Anda di halaman 1dari 42

International Review of Financial Analysis 75 (2021) 101751

Daftar isi tersedia di situs ScienceDirect

International Review of Financial Analysis

jurnal: www.elsevier.com/locate/irfa

Dampak intervensi pemegang saham terhadap investasi berlebihan arus


kas bebas oleh CEO yang terlalu percaya diri
Sewon Kwon a, Jae Hwan Ahn b,*
, Gi H. Kim c
a
School of Business, Ewha Womans University, 03760, Korea Selatan
b
Lancaster University Management School, Lancaster University, LA1 4YX, UK
c
Warwick Business School, University of Warwick, CV4 7AL, UK
FCF, 2)
Kami menguji dampak intervensi pemegang saham pada distorsi
ARTIKEL INFO investasi, yang kami tangkap menggunakan overinvestasi arus kas
bebas (FCF) oleh CEO yang terlalu percaya diri. Sementara
Klasifikasi JEL: sensitivitas arus kas investasi-positif (selanjutnya ICFS) sering
G3 dianggap mewakili distorsi investasi (Jensen, 1986), Malmendier dan
M4 Tate (2005) berpendapat bahwa ICFS perusahaan yang dikelola oleh
Kata kunci: CEO yang terlalu percaya diri lebih cenderung merupakan
Investasi- sensitivitas arus kas CEO terlalu percaya diri
distorsi investasi. Ini karena ICFS yang positif dapat diamati bahkan
Arus kas bebas
Distorsi investasi
ketika insentif diselaraskan dengan sempurna antara pemegang saham
dan CEO dan, dalam kasus seperti itu, investasi FCF yang berlebihan
Intervensi pemegang saham 1. Pendahuluan
tidak serta-merta menangkap distorsi investasi.1 Namun, ICFS positif
dari perusahaan dengan CEO yang terlalu percaya diri menunjukkan
investasi yang terdistorsi karena bias sistematis manajer. Terlepas dari
volume besar literatur tentang tata kelola pemegang saham
ABSTRAK sehubungan dengan investasi berlebih, hampir tidak ada literatur yang
berfokus pada dampaknya terhadap keputusan investasi oleh CEO
Makalah ini membahas dampak intervensi pemegang saham terhadap distorsi yang terlalu percaya diri.2 Makalah kami mengisi celah ini.
investasi, yang kami tangkap dengan menggunakan investasi berlebih dari arus
Untuk mengatasi dampak yang berpotensi berbeda pada investasi
kas bebas oleh CEO yang terlalu percaya diri. Menggunakan definisi ini dan data
AS untuk 1996–2014, efek tetap dan hasil estimasi pencocokan
perbedaan-dalam-perbedaan kami memberikan bukti yang konsisten bahwa
ancaman intervensi potensial dari pemegang saham dapat mengekang investasi berlebih, * Penulis yang sesuai.
berlebihan oleh CEO yang terlalu percaya diri. Secara khusus, perusahaan
dengan voting premium dan aktivisme hedge fund yang lebih besar mengalami
lebih sedikit investasi berlebih dan menunjukkan sensitivitas arus kas bebas yang
lebih rendah terhadap investasi. Efek pendisiplinan seperti itu lebih kuat untuk FCF CEO-positif yang tidak terlalu percaya diri, 3) FCF CEO-negatif
perusahaan yang dikelola oleh CEO yang terlalu percaya diri. Secara yang terlalu percaya diri, dan 4) FCF CEO-negatif yang tidak terlalu
keseluruhan, hasil kami menunjukkan bahwa intervensi pemegang saham sangat percaya diri. Kemudian, untuk setiap sub sampel, kami menguji
efektif dalam mengurangi investasi berlebih yang lebih mungkin terdistorsi. hubungan antara intervensi pemegang saham dan investasi berlebih.
Dalam melakukannya, kami menggunakan dua variabel sebagai proxy
untuk ancaman intervensi pemegang saham, yaitu, voting premium dan
aktivisme hedge fund, dan ukuran investasi berlebih yang diusulkan
oleh Richardson (2006).3 Fokus utama kami adalah subsampel (1),
disebut sebagai subsampel investasi terdistorsi .
Pilihan tindakan intervensi pemegang saham sangat penting dalam
jenis studi ini. Studi awal dalam literatur menggunakan kehadiran
pemegang saham yang berpengaruh dan/atau canggih sebagai proxy
untuk suara pemegang saham (misalnya, Bushee, 1998; Graves,
1988). Namun, penelitian yang lebih baru telah menyarankan tindakan
yang relatif kurang bising dan lebih langsung. Misalnya, Kalay, Karakas,
dan Pant (2014) mengusulkan nilai pasar dari ukuran premium voting.
kami membagi sampel kami menjadi empat subsampel yang berbeda Premi pemungutan suara diperkirakan dengan mengambil selisih
dengan tingkat yang berbeda
antara harga saham dengan hak suara dansintetis
dari CEO terlalu percaya diri dan FCF: 1) terlalu percaya diri CEO-positif

alamat e-mail: k4js1@ewha.ac.kr (S. Kwon), jhahn@lancaster.ac.uk (JH Ahn), gi. kim@wbs.ac.uk (GH Kim).
1
“Di bawah informasi asimetris, para manajer itu sendiri (yang bertindak demi kepentingan pemegang saham) membatasi pembiayaan eksternal untuk
menghindari menipisnya (undervalued) saham perusahaan mereka. Dalam hal ini, arus kas meningkatkan investasi, tetapi mengurangi distorsi” (Malmendier & Tate,
2005, p. 2662). 2 Huang dkk. (2011) adalah pengecualian. Menggunakan data Cina, penulis berpendapat bahwa ICFS yang terkait dengan CEO yang terlalu
percaya diri terutama disebabkan oleh masalah agensi.
3
Perubahan abnormal dalam investasi baru setelah tidak termasuk depresiasi dan amortisasi.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.irfa.2021.101751
Diterima 19 Desember 2019; Diterima dalam bentuk revisi 13 Februari 2021; Diterima 25 Maret 2021
Tersedia online 30 Maret 2021
1057-5219/© 2021 Elsevier Inc. Semua hak dilindungi undang-undang.
S.Kwon dkk. klasifikasi sampel yang disebutkan di atas, kami menemukan bahwa
premi pemungutan suara terkait secara negatif dengan investasi
harga saham tanpa hak suara. Selisih tersebut mewakili harga yang berlebih hanya pada subsampel investasi yang terdistorsi. Karena nilai
bersedia dibayar oleh pemegang saham untuk menggunakan hak rata-rata overinvestment dalam subsampel ini adalah positif, hasilnya
suara mereka, dan ini menunjukkan keterlibatan aktif pemegang saham menyiratkan bahwa intervensi pemegang saham
dalam proses pemungutan suara. Ac menurut Kalay et al. (2014) dan
Lin, Tsai, Hasan, dan Tuan (2018), terdapat variasi time series dan
cross-sectional dalam pemilihan premi. Ini lebih besar ketika pemegang
4
saham akan menggunakan hak suara mereka (misalnya, di sekitar Di AS, SEC mengharuskan investor untuk mengajukan Jadwal 13D ketika
rapat pemegang saham atau selama kontes kontrol), dan bervariasi kepemilikan saham mereka melebihi 5% dari kelas saham mana pun di
perusahaan publik, dan ketika mereka berusaha untuk mempengaruhi kontrol
secara sistematis di seluruh perusahaan. Dalam analisis kami, variasi
pada perusahaan target (Brav et al., 2008).
dalam premi pemungutan suara menyiratkan bahwa pemegang saham 5
Kami berterima kasih kepada Alon Brav karena dengan murah hati
di seluruh perusahaan tidak menghargai hak suara mereka secara
membagikan data mereka tentang pengarsipan 13D dengan kami.
setara. Besarnya variasi pada dasarnya adalah ukuran keterlibatan aktif Tinjauan Internasional Analisis Keuangan 75 (2021) 101751
pemegang saham perusahaan.
Kami juga menggunakan aktivisme hedge fund sebagai ukuran secara efektif mengurangi tingkat investasi berlebih dari perusahaan
alternatif intervensi pemegang saham. Brav, Jiang, Partnoy, dan dengan FCF positif dan CEO yang terlalu percaya diri. Menariknya, dan
Thomas (2008) mengusulkan aktivisme hedge fund sebagai proxy konsisten dengan hipotesis ancaman disiplin, efek jera ini tetap ada
untuk pemantauan pemegang saham yang aktif dan terinformasi. bahkan setelah kami secara eksplisit mengecualikan efek dari peristiwa
Penulis secara manual mengumpulkan semua Jadwal 13D yang pemungutan suara yang sebenarnya, kontes kontrol, dan litigasi
diajukan oleh aktivis hedge fund yang secara eksplisit berusaha pemegang saham.
mempengaruhi kontrol di perusahaan target,4 tidak termasuk kasus di Menggunakan sampel aktivisme hedge fund dan estimator
mana investor pasif atau non-hedge fund lainnya memegang lebih dari pencocokan perbedaan-dalam-perbedaan (DID), kami juga
5% saham. Deklarasi eksplisit mereka untuk mempengaruhi menunjukkan bahwa distorsi investasi oleh CEO yang terlalu percaya
perusahaan target menunjukkan bahwa aktivis hedge fund memiliki diri berkurang ketika perusahaan berada di bawah ancaman aktivisme
insentif yang lebih kuat untuk mengambil peran yang lebih aktif dalam hedge fund. Secara khusus, kami menemukan koefisien negatif untuk
memantau investasi perusahaan. istilah interaksi rangkap tiga kami (di antara aktivisme hedge fund,
Kami membangun prediksi empiris kami berdasarkan pasar yang variabel "pasca", dan FCF), yang pada dasarnya menunjukkan
efisien dan hipotesis ancaman disiplin. Teori-teori ini mengasumsikan pengurangan ICFS setelah aktivisme hedge fund (yaitu, pengajuan
bahwa pemegang saham melakukan intervensi secara efektif untuk 13D), hanya untuk orang yang terlalu percaya diri. subsampel CEO.
mengurangi investasi suboptimal dengan memproses semua informasi Atau, dengan menggunakan empat klasifikasi sampel yang disebutkan
yang relevan, dan bahwa manajer menganggap suara pemegang di atas
saham sebagai ancaman yang kredibel untuk melibatkan perusahaan , kami menemukan koefisien negatif yang signifikan untuk jangka waktu
dalam kontes proxy yang mahal. Dengan demikian kami berhipotesis interaksi ganda kami (antara aktivisme dana lindung nilai dan variabel
bahwa jika semuanya tetap sama, premi pemungutan suara yang lebih pos), yang menangkap pengurangan investasi berlebih pasca
besar secara negatif terkait dengan distorsi investasi, dan distorsi pengarsipan 13D. Hubungan
investasi akan berkurang dengan kedatangan aktivis hedge fund. ini juga diamati hanya pada subsampel investasi yang terdistorsi.
Namun, kami tidak memprediksi efek serupa dari intervensi pemegang Selanjutnya, kami berusaha untuk mengurangi kekhawatiran atas
saham ketika investasi berlebih bukan merupakan manifestasi dari asumsi kami bahwa ICFS perusahaan yang dikelola oleh CEO yang
distorsi investasi karena, dalam hal ini, CEO tidak akan merasa terlalu percaya diri menangkap potensi distorsi vestasi. Jika
terancam oleh suara pemegang saham. perusahaan dalam subsampel investasi terdistorsi menghasilkan
Untuk menguji hipotesis pendisiplinan kami, kami menggunakan kinerja keuangan ex post yang baik (misalnya, ROA), pemegang
dua sampel berbeda. Yang pertama terdiri dari file gabungan saham tidak perlu mengekang investasi berlebih tersebut, dan kami
Compustat, Execucomp, CRSP, dan OptionMetrics, yang menghasilkan mungkin tidak dapat mendefinisikan subsampel ini sebagai potensi
8346 pengamatan tahun perusahaan untuk periode 1996–2014 setelah distorsi investasi. Namun, dengan menggunakan pendekatan sistem
mengecualikan nilai yang hilang (selanjutnya, sampel premium generalized method of moment (GMM) dan regresi Fama MacBeth,
pemungutan suara). Kami memilih sampel ini untuk memperkirakan kami menemukan bahwa investasi berlebih secara negatif terkait
premi pemungutan suara dengan menggunakan data perdagangan dengan kinerja perusahaan baik dalam jangka pendek maupun jangka
derivatif dari OptionMetrics. Yang kedua adalah file gabungan dari panjang, tetapi sebagian besar dalam subsampel investasi kami yang
pengajuan Compustat, Execucomp, CRSP, dan 13D yang disusun oleh terdistorsi. Sebaliknya, investasi berlebih pada subsampel lain tidak
Brav, Jiang, Ma, dan Tian (2018).5 Dalam sampel ini, kami tidak menyebabkan kinerja yang buruk secara konsisten. Temuan ini
menggunakan variabel premium voting, sehingga tidak mengharuskan memberikan dukungan untuk klasifikasi kami tentang potensi distorsi
perusahaan dimasukkan dalam OptionMetrics karena persyaratan ini investasi.
mengurangi ukuran sampel kami. Sebagai gantinya, untuk mengurangi Secara keseluruhan, kami menafsirkan temuan kami sebagai
perbedaan sistematis dalam karakteristik perusahaan yang dapat menyiratkan bahwa intervensi pemegang saham tidak secara seragam
diamati antara target aktivis dan non-target, kami memilih 354 menghalangi semua jenis investasi berlebih, tetapi ini sangat efektif
pasangan yang cocok (2173 pengamatan tahun perusahaan) untuk untuk mengurangi distorsi investasi, yaitu, investasi berlebihan karena
1996–2014 berdasarkan probabilitas ex ante dari pengajuan 13D terlalu percaya diri CEO. Kami juga menunjukkan bahwa efek
(selanjutnya, dana lindung nilai contoh aktivis). Dalam semua analisis, intervensi pemegang saham yang bertindak sebagai ancaman yang
kami menangkap overinvestment, FCF, dan CEO terlalu percaya diri kredibel bagi CEO secara signifikan meningkat dibandingkan dengan
dengan mengadopsi kerangka kerja yang diusulkan oleh Richardson peristiwa pemungutan suara yang sebenarnya, kontes kontrol, dan
(2006) dan Malmendier dan Tate (2005). litigasi pemegang saham.
Dengan menggunakan sampel premi pemungutan suara dan penaksir Studi kami membuat kontribusi yang berbeda untuk literatur yang
efek tetap, kami menunjukkan bahwa premi pemungutan suara ada. Pertama, didasarkan pada penelitian yang mengeksplorasi
mengurangi distorsi investasi oleh CEO yang terlalu percaya diri. penyebab (misalnya, Fazzari, Hubbard, Petersen, Blinder, & Poterba,
Pertama, ketika kita melakukan regresi overinvestment pada istilah 1988; Kaplan & Zingales, 1997) dan faktor-faktor yang meringankan
interaksi antara FCF dan voting premium, ini membawa koefisien (misalnya, Pawlina & Renneboog, 2005; Richardson, 2006) dari ICFS.
negatif yang signifikan hanya untuk subsampel CEO yang terlalu Seperti disebutkan sebelumnya, ICFS tradisional tidak selalu
percaya diri, menunjukkan ICFS yang berkurang untuk perusahaan menangkap distorsi investasi, tetapi perusahaan yang dikelola oleh
semacam itu. Sebagai alternatif, dengan menggunakan empat CEO yang terlalu percaya diri lebih mungkin untuk melakukannya.
Namun, sejak Malmendier dan Tate (2005), hampir tidak ada penelitian empiris tentang topik ini dan interpretasinya telah dicampur, setidaknya
yang berfokus pada tipe ICFS yang unik ini.6 Sejauh pengetahuan sebagian karena ambiguitas definisi distorsi investasi
kami, makalah ini adalah yang pertama secara eksplisit . Misalnya, satu untaian penelitian menunjukkan bahwa pemantauan
mengeksplorasi faktor-faktor yang mengurangi distorsi investasi pemegang saham yang terinformasi efektif untuk mengurangi masalah
Malmendier dan Tate (2005) . Secara khusus, sementara Richardson
(2006) memberikan beberapa bukti bahwa pemegang saham aktivis
mengurangi investasi berlebih menggunakan ICFS tradisional, 6
Sebaliknya, penelitian telah menyelidiki terlalu percaya diri CEO dalam
penelitian ini melengkapi temuannya dengan mendokumentasikan konteks lain. Misalnya, studi setelah Malmendier dan Tate (2005) telah
bahwasaham menganalisis dampak terlalu percaya diri CEO pada kinerja perusahaan (Hsu
intervensi pemegangpaling efektif untuk mencegah investasi berlebih et al., 2017al., 2017), risiko jatuhnya harga saham ().Kim, Wang, & Zhang,
yang disebabkan oleh CEO yang terlalu percaya diri. 2016), pergantian CEO (Campbell etal., 2011), dan kualitas laba (Ahmed &
Kedua, makalah ini menambah literatur yang mengeksplorasi peran Duellman, 2013; Hsieh, Bedard, & Johnstone, 2014; Schrand & Zechman,
intervensi pemegang saham dalam membatasi distorsi investasi. Bukti 2012).

2
S. Kwon dkk. informasi, dalam hal ini CEO akan lebih mengandalkan dana internal
untuk menghindari menipiskan sekuritas undervalued perusahaan
investasi suboptimal (misalnya, Aghion, Van Reenen, & Zingales, 2013; mereka. Oleh karena itu, ICFS yang positif dapat mewakili investasi
Baysinger, Kosnik, & Turk, 1991; Bushee, 1998; Hansen & Hill, 1991; yang berlebihan, tetapi tidak harus sepenuhnya merupakan distorsi
Schnatterly, Shaw, & Jennings, 2008). Yang lain berpendapat bahwa investasi. Sebaliknya, Malmendier dan Tate (2005) berpendapat bahwa
peran pencegah pemegang saham tidak efektif karena cakrawala CEO yang terlalu percaya diri akan selalu menyebabkan distorsi
investasi jangka pendek mereka (misalnya, Graves, 1988; Greenwood investasi karena sifat optimis mereka membuat mereka lebih mungkin
& Schor, 2009; Porter, 1992). Dalam makalah ini, kami menunjukkan disesatkan oleh evaluasi peluang investasi yang cerah. CEO yang
bahwa intervensi pemegang saham tidak secara seragam menghalangi terlalu percaya diri karena itu secara positif memoderasi hubungan
semua investasi berlebih. Kami percaya bahwa adopsi pendekatan antara perusahaan dalam investasi dan FCF.
Malmendier dan Tate (2005) untuk menangkap potensi distorsi Dalam makalah ini, kami menggunakan ICFS Malmendier dan Tate
investasi dapat membantu menyelesaikan hasil dan interpretasi yang (2005) tipe unikdan ukuran investasi berlebih yang diusulkan oleh
beragam dalam literatur. Richardson (2006) untuk menangkap distorsi investasi, yaitu, investasi
Dalam sisa makalah ini, Bagian 2 merangkum literatur sebelumnya berlebihan FCF oleh
dan pengembangan hipotesis kami, dan Bagian 3 menjelaskan data
dan metode penelitian kami. Bagian 4 dan 5 menyajikan hasil empiris
dan pemeriksaan ketahanan kami, dan Bagian 6 menarik beberapa 7
Fazzari et al. (1988) berpendapat lebih lanjut bahwa ICFS merupakan
kesimpulan. indikator kendala pembiayaan yang disebabkan oleh ketidaksempurnaan
pasar, sementara Kaplan dan Zingales (1997) mengaitkannya (setidaknya
2. Tinjauan Literatur dan Pengembangan Hipotesis sebagian) dengan konservatisme manajerial.
Tinjauan Internasional Analisis Keuangan 75 (2021) 101751

Studi ini menyelidiki peran pencegah intervensi pemegang saham


CEO yang terlalu percaya diri, memungkinkan kami untuk menangkap
dalam mengurangi distorsi investasi, ditangkap menggunakan investasi
biaya agensi yang terkait dengan investasi berlebih dengan lebih baik.
berlebihan FCF oleh CEO yang terlalu percaya diri. Subbagian
berikutnya secara singkat meninjau literatur yang relevan (diringkas
dalam Tabel 1) dan menyajikan hipotesis kami. 2.2. Intervensi pemegang saham

2.1. Biaya agensi FCF dan terlalu percaya diri CEO Mengingat potensi distorsi investasi, pemegang saham mungkin
berusaha membatasi kegiatan CEO yang mementingkan diri sendiri
Meskipun penelitian intensif, kontroversi tetap atas interpretasi dengan menimbulkan biaya pemantauan (Jensen & Meckling, 1976).
ICFS. Studi teoritis dan empiris menunjukkan bahwa ICFS positif tidak Meskipun temuan campuran dalam literatur (misalnya, Bushee, 1998;
selalu diterjemahkan ke dalam distorsi investasi. Jensen (1986) Graves, 1988), sebagian besar studi yang tercantum dalam Tabel 1
berpendapat bahwa FCF menyebabkan inefisiensi investasi, karena menemukan bukti efektivitas intervensi pemegang saham dalam
manajer yang kepentingannya tidak sejalan dengan kepentingan meningkatkan proyek-proyek yang menjanjikan tetapi membatasi
pemegang saham akan mengarahkan FCF ke proyek yang tidak distorsi investasi potensial
memaksimalkan nilai daripada membayar dividen kepada pemegang . Misalnya, Baysinger et al. (1991) dan Brav et al. (2018) menemukan
saham. Di sini, FCF didefinisikan sebagai arus kas berlebih setelah bahwa kepemilikan saham investor institusional dan aktivisme dana
mendanai semua proyek dengan NPV positif. Sejumlah besar literatur lindung nilai secara positif terkait denganR&investasiD dan inovasi
mengeksplorasi biaya agensi FCF dalam hal penyebabnya (misalnya, perusahaan (misalnya, kutipan), masing-masing. Pawlina dan
Fazzari et al., 1988)7 dan faktor-faktor yang meringankan (misalnya, Renneboog (2005) dan Richardson (2006) juga memberikan bukti
Pawlina & Renneboog, 2005). Misalnya, Richardson (2006) bahwa intervensi pemegang saham, yang dilakukan dengan
menafsirkan hubungan positif antara investasi abnormal dan FCF menggunakan pemegang saham blockholder dan kehadiran pemegang
sebagai mencerminkan distorsi investasi atau biaya agensi yang terkait saham aktivis, secara efektif mengurangi biaya agensi FCF. Seperti
dengan investasi berlebihan FCF. dicatat sebelumnya, tidak seperti studi ini, kami menggunakan tipe
ICFS Malmendier dan Tate (2005) untuk meninjau kembali analisis
Di sisi lain, serangkaian studi menunjukkan bahwa ICFS positif juga
apakah intervensi pemegang saham membatasi distorsi investasi.
dapat menjadi akibat dari kurangnya investasi jika didorong oleh
Argumen utama yang mendukung peran pencegah pemegang
asimetri informasi (Myers & Majluf, 1984; Pawlina & Renneboog, 2005;
saham adalah hipotesis pasar efisien, yang menyatakan bahwa
Stiglitz & Weiss, 1981). Studi-studi ini berpendapat bahwa CEO yang
pemegang saham mampu memproses semua informasi yang relevan
kepentingannya selaras dengan pemegang saham sangat bergantung
(Hansen & Hill, 1991) dan dengan demikian mengoptimalkan investasi
pada dana internal daripada mengumpulkan dana eksternal yang
mahal, dan dengan demikian akan kehilangan proyek NPV yang perusahaan.8 Namun demikian, keterlibatan aktif pemegang saham
berpotensi positif. dalam proses pemungutan suara atau pemantauan mereka yang
Heaton (2002) beralih ke aspek perilaku manajer untuk terinformasi tidak memberi mereka kekuasaan langsung atas
menjelaskan inefisiensi investasi. Secara khusus, ia berpendapat keputusan investasi perusahaan. Bahkan ketika pemegang saham
bahwayang optimis manajerlebih cenderung melakukan investasi dapat melakukan intervensi langsung untuk mencegah distorsi
berlebihan dalam proyek NPV negatif, bahkan tanpa masalah agensi, investasi (misalnya, dengan mengubah CEO yang mendistorsi
karena mereka secara sistematis menilai opsi investasi terlalu tinggi. investasi), pertempuran proxy sangat mahal bagi pemegang saham
Selanjutnya, Malmendier dan Tate (2005) mencatat bahwa FCF tidak dan manajer. Oleh karena itu, suara pemegang saham kemungkinan
selalu menyebabkan distorsi investasi jika didorong oleh asimetri besar akan efektif ketika mereka menimbulkan ancaman yang lebih
kredibel untuk melibatkan perusahaan dalam kontes proxy yang mahal.
Studi sebelumnya menunjukkan bahwa jenis pemegang saham
Kami menyebutnya sebagai hipotesis ancaman disiplin (lihat juga Brav
tertentu memiliki kemampuan dan insentif yang lebih besar untuk
et al., 2018; Francis & Smith, 1995 dan Klein & Zur, 2006).
memfasilitasi mekanisme pendisiplinan (Shleifer & Vishny, 1986).
Misalnya, pemegang saham dapat secara sah menuntut agar
Misalnya, investor institusional lebih mampu mengurangi asimetri
perusahaan mengurangi distorsi investasi. Jika CEO incumbent tidak
informasi karena kepemilikan perusahaan mereka cenderung cukup
sesuai, mereka akan merasa terancam oleh intervensi pemegang
terkonsentrasi (Schnatterly et al., 2008). investasi (Baysinger et al.,
saham karena takut menghadapi pemecatan (Campbell, Gallmeyer,
1991).
Johnson, Rutherford, & Stanley, 2011) atau meningkatkan kontrol tata
Secara khusus, Brav et al. (2008) membandingkan dana lindung
kelola (misalnya, amandemen piagam perusahaan, perubahan
nilai dengan investordan jenis dana lainnya (misalnya, reksa dana),
komposisi dewan) . Akibatnya, jika semuanya tetap sama, kami
dan menemukan bahwa
memperkirakan bahwa CEO akan mengurangi distorsi investasi
ketika pemegang saham lebih mungkin untuk secara aktif
menggunakan hak suara mereka, yang kami tangkap menggunakan 8
institusionalSebaliknya, yang lain berpendapat bahwa tekanan kinerja
tingkat premi suara yang lebih tinggi (Kalay et al., 2014). Namun, kami
memberikan institusional manajer investasi perspektif jangka pendek
tidak memprediksi efek serupa ketika investasi berlebih tidak selalu
(Greenwood & Schor, 2009; Hansen & Hill, 1991), dan bahwa para manajer ini
terdistorsi karena, dalam hal ini, CEO tidak akan merasa terancam oleh tidak memiliki kecanggihan dan kemampuan yang memadai untuk menyelidiki
suara pemegang saham. investasi perusahaan yang kompleks (Barth, Cahan, Chen, & Venter, 2017;
H1. Voting premium berhubungan negatif dengan distorsi investasi. Franco, Hope, Vyas, & Zhou, 2015).

3
S. Kwon dkk. terikat Tinjauan Internasional Analisis Keuangan 75 (2001) 101751

Tabel 1
Ringkasan literatur sebelumnya.
Studi Variabel Intervensi pemegang saham Arus kas Sampel Asosiasi yang diamati

Fazzari et al. (1988) Investasi Arus kas 422 perusahaan, 1970–1984 Positive
Graves (1988) R&D Kepemilikan saham institusional 112 industri)
perusahaan-tahun, 1976–1985 (komputer Negative
R&D Kepemilikan saham institusional 129 Positive
perusahaan, 1977 –1987 (teknologi
Hansen and Hill (1991) industri)
R&D Kepemilikan saham institusional 176 perusahaan, 1981–1983
Positive
Baysinger et al. (1991)
Paten, R&D per paten 262 perusahaan, 1980–1989 Positif (negatif) kepemilikan
Francis and Smith (1995) Kepemilikan orang dalam Kepemilikan orang antara paten (R&D per paten ) dan insider
luar kepemilikan /luar
Kaplan dan Zingales (1997) mengalir Investasi Kas 719 perusahaan-tahun, 1970-1984 dibatasi finansial
positif, tetapi efeknya lebih besar ketika perusahaan tidak
Bushee (1998) Penurunan R&D Kelembagaan kepemilikan saham FCF 13.944 Negatif antara penurunan R&D dan kepemilikan saham institusional
perusahaan-tahun, 1983–1994
Pawlina dan Investasi Pemegang saham pemegang (Inggris) investasi
Renneboog (2005) saham × arus kas Arus Positif (negatif) antara arus kas ( arus kas ×
kas 3445 perusahaan-tahun, 1992-1998 pemegang saham pemegang saham) dan
Malmendier dan Tate (2005) Investasi CEO terlalu percaya diri × 1058 perusahaan-tahun, 1980-1994
arus kas Positif
kelola (misalnya, pemegang saham aktivis) Positif antara FCF dan investasi berlebih Negatif antara
Richardson (2006) Investasi berlebihan Pengendalian tata FCF 58.053 perusahaan-tahun s, 1988–2002 kontrol tata kelola dan investasiFCF positif
berlebih dalam subsampelTribo, Berrone, R&D Kepemilikan bank Kepemilikan (jenis pemegang blok) Negatif (positif) antara kepemilikan bank
dan Surroca (2007) perusahaan 3638 perusahaan, 1996–2000 (Spanyol ) (kepemilikan perusahaan) dan R&D
×pasar produk
Biddle et al. (2009) Investasi Kualitas pelaporan keuangan persaingan
× kas dan 34.791 perusahaan-tahun, 1993–2005 Positif antara kutipan, dan kepemilikan saham institusional
leverage dan kepemilikan saham institusional × persaingan pasar
Aghion et al. (2013) Kutipan Kepemilikan saham 6208 perusahaan-tahun, 1991-1999 produk
institusional Kepemilikan saham institusi Negatif
(2016) 41.626 perusahaan-tahun, 1990-2007 investasi
García Lara, García Osma, dan Penalva Investasi Konservatisme × Underinvestment Positif (negatif) antara konservatisme ×
Volatilitas arus kas underinvestment (volatilitas arus kas) dan
Brav et al. (2018) R&D, paten, kutipan Cella (2020) Investasi Kepemilikan saham institusional Negatif antara kepemilikan saham institusional jangka
Aktivisme hedge fund 1106 firm-years, 1994–2007 jangka panjang × panjang × investasi berlebih daninvestasi
Negatif (positif) antara aktivisme hedge fund dan R&D Investasi berlebihan
(paten dan kutipan) Arus kas 40.155 perusahaan-tahun, 1980-2006

Sementara ICFS telah dieksplorasi secara global (misalnya, Huang,


Jiang, Liu, & Zhang, 2011 untuk Cina), kami melakukan penelitian ini
dana lindung nilaisecara ideal diposisikan untuk bertindak sebagai dalam konteks satu negara, AS, karena dua alasan utama. Pertama,
pemantau yang terinformasi dan aktif. Mereka menyarankan bahwa ini AS adalah negara common law (La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes, Shleifer,
karena dana lindung nilai dioperasikan oleh manajer dengan insentif & Vishny, 2000) dengan perlindungan investor yang relatif kuat.
tinggi, dan cenderung memegang posisi yang relatif terkonsentrasi di Meskipun aktivisme pemegang saham berakar pada pertengahan
sejumlah kecil perusahaan. Ini menyiratkan bahwa aktivis hedge fund 1980-an di AS, lembaga awal yang berkaitan dengan perlindungan
cenderung memiliki insentif yang lebih kuat dan memiliki posisi yang pemegang saham, seperti proposal pemegang saham, dimulai sejak
lebih baik untuk mengambil peran yang lebih aktif dalam memantau Securities and Exchange Act 1934 (Denes, Karpoff, & McWilliams,
investasi perusahaan. Dengan demikian, kami memperkirakan bahwa 2017). Dengan latar belakang ini,saham AS
distorsi investasi akan berkurang dengan kedatangan aktivis hedge pemeganglebih mampu melakukan intervensi untuk mengekang distorsi
fund. investasi
melalui pertempuran proxy, aktivisme hedge fund, pengambilalihan,
H2. Distorsi investasi menurun seiring masuknya aktivis hedge fund. dan litigasi. Konteks yang menguntungkan bagi pemegang saham ini
memberikan pengaturan yang ideal untuk penelitian untuk menguji
efektivitas suara pemegang saham. Kedua, analisis satu negara di AS
2.3. Konteks kelembagaan
memfasilitasi akses kami ke data yang relevan. Misalnya, data untuk kami adopsi sebagai proxy untuk distorsi investasi. Kami menggunakan
membangun terlalu percaya diri dan memilih ukuran premium sudah ukuran ini karena investasi yang berlebihan dari FCF (Richardson,
tersedia dari Execucomp dan OptionMetrics. Kami juga dapat 2006) tidak serta merta menangkap distorsi investasi. Secara khusus,
memanfaatkan data aktivisme hedge fund yang dikumpulkan oleh Brav sementara investasi berlebihan FCF yang didorong oleh masalah
et al. (2018). Ini tidak mungkin tersedia untuk analisis lintas negara. keagenan lebih mungkin merupakan distorsi investasi, FCF yang terkait
dengan asimetri informasi dapat meningkatkan investasi tetapi
mengurangi distorsi (Malmendier & Tate, 2005). Sebaliknya, menurut
2.4. Kerangka konseptual Mal Mendier dan Tate (2005), investasi FCF yang berlebihan oleh CEO
yang terlalu percaya diri selalu menyebabkan distorsi investasi, karena
Gambar 1 merangkum bagaimana intervensi pemegang saham optimisme CEO yang terlalu percaya diri membuat mereka lebih sering
mempengaruhi investasi FCF oleh CEO yang terlalu percaya diri, yang melakukan proyek dengan NPV negatif.

4
S. Kwon dkk. Mendier dan Tate (2005), kami kemudian membagi sampel yang
dikumpulkan ini berdasarkan tingkat CEO terlalu percaya diri dan FCF:
1) FCF terlalu percaya diri-positif (N = 3434), 2) FCF tidak terlalu
percaya diri-positif (N = 2453), 3)

9
Mengikuti Richardson (2006), kami mengecualikan lembaga keuangan dari
analisis kami. Ini karena, dalam industri keuangan, demarkasi di antara ketiga
klasifikasi arus kas tidak jelas, dan beberapa komponen penting yang
diperlukan untuk menghitung investasi baru (misalnya,R&pengeluaranD) tidak
tersedia.
Tinjauan Internasional Analisis Keuangan 75 (2021) 101751

Gambar. 1. Dampak intervensi pemegang saham terhadapberlebih


investasi.
Gambar ini merangkum bagaimana intervensi pemegang saham
mempengaruhi investasi FCF yang berlebihan oleh CEO yang terlalu percaya diri.
Sementara investasi FCF yang berlebihan olehterlalu percaya diri
CEO yang tidaktidak selalu merupakan
distorsi investasi, investasi FCF yang berlebihan olehterlalu percaya diri
CEO yanglebih mungkin terjadi. Kami berpendapat bahwasaham
Dengan menggunakan definisi distorsi investasi ini, kami menguji intervensi pemegangsecara efektif mengekanginvestasiinvestasi
efektivitas intervensi pemegang saham dalam membatasi investasi distorsi, tetapi bukan jenisberlebih lainnya.
suboptimal. Secara khusus, berdasarkan hipotesis pasar yang efisien,
kami berasumsi bahwa pemegang saham pada umumnya, dan aktivis
hedge fund pada khususnya, memiliki insentif dan kemampuan untuk
mengoptimalkan investasi perusahaan. Berdasarkan hipotesis
ancaman disiplin, kami kemudian memprediksi bahwa CEO akan
mempertimbangkan suara pemegang saham sebagai ancaman yang
kredibel, dan dengan demikian akan menyesuaikan tingkat investasi
mereka, tetapi hanya jika ini menyebabkan distorsi investasi.

3. Data dan Metode


FCF negatif yang terlalu percaya diri (N = 1349), dan 4) FCF negatif
3.1. Sampel dan data yang tidak terlalu percaya diri (N = 1110). Analisis utama kami berfokus
pada subsampel (1), yang kami sebut distorsi investasi, atau ICFS dari
Kami menggunakan dua sampel untuk menguji peran pencegah CEO yang terlalu percaya diri.
pemegang saham dalam intervensi dalam mengurangi distorsi
investasi: sampel premium voting, dan sampel aktivisme hedge fund. 3.1.2. Contoh aktivisme
Kami menjelaskan keduanya secara lebih rinci dalam subbagian hedge fund Untuk menganalisis aktivisme hedge fund, kami
berikut. menggunakan kumpulan data kedua. Kita mulai dengan file gabungan
dari Compustat, Execucomp, CRSP, dan pengajuan 13D oleh dana
3.1.1. Memilih sampel premium lindung nilai yang disusun oleh Brav et al. (2018). Seperti dalam sampel
Kami memulai proses pemilihan sampel dengan menggabungkan premium voting, kami juga secara eksklusif menyertakan CEO yang
pengamatan dari OptionMetrics, Compustat, Execucomp, dan CRSP. menunjukkan perilaku terlalu percaya diri setidaknya dua kali selama
Setelah mengecualikan lembaga keuangan dan pengamatan tanpa masa jabatan mereka. Proses penggabungan ini menghasilkan 10.726
data yang memadai, tersisa 12.066 tahun perusahaan untuk periode pengamatan tahun perusahaan untuk 1996-2014 setelah
1996-2014.9 Sampel untuk memperkirakan premi pemungutan suara mengecualikan nilai yang hilang.
(VP) dimulai pada tahun 1996, karenaOpsi Untuk menguji pengaruh aktivisme hedge fund terhadap distorsi
data Metrikdimulai pada tahun tersebut. Itu berakhir pada tahun 2014, investasi, kami menggunakan pencocokan skor kecenderungan. This
untuk mencocokkan periode sampel kedua kami. Kami mengikuti approach facilitates causal inference in a non-experimental setting by
Malmendier dan Tate (2005) dan Campbell et al. (2011), yang identifying counterfactuals of which the ex ante probability of treatment
mengusulkan CEO berbasis opsi atas ukuran kepercayaan, dan is similar to actual treatment observations. Because a firm can be a
mengharuskan CEO untuk menunjukkan perilaku terlalu percaya diri target (Targets) in one year and a non-target (Non-targets) in another,
(yaitu, tidak menggunakan opsi saham yang lebih dari 67% dalam we limit potential control firms to those for which hedge funds did not
uang) setidaknya dua kali selama masa jabatan mereka untuk file a Schedule 13D at any point during our sample period. We then
dimasukkan dalam sampel kami. Dengan demikian, pengamatan dalam estimate the propensity of 13D filings by hedge fund activists using a
sampel kami memiliki peluang yang hampir sama untuk diklasifikasikan probit model (Eq. (1)), where we regress hedge fund activism (Targets)
sebagai terlalu percaya diri. Sebagai hasil dari penerapan persyaratan on agency costs (CEO_own) and informa tion asymmetry (Spread) after
ini, sampel premi pemungutan suara kami terdiri dari 8346 tahun controlling for the number of existing 13D blockholders (Num_5pct)10
perusahaan. and CEO equity-based incentives (CEO_delta).
Untuk menangkap distorsi investasi potensial yang diusulkan oleh Mal Following Brav et al. (2018), Targets is an indicator variable that
equals 1 for specific firm-years when hedge fund activists filed a probability of 13D filings, to select matched pairs of Targets and Non
Schedule 13D with the SEC, and 0 otherwise. This model is based on Targets without replacement for the propensity score caliper of 0.05.
agency theory (Jensen & Meckling, 1976), which states that ownership
structure is determined by the extent of agency costs and information
asymmetry. In this model, we include additional variables relating to the 10
Blockholder ownership data come from Thomson Reuters 13F Institutional
main financial (Size, ROA, and Leverage) and market (Turn, Stock Holdings. Among the available quarterly 13F data, we use blockholder infor
return, and Volatility) characteristics suggested in prior literature that mation for the final quarter. Specifically, if a firm files a Form 13F in the third
relate to ownership structure and equity investment risk (eg, Kim & Lu, quarter, but not in the fourth, we consider the third quarter information to be the
2011; Rogers & Stocken, 2005). In the interest of brevity, detailed annual observation. Given that all institutional investment managers with more
variable definitions are in Appendix B. than $100 million in assets under management are required to file Form 13F
Finally, we use the propensity scores, which represent the ex ante with the SEC, we replace remaining missing values with zero.

5
S. Kwon et al. (CEO_own), because equity holdings are likely to incentivize CEOs to

Subsequently, for 1996–2014, we are left with 354 matched firms (177
Targets and 177 Non-targets), or 2173 firm-year observations.11 11
Brav et al.'s (2018) original data set consists of 3242 firm-year 13D filings by
hedge fund activists for 1994–2014. We drop 41 observations in order to
Pr(Targetst)=α0+α1CEO ownt+α2Spreadt+α3Num 5pctt+α4CEO deltat
ensure this sample period matches our voting premium sample (ie,
+ΣFinancial characteristics+ΣMarket characteristics+ε
1996–2014). By merging with the files of Compustat, Execucomp, and CRSP,
we lose 2996 cases that are not listed (primarily on Execucomp). After
excluding a further 25 cases for which we could not find matched non-targets,
we are left with 177 13D filings. Note that this decrease in observations is
inevitable to analyze overconfident CEOs.
12
Malmendier and Tate (2005) set a 67% threshold following Hall and Mur
phy's (2002) calibration.
International Review of Financial Analysis 75 (2021) 101751
(1)
overinvest in order to increase their private wealth (Ghosh, Moon, &
Tandon, 2007; Ju, Leland, & Senbet, 2014). In contrast, stock
3.2. Empirical specification ownership may capture CEOs' aligned interests with shareholders
(Pawlina & Renneboog, 2005). We also include the proportion of
3.2.1. Voting premium outside directors on the board (Out_director), because CEOs under
To test for the voting premium mechanism using the voting premium weak board monitoring are less vulnerable to shareholder voices
sample, we construct a firm investment model as in Eq. (2). Our (Aktas, Andreou, Karasamani, & Philip, 2018). And we include the
dependent variable, overinvestment (Dist_invest), comprises the re Kaplan and Zingales index (KZ_in
siduals from Richardson's (2006) differencing model, wherein we
dex) as a proxy for financing constraints, because limited access to
regress new investment after excluding depreciation and amortization
capital markets will have a real effect on investment decisions. Contrary
on a vector of control variables (ie, growth opportunity, leverage, asset
to the leverage variable included in the differencing model, KZ_index
size, firm age, cash, prior-year new investment, and stock returns) (see
considers firms' reliance on both debt and equity markets. Finally, we
Eq. (6) in Appendix A). By incorporating the first differencing of new
include year dummies to control for economic conditions that may affect
investment, this model attenuates the problem of unobserved firm het
Dist_invest and VP over time, and industry dummies (Fama-French in
erogeneities that are time-invariant.
dustry groups) to address time-invariant industry heterogeneities. We
Note that Eq. (2) does not include the covariates originally consid
run Eq. (2) using the four subsamples described in subsection 3.1.1,
ered in the differencing model, because Dist_invest is orthogonal to but with our primary focus on the overconfidence-positive FCF
those variables. Instead, we incorporate additional control variables that subsample, ie, the distorted investment subsample. The coefficient on
were not considered in the model but may confound the link between
VP (β1) in this subsample captures the moderating effect of VP on the
VP and Dist_invest. For example, shareholders do not necessarily pay
ICFS of firms managed by overconfident CEOs.
more to exercise their voting rights when the internal governance
mechanism is working properly (eg, Out_director).
Dist investt =β0+β1VPt− 1+ΣControlst− 1+ΣYearfixed effect +ΣIndustry
Our main variable of interest in Eq. (2), VP, is the market value of
the voting premium, as proposed by Kalay et al. (2014). We calculate
fixed effect+ζ (2)
VP by taking the difference between a synthetic stock price without
voting rights, estimated from the put-call parity equation (Eq. (9) in For the purpose of the sensitivity tests presented in 5.3, we adopt
Appendix A), and the stock price with voting rights. The resulting an alternative investment model (Eq. (3)) proposed by Malmendier and
difference represents the extent of shareholders' active involvement in Tate (2005). For dependent variables, this model includes two alterna
the voting process. tive specifications of overinvestment (Alt_dist (I) and Alt_dist (II)) sug
We adopt an option-based measure of CEO overconfidence (CEO_ gested by previous studies. Contrary to Dist_invst, Alt_dist (I) (Alt_dist
over) and its variations (Hsu, Novoselov, & Rencheng, 2017; Mal (II)) is the abnormal total (new) investment that is not explained by the
mendier & Tate, 2005). It is an indicator variable that equals 1 for firms prior year sales growth level (Biddle, Hilary, & Verdi, 2009). For
with CEOs holding stock options that are more than 67% in the independent variables other than VP, it incorporates growth opportunity
money,12 dan 0 sebaliknya. This measure is based on the assumption (Q), cash flow (FCF), CEO equity incentives (CEO_own and
that over confidence on the part of CEOs is a relatively permanent trait. CEO_delta), size effect (Size), and corporate governance (Duality).
We therefore classify CEOs as overconfident from the first year onward ( )
Alt dist(I)t Alt dist(II)t =γ0+γ1VPt− 1+ΣControlst− 1+ΣYearfixed effect
if they fail to exercise deep-in-the-money stock options (unless they +ΣIndustry fixed effect+η
consistently exhibit the opposite behavior (Hsu et al., 2017)). However,
(3)
to test the sensitivity of our analyses, we use variations of CEO_over
after changing the assumption (ie, CEO optimism as a transitory trait)
3.2.2. Hedge fund activism
and cutoff levels (ie, 67%, 100%, or 150% of moneyness). We
Next, we employ a DID model (Eq. (4)) to test for the effect of hedge
summarize the results in subsection 5.3.
fund activism on investment distortions using the matched pairs of the
Following Richardson (2006), we define FCF as free cash flow from
hedge fund activism sample. Our dependent variable is again firm
existing assets less expected new investments. Expected new
overinvestment (Dist_invest), which we use in Eq. (2). However, in the
investment is the predicted value from Richardson's (2006) differencing
matching model (Eq. (1)), Targets was an indicator variable that
model. We provide further details of the estimation methods of our main
equaled 1 for specific firm-years when hedge fund activists filed a
variables in Appendix A.
Schedule 13D with the SEC, and 0 otherwise. Here, it now represents
As additional control variables, we use CEO stock ownership
all firm-years of firms for which a Schedule 13D was filed at least once activismt +ΣYearfixed effect+ΣIndustry fixed effect+θ
during the sample period. We set Post_activism equal to 1 for all (4)
firm-years since the first year of 13D filings for Targets and since the
matched years for Non-tar gets, and 0 otherwise. Therefore, the 3.2.3. Endogeneity concerns
coefficient on Targets × Post_ While analyzing hedge fund activism using the DID matching esti mator
activism (δ3) captures the effect of hedge fund activism on firm may be less susceptible to potential endogeneity concerns, anal ysis of
overinvestment relative to Non-targets. Finally, we include industry and the voting premium is not. Specifically, we are concerned that any
year fixed effects to control for variations in Targets and Non-targets association between the voting premium and investment distortions
across industry and time, respectively. might be driven by reverse causality from overinvestment to share
holder control rights, and/or confounded by correlated omitted
Dist investt =δ0+δ1Targetst+δ2Post activismt+δ3Targetst×Post

6
S. Kwon et al. overconfident CEOs, column (1) includes firms for which VP and
Dist_invest are significantly higher (mean differences of 0.323 and
variables (see, eg, Bhagat & Jefferis, 2002). To attenuate this concern, 0.006, respectively;
we adopt an IV approach (Ullah, Zaefarian, & Ullah, 2020), which al
lows us to better isolate the average direct effect of the voting premium
on overinvestment, which may not relate to the aforementioned endo 13
geneity concerns. A strand of literature indicates that the stock price contains information that
managers may not be able to acquire, so managers will rely on market infor
Specifically, we instrument the voting premium using the exercise
mation when making investment decisions (eg, Chen, Goldstein, & Jiang, 2007;
price of the market option (X), which appears to affect overinvestment
Morck, Shleifer, Vishny, Shapiro, & Poterba, 1990).
only through the voting premium. On the one hand, exercise price me International Review of Financial Analysis 75 (2021) 101751
chanically affects the voting premium because it is one of the input
variables used to construct the voting premium variable (Eq. (9) in standard errors for these differences are reported in column (5)). Larger
Appendix A). On the other hand, to the best of our knowledge, the firm investment in itself does not necessarily signal distorted invest
strike price of a market option does not necessarily affect firm ment, but it suggests potential for distortions.
investment. This is because strike price was pre-determined by The univariate analyses reveal further that the distorted investment
derivative market par ticipants, not by firms. Given that there are subsample is comprised of firms with relatively good performance,
various option investors with differing degrees of risk tolerance, it is measured as ROA (mean ROA = 0.098 in column (1)) relative to other
hard to imagine that CEOs make firm investment decisions in the subsamples. This preliminary finding is inconsistent with our prediction
exclusive interest of particular option investors. We believe that this that column (1) includes potential investment distortions. Therefore,
reasonably satisfies the exclusion re striction condition. using a system GMM and Fama-MacBeth approach in the following
However, we acknowledge that it may be contentious to assume analyses, we estimate the financial performance of the distorted in
that exercise price is randomly assigned to a firm because it may pick vestment subsample again.
up the effect of stock price on firm investment.13 Nonetheless, the fact Finally, in Panel D, we examine the Spearman correlation for the
that a higher stock price does not necessarily lead to a higher voting main variables in Eq. (2). As in previous studies (eg, Malmendier &
premium (because the voting premium is the difference between stock Tate, 2005; Richardson, 2006), there are positive and significant asso
price and implied stock price) gives us some comfort in adopting the ciations between Dist_invest and, respectively, CEO_over and FCF. In
exercise price as an instrumental variable. the following subsections, we explore these associations with regard to
our research question: whether shareholder intervention mitigates
4. Results investment distortions. Specifically, we explore the association between
VP and Dist_invest in the subsample where CEOs are overconfident
4.1. Descriptive statistics of the voting premium sample and firms hold positive FCF, which is equivalent to the moderating effect
of VP on the ICFS of firms managed by overconfident CEOs.
Table 2, Panel A, presents summary statistics for the variables in Descriptive statistics for the hedge fund activism sample are in
the voting premium analysis (Eq. (2)). The mean (median) of Table 4, along with the DID analysis results.
Dist_invest is virtually zero, since it represents residuals that are not
explained by the covariates in the differencing model. Average VP is
4.2. Main results
0.320, which means that shareholders in our sample pay, on average,
0.320% of the current stock price to acquire voting rights. These
4.2.1. Voting premium
statistics are broadly consis
Table 3 presents the key results from the estimation of the relation
tent with those of Richardson (2006) and Kalay et al. (2014). In
between voting premium and investment distortion, obtained using the
contrast, the means (medians) of CEO_over and FCF are 0.573 (1.000)
fixed effects estimator (Eq. (2)). Specifically, we use the voting premium
and 0.036 (0.038), respectively. The large value of CEO_over results
sample summarized in Table 2 (N = 8346) and regress Dist_invest on
from our sampling strategy that exclusively selects CEOs exhib iting
VP after controlling for financing constraints.
overconfident behavior at least twice during their tenure (Mal mendier &
We begin our analysis by estimating the well-known positive ICFS.
Tate, 2005). The firm-year observations in the voting premium sample
To this end, following Richardson (2006), we use two piecewise vari
have a similar chance of being classified as over confident. The positive
ables that divide FCF into positive and negative values (ie, FCF (posi
median value of FCF indicates that Option Metrics includes firms with
tive) and FCF (negative)). In column (1), the positive coefficient on FCF
relatively sufficient free cash flow. Panel B reports the characteristics of
(positive) is significant and greater than FCF (negative), ie, 0.100 (p
higher and lower VP firms classified at the median of VP. Firms with
higher VP have significantly more overconfident CEOs (the mean value <0.01) vs 0.020 (p-value >0.10).14 This asymmetry of ICFS is
difference in CEO_over = 0.135 in column (3)), and hold more positive consistent with Richardson (2006) and affirms the presence of positive
FCF (the mean difference in FCF = 0.011 in column (3)). These ICFS in our sample. To test for the deterrent effect of VP on this ICFS,
univariate analysis results hint at potential joint effects between VP and, in column (2), we interact VP with FCF (positive) and FCF (negative).
respectively, CEO_over and FCF. Panel C compares the firm Although the coefficients on the interaction terms are not significant at
characteristics of the four subsamples: overconfidence-positive FCF the conventional level, we find that they have opposite signs: negative
(column (1)), non-overconfidence-positive FCF (column (2)), for FCF (positive) and positive for FCF (negative). This hints at ICFS
overconfidence-negative FCF (column (3)), and non being attenuated when VP is high and when firms have positive free
overconfidence-negative FCF (column (4)). Again, our focus here is on cash flow. To examine whether CEO overconfidence moderates the
the potentially distorted investment subsample in column (1) that relation be tween VP and ICFS, we then use two subsamples where
combines overconfident CEOs and positive FCF. Compared to column CEOs are overconfident (column (3)) and non-overconfident (column
(2), where firms hold positive FCF but are not managed by (4)). The positive and significant coefficient on FCF (positive) (− 0.079
with a p value <0.05) in column (3) indicates that shareholder
intervention weakens ICFS when CEOs are overconfident. In contrast,
in column (4), the positive and insignificant coefficient on FCF 14
Note that the relatively low explanatory power of our main analyses (eg,
(negative) suggests that shareholder intervention does not necessarily 1.5% in column (1)) may be attributable to the fact that Dist_invest is already
weaken ICFS when CEOs are not overconfident. filtered by a wide range of covariates in the differencing model (Eq. (6) in
In columns (5)–(8), we conduct our main analyses to understand the Appendix A). Thus, the model already explains 24.8% of New_invest (unre
source of this deterrent effect using the four subsamples presented in ported). Similarly, the R2 of regression models in studies employing the
Panel C of Table 2. Here, column (5) represents the distorted abnormal investment variable is also generally low (eg, 1.8% in the case of
Richardson, 2006).
investment

7
S. Kwon et al. Panel A: Summary statistics

International Review of Financial Analysis 75 (2021) 101751


Table 2
Summary statistics of the voting premium sample.

Variable N Mean Std Dev Q1 Median Q3

Dist_investt+1 8346 0.000 0.106 − 0.031 − 0.001 0.035 Alt_dist (I) t+1 8346 0.000 0.110 − 0.057 − 0.017 0.035 Alt_dist (II)t+1 8346 0.000 0.111 − 0.049 − 0.012 0.035 VP 8346 0.320
0.856 − 0.129 0.335 0.800 CEO_over 8346 0.573 0.495 0.000 1.000 1.000 FCF 8346 0.036 0.107 − 0.012 0.038 0.092 CEO_own 8346 0.020 0.050 0.001 0.004 0.014 Out_director
7077 0.802 0.143 0.750 0.846 0.889 KZ_index 8346 − 5.808 22.455 − 6.192 − 1.526 0.557 ROA 8341 0.062 0.104 0.032 0.067 0.108 Size 8346 7.596 1.521 6.528 7.523 8.587
Duality 8343 0.568 0.495 0.000 1.000 1.000

Panel B: Firm characteristics by VP level (N = 8346)

VP Lower Higher Higher–Lower SE for (1)–(2) (1) (2) (3) (4)

Mean (Dist_investt+1) 0.008 0.009 0.002 0.002 Mean (CEO_over) 0.506 0.641 0.135 0.011*** Mean (FCF) 0.030 0.042 0.011 0.002*** Mean (CEO_own) 0.022 0.018 − 0.020
0.113*** Mean (Out_director) 0.7 96 0.808 0.013 0.003*** Mean (KZ_index) − 5.833 − 5.782 0.051 0.492 Mean (Size) 7.597 7.802 0.205 0.000*** Mean (ROA) 0.052 0.072 −
0.020 0.002*** N (Max) 4180 4166

Panel C: Firm characteristics by four ICFS subsamples (N = 8346)

Overconfidence Yes No Yes No SE for (1)–(2) FCF Positive Positive Negative Negative (1) (2) (3) (4) (5)

Mean (VP) 0.481 0.158 0.431 0.044 0.021*** Std Dev (VP) 0.779 0.857 0.873 0.926 Mean (Dist_investt+1) 0.016 0.010 0.003 − 0.010 0.003** Std Dev (Dist _investt+1) 0.114 0.081
0.127 0.098 Mean (CEO_own) 0.021 0.020 0.020 0.019 0.000 Mean (Out_director) 0.802 0.807 0.778 0.781 − 0.004 Mean (KZ_index) − 6.635 − 5.939 − 5.438 − 3.407 − 0.482
Mean (Size) 7.630 8.022 7.424 7.537 − 0.041*** Mean (ROA) 0.098 0.063 0.028 − 0.013 0.036*** N (Max) 3434 2453 1349 1110

Panel D: Spearman correlation matrix

Variable 1 2 3 4 5 6 7

1. Dist_investt+1 1.000
2. VP 0.005 1.000
3. CEO_over 0.040*** 0.199*** 1.000
4. FCF 0.076*** 0.038*** 0.051*** 1.000
5. CEO_own − 0.0 04 − 0.038*** 0.010 0.009 1.000
6. Out_director 0.017 0.033*** − 0.011 0.032*** − 0.155*** 1.000 7. KZ_index 0.005 0.005 − 0.025** − 0.081*** − 0.009 0.022* 1.000

The voting premium sample is comprised of 8346 firm-years for the 1996–2014 period, in which we require that CEOs show overconfident behavior at least twice
during their tenure in order to be included in the sample. The investment distortion subsample (column (1) in Panel C) comprises 3434 firm-years for the same
period, in which CEOs are overconfident and firms hold positive FCF.
Panel A presents summary statistics for the variables analyzed here. Panel B reports firm characteristics of the higher and lower VP subsamples, in which VP is the
shareholder voting premium estimated by taking the difference between a synthetic stock price without voting rights and the stock price with voting rights. Panel C
compares the firm characteristics of the four subsamples classified based on CEO overconfidence and FCF levels. In particular, column (1) includes observations
that are potential investment distortions, which we capture by the investment-cash flow sensitivity (ICFS) of firms managed by overconfident CEOs. Panel D
examines Spearman correlations for the main variables analyzed here.
Columns 3 and 4 (the “SE” columns) in Panels B and C, respectively, report standard errors for two-tailed paired Wilcoxon signed rank tests of the difference in
mean values in columns (1) and (2).
Dist_invest is the abnormal change in new investment after excluding depreciation and amortization, obtained from Richardson's (2006) differencing model.
CEO_over is an indicator variable that equals 1 for firms with CEOs who fail to exercise stock options that are more than 67% in the money, and 0 otherwise. FCF is
free cash flow from existing assets less expected new investment. See Appendix B for all other variable definitions. *, **, and *** indicate statistical significance at the
0.10, 0.05, and 0.01 levels, respectively.

8
S. Kwon et al.
DV = Dist_invest
International Review of Financial Analysis 75 (2021) 101751
Table 3
Voting premium.

Overconfidence: Yes No Yes No Yes No FCF: Positive Positive Negative Negative (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

VP − 0.001 (0.002) FCF (negative) 0.020 (0.002) 0.114*** 0.000 (0.057) (0.034) 0.099 0.004 (0.002)
FCF (positive) (0.057) (0.023) 0.010 (0.003) 0.127*** 0.003 (0.080) − 0.000 (0.004)
0.100*** (0.025) 0.002 (0.065) (0.024) − 0.039 (0.002) 0.130*** − 0.008*** (0.003) − 0.000 (0.004)
(0.027) 0.026 (0.034) 0.055* (0.027)
FCF (negative) × VP 0.035
(0.038)
− 0.079** (0.038) 0.034
FCF (positive) × VP − 0.040 (0.044)
Overconfidence KZ_index − 0.000 (0.000) 0.018** (0.009) 0.019 (0.000)
0.008*** (0.003) (0.000) (0.008) (0.043) − 0.003 0.031*** (0.009)
CEO_own − 0.017 Constant 0.019** (0.013) − 0.018* − 0.020 (0.023) 0.018*− 0.169*** (0.047)
(0.023) (0.008) − 0.017 (0.020) (0.010) − 0.000 (0.009) 0.019** 0.013
Out_director 0.015* 0.008*** (0.003) − − 0.015 (0.031) 0.007 0.022** (0.010) 0.021* (0.000) 0.028** (0.009) 0.000 (0.018) − 0.035 (0.061) 0.019
(0.007) 0.017 (0.023) 0.015* (0.011) 0.001 (0.011) 0.000 (0.013) (0.000) 0.036*** 0.033** (0.018) 0.013 (0.019)
Out_director_dum (0.008) 0.010 (0.009) − 0.000 (0.000) 0.02 3 (0.010) (0.015) − 0.000 (0.000) 0.005
0.010 (0.007) (0.007) − 0.000 (0.000) 0.023** (0.015) − 0.000 (0.029)
Year dummy Included Included Included Included Included Included Included Included Industry dummy Included Included Included Included Included Included Included Included
2
Observations 8346 8346 4783 3563 3434 2453 1349 1110 Adjusted R 0.015 0.016 0.013 0.028 0.006 0.018 0.026 0.000

The voting premium sample is comprised of 8346 firm-years for the 1996–2014 period. For the purpose of analyzing investment distortions, we classify four sub
samples based on CEO overconfidence (CEO_over) and FCF (FCF) levels (columns (3)–(8)). In particular, column (5) comprises 3434 firm-years of potential
investment distortions, in which CEOs are overconfident and firms hold positive FCF.
The dependent variable is Dist_invest in all columns. Dist_invest is the abnormal change in new investment after excluding depreciation and amortization, obtained
from Richardson's (2006) differencing model. The variable of interest, VP, is the shareholder voting premium, estimated by taking the difference between a synthetic
stock price without voting rights and the stock price with voting rights. FCF (positive) equals FCF if FCF is greater than or equal 0, and 0 otherwise. FCF (negative)
equals FCF if FCF is smaller than 0, and 0 otherwise. Out_director is the ratio of outside directors on the board to total number of directors. Out_director_dum is an
indicator variable that equals 1 for firms where Out_director is missing, and 0 otherwise. After controlling for this dummy variable, we replace missing Out_director
values with zeros. See Appendix B for all other variable definitions.
All specifications are estimated using the fixed effects estimator. Two values are reported for each covariate: the coefficient estimate, and industry-clustered
standard errors (in parentheses). *, **, and *** indicate statistical significance at the 0.10, 0.05, and 0.01 levels, respectively.
However, the negative coefficients are more likely to represent less
overinvestment (rather than more underinvestment) as the mean values
subsample where CEOs are overconfident and firms hold positive FCF of Dist_invest for the subsamples used in both columns are positive.16
(N = 3434). The negative and significant coefficient on VP (− 0.008)
means that a 1-standard deviation (0.779) increase in VP corresponds 4.2.2. Hedge fund activism
to an approximately $4.275 million decrease in Dist_invst. Insignificant In Table 4, we examine the effect of hedge fund activism on over
control variables affirm that Dist_invest is already orthogonal to most investment using the hedge fund activism sample (N = 2173) and the
DID matching estimator (Eq. (4)). Specifically, we regress Dist_invest
traditional determinants of firm investment.15 Therefore, the highly
significant coefficient on VP indicates that shareholder intervention has on the interaction term Targets × Post_activism (δ3), which captures the
an incremental effect on Dist_invst, supporting H1. We interpret this as dynamic multi-period change in firm overinvestment in Targets post
suggesting the deterrent effect of VP on ICFS in firms run by over hedge fund intervention relative to that for Non-targets.
To capture investment distortions, we again divide the sample into
confident CEOs.
four CEO overconfidence-FCF subsamples. Here, columns (3) of
In contrast, in column (6), the segment of interest is VP in firms with
Panels B and C are the potentially distorted investment subsample,
non-overconfident CEOs but positive FCF (N = 2453). The positive and
where CEOs are overconfident and firms hold positive FCF
insignificant coefficient on VP (0.004 with a p-value >0.10) indicates
simultaneously. In contrast, columns (4)–(6) do not necessarily
that the strength of ICFS is not necessarily muted for firms with positive
represent investment distortions.
FCF if CEOs are not overconfident. In columns (7) and (8), VP is not
Panel A summarizes the covariate balance of Targets and
significant at the conventional level.
Non-targets identified with Eq. (1). This equation is a hedge fund
It is informative to note that the negative coefficients for FCF (posi tive)
activism model, where we regress 13D filings by hedge fund activists
× VP in column (3) and for VP in column (5) may suggest a decrease in
on ten potential
new investment below the “optimal” levels, ie, underinvestment.

16
15
Dist_invest in around 75% of firm-years in these subsamples have positive
Unlike Richardson (2006), we include year and industry fixed effects.
FCF.
However, the exclusion of fixed effects does not alter the results, because
those effects have already been absorbed in the calculation of Dist_invest.

9
S. Kwon et al. Hedge fund activism. Panel A: Covariate balance
International Review of Financial Analysis 75 (2021) 101751
Table 4

Variable Targets (treatment) Non-targets (control) Targets – Non-targets SE for (3) (1) (2) (3) (4)

CEO_own 2.180 1.860 0.320 0.475 Spread 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 Num_5pct 3.270 3.380 − 0.110 0.186 CEO_delta 0.210 0.190 0.020 0.031 ROA 0.120 0.120 0.010 0.012
Size 7.320 7.120 0.200 0.165 Leverage 0.230 0.230 − 0.010 0.022 Turn 11.740 11.530 0.210 0.896 Stock returns 0.180 0.150 0.040 0.064 Volatility 0.030 0.030 0.000 0.001
Firm observations 177 177 354
(Firm-year observations) (1167) (1006) (2173)

Panel B: Difference-in-differences tests (t − 5 to t + 5 with Treatment at t = 0; N = 2173)

DV = Dist_invest

Overconfidence: Yes No Yes No Yes No FCF: Positive Positive Negative Negative (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

Targets 0.001 (0.011) Post_activism × FCF − 0.033 (0.148) 0.297*


Post_activism 0.011 (0.013) (0.095) (0.170) − 0.084 (0.115) 0.058
Targets × Post_activism − Targe ts × FCF 0.199 (0.126) (0.165) − 0.028** (0.011)
0.015 (0.017) Constant 0.059 (0.051) 0.014*
Targets × Post_activism × − 0.006 (0.014) − 0.014 (0.008) 0.009
FCF − 0.215 (0.181) (0.009) 0.008 (0.010) − 0.031** (0.012)
FCF 0.206** (0.091) (0.012) 0.063
− 0.010 (0.023) − 0.039** (0.019) 0.125** (0.048) − 0.009 (0.032)
− 0.001 (0.009) − 0.016* − 0.045 (0.030) 0.002 − 0.005 (0.025) − 0.009
(0.009) 0.005 (0.027) 0.023 (0.016) 0.004
(0.009) (0.045) (0.024)
Year dummy Included Included Included Included Included Included Industry dummy Included Included Included Included Included Included Observations 1025 1148 696 753 329
395 Adjusted R 2 0.091 0.089 0.008 0.006 0.148 0.003

Panel C: Difference-in-differences tests (t − 1 to t + 1 with Treatment at t = 0; N = 856)

DV = Dist_invest

Overconfidence: Yes No Yes No FCF: Positive Negative Positive Positive Negative Negative (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

Targets − 0.006 (0.021) (0.016) 0.032* (0.028) (0.050) 0.084 − 0.004 (0.028)
Post_activism 0.008 (0.022) (0.017) 0.052 (0.070)
Targets × Post_activism − (0.237) 0.165
0.020 (0.025) (0.285) 0.032
Targets × Post_activism × (0.212) 0.146
FCF − 0.330 (0.211) (0.258) 0.021
FCF 0.089 (0.121) (0.025)
Post_activism × FCF 0.116 0.033
(0.145) (0.019) 0.030 0.029
Targets × FCF 0.313** (0.118)(0.024) − 0.060** (0.027) (0.048) 0.210 0.032 (0.057)
Constant 0.128*** (0.019) − 0.021 (0.023) − 0.043* (0.034) 0.144*** (0.052)
− 0.025* (0.014) − 0.034** (0.024) 0.033 − 0.082 (0.052) − 0.055 − 0.003 (0.017) 0.003 (0.021)
Year dummy Included Included Included Included Included Included Industry dummy Included Included Included Included Included Included Observations 389 467 229 293 160 174
Adjusted R2 0.140 0.047 0.000 0.000 0.355 0.000

The hedge fund activism sample is comprised of 2173 firm-years for the 1996–2014 period. For the purpose of analyzing investment distortions, we classify four
subsamples based on CEO overconfidence and FCF levels (columns (3)–(6) in Panels B and C). In particular, columns (3) in Panels B and C comprise 229 to 696
firm

10
S. Kwon et al. firms hold positive FCF.
International Review of Financial Analysis 75 (2021) 101751
years of potential investment distortions, in which CEOs are overconfident and

Panel A summarizes the covariate balance between the treatment (13D filing) and control (non-filing) groups at t = 0. Panels B and C report results for whether
hedge fund activism influences firm overinvestment, where the dependent variable is Dist_invest. Dist_invest is the abnormal change in new investment after
excluding depreciation and amortization, obtained from Richardson's (2006) differencing model. Targets equals 1 for firm-year observations for which hedge fund
activists filed a Schedule 13D, and 0 for matched control firm observations. Post_activism equals 1 for periods after a Schedule 13D filing for Targets and
corresponding control firms, and 0 otherwise. Consequently, the coefficient for Targets × Post_activism reflects the difference-in-differences estimator of the effect of
the 13D filing on firm over
investment between the Target and control firms. FCF is free cash flow from existing assets less expected new investment. See Appendix B for all other variable
definitions.
All specifications are estimated using the fixed effects (FE) estimator. Two values are reported for each covariate: the coefficient estimate, and industry-clustered
standard errors (in parentheses). *, **, and *** indicate statistical significance at the 0.10, 0.05, and 0.01 levels, respectively.
that, relative to matched Non-targets, Targets experience a significant
drop in over
penentu. Columns (3) and (4) report the mean differences and standard investment after the entrance of hedge fund activists. The results
errors for the differences between Targets and Non-targets. The test support H2 and affirm that the contrast shown in columns (1) and (2) is
results show that the ten variables used in the matching process are not driven by the dynamic reduction in overinvestment of firms with
significantly different between matched pairs at the conventional level. simultaneously positive FCF and overconfident CEOs. However, in
The balanced covariates ensure that any change in overinvestment contrast to column (3), we do not find any similar results in any other
after the arrival of hedge fund activists may be reasonably attributed to subsamples (columns (4)–(6)).
shareholder activism rather than other observable firm characteristics. We also conduct an untabulated placebo test, in which we falsely
Using two subsamples where CEOs are overconfident and non assume that hedge fund activists filed a Schedule 13D at time t - 1. We
overconfident, we first run the DID model in columns (1) and (2) of find an insignificant coefficient for the DID estimator. This supports the
Panels B and C. Here, each panel includes observations within five- parallel trend assumption.
and one-year windows subsequent to the entrance of hedge fund Overall, using Malmendier and Tate's (2005) approach to capture
activists. The results indicate that, though not significant, the potential investment distortions, our analysis suggests that shareholder
coefficients on our triple interaction term, Targets × Post_activism × intervention does not uniformly curb overinvestment but is particularly
FCF, are opposite: negative in the overconfident CEO subsample (a effective at mitigating overinvestment that is more likely to be distorted.
range from − 0.330 to − 0.215) and positive in the non-overconfident These results add to Brav et al.'s (2018) finding that hedge fund
CEO subsample (a range from 0.052 to 0.063). Essentially, the activists facilitate firm innovation by providing additional evidence of
coefficient on this term will cap ture the change in ICFS when the firm is their role in optimizing firm investment.
under threat of hedge fund activism. A negative coefficient on this term
would suggest a reduction in ICFS, which we only observe for firms with 5. Further analysis
overconfident CEOs.
The results in columns (3)–(6) reveal the source of this contrast. The tests we presented in the previous section establish an associa
Using the four subsamples constructed based on different levels of tion between shareholder intervention and potential investment dis
CEO overconfidence and FCF (N = 160 to 753), we find that the tortions as measured by the ICFS of firms managed by overconfident
coefficients on Targets × Post_activism are negative and significant CEOs (Malmendier & Tate, 2005). However, we have not examined the
only in column (3) of both panels. This negative association suggests validity of our assumption that the ICFS of overconfident CEOs
captures potential investment distortions. We have also not sufficiently an infinite number of years.18 Specifically, in the distorted investment
addressed concerns over the potential endogeneity and noisy nature of subsamples (ie, columns (1) and (5)), the negative and significant co
the voting premium variable. In this section, we examine these issues, efficients (a range from − 0.260 to − 0.181) suggest a detrimental
in addition to conducting sensitivity checks on our main test results. impact of overinvestment on firm performance in the long run. The
5.1. Performance of the investment distortion subsample short-run effects are similar. The estimated coefficient on Dist_invest is
negative and significant (a range from − 0.141 to − 0.095), suggesting
The tests in Table 5 examine the financial performance of our four that in vestment distortions generate poor performance in the short run
subsamples by using system GMM (Blundell & Bond, 1998; Ullah, as well. The comparison of short- and long-run coefficients in columns
Akhtar, & Zaefarian, 2018) and Fama-MacBeth regression (Fama & (1) and (5) indicates a greater impact of overinvestment on firm
MacBeth, 1973) estimators. We adopt system GMM to mitigate performance in the long run (eg, − 0.181 with a p-value <0.05 in column
potential endogeneity concerns in our dynamic panel data where (1)) than in the short run (eg, − 0.095 with a p-value <0.05 in column
current-year firm performance is affected by pervious performance. (1)). The results do not alter even when we include lagged Dist_invest
Both ap (Lag_Dis t_invest) in the estimation model (column (5)). In contrast, in
proaches are commonly useful to correct for the potential correlation columns (2)–(4) and (6)–(8), where overinvestment is not necessarily
between independent variables and the error term, in which case the distorted, the estimated coefficients on Dist_invest are mostly smaller
exogeneity assumption underlying conventional OLS estimators is than those in the distorted subsamples and/or insignificant.
violated. To weaken these concerns, system GMM uses the lag of the The results are also qualitatively similar even when we adopt Fama
dependent variable as an instrument, and the Fama-MacBeth MacBeth regression (columns (9)–(12)). Here, we explicitly use future
regression uses time-series averages of regressions run each year. ROA instead of long-run GMM coefficients. Following Fu (2010), we
For the GMM estimation, we regress financial performance, adopt the 5-year median of future ROA as a dependent variable and
measured as ROA,17 on Dist_invest (and the lag of Dist_invest) after Dist_invest as the main variable of interest. We also control for all the
con trolling for lagged ROA, leverage, size effect, growth opportunity, variables used in the GMM estimation. Although the performance
and year fixed effects. In all columns, Hansen statistics for
overidentifying restrictions are insignificant, indicating valid instruments.
The tests for second-order autocorrelation in the error term (ie, AR(2)) 17
We use income before extraordinary items to construct ROA because
are also insignificant, which implies that the lag of ROA and other operating ROA does not pass the AR(2) test. Except for this serial correlation in
instrumental variables are reasonably exogenous. the error term, the estimation results using operating income are qualitatively
In columns (1)–(8), we first report the long-run GMM coefficients. similar to those using income before extraordinary items (untabulated).
18
While GMM coefficients represent immediate effects, long-run co We calculate long-run GMM coefficients using the “nlcom” command in
efficients capture the responsiveness of ROA to overinvestment after Stata 15.

11
e

y-
r

ht
e

Bc
a

e
**

)
***

)
**

)
**

)
***

)
s

b
s

m
u

e
e

t
s

lb
-

hT
a

ir
a

c
5

fr
e

n
5

OR
A

OR

F
M

le
d

Y
o

fi

e
v

t
is
o

itu
a

ge

itu
a

ge

t
is
o

t
is
o

itu
a

ge

itu
a

ge

v
i

t
is
o

t
is
o

9(

8(

7(

6(

5(

4(

3(

2(

1(

fif
e

4
1.

0−

08
0.

0−

97
0.

0−

06
2.

0−

31
1.

0−

81
0.

0−

65
0.

0−

18
1.

0−

ts
e

n
it
_

30
1.

0(

)24
0.

0(

)24
0.

0(

)29
0.

0(

)46
0.

0(

)03
0.

0(

)8
2

0.

0(

)19
0.

0(

0.

0−

37
0.

0−
99
0.

0−

08
2.

0−

ts
e

n
i

iD
__

49
0.

0(

)65
0.

0(

)81
1.

0(

)11
1.

0(
*

78
3.

19
2.

84
1.

13
3.

65
4.

*
*

69
2.

95
1.

03
3.

07
4.

OR
_
43
0.

0(

50
1.

0(

)67
0.

0(

)64
0.

0(

)75
0.

0(

)40
1.

0(

)18
0.

0(

)6
4

0.

0(

)48
0.

0(
05
0.

0−

0.

0−

76
0.

0−

35
0.

0−

*
*

14
1.

0−

97
0.

0−

51
0.

0−

73
0.

0−

59
0.

0−

ts
e

n
it
_
61
0.

0(

)0
7

0.

0(

)53
0.

0(

)72
0.

0(

)24
0.

0(

)04
0.

0(

)42
0.

0(

)8
1

0.

0(

)0
4

0.

0(

23
0.

0−

36
0.

0−

66
0.

0−

25
1.

0−
ts
e

n
i

iD
__

76
0.

0(

)84
0.

0(

)97
0.

0(

)55
0.

0(
7

0
.

0
.

0
.

0
.

0
.

0
.

0
9

0
.

0
.

0
.

e
60
0.

0(

92
0.

0(

)02
0.

0(

)01
0.

0(

)51
0.

0(

)23
0.

0(

)02
0.

0(

)90
0.

0(

)6
1

0.

0(
*

60
0.

80
0.

71
0.

10
0.

0−
*

51
0.

90
0.

71
0.

20
0.

0−

60
0.

e
10
0.

0(

71
0.

0(

)42
0.

0(

)70
0.

0(

)80
0.

0(

)81
0.

0(

)21
0.

0(

)7
0

0.

0(

)7
0

0.

0(
*

21
0.

0.

*
12
0.

23
0.

21
0.

80
0.

91
0.

23
0.

01
0.

0
20
0.

0(

)7
0

0.

0(

)60
0.

0(

)30
0.

0(

)20
0.

0(

)70
0.

0(

)50
0.

0(

)3
0

0.

0(

)2
0

0.

0(
12
1.

0−
t

ts
n
02
0.

0(

de
d

u
lc
n

de
d

u
lc
n

de
d

u
lc
n

de
d

u
lc
n

de
d

u
lc
n

I
de
d

u
lc
n

de
d

u
lc
n

de
d

u
lc
n

d
r

34
3

227

117

0771

5602

227

117

0771

5602

o
it
a

0.

0
00
0.

00
0.

00
0.

00
0.

00
0.

00
0.

00
0.

>

3.

77
1.

66
7.

02
9.

76
2.

96
1.

22
9.

0
93
8.

2i
hc

>

(
)

2.

02
6.

00
1.

02
3.

70
2.

47
1.

10
1.

62
3.

2i
hc

>

(
s

it
s

it
a

3
.

0
2

u
j
u

fi
s

a
l

d
t

la
n
a

f
s

fi

lp

v
v

dl

h
s

fi

d
fi

dan

aku

d
t

fi

(
s

a
l

it
a

870
3
e

l
e

,
a

r
a

)2
1

(
s

dan

aku

dr
o

fe
b

)
8

(
s

le
lakukan

fi

d
)6
0

(
s

'

dr
a

de
n

lc
x

dan

aku

la

t
s

fie
d
e

ht

ll

dan

aku

m
hc
a

la
v

)2
1

(
s

dan

aku

o
i

ht
e

(
s

dan

aku

fii

le
v

le
v

t
t

fii

)s
e

ht

(
s

dr
a

ht
e

B
l

ba
T
a

iF
VD
o

M
v

O
CF
o

L
s

iD
ga
L
ga
L
s

iD
ga
L
v

12
z

iS

Q
o

C
e

Y
bO
o

P
RA
a

H
dA

hT
tr
a

p
M

MG
o

I
r

i
o

l
n


c

pS
c

S. Kwon et al. diagnostic tests reported in column (1) of Table 6, where we regress VP
on X and the controls included in Eq. (2), indicate that our IV is reliable.
deteriorates most when CEOs are overconfident and FCF is negative (− Specifically, the Kleibergen-Paap RK Lagrange multiplier statistic
0.075 with a p-value <0.01 in column (11)), we find that, if FCF is (59.67; p-value = 0.000) and the Cragg-Donald Wald F statistic (75.03;
positive, future performance is poorer when CEOs are overconfident (− threshold proposed by Stock & Yogo, 2005 at the 10% bias level is
0.050 with a p-value <0.01 in column (9) vs − 0.009 with a p-value 16.38) suggest that our model and IV are neither under-identified nor
>0.10 in column (10)). weak.
Our results complement those of Fu (2010), who interprets a nega The estimation results reported in columns (2)–(5), where we
tive association between investment and future firm performance as regress Dist_invest on VP_Pred (ie, predicted values estimated from
implying overinvestment, by demonstrating that overconfident CEOs column (1)) and the controls, confirm the robustness our findings. The
mostly drive the detrimental impact of overinvestment on firm negative as sociation between VP_Pred and Dist_invest is only
performance. observed in column (2), where simultaneously CEOs are overconfident
and firms hold positive FCF. We find no significant and/or negative
coefficients of VP_Pred in columns (3)–(5).
5.2. Endogeneity concerns
5.2.2. Control contests and voting events
5.2.1. Instrumental variables analysis
We note that not all voting premiums aim to reshape firm
To attenuate the concern that the negative association between the
investment. For example, regardless of the level of investment
voting premium and investment distortions (column (5) in Table 3) may
distortion, the voting premium can become larger due to control
be confounded by endogeneity, we consider an IV strategy. As previ
contests, such as, eg, M&A (Kalay et al., 2014). Similarly, even when
ously noted, we instrument the voting premium (VP) using the exercise
shareholders are paying voting premiums to alter incumbent CEOs, this
price of the market option (X), which relates mechanically to VP (Kalay
may not be due to their investment distortions. Therefore, a larger
voting premium does not necessarily represent shareholders' exclusive
Table 6
intentions or actual ac
Instrumental variables analysis.
tions to influence firm investment. One way to reduce concerns about
DV = VP Dist_invest the voting premium variable is to remove potentially confounding ef
Overconfidence: Yes Yes No Yes No FCF: Positive Positive Positive Negative fects as much as possible (eg, control contests and actual voting
Negative Model: 1st stage 2nd stage
events), and gauge whether there is any surviving effect on over
investment. Any remaining effect is closer to the disciplinary threats of
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)
International Review of Financial Analysis 75 (2021) 101751

et al., 2014) but does not necessarily affect overinvestment. Formal


VP_Pred − 0.040** (0.020) 0.023* (0.013)
shareholder control rights Francis & Smith, 1995). To aforementioned potentially
X 0.200*** 0.023 (0.020) that prior studies have this end, we adopt a confounding effects after
(0.025) assumed in this research two-stage methodology. First, controlling
0.001 (0.020)
area (eg, Brav et al., 2018; we regress VP on the
Controls Included Included Included Included Included
for industry/year fixed effects and an exogenous variable (Eq. (5)). As
Constant − 0.383 (0.239) 0.020 (0.036) change of CEO constitute a typical voting event,
0.039 (0.022) 0.004 (0.033) noted earlier, M&A
(Pr(CEO_turn over)) control contest and respectively.
0.015 (0.022) (Pr(Takeover)) and a
Year dummy Included Included Included Included Included Industry dummy Included lawsuits is a last resort for shareholders. Again, X serves as an
Included Included Included Included Observations 3434 3434 2453 1349 1110
exogenous
We also include shareholder litigation (Pr(Litigation)), because filing
Under consistent with Kalay et al. (2014). On the other
identification test: Kleibergen Paap RK LM 16.38 hand, VP significantly and negatively relates to
statistic (Chi-sq (1))
variable here. We use the residual component Pr(Litigation), because share
Cragg-Donald Wald F statistic Stock-Yogo weak ID test
critical value (bias from this regression to capture the incremental holders will not pay premiums to exercise voting
<10%) effect of VP beyond that of M&A, CEO dismissal,rights if costly and time-consuming lawsuits have
59.67*** and shareholder litigation (VP_resid). been filed. VP_resid estimated from Eq. (5) is
Table 7, Panel A, reports the estimation results orthogonal to the effects of these three events.
of Eq. (5). Although not significant, the
coefficients of Pr(Takeover) and
Pr(CEO_turnover) are positive, which is
75.03
Adjusted R2 0.110 All specifications are estimated using the instrumental variables estimator. Two
Uncentered R2 − 0.000 0.020 0.051 0.054 values are reported for each covariate: the coefficient estimate, and robust
standard errors (in parentheses). *, **, and *** indicate statistical significance at
The voting premium sample is comprised of 8346 firm-years for the 1996–2014
the 0.10, 0.05, and 0.01 levels, respectively.
period. For the purpose of analyzing investment distortions, we classify four
columns based on CEO overconfidence and FCF levels. In particular, columns
(1) and (2) comprise 3434 firm-years of potential investment distortions in which VPt =λ0+λ1Xt+λ2Pr(Takeovert)+λ3Pr(CEO turnovert)+λ4Pr(Litigationt)
CEOs are overconfident and firms hold positive FCF. +ΣYearfixed effect+ΣIndustry fixed effect+ν
The dependent variables are VP and Dist_invest in columns (1) and (2)–(5), (5)
respectively. Dist_invest is the abnormal change in new investment after
excluding depreciation and amortization, obtained from Richardson's (2006) Second, we run our main model, Eq. (2), after substituting VP_resid
differencing model. VP is the shareholder voting premium, estimated by taking for VP. Panel B presents the results from the estimation of the relation
the difference between a synthetic stock price without voting rights and the between VP_resid and firm overinvestment, which we obtain using the
stock price with voting rights, whereas VP_Pred is the predicted values fixed effects estimator. Consistent with the results in Table 3, the re
estimated from column (1). The endogenous variable is VP and the sidual component of a voting premium is also negatively and signifi
instrumental variable is X. X is the natural logarithm of the exercise price of cantly associated with firm overinvestment only in the potentially
market option. Control variables are the same as in Eq. (2) and are explained in
distorted investment subsample (column (1)). The coefficients for
Appendix B.
VP_resid in the other subsamples are insignificant (columns (2)–(4)). tests, and shareholder litigation, and lend support to the disciplinary
These results suggest that our main findings in Table 3 are not signifi threat hypothesis.
cantly confounded by the effects of actual voting events, control con

13
S. Kwon et al. model Alternative specifications. Panel A: Overconfidence
International Review of Financial Analysis 75 (2021) 101751
Table 7
Control contests and voting events. Panel A: Residual Table 8
Pr(Takeover) 0.014 (0.157)
Pr(CEO_turnover) 0.589 (0.359)
DV at t + 1 = Dist_invest

Assumption Permanent Permanent Permanent Transitory Pseudo-mating Yes Yes

Yes No In-the-money threshold 67% 100% 150% 67% (1) (2) (3) (4)
DV = VP

X 0.263*** (0.019)
Pr(Litigation) − 0.405*** (0.103) VP − 0.008*** (0.003) − 0.008** (0.003) − 0.010** (0.004) − 0.008** (0.003)
Pr(Takeover)_dum 0.154
Controls Included Included Included Included
(0.153) Constant 0.028** (0.013) 0.032** (0.015) 0.012 (0.016) 0.031 (0.013)
Pr(CEO_turnover)_dum 0.093*
(0.047) Included Included Included Observations 3434 2314 1387 3336 Adjusted R 2 0.006
Constant − 0.470*** (0.107) 0.000 0.020 0.006
Year dummy Included Industry dummy Included Observations 8346 Adjusted R 2
0.116 Panel B: Overinvestment measure and model specification

DV at t + 1 = Dist_invest Alt_dist (I) Alt_dist (II) (1) (2) (3)


Panel B: Overinvestment model
Year dummy Included Included Included Included Industry dummy Included
DV at t + 1 = Dist_invest Positive Positive Negative Negative (1) (2) Q 0.001 (0.002) − 0.006** (0.003) 0.003
CEO_own − 0.003 (0.040) (0.002) − 0.021 (0.042)
Overconfidence: Yes No Yes No FCF: (3) (4)
− 0.007** (0.002) 0.004** (0.002) − 0.009
VP − 0.007** (0.003) (0.044)
VP_resid − 0.006*** 0.003 (0.002) − 0.000 (0.004) CEO_delta 0.000*** (0.000) 0.000*** (0.000) 0.000*** (0.000)
(0.002) − 0.001 (0.004)
Controls Included Included Included Included Size − 0.003* − 0.016*** − 0.014***
Constant 0.024 (0.013) 0.039*** (0.010) 0.004 (0.030) Duality 0.001 (0.003) − 0.005 (0.002) − 0.005
0.031 (0.007) (0.002)
Year dummy Included Included Included 0.000 1996–2014 (0.005) 0.007
Included Industry dummy Included Included (0.004) (0.038) 0.152** * (0.020)
Included Included Observations 3434 2453 The voting premium sample is Duality_dum 0.008 (0.019) (0.005) 0.020
1349 1110 Adjusted R 2 0.005 0.018 0.026 comprised of 8346 firm-years for the Constant 0.047*** (0.017) (0.022) 0.132*** (0.020)
standard errors (in parentheses). *, **, and *** indicate statistical significance at
period. For the purpose of analyzing investment distortions, we classify four
the 0.10, 0.05, and 0.01 levels, respectively.
subsamples based on CEO overconfidence and FCF levels. In particular,
Year dummy Included Included Included Industry dummy Included Included
column (1) of Panel B comprises 3434 firm-years of potential investment Included Observations 3432 3432 3432 Adjusted R 2 0.004 0.082 0.063
distortions in which CEOs are overconfident and firms hold positive FCF.
In Panel A, the dependent variable is VP, which is the shareholder voting pre The voting premium sample is comprised of 8346 firm-years for the 1996–2014
mium estimated by taking the difference between a synthetic stock price without period. For the purpose of analyzing investment distortions, we use the invest
voting rights and the stock price with voting rights. For variables capturing the ment distortion subsample, which comprises 3434 firm-years in which CEOs
ex ante probability of exercising shareholder control rights, we include Pr are overconfident and firms hold positive FCF. In Panel B, we analyze 3432 firm
(CEO_turnover), Pr(Litigation), and Pr(Takeover). Pr(CEO_turnover) is the fitted years due to the missing values of CEO_delta.
value of Pr(CEO_turnovert) = α0 + α1̂rt-1 + α2̂et-1 + α3̂rt-2 + α4̂et-2 + α5Ownershipt In Panel A, the dependent variable is Dist_invest in all columns. Dist_invest is
∑ the abnormal change in new investment after excluding depreciation and amorti
+ Firm fixed effect + ε, where r̂ t-1 and e ̂ t-1 are the fitted values and residuals of
zation, obtained from Richardson's (2006) differencing model. The variable of
̂rt-1 = α0 + α1rpeer group,t-1 + ζt-1, respectively (Jenter & Kanaan, 2015). Pr(Liti
interest, VP, is the shareholder voting premium, estimated by taking the dif
gation) is the fitted value of Pr(Litigationt) = α0 + α1Sizet + α2Stock turnovert +
ference between a synthetic stock price without voting rights and the stock
α3Betat + α4Stock returnst + α5Volatilityt + α6Skewnesst + α7Minimum Returnst +
price with voting rights. Control variables are the same as in Eq. (2). See
α8High risk industriest + ε (Rogers & Stocken, 2005). Pr(Takeover) is the fitted Appendix B for all other variable definitions.
value of Pr(Takeovert) = α0 + α1ROAt-1 + α2Leveraget-1 + α3Ln(Assets)t-1 + In this analysis, column (1) matches our main definition of CEO overconfidence
∑ as reported in Table 3. In column (2), we change the 67% cutoff to 100%, while
α4Tobin's Qt-1 + α5Asset structuret-1 + α6Blockholder ownershipt-1 + Year fixed
∑ keeping all other conditions the same as in column (1). In column (3), we set
effect + Industry fixed effect + ε (Cremers et al., 2008). Pr(CEO_turnover) the cutoff to 150%. Finally, in column (4), we assume that CEO overconfidence
_dum and Pr(Takeover)_dum are indicator variables that equal 1 for firms is a transitory trait, and thus CEOs do not retain their overconfidence
where Pr(CEO_turnover) and Pr(Takeover) are missing, and 0 otherwise, classification onward.
respectively. After controlling for these dummy variables, we replace missing
In Panel B, the dependent variables are Dist_invest, Alt_dist (I), and Alt_dist (II)
Pr(CEO_turn
in columns 1, 2, and 3, respectively. Alt_dist (I) is abnormal total investment, ob
over) and Pr(Takeover) values with zeros. X is the natural logarithm of the ex
tained from Biddle et al.'s (2009) sales growth model. Alt_dist (II) is abnormal
ercise price of market option.
new investment after excluding depreciation and amortization, obtained from
In Panel B, the dependent variable is Dist_invest in all columns. Dist_invest is
Biddle et al.'s (2009) sales growth model. The variable of interest, VP, is the
the abnormal change in new investment after excluding depreciation and amorti
shareholder voting premium, estimated by taking the difference between a
zation, obtained from Richardson's (2006) differencing model. The variable of
synthetic stock price without voting rights and the stock price with voting rights.
interest, VP_resid, is the residuals taken from Eq. (5), in which we regress VP
Duality_dum is an indicator variable that equals 1 for firms where Duality is
on the variables capturing the actual exercise of shareholder control rights.
missing, and 0 otherwise. After controlling for this dummy variable, we replace
Control
missing Duality values with zeros. Control variables are consistent with those
variables are the same as in Eq. (2), and are explained in Appendix B. All
proposed by Malmendier and Tate (2005).
specifications are estimated using the fixed effects estimator. Two values are
reported for each covariate: the coefficient estimate, and industry-clustered

14
S. Kwon et al.
All specifications are estimated using the fixed effects (FE) estimator. Two
values are reported for each covariate: the coefficient estimate, and
industry-clustered standard errors (in parentheses). *, **, and *** indicate A.1. Overinvestment
statistical significance at the 0.10, 0.05, and 0.01 levels, respectively. International Review of Financial Analysis 75 (2021) 101751

5.3. Sensitivity tests effectively addresses the agency costs of FCF, our study adds to the
literature by documenting that shareholder intervention does not uni
Lastly, we conduct sensitivity analyses by changing the formly deter all overinvestments, but is particularly effective at allevi
specifications of our main variables (Dist_invest and CEO_over) and ating investment distortions caused by both overconfident CEOs and
the investment model (Eq. (2)). Table 8, Panel A, gives the results for surplus cash flow simultaneously.
alternative specifications of CEO_over. Specifically, from the estimation As with most research of this type, the results should be interpreted
results of our base model in column (1), we modify the cutoff from 67% with some caveats. An important concern is measurement error. Given
to 100% and 150%, respectively (columns (2) and (3)). In column (4), that we use proxies for unobservable abnormal investment and share
we then measure CEO overconfidence based on an alternative holder interventions, our variables may inevitably fail to capture what
assumption that CEO optimism may be a transitory trait that changes they set out to represent. To mitigate this concern, we adopt comple
every year. Therefore, CEO_over equals 1 only in those years when mentary variables for overinvestment (ie, abnormal investment defined
CEOs do not exercise stock options that are more than 67% in the by Richardson, 2006 and Biddle et al., 2009) and shareholder
money. As consistently shown in columns (1)–(4), our results are robust interventions (ie, voting premium and hedge fund activism).
to these variations in the CEO_over variable. With this caveat in mind, our results raise important policy impli
To test the sensitivity of our results to alternative model specifica cations for the controversial debate over how much power to allocate to
tions, we adopt the investment model proposed by Malmendier and shareholders and to the board (Bebchuk, 2005). On the one hand,
Tate (2005), Eq. (3), and the two different overinvestment definitions enhancing shareholder control rights may serve to protect shareholder
from prior studies (Alt_dist (I) and Alt_dist (II)). As explained in Eq. (8) value; on the other hand, increased shareholder power may cause
of Appendix A, we use Biddle et al.'s (2009) sales growth model to expropriation by entrenched shareholders (Luo & Jackson, 2012),
estimate abnormal levels of investment. Panel B confirms that our create managerial myopia, and hinder effective and appropriate board
findings are not susceptible to alternative model specifications or func tioning (Burns & Minnick, 2013). In this regard, our results provide
estimation methods of abnormal investment. insights into the value of shareholder interventions in a context of po
tential investment distortions.
6. Conclusion Future studies could analyze more specific mechanisms of share
holder intervention through proxy contests, and might also investigate
In contrast to prior studies that have explored firm investment and whether shareholder intervention plays different roles depending on
shareholder intervention, we capture potential investment distortions by firms' industry membership (Hirshleifer, Low, & Teoh, 2012), the level of
using the ICFS of firms managed by overconfident CEOs. This unique managerial discretion, and the presence of management protection
ICFS type allows us to examine the impact of shareholder voices on provisions. Such research would broaden our understanding of the role
overinvestments that are more likely to be distorted. of shareholder voices in optimizing firm investment.
Using a range of 2173 to 8346 US firm-year observations for the
1996–2014 period, we provide consistent evidence that shareholder CRediT authorship contribution statement
interventions, as measured by the voting premium and hedge fund
activism, are effective in curbing investment distortions. However, we Jae Hwan Ahn: Conceptualization, Methodology, Software, Writing
do not find similar effects in any other types of overinvestment that are - original draft. Gi H. Kim: Conceptualization, Methodology, Writing -
not necessarily distorted. The effects of shareholder intervention acting review & editing. Sewon Kwon: Conceptualization, Methodology,
as a credible threat to CEOs are significantly incremental to those of Writing - review & editing.
actual voting events, control contests, and shareholder litigation, sup
porting the disciplinary threat hypothesis. Acknowledgements
While a strand of studies indicates that shareholder intervention
We thank Brian Lucey (editor) and two anonymous referees for their
valuable suggestions and comments that significantly improved the
Appendix A. Estimation of main variables paper.

We estimate overinvestment (Dist_invest) with the residuals from Richardson's (2006) differencing model. Adopting new investment as a
dependent variable in Eq. (6) has the advantage of excluding the effect of the ordinary maintenance of existing investment (ie, depreciation and
amortization) from total investment (Eq. (7)). This model assumes that firms' new investment decisions are affected by their growth opportunities
(Growth op portunities), as well as by financial characteristics such as leverage (Leverage), firm size (Size), firm age (Age), cash investment (Cash),
and stock returns (Stock returns). In particular, the model addresses unobserved firm heterogeneities by incorporating the first differencing of
investment levels. Variable definitions are in Appendix B.

New investt =α0+α1Growthopportunitiest− 1+α2Leveraget− 1+α3Sizet− 1


+α4Aget− 1+α5Casht− 1+α6Stock returnst− 1 +α7Newinvestmentst−
(6)
1+ΣYearfixedeffect +ΣIndustryfixedeffect+ε

Total investt = α0 + α1Maint investt + α2New investt (7)

15
S. Kwon et al. International Review of Financial Analysis 75 (2021) 101751

A.2. Alternative specifications of overinvestment


To reduce measurement bias, we construct two alternative specifications of overinvestment adopted by previous studies: total overinvestment
(Biddle et al., 2009), and new overinvestment (Richardson, 2006). Total overinvestment is the sum of new and maintenance investment.19 To test
the sensitivity of our main results, we also alternatively adopt Biddle et al.'s (2009) sales growth model (Eq. (8)). This model assumes that abnormal
investment consists of what the previous year's sales growth (Sales growth) cannot explain. The residuals from this model, estimated for each
Fama-French classification-year grouping (ie, Alt_dist (I) and Alt_dist (II)), are taken as firm overinvestment.
Investmentt = α0 + α1Sales growtht− 1 + ε (8)

A.3. Voting premium

To reduce endogeneity concerns about the percentage of ownership measures as a proxy for shareholder control rights (Cornett, Marcus,
Saunders, & Tehranian, 2007), we use the market value of the voting premium, as proposed by Kalay et al. (2014). The voting premium is
̂
calculated by deducting the price of a synthetic stock without voting rights (S(T)), estimated by the put-call parity in Eq. (9), from its current stock
market price with voting rights (S). Since the difference represents the price that shareholders would pay to exercise their voting rights, it ideally
captures the magnitude of shareholder control rights in general, and the willingness to exercise voting rights in particular. We then scale the voting
premium by the market price (S) to normalize and average it for one year (VP) (Lin et al., 2018).20

̂
S(T) = C − P + PV(X) + PV(Div)− EEPcall + EEPput (9)

where.
ˆ
S (T) = price of a synthetic stock implied in the put-call parity with maturity T;
C = premiums of call options;
P = premiums of put options;
PV(X) = present value of a bond with par value X;
PV(Div) = present value of dividend payments;
EEPcall = early exercise premiums for call options;
EEPput = early exercise premiums for put options.

A.4. CEO overconfidence

As a proxy for CEO overconfidence, we adopt the option-based measure (CEO_over) proposed by Malmendier and Tate (2005) and its
variations. Investment-based overconfidence measures (see, eg, Schrand & Zechman, 2012; and Ahmed & Duellman, 2013) are inappropriate for
our analyses, because our dependent variable is also an overinvestment measure (Dist_invest). CEO_over is an indicator variable that equals 1 for
a CEO holding stock options that are more than 67% in the money without exercising them (Campbell et al., 2011; Hsu et al., 2017; Malmendier &
Tate, 2005).21 Because risk-averse CEOs with undiversified portfolios are likely to exercise stock options once they are vested and reasonably in the
money, postponing these options implies that these CEOs have strong optimism about future firm performance.
Consistent with Malmendier and Tate (2005), we classify CEOs as overconfident from the first year onward if they fail to exercise stock options
that are more than 67% in the money, and exhibit overconfident behavior, at least twice during their tenure. However, following Hsu et al. (2017), we
allow CEOs to be reclassified as non-overconfident in years when they exhibit the opposite behavior (ie, exercising stock options that are less than
67% in the money) at least twice after they have been classified as overconfident. This enables us to avoid the potential problem that a CEO who
becomes “unbiased” will still be identified as overconfident, while maintaining the advantage of capturing relatively permanent rather than transitory
effects of optimism (see Malmendier & Tate, 2005).

A.5. Free cash flow (FCF)

To obtain a clean measure of FCF, we follow Richardson's (2006) Eq. (10)). This measure deducts expected new investment (New_invest*) – the
fitted value of Eq. (6) – from the cash flow from operating activities (CFO) to capture net sources of FCF in excess of those required to fund all
potentially positive-NPV projects (Jensen, 1986).

FCF = CFO–Maint invest + R&D–New invest* (10)

19
Consistent with Malmendier and Tate (2005), all investment measures are deflated by net PP&E (ppent).
20
Consistent with Kalay et al. (2014), we adopt pairs of American-style call and put options with identical strike prices and maturities. We then exclude options with
maturities exceeding 90 days, with locked or crossed quotes, with missing volume and implied volatility data, or with moneyness between 0.1 and − 0.1. Finally, we
require that these pairs have at least ten observations in each year. We estimate the early exercise premium of American options using Barone-Adesi and Whaley's
(1987) approximations.
21
To calculate the moneyness of stock options, we follow Campbell et al.'s (2011) method, which uses Execucomp data.

16
S. Kwon et al. International Review of Financial Analysis 75 (2021) 101751

Appendix B. Variable definitions


Variable Definition Data source Dependent variables

Dist_invest Residuals (ε) from New_investt = α0 + α1Growth opportunitiest-1 + VP Value of voting rights, estimated as the difference between the market price
α2Leveraget-1 + α3Sizet-1 + α4Age + α5Casht-1 + α6Stock returnst-1 + α7New of a stock with voting rights and the price of non-voting synthetic stock implied in
investmentst-1 + Σ Year fixed effect + Σ Industry fixed effect + ε, where put-call parity. The value is then normalized by the stock price and annualized
New_invest is the ratio of the sum of capital expenditure (capx), R&D over one year (Kalay et al., 2014).
expenditure (xrd), acquisitions (aqc), sale of PP&E (− sppe), and amortization Compustat
and depreciation (− dpc) to average total assets (at) (Richardson, 2006).
Alt_dist (I) Residuals from Total_investt = α0 + α1Sales growtht-1 + ε, where
Total_invest is the ratio of the sum of capital expenditure (capx), R&D
expenditure (xrd), acquisitions (aqc), and sale of PP&E (− sppe) to net PP&E Compustat Compustat
(ppent) (Biddle et al., 2009). Alt_dist (II) Residuals from New_investt = α0 +
α1Sales growtht-1 + ε, where New_invest is the ratio of the sum of capital
expenditure (capx), R&D expenditure (xrd), acquisitions (aqc), sale of PP&E (−
sppe), and amortization and depreciation (− dpc) to net PP&E (ppent) OptionMetrics
(Richardson, 2006).
Variables of interest

Targets Indicator variable that equals 1 for firms for which hedge fund activists filed a Schedule 13D, and 0 otherwise. Brav et al. (2018)
CEO_over Indicator variable that equals 1 for firms with CEOs holding stock 2017; Malmendier & Tate, 2005).
options that are more than 67% in the money, and 0 otherwise (Hsu et al., Execucomp

FCF Free cash flow from existing assets less expected new investments (Richardson, 2006). Compustat Financial and market ratios
Size Natural logarithm of total assets (at). Compustat ROA Ratio of income before extraordinary items (ib) to average total assets (at). Compustat
Q Ratio of the sum of the market value of equity (mktval) and the book value of Compustat
liability (lt) to total assets (at) (Malmendier & Tate, 2005).
Ratio of firm value (V) to the market value of firm (0.62/(1 + 12%–0.62)) (Richardson, 2006).
Growth equity. V is estimated as VAIP = (1–α × 12%) × ceq + Compustat
opportunity α(1 + 12%) × oiadp – α × 12% × dvc, where α =
Leveraget ((dlc + dltt)/(dlc + dltt + seq) – 39.3678 × (Dividendt/Total capitalt-1)
Leverage Ratio of the sum of debt in current liabilities (dlc) and long-term debt ((dvc + dvp)/(ppent)) - 1.314759 × (Casht/Total capitalt-1) (che/ppent) (Kaplan
(dltt) to the sum of total liabilities (lt) and the book value of common equity & Zingales, 1997).
(ceq). Compustat Compustat
KZ_index Quartile rank of the Kaplan and Zingales index estimated by KZ
index = − 1.001909 × (Cash flowt/Total capitalt-1) ((ib + dp)/(ppent)) +
0.2826389 × Tobin's Qt ((lse + csho × prcc_f – ceq – txdb)/lse) + 3.139193 ×

Cash Ratio of cash and short-term investment (che) to lagged total assets (at). Compustat Sales growth Percentage change in sales from t-1 to t. Compustat
Stock returns Annual buy-and-hold stock returns. CRSP Volatility Yearly mean of standard deviation of daily stock returns over a rolling window of 120 days by
CRSP id (ie, permno). CRSP Turn Ratio of average share volume to average shares outstanding. CRSP Spread Yearly median of the difference between bid and
ask prices divided by their midpoint price. CRSP Age Natural loga rithm of years since first CRSP date. CRSP X Natural logarithm of the exercise price of market
option. OptionMetrics CEO equity incentives
CEO_own Shares held by a CEO excluding stock options divided by total shares. Execucomp CEO_delta Sum of the sensitivities of stock options to a 1% change in stock price
(https://sites.temple.edu/lnaveen/data/). Coles, Daniel, and Naveen (2006) Governance control and CEO discretion
Out_director Ratio of outside directors on the board to total number of directors. Riskmetrics, IRRC Duality Indicator variable that equals 1 for firms with a CEO who is
also a chairman of the board, and 0 otherwise. Execucomp Num_5pct Number of institutional blockholders who own more than 5% of shares. Thomson Reuters 13F
Institutional Holdings
Exercise of control rights
Pr(CEO_turnover) Fitted value of Pr(CEO_turnovert) = α0 + α1̂rt-1 + α2̂et-1 + α3̂rt-2 + α4̂et-2
∑ Aghion, P., Van Reenen, J., & Zingales, L. (2013). Innovation and institutional
+ α5Ownershipt + Firm fixed effect + ε, where r̂ t-1 and ̂et-1 are the fitted value and
ownership. American Economic Review, 103(1), 277–304.
residuals of r̂ t-1 = α0 + α1rpeer group,t-1 + ζt-1, respectively (Jenter & Kanaan, 2015); https://doi.org/10.1257/ aer.103.1.277
CEO_turnover is an indicator variable that equals 1 if a CEO leaves the firm under the
Ahmed, AS, & Duellman, S. (2013). Managerial overconfidence and accounting
age of 60, and 0 otherwise. Ownership is an indicator variable that equals 1 for firms
conservatism. Journal of Accounting Research, 51(1), 1–30.
with CEOs holding more than 5% of shares.
https://doi.org/10.1111/ j.1475-679X.2012.00467.x
Pr(Litigation) Fitted value of Pr(Litigationt) = α0 + α1Sizet + α2Stock turnovert + α3Betat + Aktas, N., Andreou, PC, Karasamani, I., & Philip, D. (2018). CEO duality, agency
α4Stock returnst + α5Volatilityt + α6Skewnesst + α7Minimum Returnst + α8High risk costs, and internal capital allocation efficiency. British Journal of Management,
industriest + ε (Rogers & Stocken, 2005); Litigation is an indicator variable that equals 1 30(2), 473–493. https://doi.org/10.1111/1467-8551.12277
for firms for which securities class action lawsuits have been filed by investors, and 0 Barone-Adesi, G., & Whaley, RE (1987). Efficient analytic approximation of American
otherwise. option values. The Journal of Finance, 42(2), 301–320. https://doi.org/10.1111/
Pr(Takeover) Fitted value of Pr(Takeovert) = α0 + α1ROAt-1 + α2Leveraget-1 + j.1540-6261.1987.tb02569.x
∑ Barth, ME, Cahan, SF, Chen, L., & Venter, ER (2017). The economic consequences
α3Ln(Assets)t-1 + α4Tobin's Qt-1 + α5Asset structuret-1 + α6Blockholder ownershipt-1 + associated with integrated report quality: Capital market and real effects.
∑ Accounting, Organizations and Society, 62, 43–64.
Year fixed effect + Industry fixed effect + ε (Cremers, Nair, & John, 2008); Takeover is
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.aos.2017.08.005
an indicator variable that equals 1 for takeover target firms, and 0 otherwise.
Baysinger, BD, Kosnik, RD, & Turk, TA (1991). Effects of board and ownership
Execucomp structure on corporate R&D strategy. Academy of Management Journal,
34(1), 205–214. https://doi.org/10.5465/256308
Bebchuk, LA (2005). The case for increasing shareholder power. Harvard Law
Review, 118(3), 833–914.
Stanford Law School Bhagat, S., & Jefferis, R. (2002). The econometrics of corporate governance
studies. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

Thomson One Banker-Deals

References

17
International Review of Financial Analysis 75 (2021) 101751
S. Kwon et al. overconfidence, and investment–cash flow sensitivity: Evidence from listed

Biddle, GC, Hilary, G., & Verdi, RS (2009). How does financial reporting quality relate
to investment efficiency? Journal of Accounting and Economics, 48(2–3), companies in China. Pacific-Basin Finance Journal, 19(3), 261–277. https://doi.org/
112–131. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jacceco.2009.09.001 10.1016/j.pacfin.2010.12.001
Blundell, R., & Bond, S. (1998). Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic Jensen, MC (1986). Agency costs of free cash flow, corporate finance, and takeovers.
panel data models. Journal of Econometrics, 87(1), 115–143. https://doi.org/ American Economic Review, 76(2), 323–329.
10.1016/S0304-4076(98)00009-8 Jensen, MC, & Meckling, WH (1976). Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency
Brav, A., Jiang, W., Ma, S., & Tian, X. (2018). How does hedge fund activism reshape costs and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 3(4), 305–360.
corporate innovation? Journal of Financial Economics, 130(2), 237–264. https://doi. https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-405X(76)90026-X
org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2018.06.012 Jenter, D., & Kanaan, F. (2015). CEO turnover and relative performance evaluation. The
Brav, A., Jiang, W., Partnoy, F., & Thomas, R. (2008). Hedge fund activism, corporate Journal of Finance, 70(5), 2155–2184. https://doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12282 Ju, N., Leland,
governance, and firm performance. The Journal of Finance, 63(4), 1729–1775. H., & Senbet, LW (2014). Options, option repricing in managerial compensation: Their
https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.2008.01373.x effects on corporate investment risk. Journal of Corporate Finance, 29, 628–643.
Burns, N., & Minnick, K. (2013). Does say-on-pay matter? Evidence from say-on-pay https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2013.11.003 Kalay, A., Karakas¸, O., & Pant, S. (2014).
proposals in the United States. Financial Review, 48(2), 233–258. https://doi.org/ The market value of corporate votes: Theory and evidence from option prices. The
10.1111/fire.12002 Journal of Finance, 69(3), 1235–1271. https:// doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12132
Bushee, BJ (1998). The influence of institutional investors on myopic R&D investment Kaplan, SN, & Zingales, L. (1997). Do investment–cash flow sensitivities provide useful
behavior. Accounting Review, 73(3), 305–333. https://doi.org/10.1504/ measures of financing constraints? Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(1),
IJAAPE.2008.020195 169–215. https://doi.org/10.1162/003355397555163
Campbell, TC, Gallmeyer, M., Johnson, SA, Rutherford, J., & Stanley, BW (2011). CEO Kim, EH, & Lu, Y. (2011). CEO ownership, external governance, and risk-taking.
optimism and forced turnover. Journal of Financial Economics, 101(3), 695–712. Journal of Financial Economics, 102(2), 272–292. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2011.03.004 jfineco.2011.07.002
Cella, C. (2020). Institutional investors and corporate investment. Finance Research Kim, JB, Wang, Z., & Zhang, L. (2016). CEO overconfidence and stock price crash risk.
Letters, 32, 1–6. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.frl.2019.04.026 Contemporary Accounting Research, 33(4), 1720–1749. https://doi.org/10.1111/
Chen, Q., Goldstein, I., & Jiang, W. (2007). Price informativeness and investment 1911-3846.12217
sensitivity to stock price. The Review of Financial Studies, 20(3), 619–650. Klein, A., & Zur, E. (2006). Hedge fund activism. ECGI Working Paper No. 140/2006.
https://doi. org/10.1093/rfs/hhl024 Brussels, Belgium: European Corporate Governance Institute. http://ssrn.com/abstra
Coles, JL, Daniel, ND, & Naveen, L. (2006). Managerial incentives and risk-taking. ct_id=913362.
Journal of Financial Economics, 79(2), 431–468. https://doi.org/10.1016/j. La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. (2000). Investor protection
jfineco.2004.09.004 and corporate governance. Journal of Financial Economics, 58(1), 3–27. https://doi.
Cornett, MM, Marcus, AJ, Saunders, A., & Tehranian, H. (2007). The impact of org/10.1016/S0304-405X(00)00065-9
institutional ownership on corporate operating performance. Journal of Banking & Lin, CY, Tsai, WC, Hasan, I., & Tuan, LQ (2018). Private benefits of control and bank
Finance, 31(6), 1771–1794. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2006.08.006 loan contracts. Journal of Corporate Finance, 49, 324–343. https://doi.org/
Cremers, KM, Nair, VB, & John, K. (2008). Takeovers and the cross-section of returns. 10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2018.01.006
Review of Financial Studies, 22(4), 1409–1445. https://doi.org/10.1093/rfs/hhn032 Luo, Y., & Jackson, DO (2012). CEO compensation, expropriation, and the balance of
Denes, MR, Karpoff, JM, & McWilliams, VB (2017). Thirty years of shareholder activism: power among large shareholders. Advances in Financial Economics, 15, 195–238.
A survey of empirical research. Journal of Corporate Finance, 44, 405–424. https://doi.org/10.1108/S1569-3732(2012)0000015010
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2016.03.005 Malmendier, U., & Tate, G. (2005). CEO overconfidence and corporate investment. The
Fama, EF, & MacBeth, JD (1973). Risk, rerurn, and equillibrium: Empircial tests. Journal of Finance, 60(6), 2661–2700. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-
Journal of Political Economy, 81(3), 607–636. https://doi.org/10.1086/260061 Fazzari, 6261.2005.00813.x
SM, Hubbard, RG, Petersen, BC, Blinder, AS, & Poterba, JM (1988). Financing Morck, R., Shleifer, A., Vishny, RW, Shapiro, M., & Poterba, JM (1990). The stock
constraints and corporate investment. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1988(1), market and investment: Is the market a sideshow? Brookings Papers on Economic
141–206. https://doi.org/10.2307/2534426 Activity, 1990(2), 157–215.
Francis, J., & Smith, A. (1995). Agency costs and innovation: Some empirical evidence. Myers, SC, & Majluf, NS (1984). Corporate financing and investment decisions when
Journal of Accounting and Economics, 19(2–3), 383–409. https://doi.org/10.1016/ firms have information that investors do not have. Journal of Financial Economics,
0165-4101(94)00389-M 13 (2), 187–221. https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-405X(84)90023-0
Franco, G., Hope, OK, Vyas, D., & Zhou, Y. (2015). Analyst report readability. Pawlina, G., & Renneboog, L. (2005). Is investment–cash flow sensitivity caused by
Contemporary Accounting Research, 32(1), 76–104. https://doi.org/10.1111/1911- agency costs or asymmetric information? Evidence from the UK. European Financial
3846.12062 Management, 11(4), 483–513. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1354-7798.2005.00294.x
Fu, F. (2010). Overinvestment and the operating performance of SEO firms. Financial Porter, ME (1992). Capital choices: Changing the way America invests in industry.
Management, 39(1), 249–272. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1755-053X.2010.01072.x García Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, 5(2), 4–16. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1745-
Lara, JM, García Osma, B., & Penalva, F. (2016). Accounting conservatism and firm 6622.1992.tb00485.x
investment efficiency. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 61(1), 221–238. Richardson, S. (2006). Over-investment of free cash flow. Review of Accounting Studies,
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jacceco.2015.07.003 11 (2–3), 159–189. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11142-006-9012-1
Ghosh, A., Moon, D., & Tandon, K. (2007). CEO ownership and discretionary Rogers, JL, & Stocken, PC (2005). Credibility of management forecasts. Accounting
investments. Journal of Business Finance & Accounting, 34(5–6), 819–839. Review, 80(4), 1233–1260. https://doi.org/10.2308/accr.2005.80.4.1233 Schnatterly, K.,
https://doi. org/10.1111/j.1468-5957.2007.02011.x Shaw, KW, & Jennings, WW (2008). Information advantages of large institutional owners.
Graves, SB (1988). Institutional ownership and corporate R&D in the computer Strategic Management Journal, 29(2), 219–227. https://doi.org/ 10.1002/smj.654
industry. Academy of Management Journal, 31(2), 417–428. https://doi.org/ Schrand, CM, & Zechman, SL (2012). Executive overconfidence and the slippery slope
10.2307/256557 to financial misreporting. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 53(1), 311–329.
Greenwood, R., & Schor, M. (2009). Investor activism and takeovers. Journal of Financial https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jacceco.2011.09.001
Economics, 92(3), 362–375. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2008.05.005 Hall, BJ, & Shleifer, A., & Vishny, RW (1986). Large shareholders and corporate control. The Journal
Murphy, KJ (2002). Stock options for undiversified executives. Journal of Accounting and of Political Economy, 94(3), 461–488. https://doi.org/10.1086/261385 Stiglitz, JE, &
Economics, 33(1), 3–42. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0165-4101(01) 00050-7 Weiss, A. (1981). Credit rationing in markets with imperfect information. The American
Hansen, GS, & Hill, CW (1991). Are institutional investors myopic? A time-series study Economic Review, 71(3), 393–410.
of four technology-driven industries. Strategic Management Journal, 12(1), 1–16. Stock, JH, & Yogo, M. (2005). Testing for weak instruments in linear IV regression. In
https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.4250120102 DWK Andrews, & JH Stock (Eds.), Identification and inference for econometric
Heaton, JB (2002). Managerial optimism and corporate finance. Financial Management, models: Essays in honor of Thomas J. Rothenberg (pp. 80–108). Cambridge, UK:
31(2), 33–45. https://doi.org/10.2307/3666221 Cambridge University Press.
Hirshleifer, D., Low, A., & Teoh, SH (2012). Are overconfident CEOs better innovators? Tribo, JA, Berrone, P., & Surroca, J. (2007). Do the type and number of blockholders
The Journal of Finance, 67(4), 1457–1498. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540- influence R&D investments? New evidence from Spain. Corporate Governance: An
6261.2012.01753.x International Review, 15(5), 828–842. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-
Hsieh, TS, Bedard, JC, & Johnstone, KM (2014). CEO overconfidence and earnings 8683.2007.00622.x
management during shifting regulatory regimes. Journal of Business Finance & Ullah, S., Akhtar, P., & Zaefarian, G. (2018). Dealing with endogeneity bias: The
Accounting, 41(9–10), 1243–1268. https://doi.org/10.1111/jbfa.12089 generalized method of moments (GMM) for panel data. Industrial Marketing
Hsu, C., Novoselov, KE, & Rencheng, W. (2017). Does accounting conservatism Management, 71, 69–78. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.indmarman.2017.11.010
mitigate the shortcomings of CEO overconfidence? Accounting Review, 92(6), Ullah, S., Zaefarian, G., & Ullah, F. (2020). How to use instrumental variables in
77–101. https://doi.org/10.2308/accr-51718 addressing endogeneity? A step-by-swep procedure for non-specialists. Industrial
Huang, W., Jiang, F., Liu, Z., & Zhang, M. (2011). Agency cost, top executives' Marketing Management. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.indmarman.2020.03.006

18

Anda mungkin juga menyukai