracts

Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,


Chapter Eleven 183
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Strategy and game theory

Incentives also can be used to change the


game to achieve preferred outcomes

Illustration: GM card. GM came up with a


strategy where customers could apply
5% of their purchases to a GM vehicle

Illustration: Health insurance. Firms


provide a menu of care levels.
Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,
Chapter Eleven 184
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Strategy and game theory

PARTS: paradigm for studying a situation,


predicting players actions, making
strategic decisions
Players: Who are players and what are their
goals?
Added Value: What do the different players
contribute to the pie?
Rules: What is the form of competition? Time
structure of the game?
Tactics: What options are open to the players?
Commitments? Incentives?
Scope: What are the boundaries of the game?
Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,
Chapter Eleven 185
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Asymmetric information
Asymmetric information: market
situation in which one party in a
transaction has more information
than the other party. Leads to many
problems in markets:
too much or too little production
difficult contracting
possible fraud
market may disappear
Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,
Chapter Eleven 186
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Asymmetric information
Adverse selection: prior to
transaction, one party may know
more about the value of a good than
the other

Example: lemons (bad used


cars) seller knows the vehicle well,
but buyer does not, yet market does
not divide in two
Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,
Chapter Eleven 187
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Asymmetric information
Moral Hazard: transaction changes
the incentives of a party because it
cannot be monitored after the
transaction

Example: insurance industry ...


poor information takes place after
the sale, not before

Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,


Chapter Eleven 188
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Asymmetric Information
Market responses:

obtaining information from third


parties
relying on reputation of the seller
standardization of products
market signaling: demonstrated
success in one activity provides
information about success/quality in
Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,
Chapter Eleven 189
another Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Asymmetric Information

Example: education as a signal

attending college demonstrates certain


traits
employers see this a screening device

Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,


Chapter Eleven 190
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Asymmetric Information

Example: warranties

more costly on low quality goods than


high quality goods
consumers see them as a screening
device

Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,


Chapter Eleven 191
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Asymmetric Information

Example: banking systems

banks know less about the borrowers


ability to repay than the customer
arms length banking: US
relationship banking: Japan

Copyright 2011 Pearson Education,


Chapter Eleven 192
Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
Price and Output Decisions in Pure Monopoly Markets

The Absence of a Supply Curve in Monopoly

A monopoly firm has no supply curve that is independent of the


demand curve for its product.

A monopolist sets both price and quantity, and the amount of


output that it supplies depends on both its marginal cost curve
and the demand curve that it faces.
A monopoly does not necessarily supply larger quantities at
higher prices or smaller quantities at lower prices.

193 of 38
Price and Output Decisions in Pure Monopoly Markets

Monopoly in the Long Run: Barriers to Entry

barriers to entry Factors that


prevent new firms from entering
and competing in imperfectly
competitive industries.

natural monopoly An industry


that realizes such large
economies of scale in producing
its product that single-firm
production of that good or service
is most efficient.

194 of 38
Price and Output Decisions in Pure Monopoly Markets

Monopoly in the Long Run: Barriers to Entry

Economies of Scale
FIGURE 13.8 A
Natural Monopoly

A natural monopoly is a firm in


which the most efficient scale is
very large. The fixed cost is very
high. Here, average total cost
declines until a single firm is
producing nearly the entire amount
demanded in the market. With one
firm producing 500,000 units,
average total cost is $1 per unit.
With five firms each producing
100,000 units, average total cost is
$5 per unit.

195 of 38
Price and Output Decisions in Pure Monopoly Markets

Monopoly in the Long Run: Barriers to Entry

Patents
patent A barrier to entry that
grants exclusive use of the
patented product or process to
the inventor.
Government Rules

Ownership of a Scarce Factor of Production

196 of 38

Anda mungkin juga menyukai